20100527101511001

advertisement

Costing the Earth: Uncertainty and

Climate Policy

Nafees Meah

Head of Science

May 2010

Climate Change As ‘Hard’ Problem

In Public Policy

 As a public policy issue, climate change is a classic example of a ‘wicked’ problem

 Notwithstanding the compelling scientific evidence, it is still contested

 It is the case that there is and will always be irreducible scientific uncertainty – we cannot do a controlled experiment on the planet

 Even if there is consensus on the science, that does not tell us what we ought to do: what are the trade-offs that the decision-makers need to consider?

Outline

 Summary of the science of climate change

 The 2 degree target – AVOID Programme

 Key questions in the economics of climate change

 Economic modelling and cost-benefit analysis

 Stern Review and its critics

 Bottom up technical/economic models

 The task facing the decision maker

Carbon Dioxide Concentrations In The

Atmosphere Since The Beginning Of The

Industrial Revolution

MacKay (2009)

Evidence that CO

2 is Man Made

Last decade has been the warmest since records began

Observed Global Temperature

Changes Not Explained by Natural

Factors Alone

Year to year range of modelled global temperatures

Climate models show the observed warming is only explained by including human effects through GHG emissions

Excluding human influence

By 2100 Global Temperature is likely to be1.8 to 4 o

C Above 1990

Level

The scale of warming depends on emissions:

Low scenario 1.1 – 2.9

o

C

Best estimate 1.8 – 4.0

o

C

High scenario 2.4

– 6.4

o

C

IPCC (2007)

Projected temperatures – land and polar regions warm more than oceans

IPCC (2007)

IPCC Fourth Assessment

Report 2007

“Warming of the climate system is unequivocal , as is now evident from observations of increases in global average air and ocean temperatures, widespread melting of snow and ice and rising global average sea level”

p2, IPCC Synthesis

Report

Temperature, Sea Level and Snow

Cover

• The Earth’s surface has warmed by

0.75

C since 1900

• Sea levels have risen by 20cm since

1900

• Now: glaciers, snow cover and sea ice are all declining

• Now: more heatwaves, droughts, extreme rain events and more intense cyclones

IPCC (2007)

Arctic Ocean September Ice Extent

0 °C

Food

Impacts of climate change

Global temperature change (relative to pre-industrial)

1 °C 2 °C 3 °C 4 °C 5 °C

Falling crop yields in many areas, particularly developing regions

Possible rising yields in some high latitude regions

Falling yields in many developed regions

Water

Small mountain glaciers disappear – water supplies threatened in several areas

Significant decreases in water availability in many areas, including

Mediterranean and Southern Africa

Ecosystems

Sea level rise threatens major cities

Extensive Damage to Coral Reefs

Rising number of species face extinction

Extreme

Weather Rising intensity of storms, forest fires, droughts, flooding and heat waves

Events

Risk of Abrupt and

Major Irreversible

Changes

Increasing risk of dangerous feedbacks and abrupt, large-scale shifts in the climate system

Cascade of uncertainty

Emission scenario

Atmospheric concentrations

Climate sensitivity

Climate change

Range of

Impacts

Impacts may not increase linearly with warming

Lenton (2007)

Climate Sensitivity: Temperature

Response of doubling [CO

2]

Q = F-

λ∆T

Where Q = energy balance,

F = forcing and λ = feedback parameter

At eqm Q=0

F = λ∆T

For the special case of doubling CO

2

F’ = λS

Where S = Climate sensitivity

AR4 concluded that best estimate of climate sensitivity was 3 0 C with range of 2-4.5

0 C (ca. 2SD)

IPCC (2007)

Climate feedbacks include

Feedback

Water vapour

Cloud radiation

Ocean-circulation

Ice-albedo

This is the most important.

Water vapour is a powerful greenhouse gas.

Complex impact. Several processes involved. Sensitive to structure of clouds

Plays large part in determining earth’s climate. Large heat capacity and moves heat around.

Ice and snow are a powerful reflector of solar radiation

Climate feedbacks affect the sensitivity of the climate.

Why a ‘fat’ tail?

AVOID Programme and the 2 degree target

 2 degree target agreed at Copenhagen Accord balances risks against technical and social feasibility in an informal way

AVOID examined variations in:

1.

The year of peak emissions (2014 to

2030)

2.

The emission rates leading up to the peak (BAU)

3.

The emissions reduction rate following peak emissions (1 to 5% per year)

4.

The net long-term level of emissions

(zero to high levels)

Business as usual

Policy scenario

AVOID Programme: 2 degree trajectories

 AVOID uses a ‘tuned’ climate model (MAGICC)

Global average temperature determined by cumulative emissions of GHGs (2.63TtCO2e 2000-2500)

 Approximates to the area under the curve

Take home message is that to stabilise temperature at 2 degrees is going to be a huge challenge - we need to peak soon and STRONG decline thereafter

GHG emission trajectories consistent with 2˚C increase in global average temperature at 2100 at a 50% probability level

Action on Climate Change

Key questions

1.

How much will it cost to ‘stabilise’ the climate and avoid dangerous climate change?

2. Will the cost of avoiding dangerous climate change compete with other priorities such as development?

What action do we take in the light of the scientific evidence for climate change?

 So if we applied the appropriate discount rate , then we might say that action would be justified on cost-benefit grounds if:

NPV = Present Value (benefits) – Present Value (costs) > 0

 Or for a range of alternative policy actions, choose the one with highest NPV

Uncertainties in economic modelling of climate change

 This is a formidable challenge because:

 We do not and cannot know the precise benefits of policy action given the underlying uncertainty in the science

 We do not and cannot know what the future cost of the policy will be given the long time horizons

 Costs and benefits functions are likely to be highly non-linear

and we don’t know what they are

 If standard economic models are based on marginal changes, how do we account for irreversibilities?

 Given the very long time horizons, what is the appropriate discount rate to use?

Economic models for climate policy

 Number of different kinds of economic models

 Much of the debate is about Integrated

Assessment Models (IAMS) which seek to integrate science and the economic theory to optimise climate policy

 These are utility maximising models which seek to maximize, W, the social welfare, where

W = ∫ exp(-ρt)U[c(t)]dt

Where ρ is the rate of pure time preference, c(t) is the consumption at time t, and

U is the utility function specifying how much utility is derived from a particular level of consumption

Global economic activity

Outputs from Integrated Assessment

Models

Reference case without impacts

Cost of policy

Reference case with impacts

Benefits of policy

Time

Stern Review

 Uses PAGE 2002 Integrated Assessment Model

 Takes account of risk and uncertainty through Monte Carlo simulations on the climate sensitivity parameter, assumptions on risk aversion and equity

 Key finding

 Cost of trajectory consistent with 550ppm CO2e stabilisation averages 1% of global GDP per year (range

-1% to 3.5%)

 Avoided damages would be 11% of GDP (range 2-27%) for Baseline climate and 14% (range 3-32%) for High climate

 This contrasts with other IAMs which suggest a higher level of cost and lower level of damage – DICE, MERGE, FUND

 Other models propose ‘policy ramp’ and modest rates of GHG reduction

The critics

Main criticism in the literature has been over the choice discount rate used by the Stern Review

– should instead have used a market rate (i.e. 3

– 7%)

 In the Ramsay formula, the social discount rate is given by :

Social discount rate =

+ (

 x consumption/cap growth rate)

Reflects pure rate of time preference

(which Stern suggest should be

0) and risk of human extinction

(which Stern select as 0.1).

Elasticity of marginal utility of consumption

(Stern suggest this is

1, which assumes society is moderately adverse to income inequality).

Growth in per capita consumption varies over time and according to extent of climate change damages. For baseline climate scenario with market impacts only, the

5-95% range of timeaveraged growth is 1.08%

- 1.14%.

Therefore in Stern, discount rate = 0.1 + (1*(1.08 to 1.14%)) = 1.18 to 1.24%

Discount rate have an important effect on the present value of climate change impacts

Value of £100 over time using different discount rates

£

100

90

80

70

60

90.479

60.577

81.865

0.1%

1.0%

5.0%

0.5%

2.0%

10.0%

50

40

30

36.603

36.696

20

13.262

10

0

0.623

0.003

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

100 110 120 130 140 150 160 170 180 190 200

13.533

1.759

Years

On Extreme Uncertainty of Extreme

Climate Change – Martin Weitzman

 Implication of the fat tail of climate sensitivity

 Translating the pdf of climate sensitivity into confidence levels for temperature change as a function of GHG concentrations gives:

 So at 550 ppm there is a 10% of T >4.8 ˚C. This is disturbing and can’t be ignored in formal economic modelling.

Damage function

 Thought experiment on the damage function, which often takes the quadratic form in IAMs of:

C*(T) = 1/ 1+aT 2

 Where C*(T) is defined as the ‘welfare equivalent’ consumption as a fraction of what the consumption would be at T=0, and a=0.003

 However, it is impossible to know a priori what the functional form should be for high temperatures

 What if we used quartic or exponential form then the estimated damages would be very different

 For a quartic exponential function, C*(T) = exp(-bT 4 ), then at 10

˚ C C*(T) is 0.08% i.e. a catastrophic loss of ‘welfare equivalent’ consumption

Technical feasibility models -

McKinsey Marginal Abatement Cost

Curve – Bottom up estimates

Generally optimistic – it can be done and at comparatively small cost !

Choices facing the decision makers

 Is formalised cost-benefit analysis appropriate for climate change policy?

 If the answer is ‘no’ what other approach should we adopt?

 Given that a 2 ˚C has been adopted, should economic analysis focus on seeking the cost effective pathway

 Is a risk based approach formalising the ‘precautionary principle’ the appropriate way forward?

 Do we need more scientific knowledge on threshold temperatures for major discontinuities or catastrophe’s?

 What else is there any other approach that we should consider?

Thank you for your attention

Finally....

Download