108 5 The Stalic Classical and Keynesian Models production function is initially y = 2nO. 5 , but then a technological innovation shifts it to y = 3nO. 5 • For concreteness, also suppose that labor supply behavior is described by n = 100 WIP. Determine algebraically the equilibrium values of n* and y* before and after the technological improvement. Also, represent the change graphically, using diagrams like those of Figure 5-14. What would be the qualitative effects on r * , p "', and (WI P) * according to the classical model? • Steady Inflation References Bailey, Martin J., National Income and the Price Level, 2nd ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1971) Chaps. 2, 3. Barro, Robert J., Macroeconomics. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1984) Chaps. 6-8, 19. Brunner, Karl, and Allan H. Meltzer, "Money and Credit in the Monetary Transmission Process," American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 78 (May 1988), 446-5l. Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Stanley Fischer, Macroeconomics, 3rd ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1984) Chaps. 11, 12. Henderson, James M., and Richard E. Quandt, Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1980). Keynes, John M., The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. (London: Macmillan Publishing Company, 1936). Patinkin, Don, Money, Interest, and Prices, 2nd ed. (New York: Harper & Row, Publishers, 1965), Chaps. 9-15. Sargent, Thomas J., "Beyond Demand and Supply Curves in Macroeconomics," American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 72 (May 1982), 382-89. Sargent, Thomas J., Macroeconomic Theory. (New York: Academic Press, Inc. 1979), Chaps. 1,2. 6.1 Introduction At this point we begin the transition from static to dynamic analysis. In Chapter 5 the analytical method was to compare static equilibrium positions of the economy prevailing before and after some postulated change in an exogenous variable (or some postulated shift in a behavioral relation). The dynamic behavior of the variables in the time interval after the postulated change, but before the attainment of the new equilibrium position, was not considered. In effect, then, this analysis was timeless; we simply did not keep track of the passage of time. But it would clearly be extremely desirable to be able to describe the behavior of an economy functioning in real time-to explain movements in variables from quarter to quarter, for example. Full-fledged dynamic analysis is much more difficult than comparative statics, however, so we shall have to proceed slowly. The first step, accordingly, will be to develop the concept of a steady-state equilibrium, in which some of the system's variables change over time but in a restrictive manner. In particular, in steady-state analysis all variables are required to be growing at a constant rate-at a rate that is unchanging as time passes. For some of the variables that rate will be zero; that is, the values of the variables themselves will be constant. The values of the other variables, by contrast, will be changing through time, but will be doing so at a rate that is constant. This rate may in principle differ from variable to variable; all that the steady-state concept requires is that each variable be growing at some constant rate. In many cases, however, the same rate will apply to all variables that are growing at nonzero rates. By a "growth rate" what is meant here is the relative rate of change (through time) of a variable. Thus in terms of variables that change continuously through time, the measure of the growth rate is not the 109 110 6 Steady Inflation 6.1 time derivative, but that derivative divided by the value of the variable itself. For the variable x, the growth rate would be (1/x) dx/dt, not dx/dt, for instance. The amount of the change per unit time is measured relative to the magnitude prevailing. In our discussion we shall not, however, treat our variables as changing continuously through time. Instead, we will work with discrete periods of time-periods such as months or quarters or years-pretending that the value of any variable is the same throughout each period but liable to change "between" periods. From this perspective, the growth rate of x between periods t - 1 and t might possibly be defined as (x, - X'_I)/ Xt-b where XI is the value ofx in period t and Xt-l its value in period t 1. It would be just as logical, however, to define the growth rate of x as (x t XI_I)/X t, or as (x t - Xt_I)/O.S(x, + Xl-I), instead of the expression in the preceding sentence. Indeed, reference to the continuous-time concept (l/x) dx/dt suggests that a definition preferable to all of the foregoing would be growth rate of X between t - 1 and t = .:l log X t log X t - log X,-I = X (1) log-' . Xt-I Here log X t means the natural logarithm, that is, the logarithm to the base e = 2.713, of the variable Xl' The symbol.:l attached to any dated variable indicates the difference between the dated value and that of the previous period, so that (for example) .:lz, means z, - Z,-l' In the present case, then, .:llog x, means log x, log X,-I. Finally, the last equality in (1) obtains as a result of the properties of logarithms: for any number A and B, log (A/B) = log A - log B. That the definition of the growth rate given by expression (1) is consistent with the continuous-time concept may be seen by recalling that the derivative (w.r.t. x) of log X is 1/x. Thus in continuous time the concept (l/x) dx/ dt is equivalent to d log x/ dt, while the latter has .:l log x, as its discrete-time analog. The main advantage of working with expression (1) rather than the other discrete-time possibilities stems from the following fact: because of the properties of logarithms, the growth rate of a product such as YZ is equal to the sum of the growth rates of Yand Z. To prove that, note that if X t == YrZt, then .:llog XI log XI log X t- 1 = log Yr + log Z, log (YrZ,) - log (Yr-IZt-l) log Yr-l - log Z'-l Introduction 111 o' - - - - " - - - - - - - - - - - - - T i m e o Figure 6·1 Similarly, it is true that if Xl Y;/ Z" then .:l log X t = .:l log Yr .:llog Z,. That is, the growth rate of a ratio of two variables is the difference in the growth rates of these variables. These identities, which would not hold under other definitions, are highly useful. Given our definition of growth rates, the concept of a steady-state equilibrium implies that the steady-state time path of a variable Yl must conform to an equation of the form .:llog y, = b, (3) where b is some constant. This in turn implies that the steady-state values of y, are describable by an expression of the form log y, = a + bt, (4) where b is the same constant as in (3) and where a is a constant that equals the logarithm of the value of Yt in period t O. (That is, a = log Yo.) Consequently, any steady-state' time path can be represented graphically as in Figure 6-1. The slope of the line representing log Yt gives the growth rate of Yt. 1 The logarithmic definition of growth rates (or rates of change) that we have adopted for discrete-time variables may seem strange to some readers, who are familiar with some alternative concept such as (x, X,-l)/XI-l' The main reason for our choice is that algebraic manipulations with the .:llog x, definition are simpler and clearer. Also, our concept accords well with the continuous-time measure (l/x) dx/dt . These reasons seem adequate to justify our convention, especially since log Y; - log Y;-l + log Zt - log Z'_I = .:llog Y; + .:llog Zt. Strictly speaking, we should plot values of log y, only at discrete points for 0,1,2, ... when the discrete-time representation is being used. For convenience, however, we will use continuous graphs to depict discrete-time variables. I (2) t 112 6 6.3 Inflation in the Classical Model Steady Inflation II log X t is numerically close to (x t Xt-l)/Xt-l whenever the latter for growth rates of number is reasonably small relative to 1.0. That the order of magnitude of 0.05,0.10, or 0.15 (in percentage terms these are growth rates of 5, 10, and 15 percent), the values of (XI Xt-l)/X1-l and ~ log X t are approximately the same. That this must be true can be verified by noting that our concept lliog X t equals t "" 10g(_X_t 10g_X_ Xt-l Xt-l X_t-_l + 1) = 10g(1 + -,Xt_-_X.::-t--=-J) Xt-l (5) Xt-l and recalling that, for small values of the number z, log (1 + z) is approximately equal to Z.2 Thus ~ log X t is approximately equal to (x t - Xt-l)/Xt-l when the latter is small. 6.2 Real Versus Nominal Interest Rates At this point it will be convenient to introduce the heretofore ignored distinction between real and nominal interest rates. This distinction is important in the context of steady-state analysis because a steady-state equilibrium may feature a constant but nonzero rate of change of the price level, that is, a nonzero inflation rate. Since this nonzero inflation rate will be constant over time in a steady state, it is implausible to believe that the economy's individuals will not recognize the existence of inflation and correctly anticipate that it will continue to prevail in the future. Indeed, the requirement that inflation (and other variables) be correctly anticipated is a natural assumption for steady-state analysis, and is one that we shall henceforth utilize. 3 But with the price level changing over time, the economically relevant rate of interest on a loan with provisions specified in monetary terms depends on the anticipated inflation rate. Imagine, for example, a loan of $1000 for a period of one year, with the provision that the borrower must pay the lender $1100 at the end of the year. In monetary terms, the rate of interest on this loan is 0.10 (or 10 percent). But if the lender expects the price level to be 10 percent higher at the end of the year than at the time of the loan, he expects to be repaid an amount that is worth in real terms only just as much as the amount lent. Thus to him the (expected) real rate of interest on the loan is zero. If, however, he expected the price level to be only 4 percent higher, he would 2 Technically, for z close to zero the first-order Taylor series approximation to log (1+z)is1. 3 In effect, then, our definition of a steady state is an ongoing situation in which every variable is growing at some constant rate and in which expectations are correct. 113 anticipate receiving a payment worth in real terms 106 percent of his loan. In this case, the real interest rate as viewed by the lender would be 0.10 0.04 = 0.06 or 6 percent. From this type of reasoning we see that in general the real rate of interest on a loan specified in monetary terms is the nominal (monetary) rate of interest minus the expected inflation rate for the life of the loan. In particular, if R, is the nominal rate of interest on one-period loans made in t, and 7T', is the inflation rate expected between t and t + 1, the real rate r, will be given by (6) The distinction represented in this equation reflects one of the most important ideas in monetary economics. It will be utilized extensively in the discussion that follows. For other discussions of this distinction, and the material of this chapter more generally, the reader is referred to Bailey (1971, Chap. 4) and Barro (1984, Chap. 8). 6.3 Inflation In the Classical Model Having introduced some necessary tools, we are now in a position to develop the analysis of a steady, ongoing inflation. This analysis will be conducted in the context of the classical model. We begin with this model, rather than the Keynesian version, for two reasons. First, it is clear that, because of its assumption of a given money wage rate, the Keynesian model would have to be seriously modified to permit a sensible analysis of ongoing inflation. 4 Second, since steady-state comparisons represent a type of "long-run" analysis, designed for the elucidation of policies maintained over a long span of time,S the assumption of wage flexibility is not at all inappropriate-as many economists believe it would be for "short-run" issues. Let us begin the analysis by assuming that the monetary authority, in a classical economy with no growth of population and no technical progress, causes the money stock to increase period after period at the rate po. Thus we assume that (7) where M, is the money stock in period t. From the discussion in Section 6.1 we know that the path of M, can then be depicted as in Figure 6-2, which is drawn under the assumption that po is positive. Now, 4 Which would presumably be accompanied by ongoing increases in the nominal wage rate. 5 That this is so will become apparent subsequently. 6.3 114 Inflation in the Classical Model 115 6 Steady Inflation the capital stock is constant over time, an assumption that we will want to relax subsequently. With Yt equal to the constant value y*, determined in the manner just described, it remains to determine the behavior of Pr and r t • But from the discussion in Section 6.2, we know that we must consider whether it is the real or nominal interest rate that appears in the IS and LM equations. As it happens, the answer is that both appear-or, more precisely, that Rt appears in one equation and rr in the other. In particular, the analysis of Chapter 3 indicates that it is Rr that belongs in the LM equation/ which we therefore rewrite as M, ' - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - Time Figure 6·2 in a situation such as this, it seems natural to guess-on the basis of our knowledge of the comparative static properties of the classical modelthat the price level Pr will also grow over time at the rate f.k. In that case, the path of Pr would be as shown in Figure 6-2, where the slope of the path of log Pr is the same as that of log M,. 6 To verify that Pr would in fact behave in this conjectured manner, we must consider the complete model. In Section 5.6 the latter was summarized with the five following equations: Y = C(y - 7',r) + I(y,r) + g, M P = L(y,r), y = fen), - = L(y" RJ Pr Reflection on the nature of the IS function as discussed in Section 5.2 indicates, however, that it is the real rate r, that is relevant for saving and investment decisions, basically because people care about real magnitudes. The IS curve can then be represented as Yr = C(Yr T, rt ) + I(y/> rt ) + g. Here we have written the tax and government spending variables as constants, which they must be (with no growth in population) for a steady state. Solving this last equation for rh we then obtain (9) where the g and T values are suppressed for notational simplicity. Our next task is to bring the IS and LM equations together as in the various diagrams of Chapter 5. That task is rendered more difficult by the appearance of R t in (8) and r, in (9), but this problem can be overcome by means of expression (6). From (6) we· know that R, r, + 1Tr, so we can substitute (9) into the latter and obtain Rr = O(Yr) + 1T1• f'(n) = ; , Since we are now assuming that there is no change in population or technology as time passes, we can use the final three of these to determine the values of y t, n" and ~/ Pr that will prevail in our steady state. Note that in doing this, however, we are implicitly assuming that 6 Note that it is unimportant whether the log P, path is drawn above or below log M, in Figure 6-2; the relative vertical locations depend on the units of measurement of the economy's single commodity and are therefore arbitrary. (8) (10) For a given value of 1Tr, then, equations (8) and (10) may be solved for Rr and Pr since Mr is exogenously set by the policy authorities and Yt is given as y*. Graphically, we proceed as shown in Figure 6-3. There the vertical axis measures R r , so the LM curve is plotted as usual. Then the function 7 This is demonstrated formally in the analysis of Section 3.3. The basic idea can. however, be expressed very simply as follows: since the nominal interest rate paid on money is zero and that on "bonds" is R" the difference between these is R,. Similarly, the real interest rate on money is 0 -1r, = -11', while the real rate on bonds is R, 1r" so the difference between these is also R,. It is R" therefore. that measures the marginal opponunity cost of holding wealth in the form of money, which is the relevant determinant. 116 6 Steady Inflation 6.4 Comparative Steady States 117 R, !l(y,) + "-, !l(y) +,,!l(y,) L-____________________________ y, !l(y) L-________-L_________________ y, y' Figure 6-3 Figure 6-4 O( Yt) is drawn in place; it shows where the IS curve would be if 7Tt were equal to zero. Finally, the actual IS curve is obtained by adding vertically the quantity 7Tt to this last curve at each point, as suggested by (10). The relevant intersection occurs at point A. To depict a steady-state equilibrium we modify the analysis of Figure 6-3 in three ways. First, we recognize that steady-state output will be given as y*, so the relevant intersection (like point A) must lie on a vertical line through y*. Second, the value of y, R, 7T, and M/ P are recognized to be constant over time. 8 Third, the value of 7T must be the same as ~ log Pr, and for M / P to be constant ~ log Pr must be the same as f.L. Consequently, 7T = f.L in the steady state with no output growth. 9 Recognizing these modifications, we can depict a situation of steady-state equilibrium with an inflation rate of 7T = f.L as shown in Figure 6-4. Here the value of R is determined by the intersection of the IS curve R = O(y) + 7T and the vertical line y = yO. The LM curve must of course pass through that same point. So the role of the LM relation is--just as in the static analysis of Section 5.6-only to determine the value of real money balances M/P, given y and R. With M exogenous, that value determines the price level. The main conclusion of the foregoing is that we have been able to assemble the components of our model in a way that is internally consistent. This verifies, then, that Pr does indeed grow at the rate f.L in the steady state, as conjectured above. Figure 6-4 provides, conse8 We have already discussed why y and 'Tr will be constant. That R must be constant is a consequence of the fact that " must be constant-which will be explained in Section 6.6-and that R, = r, + 'Tr,. Then with y and R constant, M/ P will be con. stant by equation (8). 9 If y is growing because of technical progress or population growth, then p. WIll grow less rapidly than M,. This will be explained in Section 6.6. quently, a representation of a steady-state equilibrium. The latter differs from a static equilibrium in that the values of M and Pare continually changing from period to period. In particular, they are growing at the rate f.L, that is, ~ log Pr = ~ log Mt = f.L. This fact can be emphasized by appending to Figure 6-4 a companion diagram that would look exactly the same as Figure 6-2. 6.4 Comparative Steady States The main purpose of a diagram like Figure 6-4 is to facilitate the comparison of different steady states, just as the main purpose of a static equilibrium diagram like Figure 5-14 is to serve as a prelude to static equilibria comparisons such as that of Figure 5-15. Accordingly, we shall now carry out, as an example, a graphical analysis of a comparison of two steady states. This is done in Figure 6-5. There the initial steady-state equilibrium is one in which the money stock growth rate is f.L0, while the second (steady-state) equilibrium is with a higher money growth rate, f.Ll. The . t he value of y* is not affected by the change 0 f f.L from f.L to f.L 1 , nor IS position of the O(y) curve. Thus the relevant IS curve in terms of the nominal interest rate is higher in the second steady state: O(u) + 7T 1 lies above O(y) + 7T O• The equilibrium value of the nominal interest rate is therefore higher also; Rl > RO. Indeed, since the real interest rate r is determined by the intersection of r = O(y) and y = y*, it is the same in the two steady-state equilibria; consequently, R 1 exceeds RO by the same amount as 7T 1 exceeds 7T O, which is in turn the amount by ° 118 6 Steady Intlation 6.4 Comparative Steady States 119 R L-_ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ ~ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ Tlrne I...-_ _ _ _ _ _...L.-_ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ y y' Figure 6-5 which JLl exceeds JL o. The higher is the money growth rate, therefore, the higher is the nominal interest rate-and by the same amount. One of the main implications of the analysis in Figure 6-5 is that the value of real money balances in the second steady-state equilibrium is smaller than in the first; that is, (M/ p)1 < (M/ P)o. That this must be so is clear from consideration of the diagram-where fi(y*) + 71"1 is above fi(y*) + 71"°-since the position of the LM curve is farther to the right the higher the M / P. Thus in a comparison of steady states, the one with the higher growth rate of the nominal money stock will feature a smaller quantity of real money balances held by the economy's individuals! This somewhat paradoxical conclusion is one of the key propositions of neoclassical monetary analysis. The comparison of steady-state equilibria in Figure 6-5 may be further investigated by means of a companion diagram that plots time paths of log M t and log Pr. In Figure 6-6 it is assumed that the initial steady state (with JL JL o) prevails for time periods up to t t+. Then at time t+ the growth rate of M, changes to JLl. This is represented in Figure 6-6 by the increased slope of the log M, path for periods after t+,IO The time paths for log F; in the initial and final steady states are also shown in Figure 6-6. Since M/ P is constant in each of these 10 While the growth rate changes abruptly at [ [T, the value of the money stock M, itself does not jump upward or downward at that instant in the example depicted. Figure 6-6 steady-state equilibria, the slope of log PI is the same as the slope of log M/ in both cases. But since the value of M / P is smaller in the final equilibrium (as emphasized in the preceding paragraph) the height of the log Pr path must be higher, relative to the height of the log M, path, reflecting an increased value of P/ M. From the way in which the log Pr path is drawn in Figure 6-6, it appears that the price level jumps upward in a discontinuous fashion at time t+. This aspect of the diagram should not be taken literally, however, for the diagram is intended only to describe the comparison of steady-state positions. Although our analytical apparatus tells us a good deal about this comparison, it does not tell us enough to permit any reliable description of the transition between the initial and final steady states. In this respect, comparative steady-state analysis is similar to comparative statics: we do not know how the system behaves dynamically during the transition from one equilibrium to another. In particular, it is possible that the time path of F; would move toward the new steady-state path only gradually, as indicated by the dashed curve in Figure 6-6 rather than by jumping upward at t*, But notice that if this is the case, then during the transition F; must grow Jaster than Mt for some time. An increase in the money growth rate will, therefore, require either a jump in the price level or an inflation rate that temporarily exceeds the new (higher) money growth rate. Analogously, a sustained decrease in an economy's money growth rate requires either an abrupt fall in the price level or an interval of time 120 6 Steady Inflation 6.5 Analysis with Real-Balance Effects during which the inflation rate is lower than the new (lowered) money growth rate. These last statements depend, it should be said, on the assumption that there is no upward or downward jump in the level of the money stock-no discontinuity in the MI path. For if there were an appropriate downward jump in M I , then ~ would not have to jump upward for M/~ to fall as required. In addition, it should be pointed out that our analysis assumes that the change in the money growth rate that takes place at t+ comes as a complete surprise to the economy's private individuals. In each period before t+ they confidently believe that the money growth rate will continue to equal J.L0 indefinitely. If the change from J.L0 to J.L! at t+ were foreseen, the price level would begin to rise toward its new steady-state path before the change in .1 log MI actually occurs. To conclude this section, it may be useful to emphasize the importance of distinguishing clearly between statements pertaining to the properties of one steady state and statements comparing alternative steady states. In particular, while growth rates of all variables in a given steady state are constant over time, these may change if the economy moves to a different steady state. In the first steady state of Figures 6-5 and 6-6, for example, .1 log ~ is constant at the value J.L0 . In the second steady state it is again constant, but at a different value, namely J.Ll . If one wants to say that some variable will have the same value in different steady states, the proper terminology is not "constant" but "invariant across steady states." 6.5 Analysis with Real-Balance Effects In footnote 15 and Problem 5 of Chapter 5, the possibility was mentioned that households' consumption choices depend positively on their real wealth, in addition to the y and r determinants. In particular, the consumption function c = C( y - 'T,', M / P) was introduced, with M / P reflecting the monetary component of real wealth held by households. That change in specification gives rise, by way of analysis paralleling that of Section 5.2 and 6.3, to an IS function of the form '1 = n( ~) + Yl, 7Tt , 121 R Figure 6-7 different values of J.L = 1T). That is, the classical model ceases to have the property of "superneutrality," to use a term that is often employed to describe a model in which all real variables except M / P are independent of the inflation rate. To demonstrate graphically that supemeutrality does not prevail when the "real-balance effect" is important,l1 consider Figure 6-7. There each of the IS functions includes M/P as an argument, as required by (ll). Thus when an increase in the money growth rate increases 7T from 7T O to 7T!, the resulting decrease in M/ P itself tends to cause the IS curve to shift to the left. This type of shift also pertains to n(y, M/ which locates the position of the IS cur~e in the absence of inflation.! Thus the decrease in M/P to (M/p)1 shifts the n(y,M/p) curve leftward and drives its intersection with y y* downward. This implies that the real interest rate ,1 is lower than ,0, as suggested PI' (11) where now n is a function of two variables. With the classical model thus modified, it ceases to be true that the real interest rate, will be the same in steady-state equilibria with different inflation rates (i.e., 11 A model is said to feature a "real-balance effect" when the consumption function includes M/ P as an argument. This term was used extensively by Patinkin (1965). 12 Note that l.1[ y', (MIP)O) in Figure 6-7 does not, however. refer to the zero inflation equilibrium, for (M/P)O corresponds to the value of real balances that obtams with 11. 11.0 > O. 122 6 Steady Inflation above.13 The nominal rate increases, but by less than the difference bet",:e~n p,°.and p,I. Whether this type of effect is of major importance emp~n.~lly IS unclear, but the reader should be aware of the theoretical pOSSIbIlIty. 6.6 Analysis with Output Growth All of the foregoi~g discussion in this chapter has been conducted under the ass~mptlOn that real output is constant over time. In most actual economIes, b~ contrast, output tends to grow as time passes. We need, then, to consIder how the analysis must be modified to reflect that fact. 14 In thi.s context it is useful to distinguish three possible reasons for growth In aggregate output. They are ~!) Growth of population (and, therefore, labor supply). (ll) Growth of the capital stock. (iii) Technical progress (I.e., an increase in the amount of output possible from given inputs of labor and capital). B~ far the simpl~st case t.o analyze is the one in which only (i) applIes-all ~rowth IS due to Increased population. In this case we can proceed by sImplr reinterpreting ail the equations and diagrams above so that the quantIty measures (I.e., y, n, c, M, etc.) are understood to refer to per capita va.lues rather than aggregates. Then, with p, being understood as ref~rnng to t~e growth rate of the money stock per person, t~e equatIons and dIagrams continue to be applicable. For example, If the population (and output) growth rate were 0.02, and the total money stock growth rate were 0.10, the per capita value for p, would be.O.08. This would be the steady-state value of 7T and R would exceed r In t~e steady state by 0.08 (i.e., by 8 percent). If growth In the capital stock occurs, however, matters become somewhat mo!e c~mphcated. Within a single steady state there is no need for n:odlficatlOn of the analysis in the absence of technical progress, for III that case the steady-state condition requires that total 13 If we were permitting the capital stock to change across steady states, the lower value .of r would Induce a greater value of k. This would in turn permit a greater quantity of output for any given input of labor. ' , 14 For a useful discussion, see Barro and Fischer (1976). 6.6 Analysis with Output Growth 123 15 capital and labor must grow at the same rate. Thus the quantity of capital can be thought of in per capita terms and the argument of the preceding paragraph can be repeated. But for comparisons across steady states, this type of argument will be valid only if the values of the capital/labor ratio are not different in the two steady-state equilibria. If the model is of the simpler type discussed in Section 6.4, that condition may be satisfied. But if real-balance effects are important, as discussed in Section 6.5, the different steady states may feature different real interest rates, and these will correspond to different values of the capital stock per person (or per unit of labor). Consequently, valid comparative steady-state analysis cannot be conducted by means of the per capita reinterpretation device. A more extensive overhaul of the analysis is needed. When technical progress is recognized, full-fledged steady-state analysis is still more complex. Indeed, unless the technical progress is of a special type known as Harrod-neutral (or "labor augmenting"), steady-state growth is not possible. For an excellent discussion of this and related topics, the reader is referred to Solow (1970). There is a useful result that can easily be obtained, however, without going into the complexities of steady-state analysis that recognizes capital accumulation and technical progress. In particular, suppose that the aggregate (not per capita) money demand function is of the form M, - = L(y"R1), (12) r: where Mt and YI refer to aggregate magnitudes, and suppose that aggregate output grows steadily (for whatever reason) at the rate 11. Then we can show that if a steady-state equilibrium prevails, the inflation rate will be p, 1'1", where 1'1 is the elasticity of L with respect to y,. The best way to see that is to consider an approximation to L(y" R t ) of the Cobb-Douglas form e'Y°y/1R,Y', where 1'1 is the elasticity in question. 16 Then taking logs, we have (13) log M, log = 1'0 + 11 log y, + 12 log R, or, equivalently, Ll log M, - Lllog 11 Ll log y, + 12 Lllog R,. (14) r: r: 15 Output is given by y, F(n" k,), and the function F is typically assumed to. be homogeneous of degree 1. That property implies tha~ t!Je rate of output growth IS a weighted average of the growth rates of n, and k,. But It IS shown In footnote 17 that k, must grow at the same rate as output-so fI, must do the same. . 16 This is, of course, the form suggested by equation (20) of Chapter 3. We could Just as well use instead the form given by equation (26) of Chapter 3, which corresponds more closely to the analysis in Chapters 7 and 8. 124 6 Steady Inflation 6.7 Now in our steady state it is true that Illog Rr = 0,17 Illog Yt = v, and Illog Me = I.L by assumption. Equation (14) then shows that Il log F; = I.L 'Yl v, The Welfare Cost of Inflation 125 R (15) which is the result stated above. 6.7 The Welfare Cost of Inflation The analysis of the preceding sections suggests that the pace of a steady, anticipated inflation has little effect on the values of most real variables including per capita income, consumption, and the real rate of interest. To help bring out the main points, let us ignore growth and suppose that there is no significant real-balance effect, in which case the above-mentioned variables are entirely unaffected by the rate at which steady inflation proceeds. A natural question to ask, then, is whether the rate of inflation is of any consequence in terms of the welfare of the society's individuals. After all, these individuals care-as we have emphasized in several places-only about real magnitudes. So why should inflation be of any concern whatsoever, provided that it is steady and anticipated? From a practical perspective, actual inflation is of importance largely because it is usually irregular in pace and largely unanticipated. But in response to the foregoing question, which is of considerable theoretical interest, we note that there is one real variable that is not invariant to the inflation rate but, instead, takes on different values across alternative steady states with different rates of money creation and inflation. In particular, the level of real money balances depends negatively, as Figure 6-5 illustrates, on the prevailing inflation rate. But that suggests that there are welfare effects of inflation, for a relatively small level of real balances implies that a relatively large amount of time and energy must be devoted to "shopping" for any given level of spending. Since leisure is desired by individuals, it follows that higher steady inflation rates lead to lower utility levels for society's individuals. 17 It was promised above that we would explain why the real rate of interest must be constant in a steady state (thereby implying that R, will also be constant). Roughly speaking, the idea is that consumption and investment must grow at the same rate for their sum (and thus output) to grow at a constant rate. (Why? If one .grew at a faster rate, its share in output would increase, so output growth would Increase). Also, investment and capital must grow at the same rate, because of theIr re~atlonsh1p. Thus capital must grow at the same rate as output-the capItal/output ratIo must be co~­ stant. But this implies a constant marginal product of cal?ltal, and the latter IS m equilibrium equal to the real rate of interest. For more detaIls, see Solow (1970). L - - - - -____ ~~L- __________ ~ __ m Figure 6·8 In light of the foregoing conclusion, it is of considerable interest to develop a technique for measuring the magnitude of the welfare cost of a steady, anticipated inflation. The approach that we shall take, which was introduced by Bailey (1956), utilizes a type of reasoning that is associated with "consumer surplus" analysis in the areas of public finance and applied microeconomics. 18 For our purposes, the crucial point is that the height of any demand curve indicates the value to buyers of incremental units of the commodity in question. In the context of money demand, the relevant demand curve plots real balances demanded, m = M/ P, on the horizontal axis and the nominal interest rate, R, on the vertical axis, as in Figure 6-8. The nominal interest rate is relevant because it represents the opportunity cost to the holder of an incremental unit of money. If the prevailing interest rate is RO and real money holdings are m O, for example, a one-unit increase in m will require money holders to sacrifice RO units per period in the form of forgone interest. 19 Rational individuals would not be holding money, thereby sacrificing interest, unless they were receiving some benefits from the money balances held. But our analysis in Chapter 3 tells us what these benefits are; they are the time and energy that do not need to be devoted to 18 For a textbook exposition of consumer surplus analysis, see Varian (1987, Chap. 15). An extension and correction of Bailey's analysis is provided by Tower (1971 ), 19 If the price level has the units of dollars per bushel, then m = M/ P has the units of bushels, If the interest rate R is expressed as an annual rate, then R bushels per year must be given up for a one-bushel increase in m. Alternatively. R dollars per year must be given up for a $1 increase in m. 126 6 Steady Inflation 6.7 The Welfare Cost of Inflation R Figure 6·9 shopping because of the transaction-facilitating services provided by money. For any particular change in the level of money holdings, moreover, the change in these benefits (the volume of these services) can be calculated by summing the incremental benefits. Since those incremental benefits are represented by the height of the demand curve, the relevant sum for any change is represented by the area under the demand curve between the initial and final positions. 2o If, for example, money holdings increased from mO to m 1 in Figure 6-8, the additional transaction-facilitating services to money holders would be quantitatively represented by the shaded area under the curve between mO and mi. Conversely, if money holdings were reduced from m 1 to m O, that area would measure the reduction in money services (or the increase in time and energy devoted to shopping). N'ow consider an economy experiencing a steady inflation at the rate TTl, as depicted in Figure 6-9, and suppose that this economy is one in which superneutrality prevails. The quantity of real money balances is ml, which is smaller than the quantity mO that would be held if the inflation rate were zero. The transaction-facilitating services are accordingly less-more time and energy are devoted to shopping-and the reduced magnitude of these services is measured by the shaded area. 20 For a smooth demand curve, the argument is like that employed in the definition of a definite integral. Thus we visualize many narrow rectangles (under the curve) of common width. and consider the sum of their areas in the limit as the width of each rectangle approaches zero and the area enclosed by the rectangles approaches that under the smooth curve. 127 Thus this area represents the social cost of steady, anticipated inflation at the rate 7T I in the economy under consideration. One aspect of this result needs a bit of discussion. It is fairly eas~ to see that anticipated inflation reduces the volume of monetary servIces and decreases the welfare of money holders. But are there no other effects that need to be considered? In answer, it is necessary to recognize that the foregoing analysis assumes that newly created ~oney is turned over by the monetary authority to the gov~rnment, ~hlch then distributes it to households as transfer payments (1.e., negative taxes). In addition, the analysis assumes that these transfers are paid i~ a lump-sum fashion, that is, in such a :vay th.at any househol~'s behaVIOr has no influence on the amount that It receives. An alternative assumption regarding the way that money enters the economy will be considered toward the end of this section. For the present, let us retain the assumption that m~mey e~ters via lump-sum transfers and carry out a numerical calcul~t.lon deSigned to illustrate the general magnitude of welfare losses ansmg from steady inflation according to the analysis illustrated in Figure 6-9. For the purpose of this example, again suppose that the aggregate money demand function has the form log m = ')'0 + ')'1 log Y + 'Y2 log R and that the values of the elasticities are ')'1 = 1 and 'Y2 we have, equivalently, that (16) -0.2. Then which can be solved for R: (18) Now suppose that in the absence of inflation the rate of interest is R = r 0.03 and the ratio Ylm is 6. 21 Then to satisfy (18), the value of e'l1l must be 0.08266. With this demand function, let us calculate the welfare loss from a steady inflation rate of 10 percent per year, which makes R = 0.03 + 0.10 = 0.13. First, we find that Ylm would rise to 8.04. Then we arbitrarily set y = 1, which means that our calculated loss will be expressed as a fraction of one year's GNP. With this convention we have a value of mO 0.1667 with zero inflation and m 1 = 0.1244 with 10 percent inflation. The problem, then, is to evaluate the definite 21 For the United States, the ratio of nominal GNP to nominal Ml was about 5.96 in 1987. 128 6 Steady Inflation 6.7 The Welfare Cost of Inflation integral 0.1667 (0.08266)5 dm. J 0.1244 (19) m The steps are as follows: 0.082665 0.01667 J 0.1244 m~5 dm = 0.0000039 • [0.166T 4 - 0.1244~4] -4 0.0000039[1295 -=-44176] = 0.0028. (20) The answer, therefore, is that a 10 percent inflation rate leads to a social cost equivalent to just under three-tenths of 1 percent of GNP. If, instead, we considered an inflation rate of 100 percent per year, the result would turn out to be 2.0 percent of GNP. Clearly, the magnitude of the cost that we have calcul~ted is very small for inflation rates of the magnitude experienced In most developed countries in recent years. 22 We shall return to that point later, but first we need to consider two other topics. The first of these is the assumption, implicit in the discussion to this point that "money" is a homogeneous entity that pays no interest to its hold~rs. In fact, of course, the M1 money stock in the United States is composed of three types of assets: currency, demand deposits, and OCDs (i.e., other checkable deposits). The last of t?e~e, mor~ov~r, pays interest to its holders. Accordingly, a more reahstIc quantitative analysis of the cost of a steady inflation would have to take account of that heterogeneity. 23 The other topic concerns the way in which money enters the economy or, to express the matter differently, th~ interaction .of money creation with fiscal policy. Instead of our prevIous assumption, let us now suppose that the government uses money creation as a sour~e of revenue. Thus we imagine that the government uses newly pnnted currency not to make lump-sum transfer payments, but to finance part of its purchases of goods and services. 24 In this case, the creation of 22 It should be kept in mind, however, that Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, and Israel have recently experienced much higher inflation rates (but not steadIly). 23 Since OeDs do not pay as much interest as safe short-!erm assets su,:h as Treasury bills the difference in these rates is the relevant opportumty cost for thIS component. Taking account of such complications would probably yield even smaller estimates of the cost of steady inflation. . 24 This way of describing the process presumes that ~he monetary al!thon~y turns newly printed currency over to the government. In actuality, the process IS a little less blatant. But the effects would be the same if the government were to sell bonds to banks and the monetary authority were then to create high-powered money to keep bank reserves from falling. 129 money (and the associated inflation) yields some benefit to household (or firms) since the extra revenue enables the government to reduce its tax collections without reducing government purchases. Inflation still imposes a cost by bringing about a reduced level of real money holdings, but also provides a benefit in the form of reduced tax collections. In this situation the appropriate way to formulate the cost-ofinflation question is as follows. Suppose that the rate of government purchases is given. These purchases must be financed in some way, either by an explicit tax of some type or by money creation (i.e., revenue from inflation).25 Each type of tax has some distorting effect that imposes a cost on society, just as money creation does. The problem is to design a package of revenue sources so as to minimize the cost to society of raising the total revenue needed to finance government purchases. Basic marginal reasoning indicates that a necessary condition for this minimization to occur is that, at the margin, the cost to society per dollar of revenue be the same for each revenue source that is utilized to any positive extent. If a possible source has a high cost per dollar of revenue even when used to a small extent, it will be optimal not to make use of that source. It is possible to show that, for revenue from inflation (money creation), the marginal cost per dollar of revenue is given by the following expression: 26 _d_c_os_t ____11-=--__ d rev 1 - 11(TT/R) (21) Here 11 stands for the absolute value of the elasticity of money demand with respect to the interest rate: 1) = 1'2 = -(dm/dR)R/m. Since TT/ R == 0 when the inflation ratio is zero, but becomes positive and rises toward 1.0 as higher inflation rates are considered, expression (21) equals 11 for a zero inflation rate and exceeds 11 for higher values of TT. Accordingly, if the actual value of 11 is about 0.2, as assumed in our numerical example, then the cost per dollar of revenue raised by inflation is rather high. If the cost of raising government revenue is less than 20 cents per dollar for taxes such as the income tax, the property tax, or any specific excise tax, then it would be efficient not to use inflation (money creation) as a source of revenue. 25 We abstract from the possibility of government borrowing, which amounts to finance by means of taxes to be collected in the future. 26 This formula was described by Marty (1976). To show that it is valid, note that since the cost of inflation is f R dm. the marginal value is - R dm = + 11') dm. The marginal revenue from a change in the steady rate is d(m1T) mdlT mim. Thus the ratio, which gives the marginal cost per unit of revenue, is -(r + 1T) dm/d7r divided by m + mlm/d7r. Inserting -mTJ/R for dm/d7r = dm/dR and rearranging, one can obtain expression (21). 130 6 Steady Inflation 6.8 Concluding Comments In this chapter. we have introduced tools appropriate for the analysis of a steady, ongomg (and hence anticipated) inflation and have developed several key results of such analysis. Although actual inflations are usually unsteady in their pace and not completely anticipated, most of the points developed can be extremely useful in thinking about actual experiences. One good example is provided by the result of Section 6.4 that a sustained decrease in an economy's inflation rate requires either ~n ab.rupt fall.in the price level or an interval of time during which the mflatlOn rate IS lower than the new money growth rate. The result is highly pertinent to the experience of the United States during the years 1984-1986, when inflation was unusually low in relation to money growth. In conclusion, something should be said regarding the numerical ~esul~s of .Section 6.7, as they suggest that a moderate amount of steady mflatlOn Imposes extremely small costs on society. Do these results imply that it is rather foolish for people to dislike inflation intensely, as many seem to do? A full response to that question would require a book of its own, but three brief comments can be made. First, some of the popular dislike of inflation probably does involve a lack of understanding, as when a worker blames inflation for rising prices of things that he purchases but attributes increases in his nominal wages to his own diligence and skill. This type of illusion may affect attitudes without having any impact on economic behavior. Second, in actual economies substantial inflation is (as mentioned before) almost never steady or accurately anticipated. Consequently, there may be major distributional effects, involving wealth losses for creditors and wealth gains for debtors, whenever debts are specified in nominal units. Such redistributions do not affect aggregate wealth or income yet may reasonably be regarded as socially undesirable. Third, the possibility of achieving substantial private rewards from inflation may induce both households and fir~s to. devote valuable human resources to the task of predicting future mflatlOn rates. Also, because tax schedules are often specified in terms of nominal magnitudes, resources may be devoted to activities designed to minimize tax payments, activities that would be unnecessary in the absence of inflation. 27 In both cases, these resources are be!ng allocated to activities that are socially wasteful as they yield neIther goods nor services that give utility to the economy's individuals. For the reasons mentioned in these last two comments, and others 27 The specification of tax schedules in nominal terms can lead to resource misallocations even when inflation is anticipated. as Feldstein (1983) emphasizes. References 131 discussed by Fischer and Modigliani (1978), it is likely that even mild inflations are highly undesirable in terms of the welfare of individuals in actual economies. Problems 1. Consider a classical economy in which the full employment rate of output is Yt = 200, the money demand function is MtlPt = 0.3 YtlRt, and saving-investment behavior satisfies Y, = 250 - 1000 r" (Here and RI are real and nominal interest rates, measured in fractional units.) If the central bank creates money at a rate of 10 percent per period, what will be the steady-state values of the nominal interest rate and the real quantity of money? 2. Explain the meaning of the aphorism "the faster money is created, the less there is." It will be helpful to utilize a plot of R versus Y and an associated diagram with time on the horizontal axis. 3. Verify the calculated welfare cost of a 100 percent inflation rate in the numerical example of Section 6.7. 4. Consider the economy represented in Figure 6-9. Suppose that a slight deflation is created by the monetary authority, so that the nominal rate of interest R falls below the real rate, r. Will this deflation improve welfare, under the assumptions made for Figure 6-9, relative to the zero-inflation steady state? What is the optimum rate of inflation? Compare your answer with that given by Milton Friedman, as described by Barro and Fischer (1976, p. 144). 'I References Bailey, Martin J., "The Welfare Cost of Inflationary Finance," Journal of Political Economy 64 (April 1956), 93-110. Bailey, Martin J., National Income and the Price Level, 2nd ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1971). Barra, Robert J., Macroeconomics. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1984). Barra, Robert J., and Stanley Fischer, "Recent Developments in Monetary Theory," Journal of Monetary Economics 2 (April 1976), 133-67. Feldstein, Martin, Inflation, Tax Rules, and Capital Formation. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983). Fischer, Stanley, and Franco Modigliani, "Towards an Understanding of the Real Effects and Costs of Inflation," Weltwirtschaftsliches Archiv 114 (1978), 810-33. Marty, Alvin L., "A Note on the Welfare Cost of Money Creation," Journal of Monetary Economics 2 (January 1976), 121-24.