Core Values, Sustainability, and the Privatization of Water Joseph W. Dellapenna Professor of Law, Villanova University www.dellapen@law.villanova.edu Rapporteur, Berlin Rules on Water Resources Director, Model Water Code Project, American Society of Civil Engineers © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Water Law at all Levels Is under Stress Growing demand shaped by Burgeoning populations Changing patterns of use Efficiency promoted by rising costs Local, national, and regional management systems, and their governing laws, are already under stress Global climate disruption is adding further stress © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Water Stressed Regions © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Changing Population Density around Lake Victoria © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Getting from Potential Conflict to Potential Cooperation Disagreements and disputes are inevitable What mechanisms might be used to resolve these problems? Violence Ethics Markets Law What techniques do we use in ordinary civil society to preclude resort to violence? © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna A Discussion about Water Rights (from duckboy.com) © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Public Goods Basic characteristics Indivisible (“non-excludable”) Shared freely among a relevant population (“open access”) Consequences of treating something as a public good Funding is difficult Markets fail The “tragedy of the commons” is a risk © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna The Hydrologic Cycle © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Raw Water as the Paradigm Public Good Transaction costs are too high for markets “Equity” precludes excluding people (and others) who cannot afford to buy water Common metaphors—used even by market fundamentalists—recognize that water is the paradigm public good “Common pool resource” “Spill over effect” © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Can Ethical Appeals Prevent the Tragedy of the Commons? What happens if some heed ethical appeals to behave responsibly? Consider the Canadian lobster (or the North Atlantic cod, or any of many other examples) What about “commons” that have functioned successfully for centuries? Ethical appeals can mobilize political will, but that will must be expressed in law to be effective That water is to some extent an economic good suggests that a sound system of ethics would incorporate economic incentives (not necessarily markets as such) as management tools © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Ethics Applied to Water Three possible systems of property rights for water resources: Common property Private property Public (or collective) property Is one ethically superior? Common property systems They lead to the “tragedy of the commons” We see many overexploited water sources as a result Private property systems They also can lead to the “tragedy of the commons” Prioritized systems can freeze patterns of use because of problems with markets Public (or collective) property systems They create at least a possibility of avoiding these problems They carry all the risks inherent in bureaucratic management © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Basic Premises of Sound Water Law Sound water law must reflect the basic characteristics of water as a resource: Water is a public good Water moves Water must be conjunctively managed Water management must be integrated with the management of related resources Water is subject to economic incentives Reflected (more or less) in most traditional bodies of water law: Water generally subjected only to “usufructuary” rights Derived from Roman law concepts: Usus Fructus but not Abusus © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Is Sustainability a Legal Requirement? The “cowboy economy” vs. “spaceship earth” (Kenneth Boulding 1966) The Stockholm Declaration (1972) Principle 5: The non-renewable resources of the earth must be employed in such a way as to guard against the danger of their future exhaustion and to ensure that benefits from such employment are shared by all mankind. Pervades other principles Now found in numerous “hard law” international instruments—even in the Preamble to the World Trade Organization Agreement (1994) Embraced by the International Court of Justice in The Gabçíkovo-Nagymoros Case (Hungary/Slovakia) (1997), as well as some national courts Is this just a procedural mandate? © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Applying Sustainability to Water Definition (from the Berlin Rules, art. 2(19): [T]he integrated management of resources to ensure efficient use of and equitable access to waters for the benefit of current and future generations while preserving renewable resources and maintaining non-renewable resources to the maximum extent reasonably possible Numerous similar definitions Is this a slogan, or a rule of law? Balancing current and future needs Ensuring equitable access to resources Optimizing the use of non-renewable resources Averting the exhaustion of renewable resources Sustainable development or sustainable use? © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Problems with Sustainable Use How to know that a current use does not compromise future need? What about “fossil” waters? How does the principle of sustainability relate to the principle of “equitable utilization”? © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Current vs. Future Needs Sustainability requires ecosystem management Integrated and conjunctive management are essential No irreparable alteration of ecosystems And a comprehensive evaluation of water and its connections with other resources Now required by customary international law, Berlin Rules (2004), Pulp Mills Case (Argentina/Uruguay (International Court of Justice 2010) A highly fact-specific analysis Related to the precautionary principle © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Ecocide at the Aral Sea © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna “Fossil” Waters Certain waters (found in “uncoupled aquifers”) recycle so slowly that for all practical purposes, they are non-renewable Like minerals, if such resources are used at all, they are diminished and rendered unavailable for future use Development of such waters is sometimes necessary, but there are no clear standards for what constitutes “sustainable development” © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Sustainability and Equitable Utilization The principle of equitable utilization governs the allocation of water among States sharing a common water source Traditionally, equitable uses did not need to be sustainable The UN Convention (1997) and the Berlin Rules (2004) require both equitable use and sustainability Should international law reward States for conserving water? It is difficult to verify the amounts of water conserved Must allowance be made for States that lack the means to undertake conservation (or sustainable use or development)? Should more developed States be able to use water they save for inessential purposes while less developed neighbors cannot meet essential needs? What does this say about the human right to water? © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Markets Markets are not a natural system, but a creation of society, shaped by social expectations and law Markets are the best system if they work Market fundamentalists insist that markets are the answer for nearly every problem Markets do not work well for public goods By its nature, water is a public good and is also an economic good © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Water Withdrawal and Consumption © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Recourse to Actual Markets for Water Resources Markets are rare in all societies Markets are forbidden in some religious traditions Even in private property systems (such as are found in the western United States), markets rarely function without heavy state intervention Spontaneous markets have involved only small-scale exchanges among nearby and similar users Markets are difficult to arrange because a large-scale transfer, particularly to a different kind of use, is likely to affect many other users who have not consented to the transaction The Coors Beer case illustrates the problem Any other result deprives other water users of their property © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Are There Examples of Successful Markets for Water? Recent so-called markets The California Water Bank (1991-92) Only one lawful seller and only one lawful buyer No negotiation over prices The Imperial Valley Irrigation District “sale” to San Diego (2003) Rejected by the District’s board Imposed by the Secretary of the Interior The Chilean model (after 1980) Water redefined as strictly private property without regard to third party rights Highly touted as proof that markets work In fact, almost no market activity except in one small valley and even there it has mostly stopped because of popular resistance—Carl Bauer, The Siren Song (Resources for the Future 2004) Regulatory intervention masquerading as a market The state chooses to ignore third-party effects for itself Results in a transfer of wealth from the poor to the rich Economic incentives are critically important, but should not be confused with markets © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Marketed Water © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna What Can Law Contribute? Law is an intellectual or rhetorical system for channeling and resolving problems that otherwise would either not be dealt with or would be dealt with by force At the national level, law can: Define property systems Create incentives for responsible management At the international level, law can: Create mechanisms for allocating and managing water across boundaries Two governing principles: Equitable use Sustainability © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna Ric Masten, Stark Naked in ’69 and ’79 (1980) To Nuke or Not to is it not disturbing to consider that everything in and about a nuclear power plant will be furnished by the lowest bidder © 2013-Joseph W. Dellapenna