Microeconomics Lecture 4 Jona Linde https://sites.google.com/site/jonalinde/ j.linde@maastrichtuniversity.nl Course structure Part I Supply and demand Week 1 2 II Consumer theory 3 III Producer theory IV Perfect competition 4 5 6 V Market power and market structure 7 Task 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 Subject Supply and demand Applying the supply and demand model Consumer choice Applying the model of the consumer Firms and production Short-run costs Long-run costs Perfect competition Markets and welfare Monopoly Government and welfare Pricing Oligopoly and monopolistic competition Game theory Chapter 1, 2 3 4 5 6 7 7 8 9 11 9, 11 12 13 14 Last week: Short run production • • 120 100 output Q Total production - Maximum output produced with a specific amount of labour เดฅ - TPL = ๐ = ๐ ๐ฟ, ๐พ 80 60 40 20 Average product of labour - Average output per unit of labour - APL = ๐Τ๐ฟ 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 labour L 24 20 16 Marginal Product of labour - “extra output from using one extra unit of labor” - MPL = Δ๐เตΔ๐ฟ = ๐๐ ๐ เต๐๐ฟ APL, MPL • 12 MPL 8 APL 4 0 -4 0 2 4 6 8 labour L 10 12 14 Last week: Long run production • • Both labour and capital are variable - ๐ = ๐ ๐ฟ, ๐พ (no bar over K!) Isoquant connecting input combinations that yield the same output (level curve) - ๐เดค = ๐ ๐ฟ, ๐พ Marginal rate of technical substitution - Slope of isoquants Δ๐พ ๐๐ - MRTS= Δ๐ฟ = − ๐๐ ๐ฟ - • ๐พ diminishing marginal returns imply diminishing MRTS Returns to scale - Decreasing, increasing, or constant - ๐ 2๐ฟ, 2๐พ <? > 2๐ ๐ฟ, ๐พ 7 6 capital input K • 5 4 3 2 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 labour input L 5 6 7 From production function to costs function • 7.1) What are “costs”? • 7.2) How do costs depend on output in the short run? • 7.3) How do costs depend on output in the long run? • 7.4) Lower costs in the long run • (skip section 7.5) 7.1 What are costs • Opening quote Task 6: “Me and my wife, we own the place, so we don’t pay any rent. We don’t need staff, so we don’t have any labour costs. We cannot complain, financially.” (innkeeper of a “pannenkoekenhuis” near Maastricht, spring 2001) • Economic costs ๏น accounting costs ๏ Economic profit ๏น accounting profit - Sometimes no conflict: buying materials which are used in production directly - Sometimes big difference: buying materials as stock that could be resold Economic costs = opportunity costs - “value of the best alternative use of an input” - “what you have to give up to use that input” Basic rule: for each input, ask yourself: “what is its value in its next most valuable use?” • • 7.1 What are costs • Labour costs - Hiring labour - Simple - but permanent contracts make accounting and opportunity costs diverge - Partly sunk costs - Sunk costs irrelevant to your decisions today - “bygones are bygones” - Own labour - Accounting: some payment in salary, some in profit - Economic/opportunity costs: best alternative use of time - Earn money working elsewhere - Value of leisure 7.1 What are costs • Capital costs - Rent - Simple, but can be (partly) sunk if in a long-term lease - Own - Accounting costs: Depreciated over several years (according to tax rules) - Economic costs: imputed rents - Next best use: rent it out, alternative use - Sell and invest money - Can be very different - Real estate boom - Specialized tools - Resale value and therefore opportunity costs 0 - Initial expense sunk cost 7.2 Short-run costs • • Not all inputs can be varied - Capital (K) fixed, price per unit r rental rate - Labour (L) variable, price per unit w wage rate If capital is fixed, are capital costs sunk? - Maybe, maybe not - Perhaps can avoid by stopping production - There can be alternative uses, but plausibly less valuable in the short run than in the long run - If so, economic fixed costs lower in the short run - Conversely, no costs are fixed in the long run 7.2 Short-run costs • • • • Three basic cost-level concepts and associated curves เดฅ Fixed Costs costs of fixed inputs e.g. ๐น๐ถ = ๐๐พ FC does not depend on q Variable Costs costs of variable inputs e.g. ๐๐ถ = ๐ค๐ฟ VC rises as q rises Total Costs costs of all inputs ๐๐ถ = ๐น๐ถ + ๐๐ถ TC rises as q rises, through VC Four spin-offs: cost-per-unit concepts → curves Δ๐๐ถ Δ๐๐ถ Marginal Costs: extra costs of producing one extra unit ๐๐ถ = Δ๐ = Δ๐ • Aver. Fixed Costs: fixed costs per unit produced • Aver. Variable Costs: variable costs per unit produced • Average Costs: total costs per unit produced • • ๐น๐ถ ๐ ๐๐ถ ๐ด๐๐ถ = ๐ ๐๐ถ ๐ด๐ถ = ๐ = ๐ด๐น๐ถ + ๐ด๐๐ถ ๐ด๐น๐ถ = 7.2 Short-run costs q FC VC TC MC AFC AVC AC 0 48 0 48 X X X X 1 48 25 73 25 48 25 73 2 48 46 94 21 24 23 47 3 48 66 114 20 16 22 38 4 48 82 130 16 12 20.5 32.5 5 48 100 148 18 9.6 20 29.6 6 48 120 168 20 8 20 28 7 48 141 189 21 6.9 20.1 27 8 48 168 216 27 6 21 27 9 48 198 246 30 5.3 22 27.3 7.2 Short-run costs 80 400 70 350 60 250 FC 200 VC TC 150 Cost-per-unit Cost level 300 50 MC AFC 40 AVC AC 30 20 100 10 50 0 0 0 2 4 6 Output Q 8 10 12 0 2 4 6 Output Q 8 10 12 7.2 Short-run costs • Specifics of / relations between these seven cost concepts • FC horizontal line • VC rising curve, starting at origin • TC vertical sum of FC and VC ๏ parallel to VC • MC slope of tangent TC = slope of tangent VC • AFC declines monotonically (“spreading out”) • AVC falls when MC < AVC, rises when MC > AVC ๏ MC intersects AVC at its minimum (compare APL ๏ MPL, last week) • AC falls when MC < AC, rises when MC > AC ๏ MC intersects AC at its minimum vertical sum of AFC and AVC ๏ AC ever closer to AVC ๏ minimum AC lies beyond minimum AVC 7.2 Short-run costs From production function to cost curves เดฅ - Production function: ๐ = ๐ ๐ฟ, ๐พ เดฅ (๐=rental rate), e.g. ๐ = 5, ๐พ เดฅ = 4→ FC=20 - Fixed costs: ๐๐พ - Variable costs: w๐ฟ (w=wage rate), more complex because L is a choice เดฅ we want ๐ฟ as a function of ๐ i.e. the inverse of ๐ - Have ๐ = ๐ ๐ฟ, ๐พ 100 120 80 80 If w = 10 60 40 Variable Cost VC 100 output Q • 60 40 20 20 0 0 2 4 6 labour L 8 10 0 0 20 40 60 Output Q 80 100 120 7.2 Short-run costs • • • Short-run cost curve determined by short-run production function Relation between AVC and APL? ๐๐ถ ๐ค๐ฟ ๐ค ๐ค - ๐ด๐๐ถ = ๐ = ๐ = ๐เต = ๐ด๐ ๐ฟ ๐ฟ Relation between MC and MPL? ๐ฅ๐๐ถ ๐ค๐ฅ๐ฟ ๐ค ๐ค - ๐ด๐๐ถ = ๐ฅ๐ = ๐ฅ๐ = ๐ฅ๐ = ๐๐ เต๐ฅ๐ฟ • ๐ฟ Mathematical example เดฅ=4 - Cobb-Douglas: ๐ = ๐ฟ0.5 ๐พ 0.5 , with ๐ = 5 & ๐พ - ๐ = 2๐ฟ0.5 → ๐ฟ = 0.25๐ 2 7.2 Short-run costs Mathematical example continued เดฅ = 5 ∗ 4 = 20 - FC: ๐๐พ - VC: ๐ค๐ฟ = 10 ∗ 0.25๐ 2 = 2.5๐ 2 - TC: FC+VC= 20 + 2.5๐ 2 - AFC: 20Τ๐; AVC: 2.5๐ 20 →ATC: 2.5๐ + ๐ • - MC: 5๐ Note: - decreasing MPL → rising MC - MC > AVC → AVC rises - falling AFC and rising AVC generate U-shaped AC - MC hits AC at its minimum 50 40 Cost-per-unit • AFC 30 AVC AC 20 MC 10 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Output Q 7 8 9 10 7.3 Long-run costs • Long run: • all inputs can be varied practically both capital and labour are variable inputs ๏ q = f(L,K) no “bar” over K ! ๏ all costs are avoidable/variable: (T)C = wL + rK - only one cost-level concept: - only two cost-per-unit concepts: TC = VC, say C AC and MC 7.3 Long-run costs Isoquants - Combinations of L & K that yield the same output level ๐เดค = ๐ ๐ฟ, ๐พ Δ๐พ ๐๐ - Slope: Δ๐ฟ = ๐๐ ๐๐ = − ๐๐ ๐ฟ 7 6 ๐พ - “how much K can you replace by an extra L, with q constant” diminishing marginal returns imply diminishing MRTS ๏ convex isoquants capital input K • 5 4 3 2 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 labour input L 5 6 7 7.3 Long-run costs Isocost line: combinations of L and K that cost the same amount - Example: w=10 & r=5 Find isocost line of 30 Note: 7 - 6K, 0L or 0K, 3L 0r 1K, 2L • At given factor prices, isocost 6 - Mathematically: ๐ค๐ฟ + ๐๐พ = ๐ถาง lines are parallel 5 - Here: 10๐ฟ + 5๐พ = 30 • lines further from origin Δ๐พ ๐ค mean higher cost 4 - Slope: Δ๐ฟ = − ๐ →here: -2 • (e.g. try = 20 and = 40) 3 - “how much K do you have to give up for an extra L, 2 while costs C remain the same” capital input K • 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 labour input L 5 6 7 7.3 Long-run costs • • • What does this look like - Isoquants (see indifference curves) - Isocost lines (see budget lines) - But important difference: cost level is not fixed Cost minimization - Given factor prices find combination of inputs that minimizes costs required to produce a certain level of output - Graphically: hit relevant isoquant with lowest possible isocost line Note: - Cost minimization is necessary condition for profit maximization - All combinations on an isoquant are technologically efficient - But only the cheapest combination (given factor prices), i.e. combination on the lowest isocost line, is economically efficient 7.3 Long-run costs • Example: : w=10 & r=5; find the cheapest way to produce 24 Find the lowest possible cost line - C=30 clearly too low 7 q=24 - Shift right until you hit the isoquant 6 At optimal point 5 - Equal slopes: MRTS=ratio of prices - “rate at which inputs can be 4 substituted = rate at which they can 3 be traded” ๐๐ ๐ค ๐๐ ๐๐ 2 - Formally: ๐ฟ = → ๐ฟ = ๐พ capital input K • • - ๐๐๐พ ๐ ๐ค ๐ ‘Last euro rule’ Counter example: ๐๐๐ฟ = ๐๐๐พ safe 5 by replacing one L by 1 K 1 C=35 C=30 0 0 1 2 3 4 labour input L 5 6 7 7.3 Long-run costs • Conclusion: our analysis gives the cheapest way to produce a specific output level, given specific factor prices • Three obvious questions: 1. What happens when factor prices change? 2. What is the cheapest way of producing other outputs? 3. What determines the shape of the long-run cost curve(s)? 7.3 Long-run costs capital input K 1. What happens when factor prices change? • with w = 10 and r = 5, use L = 2 and K = 3 to produce q = 24, at min. cost of C = 35 • Imagine w falls to 2.5 - same isoquant 7 - shallower isocost line 6 - Now tangency at 5 L=3, K=2, C=17.5 4 • Two reasons for lower C 3 1. Old bundle cheaper 2 2. Substitute to relatively Q=24 1 cheaper L 0 • Changing prices change 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 costs and input mix labour input L 14 7.3 Long-run costs q=48 capital input K 2. What is the cheapest way of producing other output levels? • Assume again w=10 and r=5 know for q=24 L=2, K=3, C=35 7 q=24 • Add new isoquant, e.g. q=48 6 - L=4, K=6, C=70 5 • Connect tangency points to find expansion path 4 - Cheapest input combinations for 3 different levels of q 2 • Plot associated C against q → long-run cost curve 1 C=35 - Minimum costs per output level 0 ceteris paribus: factor prices 0 1 2 3 C=708 4 labour input L 5 6 7 7.3 Long-run costs 3. What determines the shape of the long-run cost curve(s)? • Returns to scale • Ex.: take w = 10, r = 10 and draw some typical isoquants Constant r2s Increasing r2s 6 4 2 8 6 6 capital input K capital input K capital input K 8 4 2 0 2 4 6 0 8 2 4 6 0 8 80 80 60 40 20 0 15 Output Q 20 25 30 4 6 8 100 60 40 20 80 60 40 20 0 0 10 2 labour input L Long-run cost C 100 Long-run cost C 100 5 2 labour input L labour input L 0 4 0 0 0 Long-run cost C Decreasing r2s 8 0 5 10 15 Output Q 20 25 30 0 5 10 15 Output Q 20 25 30 7.3 Long-run costs • Conclusion: - Constant returns: output rises in proportion with inputs ๏ costs rise in proportion to output ๏AC constant - Increasing returns: output rises faster than inputs ๏ costs rise less than output ๏AC falling, “economies of scale” - Decreasing returns: output rises less than inputs ๏ costs rise faster than output ๏ AC rising, “diseconomies of scale” 7.3 Long-run costs • • 350 60 300 50 250 Cost-per-unit • Typical shape long-run cost curve for competitive firms: initially increasing returns, then decreasing returns ๏ U-shaped AC- and MC-curves Same geometrical relations as in the short run: MC: slope of tangent to C = derivative of C AC: falls when MC < AC, rises when MC > AC → MC intersects AC at its minimum Cost level • • 200 150 40 MC 30 AC 20 100 10 50 0 0 2 4 6 Output Q 8 10 0 12 0 2 4 6 Output Q 8 10 12 7.3 Long-run costs • • Mathematical approach I) App. 7C: the Lagrange method; “constrained maximization” II) Alternative: translate the graph into math mathematically equivalent: this is what we’ll do Ex.: derive the long-run cost function when ๐ = 10๐ฟ0.5 ๐พ 0.5, with w = 20 and r = 5 - Note: this Cobb-Douglas production function has constant returns to scale ๐พ0.5 ๐ฟ0.5 ๐๐๐ฟ = 5 ๐ฟ0.5 , ๐๐๐พ = 5 ๐พ0.5 • Long-run cost function gives minimum costs for any level of q • This is achieved by choosing the cheapest input bundle (L,K) that can produce this q • • - ๐ถ = ๐ค๐ฟ + ๐๐พ → ๐ถ ๐ = ๐ค๐ฟ ๐ + ๐๐พ ๐ i) The cheapest input bundle for producing amount q must lie on the q-isoquant ii) Isocost line through the cheapest input bundle for q must be tangent to the q-isoquant 7.3 Long-run costs • • i) The cheapest input bundle for producing amount q must lie on the q-isoquant - ๐ ๐ฟ, ๐พ = ๐ → ๐ = 10๐ฟ0.5 ๐พ 0.5 ii) Isocost line through the cheapest input bundle for q must be tangent to the qisoquant ๐พ0.5 ๐ฟ ๐ฟ0.5 5 0.5 ๐พ 5 0.5 - ๐๐๐ฟ ๐ค = → ๐๐๐พ ๐ 20 ๐พ 20 - 10๐ฟ0.5 (4๐ฟ)0.5 = ๐ 20๐ฟ = ๐ ๐ฟ ๐ = 0.05๐, K ๐ = 0.20๐ ๐ถ ๐ = ๐ค๐ฟ ๐ + ๐๐พ ๐ = 20 ∗ 0.05๐ + 5 ∗ 0.2๐ = 2๐ - Constant returns to scale with MC=AC=2 = 5 → ๐ฟ = 5 →๐พ = 4๐ฟ (expansion path) 7.4 Lower costs in the long-run • • • Relation between short-run and long-run costs Basic message: LRAC<SRAC at any q - K fixed in the short run - Equal if (short-run) K is at the optimal level - In the long-run firm chooses K so K is always at it’s optimal level - Note the ‘envelope property’ (Fig. 7.9) - Additional reasons - Technological progress - Learning by doing Read this at home Application • • Opportunity costs of government policy - Spending more on policy x either means higher taxes (which?) or less spending elsewhere - Costs of taxation usually larger than the tax revenue - Deadweight loss and bureaucracy - Benefits of spending equally difficult to measure - Not equal to the effect on GDP - Conversely cutting spending can have more costs than the raw number suggests - E.g. government spending may have induced others to spend Businesses might face similar difficulties - E.g. effect of reducing employee benefits on future recruitment Limitations and extensions • • Time dimension - Spend money now to make money later - Matters when costs occur - Interest rate as opportunity costs of spending now rather than later - Therefor work with net present value With more than 2 inputs we could get more than 1 optimum