Uploaded by harripaulrehannah

The Role of Public Participation in Envi

advertisement
Hindy Lauer Schachter, Editor
Stephen W. Kleinschmit
North Carolina State University
he Role of Public Participation in Environmental Book Reviews
Governance
Judith A. Layzer, Natural Experiments: EcosystemBased Management and the Environment. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2008). 292 pp. $29.00
(paper), ISBN: 9780262622141.
John M. Whiteley, Helen Ingram, and Richard Warren
Perry, eds., Water, Place, and Equity. (Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press, 2008). 318 pp. $25.00 (paper),
ISBN: 9780262731911.
P
erhaps the greatest challenge of Western
civilization is to perpetuate personal liberty
and economic expansion in the face of collective societal needs and the constraints of the natural
world. Jared Diamond noted in Collapse (2005) that
societies often choose to make decisions that are
detrimental to their long-term interest. With the
advancement of technology and improvement in our
collective understanding of environmental systems,
the study of natural resource administration has taken
a more scientific and interdisciplinary approach to
mitigating environmental degradation. he two works
reviewed here examine the study of natural resource
management with an eye toward helping us meet this
great challenge.
Natural Experiments is an assessment of ecosystembased management (EBM), a natural resource
management methodology that arose in the late
1970s and 1980s. EBM utilizes landscape-scale landuse planning initiatives to overcome a fragmented
and disjointed approach to environmental resource
protection across multiple jurisdictional boundaries.
he work provides a critical assessment of EBM in
practice through the use of seven case studies; each
takes a decidedly qualitative approach to acquiring
information. he end result is a rather interesting and
thought-provoking challenge to our perceptions about
participatory governance structures.
EBM emerged as a new form of governance in
response to centralized management schemes that
lacked the flexibility or ability to adapt to the
contextual issues of individual locales, and also “ignored the interrelationships among natural systems
elements” (1). To counter these shortcomings, EBM
initiatives began to sprout up across the country.
Judith A. Layzer lists three core characteristics of these
plans: a landscape-scale focus, collaborative planning including stakeholder involvement, and flexible,
adaptive implementation of planning goals. hese
core characteristics became the basis for optimistic
and pessimistic models of EBM. he optimistic model
generally assumes a fair, consensus-based approach in
which stakeholders develop mutual concerns, work
toward common goals, and produce processes that
will enhance environmental protection better than
other management schemes. he pessimistic model
emphasizes the various pathologies of consensus-based
regulatory management (Coglianese 2001)—asymmetric power relationships among stakeholders,
self-interested actors, the lack of political will, and
the lack of elevation or even parity of environmental
concerns to economic and political considerations.
In line with general performance-based management
systems theory, the case studies use outcome-focused
evaluation criteria.
Stephen W. Kleinschmit is a doctoral
student in public administration in the
School of Public and International Affairs at
North Carolina State University. His research
interests include land-use planning reform,
environmental management, and cumulative impact assessment.
E-mail: swkleins@ncsu.edu
A theme that emerges across chapters 3–6 is the
considerable disparity in professionalization and
resource availability among stakeholders, which has
the effect of favoring private development interests
over public interest environmental organizations in
deliberations, particularly in reference to the capacity
to retain or provide legal representation (48). While
consensus-based approaches were initiated with the
intent of reducing conflict, they undermine the validity of the plan, as the ultimate goal of providing a
truly sustainable ecosystem is displaced in the interest
of gaining consensus. What was intended to be a cooperative forum for negotiation instead devolves into
competition, in which stakeholders seek to use their
advantages to dominate others. What emerges from
these deliberations is an accord beset with satisficing;
none of the stakeholders has their goals fulfilled, and
some resort to external processes to undermine the
Book Reviews 303
agreements through the use of political influence or
litigation. What emerges are minimally protective
plans that are easy to undermine.
Chapters 7–9 examine case studies that utilize the
ecosystem-based management approach, but dispense with much of the collaborative processes that
plagued early attempts at EBM. he author notes that
although public input was solicited in these cases,
the process was not intended to be collaborative. he
success of plans such as the Sonoran Desert Conservation Plan (chapter 7) was in part attributable to the
fact that “planners did not adhere to a central tenet of
ecosystem-based management: reliance on stakeholder
involvement” (202). he success of a plan because of
the outright rejection of a core assumption of EBM is
certainly worth noting.
he author challenges us to reconceptualize litigation as an indicator of success and not of failure.
Ecosystem-based management is an inherently political undertaking; landscape-scale planning initiatives
can encompass a large number of potentially affected
parties, each with different (and often conflicting)
values. In such a system, it is perhaps impossible to
avoid conflict, as it is likely that measures will have to
“impose substantial costs on some interests” to achieve
“genuine environmental improvements” (271). In
addition to resistance from private interests, groups
may even encounter institutional resistance from the
agencies themselves.
Layzer finds that traditional politics leads to the most
protective environmental management plans and that
“policymakers made fewer concessions to development or user interests” under this regime (271).
Likewise, when policy makers render a decision predicated on scientific assessment (rather than consensus),
they might not avoid litigation, but a stakeholder
should find that it is more difficult to discredit their
action than in participatory structures. he removal
of the regulatory “teeth” of a plan in an attempt to
avoid conflict is a failure of political leadership that
ultimately undermines the plan’s efficacy. It also does
not preclude the regulated entities from filing suits to
nullify the remaining tenets with which they disagree,
or from seeking the assistance of lawmakers to undermine the plan’s authority.
he entire concept of stakeholders included in a consensus-based framework begs consideration. Layzer
notes that in an effort to reach agreement, groups in
consensus-based decision making tend to include only
participants who are deemed “reasonable” and marginalize those whose views are considered “extreme”
(275). In terms of legal standing, theoretically, one
private entity is not afforded any additional standing
(other than perhaps right of ownership) than another,
so it is curious how groups justify additional criteria
304
Public Administration Review • March | April 2011
for inclusion in decision making. he penchant
for “perceived reasonableness” is disconcerting, as
environmental issues generally have not enjoyed the
same degree of salience as economic issues. he author
notes that this tendency to marginalize group members has a disproportionately detrimental effect on environmentalists, who then become “disadvantaged by
collaborative approaches” (275). he text suggests that
EBM plans are much more effective when stakeholder
input is encompassed within a format that encourages
the public provision of information, instead of deliberation within a consensus-based rulemaking process.
his helps advance a decision-making framework
predicated on technical merit, not the ability of a
group member to exercise power. What should emerge
is a management framework that remains cognizant of
its strategic goals and does not reward those who seek
to derail the initiative.
his text is not intended to challenge the concepts of
adaptive management; the author notes that it can
yield beneficial results, though only “when used in the
service of a single goal” (279). hroughout the work,
the author makes a convincing case that consensusbased approaches to environmental management
are almost certainly doomed to failure. his analysis
enjoins us to consider the wisdom of consensus-based
decision making in strategic (or landscape) planning
initiatives, and its lessons are easily devolved to the
realm of local land-use planning, which also suffer
from the same complications of ecological fragmentation, goal paradoxes, and goal displacement. he
author notes that the work is not intended to disparage the inclusion of stakeholders in the policy-making
process, but that such negotiation should occur within
a “hospitable context” (292).
Water, Place, and Equity is an examination of water
resources across the world, emphasizing the growing
potential for conflict and the ethics of allocation. he
contributors stress the theme of equity (or perhaps
more accurately, inequity) throughout the work;
detailed within its nine chapters are a myriad of problems faced by various societies across the globe. At
the root of many of these problems is the continuing
expansion of water consumption to the detriment of
disadvantaged populations and environmental sustainability. he work looks at the ethical and moral issues
associated with water use and posits their consideration in contrast to traditional market based conceptualizations of how resources are apportioned.
Hardin (1968) opined in “he Tragedy of the Commons” that conscience is self-eliminating: those who
heed the call to reduce demand would only have the
surplus of their previous allocation consumed by those
who lack this conscience. Why would one entity cede
the additional economic potential of an increased
water allocation (in the name of sustainability) when
doing so would only encourage others to waste? How,
then, are we to reward deference to the common good
when abusing the water commons is so rewarding?
incentivized and generally less susceptible to the collective action problems that plague voluntary citizen
groups.
Expanding on the premise of the economic potential
of water, Baer (chapter 7) studies the issue of privatization through the lens of Bolivian water politics.
he example of Cochabamba, Bolivia is notable in the
sense that it was “the first large-scale rejection of water
privatization in Latin America” (195). Privatization
was the strategy advanced by the World Bank under
the premise that it was the best method to help ensure
expanded service (in concert with other reforms) after
“years of fiscal mismanagement by military regimes”
(200) and as a response to abuse of the water commons. What emerges is a political catastrophe that
unravels the plan, driven ostensibly by the lack of
public input in the planning stages. While some
literature cites a lack of public input as a contributing factor to the failure of the plan, it seems that the
real criticism should be directed toward the policies
of the contractor, Aquas del Tunari. Substantial rate
increases, metering of private wells, and prohibitions on rainwater collection pushed a regressive fee
structure that stoked popular discontent. But perhaps
these policies committed a much more egregious error
by attempting to assert ownership of a resource that is
not inherently excludable.
While examining trends in Northwestern U.S. and
Western Canadian water management, Paul W. Hirt
(chapter 6, Water) denotes a “semicyclical” shift in
historical resource allocation regimes: from community control to market forces/economic elites, to political elites, a return to the markets, and eventually a
partial return to “community-based decision-making”
(178). Layzer suggests that an “appropriate scale for
addressing environmental problems” may not be the
same scale “at which participants most readily agree”
(289). Both seem to hint that the scale at which
environmental decision making is made expands and
contracts, and is an important determinant of the
efficacy of ecological management. his can be seen
as an indicator of the state of societal values, as to
whether environmental goals receive salience or parity
with economic or social goals.
hese two books contain common themes. he
concept of technocratic administration principles is
contained within both works. Layzer’s analysis reveals
greater efficacy in obtaining stated goals when policy
makers refuse to cede control of their technocratic
decision-making processes. Maria Carmen Lemos
(chapter 9 in Water) notes that Brazil has departed
from principles of technocracy, which are described
as “dysfunctional, insulated policymaking” (250), in
an attempt to “increase the level of equitable allocation, democratization, accountability and transparency of water management” (251). hese reforms are
conducted under the auspices of encouraging greater
participation and democratic reform, but they are also
susceptible to “elite capture of the decision making
processes” (252).
Both contradictory and confirmatory messages emerge
in the two works. Layzer’s lesson is that direct participation by self-interested private entities undermines
the efficacy of environmental management. Lemos
suggests that more participatory measures may
increase the “equitable” allocation of resources (251),
but admits that the devolution of resource allocation to the public will likely advance a structure that
will inevitably be dominated by those who have the
capacity to dominate the proceedings and exacerbate
power imbalances (252), consistent with Layzer. he
problem of capture thus complicates participatory
governance regimes, as economic interests are directly
Water, Place, and Equity takes a much more reflective
view of resource allocation than Natural Experiments,
in that the intrinsic hope of the work is to pursue
sustainability through a more just (and democratic)
allocation of goods in concert with progressive social
enlightenment. his speaks to a conservationist ethos
and harbors a conciliatory tone, which is exemplified
by its discussion of wise use and lengthy consideration
of the environmental justice movement. homas Clay
Arnold (chapter 1) challenges us to move past the
commodity driven western view of water and instead
supplant this conceptualization with the “moral
economy of water,” the ability of a community to
reconcile the “competing uses and meanings” (39) of
water as a component of not only economic development, but also of social and environmental systems.
Introducing the concept of a moral economy is a
thought-provoking framework with which to examine
competing values and helps create a more definitive
construct of equity.
Natural Experiments emphasizes a more ecological
basis of resource allocation, stressing the preservation
of threatened resources and remediation of degraded
lands. While they might in theory have similar results,
they sometimes have contradictory premises. In Natural Experiments, public participation is the problem.
In Water, Place, and Equity, it is part of the solution.
Perhaps the lesson is that a technocratic management
scheme is advantageous in a government that remains
politically accountable, and one predicated on public
participation is advantageous in areas that resource
allocation is one component of a larger goal of general
democratic reform.
A consideration extracted from both texts is that the
management of water resources is fundamentally
Book Reviews 305
different from that of other resources. Water does not
have the degree of abstraction and excludability of
physical property; its distributed collection makes it
much more difficult for parties to assert an absolute
right to its use. he effects of its degradation can also
be much more noticeable and sudden than slower,
incremental problems. It could be that participatory decision-making processes are more suited for
water resources than other forms of natural resource
management, particularly when they are able to elicit
broad social mobilization. In the face of an apathetic
citizenry or asymmetric deliberative processes, traditional political and technocratic procedures might be
a more useful means of protecting the public interest
than participatory democracy.
here are several lessons that are extracted from
comparing these texts. First, natural resource administrators must remain committed to the mission with
which they have been tasked, to avoid displacing the
goals of equity and sustainability with political expedience and finding agreement. he threat of litigation
should not cause decision makers to compromise or
be construed as failure. Second, managers need to be
cognizant of the motivations of participants in deciding what role the public should play in the decision-
306
Public Administration Review • March | April 2011
making process. A well-attended and truly inclusive
participatory process, in which actors are working
toward stated goals may increase the provision of
information and lead to better decision making. An
anticompetitive process that promotes elite capture
and the disparate provision of collective goods to private actors is generally undesirable. Decision makers
might also perceive the lack of greater public participation in their supposedly “democratic” process as
implied consent to perpetuate the existing management regime, instead of recognizing how the regime
might undermine participation in the first place.
Finally, administrators need to be cognizant that different resources have different meanings and values
attached to them, and thus the nature of management
must be tailored to the nature of the resource itself.
References
Coglianese, Cary. 2001. Is Consensus an Appropriate Basis for
Regulatory Policy? In Environmental Contracts, edited by Eric
W. Orts and Kurt Deketerlaere, 93–113. Boston: Kluwer Law
International.
Diamond, Jared. 2005. Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed. New York: Viking.
Hardin, Garrett. 1968. he Tragedy of the Commons. Science,
December 13, 1243–48.
Download