The Tax-Transfer System and Labor Supply Michael P. Keane University of Oxford Becker – Friedman Institute University of Chicago September 27, 2013 Why Labor Supply Matters for Design of the Tax System • “Optimal Taxation” – Basic Tradeoff: • (1) Government needs to raise a certain amount of money to pay for public goods. • (2) Taxation causes people to work less. This leads to an efficiency or welfare loss. (The economic “pie” gets smaller). Why Labor Supply Matters for Design of the Tax System • How bad is this “Shrinking Pie” problem? • It depends how much people reduce their labor supply if you tax them (How big is the labor supply elasticity?). • Basic Solution of “Optimal Tax” theory: Tax people more if their labor supply is more “inelastic” (i.e., less responsive to taxes) The Labor Supply Literature • Until recently there was a clear consensus that labor supply elasticities are small: • Saez, Slemrod and Giertz (JEL, 2012): “…the profession has settled on a value for this elasticity close to zero … This implies that the efficiency cost of taxing labor income … is bound to be low …” The Labor Supply Literature • I will argue that most existing estimates of labor supply elasticities are biased downward • This is because they ignore the fact that work experience builds human capital • See Imai and Keane (IER, 2004), Keane (JEL, 2011), Keane-Rogerson (JEL, 2012) • Recently this idea has started to gain traction Why are Labor Supply Elasticity Estimates Usually Small? • Hours vs. Wages over the Life-Cycle (Men): Wage Hours, Wages Hours Age • Given this pattern, the elasticity looks very small The Problem with Most Prior Work: Assumes Wage = Price of Time • But the after-tax wage is not the price of time • If you work more hours (today) you get both: 1.The after-tax wage rate (today) 2.The increase in future earnings due to the human capital gained from work experience • “Effective Wage” = After-Tax Wage + Human Capital Gained by Working • See Heckman (1976), Shaw (1989) The Effective Wage Rate • Effective Wage over the life-cycle: Effective wage = Wage + HC return Wage Wage HC return Age • It is much flatter than the measured wage Labor Supply and the Effective Wage • Hours vs. Effective Wage over the Life-Cycle Wage, Hours Effective Wage Hours Age • Hours look very responsive to effective wage Human Capital and Long Run Tax Effects • If work experience builds human capital it implies effect of taxes on labor supply will grow over time • I’ll illustrate this by simulating a permanent 5 percent tax rate increase in the model of Imai and Keane (IER, 2004) • Three Cases: The increase occurs when a person is 25, 30 or 35 Effects of Permanent Tax Increases on Labor Supply At Different Ages in a Model with Human Capital (Imai-Keane Model) Age 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 Age 25 Hours -2.7 -2.9 -3.2 -3.8 -5.1 -7.9 -13.3 -19.3 -29.2 Wage Age 30 (unexpected) Hours Wage Age 35 (unexpected) Hours Wage -0.4 -0.7 -1.0 -1.3 -2.0 -3.6 -7.5 -11.6 -2.4 -2.7 -3.3 -4.4 -7.0 -12.2 -18.4 -28.1 -2.3 -2.7 -3.8 -6.2 -11.0 -17.4 -26.9 -0.3 -0.6 -0.9 -1.4 -2.9 -6.6 -10.7 -0.2 -0.5 -1.0 -2.3 -5.8 -9.7 Note: The tax increase is 5%. It takes effect (unexpectedly) at the indicated age and lasts until age 65. The proceeds of the tax (in each year) are distributed back to agents in lump sum form. Effect of Permanent Tax Changes • Note: The effect of a tax increase grows over time • It slows down the rate of human capital accumulation, creating a “snowball” effect on after-tax wages • Seeing a small short-run effect may trick us into thinking elasticities are small Labor Supply Summary • What economists call the “welfare cost” of income taxation (how much it shrinks the pie) is likely to be much higher than previously thought, because: • Economists have largely ignored how taxes alter incentives to acquire human capital • Ignoring human capital has led economists to underestimate how much taxes can reduce labor supply Some Comments on Transfers • A Typical Welfare or Transfer Program Income Earnings Indifference Curve: Income vs. Hours Welfare Grant level Leisure Full-Time Work No Work Some Comments on Transfers • Lower Phase-Out Rates Don’t Work: Income Earnings Indifference Curve: Income vs. Hours Welfare Grant level Leisure Full-Time Work No Work • Making people appear insensitive to taxes Some Comments on Transfers • BUT, a modest increase in the after-tax wage can cause a big jump in hours: Income Earnings Indifference Curve: Income vs. Hours Welfare Grant level Leisure Full-Time Work No Work • Suddenly labor supply looks very elastic! Some Comments on Transfers • Lesson: The “labor supply elasticity” is not an absolute number • It can be large or small depending on the nature of the tax and/or transfer change • Keane and Rogerson (JEL, 2012) give a number of illustrations of this point in different contexts Smarter Transfers A Bonus for Work (including subsidies of fixed costs) Income Earnings New Higher Indifference Curve: Income vs. Hours Welfare Grant level Leisure Full-Time Work No Work Government Saves Money and the Person is Happier !! Smarter Transfers • This idea for welfare reform was proposed in: Keane (1995). “A New Idea for Welfare Reform.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 19:2, 2-28. • Also discussed in: Keane and Moffitt (1998). “A Structural Model of Multiple Welfare Program Participation and Labor Supply.” International Economic Review, 39:3, 553-589. • The “working families tax credit” in the UK has a similar design, with a 16 hour work requirement A Subsidy for Working = Subsidizing Costs of Work • This is sometimes called “making work pay” – i.e., subsidize work instead of paying people not to work • A big part of the cost of work is quality child care/pre-school, especially for lone mothers. • Work cost subsidies play a dual role as early childhood education and human capital policy Conclusion In general, we should think more about how the tax/transfer system interacts with human capital development