The Organizational Utility of Contingent Work: A Cost/Value Analysis Sandra L. Fisher, Clarkson University Catherine E. Connelly, McMaster University FlexWorkResearch Conference October 2011 Study Background Use of contingent labor increasing worldwide Why? ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ Increased flexibility Reduced managerial responsibility Extended screening process (temp-to-hire) Decreased costs Comparisons with “permanent” workers 2 What do we know about the cost of contingent workers? Claims about decreased costs rarely examined empirically, and then at firm level ◦ Improve gross profit margins (Nayar & Willinger, 2001) ◦ Greater return on equity and market-to-book value (Lepak, et al, 2003) ◦ Overtime may be more effective than use of temporary workers (Easton & Goodale, 2005) Focus is typically on direct costs ◦ Labor rates (DiNatale, 2001) ◦ Benefits 3 Nollen and Axel (1996) Model • Early model of individual level costs and benefits of contingent work – focused on value, not just lower direct costs • Acknowledged “downside risk” (p. 71) where costs may outweigh the benefits • Analysis built around unit labor cost, including wage/benefit rates per hour, training costs, hours worked, output per hour • Basic formula: Unit labor cost = (W x L) / Q W = wage and benefit rate per hour L = hours worked Q = quantity of output produced per hour 4 Nollen and Axel findings • Cost effectiveness varied based on the type/length of assignment Scenario A: Hourly part-time workers, variable schedules, high training costs, relatively short tenure Organization did not recoup costs Scenario B: Temporary workers, low wages, minimal training Organization profited What other parameters do we need to consider? 5 Our Research Questions How does the use of contingent labor translate into firm-level financial benefits? How do indirect costs affect the cost/value relationship? ◦ Productivity losses ◦ Transaction costs Will the cost/value relationship vary across different types of contingent workers? 6 Three Types of Contingent Workers Temporary agency workers ◦ Legally employed by an agency but perform their tasks at a client organization ◦ Agency is paid a percentage of the workers’ wages Independent contractors (ICs) ◦ Self-employed worker completes tasks for several different clients (sometimes simultaneously) ◦ Significant autonomy and control over own work Dependent contractors (DCs) ◦ Self-employed worker completes tasks for a single client (sometimes a former employer) (Connelly & Gallagher, 2006) ◦ Less autonomy and control over own work 7 Contingent Worker Costs 8 Direct Costs of Contingent Workers Wages ◦ Independent contractors are paid more than permanent workers (Kunda, Barley & Evans, 2002) ◦ Temps are paid less, often quite a bit less (DiNatale, 2001) Benefits ◦ Contingent workers (all types) rarely receive benefits ◦ High pay for ICs often considered as a trade-off for providing own benefits 9 Direct Costs, continued Transaction costs ◦ Range from 25-30% of temp workers’ direct wage (Nollen & Axel, 1996) ◦ Lower for ICs, lowest for DCs ◦ Integration costs (Feldman, 2006), low for DCs ◦ Turnover costs can be viewed as transaction costs for permanent workers Training ◦ Typically minimal for all types; very low for contractors ◦ More for familiarity than skill building Direct costs appear highest for permanent workers, followed by ICs 10 Indirect Costs: Task Performance Some evidence of lower task performance ◦ Temps 7-30% less productive than permanent workers (Nollen & Axel, 1996) ◦ Contingent workers 42% less productive in a call center (Lautsch, 2002) ◦ Little information about performance levels for contractors Some reports of relatively equal task performance, depending on situation ◦ Temp-to-hire ◦ Treating contingent workers as equals 11 Indirect Costs: Permanent Workers The presence of contingent workers can cause reductions in task performance of permanent workers ◦ Negative attitudes toward the organization (Davis-Blake, et al., 2003; Broschak & Davis-Blake, 2006) ◦ More withdrawal behaviors (Way, et al., 2010) ◦ These types of outcomes often depend on the type of contingent worker and the reason for using them perceived threat Permanent workers often required to help train new contingent workers, taking them away from their regular jobs Consider: there are usually many more permanent employees than contingent workers (so these effects might be more significant) 12 Indirect Costs: OCBs Contingent workers typically exhibit fewer organizational citizenship behaviors (VanDyne & Ang, 1998; Liden et al., 2003) Dollar value of OCBs is unclear ◦ Related to enhanced work group performance ◦ Approximately 20-40% of variance in performance criteria (Podsakoff, et al, 2000) Contingent workers can exhibit OCBs under the right conditions (e.g., fair treatment, high POS; Connelly et al., 2011) DCs likely to display OCBs; ICs less likely 13 Summary Direct and up-front costs for contingent workers are generally lower, however… We believe there are costs to using contingent workers that are not currently considered in the typical cost/benefit analysis ◦ Differences in task performance ◦ OCBs ◦ Permanent worker performance Key question: How do the reduced costs compare to the reduced productivity? 14 Future Research Directions Need empirical tests of these ideas ◦ What are the tradeoffs? ◦ Can organizations create the right conditions to maximize contingent worker performance without increasing direct costs or putting themselves at legal risk? ◦ Starting with a utility analysis approach What is the dollar value of OCBs? ◦ Literature agrees that there is value here, but how much? ◦ Some estimation done by Orr, Sackett & Mercer (1989) 15