Fin500J: Mathematical Foundations in Finance Topic 4: Unconstrained and Constrained Optimization Philip H. Dybvig Reference: Mathematics for Economists, Carl Simon and Lawrence Blume, Chapter 17, 18, 19 Slides designed by Yajun Wang Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 1 Outline Unconstrained Optimization Functions of One Variable o General Ideas of Optimization o First and Second Order Conditions o Local v.s. Global Extremum Functions of Several Variables o First and Second Order Conditions o Local v.s. Global Extremum Constrained Optimization Kuhn-Tucker Conditions Sensitivity Analysis Second Order Conditions Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 2 Unconstrained Optimization An unconstrained optimization problem is one where you only have to be concerned with the objective function you are trying to optimize. An objective function is a function that you are trying to optimize. None of the variables in the objective function are constrained. Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 3 General Ideas of Optimization There are two ways of examining optimization. Maximization (example: maximize profit) In this case you are looking for the highest point on the function. Minimization (example: minimize cost) In this case you are looking for the lowest point on the function. Maximization f(x) is equivalent to minimization –f(x) Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 4 Graphical Representation of a Maximum y 16 y = f(x) = -x2 + 8x 4 Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 8 x 5 Questions Regarding the Maximum What is the sign of f '(x) when x < x*? Note: x* denotes the point where the function is at a maximum. What is the sign of f '(x) when x > x*? What is f '(x) when x = x*? Definition: A point x* on a function is said to be a critical point if f ' (x*) = 0. This is the first order condition for x* to be a maximum/minimum. Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 6 Second Order Conditions If x* is a critical point of function f(x), can we decide whether it is a max, a min or neither? Yes! Examine the second derivative of f(x) at x*, f ' '(x*); x* is a maximum of f(x) if f ' '(x*) < 0; x* is a minimum of f(x) if f ' '(x*) > 0; x* can be a maximum, a minimum or neither if f ' '(x*) = 0; Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 7 An Example of f''(x*)=0 Suppose y = f(x) = x3, then f '(x) = 3x2 and f ''(x) =6x, This implies that x* = 0 and f ''(x*=0) = 0. y=f(x)=x3 y x x*=0 is a saddle point where the point is neither a maximum nor a minimum Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 8 Example of Using First and Second Order Conditions Suppose you have the following function: f(x) = x3 – 6x2 + 9x Then the first order condition to find the critical points is: f’(x) = 3x2 - 12x + 9 = 0 This implies that the critical points are at x = 1 and x = 3. 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 Fin500J Topic 4 -8 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 2.5 3 3.5 4 9 Example of Using First and Second Order Conditions (Cont.) The next step is to determine whether the critical points are maximums or minimums. These can be found by using the second order condition. f ' '(x) = 6x – 12 = 6(x-2) Testing x = 1 implies: f ' '(1) = 6(1-2) = -6 < 0. Hence at x =1, we have a maximum. Testing x = 3 implies: f ' '(3) = 6(3-2) = 6 > 0. Hence at x =3, we have a minimum. Are these the ultimate maximum and minimum of the function f(x)? Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 10 Local Vs. Global Maxima/Minima A local maximum is a point that f(x*) ≥ f(x) for all x in some open interval containing x* and a local minimum is a point that f(x*) ≤ f(x) for all x in some open interval containing x*; A global maximum is a point that f(x*) ≥ f(x) for all x in the domain of f and a global minimum is a point that f(x*) ≤ f(x) for all x in the domain of f. For the previous example, f(x) as x and f(x) - as x -. Neither critical point is a global max or min of f(x). Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 11 Local Vs. Global Maxima/Minima (Cont.) When f ''(x)≥0 for all x, i.e., f(x) is a convex function, then the local minimum x* is the global minimum of f(x) When f ''(x)≤0 for all x, i.e., f(x) is a concave function, then the local maximum x* is the global maximum of f(x) Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 12 Conditions for a Minimum or a Maximum Value of a Function of Several Variables Correspondingly, for a function f(x) of several independent variables x Calculate f x and set it to zero. Solve the equation set to get a solution vector x*. Calculate 2 f x . Evaluate it at x*. Inspect the Hessian matrix at point x*. Hx 2 f x Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 13 Hessian Matrix of f(x) f x is a C 2 functionof n variables, 2 f x 2 x1 Hx 2 f x 2 f x xn x1 2 f x x1xn . 2 f x 2 xn Since cross- partialsare equal for a C 2 function,H(x) is a symmetricmatrix. Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 14 Conditions for a Minimum or a Maximum Value of a Function of Several Variables (cont.) Let f(x) be a C2 function in Rn. Suppose that x* is a critical point of f(x), i.e., f x * 0. 1. If the Hessian Hx * is a positive definite matrix, then x* is a local minimum of f(x); If the Hessian Hx * is a negative definite matrix, then x* is a local maximum of f(x). If the Hessian Hx * is an indefinite matrix, then x* is neither a local maximum nor a local minimum of f(x). 2. 3. Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 15 Example Find the local maxs and mins of f(x,y) f ( x, y) x y 9 xy 3 3 Firstly, computing the first order partial derivatives (i.e., gradient of f(x,y)) and setting them to zero f 2 3 x 9y x 0 f ( x, y ) f 3 y 2 9 x y criticalpointsx*, y * is (0,0)and ( 3, -3 ). Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 16 Example (Cont.) We now compute the Hessian of f(x,y) 2 f 2 f 2 xy 6 x 9 x 2 f ( x, y ) 2 9 6 y . 2 f f yx y 2 The first order leading principal minor is 6x and the second order principal minor is -36xy-81. At (0,0), these two minors are 0 and -81, respectively. Since the second order leading principal minor is negative, (0,0) is a saddle of f(x,y), i.e., neither a max nor a min. At (3, -3), these two minors are 18 and 243. So, the Hessian is positive definite and (3,-3) is a local min of f(x,y). Is (3, -3) a global min? Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 17 Global Maxima and Minima of a Function of Several Variables Let f(x) be a C2 function in Rn, then When f(x) is a concave function, i.e., 2 f x is negative semidefinite for all x and f x * 0 , then x* is a global max of f(x); When f(x) is a convex function, i.e., 2 f x is positive semidefinite for all x and f x * 0 , then x* is a global min of f(x); Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 18 Example (Discriminating Monopolist) A monopolist producing a single output has two types of customers. If it produces q1 units for type 1, then these customers are willing to pay a price of 50-5q1 per unit. If it produces q2 units for type 2, then these customers are willing to pay a price of 100-10q2 per unit. The monopolist’s cost of manufacturing q units of output is 90+20q. In order to maximize profits, how much should the monopolist produce for each market? Profit is: f (q1 , q2 ) q1 (50 5q1 ) q2 (100 10q2 ) (90 20(q1 q2 )). T hecriticalpointsare f f 50 10q1 20 0 q1 3, 100 20q2 20 0 q2 4. q1 q 2 2 f 2 f 2 f 2 f 10, 20, 0. 2 2 q1 q2 q1q2 q2 q1 2 f is negativedefinite (3,4)is theprofit- maximizingsupply plan. Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 19 Constrained Optimization Examples: Individuals maximizing utility will be subject to a budget constraint Firms maximising output will be subject to a cost constraint The function we want to maximize/minimize is called the objective function The restriction is called the constraint Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 20 Constrained Optimization (General Form) A general mixed constrained multi-dimensional maximization problem is max f (x ) f (x 1 ,..., x n ) subject to g1 (x 1 ,..., x n ) b1 , g 2 (x 1 ,..., x n ) b2 , , g k (x 1 ,..., x n ) bk , h1 (x 1 ,..., x n ) c 1 , h2 (x 1 ,..., x n ) c 2 , , hm (x 1 ,..., x n ) c m . Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 21 Constrained Optimization (Lagrangian Form) The Lagrangian approach is to associate a Lagrange multiplier i with the i th inequality constraint and μi with the i th equality constraint. We then form the Lagrangian L (x 1 ,..., x n , 1 ,..., k , 1 ,..., m ) k f (x 1 ,..., x n ) i g i (x 1 ,..., x n ) bi i 1 m i hi (x 1 ,..., x n ) c i . i 1 Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 22 Constrained Optimization (Kuhn-Tucker Conditions) If x * is a local maximum of f on the constraint set defined by the k inequalities and m equalities, then, there exists multipliers * , , * , * , , * satisfying k 1 1 m L( x* , * , * ) f ( x* ) k * gi ( x* ) m * hi ( x* ) i i 0, j 1, x j x j x j x j i 1 i 1 hi ( x* ) ci , i 1, ,n ,m i* gi ( x* ) bi 0, i 1, , k gi ( x* ) bi , i 1, ,k i* 0, i 1, , k Fin500J Topic Topic44 Fall 2010 2008 Olin Business School 23 Constrained Optimization (Kuhn-Tucker Conditions) The first set of KT conditions generalizes the unconstrained critical point condition The second set of KT conditions says that x needs to satisfy the equality constraints The third set of KT conditions is i* gi ( x* ) bi 0, i 1, ,k That is to say if i* 0 then gi (x * ) bi if gi (x * ) bi then i* 0 Fin500J Topic Topic44 Fall 2010 2008 Olin Business School 24 Constrained Optimization (Kuhn-Tucker Conditions) This can be interpreted as follows: Additional units of the resource bi only have value if the available units are used fully in the optimal solution, i.e., if gi (x * ) bi the constraint is not binding thus it does not make difference in the optimal solution and i*=0. Finally, note that increasing bi enlarges the feasible region, and therefore increases the objective value Therefore, i0 for all i Fin500J Topic Topic44 Fall 2010 2008 Olin Business School 25 Example max x y 2 subject to x y 4 x 0, y 0. 2 2 Form the Lagrangian L=x-y 2 (x 2 y 2 4) 1 x 2 y . The first order conditions become: L 1 2 x 1 0, x L (2) 2y 2 y 2 0, y (1) (3)x 2 y 2 4 0 Fin500J Topic Topic44 (4)1 x 0, (5)2 y 0, (6)1 0, (7)2 0, (8)x 0, (8)y 0. Fall 2010 2008 Olin Business School 26 Example (cont.) By (1), 1 1 2 x , since 1 0, 1 1 0 0 and x 0, by (4), 1 0. by (2), 2 2y (1 ), since 1 0 either both y and 2 are zero, or both are positive, from (5) y 0, 2 0. By (3) and (8) x=2, from (4), 1 0, 1 1 by (1), . So, (x , y , , 1 , 2 ) (2, 0, , 0, 0). 4 4 Fin500J Topic Topic44 Fall 2010 2008 Olin Business School 27 Sensitivity Analysis We notice that L(x *, *, *) f (x *) * g (x *) b * '(h (x *) c ) f (x *) What happens to the optimal solution value if the right-hand side of constraint i is changed by a small amount, say bi , i=1…k. or ci , i=1….m. It changes by approximately * b or i* c i i i i *is the shadow price of ith inequality constraint and i* is the shadow price of ith equality constraint Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 28 Sensitivity Analysis (Example) • In the previous example, if we change the first constraint to x2+y2=3.9, then we predict that the new optimal value would be 2+1/4(-0.1)=1.975. • If we compute that problem with this new constraint, then x-y2= 3.9 1.9748. • If, instead, we change the second constraint from x≥0 to x≥0.1, we do not change the solution or the optimum value since 1* 0. Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 29 Utility Maximization Example T heutilityderivedfromexercise(X) and watchingmovies(M) is described by thefunction U X,M 100 e 2 X e M Four hours per day are available to watch moviesand exercise. Our Lagrangianfunctionis L(X,M,λ) 100 e 2 X e M X M 4 First - Order Conditions: LX 2e 2 X λ 0 LM e M λ 0 Lλ X M 4 0 Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 30 Utility Max Example Continued First - Order Conditions: LX 2e 2 X λ 0, (1) LM e M λ 0, (2) Lλ X M 4 0 (3) From (2) we get thatλ e -M . Subst it uting into(1), we get 2e - 2 X e M 0 Solving (3) for M and substituting, we get 2e-2X e ( 4 X ) 0 ln(2)- 2X -4 X or 3X ln(2) 4 ln(2) 4 8 ln(2) X* and M * 3 3 Fin500J Topic 4 Fall 2010 Olin Business School 31