Incremental Value and FRAND Licensing ANNE LAYNE-FARRAR VICE PRESIDENT COMPASS LEXECON 3 RD C O N F E R E N C E O N R E C E N T D E V E L O P M E N T S I N COMPETITION ENFORCEMENT, ROME 6 MAY 2011 Defining FRAND Licensing What FRAND means for patent licensing in standard setting still being debated No consensus yet, aside from minimum requirement of preventing a refusal to license or exclusive licensing A number of cases settled/ended before FRAND defined or precedent established Rambus cases – US FTC, EC Qualcomm cases – EC, US private lawsuits A Court Precedent May still be set… A number of cases involve FRAND KFTC on brink of Rambus investigation IPCom – HTC, Nokia lawsuits in Germany, US Nokia – Apple ITC litigation Today’s Popular Proposal: Incremental Value A number of theories/definitions suggested Patent-count “proportionality” approaches broadly rejected Ex ante/ex post test: good for ex post analysis, provides competition safe harbour (See Mariniello, forthcoming) Only applies when ex ante licenses exist The incremental value rule offered to fill the gap Suggests that FRAND limits patent holders to charging the incremental value of their patented technology, over the next closest alternative How to Define “Incremental Value” One view: Dolmans Value of innovation of technology A = price of next best alternative B + opportunity cost of “not using A” Where “next best alternative” is likely priced at zero: “Indeed, in a competitive and non-collusive environment, royalties for equivalent and competitive technical solutions would tend towards marginal costs, which is often close to zero in the case of IT.” Dolmans et al. (2007) How to Define “Incremental Value” (2) Another view: Lemley & Shapiro (2007): Bargaining power × Incremental value of patent × Probability that patent is valid (B ×V × θ) B and θ are both fractions, less than or equal to one V × θ is “is neither feasible nor desirable” when a standard involves complements because V will include spillovers (sum is greater than its parts) Important Assumptions Behind Both Views Dolmans approach (V ≈ 0) assumes stiff competition during standardization SSOs faced with plethora of existing, viable alternatives, so none is very valuable until a standard is based upon it This will apply only to certain circumstances, not clear that it will be where most disputes arise Lemley-Shapiro approach (B × V × θ) assumes particular definition of “ex ante” First round, fundamental technology is already discovered, only complementary innovation remains Protect licensees and follow-on inventors, but ignore incentives to invest in pioneering R&D Balancing Licensors and Licensees B*V*θ Appropriation of manufacturer value by patent holder v Appropriation of patent holder value by manufacturer V can be defined as specific to a patent When “Ex Ante” is Set Matters Most often, “ex ante” refers to “before the standard is voted on, published, or implemented” Meant to avoid lock in of implementers But a more complete view would be “before the technologies important for a standard have been developed” Innovators need incentives to invest in R&D and to contribute that R&D to a standard SSO participation is voluntary A Third View of Incremental Value Layne-Farrar, Llobet, and Padilla (2011) Fully ex ante view, before either party has made irreversible investments Key question is SSO participation Conditional on innovators joining SSO, the incremental value rule (V weighted by probability of successful standard) creates incentives for optimal R&D expenditure But, when we drop the assumption that all parties will join, we find that the incremental rule would lower R&D investments among innovators lower SSO participation rates among patent holders lower aggregate earnings for SSO members as a whole How to reconcile the different views? The time horizon matters: L&S notion of standard value spillovers consistent with our finding that innovators need something more than V to ensure participation, when longer time is allowed Sharing spillover rents between licensors and licensees is both fair and reasonable Allows incentives for both pioneering and complementary/followon R&D investments Incremental value is fact-specific If Dolman’s notion of value fits the facts, then V would be quite low No need restrict it further, but would need evidence first Concluding Remarks Incremental value has promise, but competition authorities should proceed carefully Rules depend critically on the assumptions and definitions Standards typically involve long term efforts, with multiple iterations Incentives to join an SSO, to continue investing in R&D, and to contribute to standard setting efforts are important There is no universal incremental value “cap” V will depend on the technologies involved and circumstances at hand