Uploaded by Makopoi Letsie

EECM3714 Lecture 10

advertisement
EECM 3714
Lecture 10: Unit 10
Returns to scale, homogeneity and partial elasticities
Renshaw, Ch. 17
21 April 2023
OUTLINE
• Returns to scale
• Homogeneity
• Partial elasticities
RETURNS TO SCALE (RTS)
• Consider the production function π‘ž = 𝑓(𝐾, 𝐿)
• Returns to scale is the property of the production
function that tells us what happens to output if both
inputs are increased by the same proportion
• E.g.: RTS tells us what happens to q if both K and L are
doubled
• Three possibilities:
• Constant returns to scale: doubling L and K doubles q
• Increasing returns to scale: doubling L and K more than
doubles q
• Decreasing returns to scale: doubling L and K less than
doubles q
• Page 558-571
RTS AND COBB-DOUGLAS PRODUCTION
• Suppose that production is Cobb-Douglas, π‘ž = 𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝐿𝛽
• Find RTS by summing 𝛼, 𝛽:
• 𝛼 + 𝛽 = 1 → constant returns to scale
• 𝛼 + 𝛽 > 1 → increasing returns to scale
• 𝛼 + 𝛽 < 1 → decreasing returns to scale
• Don’t confuse RTS with diminishing marginal productivity
• Recall that we show that a production function exhibits decreasing MP by showing that its second
derivative is negative
HOMOGENEOUS FUNCTIONS
• What if production is not Cobb-Douglas? How does one determine RTS?
• Determine if function is homogeneous; then determine the degree of homogeneity
• A function 𝑓 π‘₯, 𝑦 is said to be homogeneous if:
• 𝑓 πœ†π‘₯, πœ†π‘¦ = πœ†π‘Ÿ 𝑓(π‘₯, 𝑦), where πœ† is just a (any) constant
• π‘Ÿ is then said to be the degree of homogeneity
• A production function π‘ž = 𝑓(𝐾, 𝐿) is homogeneous if:
• 𝑓 πœ†πΎ, πœ†πΏ = πœ†π‘Ÿ 𝑓 𝐾, 𝐿 = πœ†π‘Ÿ π‘ž
• If production is homogeneous, then value of r is used to infer RTS
• π‘Ÿ = 1 → constant RTS
• π‘Ÿ > 1 → increasing RTS
• π‘Ÿ < 1 → decreasing RTS
. Page 561-570
TESTING FOR HOMOGENEITY
• Cobb-Douglas production: π‘ž = 𝐾 𝛼 𝐿𝛽
• Increase K and L by πœ†: πœ†πΎ
𝛼
πœ†πΏ
𝛽
= πœ†π›Ό 𝐾 𝛼 πœ†π›½ 𝐿𝛽 = πœ†π›Ό+𝛽 𝐾 𝛼 𝐿𝛽 = πœ†π›Ό+𝛽 π‘ž
• This function is homogeneous; degree of homogeneity is 𝛼 + 𝛽
• Linear production: π‘ž = π‘ŽπΎ + 𝑏𝐿
• Increase by πœ†: π‘Ž πœ† 𝐾 + 𝑏 πœ† 𝐿 = πœ† π‘ŽπΎ + 𝑏𝐿
• This function is homogeneous; degree of homogeneity is 1 = constant RTS
• Log production: π‘ž = π‘Ž ln 𝐾 + 𝑏 ln 𝐿
• Increase by πœ†: π‘ž = π‘Ž ln πœ†πΎ + 𝑏 ln πœ†πΏ
• = π‘Ž ln πœ† + ln 𝐾
+ 𝑏 ln πœ† + ln 𝐿
= π‘Ž + 𝑏 ln πœ† + π‘Ž ln 𝐾 + 𝑏 ln 𝐿
• This function is not homogeneous
• Test for homogeneity: multiply K and L by πœ†; try to factor the πœ† out.
• Self-check: is π‘ž =
𝛼𝐾𝛽
+ 1−𝛼
𝐿𝛽
1
ࡗ𝛽
homogeneous?
EXAMPLE
Suppose that a firm’s production function is π‘ž = 10𝐾 0.3 𝐿0.8 .
a.
Is this production function homogeneous?
b.
Does this function exhibit increasing, decreasing or constant returns to scale?
c.
Does this production function exhibit decreasing returns to capital and labour (i.e. diminishing marginal
productivity)?
SOLUTION
a. Homogeneity:
• 10 πœ†πΎ
0.3
πœ†πΏ
0.8
= 10πœ†0.3 𝐾 0.3 πœ†0.8 𝐿0.8 = 10πœ†1.1 𝐾 0.3 𝐿0.8 = 10πœ†1.1 π‘ž
• This function is homogeneous: π‘Ÿ = 1.1
b. Returns to scale:
• π‘Ÿ = 1.1 ⟹ 1.1 > 1 → increasing returns to scale
• OR: since the function is Cobb-Douglas: 𝛼 + 𝛽 = 0.3 + 0.8 = 1.1 > 1 → increasing RTS
c. Decreasing returns to labour:
•
πœ•2 π‘ž
πœ•πΏ2
= −1.6𝐾 0.3 𝐿−1.2 . This is negative for all values of K and L 𝐾 ≥ 0, 𝐿 ≥ 0
d. Decreasing returns to capital:
•
πœ•2 π‘ž
πœ•πΎ2
= −2.1𝐾 −1.7 𝐿0.8 . This is negative for all values of K and L 𝐾 ≥ 0, 𝐿 ≥ 0
EXAMPLE 2
Suppose π‘ž = 10[0.5𝐾 0.5 + 0.5𝐿0.5 ]0.5 .
Does this function exhibit increasing, decreasing or constant returns to scale?
Solution:
• First, check if function is homogenous ...
• 10[0.5 πœ†πΎ
0.5
+ 0.5 πœ†πΏ
0.5 ]0.5 =
• ⟹ 10 πœ†0.5 × 0.5𝐾 0.5 + 0.5𝐿0.5
10[0.5 πœ†0.5 × πΎ 0.5 + 0.5 πœ†0.5 × πΏ0.5 ]0.5
0.5
= 10πœ†0.25 × 0.5𝐾 0.5 + 0.5𝐿0.5
• Function is homogenous and degree of homogeneity is π‘Ÿ = 0.25
• Since 0.25 < 1, function exhibits decreasing returns to scale
0.5
= πœ†0.25 π‘ž
PARTIAL ELASTICITIES
• Recall that if 𝑦 = 𝑓(π‘₯), then 𝑒 𝑦 =
𝑑𝑦
𝑑π‘₯
×
π‘₯
𝑦
• Now suppose that 𝑧 = 𝑓(π‘₯, 𝑦). Now the partial elasticities of z w.r.t. x and y are:
πœ•π‘§
π‘₯
πœ•π‘§
𝑦
• 𝑒π‘₯𝑧 = πœ•π‘₯ × π‘§ ; and 𝑒𝑦𝑧 = πœ•π‘¦ × π‘§
• Note that these two elasticities can also be written as:
•
•
πœ•π‘§
πœ•π‘₯
𝑧
÷ π‘₯, i.e. marginal function (w.r.t. x) divided by average (w.r.t. x)
πœ•π‘§
πœ•π‘¦
𝑧
÷ 𝑦, i.e. marginal function (w.r.t. y) divided by average (w.r.t. y)
PARTIAL DEMANDELASTICITIES
• Suppose that demand is π‘ž 𝑑 = 𝑓(𝑝, 𝑝𝑧 , 𝑦), where 𝑝𝑧 , 𝑦 are the price of another product and the
income of consumers
• The partial demand elasticities are:
• price elasticity of demand, 𝑒 𝑝
• cross-price elasticity of demand, 𝑒 𝑧
• income elasticity of demand, 𝑒 𝑦
• Do examples 17.5 and 17.6
PRICE, CROSS PRICE AND INCOME ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
Price elasticity of demand is:
• 𝑒𝑝 =
πœ•π‘ž
πœ•π‘
×
𝑝
π‘ž
Income elasticity of demand is:
• 𝑒𝑦 =
πœ•π‘ž
πœ•π‘¦
×
𝑦
π‘ž
Interpretation:
Interpretation:
• If 𝑒 𝑝 > 1 → price elastic demand
• If 𝑒 𝑦 > 0, the good is a normal good
• If 𝑒 𝑝 < 1 → price inelastic demand
• If 𝑒 𝑝 = 1 → unit elastic demand
Cross-price elasticity of demand is:
• 𝑒𝑧 =
πœ•π‘ž
πœ•π‘π‘§
×
𝑝𝑧
π‘ž
Interpretation:
• If 𝑒 𝑧 < 0, the two products are complements
• If 𝑒 𝑧 > 0, the two products are substitutes
• If 0 < 𝑒 𝑦 < 1, the good is a necessity
• If 𝑒 𝑦 > 1, the good is a luxury
• If 𝑒 𝑦 < 0, the good is an inferior good
EXAMPLE 1
Suppose that the demand function is π‘žπ‘‘ = 1000 − 5𝑝 − 𝑝𝑧2 + 0.005𝑦 3 and 𝑝 = 15; 𝑝𝑧 = 20; 𝑦 =
100.
Find and interpret the
• Price elasticity of demand
• Cross-price elasticity of demand
• Income elasticity of demand
SOLUTION, 1
π‘ž 𝑑 = 1000 − 5𝑝 − 𝑝𝑧2 + 0.005𝑦 3 .
𝑝 = 15; 𝑝𝑧 = 20; 𝑦 = 100.
• So, π‘žπ‘‘ = 1000 − 5 15 − 202 + 0.005 100
• 𝑒𝑝 =
πœ•π‘ž
πœ•π‘
𝑝
π‘ž
× = −5 ×
15
5525
3
= 5525
= −0.014
• 𝑒 𝑝 = −0.014 = 0.014 < 1 → demand is price inelastic
• 𝑒𝑧 =
πœ•π‘ž
πœ•π‘π‘§
×
𝑝𝑧
π‘ž
= −2𝑝𝑧 ×
20
5525
= −2 20 ×
20
5525
= −0.145
• −0.145 < 0 → the two products are complements
• 𝑒𝑦 =
πœ•π‘ž
πœ•π‘¦
𝑦
π‘ž
× = 0.015𝑦 2 ×
100
5525
= 0.015 1002 ×
• 2.715 > 0 → the product is a normal good;
• 2.715 > 1 → the product is a luxury
100
5525
= 2.715
EXAMPLE 2
Suppose π‘žπ‘‘ = 10 + 5Τ𝑝 + 2 ln 𝑦 − 2𝑒 0.1𝑝𝑧 . Also suppose that 𝑝 = 2, 𝑦 = 100 and 𝑝𝑧 = 3.
a. Find and interpret:
• The price elasticity of demand
• The income elasticity of demand
• The cross-price elasticity of demand
SOLUTION
• = 10 + 5Τ𝑝 + 2 ln 𝑦 − 2𝑒 0.1𝑝𝑧
• So, π‘žπ‘‘ = 10 + 5Τ2 + 2 ln 100 − 2𝑒 0.1×3 = 11.9394 wrong correct
•
𝑒𝑝
=
πœ•π‘ž 𝑑
πœ•π‘
×
𝑝
π‘žπ‘‘
= −5𝑝−2 ×
2
11.9394
=
−5
23.8788
= −0.2094
• 𝑒 𝑝 = −0.2094 = 0.2094 < 1 →demand is price inelastic
•
𝑒𝑦
=
πœ•π‘ž 𝑑
πœ•π‘¦
×
𝑦
π‘žπ‘‘
2
𝑦
= ×
100
11.9394
=
2
11.9394
= 0.1675
• 𝑒 𝑦 = 0.1675 > 0 → normal good;
• 𝑒 𝑦 = 0.1675 < 1 → necessity
• 𝑒
𝑝𝑧
=
πœ•π‘ž 𝑑
πœ•π‘π‘§
×
𝑝𝑧
π‘žπ‘‘
= −0.2𝑒
0.1𝑝𝑧
×
𝑝𝑧
11.9394
=
−0.6𝑒 0.3
11.9394
= −0.0678
• 𝑒 𝑝𝑧 = −0.0678 < 0 → the two goods are complements
OTHER PARTIAL ELASTICITIES
Production elasticities:
• Labour elasticity of production (elasticity of production w.r.t. labour):
• 𝑒𝐿 =
πœ•π‘ž
πœ•πΏ
𝐿
π‘ž
× =
𝑀𝑃𝐿
.
𝐴𝑃𝐿
• This shows the (percentage) change in production due to a 1% change in labour input.
• Capital elasticity of production (elasticity of production w.r.t. capital):
• 𝑒𝐾 =
πœ•π‘ž
πœ•πΎ
×
𝐾
π‘ž
=
𝑀𝑃𝐾
.
𝐴𝑃𝐾
• This shows the (percentage) change in production due to a 1% change in capital input.
EXAMPLE
Suppose production is π‘ž = 10𝐾 0.3 𝐿0.8 .
a.
Find and interpret the labour and capital elasticity of production.
Solution
• 𝑒𝐿 =
• 𝑀𝑃𝐿
𝐿
• 𝑒 =
𝑀𝑃𝐿
𝐴𝑃𝐿
πœ•π‘ž
= πœ•πΏ
𝑀𝑃𝐿
𝐴𝑃𝐿
π‘ž
= 8𝐾 0.3 𝐿−0.2 and 𝐴𝑃𝐿 = 𝐿 = 10𝐾 0.3 𝐿−0.2
=
8𝐾0.3 𝐿−0.2
10𝐾0.3 𝐿−0.2
= 0.8
• This means that if labour input increases by 1%, production will increase by 0.8%. (note that for CobbDouglas, this is equal to 𝛽)
• 𝑒𝐾 =
• 𝑀𝑃𝐾
• 𝑒𝐾 =
𝑀𝑃𝐾
𝐴𝑃𝐾
πœ•π‘ž
= πœ•πΎ
𝑀𝑃𝐾
𝐴𝑃𝐾
π‘ž
= 3𝐾 −0.7 𝐿0.8 and 𝐴𝑃𝐾 = 𝐾 = 10𝐾 −0.7 𝐿0.8
3𝐾−0.7 𝐿0.8
= 10𝐾−0.7𝐿0.8 = 0.3
• This means that if capital input increases by 1%, production will increase by 0.3%. (note that for CobbDouglas, this is equal to 𝛼)
PARTIAL ELASTICITIES AND LOGS
• Recall from ch. 9 that if 𝑦 = 𝑓(π‘₯), then
𝑑 ln 𝑦
𝑑 ln π‘₯
= 𝑒π‘₯
• Extending this to a multivariate function is simple:
• If 𝑧 = 𝑓(π‘₯, 𝑦), then
• Page 580-582
𝑑 ln 𝑧
𝑑 ln π‘₯
= 𝑒 π‘₯,
𝑑 ln 𝑧
𝑑 ln 𝑦
= 𝑒𝑦
Homework
1. Consider the utility function 𝒖 = 𝟏𝟎𝟎 πŸ’π’™πŸŽ.πŸπŸ“ + πŸ’π’šπŸŽ.πŸπŸ“
𝟎.πŸ–
.
a. Write down the degree of homogeneity (𝒓) of this utility function. [2]
b. Write down the elasticity of utility with respect to 𝒙 (𝒆𝒙 ) for this utility function. [2]
πŸ‘
2. Consider the following production function: 𝒒 = πŸ” 𝟎. πŸ’π‘²πŸŽ.πŸ‘ + 𝟎. πŸ”π‘³πŸŽ.πŸ‘ .
2a. Does this production function exhibit increasing, decreasing, or constant returns to scale? Briefly explain. [3]
2b. Use implicit differentiation to find the marginal rate of technical substitution, 𝑴𝑹𝑻𝑺. [2]
2c. Write down an expression for the isoquant if 𝒒 = πŸπŸ”πŸ. [2]
2d. Write down an expression for the capital elasticity of production, 𝒆𝑲 . [2]
3. The demand for fireworks is 𝒒𝒅 = 𝟐 +
πŸ‘πŸŽ
+
𝒑
𝟐 π₯𝐧 𝒑𝒛 − πŸ“π’†−𝟎.πŸŽπŸŽπŸ“π’š. Find and interpret the following partial
demand elasticities (at 𝒑 = 𝟏𝟎𝟎, 𝒑𝒛 = πŸ“πŸŽ and π’š = 𝟏𝟎𝟎):
3a. Price elasticity of demand (𝒆𝒑 ). [2]
3b. Income elasticity of demand (π’†π’š ). [2]
3c. Cross-price elasticity of demand (𝒆𝒑𝒛 ). [2]
FINALLY…
• Work through the examples and progress exercises in Ch. 17
• Next: Unit 11 - Integration
Download