LECTURE 6: DYNAMIC INCONSISTENCY OF MONETARY POLICY, AND HOW TO ADDRESS IT Question: Why is inflation, π, often high? Why π > 0 more often than π < 0? One of several answers: Proclamations of low-inflation monetary policy by central banks are “dynamically inconsistent.” Next question: What institutions can address dynamic inconsistency? API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Inflation is usually > 0 and was a chronic problem during 1950-2000. Source: Carmen Reinhart & Ken Rogoff, This Time is Different: A Panoramic View of Eight Centuries of Financial Crises. If monetary expansion can’t reduce unemployment in the long run, why is inflation so common? Four possible explanations: Governments think expansion can reduce unemployment in the long run. They give low weight to price stability, or have high discount rates (e.g., political business cycle). Plans to set non-inflationary monetary policy are perceived by the public to be time-inconsistent. Governments want seignorage, to pay for spending that is not financed by taxes or borrowing. API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Dynamic inconsistency: The intuition • Assume governments, if operating under discretion, choose monetary policy and hence AD so as to maximize a social function of Y & π. – => Economy is at tangency of AS curve & one of the social function’s indifference curves. – Assume also that the social function centers on 𝑌 > 𝑌 , even though this point is unattainable, at least in the long run. • Assume W & P setters have rational expectations. – – => πe (& AS) shifts up if rationally-expected E π shifts up. => πe = E π = π on average. • economy is at point B on average. Inflationary bias: πe = E π > 0. • • Lesson: The authorities can’t raise Y anyway, so they might as well concentrate on price stability at point C. 3. But πe adjusts upward in response to observed π>0. The LR or Rational Expectations equilibrium must feature πe = π. Result: inflationary bias π>0, despite failure to raise Y above 𝑌 . 4. The country would be better off “tying the hands” of the central bank. Result: π=0. And yet Y = 𝑌 (no worse than average under discretion). 2. If πe would stay at 0, π πe then to get the higher Y it would be worth paying the price of π>0. ● ● ● 𝑌 API-120 Prof. J.Frankel • Yˆ 1. Barro-Gordon innovation: It is useful to think of society’s 1st choice as Y=𝑌 (& π=0), even if it is unattainable. Time-Inconsistency of Non-Inflationary Monetary Policy y y ( ) e (Romer 11.53) + Policy-maker minimizes quadratic loss function: (11.54) 1 ( y yˆ ) 2 2 1 a ( ) 2 2 where the target yˆ y. => 1 ( y ( ) yˆ ) e 2 2 1 2 API-120 Prof. J.Frankel a ( ) 2 Given discretion, the CB chooses the rate of money growth and inflation (assuming it can hit it) where d d ( y ( ) yˆ ) a ( ) 0 e Take the mathematical expectation: ( y E ( ) yˆ ) aE ( ) 0 . e + Rational expectations: (11.58) (10.15) E E e => ( yˆ y ) 0 , the inflationary bias. a API-120 Prof. J.Frankel . ADDRESSING THE TIME-INCONSISTENCY PROBLEM How can the CB credibly commit to a low-inflation monetary policy? Announcing a target π = 0 is time-inconsistent, because a CB with discretion will inflate ex post, and everyone knows this ex ante. CB can eliminate inflationary bias only by establishing non-inflationary credibility, which requires abandoning the option of discretion. so public will see the CB can’t inflate even if it wants to. CB “ties its hands,” as Odysseus did in the Greek myth. API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Addressing the Time-Inconsistency Problem (continued) Reputation Delegation. Rogoff (1985): Appoint a CB with high weight on low inflation a′ >> a , and grant it independence. It will expand at only a ( yˆ y ) << inflationary bias of discretion. Binding rules. Commit to rule for a nominal anchor: 1. Price of gold 3. Exchange rate 5. CPI 2. Money growth 4. Nominal GDP 6. GDP deflator API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Addressing the Time-Inconsistency Problem (continued) • Reputations. With multiple periods, a CB can act tougher in early periods, to build a reputation for monetary discipline. – Backus-Driffill (1985) model: people are uncertain if the CB is of hard-money or soft-money “type.” – Then even a soft CB may act tougher, to influence subsequent expectations. API-120 Prof. J.Frankel • Delegation Alesina & Summers: Central banks that are institutionally independent of their governments have lower inflation rates on average. API-120 Prof. J.Frankel for transition economies “Central Bank Independence, Inflation and Growth in Transition Economies,” P.Loungani & N.Sheets, IFDPS95-519 (1995) API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Limitations to the argument for central bank independence 1. Some consider it undemocratic. 2. The argument only works if the right central bankers are chosen. 3. Although independence measures are inversely correlated with inflation, these measures have been debated and, 4. more importantly, the choice to grant independence could be the result of priority on reducing inflation. 5. As with rules to address time-inconsistency, there is little empirical evidence that it succeeds in reducing inflation without loss of output. 6. As with rules, one loses ability to respond to SR shocks. API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Inflation Targeting (IT) Five advanced countries adopt IT: 199093 Many developing countries adopt IT: 19992008 Agénor & Pereira da Silva, 2013, Fig.1. "Rethinking Inflation Targeting: A Perspective from the Developing World," CGBCR DP 185, U.Manchester. . Countries adopting IT experienced lower inflation Gonçalves & Salles, 2008, “Inflation Targeting in Emerging Economies…” JDE API-120 Prof. J.Frankel by tying hands Introducing disturbances into the Barro-Gordon model à la Rogoff (1985) and Fischer (1987) AS shocks No effect on inflation bias. Average inflation = E ( yˆ y ) a Shocks will show up as fluctuations in actual & y. But discretionary monetary policy can’t offset AS shocks anyway (can only choose the split vs. y). => Strong case for committing to E=0. AD shocks Again no effect on inflation bias. Need not show up as fluctuations in actual & y : If lags in monetary policy < lags in adjustment of W & P, under discretion CB can offset AD shocks. => Choice of rules vs. discretion then becomes choice of eliminating LR inflation bias (E=0) vs. SR shocks. API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Appendix 1: GLOBAL INFLATION HAS DECLINED SINCE 1990. WHY? Better understanding of costs of inflation and the temporariness of the AS tradeoff ? Spread of commitment devices such as central bank independence, hard exchange rate pegs (currency boards & monetary unions), & IT? Rogoff (2003): Globalization & increased competition have reduced and/or ( yˆ y ) and thereby the inflationary bias ( yˆ y ) . a peak: early 80s API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Continued from previous peak: ≈ 1990 peak: early 90s API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Appendix 2: Targets & Instruments of Policymaking OBJECTIVES Inflation Growth & Unemployment Balance of payments INSTRUMENTS INTERMEDIATE TARGETS Overnight interest rate Open market operations Reserve requirements Foreign exchange intervention M1 Exchange rate Core CPI Nominal GDP INDICATORS Stock market, Commodity prices, Consumer confidence, PMI … Appendix 3: Comparison of alternate rules (M1 vs. E vs. CPI …) The choice of anchor depends on: 1. Credibility of the commitment 2. Tradeoff: advantage of time-consistent commitment vs. ability to stabilize short-term shocks Must compare E(Loss) function for M vs. GDP vs. ex.rate vs. P targets) Original treatment due to Rogoff (1985) 3. Other objectives served (e.g., a peg cuts exchange rate risk) API-120 Prof. J.Frankel 6 proposed nominal targets and the Achilles heel of each: Monetarist rule Inflation targeting Nominal GDP targeting Gold standard Commodity standard Fixed exchange rate Targeted variable Vulnerability Example M1 Velocity shocks US 1982 CPI Supply/import price shocks Oil shocks of 1974, 1980, 2008 Nominal GDP Measurement problems Vagaries of Price world gold of gold market Price of agr. Shocks in & mineral imported basket commodity $ Appreciation of $ (or euro) (or other) API-120 Prof. J.Frankel Less developed countries 1849 boom; 1873-96 bust Oil shocks of 1974, 1980, 2008 1995-2001