THE DOMINANT ROLE OF SAUDI ARABIA IN THE OIL MARKET 1997-2010 Nourah AlYousef Associate Professor of Economics. King Saud University. alyousefn@yahoo.com 1 Saudi Arabia and the oil market Saudi Arabia played an effective part for the period 1974-1985, where it had the title role in the Swing Producer Model. In 1985, Saudi Arabia abandoned that role. Since 1987, Saudi Arabia maintained its share in the oil market. However, with a decline in prices in 1998, a decline in OPEC’s spare capacity and with low growth in nonOPEC supply, Saudi Arabia gained more power in the oil market. 2 Objective of the paper Test the role of Saudi Arabia in the oil market by considering the swing producer model for the period 1997-2010. 3 Why Since the mid-nineties as an official policy, Saudi Arabia maintained, excess capacity of 1.5-2 MB/D. In 2010, oil production capacity was estimated at over 12 MB/D. Saudi Arabia’s average production in 2010, 8.2 MB/D. Saudi Arabia can increase production during demand surge and market interruption. Saudi Arabia can decrease production during low oil prices. Objective: to moderate oil prices. 4 Importance of Saudi Arabia Has the highest world proven oil reserves, 262.5 billion barrels. Constitutes 12% of world oil production. Is a key crude oil supplier to the United States (14%), Europe (4%) and Asia (57%) in 2009. Has two primary oil export terminals, in the Gulf and in the Red Sea. Exports five crude qualities ranging from the 450 API Arab Super Light (ASL) to the 23.70 API Arab Heavy (AH) 5 Review of literature Griffin and Teece (1982) Adelman (1982) Dahl and Yucel (1991) Griffin and Neilson (1994), Alhajji and Huettner (2000) Smith (2005) emphasize on the dominant role of Saudi Arabia in OPEC. Doran (1977) Moran (1982) Askari (1991) Stevens (1991,1995) , Khadduri (1996) political objective behind Saudi Arabia’s policy. De Santis, and Roberto (2003) claim profits and welfare are incentives. 6 Figure 1: OPEC production ceiling and oil price $/B 160 32000 140 30000 120 Price OPEC production Ceiling 28000 80 26000 MB/D $/B 100 60 24000 40 22000 20 0 Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul97 97 98 98 99 99 00 00 01 01 02 02 03 03 04 04 05 05 06 06 07 07 08 08 09 09 10 10 20000 7 OPEC decisions on production 19972010 With prices close to $20/b, in December 1997, OPEC increased its quota by 2.5 MB/D (10%) to 27.5. Decline in demand resulting from the Asian crisis caused the price to fail; it reached $10/b in Dec. 1998 In response, OPEC cut quotas 3 times (In April 99, total reduction was 3 MB/D). Prices increased to $25/B. Growing world economics: between April and October, 2000, there were three successive OPEC quota increases totaling 3.2 MB/D. In 2001, a weakened US economy, prices declined OPEC carried out several reductions, cutting 3.5 MB/d by September 1, 2001. Prices reached $15/B in in Jan 2002, OPEC cut production joined by Russia. Prices reached 26 in Dec 2003. In 2003, With an improving economy, US demand was increasing and Asian demand for crude oil was growing at a rapid pace (China and India). Advanced economies proved more resilient to rising oil prices than previously believed. 2004 and 2005, the spare capacity to produce oil was under 1 MB/dD. On April to June 2004, OPEC (excluding Iraq) announced an agreement to reduce actual production by 1 MB/d by January 1 Oil prices peaked in July 2008 at over. $145/barrel for WTI. However, the prices declined, because of the financial crisis of 2008/2009. OPEC agreed to cut production by 4.2 MB/D after a dramatic decline in oil prices to below $40. In 2009 and 2010, OPEC left its production target unchanged. Prices reached an average of $63/barrel in 2009, and increased in 2010 to reach an average. $80/barrel. 8 n97 Ju l-9 Ja 7 n98 Ju l-9 Ja 8 n99 Ju l-9 Ja 9 n00 Ju l-0 Ja 0 n01 Ju l-0 Ja 1 n02 Ju l-0 Ja 2 n03 Ju l-0 Ja 3 n04 Ju l-0 Ja 4 n05 Ju l-0 Ja 5 n06 Ju l-0 Ja 6 n07 Ju l-0 Ja 7 n08 Ju l-0 Ja 8 n09 Ju l-0 Ja 9 n10 Ju l-1 0 Ja thousan barrel per day Figure 2: Other OPEC and Saudi Arabia Quotas and actual production (1997 – 2010). 35,000.00 KSA Production OPEC Production KSA Quota OPEC Ceiling 30,000.00 25,000.00 20,000.00 15,000.00 10,000.00 5,000.00 0.00 9 Figure 3: Saudi Oil Production and the Market Price (1997.1 – 2010.12) 160 10,000.00 Price 140 production 9,500.00 120 9,000.00 100 8,500.00 80 8,000.00 60 7,500.00 40 7,000.00 20 6,500.00 0 Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul- Jan- Jul97 97 98 98 99 99 00 00 01 01 02 02 03 03 04 04 05 05 06 06 07 07 08 08 09 09 10 10 6,000.00 10 The Swing Producer Model Price control means setting an effective transaction price preventing market forces from changing it. However, high prices will induce competitors to enter the market. A dominant supplier thus has a choice; it can achieve short run profits by raising price at the expense of losing its dominance in the future, or it can charge a moderate price that supports its market share and generates high competitive profits over time. When engaged in the latter strategy, the dominant supplier will try to lead the market by signaling what price it strives to maintain as the target price (PT). 11 Target Price Since 1987, OPEC set a reference price, which is the OPEC Reference Basket, used as a guideline for determining the ceiling of OPEC production. In 1987, the price was $18 per barrel; In the 1990s, a minimum reference price of $21/b is used. In June 2000, members of OPEC established a mechanism to adjust the supply of oil by 500,000 B/D if the 20-day average price of oil moved outside a $22 to $28 price band. From June 2003 until Nov. 07, no target price was determined but an implicit price resulted from the OPEC decision. Nov. ‘03 – Mar. ‘04 it was $30. Apr. ‘04 to Mar. ’05, it was $35 Apr. ‘05 – Oct. ’06, it was $50. Between Nov. ‘06 and Nov. ’07, it was $70. At the end of 2007 it was announced that the target price of OPEC was $75 12 PT PM 1 The Model Saudi Arabia manipulated its production in order to minimize the difference between the target price PT and the market price PM. However, it was not concerned about the absolute value; it was concerned about the proportionate difference. Thus, the objective function is (PT/PM) keeping the difference between both prices equal to zero If the demand were high for OPEC oil (PT/PM)<1, Saudi Arabia would increase its output If demand were low for OPEC oil, Saudi Arabia would decrease its output (PT/PM)>1 13 Model Using the notation PTM=(PT/PM) َQSA=f(PTM) Saudi Arabia is a member of OPEC, so its production is also a proportion of total OPEC production QSA=f(Qoo,PTM) 14 Data Source: OPEC secretariat Monthly Data from 1997.1 – 2010.12, n=168 Production Data from six sources (Petroleum Argus, Reuters, Petroleum Intelligence Weekly (PIW), Platt’s Oilgram Price Report, International energy Agency (IEA), Middle East Economic Survey (MEES), Petrostrategies, taking a simple average of the estimation of those sources of OPEC members’ actual production. We will rely on this data for that period as reported by OPEC secretariat. 15 Price Data The Market Price: the OPEC Reference Basket The Target Price: determined by OPEC Source: OPEC secretariat 16 Method of analysis Using the autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) cointegration procedure introduced by Pesaran et al. (2001), we test for the null of no cointegration against the existence of a long-run relationship Estimate the error correction representation of the ARDL model 17 2QtSA0 12.44 0.34 ln QtOO 0.46 ln P TM ut ln t value 2.49[0.013] 0.68[0.495] 2.51[0.013] Result Long-run relationship lnQsa=12.44-0.34lnQoo-0.46lnPTM+e t-value -0.68[0.495] -2.5[0.013] For a swing producer role β3≠ 0, which means the difference between the Saudi price and the market price has an influence on the Saudi output decision When the ratio between (PT, PM) decreases, Saudi Arabia would increase its production to lower PM. When the ratio increases (PT.PM), Saudi Arabia would decrease its production to increase PM ß<0 that is Saudi Arabia has a negative relationship with the production of other members of OPEC, which shows we have cartel behavior with Saudi Arabia acting as the swing producer However, it is not significant 18 Error correction representation for the selected ARDL coefficient-value intercept ΔQsat-1 ΔQoot ΔQoot-1 ΔPTMt ΔPTMt-1 ΔPt2ECMt-1 0.000560. 0.367 0.096 -0.068 -0.031 -0.018 -0.023 -0.030 t-value .49[.961] 5.26[000] 1.79[.075] 1.273[.205] -2.796[.005] -1.371[.172] -2.033[.044] -2.401[.017] 19 Error Correction Model ECMt-1 The speed of adjustment itself, which is 3%, indicates a low rate of convergence to equilibrium. The larger the error correction coefficient, the faster the economy returns to its equilibrium, once shocked. Short-run elasticity 0.07 and 0.03 20 Elasticities for the model (1997–2010) comparison with swing producer for Saudi Arabia (1976–1985) Long-Run Elasticity OPEC Others PTM -0.34 -1.44 -0.46 -0.87 21 Conclusion Saudi Arabia has a significant role in the oil market. It changes its production in order to stabilize the price of oil, we can say the Swing Producer Model is partially applicable to Saudi Arabia because the kingdom changed its production in order to keep oil prices stable 22 Thank You 23