Economics for the IB Diploma Ellie Tragakes cambridge university press Cambridge, New York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town, Singapore, São Paulo, Delhi, Dubai, Tokyo Cambridge University Press The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge CB2 8RU, UK www.cambridge.org Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9780521744348 © Cambridge University Press 2009 This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements, no reproduction of any part may take place without the written permission of Cambridge University Press. First published 2009 Printed in the United Kingdom at the University Press, Cambridge A catalogue record for this publication is available from the British Library ISBN 978-0-521-74434-8 Paperback with CD-ROM ISBN 978-0-511-79031-7 Adobe Reader Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of URLs for external or third-party Internet websites referred to in this publication, and does not guarantee that any content on such websites is, or will remain, accurate or appropriate. Information regarding prices, travel timetables and other factual information given in this work are correct at the time of first printing but Cambridge University Press does not guarantee the accuracy of such information thereafter. notice to teachers The CD-ROM at the back of this book is provided on the following terms and conditions: • The CD-ROM is made available for the use of current teachers and students within a purchasing institution, or for private purchasers, only. A purchase of at least one copy of the book must be made in respect of each teacher, student or private purchaser who uses the CD-ROM. The CD-ROM may be installed on individual computers or networks for use as above. • Subject to the above, the material on the CD-ROM, in whole or in part, may not be passed in an electronic form to another party, and may not be copied (except for making one copy of the CD-ROM solely for backup or archival purposes), distributed, printed or stored electronically. It may not be posted on a public website, and may not be altered for any reason without the permission of Cambridge University Press. • Permission is explicitly granted for use of the materials on a data projector, interactive whiteboard or other public display in the context of classroom teaching at a purchasing institution. • Once a teacher or student ceases to be a member of the purchasing institution all copies of the material on the CD-ROM stored on his/her personal computer must be destroyed and the CD-ROM returned to the purchasing institution. • All material contained within the CD-ROM is protected by copyright and other intellectual property laws. You may not alter, remove or destroy any copyright notice or other material placed on or with this CD-ROM. • The CD-ROM is supplied ‘as-is’ with no express guarantee as to its suitability. This material has been developed independently by the publisher and the content is in no way connected with nor endorsed by the International Baccalaureate Organization. Contents Preface xxi Acknowledgments xxiii Part 1 Introduction to Economics Chapter 1 Fundamental concepts in Economics Objectives 1.1 Key concepts in Economics Defining Economics Scarcity and choice Consumer choice and utility Scarcity, choice and opportunity cost: the economic perspective Free and economic goods The factors of production Understanding the economic world by use of models The circular flow model Microeconomics and macroeconomics Ceteris paribus Positive and normative concepts Economic growth, economic development and sustainable development Economic growth Economic development Sustainable development 1.2 The production possibilities model The production possibilities curve (frontier) Introducing the production possibilities curve The production possibilities curve and scarcity, choice and opportunity cost The shape of the production possibilities curve Shifts of the production possibilities curve (frontier) Applications of the production possibilities model Economic growth and economic development Environmental issues Present choices and future growth possibilities 1.3 Basic economic questions, rationing systems and the mixed market economy Three basic economic questions: resource allocation and output/income distribution How the basic economic questions are answered by market and command economies Characteristics of market and command economies Evaluating the market economy Key advantages Key limitations Evaluating the centrally planned (command) economy The mixed market economy Economies in transition: moving towards the mixed market Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union China Questions for review 2 2 2 3 3 4 4 5 5 6 7 7 8 9 9 9 10 11 11 11 12 12 13 15 15 15 16 16 16 18 19 21 21 21 22 23 24 24 25 26 Contents iii Part 2 Microeconomics Chapter 2 Markets Objectives 2.1 Introduction to markets and market structures Markets Firms, industries and market structures Perfect competition (or pure competition) Monopoly Monopolistic competition Oligopoly Market structure, competition and market power 2.2 Demand, supply and price determination Demand Individual demand HL The law of demand: why the demand curve slopes downward Market demand Determinants of demand Movement along a demand curve and shift of the demand curve Exceptions to the law of demand (higher level topic) Veblen goods Giffen goods The role of expectations Supply Individual supply The law of supply: why the supply curve slopes upward Market supply The vertical supply curve Determinants of supply Movement along a supply curve and shift of the supply curve Market equilibrium: demand and supply Shortages and surpluses Market equilibrium Changes in market equilibrium Free and economic goods revisited 2.3 Prices and efficiency in the market economy The role of prices in markets Price rationing and the invisible hand of the market Prices as signals and incentives Economic efficiency and the market economy Productive (or technical) efficiency: how to produce Allocative efficiency: what to produce Economic efficiency: maximizing consumer and producer surplus A word of caution 2.4 G overnment intervention in the market: price controls and market disequilibrium Price ceilings: setting a legal maximum price What is a price ceiling? Consequences of price ceilings Examples of price ceilings Price floors: setting a legal minimum price What is a price floor? Consequences of price floors Examples of price floors Setting fixed prices Commodity agreements and buffer stock schemes Questions for review iv Contents 28 28 28 29 29 29 30 30 31 32 32 32 33 34 35 36 37 37 38 40 40 40 41 41 42 42 43 44 44 45 45 46 47 47 47 48 49 49 50 50 52 53 53 53 53 54 55 55 55 55 57 57 60 Chapter 3 Elasticities Objectives 3.1 Price elasticity of demand (PED) Determinants of the price elasticity of demand Definition and formula for the price elasticity of demand The formula for the PED The sign of the PED The use of percentages Calculating the PED Interpreting the price elasticity of demand The range of values for the PED Variable PED and the straight-line demand curve PED and the relative steepness of the demand curve (supplementary material) Applications of the price elasticity of demand PED and total revenue PED and firm pricing decisions HL PED and price discrimination (higher level topic) PED and excise taxes PED and short-term price instability of agricultural products 3.2 Cross-elasticity of demand (CED) Definition and formula for the cross-elasticity of demand Interpreting the cross-elasticity of demand Positive CED: substitutes Negative CED: complements Zero CED: unrelated products Applications of the cross-elasticity of demand Substitute goods Complementary goods 3.3 Income elasticity of demand (YED) Definition and formula for income elasticity of demand Interpreting the income elasticity of demand The sign of the income elasticity of demand (normal or inferior goods) The value of the income elasticity of demand Determinants of the income elasticity of demand Applications of the income elasticity of demand YED and the rate of expansion of industries YED and sectoral change in an economy YED and long-term impacts on agricultural and other primary product prices 3.4 Price elasticity of supply (PES) Definition and formula for the price elasticity of supply Interpreting the price elasticity of supply The range of values for the PES Determinants of the price elasticity of supply Length of time Spare capacity of firms Applications of the price elasticity of supply HL PES and short-term price instability of agricultural products Short-run and long-run price elasticities of supply 3.5 Elasticities of demand and supply and incidence of taxes and subsidies (higher level topic) Indirect taxes: flat rate and ad valorem The incidence of indirect taxes and subsidies on consumers and producers The incidence of indirect taxes The incidence of subsidies Elasticity of demand and supply and the incidence of indirect taxes The case of demand elasticities The case of supply elasticities Questions for review 62 62 62 63 63 64 64 64 65 65 66 67 69 69 70 70 71 71 73 73 73 73 74 74 75 75 75 76 76 76 76 77 77 78 78 78 79 80 80 81 81 83 83 83 84 84 85 85 85 86 86 87 87 87 88 89 Contents v HL Chapter 4 T heory of the firm I: costs, revenues and profits (higher level topic) Objectives 4.1 Costs Introduction to costs of production Accounting, implicit and economic costs The short run and the long run Fixed, variable and total costs Average costs Marginal cost Costs of production in the short run Total product, marginal product and average product The relationship between the marginal and average product curves Generalized product curves Law of diminishing marginal returns Short-run costs of production: deriving the short-run cost curves The law of diminishing marginal returns and the shape of the cost curves Shifts in the cost curves Costs of production in the long run 91 91 91 91 93 93 93 94 94 94 96 96 96 97 99 100 101 Average costs in the long run Long-run average total cost curve Economies and diseconomies of scale Minimum efficient scale and the structure of industries (supplementary material) 101 102 103 104 4.2 Revenues and profits Revenues Profits 105 105 106 106 106 108 108 108 108 109 110 110 110 110 110 111 112 Economic profit versus accounting profit Normal profit 4.3 Goals of firms Profit maximization Profit maximization based on the total revenue and cost approach Profit maximization based on the marginal revenue and cost approach Evaluating profit maximization as the firm’s main goal Additional firm goals Revenue maximization Growth maximization Managerial utility maximization Satisficing firm behaviour Ethical and environmental concerns Questions for review Chapter 5 Theory of the firm II: market structures (higher level topic) Objectives 5.1 Perfect competition Assumptions of the model Demand and revenue curves under perfect competition The demand curve facing the firm The firm’s revenue curves Profit maximization in the short run Short-run profit maximization based on the total revenue and cost approach Short-run profit maximization based on the marginal revenue and cost approach The firm’s short-run supply curve Short-run equilibrium under perfect competition Perfect competition in the long run Role of economic (abnormal) profits and losses in adjustment to long-run equilibrium Changes in demand and adjustment to long-run equilibrium Changes in technology or resource prices, and adjustment to long-run equilibrium vi Contents 113 114 114 114 114 114 116 116 117 120 120 121 121 121 123 HL Allocative and productive (technical) efficiency Allocative efficiency Productive efficiency Efficiency and perfect competition in the long run Efficiency and perfect competition in the short run Evaluating perfect competition Insights provided by the model Limitations of the model 5.2 Monopoly Assumptions of the model Barriers to entry Economies of scale Natural monopoly Legal barriers Control of essential resources Aggressive tactics The demand and revenue curves under monopoly The demand curve facing the monopolist The monopolist’s revenue curves The monopolist’s output and price elasticity of demand Profit maximization by the monopolist Profit maximization based on the total revenue and cost approach Profit maximization based on the marginal revenue and cost approach Revenue maximization by the monopolist Evaluating monopoly and comparing with perfect competition Criticisms of monopoly Benefits of monopoly Monopoly and government regulation Perfect competition and monopoly as guides to understanding the real world 5.3 Monopolistic competition Assumptions of the model Product differentiation and the demand curve Elements of competition and monopoly The roles of price and non-price competition Profit maximization Economic profit or loss in the short run Normal profit in the long run Criticisms of the model Efficiency in monopolistic competition Allocative and productive inefficiency Excess capacity Comparison of monopolistic competition with other market structures Monopolistic competition and perfect competition Monopolistic competition and monopoly 5.4 Oligopoly Assumptions of oligopoly Collusive oligopoly Formal collusion: cartels Obstacles to forming and maintaining cartels Informal collusion: price leadership and other approaches Non-collusive oligopoly: the kinked demand curve The role of non-price competition in oligopoly Evaluating oligopoly Criticisms of oligopoly Benefits of oligopoly Advantages and disadvantages of advertising (supplementary material) 123 124 124 124 125 125 125 125 126 126 127 127 127 127 128 128 128 128 129 129 131 131 131 132 133 133 136 137 137 137 137 138 138 139 139 139 140 141 141 141 141 142 142 142 143 143 144 144 145 145 146 148 148 148 148 149 Contents vii HL 5.5 The theory of contestable markets 5.6 Price discrimination Definition and conditions for price discrimination The single-price firm versus the price discriminating firm Conditions for price discrimination Types of price discrimination First degree: discrimination among individual consumers Second degree: discrimination among quantities Third degree: discrimination among consumer groups Summary of advantages and disadvantages of price discrimination From the firm’s perspective From the consumer’s perspective From a social perspective Questions for review 149 150 150 150 151 152 152 153 154 155 156 156 156 157 Chapter 6 Market failure Objectives 6.1 Market failure and allocative inefficiency 6.2 Externalities Diverging private and social benefits and costs Negative production externalities (spillover costs) Illustrating negative production externalities Correcting negative production externalities Evaluating alternative policies Negative consumption externalities (spillover costs) Illustrating negative consumption externalities Correcting negative consumption externalities Evaluating alternative policies Environmental concerns and sustainable development Environmental concerns and negative externalities The meaning of sustainable development Addressing the overuse of open access resources Positive production externalities (spillover benefits) Illustrating positive production externalities Correcting positive production externalities Positive consumption externalities (spillover benefits) Illustrating positive consumption externalities Correcting positive consumption externalities Evaluating measures to correct spillover benefits 6.3 Merit goods, demerit goods and public goods Merit and demerit goods Public goods Public goods versus private goods Public goods and the free rider problem Public goods that are not ‘pure’ Correcting the market’s failure to provide public goods 6.4 Monopoly power 6.5 Additional failures (supplementary material) Imperfect information and information asymmetries Coordination failures Weak or missing market institutions Macroeconomic objectives The problem of government failure (policy failure) Questions for review viii Contents 159 159 160 160 161 161 162 163 164 164 165 166 166 166 167 168 169 169 170 170 170 171 172 172 172 174 174 174 174 175 175 176 176 178 178 179 179 180 Part 3 Macroeconomics Chapter 7 Macroeconomic concepts and measurement Objectives 7.1 Measuring national income and output The circular flow model revisited The simple circular flow of income Adding leakages and injections National income accounting The expenditure method The income method The output method Key distinctions relating to measures of the value of output Distinction between gross and net Distinction between nominal and real Calculating nominal and real GDP Distinction between total and per capita Distinction between domestic and national: GDP versus GNP 7.2 Concepts and measurement of economic growth and economic development Economic growth Defining and calculating economic growth The sources of economic growth The significance of economic growth Economic development Distinguishing between developing and developed countries Defining economic development Relating economic growth to economic development Limitations of the GDP measure in international welfare comparisons Why GDP figures understate welfare (or why true welfare is greater than indicated by GDP per capita) Why GDP figures overstate welfare (or why true welfare is smaller than indicated by GDP per capita) Why GDP figures understate or overstate welfare (or why true welfare may be greater or smaller than indicated by GDP per capita) Purchasing power parities and welfare comparisons across countries 7.3 Measuring economic development The complexities of measuring economic development Individual indicators World Development Indicators (World Bank) Millennium Development Goals and indicators Examples of individual indicators Health indicators Income poverty Income distribution Literacy, improved water source and improved sanitation Demographic indicators Relative importance of primary, secondary and tertiary sectors Composite indicators The Human Development Index Other composite indicators Questions for review 182 183 183 183 183 185 185 186 186 187 187 188 188 190 191 192 192 192 193 194 196 196 197 199 200 200 201 201 202 204 204 205 205 205 208 208 211 212 214 214 215 215 216 217 220 Contents ix Chapter 8 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply Objectives 8.1 The business (trade) cycle: economic fluctuations Understanding the business (trade) cycle The phases of the business (trade) cycle The relationship between real GDP and unemployment Actual and potential GDP Why we study the business (trade) cycle 8.2 The aggregate demand and aggregate supply model in the short run Introducing the aggregate demand and aggregate supply (AD-AS) model Aggregate demand and the aggregate demand curve Defining aggregate demand and the aggregate demand curve The downward slope of the aggregate demand curve (supplementary material) Changes in aggregate demand (shifts in the AD curve) Aggregate supply and the short-run aggregate supply curve The short run and long run in macroeconomics Defining aggregate supply and the short-run aggregate supply curve Changes in short-run aggregate supply (shifts in the SRAS curve) Macroeconomic equilibrium in the short run Short-run equilibrium level of prices and output Changes in short-run equilibrium Recessionary (deflationary) gaps, inflationary gaps and short-run full employment equilibrium Shifts in AD or SRAS: possible causes of the business cycle 8.3 Macroeconomic controversies: the neoclassical perspective The AD-AS model in the long run Defining the long-run aggregate supply curve and long-run macroeconomic equilibrium Why the LRAS curve is vertical Why the LRAS curve is situated at the level of potential GDP (or why inflationary and deflationary gaps cannot persist in the long run) Why in the long run aggregate demand influences only the price level, leaving real GDP unchanged Changes in long-run aggregate supply (shifts in the LRAS curve) Economic growth in the AD-AS model The relationship between the SRAS and LRAS curves 8.4 Macroeconomic controversies: the Keynesian perspective Getting stuck in the short run Wage and price downward inflexibility The inability of the economy to move into the long run The shape of the Keynesian aggregate supply curve The three short-run equilibrium states of the economy in the Keynesian perspective Some key features of the Keynesian perspective Recessionary gaps can persist over long periods of time Increases in aggregate demand need not cause increases in the price level Illustrating economic growth in the Keynesian perspective 8.5 Some final observations Illustrating the neoclassical and Keynesian perspectives Policy implications of the neoclassical and Keynesian perspectives The business cycle and government policy in the neoclassical perspective The business cycle and government policy in the Keynesian perspective The mainstream economic perspective Questions for review Chapter 9 Demand-side and supply-side policies Objectives 9.1 Demand-side policies: shifts in the aggregate demand curve Objectives of demand-side policies x Contents 221 222 222 222 223 223 224 225 225 226 226 227 227 231 231 231 232 233 233 233 234 235 237 237 237 238 238 239 240 240 241 241 242 242 242 243 244 244 244 245 245 246 246 246 246 247 247 248 249 249 249 Fiscal policy Background to government finance Expansionary fiscal policy Contractionary fiscal policy Monetary policy Determination of the rate of interest Changes in interest rates and aggregate demand Expansionary (easy money) policy Contractionary (tight money) policy Strengths and weaknesses of demand-side policies for short-term stabilization Strengths of fiscal policy Weaknesses of fiscal policy Strengths of monetary policy Weaknesses of monetary policy Inability of fiscal and monetary policies to address supply-side causes of economic contractions Fiscal or monetary policy? Discretionary policy or a monetary rule? (supplementary material) Demand-side policies and long-term economic growth 9.2 Supply-side policies: shifts in the aggregate supply curve Objectives of supply-side policies Market-oriented supply-side policies HL The theoretical justification of market-oriented supply-side policies Reducing the size of the government sector and increasing competition Strengths and weaknesses of these policies Improving incentives by lowering taxes Strengths and weaknesses of these policies Making the labour market more responsive to supply and demand Strengths and weaknesses of these policies Liberalizing (freeing up) international trade and capital flows Interventionist supply-side policies Interactions between demand-side and supply-side policies 9.3 The multiplier, accelerator and crowding-out effects (higher level topics) The multiplier effect Defining the multiplier effect Calculating the multiplier The multiplier and aggregate demand The multiplier and fiscal policy The multiplier in the real world: the role of leakages and the price level The accelerator theory Interactions between the multiplier and accelerator The crowding-out effect Questions for review Chapter 10 Unemployment and inflation Objectives 10.1 Unemployment Definitions Full employment Unemployment and underemployment The unemployment rate Difficulties in measuring unemployment The costs of unemployment Economic costs Non-economic costs 250 250 250 251 252 253 254 254 255 256 256 256 257 257 258 259 259 260 261 261 261 261 262 263 264 265 265 266 266 267 268 269 269 269 269 271 272 272 273 275 275 277 278 278 278 279 279 279 279 280 280 280 Contents xi Natural rate of unemployment: structural, frictional and seasonal unemployment Structural unemployment Frictional unemployment Seasonal unemployment The natural rate of unemployment in relation to the AD-AS model Unemployment in a recessionary gap: real wage and cyclical unemployment Real wage unemployment Cyclical unemployment Summary of the five types of unemployment in relation to the AD-AS model 10.2 Inflation and deflation Introduction to inflation and deflation Definitions Distinguishing between changes in the price level and changes in the rate of inflation Causes of inflation Demand-pull inflation Cost-push inflation Excessive growth in the money supply Consequences and costs of inflation The relationship between inflation, purchasing power and nominal and real income Costs of inflation Costs of hyperinflation Causes of deflation HL Why deflation occurs rarely in the real world Causes of deflation Costs of deflation 10.3 Measuring inflation (higher level topic) Measurement of inflation and price indexes Price index using a base year basket of goods and services (CPI) Using the consumer price index to calculate the rate of inflation A word of caution Price index using current output (the GDP deflator) (supplementary material) Using the GDP deflator to calculate the rate of inflation Problems with measuring inflation Problems with the consumer price index (CPI) Problems with the GDP deflator (supplementary material) 10.4 The Phillips curve, the NRU and the NAIRU (higher level topics) The relationship between inflation and unemployment The breakdown in the relationship Distinguishing between the short-run and long-run Phillips curves The short-run Phillips curve The long-run Phillips curve The natural rate of unemployment (NRU) and the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) The NAIRU and the natural rate of unemployment (NRU) The NAIRU and the NRU: building a consensus view of the inflation–unemployment relationship Questions for review Chapter 11 Distribution of income Objectives 11.1 Income distribution and redistribution The meaning of income distribution and redistribution Methods that can be used to redistribute income and output Transfer payments Subsidized provision of merit goods Government intervention in markets Taxation xii Contents 281 281 282 283 283 284 284 285 286 288 288 288 288 288 288 289 290 291 291 291 294 294 294 295 296 297 297 297 298 299 299 299 299 299 300 302 302 303 303 303 304 306 306 306 308 309 309 309 310 310 310 311 311 11.2 The role of taxation in income redistribution Direct and indirect taxation Direct taxes Indirect taxes The ability-to-pay principle Proportional, progressive and regressive taxation Understanding the principles of proportional, progressive and regressive taxation Progressivity and personal income taxes Other types of taxes HL Why income redistribution is a controversial issue: an evaluation 11.3 M easuring income inequalities: the Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient (higher level topic) Presenting some data on income distribution The Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient Lorenz curve The Gini coefficient Using Lorenz curves to illustrate income redistribution Income distribution and the level of economic development 11.4 The Laffer curve (higher level topic) Understanding the Laffer curve Evaluating the Laffer curve Questions for review 311 311 311 312 312 313 313 314 314 315 317 317 317 317 319 319 319 320 320 321 322 Part 4 International economics Chapter 12 International trade HL Objectives 12.1 International trade theory The benefits of trade Absolute and comparative advantage (higher level topic) The theory of absolute advantage The theory of comparative advantage PPCs, absolute advantage and comparative advantage Absolute advantage as a special case of comparative advantage The sources of comparative advantage Evaluating the theory of comparative advantage 12.2 International trade policy: free trade and protectionism Defining free trade and protectionism Free trade versus protectionism Using diagrams to illustrate international trade Tariffs Tariffs and their impacts The impacts of tariffs on consumer and producer surplus Import quotas Import quotas and their impacts The impacts of quotas on consumer and producer surplus Subsidies Production subsidies and their impacts Export subsidies and their impacts (supplementary material) Voluntary export restraints Administrative and technical regulations Administrative regulations Health, safety and environmental standards Summary of arguments against protectionism 324 324 324 326 327 329 331 331 331 332 333 333 333 333 334 334 336 336 336 337 338 338 339 340 341 341 341 341 Contents xiii Arguments for protectionism Qualified arguments Questionable arguments Incorrect arguments 12.3 Economic integration Trading blocs HL Free trade area Customs union Common market Economic and monetary union Advantages and disadvantages of trading blocs Trade creation and trade diversion (higher level topic) Trade creation and its impacts Trade diversion and its impacts The impacts of trade creation and diversion on consumer and producer surplus (supplementary material) Obstacles to achieving economic integration (higher level topic) Reluctance to surrender political and economic sovereignty Globalization 12.4 World Trade Organization Brief history WTO objectives Evaluating the WTO Potential benefits Evaluating the Uruguay Round The Doha Development Round: inability to reach agreement Questions for review 343 343 345 346 347 347 347 347 347 347 348 349 349 350 351 352 352 352 353 353 354 354 354 355 356 357 Chapter 13 Balance of payments and exchange rates Objectives 13.1 The balance of payments Introducing the balance of payments and foreign exchange The balance of payments Demand and supply of foreign exchange Relating the demand and supply of a currency to the balance of payments Understanding the balance of payments The current account The capital account The financial account A clarification concerning the capital account and the financial account The meaning of ‘balance’ in the balance of payments The statistical discrepancy Understanding the balance of payments from a different perspective 13.2 Exchange rates Exchange rates Exchange rates in a floating (flexible) exchange rate system The exchange rate as the ‘price’ of a currency The equilibrium exchange rate Exchange rate changes: appreciation and depreciation Causes of changes in exchange rates The significance of depreciating and appreciating currencies for a country’s exports and imports Relating exchange rates to the balance of payments Exchange rates in a fixed exchange rate system Understanding fixed exchange rates How fixed exchange rates can be maintained Changing the fixed exchange rate xiv Contents 359 359 359 359 360 360 361 361 362 362 363 363 364 364 366 366 366 366 366 367 369 370 371 372 372 373 373 Exchange rates in a managed float Understanding managed exchange rates Pegging exchange rates The problem of overvalued or undervalued currencies Overvalued currencies Undervalued currencies Monetary policy and conflicting objectives in an open economy 13.3 Topics on exchange rates (higher level topics) Advantages and disadvantages of fixed and floating exchange rates Advantages of fixed exchange rates Disadvantages of fixed exchange rates Advantages of floating (flexible) exchange rates Disadvantages of floating (flexible) exchange rates Evaluating the managed float (managed exchange rates) Advantages and disadvantages of single currencies/monetary integration Arguments in favour of a single currency Arguments against a single currency HL Adjustment mechanisms within European Monetary Union (EMU) countries Purchasing power parity (PPP) theory Understanding PPP theory HL Why PPP theory does not work in practice 13.4 Topics on the balance of payments Consequences of persistent current account deficits and financial account surpluses Persistent current account deficits financed by loans Persistent current account deficits financed by the sale of domestic assets Consequences of persistent current account surpluses and financial account deficits Methods to correct persistent current account deficits Marshall-Lerner condition and J-curve (higher level topic) Marshall–Lerner condition J-curve Questions for review Chapter 14 Terms of trade Objectives HL HL 14.1 Understanding the terms of trade Defining the terms of trade Measurement of the terms of trade (higher level topic) Causes of changes in the terms of trade (higher level topic) 14.2 Consequences of changes in the terms of trade The terms of trade and the balance of trade How the terms of trade and the balance of trade are related to each other The role of price elasticities of demand for exports and imports (higher level topic) Consequences of changes in the terms of trade for the balance of trade Changes in demand for an export product Increases in supply of an export product: impacts of deteriorating terms of trade Decreases in supply of an export product: impacts of improving terms of trade Changes in exchange rates Consequences of long-term changes in the terms of trade for the domestic economy Long-term deterioration in the terms of trade in developing countries Causes of deteriorating terms of trade in developing countries Impacts of deteriorating terms of trade in developing countries Short-term changes in terms of trade: terms of trade volatility and commodity booms (supplementary material) Causes of commodity booms and terms of trade volatility Impacts of terms of trade volatility and commodity booms Questions for review 374 374 375 376 376 376 377 377 377 377 378 378 378 379 379 380 380 381 381 381 382 383 383 383 384 384 385 386 386 387 389 390 390 390 391 392 394 394 394 395 397 397 397 398 398 399 400 400 401 402 402 404 406 Contents xv Part 5 Economic development Chapter 15 Sources of economic growth and development Objectives 15.1 F actors of production and technology as sources of economic growth and development Some distinctions relating to the factors of production Expanding the meaning of ‘capital’ Capital, investment and saving Physical capital and technological factors Physical capital, technology and economic growth Physical capital, technology and economic development Human resources (human capital) Human resources and economic growth Human resources and economic development Natural resources (natural capital) Natural resources and economic growth Natural resources and economic development 15.2 T he role of institutional factors in the development of human capital and technology The development of human capital: education and health services The contribution of education and health services to human capital formation Benefits of education and good levels of health for the individual Spillover benefits (positive externalities) of education Spillover benefits (positive externalities) of health The importance of elementary education and universal literacy Research and development, technological change and innovation (supplementary material) Questions for review Chapter 16 Barriers to economic growth and development Objectives 16.1 Domestic barriers to growth and development The poverty cycle (trap) Understanding the poverty cycle How poverty is perpetuated across generations Breaking out of the poverty cycle Banking and credit The importance of banking and credit in economic growth and development Exclusion of the poor from access to credit Infrastructure The importance of infrastructure Infrastructure and economic growth Infrastructure and economic development Lack of infrastructure as a barrier to growth and development Ineffective taxation structures Low levels of revenues Inequities in tax systems Negative impacts on resource allocation Lack of property rights Property rights and investment Property rights and access to credit Property rights and benefits for non-owners Inequalities in income distribution The informal economy (informal sector) Definition and characteristics of the informal economy (sector) The size of the informal economy The failure of the formal sector to provide enough employment opportunities The role of the informal sector in growth and development xvi Contents 408 408 408 409 409 409 409 410 411 411 412 412 412 413 414 414 414 415 415 415 416 416 418 419 419 419 419 420 421 421 421 422 422 422 422 423 423 424 424 425 425 426 426 426 426 426 427 427 428 428 428 Political stability Corruption Social and cultural barriers 429 431 432 432 433 434 434 Culture and tradition in early theories of growth and development Cultural factors as obstacles to growth and development Gender inequalities Consequences of gender inequality: deprivations faced by women and girls Spillover benefits (positive externalities) of reducing gender inequalities and deprivations faced by women Population growth and the demographic trap (supplementary material) The challenges of population growth The vicious cycle of poverty and population growth: the demographic trap Breaking out of the demographic trap 16.2 International trade barriers Too much dependence on primary products and a narrow range of exports The importance of the primary sector in developing countries Consequences of too much dependence on primary products Protectionism Tariff barriers Agricultural trade and rich country subsidies Other non-tariff barriers: the ‘new protectionism’ 16.3 International financial barriers Developing country indebtedness Explaining indebtedness Brief history of the debt problem (supplementary material) Consequences of high indebtedness Consequences of some policies intended to address high indebtedness in developing countries Capital flight Non-convertible currencies Defining convertibility and non-convertibility Non-convertibility for current account transactions Non-convertibility for financial account transactions Conditions that should be met before adopting full currency convertibility Currency convertibility and financial crises Questions for review Chapter 17 Growth models and international trade and growth strategies Objectives 17.1 Early growth models and strategies The Harrod–Domar growth model The model Policy implications Criticisms of the model The structural change/dual sector model The model Criticisms of the model Policy implications and policy impacts 17.2 International trade and growth strategies Import substitution/inward orientation with strong government intervention The rationale of import substitution Import-substitution policies and consequences Export-led growth/outward orientation with strong government intervention The experience of export promotion Factors behind the success of export promotion over import substitution 436 437 437 437 438 439 439 439 440 442 442 443 444 445 445 445 445 446 447 448 449 449 449 450 451 451 452 453 453 453 453 454 454 455 455 455 456 457 458 458 458 460 460 461 Contents xvii Export-led growth strategies with market liberalization: the Washington Consensus The Washington Consensus The impacts of economic and trade liberalization Export-led growth strategies with selective government intervention: the New Development Consensus Evaluating the roles of inward-oriented and outward-oriented strategies in international trade and economic growth and development How an outward orientation to international trade can contribute to growth and development Obstacles to achieving growth and development through an outward orientation Can developing countries imitate the trade and growth strategies of the Asian Tigers? Evaluating the roles of market-led and interventionist strategies in international trade and economic growth and development Two responses to developing country trade problems: fair trade organizations and commodity agreements Fair trade organizations Commodity agreements Questions for review Chapter 18 S trategies focusing on the savings, foreign exchange and technology constraints Objectives 18.1 Overview of foreign sources of finance Foreign aid: concessional loans and grants Non-concessional lending Private investment 18.2 Foreign aid: concessional financial flows Public aid: Official Development Assistance (ODA) Bilateral and multilateral aid Donor motives for providing aid Factors that limit the effectiveness of aid The quantity of aid and poverty alleviation Evaluating the aid/trade controversy Arguments supporting the ‘trade, not aid’ perspective Arguments supporting the ‘trade and aid’ perspective Arguments supporting the ‘aid for trade’ perspective Private (civil society) aid: non-governmental organizations (NGOs) Understanding the role of NGOs in development Evaluating the role of NGOs in developing countries 18.3 Non-concessional financial flows: public and private lending Organizations involved in multilateral (public) lending The World Bank World Bank activities Evaluating the role of the World Bank The International Monetary Fund Activities of the International Monetary Fund Evaluating the role of the International Monetary Fund Private-sector bank (commercial bank) lending 18.4 Private investment Foreign direct investment: the role of multinational (transnational) corporations The scope and growth of multinational corporations Geographical distribution of foreign direct investment Country characteristics that attract multinational corporations xviii Contents 461 461 462 464 466 466 466 467 468 470 470 471 472 473 473 474 474 475 476 476 476 477 478 479 479 480 481 482 483 483 484 486 486 487 487 488 489 489 489 490 491 491 492 493 493 Evaluating foreign direct investment and multinational corporations in developing countries Potential benefits of multinational corporations (MNCs) for host developing countries Potential costs of multinational corporations (MNCs) to the host developing country Measures to increase MNC responsiveness to developing country needs (supplementary material) Foreign portfolio investment (supplementary material) 18.5 Confronting poverty: micro-credit schemes The importance of access to credit by poor people Micro-credit schemes Muhammad Yunus, the Grameen Bank, and the 2006 Nobel Prize for Peace Controversial issues in micro-credit Questions for review Chapter 19 Consequences of economic growth Objectives 494 494 495 497 498 499 499 500 500 501 503 19.1 Economic growth and income distribution The development of thinking on economic growth and income distribution Why is income inequality increasing in many countries? Policies to achieve a more equitable distribution of income 19.2 Economic growth, environmental externalities and sustainable development Distinguishing between the pollution of affluence and the pollution of poverty Negative environmental impacts of increasing economic activity Social costs of environmental degradation Economic growth and sustainable development: conflicting or compatible objectives? 504 504 504 505 506 507 507 508 508 509 509 510 Economic growth and sustainability over the long term Economic growth and sustainability: taking a short-term perspective Strategies for sustainable development Sustainable development: developing a strategy framework Policies within a strategy for sustainable development Green accounting methods (supplementary material) Questions for review Content from the CD-ROM accompanying the print book 510 511 512 514 515 Introduction to the CD-ROM Answers to select questions for review 1 Fundamental concepts in Economics 2 Markets 3 Elasticities 4 Theory of the firm I 5 Theory of the firm II 6 Market failure 7 Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 8 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 9 Demand-side and supply-side policies 10 Unemployment and inflation 11 Distribution of income 12 International trade 13 Balance of payments and exchange rates 14 Terms of trade 15 Sources of economic growth and development 16 Barriers to economic growth and development 17 Growth model and international trade and growth strategies 18 Strategies focusing on the savings, foreign exchange and technology constraints 19 Consequences of economic growth Case studies and data response questions and answers Preparing for evaluation questions in Standard level Paper 1 and Higher level Paper 1 The Nobel Prize in Economics Glossary 516 Index 526 Contents xix For Alexios and Alkeos Preface Economics is a relatively new social science that touches upon many aspects of our lives and has important effects on the well-being of all people around the world. Studying it as a scientific discipline allows us to organize the way we think about the numerous economic problems faced by our own and other societies, and helps us make informed and responsible choices. Economics for the IB Diploma has been written for students of Economics in the International Baccalaureate (IB) Diploma Programme. It covers the entire IB Economics syllabus at both standard and higher levels. Each of the five parts of the book corresponds to one of the five sections of the syllabus, and the chapters within each part correspond closely to the syllabus subsections. The book supposes no prior knowledge of Economics from the student. Every section and subsection begins with a simple presentation that gradually progresses to a more advanced level, enabling the student to gradually master complex topics. The book fully covers the needs of the IB Economics student, in terms of both breadth and depth of coverage of all items in the syllabus. Note to the reader about the book The book contains the following main features: · Learning outcomes At the beginning of each chapter, there is a bulleted list of objectives indicating what you should have learnt and what you should be able to do after studying the chapter. · Standard level and higher level material The subdivision of the book’s content into two levels is clearly demarcated. A vertical dashed bar labelled ‘HL’ runs down the margin of all higher level material, allowing you to easily distinguish higher level from standard level material. · Key points Material that is especially important, such as important concepts, laws, definitions and conclusions, is highlighted in a box shaded light blue. This helps you focus on key points of the chapter, and can facilitate reviewing. · Use of bullet points There is extensive use of bullet points where there are lists of items relating to a particular topic. These will help you keep the material well organized in your mind, and can also help you review. · Syllabus terms and glossary All syllabus terms are highlighted in blue bold font at their first appearance in the book so that you can immediately recognize them. (You should note that when a syllabus term reappears in a later section of the book, it is not highlighted in blue bold.) At the end of the book, there is a glossary that defines all the syllabus terms. In the glossary, terms that are part of higher level material are demarcated using the vertical ‘HL’ bar. · Supplementary material The book includes some material that is not part of the IB Economics syllabus and that you will not be examined on. Such material is accompanied by the heading ‘supplementary material’ so that you can readily recognize it. It is included in the book in order to provide a more rounded view of some topics that are not bounded by the rigid IB syllabus. · ‘Test your understanding’ questions Each chapter contains a series of ‘Test your understanding’ questions, which appear at the end of every topic. These questions are concerned very specifically with the material of the preceding section and can help you review the section’s main points. The questions can be used as the basis for class discussions or homework assignments. You can also use them for studying and reviewing on your own. If you can answer these questions, it means you have understood the important points of the section. · End-of-chapter questions for review Each chapter ends with a set of review questions. These questions are broader in scope than the ‘Test your understanding’ questions. Many (though not all) are similar to IB Economics exam questions. Each is assigned a maximum number of marks, which is intended to Preface xxi guide you on how extensive your answer should be. The questions can help you review the chapter material, but they can also give you practice in answering IB-style exam questions. Answers to selected questions are provided in the accompanying CD-ROM (in bullet-point form). The corresponding questions have a CD-ROM icon in the margin. You should attempt to answer these questions on your own before reading the answers. Note to the reader about the CD-ROM The CD-ROM contains the following main features: · Introduction This explains how the material on the CD-ROM can help you develop the skills you will need in order to perform well in your IB Economics exams and in your portfolio of commentaries. It is important that you read this introduction before proceeding to the other CD-ROM files. · Answers to the end-of-chapter questions for review There is a separate file for each of the book’s 19 chapters, in which a selected number of end-of-chapter questions have been answered (in bullet-point form). These questions (and their answers) are based on the material presented in the corresponding chapters and are intended to sharpen your analytical skills and introduce you to evaluation questions. · Case studies and data-response questions and answers This file contains a series of texts (or ‘case studies’) on topics of current interest, together with questions and answers, all of which have been modelled on the data-response questions of Standard level Paper 2 and Higher level Paper 3. These questions and answers involve definitions, economic theory and analysis, and evaluation, showing how you can make connections and find relationships between different parts of Economics, thus improving the quality of your answers. · Preparing for evaluation questions in Standard level Paper 1 and Higher level Paper 1 This file contains further evaluation questions together with answers based on material that comes from more than one chapter of the textbook. · List of Nobel Prize winners For the interested student, there is also a list of all Nobel Prize winners in Economics and a brief description of their work, beginning in 1969 when this prize was first awarded. Acknowledgments I would like to express my immense gratitude and debt to Julia Tokatlidou for her thorough, detailed and insightful review of the book and CD-ROM, as well as for her enthusiasm and support. Whatever merit this book may have would be less were it not for her invaluable contributions. I would also like to extend my thanks to Ann Bone for her very careful, meticulous editing of the text and her many useful suggestions. My thanks also go to K.A. Tsokos, for his great help and support, and for the guidance that his book, Physics for the IB Diploma, provided for me. Finally, I would like to thank Alexios and Alkeos for their patience, for reading and commenting on chapters of the book, and, above all, for the inspiration and motivation they gave me to write this book. Information about the author Ellie Tragakes received a BA degree in Economics from Columbia University in the USA, a Master’s from the University of Birmingham in the UK, and a PhD from the University of Maryland in the USA. She has worked in the areas of economic development of agriculture of less developed countries, financial services and health systems, in several national and international organizations, including the World Bank and the World Health Organization. She is a highly experienced teacher and author, with over forty professional publications. Many of these are in the area of health system financing and reforms in transition economies, and they have been translated into several languages including Russian and Chinese. She has been teaching in the Economics Department at the American College of Greece since 1996 and has been a consultant for the World Health Organization since 1992. xxii Preface Acknowledgements The author and publishers are grateful for the permissions granted to reproduce texts in either the original or an adapted form. Whilst every effort has been made, it has not always been possible to identify the sources of all materials used, or to trace all copyright holders. If any omissions are brought to our notice, we will be happy to include the appropriate acknowledgements on reprinting. Cover image: Russ Widstrand / Alamy On occasion, the author has referred the reader to related sources (e.g. books, articles and websites) for further information. These sources have been acknowledged in footnotes on the appropriate pages. The author has also referred to selected data from the following sources in some of the tables and graphs: United Nations Human Development Programme, Human Development Reports, available at www.undp.org; UN Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), World Investment Reports; World Bank, World Development Reports and Development Indicators; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). These sources have been acknowledged in footnotes on the appropriate pages. Acknowledgements xxiii Part 1 Introduction to Economics Many urgent issues in our world today, such as pollution, economic growth, improvements in standards of living, unemployment, inflation, technology, poverty, international trade, taxes, the role of markets and government, and many more, involve economics. The objective of economists is to explain, analyse and understand issues such as these, in the hope of finding ways to deal with them so as to bring about improvements in the well-being of people everywhere. Part 1 of this book is an introduction to the social science of Economics. We will discover the meaning of Economics, and we will discuss the important concepts of scarcity, opportunity cost and choice, which form the basis of the economic perspective of the world. We will see how economists use models to analyse economic problems, and we will discover that even very simple models of the economy can be used to shed light on important economic issues. In Chapter 1 we will also learn about the organizing principles of market and command economies, which will allow us to go on to understand the workings of real-world economies based on a mix of market and command principles. Chapter 1 Introduction to Economics Fundamental concepts in Economics This chapter is an introduction to the study of economics. It is also an introduction to many of the topics that will be explored in depth in later chapters. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · · · · · · · · · define Economics as the social science of scarcity and choice identify the relationships illustrated by the circular flow model distinguish between macroeconomics and microeconomics, and positive and normative concepts, and understand why economists use the ceteris paribus assumption distinguish between economic growth, economic development and sustainable development use the production possibilities model to analyse a variety of economic issues explain the concept of opportunity cost in relation to scarcity and choice identify the three basic economic questions, and their relationship to resource allocation and output/income distribution compare and contrast the organizing principles of market and command economies define transition economies and understand the kinds of reforms they pursue. 1.1 Key concepts in Economics Defining Economics The social sciences are academic disciplines that study human society and social relationships. They are concerned with discovering general principles describing how societies function and are organized. The social sciences include anthropology, economics, political science, psychology and sociology. Economics is a social science because its approach to studying human society is based on the scientific method. It is a social science because it deals with human society and behaviour, and particularly those aspects concerned with how people organize their 2 Part 1: Introduction to Economics activities and how they behave in order to satisfy their needs and wants. Human beings have very many needs and wants. Some of these are satisfied by physical objects and others by non-physical activities. All the physical objects people need and want are called goods (food, clothing, houses, books, computers, cars, televisions, refrigerators and so on); the non-physical activities are called services (education, health care, entertainment, travel, banking, insurance and many more). The study of Economics arises because people’s needs and wants are unlimited. Whereas some individuals may be satisfied with the goods and services they have or can buy, most would prefer to have more. They would like to have more and better computers, cars, educational services, transport services, housing, recreation, travel and so on; the list is endless. Yet it is not possible for societies and the people within them to produce or buy all the things they want. Why is this so? It is because there are not enough resources. Resources are the inputs used to produce goods and services wanted by people. They include things like human labour, machines and factories, and ‘gifts of nature’ like agricultural land and metals inside the earth. Resources do not exist in unlimited abundance: they are scarce, or limited and insufficient in relation to unlimited uses that people have for them. Scarcity is a very important concept in Economics. It arises whenever there is not enough of something in relation to the need for it. For example, we could say that food is scarce in poor countries. Or we could say that clean air is scarce in a polluted city. In Economics, scarcity is especially important in describing the condition of insufficient resources, because the scarcity of resources causes scarcity in goods and services. Defining scarcity, we can therefore say that: The conflict between unlimited needs and wants, and scarce resources has a second important consequence. Since resources are scarce, it is important to avoid waste in how they are used. If resources are not used effectively and are wasted, they will end up producing less; or they may end up producing goods and services that people don’t really want or need. Economics must try to find how best to use scarce resources so that waste can be avoided. Defining Economics, we can therefore say that: Economics is the study of choices leading to the best possible use of scarce resources in order to best satisfy unlimited human needs and wants. As you can see from this definition of Economics, economists study the world from a social perspective, with the objective of determining what is in society’s best interests. Test your understanding 1.1 1 Think of some of your most important needs Scarcity is the condition in which available resources are not enough to produce everything that human beings need and want. and wants, and then explain whether these are satisfied by goods or by services. 2 Define scarcity, and then think of some things that are (a) scarce, and (b) not scarce. 3 Why is Economics a study of choices? 4 Explain the relationship between scarcity and It follows that societies face a fundamental problem, which is the conflict between unlimited human needs and wants on the one hand, and limited or scarce resources on the other. The subject of Economics is how to best resolve this conflict. The conflict between unlimited needs and wants, and scarce resources has an important consequence. Since people can’t have everything they want, they must make choices. The classic example of a choice forced on society by resource scarcity is that of ‘guns or butter’, or more realistically the choice between producing defence goods (guns, weapons, tanks) or food: more defence goods mean less food, while more food means fewer defence goods. Societies must choose how much of each they want to have. Note that if there were no resource scarcity, a choice would not be necessary, since society could produce as much of each as was desired. But resource scarcity forces the society to make a choice between available alternatives. Economics is therefore a study of choices. the need to avoid waste in the use of resources. Scarcity and choice We have seen that the condition of scarcity forces people and societies to make choices. Let’s have a closer look at some of the types of choices that must be made. Consumer choice and utility Utility is the benefit or satisfaction that consumers derive from consuming a good or service. Utility is a subjective concept – the satisfaction you receive from buying and using a particular good depends on your own particular preferences, and is unlikely to be the same as your friend’s. Consumers, acting in their best interests, attempt to maximize the utility (i.e. get the greatest possible utility) from buying a variety of goods and services. This means that they make choices about how to spend their income on different possible purchases of goods and services, so as to buy Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 3 those things that will provide them with the greatest possible benefit or satisfaction. (Note that if consumers had an unlimited income, it would not be necessary for them to make choices between alternative purchases.) Utility maximization by the consumer is an example of one of the many kinds of choices that are studied by economists. If resources were limitless, no sacrifices would be necessary, and the opportunity cost of producing anything would be zero. Test your understanding 1.2 1 Explain the relationship between scarcity and choice. Scarcity, choice and opportunity cost: the economic perspective Opportunity cost is defined as the value of the next best alternative that must be given up or sacrificed in order to obtain something else. Every time we choose to do something, we give up something else that we could have done instead. For example, your decision to read this book now means that you have given up a different activity, such as sleeping, watching TV, reading a novel, or visiting a friend. If your best or favourite alternative to reading this book is watching TV, the TV time you have sacrificed is the opportunity cost of reading this book. Opportunity cost in this case arises from the fact that time is limited or scarce; if it were endless, you would never have to sacrifice any activity in order to do something else – you could simply watch TV after reading, and your reading time would not have any opportunity cost; we would say that your reading time has an opportunity cost of zero. The concept of opportunity cost, or the value of the next best alternative that must be sacrificed to obtain something else, is central to the economic perspective of the world, and results from the condition of scarcity that forces a choice between competing alternatives. When a consumer chooses to use her $100 to buy a pair of shoes, she is also choosing not to use this money to buy books, or CDs, or anything else; if CDs are her favourite alternative to shoes, the CDs she sacrificed (did not buy) are the opportunity cost of the shoes. When a business chooses to use the resources at its disposal to produce hamburgers, it is also choosing not to produce hotdogs or pizzas, or anything else; if hotdogs are the preferred alternative, the hotdogs sacrificed (not produced) are the opportunity cost of the hamburgers. Note that if the consumer had endless amounts of money, she could buy everything she wanted and the shoes would have no opportunity cost. Similarly, if the business had endless resources at its disposal, it could produce hotdogs, pizzas and a lot of other things in addition to hamburgers, and the hamburgers would have no opportunity cost. 4 Part 1: Introduction to Economics 2 Define opportunity cost. 3 Think of three choices you have made today, and describe the opportunity cost of each one. Free and economic goods Based on the concept of opportunity cost, we can make a distinction between free and economic goods (note that the term ‘good’ is used here in a general sense to include goods, services and resources): A free good is any good that is not scarce, and therefore has a zero opportunity cost. Since it is not limited by scarcity, it includes anything that can be obtained without sacrificing something else. An economic good is any good that is scarce, either because it is a naturally occurring scarce resource (such as oil, gold, coal, forests, lakes), or because it is produced by scarce resources. All economic goods have an opportunity cost greater than zero. Free goods are rare. Sometimes a good can be a free good in certain situations and an economic good in others. For example, arable land in America before European colonizers arrived was a free good because it was so abundant; as the colonizers grew in numbers it became increasingly scarce and therefore an economic good. Salt used to be a free good and has become an economic good. Oxygen in the open unpolluted countryside can be a free good; in a room with no windows that is crowded with people it becomes an economic good. Unobstructed sunshine is also a free good in many situations. It is important to distinguish free goods from goods or resources that are available free of charge to their users. There are two categories of goods that are available free of charge, but which do have opportunity costs and are therefore economic goods (both of these will be studied in Chapter 6): · goods provided by the government, such as the road system, public parks and playgrounds, free education, free health care services; all these are economic goods produced by scarce resources, and are paid for out of tax revenues · certain natural resources, such as clean air, forests, rivers, lakes and wildlife, that are not owned by anyone (they are called ‘open access resources’); these are also economic goods because they are scarce (they are not unlimited), and are becoming increasingly scarce due to overuse and depletion. opportunities for opening and running a business. Entrepreneurship organizes the other three factors of production and takes on the risks of success or failure of a business. Owners of factors of production receive a payment for providing their resources to the production process: · Rent is payment to owners of land resources who supply their land to the production process. Test your understanding 1.3 1 Explain the difference between a free good and an economic good. 2 Are any of the following goods ‘free goods’? Explain why or why not: (a) public parks; (b) sand in the Sahara desert; (c) garbage collection; (d) free health care services; (e) wildlife. 3 Why do you think free goods are rare? The factors of production Resources, or all inputs used to produce goods and services, are alternatively known as factors of production. Factors of production are grouped under four broad categories: · Land includes all natural resources, including all agricultural and non-agricultural land, as well as everything that is under or above the land, such as minerals, oil reserves, underground water, forests, rivers and lakes. Natural resources are also called ‘gifts of nature’. · Labour includes the physical and mental effort that people contribute to the production of goods and services. The efforts of a teacher, a construction worker, an economist, a doctor, a taxi driver or a plumber all contribute to producing goods and services, and are all examples of labour. · Capital, also known as physical capital, is a man-made factor of production that is used in the production process to produce goods and services. Examples of physical capital include machinery, tools, factories, buildings, road systems, airports, harbours, electricity generators and telephone supply lines. Physical capital is also referred to as a capital good or investment good. · Entrepreneurship/management is a special human skill possessed by some people, involving the ability to innovate by developing new ways of doing things, to take business risks and to seek new · Wage is a payment to those who provide labour; this includes all wages and salaries, as well as supplements (such as bonuses and commissions). · Interest is a payment to owners of capital resources. · Profit is payment to owners of entrepreneurship. The payments to the factors of production are usually expressed as payment for the amount of time they are used. For example, they can be expressed as rent per month; wage per hour or salary per month; interest per year; profit per year, and so on. Test your understanding 1.4 1 Why do you think resources are also called ‘factors of production’? 2 What are the factors of production? What kind of payments do their owners receive for supplying them in the economy? 3 How does physical capital differ from the other three factors of production? 4 Why is entrepreneurship considered to be a factor of production separate from labour? Understanding the economic world by use of models Everyone is familiar with the idea of a model. As children many of us played with paper airplanes, which are models of real airplanes. In chemistry at school, we studied molecules and atoms, which are models of what matter is made of. Models are a simplified representation of something in the real world, and are used extensively by scientists and social scientists in their efforts to understand and explain real-world situations. Models represent only the important aspects of the real world that is being investigated, ignoring unnecessary details, thereby allowing scientists and social scientists to focus on important relationships. Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 5 in ( ho u , la households (consumers) ip rsh land land, lab s hi p our, eneur cap repr ital t n resource e ,e , l a nt t i markets c re p o s e ca t m so o c n f i p ld , ro d ages it) ho se t, wt, prof n re res te eu en pr bo ur , and services. They then sell the goods and services to consumers in product markets. We therefore see a flow in the clockwise direction of factors of production from households to firms, and of goods and services from firms to households. n tio uc Whereas sciences like biology, chemistry and physics offer the possibility to construct threedimensional models (as with molecules and atoms), this cannot be done in the social sciences, because these are concerned with human society and social relationships. In Economics, models are often illustrated by use of diagrams showing the relationships between key variables. In more advanced Economics (beyond the scope of this course), models are illustrated by use of mathematical equations. To construct a model, economists select particular variables and make assumptions about how these are interrelated. Different models illustrate different aspects of the economic world. Some models may be better than others in their ability to explain economic phenomena, and as we will see in later chapters, economists sometimes disagree about which model can offer a better explanation of some aspect of the real world. firms (businesses) ou pe sehol d nd itur e h In our study of Economics, we will encounter a variety of economic models and will make extensive use of diagrams. We now turn to a very simple model of the economy. The circular flow model The circular flow model is a very simple model that illustrates a number of economic concepts and relationships. The simplest version of this model is shown in the diagram in Figure 1.1. The model assumes that households (or consumers) and firms (or businesses) are the main decision-makers in the economy; both are shown in square boxes. Households and firms are linked together through two kinds of markets, shown in diamonds. A market, in Economics, is any arrangement that allows buyers and sellers to conduct their buying and selling activities (we will study markets in detail in Chapter 2). Households or consumers (we use these terms interchangeably) are owners of the factors of production (land, labour, capital and entrepreneurship), which they sell to firms in resource markets. Firms buy the factors of production in resource markets and use them to produce goods 6 Part 1: Introduction to Economics go o ds a nd ser v ices product markets es s nue reve ex Models are very closely related to theories. A theory is a generalization or simplification about the real world that shows how particular variables are interrelated, and attempts to explain real-world phenomena. Models are sometimes built on the basis of wellestablished theories. In some contexts, economists use the terms ‘model’ and ‘theory’ interchangeably. d goo ic rv se d s an Figure 1.1 The simple circular flow model. In the counterclockwise direction, there is a flow of money used as payments for sales and purchases. When households sell their factors of production to firms, they receive payments taking the form of rent (for land), wages (for labour), interest (for capital) and profit (for entrepreneurship). These payments constitute the income of households. The payments that households make to buy goods and services are household expenditures (or simply household or consumer spending). The payments that firms make to buy factors of production represent their costs, and the payments they receive by selling goods and services are their revenues. The circular flow model provides a visual representation of some key aspects of an economy relying on markets. It shows how production of goods and services and consumption of these are linked together through the economic decisions made by households and firms. These decisions involve choices, necessitated by the condition of scarcity. Test your understanding 1.5 1 The circular flow model represents a simplification of the real world. Can you think of some important features of the real world that this model ignores? 2 What are the two kinds of markets shown in the circular flow model? Can you provide examples of what is exchanged (bought and sold) in each of these? 3 What are the two flows shown in the circular flow model? 4 The circular flow model shows that households and firms are both buyers and sellers simultaneously. How is this possible? Microeconomics and macroeconomics Economics is studied on two levels. Microeconomics examines the behaviour of individual decisionmaking units in the economy. The two key groups of decision-makers are consumers (or households) and firms (or businesses), introduced in the circular flow model. Microeconomics is concerned with how these decision-makers behave, how they make choices and how their interactions in markets determine the prices of individual goods and services (in product markets), and prices of individual factors of production (in resource markets). As the circular flow model illustrates, consumers choose what particular goods and services and what quantities of these they wish to buy, and they also choose the quantities of factors of production that they wish to sell to firms. Firms, on the other hand, choose the quantities of factors of production they wish to buy, and they also choose what particular goods and services and what quantities of these to produce and sell to consumers. These countless decisions are coordinated through the operation of product and resource markets that we will study in the chapters on microeconomics. Macroeconomics examines the economy as a whole to obtain a broad or overall picture, by use of aggregates, which are wholes or collections of many individual units, such as the sum of consumer behaviours and the sum of firm behaviours, and total income and output of the entire economy, as well as total employment and the general price level (as opposed to prices of individual goods, services and resources). In terms of the circular flow model, macroeconomics is concerned with the overall size of output and income flows, as well as with explaining how their size is determined. Test your understanding 1.6 Which of the following topics are studied in microeconomics and which in macroeconomics? (a) Total household spending increased by 1.5% in 2006. (b) Unemployment fell to 4% in 2005. (c) The price of petrol (gasoline) increased due to the government’s decision to increase taxes. (d) The economy’s total output has been declining over the last two years. (e) As firms are showing a greater interest in hiring skilled labour, there has resulted an increase in average wage rates received by skilled workers. Ceteris paribus When we try to understand the relationship between two or more variables in the context of economic models, we must assume that everything else, other than the variables we are studying, does not change. We do this by use of the ceteris paribus assumption: Ceteris paribus is a Latin expression that means ‘other things equal’. Another way of saying this is that all other things are assumed to be constant or unchanging. Consider the simple circular flow model, and suppose that households decide to save (not spend) a portion of the income they receive from selling their factors of production. What will happen to household spending on goods and services? We might think that household spending will fall by an amount equal to savings. But will this necessarily happen? The answer is no, it may not, if other things happen at the same time that also affect household spending. For example, let’s say that at the same time that households decide to start saving, they also decide to work longer hours (sell more of their labour in the labour market to firms) in order to increase their income. If they succeed, their longer working hours will have the effect of increasing their income and therefore their spending, at the same time that their saving will have the effect of lowering their spending. We have no idea what will happen on balance. Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 7 If we want to study the relationship between household saving and spending, we can do it by assuming that all other things that could affect spending are constant and unchanging. More formally, we could say that we are examining the impact of the decision to save on household spending, ceteris paribus. This means simply that we are studying the relationship between saving and spending on the assumption that nothing else happens that can influence this relationship. By eliminating all other possible interferences, we isolate the impact of saving on spending, so we can study it alone. In the real world all the variables that can affect household spending are likely to be changing at the same time. The ceteris paribus assumption does not say anything about what happens in the real world. It is simply a tool used by economists to construct models and theories. Test your understanding 1.7 Consider the statement, ‘If you increase your consumption of calories, you will put on weight.’ Do you think this statement is necessarily true? Why or why not? How could you rephrase the statement to make it more accurate? Positive and normative concepts Economists think about the economic world in two different ways: one way tries to describe and explain how things in the economy actually work, and the other deals with how things ought to work. The first of these is based on positive statements, which are about something that is, was or will be. Positive statements are used in several ways: · They may describe something (e.g. the unemployment rate is 5%; industrial output grew by 3%). · They may be statements in a theory (e.g. an increase in price leads to a decrease in quantity bought). · They may be about a cause-and-effect relationship (if the government increases spending, unemployment will fall). 8 Part 1: Introduction to Economics The second way of thinking about the economic world, dealing with how things ought to work, is based on normative statements, which are about what ought to be. These are subjective statements about what should happen. Examples include the following: the unemployment rate should be lower; health care should be available free of charge; extreme poverty should be eradicated. Positive statements may be true or they may be false. For example, we may say that the unemployment rate is 5%; if in fact the unemployment rate is 5% this statement is true; but if the unemployment rate is actually 7%, the statement is false. Normative statements, by contrast, cannot be true or false. They can only be assessed relative to beliefs and value judgements. Consider the normative statement ‘the unemployment rate should be lower’. We cannot say whether this statement is true or false, though we may agree or disagree with it, depending on our beliefs about unemployment. If we believe that the present unemployment rate is too high, then we will agree; but if we believe that the present unemployment rate is not too high, then we will disagree. Positive statements play an important role in economics because they are used to describe economic events and to construct theories and models that try to explain these events. Normative statements are important because they form the basis of economic policy-making. Economic policies are government actions that try to solve economic problems. When a government formulates a policy to lower the unemployment rate, this is based on a belief that the unemployment rate is too high, and the value judgement that high unemployment is not a good thing. If a government pursues a policy to make health care available free of charge, this is based on a belief that people should not have to pay for receiving health care services. Positive and normative statements, while distinct, often work together in economics. To be successful, an economic policy aimed at lowering unemployment (the normative dimension) must be based on a body of economic knowledge about what causes unemployment (the positive dimension). The positive dimension provides guidance to policy-makers on how to achieve their economic goals. Test your understanding 1.8 Which of the following are positive statements and which are normative? (a) (b) (c) (d) It is raining today. It is too humid today. Economics is a study of choices. Economics should be concerned with how to reduce poverty. (e) If household saving increases, ceteris paribus, there will be a fall in household spending. (f) Households save too little of their income. Economic growth, economic development and sustainable development Economic growth, economic development and sustainable development are three distinct but closely related concepts. Economic growth can be expressed as a percentage change in real GDP over a specified period of time. (As we will see in Chapter 7, ‘real’ means that the measure of GDP accounts for changes only in quantities of goods and services produced, and ignores changes in prices.) For example, China’s real GDP increased by 9.1% in 2004; this means that the real value of output produced within China in the course of the year 2004 grew by 9.1%. ‘Real GDP per capita’ considers the GDP of a country divided by that country’s population, in other words, real GDP per person. We will study these concepts in more detail in Chapter 7. Test your understanding 1.9 1 How would you use the circular flow model to explain economic growth? 2 In Egypt, real GDP grew by 3.1% in 2004, yet real GDP per capita in the course of the same year grew by 1.3%. What do you think accounts for the difference between the two growth rates? Economic growth All economies produce some output, which includes all goods and services produced for consumers, as well as all capital goods (physical capital). Over time, the quantity of output that is produced in a given period of time (say a year) changes. When the quantity of output produced by an economy over a period of time increases, there is economic growth; if it decreases there is economic contraction or negative economic growth. In the circular flow model, economic growth would be illustrated by an increase in the size of the flows of goods and services moving from firms to households, as well as in flows of resources. At the same time, growth would also appear as an increase in the money flows, including household incomes and expenditures. A contraction, on the other hand, would be shown by a reduction in the size of the flows. To have a clear picture of how much output is being produced and how this changes over time, we must be able to measure the quantity of output. Common measurements of output include GDP (gross domestic product) and GDP per capita (GDP per person). GDP measures the value of all goods and services produced within the boundaries of a particular country over a particular time period, typically a year. Economic development There are enormous differences between countries in the volume of output (or GDP) per capita that they produce and in their levels of income. Whereas countries are commonly referred to as being ‘rich’ or ‘poor’, economists try to classify them in a more precise way. The World Bank (this is an international financial institution that lends to developing countries in order to assist them in their development efforts) divides them into four groups according to their level of GDP per capita; these groups are: low income economies, lower middle income economies, upper middle income economies and high income economies. The first three groups comprise the less developed countries (LDCs) or developing countries, while high income economies are known as more developed countries (MDCs). Economic development refers to raising the standard of living and well-being of people, particularly in less developed countries (LDCs). It involves increasing income levels and reducing poverty, reducing income inequalities and unemployment, and increasing provision of, and access to, basic goods and services such as food and shelter, sanitation, education and health care services. Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 9 Economic development must be sharply distinguished from economic growth. Economic growth involves increases in the volume of output produced. This is an essential prerequisite for economic development to occur; however it does not by itself ensure that development will take place. There may, for example, be growth in the volume of output produced, but this may not result in a reduction in poverty of lower income groups, or in the provision of increased social services such as education and health care, or in less income inequality and greater employment. It follows, then, that measures of growth such as changes in real GDP and real GDP per capita over time, though used extensively, are not fully appropriate as measures of economic development. Measures of economic growth cannot take into account all of the above dimensions that development involves. Because of these many dimensions, it follows, too, that the division of countries into LDCs and MDCs on the basis of their GDP per capita can be misleading. Some countries may be more advanced than others with respect to the provision of basic social services, or with respect to literacy of the population, or income distribution, or other factors, and yet they may have relatively low GDPs per capita. These issues will be explored at length in Chapter 7 and in Part 5 of this book. Test your understanding 1.10 Which country do you think is more ‘developed’: that with a higher GDP per capita and low provision of social services (such as health care services and sanitation), or that with a lower GDP per capita and higher provision of social services? Sustainable development Economic growth and economic development in many countries are often achieved at the expense of the natural environment and natural resources. There may be growth in output, or there may be a general improvement in the standard of living of the population, but these very often result in increased air and water pollution, and the destruction or depletion of forests, wildlife and the ozone layer, among many other natural resources. Growing awareness of this 1 Brundtland Commission (World Commission on Environment and Development), Our Common Future (Oxford University Press, 1987). 10 Part 1: Introduction to Economics issue in virtually all countries of the world has given rise to the concept of sustainable development: Sustainable development is defined as ‘development which meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs’.1 What this says in effect is that as societies make efforts to grow and develop, they should take care not to leave behind fewer or lower quality resources available for use by future generations. The World Bank has expanded this definition to mean growth and development that do not give rise to environmental degradation, and which if possible include improvements in environmental quality. Both this and the previous definition suggest that there are close interconnections between the economy and the environment, and that growth and development efforts in the present should take into account the needs of future generations. This can only be accomplished by pursuing activities that preserve and even improve the quality of the natural environment. Sustainable development will be discussed in Chapters 6 and 19. Test your understanding 1.11 Consider the following: ‘But just as the speed and scale of China’s rise as an economic power have no clear parallel in history, so its pollution problem has shattered all precedents. Environmental degradation is now so severe that pollution poses not only a major long-term burden on the Chinese public but also an acute political challenge to the ruling Communist Party’. (a) In your opinion, is China achieving sustainable development? (b) What can you conclude about China’s rapid economic growth and its impacts on future generations? (c) Why do you think the ruling party is being challenged? 1.2 The production possibilities model The production possibilities model is a simple model of the economy illustrating the concepts of scarcity, choice and opportunity cost, as well as the concept of efficiency to be introduced in this section. The production possibilities curve (frontier) Introducing the production possibilities curve Let’s consider a very simple hypothetical economy producing only two goods: microwave ovens and computers. This economy has a fixed (unchanging) quantity and quality of resources (factors of production) and a fixed technology (the method of production is unchanging). Table 1.1 shows the combinations of the two goods that this economy can produce with the resources and technology at its disposal. Figure 1.2 plots the data of Table 1.1: the quantity of microwave ovens is plotted on the vertical axis, and the quantity of computers on the horizontal axis. Table 1.1 Combinations of microwave ovens and computers. Point Microwave ovens Computers A 40 0 B 35 17 C 26 25 D 15 31 E 0 33 40 A B 35 microwave ovens 30 G In order for the economy to produce the greatest possible output, in other words somewhere on the PPC, two conditions must be met: · All resources must be fully employed: this means that all resources are being fully used. If there were unemployment of some resources, in which case they would be sitting unused, the economy would not be producing the maximum it is capable of producing. · All resources must be used efficiently: specifically, there must be productive efficiency. The term ‘efficiency’ in a general sense means that resources are being used in the best possible way. (If they are not used in the best possible way, we say there is ‘inefficiency’.) Productive efficiency means that output is produced by use of the fewest possible resources; alternatively, we can say that output is produced at the lowest possible cost. If output were not produced using the fewest possible resources, the economy would be ‘wasting’ some resources that could have been used to produce something else instead, and it would not be producing the maximum that it can produce. C 25 20 F 15 The production possibilities curve (or frontier) represents all combinations of the maximum amounts of two goods that can be produced by an economy, given its resources and technology, when there is full employment of resources and productive efficiency. D 10 5 0 If all of the economy’s available resources are used to produce microwave ovens, the economy will produce 40 microwave ovens and 0 computers, as shown by point A. If on the other hand all resources are used to produce computers, the economy will produce 33 computers and 0 microwave ovens; this is shown by point E. All the points on the curve joining A and E represent other production possibilities where some of the resources are used to produce microwave ovens and the rest to produce computers. For example, at point B there would be production of 35 microwave ovens and 17 computers; at point C, 26 microwave ovens and 25 computers, and so on. The line joining points A and E is known as the production possibilities curve (PPC) or production possibilities frontier (PPF). 5 10 15 20 25 computers Figure 1.2 Production possibilities curve. E 30 35 40 What would happen if either of the two conditions (full employment and productive efficiency) is not met? Very simply, the economy will not produce at a point on the PPC; it will be somewhere inside the PPC, such as at point F. At F, the economy is producing only 15 microwave ovens and 12 computers. Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 11 Yet it has the resources and the technology to increase production of both goods, by eliminating unemployment of resources and/or using resources more efficiently. If it uses its resources fully and efficiently it could, for example, move to point C and produce 26 microwave ovens and 25 computers. In fact, as we will see in more detail in later chapters, in the real world no economy ever produces on its PPC. An economy’s actual output, or the quantity of output actually produced, is always at a point inside the PPC, because in the real world all economies have some unemployment of resources and some productive inefficiency. The greater the unemployment or the productive inefficiency, the further away is the point of production from the PPC. The production possibilities curve and scarcity, choice and opportunity cost The production possibilities model is very useful for illustrating the concepts of scarcity, choice and opportunity cost: · The condition of scarcity does not allow the economy to produce outside its PPC With its fixed quantity and quality of resources and technology, the economy cannot move to any point outside the PPC, such as G, because it doesn’t have enough resources (there is resource scarcity). · The condition of scarcity forces the economy to make a choice about what particular combination of goods it wishes to produce Assuming it could achieve full employment and productive efficiency, it must decide at which particular point on the PPC it wishes to produce. (In the real world, the choice would involve a point inside the PPC.) · The condition of scarcity means that choices involve opportunity costs If the economy were at any point on the curve, it would be impossible to increase the quantity produced of one good without decreasing the quantity produced of the other good. In other words, when an economy increases its production of one good, there must necessarily be a sacrifice of some quantity of the other good; this sacrifice is the opportunity cost. Let’s consider the last point more carefully. Say the economy is at point C, producing 26 microwave ovens 12 Part 1: Introduction to Economics and 25 computers. Suppose now that consumers would like to have more computers. It is impossible to produce more computers without sacrificing production of some microwave ovens. For example, a choice to produce 31 computers (a move from C to D) involves a decrease in microwave oven production from 26 to 15 units, or a sacrifice of 11 microwave ovens. The sacrifice of 11 microwave ovens is the opportunity cost of 6 extra computers (increasing the number of computers from 25 to 31). Note that opportunity cost arises when the economy is on the PPC (or more realistically, somewhere close to the PPC). If the economy is at a point inside the curve, it can increase production of both goods with no sacrifice, hence no opportunity cost, simply by making better use of its resources (reducing unemployment or increasing productive efficiency). The shape of the production possibilities curve In Figure 1.3(a) the PPC’s shape is similar to that of Figure 1.2, while in Figure 1.3(b) it is a straight line. When the PPC bends outward and to the right, as in panel (a), opportunity costs change as the economy moves from one point on the PPF to another. In Figure 1.3(a), for each additional unit of computers that is produced, the opportunity cost, consisting of microwave ovens sacrificed, gets larger and larger as computer production increases. This happens because of specialization of factors of production, which makes them not equally suitable for the production of different goods and services. As production switches from microwave ovens to more computers, it will be necessary to give up increasingly more microwave ovens for each extra unit of computers produced, because factors of production suited to microwave oven production will be less suited to computer production. By contrast, when the PPC is a straight line (as in panel (b)), opportunity costs are constant (do not change) as the economy moves from one point of the PPC to another. Constant opportunity costs arise when the factors of production are equally well suited to the production of both goods, such as in the case of basketballs and volleyballs, which are very similar to each other, therefore needing similarly specialized factors of production to produce them. As we can see in Figure 1.3(b), for each additional unit of volleyballs produced, the opportunity cost, or sacrifice of basketballs, does not change. (a) Increasing opportunity costs. basketballs microwave ovens (b) Constant opportunity costs. computers volleyballs Figure 1.3 Production possibilities curve with increasing and constant opportunity costs. Test your understanding 1.12 1 Consider the production possibilities data in Table 1.1 and Figure 1.2. If the economy is initially at point A and moves to point B, computer production will increase by 17 units. (a) What is the opportunity cost of the increase in computer production? (b) If the economy moves from D to C, what will be the gain and what will be its opportunity cost? (c) If it moves from point C to B, what will be the gain and what will be its opportunity cost? 2 Use the concept of opportunity cost to explain why the following two statements have the same meaning: (a) productive efficiency means producing by use of the fewest possible resources; (b) productive efficiency means producing at the lowest possible cost. 3 (a) Distinguish between actual output and output that occurs on the PPC. (b) Why is an economy’s actual output most likely to be located somewhere inside its PPC? 4 Say an economy is initially at point F, producing 15 microwave ovens and 12 computers (Figure 1.2). What would be the opportunity cost of moving to a point on the production possibilities curve, such as point C, where it would be producing 26 microwave ovens and 25 computers? 5 Consider the statement, ‘The opportunity cost of computers in terms of microwave ovens depends on the quantity of each that is being produced.’ Is this statement true or false? Explain why. (Hint: consider the shape of the production possibilities curve, and what this means.) Shifts of the production possibilities curve (frontier) If the production possibilities curve shifts outward and to the right, this means that there has occurred an increase in the economy’s production possibilities, or what the economy is capable of producing; the economy has the possibility to produce more of both goods (X and Y), as shown in Figure 1.4(a) (page 14). An increase in production possibilities can result from any of the following: · an increase in the quantity of resources (factors of production) in the economy; with more resources, the economy can produce greater quantity of output · an improvement in resource quality; if the quality of the resources improves (such as for example, through more highly educated labour), then the economy can produce more output · a new and improved technology used to produce the goods; improvements in technology, or methods of production, allow the economy to produce a greater amount of output. An inward (leftward) shift represents a decrease in the economy’s production possibilities, i.e. less of the two goods can be produced, as shown in Figure 1.4(b). This can result from a decrease in the quantity of resources, deterioration in resource quality, or use of a less productive technology. 6 If you were asked to draw a PPC illustrating the possible choices between consuming two free goods, what would you say? Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 13 (b) Decrease in production possibilities. good Y good Y B A 0 (c) Non-parallel shifts of the PPC. good Y (a) Increase in production possibilities. PPC1 PPC2 good X 0 PPC2 PPC1 good X 0 PPC1 PPC2 good X Figure 1.4 Shifts of the production possibilities curve. An outward or inward shift need not be parallel, as shown in Figure 1.4(c). For example, a technological change favouring the production of one good (good X) will increase the production of that good proportionately more. Similarly, an influx of unskilled workers into a country will result in a larger proportionate increase in the production of goods using relatively more unskilled labour. Test your understanding 1.13 1 Can you think of two reasons why the model we have been considering in this section is called the ‘production possibilities’ model? (Hint: consider (a) the necessity of making a choice, and (b) the consequences of unemployment and productive inefficiency.) 2 How would you illustrate each of the following An outward shift of the PPC, or an increase in production possibilities, may signify economic growth, involving increases in the volume of output produced over time, because the economy becomes capable of producing more of both goods. By contrast, an inward shift of the PPC may signify economic contraction or negative economic growth, as the economy’s production possibilities are reduced. However, an increase in production possibilities only means that the economy is capable of producing a greater volume of output; it does not mean that the economy will actually produce more output. An economy’s actual output could, for example, remain stuck at point A in Figure 1.4(a) even as the PPC shifts from PPC1 to PPC2, though this is not very likely. The most likely result of an increase in production possibilities is that the economy’s actual output will move from a point like A inside PPC1 to point B inside PPC2, because of unemployment of resources and some productive inefficiency. We will examine these points more carefully in Chapter 7. 14 Part 1: Introduction to Economics events by use of a PPC model? (Hint: remember the difference between a shift of the PPC and a movement from one point to another.) (a) A violent conflict destroys a portion of a country’s factories, machines and road system. (b) A nationwide public health campaign improves the general level of health of the population. (c) There is an increase in unemployment of resources. (d) There is a widespread introduction of a new technology of production. (e) There is large emigration (departure) of working age people to another country. (f) There is an increase in the quantity of capital goods. (g) There is an improvement in the level of education and skills of workers. (h) There is an improvement in productive efficiency. 3 We have studied two very different models, both of which can illustrate economic growth: the circular flow model and the production possibilities model. Which of the two do you think is better suited to explaining the causes of economic growth? Why? Which of the two offers a better illustration of the role of markets in the economy? Applications of the production possibilities model Economic growth, as you may remember, involves an increase in the volume of output produced, or an increase in volume of output produced per person (per capita). Economic development involves improvements in the general standard of living of the population, which can come about from increased provision of services such as health care, education, clean water supplies and improved sanitation facilities. Such services can collectively be termed ‘merit goods’ (they will be discussed in Chapter 6). The production possibilities model can be used to illustrate an economy’s choice between economic growth without economic development, and economic growth with economic development. This is shown in Figure 1.5, where the vertical axis measures industrial goods production and the horizontal axis represents merit goods production. Assume that a country is initially at point A on PPC1. A rightward shift of its production possibilities frontier to PPC2 shows an increase in production possibilities. The country can choose to move to point B or point C on PPC2. (We are assuming for simplicity that the economy is producing at some point on its PPC.) Both moves indicate that economic growth has occurred, because in both cases the economy is capable of producing a greater volume of output. Moving to point B indicates growth without development, because the country has chosen to use its increased productive capacity to produce relatively more industrial goods compared to merit goods. Moving to point C shows growth with development, since the country has made a choice to place a relatively greater emphasis on the production of merit goods rather than industrial goods. Note that the production possibilities model can illustrate that economic development is occurring only with respect to increased merit goods production, which is only one aspect of development. It cannot illustrate other aspects of development (such as poverty reduction, improved income distribution, improved employment opportunities, and others to be discussed in Chapter 7 and Part 5). industrial goods Economic growth and economic development B C A D 0 PPC2 PPC1 merit goods Figure 1.5 Economic growth and economic development. Economics for the IB Diploma Figure 1.5 Environmental issues Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s The production Text: Agendapossibilities model can be used to illustrate choices between any two competing emcdesign Studio: & ZabranskyAs an example, we or confl ictingPeters alternatives. will consider choices that have impacts on the environment. Consider the consequences of fishing activities on marine resources. In Figure 1.6, the vertical axis measures the size of the fish harvest in the fishing industry, and the horizontal axis the quality of marine resources. The greater the fish harvest, the lower the quality of marine resources, i.e. the greater the environmental damage (destruction of reefs, lower survival of young fish, disruption of the marine ecosystem and so on). On the other hand, efforts to preserve the quality of marine resources, such as moving from point A to B, involve restrictions on fishing activities and a lower fish harvest. A fish harvest The production possibilities model is a useful tool that can be used to analyse numerous situations involving choices between competing alternatives. The following examples illustrate some of the kinds of choices faced by economies. 0 B quality of marine resources Figure 1.6 Fishing and the quality of marine resources. Economics for the IB Diploma Figure 1.6 Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s concepts in Economics Chapter 1: Fundamental Text: Agenda emcdesign Studio: Peters & Zabransky 15 Choices made by an economy in the present can affect the position of its production possibilities curve in the future. Consider two economies that we will call Country A and Country B, with identical resources and technologies in the present, and therefore identical PPCs; these are shown as PPCp in Figure 1.7 for both Country A and Country B. Each country must make a choice in the present concerning what quantity of consumer goods and what quantity of capital goods to produce, that is, each must choose where it wants to be on its PPCp. Consumer goods are goods purchased by consumers that satisfy immediate needs and wants; they represent consumption in the present (for example, food, clothing, books, DVD players, cars and so on). Capital goods, as we know from Section 1.1, are one of the factors of production; they are the one factor that is man-made or produced, and includes factories, machines, tools, buildings, airports and so on. Country A chooses to produce relatively more consumer goods in the present (point X), while Country B chooses to produce relatively more capital goods in the present (point Y). What will be the future consequences of each country’s present choice? PPCf, showing the future PPC for both countries, indicates that Country B expects to experience a larger PPC shift. Why is this so? Remember from our earlier discussion on shifts in the PPC that any increase in the quantity of a factor of production leads to an outward shift of this curve, and therefore an increase in the economy’s production possibilities. Country B expects a larger shift because it accumulates a larger quantity of capital goods, thus increasing its production possibilities relatively more than Country A. Country B’s larger PPC shift in the future PPC means that it has possibilities to experience greater economic growth than country A. 16 Part 1: Introduction to Economics Country A consumer goods Present choices and future growth possibilities (In Part 5, we will discover that a number of countries in the 1950s and 1960s tried to achieve rapid economic growth by accumulating large quantities of capital goods; however they were not as successful in actually achieving high rates of economic growth as was hoped. We will study their experiences more carefully in Chapter 17.). X PPCp 0 PPCf capital goods Country B consumer goods Societies must therefore make a choice between the two conflicting objectives: greater fish harvest or maintenance of marine resource quality. Each of these has an opportunity cost: sacrificed fish harvest is the opportunity cost of marine resource preservation. Sacrificed marine resource quality (including young fish survival, reef preservation and so on) is the opportunity cost of greater than sustainable fishing activities. Note that marine source quality conflicts with the size of the fish harvest (the more there is of one, the less there is of the other) because of resource scarcity. If resources were not scarce, it would be possible to fish any quantity of fish, and there would be no damage to the quality of the environment. 0 Y PPCp PPCf capital goods Figure 1.7 Present choices and future growth. 1.3 Basic economic questions, rationing systems and the mixed market economy Three basic economic questions: resource allocation and output/income distribution Scarcity forces every economy in the world, regardless of its form of organization or its level of economic development, to address three basic questions: · What to produce: all economies must choose what particular goods and services and what quantities of these they wish to produce. · How to produce: all economies must make choices on how to use their resources in order to produce goods and services. Goods and services can be produced by use of different combinations of factors of production (for example, relatively more labour with less capital, or relatively more capital with less labour), by using different skill levels of labour, and by using different technologies. · For whom to produce: all economies must make choices about how the goods and services produced are to be distributed among the population. Should everyone get an equal amount of these? Should some people get more than others? Should some goods and services (such as education and health care services) be distributed more equally? The first two of these questions, what to produce and how to produce, are about resource allocation, while the third is about the distribution of income (or output). Let’s see what these mean. Resource allocation refers to assigning available resources, or factors of production, to specific uses chosen among many possible and competing alternatives, and involves answering the what to produce and how to produce questions. When an economy makes a choice about what goods and services to produce, it is also making a decision to assign resources to the production of those goods and services. Consider an example provided by the production possibilities model in Table 1.1 and Figure 1.2. If the economy is initially at point B, it has allocated all its resources to produce 35 microwave ovens and 17 computers. If it wants to move to point C, where it reduces microwave oven production to 26 units and increases computer production to 25 units, it must take some resources out of microwave oven production and move them into computer production; this is called a reallocation of resources: the economy has reassigned resources to the production of a different combination of the two goods. If the economy assigns too many resources to the production of a good or service relative to what is socially desirable, in other words if too much of a good or service is produced, this is referred to as an overallocation of resources to the good or service. If too few resources are assigned to what is socially desirable, there is an underallocation of resources to the good or service. When the economy makes a choice about how to produce its goods and services, it is making a decision about which particular resources and in what quantities these are to be assigned to the production of the goods and services; in other words, it is once again allocating types and quantities of resources to its production. Here, too, if a decision is made to change the particular combinations and quantities of resources used in producing goods and services, there will result a reallocation of resources. The distribution of income (or output) is concerned with how much income different individuals or different groups in the population will receive, and involves answering the for whom to produce question. The distribution of income and of output may be considered together because the amount of goods and services that households can have is closely related to what they are able to buy, which in turn is related to their income level. You can see this in the circular flow model (Figure 1.1), where households receive income by selling the factors of production they own, and use this income to buy goods and services. When the distribution of income or output changes so that different social groups now receive more, or less, income and output than previously, this is referred to as redistribution. In the real world the situation is more complicated because governments (not shown in the simple circular flow model) often intervene in the economy to influence both the allocation of resources and the distribution of income and output. We will study the role of governments in later chapters. Test your understanding 1.14 1 What are the three basic economic questions that must be addressed by any economy? 2 Explain the relationship between the three basic economic questions, and the allocation of resources and the distribution of income or output. (...continued) Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 17 Test your understanding 1.14 (...continued) 3 Consider the following, and identify each one as referring to output/income distribution or redistribution; or to resource allocation, reallocation, overallocation or underallocation (note that there may be more than one answer): (a) Evidence suggests that over the last two decades in many countries around the world the rich are getting richer and the poor are getting poorer. (b) In Brazil, the richest 10% of the population receive 48% of total income. (c) Whereas rich countries typically spend 8–12% of their GDP on providing health care services to their populations, many poor countries spend as little as 2–3% of GDP. (d) Many developing countries devote a significant proportion of their government budget funds for education to spending on university level education, while a substantial proportion of their population remains illiterate. (e) If countries around the world spent less on defence, they would be in a position to expand provision of social services, including health care and education. (f) Pharmaceutical companies spend most of their research funds on developing medicines to treat diseases that are common in rich countries, while ignoring the treatment of diseases that are common in poor countries. How the basic economic questions are answered by market and centrally planned (command) economies Countries around the world differ enormously in the ways they make allocation and distribution decisions. At the heart of their differences lie the methods used to make and coordinate the choices demanded by the what, how and for whom questions. There are two main methods that can be used to make and coordinate choices: the market (also known as ‘free market’) method and the central planning (or command) method. These two methods can be thought of as two ‘ideal types’ of economies. An ‘ideal type’ is an abstract idea that does not claim to represent the real world, but 18 Part 1: Introduction to Economics rather contains some characteristics that serve as a standard for comparison of real-world situations. (Note that an ideal type is not ‘ideal’ in the sense of perfect or excellent.) No actual economy is or ever was a pure market or pure centrally planned (command) type of economy. Real-world economies combine markets and commands in many different ways, and each country is unique in the ways they combine them. The ideal-type market and centrally planned (command) economies are distinguished from each other on the basis of three criteria: · Resource ownership: public or private sector Ownership of society’s resources can be ‘public’ or ‘private’. The public sector refers to the parts of the economy that are under the ownership of the government (whether national, regional or local). The government is also sometimes referred to as the ‘state’. The private sector includes the parts of the economy that are under the ownership of private individuals or groups of individuals; these include consumers (households), firms (businesses) and resource owners, as well as organizations such as NGOs (non-governmental organizations) and interest groups (for example, consumer protection organizations). The market economy has private sector resource ownership, and the centrally planned (command) economy has public sector resource ownership. · Economic decision-making Economic decisions and choices regarding the what, how and for whom questions can be made by the public sector, i.e. the government, or by the private sector. There many private decision-makers, as noted above, but the most important of these are consumers (households), firms (businesses) and resource owners. The market economy has private sector economic decision-making and the centrally planned (command) economy has public sector economic decision-making. · Rationing systems The term rationing can be defined as a method used to apportion or divide something up between its interested users. In Economics it refers to the method used to make resource allocation and output/income distribution decisions. There are two categories of rationing systems: price rationing and non-price rationing: ❍ The market economy uses price rationing to make resource allocation and output/income distribution decisions. This means that all economic decisions relating to what will be produced, how it will be produced and who will receive the output are made on the basis of prices of goods, services and resources that have been determined in markets. ❍ The centrally planned (command) economy uses non-price rationing to make resource allocation and output/income distribution decisions. This means that all decisions relating to what will be produced, how it will be produced and who will receive the output are made by use of methods that have nothing to do with prices determined in markets. Non-price rationing results when there are no markets, or when governments interfere in markets, in which case the government acts as a central authority and makes economic decisions by commands. Both price rationing and non-price rationing will become much clearer to you after you have studied Chapter 2. The market economy is illustrated by the circular flow model (Figure 1.1). This model shows households and firms (the private sector) to be owners of resources, as well as economic decision-makers who make buying and selling decisions, and who are linked together in product and resource markets. As we will see in Chapter 2, product and resource markets determine prices of goods, services and resources, which act as the basis of price rationing. The centrally planned (command) economy is characterized by the absence of markets or the limited operation of markets. As owner of resources and economic decision-maker, the government makes all allocation and distribution decisions through nonprice rationing. This is called a ‘centrally planned’ economy because the government bases all economic decisions on economic plans. It is also known as a ‘command’ economy because the government authority directs and coordinates economic decisions through commands. In the real world, virtually all economies combine elements of both markets and commands. Differences between actual economies lie mainly in the ways the two are combined and in the degrees to which one Table 1.2 predominates. For this reason, most economies in the world today are called mixed economies. Over the past 30 or so years, most economies around the world have been basing their economies increasingly on the market, and correspondingly less on commands. Countries that tend to rely relatively more on the market are called mixed market economies. Table 1.2 provides a summary of the three criteria as they apply to each type of economy. The market economy, also known as free market economy is based on private ownership of resources and private decision-making, and relies on prices determined in free markets and price rationing to coordinate choices that allocate resources and distribute income/output. The centrally planned economy based on central planning (or commands) is based on government (public) ownership of resources and government decisionmaking, and relies on commands and non-price rationing techniques to coordinate choices that allocate resources and distribute income/output. The mixed economy relies on a mix of public and private resource ownership and decision-making, and price and non-price rationing. Characteristics of market and centrally planned (command) economies (You may find that some of the concepts and ideas introduced in the remaining part of this chapter are difficult to understand at this point. However, they will become very clear to you after you have read Chapters 2, 3 and 6 on Microeconomics. You will therefore be reminded to reread and review this part of the chapter after you have completed Chapter 6.) Table 1.3 (page 20) uses the same criteria as in Table 1.2 to show the main characteristics of the two idealtype economies in greater detail. Market, centrally planned (command) and mixed economies. Criteria Market economy Centrally planned (command) economy Mixed economy and mixed market economy Resource ownership private sector public sector public and private sectors Economic decision-making private sector public sector public and private sectors Rationing system price rationing non-price rationing price rationing and non-price rationing Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 19 Table 1.3 Characteristics of market and command economies. Criteria Market economy Centrally planned (command) economy Resource ownership (land and capital) Land and capital resources are privately owned (by consumers and firms); the institution of private property is established and enforced by the government. Land and capital resources are publicly owned (by the government, or state). The institution of private property is limited. Economic decision-making Key decision-makers are consumers, firms and resource owners, all acting in their best self-interest. Consumers maximize the satisfaction (utility) they get from buying goods and services, firms maximize profits, and owners of resources maximize the income they get from selling their resources: for example, workers try to maximize wages, owners of capital maximize interest income, and so on. All decision-makers have freedom of choice. Firms are free to use whatever production method they prefer, and produce and sell whatever good or service they believe will be most profitable. Consumers are free to buy those goods and services that will best satisfy their needs and wants, workers are free to work at whatever job they prefer, and so on. Government planning bodies are the sole decisionmakers. They engage in central planning (also known state planning). All economic activities are based on a ‘central plan’ made by the government, that sets out the economy’s production activities and makes detailed decisions on what and how much of each good and service will be produced, and what resources will be used for production. Freedom of choice is limited: consumers have some limited choice, but there is no possibility of choice by firms and resource (land and capital) owners as firms and resources are government owned and managed. Rationing system Price rationing is used to ration (apportion) all resources, goods and services among their alternative uses. Prices of all goods, services and resources are determined in markets. Prices determined in markets provide all the information to firms, consumers and resource owners that is necessary to guide them in their buying and selling decisions; prices act as signals and incentives. Non-price rationing is used to ration (apportion) all resources, goods and services among their alternative uses. Markets and market-determined prices do not exist. Prices of all goods, services and resources are set administratively by the government in its central plan through the command mechanism; these prices do not act as signals and incentives. Rationing system and resource allocation: answering the what and how to produce questions Resource allocation is accomplished by price rationing. Prices established in markets determine what goods and services will be produced, and how goods and services will be produced, in other words by use of what combinations of resources and technologies. Resource allocation is accomplished through non-price rationing. The government’s central plan determines what goods and services to produce, as well how to produce (i.e. using what resource combinations) by use of commands. Rationing system and income distribution: answering the for whom question Income distribution is also accomplished by price rationing. There are two aspects to this. (i) Prices established in resource markets determine the payments that resource owners will receive (i.e. their income) in exchange for providing their resources to the production process (i.e. owners of labour resources receive wages, owners of capital resources receive interest, etc.). The resource owners use the income they receive to purchase goods and services. (ii) Prices established in product markets determine how much of each good and service will be purchased by individuals: if an individual is willing and able to pay the price in order to buy a good, she or he will get the good. Income distribution is also accomplished by nonprice rationing. There are two aspects to this. (i) Incomes are administratively determined for each worker and paid by the government, who is the sole employer. (ii) Goods and services (all of which are produced by government enterprises) are distributed most commonly by means of waiting in line (a queue), which works on the first come, first served principle (those who come last don’t get the good if it is sold out). Goods that are considered to be important for the satisfaction of basic needs (such as staple foods, essential clothing) may be assigned a low price, whereas luxury goods are likely to be assigned a high price. Certain goods and services that are considered to be socially desirable are provided free of charge (such as education and health care). 20 Part 1: Introduction to Economics Test your understanding 1.15 1 What are the basic economic questions that must be answered by (a) free market economies; (b) centrally planned economies; (c) mixed economies? · Promotion of efficiency The operation of the invisible hand means that the free and self-interested behaviour of economic decision-makers linked together through markets improves society’s welfare by promoting economic efficiency. The market mechanism results in two types of efficiency: ❍ 2 Use the criteria appearing in Table 1.3 to compare and contrast the main characteristics of the market and centrally planned economies. 3 Differences in resource ownership between market and centrally planned economies refer only to ‘land’ and ‘capital’. Why do you think labour and entrepreneurship are excluded? (Hint: is it possible for labour and entrepreneurship to be publicly owned?) 4 Why is the command economy also referred to as a centrally planned economy? 5 Compare and contrast the methods by which allocation and distribution choices are made in the market economy and the centrally planned economy. ❍ Productive efficiency (that we defined in connection with the production possibilities model) means that output is produced by use of the fewest possible resources (or at the lowest possible cost). When productive efficiency is achieved, the how to produce question is answered in the best possible way from society’s point of view, because there is no waste of resources. Allocative efficiency means that resources are being used to produce those goods and services that are mostly wanted by society. When allocative efficiency is achieved, the what to produce question is answered in the best possible way, because resources are used to produce those goods and services that result in the greatest possible benefits for consumers. 6 (a) Define and explain the difference between price rationing and non-price rationing. (b) What are the functions of these two rationing mechanisms? (c) In what kind of economic system does each one predominate? When there is both productive and allocative efficiency, an economy achieves the best possible allocation of resources, as it answers both the what to produce and the how to produce questions in the best possible way from the point of view of what is in society’s best interests. Evaluating the market economy Key advantages The key advantages of the market economy include the following: · Systematic and automatic coordination of individual decisions: the invisible hand of the market The market economy gives rise to a systematic and automatic coordination of innumerable individual decisions in the absence of any central authority. In the free market system, the decisions of individual consumers, firms and resource owners are coordinated through their interactions in resource and product markets. There is no one managing or coordinating these decisions; the system is decentralized, and markets themselves are the organizing principle of the economy. This mechanism was termed ‘the invisible hand’ of markets by one of the earliest economists, Adam Smith, in the 18th century. · The pursuit of self-interest provides incentives that promote economic growth When all private decisionmakers (consumers, firms and resource owners) make decisions on the basis of what they believe to be in their best self-interest (as explained in Table 1.3), this gives rise to incentives for hard work, risktaking and innovation, which lead to higher levels of output and improved levels of living. The market system may therefore promote general welfare by advancing economic growth. Key limitations As noted earlier, the market mechanism is an ideal type that does not and cannot ever exist in the real world. The advantages noted above can only be realized under some very strict conditions that are never met in the real world. In the absence of these conditions, the market fails to achieve the socially desirable objectives listed above. The reasons are that: Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 21 · The market can fail to provide certain goods that are desirable, or can result in the production of some goods in smaller quantities than are socially desirable. · The market can end up producing certain activities that are socially undesirable (such as the polluting activities of many firms). · Large producers/sellers can limit competition, and produce less output at higher cost, and sell this output at higher prices than are socially desirable. · The market is unable to deal effectively with the issues of unemployment, inflation and economic growth and development. · People in vulnerable social groups may receive very low or no income if they have few or no resources to sell, or if they are unable to work (i.e. sell their labour). · The market cannot operate effectively without a strong institutional and legal framework that must be established and enforced by the government, such as, for example, the institution of private property and property rights. Because of these shortcomings, governments intervene in the market with various policies in order to improve outcomes in favour of society’s general welfare. We therefore never see a free market economy operating in the pure form described above. All the problems listed here require some form of government intervention that we will study in later chapters. Test your understanding 1.16 1 Explain the role of the invisible hand in a market economy. 2 What is the relationship between allocative and productive efficiency and resource allocation? 3 Explain the main advantages of the market economy. 4 Why has there never existed a pure free market economy in the real world? Evaluating the centrally planned (command) economy The centrally planned or command economy as an ideal type described above has never existed in the real world; however, it was approximated during the 20th century by communist countries, which relied 22 Part 1: Introduction to Economics heavily on central planning of most of their economic activities. Also, many non-communist less developed countries adopted some elements of central planning in the 1950s–1970s in the belief that this would promote more rapid growth and development (among them, India, Egypt and many countries in Africa). The development of central planning historically was prompted in part by a recognition of the disadvantages of markets, noted above, which tend to be even more pronounced in less developed countries. It was also associated with the ideological principle that the institution of private property goes against the interests of the broader population. It was believed that certain objectives such as rapid economic growth and development would be better served through direct administration and government planning of economic activities. Another important objective was poverty alleviation through a more equal distribution of income, as well as provision by the government of important social services (health care, education) that would be widely distributed throughout the population. However, centrally planned economies have run into serious difficulties: · highly inefficient use of resources (productive inefficiency), due to the extreme technical difficulties involved in central planning of all economic activities, and its dependence on very detailed information – essential for planning economic activities but not readily available · absence of incentives for producers since they do not own resources (land and capital) and have no price system on which they can base their decisions · excessive bureaucracy that interferes with achieving economic objectives effectively · goods and services produced are unlikely to reflect society’s preferences as planners do not base their output decisions on what consumers want (allocative inefficiency) · limited variety in the goods and services produced (allocative inefficiency) · limited freedom of choice for all non-governmental economic decision-makers (consumers, producers). There remain very few countries in the world today that are still highly centrally planned; these include North Korea, and to a lesser extent Cuba; most others have begun to introduce major reforms intended to strengthen the role of markets. Test your understanding 1.17 1 What are the main limitations of the centrally planned economy? 2 What do you think are some of the advantages that market economies have over planned economies and central planning of most economic activities? The mixed market economy Virtually all economies are mixed economies, but increasingly, economies in the world today are becoming mixed market economies, strongly based on the market system, with varying degrees and types of government involvement. There is a mix of private and public sector ownership and decision-making, and a mix of price and non-price rationing systems, but a significant portion of economic activity is based on the market mechanism with price rationing playing a more important role in determining resource allocation and income distribution. In mixed market economies, public or private sector ownership and decision-making often go together; for example, privately owned firms usually make decisions about what and how they will produce and sell, while the government makes decisions about economic activities that fall under its ownership (such as or public health services, public road systems, public parks, defence facilities and many others). However, the government’s decision-making role in the mixed market economy is not limited to activities falling under its ownership; it also extends into private sector activities. For example, the United States, one of more market-oriented countries in the world, has a government presence in the form of government decision-making that affects the workings of the private sector in such diverse areas as minimum wage legislation, subsidies for agricultural products, restrictions on imports, regulation of private sector activities, anti-monopoly legislation, tax collection, income redistribution and many others. All mixed market economies in fact have government involvement with the private sector that arises either as a response to the failure of the pure market mechanism to work well for the reasons noted earlier, or in response to the demands of politically powerful interest groups. We will examine government intervention in the market for both these sets of reasons extensively in later chapters. Government involvement in the private sector varies widely from country to country in extensiveness. For example, the free market plays a more prominent role in the United Kingdom and the United States than in France and Japan. Also, government involvement in the private sector varies in the form that it takes. For example, in the Nordic countries (Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway and Sweden), there is extensive government intervention in income redistribution; in Japan, extensive government intervention takes the form of planning and coordinating private sector activities. It is important to note that whatever the reasons for and types of government intervention in the market, government intervention changes the allocation of resources and distribution of income and output from what the market system working on its own would have achieved. In mixed market economies, both price and non-price rationing can be observed, but with price rationing predominating. In general, price rationing arises in situations where there is a market for resources, goods and services. If there is no market (or if markets are not free because of government intervention), then some form of non-price rationing occurs. For example, when governments in market economies provide national defence, public health care systems, public road systems and flood control, they do not rely on price rationing to determine resource allocation and output distribution, and the role of the government agencies that plan and provide these services is similar to the role of the central planner. Consider the case of national health systems, where the government, through tax financing, undertakes to provide health care services that are made available to the entire population free (or nearly free) of charge. Since there is no price charged to the consumer who receives a service, some mechanism other than price, i.e. nonprice rationing, must be used to distribute the service among its users. The most commonly used non-price mechanism is waiting in line or a waiting period (i.e. queues). There have been significant changes over time in the relative prominence of private versus public sector activities. During much of the 20th century, many Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 23 countries throughout the world saw significant increases in government participation in economic decision-making. Since the 1980s, there has been a shift once again in the direction of less public sector involvement and a corresponding growth in private sector activities. In many countries around the world, including both more developed and less developed ones, the increasing importance of market-based activities has been due to the growing popularity of supply-side economic policies (to be discussed in Chapters 9 and 17), as well as a recognition of the limitations of central planning. In China and former communist countries whose economies used to be strongly based on central planning, a deliberate choice was made to move away from planning and towards a mixed market economy; these economies are called ‘economies in transition’ and will be the topic of the next section. Test your understanding 1.18 1 How do mixed market economies differ from (a) pure market economies and (b) mixed economies? Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union Measures designed to achieve a very rapid transition to a market system have been termed ‘shock therapy’, and include the following key reforms: · privatization of state enterprises (firms) and government property in many areas, including manufacturing, agriculture, services and housing; privatization involves the transfer of ownership from the public sector to the private sector · reform of the price system, consisting of freeing of prices so that they become more responsive to the forces of demand and supply; this involves a transition from methods of non-price rationing to price rationing · promotion of competition by breaking up large state monopolies; this involves the break-up of large government-owned firms, or state monopolies, into a number of smaller privately owned firms that compete with each other · opening trade and finance to the international economy; under central planning countries were for the most part cut off from the global economy. 2 Can you provide some examples of command practices in mixed market economies? 3 Why do you think most economies in the world today are mixed market economies? Economies in transition: moving towards the mixed market The term economy in transition refers to any country that is making the transition from a predominantly centrally planned economy towards a mixed market economy, as for example after the collapse of communist regimes in eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union in 1989–90. The countries in this group include the ones that emerged after the break-up of the Soviet Union (15) and Yugoslavia (7), plus the countries of eastern Europe that experienced a transition to democratic regimes. China, also a transition economy, has taken a different route by choosing to introduce market reforms gradually under the strong direction of its Communist Party. 24 Part 1: Introduction to Economics The experiences of the various economies in transition have been highly diverse with respect to how far they have progressed with these reforms, as well as in the degree of their success. In the early years many encountered severe difficulties due to hyperinflation (very high rates of inflation, or rapid increases in the general price level) that emerged from the freeing of prices, and very significant drops in incomes and output (negative growth over a period of several years). This followed from the bankruptcy of many government enterprises because of their inability to compete in the new environment, rapidly growing unemployment, the break-up of trade relationships with former communist-block trade partners and a highly uncertain environment for economic activity. In addition, many problems arose from the absence of appropriate legislative and regulatory measures for the smooth operation of private sector activities. Many countries, particularly in eastern Europe, have succeeded in resolving most of the difficulties, and are on the road to developing strong mixed market economies (for example, Czech Republic, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Hungary, Poland, Slovenia and others) while some other countries are progressing more slowly. China In contrast to the rapid reforms undertaken by the countries of the former Soviet Union and eastern Europe, China has pursued a more gradual approach to reform, occurring in several steps: · Reform of agriculture Beginning in 1978, agricultural reform consisted of abolishing the commune system. Under the commune system, farmers had to sell all their output to the government at low fixed prices. Since their income depended on the overall commune output and not on the output produced by each individual farmer, the system deprived farmers of the incentive to work harder and increase output. The commune system was replaced by farming on individual leased plots of land, with the right to sell a portion of agricultural output in markets; this gave an enormous boost to agricultural production. · Freedom of farmers to leave the farm Since the 1980s, farmers have been permitted to seek work in township and village industrial enterprises, providing a boost to the industrial sector that used labour-intensive production techniques (the term ‘labour intensive’ refers to production methods that use a relatively large proportion of labour compared to other factors of production. We will return to this concept in Chapter 15). · Establishment of special economic zones or special free-trade zones Beginning in the 1980s, private ownership, foreign investment and international trade were permitted in special economic zones established for this purpose; this marked the beginning of China’s boom in exports of textiles, clothing, footwear, toys and plastics. · Greater freedom granted to state-owned enterprises Beginning in the 1980s, state-owned enterprises were permitted to determine what quantities of output to produce, to make decisions on employment, to sell a portion of output in markets, and to retain a large portion of profits (as opposed to the previous practice of transferring their profits to the central government); while granting state enterprises greater authority, this reform has stopped short of privatizing them. China has attracted a deal of attention around the world, because it has succeeded in achieving very rapid economic growth over many years. However, the Chinese economy is not without problems, which include: · Incomplete property rights Property rights (or ownership rights) are the rights of an owner over property, and are established by law. If there are no clear property rights, a market economy cannot function properly as there is uncertainty and risk associated with undertaking activities relating to the ‘property’. For example, it is risky to build a house or a factory on a piece of land whose ownership has not been legally secured. · Financial indebtedness of state-owned enterprises Many government-owned enterprises operate inefficiently and have contributed to a huge government debt that some fear may lead to a financial crisis. · Periodic inflation The Chinese economy every now and then experiences high rates of inflation (a rapidly rising general price level). · Lack of integration in the global economy The Chinese economy is not yet fully integrated in the international finance system. · Uneven economic growth and development by geographical region Some regions experience far greater economic growth and development while other regions lag significantly behind; this is a serious problem as the benefits of growth and development are not shared equally throughout the population. · Serious environmental degradation China’s growth is environmentally unsustainable; it is occurring at the expense of the natural environment, which has been severely neglected by the public sector (the government) and the private sector. Test your understanding 1.19 1 (a) What are ‘economies in transition’? (b) What are their economic objectives and what principal reforms are they pursuing? 2 Based on the experiences of transition economies, what are some of the problems that can be encountered when moving from a centrally planned to a mixed market economy? 3 What are some of the ways that China’s approach to transition differs from the approach followed by eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union? 4 Why do you think secure property rights are an important feature of a mixed market economy? Chapter 1: Fundamental concepts in Economics 25 Questions for review 1.1 [10 marks] (a) It has been said that if there were no scarcity, there would be no social science of economics. Do you agree with this statement? Explain why or why not. (b) Using examples, explain the fundamental problem of Economics. 1.2 [15 marks] Assuming that a simple hypothetical economy produces two goods, use appropriate diagrams to answer the following: (a) How likely is it that the economy’s actual output will be located at some point on its production possibilities curve? Explain. (b) If the economy produces at a point inside the curve, what must it do if it wants to increase its actual production of both goods? (Use the concepts of full employment and productive efficiency in your answer.) (c) What is the opportunity cost of moving from a point inside the PPC to a point closer to the PPC? (d) What is the opportunity cost of moving from one point on the PPC to another point on the PPC? (e) Explain why your answers to questions (c) and (d) are different. (f) Can the economy produce at a point outside its PPC? Why or why not? 1.3 [10 marks] Define opportunity cost, and use the production possibilities model to explain how it is related to the concepts of scarcity and choice. 1.4 [10 marks] Do you think the production possibilities model can be useful in explaining the concept of a free good? Explain why or why not. 1.5 [10 marks] A hypothetical country discovers oil within its territory. (a) Show the impact of this discovery diagrammatically using the production possibilities model. (b) Using your diagram of part (a), show the possible choices that can be made between (i) growth without economic development, (ii) growth with economic development. 1.6 [10 marks] A number of countries (such as the former Soviet Union and India) during the 1950s and 1960s directed a relatively large proportion of their resources to heavy industries involved in capital goods production, while they tended to neglect consumer goods production. Explain the reasoning behind their choice by use of the production possibilities model. 26 Part 1: Introduction to Economics 1.7 [20 marks] (a) What are the three basic economic questions that must be answered by all economies regardless of their form of organization? (b) Explain the concepts of resource allocation and income/output distribution. (c) How do resource allocation and income/output distribution relate to the three basic economic questions? (d) Compare and contrast how resource allocation and output/income distribution are achieved in market and centrally planned economies. Part 2 Microeconomics Microeconomics is concerned with the behaviour of consumers, firms and resource owners, who are the most important economic decision-makers in a market economy. We will study the model of demand and supply, which forms the basis of the market economy and is one of the most important analytical tools in microeconomics. We will learn about the benefits of free markets, and we will also examine some of their imperfections. We will also examine the role of governments in a variety of situations. We will see what effects governments have when they interfere in markets, as well as how they can help achieve better social outcomes when markets fail to perform well. In addition, Part 2 will also be concerned with market or industry structures (at higher level). We will learn about a variety of ways in which real-world industries are organized, and their advantages and disadvantages from the perspectives of consumers, firms and societies. The tools that we will develop in microeconomics are very important, because they provide many insights into the workings of the market economy, and into the effects of different types of government intervention. But, in addition, these tools are important because they form the basis of additional topics that we will study in later parts of this book, particularly in the area of international economics. Chapter 2 Microeconomics Markets In this chapter we examine what lies at the heart of every market-based economy: the forces of demand and supply. We will also study what happens in an economy when governments interfere with these forces. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · · · · · · · · · · explain the basic differences between the four different market structures explain the factors that influence demand identify exceptions to the law of demand (higher level topic) explain the factors that influence supply understand the behaviour of buyers and sellers, and explain how demand and supply interact in competitive markets to determine equilibrium price and quantity analyse the effects of changes in demand and supply and predict changes in equilibrium prices and quantities explain the rationing function of prices in competitive markets, and their role in resource allocation and output/ income distribution explain the significance of allocative and productive efficiency in the market economy analyse the consequences of price ceilings and price floors analyse how buffer stock schemes are intended to work. 2.1 Introduction to markets and market structures Markets A market originally was a place where people gathered to buy and sell goods. Such markets still exist today, for example cattle markets, fish markets, fruit and vegetable markets, flea markets, involving a physical meeting place where buyers and sellers meet face to face. The term market has since evolved to include any kind of arrangement where buyers and sellers of a particular good, service or resource are linked together to carry out an exchange. The market may be in a specific place (such as a vegetable market), or it may involve many different 28 Part 2: Microeconomics places (such as the oil market). Buyers and sellers may meet (say, in a shop), or they may never meet, communicating by fax, phone, internet, classified ads, or any other method which allows them to convey information about price, quantity and quality. A market can be local, where the buyers and sellers originate from a local area; it may be national, in which case the buyers and sellers are from anywhere within a country; or it may be international, with buyers and sellers from anywhere in the world. For example, small neighbourhood bakeries produce and sell bread and other baked goods for the local community – this is a local market. Local takeaway restaurants also produce for the local market. The labour market, on the other hand, tends to be mostly a national market. By contrast, the world oil market includes oil producers in different countries, and buyers of oil virtually everywhere in the world, as well as wholesalers, retailers and other intermediaries involved in buying and selling oil around the world. Goods and services are sold in product markets, while resources (or factors of production) are sold in resource markets (or factor markets). As we know from the circular flow model (Chapter 1, page 6), households (or consumers) are buyers of goods and services in product markets and sellers of factors of production in resource markets; firms (or businesses) are buyers of factors of production in resource markets and sellers of goods and services in product markets. · how easy or difficult it is for new firms to enter the industry and begin producing, which depends on the degree to which there are barriers to entry in the industry; barriers to entry include anything that can prevent a firm from entering an industry and beginning production. Perfect competition (or pure competition) Test your understanding 2.1 Perfect competition has the following characteristics: 1 What is a market? · There is a very large number of firms in the industry. · Each firm has no control over the price at which 2 Can you think of more examples of local, national and international markets? Firms, industries and market structures A firm (or business) is an organization that employs factors of production to produce and sell a good or service. A group of one or more firms producing identical or similar products (goods or services) is called an industry. For example, the car industry consists of a number of firms that are car manufacturers (Ford, Honda, Mercedes, etc.); the shoe industry consists of firms that are shoe manufacturers; the banking industry consists of firms that provide banking services (banks); the agricultural industry consists of firms that produce agricultural products (farms). There are many kinds of industries with various characteristics, which economists analyse by use of models called market structures. A market structure describes characteristics of a market organization that determine the behaviour of firms within an industry. There are four market structures identified by economists: · perfect competition (also known as pure competition) · monopoly · monopolistic competition · oligopoly. Market structures can be defined on the basis of four main characteristics: · the number of firms in the industry · the ability of the firm to control the price at which the good is sold in the market · the type of product, in particular how similar or different are the goods or services produced by firms in the industry it sells its product; because of the large number of firms, each firm’s output is a very small fraction of the total output of the industry so it cannot influence price. · All the firms in the industry sell a standardized or identical (undifferentiated) product; from the consumers’ point of view it makes no difference from which firm they buy the product, as it is exactly the same in all firms; there are no brand names. · There are no barriers to entry into the industry; any firm that would like to enter the industry and begin producing and selling the good or service can do so freely. Examples of perfect competition include the international markets for agricultural commodities such as wheat, rice, corn and livestock, other commodities like silver and gold, stock and bond markets, and the foreign exchange market (in which currencies of different countries are bought and sold). In all these cases, each firm is so small relative to the total number of firms that it is impossible for any one of them to have any control over the price of the item being sold. Further, the product sold by all firms is identical, and any new firm is free to enter the industry. Note that perfect competition occurs mostly in international markets and sometimes in national ones. Perfectly competitive markets are not encountered frequently in the real world. Monopoly Monopoly has the following characteristics: · There is a single firm in the industry. · The firm has significant control over the price at which its product is sold in the market. · The firm produces and sells a unique good or service, which cannot be purchased elsewhere. Chapter 2: Markets 29 · There are high barriers to entry in the industry; if a new firm would like to enter the industry, it cannot do so. (The reasons for this are examined in Chapter 5 at higher level.) Examples of monopolies include telephone, water and electricity companies in areas where they operate as a single supplier. These may be local areas, in which case the firm is a local monopoly, or it may involve a national market if it covers all residents of a country. A postal service is another example of a monopoly with a national market. On the other hand, Microsoft Corporation is a monopoly in the market for Windows®, which is an international market. In all these cases, there is a single firm providing the entire, or at least the greatest part of the market, whether this is local, national or international; the consumer has no choice but to purchase the good or service from this firm; and it is extremely difficult for other firms to enter the industry. Since a monopolist is the sole producer in an industry, it has significant control over the price at which it sells its good or service. Like firms in perfect competition, monopolies are not frequently encountered in the real world. Monopolistic competition Monopolistic competition has the following characteristics: · There is a fairly large number of firms in the industry (but not as large as in perfect competition). · Each firm has a substantial amount of control over the price at which its product is sold. · There is product differentiation; this means that each firm in the industry tries to make its product different from those of the other firms in the industry; these differences may be in the many different characteristics of the product, the quality, the servicing or the packaging. · There are very low barriers to entry in the industry; any new firm can easily enter the industry and begin producing and selling the good or service. Examples of monopolistic competition include the shoe, clothing, detergent, computer, publishing, furniture and restaurant industries. Monopolistic competition is like perfect competition in that there are many firms in the industry. It differs from perfect competition mainly because of product differentiation. By trying to make its good or service different from any other, each firm tries to be like a little monopoly. 30 Part 2: Microeconomics This is possible because each firm is the only producer of that particular version of the product. For example, Nike is a monopolist of Nike shoes, and Reebok is a monopolist of Reebok shoes. Monopolistically competitive firms use product differentiation in order gain some control over the price at which their products are sold. However, the existence of other similar products (in the example here, other brands of shoes) limits the degree of its power to control the market prices. Monopolistic competition occurs in local, national and international markets. Oligopoly Oligopoly has the following characteristics: · There is a small number of large firms in the industry. · Firms have significant control over price, but this occurs only when they recognize that because of their small number their actions are interdependent. · The products may be either differentiated or undifferentiated. · There are high barriers to entry; it is not easy for a new firm to enter and begin producing and selling in the industry. Examples of oligopolies include the car industry, airlines, electrical appliances, electronic equipment (differentiated products) and the steel, aluminium, copper, cement industries (identical or undifferentiated products). They often operate in international markets, and sometimes in national ones. There are different kinds of oligopolies: there might be one dominant firm in the industry in terms of size and its share of the market coexisting with several other smaller firms; or there might be a group of dominant firms alongside a number of smaller firms. Oligopolies have significant control over price. A feature of oligopolies that makes them different from the other three market structures is that because of their small number in the industry, the firms are interdependent: the behaviour of one firm affects the behaviour of the others. As a result they engage in actions unlike those of firms in the other three market structures in an effort to exercise control over price. Most industries in the real world are monopolistically competitive or oligopolistic. Table 2.1 summarizes the main characteristics of each of the four market structures. Table 2.1 Characteristics of market structures. Perfect competition Monopoly Monopolistic competition Oligopoly Number of firms Market power/control over price Type of product Barriers to entry into the industry Examples very many none undifferentiated/ standardized none agriculture one, large very significant one product with no close substitutes high public utilities relatively many, relatively small some differentiated very low restaurants, CDs, computer games, books, furniture few large significant differentiated or undifferentiated high steel, aluminium, cars, household appliances Test your understanding 2.2 1 What are the four market structures? Define them on the basis of their key characteristics. 2 Can you think of examples of industries that are (a) perfectly competitive (b) monopolistic (c) monopolistically competitive (d) oligopolistic? Market structure, competition and market power Competition is generally understood to be a process in which rivals compete in order to achieve some objective. For example, firms may compete with each other over who will sell the most output, consumers may compete over who will buy a scarce product, workers compete over who will get the best jobs with the highest salaries, countries compete over which will capture the biggest export markets, and so on. But beyond this everyday sense, the term ‘competition’ in economics is meaningful in the context of market structures. Competition occurs when there are many buyers and sellers acting independently, so that no one has the ability to influence the price at which the product is sold in the market. By contrast, market power, also known as monopoly power, refers to the control that a firm has over the price of the product it sells in the market. The greater the market power, the greater is the control over price. It follows that the greater the degree of competition in an industry, the less the market power of firms, and the weaker is each firm’s control over the price that prevails in the market. Figure 2.1 (page 32) shows how the four market structures relate to each other in these respects. Moving from left to right, there is less competition, more market power and greater control over price. At one extreme of the four market structures is perfect competition, which is completely (or perfectly) competitive, where firms have no market power and no control over price. At the opposite extreme lies monopoly, where a single seller faces no competition, has significant market power, and therefore significant control over price. In between the two extremes lie monopolistic competition and oligopoly. In monopolistic competition there is a substantial degree of competition between firms, but in trying to create some monopoly power for the particular version of their product, firms end up having substantial influence over the price that prevails in the market for their own particular product. Oligopolistic firms, on the other hand, usually go to great lengths to try to limit the competition between them, and this results in significant control over price. Chapter 2: Markets 31 Perfect competition Monopolistic competition Oligopoly most competition least (zero) competition zero market power most market power zero control over market price Figure 2.1 Monopoly significant control over market price Market structure, competition and market power. The different market structures, and their varying degrees of competition, market power and control over price are important issues because each one affects the allocation of resources and the efficiency of resource use differently. Each structure has its own particular advantages and disadvantages. Of the four market structures, perfect competition gives rise to highly desirable outcomes from a social point of view. It usually results in larger quantities of output, and products are sold at lower prices. It can give rise to an allocation of resources which best satisfies the needs and wants of consumers, and it can also minimize waste in the use of resources, by ensuring that they are used in the most efficient way. The greater the degree of competition, understood to mean the inability of economic decision-makers to control price, the closer is an economy to realizing these desirable results. The model of perfect competition is therefore studied extensively, even though in the real world most markets are not perfectly competitive. Perfect competition provides a standard for comparison of other market structures with an ideal. In addition, a study of perfect competition offers important insights into the workings of mixed market economies, discussed in Chapter 1, page 23. Test your understanding 2.3 2.2 Demand, supply and price determination We now turn to a study of a competitive market. We are interested in seeing how the independent actions of numerous buyers and sellers, none of whom individually have any control over price, interact in markets where prices are determined. Demand Demand is concerned with the behaviour of buyers. Consumers (or households) are buyers of goods and services in product markets, whereas firms are buyers of factors of production in resource markets (recall the circular flow model). In our analysis of demand and supply we will focus mainly on product markets and therefore on the behaviour of consumers as buyers (though the same general principles described here apply also to the behaviour of firms as buyers in resource markets). Individual demand Consumers buy goods and services in product markets. As buyers, they are demanders of those items they wish to buy. 1 What is the meaning of ‘competition’ in Economics? 2 Explain the relationship between competition and market power, and show how the four market structures relate to each other with respect to these features. The demand of an individual consumer indicates the various quantities of a good (or service) the consumer is willing and able to buy at different possible prices during a particular time period, ceteris paribus (all other things equal). 3 Why are competitive markets studied extensively? 32 Part 2: Microeconomics A consumer’s demand for a good can be presented as a demand schedule, which is a table listing quantity demanded at various prices. Table 2.2 shows a consumer’s demand schedule for chocolate bars. When the price of chocolate bars is $5, the consumer is willing and able to buy two chocolate bars in a week. Quantity of chocolate bars demanded (per week) 5 2 4 4 3 6 2 8 1 10 (a) Demand curve for an individual consumer. (b) Willingness to pay and marginal benefit. 5 5 4 3 2 1 D 0 2 4 6 8 10 quantity of chocolate bars (per week) willingness to pay ($) Price of chocolate bars ($) price of chocolate bars ($) Table 2.2 Demand schedule for a consumer. 4 3 2 1 D = MB 0 2 4 6 8 10 quantity of chocolate bars (per week) Figure 2.2 Demand, willingness to pay and marginal benefit. When the price is $4, the consumer is willing and able to buy four chocolate bars in a week, and so on. ‘Willing’ means the consumer wants to buy the good; ‘able’ means that the consumer can afford to buy it. (You may want to buy a Ferrari, but can you afford it? If not, your desire to buy one will not show up as demand for Ferraris.) Ceteris paribus means that all things other than price that can affect how much the consumer is willing and able to buy are assumed to be constant and unchanging. In fact, the consumer’s demand is affected not only by price, but also by many other things, such as the consumer’s income and tastes, and the prices of related goods. For the moment, we put all those other things aside and concentrate only on the relationship between the quantity of a good the consumer is willing and able to buy, and its price. Later we will also consider the effects of all those other influences on the consumer’s demand. The information contained in the demand schedule can be plotted as a graph, shown in Figure 2.2(a). In the graph, the price of chocolate bars is plotted on the vertical axis and quantity of chocolate bars on the horizontal axis. The curve in Figure 2.2(a) is a demand curve. (Note that even though this is a straight line, it is referred to as a ‘curve’.) The demand schedule and the demand curve do not tell us anything about how many chocolate bars the consumer will actually buy, and what price the consumer will pay. This information will be given to us later through the interaction of demand with supply. The demand information alone only tells us how many chocolate bars the consumer would be prepared to buy if the price were $5, or $4, and so on. The law of demand: why the demand curve slopes downward The demand curve plotted in Figure 2.2(a) illustrates a very important relationship: as the price of a good falls, the quantity of the good demanded increases. When two variables change in opposite directions (so that as one falls the other increases) they are said to have an ‘inverse’ or ‘indirect’relationship. The inverse relationship between the two variables, price and quantity demanded, is known as the ‘law of demand’. According to the law of demand, there is an inverse relationship between the quantity of a good demanded over a particular time period and its price, ceteris paribus: as the price of the good increases, the quantity of the good demanded falls; as the price falls, the quantity demanded increases, all other things equal. The law of demand is most likely to be consistent with your experience. The higher the price of a good, the less of it you are probably willing and able to buy; as the price falls, the good becomes more affordable, and you are likely to want and be able to buy more of it. Chapter 2: Markets 33 What is the economic reasoning behind this relationship? As you may remember from Chapter 1, page 3, consumers buy goods and services because these provide them with some benefit, or satisfaction, also known as utility (we are using these words interchangeably). The greater the quantity of a good consumed, the greater the benefit derived. However, as the quantity of a good consumed increases, the extra benefit provided by each additional unit does not increase by a constant amount; rather it increases by less and less. Consider the following example. Imagine you are thirsty and would like to drink a soft drink. You buy one soft drink, which provides you with a certain amount of benefit. You are still thirsty, so you buy a second. Whereas you will enjoy your second soft drink, you will most likely enjoy it less than you had enjoyed the first; in other words the second soft drink provides you with less benefit than the first. If you buy a third, you will get even less benefit than from the second, and so on with each additional soft drink. The extra benefit that you get from each additional unit of something you buy is called the marginal benefit (marginal means extra or additional). This example illustrates a general principle: As the quantity of a good consumed increases, the marginal (or additional) benefit it provides to the consumer decreases. This principle is known as the law of diminishing marginal utility. Remember now the definition of the demand curve: it shows the quantity of a good a consumer is willing and able to buy at different prices (ceteris paribus). Another way of saying the same thing is to say that the demand curve shows what price the consumer is willing to pay in order to get different quantities of the good. The consumer’s willingness to pay is the amount she or he is willing to spend in order to get a unit of the good. It is determined by what the good is worth to the consumer, which is the marginal benefit. You can see this in Figure 2.2(b), which is exactly the same as Figure 2.2(a), except that the vertical axis now shows the consumer’s willingness to pay for the good, and the demand curve is labelled MB (for marginal benefit). Figure 2.2(b) shows that willingness to pay for an additional unit of a good falls as the number of units bought increase. The reason behind falling willingness to pay is decreasing marginal benefit. It follows then that: 34 Part 2: Microeconomics The explanation for the shape of the demand curve can be found in the principle of decreasing marginal benefit: since marginal benefit falls as quantity consumed increases, the consumer’s willingness to pay also falls as the quantity increases. Note that different consumers have a different willingness to pay for a good, because they have different preferences (likes and dislikes), and therefore derive different marginal benefits from consumption of a good. This is reflected in different demands (or demand curves) for different consumers. Market demand So far we have considered the demand for a good of one individual consumer. Market demand indicates the total quantities in the market for the good consumers are willing and able to buy at different prices (during a particular period of time, all other things equal). Market demand is the sum of all individual demands for that good. Figure 2.3 shows how the quantity demanded by Consumer A is added to the quantity demanded by Consumer B, and so on until all the quantities demanded by all consumers of chocolate bars are added up. (Note that Consumer A has a different demand for chocolate bars than Consumer B, indicating different preferences, and therefore different marginal benefits and willingness to pay.) For example, at the price of $4, we add the 4 bars demanded by Consumer A to the 5 bars demanded by Consumer B, and so on to all the quantities demanded by other consumers, to arrive at the sum of 6000 chocolate bars per week. This sum is a point on the market demand curve Dm. When we add individual demands in this way for each of the possible prices, we derive the entire market demand curve Dm, showing the total demand in the chocolate bar market. Market demand is the sum of all individual demands for a good. The market demand curve illustrates the law of demand, shown by an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded. The market demand curve can also be considered as the sum of consumers’ marginal benefits. price of chocolate bars ($) (a) Demand of Consumer A. (b) Demand of Consumer B. (c) Market demand. P($) P($) 5 5 5 4 4 + 3 + 3 2 2 1 DA 1 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 quantity of chocolate bars 0 demands of other consumers in the market 4 = 3 2 1 DB 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 quantity of chocolate bars Dm 2 4 6 8 10 12 quantity of chocolate bars (thousands) Figure 2.3 Market demand as the sum of individual demands. Determinants of demand The determinants of demand are the variables other than price that can influence demand. They are the variables that were assumed to be constant and unchanging when the relationship between price and quantity demanded was being examined, by use of the ceteris paribus assumption. We will now see what happens to the demand curve when these variables change. Changes in the determinants of demand cause shifts in the demand curve. This means that the entire demand curve moves to the right or to the left. In Figure 2.4, note that the vertical axis is labelled ‘P’, which stands for price, and the horizontal axis is labelled ‘Q’, standing for quantity. (This is the standard labelling practice we will be following from now on.) Let’s say that the original demand curve is given by D1. If price is P1, then the demand curve D1 indicates that quantity Q1 will be demanded. What happens if the demand curve now shifts to the right, to D2? As we can see in the figure, at the same price P1, a larger quantity, Q2, will be demanded. If on the other hand the demand curve shifts to the left, from D1 to D3, then a smaller quantity, Q3, will be demanded at the same price P1. A rightward shift of the demand curve indicates that more is demanded for a given price; a leftward shift of the demand curve indicates that less is demanded for a given price. A rightward shift of the curve is called an increase in demand; a leftward shift is called a decrease in demand. P decrease in demand increase in demand P1 D3 0 Q3 D1 Q1 D2 Q2 Q Figure 2.4 Shifts in the demand curve. The determinants of market demand include: · The number of buyers If there is an increase in the number of buyers (demanders), demand increases and therefore the market demand curve shifts to the right; if the number of buyers decreases, demand decreases and the curve shifts to the left. This follows simply from the fact that market demand is the sum of all individual demands. · Tastes If tastes change in favour of a product (the good becomes more popular), demand increases and the demand curve shifts to the right; if tastes change against the product (it becomes less popular) demand decreases and the demand curve shifts to the left. · Income in the case of normal goods When demand for a good increases in response to an increase in consumer income, the good is a normal good Chapter 2: Markets 35 (a good is normal if the demand for it varies directly with income). Most goods are normal goods. Therefore an increase in income will give rise to a rightward shift in the demand curve when the good is normal, and a decrease in income will give rise to a leftward shift. · Income in the case of inferior goods While most goods are normal, there are some goods the demand for which falls as consumer income increases; the good is then an inferior good (a good is inferior if the demand for it varies inversely with income). Examples of inferior goods are used clothes, used cars, and bus tickets. As income increases, consumers switch to more expensive alternatives (new clothes, new cars, and cars or aeroplanes rather than travelling by bus), and so the demand for the inferior goods falls. Thus an increase in income will give rise to a leftward shift in the demand curve for an inferior good, and a decrease in income will produce a rightward shift. · Prices of substitute goods Two goods are substitutes if they satisfy a similar need. An example of substitute goods is Coca-Cola® and Pepsi-Cola®. A fall in the price of one (say Coca-Cola®) will result in a fall in the demand for the other (Pepsi-Cola®). The reason is that as the price of Coca-Cola® falls, some consumers will switch from Pepsi® to Coca-Cola®, and so the demand for Pepsi® will fall. On the other hand, if there is an increase in the price of CocaCola®, there will result an increase in the demand for Pepsi® as some consumers switch away from Coca-Cola® and towards Pepsi®. Therefore for any two substitute goods X and Y, a decrease in the price of X will produce a leftward shift in the demand for Y, while an increase in the price of X will produce a rightward shift in the demand for Y. In brief, in the case of substitute goods, the price of X and demand for Y change in the same direction (they both increase or they both decrease). Other examples of substitute goods are oranges and apples, Cadbury and Nestlé chocolate, and milk and yoghurt. · Prices of complementary goods Two goods are complements (complementary goods) if they tend to be used together. An example of complementary goods is CDs and CD players. In this case, a fall in the price of one (say CD players) will give rise to an increase in the demand for the other (CDs). This is because the fall in the price of CD players leads to a bigger quantity of CD players being purchased, and therefore the demand for CDs will increase. Therefore, for any two complementary goods X and Y, a fall in the price of X will lead to a rightward shift in the demand for Y, and an increase in the price of X will lead to a leftward shift 36 Part 2: Microeconomics in the demand for Y. In the case of complementary goods, the price of X and the demand for Y change in opposite directions (as one increases, the other decreases). More examples of complementary goods are computers and computer software, DVD players and DVDs, tennis shoes and tennis rackets, and ping-pong balls and ping-pong rackets. Note that most goods are not related to each other; these are called independent goods. For example, pencils and apples, cars and ice cream, telephones and books are unrelated to one another, and the change in the price of one will have little or no effect on the demand for the other. · Expectations of future income If consumers expect that their future income will increase, their demand for a good in the present will be likely to increase (rightward shift in the demand curve); if they expect their income to fall in the future, their demand for a good in the present will be likely to fall (a leftward shift in the demand curve). · Expectations of future price changes If consumers expect that the price of a good will increase in the future, they will probably demand more of it in the present in order to take advantage of the lower present price, and so demand will shift to the right; if they expect that the price will fall in the future, they will demand less of it in the present, as they will postpone their purchases for the future, and so demand in the present shifts to the left. Movement along a demand curve and shift of the demand curve It is important to distinguish between movements on or along a demand curve, and shifts of a demand curve. Whenever the price of a good changes, ceteris paribus, it gives rise to a movement along the demand curve. In Figure 2.5(a), if the price falls from P1 to P2, the quantity of the good demanded increases from Q1 to Q2. A movement along the demand curve from A to B has occurred; this is referred to as an increase in quantity demanded. Conversely, an increase in price would give rise to a decrease in quantity demanded. By contrast, any change in one or more determinants of demand gives rise to a shift in the whole demand curve, as shown in Figure 2.5(b); this is called a change in demand. Let’s say, for example, that there is an increase in the number of buyers. We know that the demand curve will shift rightward (from D1 to D2); this is called an increase in demand, shown in Figure 2.5(b). A decrease in the number of buyers would cause a leftward shift of the demand curve (from D1 to D3); this is called a decrease in demand. To summarize: Test your understanding 2.4 (a) A movement along the demand curve, caused by a change in price, is called a ‘change in quantity demanded’. 1 (a) Define ‘demand’. (b) What is the law of demand? (c) Show the law of demand graphically. (d) What is the relationship between individual demand and market demand? (e) Distinguish between a ‘change in demand’ and a ‘change in quantity demanded’ and explain the cause or causes of each. (f) What are the determinants of demand? 2 Explain why a consumer’s willingness to pay for an additional unit of a good falls as the quantity purchased increases. P A P1 change in quantity demanded B P2 D 0 Q1 3 Using appropriate diagrams, show the impact Q2 of each of the following on the demand curve for product A, and explain what happens to demand in each case: Q (b) A shift of a demand curve, caused by a change in a determinant of demand, is called a ‘change in demand’. P change in demand decrease in D increase in D D2 D3 0 D1 Q Figure 2.5 Movement along and shift of a demand curve. Any change in price produces a change in quantity demanded, shown as a movement on the demand curve. Any change in a determinant of demand (other than price) produces a change in demand, represented by a shift of the whole demand curve. HL (a) the number of consumers in the market for product A increases (b) consumer income increases and product A is an inferior good (c) consumer income decreases and product A is a normal good (d) consumers expect a drop in their future income (e) a news report claims that use of product A has harmful effects on health (f) the price of substitute good B falls (g) the price of complementary good B increases. Exceptions to the law of demand (higher level topic) The law of demand states that there is an inverse relationship between the price of a good and quantity of the good demanded, all other things equal. However, in the situations described below, this law does not hold. HL Veblen goods Veblen goods are goods whose demand curve is upward sloping due to ostentation (defined as a pretentious display of wealth) or a belief that a lower price of a good means lower quality. Veblen goods are named after Thorstein Veblen, who explained this phenomenon in his book The Theory of the Leisure Class in 1899. They are alternatively known as ‘ostentatious goods’, or ‘conspicuous consumption’ goods. In such a demand curve there is a positive (direct) relationship between price and quantity demanded, as shown in Figure 2.6(b). In the case of Veblen goods, a consumer derives more utility (satisfaction) from the desire to impress other people than from consumption of the good itself. As price increases, the good becomes more attractive because the consumer associates possession of the good with increased social status. Therefore quantity demanded Chapter 2: Markets 37 Giffen goods HL (a) The law of demand. P D 0 Q (b) Violation of the law of demand. P D 0 Q Figure 2.6 The law of demand and violations of the law of demand. increases as price increases, while quantity demanded falls as price falls. Examples of Veblen goods may include diamonds, mink coats and luxury cars (such as Rolls-Royces). Consumers displaying this kind of behaviour are more likely to be higher income individuals purchasing items in the luxury market. The upward sloping demand curve is likely to be an individual demand curve, or a demand curve for a group of high income consumers. It is far less likely to be a market demand curve that includes all consumers, as the market demand curve is the sum of all individual demands, and therefore also includes the demand of lower income individuals whose behaviour is consistent with the law of demand (shown in Figure 2.6(a)). In fact, the existence of an upward-sloping market demand curve has never been established by economists for any good. 1 To understand what this means, consider the following simple example. Say you have $12 and you want to buy some pencils. When the price is $4 per pencil, you can buy 3 pencils. Suppose then that the price of pencils falls to $3 per pencil. You can now buy 4 pencils. The sum of money at 38 Part 2: Microeconomics In Economics, there is often more than one way to explain something. The law of demand, for example, has more than one explanation of why price and quantity demanded are inversely related to each other. Earlier in this chapter (page 33), we saw that the declining marginal benefit that a consumer enjoys by consuming additional units of a good explains the downward-sloping demand curve (the law of demand). Now we will consider a different explanation for the downward-sloping demand curve, which will help us understand a special category of goods for which the law of demand may not hold. (Note that the two explanations of the law of demand, though different, are entirely consistent with each other.) Recall that demand shows the relationship between the price of a good and quantity of the good demanded, all other things equal. As we know, any price change produces a change in quantity demanded, shown as a movement along the demand curve. We will now see that the total effect of a price change on quantity demanded can be broken down into two separate effects: the substitution effect and the income effect, with the total effect of a price change being the sum of the two effects. · The substitution effect Say there is a price decrease; the consumer substitutes more of the now less expensive good for other similar products that have become relatively more expensive. The result is that quantity of the good demanded increases. There is always an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded as a result of the substitution effect: as price increases, quantity demanded falls; as price decreases, quantity demanded increases. · The income effect Consider again the price decrease; a fall in the price of the good means that the consumer’s real income (or purchasing power) has increased.1 There are two possible impacts on how much of the good will be demanded, depending on whether it is normal or inferior: m If the good is normal, as real income increases, quantity demanded of the good increases. In this case, the income effect gives rise to an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded; as price falls, quantity demanded increases. your disposal ($12) has not changed, and yet the ‘purchasing power’ of $12, or what your money can buy, has increased as a result of the fall in the price of pencils. ‘Real income’ is the same as ‘purchasing power’; it increases as prices fall, and it decreases as prices rise. HL m If the good is inferior, as real income increases, quantity demanded of the good falls. The income effect now gives rise to a direct relationship between price and quantity demanded; as price falls, quantity demanded falls. When a good is normal, the income effect and the substitution effect reinforce each other: both lead to an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded, and there results the standard downward sloping demand curve, indicating that the law of demand holds. If on the other hand a good is inferior, there are two possibilities: · If the income effect is smaller than the substitution Giffen goods are very rare; in fact some economists claim they may not even exist at all. They were named after Sir Robert Giffen, a 19th century economist who observed increased consumption of bread by lower income people as the price of bread increased. The explanation provided by Sir Robert Giffen was that as the price of bread increased, poor people’s real income fell. As bread consumption made up a large proportion of household expenditures, an increase in the price of bread could make a perceptible difference in households’ real income. Bread was an inferior good, therefore the fall in real income led to an increase in the demand for bread. The income effect was larger than the substitution effect, and thus the overall effect of the increase in the price of bread was to increase bread consumption. effect, there results a downward-sloping demand curve so that the law of demand holds; the good is inferior but not Giffen. ct ffe ee om inc effect, there results an upward-sloping demand curve; the law of demand does not hold and the good is a Giffen good. substitution effect price quantity demanded inc om rm e ef fe al go ct od · If the income effect is greater than the substitution no HL These relationships will become clearer if you carefully study Figure 2.7. (Note that upward-pointing arrows signify an increase, and downward-pointing arrows signify a decrease.) Figure 2.8 shows the demand curves that correspond to each kind of good. real income For an inferior good, if income effect < substitution effect, the good is not Giffen, ct ffe e e ood om r g inc erio inf A Giffen good is a kind of inferior good whose demand curve is upward sloping because the income effect of a price change is greater than the substitution effect. quantity demanded if income effect > substitution effect, the good is Giffen. Figure 2.7 Normal, inferior and Giffen goods. (a) Normal good or inferior good that is not Giffen. P (b) Giffen good. P D D 0 Q 0 Q Figure 2.8 Demand curves: normal, inferior and Giffen goods. Chapter 2: Markets 39 HL HL The role of expectations If the price of a good falls, and the consumer expects it to fall further, she or he may postpone purchases for the future when the price will be lower, and therefore quantity demanded can fall; there results a positive relationship between price and quantity demanded. If the price of a good increases and the consumer expects it to increase further, s/he may increase quantity demanded in the present to take advantage of the current lower price. Once again there may result a positive relationship between price and quantity demanded. Test your understanding 2.5 1 (a) What are Veblen goods? (b) How might they violate the law of demand? (c) Explain why a violation of the law of demand in the case of a Veblen good is more likely to involve individual demand than market demand. 2 (a) Explain the substitution effect of a price change; what does it tell us about the relationship between the price of a good and quantity demanded? (b) Explain the income effect of a price change; what does it tell us about the price of a good and quantity demanded in the case of (i) normal goods, and (ii) inferior goods? (c) How can we use these concepts to explain the possibility of an upward-sloping demand curve in the case of Giffen goods? (d) When does an inferior good not violate the law of demand? (e) Do you think that most inferior goods are Giffen or not Giffen goods? Explain. 3 How can expectations lead to an upward-sloping demand curve? The supply of an individual firm indicates the various quantities of a good (or service) the firm is willing and able to produce and supply to the market for sale at different possible prices, during a particular time period, ceteris paribus (all other things equal). A firm’s supply of a good can be presented as a supply schedule, which is a table showing the various quantities of a good the firm is willing and able to produce and supply at various prices. Table 2.3 shows a firm’s supply schedule for chocolate bars. The same information appears as a graph in Figure 2.9, where price is plotted on the vertical axis and quantity supplied on the horizontal axis. The line appearing in the diagram is the supply curve of the firm. If the price is $4, the firm supplies 500 chocolate bars in the course of a week; if price were $3, then the firm would supply 400 chocolate bars, and so on. Just as in the case of demand, where price is only one thing that determines how much is demanded, so in the case of supply, price is only one thing that influences how much the firm will supply to the market; hence the ceteris paribus assumption. For the moment, we will ignore other possible influences on supply, and focus only on the relationship between price and quantity. The supply schedule and the supply curve do not tell us anything about how many chocolate bars the firm will actually supply to the market, and what price the firm will receive. The supply information alone tells us how many chocolate bars the firm would be prepared to produce and sell if the price were $5, or $4, and so on. Table 2.3 Supply schedule for a firm. Supply Supply is concerned with the behaviour of sellers, which include firms in the product markets and households in the resource markets. In line with our focus on product markets, we will consider the behaviour of firms as sellers (though the same general principles also apply to consumers as sellers of factors of production in resource markets). Individual supply Firms produce goods and services, and they supply them to the product markets for sale. As sellers, therefore, they are suppliers of goods and services. 40 Part 2: Microeconomics Price of chocolate bars ($) Quantity of chocolate bars supplied (per week) 5 600 4 500 3 400 2 300 1 200 S price of chocolate bars ($) 5 4 3 2 1 0 What is the economic reasoning behind the law of supply? Higher prices generally mean that the firm’s profits increase, and so the firm faces an incentive to produce more output. Lower prices mean lower profitability, and so the incentive facing the firm is to produce less. Therefore, there results a direct relationship between price and quantity supplied: the higher the price, the greater the quantity supplied by the firm. Market supply 100 200 300 400 500 600 quantity of chocolate bars (per week) Figure 2.9 Supply curve for a firm. The law of supply: why the supply curve slopes upward The supply curve shown in Figure 2.9 illustrates a very important relationship: as price increases, quantity supplied also increases. When two variables change in the same direction (as one increases the other also increases), they are said to have a ‘positive’ or ‘direct’ relationship. The direct relationship between the two variables, price and quantity supplied, is summarized in the ‘law of supply’. The market supply indicates the total quantities of a good that firms are willing and able to supply in the market at different possible prices, and is given by the sum of all individual supplies of that good. Figure 2.10 provides an example where at each price, the quantity supplied by Firm A is added to the quantity supplied by Firm B, and so on until all the quantities supplied by all firms producing chocolate bars are added up. For example, at the price of $3, Firm A supplies 400 bars per week and Firm B supplies 300 bars. If we add up these quantities together with all the quantities supplied by other firms, we obtain 8000 bars per week, which is a point on the market supply curve Sm, corresponding to the price of $3. When the firm supplies are added up this way for each possible price, we derive the market supply curve, Sm. According to the law of supply, there is a direct relationship between the quantity of a good supplied over a particular time period and its price, ceteris paribus: as the price of the good increases, the quantity of the good supplied also increases; as the price falls the quantity supplied also falls, all other things equal. price of chocolate bars ($) (a) Supply of Firm A. Market supply is the sum of all individual firms’ supplies for a good. The market supply curve illustrates the law of supply, shown by a direct relationship between price and quantity supplied. (b) Supply of Firm B. (c) Market supply. P$ SA 5 4 3 + 3 2 2 1 1 200 400 600 quantity of chocolate bars SB 5 4 0 P$ 0 Sm 5 + supplies of other firms in the market 4 = 3 2 1 200 400 600 quantity of chocolate bars 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 quantity of chocolate bars (thousands) Figure 2.10 Market supply as the sum of individual supplies. Chapter 2: Markets 41 The vertical supply curve Determinants of supply Under certain special circumstances, the supply curve, rather than slope upward, is vertical at some particular fixed quantity, as in Figure 2.11. A vertical supply curve tells us that even as price increases, the quantity supplied cannot increase; it remains constant. The quantity supplied is independent of price (it does not depend on price). There are two reasons why this may occur: We now turn to the determinants of supply, or the factors other than price that can influence supply. Changes in the determinants of supply cause shifts in the supply curve. A rightward shift means that for a given price, supply increases, i.e. more will be supplied; a leftward shift means that for a given price, supply decreases, and less will be supplied. As Figure 2.12(b) shows, when supply is S1, quantity Q1 will be supplied at price P1. If there is an increase in supply to S2, at the same price P1 then Q2 quantity is supplied. If supply falls to S3, then Q3 quantity is supplied at the same price P1. P 0 S A rightward shift of the supply curve indicates that more is supplied for a given price; a leftward shift of the supply curve indicates that less is supplied for a given price. A rightward shift of the curve is called an increase in supply; a leftward shift is called a decrease in supply. Q theatre tickets for one show OR Stradivarius violins Figure 2.11 The vertical supply curve. · There is a fixed quantity of the good supplied because there is no time to produce more of it. For example, there is a fixed quantity of theatre tickets in a given theatre, because there is a fixed number of seats. No matter how high the price, it is not possible to increase the number of seats in a short period of time (we will see more of this in Chapter 3). · There is a fixed quantity of the good because there is no possibility of ever producing more of it. This is the case with original antiques (for example, Stradivarius violins) and original paintings and sculptures of famous artists. It may be possible to make reproductions, but it is not possible to make more originals. The supply curve is therefore vertical at the fixed quantity of the good that exists. (a) A movement along the supply curve, caused by a change in price, is called a ‘change in quantity supplied’. P 0 firms producing the good in question increases supply and gives rise to a rightward shift in the supply curve; a decrease in the number of firms decreases supply and produces a leftward shift. This follows from the fact that market supply is the sum of all individual supplies. · Resource prices and costs of production The firm buys various resources (factors of production) that it uses to produce its product. If the price of one or more resource rises, production becomes less profitable and the firm produces less; the supply curve shifts to the left. If one or more resource prices fall, production (b) A shift of a supply curve, caused by a change in a determinant of supply, is called a ‘change in supply’. A Q1 change in quantity supplied Q2 P1 Q Part 2: Microeconomics 0 S1 S3 B Figure 2.12 Movements along and shifts in the supply curve. 42 · The number of firms An increase in the number of P S P2 P1 The determinants of market supply include the following: Q3 decrease in supply increase in supply Q1 Q2 S2 Q becomes more profitable and the firm will produce more; the supply curve shifts to the right. Resource prices are important in determining the firm’s costs of production. In general, when costs of production increase, production becomes less profitable, and so supply falls (the supply curve shifts to the left) and when costs decrease, supply increases (the supply curve shifts to the right). · Technology A new improved technology lowers costs of production, thus making production more profitable. Supply increases and the supply curve shifts to the right. In the (unlikely) event that a firm employs a less productive technology, costs of production increase and the supply curve shifts leftward. · Prices of other goods the firm can produce Suppose a farmer grows wheat. If the price of another product, say corn, increases, the farmer may switch to corn production, which is now more profitable; this results in a fall in wheat supply: the supply curve shifts to the left. If the price of corn falls, corn producers may switch to growing wheat, as this is now more profitable; the supply of wheat increases and the supply curve shifts to the right. Therefore the supply curve of a good can shift in response to changes in the prices of other goods that the firm can produce. · Producer (firm) expectations If firms expect the price of their product to rise, they may withhold some of their current supply from the market (i.e. not offer it for sale), with the expectation that they will be able to sell it at the higher price in the future; in this case there will result a fall in supply in the present, and hence a leftward shift in the supply curve. If the expectation is that the price of their product will fall, they will increase their supply in order to take advantage of the current higher price, and hence there will be a rightward shift in the supply curve. · Taxes Firms treat taxes as if they were costs of production. Therefore the imposition of a new tax or the increase of an existing tax represents an increase in production costs, so supply will fall and the supply curve will shift to the left. The elimination of a tax or a decrease in an existing tax represent a fall in production costs; supply increases and the supply curve shifts to the right. · Subsidies A subsidy is a payment made to the firm by the government, and so has the opposite effect of a tax. (Subsidies may be given in order to increase the incomes of producers or to encourage an increase in the production of the good produced.) The introduction of a subsidy or an increase in an existing subsidy is equivalent to a fall in production costs, and will give rise to a rightward shift in the supply curve, while the elimination of a subsidy or a decrease in a subsidy will give rise to a leftward shift in the supply curve. · Supply shocks Supply shocks are sudden events that have an impact on supply, such as unusual weather, war or cuts in major input supplies (for example, imports of oil). An adverse supply shock, such as unusually bad weather that affects agricultural output, or a cut in oil supplies, will result in a decrease in supply and leftward shift in the supply curve. A beneficial supply shock (such as unusually good weather) results in an increase in supply and a rightward shift in the supply curve. Movement along a supply curve and shift of the supply curve Just as in the case of the demand curve, so in the case of the supply curve we distinguish between movements along the curve and shifts of the entire curve. Movements along a supply curve can occur only as a result of changes in price. In Figure 2.12(a), as price increases from P1 to P2, quantity supplied increases from Q1 to Q2. There has been a movement along the supply curve from A to B. This is called change in quantity supplied. If there is a change in one more determinant of supply, supply will increase or decrease, and the entire curve will shift to the right or to the left, as in Figure 2.12(b). This is called a change in supply. Any change in price produces a change in quantity supplied, shown as a movement on the supply curve. Any change in a determinant of supply (other than price) produces a change in supply, represented by a shift of the whole supply curve. Test your understanding 2.6 1 (a) Define ‘supply’. (b) What is the law of supply? (c) Show the law of supply graphically. (d) What is the relationship between individual supply and market supply? (e) Distinguish between a ‘change in supply’ and a ‘change in quantity supplied’ and explain the cause or causes of each. (f) What are the determinants of supply? 2 What are some examples of goods with a vertical supply curve? (...continued) Chapter 2: Markets 43 (...continued) 3 Using appropriate diagrams, show the impact of each of the following on the supply curve of product A, and explain what happens to supply in each case: (a) the number of firms in the industry producing product A decreases (b) the price of oil, a key input in the production of product A, increases (c) firms expect that the price of product A will fall in the future (d) the government grants a subsidy on each unit of A produced (e) a war causes disruption of imports of inputs used in the production of A (f) the price of product B increases, and B is a substitute in production (g) a new technology is adopted by firms in the industry producing A. Market equilibrium: demand and supply The market demand and market supply for chocolate bars that we have considered separately above show the quantities that consumers and firms are willing and able to buy and sell at each price; not how much they actually buy and sell. We will now put market demand and market supply together to find out how these interact to determine what actually happens in the market for chocolate bars. Shortages and surpluses Figure 2.13 presents the same market demand and supply curves that appeared in Figures 2.3 and 2.10. The same information appears as a demand schedule and a supply schedule in Table 2.4. Table 2.4 Market demand and supply schedules for chocolate bars. Price of chocolate bars ($) Quantity of chocolate bars demanded (per week) Quantity of chocolate bars supplied (per week) 5 4,000 12,000 4 6,000 10,000 3 8,000 8,000 2 10,000 6,000 1 12,000 4,000 44 Part 2: Microeconomics price of chocolate bars ($) Test your understanding 2.6 S 5 surplus 4 3 equilibrium price market equilibrium 2 shortage 1 D equilibrium quantity 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 quantity of chocolate bars (thousands) Figure 2.13 Equilibrium in the chocolate bar market. In both Table 2.4 and Figure 2.13 we see that when the price of chocolate bars is $3, quantity demanded is exactly equal to quantity supplied, at 8000 chocolate bars. Note that there is only one price where this can occur. At a higher price, say $4, quantity supplied (10,000 bars) is greater than quantity demanded (6000 bars). There is a surplus of chocolate bars, or excess quantity supplied, of 4000 bars (= 10,000 – 6000). At the even higher price of $5, there is a larger surplus of 8000 bars. Let’s say that the price in this market is initially $5. At this price, chocolate producers would be willing and able to produce 12,000 bars, but consumers would only be willing and able to buy 4000 bars. What will happen? When the producers see that they have unsold output of 8000 bars, they will lower their price in order to encourage consumers to buy more chocolate. As the price falls, quantity supplied becomes smaller and quantity demanded becomes bigger. As long as there is a surplus, there will be a downward pressure on the price. The price will keep falling until it reaches the point where quantity demanded is equal to quantity supplied. At a lower than equilibrium price, say $2, quantity demanded (10,000 bars) is larger than quantity supplied (6000 bars). There is now a shortage of chocolate bars, or excess quantity demanded of 4000 bars (10,000 − 6000). If price were even lower, at $1, the shortage would be larger, at 8000 bars. Say that the price is initially $1. Chocolate producers would be willing and able to supply only 4000 bars, whereas consumers would be willing and able to buy 12,000 bars. Producers will notice that all the chocolate bars will be quickly sold out, and so begin to raise the price. As they do so, the quantity of bars demanded begins to fall and the quantity supplied begins to increase. The shortage in the chocolate market exerts an upward pressure on price. The price will keep increasing until the shortage is eliminated; this will happen when quantity supplied is exactly equal to quantity demanded. If quantity demanded of a good is smaller than quantity supplied, the difference between the two is called a shortage; if quantity demanded of a good is larger than quantity supplied, the difference is called a surplus. The existence of a shortage or a surplus in a free market will cause the price to change so that the quantity demanded will be made equal to quantity supplied. In the event of a shortage, price will rise; in the event of a surplus, price will fall. Market equilibrium Equilibrium is defined as a state of balance between different forces, such that there is no tendency to change. This is an important concept in Economics that we will encounter repeatedly. When quantity demanded is equal to quantity supplied, there is market equilibrium; the forces of supply and demand are in balance, and there is no tendency for the price to change. Market equilibrium is determined at the point where the demand curve intersects the supply curve. The price that prevails in market equilibrium is the equilibrium price, and the quantity is the equilibrium quantity. At the equilibrium price, the quantity that consumers are willing and able to buy is exactly equal to the quantity that firms are willing and able to sell. The buyers and sellers are satisfied, and there is no pressure on the price to change. This price is also known as the market-clearing price, or simply market price. In the market for chocolate bars considered in Figure 2.13, the equilibrium price is $3 per chocolate bar, and the equilibrium quantity is 8000 bars. At any price other than the equilibrium price, when there is a shortage or a surplus, there is market disequilibrium. At a market disequilibrium, the activities of many buyers and sellers, through their demand and supply, as we have seen, force the price to increase or decrease until it reaches its equilibrium level. Changes in market equilibrium Once a price reaches its equilibrium level, consumers and firms are satisfied and will not engage in any action to make it change. This presupposes that the demand and supply curves are fixed; in other words, that all those factors that can cause shifts in these curves (the determinants of demand and supply) are constant and unchanging (recall the ceteris paribus assumption). If there occurs a change in any of the determinants of demand or supply, there will result a shift in the curves, and the market will adjust to a new equilibrium. Changes in demand (demand curve shifts) In Figure 2.14(a) (page 46) the demand curve, D1, intersects the supply curve, S, to give rise to equilibrium price and quantity P1 and Q1. Consider a change in a determinant of demand that causes the demand curve to shift to the right from D1 to D2. For example, an increase in consumer income in the case of a normal good, or an increase in the number of consumers, will produce a rightward shift in the demand curve to D2. There will result a new, higher equilibrium price, P2, and greater equilibrium quantity, Q2, given by the intersection of D2 with S. On the other hand, a decrease in demand, shown in Figure 2.14(b), which could arise from a decrease in the number of consumers, or a fall in consumer income in the case of a normal good, will give rise to a leftward shift in the demand curve from D1 to D3, and a fall in both the equilibrium price to P3, and the equilibrium quantity to Q3. Changes in supply (supply curve shifts) We now consider supply curve shifts that can arise from changes in the determinants of supply. In Figure 2.15(a), the initial equilibrium is given by the intersection of D with S1, giving rise to equilibrium price and quantity P1 and Q1. An increase in supply, which could be caused for example by an increase in the number of firms in the industry, will shift the supply curve to S2 and give rise to a lower equilibrium price, P2, but a higher equilibrium quantity, Q2. A decrease in supply as shown in Figure 2.15(b), caused for example by a fall in the number of firms in the industry, will shift the supply curve to S3, and the new equilibrium will be at a higher price P3 and lower quantity Q3. When a market is in equilibrium, quantity demanded is equal to quantity supplied, and there is no tendency for the price to change. In a market disequilibrium, there is a shortage or surplus, and the forces of demand and supply cause the price to change until the market reaches equilibrium. Chapter 2: Markets 45 (a) Increase in demand. P (b) Decrease in demand. initial equilibrium P2 S P final equilibrium P1 P1 final equilibrium S initial equilibrium P3 D2 D1 D1 0 Q1 D3 Q2 0 Q Q3 Q1 Q Figure 2.14 Changes in demand and the new equilibrium price and quantity. (a) Increase in supply. (b) Decrease in supply. initial equilibrium final equilibrium S1 P P S2 P1 S1 P3 final equilibrium P2 S3 initial equilibrium P1 D 0 Q1 Q2 D 0 Q Q3 Q1 Q Figure 2.15 Changes in supply and the new equilibrium price and quantity. Free and economic goods revisited You may remember from Chapter 1, page 4, that free goods are goods that are not subject to the condition of scarcity and have a zero opportunity cost, while economic goods are subject to scarcity and have an opportunity cost greater than zero. We are now in a better position to understand the difference between the two by use of demand and supply analysis. Figures 2.16 (a) and (b) show a free and economic good respectively. A free good is a good for which the quantity supplied is greater than the quantity demanded when the price is zero. Supply is so large relative to demand that there is excess quantity supplied even at a zero price. An economic good is a good for which quantity supplied is smaller than quantity demanded when the price is zero. A free good can change into an economic good as a result of a leftward shift in the supply curve (reduced supply) or a rightward shift in the demand curve (increased demand). When demand and supply intersect at a price greater than zero, the good has become an economic good. (a) Free good. (b) Economic good. P P supply demand supply demand 0 Figure 2.16 Free and economic goods. 46 Part 2: Microeconomics Q 0 Q Test your understanding 2.7 1 In Figure 2.13, state whether there is a surplus or shortage, and how large this is if (a) price is $5 per chocolate bar (b) price is $4 per chocolate bar (c) price is $3 per chocolate bar (d) price is $2 per chocolate bar (e) price is $1 per chocolate bar 2 Use a demand and supply diagram to: (a) show equilibrium price and quantity (b) show disequilibrium prices and quantities (c) relate disequilibrium prices to shortages and surpluses (d) explain the meaning of ‘market equilibrium’ (e) explain the roles of demand and supply in achieving market equilibrium. 3 Use supply and demand diagrams to illustrate the following events: (a) freezing weather destroys the orange crop and the price of oranges rises (b) the mass media report on the fat content of cheese and the price of cheese falls (c) a new technology of production for computers is developed and the price of computers falls (d) the price of milk increases and the price of ice cream increases (remember that milk is an input in ice cream production) (e) the mass media report on outbreaks of bird flu and the price of chicken falls. 4 Assuming a competitive market, use demand and supply diagrams to show the impact on equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity of product A that each of the following will have: (a) consumer income increases, ceteris paribus (A is a normal good) (b) consumer income falls, ceteris paribus (A is an inferior good) (c) there is an increase in labour costs, all other things equal (d) the price of substitute good B falls, all other things equal (e) the number of firms in the industry producing product A increases, ceteris paribus (f) a successful advertising campaign emphasizes the health benefits of product A, ceteris paribus. (...continued) Test your understanding 2.7 (...continued) 5 Use supply and demand diagrams to show how (a) land in America, which initially was a free good, became an economic good after colonizers arrived; (b) deforestation (the cutting of forest trees) on a massive scale over many decades has transformed forests from a free good into an economic good. 2.3 Prices and efficiency in the market economy The role of prices in markets Prices determined by the forces of supply and demand in competitive markets serve a number of important functions. Price rationing and the allocation of resources As we know from Chapter 1 (Section 1.3, page 18), rationing is a method of apportioning or parcelling out resources among their many competing uses, as well as apportioning goods and services among households. The market mechanism uses price rationing for this purpose, which involves the use of prices that are freely determined in markets by the forces of supply and demand. We have learned in this chapter that when a market operates under conditions of competition, market demand and market supply, composed of numerous individual demanders and numerous individual suppliers, each making his or her individual choices, determine an equilibrium price and quantity for a particular good (or service or resource). At this equilibrium, the buying and selling choices of all buyers and sellers are satisfied and are in balance. Now imagine that there exists a market for each and every good and service produced and for each and every resource, and that all these markets have established a market-clearing price. This means that all decision-makers, whether they are households, firms or resource owners, having made their buying and selling choices, are now satisfied since everyone who was willing and able to buy or sell specific quantities at different prices has succeeded in doing so! The market mechanism, through price rationing, is known as the invisible hand of the market, which succeeds in coordinating the countless buying and selling decisions of thousands or millions of decisionmaking units in an economy without any central Chapter 2: Markets 47 Prices as signals and incentives How do prices and markets achieve the task of resource allocation? in price is also an incentive for producers to increase the quantity of strawberries supplied; at the higher price, strawberry production is more profitable, so producers move along the supply curve from point A to point C, thereby increasing quantity supplied from Q1 to Q3. But the new, higher price is a signal and incentive for consumers: it signals that strawberries are now more expensive, and it is an incentive for them to buy fewer strawberries; they therefore move along the new demand curve from B to C, buying fewer strawberries than they would have bought at the original price P1 (Q3 is smaller than Q2). The increase in the price of strawberries resulted in a reallocation of resources. More resources are now allocated to strawberry production. (This has affected the answer to the what question of resource allocation.) (a) Adjustment of price to increased demand. The key to the market’s ability to allocate resources can be found in the role of prices as signals and as incentives. As signals, prices communicate information to decision-makers. As incentives, prices motivate decision-makers to respond to the information. As signals and incentives, prices guide resource owners on what and how much of their resources they will sell; they guide consumers on what and how much of goods and services they will buy; and they guide firms on what and how much of resources they will buy, and what and how much of goods and services they will produce and sell. An example from a product market Suppose consumers decide they would like to eat more strawberries because of their health benefits (a change in tastes that causes the demand curve to shift); demand increases and the demand curve shifts to the right from D1 to D2 in Figure 2.17(a). At the initial price, P1, there results a shortage equal to the difference between Q2 and Q1: the quantity demanded Q2, due to the increase in demand to D2, is larger than quantity supplied, Q1. The price of strawberries will therefore begin to rise, and will continue to rise until the shortage has disappeared; this happens at price P2 and quantity Q3, given by the point of intersection of the supply curve with the new demand curve, D2. What has happened? The new, higher price signalled or conveyed information to producers that there was a shortage in the strawberry market. The increase 48 Part 2: Microeconomics P S C P2 A P1 B shortage D2 D1 0 (b) Adjustment of the price of labour to increased labour supply. price of labour (wage) authority. Prices and markets determine the allocation of resources (and the distribution of output/income). The what question of resource allocation is answered because firms will only produce those goods and services consumers are willing and able to pay for; the how question of resource allocation is answered because firms will use those resources and technologies in their production process they are willing and able to pay for. (The for whom question of distribution is answered because consumers will get those goods and services they are willing and able to pay for, which in turn depends on the prices at which they sell their resources to firms, and therefore their income.) Q3 Q1 S1 P W1 W2 Q2 Q A S2 surplus B C D 0 Q1 Q3 Q2 quantity of labour Figure 2.17 Illustrating how price works as a signal and incentive. An example from a resource market Consider another example, this time from the labour market (one of the resource markets). The vertical axis in Figure 2.17(b) measures the price of labour (the wage) and the horizontal axis the quantity of labour. Firms are interested in buying labour services, and their demand for labour is shown by the demand curve D. Owners of labour services (workers) supply their labour in the labour market, and the initial supply of labour is shown by the supply curve S1. (The demand curve has the usual downward-sloping shape, because as the wage falls, firms are prompted to hire more labour and so the quantity of labour demanded increases. The supply curve has the usual upward-sloping shape because the higher the wage, the more willing workers will be to supply their labour in the market.) Assume now that because of immigration (foreign workers enter the country), the supply of labour increases, giving rise to a rightward shift in the labour supply curve, to S2. At the old wage, W1, there will be a surplus of labour in the market given by the difference between Q2 and Q1 of labour. The surplus will cause the wage rate to start falling, and this will keep falling until the surplus has disappeared. The new equilibrium wage will be W2, and the equilibrium quantity of labour Q3, given by the intersection of the demand for labour, D, with the new supply of labour curve, S2. The falling wage has acted as a signal and an incentive. It signalled to firms that there was a surplus in the labour market, and it has provided them with an incentive to hire a bigger quantity of labour to which they responded by moving along the labour demand curve from point A to point C, where they now hire more labour (Q3 is larger than Q1). At the same time, the lower wage is a signal to workers, and it provides them with the incentive to move along the new supply curve, S2, from point B to point C, where they offer less of their services at the lower wage than they were willing to offer at the old higher wage (Q3 is less than Q2). Therefore both firms and workers have responded to the signals and incentives provided by prices. This has resulted in a reallocation of labour resources as firms are now producing output with a larger quantity of labour. (This has affected the answer to the how question of resource allocation.) Test your understanding 2.8 1 What are the key functions of prices in competitive markets? 2 How are markets related to price rationing? 3 How do prices help answer the how and what questions of resource allocation? (...continued) Test your understanding 2.8 (...continued) 4 Consider the market for coffee, and suppose that the demand for coffee falls (because of a fall in the price of tea, a substitute good), giving rise to a new equilibrium price and quantity of coffee. Explain the role of price as a signal and as an incentive for consumers and for firms in reallocating resources. 5 Consider the labour market, and suppose that the supply of labour falls (due to large-scale emigration, or departure of workers to another country), giving rise to a new equilibrium price and quantity of labour. Explain the role of price as a signal and as an incentive for workers (the suppliers of labour) and firms (the demanders of labour) in reallocating resources. Economic efficiency and the market economy Economic efficiency broadly means making the best possible use of resources. More precisely, economic efficiency consists of: productive efficiency and allocative efficiency, achieved in the ideal-type market economy studied in Chapter 1, page 18. Productive (or technical) efficiency: how to produce As we know from Chapter 1, page 11, an economy achieves productive efficiency when it produces at the lowest possible cost; or alternatively by producing by use of the fewest possible resources. The competitive market induces firms to produce at the lowest possible cost. If some firms produced at a higher cost, they would have to charge a higher price in order to cover their costs; but then consumers would prefer the lower price sellers, and the higher price ones would go out of business. Productive efficiency in the economy as a whole means that it is not possible to produce more of one good without producing less of any other good. To see this, consider that if production takes place by use of the fewest possible resources, this must mean that the economy is producing the maximum it can produce, in which case it is producing on the production possibilities curve (PPC). But if it is producing on the PPC, it is not possible to produce more of one good without producing less of another good. Chapter 2: Markets 49 The competitive market achieves productive efficiency, which involves producing at the lowest possible cost. When there is productive efficiency, the economy is producing on its production possibilities curve, and the ‘how to produce’ question is answered in the best possible way in the sense that there is no waste of resources. Allocative efficiency: what to produce An economy achieves allocative efficiency when it produces the combination of goods that are mostly wanted by society. Alternatively, we can say that allocative efficiency for the economy as a whole is achieved when the economy allocates its resources so that it produces a combination of goods and services such that it is not possible to make anyone better off in terms of increasing their benefit from consumption without making someone else worse off. In other words, the benefits from consumption are maximized for the whole of society. Allocative efficiency is reached when the economy produces at some specific point on its PPC selected by society, because it specifies the combination of goods that society mostly desires. Economic efficiency: maximizing consumer and producer surplus To understand how economic efficiency is achieved by the competitive market economy, we will study two new concepts: consumer surplus and producer surplus. Consumer surplus Consumer surplus is defined as the highest price consumers are willing to pay for a good minus the price actually paid. As you may remember from our discussion on demand, willingness to pay is the price that a consumer is willing to pay in order to get a unit of the good (see Figure 2.2(b)). In a competitive market, the price actually paid is determined at the market equilibrium by supply and demand. Consumer surplus is shown in Figure 2.18 as the shaded area between the demand (or marginal benefit) curve, and the equilibrium price Pe. It represents the difference between total benefits consumer receive and the price paid to receive them. P1 P2 P3 consumer Pe P4 P5 The competitive market achieves allocative efficiency, which involves producing the combination of goods and services mostly wanted by society. When there is allocative efficiency, the ‘what to produce’ question is answered in the best possible way in the sense that scarce resources are used to best satisfy consumers’ unlimited wants. Note that if an economy as a whole is achieving allocative efficiency, it must also be achieving productive efficiency. Since allocative efficiency involves being at a point on the PPC, productive efficiency is necessarily also being achieved, otherwise the economy would not be on the PPC. When the economy achieves both productive and allocative efficiency, the society is said to have achieved economic efficiency (also known as Pareto efficiency or Pareto optimality2). 2 This condition is named after Vilfredo Pareto, a 19th century economist. 50 Part 2: Microeconomics S = MC at market equilibrium MB = MS surplus producer surplus D = MB P6 0 Qa Qb Qe Q Figure 2.18 Consumer and producer surplus in a competitive market. Consumer surplus indicates that whereas many consumers were willing to pay a higher price to get the good, they actually received it for less. For example, many consumers were willing to pay price P2 to get quantity Qa. Yet they got Qa by paying only the lower price Pe. The difference between P2 and Pe is consumer surplus for quantity Qa. Similarly, many consumers were willing to pay price P3 in order to get quantity Qb, yet they got it by paying only Pe. Again, the difference P3 − Pe is consumer surplus for quantity Qb. The same principle applies to all possible prices between the highest price P1 and the equilibrium price Pe. This means that all the consumers who were willing to pay a higher price than Pe to get the good received some benefit (or utility) over and above what they actually paid for the good. This extra benefit is called consumer surplus. Producer surplus Producer surplus is defined as the price received by firms for selling their good minus the lowest price that they are willing to accept in order to produce the good. The lowest price they are willing to accept represents the firms’ cost of producing an extra unit of the good (or marginal cost), and is shown by the supply curve. (The logic behind this is very simple: the lowest price that the firm is willing to accept must be just enough to cover its cost of producing each extra unit; this cost is known as marginal cost, and will be studied in Chapters 4 and 5.) Producer surplus is shown diagrammatically as the area above the firms’ supply curve and below the price received by firms, Pe, which is determined in the market. As we can see in Figure 2.18, firms that were willing to produce quantity Qa for price P5 actually received price Pe. The difference Pe − P5 is producer surplus for quantity Pa. Similarly the producer surplus for quantity Qb is given by the price Pe actually received minus P4 that the firms were willing to accept for producing Qb. The same principle applies to all possible prices between the lowest price P6 and the equilibrium price Pe. Therefore producer surplus is shown by the shaded area between the equilibrium price Pe and the supply curve, representing the difference between price received and marginal cost. Reinterpreting market equilibrium As we know, market equilibrium occurs at the point of intersection of the demand curve and the supply curve, which is the point where quantity demanded is equal to quantity supplied. But depending on how we interpret the demand and supply curves, the point of market equilibrium can be thought of differently. If we think of the demand curve as a marginal benefit (MB) curve, and of the supply curve as a marginal cost (MC) curve, then the point of market equilibrium is the point where MB = MC. The equality of MB with MC tells us that the extra benefit to society of getting one more unit of the good is equal to the extra cost to society of producing one more unit of the good. When this happens, it means that society’s resources are being used to produce the ‘right’ quantity of the good; in other words, society has allocated the ‘right’ amount of resources to the production of the good, 3 To understand this, consider that if MB > MC, then society would be placing a greater value on the good than it costs to produce it, and so more of it should be produced. If on the other hand MC > MB, then it would be costing society more to produce the good than the value society puts on it, and so less should be produced. If MC = MB, then just the ‘right’ quantity of the good is being produced. and is producing the quantity of the good that is mostly wanted by society.3 But this is none other than allocative efficiency in the case of a single market. It follows then that when MB = MC, which occurs at the point of competitive market equilibrium, the market is achieving allocative efficiency. There is also another way to interpret the demand and the supply curves. Every point on the demand curve represents the highest price consumers are willing to pay for the corresponding quantity of the good, while every point on the supply curve represents the lowest price firms are willing to accept to produce the corresponding quantity of the good. This means that at the point of competitive market equilibrium, the highest price that consumers are willing to pay is equal to the lowest price firms are willing to accept. When this happens, the sum of consumer and producer surplus is maximum, or the greatest it can be.4 Putting the above points together, we can conclude that allocative efficiency is achieved at the point of competitive market equilibrium, where MB = MC, and where the sum of consumer and producer surplus is maximum. Now we know from the discussion above that when allocative efficiency is achieved, this means that productive efficiency has been achieved as well. In fact, the condition of maximum consumer plus producer surplus indicates that the economy is achieving not only allocative but also productive efficiency. To see why this is so, suppose that firms in some markets are not producing at the lowest possible cost, i.e. they are productively inefficient. As they compete with each other to lower their costs, resources are transferred from the higher cost firms to lower cost firms. With lower costs, these firms will also have a lower minimum price they are willing to accept for selling their output, and therefore a greater producer surplus (since producer surplus is the price firms receive minus the lowest price they are willing to accept). Producer surplus will continue to increase as long as resources can be shifted out of higher cost producers and into lower cost producers, and will be maximized when all output is produced by firms producing at the lowest possible cost. 4 To see this, consider what would happen if any quantity less than Qe were produced in Figure 2.18. If, say, Qb is produced, the highest price consumers are willing to pay would be greater than the lowest price firms are willing to accept, and the sum of consumer plus producer surplus would be smaller, as this sum would then be equal to the shaded area between the demand and supply curve only up to output Qb. The sum of consumer plus producer surplus is the greatest it can be, or is maximized, at the point of market equilibrium. Chapter 2: Markets 51 Note that so far we have been considering what happens in one single competitive market. If allocative and productive efficiency are to be achieved for the economy as a whole, the condition MB = MC, indicating maximum consumer plus producer surplus, must hold in all markets. When this occurs, allocative and productive efficiency have been achieved for the economy as a whole. It follows then that economic efficiency, including both allocative and productive efficiency, has been attained by the operation of free markets. The competitive market ensures that production of a good will occur at the point where MB = MC (marginal benefit equals marginal cost), which is also the point where the sum of consumer plus producer surplus is maximum. The conditions MB = MC and maximum consumer plus producer surplus are achieved at the point of competitive market equilibrium. When MB = MC, the market is achieving economic efficiency, which includes both allocative and productive efficiency, thereby producing the quantity of the good that is mostly desired by society at the lowest possible cost. Economic efficiency in the economy as a whole is achieved when MB = MC in every market. A word of caution We have seen that the competitive market economy offers major advantages, in that through the workings of the invisible hand coordinating the economic decisions of individual consumers, firms and resource owners, it succeeds in achieving allocative and productive efficiency, thereby addressing the ‘what to produce’ and ‘how to produce’ questions in the best possible way from the point of view of society’s interests. Productive and allocative efficiency are highly desirable objectives because they indicate that society is making the best possible use of its scarce resources. Yet it should be stressed that efficiency can only arise in the ideal-type market economy, under a number of very strict and highly unrealistic conditions that are practically never met in the real world. This means that in the real world, the market actually fails with respect to achieving many of the highly desirable outcomes. We will study market failures and what can be done to solve the problems they pose in Chapter 6. Moreover, the competitive market economy is unable to provide a satisfactory answer to the ‘for whom to produce’ question, or output and income distribution. The topic of distribution and what can be done to improve outcomes will be examined in Chapter 11. 52 Part 2: Microeconomics These observations do not lessen the significance of the market’s potential advantages; they only point out that in the real world, there is a need for government policies that will counteract the failings of markets, thus allowing them to realize their potential advantages (we will study such policies in Chapters 6 and 9–11). There are several reasons why economists study the market economy extensively, even though this is not fully achievable in practice. One is that it provides standards for economic efficiency against which actual economies, which are less than perfectly efficient, can be assessed. Another is that it can form the basis for government policies that try to create conditions in the real world that will allow actual economies to come closer to achieving economic efficiency. A third is that government policies undertaken for reasons unrelated to efficiency can themselves be assessed with respect to their efficiency impacts. We now turn to consider some such policies and their efficiency impacts in Section 2.4 (page 53). Test your understanding 2.9 1 Consider whether each of the following situations involves problems relating to productive efficiency, or allocative efficiency, or both. What could be done in each case in order to improve productive or allocative efficiency? (a) An economy produces mostly videotape players, whereas consumers mostly prefer DVD players. (b) An economy that has a large labour force (number of working-age people who are working or looking for a job) and relatively small amounts of capital decides to produce a variety of goods by using production methods that require large amounts of capital and relatively small amounts of labour (hint: think about the ‘how to produce’ basic question). (c) A farmer has just purchased a large, modern tractor and uses it to drive from the farm to the nearby town in order to buy seeds, fertilizer and other agricultural inputs (hint: is the farmer making good use of the tractor, which is an expensive piece of equipment, or does the tractor have better uses on the farm?). (d) An economy with a temperate zone climate produces bananas, whereas it could have been producing apples at a much lower cost. (...continued) Test your understanding 2.9 HL Price ceilings: setting a legal maximum price (...continued) Higher level What is a price ceiling? 2 (a) Use a demand and supply diagram to A government may in some situations set a legal maximum price for a particular good; this is called a price ceiling. This means that the price that can be legally charged by sellers of the good must not be higher than the price ceiling, or maximum price. Figure 2.19 shows how this works. In panel (a), the equilibrium price is Pe, determined by the forces of demand and supply. The price ceiling, Pc, has been set by the government at a level below the equilibrium price. At this price, there arises a shortage, because the quantity demanded, Qd is greater than quantity supplied, Qs. If the market were free, the forces of demand and supply would exert an upward pressure on price until it reached Pe. However, now this cannot happen, because the price hits the legally set price ceiling. illustrate consumer and producer surplus. At which level of output is their sum maximum? (b) Explain the condition MB = MC. Use your diagram to show at which level of output it occurs. (c) What do the conditions of maximum consumer plus producer surplus, and MB = MC tell us about allocative and productive efficiency? 2.4 Government intervention in the market: price controls and market disequilibrium Demand and supply interact to determine an equilibrium, market-clearing price and equilibrium quantity only when they are free to do so, that is, when there is nothing preventing them from arriving at a market-clearing price. Sometimes, governments (as well as private organizations) intervene in markets in pursuit of particular objectives, thereby preventing the market from achieving equilibrium. One common method of intervention in markets involves price controls. P Consequences of price ceilings · Shortages A price ceiling that is set below the equilibrium price of a good creates a shortage of the good. There will be excess quantity demanded, as not all interested buyers who are willing and able to buy the good will be able to do so, simply because at the maximum legal price there isn’t enough of the good being supplied. In Figure 2.19(a), there is a shortage equal to the difference between Qd and Qs. Price controls refer to the setting of prices by the government (or private organizations) so that they are unable to adjust to their equilibrium level determined by demand and supply. Price controls result in market disequilibrium, and therefore in shortages or surpluses. (a) Price ceiling that is constraining. Note that in order to have an impact, the price ceiling must be below the equilibrium price. Figure 2.19(b) shows a situation where the price ceiling has no effect on the market, because it is higher than the equilibrium price: Pc lies above Pe. The market achieves equilibrium price and quantity (Pe and Qe), and the price ceiling has no practical impact. (b) Price ceiling that is not constraining. S P S Pc Pe Pe Pc shortage 0 Qs Qe D Qd D Q 0 Qe Q Figure 2.19 Price ceilings. Chapter 2: Markets 53 · Smaller quantity supplied and sold A price ceiling gives rise to a lower quantity supplied and sold than what would have prevailed at the equilibrium price. This can be seen in Figure 2.19(a), where Qs corresponding to Pc is less than the quantity that suppliers would sell in the market at price Pe. · Underallocation of resources to the good and failure to achieve allocative efficiency Since a lower than equilibrium price results in a smaller quantity supplied than the amount that would have prevailed at equilibrium, this means that too few resources are being allocated to the production of the good, resulting in a quantity produced that is smaller than optimum (or ‘best’). Whereas the optimum quantity that should be produced would be Qe, actually Qs is produced. This means that the price ceiling results in failure to achieve allocative efficiency: consumers are worse off because less than the optimal amount of the good is being produced. · Non-price rationing Once a shortage arises, the price mechanism is no longer able to achieve its rationing function. Some of the demanders who want and are able to buy the good at the maximum price Pc in Figure 2.19(a) will have to go unsatisfied. At this price only quantity Qs is being supplied. The question then arises, how will this quantity be distributed among all interested buyers? This can only be done through a mechanism of non-price rationing (introduced in Chapter 1, pages 18 and 20). Non-price rationing methods include the following: m m m waiting in line and the first-come-first-served principle: those who come first will buy the good the distribution of coupons to all interested buyers, so that they can purchase a fixed amount of the good in a given time period favouritism: the sellers can sell the good to their preferred customers. · Underground (or informal) markets Underground markets are a special kind of price rationing, as they are illegal. They involve buying a good at the maximum price set, and then illegally reselling it to interested buyers at a price above the legal maximum. Underground markets can arise when there exist dissatisfied people who have not succeeded in buying the good because there wasn’t enough of it, and are willing to pay more than the ceiling price to get it. Therefore underground markets can only arise in situations where there is a shortage (if there were no shortage, the price of the good would be at its equilibrium price, and no one would be interested in paying a higher than 54 Part 2: Microeconomics equilibrium price for it). Underground markets are inequitable, and tend also to frustrate the objectives sought by the price ceiling. Examples of price ceilings Rent controls Rent controls consist of a maximum legal rent on housing, which is below the market-determined level of rent (i.e. the market-determined price of rental housing). It is undertaken by governments in many cities around the world in order to make housing more affordable to low income groups. Consequences of rent controls include the following: · They result in a shortage of housing, as the quantity of housing demanded at the legally maximum rent is greater than the quantity of housing available. · The quantity of housing available at the legally maximum rent is lower than if the free market rent had prevailed, because landlords (owners of housing) are less willing to make their housing available for rent at the lower price; this can be seen in Figure 2.19(a) where at price Pc, the quantity supplied Qs is lower than the quantity that would have been supplied at the equilibrium price (Qe). · There arise long waiting lists of interested tenants waiting for their turn to secure an apartment. · There may develop a market for rented units where tenants sublet their apartments at rents above the legal maximum (an underground market). · It becomes unprofitable for landlords to maintain or renovate their rental units because of the low rent, with the result that over long periods of time these become run down. Setting price ceilings by setting prices administratively In former communist countries, most consumer good prices were set by the government at artificially low levels, in order to make them affordable to everyone; there resulted significant shortages and long queues where consumers commonly spent hours in order to buy their food and other basic goods. In addition, there developed underground markets for many goods and services. Petrol (gasoline) prices In the early 1970s, the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) succeeded in significantly raising the market price of oil by restricting output. In response, some governments imposed price ceilings on petrol (gasoline), with the result that there developed long queues at petrol stations because of the shortage created by lower than equilibrium prices. Price floors: setting a legal minimum price floor gives rise to a lower quantity demanded and purchased than the amount that would have prevailed at the equilibrium price. This can be seen in Figure 2.20(a), where Qs, corresponding to Pf, is larger than the quantity that would have been demanded and purchased at price Pe. · Firm inefficiency In product markets, higher than What is a price floor? A legally set minimum price is called a price floor. In this case the price that can be legally charged by sellers of the good must not be lower than the price floor, or minimum price. In Figure 2.20(a), a price floor, Pf, has been set above the equilibrium price, Pe. At this price, there arises a surplus, because the quantity demanded, Qd, is smaller than quantity supplied, Qs. If the market were free, the forces of demand and supply would exert a downward pressure on price until it reached Pe. However, now this cannot happen, because the price hits the legally set price floor. In order to have an impact, the price floor must be above the equilibrium price. Figure 2.20(b) shows a situation where the price floor has no effect on the market, because it is lower than the equilibrium price: Pf lies below Pe. The market achieves equilibrium price and quantity (Pe and Qe), and the price floor has no practical impact. Consequences of price floors · Surpluses The effect of a price floor set above the equilibrium price of a good is to create a surplus of the good or resource. There will be excess quantity supplied, and sellers of the product will be unable to sell all of it at the legal minimum price. In Figure 2.20(a), the difference between Qs and Qd represents the excess quantity supplied, or surplus. In general, the imposition of price floors leads to surpluses. (a) Price floor that is constraining. · Smaller quantity demanded and purchased A price P S surplus equilibrium product prices can lead to inefficient production; firms that have high costs of production due to inefficiencies do not face incentives to cut costs by using more efficient production methods, because the high price offers them protection against lower cost competitors. This leads to inefficiency. · Overallocation of resources to the production of the good In product markets, a higher than equilibrium price results in too many resources being allocated to the production of the product, resulting in a larger than optimum (or ‘best’) quantity produced of the good. Whereas the optimum quantity that should be produced would be Qe, actually Qs is produced. · Illegal sales at prices below the floor Since firms cannot sell their entire product, they may illegally try to sell part of their surplus product at prices below the legal minimum. In the labour market, if there is a minimum wage set by the government, this can be a major problem as some workers may illegally offer their labour at wages (the price of labour) below the legal minimum (see the example below on minimum wages). Examples of price floors Minimum wages Many countries around the world have minimum wage laws that determine the minimum price of labour (the wage rate) that an employer (a firm) must pay. The objective is to guarantee an adequate income (b) Price floor that is not constraining. P S Pf Pe Pe Pf D D 0 Figure 2.20 Price floors. Qd Qs Q 0 Qe Q Chapter 2: Markets 55 to low income workers (who tend to be mostly unskilled). Figure 2.21(a) shows the market for labour, which is one of the resource markets, with standard demand and supply curves. The ‘price’ of labour is the wage. The demand for labour curve shows the quantity of labour that firms are willing and able to hire at each wage, and the supply of labour curve shows the quantity of labour that workers supply at each wage. Supply and demand determine the equilibrium wage, We, where the quantity of labour demanded is equal to the quantity of labour supplied. The minimum wage, Wm, lies above the equilibrium wage, We. Therefore the quantity of labour supplied at the minimum wage rate, Qs, is larger than the quantity of labour demanded, Qd. There results a surplus of labour in the market equal to the difference between Qs and Qd. This surplus of labour is unemployment, as it corresponds to people who would like to work but have not been employed. The impacts of the minimum wage are: · a surplus of labour equal to Qs − Qd · an increase in the wage of those who are employed, from We to Wm · an increase in costs of production for firms · a decrease in the quantity of labour employed, from Qe to Qd · an increase in unemployment, due partly to the decrease in quantity of labour employed (the difference between Qe and Qd) and partly to an increase in the quantity of labour supplied due to the higher wage rate (the difference between Qs and Qe) price of labour (wage) wages below the legal minimum; this often involves illegal immigrants who may be willing to supply their labour at very low wages. P supply of labour Wm We Farmers’ incomes in many countries, resulting from the sale of their products in free markets, are often considered to be too low (some of the reasons for this will be considered in Chapter 3). One way that governments support farmers’ incomes is by setting price floors for certain key agricultural products. Price floors for agricultural products are called price supports. Price support schemes generally are methods used to raise the price of a product above its equilibrium market price. Figure 2.21(b) shows the market for an agricultural product with a price floor, Pf, set above the equilibrium price, Pe. The impacts of the price floor are the following: · There results a surplus equal to Qs − Qd, since at Pf the quantity consumers demand is given by Qd, while the quantity farmers supply is Qs; this surplus quantity must be disposed of in some way, and is usually bought by the government at price Pf. by total quantity sold times the price at which it is sold. In the free market, farmers’ revenues would have been Qe × Pe, which is equal to the rectangle 0QeAPe. Following the imposition of the price floor, farmers’ revenues increase to an amount equal to the rectangle 0QsBPf. · Consumers are worse off; whereas in the free market situation they would be buying Qe at the price Pe, they now buy a smaller quantity (Qd) and pay a higher price (Pf). (b) An agricultural product market with price floor. P Pf S C surplus B A Pe demand for labour 0 Figure 2.21 Examples of price controls. 56 labour surplus = unemployment Price floors to support farmers’ incomes · Farmers’ revenues increase; revenue is determined · possible illegal employment of some workers at (a) Labour market with minimum wage. The consequences of minimum wage legislation are quite controversial, as it is uncertain whether it results in an increase in unemployment in practice. Some economists argue that labour productivity (defined as the amount of output produced per worker) may increase due to the minimum wage, with the result that employment of unskilled labour could even increase following the imposition of minimum wages. Part 2: Microeconomics Qd Qe Qs quantity of labour Q D 0 Qd Qe Qs Q · There results encouragement of inefficient producers; the higher than equilibrium minimum price offers protection to high cost, inefficient farmers against lower cost, more efficient ones. · There are significant costs to the government, which are paid for out of taxes (and therefore by taxpayers). The cost to the government of buying the surplus is equal to the quantity of the surplus times the price at which it sold, Pf; this is given by the area of the rectangle QdQsBC. In addition, there are further costs of storing the surplus. · There results an overallocation of resources to the production of the product, and therefore allocative inefficiency. Too many resources are allocated to the production of the good. Whereas an optimal (or ‘best’) allocation would mean that Qe would be produced (determined by the free market equilibrium) now the greater quantity Qs is being produced. · There follows, further, a global misallocation of agricultural resources. The European Union, the United States and many other countries rely on price supports for agricultural products to support their farmers, giving rise to an overallocation of resources to these products, excess production and surpluses. The surpluses are sometimes sold in world markets, with the result that they work to lower world prices. Countries that do not have price supports are then forced to sell their agricultural exports at artificially low world prices. The low prices that prevail in these countries signal to local farmers that they should cut back on their production, resulting in an underallocation of resources to the production of such products. Low world prices also mean lower export revenues. This pattern often involves less developed countries that feel frustrated in their development efforts, and is a highly contentious issue (it will be discussed further in Chapters 12 and 15). (a) Price fixing resulting in a shortage. Commodity agreements and buffer stock schemes A commodity is a standardized product, and usually refers to a good that is produced in the primary sector. The primary sector is that part of the economy that makes direct use of natural resources; it therefore includes agriculture, forestry, fishing and extractive P S a b D1 0 Let’s consider tickets for a sports event, shown in Figure 2.22. Note that the supply curve is vertical, indicating that there is a fixed supply of tickets, determined by the fixed number of seats available for each event (the vertical supply curve was considered earlier in the section on ‘Supply’, page 42). The ticket price is given by Pf, and is fixed by the organizing body. Panel (a) illustrates an event for which there is large demand, given by D1. If the price could respond to market forces, it would rise to Pe. However it is fixed at Pf, where there arises a shortage of tickets equal to the horizontal difference between points a and b. Panel (b) illustrates an event for which there is low demand, given by D2. Here, the equilibrium price would have been Pe, however price is fixed at the higher level Pf, giving rise to a surplus of tickets equal to the horizontal difference between points c and d. (b) Price fixing resulting in a surplus. Pe Pf The price controls considered above involve setting a legal maximum or legal minimum price. In these cases, the price is allowed to change, as long as it does not rise above the price ceiling or fall below the price floor. However, there are other situations where the price is fixed so that it cannot change at all. This is seen most frequently in the case of ticket prices for theatres, movies and sports events of all kinds, where prices are usually fixed ahead of time by the organizing body (which may be private or public), and cannot increase or decrease according to the forces of supply and demand. P of tickets P of tickets P Setting fixed prices Q Figure 2.22 Price fixing and surpluses and shortages. Pf S c d Pe D2 0 Q Chapter 2: Markets 57 industries (fuels, metals and so on). The primary sector tends to be more important in less developed countries, and declines in relative importance as a country becomes more developed. Many developing country economies depend heavily on production and exports of commodities. This dependence can pose serious problems for these economies, because commodity prices tend to fluctuate a lot (increase and decrease) over short periods of time, and they also tend to fall over long periods of time. Commodity agreements are agreements attempting to increase or stabilize world prices of commodities on which developing countries depend for their export earnings, so as to protect members against price fluctuations and falling prices. They generally involve international agreements between representatives of producers as well as government authorities. Buffer stock schemes are a special type of commodity agreement intended to limit price fluctuations. These have existed at different times for a number of commodities, including cocoa, coffee, rubber, sugar, tin and wheat. Another type of commodity agreement involves setting export quotas, which attempt to limit the quantity of exports and therefore increase price. Commodities for which these have been tried are sugar and coffee. Buffer stock schemes try to provide price stability for products whose price can fluctuate widely over short periods of time. Agricultural product prices are especially subject to wide fluctuations, partly because production depends on factors beyond the farmer’s control, such as floods, drought, pests and so on, causing shifts in the supply curve, and giving rise to higher or lower prices. Price fluctuations can also be caused by changes in demand, so as the demand curve shifts, this also gives rise to higher or lower prices. (The reasons for price fluctuations of agricultural products will be considered more fully in Chapter 3.) (a) Buffer stock scheme to stabilize price when price fluctuates due to unstable supply. S2 P P2 Pt Qt The way the scheme works is as follows: When supply is large, say at S1, and prices are low (P1), at the target price Pt there results a surplus (or excess quantity) of the product equal to Q1 − Qt. The authorities buy up this surplus and put it in storage; in so doing, they succeed in keeping the price at Pt, and prevent it from falling due to the surplus. When supply is low, say at S2 and prices are high (P2), at the price Pt there results a shortage (or insufficient quantity) of the product equal to Qt − Q2. The authorities now sell this quantity of the product from the stocks they have kept in storage, and thus keep the price from rising due to the shortage. The result is that the price stabilizes at Pt. We can also carry out the analysis in terms of price fluctuations due to unstable demand, as shown in Figure 2.23(b). When demand is low, say at D1, there results a low price of P1, whereas a high demand of D2 gives rise to price P2. Say now the authorities set the target price at Pt (between P1 and P2). When demand is low, say at D1, at the target price Pt there results a surplus equal to Qt − Q1, which the authorities buy up (b) Buffer stock scheme to stabilize price when price fluctuates due to unstable demand. P S1 shortage Q2 Figure 2.23(a) shows how a buffer stock scheme is intended to work when price fluctuations are due to unstable supply. Say that weather conditions have been good in one particular season, the supply curve is S1, and given the demand curve D, the market price is P1. But if in the next season the weather conditions are adverse, this will cause a decrease in output, and therefore a leftward shift of the supply curve to S2, and an increase in price to P2. If a government (or group of governments) decides to implement a buffer stock scheme to stabilize prices, it will determine a price at which it would like the product to sell. We can call this the target price, Pt, and it will be somewhere between P1 and P2. At price Pt, quantity qt should be supplied. The purpose of the scheme is to try to ensure that this quantity qt will be supplied all the time, so as to maintain the price at Pt. Q1 P1 surplus S P2 Pt P1 Q1 Qt shortage q2 qt Figure 2.23 Buffer stock schemes. 58 Part 2: Microeconomics q1 D2 surplus D 0 Q2 D1 Q 0 q1 qt q2 Q and put into storage. When demand is high, say at D2, at the target price Pt there results a shortage equal to Q2 − Qt. The authorities then sell some of the stocks they have in storage, and so prevent the price from increasing. In practice, the authorities would not need to keep track of changing demand and supply. They would buy some of the product during times when price is falling in order to prevent the price decrease, and sell during times of rising prices in order to prevent the price increase. However, in practice buffer stock schemes have not worked very well. Problems include the following: · high costs of storage · underfunding of the schemes · the need to be able to predict future prices that arise from supply or demand shifts; this is very difficult due to the unpredictability of the shifts · the need to balance surpluses with shortages over several years which may not match each other · running out of stocks during times of rising prices · the inability to address the problem of declining prices over the long run (to be discussed in Chapters 14 and 16); when market prices fall over long periods, there result a series of surpluses that accumulate at the ‘target’ price season after season; purchasing these surpluses leads to major financial difficulties. For example, a buffer stock scheme for tin ran into serious difficulties when a dramatic fall in the demand for tin occurred; this led to a very large accumulation of stocks that bankrupted the tin scheme in 1985. Test your understanding 2.10 1 Why do price controls result in market disequilibrium? 2 The ceiling of a room is its upper surface and the floor is its lower surface. Yet in demand and supply analysis we have the reverse: a ceiling lies below equilibrium price and a floor lies above equilibrium price (if they are to be effective). Using appropriate diagrams, explain why this is so. 3 Explain, using diagrams, how price ceilings and price floors give rise to surpluses and shortages. 4 Explain, using diagrams, how fixing price at a particular level can give rise to surpluses when demand is low and shortages when demand is high. 5 In what way are underground markets a kind of price rationing? 6 Using appropriate diagrams, explain how price controls (price ceilings and floors) can work to prevent the achievement of allocative and productive efficiency. 7 (a) Using an appropriate diagram, show how a price ceiling impacts upon price and quantity in the market. (b) Discuss the likely consequences of price ceilings. (c) Evaluate the desirability of these consequences from a social point of view. 8 (a) Using an appropriate diagram, show how a price floor impacts upon price and quantity in the market. (b) Discuss the likely consequences of price floors. (c) Evaluate the desirability of these consequences from a social point of view. Commodity agreements were popular from about the 1960s to the 1980s. Most have since collapsed because of the various difficulties listed above. None succeeded in stabilizing or increasing commodity prices over long periods of time, and they are therefore no longer seriously considered as a method to assist developing countries in their development efforts. Chapter 2: Markets 59 Questions for review 2.1 [10 marks] Identify, and compare and contrast, the main characteristics of the four market structures: perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly. 2.2 [10 marks] Growing populations and rising incomes in developing countries have affected the price of meat. (a) Assuming meat is a normal good, use a demand and supply diagram to explain the impacts on the price of meat. (b) Producers of meat responded to the change in price by increasing the quantity of meat supplied; use your diagram from part (a) to show the increase in quantity of meat supplied. 2.3 [10 marks] ‘Quantity demanded increases as price falls. Yet a fall in demand, ceteris paribus, leads to a fall in price.’ Do these two statements contradict each other? Explain. 2.4 [10 marks] Figure 2.15(a) presents two market equilibrium positions. A comparison of the two shows that a lower price is associated with a greater quantity sold. Does this violate the law of supply? Explain. 2.5 [10 marks] In the standard demand and supply analysis, an increase in demand, ceteris paribus, leads to a larger equilibrium quantity supplied, and yet supply does not change. How is this possible? 2.6 [10 marks] Using supply and demand diagrams, show how prices function as signals and incentives in a market economy. 2.7 [15 marks] (Based on Chapters 1 and 2.) Wassily Leontief, a Russian-born economist who emigrated to the United States in 1925 because of his opposition to Soviet communism, and who in 1973 won the Nobel Prize in Economics, was a keen supporter of strong government intervention in the economy and state economic planning (central planning). Using a mathematical technique known as input–output analysis, he proved that a centrally planned economy can achieve the identical allocation of resources as a free market economy. Yet, in practice, one of the greatest shortcomings of economies that made heavy use of central planning (such as communist systems) has been the failure to achieve efficient resource allocation. (a) Explain resource allocation and relate it to the ‘what to produce’ and ‘how to produce’ economic questions. (b) What are the 60 Part 2: Microeconomics most likely causes of inefficient resource allocation in centrally planned economies? (c) What characteristics of market systems do you think are mainly responsible for the advantages that markets have over command mechanisms and central planning? (Hint: consider the problem of information required by decision-makers to plan economic activities, as opposed to the role of prices as signals and incentives; how does the invisible hand in market economies solve this problem?) 2.8 [5 marks for part (a); 15 marks for part (b)] Greece has legislation that determines a national minimum wage. At one time the government proposed that the law be suspended (not enforced) in areas that have high unemployment. Public reaction to the proposal was mixed, with some people in favour and others against. (a) Use demand and supply diagrams to explain what the proposal was trying to achieve. (b) Evaluate the likely impacts of such a policy, considering who may gain, who may lose, and why. 2.9 [10 marks for parts (a) and (b); 15 marks for parts (c), (d) and (e)] In 1973 OPEC (the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries) increased the price of crude oil, which is the key input in petrol (gasoline) production. This led to an increase in the price of petrol. Some countries initially responded by imposing price controls (a price ceiling, or legal maximum price) on petrol. Following this sequence of events, there emerged shortages in the petrol market. (a) Use a demand and supply diagram to show the impact of the increase in the price of crude oil on the equilibrium price and quantity of petrol/gasoline. (Hint: what effect does an increase in the price of an input (crude oil) have on the supply of petrol?) (b) Use a supply and demand diagram to show the effects of the price ceiling in the petrol market. (c) Was the petrol shortage due to the actions of OPEC or due to the price controls? Explain. (d) What could have been done to prevent the shortage? (e) Evaluate the policy of petrol price controls. 2.10 [15 marks] The United States and the European Union use price supports (price floors, or legal minimum prices) for sugar to support sugar producers. Use a demand and supply diagram to illustrate, explain and evaluate the impacts in the market for sugar. HL 2.11 [10 marks] In athletic and artistic events where ticket prices are fixed ahead of time by the organizing body, and are not allowed to fluctuate in response to demand and supply, we often see the practice where some people buy tickets at the official price and later resell them to interested viewers at a higher price. Use a demand and supply diagram to explain why this practice occurs. 2.12 [15 marks] (a) What are commodity agreements and buffer stock schemes? (b) What do they attempt to achieve? (c) Why are buffer stock schemes no longer used by developing countries as part of their development strategies? (d) Using demand and supply diagrams, show how buffer stock schemes attempt to achieve their objective in the event that (i) prices fluctuate due to unstable demand, and (ii) prices fluctuate due to unstable supply. Higher level 2.13 [10 marks] What are Giffen goods? Under what circumstance might they exist? What do they tell us about the law of demand? 2.14 [10 marks] (a) Provide two possible explanations (other than Giffen goods) for a demand curve that slopes upwards. (b) Why are these a violation of the law of demand? (c) Do you think that each of these is likely to be a violation of individual demand or market demand? Chapter 2: Markets 61 Chapter 3 Microeconomics Elasticities Elasticity is a measure of the responsiveness or sensitivity of a variable to changes in price or any of the variable’s determinants. In this chapter we will examine four kinds of elasticities, selected because of their numerous applications to important economic problems. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · · · · · · define and calculate the price elasticity of demand, the cross-elasticity of demand, the income elasticity of demand, and the price elasticity of supply understand the technical characteristics of each of these elasticities identify the determinants of each elasticity concept and be able to predict their impacts on demand or supply apply each elasticity concept to a variety of real-world situations define and explain flat rate and ad valorem taxes (higher level topic) analyse the incidence of taxes and subsidies on consumers and producers, taking elasticities into consideration (higher level topic). 3.1 Price elasticity of demand (PED) According to the law of demand, there is an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded: the higher the price, the lower the quantity demanded, and vice versa, all other things equal. We now want to know by how much quantity responds to change in price. Price elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity of a good demanded to changes in its price. In general, if there is a large responsiveness of quantity demanded, demand is referred to as being elastic; if there is a small responsiveness, demand is inelastic. 62 Part 2: Microeconomics Determinants of the price elasticity of demand Let’s consider the factors that determine whether the demand for a good is elastic or inelastic: · Availability of substitutes The more substitutes a good or service has, the more elastic will be its demand. If a good or service has many close substitutes, then an increase in its price will make consumers switch to other products that satisfy the same need, therefore there will be a relatively large drop in quantity demanded, i.e. large responsiveness to the price increase. For example, there are many brands of toothpaste, all of which are close substitutes for each other. If there is an increase in the price of one brand of toothpaste, with the prices of all the others remaining the same, consumers are likely to switch to these others. This means there will be a relatively large drop in quantity demanded of the now more expensive toothpaste following the increase in its price, so its demand is elastic. If a good or service has few or no substitutes, then an increase in price will bring forth a small drop in quantity demanded. For example, an increase in the price of petrol (gasoline) is likely to give rise to a small drop in quantity demanded, because there are no close substitutes; therefore the demand for petrol is inelastic. · Broad or narrow definition of a good or service A good can be defined broadly (for example, fruit) or narrowly (a specific kind of fruit, such as oranges, apples, pears, etc.). The broader the definition of a good, the fewer substitutes it will have and the less elastic the demand will be. The narrower the definition, the more there are substitutes, and the more elastic the demand. The demand for apples is more elastic than the demand for fruit, because of the availability of oranges, pears or other fruits that are close substitutes for apples. An increase in the price of apples, for example, will lead consumers to switch to a substitute good. Similarly, a Honda has a higher price elasticity of demand than all cars considered together. · Necessities versus luxuries Necessities are goods or services that we consider to be essential or necessary in our lives; we cannot do without them. Luxuries, on the other hand, are not necessary or indispensable. The demand for goods that are necessities is less elastic than the demand for luxuries. For example, the demand for medications tends to be very inelastic because people’s health or life depend on them; therefore quantity demanded is not very responsive to changes in price. The demand for food is also inelastic, because people cannot live without it. On the other hand, the demand for diamond rings is elastic as most people view them as luxuries. · Length of time The longer the time period in which a consumer makes a purchasing decision, the more elastic the demand. As time goes by, consumers have the opportunity to consider whether they really want the good, and to get information on the availability of alternatives to the good in question. For example, if there is an increase in the price of heating oil, consumers can do little to switch to other forms of heating in a short period of time, and therefore demand for heating oil tends to be inelastic over short periods of time. But as time goes by, they can switch to other heating systems, such as gas, or they can install better insulation, or they can buy more blankets, and demand tends to become more elastic. · Proportion of income spent on a good or service The a good or service, the more elastic the demand. An item such as a pen takes up a very small proportion of one’s income, whereas summer holidays take up a much larger proportion. If there is an increase in the price of pens and in the price of summer holidays, the response in quantity demanded is likely to be greater in the case of summer holidays than in the case of pens. · Addiction The greater the degree of addiction to a substance (drugs, cigarettes and so on) the more inelastic the demand. A price increase will not bring forth a significant reduction in quantity demanded if one is severely addicted. Test your understanding 3.1 1 Identify and explain the determinants of the price elasticity of demand. 2 State in which case demand is likely to be more elastic in each of the following pairs of goods, and why: (a) (b) (c) (d) (e) (f) chocolate or Cadbury’s chocolate orange juice or water cigarettes or candy bars a notepad or a computer heating oil in one week or in one year bread or caviar. Definition and formula for the price elasticity of demand We now turn to an examination of the technical properties of the price elasticity of demand (PED). The formula for the PED Let’s say we are considering the price elasticity of demand (PED) for good X. The formula used to measure its PED is the following: price elasticity = PED = of demand percentage change in quantity of good X demanded percentage change in price of good X If we abbreviate ‘change in’ by the Greek letter Δ, this formula can be rewritten as: PED = %Δ Qx %Δ Px larger the proportion of one’s income needed to buy Chapter 3: Elasticities 63 To calculate the percentage change in quantity (%Δ Q), we divide the change in quantity by the initial quantity and multiply by 100. Similarly, to calculate the percentage change in price (%Δ P), we divide the change in price by the initial price and multiply by 100. The above formula can therefore be rewritten as shown below: Δ Qx PED = Qx Δ Px Px Δ Qx × 100 = × 100 Qx Δ Px Px The sign of the PED Since price and quantity demanded are inversely related, the PED will always be a negative number. This is because for any percentage increase in price (a positive denominator), there will be a percentage decrease in quantity demand (a negative numerator), giving rise to a negative PED. Similarly, for a percentage price decrease there will be a percentage price increase, again resulting in a negative PED. However, the common practice is to drop the minus sign and consider the PED as a positive number. (In mathematics dropping the minus sign of a number is called taking its absolute value.) This is done in order to avoid confusion when making comparisons between different values of PED. Using positive numbers, we can say, for example, that a PED of 3 is larger than a PED of 2. (Had we been using the minus sign, − 2 would be larger than − 3.) The use of percentages Elasticity is measured in terms of percentages for two reasons: · We need a measure of responsiveness that is independent of units. First, we want to be able to compare the responsiveness of quantity demanded of different goods; it makes little sense to compare units of oranges with units of computers or cars. Second, we want to be able to compare responsiveness across countries that have different currency units; an elasticity measured in terms of euros will not be comparable with an elasticity 1 The more advanced student may note that the value of this elasticity of demand depends on the choice of the initial price–quantity combination. In the calculation above, this was taken to be 255, 6000. If we had taken 300, 5000 as the initial price–quantity combination, we would get a PED value of 0.94. (The student can calculate this as an exercise.) This difficulty can be overcome by use of the ‘midpoint formula’: Δ Qx PED = average Qx Δ Px . average Px 64 Part 2: Microeconomics measured in yen or pounds. By computing changes in quantity and changes in price as percentages, we express them in common terms, thereby making comparisons of responsiveness for different goods and across countries possible. · It is meaningless to think of changes in prices or quantities in absolute terms (for example, a $15 increase in price or a 20 unit decrease in quantity) because this tells us nothing about the relative size of this change. For example, a $15 price increase means something very different for a good whose original price is $100 than for a good whose original price is $5000. In the first case there is a 15% increase, and in the second there is a 0.3% increase. Using percentages to measure price and quantity changes allows us to put responsiveness into perspective. The same arguments apply to all other elasticities that we will consider. Calculating the PED We can now use the formula given above to calculate the PED. Let’s suppose that consumers buy 6000 CD players when the price is $255 per CD player, and they buy 5000 CD players when the price is $300. PED = 6000 − 5000 5000 255 − 300 300 = 1000 5000 − 45 300 = 0.20 − 0.15 = −1.33 or 1.33 since we drop the minus sign. Therefore in this example the price elasticity of demand (PED) for CD 1 players is 1.33. Test your understanding 3.2 1 It is observed that when the price of pizzas is $16 per pizza, 100 pizzas are sold; when the price falls to $12 per pizza, 120 pizzas are sold. Calculate the price elasticity of demand. 2 A 10% increase in the price of a particular good gives rise to an 8% decrease in quantity bought. What is the price elasticity of demand? <tyu>Test your understanding 3.2 In the example above, 1000 PED = 5500 45 = 1.12, where 5500 = 5000 + 6000 2 and 277.5 = 255 + 300 2 , 277.5 i.e. we use the average of the two Qx values and the average of the two Px values instead of the initial Qx and initial Px. Interpreting the price elasticity of demand to price changes, and demand is said to be price elastic or elastic. In Figure 3.1(b) demand is elastic: the percentage change in quantity demanded (10%) is larger than the percentage change in price (5%), therefore the PED is greater than one. The range of values for the PED The value of the PED involves a comparison of two numbers: the percentage change in quantity demanded (the numerator in the formula for the PED) and the percentage change in price (the denominator). This comparison yields several possible values and range of values for the PED. Each of these values and range of values are summarized in Table 3.1 and shown graphically in Figure 3.1. In addition, there are three special cases: · Demand is unit elastic when PED = 1 The percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to the percentage change in price, so that the PED is exactly equal to one; demand is then said to be unit elastic. Figure 3.1(c) shows a unit elastic demand curve, where the percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to the percentage change in price, and therefore PED is equal to one. In the example shown, a 5% increase in price results in a 5% decrease in quantity demanded · Demand is price inelastic when PED < 1 (but greater than zero) The percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller than the percentage change in price, so that the value of the PED is less than one; quantity demanded is relatively unresponsive to changes in price, and demand is said to be price inelastic or inelastic. Figure 3.1(a) illustrates inelastic demand: the percentage change in quantity demanded (in this example a 5% decrease) is smaller than the percentage change in price (a 10% increase), therefore the PED is less than one. · Demand is perfectly inelastic when PED = 0 The percentage change in quantity demanded is zero; there is no change in quantity demanded no matter what happens to price; the PED is then equal to zero and demand is said to be perfectly inelastic. For example, a heroin addict’s quantity of heroin demanded is unresponsive to changes in the price of heroin. Figure 3.1(d) presents a perfectly inelastic demand curve, where the PED is equal to zero. The perfectly inelastic demand curve is vertical (parallel · Demand is price elastic when PED > 1 (but less than infinity) The percentage change in quantity demanded is larger than the percentage change in price, so that the value of the PED is greater than one; quantity demanded is relatively responsive Frequently encountered cases. (a) Price inelastic demand: 0 < PED < 1. (b) Price elastic demand: 1 < PED < ∞. P P 5% P2 P2 P1 10% P1 D D 0 Q2 Q1 5% Special cases (d) Perfectly inelastic demand: PED = 0. (c) Unit elastic demand: PED = 1. P 5% 0 Q P 0 Q 10% (e) Perfectly elastic demand: PED = ∞. P D P1 P2 P1 Q2 Q1 D D Q2 Q1 Q 0 Q1 Q 0 Q 5% Figure 3.1 Demand curves and PEDs. Economics for the IB Diploma Figure 3.1 Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s Text: Agenda emcdesign Studio: Peters & Zabransky Chapter 3: Elasticities 65 Table 3.1 Characteristics of price elasticity of demand. Value of PED Classification Interpretation 0 < PED < 1 (greater than zero and less than one) inelastic demand quantity demanded is relatively unresponsive to price 1 < PED < ∞ (greater than 1 and less than infinity) elastic demand quantity demanded is relatively responsive to price PED = 1 unit elastic demand percentage change in quantity demanded equals percentage change in price PED = 0 perfectly inelastic demand quantity demanded is completely unresponsive to price PED = ∞ perfectly elastic demand quantity demanded is infinitely responsive to price Frequently encountered cases Special cases to the vertical axis). Price changes do not give rise to any change in quantity demanded, which remains constant at Q1. · Demand is perfectly elastic when PED = infinity When a change in price results in an infinitely large response in quantity demanded, demand is perfectly elastic. As we can see in Figure 3.1(e) the perfectly elastic demand curve is parallel to the horizontal axis. At price P1, consumers will buy any quantity that is available. If there is a fall in price, buyers will buy all that they can get (an infinitely large response); if there is an increase in price, quantity demanded will drop to zero. This apparently strange kind of demand will be considered in Chapter 5 (at higher level). The numerical value of the PED can therefore vary from zero to infinity. In general, the larger the value of the PED, the greater the responsiveness of quantity demanded. The PED for most goods and services is greater than zero and less than infinite, and other than exactly unity (or one). The cases of unit elastic, perfectly inelastic and perfectly elastic demand are rarely encountered in practice; however, they have applications in economic analysis and for this reason are included in our discussion of PEDs. Variable PED and the straight-line demand curve In our classification of demand curves above, only three demand curves have constant (unchanging) PEDs throughout their entire range. These are the special and unusual cases of the vertical demand curve with a PED of zero for all prices, the horizontal 66 Part 2: Microeconomics demand curve with a PED of infinity for all quantities, and the unit elastic demand curve with a PED equal to one. Most demand curves that are observed in the real world have variable PEDs over the range of the demand curve. To illustrate this, let’s consider a demand curve that consists of a straight line (which is the kind of demand curve that we are using), shown in Figure 3.2. Figure 3.2 illustrates the following principle. When price is low and quantity is high, demand is inelastic; as we move up the demand curve towards higher prices and lower quantities, demand becomes progressively more elastic. We can see this by calculating the PED at three different points. · PED between points a and b Price increases from $10 per unit of A to $15. Quantity demanded falls from 80 units of A to 70 units. Δ Q = 10 , and Q 80 Δ P = 5 . Using the formula for PED, we divide the P 10 percentage change in quantity demanded Δ Q by Q the percentage change in price Δ P and find that P the PED is 1 (= 0.25). Demand is inelastic. 4 · PED between points c and d Suppose that price increases from $25 to $30. Quantity demanded falls from 50 to 40 units. Δ Q = 10 and Δ P = 5 . Q 50 P 25 The percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price is equal to 10 divided by 5 , and that is equal to one or 50 25 unit elasticity. PED and the relative steepness of the demand curve (supplementary material) P ($) 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 f PED = 4 e d elastic portion of demand curve PED = 1 c inelastic portion of demand curve b PED = 0.25 a 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 units of good A Figure 3.2 Variability of PED along a straight-line demand curve. · PED between points e and f Suppose finally that price increases from $40 per unit of A to $45. Quantity demanded falls from 20 units of A to 10 units. Δ Q = 10 , and Δ P = 5 . Dividing the Q 20 P 40 percentage change in quantity demanded by the percentage change in price we find that the PED is 4. Demand is elastic. On any straight-line demand curve, there is an elastic portion of the curve at high prices and low quantities, and an inelastic portion at low price and high quantities. At the midpoint of the demand curve, there is unit elastic demand. There is no special economic meaning in this pattern; it results simply from the arithmetic involved in calculating elasticities.2 Therefore the terms elastic and inelastic should not be used to refer to an entire demand curve (with the exception of the three special cases where PED is constant throughout the entire demand curve). Instead, they should be used to refer to a portion of the demand curve that corresponds to a particular price or price range. Figure 3.1, which showed the particular demand curve that corresponds to each category of elasticities, suggests that the value of the PED is closely related to the steepness (or flatness) of the demand curve.3 It would appear that the flatter the demand curve, the more elastic the demand and the higher the PED; the steeper the demand curve, the less elastic the demand and the lower the PED. However, we cannot conclude whether demand is more or less elastic in different demand curves simply by comparing the steepness of the corresponding demand curve. The reasons for this are the following: · Demand curves drawn on different scales are not comparable. Figure 3.3 shows two identical demand curves with different scales on the horizontal axis. It would be incorrect to conclude that the steeper demand curve has a less elastic demand. · Even if two or more demand curves are drawn on the same diagram, in which case there is no problem of scale, it is still not always possible to say which curve is the more or less elastic. The reason for this is that the PED is not constant along most demand curves; as we have seen, it varies from being highly elastic to highly inelastic. P 5 4 3 2 1 D 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 Q P 5 4 3 2 1 0 D 5 10 15 20 25 Q Figure 3.3 Two identical demand curves. 2 The varying PED along a straight-line demand curve may be contrasted with the slope, which is always constant along a straight line. The slope is defined as the vertical change between two points on the curve divided by the horizontal change between the same two points; in the ΔP case of the demand curve it is given by . A comparison of the slope ΔQ with PED shows that the two are different and should not be confused. The constant slope of the straight-line demand curve tells us that an increase in price produces the same unit decrease in quantity demanded anywhere along the demand curve. This is different from the concept of elasticity, which provides a measure of the responsiveness of quantity demanded to changes in price in percentage terms. The slope measures absolute changes; the elasticity measures relative changes. The slope is not appropriate as a measure of the responsiveness of quantity demanded for the reasons discussed earlier in the section ‘Definition and formula for price elasticity of demand’. 3 In mathematical terms the steepness (or flatness) of a curve is referred to as the slope of the curve. See the previous footnote for a discussion of the difference between the slope and the elasticity. Chapter 3: Elasticities 67 So when is it correct to compare PEDs of demand curves by referring to their steepness? PEDs can be compared by reference to the steepness of the demand curves only in the event that the demand curves in question intersect at some point, that is, when the demand curves share a price and quantity combination, such as demand curves D1 and D2 in Figure 3.4(a). In this figure, for any given price, D1 is flatter and more elastic than D2. For example, if price falls from P1 to P2, the resulting percentage change in quantity will be larger for D1 (increase from Q1 to Q3) than for D2 (increase from Q1 to Q2). In general, when demand curves intersect, then for any given price, the flatter the demand curve, the more elastic is the demand; the steeper the demand curve, the less elastic is the demand.4 Note that this generalization holds only for comparisons between two demand curves at a particular price. It does not hold for different prices because of the variability of the PED along the demand curve. If demand curves do not intersect, comparing PEDs on the basis of steepness or flatness, even for a particular price, can be misleading. For example, consider the two parallel demand curves shown in Figure 3.4(b), which obviously do not share a price–quantity combination. It is tempting to conclude that their (a) Intersecting demand curves and PEDs. P PED of D1 > PED of D2 at each possible price PEDs are the same at each price since they are parallel to each other. However, this would be incorrect, because in fact, for each price, D2 is less elastic (has a lower PED) than D1. To see why, consider price P1, which corresponds to the midpoint of D1, and hence represents the point at which PED = 1 for D1. At this price level, PED < 1 for D2, as it lies in the inelastic portion of this demand curve. Therefore at P1, the PED corresponding to D2 is lower than the PED corresponding to D1. Test your understanding 3.3 1 Specify the value for each of the PEDs below and show diagrammatically the shape of the demand curve that corresponds to each one: (a) perfectly elastic demand; (b) unit elastic demand; (c) perfectly inelastic demand. 2 How would you show price elastic and price inelastic demand in the same diagram? Explain. 3 Provide examples of goods the demand for which is likely to be (a) elastic, and (b) inelastic. 4 Which price elasticity of demand values or range of values do we see most frequently in the real world? 5 Why must we always compare the PEDs of different demand curves at the same price? (...continued) (b) Parallel demand curves and PEDs. P PED = 1 P1 PED < 1 P1 P2 D1 D2 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q 0 PED = 1 0 D1 D2 Q Figure 3.4 Demand curves and PEDs. 4 To see why this is so, the more advanced student can consider the ratio of PEDs of D1 and D2 in Figure 3.4: %Δ Q1 PED1 = PED2 %Δ P %Δ Q2 %Δ P where %Δ Q1 is the percentage change in quantity for D1, %Δ Q2 is the 68 Part 2: Microeconomics percentage change in quantity for D2, and %Δ P is the percentage change in price when price changes from P1 to P2. The %Δ P cancels out from the numerator and denominator, and we are left with PED1 %Δ Q1 , = PED2 %Δ Q2 in other words, the ratio of PEDs is equal to the ratio of percentage changes in quantity. This is exactly what we see in Figure 3.4: the flatter demand curve D1, with the larger PED, has the larger percentage change in quantity. Test your understanding 3.3 (...continued) 6 What can we conclude about the relative PEDs of two demand curves that (a) are parallel to each other; (b) that intersect; (c) that do not intersect? 7 Suppose that the demand for good X increases (shifts to the right) as a result of a successful advertising campaign. Using an appropriate diagram, explain what will happen to the price elasticity of demand at each particular price. Applications of the price elasticity of demand The price elasticity of demand is a very important concept in economics, with numerous applications. Some of these will be considered presently; others will be studied in later chapters. PED and total revenue Total revenue (TR) is the amount of money received by firms when they sell a good (or service), and is equal to the price (P) of the good times the quantity (Q) of the good sold. Therefore TR = P × Q. We are interested in examining what will happen to the firm’s total revenue (TR) when there is a change in the price of the good it produces and sells. We know that P and Q are inversely related to each other, so that an increase in P will give rise to a decrease in Q demanded and vice versa. What can we say about the resulting change in total revenue? Will it increase or decrease? The change will depend on the price elasticity of demand of the good. We have the following three possibilities. Demand is elastic (PED > 1) When demand is elastic, an increase in price causes a fall in total revenue, while a decrease in price causes a rise in total revenue. To see why, consider that if demand is elastic, a 10% price increase will result in a larger than 10% decrease in quantity demanded (since PED > 1). The impact on total revenue of the decrease in quantity is bigger than the impact of the increase in price; therefore total revenue falls. If there is a price decrease, a 10% price fall results in a larger than 10% increase in quantity demanded, and total revenue increases. These results are shown graphically in Figure 3.5(a) (page 70). Recall how the PED varies along the demand curve. Since we are considering elastic demand, we are examining a price change that occurs in the upper left portion of the demand curve. Total revenue is represented by the area of the rectangles obtained by multiplying price times quantity (since TR = P × Q). At the initial price and quantity, P1 and Q1, total revenue is given by the sum of the rectangles A and B. When price increases to P2 and quantity drops to Q2, total revenue is given by the sum of the rectangles A and C. What happened to total revenue due to the price increase? The rectangle B was lost and the rectangle C was gained. Since the loss (B) is larger than the gain (C), total revenue fell. We can use the same diagram to explore a price decrease when PED > 1, simply by assuming that the initial price and quantity are P2 and Q2; price then falls to P1 while quantity increases to Q1. In this case, the gain is given by rectangle B, which is greater than the loss shown by rectangle C, thus total revenue increases. When demand is elastic, an increase in price causes a fall in total revenue, while a decrease in price causes a rise in total revenue. Demand is inelastic (PED < 1) When demand is inelastic, an increase in price causes an increase in total revenue, while a decrease in price causes a fall in total revenue. Since PED < 1, the percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller than the percentage change in price. In this case, a 10% price increase will produce a smaller than 10% decrease in quantity demanded, and total revenue will rise. This happens because the impact on total revenue of the increase is larger than the impact of the decrease. If price falls, a percentage price decrease will give rise to a smaller percentage increase in quantity demanded and total revenue will fall. Graphically these results can be seen in Figure 3.5(b). We are now examining the bottom right portion of the demand curve where demand is inelastic (PED < 1). In the case of a price increase, total revenue gained (rectangle C) is larger than total revenue lost (rectangle B); therefore total revenue increases. If price falls from P2 to P1, the gain in total revenue (rectangle B) is smaller than the loss (rectangle C); therefore total revenue falls. Chapter 3: Elasticities 69 (a) PED > 1 (elastic demand). (b) PED < 1 (inelastic demand). (c) PED = 1 (unit elastic demand). P P P PED > 1 P2 P1 C PED > 1 PED = 1 PED < 1 A B 0 Q2 Q1 Q D PED = 1 P2 P1 0 PED < 1 C A Q2 Q1 P2 B Q D P1 C A 0 Q2 D B Q1 Q Figure 3.5 PED and total revenue. When demand is inelastic, an increase in price causes an increase in total revenue, while a decrease in price causes a fall in total revenue. Demand is unit elastic (PED = 1) When demand is unit elastic, the percentage change in quantity is exactly equal to the percentage change in price, and total revenue remains constant. In Figure 3.5(c), as price and quantity change, the gain in total revenue is exactly matched by the loss, and total revenue remains unchanged. When demand is unit elastic, a change in price does not cause any change in total revenue. These results are summarized as follows: Elastic PED (PED > 1): price and total revenue change in opposite directions. Inelastic PED (PED < 1): price and total revenue change in the same direction. Unit elastic PED (PED = 1): as price changes, total revenue remains unchanged. PED and firm pricing decisions The above discussion on the relationship between price elasticity of demand and total revenue shows that businesses must take the PED into consideration when considering changes in the price of their product. If a business wants to increase its total revenue, it must decrease its price if demand is elastic, or it must increase its price if demand is inelastic. 70 Part 2: Microeconomics If demand is unit elastic, the firm will be unable to change its total revenue by changing its price. Remember that the PED falls as price falls along a straight-line demand curve. In the upper left portion of the curve, demand is highly elastic. At high prices, where demand is elastic, a firm can increase its total revenue by lowering price. Total revenue will continue to increase as price falls until price reaches the point on the demand curve where PED is unit elastic. If price falls further, total revenue will begin to fall because price is now in the inelastic range of the demand curve. This means that total revenue is at a maximum when price is at the point where demand is unit elastic. It is important not to confuse a firm’s total revenue with profit. Profit is total revenue minus total costs. A firm interested in maximizing profits may not want to maximize total revenue. As total revenue rises, it is possible that total costs may rise faster, in which case the firm’s profit will be lower. It is impossible to say what will happen to profit as total revenue rises without looking at what happens to costs. Costs will be examined in Chapter 4 (a higher level topic). PED and price discrimination (higher level topic) Price discrimination takes place when firms charge distinct groups of buyers different prices for the same good or service. This can occur because each group of buyers has a different PED for the good or service. Therefore firms can increase their revenues by charging a higher price to those buyers whose demand for the good is inelastic and a lower price to those buyers with elastic demand. Price discrimination will be discussed in Chapter 5 (at higher level). HL PED and excise taxes Governments often levy taxes on specific goods. Such taxes are called excise taxes, also known as indirect taxes. Governments must consider the price elasticity of demand for the goods to be taxed if they are interested in increasing tax revenues (i.e. the revenues of the government resulting from taxation). The lower the elasticity of demand for the good being taxed, the larger the tax revenues for the government. This can be seen in Figure 3.6, showing the case of inelastic demand in panel (a) and elastic demand in panel (b). Note that we are assuming that the two demand curves are drawn on the same scale, and that if they were drawn in the same diagram they would intersect. (In fact, they would intersect at the point of the initial equilibrium, which is the same price– quantity combination in both diagrams.) Recall from Chapter 2, page 43, that the imposition of a tax on a good has the impact of shifting the supply curve to the left (or upward). The curve will shift from S1 to S2 so that the vertical distance between S1 and S2 is equal to the amount of the tax per unit of output. The new, after-tax equilibrium occurs at price Pt and quantity Qt, determined by the point of intersection between the demand curve, D, and the new supply curve, S2. The shaded area represents the government’s tax revenue, and is obtained by multiplying the amount of the tax per unit times the number of units, or quantity Qt. A comparison of the two figures indicates that tax revenue is larger in the case of inelastic demand. Excise taxes are therefore as a rule levied on goods such as cigarettes and petrol (gasoline), all of which have a low PED. (a) Inelastic demand. P PED and short-term price instability of agricultural products Food (produced in the agricultural sector) has a highly price inelastic demand, because it is a necessity and it has no substitutes. The same applies to a variety of other primary products (such as oil and minerals), known as commodities. In the case of food, in developed countries its PED is estimated to be between 0.20 and 0.25. Low price elasticity of demand, in combination with fluctuations in agricultural output over short periods of time, creates serious problems for agriculture because of major fluctuations in agricultural product prices, which in turn impact on farmers’ incomes. Let’s see why. Agricultural production depends on many factors beyond the farmer’s control, such as drought, pests, floods, frost and other such natural disasters, as well as exceptionally good weather conditions, which occur over short periods of time. These appear in our standard demand and supply analysis as wide supply changes (supply curve shifts). In Figure 3.7 (page 72), let’s say that S1 represents supply under normal weather and other environmental conditions; the supply curve shifts to the left to S2 in the event of adverse conditions, and to the right to S3 in the event of favourable conditions. Such supply shifts are considered together with inelastic demand in panel (a), which characterizes demand for food. Panel (b) shows supply shifts together with elastic demand, which characterizes other goods (manufactured or industrial products) and services. A comparison of the two diagrams reveals that the supply curve shifts give rise to major price fluctuations in the case of inelastic demand, and much milder price fluctuations in the case of elastic demand. Large price fluctuations occurring over short periods of time are referred to as price volatility. (Volatility means instability or high variability.) We can see, (b) Elastic demand. final equilibrium P S2 tax per unit Pt S1 initial equilibrium P1 final equilibrium Pt P1 Qt Q tax per unit S1 initial equilibrium D D 0 S2 0 Qt Q Figure 3.6 PED, excise (indirect) taxes and tax revenues. Economics for the IB Diploma Figure 3.6 Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s Text: Agenda Chapter 3: Elasticities 71 (a) Supply shifts with inelastic demand. (b) Supply shifts with elastic demand. S2 S2 S1 P P2 S1 P S3 S3 P2 P1 P1 P3 P3 D D 0 Q2 Q1 Q3 0 Q Q2 Q1 Q3 Q Figure 3.7 The effect of changes in supply on agricultural product prices and farmer revenues. for the Diploma therefore, Economics why prices inIBthe agricultural sector tend to Figure 3.7 be highly Mac/eps/Illustrator volatile, whereas they tend to be much less Col s/s Text: Agenda so in the manufacturing and services sectors, where emcdesign demand tends to be more elastic. Studio: Peters & Zabransky Two important results follow from this analysis: · As agricultural product prices fluctuate widely, so do farmers’ incomes, which depend on the revenues (price times quantity) that farmers receive from selling their output. · A poor crop (giving rise to S2) results in a higher price, P2, compared to the normal price P1, and a lower quantity of output, Q2. Because of inelastic demand for farm products, the percentage increase in price is larger than the percentage decrease in quantity, and so total revenue increases for farmers. A good crop (leading to S3) results in a lower price, P3, and higher output, Q3; here the percentage decrease in price is larger than the percentage increase in quantity, and so farmers’ revenue falls. The rectangle given by P3 times Q3, representing farmers’ revenue when the crop is good, is smaller than the rectangle given by P2 times Q2, or farmers’ revenue when the crop is poor. By comparison, in the case of elastic demand, revenue increases when the crop is good and decreases when the crop is poor. This means that for consumers, a good harvest results in lower food prices, while for farmers a good harvest ironically translates into lower revenues. Fluctuating prices and hence fluctuating farmers’ incomes over short periods of time have been a key rationale for price support schemes (see Chapter 2, page 56, as well as Chapters 12 and 16). 72 Part 2: Microeconomics Test your understanding 3.4 1 Explain and show diagrammatically how total revenue will change if: (a) price increases and demand is elastic (b) price decreases and demand is inelastic (c) price increases and demand is perfectly inelastic (d) price increases and demand is inelastic (e) price decreases and demand has unit elasticity (f) price decreases and demand is elastic. 2 How can knowledge of the price elasticity of demand for a product help the firm that is producing it? 3 Suppose flooding destroys a substantial portion of this season’s crop. Using appropriate diagrams, explain what is likely to happen to farmers’ revenues, assuming the demand for the product is highly inelastic. 4 The government would like to levy indirect taxes (excise taxes) on certain goods in order to raise tax revenue. Using appropriate diagrams, explain how price elasticity of demand can help it decide which products it should tax. 5 Use the concept of PED and appropriate diagrams to explain why agricultural product prices tend to fluctuate more (are more volatile) compared to manufactured product prices over the short term. 3.2 Cross-elasticity of demand (CED) Interpreting the cross-elasticity of demand Definition and formula for the cross-elasticity of demand · the sign of the CED: unlike the PED, whose minus In Chapter 2, page 36, we learned that the prices of substitutes and complements of a good are among the factors that influence demand for the good and determine the position of its demand curve. We saw that changes in the prices of substitutes and complements cause demand curve shifts. What we would now like to ask is by how much a demand curve will shift, or what is the responsiveness of demand, given a change in the price of a substitute or complement? The cross-elasticity of demand (also known as cross-price elasticity of demand) is a measure of the responsiveness of the demand for one good (say X) to a change in the price of another good (say Y). It provides us with information on the direction of change of demand (whether it increases or decreases), and on the magnitude of the demand shift (by how much demand shifts). The formula for the cross-elasticity of demand is the same as the formula for the PED, only now we consider the relationship between the percentage change in demand of one good (X) and the percentage change in the price of another good (Y): percentage change in demand for good X cross elasticity = CED = of demand CED = percentage change in price of good Y %Δ Qx %Δ Py which can be rewritten as: Δ Qx CED = Qx Δ Py Py Δ Qx × 100 = × 100 Qx Δ Py Py The cross-elasticity of demand provides two kinds of important information: sign is ignored, the cross-elasticity of demand is either positive or negative, and the sign is crucially important to its interpretation · the magnitude of the CED: how small or large is its numerical value. Positive CED: substitutes The cross-elasticity of demand is positive (CED > 0) when the change in the demand for the one good is in the same direction as the change in the price of the other good, in other words, when the price of Y increases the demand for X also increases; and when the price of Y falls, the demand for X also falls. This occurs when the two goods, X and Y, are substitutes for each other (substitutes were defined in Chapter 2, page 36). For example, Coca-Cola® and Pepsi-Cola® are substitutes for each other. Let’s consider what happens to the demand for Pepsi®, shown in Figure 3.8(a) (page 74), as the price of Coca-Cola® changes. If the price of Coca-Cola® increases, the quantity of CocaCola® demanded falls, and the demand for Pepsi® increases as consumers switch from Coca-Cola® to Pepsi®, that is, there will be a rightward shift in the demand curve for Pepsi®. On the other hand, if the price of Coca-Cola® falls, the quantity of Coca-Cola® demanded increases, and the demand for Pepsi® falls as consumers now switch from Pepsi® to Coca-Cola®; there results a leftward shift in Pepsi®’s demand curve. (Note that in the case of Coca-Cola®, whose own price is changing, we refer to increases or decreases in the ‘quantity demanded’, whereas with Pepsi® we refer to increases or decreases in ‘demand’ because of demand curve shifts.) In fact, the cross-elasticity of demand for Coca-Cola® and Pepsi-Cola® has been estimated to be about + 0.7.5 This means that a 1% increase in the price of one will give rise to a 0.7% increase in demand for the other. Alternatively, a 10% increase in the price of one will give rise to a 7% increase in the demand for the other. This is considered to be an example of fairly high substitutability. 5 F. Gasmi et. al. ‘Econometric Analysis of Collusive Behavior in a Soft-Drink Market’, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy (Summer 1992), Chapter 3: Elasticities 73 (a) Substitutes and positive CED: demand for Pepsi Cola® P S D2 D3 D1 D increases as price of Coca-Cola® increases D falls as price of Coca-Cola® decreases 0 The larger the numerical value of the negative cross-elasticity of demand, the greater is the complementarity between two goods, and the larger will be the demand curve shift. Two goods with a CED of − 0.8 are stronger complements than two goods with a CED of − 0.5. Q (b) Complements and negative CED: demand for tennis balls P S D2 D3 0 balls will also fall; there will therefore be a leftward shift in the demand curve for tennis balls. If there is a fall in the price of tennis rackets, the quantity of tennis rackets demanded will increase, and the demand for tennis balls will also increase; the demand curve for tennis balls will shift to the right. D1 D increases as price of tennis rackets decreases D decreases as price of tennis rackets increases Q Figure 3.8 Cross-price elasticities. Economics for the IB Diploma Figure 3.8 The larger the value of the cross-elasticity of demand, Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s the greater Text: Agenda is the substitutability between two goods, emcdesign and the larger will be the demand curve shift. For Studio: Peters & Zabransky example, two substitute goods with a CED of + 0.7 are stronger substitutes for each other than two goods with a CED of + 0.3. Negative CED: complements Zero CED: unrelated products If the cross-elasticity of demand is zero (CED = 0) or close to zero, this means that two products are unrelated or independent of each other. For example, potatoes and telephones are unrelated to each other: a change in the price of one is unlikely to have an impact on demand for the other. Test your understanding 3.5 1 What can you conclude about the relationship of goods A and B in the following situations? (a) the quantity of good A increases by 10% in response to a price decrease in good B of 15% (b) the quantity of good B decreases by 10% in response to a price decrease in good A of 15% (c) the quantity of good B remains unchanged in response to a price decrease in good A of 15%. 2 Can you provide examples of pairs of goods that might correspond to goods A and B in parts (a), (b) and (c) of question 1? 3 If the CED between Coca-Cola® and Pepsi® The cross-elasticity of demand is negative (CED < 0) when the demand for one good and the price of another good change in opposite directions; this occurs when the two goods are complements. (Complements were defined in Chapter 2, page 36.) Figure 3.8(b) shows the demand for tennis balls. If the price of tennis rackets increases, the quantity of tennis rackets demanded will fall, and since tennis rackets are used together with tennis balls, the demand for tennis 74 Part 2: Microeconomics is 0.7, how will the quantity of Coca-Cola® demanded change if the price of Pepsi® increases by 5%? (Your answer should be in percentage terms, and should indicate whether the quantity of Coca-Cola® will increase or decrease.) 4 For the answer to question 3, show diagrammatically (a) the ‘change in quantity demanded’, and (b) the ‘change in demand’ for Pepsi® and Coca-Cola®, respectively, that will result from the 5% increase in the price of Pepsi®. Applications of the cross-elasticity of demand There are a number of situations where businesses as well as government would be interested in knowing the cross-elasticities of demand for various products. It is not only of interest to know whether two or more goods are substitutes or complements (positive or negative sign), but also, knowing the degree of substitutability or complementarity (the magnitude of the numerical value) can be very useful. Substitute goods Substitutes produced by a single business When a business produces a line of products that are similar to each other, such as Coca-Cola® and Sprite®, which are both produced by Coca-Cola®, it must consider the cross-elasticity of demand for these products when making decisions about prices. Since the two goods are substitutes, a fall in the price of Coca-Cola® would be followed by a fall in the demand for Sprite®. Should Coca-Cola® cut the price of CocaCola®? To make a decision it must have information about: · the PED for Coca-Cola®, so that it can determine whether a price cut will lower or raise total revenue from Coca-Cola® · the CED for Coca-Cola® and Sprite®; it is not enough to know that the CED > 1 (i.e. that the two goods are substitutes for each other). In addition, it is important to know the degree of substitutability between them. If the value of the CED is positive but low (low substitutability), a percentage decrease in the price of Coca-Cola® will produce only a small percentage drop in demand for Sprite®, so that the sales of Sprite® would not be seriously affected. But if the value of the CED is positive and high, a fall in the price of Coca-Cola® will produce a large drop in demand for Sprite®. Increased sales of CocaCola® would come at the expense of Sprite® sales – something that the company would probably want to avoid. Substitutes produced by rival businesses A business is also interested in knowing the CED of substitutes in the event that they are produced by rival businesses. For example, Coca-Cola® would be interested in knowing the CED between Coca-Cola® and Pepsi-Cola®. A large CED would mean that if Coca-Cola® dropped its price, Pepsi® would suffer a serious drop in sales, whereas a low CED would mean that Pepsi® would not be seriously affected. Coca-Cola® would also want to know this CED in order to be able to predict the effect on Coca-Cola® sales of any change in the price of Pepsi®. Substitutes and mergers between firms A merger takes place when two firms unite to form a single firm. Businesses that produce close substitutes, i.e. goods with a high CED, might be interested in merging because that way they would eliminate the competition between them. Governments generally try to prevent firm mergers that are likely to result in a major reduction of competition. One of the roles of government in the economy is to try to promote competition between firms. (The reasons for this will be explored in Chapters 5 and 6.) Therefore knowledge of the CED of goods produced by rival firms interested in merging can be used to determine whether the merger should be permitted to take place. Complementary goods Knowledge of the CED for complementary products is also useful for business pricing decisions. Products that have a low (negative) CED are weakly complementary and will not be of much interest. However a high (negative) CED means that lowering the price of one good can result in a significant increase in demand and sales for the other. This prompts collaboration between businesses that produce complementary goods. For example, sports clothing and sports equipment are highly complementary, as are charter flights and holiday hotels. A fall in the price of charter flights is likely to produce a significant increase in holiday hotel occupancy. We find airlines frequently collaborating with hotels to take advantage of the complementarities. Test your understanding 3.6 1 How can knowledge of cross-elasticities of demand help firms decide on how to price their products in the case of (a) substitutes; (b) complements? 2 In what way can the cross-elasticity of demand help governments decide whether or not to allow a merger between two firms to take place? Chapter 3: Elasticities 75 3.3 Income elasticity of demand (YED) Definition and formula for income elasticity of demand Another factor influencing demand for a good and the position of the demand curve is consumer income. Recall from Chapter 2, page 35, that the impact of income on demand depends on whether the good in question is normal or inferior. If the good is normal, income and demand change in the same direction: an increase in income gives rise to an increase in demand (a rightward shift of the demand curve) while a fall income causes demand to fall (a leftward demand shift). On the other hand, if the good is inferior, income and demand change in opposite directions: an increase in income produces a decrease in demand, and a decrease in income produces an increase in demand. The income elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of demand to changes in income. It provides information on the direction of change of demand, given a change in income, and on the magnitude of the change (by how much the demand curve will shift). The formula for the income elasticity of demand is the same as the formula for the PED, only now we consider the relationship between the percentage change in demand for a good, X, to a percentage change in income, which we abbreviate as Y: income elasticity of = YED = demand YED = percentage change in demand for good X percentage change in income %Δ Qx %Δ Y which can be rewritten as: Δ Qx YED = Qx ΔY Y 76 Part 2: Microeconomics Δ Qx × 100 = × 100 Qx Δ Yy Y Interpreting the income elasticity of demand The income elasticity of demand provides two kinds of important information: · its sign (whether it is positive or negative) · its numerical value: whether it is greater or smaller than one. The sign of the income elasticity of demand (normal or inferior goods) The sign of the income elasticity of demand provides us with the following information. · YED > 0 The income elasticity of demand is positive (YED > 0) when demand and income change in the same direction (i.e. both increase or both decrease). A positive YED indicates that the good in question is normal. Most goods are normal goods (normal goods were defined in Chapter 2, page 35). · YED < 0 A negative income elasticity of demand (YED < 0) indicates that the good is inferior: demand for the good and income move in opposite directions (as one increases the other decreases). Examples include bus rides, used clothes and used cars; in these cases, as income increases, the demand for these goods fall as consumers switch to consumption of normal goods (new cars, new clothes and so on). (Inferior goods were defined in Chapter 2, page 36). The value of the income elasticity of demand Test your understanding 3.7 We are especially interested in examining normal goods (since most goods are normal). We are therefore looking at goods with a YED that is greater than zero (positive). · YED > 1 If a good has an YED that is greater than one, it is said to be income elastic. This means that a percentage change in income will give rise to a larger percentage change in demand (in the formula for the YED, the numerator is larger than the denominator). · YED < 1 If on the other hand a good has an YED that is less than one, it is said to be income inelastic: the percentage change in income produces a smaller percentage change in demand (the numerator is smaller than the denominator). Figure 3.9 shows an initial demand curve, D1, and shifts of the curve that occur in response to increases in income, depending on the sign and value of the YED. If the YED is negative, indicating an inferior good, an increase in income causes a leftward shift of the demand curve to D2. If the YED is positive, indicating a normal good, the demand curve shifts to the right to D3 or D4. The greater the (positive) YED, the larger the rightward shift of the demand curve. P YED < 0 0 < YED < 1 YED > 1 inferior good 0 D2 income inelastic demand, normal good D1 income elastic demand, normal good D3 D4 Q Figure 3.9 Demand curve shifts in response to increases in income for Economics for the IB Diploma different values of the YED. Figure 3.9 Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s Text: Agenda emcdesign Studio: Peters & Zabransky 1 Your income increases from £1000 a month to £1200 a month. As a result, you increase your purchases of pizzas from 8 to 12 per month, and you decrease your purchases of cheese sandwiches from 15 to 10 per month. (a) Calculate your income elasticity of demand for pizzas and for cheese sandwiches. (b) What kind of goods are pizzas and cheese sandwiches for you? (c) Show diagrammatically the impacts of your increase in income on your demand for pizzas and cheese sandwiches. 2 A 15% increase in income leads to a 10% increase in demand for good A and 20% increase in demand for good B. Explain which of the two goods is income elastic and which is income inelastic. Determinants of the income elasticity of demand Assuming that the YED > 0 (so we are talking about normal goods), the following factors determine whether the YED will be high or low. · Necessities or luxuries This is the most important determinant. Necessities, such as food, clothing and housing, tend to have an income elasticity of demand that is positive but less than one; they are in other words income inelastic. In the case of food, for example, as income increases, people will buy more food but the proportion of income spent on food increases at a lower rate (more slowly) than income. In developed countries, the YED for food is about 0.15 to 0.2. This means that a 1% increase in income will produce a 0.15% to 0.2% increase in spending on food. Alternatively a 10% increase in income will result in a 1.5% to 2% increase in spending on food. By contrast, luxuries, such as travel to other countries, private education and eating in restaurants have an income elasticity greater than one; they are income elastic. This means that as income increases, the proportion of income spent on such goods increases at a higher rate than income. · Income level of consumers What is a necessity and what is a luxury depends on income levels. For people with extremely low incomes, even food and certainly clothing can be luxuries. As income increases, certain items that used to be luxuries become necessities. For example, items like CocaCola® and coffee for many poor people in less Chapter 3: Elasticities 77 developed countries are luxuries, whereas for consumers in developed countries they have become necessities. The income elasticity of demand for particular items therefore varies widely depending on income levels. The income elasticity of demand for food is about 0.15 in some more developed countries, but is about 0.8 in very poor countries. This means that for an increase in income of 10%, spending on food increases by only 1.5% in rich countries and by 8% in poor countries. Test your understanding 3.8 1 What do you think is most likely to have happened to the income elasticity of demand for laptops since they were first introduced? Explain. 2 How can you account for the fact that income elasticity of demand for food has been estimated to be about 0.15 to 0.2 in more developed countries and about 0.8 in less developed countries? Applications of the income elasticity of demand YED and the rate of expansion of industries Over time, as countries grow and develop economically, society’s income increases. Increasing income means a growing demand for goods and services, and a growing output to meet this demand. Let’s say that total income in an economy grows at an average of about 3% per year. Some industries produce goods and services the demand for which grows at a rate of more than 3% (elastic demand), with a YED greater than one. Examples include restaurants, movies and foreign travel. Other industries produce goods and services the demand for which grows at a rate of less than 3% (inelastic demand); these have a YED less than one, and include items like food, clothing and furniture. The first group (with the elastic demand) represents goods and services or industries that grow and expand faster than total income in the economy, whereas the second group represents goods or services or industries that grow more slowly than total income. Information on the YED of different products can be interesting for firms as it reveals the products that are likely to have the most rapidly expanding markets. The higher the YED for a particular good or service, 78 Part 2: Microeconomics the greater the expansion of its market is likely to be in the future; the lower the YED, the smaller the expansion. YED and sectoral change in an economy A sector is defined to be a part of an economy. All economic activity in every economy can be classified under the following three sectors: · the primary sector, dominated by agriculture, and also including fishing, forestry and all extractive activities (such as mining) · the secondary sector, including manufacturing · the tertiary sector, including commerce, finance, transportation and all other services (education, health care, and so on), also referred to as the services sector. The contribution of each of these sectors to total economic activity can be measured in several ways, such as in terms of the value of output they produce (GDP), or the number of people they employ. Regardless of how it is measured, the relative size of this contribution tends to change over time as a country grows and becomes economically more developed. Less developed countries tend to have very large primary sectors due to the predominance of agriculture in the economy as well as extractive activities (oil, minerals, natural gas and so on) and small manufacturing and services (secondary and tertiary) sectors. This means that the bulk of output they produce is agricultural and other primary product output, and a very large proportion of the working population is employed in the primary sector. The developed countries of today were in a similar position many decades ago. Their historical experience shows that as they grew and developed, their agricultural sector became less and less important, and was partly replaced by manufacturing and services. As they grew and developed further, and the relative importance of agriculture and the primary sector generally continued to shrink, manufacturing became increasingly replaced by services. Thus, while less developed countries tend to be dominated by the primary sector, more developed countries tend to be dominated by services. Figure 3.10 illustrates this process for a hypothetical growing economy. Each sector’s relative importance is measured in terms of its percentage contribution to GDP (recall from Chapter 1, page 9, that GDP refers to a common measurement of the value of output of an economy). Note that the changing percentages shown in Figure 3.10 refer to changing shares or percentage (a) (b) 5% agriculture (primary sector) (c) 10% services 15% manufacturing 75% agriculture (primary sector) 30% services 40% agriculture (primary sector) 65% services 30% manufacturing 30% manufacturing Figure 3.10 Changing relative shares (in terms of percentage of GDP) of the primary, secondary and tertiary sectors for a hypothetical economy as it grows. contributions of each sector to total output. If total output is increasing over time, a falling share over time for a particular sector (such as the primary sector) does not mean that primary sector output is falling; it could mean that this sector’s output is growing, but growing more slowly than total output, so that its percentage share is falling. An increasing share for a sector means that output for that sector is growing more rapidly than total output. the agricultural and manufacturing sectors; this is shown in the progression from panel (a) to (b) to (c) in Figure 3.10. Many services have very high YEDs, so that the percentage increase in the demand for these is significantly larger than the percentage increase in income. In the developed world today, among the industries experiencing the fastest growth are services, including education, health care, travel and financial services. Changes in the relative importance of the three sectors as economic growth and development occur can be explained in terms of income elasticity of demand. Agriculture, the main part of the primary sector, produces food, which as we know has a YED that is positive but less than one (it is income inelastic). This means that as society’s income grows over time, the demand for agricultural output grows more slowly than the growth in income. Other primary products tend to have a low income elasticity of demand as well.6 By contrast, manufactured products (cars, televisions, computers and so on) have a YED that tends to be greater than one (income elastic), so that as society’s income grows, the demand for these products grows faster than income. The result is that over time, the share of agricultural output as a share of total output in the economy shrinks, while the share of manufactured output grows. In Figure 3.10, this is shown in the change in output shares from panel (a) to panel (b). YED and long-term impacts on agricultural and other primary product prices At the same time that the share of manufacturing output is increasing at the expense of agriculture, the services sector tends to expand at the expense of both In developed countries, major technological advances in agriculture have occurred over several decades that have shifted the supply curve of agricultural products A low YED for food (agricultural products), compared to a high YED for manufactured products and services, has important implications for the level of prices of agricultural products relative to prices of manufactured products and services over long periods of time. We have seen that a low YED for food compared to manufacturing and services means that as income rises, a relatively smaller proportion of income is spent on food and a relatively larger proportion on manufactured products and services. This indicates that as incomes rise, demand for manufactured products and services rises more rapidly than the demand for food. The result is that the prices of these goods and services rise more rapidly than the prices of agricultural products. The case of more developed countries 6 For example, cotton and rubber have synthetic substitutes, so as income increases, a relatively larger proportion of it is spent on the synthetic materials, while a relatively lower fraction goes towards cotton and rubber. Chapter 3: Elasticities 79 to the right. Against this background of increasing supply, low income elasticity of demand for food is responsible for the failure of demand for agricultural products to grow sufficiently over long periods of time in order to keep up with the increases in supply. This is shown in Figure 3.11. Supply has shifted from S1 to S2 due to substantial technological advances. Demand shifts from D1 to D2 due to economic growth and increasing incomes, but because of the low YED the size of the demand shift is relatively small. With the increase in demand being smaller than the increase in supply, there is a downward pressure on prices. Less developed countries (LDCs) tend to have very large agricultural sectors, and in many cases their economies depend heavily on exports of agricultural products. Over the past several decades, there have been large increases in the supply of a number of agricultural products exported by LDCs (cocoa, coffee, sugar, cotton and others). Given low YEDs for these products, there has been by slow growth in global demand. Figure 3.11 illustrates the results of large growth in supply with relatively slower growth in demand. Downward pressures on agricultural product prices mean that LDCs that rely heavily on exports of such products have been suffering declines in export revenues over many years, with major negative consequences for their growth and development efforts. (We will return to these topics in Chapters 14 and 16.) S1 P2 D2 D1 Q Figure 3.11 Long-term decline in agricultural product prices. 80 Economics for the IB Diploma Figure 3.11 Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s Text: Agenda emcdesign Part 2: Microeconomics Studio: Peters & Zabransky observed rapid growth in certain service industries, including health care, education, and financial services compared to other industries such as food (in the primary sector) and furniture (n the secondary sector)? 2 Using the concept of YED and an appropriate diagram, explain why agriculture is often referred to as a ‘declining industry’. diagram to explain why agricultural product prices tend to fall relative to prices of manufactured products over the long term. 3.4 Price elasticity of supply (PES) Definition and formula for the price elasticity of supply Until now we have been studying demand elasticities, all of which involve consumer responses. We now turn to examine the price elasticity of supply, which concerns firm responses to changes in price. We know that according to the law of supply, there is a positive (direct) relationship between price and quantity supplied: when price increases, quantity supplied increases, and vice versa. But by how much does quantity supplied change? Price elasticity of supply is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity of a good supplied to changes in its price. In general, if there is a large responsiveness of quantity supplied, supply is referred to as being elastic; if there is a small responsiveness, supply is inelastic. S2 P1 0 1 What is one likely explanation behind the 3 Use the concept of YED and an appropriate The case of less developed countries P Test your understanding 3.9 The formula for the price elasticity of supply (PES) is the same as the formula for the PED, only now we consider the relationship between the percentage change in quantity supplied of a good, X, and the percentage change in its price: In addition, there are three special cases: price elasticity = PES = of supply PES = percentage change in quantity of good X supplied percentage change in price of good X %Δ Qx %Δ Px which can be rewritten as: Δ Qx PES = Qx Δ Px Px Δ Qx × 100 = × 100 Qx Δ Px Px Interpreting the price elasticity of supply The range of values for the PES The price elasticity of supply ranges in value from zero to infinity. Note that because of the direct relationship between price and quantity supplied, the PES is positive. The value of the PES involves a comparison of the percentage change in quantity supplied (the numerator in the formula for the PES) with the percentage change in price (the denominator). This comparison yields the following possible values and range of values of the PES, each of which is summarized in Table 3.2 and shown graphically in Figure 3.12 (both on page 82): · Supply is price inelastic when PES < 1 The percentage change in quantity supplied is smaller than the percentage change in price, so that the value of the PES is less than one; quantity supplied is relatively unresponsive to changes in price, and supply is said to be price inelastic or inelastic. Figure 3.12(a) shows an inelastic supply curve (PES < 1): in the example considered here, a 10% increase in price gives rise to a 5% increase in quantity supplied. · Supply is price elastic when PES > 1 The percentage change in quantity supplied is larger than the percentage change in price, so that the value of the PES is greater than one; quantity supplied is relatively responsive to price changes, and supply is said to be price elastic or elastic. Figure 3.12(b) shows an elastic supply curve (PES > 1) where the percentage increase in price (10%) is smaller than the percentage increase in quantity (20%). · Supply is unit elastic when PES = 1 The percentage change in quantity supplied is equal to the percentage change in price, so that the PES is exactly equal to one; supply is then said to be unit elastic. In Figure 3.12(c), all three supply curves shown are unit elastic curves, i.e. for all three, PES = 1. Any supply curve that passes through the origin has a PES equal to unity. The reason for this is that along any straight line that passes through the origin, between any two points on the line the percentage change in the vertical axis (in this case price) is equal to the percentage change in the horizontal axis (in this case quantity). Therefore, for lines that pass through the origin, it is important not to confuse the steepness of the curve with the elasticity of the curve. · Supply is perfectly inelastic when PES = 0 The percentage change in quantity supplied is zero; there is no change in quantity supplied no matter what happens to price; the PES is then equal to zero and supply is said to be perfectly inelastic. In Figure 3.12(d), the PES is equal to zero; no matter what happens to price, quantity supplied does not respond. The supply curve is vertical at the point of fixed quantity supplied, Q1. The student will note that this is exactly the same as the supply curve shown in Figure 2.11 in Chapter 2, page 42). Examples of a vertical supply curve include the supply of fish at the moment when fishing boats return from sea; the season’s entire harvest of fresh produce brought to market; the supply of Picasso paintings; and the number of seats in a stadium or theatre. · Supply is perfectly elastic when PES = ∞ The percentage change in quantity supplied is infinite; what this means in effect is that a very small a change in price will result in a very large response in quantity supplied; supply in this case is called perfectly elastic, and is shown in Figure 3.12(e) as a line parallel to the horizontal axis. What such a supply curve means in practice is that at the price where the supply curve is situated, firms can supply any quantity of the good. (We will encounter such a supply curve in Chapter 12.) Chapter 3: Elasticities 81 Table 3.2 Characteristics of price elasticity of supply. Value of PED Classification Interpretation inelastic supply quantity supplied is relatively unresponsive to price elastic supply quantity supplied is relatively responsive to price PED = 1 unit elastic supply percentage change in quantity supplied equals percentage change in price PED = 0 perfectly inelastic supply quantity supplied is completely unresponsive to price perfectly elastic supply quantity supplied is infinitely responsive to price Frequently encountered cases 0 < PED < 1 (greater than zero and less than one) ∞ 1 < PED < (greater than 1 and less than infinity) Special cases PED = ∞ (a) Price inelastic supply PES < 1. P Frequently encountered cases (b) Price elastic supply PES > 1. P S S P2 10% 10% P1 0 Q1 Q2 P Q1 Special cases P Q2 Q 20% (d) Perfectly inelastic supply PES = 0. S1 P1 0 Q 5% (c) Unit elastic supply PES = 1. P2 (e) Perfectly elastic supply PES = ∞. P S S2 S3 0 P1 Q 0 Q1 Q 0 S Q Figure 3.12 Supply curves and the PES. Economics for the IB Diploma Figure 3.12most commonly Price elasticities of supply Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s encountered in the Text: realAgenda world are those representing elastic or inelastic supply, emcdesignwith perfectly elastic, Studio: Peters & Zabransky perfectly inelastic and unit elastic supply being special cases. Note that only when two supply curves intersect (that is, when they share a price and quantity combination) is it possible to make comparisons of price elasticities of supply by reference to the steepness 82 Part 2: Microeconomics of the curves. (You may remember that we have the same condition for making comparisons of PEDs in the case of demand curves.) In the case of intersecting supply curves, the flatter the supply curve, the more elastic it is at any given price. For example, in Figure 3.13, at any one particular price level, S3 is more elastic than S2, which is more elastic than S1. · The immediate time period This is a time period so P 10% short that the firm is unable to increase (or decrease) any of its inputs in order to change the quantity it produces. In this case supply is highly inelastic, and may even be perfectly inelastic (PES = 0). In Figure 3.13, this is represented by S1. S2 S1 S3 P2 · The short run The short run is defined as a period P1 0 Q1 Q2 3% Q3 Q 15% Figure 3.13 The length of time and PES. It should also be noted that the PES varies along any straight-line supply curve (as in the case of PED and demand curves) so that when comparing the PES of two different supply curves, this should be done only at a specific price or price range. Test your understanding 3.10 1 Specify the value or range of values for each of the PESs below, and show diagrammatically the shape of the supply curve that corresponds to each one: (a) perfectly elastic supply; (b) unit elastic supply; (c) perfectly inelastic supply. 2 How would you show price elastic and price inelastic supply in the same diagram? Explain. 3 Which price elasticity of supply values or range of values do we see most frequently in the real world? Determinants of the price elasticity of supply Length of time The main factor determining the price elasticity of supply is the ease and speed with which firms can shift resources and production between different products, and this in turn depends on the amount of time firms have to adjust resource use and therefore the quantity supplied in response to a change in price. We can distinguish between three time periods: of time during which a firm can vary (increase or decrease) some but not all of its inputs. At least one of its inputs is fixed in quantity. For example, in the event of a price increase it can hire more labour, but there is not enough time to expand its factories or build new ones. This means that the firm can increase the quantity it produces by using more of some inputs (such as labour) but these will have to work together with the other inputs that are fixed in quantity. The result is that quantity supplied will increase only a little in response to the price increase; supply is inelastic (PES < 1) and is represented by a curve such as S2 in Figure 3.13. · The long run The long run is defined to be a period of time long enough so that a firm can vary all of its inputs: factories, machinery and so on can be adjusted to respond fully to the price change. The response of quantity supplied to the price change will be much greater, and quantity supplied increases substantially in response to a price increase; supply is elastic (PES > 1) as shown by S3 in Figure 3.13. Thus in the examples of Figure 3.13, we see that a 10% price increase (from P1 to P2) produces a zero change in quantity supplied in the case of S1 where PES = 0 (the immediate time period); or a 3% increase in quantity supplied in the case of S2 when PES < 1 (the short run), and a 15% increase in quantity supplied for S3 when PES > 1 (the long run). As the time available to firms to adjust their inputs increases, the responsiveness of quantity supplied to a price change increases. Spare capacity of firms Sometimes firms may have capacity to produce that is not being used (for example, factories or equipment may be idle for some hours each day). If this occurs, it is relatively easy for a firm to respond with increased output to a price rise. But if the firm’s capacity is fully used, it will be more difficult to respond to a price rise. The greater the spare (unused) capacity, the higher is the PES (the more elastic the supply); the less the spare capacity, the smaller the PES (the less elastic the supply). Chapter 3: Elasticities 83 Test your understanding 3.11 1 Suppose that in response to an increase in the price of good X from $10 to $15 per unit, the quantity of good X produced (a) does not respond at all during the first week; (b) increases from 10,000 units to 12,000 units over five months; and (c) increases from 10,000 to 18,000 units over two years. Calculate the PES for each of these three time periods. 2 (a) How can you account for the difference in the size of the three elasticities of Question 1? (b) Draw a supply curve that is likely to correspond to each of the three elasticities in a single diagram. Applications of the price elasticity of supply PES and short-term price instability of agricultural products In general, agricultural products (as well as other primary products) tend to have a lower price elasticity of supply than industrial (manufactured) products, particularly over short periods of time. The main reason for this is the time needed for quantity supplied to respond to price changes. It takes relatively long periods of time for resources to be shifted in and out of agriculture, and agriculture is also constrained by growing seasons for particular products that farmers cannot control. In the case of other primary products (such as oil, natural gas and minerals), time is needed to make the necessary investments and to begin production. Earlier, in our discussion of price elasticity of demand (PED), we saw that fluctuating supply over short periods of time in combination with price inelastic demand for food is a major factor contributing to short-term price and income instability for farmers. Now we will see that fluctuating demand over short periods of time in combination with price inelastic supply of agricultural and other primary products also contributes to price and income instability in the farm sector. Why does demand for agricultural products fluctuate? Within any particular country, the demand for food tends to be relatively stable (i.e. the determinants of demand do not change significantly). However, if a country exports (i.e. sells to other countries) a relatively large portion of its agricultural output, then 84 Part 2: Microeconomics a part of its total demand for agricultural products will be made up of foreign demand. Foreign demand for agricultural products can be unstable for several reasons. Crop failures in other countries can raise foreign demand for a country’s products, while good harvests will lower it. Increased protection of farmers in other countries through government policies such as price supports (discussed in Chapter 2, page 56) or quotas and tariffs (to be discussed in Chapter 12) will lower foreign demand whereas reduced protection will increase it. Changes in consumer tastes can also affect demand. Figure 3.14 shows a fluctuating demand curve (it is steep, indicating low price elasticity of demand); in panel (a) it interacts with inelastic supply, which is typical in the case of agriculture, and in panel (b) with elastic supply, which is more typical of manufactured products. Clearly, price fluctuations are substantially larger in the case of inelastic supply. Large price fluctuations mean large revenue fluctuations, or unstable income for farmers. (a) Demand shifts with inelastic supply. S P P2 P1 P3 0 D3 D1 D2 Q (b) Demand shifts with elastic supply. P S P2 P1 P3 D2 D3 0 D1 Q Figure 3.14 The effect of changes in demand on agricultural product prices and farmer revenues. Short-run and long-run price elasticities of supply It was noted above that agricultural products tend to have lower price elasticities of supply than manufactured products over short periods of time because they need more time to respond to price changes. This suggests that over longer periods of time the PES of agricultural products is larger. Table 3.3 shows that this is in fact the case. The longer the time producers (firms) have to make the necessary adjustments, the greater the responsiveness of quantity supplied to price changes (see Figure 3.13). Because the length of time available to producers is such an important determinant of the price elasticity of supply, it is important to make a distinction between short-run and long-run price elasticities of supply. Table 3.3 Short-run and long-run PES for selected commodities. Commodity Short-run PES Long-run PES Cabbage 0.36 1.20 Carrots 0.14 1.00 Cucumbers 0.29 2.20 Onions 0.34 1.00 Green peas 0.31 4.40 Tomatoes 0.16 0.90 Cauliflower 0.14 1.10 Celery 0.14 0.95 Test your understanding 3.12 1 Use the concept of PES to explain why agricultural product prices are volatile over the short term. 2 Why is it important to make a distinction between short-run and long-run price elasticities of supply? 3 Why do agricultural products generally tend to have a lower PES than manufactured products over short periods of time? Table 3.4 provides a summary of key characteristics of all the elasticities considered in this chapter. Table 3.4 Elasticity concepts summarized. Elasticity Formula Values Description PED = 0 perfectly inelastic PED < 1 price inelastic PED = 1 unit elastic PED > 1 price elastic PED = ∞ perfectly elastic Cross%Δ Qx elasticity of CED = demand %Δ Py CED > 0 substitutes CED < 0 complements CED = 0 unrelated Income elasticity of demand YED > 0 normal good YED < 0 inferior good YED > 1 income elastic YED < 1 income inelastic PES = 0 perfectly inelastic PES < 1 price inelastic PES = 1 unit elastic PES > 1 price elastic PES = ∞ perfectly elastic Price elasticity of demand PED = YED = %Δ Qx %Δ Px %Δ Qx %Δ Y Price elasticity of supply PES = %Δ Qx %Δ Px 3.5 Elasticities of demand and supply and incidence of taxes and subsidies (higher level topic) This topic involves an additional application of the concepts of price elasticity of demand and price elasticity of supply. Indirect taxes: flat rate and ad valorem Indirect taxes are taxes levied on spending to buy goods and services. They are called indirect because, whereas they involve payment of some of the tax by the consumer, they are paid to the government authorities by the suppliers (firms), that is, indirectly. Examples of indirect taxes are excise taxes (or excise duties), which are taxes on specific goods and services (such as taxes on cigarettes), general sales taxes and Chapter 3: Elasticities 85 HL HL value added tax (VAT). Indirect taxes can be contrasted with direct taxes, involving payment of the tax directly by consumers or firms to the government (such as personal income taxes). (Both direct and indirect taxes will be considered in Chapter 11.) Indirect taxes can be · flat rate taxes, involving an absolute amount per unit of the good or service sold, such as for example, €5 per packet of cigarettes. · ad valorem taxes, involving a fixed percentage of the price of the good or service; in this case the amount of tax increases as the price of the good or service increases. When a tax is imposed on a good or service, this tax must be paid to the government by the firm. From the point of view of the firm, this means that for every level of output that the firm is willing and able to produce and supply, it must now receive a price that is higher than the original price by the amount of the tax. This in effect involves a shift of the supply curve upward by the amount of the tax. (Note that this is equivalent to a leftward shift of the supply curve; a leftward shift means that for each price, the firm is now willing to supply less output.) Figure 3.15 shows how the supply curve shifts in the case of a flat rate tax and an ad valorem tax. In the case of a flat rate tax, the shift of the supply curve is parallel, because the tax is an absolute amount for each unit of output sold and so is the same for all prices. Therefore in panel (a) S2 is parallel to S1. In the case of the ad valorem tax, the new supply curve S2 is steeper than S1; since it involves a percentage of the price, the absolute amount of the tax (shown in the diagram) increases as price increases. (a) Flat rate tax. P The incidence of indirect taxes and subsidies on consumers and producers The incidence of indirect taxes It was noted above that when a tax is imposed on a good or service, the tax is paid to the tax authorities by the producers (firms). However, this tells us nothing about who ultimately pays the tax. Suppose, for example, that producers are able to pass on to consumers a part of the tax in the form of higher prices. Although the producers are responsible for payment of the tax to the government, the burden of the tax is no longer fully on the producers, as part of the tax has been passed to consumers. The idea of who ultimately pays the tax is referred to as tax incidence. Tax incidence refers to the burden of a tax, or those who are the ultimate payers of the tax. Let’s consider the case of the incidence of a flat rate tax for simplicity (the analysis would be exactly the same in the case of an ad valorem tax). Figure 3.16(a) shows a supply curve shift from S1 to S2 due to the imposition of a tax. The demand curve remains constant at D since demand is not affected by the tax. The initial equilibrium is at point a, so the price paid by consumers is P1 and quantity purchased is Q1. After the tax is imposed, the equilibrium moves to point b, given by the intersection of the demand curve with the new supply curve, S2, so that the price paid by consumers increases to P2, and the quantity purchased falls to Q2. Remember that the vertical difference between the two supply curves (P2 − P3) represents the amount of tax per unit of output. This means that whereas producers receive from consumers price P2 per unit, they must also pay the government the amount of P2 − P3 per unit (or the tax per unit). Therefore the final price received by the producer after payment of the tax is P3. (b) Ad valorem tax. S2 P S2 tax per S 1 unit tax S1 tax 0 Figure 3.15 Supply curve shifts due to indirect taxes. 86 Part 2: Microeconomics Q 0 Q HL HL What can we now say about the incidence of the tax? The full amount of the tax is given in the figure by (P2 − P3) × Q2, or the amount of tax per unit multiplied by the number of units sold; this is the entire shaded area, and is equal to the government’s tax revenue. The incidence of the tax is partly on consumers and partly on producers: Tax burden of consumers = (P2 − P1) × Q2 Tax burden of producers = (P1 − P3) × Q2 Tax revenue for the government = (P2 − P3) × Q2 (a) Incidence of flat rate tax. S2 P P2 tax per unit b consumers P1 P3 S1 a producers Q2 Q1 Q (b) Incidence of flat rate subsidy. P P3 P1 S1 producers consumers subsidy per unit c S2 P2 d Subsidy share of consumers = (P1 − P2) × Q2 Subsidy share of producers = (P3 − P1) × Q2 Q1 Q2 Note that the imposition of an indirect tax or a subsidy has the effect of changing the allocation of resources. In Figure 3.16(a), the indirect tax results in an underallocation of resources to the production of the good, since the final equilibrium point, b, gives rise to a lower level of output: Q2 < Q1. By contrast, the imposition of a subsidy results in an overallocation of resources to the production of the good, since in the final equilibrium, d, quantity is greater: Q2 > Q1. Elasticity of demand and supply and the incidence of indirect taxes D 0 A flat rate subsidy is one that involves a fixed payment per unit of output, and results therefore in a downward, parallel shift of the supply curve, from S1 to S2 as shown in Figure 3.16(b). The vertical difference between the two supply curves represents the amount of subsidy per unit of output. The initial equilibrium is at point c, determining price P1 and quantity Q1; following the granting of the subsidy, the final equilibrium occurs at point d, with lower price P2 and larger quantity Q2. In the final equilibrium, consumers pay price P2, but producers receive price P3. The difference between the two, P3 − P2, represents the amount of the subsidy per unit. The full amount of the subsidy is therefore given by (P3 − P2) × Q2. The subsidy is shared between consumers and producers: Total cost of subsidy to government = (P3 − P2) × Q2 D 0 government to firms, in order to study the incidence of subsidies, or how the payment by the government is shared between consumers and firms. Q Figure 3.16 Incidence of flat rate tax and subsidy, shared between consumers and producers. The incidence of subsidies A subsidy is a payment made by the government to producers or consumers and has the opposite effect of a tax. Possible objectives of subsidies may be to change the distribution of output or income (in favour of producers or consumers; see Chapter 11); or to correct positive externalities (see Chapter 6); or to increase exports (see Chapter 12). For now, we will confine ourselves to subsidies involving payments from the We have seen that the burden (or incidence) of indirect taxes is shared between consumers and firms. The distribution of the burden, however (i.e. who has a larger burden and who has a smaller burden), depends on the price elasticities of demand and supply for the good or service that is being taxed. As we will see, these elasticities determine: · the relative tax burdens of consumers and producers · the size of the government’s tax revenues. The case of demand elasticities Figure 3.17 (page 88), showing the burden of a flat rate tax being shared between consumers and producers, is similar to Figure 3.16(a), only in Figure 3.17(a) demand is elastic, whereas in panel (b) it is inelastic. Chapter 3: Elasticities 87 HL HL of the tax, and tax revenues for the government are substantial. (a) Elastic demand. P S2 tax per unit P2 P1 P3 The case of supply elasticities Figure 3.18 is also similar to Figure 3.16(a), only now panel (a) shows elastic supply and panel (b) inelastic supply. S1 consumers producers D 0 Q2 Q1 Q (b) Inelastic demand. P S2 tax per unit S1 P2 consumers P1 producers P3 0 D Q2 Q1 Q Figure 3.17 The incidence of an indirect tax with elastic and inelastic demand. Once again, the full amount of tax is given by (P2 − P3) × Q2, or the amount of tax per unit multiplied by the number of units sold; this is the entire shaded area, and is equal to the government’s tax revenue. The incidence of the tax is partly on consumers and partly on producers: Tax burden of consumers = (P2 − P1) × Q2 Tax burden of producers = (P1 − P3) × Q2 Tax revenue for the government = (P2 − P3) × Q2 When supply is elastic, most of the tax burden falls on consumers, whereas with inelastic supply, most of the tax burden falls on producers. Further, tax revenue for the government is larger the more inelastic the supply. For example, the supply of oil is inelastic in the short run, but becomes more and more elastic over longer periods of time (the long run). Therefore taxes on oil have a larger incidence on producers than consumers in the short run, and tax revenues are larger in the short run. As time goes by, since supply becomes more elastic in the long run, the incidence of the tax begins to shift more towards the consumer and tax revenues begin to fall. P P2 P1 P3 88 Part 2: Microeconomics S2 S1 producers Q2 D Q Q1 (b) Inelastic supply. S2 S1 tax per unit P2 P1 consumers producers P3 0 This is why we generally see excise taxes being imposed on goods whose demand is inelastic, such as cigarettes and petrol; consumers pay the larger part tax per unit consumers 0 P In the case of elastic demand, shown in panel (a), most of the tax burden falls on producers, while with inelastic demand, shown in panel (b), most of the burden falls on consumers. Moreover, tax revenue for the government is greater in the case of inelastic demand, because as price rises due to the tax, quantity demanded falls proportionately less, and so tax revenue is high. (a) Elastic supply. Q2 Q1 D Q Figure 3.18 The incidence of an indirect tax with elastic and inelastic supply. HL HL In general, tax revenues for the government will be greater the more inelastic the demand and the more inelastic the supply. Further, the tax burden will fall proportionately more on the group whose activities are less responsive to price changes: on consumers whose purchases are not very responsive to price increases (inelastic demand), and on producers whose sales are not very responsive to price increases (inelastic supply). The low responsiveness (low price elasticities) means that as price increases due to the imposition of the tax, consumers or producers do not change their buying and selling activities substantially, and so as a result must bear a relatively larger portion of the tax burden. HL Test your understanding 3.13 1 Indirect taxes are usually paid to the government by firms. Yet firms do not bear the full burden (incidence) of such taxes. Why? 2 (a) Define flat rate and ad valorem taxes; (b) provide examples of each; and (c) show how the supply curve shifts when each of these is imposed on a product. 3 What determines whether the incidence of an indirect tax or the incidence of a subsidy falls mainly on consumers or mainly on producers? 4 Using appropriate diagrams, show how the incidence of an ad valorem tax will be shared between consumers and producers in the case of (a) elastic demand; and (b) inelastic demand. What conclusions can you draw about relative tax burdens and price elasticities of demand? 5 Using appropriate diagrams, show how the incidence of an ad valorem tax will be shared between consumers and producers in the case of (a) elastic supply; and (b) inelastic supply. What conclusions can you draw about relative tax burdens and price elasticities of supply? Questions for review 3.1 [15 marks] (a) Define the concept of elasticity. (b) Define the four elasticity concepts you have studied. (c) Show the formula you would use to calculate each of these elasticities. (d) Which elasticities involve movements along the demand or supply curves, and which involve shifts of the curve(s)? 3.2 [15 marks] Explain the factors that determine the value of each of the four elasticities. 3.3 [10 marks] It is commonly believed that a producer of a good will increase total revenue by increasing the price of the good produced. Do you agree? Explain, using a diagram in your answer. 3.4 [10 marks] Use demand and supply analysis and a diagram, and the fact that the demand for agricultural products tends to be price inelastic, to show how a good crop can impact on farmers’ revenues. 3.5 [15 marks] The price of meat increases by 10%, the quantity demanded of meat falls by 12% and the demand for fish increases by 9%. (a) What is the price elasticity of demand for meat? (b) What is the cross-elasticity of demand between meat and fish? (c) What can you conclude about the demand for meat (is it price elastic or inelastic)? (d) What can you conclude about the relationship between meat and fish? (e) Using appropriate diagrams, illustrate the impact of the increase in the price of meat on the quantity of meat demanded and the demand for fish. 3.6 [10 marks] The price of pizzas falls by 15%, the quantity demanded of pizzas increases by 17% and the demand for colas increases by 20%. (a) What is the price elasticity of demand for pizzas? (b) What is the cross-elasticity of demand for pizzas and colas? (c) What can you conclude about the demand for pizzas? (d) What can you conclude about the relationship between pizzas and colas? Chapter 3: Elasticities 89 Questions for 3.7 3.8 review [15 marks] Your annual income increased from $16,000 to $20,000 (a 25% increase). Your spending on purchases of bread fell by 5%, while your spending on purchases of food in general and eating out in restaurants increased by 15% and 30% respectively. (a) Which elasticity of demand concept is relevant for analysing the changes in your consumption patterns? (b) Calculate this demand elasticity for each of these items. (c) What can you conclude about the changes in your demand for these three items? (d) Show diagrammatically the impact on your demand for these three items that resulted from your increase in income. [10 marks] You are conducting an international comparative study on income elasticities and find that the income elasticities of demand for many products are higher in more developed countries than the corresponding figures in less developed countries. How can you explain these differences? 3.9 [20 marks] (a) Explain which elasticity concepts may be important to firms and why. (b) Explain which elasticity concepts may be important to governments and why. 3.10 [10 marks] Which elasticity of demand concept is useful in explaining the fall in agriculture’s share in GDP and the increase in the shares of manufactured products and services as a country grows and develops? Explain. 3.11 [10 marks] (a) What is the main determinant of the price elasticity of supply? (b) How does this help explain the different price elasticities of supply we generally find between agricultural and manufactured products? 3.12 [5 marks] What do you think is the price elasticity of supply of Picasso’s paintings? Explain. 3.13 [20 marks] Prices of agricultural products (as well as other primary products) tend to be volatile (to fluctuate) over the short term and tend to decline over the long term. Use the concepts of price elasticity of demand, price elasticity of supply and income elasticity of demand to explain short-term volatility and long-term price declines. 90 Part 2: Microeconomics Higher level 3.14 [10 marks] (a) How is the incidence (burden) of indirect taxes affected by the price elasticity of demand and the price elasticity of supply of the particular goods being taxed? (b) Under what conditions does the greater part of tax incidence fall on producers and under what conditions on consumers? Use diagrams to illustrate your answers. 3.15 [10 marks] How are government tax revenues from indirect taxes affected by the price elasticity of demand and the price elasticity of supply of the particular goods being taxed? 3.16 [15 marks] The government is considering imposing an indirect tax on cigarettes or on yachts. (a) Which of the two goods should it tax if it is interested in increasing its tax revenues? (b) Using diagrams, explain how the incidence (burden) on consumers and producers of a flat rate tax on cigarettes and on yachts is likely to be different. HL Chapter 4 Microeconomics The theory of the firm I Costs, revenues and profit (higher level topic) This chapter and the next are concerned with the behaviour of firms. Much of firm behaviour depends on the type of market structure within which the firm operates. Market structures were introduced in Chapter 2, page 28, and will be studied in greater detail in Chapter 5. The present chapter introduces the student to the fundamental concepts that are necessary to analysing firm behaviour: costs, revenues and profit. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · · · · HL · · · · · · · distinguish between accounting and implicit costs distinguish between the short run and the long run identify a variety of cost concepts and cost curves understand the short-run technical relationship between inputs and output illustrated by the law of diminishing marginal returns explain how the law of diminishing marginal returns is related to costs of production in the short run explain how short-run costs are related to long-run costs explain the factors that account for the shape of the long-run average total cost curve understand revenue concepts distinguish between accounting, economic and normal profit evaluate the profit maximization goal of firms assumed by standard economic theory identify and explain alternative theories of firm behaviour. HL 4.1 Costs Introduction to costs of production Firms use resources, or factors of production, or inputs (these terms are used interchangeably) to produce goods and services. When firms use resources to produce, they incur costs of production, which include money payments plus anything else given up by a firm for the use of resources. Let’s examine costs of production more closely. Accounting, implicit and economic costs In Chapter 1, page 4, the concept of opportunity cost was introduced and defined as the value of the best alternative that must be sacrificed in order to obtain something. Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 91 HL In economics, because of the condition of scarcity, all costs are opportunity costs. Therefore the costs of all resources used by a firm to produce goods and services can be considered as opportunity costs. What this means in effect is that all the resources used by the firm have alternative uses that must be sacrificed in order that they can be used by the firm. This sacrifice is the opportunity cost. From the point of view of the firm, we can distinguish between two kinds of opportunity costs, depending on who owns the resources the firm uses. Resources are either owned by the firm itself, or are owned by outsiders to the firm from whom the firm acquires them. This very obvious distinction has important implications for understanding costs from an economist’s perspective. Accounting costs When the firm needs resources that it does not own, it must purchase them from outsiders and make a monetary payment (a payment of money) to the resource suppliers in exchange for acquiring the resources. For example, a firm hires labour and pays a wage; it purchases materials and pays the price to the seller; it uses electricity and pays the electricity supplier, and so on. The payments made by a firm to outsiders in order to acquire resources for use in production are called accounting costs (also sometimes known as ‘explicit costs’). Accounting costs are so termed because they include the costs usually recorded by accountants in the firm’s books. The opportunity cost of using resources that are not owned by the firm is equal to the amount paid to acquire them; the monetary payments could have been made to buy something else instead, which is now being sacrificed. Implicit costs The firm may own some of the resources that it uses for its production, such as, for example, an office building that is owned and used by the same business. In this case, the firm does not make a monetary 92 Part 2: Microeconomics payment to acquire the resource. There is nonetheless a cost involved in the use of the self-owned resource, which is the sacrifice of income that would have been earned if the resource had been employed in its best alternative use. The sacrificed income that arises from the use of selfowned resources by a firm is an opportunity cost that is called an implicit cost. For example, in the case of the office building owned and used by the firm, the opportunity cost is the rental income that could have been earned had the building been rented out. The hours of work that a firm owner puts into his or her own business have an opportunity cost equal to what the firm owner could have earned if he or she had worked elsewhere. The entrepreneurial abilities that the firm owner puts into the business (risk-taking, innovative capabilities, organizational and managerial abilities) entail a further opportunity cost equal to what these abilities could have earned elsewhere. Economic costs When we add a firm’s accounting costs to its implicit costs, we obtain the firm’s ‘economic costs’. Economic costs are the sum of accounting and implicit costs, or the total opportunity costs incurred by a firm for its use of resources, whether purchased or self-owned. When economists refer to ‘costs’ they are actually referring to ‘economic costs’. Economic costs are larger than accounting costs by the amount of the implicit costs. Consider the following example. Let’s say you were holding a job paying you a salary of £60,000 a year, which you decided to quit because you wanted to open your own business. You estimate that your entrepreneurial talent that you are putting into your business is worth £45,000 a year. You set up your office in a spare room of your house that you used to rent out for £4000 a year. Further, you borrowed £30,000, for which you are paying interest of £2000 a year. You then used the borrowed sum of £30,000 to purchase supplies and materials. You have also hired an assistant whom you pay £18,000 a year. Your implicit, accounting and economic costs are as follows: HL HL Implicit costs £ 60,000 (your foregone salary) + £ 45,000 (your foregone income from your entrepreneurial talent) + £ 4,000 (your foregone rental income from your spare room) £109,000 Accounting costs £ 2,000 (interest on your loan) + £ 30,000 (purchase of supplies and materials) + £ 18,000 (assistant’s salary) £ 50,000 Economic costs ( = total opportunity costs) £ 109,000 (implicit costs) + £ 50,000 (accounting costs) £ 159,000 An accountant would only add up the accounting costs of £50,000, and would ignore the implicit costs of £109,000. Fixed, variable and total costs The distinction between fixed and variable inputs discussed above in connection with the short and long run leads us to a distinction between fixed and variable costs: · Fixed costs arise from the use of fixed inputs Fixed costs are defined to be costs that do not change as output changes. Examples of fixed costs include rental payments, property taxes, insurance premiums and interest on loans. These are payments that do not increase if the firm produces more output, and do not decrease if it produces less. Even if a firm ceases to produce (i.e. there is zero output), these payments will still have to be made in the short run. · Variable costs arise from the use of variable inputs These are costs that vary (or change) as output increases or decreases, therefore they are ‘variable’. An example of a variable input is labour. To produce more output, the firm hires more labour, and therefore has increased wage costs. In general, the more variable inputs a firm uses, the greater will be the variable costs of production. · Total costs are the sum of fixed and variable costs The short run and the long run In Chapter 3, page 83, we distinguished between the short run and the long run as two different time periods during which firms adjust their inputs to change the amount of output produced. We now return to the difference between the short and long run once again because it is very closely related to a key distinction relating to costs of production. · The short run is a time period during which at least one input is fixed and cannot be changed by the firm. For example, if a firm wants to increase output, it can initially hire more labour and increase materials, tools and equipment, but it cannot quickly change the size of its buildings, factories and heavy machinery. As long as these latter inputs are fixed, the firm is operating in the short run. · The long run is a time period long enough so that all inputs can be changed. Using the example above, in this time period the firm can build new buildings and factories and buy more heavy machinery; in other words it can change all of its inputs. In the long run the firm has no fixed inputs; all inputs are variable. Note that the long run and the short run do not correspond to any particular length of time. Some industries may require months to change their fixed inputs while other may require years. Note that fixed costs arise only in the short run when the firm has fixed inputs. In the long run all inputs are variable and so all costs are variable. Therefore in the long run, with fixed costs equal to zero, a firm’s total costs are equal to its variable costs. Average costs Average costs are costs per unit of output. They tell us how much each unit of output produced by the firm costs on average. Average cost is simply total cost divided by the number of units of output. From our discussion above, we have three total costs, each of which corresponds to an average cost: total costs average total fixed costsaverage (TFC) (AFC) total variable costsaverage (TVC) (AVC) total costsaverage (TC) (ATC) costs fixed costs variable costs total costs To calculate average costs, we simply divide each of the totals by the units of output (Q) that the firm produces: AFC = TFC Q AVC = TVC Q ATC = TC Q Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 93 HL HL It was noted above that total cost is the sum of fixed costs plus variable costs: TC = TFC + TVC Similarly, average total costs are the sum of average fixed costs plus average variable costs: ATC = AFC + AVC Test your understanding 4.1 (...continued) 6 (a) Define the three kinds of average costs, and explain how they are derived from the three kinds of total cost. (b) How are the three kinds of average costs related to each other? 7 Define marginal cost; how is it related to total cost and total variable cost? Marginal cost Marginal cost (MC) is the extra or additional cost of producing one more unit of output. It tells us by how much total costs increase if there is an increase in output by one unit. It is calculated by considering the change in total cost (TC) resulting from a change in output. In addition, it can be calculated by considering the change in total variable cost (TVC) that results from a change in output. The reason why the two are equivalent is that fixed costs are constant (do not change) as output increases or decreases. Marginal cost is given by MC = Δ FC ΔQ = Δ TVC ΔQ where the Greek letter Δ stands for ‘change in’. As we will see later in this chapter, the concept of marginal cost plays a very important role in a firm’s decision on what quantity of output to produce. Test your understanding 4.1 1 Provide some examples of (a) accounting costs; and (b) implicit costs. 2 Why do both implicit costs and accounting costs Costs of production in the short run We are now in a position to examine costs of production more closely. We will begin with a discussion of costs in the short run; we are therefore dealing with both fixed and variable inputs, and therefore with both fixed and variable costs. A firm’s costs of production depend on the level of output it produces, but for any particular level of output, costs depend on · input prices, which are determined in product markets through supply and demand · the quantities of inputs required for production, which in turn depend on a technical relationship between the inputs and the output that these produce. The technical relationship between inputs and output is of crucial importance in understanding short-run costs. This is because it provides us with information on the quantities of inputs required to produce a particular level of output. represent opportunity costs to the firm? 3 Why are economic costs greater than accounting costs? 4 Define (a) fixed costs, (b) variable costs, and (c) total costs, and explain how they are related to the distinction between the short run and the long run. 5 Which of the following are fixed and which are variable costs: (a) insurance premiums on the value of the property owned by a business (b) interest payments on a loan taken out by a business (c) wage payments to the workers that are hired by a business (d) payments for the purchase of seeds and fertilizer by a farmer. (...continued) 94 Part 2: Microeconomics Total product, marginal product and average product To study the relationship between inputs and output, we need to develop three more concepts. Since we are studying the short run, we know that the firm has both fixed and variable inputs. For simplicity, let’s consider a hypothetical firm that uses only two inputs, land and labour, where land is the fixed input and labour is the variable input; we can think of this firm as a very simple farm. The only way that the farm can increase the quantity of its output in the short run is by increasing the quantity of the labour it hires. The three new concepts are the following: · Total product (TP) is the total quantity of output produced by a firm. · Marginal product (MP) is the extra or additional output that results from one additional unit of the variable input, labour; it tells us by how much output increases as labour increases by one unit. HL HL Table 4.1 Total, marginal and average products. (1) Units of variable input (labour) HL (2) Total product (units of output) = TP (4) Average product (units of output) = AP (3) Marginal product (units of output) = MP Δ TP MP = Δ units of labour 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 0 2 5 9 14 18 21 23 24 24 23 21 Marginal product is given by MP = Δ TP Δ units of labour · Average product (AP) is the total quantity of output per unit of variable input, or labour; this tells us how much output each unit of labour (i.e. each worker) produces on average. Average product is given by AP = Δ TP units of labour Table 4.1 shows a hypothetical example of the total product that results as the number of units of labour working on the fixed piece of land (the farm) increase. Once we are given the information in columns (1) and (2), it is a simple matter to calculate marginal and average products. Marginal product is calculated by taking the change in TP (due to the increase in labour) and dividing it by the change in the units of labour. For example, the marginal product of the third unit of labour is (9 – 5) (3 – 2) = 4 1 =4 the marginal product of the sixth unit of labour is (21 – 18) (6 – 5) = 3 1 =3 − 2 3 4 5 4 3 2 1 0 −1 −2 TP AP = units of labour − 2 2.5 3 3.5 3.6 3.5 3.3 3 2.7 2.3 1.9 The total, marginal and average products appearing in Table 4.1 are shown graphically in Figure 4.1(a) and (b) (page 96). Panel (a) plots the total product data of column (2) of the table, while panel (b) plots the marginal and average product data of columns (3) and (4). The vertical axis in both figures measures units of output, and the horizontal axis measures units of the variable input (labour). Note that the scale of variable input units on the horizontal axis is identical in both panels, so that the MP and AP curves in panel (b) correspond to the TP curve in panel (a). Both panels (a) and (b) are divided into three parts: · Increasing marginal product When labour units are between 0 and 4, the marginal product of labour is increasing, as we see in panel (b). This means that the addition to total product made by each successive unit of labour gets bigger and bigger as shown in panel (a) (we can say that total product increases at an increasing rate). When 4 units of labour are employed, marginal product (equal to five units of output) is maximum. · Decreasing marginal product When labour units are between 4 and 9, the marginal product of labour is decreasing, as we can see in panel (b). Here, the addition to total product made by successive units of labour becomes smaller and smaller, shown in panel (a) (it increases at a decreasing rate). Average product is calculated by taking the total product and dividing it by the units of labour that gave rise to this amount of product. For example, the average product of the third unit of labour is 9 3 = 3; of the sixth unit of labour it is 21 6 = 3.5 Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 95 HL (c) Total product curve. 25 20 units of output (a) Total product curve based on data of Table 4.1. units of output HL TP 15 10 TP 5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 units of variable input (labour) increasing decreasing negative marginal marginal 6 marginal product product 5 product 4 3 2 AP 1 0 -1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 -2 units of variable input MP -3 (labour) (d) Marginal and average product curves. units of variable input (labour) units of output (b) Marginal and average product curves based on data of Table 4.1. units of output 0 AP 0 MP units of variable input (labour) Figure 4.1 Total, marginal and average products. Economics for the IB Diploma · Negative marginal product At 8 Figure and4.1 9 unitsColof Mac/eps/Illustrator s/s labour, Text: Agenda a maximum, as we can see in emcdesign Studio: Peters & Zabransky ninth unit of labour adds zero total product is at panel (a), and the units of output, i.e. the marginal product of the ninth unit of labour is zero, shown in panel (b). Beyond 9 units of labour, total product begins to fall; this corresponds to the negative marginal product of the tenth and eleventh units of labour that can be seen in panel (b).1 The relationship between the marginal and average product curves example involving test scores. Assume that you have an average of 80 in your tests so far in a particular subject, and you would like to increase your average. If your next text score (the ‘marginal’ score) is greater than your average of 80, your average will increase. If, on the other hand, your next test score is lower than your average of 80, then your average will fall. This relationship between your average and marginal test scores is exactly the same as the relationship between average and marginal products. Generalized product curves Average product also rises initially and then declines (panel (b) of Figure 4.1). Note the relationship between the average and marginal product curves: when the marginal product curve lies above the average product curve (MP > AP), average product is increasing; and when the marginal product curve lies below the average product curve (MP < AP), average product is decreasing. This means that the marginal product curve must always intersect the average product curve when this is at its maximum. The reason for this lies in the mathematical relationship between the average and marginal values of any variable. To understand this relationship, we can consider a simple Panels (c) and (d) of Figure 4.1 show the total, marginal and average product curves that result in the general case when a variable input is added to a fixed input. These curves illustrate the technical relationship between inputs and output that we need to understand in order to study cost of production in the short run. We turn to this relationship next. The mathematically inclined student will note that the marginal product, measuring the change in total product that arises from an additional unit of labour, is the slope of the total product curve. Therefore with increasing marginal product, MP increases (panel (b)) because the slope of the TP curve is increasing (panel (a)). With decreasing marginal product, MP falls because the slope of the TP curve decreases. When 9 units of labour are employed, the slope of the TP curve is 0 (i.e. the marginal product of the ninth worker is zero) and beyond that the MP, or the slope of the TP curve, becomes negative. 1 96 Part 2: Microeconomics Law of diminishing marginal returns In the short run, the technical relationship between inputs and output is provided by the law of diminishing marginal returns: HL According to the law of diminishing marginal returns (also known as the law of diminishing marginal product), as more and more units of a variable input (such as labour) are added to one or more fixed inputs (such as land), the marginal product of the variable input at first increases, but there comes a point when the marginal product of the variable input begins to decrease. This relationship presupposes that that the fixed input(s) remain fixed, and that the technology of production is also fixed. The law of diminishing marginal returns is reflected in the data of Table 4.1 and the curves of Figure 4.1. Let’s examine it more carefully. When there are zero workers on the land, there is no farm output at all; it is equal to zero. When one worker is hired, there will be some output, and so total product is equal to two units. Marginal product, given by the change in total product that arises when one unit of labour is added, is also equal to two units. But one worker alone on the farm must do all the ploughing, planting, harvesting, etc., with the result that output is quite low. Say now that a second worker is hired. The two workers share the work, and total product increases to five units, indicating that the output that the two together produce is more than double the output of the first working alone. The additional (or marginal) product due to the second worker (three units) is greater than that of the first (two units). This process is repeated with the addition of the third and fourth workers, and marginal product increases with the addition of each one. With four workers, marginal product is the greatest it can be; when the fifth worker is added, marginal product begins to fall, and falls continuously thereafter. This is the point at which diminishing returns set in. Why does this happen? On the farm, it happens because of overcrowding: each additional worker has less and less land to work with, and so produces less and less output. Eventually, the conditions on the farm become so crowded that the ninth worker adds zero extra output; with the addition of the tenth worker the marginal or extra product is negative and total product begins to decrease. More generally, marginal product will begin to fall at some point not just on a farm with a fixed piece of land, but whenever more and more units of a variable input are added to a fixed input (provided the technology of production is unchanging). For example, in the case of a factory where more and more workers are hired, each worker will have fewer and fewer machines and equipment to work with, and so will add less and less output. (Imagine what would happen if diminishing returns did not exist. Using our farm example, it would be possible for food production to increase indefinitely just by continuously adding variable inputs to a fixed piece of land – a clear impossibility!) Test your understanding 4.2 1 Define (a) total product, (b) marginal product, and (c) average product and show how they are related to each other. 2 Copy the following table, filling in the missing figures on your copy: Units of variable input (labour) Total product 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 10 22 35 46 54 59 61 60 Marginal product Average product 3 Using the information in question 2, (a) Plot the total product, marginal product and average product curves. (b) Define the law demonstrated by the pattern shown by the marginal product and average product figures and curves. (c) Why does this law only hold in the short run? (d) With how many units of the variable input do we see the beginning of diminishing marginal returns (diminishing marginal product)? (e) With how many units of the variable input do we see the beginning of negative marginal returns? (f) Explain the relationship between the average product and marginal product curves. Short-run costs of production: deriving the short-run cost curves The law of diminishing marginal returns is very important to understanding costs of production in the short run. We will now examine a typical firm’s total, average and marginal costs. Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 97 HL HL · column (9) shows marginal cost, obtained by Let’s continue with our example of the simple farm and the data in Table 4.1, and assume that the farm incurs fixed costs of €200 per week (for rent for the land), and that the cost of labour is €100 per worker (or per unit of labour) per week. We now have all the information we need to calculate the firm’s shortrun production costs, and to see how these change as output increases. All of the farm’s short-run costs appear in Table 4.2, where dividing the change in total cost (from column 5) by the change in the number of units of output (from column 1); for example, when total cost increases from €200 to €300, so that Δ TC = 100, TP increases from 0 to 2 units of output, so that ΔQ = 2. Dividing 100 by 2, we obtain MC = 50. Marginal cost can also be calculated as the change in total variable cost divided by the change in total product, because Δ TVC = Δ TC. (You can confirm this by comparing the figures in column 4 with those in column 5). · columns (1) and (2) contain the same data on total product and corresponding labour input that appear in Table 4.1 · column (3) shows the farm’s total fixed cost (TFC) All the cost information of Table 4.2 is shown graphically in Figure 4.2 (a) and (b). (Panels (c) and (d) show cost curves in the general case for a firm in the short run.) Both panels (a) and (b) measure costs on the vertical axis, and units of output on the horizontal axis. Panel (a) illustrates the three total cost curves (total fixed cost, total variable cost and total cost), and panel (b) the three average cost curves and the marginal cost curve. consisting of rental payments of €200 · column (4) shows the farm’s total variable cost, which is simply the number of workers (from column 2) times the cost of €100 per worker · column (5) calculates total cost, which is the sum of total fixed cost (column 3) plus total variable cost (column 4) · column (6) shows average fixed cost, obtained by dividing total fixed cost (column 3) by the number of units of output (column 1) In panel (a): · The TFC curve is parallel to the horizontal axis, as · column (7) calculates average variable cost, obtained it represents a fixed amount of costs that do not change as output changes. by dividing total variable cost (column 4) by the number of units of output (column 1) · The TVC curve shows that TVC increases as output · column (8) shows average total cost, obtained by increases; however, it does not increase at a constant rate; this is due to the law of diminishing marginal returns, which we will reconsider shortly. dividing total cost (column 5) by the number of units of output (column 1): alternatively, average total cost is the sum of AFC plus AVC · The TC curve is the vertical sum of TFC and TVC, and so the vertical difference between TC and TVC is equal to TFC. Table 4.2 Total, average and marginal costs. (1) Total product = TP or Q (units) 98 (2) Labour (units of labour) (3) Total fixed cost = TFC (¤) (4) Total variable cost = TVC (¤) (5) Total cost = TC TC = TFC + TVC (¤) (6) Average fixed cost = AFC TFC AFC = Q (¤) (7) Average variable cost = AVC TVC AVC = Q (¤) 0 0 200 0 200 - - 2 5 9 14 18 21 23 24 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 200 200 200 200 200 200 200 200 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000 100 40 22.2 14.3 11.1 9.5 8.7 8.3 50 40 33.3 28.6 27.8 28.6 30.4 33.3 Part 2: Microeconomics (8) Average total cost = ATC TC ATC = Q or ATC = AFC + AVC (¤) (9) Marginal cost = MC Δ TC MC = ΔQ MC = Δ TVC ΔQ (¤) - 150 80 55.5 42.9 38.9 38.1 39.1 41.6 50 33.3 25 20 25 33.3 50 00 HL HL HL TC 1000 TVC 800 600 TC TVC 400 200 TFC 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 output, Q 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 TFC MC output, Q (d) Average cost and marginal cost curves. MC ATC costs costs 0 (b) Average cost and marginal cost curves based on the data of Table 4.2. (c) Total cost, total variable cost, and total fixed cost curves. costs 1200 costs (a) Total cost, total variable cost, and total fixed cost curves based on the data of Table 4.2. AVC ATC AVC AFC AFC 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 output, Q 0 output, Q Figure 4.2 Total, average and marginal cost curves In panel (b): · The AFC curve indicates that AFC falls continuously as output increases, because it represents the amount of fixed costs (TFC) divided by an ever growing quantity of output. · The three remaining curves, AVC, ATC and MC, though they are different from each other, all follow the same general pattern: at first they fall, they reach a minimum, and then they begin to rise.2 · Note that the ATC curve is the vertical sum of AFC and AVC, and so the vertical difference between the ATC and the AVC curves at any level of output is equal to AFC. · The MC curve intersects both the AVC and ATC curves at their minimum points. The reason behind these relationships is the same as in the case of marginal and average products, discussed earlier (recall the example of test scores, which applies equally well here). When marginal cost is below average variable cost (MC < AVC), then average variable cost is falling; when marginal cost is greater than average variable cost (MC > AVC), then average variable cost is rising. The same applies to the relationship between marginal cost and average total cost: when MC < ATC, then ATC is falling, and when MC > ATC, then ATC is rising. The law of diminishing marginal returns and the shape of the cost curves The law of diminishing marginal returns is very important in determining the shape of the cost curves. The reason for the U-shape of the AVC curve (as well as the ATC curve) can be found in the law of diminishing marginal returns. Remember that the marginal product of labour at first increases. This means that each additional unit of output can be produced with fewer and fewer units of labour; therefore the labour cost of each unit of output (or what is average variable cost) falls initially. But when additional units of labour eventually run into diminishing returns, the marginal product of labour begins to fall. Each additional unit The mathematically more advanced student may note that marginal cost (MC) represents the slope of the total cost (TC) curve. 2 Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 99 Note from Table 4.1 that when five units of labour are hired, average product is at its maximum; this is exactly the point of production at which average variable cost is at its minimum (as shown in Table 4.2). This happens because when workers on average produce the most they can produce, the labour cost of producing each unit of output is the lowest it can be. The explanation for the shape of the marginal cost curve can also be found in the law of diminishing marginal returns. When marginal product is increasing, the extra output produced by each additional unit of labour rises. When this happens, the additional cost of one more unit of output, or marginal cost, falls. Decreasing marginal product, on the other hand, means that the additional output of each unit of labour is falling, and so the additional cost of each extra unit of output (marginal cost) must be increasing. Note that maximum marginal product (shown in Table 4.1) occurs when four units of labour are hired; this is also when marginal cost is at its minimum (see Table 4.2). In other words, when the additional output produced by an extra worker is the most it can be, then the extra labour cost of producing an additional unit of output is the least it can be. These relationships are illustrated in Figure 4.3, indicating that the product curves are mirror images of the cost curves. The MC curve mirrors the MP curve, and the AVC curve mirrors the AP curve. (You must note the labelling of the axes of the product and cost curves, which are different from each other.) The U-shape of the AVC and ATC, as well as the MC curves is due to the law of diminishing marginal returns. Shifts in the cost curves The cost curves shown above will shift in response to two factors: changes in resource prices, or changes in Another way to see this numerically, is to consider the average product figures in Table 4.1. We know that each unit of labour costs €100, i.e. €100 = cost per unit of labour. If we divide 100 by average product, cost per unit of labour = variable cost per unit of output, we have output per unit of labour 3 100 Part 2: Microeconomics HL units of output (AP, MP) of output now requires more and more units of labour, and so the labour cost of each unit of output, or average variable cost, begins to increase.3 AP 0 MP units of variable input (labour) MC costs (AVC, MC) HL AVC 0 output, Q Figure 4.3 Product curves and cost curves. technology. If resource prices increase, there will result an increase in costs of production. Which particular curves will be affected will depend on whether the price increases involve fixed or variable costs. If there is an increase in a fixed cost of production, this will affect total fixed cost and total cost, as well as average fixed cost and average total cost, all of which will shift upward. Variable costs and marginal cost will remain unaffected. This is shown in Figure 4.4(a), where we see AFC and ATC shifting upward to the dotted lines, while AVC and MC remain unchanged. If, on the other hand, there is an increase in variable costs (say, because of an increase in wages), total variable cost and total cost, as well as average variable cost, average total cost and marginal cost, will all increase. This can be seen in Figure 4.4(b), where AVC, ATC and MC have shifted upward to the dotted lines. In the event that resource prices fall, giving rise to decreases in costs of production, the corresponding curves will shift downward. which is average variable cost. When the units of labour are few, AVC is high; as the labour units increase AVC falls, and after reaching a minimum, AVC begins to rise, thus resulting in the U-shaped curve. HL (a) Increase in FC. HL (b) Increase in VC. ATC1 ATC AVC MC1 ATC1 MC ATC cost cost MC AVC1 AVC AFC1 AFC 0 output AFC 0 output Figure 4.4 Shifts in the cost curves. Changes in technology also impact upon costs of production because they increase the amount of output that can be produced by a given level of inputs. An improved technology would therefore shift the product curves of Figure 4.1 (total product, average product and marginal product) upwards, and this would correspond to a downward shift in the cost curves. Test your understanding 4.3 1 For question 2 of Test your understanding 4.2, suppose that the price of labour is $2000 a month and fixed costs are $1500 a month. Calculate TFC, TVC, TC, AFC, AVC, ATC and MC. 2 Why does the average fixed cost curve decline continuously throughout its range? 3 What accounts for the U-shape of (a) the average variable cost curve; (b) the average total cost curve? 4 Given a diagram such as Figure 4.2(a), explain what is represented by (a) the vertical distance between the TC and TFC curves; (b) the vertical distance between the TC and TVC curves. 5 In Figure 4.2(b), explain what is represented by (a) the vertical distance between ATC and AFC; (b) the vertical distance between ATC and AVC. 6 How does the law of diminishing marginal product affect the shape of the marginal cost curve? 7 Why does marginal cost intersect both average variable cost and average total cost at their minimum points? 8 Show diagrammatically how (a) a fall in insurance premiums, and (b) a fall in wage rates would impact upon the AFC, AVC, ATC and MC curves of a firm. Costs of production in the long run In the long run, there are no fixed inputs, and there are therefore no fixed costs. All the inputs can be changed, including those that require time, such as building new factories and buildings and acquiring more capital equipment and machines. In the long run all inputs are variable, and there are only variable costs. Total costs include only total variable costs, and average total costs are average variable costs. Average costs in the long run When a firm changes or varies its inputs that are fixed in the short run, in effect it changes its size or scale. We can consider the firm’s fixed inputs collectively as the firm’s plant (including land, buildings, factories and heavy machinery). If we think of the farm example we considered earlier, suppose the farmer changes the size of the land making up the farm (what used to be the fixed input); the result is to change plant size. Therefore, whereas in the short run the plant size is fixed, in the long run it is variable. Although the firm has the option of changing its plant size over the long run, at any given point in time it operates in the short run. This follows simply from the fact that the firm cannot be changing plant size all the time the way it can easily change variable inputs like labour. A firm can hire or fire workers on a daily basis if the need arises, but it cannot change the size of the land comprising a farm, or the size and number of buildings and factories, over short periods of time. Once the decision to change plant size materializes, and all the inputs have been changed accordingly, the Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 101 HL larger plant becomes fixed again, and the firm is once more in the short run. So what do we mean when we talk about the long run? It is convenient to think of the long run as the firm’s planning horizon. If a firm wants to expand its production, it must at some point think in terms of expanding the size or scale of its plant, in other words, to change and increase its fixed inputs. If it does not increase its fixed inputs, its production process will run into diminishing marginal returns of its variable inputs (diminishing marginal product). Therefore, to expand output it must increase its size or scale. To do this, it will consider what level of output it wants to produce, and will then choose the scale accordingly. Therefore, as the firm plans its future activities, in the long run, it can select any size or scale for its plant, depending on the quantity of output it is aiming for. The particular size it will choose will be the one that allows the firm to minimize costs for that particular level of output, i.e. to produce that level of output at the lowest possible cost. Let’s take a closer look at what this means. Long-run average total cost curve Let’s consider our farmer who produces with two inputs, land and labour. The farmer wants to expand production and considers the long-run options. To simplify our analysis, let’s assume that there are only four possible farm (or plant) sizes. Each farm size, with its own particular level of the fixed input of land, is represented by a different short-run average total cost curve (SRATC), shown in Figure 4.5(a). Let’s assume that the farmer is initially producing output Q1 on SRATC1, but would like to increase production. Which SRATC should the farmer select? The answer depends on how much output the farmer wants to produce, and which SRATC will minimize cost for that particular level of output. If the farmer wants to increase output to Q2, for example, this can be done without changing farm size, by remaining on SRATC1 in the short run. Yet a larger farm size, corresponding to SRATC2, can produce output Q2 at a lower average cost. As the farmer increases output Note that while a decision to produce a particular level of output in the long run involves selection of the firm scale that minimizes costs for that level of output, the firm will not necessarily be operating at the lowest possible cost on the SRATC curve of its choice. In Figure 4.5(b), say a firm wants to produce output Q1; it will then choose to be on SRATC1 at point a, which is the point where SRATC1 just touches the long-run curve, corresponding to output level Q1. But the point of minimum average cost on SRATC1 is point b, representing output Q2, not point a. Therefore minimum average cost in the short run is not necessarily the 4 102 Part 2: Microeconomics in the short run it will be possible to produce at the lowest possible cost on SRATC1 only up to point a, where the farmer should consider increasing farm size (going into the long run) and moving onto SRATC2. If the decision is made to increase the farm size and move onto SRATC2, output can continue to increase at the lowest possible cost until point b is reached, where the farmer once again should consider increasing farm size (going into the long run again) and switching to SRATC3. We can see then that points like a, b and c represent output levels at which the farmer should increase the farm size, so as to continue to minimize average costs as output increases. It follows then that the farmer’s planning horizon is made up of the boldface portions of the short-run average cost curves in Figure 4.5(a), which connect all possible points of intersection between successive SRATC curves. In practice, it is likely that there will not be only four possible firm sizes as in our example, but rather many more, as shown in Figure 4.5(b). In this case the long-run average total curve is the curve that just touches (i.e. is tangent to) each of the short-run cost curves. It represents the lowest possible average cost, or cost per unit of output, for every level of output, when all resources are variable. When the firm plans its activities over the long run, it can choose where on the long-run curve it wishes to be; it will then end up on the SRATC curve at the point where this just touches the long-run curve (i.e. the point of tangency between the two). The long-run average total cost curve is also called a firm’s planning curve, as well as an envelope curve (because it envelopes the short-run curves).4 The long-run average total cost curve is defined as a curve that shows the lowest possible average cost that can be attained by a firm for any level of output when all of the firm’s inputs are variable. It is also known as a planning curve, or envelope curve. This leads us to an important question to which we turn next: why does the long-run average total cost curve have downward-sloping and upward-sloping segments? same as minimum average cost in the long run. When the long-run curve is downward sloping, there will always be a larger firm size that can achieve lower average costs than the short-run minimum (i.e. SRATC2 achieves lower average costs than point b on SRATC1); and when the long-run curve is upward sloping, there will always be a smaller firm size that can achieve lower average costs than then short-run minimum. There is only one SRATC curve whose minimum coincides with the long-run minimum, and that is SRATCm, shown in boldface in Figure 4.5(b). HL (a) Short- and long-run average total cost curves. SRATC4 SRATC1 b SRATC2 SRATC3 c b LRATC SRATC1 SRATC2 SRATCm costs a HL (b) Long-run average total cost curve as an envelope curve. a costs HL LRATC 0 Q1 Q2 output, Q Q3 0 Q1 Q2 output, Q Figure 4.5 The long-run average total cost curve. Economies and diseconomies of scale The long-run average total cost curve (LRATC) has a U-shape (see Figure 4.5(b)). The reasons for the U-shape of the long-run average total cost (LRATC) curve have nothing whatever to do with diminishing marginal returns, which are a feature only of short-run production and short-run average costs, including costs associated with fixed inputs. Instead, the shape of the long-run average total cost curve can be found in economies and diseconomies of scale. Economies of scale Economies of scale are decreases in the average costs of production that occur as a firm increases its output by increasing its plant size, i.e. by increasing all its inputs. Economies of scale explain the downwardsloping portion of the long-run average total cost curve: as output increases, and a firm increases plant size by increasing all inputs, the average cost, or cost per unit of output, falls. There are several reasons why this can occur: · Specialization of labour As plant size increases, more workers must be employed, allowing for greater labour specialization. Increased labour specialization means that each worker specializes in performing tasks that make use of skills, interests and talents, thereby increasing efficiency and allowing output to be produced at a lower average cost. · Specialization of management Larger plant sizes allow for more managers to be employed, each of whom can be specialized in a particular area (such as production, sales, finance, etc.) again resulting in greater efficiency and lower average cost. · Efficiency of capital equipment Large machines are sometimes more efficient than smaller ones; for example, a large power generator is more efficient than a small one (it can produce more output per unit of inputs). However, a small firm with a small volume of output cannot make effective use of large machines, and so is forced to use the smaller, less efficient ones. · Indivisibilities of capital equipment Some machines are only available in large sizes that require large volumes of output in order to be used effectively. They cannot be divided up into smaller pieces of equipment. · Indivisibilities of efficient processes Some production processes, such as mass production assembly lines, require large volumes of output in order to be used efficiently. Even if all inputs are used in proportionately smaller quantities, it may not be possible to achieve the same degree of efficiency. · Spreading of certain costs over larger volumes of output Costs of certain activities such as design, research and development, and advertising result in lower average costs if they can be spread over large volumes of output. Diseconomies of scale Diseconomies of scale are increases in the average costs of production that occur as a firm increases its output by increasing its plant size, i.e. increasing all its inputs. Diseconomies of scale are responsible for the upward-sloping part of the long-run average total cost curve: as a firm increases plant size, costs per unit of output increase. Reasons for diseconomies of scale can include: · Management inefficiencies As a firm grows larger and larger, there may come a point where its management runs into difficulties of coordination, Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 103 organization, cooperation and monitoring. The result is that average costs begin to increase as the firm expands. · Poor worker motivation If workers begin to lose their motivation, to feel bored and to care little about their work, they become less efficient, with the result that costs per unit of output start to increase. Constant returns to scale Constant returns to scale may appear in some longrun average total cost curves as in Figure 4.6(a), where there is a horizontal segment of the curve between the downward-sloping and the upward-sloping portions. Constant returns to scale involve constant long-run average costs over a certain range of output. In this range, as output increases (with all inputs increasing), average costs do not change, i.e. the firm does not encounter economies or diseconomies of scale. average total cost (a) Varying firm sizes. 0 economies of scale diseconomies of scale constant returns to scale Qmes LRATC average total cost (b) Few large firms. 0 LRATC Q1 output, Q Qmes (c) Natural monopoly. 0 LRATC output, Q Qmes Figure 4.6 Minimum efficient scale and the structure of industry. 104 Part 2: Microeconomics Firms are generally eager to take advantage of economies of scale, and try to take care so as to avoid diseconomies of scale. Empirical studies agree that firms can achieve substantial economies of scale by increasing their size, but there is some debate over whether firms experience diseconomies. Some studies suggest that after exhausting economies of scale, many firms exhibit constant returns to scale, and do not run into diseconomies of scale even as size becomes very large. Minimum efficient scale and the structure of industries (supplementary material) There is a point on the long-run average total cost curve that represents the lowest level of output at which the lowest long-run total average costs are achieved, called the minimum efficient scale (MES). In Figure 4.6 this is represented by Qmes. The minimum efficient scale is the level of output at which economies of scale are exhausted; beyond that level of output average costs will either be constant or they will begin to increase. When there are constant returns to scale, the minimum efficient scale can be achieved by firms of varying sizes, producing any output ranging from Qmes to Q4 in Figure 4.6(a). The importance of the concept of minimum efficient scale lies in the information it can reveal about the structure of industries, such as whether it is likely that an industry will consist of many firms, some of which are smaller and some larger, as opposed to a small number of large firms, or at the extreme a single very large firm providing for the entire market. Each of these possibilities is illustrated in Figure 4.6. (Market structures were discussed in Section 2.1.) Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 output, Q average total cost HL The long-run average total cost curve in Figure 4.6(a) indicates that the firm reaches the minimum efficient scale at a low level of output, shown as Qmes, and then begins to experience constant returns to scale, that is, long-run average costs remain constant for an extended range of output. If this level of output, Qmes, is a small fraction of the total market, then there are likely to be many firms of varying sizes in the industry; examples include clothing and shoe manufacturing, other light manufacturing such as furniture and wood products, food processing, retailing and banking. These tend to be industries that fall under the market structure of monopolistic competition. Panel (b) shows the LRATC curve of a firm that experiences economies of scale over a very large range of output. It is only at the very large level of output of Qmes that the minimum efficient scale is achieved, HL HL at which point the firm runs into either diseconomies of scale or constant returns to scale (the dotted lines beginning at Qmes indicate that either of these two possibilities may arise). Qmes in this figure represents a large fraction of the total market. This means that there can only be a small number of large firms in this industry. If smaller firms tried to enter this industry, they would have difficulty competing with the larger firms because of their higher average costs. (Compare the average total costs of a firm producing output Q1 with the average costs of a firm producing at Qmes.) Examples of such industries include car and refrigerator manufacturers, heavy industries such as aluminum and steel, and pharmaceutical industries. These tend to be industries that fall under the market structure of oligopoly. In panel (c), the minimum efficient scale occurs at a level of output, Qmes, so large that if the firm expands to that point where it exhausts all economies of scale, it will be supplying the entire market. Such a firm is called a natural monopoly (studied in Chapter 5). (It may be noted that the U-shaped long-run average total cost curve does not cover firms under perfect competition. This is because firms under perfect competition do not experience economies and diseconomies of scale, as we will see in Chapter 5.) Test your understanding 4.4 1 (a) Define the long-run average total cost curve. (b) Why is the long-run average total cost curve also referred to as a ‘planning curve’? 2 Explain what factors can cause (a) economies of scale; (b) diseconomies of scale. 3 (a) What is the relationship between economies and diseconomies of scale and the shape of the LRATC? (b) What do constant returns to scale signify? 4 If, as many economists suggest, a firm is unlikely to run into diseconomies of scale after achieving all possible economies of scale, what would its long-run average total cost curve look like? 5 Explain (a) the concept of minimum efficient scale, and (b) its relationship to market structures. 4.2 Revenues and profits HL Revenues As we learned when examining the circular flow model in Chapter 1, page 6, revenues are the payments firms receive when they sell the goods and services they produce over a given time period. We will now make a distinction between three fundamental revenue concepts: total, marginal and average revenue. The firm’s total revenue (TR) is obtained by multiplying the price at which a good is sold (P) by the number of units of the good sold (Q): TR = P × Q The firm’s marginal revenue (MR) is the additional revenue arising from the sale of an additional unit of output, and is given by MR = Δ TR ΔQ The firm’s average revenue (AR) is revenue per unit of output sold: AR = TR Q The analysis of revenues is not the same for all firms, regardless of market structure, because it depends on whether or not the firm has any control over the price at which it sells its product. As you may remember from our discussion in Chapter 2, Section 2.1, page 29, firms under perfect competition have no control over price. By contrast, firms under the three other market structures do have varying degrees of control, which depend on their degree of market power. In analysing revenues, we must therefore make a distinction between situations where: · The firm has no control over price, and price is constant as output varies In this case, the price at which the good is sold does not change; no matter how much quantity the firm sells, the price is always the same; this occurs only under perfect competition, where the firm has no control over the price at which it sells its product. · The firm has at least some degree of control over price, and price varies with output In this case, as output changes, the price at which the good is sold also changes; this occurs under all market models other than perfect competition, where the firm has some degree of control over the price at which it sells its product. Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 105 HL We will examine revenues and the curves that correspond to each revenue concept in detail in Chapter 5 in the context of market structures. Profits Economic profit versus accounting profit In a general sense, profit equals total revenue minus total costs. The precise meaning of the term ‘profit’ in this expression depends on the meaning ascribed to ‘costs’. In Section 4.1, we made a distinction between accounting costs (the monetary payments made by a firm to acquire resources owned by others), implicit costs (the opportunity costs of using resources owned by the firm), and economic costs or total opportunity costs (the sum of accounting plus implicit costs). Based on these cost distinctions, we can make the following profit distinctions: accounting profit = total revenue minus accounting costs Figure 4.7(b) shows the case where the firm is making zero economic profit. It is assumed here that the firm’s total revenue is £159,000. But this is exactly equal to economic costs; therefore economic profit is zero. When economic profit is zero, accounting profit (£109,000) is equal to implicit costs. (a) Positive economic profit. economic profit (supernormal, abnormal profit) (£21,000) economic costs = opportunity costs The profit definition that is relevant for our purposes is economic profit, which is equal to total revenue minus economic costs. In Economics, when we use the term ‘profit’ on its own, we generally mean ‘economic profit’. In Figure 4.7 we can see the difference between economists’ and accountants’ perspectives. Each box represents a firm’s total revenue, which is split up between profits and costs. Let’s use our numerical example of costs presented in Section 4.1, in order to calculate economic and accounting profit. In Figure 4.7(a), let’s assume that the firm is making total revenue of £180,000. Implicit costs = £109,000, and accounting costs = £50,000, and when these are added up we obtain economic costs, which amount to £159,000. Economic profit is therefore £21,000 (= £180,000 − £159,000). Accounting profit, on the other hand, is £130,000 (= £180,000 − £50,000). Note that economic profit is smaller than accounting profit, since accounting profit ignores implicit costs. 106 Part 2: Microeconomics implicit costs (£109,000) total revenue (£180,000) accounting costs (£50,000) accounting profit (£130,000) accounting costs (£50,000) (b) Zero economic profit. Accountants' perspective Economists' perspective economic profit = total revenue minus economic costs = total revenue minus the sum of accounting costs plus implicit costs Accountants' perspective Economists' perspective economic costs = opportunity costs implicit costs (£109,000) accounting costs (£50,000) total revenue (£159,000) accounting profit (£109,000) accounting costs (£50,000) Figure 4.7 Economists’ and accountants’ perspectives on costs and profits. Normal profit We can now make one more distinction. When economic profit is equal to zero, and total revenue is equal to total economic costs, as in Figure 4.7(b), the firm is said to be making normal profit. Normal profit can be defined as the minimum amount of revenue that the firm must receive so that it will be induced to keep the business running (as opposed to shutting down). It can also be defined as that part of revenue that covers total economic costs (opportunity costs), which include all accounting plus implicit costs. HL HL These apparently different definitions are in fact consistent: the minimum amount of revenue the firm must receive to make it worthwhile to stay in business and keep all its resources employed in the firm is equal to the revenue that covers all the firm’s costs, implicit costs plus accounting costs. Normal profit is included among the economic costs of the firm, since it involves payments for the use of all resources, whether owned by outsiders (accounting costs) or self-owned resources (implicit costs). Note that any accounting profit in excess of normal profit is economic profit. For this reason, economic profit is also known as supernormal profit (because it involves profit that is over and above normal profit), or abnormal profit. Table 4.3 summarizes the cost, product, revenue and profit concepts we have studied. Table 4.3 Summary of cost, product, revenue and profit concepts. Cost concepts Definition Equation Accounting cost The monetary payment made by a firm to an outsider to acquire an input. Implicit cost The income sacrificed by a firm that uses a resource it owns. Economic cost The sum of accounting and implicit costs, also equal to the firm’s total opportunity costs. Total fixed cost (TFC) Costs that do not change as output changes; arise from the use of fixed inputs. Total variable cost (TVC) Costs that vary (change) as output changes; arise from the use of variable inputs. Total cost (TC) The sum of fixed and variable costs. TC = TFC + TVC Average fixed cost (AFC) Fixed cost per unit of output. AFC = Average variable cost (AVC) Variable cost per unit of output. AVC = Average total cost (ATC) Total cost per unit of output. Marginal cost (MC) The change in cost arising from one additional unit of output. ATC = AFC + AVC Δ TC Δ TVC MC = = ΔQ ΔQ Long-run average total cost (LRATC) curve A curve showing the lowest possible average cost that can be attained for any level of output when all of the firm’s inputs are variable. TFC Q TVC Q Product concepts Total product (TP or Q) The total amount of product (output) produced by a firm. Marginal product (MP) The additional product produced by one additional unit of variable input. MP = ΔTP Δ units of variable input Average product (AP) Product per unit of variable input. AP = TP Δ units of variable input Revenue concepts Total revenue The total earnings of a firm from the sale of its output. Marginal revenue The additional revenue of a firm arising from the sale of an additional unit of output. Average revenue Revenue per unit of output. MR = AR = Δ TR ΔQ TR Q Profit concepts Accounting profit Total revenue minus accounting (explicit) costs. Economic profit (= abnormal, supernormal, pure profit) Total revenue minus economic costs (or total opportunity costs, or the sum of accounting plus implicit costs). Normal profit The minimum amount of revenue required by a firm so that it will be induced to keep running, which is equal to that part of revenue that covers total opportunity costs (all explicit plus implicit costs). Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 107 HL HL Test your understanding 4.5 1 Define (a) total revenue, (b) marginal revenue, and (c) average revenue. 2 (a) Distinguish between economic profit and accounting profit. (b) Which of the two is larger and why? (c) Using the concept of opportunity cost, explain which of the two concepts is used by economists and why. 3 Define each of the following concepts and explain the relationship between them: normal profit, accounting profit and economic profit. 4.3 Goals of firms Profit maximization Standard economic theory of the firm assumes that firm behaviour is guided by the firm’s goal to maximize profit. Profit maximization involves determining the level of output that the firm should produce in order to make profit as large as possible. Yet firms do not always make a profit; in some cases their total revenue is not sufficient to cover all their costs, in which case they make a loss. If a firm is making a loss, it may eventually go out of business, but until it decides to shut down, it will be interested in producing the quantity of output that will make its loss as small as possible. Therefore the theory of the firm is also concerned with how much output a lossmaking firm should produce in order to minimize its loss. There are two approaches to analysing profit maximization (or loss minimization): one involves the use of the total revenue and cost concepts, and the other involves the use of marginal revenues and costs. Both these approaches yield identical results for the profit-maximizing (or loss-minimizing) level of output, though the second approach is more relevant to analysing market structures (as we will see in Chapter 5). Profit maximization based on the total revenue and cost approach This approach is based on the simple principle that profit = total revenue (TR) − total cost (TC) where TC includes the firm’s economic or opportunity costs (accounting plus implicit costs). We can see that: 108 Part 2: Microeconomics · If TR > TC, profit is positive; since ‘profit’ in Economics means ‘economic profit’, the firm is here making an economic profit. · If TR = TC, the firm is making zero economic profit (though it is earning normal profit). · If TR < TC, the firm is making a loss (negative economic profit). The firm’s profit-maximization (loss-minimization) rule in this approach is to choose to produce the level of output where the value of TR − TC (= profit) is as large as possible. When TR > TC and the firm is able to make a profit, profit is maximized when the firm produces a level of output where the difference between TR and TC (TR − TC) is the largest. When TC > TR and the firm is unable to make a profit and therefore incurs a loss, the loss is minimized when the difference between TC and TR is the smallest. The amount of profit made by the firm is equal to the numerical difference between TR and TC. If the firm is making a loss, the amount of loss will be equal to the numerical difference between TC and TR. Profit maximization based on the marginal revenue and cost approach Profit maximization using this approach is based on a comparison of marginal revenue with marginal cost to determine the profit-maximizing level of output. The firm’s profit-maximization rule in this approach is to choose to produce the level of output where marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue, i.e. where MC = MR. The same rule, MC = MR, is used by the firm that is interested in minimizing its loss. We can best understand why the use of this rule maximizes profit by use of diagrams that show the relationship between MC and MR. In Figure 4.8, both panels (a) and (b) show the standard MC curve that we studied earlier in Section 4.1. There are two kinds of marginal revenue curves, depending on whether or not the firm has any control over the price at which it sells its output. You need not concern yourself at this point about the shape of the MR curve, as it has no bearing on the present argument (we will study these MR curves in more detail in Chapter 5). Both panels (a) and (b) illustrate the identical principle about profit maximization. HL (a) Price constant. HL (b) Price varies with output. MC 0 MC, MR MC MC, MR HL MR Q1 Q max Q2 Q 0 Q1 Q Q max 2 MR Q Figure 4.8 Profit maximization based on MR = MC. According to the profit-maximizing rule, MC = MR, so the level of output that should be chosen by the firm is determined by the point of intersection between the MC and MR curves. Therefore in Figure 4.8 (a) and (b), Qπmax is the level of output where profit is maximized. Let’s see why this is so. Consider a firm producing output Q1 in both panels (a) and (b), where MR > MC. If this firm were to increase its output by one unit, the additional revenue it would receive (MR) would be greater than the additional cost it will incur (MC). It is therefore in the firm’s interests to increase its level of output. As long as it is producing any Q where MR > MC, the firm should keep on increasing output, and should stop where MR = MC, at output Qπmax. What happens if it continues to increase its output level beyond Qπmax, say to Q2, where MR < MC? At Q2, the additional revenue it would receive for one extra unit of output is less than the additional cost it would incur, and so it should cut back on its Q. As long as MR < MC, the firm should keep decreasing output. There is only one point where the firm can do nothing to improve its position, and that it is at Qπmax, where MR = MC. At Qπmax, its profit will be the greatest it can be. · The model is based on the assumption that firms Evaluating profit maximization as the firm’s main goal · The expectation that profits can be earned is a major Standard economic theory assumes that profit maximization is the overriding goal of firms. Yet the assumption of profit maximization has been criticized on a number of grounds: · Profits ensure that a business can survive over the · The use of marginal concepts (MR and MC) in the theory is very unrealistic; firms cannot easily identify marginal revenues and marginal costs, and don’t even try to do so; therefore this theory does not accurately describe methods actually used by firms to determine price and output. have perfect information at their disposal, whereas in fact the information on which they base their decisions is highly fragmentary and uncertain; firms do not know what demand curves they face for their products and they do not know how competitor firms will behave in response to their actions. · Short-run profit maximization may be unrealistic; firms may not try to maximize profits in the short run, as they might prefer lower profits in the short run in exchange for larger profits over the long run. · The factors determining demand and supply for products and resources are continuously changing, with demand and supplies continuously shifting, so that any profit-maximizing decisions regarding prices and output made today under current conditions may be irrelevant by the time the output is produced and ready for sale in the market. · There is empirical evidence suggesting that some firm behaviour may be prompted by objectives other than profit maximization. Yet the following arguments suggest that making profit remains an important goal of firms: consideration for going into business. long term. · Profits can be used to finance future investments as well as a variety of activities, including research and product development. · Profits make it easier for a firm to obtain external financing (such as borrowing from a bank). · Profits are important to shareholders in the form of higher dividends. Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 109 HL · Profits are often used as a measure of management · As a firm grows it can diversify into different effectiveness. markets and reduce its dependence on a single market. · Many empirical studies show that making profit is · A larger firm has greater market power and increased an important objective of firms. ability to influence prices. Additional firm goals · A larger firm reduces its risks because it may be less Over the years, economists have developed many theories about firm behaviour. The following is a brief survey of some of the more important of these. · The objective of growth maximization reconciles affected in an economic downturn and is less likely to be taken over by another firm. the interests of both owners and managers, because both groups have much to gain from a growing firm (whereas other maximization objectives pit firm owners against firm managers: for example, profit maximization is favoured by owners while sales revenue maximization is favoured by managers). Revenue maximization In an alternative theory of firm behaviour,5 it has been argued that the separation of firm management from firm ownership, which increasingly dominates business organization, has meant that firms’ objectives have changed. Whereas profit maximization may be the dominant motive of the traditional ownermanaged firm, firm managers who are hired by the owners to perform management tasks may be more interested in increasing sales and maximizing the revenues that arise from larger quantities sold. This goal of firms is referred to as revenue maximization. The following arguments have been used to explain why increasing sales and maximizing revenues may be more useful to a firm than profit maximization: Managerial utility maximization In this view, when firm management is separated from firm ownership, managers develop their own objectives that revolve around the maximization of their own utility (satisfaction).7 Managerial utility can be derived from increased salaries, larger fringe benefits (such as free cars and expense accounts), employment of more staff that gives rise to a feeling of importance, and investments in the managers’ favoured projects. The result of all these activities may be to cut into profits and make these lower than they would otherwise be. · Sales can be identified and measured more easily over the short run than profits, and increased sales targets can be used to motivate employees. Satisficing firm behaviour · Rewards for managers and employees are often All of the above objectives assume that the firm tries to maximize some variable, whether it is profit, sales revenue, growth or managerial utility. H. Simon, a Nobel Prize winning economist, has argued that the large modern enterprise cannot be looked upon as a single entity with a single maximizing objective; instead it is composed of many separate groups within the firm, each with its own objectives which may overlap or may conflict. This multiplicity of objectives does not allow the firm to pursue any kind of maximizing behaviour. Firms therefore try to establish processes through which they can make compromises and reconcile conflicts to arrive at agreements, the result of which is the pursuit of many objectives that are placed in a hierarchy. This behaviour was termed satisficing by Simon, referring to the idea that firms try to achieve satisfactory rather than optimal or ‘best’ results. linked to increased sales rather than increased profits. · It is often assumed that revenue from more sales will increase more rapidly than costs; if this is the case, profit (= TR − TC) will also increase. · Increased sales give rise to a feeling of success, whereas declining sales create a feeling of failure. Growth maximization In other approaches it is assumed that firms may be interested in maximizing their growth rather than their profits.6 Growth is seen as attractive for the following reasons: · A growing firm can achieve economies of scale and lower its average costs. · As a firm grows it can diversify into the production of different products and reduce its dependence on a single product. 5 The revenue-maximization goal of firms was described by W. J. Baumol in 1959. 110 Part 2: Microeconomics 6 7 This is based on the work of R. Marris and others. This is based on the work of O. E. Williamson in 1963. HL HL Ethical and environmental concerns The self-interested behaviour of firms often leads to consequences that are detrimental to society. (Many of these consequences will be examined in Chapter 6 under the topic of market failure.) It may often be the case that the welfare of the firm is not consistent with the welfare of society. A prime example involves the self-interested firm that pollutes the environment. In addition, firms can engage at times in actions that most consumers would consider to be ethically unacceptable, such as the practice in many developing countries of employing children who are extremely poorly paid and forced to work long hours, or employing labour that is forced to work under unhealthy or dangerous conditions. These situations may arise in countries where there is widespread poverty, and government legislation protecting the rights of children and workers is either non-existent or poorly enforced. However, many firms are increasingly recognizing that the pursuit of self-interest need not necessarily conflict with ethical and environmentally responsible behaviour. A negative image of the firm held by workers and customers (buyers of the product) can cut deeply into the firm’s revenues and profits by lowering worker productivity and the firm’s sales. Further, socially irresponsible firm behaviour may lead to government regulation of the firm intended to minimize the negative consequences of the firm’s actions for society, whereas socially responsible behaviour could instead result in avoidance of government regulation. Therefore, firms face strong incentives to engage in socially beneficial activities. These can take many forms, including: · avoidance of polluting activities · engaging in environmentally sound practices · support for human rights, such as avoiding exploitation of child labour and labour in general in less developed countries, or avoiding investments in countries with politically oppressive regimes · art and athletics sponsorships · donations to charities. Many of these practices have been the result of increased consumer awareness of social and environmental issues, growing consumer concern over ethical and environmental aspects of business practices, and even consumer activism that results in boycotts of offending firms. One indication of the influence and concern of consumers is the rapidly growing interest in investments in companies (through stock markets) that meet certain social, ethical and ecological criteria. It used to be held that ethical and environmentally responsible behaviour on the part of firms will cut into their profits. This presumption took into consideration only the cost aspect of profits: for example, firms using cheap child labour will face lower costs, and hence will make higher profits than firms avoiding such practices. Yet profits depend not only on costs, but also on revenues. If consumers avoid buying the products of offending firms, revenues will decline and profits will go down as well, in spite of the lower costs. The same arguments also apply to firms that may be pursuing some strategy other than profit maximization, such as revenue maximization. A number of studies have attempted to measure the impacts of socially responsible behaviour on the profits of firms. Does ethical and environmentally responsible behaviour lower or increase firms’ profits? The results of these studies have been inconclusive. The behaviour of firms themselves, however, suggests that they do not want to risk consumer displeasure. Test your understanding 4.6 1 (a) What are the two approaches to profit maximization by firms? (b) What is the profitmaximizing rule of firms in each of the two approaches? 2 What do firms determine by use of the profitmaximizing rules? 3 (a) Say a firm is producing a level of output Q where MC > MR. What should it do to increase its profit (or reduce its loss)? (b) If it is producing Q where MC < MR, what should it do? 4 (a) Why are many economists critical of the assumption made by the standard theory of the firm that firm behaviour is prompted by the objective to maximize profits? (b) What are some arguments suggesting that profits are an important consideration in firm behaviour? 5 Discuss some alternative possible goals of firms that may influence their behaviour. Chapter 4: Theory of the firm I 111 HL Questions for HL review 4.1 [10 marks] Define and explain the law of diminishing marginal returns, and provide an example illustrating this law. 4.2 [10 marks] (a) Draw the marginal product and average product curves of a firm, paying special attention to their points of intersection. (b) Explain the relationship between the two curves. (c) What important economic principle is responsible for their shapes? (d) How is the distinction between the short run and the long run related to this law? 4.3 [10 marks] (a) Draw the marginal cost (MC) and average cost curves (AVC and ATC), paying special attention to their points of intersection. (b) Explain the relationship between MC and AVC; MC and ATC. (c) What important economic principle accounts for their shapes? 4.4 [10 marks] Show diagrammatically the impacts on TFC, TVC, TC, AFC, AVC, ATC and MC of (a) an increase in a fixed cost of production; (b) a decrease in a variable cost of production. 4.5 [10 marks] Distinguish between a variety of factors that can contribute to (a) economies of scale, and (b) diseconomies of scale and illustrate using a diagram. 4.6 [10 marks] Explain why a firm cannot be maximizing profit if MC < MR or if MC > MR. 4.7 [10 marks for part (a); 15 marks for part (b)] (a) Explain two ways that can be used by economists to study profit maximization by a firm. (b) Evaluate the assumption made by the standard theory of the firm, that firm behaviour is guided by the objective to maximize profits, referring to possible alternative goals that firms may have. 4.8 [10 marks] Environmentally responsible behaviour could involve the installation by firms of anti-pollution equipment, giving rise to an increase in their costs of production. And yet studies suggest that this need not result in a decrease in a firm’s profits. Use total revenue and total cost concepts to explain how this is possible. 4.9 [10 marks] Using your knowledge about the profit-maximizing behaviour of firms, explain why a firm would be interested in producing a level of Q after diminishing marginal returns (diminishing marginal product) have set in, indicating that marginal cost is increasing. 112 Part 2: Microeconomics HL 4.10 [10 marks for part (a); 10 marks for part (b)] David Ricardo, a famous English economist of the 19th century, believed that agricultural output would eventually stop growing, because as more and more labour and capital inputs were added to land that was fixed in quantity, the additional output of labour and capital would become smaller and smaller until it would no longer be possible for total output to increase further. (a) What is the law that describes the process that Ricardo was referring to? (b) Do you think Ricardo’s fears were justified? Explain why or why not. 4.11 [15 marks] Compare and contrast, and explain the causes of the U-shape of the short-run and long-run average cost curves. 4.12 [10 marks] Why would a firm be interested in keeping its business running even though it may be earning zero economic (supernormal) profit? 4.13 [10 marks for parts (a) and (b); 10 marks for part (c)] Consider the following statements, and in each case explain why you agree or disagree. (a) The ‘short run’ refers to a short period of time; the ‘long run’ refers to a long period of time. (b) When a firm is earning zero normal profit, this means that it is just covering all its costs. (c) Both the short-run average total cost curve and the long-run average total cost curve have a similar U-shape because of the law of diminishing marginal returns. Chapter 5 Microeconomics The theory of the firm II Market structures (higher level topic) This chapter continues our study of firm behaviour. We will use the general principles that were outlined in Chapter 4 to study how firms behave in the context of the structure of the market in which they operate. A market structure (introduced in Chapter 2, page 29) describes the characteristics of market organization that influence the behaviour of firms within an industry. It defines the firm’s environment, and determines a number of outcomes such as how much quantity a firm will produce, what price it will charge, how much profit it can make, how efficiently it can produce, and to what extent its actions benefit consumers and society at large. Before reading this chapter, the student should review Section 2.1, containing an overview of market structures. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · HL · · · · · · · · · · · identify the main characteristics of each of the four market structures: perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly examine how firms in each of the market structures determine the profit-maximizing level of output understand the different demand curves faced by firms in each of the market structures explain the significance of entry and exit in competitive market structures appreciate the significance of barriers to entry and the consequences of market power distinguish between the short-run and long-run equilibrium positions of the firm and industry in the different market structures analyse and explain the adjustment to long-run equilibrium in competitive market structures explain the efficiency characteristics of each of the market structures evaluate the desirability of each of the market structures from various perspectives, by identifying and comparing their advantages and disadvantages explain the theory of contestable markets and its implications for government policy explain why firms often practise price discrimination, and identify the necessary conditions for this practice to take place evaluate price discrimination by considering its advantages and disadvantages from various perspectives. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 113 HL HL 5.1 Perfect competition Assumptions of the model The model of perfect competition is based on the following assumptions: · There is a very large number of firms The large number ensures that each firm’s output is very small in relation to the size of the market. In addition, it ensures that the firms cannot collude (agree to act together so as to secure market power). The firms act independently of each other and the actions of each have an imperceptible impact on the others and on market price. · Each firm is a price-taker A price-taker is one who accepts the price that is determined in the market by the forces of demand and supply, and has no power to influence it. Because the number of firms in the perfectly competitive market is very large, and the output of each is a small fraction of the total offered in the market for sale, the firm cannot affect the market price by varying its output, and must accept the price as given. It is then free to sell whatever quantity of output will maximize its profit at that price. · All firms produce identical products There is no product differentiation; all products are identical to each other. It is not possible to distinguish the product of one producer from that of another. · There is free entry and exit Another way of saying this is that there are no barriers to entry and exit. Any firm that wishes to enter the market can do so freely as there is nothing to prevent it from doing so; similarly if it wishes to leave the market it can do so freely. · There is complete information All firms and all consumers have complete information regarding products, prices, resources and methods of production. This assumption ensures that no firm has access to information not available to all others that would allow it to produce at a lower cost compared to its competitors. Also, it ensures that all consumers are aware of the market-determined price, and would therefore not be willing to pay any higher price for the product. These assumptions define a perfectly competitive market. Although they are rarely if ever fully met in the real world, there are certain industries that are described more accurately by this model than by any other, such as for example some agricultural commodities (wheat, corn, livestock), other commodities (silver and gold), and the foreign 114 Part 2: Microeconomics exchange market. In spite of its limited applicability to real-world industries, this model is studied because it offers major insights into the workings of the competitive market. In addition, it serves as an important standard or benchmark used by economists to assess the degree of efficiency that is achieved in the other market structures. Demand and revenue curves under perfect competition The demand curve facing the firm Consider the market or industry (these terms are used interchangeably) for a product produced under perfect competition. Figure 5.1(a) shows market demand and supply for this product, which determine the equilibrium price, Pe. Market demand is represented by a standard downward-sloping demand curve, and market supply by a standard upward-sloping supply curve. Panel (b) shows the demand curve for the product as it appears to the individual firm. It is a perfectly elastic demand curve, shown by a horizontal line at the price level Pe that has been determined in the market. As we know from Chapter 3, page 66, a perfectly elastic demand curve has a price elasticity of demand (PED) equal to infinity throughout its range. What does this mean for the firm? The individual firm, being very small, can do nothing to influence this price; it must accept it and sell whatever output will maximize profit at the price Pe. This explains why the firm is a price-taker. If the firm raised its price above Pe, it would not be able to sell any output, because buyers would buy the product elsewhere at the lower price Pe. On the other hand, since the firm can sell all it wants at price Pe, it would have nothing to gain and something to lose (in terms of revenue) if it dropped its price below Pe. Therefore the firm will sell all its output at Pe. The assumption that the perfectly competitive firm is a price-taker has a very important implication: the demand curve facing the firm is perfectly elastic (horizontal) at the price for the good that has been determined in the market for that good. The firm’s revenue curves The demand curve faced by the perfectly competitive firm influences its revenue. This follows simply from the principle that total revenue is equal to the price of the good times the quantity sold (TR = P × Q). Let’s HL HL P (a) Individual firm. HL (b) Market/industry. P S Pe Pe D D 0 Q 0 Q Figure 5.1 Market (industry) demand and supply versus demand faced by the individual perfectly competitive firm. assume that a perfectly competitive firm produces and sells a good at €10 per unit. Based on this price, we can calculate the firm’s total revenue, marginal revenue and average revenue, and see how these change as its output increases. The data are shown in Table 5.1. Column (3) shows total revenue, calculated by multiplying the units of output in column (1) by the price shown in column (2). Column (4) calculates marginal revenue, by taking the change in total revenue and dividing it by the change in output. Column (5) shows average revenue, obtained by dividing total revenue by quantity, for each level of output. The data in the table reveal an interesting pattern: No matter how much output the perfectly competitive firm sells, P = MR = AR (price is equal to marginal revenue which is equal to average revenue). This follows simply from the fact that price is constant regardless of the level of output sold. This is an important result that holds only for firms operating under perfect competition, because these are the only firms that have no control over price and are TR 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 forced to sell all their output at the single price that is determined in the market. The data of Table 5.1 are plotted in Figure 5.2. In Figure 5.2(a) we can see that total revenue increases at a constant rate, i.e. it is a straight line. Figure 5.2(b), plotting marginal and average revenues, shows that since price is constant at €10, P = MR = AR, and they all coincide with the horizontal demand curve. Table 5.1 Total, marginal and average revenue when price is constant. (1) Units of output (Q) (2) Product price (P) (¤) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 (3) (4) Total Marginal revenue revenue TR = P × Q Δ TR MR = (¤) ΔQ (¤) 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 (5) Average revenue TR MR = Q (¤) 0 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 P, MR, AR (b) Marginal and average revenue. (a) Total revenue. TR 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Q Figure 5.2 Revenue curves under perfect competition. 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 D = P = MR = AR 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Q Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 115 HL Test your understanding 5.1 1 What are the assumptions defining the perfectly competitive market model? 2 (a) Explain why the perfectly competitive firm is a price-taker. (b) What would happen if this firm tried to raise its price above the market price? (c) What would happen if it lowered its price below the market price? 3 How is the demand curve facing the perfectly competitive firm related to the industry/market demand curve? As we know from Chapter 4, page 108, there are two approaches to analysing profit maximization (or loss minimization): the total revenue and cost approach, and the marginal revenue and cost approach, both of which yield identical results. We will now examine each of these approaches in turn. Short-run profit maximization based on the total revenue and cost approach As we know, profit is equal to total revenue minus total cost (TR − TC). The firm is faced with the following possibilities: 4 (a) Explain the relationship between the firm’s average revenue (AR) and marginal revenue (MR) in perfect competition. (b) How are they related to product price? (c) How are they related to the demand curve facing the firm? · If TR > TC, the firm makes economic profit. · If TR = TC, the firm is makes zero economic profit, though it is earning normal profit. · If TR < TC, the firm makes a loss (negative economic profit). Profit maximization in the short run We now turn to profit maximization by the perfectly competitive firm in the short run. Recall that the short run is the period during which the firm has at least one fixed input, or a fixed plant. This means that the number of firms in the industry we are considering is also fixed; since firms cannot vary their plant in the short run, they cannot enter the industry or leave the industry, as this would involve varying their fixed resources. What decisions are open to the firm in the short run? Since the firm is a price-taker, having no power to influence the price at which it sells its output, it can only make decisions over (i) how much quantity of output it should produce in order to maximize its profit (or minimize its loss), and (ii) in the event that it is making a loss, whether it should go on producing or should shut down. TC, TR (a) Profit-making firm. TC, TR TC b Figure 5.3 (a) and (b) shows the standard total cost curve that we considered in Chapter 4, page 99 (which applies to all firms regardless of market structure; see Section 4.1), together with the total revenue curve derived in Figure 5.2(a) above. In panel (a), we note that there is a range of output, Q, where TR lies above TC, indicating that the firm is making economic profit. The firm must now determine which is the profit-maximizing level of Q. This occurs where the difference between TR and TC is largest, and is given by Qπmax. The amount of economic profit made by the firm at this level of output is given by the vertical difference between TR and TC. Note that at the points where the TC and TR curves intersect, given by a and b, TR = TC and economic profit is zero. These are called break-even points, where the firm is earning only normal profit. (b) Loss-making firm. TR TC TR profit a 0 loss Q max Q 0 Figure 5.3 Profit maximization under perfect competition: total revenue and total cost approach. 116 Part 2: Microeconomics Ql min Q HL HL Panel (b) illustrates the case where the firm is making a loss. There is no level of output at which TR is greater than TC, and there are no points of intersection between TR and TC, indicating that there is no level of output the firm can produce that will allow it to break even. The firm’s objective here is to minimize its loss, and this is done at output level Qlmin, where the difference between TC and TR is the smallest. The amount of loss made by the firm is equal to the vertical difference between TC and TR. Short-run profit maximization based on the marginal revenue and cost approach Profit maximization using this approach involves two steps: (i) Comparison of marginal revenue with marginal cost to determine profit-maximizing (or loss-minimizing) level of output As we know from Chapter 4 (Section 4.3, page 108) a firm interested in maximizing profit (or minimizing loss) produces that level of output where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost, or where MR = MC. This can be seen in Figure 4.8(a) in Chapter 4, page 109, where Qπmax was shown to be the profit-maximizing level of output. (ii) Comparison of average revenue and average cost to determine the amount of profit (or loss) To determine the size of the profit or loss, the firm must consider average revenue and average cost. We know that profit = TR − TC. If we divide this throughout by output, Q, we obtain an expression for profit per unit of output, in other words, in terms of averages: profit Q = TR Q − TC Q or alternatively profit Q = AR − ATC (since AR = TR Q and ATC = TC Q ). Moreover, since P = AR (as shown in Table 5.1 and Figure 5.2(b)), it follows that profit Q = P − ATC This is the key to calculating the size of the firm’s profit or loss. HL At the profit-maximizing level of output Q (given by the MC = MR rule): · If P > ATC, the firm makes an economic profit. · If P = ATC, the firm breaks even, making zero economic profit, though it is earning normal profit. · If P < ATC, the firm is makes a loss (negative economic profit). Using this two-step approach, we will now examine the behaviour of the perfectly competitive firm in the short run. To do this, we will make use of the diagrams appearing in Figure 5.4 (page 118). Each of these diagrams contains identical cost curves (AVC, ATC and MC; note that MC always intersects AVC and ATC at their minimum points). The only thing that differs between the diagrams is the position of the perfectly elastic demand curve, which shows different possible prices that the firm, being a price-taker, must accept. Figure 5.4(a): profit maximization and economic profit in the short run As shown in the diagram, market price is P1, and thus P1 = MR1 = AR1 represent the demand curve facing the firm. Using the profit-maximizing rule MR = MC, the intersection of the MR and MC curves determines the firm’s profit-maximizing level of output, Q1 (simply draw a line from the point of intersection to the horizontal axis). To determine the profit level of the firm, we compare P1 with ATC along this same vertical line at the level of output Q1. Since P > ATC, we conclude the firm is making profit per unit equal to P1 − ATC, which is represented by the vertical distance between points a and b. To find total profit, we multiply profit per unit times the total number of units produced; this is given by profit = profit Q ×Q and is represented by the shaded area in the diagram. Note that all profit measures in our discussion refer to economic profit, also known as abnormal or supernormal profit. In general, when P > ATC at the level of output where MC = MR, the firm is making an economic profit. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 117 HL price, revenue, costs (a) Economic profit. MC P1 a total profit b ATC AVC P1 = MR1 = AR1 = D1 profit Q Q1 0 Q price, revenue, costs (b) Zero economic profit (normal profit). MC ATC P2 AVC P2 = MR2 = AR2 = D2 Q2 0 Q price, revenue, costs (c) Economic loss; the firm continues to produce. MC P3 ATC c total loss d loss Q Q3 0 AVC P3 = MR3 = AR3 = D3 = break-even price Q price, revenue, costs (d) Loss in the short run and the shut-down price. MC ATC AVC e P4 0 total loss P4 = MR4 = AR4 = D4 f loss = AFC = shut down price Q Q4 Q price, revenue, costs (e) The loss-making firm that will not produce. MC ATC g P5 h 0 Q5 AVC P5 = MR5 = AR5 = D5 Q Figure 5.4 Short-run equilibrium positions of the perfectly competitive firm. Figure 5.4(b): zero economic profit (normal profit) in the short run The market-determined price has fallen to P2, corresponding to demand curve D2. Applying once again the MR = MC rule, we find the profit-maximizing level of output to be Q2. Note that at the point of 118 intersection of MR and MC, price P2 is exactly equal to minimum ATC. What does this tell us about the firm’s profit position? Profit per unit is given by P2 − ATC, which in this case is equal to zero. Therefore the firm is making zero economic profit. However, it is earning normal profit, meaning that its revenues are just sufficient to cover all of implicit plus accounting costs, or all economic costs of production. The price that is equal to minimum ATC is called the break-even price. This is the price at which the firm breaks even, where its total revenues are equal to its total costs (implicit plus accounting costs), making economic profit equal to zero. Part 2: Microeconomics In general, when P = minimum ATC at the level of output where MC = MR, the firm is breaking even: it is making zero economic profit, but is earning normal profit. Figure 5.4(c): loss minimization in the short run In some cases, the market price that the firm must accept is too low to provide enough revenue to enable it to cover all its costs. This occurs when the price falls to a level such as P3, corresponding to demand curve D3, which is below minimum ATC. Using the MC = MR rule, we see that the profit-maximizing or lossminimizing level of output is Q3, for which P < ATC, indicating that the firm is making a loss. Therefore output Q3 represents the firm’s loss-minimizing output. The vertical difference between ATC and P3, or the difference between points c and d, represents the firm’s loss per unit of output, or loss Q . If we multiply this vertical distance by Q3, we get the total loss incurred by this firm, given by the shaded area. What should this firm do? Should it go on producing at a loss or should it stop producing and shut down? To answer this question, we must remember that the firm is in the short run. This means that if it stops producing, it will have zero revenue and zero variable costs (it will have fired all its workers, and will not be purchasing any other variable inputs), but since it will still have some fixed inputs it will have some fixed costs (such as interest payments on loans, insurance payments, rental payments, etc.). The fixed costs are costs that must be paid even though the firm is not producing anything. Therefore, with zero revenues and zero variable costs, the firm that does not produce in the short run will incur a loss equal to its fixed costs. Remember that the firm’s objective is to make its HL HL loss as small as possible. What if by producing some output the firm can receive enough revenue to cover a portion of its fixed costs, plus whatever variable costs it is incurring? In this event, it will be worthwhile for the firm to continue to produce even though it is making a loss, because its loss will be smaller than the loss it would make if it stopped producing. This answers the loss-making firm’s question: it is better to produce rather than shut down, as long as the loss it makes by producing is less than its total fixed cost. In terms of our per unit analysis here, the firm should produce as long as the loss per unit incurred by producing is less than its average fixed cost (AFC, or cost per unit). This situation is illustrated in panel (c). The vertical difference between ATC and AVC is equal to AFC (since AFC + AVC = ATC). Therefore the loss per unit, which is given by ATC − P3 at output level Q3 (or the vertical difference between points c and d), is smaller than AFC. Therefore this firm should not shut down in the short run; it should produce its loss-minimizing output, because the loss it makes by producing is smaller than its fixed cost. In general, when ATC > P > AVC at the level of output where MC = MR, the firm is making a loss but should continue to produce because its loss is smaller than its fixed cost. Graphically, this occurs when the demand curve lies below minimum ATC and above minimum AVC. Figure 5.4(d): loss in the short run and the shut-down price There is a price level below which the firm will stop producing, termed the shut-down price, given by P = minimum AVC, and shown as P4 in panel (d), corresponding to demand curve D4. At exactly this price, the firm will be indifferent between producing Q4, given by the intersection between MR and MC, and not producing at all. Whether the firm produces output Q4 or whether it does not produce at all, the loss per unit of output will be exactly equal to AFC, given by ATC − AVC (or the vertical difference between points e and f). Figure 5.4(e): the loss-making firm that will not produce If the market price that the perfectly competitive firm must accept is so low that it falls below minimum AVC, then it will no longer be worthwhile for the firm to go on producing. As panel (e) shows, if the firm were to produce, it would produce Q5 units of output, given by the point of intersection between the MR and MC curves. However, at this level of output, the loss per unit is equal to the difference between points g and h, which is greater than AFC. Therefore in this case the firm is better off not producing at all. In general, when P < minimum AVC at the level of output where MC = MR, the firm should shut down because the loss it will incur by shutting down is smaller than if it produces any level of output. The firm’s short-run decisions on how much output to produce, and whether or not it should produce if it is making a loss, are summarized in Figure 5.5. The cost curves, and the five prices and demand curves depicted here are exactly the same as those appearing in the five panels of Figure 5.4. We can summarize these results as follows: In perfect competition: · When P > ATC, the firm realizes an economic profit. · When P = minimum ATC, the firm realizes zero economic profit, and therefore earns normal profit; this is the break-even point, achieved at the breakeven price. · When ATC > P > AVC, the firm produces at a loss, but its loss is less than fixed costs (loss per unit < AFC) and therefore it continues to produce. · When P = minimum AVC, the firm is indifferent between producing and shutting down; in both cases its loss = fixed costs (loss per unit = AFC); this is the shut-down point, reached at the shut-down price. · When P < AVC, the firm shuts down (stops producing) because if it continues to produce, it will make a loss greater than its fixed costs (by not producing it will have a loss equal to its fixed costs). In general, when P = minimum AVC at the level of output where MC = MR, the firm is indifferent between producing its loss-minimizing level of output or shutting down. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 119 HL HL ATC price, revenue, costs P = minimum ATC = break-even price firm makes normal profit, or zero economic profit P = minimum AVC = shut-down price firm is indifferent between producing at a loss or not producing P > ATC firm makes economic (supernormal) profit MC 1 P1 2 P2 ATC > P > AVC firm makes loss but continues to produce P < AVC firm makes loss and shuts down 3 P3 P4 P5 0 AVC 4 5 Q5 Q4 Q3 Q2 Q1 output, Q Figure 5.5 Summary of the perfectly competitive firm’s short-run decisions, and the firm’s short-run supply curve. The firm’s short-run supply curve As we know, any profit-maximizing firm produces the level of output determined by the rule MC = MR. But under the assumptions of perfect competition, where price is constant for all levels of output, it is also the case that MR = P, so that the profit-maximizing rule can be rewritten as MC = P. This means that the MC curve shows the level of output Q that the perfectly competitive firm is willing and able to supply in the market in a series of possible prices. Note that this is none other than the definition of the firm’s supply curve, which we studied in Chapter 2, page 40. However, as we now know, the firm will not supply the market if the price falls below minimum AVC. We can therefore redefine the perfectly competitive firm’s short-run supply curve to be the portion of its marginal cost curve that lies above the point of minimum AVC. In Figure 5.5, the firm’s short-run supply curve is represented by the boldface segment of the MC curve. As we know from Chapter 2, page 41, the industry (market) supply curve is obtained by adding up, or summing horizontally, all the individual firm supplies; therefore the industry supply is the sum of all individual firm MC curves above minimum AVC. Short-run equilibrium under perfect competition Each of the positions shown in the five panels of Figure 5.4 represents a short-run equilibrium position for an individual firm operating within a perfectly 120 Part 2: Microeconomics competitive market structure (industry). Each firm equilibrium corresponds to an equilibrium in the market as well, where the point of equality between quantity demanded and quantity supplied determines the market price that each firm accepts (as shown in Figure 5.1). These short-run equilibrium positions for the individual firm and for the market hold and will continue to hold, ceteris paribus. In other words, as long as everything that could cause a disturbance to the system is held constant and unchanging, and as long as the firm remains in the short run, these equilibrium positions will continue indefinitely. In the short run, the firms cannot change any of their fixed resources, and as long as nothing else changes (such as market demand, resource prices, the technology of production, etc.), the individual firms in the industry will go on producing the output levels shown in Figure 5.4, earning economic profit, or normal profit, or making a loss by producing, or not producing at all. Test your understanding 5.2 1 (a) Using the total revenue and cost approach to profit maximization, how do we know if a firm is making economic profit, normal profit, or loss? (b) How will the firm maximize its profit or minimize loss using this approach? 2 (a) Using an appropriate diagram, illustrate the case where a firm is earning normal profit using the total revenue and cost approach to profit maximization. (b) Suppose now there is a fall in the market price; how would this would affect your diagram of part (a)? (c) What will happen to the firm’s normal profit after the price fall of part (b)? (...continued) HL HL Test your understanding 5.2 (...continued) 3 We know from Chapter 4 (page 108) that the profit-maximizing (loss-minimizing) rule using the marginal revenue and cost approach is MC = MR. Yet in perfect competition, the firm will maximize profit (minimize loss) where MC = P. How is this possible? 4 Using appropriate diagrams and the marginal revenue and cost approach to profit maximization, show when a firm (a) earns economic profit (you must show profit per unit and total profit); (b) earns normal profit; (c) incurs a loss (you must show loss per unit and total loss). 5 Suppose a firm in the short run is making a loss. (a) Use appropriate diagrams to show how it makes a decision between continuing to produce in the short run or shutting down (stopping production). (b) What is the largest possible loss it will be prepared to accept before shutting down? (c) Using an appropriate diagram, show the lowest possible price it will be prepared to accept before shutting down. 6 (a) Show diagrammatically the perfectly competitive firm’s short-run supply curve. (b) What does your diagram indicate about the relationship between the firm’s supply curve and AVC? Perfect competition in the long run In the short run the number of firms in an industry cannot change, because each firm has at least one fixed resource, which it cannot vary. In the long run all of the firm’s resources are variable, therefore the number of firms in the industry is no longer unchanging. New firms can enter the industry, existing firms can change their plant size (increase or decrease their fixed resources), or firms can liquidate (sell) their fixed resources and leave the industry altogether. There is therefore free entry and exit of firms in an industry, which is one of the characteristics of this market structure noted at the beginning of Section 5.1. Free entry and exit is the key to understanding the long run under perfect competition, and depends crucially on the assumption that there are no fixed resources. The difference between shutting down in the short run and shutting down in the long run is that in the short run, whereas a loss-making firm can choose to produce zero output, it still has a fixed plant for which it incurs fixed costs. In the long run the loss-making firm can shut down its plant completely and stop incurring any costs at all. For example, say you are running a dry cleaning business, and you are renting the premises. Suppose that in the short run the price of your services has fallen so low that it is less than your minimum AVC. You therefore ‘shut down’ in the sense that you stop providing dry cleaning services. However, you still have to go on paying the rent (your fixed costs) until your rental contract expires. It is only when your rental contract expires that you can go into the long run and ‘shut down’ completely, thus not having any more fixed costs. Role of economic (abnormal) profits and losses in adjustment to long-run equilibrium In the long-run equilibrium of the perfectly competitive market structure, all firms earn zero economic profits (they earn normal profit). The reason behind this important principle is that if firms earn economic profit or make losses in the short run, the profits and losses give rise to a process of entry and exit of firms that makes the short-run profits or loss tend to zero. The long-run equilibrium position of the firm and the industry under perfect competition is shown in Figure 5.6. As a result of entry or exit, the market settles at the price Pe, which is just equal to the firm’s short-run and long-run minimum ATC, where each firm is earning normal profit. Each firm in the industry produces output Qf, and the industry as a whole produces output Qi (equal to the sum of all the firms’ outputs). In perfectly competitive long-run equilibrium, firms’ economic profits and losses are eliminated, and revenues are just enough to cover all economic costs so that every firm earns normal profit. We will see how firms and the industry arrive at this long-run equilibrium position by considering two examples below. Changes in demand and adjustment to long-run equilibrium Let’s assume that a perfectly competitive industry is in long-run equilibrium; each firm is producing the level of output that allows it to earn normal profit. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 121 HL HL (a) The firm. HL (b) The industry (market). price, costs, revenue P MC SRATC D = MR Pe S LRATC Pe D 0 Qf Q Qi 0 Q Figure 5.6 The firm and industry long-run equilibrium position under perfect competition. This is shown in Figure 5.7(b), with D1 and S1 determining price P1 (initial position 1 for the industry). P1 is the price accepted by each firm in the industry, and is equal to minimum ATC for each firm, as shown in Figure 5.7(a). Suppose now that there is a change in consumer tastes in favour of the product produced in this industry; the industry demand curve shifts to the right, from D1 to D2 in panel (b) (position 2 for the industry). With market demand at D2, the market price increases to P2, which becomes the new price that firms in the industry now accept. In panel (a) we see that, at the higher price P2, by the MC = MR rule, firms now equate MC with P2 (which is their new MR). Firms therefore begin to earn a short-run economic profit, since P2 > ATC, and profit per unit of output = a − b. In the long run, the increased profit realized by firms in the industry leads to the entry of new firms into the industry, that are attracted by the prospect of making economic profits. Output in the industry increases, and, as a result, the industry supply curve S1 in panel (b) begins to shift to the right, and it continues to shift costs, revenue, P (a) The firm. until it reaches S2, where the market price has fallen back to the level of P1 (position 3 for the industry). At price P1, all firms are earning normal profit once again. What has happened in this adjustment process? The increased consumer demand initially resulted in a higher market price for the good, as well as in economic profits for firms, which acted as a signal and incentive for new firms to enter the industry. As supply increased, the price fell back to its original level, but output for the industry as a whole increased from Q1 to Q2, as shown in panel (b). Therefore the market responded to the consumers’ desire for an increased supply. In the event that market demand were to fall, the market demand curve would shift to the left, price would fall, and firms would begin to incur losses. The long-run response will be for firms to leave the industry. The industry supply curve will shift to the left up to the point that price climbs back to its original position (where it is equal to firms’ minimum ATC), and the industry’s output will be reduced. P S1 MC a P2 P1 0 b Qf ATC profit unit Q P2 P1 0 Figure 5.7 An increase in demand and the long-run response of firms and the industry. 122 (b) The industry (market). Part 2: Microeconomics S2 2 1 Ql 3 D2 D1 Q2 Q Changes in technology or resource prices, and adjustment to long-run equilibrium Test your understanding 5.3 If there is an improvement in the technology of production, or if resource prices change, these will be reflected in the firm’s cost curves. Both an improvement in technology and a fall in resource prices mean lower costs for the firm, and appear as a downward shift in the firm’s cost curves. This means that firms that were previously earning only normal profit (at the long-run equilibrium) will now be earning economic profit. This will result in new entrants into the industry, and the industry supply curve will shift to the right. As it does so, the market price begins to fall, and the supply curve will keep shifting and the price falling until the new market price is equal to the new, lower minimum ATC curve, intersected at its minimum point by the new lower MC curve. The end result will be that output of the industry will increase, the final market price will be lower, and all firms will be earning normal profit once again. If resource prices were to increase, there would result an upward shift in the firm’s cost curves, and the final equilibrium for the industry would involve a lower quantity of output produced and a higher equilibrium price. losses in the short run. Using appropriate diagrams, show what will happen to (a) the number of firms in the industry; (b) industry supply; (c) the market price; (d) the losses of the firms; and (e) the quantity of output. 4 (a) Use diagrams to show an individual firm’s and the market’s equilibrium position in the long run. (b) What is the relationship between price, ATC and MC for the individual firm when it is in long-run equilibrium? (c) Does the firm earn any profit when it is in long-run equilibrium (recall that the term ‘profit’ in Economics refers to ‘economic profit’)? 5 Consider a perfectly competitive market that is in long-run equilibrium. Using appropriate diagrams, explain the process of adjustment to a new long-run equilibrium, and show what happens to equilibrium price and quantity in the event that there is (a) a change in consumer tastes against the product (i.e. market demand falls); and (b) an improvement in the technology of production. 1 How would you use the assumption of free entry Allocative and productive (technical) efficiency and exit in a perfectly competitive industry to distinguish between the short run and the long run? The concept of economic efficiency was explained in Chapter 2, page 49, where we saw that competitive markets achieve economic (allocative and productive) efficiency. Figure 5.8 shows the long-run equilibrium position of a firm and industry in perfect competition. (Note that 5.8(b) is the same as Figure 2.18 of Chapter 2, page 50). The equilibrium price accepted by the firm when it is in long-run equilibrium is Pe, determined in the market by the intersection of the supply and demand curves, where the market supply curve illustrates marginal cost (MC) and the market 2 Consider an industry where firms are earning economic profits in the short run. Show diagrammatically what will happen to (a) the number of firms in the industry; (b) industry supply; (c) the market price; (d) the economic profits of the firms; and (e) the industry’s quantity of output. (...continued) (a) The firm. (b) The market/industry. P MC S = MC ATC Pe 0 HL (...continued) 3 Consider an industry where firms are making Test your understanding 5.3 costs, revenue, P HL P = MR = Pe Q Figure 5.8 Productive and allocative efficiency in perfect competition. Pe 0 consumer surplus producer surplus D = MB Q Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 123 HL demand curve marginal benefit (MB). We know from Chapter 2, page 51, that when the competitive market is in equilibrium, price is determined where MB = MC, and the sum of consumer plus producer surplus is maximized. We will now examine the concepts of productive and allocative efficiency at the level of the firm. Allocative efficiency Allocative efficiency occurs when firms produce the particular combination of goods and services that consumers mostly prefer. The condition is the following: Allocative efficiency is achieved when MB = MC; since MB = P, this condition can be restated as P = MC. Productive efficiency Productive efficiency occurs when firms produce at the lowest possible cost. The condition for productive efficiency is the following: Productive efficiency is achieved when P = minimum ATC. When the price of a good is equal to the lowest possible cost per unit (minimum ATC), this means that resources are being used economically, and that they are not being wasted. Production of the good uses up the least amount of resources possible. Efficiency and perfect competition in the long run Figure 5.8(a) indicates the following: Let’s examine this idea more carefully. The price, P, paid by consumers to acquire a good reflects consumer preferences and the benefits that consumers feel they derive from consumption of a good; more precisely, P reflects the marginal or additional benefit that consumers derive from consumption of one more unit of the good. This marginal benefit is represented by the amount of money consumers are willing to pay in order to buy one more unit of the good. Marginal cost, MC, is a measure of the value, or opportunity cost, of the resources used to produce one extra unit of the good. When price is equal to marginal cost, there is equality between what consumers are prepared to pay to get one more unit and what it costs to produce it. We can better understand why allocative efficiency is achieved when P = MC by considering what happens when the two are not equal to each other. In the event that P > MC, an additional unit of the good is worth more to consumers than what it costs to produce it. There is an underallocation of resources to the production of the good; in other words, too few resources are used to produce the good, too little of the good is produced, and consumers would be better off if more resources were devoted to the good’s production. If P < MC, an additional unit of the good costs more to produce than what the unit is worth to consumers; there is an overallocation of resources to the good. Too much of it is being produced, and consumers would be better off if output were reduced. In both these cases, allocative inefficiency results. Therefore, resources are allocated efficiently among their competing uses only when the price of a good is equal to the marginal cost of producing it. 124 Part 2: Microeconomics Both allocative and productive efficiency are achieved by the perfectly competitive firm when it is at its longrun equilibrium position. At the point of production, determined by MR = MC, price is equal to marginal cost, and therefore society’s scarce resources are being allocated efficiently. Also, at the point of production, P = minimum ATC, and therefore the lowest possible costs are being achieved; hence there is no waste of resources. The achievement of economic (allocative and productive) efficiency by the firm when it is in long-run equilibrium is summarized by: P = MC = minimum ATC. Panel (b) shows how the economic efficiency at the level of the firm corresponds to economic efficiency at the level of the industry. We can examine industrywide efficiency by considering the size of consumer and producer surplus, introduced in Chapter 2, page 50. As you may remember, the sum of consumer and producer surplus is maximum when price is determined by MB = MC, indicating that economic efficiency is being achieved. When P = MC and P = minimum ATC for the firm, the sum of consumer and producer surplus is maximum for the industry. Another way to see that efficiency at the level of the industry is being achieved is to note that marginal benefit is equal to marginal cost (MB = MC). HL HL The achievement of economic (allocative and productive) efficiency in long-run equilibrium in perfect competition is a very important result, because perfect competition is the only market structure where allocative and productive efficiency are realized. This is a key reason why economists use perfect competition as a standard or benchmark for assessing the efficiency of the other three market structures. Efficiency and perfect competition in the short run Figures 5.4 (a) and (c) illustrated the firm’s short-run equilibrium position when it is making economic profits and losses, respectively. What can we say about the achievement of efficiency in the short run? When the firm is earning an economic profit, as in panel (a), at the profit-maximizing level of output, determined by MR = MC, we can see that the firm achieves allocative efficiency, since P = MC. The same is true for the loss-making firm, at its loss-minimizing level of output, as shown in panel (c). Therefore the perfectly competitive firm always achieves allocative efficiency (both in the short run and in the long run). What can we say about productive efficiency? In the short run, neither the profit-making nor the lossmaking firm achieves productive efficiency, though for different reasons. In the case of the profit-making firm, P > minimum ATC, whereas in the case of the loss-making firm, P < minimum ATC. Evaluating perfect competition It was noted in the beginning of this chapter (page 114), that perfect competition, though not a very realistic market structure, offers a number of insights into the workings of the competitive market mechanism. Let’s consider what these are. of productive efficiency), and (b) the absence of economic profits, which would have led to a higher price. You can check this by comparing panels (a) and (b) in Figure 5.4, indicating that the price that allows the firm to earn economic profit is higher than the price that prevails in long-run competitive equilibrium, where the firm earns only normal profit. · Competition leads to the closing down of inefficient producers Inefficient firms are those that produce at higher than necessary costs. Inefficiency (in the sense of productive inefficiency) could be due to factors like less productive labour, or the use of outdated technologies, or poor entrepreneurship. The revenues of inefficient firms are insufficient to cover all the costs, and so these firms make losses and are therefore forced to shut down in the long run and leave the industry. When this occurs, we say that inefficient firms cannot compete with more efficient, lower cost firms. · The market responds to consumer tastes We have seen that changes in consumer tastes will be reflected in changes in market demand and therefore market price. By creating short-run economic profits or losses, price changes result in long-run adjustments that make the quantity of output produced by the industry respond to consumer tastes. · The market responds to changes in technology or resource prices We have also seen that if there is an improvement in the technology of production, or if there is a change in resource prices, the cost curves will shift upward or downward, leading to economic profits or losses, once again setting into motion a long-run adjustment process that will lead finally to a long-run equilibrium that has accommodated all the changes. Limitations of the model Insights provided by the model · Allocative efficiency As we have seen, perfect competition leads to the best or ‘optimal’ allocation of resources based on the mix of goods and services that consumers mostly want, achieved through the equality of P with MC in long-run equilibrium. · Productive efficiency Perfect competition also leads to production at the lowest possible cost, thereby using resources in the best possible way, achieved through the equality of P with minimum ATC in long-run equilibrium. · Low prices for the consumer The consumer benefits from low prices, which are due to (a) production at the lowest possible cost (from the achievement · Unrealistic assumptions The model rests on a number of very strict and unrealistic assumptions that are rarely met in the real world. · Limited possibilities to take advantage of economies of scale Economies of scale (studied in Chapter 4, page 103) lead to lower average costs as a firm grows larger and larger. In perfect competition the requirement that the firms are many and small prevents them from growing to a size large enough to take advantage of economies of scale. · Lack of product variety All firms within an industry produce identical or undifferentiated products. This is a disadvantage for consumers, who tend to prefer product variety. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 125 HL HL · Waste of resources in the process of long-run adjustment It is possible that the continuous opening and closing of firms as the industry adjusts to changes in demand, resource prices and technology in the long run may lead to a waste of resources. · Limited ability to engage in research and development The lack of economic profits in the long run may be a major constraint on engaging in research and development, as firms have limited resources to devote to this activity. · Market failure Even if it were possible to meet all of the assumptions of the perfectly competitive market model, there are many situations that arise in the real world leading to a less than ‘best’ (this is known as suboptimal) allocation of resources, because of market failures. Market failures arise when the actions of consumers or producers have unintended side-effects that impact on third parties, or parties outside the market. Market failures will be the subject of Chapter 6. Test your understanding 5.4 1 Why do you think we study the perfectly competitive market model extensively, when there are only very few industries in the real world that tend to meet the unrealistic assumptions of this model? 2 What do we mean by (a) productive efficiency, and (b) allocative efficiency? (c) Using appropriate diagrams, show how the perfectly competitive firm achieves both productive and allocative efficiency in long-run equilibrium. (d) Show diagrammatically which of these two conditions is not likely to be achieved in the short run. (e) How would you show the achievement of economic (allocative and productive) efficiency for the perfectly competitive industry? 3 How do you think the achievement of productive and allocative efficiency are related to the definition of Economics that we discussed in Chapter 1 (Section 1.1, page 3)? 4 Evaluate the perfectly competitive market model by referring to the insights it offers and its limitations. 126 Part 2: Microeconomics 5.2 Monopoly Assumptions of the model The model of monopoly rests on the following assumptions: · There is a single seller The term monopoly is derived from the Greek work meaning ‘single seller’. When there is a single firm producing a good or service for the entire market, it is called a pure monopoly. The firm is therefore the entire industry. (In the real world, a monopolistic industry may consist of one firm that dominates the market with a very large market share. For example, DeBeers Company of South Africa controls over 80% of diamond sales, and is considered to be a monopoly.) · There are no close substitutes If substitute goods existed, then consumers could easily switch to buying a substitute good, in which case there would no longer be a monopoly for the good in question. Therefore the monopolist produces a good or service that has no close substitutes. · The monopolist is a price-maker In contrast to perfectly competitive firms, which are pricetakers (accepting the price that is determined in the market), the monopolist exercises substantial power to influence the price at which it sells its good, and is therefore called a price-maker. Since the monopolist is the entire industry, it faces a downward-sloping demand curve (the industry or market demand curve). Therefore, by choosing a level of output to produce, it also determines the price at which this output will be sold. (This will be further explained below.) · There are significant barriers to entry The monopolist owes its dominance in the market and the absence of competitor firms to the inability of other firms to enter the industry. Anything that prevents other firms from entering the industry is called a barrier to entry (also defined in Chapter 2, page 29). Monopoly lies at the opposite extreme of market structures to perfect competition. As a single seller, the monopolist faces no competition from other firms and it has substantial market power (the ability to control price; see Figure 2.1). Yet a pure monopoly is quite rare in the real world. Like perfect competition, it is studied because of the insights it offers into the ability of firms to exercise market power, also known as monopoly power. Monopoly power arises whenever a firm faces a demand curve that is downward-sloping. As we will see throughout the rest of this chapter, firms in all market structures except perfect competition face a downward-sloping demand curve, and therefore have HL Barriers to entry There are several kinds of barriers to entry. Economies of scale Economies of scale result in the downward-sloping portion of a firm’s long-run average total cost curve, and permit lower average costs to be achieved as the firm increases its scale or size (see Chapter 4, page 103). A barrier to entry exists when economies of scale are extensive and the LRATC curve declines over a very large range of output. In Figure 5.9(a) it can be seen that the average total costs incurred by a large firm on SRATC1 are substantially lower than the average costs faced by a smaller firm on SRATC2. The large firm will be able to remain in business, because it can charge a lower price than the smaller firm and force the smaller firm into a situation where it will not be able to cover its costs. Therefore, if a new firm tries to enter the industry on a small scale it will be unable to compete with the larger one due to its higher average costs. Figure 5.9(b), at the point where market demand, D, intersects the LRATC curve, LRATC is still declining, meaning that economies of scale have not yet been fully exhausted and the minimum efficient scale occurs at a higher level of output. (The minimum efficient scale, you may remember from Chapter 4, page 104, is the lowest level of output at which lowest average total costs are achieved.) As output increases, average costs (or costs per unit of output) fall, and keep on falling even beyond the point where the entire market demand for the product is satisfied. A market like this cannot support more than one firm. Natural monopoly acts as a strong barrier to entry of new firms into the industry because potential entrants realize that it would be extremely difficult to attain the low costs of the already existing firm. Examples of natural monopolies include water, gas and electricity distribution, cable television, fire protection and postal services. The falling average costs over a very large range of output often occur because of very large capital costs (such as laying pipes for water distribution, or laying cables for electricity distribution, or putting a satellite into orbit). (b) Natural monopoly. (a) Economies of scale. SRATC2 SRATC1 LRATC 0 Q costs varying degrees of monopoly power, or the ability to influence the price at which they sell their output. We therefore study monopoly not only to better understand those markets where firms come close to meeting the conditions of pure monopoly, but also to familiarize ourselves with some of the issues relating to the market structures lying between the extremes of perfect competition and pure monopoly. costs HL 0 LRATC D minimum efficient scale Q On the other hand, a new firm attempting to enter the market on a very large scale so as to be able to take advantage of the economies of scale would encounter huge start-up costs, and would be unlikely to take the risk involved. As we will see later in this chapter, economies of scale form a significant barrier to entry in the case not only of monopolies but also of oligopolies. Figure 5.9 Economies of scale and natural monopoly as a barrier to entry. Natural monopoly · patents, which allow a firm that has developed a A natural monopoly is illustrated in Figure 5.9(b). If the market demand for a product is within the range of falling LRATC, this means that a single large firm can produce for the entire market at a lower average total cost than two or more smaller firms. When this occurs, the firm is called a natural monopoly. Note that there are two factors at work making for a natural monopoly: costs and market demand. In Legal barriers Legal barriers include: new product or invention to be its sole producer for a specified period of time; for that period, the firm producing the patented product has a monopoly on that particular product; examples include patents on new pharmaceutical products; Polaroid and instant cameras, Intel and microprocessor chips used by IBM computers · licences, granted by governments, for particular professions or particular industries; licences may be required, for example, to operate radio or television stations, or to enter a particular profession (such as medicine, dentistry, architecture, law and others); Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 127 HL HL such licences do not usually result in a monopoly but they do have the impact of limiting competition · copyrights, which guarantee that an author (or an author’s appointed person) has the sole rights to print, publish and sell copyrighted works The demand and revenue curves under monopoly The demand curve facing the monopolist · public franchises, which are granted by the government to a firm which is to produce or supply a particular good or service · tariffs, quotas and other trade restrictions, which limit the quantities of a good that can be imported into a country, thus reducing competition. Note that not all of these legal barriers lead to monopoly. What they all have in common, instead, is that they limit competition, and in so doing contribute to the creation of some degree of monopoly power. Control of essential resources Monopolies can arise from ownership or control of an essential resource. A classic example of an international monopoly is DeBeers, the South African diamond firm, that mines roughly 50% of the world’s diamonds and purchases about 80% of diamonds sold on open markets. Whereas it is not the sole diamond supplier, its large market share allows it to have a significant control over the price of diamonds. On a national level, an example is Alcoa (the Aluminum Company of America), which, following the expiration of patents in 1909, was able to maintain its monopoly position on the production of aluminium within the United States until the Second World War, because of its control of almost all the bauxite resources within the country. On a local level, professional sports leagues create a local monopoly by signing long-term contracts with the best players and securing exclusive use of sports stadiums. A local monopoly is a single producer/supplier within a particular geographical area. Local monopolies appear more commonly than national or international ones. For example, a local grocery store in a residential area located some distance from any other stores may be a local monopoly. Aggressive tactics If a monopolist is confronted with the possibility of a new entrant into the industry, it can create entry barriers by cutting its price, advertising aggressively, threatening a takeover of the potential entrant, or any other behaviour that can dissuade a new firm from entering the market. 128 Part 2: Microeconomics Since the pure monopolist is the entire industry, the demand curve it faces is the industry or market demand curve, which is downward sloping. This is the most important difference between the monopolist and the perfectly competitive firm, which faces perfectly elastic demand at the price level determined in the market. The two demand curves shown in Figure 5.10 indicate that the perfectly competitive firm is a price-taker with zero market power, while the monopolist is a pricemaker with a significant degree of market power. All firms under market structures other than perfect competition are to varying degrees price-makers, as they all face downward-sloping demand curves. Of these, the monopolist has the greatest degree of market power, or the ability to influence price, because it is the sole firm in the industry. However, whereas the monopolist has a significant degree of control over price, its control is limited by the position of the market demand curve. Given a market demand curve such as that shown in Figure 5.10(b), when it chooses how much output to produce, say Q1, it simultaneously determines the price at which the good can be sold, which in this case is P1. It could not possibly sell output Q1 at a price such as P2; note that the price–quantity combination P2 and Q1 is at point a, which lies off the demand curve. If it wants to sell its output at price P2, it can do so, but it will only be able to sell quantity Q2 at that price. In other words, the monopolist cannot make independent decisions on both price and quantity; when it decides on one, P or Q, this simultaneously determines the other, because of the constraining effect of the demand curve. To say the same thing differently, the monopolist cannot choose any price–quantity combination that is not on the market demand curve. HL · Average revenue (shown in column 5 of Table 5.2) is HL (a) Facing the perfectly competitive firm. (b) Facing the monopolist. P P P2 P=D 0 equal to price (shown in column 2 of the table): TR since TR = P × Q, and AR is , it follows that P must Q be equal to AR. · The AR and P curves represent the demand curve a facing the firm. P1 · MR is less than P, represented by the demand D Q 0 Q2 Q1 Q Figure 5.10 Demand curves. The monopolist’s revenue curves Under perfect competition where the firm is a pricetaker, the market-determined price is constant for all levels of output, giving rise to the perfectly elastic (horizontal) demand curve. But when a firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve, it is no longer true that price is constant for all levels of output that can be produced by the firm. When the demand curve is downward sloping, if the firm wants to sell a greater quantity of output, it must lower its price. Since total revenue is equal to price times quantity sold (TR = P × Q), the variability of price as output changes means that the firm facing a downward-sloping demand curve has revenues and revenue curves that are very different from those of the perfectly competitive firm. Table 5.2 provides some hypothetical data for the monopolist’s total, marginal and average revenues, and the diagrams in Figure 5.11 plot these data. Observing Table 5.2 and Figure 5.11, we may note the following: · As output (Q) increases, product price (P) falls (because of the downward-sloping demand curve). Total revenue (TR), obtained by Q × P, at first increases, reaches a maximum at six and seven units of output, and then begins to fall. · Marginal revenue, showing the change in total revenue resulting from a change in output, falls continuously; MR is equal to zero when total revenue is at its maximum (at seven units of output), and becomes negative when total revenue falls. Since total revenue begins to fall beyond seven units of output, marginal revenue, showing the change in total revenue, must be negative.1 1 Marginal revenue represents the slope of the total revenue curve (just as marginal cost is the slope of the total cost curve). 2 To understand this, consider the following numerical example. Say output increases from 3 to 4 units. Marginal revenue will be the result of a gain curve; in other words the MR curve lies below the demand curve (except the first unit of output). The reason is that, unlike in perfect competition, where MR = P, here the firm must lower its price in order to sell more output. The lower price is charged not only for the last unit of output but all the previous units of output sold. Marginal revenue, or the extra revenue from selling an additional unit of output, is therefore equal to the amount of the price of the last unit sold minus what is lost by selling all the other units of output at the now lower price.2 Table 5.2 Total, marginal and average revenue when price varies with output. (1) Units of output (Q) (2) (3) (4) Product Total Marginal price revenue revenue (P) (TR = Q × P) Δ TR MR = (¤) (¤) ΔQ (¤) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 12 22 30 36 40 42 42 40 36 30 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 (5) Average revenue TR AR = Q (¤) 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 The monopolist’s output and price elasticity of demand In Table 5.2 and Figure 5.11, in the range of output where total revenue is increasing and marginal revenue is positive, the demand curve facing the firm (represented by P = AR) is price elastic (PED > 1); in the range of output where total revenue is falling and marginal revenue is therefore negative, the demand curve is price inelastic (PED < 1). To see why this is so, recall from Chapter 3, page 69, the relationship between PED and total revenue. When demand is and a loss. The gain is €9, obtained from selling the fourth unit of output at the price of €9. The loss is equal to €1 for each of the initial 3 units of output that previously were selling for €10 and must now sell for €9, equal to €3. Marginal revenue is equal to the gain minus the loss, or 9 − 3 = 6. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 129 HL HL The above observations have some important implications for the level of output produced by the monopolist. total revenue ( ) (a) Total revenue. 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 The monopolist will not produce any output in the inelastic portion of its demand curve. TR 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Q (b) Marginal and average revenue. price, revenue ( ) 15 PED > 1 (elastic demand) PED = 1 (unit elastic demand) Test your understanding 5.5 PED < 1 (inelastic demand) 10 1 What are the assumptions defining the market model of monopoly? 5 P = AR = D 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Q -5 MR Figure 5.11 Revenue curves under monopoly. elastic, price and total revenue change in opposite directions (so that a percentage decrease in price gives rise to a larger percentage increase in quantity demanded and total revenue rises); when demand is inelastic, price and total revenue change in the same direction (a percentage decrease in price gives rise to a smaller percentage increase in quantity demanded, and total revenue falls). These relationships can be seen in Figure 5.11. Price decreases shown in panel (b) from €12 to €6 (along the demand curve) correspond to positive marginal revenue, as well as increasing total revenue in panel (a); therefore in this price range demand is elastic. Price decreases beyond €6 (along the demand curve) correspond to negative marginal revenue, shown in panel (b), and falling total revenue, shown in panel (a). Another way to see the same thing is to remember (from Chapter 3, page 66) that the PED varies along a straight-line demand curve, with the upper left segment being elastic, the midpoint being unit elastic, and the lower right segment being inelastic. In Figure 5.11(b), the point where PED = 1 occurs at the level of output where total revenue is maximum, and MR = 0. 130 Part 2: Microeconomics In Figure 5.11(b), the monopolist will not produce any output greater than seven units, which is where TR is maximum and MR = 0. If it did, its total revenue would fall, while its total cost would increase (since greater output always involves more cost). Since profit = TR − TC, a lower TR and a higher TC mean lower profit. 2 Explain how (a) economies of scale and (b) natural monopoly can result in a monopolistic market structure by posing barriers to entry. Use diagrams and examples to illustrate your answers. 3 Why is the size of a market important in determining whether a monopoly is ‘natural’ or not? 4 How can legal factors provide barriers to entry into an industry? Provide some examples. 5 (a) Compare and contrast the demand curve facing the perfectly competitive firm and that facing the monopolist. (b) What is the relationship between market power and the differences between the two demand curves? (c) Why is one firm a ‘price-taker’ and the other a ‘price-maker’? 6 Explain why P = MR in perfect competition, and both of these coincide with the demand curve facing the firm, whereas in monopoly, MR < P for all units of output (except the first), and therefore the MR curve lies below the demand curve. 7 (a) Explain the relationship between the monopolist’s average revenue (AR) and marginal revenue (MR). (b) How are they related to product price? (c) How are they related to the demand curve facing the firm? (...continued) HL HL Test your understanding 5.5 (...continued) 8 Show diagrammatically the relationship between total revenue (TR), marginal revenue (MR), and demand (D) for a monopolistic firm. TC b TR 9 Why will the monopolist avoid producing in a the inelastic portion of its demand curve? Use diagrams to support your answer. 10 What is the maximum level of output that a monopolist might consider producing? What would the monopolist be maximizing at this level of output? Use diagrams to support your answer. HL (a) Profit maximization. TC, TR 0 Q Q max (b) Loss minimization. TC TC, TR Profit maximization by the monopolist The identical principles govern the profit-maximizing behaviour of the monopolist as that of the perfectly competitive firm; what differs between the two in the analysis of profit maximization are the shapes of their respective demand and revenue curves. The monopolist therefore follows the same profitmaximizing rules: maximize the difference between TR and TC in the total revenue and cost approach; or find the point of equality between MC and MR in the marginal revenue and cost approach. Profit maximization based on the total revenue and cost approach The diagrams in Figure 5.12 show the standard total cost curve derived in Chapter 4, page 99 (which applies equally to firms under all market structures). In addition, they show the total revenue curve shown in Figure 5.11(a) above. Panel (a) illustrates the case of a profit-making firm, whereas the firm in panel (b) is making a loss. Profit is maximized when the difference between TR and TC is largest; this occurs at output level Qπmax, where the difference between TR and TC is maximum. The amount of profit made by the firm is given by the vertical difference between TR and TC at Qπmax. TR 0 Q Figure 5.12 Profit maximization and loss minimization under monopoly: total revenue and cost approach. In Figure 5.12(b), there is no level of output for which TR > TC; instead, TC > TR for all output levels; therefore the firm can only make a loss. Output level Qlmin shows the level of output where the firm’s loss is minimized, and the amount of loss is represented by the smallest difference between TC and TR. Profit maximization based on the marginal revenue and cost approach The monopolist interested in maximizing profit (or minimizing loss) will follow the same two-step approach used by the perfectly competitive firm. The monopolist, like the perfectly competitive firm, will determine the profit-maximizing level output by use of the MC = MR rule. Then, for that level of output, it will determine whether it is making a profit or loss by use of the principle that profit Note that at the points where the TC curve intersects the TR curve, points a and b, TR = TC, and economic profit is equal to zero (at these points, the firm would be earning normal profit). Ql min Q = P − ATC If P > ATC, the monopolist is making a profit; if P = ATC it is earning normal profit (zero economic profit); if P < ATC it is making a loss. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 131 Let’s consider these steps in more detail by examining Figure 5.13. Both panels (a) and (b) of the figure show the standard ATC and MC curves (derived in Chapter 4, page 99). On these cost curves, the monopolist’s demand and marginal revenue curves are superimposed. Consider first panel (a). the demand curve at output level Qlmin. Loss per unit of output (loss/Q) is given by ATC − P (the distance c–d), and total loss is given by the shaded area, found by multiplying loss per unit of output by the total number of units produced. · We first find the point of intersection between MR Just as in perfect competition, the loss-making monopolist will continue to produce in the short run as long as its losses are smaller than its fixed costs (i.e. as long as P > minimum AVC). In the long run (when all resources are variable), the loss-making monopolist is likely to shut down or move its resources to another more profitable industry. However, the distinction between the short run and the long run is not as important in the case of monopoly as it is in perfect competition. Under perfect competition, the distinction between the short and long runs is of crucial importance because as firms enter and exit an industry, economic profits and losses disappear, and firms are left with normal profits in their long-run equilibrium. and MC, or where MR = MC, which determines the profit-maximizing level of output, Qπmax. · For that level of output, Qπmax, we draw a vertical line upward to the AR (or demand) curve (point a) and from there extend a horizontal line leftward to the vertical axis; this will determine the price, Pe, at which the monopolist will sell output Qπmax. · For the output level Qπmax, we then find profit per unit (profit/Q), given by P − ATC; this is simply the vertical difference between the average revenue (or demand curve) and the ATC curve, represented by the vertical distance between points a and b. · To find total profit, we multiply profit per unit times the total number of units produced; this is given by profit = profit Q ×Q and is represented by the shaded area. The monopolist need not always make profits. Yet how is it that a monopolist, being a price-maker, can incur losses? This can happen simply because the price that the monopolist can charge is always constrained by the industry demand curve, as explained earlier. If the costs faced by the monopolist are high relative to demand, and price cannot cover ATC, losses will be inevitable. This is shown in Figure 5.13(b), where the monopolist is minimizing loss. At the level of output Qlmin, determined by the point of intersection between MR and MC (where MR = MC), the monopolist’s loss will be minimized. The price that will be charged is given by Pe, found by extending a line upward to (a) Profit maximization. Under monopoly, high barriers to entry prevent potential competitor firms from entering a profitmaking industry, and the monopolist can therefore continue making economic profits indefinitely in the long run. Revenue maximization by the monopolist In Chapter 4, we saw that whereas the standard theory of the firm assumes that firm behaviour is governed by the goal of profit maximization, alternative theories of firm behaviour argue that firms may pursue other goals instead. One of these is the goal of revenue maximization. If a firm attempts to maximize revenue (rather than profit), how much output will it produce? (b) Loss minimization. Pe profit 0 MC a ATC b Q MR max D = AR Q price, costs, revenue MC price, costs, revenue HL c d Pe loss 0 MR Ql min Figure 5.13 Profit maximization and loss minimization under monopoly: marginal revenue and cost approach. 132 Part 2: Microeconomics ATC D = AR Q HL The answer to this question can be seen in Figure 5.11 above. In panel (a), we can see that total revenue (TR) is maximum when seven units of output are produced. This corresponds to the point where marginal revenue (MR) is equal to zero in panel (b). Therefore the revenue-maximizing monopolist produces that level of output where MR = 0. A comparison of the profit-maximizing firm with the revenue-maximizing firm will reveal that the revenue maximizer will produce a larger quantity of output and sell it at a lower price than the profit maximizer. If you examine Figure 5.13(a), showing the equilibrium position of a profit-maximizing monopolist, you will notice that the profit-maximizing level of output, which occurs where MC = MR, lies to the left of the level of output where MR = 0. Also, in view of the downward-sloping demand curve facing the monopolist, the higher level of output produced where MR = 0 must be sold at a lower price than Pe, which is the price of the profit-maximizing monopolist. Test your understanding 5.6 1 (a) What are the profit-maximizing rules used by the monopolist in the total revenue and cost approach, and in the marginal revenue and cost approach? (b) Do they differ from those used by the perfectly competitive firm? 2 How does the profit-making monopolist determine (a) the price at which output will be sold; (b) whether the firm is earning economic profit, normal profit, or incurring a loss? (c) Is there any difference in methods used by the perfectly competitive firm and the monopolist to determine profits or losses? (...continued) (a) Industry in perfect competition. Test your understanding 5.6 monopolist (a) earns economic profit (show profit per unit and total profit); (b) earns normal profit; (c) incurs losses (show loss per unit and total loss). 4 Why can a monopolist continue to earn economic profits in the long run? Evaluating monopoly and comparing with perfect competition Criticisms of monopoly Higher price, lower output by the monopolist compared to the industry in perfect competition A comparison of monopoly with perfect competition at the level of the industry reveals that price is higher and quantity of output produced lower in monopoly than in a perfectly competitive industry. Figure 5.14 shows the long-run equilibrium positions of a perfectly competitive industry, composed of many small firms, and of a monopoly, which is the entire industry. Panel (a) shows the standard market demand (= MB or marginal benefit) and supply (= MC or marginal cost) curves for the perfectly competitive industry, determining the equilibrium price and quantity, Ppc and Qpc. The equilibrium position of this industry is given by point a, or the point of point of intersection of the industry demand and supply curves. (b) Monopoly. MC a P = MRpc D = MB 0 Qpc Q price, costs, revenue Ppc HL (...continued) 3 Show diagrammatically the case where a S = MC price, costs, revenue HL Pm b a Ppc D = MB 0 Qm Qpc Q MRm Figure 5.14 Lower output and higher price under monopoly. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 133 HL Now let’s suppose that the numerous small firms in the perfectly competitive industry of panel (a) are bought up by one firm, so that what was a perfectly competitive industry becomes a monopoly, shown in panel (b). The MC curve of panel (a), or what was the competitive industry’s supply curve (equal to the sum of all the individual firm supplies, or MC curves), is now the monopolist’s marginal cost curve. The demand curve remains unchanged, but this demand curve takes on a different significance. Under perfect competition, each firm was faced by a perfectly elastic demand curve at the price level Ppc, and the firm’s marginal revenue was equal to price (MRpc = Ppc). But the monopolist is faced with the entire industry demand curve, D, and therefore its marginal revenue (MRm) curve now lies below D. When the monopolist applies the MR = MC rule to determine the profitmaximizing level of output, the result is Qm output; and given the demand curve that determines price for each level of output, the equilibrium price is Pm. Since Qm < Qpc, the industry under monopoly produces a smaller quantity of output than the industry under perfect competition. And since Pm > Ppc, the monopolist sells output at a higher price than the perfectly competitive industry. Higher prices and lower output go against consumers’ interests. Impacts on consumer and producer surplus, and deadweight loss The lower output and higher price of the monopolist have important implications for consumer and producer surplus. As you may remember from our earlier discussion, the perfectly competitive industry is economically efficient because the sum of consumer and producer surplus is maximum. In monopoly, this condition no longer holds, and the industry is therefore inefficient. This can be seen in Figure 5.15, which is the same as Figure 5.14, only consumer and producer surplus are now shown for both the perfectly competitive industry and the monopoly. In panel (a), triangle A represents consumer surplus, while triangle B is producer surplus. Panel (b) shows the inefficiencies that result in monopoly. Note the following: · Triangle C, representing consumer surplus in monopoly, is smaller than triangle A in perfect competition. There are two reasons for this. One is that the higher price of the monopolist (Pm rather than Ppc) has cut into consumer surplus and reduced it. The other is that the lower quantity produced by the monopolist (Qm rather than Qpc) has cut another portion of consumer surplus, shown as triangle E. · The area D, representing producer surplus in monopoly shows that producer surplus has increased by taking away a portion of consumer surplus (due to the monopolist’s higher price), and it has also decreased by losing the triangle F (due to the monopolist’s lower quantity). · The sum of triangles E + F represents deadweight loss, defined as the loss of total (consumer and producer) surplus due to a higher price and lower quantity. The presence of deadweight loss in monopoly indicates that there is economic inefficiency: the sum of consumer plus producer surplus is less in monopoly compared to perfect competition by the amount of the deadweight loss. Moreover, the monopolist gains at the expense of consumers as a portion of consumer surplus is converted into producer surplus. (a) Perfect competition. P Ppc (b) Monopoly. S = MC A consumer surplus P Pm producer surplus B Qpc Q MC C D E F deadweight loss producer surplus D = MB 0 consumer surplus 0 Qm D = MB Qpc MRm Figure 5.15 Consumer and producer surplus and deadweight loss in monopoly, and comparison with perfect competition. 134 Part 2: Microeconomics Q HL MC ATC Pe 0 Qpe HL (b) Monopoly. price, costs, revenue (a) Perfectly competitive firm. price, costs HL MC Pe D 0 Q at long-run equilibrium Pe = min ATC (productive efficiency) Pe = MC (allocative efficiency) ATC Qm Q MR at long-run equilibrium Pe > min ATC (productive inefficiency) Pe > MC (allocative inefficiency) Figure 5.16 Allocative and productive efficiency in perfect competition and monopoly Allocative and productive inefficiency In the above discussion we compared the equilibrium positions of perfect competition and monopoly at the level of the industry. We will now see how economic inefficiency can be explained at the level of the individual firm. Figure 5.16, showing the long-run equilibrium position of the firm in perfect competition and monopoly, indicates that, unlike the perfectly competitive firm, the monopolist does not achieve allocative or productive efficiency. The condition for allocative efficiency is given by P = MC at the profit-maximizing level of output (as explained on page 124). At the profit-maximizing level of output Qm, the monopolist’s price, Pe, is higher than marginal cost, and therefore there is allocative inefficiency and a misallocation of resources. The fact that P > MC means that some consumers place a greater value on the production of the good than it costs the monopolist to produce it. In monopoly there is an underallocation of resources to the good; too few resources are being used to produce it, too little is produced and there is therefore allocative inefficiency, since P > MC at the profitmaximizing level of output. The condition for productive efficiency is given by P = minimum ATC at the profit-maximizing level of output (as explained on page 124). Figure 5.16 indicates that the monopolist does not achieve productive efficiency. At the profit-maximizing level of output, Qm, the monopolist’s price, Pe, is higher than minimum ATC, therefore there is productive inefficiency. The output produced by the monopolist, Qm, is not at the point of minimum ATC. The monopolist produces at higher than minimum average total cost, and there is therefore productive inefficiency, shown by P > minimum ATC at the profitmaximizing level of output. Lack of competition may give rise to higher costs Whereas in perfect competition firms are under constant pressure to produce with the lowest possible costs in order to survive, under monopoly the absence of competitor firms may result in higher costs for many possible reasons such as a poorly motivated workforce, lack of innovation and use of new technologies, poor management, or avoidance of risk. The possibility of making and maintaining economic profits over the long run due to the presence of barriers that prevent the entry of competitors can make the monopolist less concerned about keeping costs as low as possible. This is known as Xinefficiency, defined as producing at a higher than necessary ATC. Note that this is a separate issue from the lack of productive efficiency noted above. Lack of productive efficiency means that while the firm does not produce at the point of minimum ATC, it does produce at some point on the ATC curve. Xinefficiency indicates that the firms’ costs are higher than ATC, as shown in Figure 5.17 (page 136). Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 135 HL HL minimum ATC (prod. efficiency) ATC costs costs > ATC (X-inefficiency) ATC > minimum ATC (prod. inefficiency) 0 Q Figure 5.17 X-inefficiency in monopoly. Possibly not technologically innovative The presence of economic profits over the long run enables monopolists to engage in research and development (R&D) in the quest for new products and new technologies, yet it is possible that the lack of competition deprives them of incentives to pursue such activities aggressively. Under perfect competition, by contrast, firms are under constant pressure to innovate technologically so that they can outperform their competitors, yet the normal profits they earn over the long run do not allow them to finance major R&D activities. Negative impacts on the distribution of income The persistence of economic profits over the long run is another key criticism of monopolies. This problem clearly does not arise in perfect competition. Since monopolies charge higher prices than perfectly competitive firms, this involves a distribution of income away from consumers (who must pay the higher prices) and toward the owners of the monopoly (in the form of economic profits). Benefits of monopoly When a monopoly can achieve substantial economies of scale, it is even possible that its lower costs will permit price and output levels that approach those of a perfectly competitive industry. This is shown in Figure 5.18, where Qm and Pm are the output and price of the standard monopolist, and Qpc and Ppc are the output and price of the perfectly competitive industry. Let’s say now that the monopolist succeeds in achieving significant economies of scale, so that its costs fall, and its MC curve shifts downward to MCes. The intersection of MCes with the monopolist’s MR curve determines the profit-maximizing level of output, Qpc, which is identical to that of the perfectly competitive industry. Moreover, the monopolist will sell output Qpc at price Ppc, which is the price of the perfectly competitive industry. Note that if the MCes curve was even lower, then the monopolist would produce a larger quantity of output and sell it at a lower price than the perfectly competitive industry. Consumers can therefore gain from economies of scale because lower costs of production translate into lower prices, as well as the increased quantity of output. Society as a whole also gains because lower costs of production mean increased efficiency in the use of resources. By contrast, a perfectly competitive firm, due to its very small size, cannot capture economies of scale. P Economies of scale Pm In the beginning of this section we saw that economies of scale are a major barrier to entry in the case of monopoly, particularly in the case of a natural monopoly. Economies of scale lead to falling average costs over a large range of output and firm scale, and when there is a natural monopoly average costs may continue to fall even at the level of output that satisfies market demand. Ppc Extensive economies of scale are a major argument in favour of large firms that can achieve lower costs as they grow in size. 136 Part 2: Microeconomics MC MCes D 0 Qm Qpc Q MRm Figure 5.18 Economies of scale leading to lower price and greater quantity produced by the monopolist. HL Product development and technological innovation Perfect competition and monopoly as guides to understanding the real world It was noted earlier that the protection offered to monopolies by high barriers to entry, shielding them from competition, could make them less likely to innovate than small firms that are continuously subject to the pressures of competition. Yet there are also arguments suggesting that monopolies have good reasons to be more innovative than small competitive firms. First, their economic profits provide them with the ability to finance large research and development (R&D) projects. Second, protection from competition due to high barriers to entry arguably favours innovation and product development, by offering firms the opportunity to enjoy the profits arising from their innovative activities (new inventions, new products, new technologies, etc.); this, after all, is the rationale of awarding firms patent protection for a period of time. Third, it is possible that firms may use product development and technological innovation as a means of creating barriers to entry for new potential rivals; if a firm can develop a new product that potential rivals are unable to produce, the rivals may be less likely to try to enter the industry and compete with the innovating firm. While both these models are unrealistic representations of the real world, they serve as powerful analytical tools for understanding and evaluating real-world situations, as well as for helping governments prescribe policy measures to deal with issues in the industrial sector. Possibility of greater efficiency and lower prices due to technological innovations In the event that monopolies successfully engage in R&D that leads to technological innovations, they may adopt production processes and new technologies that can make them more efficient (i.e. able to produce at a lower cost), and some of these lower costs could be passed to consumers in the form of lower prices. Small, competitive firms have limited abilities to innovate and develop new technologies. Monopoly and government regulation Whereas monopoly may offer some potential benefits to society, there is general agreement among economists that its disadvantages outweigh its advantages. The absence of competition, higher prices, lower quantity of output produced, productive and allocative inefficiencies, higher than necessary costs and negative impacts on income distribution are held to be detrimental to society. Therefore most countries around the world do not encourage private monopolies. In the event that there are natural monopolies, these are usually owned or regulated by the government, so that they will not be permitted to engage in behaviour that goes against society’s interests. HL The model of perfect competition is the basis of an idealized free market economy, where price is the rationing system that supplies answers to the what, how and for whom questions. The market and the price mechanism are the means by which allocative and productive efficiency can be achieved, thereby avoiding waste of resources, and allowing people to achieve mutually advantageous outcomes. The model of monopoly, on the other hand, reveals the consequences of restrictions of competitive forces at the extreme. Whereas pure monopolies are rare in the real world, the monopoly model sheds light on the behaviour of firms under conditions of limited competition. We will therefore return to the topics discussed above in our discussion of the two structures that lie in between perfect competition and monopoly: monopolistic competition and oligopoly. Test your understanding 5.7 1 Using an appropriate diagram, show whether or not the monopolist achieves (a) productive efficiency, and (b) allocative efficiency. 2 Use the concepts of consumer and producer surplus and deadweight loss to show economic inefficiency of monopoly. 3 Why do you think monopoly as a market structure, and monopolistic power generally, come under heavy criticism and are held to be against the society’s best interests? 4 What are some potential benefits of monopolies? 5.3 Monopolistic competition Assumptions of the model The model of monopolistic competition is based on the following assumptions: · There is a large number of firms This assumption is similar to that of perfect competition, where the large firm number ensures that each firm has a Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 137 HL small share of the market, and that each firm acts independently of the others. Moreover, the large number of firms ensures that collusion (agreement to act together so as to secure market power) is not possible. However, though large, the number of firms may not be quite as large as in perfect competition. · There is relatively free entry and exit This assumption is also similar to perfect competition in that there are no significant barriers to entry of new firms into the industry. · There is product differentiation Unlike in perfect competition, where firms within an industry produce and sell an identical product, in monopolistic competition each firm produces and sells a product that is different from any other. Product differentiation can be achieved in a number of ways: ❍ ❍ ❍ ❍ ❍ physical differences: products may differ in size, shape, materials, texture, taste, packaging, etc. (think, for example, of the variety of clothes, shoes, books, processed foods, furniture) quality differences: over and above their physical differences, products can differ in quality location: some firms attempt to differentiate their product by locating themselves in areas that allow easy access for customers, such as, for example, hotels near airports and convenience stores in residential areas services: some firms offer specific services to make their products more attractive, such as home delivery, product demonstrations, free support, warranties, purchase terms, and others product image: some firms attempt to create a favourable image by use of celebrity advertising or endorsements, by brand names, or attractive packaging. Examples of monopolistically competitive industries include book publishing, clothing, shoes, processed foods of all kinds, jewellery, furniture, textiles, drycleaners, petrol (gas) stations, restaurants. Product differentiation and the demand curve Elements of competition and monopoly As the term ‘monopolistic competition’ suggests, this market structure combines elements of both competition and monopoly. It resembles perfect competition in that there are many firms in the industry and that there is freedom of entry and exit. It is like monopoly, on the other hand, because of product differentiation. The reason is that each firm in an industry is a ‘mini’ monopoly in the specific version of the good that it produces. For example, Adidas is a monopoly in Adidas shoes, Nike is a monopoly in Nike shoes, and Puma is a monopoly in Puma shoes. This means that each of these producers faces a downward-sloping demand curve for its product. However, because each of these products is at the same time a substitute for the other, this demand curve is relatively elastic, i.e. it is more elastic than in monopoly, but less elastic than in perfect competition, as shown in Figure 5.19. Let’s examine this idea more closely. In perfect competition, we know that if a firm raises its price, it will lose all its sales to its competitors (Figure 5.19(a)). In monopoly, if a firm raises its price, it will lose some but not all sales, as it is the sole producer of the good, and consumers have no alternative product to which they can turn (Figure 5.19(b)). In monopolistic competition (Figure 5.19(c)), if a firm raises its price, it will lose more sales than the monopolist, because consumers now do have substitute products that they can purchase instead; but it will not lose as many sales as the perfectly competitive firm because of product differentiation (a) Perfect competition. (b) Monopoly. (c) Monopolistic competition. P P P D D D 0 Q 0 Figure 5.19 Demand curves facing the firm under three market structures. 138 Part 2: Microeconomics Q 0 Q HL HL – in other words, the substitutes that are available are not perfect substitutes, as they are under perfect competition. This has important implications for the firm under monopolistic competition. It means that to the extent that consumers can be convinced that the product they are purchasing (for example, Puma shoes) is superior to the available substitutes (Adidas and Nike shoes), then Puma has succeeded in establishing a mini-monopoly for its product. Therefore if the price of Puma shoes increases, only some, and not all, buyers of Puma shoes will switch to other brands. Those who believe that Puma shoes are superior will continue to buy them, in spite of the higher price. Monopolistically competitive firms engage heavily in product development (research that leads to new and/ or better products) leading to product differentiation. The greater the degree of product differentiation, the less elastic will be the demand curve facing the firm (because the less close will be the substitutes), the greater the degree of monopoly power of the firm, and hence the greater the potential for making economic profits. the product is from its substitutes and the more successful the advertising and branding as methods of convincing consumers about the superiority of a product, the less elastic will be the demand curve facing the firm, the greater the monopoly power (the ability to control price), and the larger the firm’s potential to increase short-run economic profits. Monopolistically competitive firms compete with each other on the basis of both price and nonprice competition. The more successful they are in increasing their sales and market share through nonprice competition methods, the less they need to rely on price competition. By contrast, firms that are less able to achieve consumer loyalty for their product, and whose product is less differentiated from substitutes, may have to rely more on price competition (in other words price reductions) in order to increase their sales and market share. Test your understanding 5.8 1 What are the assumptions defining the market model of monopolistic competition? Yet product differentiation by itself is not enough for the creation of monopoly power; it is also important for consumers to be convinced that the product is worth purchasing. Monopolistically competitive firms pursue this objective through advertising and branding (creating brand names for their products). The objective of advertising and branding is to influence consumer tastes in favour of the product. They attempt to achieve this by making the demand curve for a good shift to the right, and by making it rotate so it becomes steeper. These two changes mean that demand increases and it becomes less elastic. The roles of price and non-price competition Price competition among firms occurs when a firm lowers its price in order to attract customers away from rival firms, and thereby increase its sales at the expense of other firms. Non-price competition, by contrast, occurs when firms use methods other than price reductions in order to attract customers away from rivals. The most common forms of non-price competition are product differentiation, advertising and branding. Firms that can attract customers by use of these methods increase their monopoly power and their ability to control the price of their product. They can charge a higher price without risking loss of buyers to rival firms. In general, the more differentiated 2 Think of some examples of monopolistically competitive firms in your neighbourhood. 3 (a) In what ways is a monopolistically competitive firm like a firm in perfect competition; in what ways is it like a monopoly? (b) Explain how and why the demand curve of the monopolistically competitive firm differs from the demand curves of the firm in perfect competition and in monopoly. 4 (a) What do firms in monopolistic competition try to achieve through product differentiation, advertising and branding? (b) How do these activities relate to the demand curve facing the firm? 5 What is (a) price competition, and (b) nonprice competition? (c) How do monopolistically competitive firms compete with each other? 6 Why do you think we never see price competition and non-price competition in (a) perfectly competitive firms, and (b) monopolies? Profit maximization Economic profit or loss in the short run The short-run equilibrium position of the individual firm under monopolistic competition is identical to Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 139 HL (b) Normal profit. economic profit MC Pe ATC D 0 Qe Q MC ATC Pe D 0 Qe MR HL (c) Losses. Q price, costs, revenue price, costs, revenue (a) Economic profit. price, costs, revenue HL losses MC ATC Pe D 0 Qe MR MR Q Figure 5.20 Short-run equilibrium of the firm under monopolistic competition. that of the monopolist, the only difference being in the price elasticity of demand of the demand curve facing the firm, as the demand curve is more elastic and flatter in monopolistic competition than in monopoly. In the short run, the firm can make economic profits, or normal profit, or losses. Each of these possibilities is shown in Figure 5.20. The firm applies the MR = MC rule to find the profit-maximizing or loss-minimizing level of output (Qe), and then for that level of output compares price (given by the demand curve) with ATC to determine profit per unit or loss per unit. In panel (a) the firm is realizing economic profits, since P > ATC at Qe; in panel (b) the firm’s economic profit is exactly zero since P = ATC at Qe, and therefore the firm is earning normal profit; and in panel (c), the firm is incurring losses because P < ATC at Qe. Each of these positions is a possible short-run equilibrium for the firm. Normal profit in the long run The assumption of free entry and exit of firms in the industry is of crucial importance in determining the long-run equilibrium position of the firm (just as under perfect competition). The profitable industry Panel (a) of Figure 5.20 shows the short-run equilibrium position of a firm that is making economic profit. In the long run, when firms can adjust their plant sizes by changing their fixed inputs, the economic profit will draw new entrants into the industry. As new firms enter, they will attract customers away from the existing firms. The impact on the existing firms will be to shift the demand curve they face to the left, in other words the demand facing the firms will decrease as the new firms capture a share of their market. Firms will continue to enter, and the demand curve facing them will keep shifting leftward, until it reaches the point where it is tangent to (it just touches) the ATC curve. Here, the firms in the industry will be earning only normal profits, and entry of new firms into the industry will stop. Figure 5.21 shows the long-run equilibrium position of the firm under monopolistic competition. At the level of output where MR = MC, P = ATC, therefore economic profit is zero and each firm is earning normal profit. Note that this figure is the same as panel (b) of Figure 5.20, where it happens that a firm is earning normal profit in the short run. The unprofitable industry In monopolistic competition, over the long run, industries in which firms earn economic profits will attract new entrants, while loss-making firms in unprofitable (loss-making) industries will shut down their plants and leave the industry. The process of entry and exit of firms in the long run ensures that economic profit or loss is zero and all firms earn normal profit. Let’s examine the process of adjustment. 140 Part 2: Microeconomics In panel (c) of Figure 5.20 we see the short-run equilibrium of a loss-making firm. The presence of losses will make some firms shut down completely and leave the industry. As they do so, their customers will switch their purchases to the remaining firms, which will experience an increase in demand for their product. This will show up as a rightward shift of the demand curve facing them, and this process will continue until losses disappear and firms are earning normal profit. As before, this will occur when the demand curve is tangent to (just touches) the ATC curve, so that at the level of output where MR = MC, HL HL price, costs, revenue MC ATC Pe D 0 Qe Qc MR Q Figure 5.21 Long-run equilibrium of the firm under monopolistic competition. P = ATC, and economic profit is zero. Once again the long-run equilibrium will be as shown in Figure 5.21, where the firm is earning zero economic profit. Criticisms of the model · A difficulty with the above analysis is that it suggests that firms make decisions only on quantity of output and price, whereas in fact, as we have seen, a major dimension of their decisions involves non-price competition (product development and advertising). This means that profit-maximization decisions are more complex than this simple model suggests, since they involve additional decisions on research and development (R&D) for product differentiation, as well as advertising, all of which lead to some monopoly power. · In the real world, entry into the industry may not be as free as the model suggests, and this is another factor leading to some monopoly power. · Another difficulty presented by this model is that in view of product differentiation, it is not possible to derive an industry demand curve, as each product is different from the others. Therefore we can only examine monopolistic competition at the level of the firm. Efficiency in monopolistic competition Allocative and productive inefficiency As we know, allocative efficiency is given by the condition P = MC, and productive efficiency by the condition P = minimum ATC. Figure 5.21, illustrating the long-run equilibrium position of the firm under monopolistic competition, reveals that neither allocative nor productive efficiency is achieved. Comparing price with marginal cost along the vertical line at the equilibrium level of output, Qe, we can see that price is higher than MC, indicating that there is an underallocation of resources to the production of the good: society would have liked to have more units of the good produced. Also, price is greater than minimum average total cost, and therefore average cost is higher than what is optimal from society’s point of view. Excess capacity A firm’s capacity output is that output at which ATC is minimum; this is the output level at which the firm’s plant capacity is fully used. In Figure 5.21, capacity output is Qc. Yet the firm does not produce output Qc; the profit-maximizing rule MR = MC makes it produce output Qe in order to maximize profit, which is smaller than Qc. The difference between capacity output and profit-maximizing output is called excess capacity. Excess capacity is the amount of output that is lost when firms underuse their plant and produce a level of output that does not minimize average total cost. If all firms produced at the point of minimum ATC, the same quantity of total (industry) output could have been produced by fewer firms, and the costs to society would have been lower. Excess capacity results from the firm’s downwardsloping demand curve. (Only if the demand curve were horizontal could it be tangent to the ATC curve at its minimum point, as in perfect competition.) Excess capacity is therefore the result of product differentiation, which gives rise to the downwardsloping demand curve. (Note that excess capacity is closely related to productive inefficiency: they are both the result of P > minimum ATC.) There are numerous examples of excess capacity: restaurants with empty tables, gas (petrol) stations with no one at the pump, retail outlets of all kinds with few customers, hotels with empty rooms. Yet product differentiation gives rise to greater product variety for consumers. It is often argued that excess capacity (or productive inefficiency) is the ‘price’ consumers must pay for product variety. The greater the product variety, the larger will be the excess capacity, and the greater the productive inefficiency Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 141 HL (and the closer will the firm be to monopoly). By contrast, the less the product variety, the lower the excess capacity and the greater the productive efficiency (the closer will be the firm to perfect competition). Comparison of monopolistic competition with other market structures The discussion above has covered many of the relevant issues that arise in a comparison of monopolistic competition with perfect competition and monopoly. What follows is simply a summary of the key differences between the market models. Monopolistic competition and perfect competition · Normal profit According to the models, firms in both perfect and monopolistic competition achieve zero economic profit (normal profit) in the long run. However, the similarity ends here because of the different price elasticities of demand of the demand curve facing each firm. · Productive and allocative efficiency Whereas the perfectly competitive firm achieves both productive and allocative efficiency in long-run equilibrium, the monopolistically competitive firm achieves neither. Fewer than optimal resources are allocated to the production of the good, and average cost is not minimum at the point of production. · Excess capacity Since the firm under perfect competition produces the level of output where ATC is minimum, it is making full use of its plant and has no excess capacity. The firm under monopolistic competition produces a lower level of output than that where ATC is minimum, and therefore has excess capacity. · Product variety Whereas all firms under perfect competition produce the identical product, under monopolistic competition firms go to great lengths to differentiate their products. From the consumer’s perspective, product variety is usually an advantage; perfect competition cannot offer this advantage. Monopolistic competition and monopoly · Normal and economic profits Whereas the firm under monopolistic competition earns normal profit in the long run, the monopoly can earn economic profits due to high barriers to entry that prevent new entrants from entering the industry. · Allocative and productive efficiency Both these market structures face downward-sloping demand curves, 142 Part 2: Microeconomics and therefore both have MR curves that lie below the demand curve. This means that at the profitmaximizing level of output (found by MR = MC), P > MC for both (i.e. no allocative efficiency). Also, P > minimum ATC for both (i.e. no productive efficiency). · Competition and costs Competition between firms under monopolistic competition puts a downward pressure on costs as firms compete with each other; these competitive pressures may force less efficient firms to leave the industry. The absence of competition in monopoly does not exert such a downward pressure on costs. · Competition and prices Free entry and exit under monopolistic competition drives economic profits down to zero in the long run, and allows prices to be lower for the consumer than is possible under monopoly, where barriers to entry allow the firm to maintain profits over the long run. · Economies of scale Some economies of scale may be achieved by the firm under monopolistic competition, but the potential for this is much greater under monopoly, which can be to the benefit of the consumer (see the discussion under monopoly). · Research and development The evidence is ambiguous on the incentives faced by monopolies to engage in R&D; however, the economic profits that they can earn over the long run puts them in a better position with respect to financing R&D. Test your understanding 5.9 1 Show diagrammatically the case where a firm in monopolistic competition (a) earns economic profit (show profit per unit and total profit); (b) earns normal profit; (c) incurs losses (show loss per unit and total loss). 2 What is the role of free entry and exit of firms in monopolistic competition in the adjustment from short-run to long-run equilibrium? 3 (a) Show diagrammatically the firm’s longrun equilibrium position in monopolistic competition. (b) Comment on whether the firm achieves economic profit or normal profit in long-run equilibrium. 4 To what extent does the firm in monopolistic competition achieve efficiency? (Refer to the different efficiency concepts discussed in this section.) (...continued) HL HL Test your understanding 5.9 (...continued) 5 Explain what is meant by the idea that excess capacity is the ‘price’ of product variety. 6 Evaluate the desirability of monopolistic competition from a social perspective. 5.4 Oligopoly Assumptions of oligopoly Oligopoly is more complex than the other market models because there is not just one type of oligopoly; as we will see there are several models of oligopolistic behaviour. However, the following characteristics are shared by all of these: · A small number of large firms The term ‘oligopoly’ derives from the Greek word meaning ‘few sellers’. Oligopolistic industries tend to be dominated by a small number of large firms, though in any one industry the firms are likely to vary in size. · High barriers to entry All the barriers to entry discussed under monopoly are also relevant to oligopoly. They include economies of scale, which make it prohibitive for new firms starting on a small scale to compete due to very high costs (for example, the aircraft and car industries); or legal barriers such as patents (the pharmaceutical industry); or control of natural resources (such as oil, copper, silver); or aggressive tactics such as advertising or threats of takeovers of potential new firms. An additional barrier to entry in oligopoly includes high start-up costs (the costs of starting a new firm) associated with developing a new or differentiated product. Many established oligopolies spend enormous sums on product differentiation and advertising, making it very difficult for new firms to match such expenditures. In addition, oligopolistic firms share some further characteristics that make them uniquely different from any other market structure: · Mutual interdependence Firms in perfect and monopolistic competition, due to their large numbers in the industry, behave independently of each other, so that when they make decisions such as how much output to produce, they do not take the possible actions of other firms into consideration. By contrast, the small number of firms in oligopolistic industries makes the firms mutually interdependent; in other words, decisions taken by one firm affect other firms in the industry, so that they depend on each other. If any one firm changes its behaviour, this can have a major impact on the demand curve facing the other firms. Therefore firms are keenly aware of the actions of their rivals. Mutual interdependence explains why oligopolistic firms behave differently from firms under other market structures. · Strategic behaviour Strategic behaviour is based on plans of action that take into account rivals’ possible courses of action. It is similar to playing a card game, or chess, where each player’s actions are based on the expected actions and reactions of its rival(s). Strategic behaviour of oligopolistic firms is the result of their mutual interdependence. For example, a firm plans a course of action X if its rivals follow a specific policy, and it plans course of action Y if its rivals follow a different policy. Under oligopoly, firms planning their strategies make great efforts to guess the actions and reactions of their rivals in order to formulate their own strategy. · Conflicting incentives Firms under oligopoly face incentives that conflict, or clash with each other: ❍ · Differentiated or homogeneous (undifferentiated) products Firms under oligopoly may produce differentiated products or undifferentiated products. Examples of oligopolies producing differentiated products include pharmaceuticals, cars, aircraft, breakfast cereals, cigarettes, refrigerators and freezers, cameras, tyres, bicycles, motorcycles, soaps, detergents. Examples of oligopolies producing undifferentiated products are fewer; examples include oil, steel, aluminium, copper, cement. ❍ Incentive to collude The term collusion refers to an agreement between the firms to limit competition between them. Firms in oligopoly are especially concerned to limit price competition between them as much as possible. By colluding, firms reduce uncertainties resulting from not knowing how rivals will behave, and maximize profits for the industry as a whole. Collusion can involve an agreement to divide the market between the firms in some specific way (such as according to market shares), or to limit quantity to be produced by the industry as a whole and therefore fix the price; the result involves limiting competition and increasing industry profits. Incentive to compete At the same time, each oligopolistic firm also faces an incentive to compete with its rivals, in the hope that in this Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 143 HL Clearly, firms in an industry cannot both collude and compete; they must do one or the other. There is significant diversity in the behaviour of oligopolistic firms, and for this reason there is no one theory, or model, of oligopoly. Instead, there are a number of models, each of which attempts to explain some aspects of oligopolistic behaviour, but none of which is wholly satisfactory as a general theory of oligopoly. The models can be classified under two main categories: collusive and non-collusive oligopoly. We will discuss each of these in turn. Test your understanding 5.10 1 Identify the main characteristics of the oligopolistic market structure. Suppose the firms of an industry decide to form a cartel by fixing price. Figure 5.22 illustrates how the cartel maximizes profit. Note that this figure is identical to Figure 5.13(a), which illustrates profit maximization for a monopolist. price, costs, revenue way it will capture at least a portion of its rivals’ market shares and profits, thereby increasing its profits at the expense of the other firms. HL MC a Pe b profit 0 ATC Q MR D = AR max Q Figure 5.22 Profit maximization by a price-fixing cartel. 2 Why do firms under oligopoly face conflicting objectives? 3 Are oligopolistic firms independent or interdependent? What kind of behaviour does this characteristic make them engage in (that tends to resemble a card game)? Collusive oligopoly It was noted above that firms under oligopoly face an incentive to collude, the main objective being to coordinate prices, limit competition between them, and reduce uncertainties. Collusive oligopoly refers to the type of oligopoly where firms agree to restrict output and fix the price, in order to limit competition, increase monopoly power and increase profits. Collusion may be formal, usually taking the form of a cartel, or it may be informal, such as price leadership. Formal collusion: cartels A cartel is a formal agreement between firms in an industry to undertake concerted actions to limit competition. The agreement may involve limiting and fixing the quantity to be produced by each (setting production quotas); fixing the price at which output can be sold; setting restrictions on non-price competition (such as advertising); dividing the market according to geographical or other factors; or agreeing to set up barriers to entry. Whatever the case, the objective is to increase the monopoly power of the firms within the industry. 144 Part 2: Microeconomics In effect, when the firms in an industry collude (agree to limit competition between them), they collectively behave like a monopoly. In Figure 5.22 the demand curve and marginal revenue curve shown are for the industry as a whole. The MC curve is the sum of all the MC curves of all the firms in the cartel. The cartel equates MR with MC to find the cartel’s profit-maximizing level of output, Qπmax, and then determines price Pe (given by the demand curve). It is then a question of dividing up industry output Qπmax between all the firms, or deciding how much of the total quantity will be produced by each firm. One way this can be done is to agree on what share of the market each firm will have based on historical market shares. Another way is that firms may agree to compete with each other for market shares using non-price competition (product differentiation and advertising). The best-known example of a cartel is OPEC (the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries), composed of a group of 13 oil-producing countries. OPEC periodically tries to raise the world price of oil by cutting back on its total output. Each member country is assigned an output level (quota) that it is permitted to produce. The restricted quantity of oil results in a higher price. HL HL Firms participating in a cartel have much to gain in terms of monopoly power and increased profits; however, there are a number of problems involved with setting up and maintaining a cartel, to which we turn next. Obstacles to forming and maintaining cartels The following factors make it difficult for a cartel to be established and maintained: · Cost differences between firms Ideally, each firm would like to have a share of output that will allow it to equate its MC with MR, as this will maximize profit for each individual firm as well as for the cartel as a whole; however, this is extremely difficult in practice, since each firm faces different cost curves (it is most unlikely that all the firms will have identical costs). Since the price that is agreed upon by the cartel is common to all the firms, firms with higher average costs will have lower profits, while the lower cost firms will enjoy higher profits. In general, cost differences between firms are a major constraint to the successful formation of a cartel because of the difficulties this entails in agreeing on a common price and on how to allocate the output among the firms. · Firms face different demand curves Firms are likely to face different demand curves partly because they have different market shares and partly because of product differentiation. The more differentiated the product, the greater the differences between demand curves facing the firms are likely to be. Differences in the demand curves mean difficulties in reaching agreement on a common price. · Number of firms The larger the number of firms, the more difficult it is to arrive at an agreement regarding price and the allocation of output, as the greater number of contending views make consensus and compromise more difficult to achieve. · The possibility of cheating Every firm in a cartel faces an incentive to cheat on the agreement, by offering to secretly lower the price for some buyers, or else offer other concessions. A firm that cheats can increase its market share and its profit at the expense of other firms. But if many firms cheat, or if cheating is discovered by other firms in the cartel, then the cartel is in danger of collapsing. · The possibility of a price war A possible outcome of one or more firms cheating on the cartel agreement is a price war where one firm’s price cut is matched by a retaliatory price cut by other firm. Say one firm decides to cheat on the cartel by secretly lowering its price. If another firm discovers the cheating firm, it may react by lowering its price as well; there may follow a succession of price cuts as firms try to capture market shares from their rivals. The result of a price war is to make all the firms of an industry collectively worse off due to the low resulting prices and lower profits. It is even possible for a price war to result in prices that are lower than average costs, thus giving rise to losses for the firms. Price wars eventually wind down and firms return to higher price policies. · Recessions During recessions (periods of low or falling incomes and low levels of economic activity) sales fall and profits are reduced; at such times firms have an increased incentive to lower their prices and cheat on the agreement in order to increase their sales at the expense of other firms, thus endangering the survival of the cartel. Economic stability (the absence of recession or inflation) makes it easier for firms to plan for the future and this facilitates agreements between the firms. · Potential entry into the industry If a cartel is successful, it will make large economic profits, and this will encourage new entry into the industry. If there are new entrants, increased industry supply will drive price down and will cut into the cartel’s profits. The cartel’s long-run survival therefore depends on high barriers to entry that block potential new entrants. · The industry lacks a dominant firm The presence of a dominant firm facilitates reaching agreement, as this firm can assume a leadership position in the negotiations leading to the agreement. For example, in the case of OPEC, the dominant member of the cartel is Saudi Arabia, which is also the largest producer of oil among all the members. The lack of a dominant firm makes agreement among the cartel members more difficult to reach. · Legal barriers Cartels are illegal in many countries, including the European Union, the United Kingdom and the United States. The reason is that they restrict competition and are therefore held to be against consumers’ and society’s best interests. Informal collusion: price leadership and other approaches The difficulties involved in establishing and maintaining cartels as well as their illegality sometimes make firms turn towards informal types of collusion, where the objective once again is to avoid competitive price-cutting, coordinate prices, limit competition and reduce uncertainties. One type of informal collusion is price leadership, where a dominant firm Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 145 HL HL in the industry (which may be the largest, or it may be the one with lowest costs) sets a price and also initiates any price changes. The remaining firms in the industry in effect become price-takers, accepting the price that has been established by the leader. The agreement binds the firms as far as price goes, but they are then free to engage in non-price competition. A characteristic of price leadership arrangements is that price changes tend to be infrequent, and are undertaken by the leader only when major demand or cost changes occur. Examples of industries that have at different times followed the price leadership model include US Steel, Kellogg’s (breakfast cereals), and R. J. Reynolds (cigarettes). Obstacles to sustained price leadership are similar to the obstacles faced by cartels: · Cost differences between firms, particularly in cases where there is significant product differentiation, make it difficult for firms to follow a leader. · Whereas some firms may follow the leader, others may not, in which case the leader risks losing sales and market share in the event it initiates a price increase that is not followed. · Firms still face the incentive to cheat by lowering their price (below that of the leader) in order to capture market share and increase profits; a breakdown in price leadership can result in a price war among firms where successive rounds of price cuts leave the firms in the industry worse off due to lower profits. · High industry profits can attract new firms that will cut into market shares and profits of established firms and endanger the price leadership arrangement. · Price leadership, depending on where and how it is practised, may or may not be legal. Another type of informal collusion may involve informal agreements where the firms agree to use a rule for coordinating prices. One such rule is limit pricing, where the firms informally agree to a set a price that is lower than the profit-maximizing price, so as to achieve lower than the highest possible profits and therefore discourage new firms from entering the industry (recall that new firms are attracted to highly profitable industries). With limit pricing, firms may in effect end up sacrificing some profit in order to avoid attracting new firms into the industry. Whenever some agreement is reached on a method of price coordination, market shares can then be determined on the basis of non-price competition. 146 Part 2: Microeconomics Test your understanding 5.11 1 What do firms in oligopoly try to achieve through collusion? 2 (a) What is a cartel and how is it related to collusive oligopoly? (b) Show how a cartel resembles a monopoly. 3 What are the obstacles to forming and maintaining cartels? 4 Identify other approaches that may be used by firms in oligopoly to achieve collusion. Non-collusive oligopoly: the kinked demand curve It is generally observed in the real world that prices of oligopolistic industries tend to be inflexible or ‘sticky’; once a particular price is reached, it tends to be relatively stable over extended periods of time. Moreover, in situations when prices do change, they tend to change in unison for all the firms in an industry. Price inflexibility can be easily explained in the case of collusive oligopoly, since in this case firms collude to coordinate prices. However, price inflexibility is also observed in the real world in situations of non-collusive oligopoly, where oligopolistic firms do not agree, whether formally or informally, to fix prices or collaborate in some way. The kinked demand curve is a model that has been developed to explain price inflexibility of oligopolistic firms that do not collude, and is illustrated in Figure 5.23. In this model, firms do not make formal or informal agreements with each other on how to fix or coordinate prices; instead, their pricing behaviour is strongly influenced by their expectations of how rival firms will react if they undertake a price change. These expectations are reflected in the kinked (i.e. not straight) demand curve facing each firm, as shown in the figure. Note that corresponding to the kinked demand curve is a broken marginal revenue curve; the break in MR occurs exactly at the point of the kink in the demand curve, and is a reflection of the abrupt drop in marginal revenue at the point where the demand curve suddenly bends. Imagine that there are three firms, A, B, and C, each producing output Q1 and selling it at price P1; this price–quantity combination corresponds to point Z on the demand curve, or the point of the kink. We now want to see why the firms perceive the demand curve that faces them to have this peculiar shape. HL This simple model illustrates three important points: HL P · Firms that do not collude are forced to take into account P1 the actions of their rivals in making pricing decisions, otherwise they risk lowering their revenues and profits, which in turn could lead to price instability. The kinked demand curve model illustrates the interdependence of oligopolistic firms. Z · Even though the firms do not collude, there is still price stability; firms are reluctant to change their price because of the likely actions of their rivals, which could result in lower profits for the firm initiating price changes. D 0 Q1 Q MR Figure 5.23 The kinked demand curve. Let’s say that firm A contemplates a price change, but before changing (increasing or decreasing) its price, it tries to predict how firms B and C will react, and what will be the consequences of their reaction. Firm A’s line of reasoning is the following: · If I raise my price, what will A and B do? They are unlikely to increase their price as well, because if they continue to sell at price P1, many of my customers will leave me and start buying from B and C. It follows that B’s and C’s market share will increase, while my market share will fall. It is therefore not in my interests to increase my price. My demand curve is relatively elastic above Z, because for any price increase I will face a relatively large decrease in sales and revenues, and my profits may fall (though not all my customers will leave me because of my differentiated product). · If I decrease my price, what will A and B do? They are now likely to decrease their price as well, because if they do not, I will capture a large portion of their sales, and I would be better off at their expense. If they decrease their price, then I will capture only a very small part of their market shares. My demand curve is relatively inelastic below Z, because for any price decrease I will have only a very small increase in sales and revenues, and my profits may fall. It is therefore not in my interests to drop my price. · I should therefore not change my price, and should continue selling at P1. This line of reasoning is the same for all three firms, A, B and C. · Firms do not compete with each other on the basis of price; they do not try to increase their sales by attracting customers through lower prices. A lower price not only invites price cuts by rivals, with resulting lower profits for all the firms involved, but also, if some firms overreact with price cutting, there is a risk of setting off a price war. In the kinked demand curve model, shown in Figure 5.23, each firm perceives the demand curve it faces to be elastic for prices above Z and inelastic for prices below Z. If one firm raises its price above Z, the others will not follow; if it lowers its price below Z, the others will match the price decrease. In either case, the firm will be worse off. Therefore no firm takes the initiative to change its price, and they all remain ‘stuck’ at point Z for extended periods of time. However, the model is subject to limitations: · It cannot explain how the firms arrived at point Z, or the point of the kink in the demand curve. · It is inappropriate as an explanation of oligopolistic pricing behaviour during periods of inflation, when prices are observed to increase, and during recession, when prices often drop, to the point that at times they can initiate price wars. Test your understanding 5.12 1 How does non-collusive oligopoly differ from collusive oligopoly? 2 a) Show the kinked demand curve model diagrammatically. (b) How can you account for the shape of the kinked demand curve (use the elasticity concept in your answer). (c) What does this model try to explain? (d) What are the limitations of the model? Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 147 HL HL The role of non-price competition in oligopoly Unlike firms in monopolistic competition that compete on the basis of both price and non-price competition, oligopolistic firms go to great lengths to avoid price competition; in other words, they avoid trying to increase market shares by cutting prices. Firms in oligopoly are better off coordinating their pricing behaviour where they can (through formal or informal collusion), and when they do not collude they still avoid competitive price-cutting as this is likely to result in lowering their profits. However, oligopolistic firms usually do engage in intense nonprice competition. Non-price competition, as we learned in Section 5.3, involves efforts by firms to increase their market share by methods other than price, which typically include product development, advertising and branding. This applies to firms under both collusive and non-collusive oligopoly. Non-price competition is very important in oligopoly for the following reasons: · Oligopolistic firms very often have considerable financial resources (due to large profits) that they can devote to both R&D (research and development) and advertising. Whereas monopolistically competitive firms also engage in non-price competition, the resources at their disposal for these purposes are generally not as significant. · The development of new products provides firms with a competitive edge; they increase their monopoly power, demand for the firm’s product becomes less elastic, and successful products give rise to opportunities for substantially increased sales and profits. · Product differentiation can increase a firm’s profit position without creating risks for immediate retaliation by rivals. It takes time and resources for rival firms to develop new competitive products. It would be very difficult to engage in a ‘new product war’ as opposed to a price war, in which price cuts can be very quickly matched or exceeded by rival firms. Evaluating oligopoly Criticisms of oligopoly We have seen that oligopolistic firms avoid price competition and often engage in practices that aim at fixing or coordinating prices, the objective being to gain monopoly power. To the extent that they succeed in avoiding price competition, they achieve a considerable degree of monopoly power, and are therefore subject to the same criticisms as monopoly: 148 Part 2: Microeconomics · Neither productive nor allocative efficiency is achieved. · Higher prices are charged and lower quantities of output are produced than under competitive conditions. · There may be higher production costs due to lack of competitive pressures. · Firms may possibly be less technologically innovative. · They contribute to a more unequal distribution of income. For more details on each of these points, see the earlier section on monopoly (page 127). In addition, it may be argued that oligopoly may be an even less socially desirable market structure than monopoly because: · Whereas there is anti-monopoly legislation in many countries that protects against the abuse of monopoly power, the difficulties of detecting and proving collusion among oligopolistic firms means that such firms may actually behave like monopolies by colluding and yet may get away with it. Benefits of oligopoly The benefits of oligopoly are also similar to the benefits of monopoly: · Economies of scale can be achieved due to the large size of oligopolistic firms, leading to lower production costs to the benefit of society and the consumer (through lower prices). · Product development and technological innovations can be pursued due to the large economic (supernormal) profits from which research funds can be drawn. This benefit of oligopoly is more important than in the case of monopoly, since nonprice competition forces firms to be innovative in order to increase their market share and profits. · Technological innovations that improve efficiency and lower costs of production may be passed to consumers in the form of lower prices. For more details on these points see the earlier section on monopoly. Over and above the benefits of oligopoly that are similar to monopoly, oligopoly also offers the following advantage: · Product development leads to increased product variety, thus providing consumers with greater choice (monopoly does not offer product differentiation and variety). HL HL Advantages and disadvantages of advertising (supplementary material) Oligopolies engage heavily in advertising as part of non-price competition. The only other market structure where advertising figures prominently is monopolistic competition, where firms also engage in non-price competition. Therefore many of the issues discussed here apply also to monopolistic competition. Firms under perfect competition obviously do not advertise as they produce a homogeneous product, whereas under monopoly there is no need for advertising as the monopolist is the sole producer of a good. Economists disagree on the efficiency aspects of advertising. On the positive side, the following arguments suggest that advertising can increase overall efficiency: · Advertising provides consumers with information about alternative products; it makes it easier for consumers to search for the product that is best suited to their needs, and therefore reduces time and effort that could be wasted searching for alternative products. · Advertising may create needs that consumers would not otherwise have; this ultimately results in a waste of resources as consumers end up buying goods and services that they would not have desired had they not been influenced by advertising. Some of the points noted under advantages and disadvantages of advertising contradict each other. It is possible that different circumstances give rise to different (positive or negative) results, though it is also possible that economists sometimes interpret the same observations differently, thus coming up with conflicting conclusions. Test your understanding 5.13 1 (a) Why is non-price competition important to firms in oligopoly? (b) Why do oligopolistic firms avoid price competition? 2 Evaluate oligopoly, referring to advantages and disadvantages from a social perspective. 3 (optional) What are the likely advantages and disadvantages of advertising? · Advertising by rival firms increases competition between them, and therefore contributes to decreasing their monopoly power. · Advertising facilitates the introduction of new products by providing the relevant information to consumers; in this way, competition (non-price) increases between firms. · By facilitating the introduction of new products, advertising can help lower barriers to entry of new firms into the industry. · By facilitating the introduction of new products, advertising can also provide firms with an added incentive to engage in research and development for the development of new products. On the negative side, the following arguments suggest that advertising contributes to lowering efficiency: · Huge sums spent on advertising by large oligopolistic firms can create barriers to the entry of new firms that cannot match such expenditures. · Advertising increases costs of production and ultimately means higher prices for consumers. · Successful advertising increases a firm’s monopoly power. · Consumers may become confused and misled as to the qualities of the product, and may end up paying higher prices for inferior products. 5.5 The theory of contestable markets In our study of market structures, we have seen that the degree of competition between firms varies enormously, ranging from perfect competition where there is a large number of firms, to no competition when there is a single firm in the market. In between the two extremes lie monopolistic competition, where there is a relatively large number of firms, and oligopoly, where there is only a small number of firms. The degree of competition in an industry appears to be inversely related to the number of firms in the industry: the fewer the firms, the less the competition, and the greater will be the potential for monopoly power and economic profits. The theory of contestable markets is an approach to the study of market structures developed recently which suggests that the degree of competition achieved in a market may not depend on the actual number of firms in the industry after all, but rather on the ease with which potential firms can enter and leave an industry. This is a theory with possible applications to markets where there are a few large sellers (oligopoly), or there is a single large seller (monopoly). Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 149 HL HL It is argued in this approach that what matters more in achieving competitive conditions for firms is not so much whether they face actual competition from existing rivals, but whether they face potential competition from potential new entrants. If the barriers to entry are low, then there is a constant threat that new firms may enter the industry. And if the costs of exiting the industry are also low (that is, a new firm can easily leave the industry by selling its assets or transferring them for use in another industry), then a potential new entrant will be less concerned about the possibility of losses from the purchase of costly fixed inputs. The implication then is that even if the industry is a monopoly or an oligopoly, the threat of new firms will make the established firms behave as if they were in a competitive industry. If this is the case, competition will be limited and the conclusions of the traditional theory of the firm, as discussed in this chapter, still hold. The contestable markets theory is in the process of being empirically tested, and no conclusions have as yet emerged regarding its validity. The credibility of this theory depends crucially on the extent of barriers to entry and costs of exit from the industry. For a market to be contestable, there must be low entry barriers and low exit costs. If these conditions hold, the following conclusions can be drawn: 5.6 Price discrimination · If a market is contestable, the firm(s) will behave in The single-price firm versus the price discriminating firm a competitive way. · Costs of production will be lower and the extent of inefficiencies will be reduced. · Lower costs of production mean lower prices for the consumer. · Government policy should be directed towards lowering barriers of entry and costs of exit in industries so to make them more contestable and therefore make the firm(s) behave competitively. A contestable market is a market that new firms can enter and exit at a low cost. In a contestable market, the threat of possible new entrants causes existing firms in the industry to behave competitively (resulting in greater efficiency and lower prices) even though the industry may be a monopoly or an oligopoly. The theory of contestable markets has been criticized because it presumes that barriers to entry and costs of exit are low in oligopolistic and monopolistic industries, whereas in fact in many industries they may be quite high. High barriers to entry mean a limited threat of new entrants; high costs of exit mean a potential entrant will be less likely to risk entering. 150 Part 2: Microeconomics Test your understanding 5.14 1 Explain the theory of contestable markets. 2 What conditions must hold for this theory to be valid? 3 If the theory is valid, how would it change the conclusions of the traditional theory of the firm? Definition and conditions for price discrimination So far in our study of firm behaviour we have assumed that firms under all market structures charge a single price for all units of output they sell. This applies not only to firms under perfect competition (where price is constant for all units of output), but also to firms under monopoly, oligopoly and monopolistic competition. In monopoly, for example, we have seen that while price varies according to the quantity of output that can be sold, once the firm makes a choice on what quantity of output it will sell, all the units of output are sold at the same price. In Figure 5.10(b) above, if the firm chooses to produce Q1 units of output, all of that output will be sold at the single price P1. If it had chosen to produce Q2 units of output, all of that output would be sold at the single price P2. Firms that sell all of their output at the same price do not practise price discrimination. Yet firms often find that they can increase their profits by selling their product at different prices. Price discrimination is the practice of charging a different price for the same product when the price difference is not justified by differences in costs of production. (If price differences are due to differences in a firm’s costs of production, then they do not qualify as ‘price discrimination’.) HL HL Price discrimination allows firms to increase their profit because it offers them opportunities to reduce consumer surplus and convert it into profits, or reduce deadweight loss and convert that into profits, or a combination of both. We will see how this is done in the discussion that follows. Conditions for price discrimination In order for a firm to be able to practice price discrimination, the following conditions must be satisfied: The price discriminating firm must have some market power In all types of price discrimination, the price discriminating firm must have some degree of market power, or some ability to control price; in other words, it must face a downward-sloping demand curve. Price discrimination can in fact occur in all the market structures except perfect competition. Natural monopolies (such as electricity, gas and water companies), having a significant degree of market power, practise price discrimination whenever they can. For example, electricity companies often charge lower prices at night than during the day for consumption of electricity. Water companies often charge different prices according to the quantity of water consumed. Oligopolistic firms also often practise price discrimination; for example, airlines as a rule charge higher fares during peak travel seasons such as during summer months. Similarly, firms under monopolistic competition also price discriminate: movie theatres may charge different prices to children or older people, or different prices according to viewing time; restaurants often offer discounts (lower prices) for particular groups of customers or on particular days. On the other hand, the firm under perfect competition can sell any amount of its output at the single price that has been determined in the market; if it tries to increase its price to some customers, it will lose those customers to different sellers; and it would have no reason to lower its price for some customers since it can sell its entire output at the higher market price. Therefore the perfectly competitive firm has no possibility of charging different prices for the same good. Separation of consumers as individuals or into groups Consumers must be separated from each other on the basis of some characteristic, such as time, geography, age, gender, technology, income or other factors. Firms differentiate their prices on the basis of these characteristics. For example, movie theatres and hotels often charge lower prices to older people and children (consumer separation by age); telephone companies sometimes offer lower rates for evening or weekend calls (consumer separation by time); publishers often charge different prices for the same books in different countries (consumer separation by geography); car salespeople sometimes try to sell cars at different prices by guessing customers’ income levels (consumer separation by income). No possibility of resale The price discriminating firm must ensure that it is not possible (or at least it is very difficult and costly) for any consumer to buy at the low price and resell at the higher price. If resale were possible or easy, consumers would avoid purchasing from the firm at the higher price, and would try to buy the product from other consumers who had bought at the lower price. In some cases, resale is impossible due to the nature of the product, especially where services are involved, such as in the case of medical services, legal services and education. Different willingness to pay or different price elasticities of demand Consumers must have a different willingness to pay for the product or different price elasticities of demand. The idea of willingness to pay is very closely related to demand, which we studied in Chapter 2, page 32. As you may remember, the demand curve shows what price the consumer is willing to pay in order to get different quantities of a good (ceteris paribus). There are two points to bear in mind about willingness to pay that are important for our purposes. One is that different people have a different willingness to pay for the same good, because they have different tastes and preferences, and different incomes. This is an important reason why different people have different demands for a good. The second point is that as the available quantity of a good increases, an individual consumer’s willingness to pay for the good falls (as a result of the principle of falling marginal benefit; see Section 2.2 for a review of these concepts). This is entirely consistent with what we know about the law of demand, according to which any one consumer is willing to buy more of a good as its price falls; hence the downward slope of the demand curve. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 151 HL Types of price discrimination There are three types of price discrimination, to which we now turn. First degree: discrimination among individual consumers First degree price discrimination is based on the principle that each consumer has a different willingness to pay for a good, because of different preferences or income. The firm sells each unit of the product to a different consumer, and charges the maximum price for each unit of the good sold that the consumer is willing to pay. This type of discrimination is also known as perfect price discrimination, or ‘discrimination among individual consumers’, because each consumer pays a different price. Perfect price discrimination is extremely difficult, if at all possible, to achieve in practice, for the following reasons: · It presupposes that the firm has detailed knowledge of each consumer’s demand, and therefore knows the maximum price that each consumer is willing to pay for the product; yet it is virtually impossible for any firm to acquire such information. · It presupposes that the firm can prevent resale; this means that each consumer would have to be kept separate from every other, which is virtually impossible to achieve. Yet there are a number of situations where sellers try to approximate perfect price discrimination by trying to obtain the highest possible price that a consumer is willing to pay. For example, haggling and bargaining over price in a flea market can result in getting some consumers to pay a price in line with their willingness to pay, which can vary according to their desire for the product or their income. Certain service providers like doctors and lawyers try to size up their clients according to characteristics like income, on the basis of which they can then try to charge the highest price the consumer is willing to pay. Car dealers and 152 Part 2: Microeconomics real estate agents similarly try to estimate willingness to pay of potential car and house buyers so as to ask for the highest possible price. Note that most of these examples involve the provision of services, and therefore preclude the possibility of resale because of the nature of the transaction (it is not possible to resell a medical or legal service). Why would a firm gain if it could practise first degree or perfect price discrimination? We can see the answer to this question in Figure 5.24, which shows the profit-maximizing position of two firms with market power (they face downward-sloping demand curves). Panel (a) shows the familiar profit-maximizing position of the firm that charges a single price for all units of output. The firm maximizes profit at the level of output Q1, where MR = MC, and the demand curve determines the profit-maximizing price P1 at which all units of output are sold. The shaded area under P1 represents the firm’s profit (given by (P1 − ATC) Δ Q1). The figure also shows the area of consumer surplus, under the demand curve above price P1. (a) Single-price firm. price, costs, revenue The consumer’s willingness to pay is related to price elasticity of demand, which we studied in Chapter 3, page 62. Consumers who have a high willingness to pay for a good also have a lower price elasticity of demand (PED) for the good. In other words, for a particular price and quantity combination, the demand curve of the consumer with a higher willingness to pay is steeper (i.e. less elastic) than the demand curve of a consumer with a lower willingness to pay. P1 cons. surplus MC ATC econ. profit deadweight loss 0 D Q1 Q MR (b) Perfectly (first degree) price discriminating firm. price, costs, revenue HL economic profit MC ATC D = MR 0 Q2 Q Figure 5.24 Comparison of the non-price discriminating (single price) firm with the perfectly (first degree) price discriminating firm. HL HL Panel (b) shows the profit-maximizing position of a firm that perfectly price discriminates; note that here, the demand curve is the same as the marginal revenue curve. The reason is that when the firm practises perfect price discrimination, its marginal revenue for each unit of output is equal to the price at which this unit of output is sold. When the firm lowers its price to sell the next unit of output, this price is its marginal (or additional) revenue for that unit of output. The firm in panel (b) maximizes profit by equating MR with MC, giving rise to output Q2. But now, we don’t have a single price but a whole range of prices, given by the demand curve, corresponding to each level of output from 0 to Q2. Based on Figure 5.24, it can be concluded that the firm that practises first degree price discrimination has: · Increased profits Profit increases from the area in panel (a) to the entire area under the demand curve up to ATC in panel (b). The increased profit is the firm’s rationale for pursuing price discrimination. · No consumer surplus under perfect price discrimination All of the consumer surplus is taken away from consumers, and is converted into profit, as can be seen in panel (b). Consumer surplus is reduced to zero. · Increased output under perfect price discrimination Both firms produce the level of output where MR = MC. But since in the case of the price discriminating firm the MR curve is the same as the demand curve, the point of intersection of MR with MC occurs at a higher level of output than that of the non-price discriminating firm: Q2 > Q1. Therefore perfect price discrimination leads to a higher level of output. · No deadweight loss under perfect price discrimination Part of the deadweight loss of the single-price firm with market power is converted into profit, as can be seen in panel (b). The remaining part of the deadweight loss (the part that is under the ATC) is in any case producer surplus, and therefore the firm has captured the total surplus (consumer plus producer surplus). · Allocative efficiency under perfect price discrimination Allocative efficiency is given by the condition P = MC. Since under perfect price discrimination the demand curve, which determines price, is also the marginal revenue curve, when we equate MC with MR to get the profit-maximizing level of output, we are also equating MC with P. The firm that practises perfect price discrimination achieves the socially desirable condition of allocative efficiency, meaning that the quantity of output has increased to the socially desirable level. Second degree: discrimination among quantities Second degree price discrimination is based on the principle that an individual consumer’s willingness to pay decreases as larger quantities of a good are purchased; this means simply that the consumer is willing to buy a larger quantity of the product only if the price of the product for successive units falls. This type of price discrimination usually involves charging a higher price for the first units of the product purchased, a lower price for additional units purchased, and so on, as the buyer purchases more units of the product. This is why this type of discrimination is also known as ‘discrimination among quantities’. There are many real-world examples of second degree price discrimination: · food items at the retail level offering discounts when a large quantity is purchased, so that as the quantity purchased increases, the price per unit falls · industrial buyers receiving large discounts for bulk buying · airline programmes for frequent flyers · discounts for frequent users of mass transport systems · season tickets for concerts · utility companies, such as natural monopolies (electricity, gas, water) commonly charging consumers one price for a specific quantity of the product, a lower price for an additional quantity, and so on. Figure 5.25 (page 154) illustrates what could happen if a single-price firm decides to practise second degree price discrimination. As a single-price firm, it equates MC with MR (not shown in the figure) to determine output Q1 and price P1. Profit is given by area A. Let’s say that Q1 is equal to 100 units of output. Now the firm decides to take advantage of consumers’ varying willingness to pay, by varying the prices at which it sells different quantities. It decides to sell the first 50 units of output at the higher price P2, with the result that it receives additional profit by the amount of area B. Then it also sells an additional 30 units of output at the lower price P3, which gives it further extra profit of the amount in area C. The results of second degree price discrimination are usually the following: · total revenue and profit increase · the firm’s output increases · there will be an improvement in allocative efficiency, although the result will not be full Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 153 HL HL allocative efficiency, where P = MC, as in perfect price discrimination · the firm will convert some (though not all) of consumer surplus and deadweight loss into profit. P P2 P1 P3 0 B A 50 C Q1 130 100 D Q Figure 5.25 Second degree price discrimination. Third degree: discrimination among consumer groups Third degree price discrimination is based on the principle that different consumer groups have different price elasticities of demand for the product. This is the most common type of price discrimination, occurring when consumers are separated into different groups (or markets) each of which is charged a different price; hence it is also known as ‘discrimination among consumer groups’. The firm charges higher prices to consumers with a lower price elasticity of demand, and lower prices to those with a higher elasticity of demand. There are numerous examples of this type of price discrimination: · cinemas, museums, hotels, transport companies and others often charge lower prices for children and older people than to the rest of consumers · airlines charge higher prices for business travellers than for leisure travellers · airlines charge higher prices the closer the booking date is to the date of travel · restaurants and theatres may offer special discounts (i.e. lower prices) on week nights · hotels may offer discounts (i.e. lower prices) for winter or mid-week stays · telephone companies often charge lower rates in the evenings and at weekends · hairdressers may charge higher prices for women · dry-cleaners may charge higher prices for women’s clothes · bars may offer lower prices for a short period immediately after working hours (5 or 6 p.m.). 154 Part 2: Microeconomics The key condition that makes this kind of price discrimination profitable for a firm is that each consumer group must have a different price elasticity of demand. For example, business travellers’ demand for airline tickets is relatively inelastic (low PED), and therefore airline tickets are often more expensive if there is no stay-over on a Saturday night; this pricing policy is based on the assumption that business travellers are usually unwilling to stay overnight on a Saturday. Children and elderly people have a more elastic demand (higher PED) for movies, transport services and other products and are therefore charged lower prices. The demand for telephone services by businesses is less elastic during the day on weekdays, and therefore higher prices are charged during those hours. The demand for hotels in winter and on weekdays, as well as the demand for restaurant meals on weekdays, are more elastic than during holidays and on weekends, and therefore lower prices are charged during these times. Similarly, the demand for drinks in bars is more elastic in the early hours of the evening and therefore here, too, lower prices are charged. The firm’s profit-maximizing strategy in third degree price discrimination is illustrated in Figure 5.26. Let’s assume that there are only two consumer groups (or two markets) for product X, which are distinguished from each other on the basis of differing price elasticities of demand (PEDs). Panel (a) shows the consumer group of market 1 to have a relatively inelastic demand (low PED), while panel (b) shows the consumer group of market 2 to have a relatively elastic demand (high PED). The two marginal revenue curves are added horizontally to give rise to the total market marginal revenue curve in panel (c), which also shows the firm’s marginal cost curve. To maximize profit, the firm equates MR with MC, and the point of intersection between the two determines the profit-maximizing level of output Q3. The firm must now divide the output Q3 between the two markets. It will do this by equating its MC of the total market with the marginal revenue of each individual market, i.e. MC = MR = MR1 = MR2. This will yield output level Q1 in market 1, which is sold at price P1 (determined by the demand curve D1), and output level Q2 in market 2, which is sold at price P2 (determined by the demand curve D2). (Note that Q1 + Q2 = Q3.) Figure 5.26 shows that the firm will charge: · a higher price (P1) for the consumer group with the relatively inelastic demand · a lower price (P2) for the consumer group with the relatively elastic demand. HL HL (a) Market 1. (b) Market 2. P P P1 P MC P2 MR = MR1 + MR2 D2 D1 0 HL (c) Market 1 and market 2. Q1 MR1 Q 0 Q2 MR2 Q 0 Q3 Q Figure 5.26 Third degree price discrimination. · Consumer surplus increases for some groups (those When the firm raises price for consumers with the low PED, total revenue increases because the price rise is proportionately larger than the decrease in quantity demanded. When the firm lowers price for consumers with the high PED, total revenue again increases because the increase in quantity demanded is proportionately larger than the decrease in price. Higher total revenues mean higher economic profits. The results of third degree price discrimination are very complex, and it is difficult to generalize. The following points may be noted: · As in all cases of price discrimination, total revenue that gain from the price fall) and it decreases for other groups (those that lose from the price increase). · What happens to overall consumer surplus depends on what happens to output. If output falls, consumer surplus falls; if output increases, consumer surplus may either increase or decrease, depending on the particular situation. Summary of advantages and disadvantages of price discrimination The desirability of price discrimination from a social point of view is controversial, because it presents a trade-off between efficiency and equity. and economic profits increase. · Total output may increase or decrease; if it increases, it does not reach the socially optimum level (allocative efficiency will not be achieved). · If output increases, then under certain conditions it will also increase allocative efficiency; if output falls, then allocative efficiency will worsen. · Prices under third degree price discrimination will be lower for some groups and higher for other groups, compared to the single price charged by the single-price firm. Therefore some consumer groups can benefit if a product that was previously not affordable now comes within their reach, for example students, pensioners, leisure travellers who plan far ahead of time, mid-week restaurant goers, and many others). On the other hand, those groups who have to pay higher prices will clearly lose, and for some of them, the product will become unaffordable. At the most general level, if output increases as a result of price discrimination, there is usually also an improvement in allocative efficiency, which is desirable from a social point of view. However, the increase in allocative efficiency is often achieved as a result of the conversion of consumer surplus into profit, which is undesirable from a social point of view because of negative impacts on equity and income distribution. To complicate matters further, the impacts of price discrimination on the consumer, the producer and overall society are ambiguous, partly because they depend on the type of price discrimination being practised, and partly because for each type of price discrimination, the outcomes are not always certain, as they depend on the circumstances of each market. The following contains a summary of possible impacts of price discrimination. Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 155 HL From the firm’s perspective · Higher revenues and profits The price discriminating firm benefits as a result of higher revenues and higher profits. This is, after all, the rationale of price discrimination from the point of view of the firm. If profits did not increase, the firm would not engage in price discrimination. · Possibility of increased monopoly power A firm that uses aggressive tactics to increase its monopoly power can use price discrimination to charge high prices in one market and low prices in another market with the intention of driving out rival firms that may be unable to compete with the low price. If it succeeds, it increases its monopoly power. · No deadweight loss under perfect price discrimination As noted earlier, part of the deadweight loss of the firm that does not price discriminate is converted into profit (see Figure 5.24). The remaining part of the deadweight loss (the part that is under the ATC) is in any case producer surplus, and therefore the firm captures the total surplus (consumer plus producer surplus). From the consumer’s perspective · Output Total output increases under first and second degree price discrimination; under third degree price discrimination total output may increase or decrease. When total output increases, consumers benefit either because some can consume more of the product (second degree price discrimination), or because some consumers who would not have purchased the product can now do so because it is offered at a lower price (third degree price discrimination). However, it is also possible that total output may decrease under third degree price discrimination, in which case consumers will be worse off. · Prices Those consumers who pay the lower price benefit, but those who pay the higher price lose. Second degree price discrimination could be considered an unfair practice for consumers who live alone and therefore do not buy large quantities of items that are discounted when bought in larger quantities, as well as for low income consumers who cannot take advantage of the discounts that come 156 Part 2: Microeconomics with large volumes of consumption. Third degree price discrimination is arguably an unfair practice for those consumers with a low PED who must pay more than those with a higher PED, i.e. there arises a problem of equity. · Consumer surplus and income distribution Consumer surplus usually decreases (though this is unclear in the case of third degree price discrimination). When it decreases, it is because it is converted into profits, thereby transferring income from consumers to producers, which is undesirable from consumers’ perspective. · Higher prices due to increased monopoly power If a firm succeeds in driving rival firms from a market, it can use its increased monopoly power to increase prices, which is to the detriment of consumers. From a social perspective · Allocative efficiency If there is an improvement in allocative efficiency, society as a whole gains, because resources come closer to being allocated in accordance with the condition P = MC (or more generally, where marginal benefit is equal to marginal cost). However full allocative efficiency is only achieved under perfect price discrimination, which is highly unrealistic. In the real world, where actual price discriminating practices depart from perfect price discrimination, second degree price discrimination is likely to lead to an improvement in allocative efficiency, whereas in third degree price discrimination allocative efficiency may improve or it may worsen. · Economies of scale and lower prices If total output increases significantly, there may result lower average costs due to economies of scale, which could benefit the firm as well as consumers if the lower costs translate into lower consumer prices. · Technological innovation Greater economic profits for the firm may be reinvested in research and development (R&D) activities, with the result that the consumer and society as a whole may benefit from increased product development and from technological innovations leading to lower costs and lower consumer prices. HL HL Test your understanding 5.15 1 (a) Explain the meaning of price discrimination. (b) What conditions must hold for price discrimination to take place? (c) Why do firms practise price discrimination? 2 Why is it impossible for a perfectly competitive firm to practise price discrimination? 3 (a) Which type of price discrimination is very difficult (if at all possible) to achieve in practice? Why? (b) Which is the most common type of price discrimination? (...continued) Questions for (...continued) HL 4 There are three types of price discrimination. Identify what these are, and explain which discriminates among (a) individual consumers; (b) quantities of the good purchased; and (c) consumer groups. (d) Can you provide examples of each type of price discrimination? 5 (a) What can happen to consumer surplus and deadweight loss when firms practise price discrimination? (b) What are the impacts on the profits of the price discriminating firm? review 5.1 [10 marks] (a) Using appropriate diagrams, explain the difference between a firm that is a ‘price-taker’ and one that is a ‘price-maker’. (b) Under what market structure(s) can we expect to find each of these? 5.2 [10 marks] Explain the relationship between price, average revenue and marginal revenue for firms that are (a) ‘price-takers’; and (b) ‘price-makers’. 5.3 Test your understanding 5.15 [10 marks] Explain and use diagrams to show why in long-run equilibrium a perfectly competitive firm makes normal profit (zero economic or supernormal profit), whereas in the short run it can make an economic (or supernormal) profit or loss. (Hint: you must refer to the importance of economic profits and losses in moving from shortrun to long-run equilibrium.) 5.4 [10 marks] Using diagrams, show under what conditions a perfectly competitive firm will (a) continue to produce in the short run even though it is making a loss; (b) shut down. 5.5 [10 marks] Using diagrams, explain the difference between the break-even price and the shut-down price of a perfectly competitive firm. 5.6 [10 marks] Using diagrams, compare and contrast how firms in perfect competition and monopoly determine the profit-maximizing (loss-minimizing) level of output, using marginal revenue and cost concepts. 5.7 [10 marks] (a) Using a diagram, show how a monopolist maximizes profit. (b) Is there a difference between the short-run and long-run equilibrium of the monopolist? 5.8 [10 marks] (a) Using diagrams, show the profitmaximizing position of a firm that is earning abnormal (economic) profit under monopolistic competition in the short run. (b) Can this firm earn abnormal profit also in the long run? (c) Show the long-run equilibrium position of this firm. 5.9 [20 marks] (a) Distinguish between collusive and non-collusive oligopoly. (b) Provide examples of models that explain the behaviour of firms in each of these two types of oligopoly. 5.10 [10 marks for parts (a), (b) and (c); 8 marks for part (d)] (a) What is a cartel? (b) If a group of firms formed a cartel that tried to coordinate prices, what market structure would they be similar to? Using a diagram, show their profitmaximizing level of output and price. (c) What factors make it difficult for a cartel to be maintained over a long period of time? (d) Why do many countries have laws that make cartels illegal? 5.11 [10 marks for parts (a) and (b); 5 marks for part (c)] (a) What model is appropriate for the study of non-collusive oligopoly? (b) Use this model to show why prices in oligopolistic markets tend to be stable over extended periods of time. (c) How does this model help us understand the importance of non-price competition in oligopoly (or why firms in oligopoly try to avoid price competition)? Chapter 5: Theory of the firm II 157 HL 5.12 [10 marks] (a) Explain why many firms in monopolistic competition try to behave like monopolists. How do they try to achieve this objective? (b) Explain why many oligopolistic firms try to behave like monopolists. How do they try to achieve this objective? 5.13 [10 marks] What are some explanations of price stability that we generally observe in oligopolistic markets? 5.14 [15 marks] (a) In what market structures do we find price competition and non-price competition? (b) What role do price competition and nonprice competition play in these market structures? (c) What are the impacts on the demand curve facing firms that successfully engage in non-price competition? (d) What is the significance of this kind of demand curve from the point of view of the firm? 5.15 5.16 [15 marks] (a) Why do we study perfect competition and monopoly even though they are not encountered very frequently in the real world? (b) Evaluate the perspective that governments should try to increase the degree of competition in industries. [10 marks] (a) Discuss allocative and productive efficiency and use diagrams to show in which market model(s) they occur. (b) Why are they important concepts? 5.17 [20 marks] Evaluate each of the four market structures, discussing its advantages and disadvantages from the point of view of consumers and society: (a) perfect competition; (b) monopoly; (c) monopolistic competition; (d) oligopoly. 5.18 [10 marks for parts (a), (b) and (c); 5 marks for part (d)] (a) What is the theory of contestable markets? (b) Which market structures is it relevant to? (c) How do its conclusions differ from those of the standard theory of the firm? (d) What are its implications for government policy? 5.19 [15 marks] (a) Explain the meaning of ‘barriers to entry’ and provide examples of different kinds of barriers. (b) What role do barriers to entry play in determining types of market structure? 5.20 [10 marks] Many countries have legislation making unregulated, privately owned monopoly illegal. What are the reasons behind this government policy? 158 Part 2: Microeconomics 5.21 [15 marks] (a) Using an appropriate diagram, explain what a ‘natural monopoly’ is. (b) Using your diagram of part (a), explain why governments often do not break up natural monopolies in order to increase competition. 5.22 [15 marks] Evaluate the desirability of monopoly from consumers’ and society’s point of view, and compare with perfect competition. 5.23 [15 marks] Evaluate the desirability of monopolistic competition from consumers’ and society’s point of view, and compare with perfect competition. 5.24 [15 marks] Evaluate the desirability of monopolistic competition from consumers’ and society’s point of view, and compare with monopoly. 5.25 [15 marks] Evaluate the desirability of an oligopolistic market structure from the point of view of consumers’ and society’s interests, and compare with perfect competition. 5.26 [15 marks] Evaluate the desirability of an oligopolistic market structure from the point of view of consumers’ and society’s interests, and compare with monopolistic competition. 5.27 [15 marks] Some firms may pursue the goal of revenue maximization rather than profit maximization. (a) Using the monopoly market model, illustrate how a firm can determine the level of output at which its revenue will be maximum. (b) Show how the revenue-maximizing level of output differs from the profit-maximizing level of output. (c) Can a perfectly competitive firm maximize revenue? Why or why not? 5.28 [10 marks for parts (a) and (b); 15 marks for part (c)] (a) What conditions must be satisfied for a firm to be able to successfully practise price discrimination? (b) Provide examples of price discrimination. (c) Discuss some of the positive and negative effects of price discrimination from the point of view of firms, consumers and society. 5.29 [15 marks] It is often the case that airline fares are lower for travellers who purchase their tickets ahead of time than for flyers who purchase their tickets the last moment. (a) Explain how this can occur. (b) What characteristic of consumer demand allows airline companies to do this? (c) Evaluate the impacts for consumers, producers and society. HL Chapter 6 Microeconomics Market failure In this chapter we will see why the market economy fails to achieve many of its promises, and how government intervention can help markets overcome their failures. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · · · · · · · · · · explain the meaning of market failure in terms of the inefficient allocation of resources relate externalities to market failure examine negative externalities and identify appropriate government policies intended to correct them understand the relationship between environmental externalities and sustainable development examine positive externalities and identify appropriate government policies intended to correct them explain and distinguish between merit goods, demerit goods and public goods, and identify appropriate policies to address the market failures they pose evaluate the range of policies that governments can use to correct market failures understand why monopoly power constitutes market failure, and identify appropriate policies intended to address it have an awareness of the existence of additional market failures, and the possible failure of government policy evaluate the free market economy. 6.1 Market failure and allocative inefficiency Our discussion so far has shown that a free, competitive market economy will give rise to a number of highly desirable outcomes (see Chapter 1, page 21 and Chapter 2, page 47). However, the achievement of these outcomes depends on a number of very strict and unrealistic conditions that are practically never met in the real world. Therefore, in reality, the market mechanism, working freely and on its own, fails to achieve these highly desirable results. Yet this failure does not lessen the significance of the market as a mechanism that can advance the wellbeing of societies; instead, it suggests that if markets are to achieve their potential to improve social wellbeing, they must be supported by government policies that correct for their failings. Market failures constitute a major justification for government intervention in the market economy, giving rise to the mixed market economy (studied in Chapter 1, page 23). The study of market failure focuses on one particular failing: the free market’s inability to achieve allocative efficiency in a variety of circumstances. In Chapter 2, page 50, we learned that in a free market, when the price of a good adjusts to make quantity demanded equal to quantity supplied, the equilibrium quantity reflects the ‘best’ or optimal allocation of resources to the production of that good. This condition is known as allocative efficiency, defined as the production of the particular combination of goods and services that consumers mostly prefer, and is achieved when marginal benefit equals marginal cost, at which point Chapter 6: Market failure 159 the what to produce question is answered in the most satisfactory way. Yet in the real world, the market often fails to achieve efficient outcomes: Market failure refers to the failure of the market to allocate resources efficiently, or to provide the quantity and combination of goods and services mostly wanted by society (the optimum). Market failure results in allocative inefficiency, where too much or too little of goods or services are produced and consumed from the point of view of what is socially most desirable. Allocative efficiency can be attained only under the strict conditions of perfect competition, which, as we know from Chapter 2 (and Chapter 5 for higher level students), can in fact only be somewhat approximated by a very limited number of markets in the real world. Therefore it is not surprising that real–world markets rarely, if ever, allocate resources efficiently. To complicate matters further, while perfect competition is necessary for the achievement of allocative efficiency, it is not enough. In addition, there are numerous other sources of allocative inefficiency that are unrelated to the degree of competition. We will study some of the more important kinds of these failures under the following topics: 6.2 Externalities Diverging private and social benefits and costs When a consumer buys and consumes a good, she or he derives some benefits. When a firm produces and sells a good, it incurs costs. But sometimes, the benefits and the costs spill over onto other consumers or producers who have nothing to do with consuming or producing the good. When this happens, there is an externality. An externality occurs when the actions of consumers or producers give rise to positive or negative side-effects on other people who are not part of these actions, and whose interests are not taken into consideration. The other people feeling the effects of an externality are often referred to as ‘third parties’, outsiders to the transaction. If the side-effects on third parties involve benefits, there arises a positive externality, also known as a spillover benefit; if they involve costs, in the form of adverse or negative side-effects, there arises a negative externality, also known as a spillover cost: · externalities, arising when the actions of consumers or producers have side-effects in the form of costs or benefits for others who are external to the market · merit and demerit goods, which are goods that are underprovided or overprovided by the market · public goods, which are usually not provided at all by the market · abuse of monopoly power, arising in situations where the absence of competitive conditions permits firms to take actions that are against the public interest · some additional failures of markets and government failure (supplementary material). Allocative efficiency is a very useful concept as a standard or benchmark, used by economists to identify real-world situations that involve serious departures from the ideal of a perfect allocation of resources. Once these are identified, it is possible to design government policies aimed at eliminating or reducing the extent of the inefficiencies, thereby bringing the economy closer to the achievement of the ideal. For each of the above causes of market failure, we will also discuss a variety of policies that governments can pursue to correct the failures. 160 Part 2: Microeconomics positive externalities = spillover benefits = positive side-effects on third parties negative externalities = spillover costs = negative side-effects on third parties Externalities can result either from consumption activities (consumption externalities) or from production activities (production externalities). To fully understand externalities, let’s return for a moment to the demand and supply curves that we studied in Chapter 2. The standard demand curve of the market model reflects the value that consumers attach to the good demanded, or, what is the same thing, the benefits that consumers derive from purchasing and consuming the good, measured by the prices they are willing to pay for it. As we know, P S = MPC Pe very important implications: it means that if there are externalities, the equilibrium price and quantity determined by the intersection of the standard demand curve (MPB), and the standard supply curve (MPC) will no longer be a social optimum, and there will now be allocative inefficiency. To address this problem, we must find the social benefits and the social costs: D = MPB 0 Qopt allocative efficiency is achieved Q Figure 6.1 Demand, supply and allocative efficiency when there are no externalities. the demand curve can be thought of as a ‘marginal benefit curve’ (see Figure 2.2(b)). Since the benefits derived from consuming the good go to private individuals (the consumers buying the good), we can think of the demand curve as representing marginal private benefits, shown as MPB in Figure 6.1. The standard supply curve, on the other hand, reflects firms’ costs of production, specifically marginal costs. We can therefore think of the supply curve as representing marginal private costs, appearing as MPC in Figure 6.1. The market demand and supply curves that we are familiar with therefore reflect the marginal private benefits and marginal private costs accruing to buyers and sellers. Now, if there are no externalities, so that the actions of buyers and sellers do not produce any side-effects on third parties, the marginal private benefit (or demand) curve and marginal private cost (or supply) curve determine an equilibrium price and quantity that reflect a social optimum, or ‘best’ outcome in which there is allocative efficiency. In Figure 6.1, allocative efficiency is achieved at output Qopt. This is none other than the market equilibrium achieved by the intersection of the demand and supply curves we are familiar with, where MPB = MPC, illustrating the achievement of allocative efficiency (see also Figure 2.18). If, however, there is an externality, there will arise additional benefits or costs affecting third parties, or outsiders to the transaction, in which case the full benefits and costs to society will differ from the private ones. Specifically, there will arise marginal social benefits that will be different from the marginal private benefits; or marginal social costs that will be different from the private costs. This has Social benefits = private benefits + externality Social costs = private costs + externality Social benefits and social costs in relation to private benefits and costs appear in Figures 6.2 and 6.4–6.6. In a diagram, social benefits appear as a marginal social benefit curve, MSB, representing the full benefits to society from the consumption of a good, and social costs as a marginal social cost curve, MSC, representing the full costs to society of producing the good. The intersection of MSB and MSC represents a social optimum in which allocative efficiency is achieved. There are four types of externalities: · negative externalities (spillover costs) in production · negative externalities (spillover costs) in consumption · positive externalities (spillover benefits) in production · positive externalities (spillover benefits) in consumption. Test your understanding 6.1 1 (a) What is an externality? (b) Use the concept of allocative efficiency to explain how externalities relate to market failure. 2 Explain the difference (a) between private benefit and social benefit; and (b) between private cost and social cost. Negative production externalities (spillover costs) Illustrating negative production externalities Negative production externalities are spillover costs created by producers. The problem of environmental Chapter 6: Market failure 161 (a) Negative production externality. (b) Correcting the negative production externality by imposing a tax on the firm. MSC P P spillover cost S = MPC P1 0 P2 MSC tax = spillover cost S = MPC P1 Qopt Qm D = MPB Q D = MPB 0 Qopt Qm Q Figure 6.2 Negative production externalities. pollution, created as a side-effect of production activities, is very commonly analysed as a negative externality in production. Consider the case of a cement factory that emits smoke into the air and disposes of its waste by dumping it into the ocean. There is a production externality, because over and above the firm’s private costs of production, there are additional costs that spill over onto society (spillover costs) due to the polluted air and ocean, with negative consequences for the local inhabitants, swimmers, sea life, the fishing industry, and the marine ecosystem. This is shown in Figure 6.2(a), where the supply curve given by MPC reflects the firm’s private costs of production, and the marginal social cost curve given by MSC represents the full cost to society of producing cement. The vertical difference between MSC and MPC represents the spillover costs, or the costs arising from the externality. Therefore, for each level of output, Q, social costs given by MSC, or the full cost to society of producing cement, are greater than the firms’s private costs by the amount of the spillover costs to third parties from the pollution. In Figure 6.2(a), the free market gives rise to quantity Qm of cement produced, determined by the intersection of MPB and MPC. But the socially optimum (or ‘best’) quantity is Qopt, determined by the intersection of MPB and MSC. At Qopt, the value of cement to consumers (MPB) is exactly equal to the social cost of producing it. This gives rise to a very important result: 162 Part 2: Microeconomics When there is a negative production externality, the free market overallocates resources to the production of the good; in other words, too many resources are allocated to produce the good, and too much of it is produced relative to the social optimum. This is shown by Qm > Qopt in Figure 6.2(a). Correcting negative production externalities If this problem could be corrected, then Qopt quantity of cement would be produced, and allocative efficiency would be achieved. There are several options that governments may pursue. Legislation and regulations Legislation and regulations can be used to prevent or reduce the effects of production externalities. In the case of the polluting firm, legislation can be used to completely forbid the dumping of certain toxic substances into the environment (into the rivers, oceans, etc.). More commonly, however, legislation may not totally ban the production of pollutants, but rather could attempt to achieve one of the following: · limit the emission of pollutants by setting a maximum level of pollutants that are permitted · limit the quantity of output produced by the polluting firm · require polluting firms to install technologies reducing the emissions. In all these cases, the impact would be to lower the quantity of the good produced, and to bring it closer to the optimal quantity Qopt in Figure 6.2(a) by shifting the MPC supply curve upward towards the MSC curve. Pollutant and output restrictions achieve this directly by forcing the firm to produce less. Requirements to install technologies reducing emissions achieve this by imposing higher costs of production due to the purchase of the non-polluting technologies. The government’s objective is to make the MPC curve shift upwards until it coincides with the MSC curve, in which case Qopt will be produced, price will increase from P1 to P2, and the problem of overallocation of resources to the production of the good will be corrected. Imposing a tax on the firm causing the negative production externality A different kind of policy involves the imposition of taxes on the polluting firm. The government could impose a tax on the firm per unit of the good produced, or a tax per unit of pollutants emitted. Both of these would result in an upward shift of the supply (MPC) curve. The optimal (or best) tax policy will be to impose a tax that is exactly equal to the spillover cost, in which the MPC curve will shift upward until it overlaps with MSC. This is shown in Figure 6.2(b), where the new, after-tax equilibrium quantity is Qopt, given by the intersection of MSC (= MPC + tax) and the demand curve, MPB. The tax has resulted in production of a lower quantity, which is also the optimum quantity, and a higher price (P2). At this equilibrium, the overallocation of resources will be corrected. Tradable permits Tradable permits are permits to pollute that are issued to firms by a government or an international body, and that can be traded (bought and sold) in a market. This is a relatively new policy option, which works in the following way. Consider a number of firms whose production results in environmental pollution. Each firm is granted by the government a particular number of permits (or rights) to produce a particular level of pollutants over a given period of time. The permits to pollute can be bought and sold among interested firms, with the price of permits being determined by supply and demand. If a firm can produce its product by emitting a lower level of pollutants than the level set by its permits, it can sell its extra permits in the market. If a firm needs to emit more pollutants than the level set by its permits, it can buy more permits in the market. Figure 6.3 shows a market for tradable pollution permits. The supply of permits is perfectly inelastic (i.e. the supply curve is vertical), as it is fixed at a particular level by the government (or an international authority if several countries are participating). This fixed supply of permits is distributed to firms. The position of the demand-for-permits curve determines the equilibrium price. As an economy grows and the firms increase their output levels, the demand for permits is likely to increase, as shown by the rightward shift of the demand curve from D1 to D2. With supply fixed, the price of permits increases from P1 to P2. P S of tradable permits P2 P1 D2 D1 0 Q1 Q Figure 6.3 Market for tradable pollution permits. Correction of negative production externalities involves pursuing policies that shift the MPC (supply) curve upward towards the MSC curve in Figure 6.2(b). If the MPC curve shifts so that it overlaps with the MSC curve, then the optimal quantity of the good will be produced, the overallocation of resources will be corrected, and allocative efficiency will be achieved. The effect will be to lower the quantity of the good produced so that it equals Qopt, and to raise the price of the good from P1 to P2. Evaluating alternative policies Economists usually prefer solutions to negative production externalities based on taxes and tradable permits, rather than government legislation and regulations. Both taxes and tradable permits dealing with negative production externalities have the effect of internalizing the externality, meaning that the spillover costs that were previously external are now internal: they are now paid for by producers who are parties to the transaction. When the externality is internalized, firms pay for the spillover costs themselves, whether by having to pay taxes, or by having to buy tradable permits. Chapter 6: Market failure 163 Both taxes and tradable permits are market-based methods of dealing with externalities. Unlike legislation and regulations (which are based on the command mechanism), taxes and tradable permits make firms internalize the externality, thereby providing firms with incentives to cut back on the pollution they produce. In the case of taxes, if firms are taxed on the basis of pollutants emitted, they face an incentive to use production methods that pollute less. Firms do not all face the same costs of reducing pollution; for some firms, the costs of reducing pollution will be much lower than for others, and they will be the ones most likely to cut their pollution emissions to avoid paying the tax. The firms that face the highest costs of reducing pollution will be the ones least likely to cut their pollutants, and so will pay the tax. The result is that taxation can lead to lower pollution levels at a lower overall cost. Similarly, in the case of tradable permits, the system creates incentives for firms to cut back on their pollution if they can do so at relatively low cost. If it is a relatively low cost procedure for a firm to cut back on its pollutant emissions, it will be in its interests to do so and sell excess permits. Firms that can only reduce pollution at high cost will be forced to buy additional permits. There are, however, some difficulties involved with both taxes and tradable permits. In the case of taxes, there are serious practical difficulties in determining the amount of pollutants emitted and in designing a tax that will be equal in value to the amount of the pollution. Tradable permits require the government to determine not only the amount of pollutants emitted, but also to set a maximum level for each type of pollutant for which permits will be distributed to the polluting firms; this latter task would involve having technical information on how much of each pollutant is acceptable from an environmental point of view, which is often not available. Therefore, in practice, assuming that a government is interested in correcting negative production externalities involving pollution, it is most unlikely that it could achieve the desired shift in the MPC curve shown in Figure 6.2(b), leading to production of the optimal quantity Qopt. Legislation and regulations, apart from being based on the command method (rather than the market), suffer from similar limitations, and can at best be only partially effective, given the difficulties of devising measures that can shift the supply (MPC) curve so that 164 Part 2: Microeconomics it exactly overlaps with the MSC curve. Therefore, such measures can only attempt to partially correct the problem. Test your understanding 6.2 1 (a) Using diagrams, show how private and social costs differ when there is a negative production externality. (b) How does the equilibrium quantity determined by the market differ from the quantity that is optimal from the point of view of society’s preferences? (c) What does this tell you about the allocation of resources achieved by the market when there is a negative production externality? 2 Provide some examples of negative production externalities. 3 For each of the examples you provided in question 2, state and explain the most effective method(s) of correcting the externality. 4 Using diagrams, show how the negative externality can be corrected by use of (a) taxes, and (b) legislation and regulations that limit the quantity of pollutants. 5 Explain how tradable pollution permits can contribute to correcting negative production externalities. 6 (a) What does it mean to ‘internalize an externality’? How can this be achieved? (b) Why do economists prefer market-based methods that internalize negative production externalities to command methods (such as legislation and regulations)? (c) What are some difficulties that governments face in designing market-based methods? Negative consumption externalities (spillover costs) Illustrating negative consumption externalities Negative consumption externalities are spillover costs created by consumers. For example, when consumers smoke in public places, there are spillover costs in the form of costs to non-smokers due to passive smoking. When there is a consumption externality, the marginal private benefit (demand) curve does not reflect social benefits. In Figure 6.4(a), the buyers of cigarettes have a demand curve, MPB, but in the course of smoking (b) Advertising and persuasion. (a) Negative consumption externality. (c) Correcting the negative consumption externality by imposing a tax on the firm producing the good. MPC + tax P S = MPC P1 D = MPB spillover cost P S = MPC spillover cost Qopt Qm P1 P2 Q 0 P2 S = MPC P1 D = MPB D1 = MPB1 MSB = D2 = MPB2 after demand decreases MSB 0 tax = spillover cost P Qopt Qm Q MSB 0 Qopt Qm Q Figure 6.4 Negative consumption externalities. create costs for non-smokers. Because of these costs, the marginal social benefit curve, MSB, lies below the MPB curve. The vertical difference between MPB and MSB represents the spillover costs. The market determines an equilibrium quantity, Qm, given by the intersection of the MPB and MPC curves, but since there are spillover costs of consumption, the social optimum is given by Qopt, determined by the intersection of the MSB and MPC curves. Since Qm > Qopt, the market overallocates resources to the production of the good, and too much of the good is produced and consumed. Other examples of negative consumption externalities include: · heating homes and driving cars by use of fossil fuels that pollute the atmosphere · partying with loud music until the early hours of the morning, and disturbing the neighbours. Correcting negative consumption externalities If this problem were corrected, Qopt quantity of the good would be produced, reflecting allocative efficiency. Options that can be pursued by the government include the following: · Advertising and persuasion Advertising and campaigns by the government can be used to try to persuade consumers to buy fewer goods with negative externalities, such as anti-smoking campaigns. In this case the objective is to try to decrease demand for such goods and services, so that the private marginal benefit (demand) curve, MPB, shifts leftward towards MSB. Figure 6.4(b) illustrates the case where D1 = MPB1 (before the advertising campaign) shifts to D2 = MPB2 after the campaign, where it coincides with MSB. Qopt is produced and consumed, and the price falls from P1 to P2. · Legislation and regulations Legislation can be used When there is a negative consumption externality, the free market overallocates resources to the production of the good, and too much of it is produced relative to what is socially optimum. This is shown by Qm > Qopt in Figure 6.4(a). In general, negative externalities (spillover costs), whether these arise from production or consumption activities, lead to an overallocation of resources to the good in question, and therefore to overprovision of the good. to prevent or limit consumer activities that impose costs on third parties. For example, there may be legal restrictions on such activities as smoking in public places, playing loud music in the middle of the night and discarding rubbish (trash) in public places. This also has the effect of shifting the marginal private benefit (demand) curve towards the marginal social benefit curve, so that Qopt will be produced and consumed, and the price of the good will fall. · Imposing a tax on the firm producing the good that causes the negative consumption externality As we have seen in Figure 6.4(a), the marginal social benefit curve (MSB) lies below the marginal benefit (demand) curve (MPB) by an amount that is equal Chapter 6: Market failure 165 to the spillover cost. If a tax is imposed on the firm producing the good that has the negative consumption externality, there will result a decrease in supply and an upward shift of the supply curve from MPC to MPC + tax, as shown in Figure 6.4(c). If the tax is exactly equal to the spillover cost, then the quantity produced and consumed will drop to Qopt, which is determined by the intersection of the MPB curve with the MPC + tax curve. Qopt represents the socially optimum quantity, and price will increase from P1 to P2. The tax can therefore permit allocative efficiency to be achieved. Moreover, there are also problems with calculating the precise magnitude of the tax required, as well as the type of legislation or regulations that would be effective. Therefore, in the cases of all policies (advertising, legislation, regulations and taxes), it is only possible to move the economy in a direction towards correction of the externality, rather than achieving a precise allocation of resources where Qopt is produced and consumed. Test your understanding 6.3 1 (a) Show diagrammatically how private and Correction of negative consumption externalities involves decreasing demand and shifting the demand (MPB) curve leftward toward the MSB curve, as in Figure 6.4(b), or decreasing supply and shifting the supply (MPC) curve upward (through the imposition of a tax) so that its intersection with MPB determines Qopt in Figure 6.4(c). When production occurs at Qopt, the overallocation of resources will be corrected and allocative efficiency is achieved. The effect will be to lower the quantity of the good produced, and lower or raise the price of the good paid by the consumer depending on whether the correction was brought about by a decrease in demand (price will fall) or a decrease in supply (price will increase). Evaluating alternative policies As in the case of negative production externalities, economists prefer market-based solutions to the problem of negative consumption externalities as well; therefore taxes are the preferred measure. A possible difficulty that arises in this respect is that some of the goods whose consumption leads to negative consumption externalities have an inelastic demand. As higher-level students may remember from Chapter 3, page 71, the imposition of a tax on a good with an inelastic demand results in an increase in government revenues, because the percentage decrease in quantity demanded is smaller than the percentage increase in price (due to the tax). Therefore it is possible that imposing taxes on such goods as petrol/gasoline and cigarettes (both of which have an inelastic demand) works to increase government tax revenues more than it works to decrease the demand for these goods. An additional difficulty involves the technical problem of information needed on the amount of pollution created, by which products and produced by which firms, which is exceedingly difficult to collect. 166 Part 2: Microeconomics social benefits diverge when there is a negative consumption externality. (b) When there is a negative consumption externality, how does the equilibrium quantity determined by the market diverge from the quantity that is optimal from the point of view of society’s preferences? (c) What does this tell you about the allocation of resources achieved by the market when there is a negative consumption externality? 2 Provide some examples of negative consumption externalities. 3 For each of the examples you provided in question 2, state and explain the most effective method(s) of correcting the externality. 4 Show diagrammatically how a negative consumption externality can be corrected by use of (a) legislation and regulations that limit the spillover costs, (b) advertising and persuasion, and (c) taxes. 5 How does a negative consumption externality differ from a negative production externality? 6 (a) What kinds of measures do economists prefer to correct negative consumption externalities? (b) Why might these not be very effective? Environmental concerns and sustainable development Environmental concerns and negative externalities Environmental pollution involves negative externalities of monumental proportions, and results from both production and consumption activities. Factories that pollute the air, water, and soil, or that cause any other kind of environmental damage, are producers who do not bear the costs of the pollution they create, thus imposing spillover costs that are borne by society at large. The social costs of production are greater than the private costs of production by the amount of the spillover cost (i.e. the cost to society due to the pollution). Emissions by cars and homes using fossil fuels pollute the atmosphere and are by-products of consumption activities involving the use of cars and home heating by consumers. These also impose spillover costs on society, and the social benefits from consumption are lower than private benefits by the amount of the spillover costs. These are just some examples of the many ways that producers and consumers can damage the environment. When societies produce and consume without regard for the natural environment, they are likely to engage in activities that result in environmental pollution and degradation. Environmental pollution and degradation arise to a very large extent from the use and overuse of natural resources that have no ownership, in other words, they do not belong to anyone. Examples of natural resources without ownership are the air, the oceans, rivers and lakes, wildlife, the fish in the sea, forests, biodiversity, and even the global climate and the ozone layer. Although we often don’t think of these goods as being natural resources, they are a very important part of what economists traditionally have called the factor of production ‘land’, which includes all ‘gifts of nature’. When factories, homes or cars use fossil fuels that emit pollutants into the atmosphere or into oceans, rivers and lakes, they ‘use up’ a portion of these natural resources, although they do not pay for them. Some of these activities result in ozone depletion, with harmful effects on life from the sun’s radiation; they ‘use up’ part of the ozone layer, yet they don’t pay for its use. Some of these activities also give rise to global warming, with possibly devastating effects on agriculture, health and ecosystems; this involves ‘using up’ the benefits provided by a stable global climate, which are also not paid for. When fish are fished out of the sea, the fishing industry uses up a portion of the global stock of fish and possibly disrupts the marine ecosystem, both of which it does not pay for. Similarly, when forests are cleared to create land for use in agriculture or for the sale of timber by the lumber industry, there are huge consequences in terms of loss of biodiversity, and threats to wildlife and the ozone layer, yet once again resources are used up but are not paid for. Why are all these natural resources not paid for even though they are being used up? The reason is that they are not owned by anyone. Since they have no owner, they are not exchanged in any market; they do not have a price, and they are therefore available for anyone to use without payment. Since there is no price to ration their use, they are subject to overuse. Natural resources that have no ownership and are therefore subject to overuse are called open access resources, or common property resources. Thinking about pollution and environmental degradation in terms of use and overuse of open access resources is another way of viewing negative environmental externalities. The use of open access resources involves negative externalities due to depletion of essential resources not paid for by the user, thereby imposing spillover costs on society. To see this more clearly, consider Figure 6.2(a) above, illustrating a negative production externality. The marginal private cost (supply) curve, MPC, can represent the private costs of a fishing firm that fishes in the open seas. The fishing activities of this firm may impose spillover costs in the form of depletion of the stock of fish, and environmental damage due to disruption of the marine ecosystem. The presence of spillover costs means that the marginal social cost curve, MSC, lies above the private marginal cost (or supply) curve, MPC, since social costs of fishing are greater than the private costs. The vertical difference between the two curves represents costs to society, consisting of depletion of the fish stock and disruption of the marine ecosystem (the open access resources) that the fishing firm has used up but has not paid for. Overuse of common access resources can also be seen to result from negative consumption externalities, shown in Figure 6.4(a) above. Take the demand for heating oil, represented by the demand curve MPB. The use of clean air (and the creation of pollution) is represented by the spillover cost that causes the marginal social benefit curve (MSB) to lie below MPB. The spillover cost represents the clean air (the open access resource) that consumers have used up in heating their homes but have not paid for. The meaning of sustainable development Environmental pollution and degradation are closely related to the concept of sustainable development (introduced briefly in Chapter 1, page 10). Sustainable development has been defined as ‘development that meets the needs of the present without compromising Chapter 6: Market failure 167 the ability of future generations to meet their own needs’. 1 This concept has been developed in an effort to link economic and environmental goals. Economic goals involve efforts to increase the quantities of output produced and consumed (economic growth) in order to satisfy ever more needs and wants of human beings; environmental goals involve the preservation of the environment. The economic goal of continuously increasing quantities of output produced and consumed is very often pursued without regard for possible impacts on the environment; in other words, the goal of preservation of the environment is often ignored. Yet as long as this occurs, there may arise serious ecological dangers for future generations of people. The concept of sustainable development highlights the point that there are trade-offs between the well-being of present generations of people and the well-being of future generations. If we in the present use up resources at a rate that leaves fewer or lower quality resources behind, we are satisfying our needs and wants now at the expense of the well-being of people in the future, who with fewer or lower quality resources at their disposal will be less able to satisfy their own needs and wants. If we enjoy the benefits today of production and consumption by changing the global climate and by using up clean air, seas and rivers, forests and the ozone layer, we are penalizing future generations, who will suffer the consequences of our excesses. Negative production and consumption externalities, if they occur on a large scale, lead to unsustainable development. We will return to the relationships between economic growth and sustainable development in Chapter 19. Addressing the overuse of open access resources Many of the measures considered earlier for the purpose of dealing with negative production and consumption externalities apply equally to the overuse of open access resources: · Taxes If the overuse of clear air, rivers and seas by firms is considered as spillover costs of firms whose private costs of production are lower than the social costs, taxes on the polluting firms can be used to address the problem of resource misallocation. The analysis is the same as that shown in Figure 6.2(b). 1 Brundtland Commission (World Commission on Environment and Development), Our Common Future (Oxford University Press, 1987). 168 Part 2: Microeconomics · Legislation and regulations Legislation can impose restrictions on the use of open access resources. For example, there can be restrictions on permissible fishing practices, or limits by setting quotas on quantities that can legally be fished. Hunting laws restrict what can be hunted and at what times of the year, and often impose total bans on the hunting of particular species. Alternatively, the government may grant or sell licences for the use of specific resources, as with fishing or hunting licences. · Advertising and persuasion Governments can make efforts to convince consumers to cut back on use of pollution-creating substances, and to increase consumption of energy-efficient consumer goods, such as cars, heating systems, light bulbs, etc. They can also try to use persuasion to convince producers to cut back on their emissions of hazardous and polluting wastes. · Tradable permits Tradable permits can be used to deal with the problem of open access resources if potential users of particular resources are assigned tradable quotas specifying the amount of the resource they are permitted to use. In addition, there is another policy measure that attempts to strike at the problem of open access resources by going to the source of the problem, which is their lack of ownership: · Extension of property rights When clean air is polluted, no one can claim damages because no one owns it. In effect, the lack of property rights over open access resources means that producers and consumers use them as if they were free goods (i.e. goods with a zero opportunity cost). However, open access resources are subject to the condition of scarcity, and have an opportunity cost greater than zero; therefore they are not free goods. The lack of ownership of open access resources lies at the heart of the problem of their overuse, i.e. their overallocation to the production of goods and services. When there are no property rights over resources, producers and consumers use them as if they were free goods. The market fails to allocate resources efficiently because there is no market. Extension of property rights would involve establishing property rights over resources that no one owns, allowing the holder of the property rights to charge a price for the use of the resource. Price would ration the use of the resource, and less of it would be used up. This approach could include, for example, the right to clean air, or the right to a smoke-free environment. The impact of an extension of property rights would be that anyone who violates them would be liable to pay, and therefore negative externalities, or spillover costs, would be transformed into private costs. If there is ownership of clean air, then anyone who uses it up by polluting it would have to pay for it, and the cost of the pollution would become a private cost borne by the polluter. By having to pay for the use of the resource, its use will be reduced and overallocation of the resource will be corrected. This is another way of internalizing the externality. However, whereas extension of property rights is a sound approach in theory, in practice there are significant problems in trying to establish property rights over common access resources. It would be very difficult and costly to try to establish property rights over oceans, rivers and the atmosphere. Therefore, governments interested in preservation of open access resources often resort to other more practical solutions, such as legislation and regulations (fishing quotas, hunting and logging restrictions) or tradable permits in the case of the right to use up clean air. Many negative externalities that relate to the environment have impacts that extend beyond national boundaries. When this occurs, international collaboration is called for. International cooperation/agreements Policies are made mainly by national governments. However, when externalities have international repercussions, cooperation among governments is crucially important as a method of controlling adverse consequences on certain open access resources, such as the global climate and the ozone layer. For example, the ozone layer has suffered ozone depletion, giving rise to reduced protection against the sun’s ultraviolet radiation. This has been the result of human activities involving the production of nitrogen oxides and chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs). The ozone layer is an open access resource over which there are no property rights. No one can claim damages for its destruction. The responsibility for its destruction lies with polluting activities within virtually every country, and the consequences of its destruction are felt globally. An important example of international collaboration intended to deal with a negative environmental externality with enormous global repercussions is the Kyoto Protocol of 1997. Its objective was to make signatory countries commit themselves to reduce emissions of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases over a period of time so as to slow down the problem of global warming and climatic change. It also contained provisions for the development of a market of tradable emissions permits, according to which each participating country was to be assigned certain pollution permits which it would be able to trade (buy and sell) with other countries. However, the Kyoto Protocol came under a great deal of criticism and has not been implemented in full. Many environmental specialists argued that even if it were implemented, the agreed reductions in emissions were too small to have a significant impact on the problem of global warming. In February 2007, in the ‘Washington Declaration’, a number of the larger more developed and less developed countries began discussions on an agreement that is intended to replace the Kyoto Protocol, to be developed by 2009. Like the Kyoto Protocol, the new agreement is intended to be based on limits to emissions and a tradable emissions permit system. Test your understanding 6.4 1 (a) Define open access resources. (b) Explain the consequences of the lack of price as a rationing mechanism. (c) Since open access resources have no price, are they free goods? 2 How do property rights (or lack of these) relate to the overuse of open access resources? 3 Under what circumstances is international collaboration essential for the preservation of the environment? 4 How does overuse of common access resources relate to sustainable development? Positive production externalities (spillover benefits) Illustrating positive production externalities Positive production externalities are spillover benefits created by producers. If, for example, a firm engages in research and development, and succeeds in developing a new technology that spreads throughout the economy, there are spillover benefits, because not only the firm, but also society as a whole benefits from widespread adoption of the new technology. Because of the spillover benefits, the social costs of research and development are lower than the private costs. In Figure 6.5(a) (page 170), MSC lies below MPC. The Chapter 6: Market failure 169 · A pharmaceutical company develops a new (a) Positive production externality. S = MPC P spillover benefit MSC medication that benefits not only its users but also those around them from the improved quality of life, increased life expectancy, and so on. Correcting positive production externalities Subsidies 0 D = MPB Q Qm Qopt (b) Correcting the positive production externality by use of a subsidy. P S = MPC subsidy = spillover benefit MSC P1 P2 0 Qm Qopt D = MPB Q Figure 6.5 Positive production externality. market determines equilibrium Qm, determined by the intersection of the MPB and MPC curves, while the social optimum is given by Qopt, determined by the intersection of the MPB with MSC curves. Since Qm < Qopt, the market underallocates resources to research and development activities that lead to new technologies, and not enough of them are undertaken. When there is a positive production externality, the free market underallocates resources to the production of the good, in other words, too few resources are allocated to produce the good, and too little of it is produced relative to what is socially optimum. This is shown by Qm < Qopt in Figure 6.5(a). Further examples of positive production externalities include the following: · Firms train workers who after a period switch jobs and work elsewhere; spillover benefits are created as the new employers and society as a whole benefit from the trained workers. 170 Part 2: Microeconomics A positive production externality gives rise to a marginal social cost curve (MSC) that lies below the marginal private cost (supply) curve, the difference between the two being the spillover benefit. If the government provides a subsidy to the firm per unit of the good produced that is equal to the spillover benefit, then the private marginal cost (supply) curve will shift downward so that it will coincide with the social marginal cost curve, as shown in Figure 6.5(b). The result will be to increase quantity produced to Qopt and to lower the price from P1 to P2. The problem of underallocation of resources and underprovision of the good is corrected, and allocative efficiency is achieved. Correction of positive production externalities involves shifting the MPC (supply) curve downward (through the imposition of a subsidy) towards the MSC curve in Figure 6.5(b). If the MPC curve shifts so that it overlaps with the MSC curve, then the optimal quantity of the good will be produced, the underallocation of resources will be corrected, and allocative efficiency will be achieved. The effect will be to increase the quantity of the good produced so that it equals Qopt, and to lower the price of the good from P1 to P2. Positive consumption externalities (spillover benefits) Illustrating positive consumption externalities When there is a positive consumption externality, spillover benefits are created by consumers. For example, the consumption of education benefits the person who receives the education, but in addition gives rise to spillover benefits, involving benefits to society from a more productive workforce, lower unemployment, higher rate of growth, more economic development, lower crime rate, etc. Similarly, the consumption of health care services benefits not only the person receiving the services, but also society and the economy, because a healthier population is more productive, and may enjoy a higher rate of economic growth. In such cases, the marginal social benefit curve, MSB, in Figure 6.6(a), lies above the marginal private benefit curve and the difference between the two consists of the spillover benefits to society. Since Qopt > Qm, the market underallocates resources to education, and too little of it is produced. When there is a positive consumption externality, the free market underallocates resources to the production of the good, and too little of it is produced relative to what is socially optimum. This is shown by Qm < Qopt in Figure 6.6(a). In general, positive externalities (spillover benefits), whether these arise from production or consumption activities, lead to an underallocation of resources to the good in question, and therefore to underprovision of the good. Correcting positive consumption externalities · Advertising and persuasion Governments can use advertising to try to persuade consumers to buy more goods with positive externalities. For example, they can try to encourage the use of sports facilities for improved health. The objective here is to increase demand for such services, so that once again the marginal private benefit curve, D1 = MPB1, will shift to the right in the direction of the marginal social benefit curve (MSB) in Figure 6.6(b). If the MPB curve shifts enough, it will shift to D2 = MPB2 to coincide with MSB, and Qopt will be produced and consumed. · Subisidies When there is a positive consumption externality, the marginal social benefit curve lies above the marginal private benefit (demand) curve. A subsidy to the producer of the good with the positive externality will result in increasing supply and shifting the supply curve downward. If the subsidy is equal to the spillover benefit, the new supply curve will be MPC + subsidy, shown in Figure 6.6(c). The socially optimum quantity Qopt will now be produced, determined by the intersection of the MPB and MPC + subsidy curves, and the price will fall from P1 to P2. The problems of underallocation of resources and underprovision of the good have been addressed, and allocative efficiency is achieved. · Legislation Legislation can be used to promote greater consumption of goods with positive externalities. For example, many countries have legislation that makes education compulsory up to a certain age. In this case, demand for education increases, and the marginal private benefit curve shifts to the right. Ideally, it will shift until it reaches the MSB curve, as shown in Figure 6.6(b), with the shift from D1 = MPB1 to D2 = MPB2, where Qopt will be produced and consumed. Correction of positive consumption externalities involves increasing demand and shifting the demand (MPB) curve rightward towards the MSB curve, as in Figure 6.6(b), or increasing supply and shifting the supply (MPC) curve downward (through the imposition of a subsidy) so that its intersection with MPB determines Qopt in Figure 6.6(c). (a) Positive consumption externality. (b) Correcting the positive externality by legislation or persuasion. (c) Correcting the positive consumption externality by use of a subsidy. P P P S = MPC S = MPC S = MPC subsidy = spillover benefit P2 P1 MSB MSB = D2 = MPB2 P1 spillover benefit spillover benefit 0 Qm Qopt D = MPB Q 0 D1 = MPB1 Qm Qopt Q MPC + subsidy P1 MSB P2 0 Qm D = MPB Qopt Q Figure 6.6 Positive consumption externality. Chapter 6: Market failure 171 When production occurs at Qopt, the underallocation of resources will be corrected and allocative efficiency is achieved. The effect will be to increase the quantity of the good produced, and raise or lower the price of the good paid by the consumer depending on whether the correction was brought about by an increase in demand (price will increase) or an increase in supply (price will fall). Evaluating measures to correct spillover benefits Subsidies are widely used as a method to deal with positive consumption externalities, and also to a lesser extent positive production externalities. However, a difficulty involved in achieving the results indicated in Figure 6.5(b) and Figure 6.6(c) in practice is that it is very difficult to measure the size of the spillover benefits, and to calculate the precise size of the subsidy that the activities in question should receive. Therefore, in the real world it is very unlikely that governments are able to shift the MPC curves by the amount necessary to correct the positive externalities. The most that can be hoped is that the policies in question will be a step in the right direction. Legislation and advertising are subject to similar limitations concerning calculating the size of the spillover benefits, and can only help shift the MPB curve in the right direction, rather than achieve a demand increase that will bring the economy to the Qopt level of output. Test your understanding 6.5 1 Show diagrammatically how a positive consumption externality differs from a positive production externality, and explain the difference. 2 What is the impact on resource allocation of (a) positive production externalities, and (b) positive consumption externalities. 3 Provide examples of (a) positive production externalities, and (b) positive consumption externalities. 4 What policy options are available to governments wishing to correct (a) a positive production externality, and (b) a positive consumption externality? 172 Part 2: Microeconomics 6.3 Merit goods, demerit goods and public goods Merit and demerit goods Merit goods are goods that are held to be desirable for consumers, but which are underprovided by the market. Note that the term ‘good’ in the expression ‘merit good’ applies to both goods and services. Reasons for underprovision include: · The good may have positive externalities In this case too little is provided by the market. Examples of merit goods include education (for the reasons noted above in the discussion of externalities); immunization programmes (which benefit not only those who have received them but also the broader population by wiping out a disease). · Low levels of income and poverty Some consumers may want certain goods or services but cannot afford to buy them. Recall that demand shows the quantities of a good or service that consumers are willing and able to buy at different prices. If they have low incomes, they may be willing but not able to buy the good or service, in which case their desire does not show up in the market, and market demand (the sum of all individual demands) is too low. Examples include health care services, medicines, education and recreational facilities, which people on low incomes often cannot afford to buy in the market. · Consumer ignorance Consumers may be better off if they consume certain goods and services but they may be ignorant of the benefits, and so do not demand them. For example, preventive health care (such as immunization, annual health check-ups) can prevent serious diseases, but lack of knowledge about the benefits may lead consumers to demand too little of these services. Note that more than one factor may be at work simultaneously; for example, the underprovision of health care services can result from all three reasons listed above. Subsidies in the case of merit goods Demerit goods are goods that are considered to be undesirable for consumers and are overprovided by the market. Reasons for overprovision include: · The good may have negative externalities Too much of it will be provided by the market. One example is cigarettes. · Consumer ignorance or indifference Consumers may not be aware of the harmful effects upon others of their actions, or they may not care. There are several ways governments can address the problem of merit and demerit goods: Direct public provision of merit goods Merit goods are provided by the market, but in quantities lower than the social optimum. The government can use tax revenues to provide the merit goods directly, thereby supplementing the market’s provision. In addition, if the government directly provides the merit good, it is also likely to ‘subsidize’ it, meaning that it makes it available to its users at a very low or zero price. Examples include health care, education, and sports facilities, which are often provided by the government in parallel with the private sector. For example, national health systems in many countries use tax revenues to provide health care services to their populations free or nearly free of charge. Other countries with social insurance systems similarly use social insurance contributions (which are also a type of tax) to provide health services to their populations free or nearly free of charge. In the United States the government provides free health care to certain consumer groups (elderly people and low income people). Many governments of less developed countries that don’t have sufficient tax revenues to provide a broad range of health care services try to provide basic health services to people on low incomes free of charge. In the case of education, elementary education is provided by the government free of charge to consumers in most countries, and many governments also provide education up to university level at no or low cost to consumers. In most countries where there is government provision of health care and education services, there is also private sector provision of these services (though to varying degrees). Merit goods are often goods with positive externalities, so by increasing the supply through subsidies provided to private producers, the quantity supplied will increase to the optimal quantity, thus correcting the underprovision (see Figure 6.6(c)). For example, in the United States, private universities often receive subsidies by the government. Taxes in the case of demerit goods Since demerit goods are often goods that have negative externalities, the logic of using taxes to correct this problem is that taxes lower the quantity of the demerit good produced to the optimal quantity, so that they correct the problem of overallocation of resources and overprovision of the good (see Figure 6.4(c)). Advertising and persuasion for both merit and demerit goods Governments can use advertising to provide information to consumers and try to persuade them to buy more merit goods. For example, they can try to encourage consumers to have annual health checks for improved health. The objective here is to increase demand for such services, so that the private benefits demand curve (MPB) will shift to the right in the direction of the social benefits demand curve (MSB) in Figure 6.6(b). Similarly, advertising can be used to try to persuade consumers to buy fewer goods with negative externalities and demerit goods, such as antismoking campaigns. In this case, the objective is to try to decrease demand for such goods and services, so that the private benefits demand curve, MPB, will shift leftward towards MSB in Figure 6.4(b). Legislation and regulations for both merit and demerit goods Legislation can be used to promote greater consumption of merit goods. For example, many countries have legislation that makes education compulsory up to a certain age. Legislation can also be used to prevent or limit consumer activities that impose costs on third parties and consumption of demerit goods. For example, such activities as smoking in public places, and playing loud music in the middle of the night are often prohibited. Chapter 6: Market failure 173 Public goods Public goods versus private goods To understand what public goods are, it is useful to consider the definition of private goods. A private good has two characteristics: produced by a private firm, people could not be prevented from using it even though they would not pay for it. Yet no profit-maximizing firm would be willing to undertake the production of a good it cannot sell to users at some price. As a result, the market fails to produce goods that are non-excludable. · It is rivalrous, meaning that its consumption by one person reduces its availability for someone else; for example, your computer, your textbook, your pencils, your clothes are rivalrous, because when you buy them, another person cannot buy the same ones; most goods are rivalrous. · It is excludable, meaning that it is possible to exclude people from using the good; exclusion is usually achieved by charging a price for the good; if someone is unwilling or unable to pay the price, he or she will not have the benefit of using it; most goods are excludable. Since most goods are rivalrous and excludable, it follows that most goods are private goods. A public good has the following two characteristics: · It is non-rivalrous; its consumption by one person does not reduce consumption by someone else. · It is non-excludable; it is not possible to exclude someone from using the good. Goods that are non-rivalrous and non-excludable are also known as pure public goods. For example, a lighthouse is non-rivalrous, because its use by one person does not make it less available for use by others. Also, it is non-excludable, because there is no way to exclude anyone from using it. Other examples of public goods include the police force, national defence, flood control, non-toll roads, fire protection, basic research, anti-poverty programmes, and many others. Public goods and the free rider problem How do public goods relate to market failure? In the case of excludable goods, it is possible to prevent people from buying and using the good simply by charging a price for it; those who don’t pay the price do not buy it and do not get to use it. Therefore private firms have an incentive to provide excludable goods because they can charge a price to sell them, and therefore can cover their costs. Non-excludable goods differ: if a non-excludable good were to be 174 Part 2: Microeconomics Public goods illustrate the free rider problem, which arises in situations where people can enjoy the use of a good without having to pay for it, in other words they take a ‘free ride’. The free rider problem arises from non-excludability. (Note that open access resources, discussed earlier, are also subject to the free rider problem, because they are also non-excludable.) Public goods are like merit goods in the sense that they are goods that are desirable for society but are underprovided by the market. However, they also differ from merit goods. Merit goods are usually provided by the market (private firms), but in smaller than optimal quantities. Public goods, on the other hand, are usually not provided at all by the market. Also, merit goods are often private goods in that they are rivalrous and excludable, while public goods are neither. Note also that public goods, though provided to consumers free of charge, are not ‘free goods’. Free goods (recall from Chapter 1, page 4) are not subject to the condition of scarcity, thus having an opportunity cost of zero. Public goods, on the other hand, are produced by the government with scarce resources that have alternative uses; they therefore have an opportunity cost greater than zero. It should also be noted that not all goods provided by the government are public goods. The government provides (or sometimes subsidizes) many other goods, such as merit goods, as well as goods produced by natural monopolies. Public goods that are not ‘pure’ There are some goods that do not fit neatly into the category of private goods or public goods (they can be considered to be ‘impure’ public goods). There are goods that are: · non-rivalrous (like public goods), and · excludable (like private goods). Examples include public museums that charge an entrance fee, public recreational facilities that charge fees for use of the facilities, and toll roads. All these goods and services are excludable because consumers must pay to use them. Since the price system can be made to work here as a rationing mechanism, they could be provided by private firms. However, they all have very large positive externalities, thus justifying direct government provision. Correcting the market’s failure to provide public goods The market fails to allocate resources to public goods, since they are usually not provided by private firms. Therefore the government must step in to ensure that public goods will be produced, and will be produced at socially desirable levels. Thus public goods are directly provided by the government, are financed out of taxation revenues, and are made available to the public free of charge. Test your understanding 6.6 1 Provide examples of (a) merit goods, (b) demerit goods, and (c) public goods. position of the single seller can be preserved. This market structure is characterized by the absence of competition. Monopoly power (explained in Chapter 2, page 31) refers to the ability of a firm or a group of firms to control the price of the product that prevails in the market. This type of power can be exercised not only by monopolies, but also by oligopolies that behave like monopolies (through collusion or cooperation). An oligopoly, it will be recalled, is a market structure characterized by a few large sellers and high barriers to entry. Monopoly power can also be exercised by firms in monopolistic competition, which also have some degree of control over prices (though less than in the cases of monopoly and oligopoly). The exercise of monopoly power is considered to be socially undesirable for the following reasons: · It results in allocative inefficiency: the value attached to the good by consumers is greater than the cost of producing the good, and therefore there is an underallocation of resources to the good – too few resources are devoted to the good. 2 Use the concept of resource allocation to explain · It results in productive inefficiency: production does how (a) merit goods, (b) demerit goods, and (c) public goods are related to market failure. · It results in lower output of the industry as a whole 3 Explain why (a) public goods, and (b) open access resources are subject to the free rider problem. 4 Explain the differences between merit goods and public goods. 5 What are appropriate government policies to correct market failures associated with (a) merit goods, (b) demerit goods, and (c) public goods? 6 (a) Define the characteristics of ‘rivalry’ and ‘excludability’, and use them to classify and define private goods, public goods and impure public goods. (b) How do you think these characteristics apply to free goods? 6.4 Monopoly power Monopoly was discussed briefly in Chapter 2 (Section 2.1, page 29) and extensively in Chapter 5, page 126 (at higher level). It refers to a type of market structure where (a) there is a single firm dominating the market for a product, (b) the product has no close substitutes, and (c) there are high barriers to entry (it is very difficult for other firms to enter the industry). Barriers to entry ensure that the monopoly not take place at the lowest possible cost. than the output that would have resulted if the industry were organized as a competitive one. · It results in a higher price for the product than the price that would have prevailed if the industry were organized as competitive one. · Monopoly power entails an absence of competition, and this may lead to higher costs of production, as the firm is not under any competitive pressure to increase efficiencies in production. · The persistence of profits over the long run earned by the owners of the firm(s) exercising monopoly power may contribute to a more unequal distribution of income (note that this does not apply to firms in monopolistic competition in the long run). Governments can pursue the following kinds of policies to prevent the exercise of excessive monopoly power: Legislation and regulation Legislation in the form of anti-monopoly laws can be used to prevent the development of substantial monopoly power or the exercise of monopoly power. For example, legislation is often used to prevent collusion among oligopolistic firms and to Chapter 6: Market failure 175 Table 6.1 Market failures and their impacts on resource allocation. Type of market failure The market’s impact on resource allocation negative production externality overallocates resources negative consumption externality overallocates resources positive production externality underallocates resources positive consumption externality underallocates resources merit goods underallocates resources demerit goods overallocates resources public goods underallocates resources (or allocates no resources) monopoly power underallocates resources encourage competition between them; to prevent mergers between firms that would result in too much monopoly power; to break up monopolies or near-monopolies that have been found to engage in monopolistic practices into smaller units that will behave more competitively; and in general to encourage competitive behaviour in the economy. Test your understanding 6.7 (...continued) 2 What kinds of policies can governments pursue to avoid undesirable consequences of excessive monopoly power? Government regulation of natural monopolies (for example, gas, electricity, water, etc.) can result in the enforcement of policies that are more favourable to consumers: prices can be set at lower levels and quantities at higher levels than the unregulated monopolist is likely to set. Ideally, regulation would force the natural monopoly to produce the level of output that achieves allocative efficiency. Table 6.1 lists the various kinds of market failures considered in Sections 6.2–6.4, and shows what impact the free, unregulated market will have on the allocation of resources to the production of the good or service. The objective of government policy in each case should be to correct the misallocation problem so as to achieve an outcome that comes as close as possible to the social optimum. Public (government) ownership Important note Government ownership of a monopoly is another method governments use to prevent abuse of monopoly power. Government ownership is sometimes pursued as an alternative to government regulation of natural monopolies, such as water, electricity and telephone companies, and the postal service. The objectives of government ownership are similar to the objectives of government regulation of natural monopolies: to ensure that prices are lower and output greater than would result from an unregulated monopoly. Ideally, the level of output should be such that allocative efficiency will be achieved. Now that you have completed the required part of Chapter 6 and Microeconomics, you are reminded to go back to Chapter 1 and reread Section 1.3, starting on page 16. You will find that it will now make much more sense to you. Test your understanding 6.7 1 (a) Why is abuse of monopoly power socially undesirable? (b) What impacts does this kind of market failure have on the allocation of resources? (...continued) 176 Part 2: Microeconomics 6.5 Additional failures (supplementary material) Markets can fail in a number of additional ways as well. Moreover, even the government, intending to pursue policies that will correct market failures, may itself fail to improve the operation of markets, and may in fact worsen it. Imperfect information and information asymmetries The competitive market mechanism presupposes that all firms and all consumers have complete information regarding products, prices, resources and methods of production. This kind of information is important for markets to work well, as firms, consumers and resource owners must be in possession of sufficient and equal information in order to make informed decisions about their buying and selling activities. However, the real world abounds with examples where firms and consumers are in situations where information is missing, or where they do not have equal access to information. It is often the case that sellers have information about the quality of a good or service that they do not make available to consumers. For example, sellers of used cars have information regarding the car’s quality that they are unlikely to reveal to potential buyers in the event that the car has a defect. In a free and unregulated market, sellers of food could sell products that are unsafe for human consumption, possibly leading to illness and even death. Sellers of medicines could sell unsafe medications that could be ineffective or dangerous to human health. Individuals claiming to be doctors, some of whom have had little or no training in medicine, could practice medicine and even surgery, giving rise to huge costs in terms of human health and safety. Examples along these lines are endless, and illustrate the problem of asymmetric information between sellers and buyers, in cases where sellers have access to information that is not readily available to buyers. In addition, sellers of goods and services could also withhold information related to their role as buyers of resources, specifically labour resources; for example, they could hide information from potential employees regarding unsafe working conditions, also with serious negative consequences for the safety of the workers they employ. And yet, in the real world, as consumers and as workers, we are not as a rule concerned about the possibility of buying foods and medications that will harm us, or about the possibility of being treated by a doctor with no training in medicine, or about being deceived by a firm about the level of safety in working conditions. The reason is that the government intervenes in markets by passing laws and regulations that ensure that there are certain quality standards that must be maintained by producers and sellers of food and medications (and goods and services generally), as well as minimum safety standards in the workplace. In the case of doctors, most countries around the world have laws that require doctors to be licensed, and a licence can only be obtained upon proof of adequate medical competence. Licensing is similarly required for many other professions in many countries, from lawyers to plumbers to electricians. However, even though governments intervene in the interests of the consumer and the worker, it is not always possible to eliminate the information asymmetries that exist between sellers and buyers. To illustrate this point, we may consider the following important examples from the areas of health care and law, where doctors and lawyers have specialized, technical (medical and legal) information about their clients that the clients themselves do not possess (because they do not have the necessary technical expertise). Doctors and lawyers often use this information for their own private gain by selectively revealing information to their clients that causes them to demand more services, whether medical or legal, than are necessary. This practice leads to what is known as supplier-induced demand, meaning that it is demand induced (i.e. created) by the supplier, which would not have arisen if the supplier and the client had equal access to information. Problems with asymmetric information also involve situations where the buyer has information that she or he does not make available to the seller. Such problems often arise in the area of insurance. For example, people in poor health may try to buy health insurance without revealing their true state of health to the insurance company. In all cases where asymmetric information is involved, the allocation of resources is affected. The impact may be to overallocate or underallocate resources to the production of goods and services, depending on the nature of the information asymmetry. For example, in cases of supplier-induced demand, there results an overallocation of resources to the services provided by the suppliers who induce the extra, unnecessary demand for the service. In cases where the buyer of insurance withholds information from the seller, there results an underallocation of resources to insurance services, as the insurance company reduces provision of insurance in an effort to protect itself against the possibility of providing insurance coverage to very high risks. In the area of health care, the problem of underallocation of resources by the market to health insurance (private insurance companies) has given rise to government Chapter 6: Market failure 177 intervention in health care in many countries around the world. Government intervention may take the form of direct provision of health care services at low or zero prices to an entire population, financed by tax revenues, so as to ensure that the entire population has health insurance coverage (as in all countries with a National Health Service); alternatively government intervention can take the form of social health insurance, which may cover a country’s entire population (as in many European countries), or which selectively covers only certain vulnerable groups of the population (as in the United States). Coordination failures One of the objectives of virtually every country in the world is to achieve economic growth. This objective is particularly important in less developed countries, many of which show stagnating economies that register very low and sometimes even negative growth rates. Coordination failures provide a possible explanation for the failure of firms to be set up and to contribute to growth in developing countries. Consider the following example. Let’s say that firms would be able to increase their output, thereby contributing to economic growth, if they began producing in a market requiring skilled labour. But they will not enter this market if the skilled labour is not available; at the same time, workers will not acquire the skills if the firms that could hire them don’t exist. As a result, the firms do not enter this market, and the workers don’t acquire the skills. Both the firms and the workers get stuck in a position where they are worse off than they would have been if they could coordinate their activities and simultaneously enter the new market and acquire the necessary skills. Consider another example, where farmers could increase their production of agricultural goods for sale in the market, thereby giving rise to growth of output and increases in their incomes. To do this they need intermediaries, or ‘middlemen’, who will effectively represent them in distant markets. As long as the middlemen are not available, the farmers will not begin producing for the market; and as long as the agricultural output for the market is not produced, the middlemen will not become available.2 Once again, the farmers get stuck in a position where they are producing less output than they could, and potential 2 See Michael P. Todaro and Stephen C. Smith, Economic Development (Pearson Education, 2006), where these ideas are explored more fully. 178 Part 2: Microeconomics middlemen that could have benefited themselves and the economy do not emerge. Once again, everyone is worse off, and the possibilities for expanding output remain unrealized. A coordination failure involves a situation where the inability of economic decision-makers to coordinate their behaviours results in an outcome where everyone is worse off than they would have been had coordination been possible. Coordination failures arise when two or more activities that must begin simultaneously fail to do so. The important point is that coordination failures occur even as decision-makers make economic decisions that are in their best self-interest. Coordination failures lead to underdevelopment traps, where the inability to coordinate activities that must begin simultaneously traps people into a situation from which they cannot escape without outside help. Development economists are looking increasingly at coordination failures as a likely cause of the inability of some developing countries to begin growth and development. Coordination failures require government intervention or foreign aid to help people escape underdevelopment traps by allowing the simultaneous occurrence of the necessary activities. Weak or missing market institutions In order to be able to function effectively, markets need a particular social, institutional and legal environment that is often missing in the real world, particularly in less developed countries and in transition economies. This environment must include the existence and enforcement of property rights, enforcement of legal contracts, effective legal recourse, a stable currency, a well-developed banking and insurance system, an effective road and utility infrastructure system, and readily available information on prices, quantities and quality of goods, services and resources to consumers, firms and resource owners. In the absence of these conditions, markets are highly imperfect in their functions and fail to function effectively. We will come back to these institutions in Chapters 15 and 16, where we will study their importance to growth and development in less developed countries. Macroeconomic objectives Every real-world economy has certain macroeconomic objectives that must be addressed. These include price stability (the general price level should rise only gradually); full employment (everyone who is willing and able to work should be able to find a job); economic growth (the economy’s output should be steadily increasing); and a reasonable balance of trade (exports and imports of goods and services should be reasonably balanced). The market mechanism cannot accomplish these tasks on its own, and requires government intervention through the use of appropriate policies in pursuit of these objectives. The first three of these objectives and appropriate policies will be discussed in Part 3; the fourth in Part 4. The problem of government failure (policy failure) We have learned in this chapter that government intervention in markets is essential in order to ensure that markets work effectively and that failures are corrected. Yet government intervention does not always improve the operation of markets. Sometimes, not only are market failures not corrected, but instead they may be magnified, or may even be created where they did not previously exist. We have already seen examples of government intervention in markets that has the effect of worsening the allocation of resources, in our study of price controls in Chapter 2 (Section 2.4, page 53). Economists generally do not look upon price controls very favourably, because these invariably intensify problems of resource misallocation. Yet they are often used nonetheless, because governments are driven by various objectives, not all of which involve improving the functioning of the economy. (For example, price support systems in agriculture are used to support farmers’ incomes, even though it is well known that these increase allocative inefficiency, that they result in higher prices and lower quantities of output, etc., as discussed in Chapter 2, page 56.) Government failure, also known as policy failure, occurs when government intervention in markets results in less efficient outcomes than those that would have prevailed in the absence of the intervention. It occurs because: · Governments are a reflection of politics, and respond to political pressures created by the influence of powerful interest groups and the sometimes narrow interests of their supporters. This is certainly the case in the use of price supports to support farmers’ incomes in many developed countries, giving rise to a global misallocation of resources, at the same time as they hurt consumers and taxpayers as well as farmers in less developed countries. (This example of government failure is so important it will be studied in more detail in Chapter 16.) · Governments do not always have all necessary information at their disposal to formulate appropriate policies. · Government policies have a certain inertia that is sometimes difficult to change. Once particular laws, rules and regulations have been established, they cannot be changed easily because of rigidities and the unwieldiness of the political process. One of the more striking examples of government failure involves the use of ‘perverse subsidies’. As we know, subsidies have the effect of increasing output produced by shifting the market supply curve downward (or to the right; see Figure 6.5(b) and 6.6(c)). In more developed and less developed countries alike, subsidies are often used for fossil fuels, with the effect of encouraging fossil fuel production and consumption, contributing significantly to environmental pollution, and reducing incentives for the development of alternative non-polluting energy sources. Reasons for fossil fuel subsidies include the promotion of the industrial sector by keeping costs down, promotion of international competitiveness of industrial products, support of domestic fuel production to ensure adequate domestic supply and to reduce reliance on foreign sources (for those countries that are fossil fuel producers), and to keep fuel prices low for consumers. The impacts of subsides on fossil fuels are entirely inconsistent with the pursuit of sustainable development. Test your understanding 6.7 1 How do information problems give rise to market failure? 2 (a) What are coordination failures? (b) Why are they important to less developed countries? 3 What are some of the institutions that are necessary for a market to function effectively? 4 Problems relating to government behaviour have traditionally been studied by sociologists and political scientists. Why do you think these subjects are now also studied by economists? Chapter 6: Market failure 179 Questions for 6.1 6.2 6.3 6.4 6.5 6.6 180 review [10 marks] (a) Explain the meaning of ‘market failure’, using the concept of allocative efficiency. (b) Referring to the difference between (i) private and social benefits; and (ii) private and social costs, explain why this distinction is important in connection with the achievement of allocative efficiency. [20 marks] Using diagrams, show the impacts on resource allocation, and provide an example, in each of the following cases: (a) a negative externality in production; (b) a negative externality in consumption; (c) a positive externality in production; (d) a positive externality in consumption. [15 marks for part (a); 15 marks for part (b)] (a) Using diagrams, show how the concept of (i) negative production externalities and (ii) negative consumption externalities can be used to analyse the problem of pollution. (b) Evaluate possible policy responses in the case of each of these. [20 marks] Using diagrams and the concepts of positive and negative externalities, show how each of the following leads to market failure: (a) a cure is discovered for HIV/AIDS; (b) a firm discovers a new robot technology that is widely adopted by other firms; (c) in some poor countries, very poor farmers are forced to clear forests to create more arable land for farming; (d) in many poor countries, very poor farmers use wood and other biomass fuels for heating and cooking purposes in their homes, often with very poor ventilation. [10 marks for part (a); 10 marks for part (b)] A policy tool that governments can use to correct market failures involving spillover benefits is subsidies. Using diagrams, explain how subsidies can help correct (a) a positive consumption externality resulting from the consumption of education; (b) a positive production externality resulting from a firm’s activities in research and development (R&D). [15 marks] (a) How can the concept of market failure be used to explain environmental problems? (b) Define ‘sustainable development’ and explain its relationship to environmental problems. (c) What are some policies governments can use to try to correct these kinds of market failures. Part 2: Microeconomics 6.7 [15 marks] (a) Using the concept of ‘merit good’, explain the reasons why education and health care services are underprovided by the private sector. (b) What are the policy options open to governments to correct this problem? 6.8 [15 marks] (a) Define merit goods and public goods; discuss their similarities and differences; and show how each one is a type of market failure. (b) What kinds of policies can governments pursue to deal with the market failure that each of these gives rise to? 6.9 [15 marks] (a) Providing examples and using diagrams, explain the difference between merit and demerit goods. (b) What are some appropriate government policies governments can use to correct these types of market failure? 6.10 [10 marks] Both public goods and free goods are non-rivalrous and non-excludable. Yet they differ from each other in very important ways. Define public goods and free goods, and explain how they differ from each other. 6.11 [10 marks] (a) Define monopoly power. (b) Why is it considered to be socially undesirable? (c) What can the government do to limit excessive monopoly power? 6.12 [10 marks] (a) What are tradable permits? (b) Using a diagram, explain how a market for tradable permits is intended to work. (c) What kinds of problems can they be used to address? 6.13 [15 marks] (Based on Chapters 3 and 6) Explain the following statement: ‘An indirect tax imposed by the government on heating oil for the purpose of addressing the problem of pollution (a negative consumption externality) will be less effective the more inelastic is the demand for oil.’ 6.14 [15 marks] Using your knowledge of Economics acquired by reading Chapters 1–2 and Chapter 6, evaluate the free market economy, taking into account its potential advantages and its shortcomings. Part 3 Macroeconomics Macroeconomics studies the economy as a whole. In contrast to microeconomics, where we examine specific product and resource markets and the behaviour of individual decision-making units such as consumers, firms and resource owners, we now focus on the larger picture of the economy, composed of collections of many consumers, firms, resource owners and markets. Instead of individual product prices, we study the general price level of the economy; instead of demand for individual products, we examine total demand for goods and services; and instead of individual firm and industry supply, we examine the total output produced in the economy. Further, we study total employment, total investment, total exports and imports and more such totals or wholes, which in macroeconomics are called aggregates. The study of macroeconomics is prompted by some very important economic objectives that cannot be understood and analysed at the level of microeconomics. The most important of these objectives are the following: · · · · · how to achieve full employment how to achieve a stable or gently rising price level how to achieve economic growth how to achieve an equitable distribution of income how to achieve external balance (balance of trade and avoidance of balance of payments problems). The first four of these objectives are the subject of Part 3 of this book on Macroeconomics. External balance is discussed in Part 4, which deals with the international economy. Chapter 7 Macroeconomics Macroeconomic concepts and measurement In this chapter we will discover how economists measure an economy’s total output and income, as well as growth in output and income. We will also study measurement of economic development, which, though related to output and income growth, extends far beyond it. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 182 use the circular flow of income model to explain three ways of measuring the economy’s aggregate output and income understand the significance of leakages and injections for the size of the circular flow of income distinguish between gross and net investment, and GDP and NDP explain the difference between GDP and GNP, and explain how they relate to measurement of output as opposed to measurement of the standard of living distinguish between nominal and real values of income and output measures, and explain their significance in making comparisons of output and income measures over time distinguish between total and per capita measures, and explain their significance in measuring total output, standards of living and economic growth explain the concept of economic growth and how this is measured analyse the sources of economic growth explain the concept of economic development and how this differs from economic growth explain why some limited economic development is possible without growth, but that growth is essential to development over extended periods of time evaluate the GDP measure as the basis for making international comparisons of welfare explain the significance of purchasing power parities in international comparisons of GDP identify and explain the complexities of measuring economic development use individual and composite indicators as indicators of economic development and show the limitations of GDP as a measure of economic development. Part 3: Macroeconomics The simple circular flow of income In Chapter 1, page 6, we developed the circular flow model to help us understand how the different parts of the economy are interrelated. We will now use the same model to see how the output and income of a nation are measured. If you refer to Figure 1.1 (page 6), you will remember that there are two flows in this model: the flow of factors of production and goods and services (called the ‘real flow’), and the flow of payments from firms to consumers and from consumers to firms (called the ‘money flow’). In the money flow, households receive payments from firms when they sell their factors of production, consisting of rent (for land), wages (for labour), interest (for capital) and profit (for entrepreneurship); these represent the income of households. Households use their income to pay firms for the goods and services they buy. These payments are household expenditure (or consumer expenditure). This simple model demonstrates an important principle: the income flow from firms to households is equal to the expenditure flow from households to firms. In other words, the incomes generated through the sale of all the factors of production must be equal to the expenditures by households on goods and services. This constitutes the circular flow of income. In addition, these two flows must be equal to the value of goods and services, or the value of total output produced by the firms. The reasoning of this is as follows: if each good and service is multiplied by its respective price, we obtain the value of each good and service. Adding up all these values, we arrive at the value of total output. This value is the same as consumer expenditure, because spending by consumers is equal to each item they buy multiplied by its respective price. Therefore the factor income flow equals the expenditure flow that equals the value of output. Adding leakages and injections The real-world economy is more complicated than this simple model suggests. We can arrive at a closer approximation of the real world by adding injections and leakages (also known as withdrawals) to the money flow of Figure 1.1. To understand what these are, consider a pipe with water flowing through it, as in Figure 7.1. As the water flows through the pipe, some of it leaks out (the leakages), while new supplies of water are injected in (the injections). It is the same with the flows of money in the circular flow model. lea k The circular flow model revisited es ag water flow ns We will begin our study of macroeconomics with an examination of the overall quantity of goods and services, or total output produced in an economy, also known as aggregate output. This concept is closely related to the economy’s total income. The circular flow of income illustrates an important principle: in any given time period (say a year), the value of output produced by an economy is equal to the total income that is generated in producing that output, which is equal to the expenditures made to purchase that output. tio 7.1 Measuring national income and output ec inj Figure 7.1 Leakages and injections Leakages and injections are paired together so that what leaks out of the flow can come back in as an injection. The most important pairs are the following: leakages saving taxes imports injections investment government spending exports Saving and investment The first pair involves saving and investment. Saving is that portion of consumer income that is not spent but is saved. Investment is spending by firms for the production of capital goods. You may remember from Chapter 1, page 5, that capital is one of the four factors of production. Investment is therefore the spending by firms to produce capital goods. This is why capital goods are also known as investment goods. How are saving and investment linked together as leakages and injections? Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 183 Households usually save a portion of their income; this represents a leakage from the circular flow of income because it is income that is not spent to buy goods and services. Households place their savings in financial markets (bank accounts, purchases of stocks and bonds, etc.). Firms obtain funds from financial markets (through borrowing, issuing stocks and bonds, etc.) in order to finance investment, or the production of capital goods. These funds therefore flow back into the expenditure flow as injections. This process is shown in Figure 7.2, which, in addition to the simple money flow of Figure 1.1, shows the three leakage/injection pairs listed above. (For simplicity, this figure omits the real flow.) The leakages appear in the left-hand side of the figure, and the injections on the right. We can see that saving leaks out of the flow of consumer expenditures, and after passing through financial markets is injected back into the expenditure flow as investment. and purchased by foreigners. Imports and exports are linked together through ‘other countries’. Imports appear as a leakage because they represent household spending that leaks out as payments to the other countries that have produced the goods and services. Exports are an injection because they are spending by foreigners who buy goods and services produced by the domestic firms. Taxes and government spending Next we consider taxes and government spending, which are connected to each other through the government. Households pay taxes to the government; this represents a leakage because it is income that is not spent to buy goods and services. The government uses the funds collected through taxes to finance government expenditures (on education, health, defence, etc.) and this spending is an injection back into the expenditure flow. As we can see in Figure 7.2, taxes flow out of the expenditure flow as leakages, and government spending flows back in as injections. Imports and exports The third pair involves imports and exports. Imports are goods and services that have been produced in other countries and purchased by domestic buyers. Exports are goods and services produced domestically It should be noted that leakages and injections do not have to be equal to each other. In fact, in the real world, they are unlikely to be equal. When they are unequal, there are important consequences for the circular flow of income. If a leakage is greater than an injection, then the size of the circular flow of income becomes smaller. For example, say that saving (a leakage) is larger than investment (an injection). This means that a portion of the household income that leaks in the form of saving into financial markets does not come back into the flow as investment. The result is that the expenditure flow will become smaller. Fewer goods and services will be purchased, firms will cut back on their output of goods and services, they will buy fewer factors of production, unemployment will increase (since firms buy a smaller quantity of labour services) and household income will be reduced. If, on the other hand, a leakage is smaller than an injection, then the size of the circular flow will become larger. For example, if exports are larger than imports, the size of the expenditure flow increases since more expenditures are injected into the spending flow than are leaking out. Households will demand more goods and services, firms will begin to produce more by purchasing more factors of production, unemployment will fall (as firms now buy a larger quantity of labour services), and household income will increase. Summarizing we can say that: factor incomes (wages, rents, interest, profit) households (consumers) firms (businesses) consumer expenditure (spending on goods and services) ni mp ort s Figure 7.2 Circular flow of income with leakages and injections. 184 Part 3: Macroeconomics t en st m inve government me ern v o g nt spe n di ng on exp orts di en sp ng o tax es financial markets di ng savi ng en sp other countries Leakages from the circular flow of income (saving, taxes and imports) are matched by injections into the circular flow of income (investment, government spending and exports), though these need not be equal to each other. If leakages are larger than injections, the income flow becomes smaller; if injections are larger than leakages the income flow becomes larger. Test your understanding 7.1 1 Use the simple circular flow model to (a) illustrate the circular flow of income, and (b) show the equality between factor income flow, the household expenditure flow and the value of output. 2 (a) What are leakages and injections in the circular flow of income? (b) Use the circular flow of income model to illustrate how the three pairs of leakages and injections are linked together. 3 What happens to the size of the income flow when (a) leakages are larger than injections, and (b) injections are larger than leakages? National income accounting We have seen that the circular flow of income illustrates an important principle: in any given time period, the value of total (or aggregate) output produced by an economy is equal to the total income that is generated in producing that output, which is equal to the expenditures made to purchase that output. We will now use this principle to see how national income or the value of output is measured. Measurement of an economy’s national income or output is referred to as national income accounting. Knowing the value of national income or output is very useful because it allows us to: · assess an economy’s performance over time (are income and output increasing over time; are they decreasing?) · make comparisons of income and output performance with other economies · establish a basis for devising policies that will meet economic objectives. Note that we have been referring throughout to the ‘value’ of output. Why speak in terms of values, and not in terms of quantities, as we did in microeconomics? The answer is that in macroeconomics we must find a way to add up the quantities of output of hundreds of thousands of different goods and services. Yet how can we add up quantities of computers, apples, cars and theatre tickets? What unit of measurement can we use? To get around this difficulty, we measure output in money terms, or in terms of the value of goods and services. When we speak of the ‘value’ of a good, we mean simply the quantity of the good multiplied by its respective price. Sometimes the term ‘value’ may not be explicitly mentioned. For example, one may speak of the ‘level of aggregate output’ or just simply ‘aggregate output’. Whatever the case, in macroeconomics output is always measured in value terms. There are three ways to measure the value of aggregate output, all suggested by the circular flow of income model, and all giving rise to the same result: · the expenditure method, which adds up all spending on final goods and services produced within a country in a given time period · the income method, which adds up all income earned by the factors of production in the course of producing all goods and services within a country in a given time period · the output method, which calculates the value of all final goods and services produced in the country within a given time period. The expenditure method The expenditure method measures the total amount of spending on final goods and services within a country in a particular time period (usually a year). The term ‘final’ requires some explanation. Final goods and services are those that are ready for final use, and can be contrasted with intermediate goods and services, which are those purchased as inputs for the production of final goods. When we measure the value of aggregate output, we include only purchases of final goods and services. For example, food items such as meat and vegetables are intermediate goods for a restaurant that uses them to prepare a meal, and the meal is the final good. If in measuring expenditures we included spending on the food items plus spending on the meal, this would involve double counting and the value of aggregate output would be exaggerated. On the other hand, meat and vegetables purchased by a household for Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 185 consumption count as final goods, since they are not used as inputs for the production of another good or service. Total spending can be broken down into four components: consumption, investment, government purchases, and net exports: · Consumption spending, abbreviated as C, includes all purchases by households on final goods and services in the course of a year (except housing, which is classified under investment). These expenditures include spending on ❍ ❍ ❍ consumer durables (goods that have an expected life of more than three years, such as cars, refrigerators, washing machines, televisions, etc.) spending on consumer non-durables (goods with an expected life of less than three years, such as food, clothing and medicines) spending on services (entertainment, banking, health care, education, etc.). · Investment spending, abbreviated as I, includes the following: ❍ ❍ all spending by firms on capital goods (i.e. buildings, machinery, equipment, etc.) all spending on new construction (housing and other buildings).1 · Government purchases, abbreviated as G, refers to all spending on goods and services by governments at all levels within a country (national, regional, local). It includes purchases by the government of factors of production, including labour services. It excludes transfer payments, as these do not represent government purchases.2 · Net exports (exports minus imports), abbreviated as X − M, refers to the value of all exports (abbreviated as X) minus the value of all imports (abbreviated as M). Exports are goods and services produced within the country and so must be included in the measurement of aggregate output. Imports, 1 Investment spending includes one more item: changes in inventories. Inventories refer to output produced by firms that remains unsold. Businesses as a rule keep inventories to help them meet unexpected increases in the demand for their product. Since inventories are output, it means that they must be counted as part of the aggregate output that is being measured. However, since they are output that has not been sold, they cannot be counted under consumption expenditure (C); they are therefore counted under investment. 2 Transfer payments are all payments transferred by the government to particular social groups, such as unemployment benefits, disability benefits and various other welfare payments. They are not included under government spending because they do not represent payment for factors of production, or payment for purchases of final goods and services. Transfer payments will be considered in Chapter 11 under the topic of income distribution. 186 Part 3: Macroeconomics however, involve domestic spending on goods and services that have been produced in other countries, and so must be subtracted from expenditures measuring domestic output. If we add together the four components of spending, we obtain a measure of aggregate output known as gross domestic product (GDP): C + I + G + (X − M) = GDP Gross domestic product or GDP is defined as the market value of all final goods and services produced within a country during a given time period (usually a year). It includes spending by the four components, C + I + G + (X − M). It is the most commonly used measure of the value of aggregate output. The income method The income method adds up all income earned by the factors of production within a country in a given time period: wages earned by labour, rent earned by land, interest earned by capital, and profits earned by entrepreneurship. When all factor incomes are added up, the result is national income. Whereas national income is often used as a measure of the level of economic activity, it is not the same as GDP arrived at by use of the expenditure approach. To arrive at GDP using the income approach, it is necessary to make some adjustments to national income.3 The output method The output method measures the value of each good and service produced in the economy over a particular time period (usually a year) and then sums them up to obtain the total value of output produced. It measures the value of all final goods and services, in order to avoid the double counting that would arise from including the values of intermediate goods and 3 A detailed consideration of these adjustments is beyond the scope of this book. For the interested student, they will be mentioned briefly here. If we add depreciation and indirect taxes to national income, we obtain a measure of aggregate output called gross national product (GNP). The difference between GNP and GDP will be considered later in this chapter. Depreciation refers to the wearing out of capital goods, and will also be considered later. The reason we add depreciation and indirect taxes to national income in order to obtain GNP (and GDP) is that the value of output measured by the expenditure approach includes both these items. By contrast, national income, measuring only the incomes of the factors of production, does not include either of the two. services. The method used to obtain the value of only final goods and services is to count only the value added in each step of the production process.4 The output approach calculates the value of output by economic sector, such as, for example, agriculture, manufacturing, transport, banking, etc. The value of output of each sector is then added up to obtain the total value of output for the entire economy. This approach provides us with the opportunity to study the performance of each individual sector, and to make comparisons of performance across sectors. The three approaches give rise to the same result, after allowance is made for statistical discrepancies that arise in the course of measuring the different variables involved. Test your understanding 7.2 and are discarded. The loss of value of capital that gets worn out in the course of a year is called depreciation. Capital goods that become worn out and are discarded must be replaced. This means that in any given year, of the total new production of capital goods, a portion goes to replace capital goods that have been discarded (depreciated), and the rest are new additions to the stock of capital goods. Recall that investment, one of the components of GDP, refers in part to spending by businesses on capital goods. Total investment that takes place within a year is known as gross investment. Gross investment can therefore be divided into two parts: · the part that goes toward replacing worn out capital goods, or depreciation · the part that consists of new additions to the stock of capital goods, known as net investment. 1 Why is it useful to know the value of aggregate output? To put it more simply: 2 Explain why (a) we measure aggregate output in value terms; (b) we count only the value of final goods and services when measuring the value of output. 3 What are the four expenditure components of GDP? Explain each of these. 4 (a) Explain three ways that GDP can be measured. (b) Why do they give rise to the same result? Key distinctions relating to measures of the value of output gross investment = depreciation + net investment (total investment) = (discarded + (additions of capital goods) new capital) This means that gross investment − depreciation = net investment. It follows that: · If gross investment is greater than depreciation, there is positive net investment, and the stock of capital goods has increased. · If gross investment is less than depreciation, then net investment is negative, and the stock of capital goods has declined. Distinction between gross and net What does the term ‘gross’ in ‘gross domestic product’ refer to? It is related to spending to produce capital. You may remember from Chapter 1, page 5, that capital, which is a produced factor of production, consists of buildings, equipment and machinery. All of these have a finite life, in other words, they do not last forever. Within any given year, some of the capital goods in an economy become completely worn out 4 For example, say the production of a good goes through the following steps. Firm A sells raw materials for $700 to Firm B. Firm B uses the raw materials and produces an intermediate good that it sells to Firm C for $1100. Firm C uses this intermediate good to produce a final good that it sells for $1700. How much value has been added in this process? Firm A added $700 of value. Firm B added $400 of value (= $1100 − $700), and Firm C added $600 of value (= $1700 − $1100). When we add these up we obtain: Returning now to our discussion of measures of the value of output, it becomes clear that in the expression for gross domestic product, GDP = C + I + G + (X − M), I refers to gross (or total) investment. This is because GDP measures an economy’s total output, and therefore includes total spending on capital goods, whether these involve replacements of depreciated capital, or new additions to the capital stock. $700 + $400 + $600 = $1700. Note that the sum of the values that were added in each step of the production process is exactly equal to the value of the final product. If we had added up the values of the two intermediate products and the final product, we would have: $700 + $1100 + $1700 = $3500, which greatly exaggerates the value of the product due to double counting. By counting only values added in each step of the production process, the problem of double counting is avoided. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 187 An alternative way of measuring the value of aggregate output is to use net investment instead. We then arrive at a measure called net domestic product (NDP): NDP = C + In + G + (X − M) where In = net investment. It follows then that NDP = GDP − depreciation Test your understanding 7.3 1 (a) Explain the concepts of gross investment, net investment and depreciation. (b) What is the relationship between them? 2 How do the concepts in question 1 relate to the stock of capital goods? To eliminate the influence of changing prices on the value of output, we must calculate real values. Real value is a measure of value that takes into account changes in prices over time. It is measured in terms of prices that prevailed in one particular year in the past, called a base year. Real GDP, in particular, is GDP that is valued in the prices of the base year. Meaningful comparisons over time in the value of output, or expenditures, or income, or any variable that is measured in money terms, require the use of real values. For example, when we make comparisons of GDP in a country over time, we must be sure to use real GDP values, as these have eliminated the influence of price changes, and give us an indication of how actual output produced has changed. 3 How is it possible for net investment to be negative? What does this mean for the stock of capital goods? 4 What is the meaning of ‘gross’ in ‘gross domestic product’? 5 What is the difference between GDP and NDP? Distinction between nominal and real Earlier it was noted that in macroeconomics we measure output in value terms, and we defined ‘value’ to be the quantity of a good multiplied by its price. Nominal value is money value, or value measured in terms of prices that prevail at the time of measurement. For example, if a pair of shoes costs £100, this is its nominal value. If you buy this pair of shoes, £100 is your nominal expenditure on these shoes. If your monthly income is £2000, this is your nominal income. Therefore when we calculate the value of aggregate output, or expenditure, or income, in money terms, we speak of nominal GDP, nominal expenditure, nominal income, etc. Yet prices change over time, and this poses a measurement problem. Let’s say that nominal GDP increases in the course of a year. This increase may be due to changes in the quantities of output produced, or changes in the prices of goods and services, or a combination of both. We have no way of knowing what part of the increase in nominal GDP is due to changes in output and what part to changes in prices. Yet we are interested in knowing how much the quantity of goods and services has increased. We must therefore find a measure of GDP that is not influenced by changes in prices. 188 Part 3: Macroeconomics Nominal value is value measured in terms of current prices (prices at the time of measurement), which does not account for changes in the price level. Real value is a measure of value that has eliminated the influence of changes in the price level, and is calculated by reference to constant prices. When a variable is being compared over time, it is important to use real values. Test your understanding 7.4 1 Why do price changes over time pose a problem when we want to make comparisons of GDP (or any measure of output or income) over time? 2 Explain the difference between nominal and real values. 3 Why is it important to use real values when making comparisons over time? 4 You read in the newspaper that government spending on education in your country increased by 7% last year. What information do you need to be able to make sense of this figure? Calculating nominal and real GDP We can better understand the use of base year prices to calculate real GDP if we consider a numerical example where we calculate nominal and real GDP. Let’s consider a hypothetical economy producing three items (a consumer good, a service and a capital good): hamburgers, haircuts and tractors. Table 7.1(a) shows the quantities of the three items produced and their prices over a period of three years, and calculates nominal GDP for each of the three years. Table 7.1 Nominal and real GDP in a hypothetical economy. (a) Calculating nominal GDP. (1) Goods and services (2) 2001 Q (3) 2001 P Hamburgers 37 £3 Haircuts 15 Tractors 10 (4) 2001 value (Q × P) (5) 2002 Q (6) 2002 P (7) 2002 value (Q × P) (8) 2003 Q (9) 2003 P (10) 2003 value (Q × P) £111 40 £4 £160 39 £5 £195 £18 £270 17 £20 £340 18 £21 £378 £50 £500 11 £60 £660 10 £65 £650 £881 Nominal GDP £1160 £1223 (b) Calculating real GDP. (1) Goods and services (2) 2001 Q (3) 2001 P Hamburgers 37 £3 Haircuts 15 Tractors 10 Real GDP (4) 2001 output in 2001 P (Q × P) (5) 2002 Q (6) 2001 P (7) 2002 output in 2001 P (Q × P) (8) 2003 Q (9) 2001 P (10) 2003 output in 2001 P (Q × P) £111 40 £3 £120 39 £3 £117 £18 £270 17 £18 £306 18 £18 £324 £50 £500 11 £50 £550 10 £50 £500 £881 In 2001, 37 hamburgers were produced and sold at £3 each, making the total value of hamburgers in that year £111; 15 haircuts were provided at £18 each making a total value of haircuts of £270; and 10 tractors were produced and sold at £50 each, with a total value of tractors equal to £500. When we add up the total values of the three goods and services, we obtain nominal GDP, or the nominal value of goods and services produced, which was £881 in 2001. The nominal GDP figures appearing for 2002 and 2003 are calculated in the same way. Part (b) of Table 7.1 shows how we can use the information given in part (a) to obtain real GDP figures. Our objective is to calculate GDP figures for each of the three years that, when compared with each other, show us whether a larger or smaller quantity of goods and services was produced in 2002 and 2003 compared to 2001. In order to do this we must find the value of quantities produced in 2001, 2002 and 2003 using the same prices of any one year, called a base year. Therefore real GDP is a measure of output valued at constant (unchanging) prices. These constant prices are simply the prices that prevailed during the base year. We can choose any year we like as the base year. In the example here the base year selected is 2001. To calculate real GDP, we simply £976 £941 multiply the quantities of output produced each year by the prices of the base year. If you compare part (a) of the table with part (b), you will see that the figures in columns 2, 5 and 8 are exactly the same in both parts; this is because in calculating both nominal and real GDP, we use the quantities that were produced and sold in the current year. Also, you will notice that in part (b) of the table, the prices appearing in columns 3, 6 and 9 are identical and are the prices that had prevailed in 2001; this is because we use the prices of the base year, or 2001, to calculate real GDP. For example, in 2002, the 40 hamburgers that were produced and purchased are valued at the 2001 price of hamburgers, which was £3; the 17 haircuts are valued at the 2001 price of £18, and the 11 tractors are valued at the 2001 price of £50. When we add up the resulting values of the three goods and services shown in column 7, we get a measure of real GDP of £976 in 2001 prices. Similarly, in 2003, the 39 hamburgers, 18 haircuts and 10 tractors were also valued at the prices of 2001. What can we conclude about the changes in real GDP that occurred between 2001 and 2003? Whereas real Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 189 GDP increased from 2001 to 2002 (from £881 it went up to £976), between 2002 and 2003 it decreased, falling from £976 to £941. Note that real GDP fell in 2002–03 even as nominal GDP increased over the same period. The reason is that price increases caused nominal GDP to rise, while falling quantities meant that real GDP was falling. (Note that in the base year, 2001, nominal GDP is equal to real GDP; this must be the case since real GDP is valued at base year prices. In the other two years, 2002 and 2003, real GDP is lower than nominal GDP; this is to be expected, because prices have been increasing, and the real figures measure the value of output after the influence of price increases has been eliminated, while the nominal values also contain the influence of the price increases.) Nominal GDP measures the value of current output valued at current prices, while real GDP measures the value of current output valued at constant (base year) prices. In order to make meaningful comparisons over time, we must be sure we are using real values that have eliminated the impacts of price changes. It should be noted that when we refer to real GDP figures, we must at the same time refer to the specific base year whose prices were used for the computation. In the example above, we must say ‘in 2003 real GDP at 2001 prices was £941’. The figure of £941 is meaningless if we don’t know that 2001 prices were used to calculate it. The reason is that if we had used a different base year, we would have arrived at a completely different figure for 2003 real GDP. It follows, too, that it is meaningless to compare real GDP figures that were calculated on the basis of different base years. Test your understanding 7.5 1 Explain the difference between nominal and real GDP. 2 You read in one source of information that real GDP in a hypothetical country in 2001 was $243 billion; in another source of information you read that real GDP in 2002 was $277 billion. (a) What information do you need to be able to make sense of these figures? (b) What information do you need to be sure that the two figures can be compared with each other? 190 Part 3: Macroeconomics Distinction between total and per capita Per capita means per person or per head. A per capita measure takes the total value (of output, income, expenditure, etc.) and divides this by the total population of a country. Therefore per capita GDP of a country is total GDP of that country divided by its population. The distinction between total and per capita measures is very important for two reasons: · Differing population sizes across countries Let’s say there are two countries that have identical total GDPs of £10 billion. Country A has a population of 1 million people and Country B has a population of 2 million people. If we divide total GDP by population we get GDP per capita of £10,000 for country A and £5000 for Country B. Whereas both countries have identical GDPs, Country B’s per capita GDP is only half that of Country A, because of differing population sizes. · Population growth Changes in the size of GDP per capita over time depend very much on the relationship between growth in total GDP and growth in population. In general, if total GDP increases faster than the population, then GDP per capita increases. But if the country’s population increases faster than total GDP, then GDP per capita falls. (We will soon do a numerical example to illustrate this point, see page 192.) Total measures of the value of output, such as GDP, GNP, and income, provide a summary statement of the overall size of an economy. Per capita figures are useful as a summary measure of the standard of living in a country, because they provide an indication of how much of total output in the economy corresponds to each person in the population on average. Note that if we are interested in making comparisons in per capita GDP over time, we must examine real GDP per capita, which is total real GDP divided by the size of the population. Test your understanding 7.6 1 Why is it sometimes important to make a distinction between total measures and per capita measures of income and output? (...continued) Test your understanding 7.6 (...continued) 2 What kind of information about an economy does a total GDP figure provide, as opposed to a per capita GDP figure? 3 If we want to compare GDP per capita in a particular country over a period of years, why must we use real per capita GDP figures (refer to the previous section)? Distinction between domestic and national: GDP versus GNP The distinction between ‘domestic’ and ‘national’ arises because in practically every country, income generated within the country is not exactly the same as income received by the residents of the same country. The reason is that incomes (wages, rent, interest and profits) are sometimes generated by factors of production located within one country, but whose owners are residents of another. Consider the case where a United States multinational firm operating in India remits (sends back) its profits to the United States. The profit income is generated in India (it is income resulting from a process of production that is located in India), but is received by residents in the United States. Should this income count as part of the income and output of the United States or of India? Consider also a Russian worker who lives and works in Spain, and sends a large part of her income to her family in Russia. Should her income count as part of Spanish or Russian income and output? The concepts ‘domestic’ and ‘national’ are used to distinguish between different measures of aggregate output and income that have been developed to deal with this issue. The term ‘domestic’ in ‘gross domestic product’ means that the output being measured has been produced by factors of production located within the boundaries of a country, regardless of whether these factors of production are owned by residents of the country or by foreigners. The income represented by the GDP measure is similarly income generated within the boundaries of the country, regardless of factor ownership. By contrast, the term ‘national’ is used in another measure of aggregate output known as gross national product (GNP). The term ‘national’ means that the output being measured has been produced by factors of production owned by residents of a single country, regardless of the factors’ location within or outside of the country. The income represented by the GNP measure is therefore the income of the residents of a country, regardless of where this income was generated, i.e. regardless of where the factors of production are located. (You may note that the GNP measure is closer to national income, or the sum of factor incomes as in the income approach to measuring aggregate output, than to GDP, because national income includes the income earned by factors of production of the residents of a country, regardless of the location of the factors. In fact, since 1998, the expression ‘gross national product’, which had been in use for many decades, has been replaced by ‘gross national income’ (GNI). GNI is identical to GNP. In this text we are using the GNP terminology in keeping with the IB syllabus.) To convert GDP to GNP, we: · add to GDP the income of domestic residents that is earned abroad, and · subtract from GDP the income earned domestically and paid abroad to foreigners. Therefore GNP = GDP + income from abroad − income sent abroad Returning to the example above, the profit income remitted (sent back) to the United States counts as Indian gross domestic product (GDP), because it was generated within India, but it counts as part of United States gross national product (GNP), because it is income paid to United States residents. GDP is the total market value of all final goods and services produced within the boundaries of a country during a given time period (usually a year), regardless of ownership of the factors of production. GNP is the total market value of all final goods and services produced by the factors of production supplied by the residents of a country during a given time period (usually a year), regardless of where the factors are located. For some countries the difference in the relative sizes of the two measures of output, GDP versus GNP, is not very large. This happens when most of the production occurring within the geographical boundaries of a country is by factors of production owned by residents of the country. When this is not the case, the difference can be quite significant. The factors of production that mainly account for differences in the two measures are labour and capital. Countries that Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 191 have a large foreign presence, either as workers from other countries (labour), or as foreign corporations (capital), tend to have a larger GDP per capita than GNP per capita, because the wages and profits of the foreigners are included in their measure of GDP but excluded from GNP. This is because a portion of wages of foreign workers and profits of foreign corporation owners are sent back to the home country, thus counting as the GNP of workers’ and corporation owners’ home country. By contrast, countries that receive large transfers of money from workers or corporation owners located in a foreign country are likely to have a larger GNP per capita than GDP per capita. For this reason, it is possible for some countries to enjoy a higher standard of living even though they may have relatively low levels of domestic production. 7.2 Concepts and measurement of economic growth and economic development In developing countries, the presence of multinational corporations that ‘repatriate their profits’, in other words, send their profits back to the home country, tends to make GDP larger than GNP. On the other hand, if there are workers living abroad who are sending some of their income back home (this is referred to as ‘worker remittances’), this will tend to make GNP larger than GDP. On balance, for most developing countries that host multinational corporations (have multinational corporation operating within their boundaries), profit repatriation tends to be far more important than worker remittances, and therefore GDP is likely to be larger than GNP. Economic growth (introduced in Chapter 1, page 9) refers to increases in the quantity of output (goods and services) produced over a period of time (typically a year), and is usually expressed as: GNP per capita is a better indicator of the standards of living of a country, because it represents incomes actually received by the residents. On the other hand, GDP per capita is a better indicator of the level of output per person produced in a country. Test your understanding 7.7 1 Define GDP and GNP, and explain how they differ. 2 Think of some examples of countries where (a) GNP is likely to be larger than GDP; (b) GDP is likely to be larger than GNP. 3 Is GDP per capita or GNP per capita likely to be a better indicator of (a) standards of living in a country, and (b) the level of output produced per person? Explain why in each case. 192 Part 3: Macroeconomics Sections 7.2 and 7.3 serve as an introduction to the topic of economic development of less developed countries (LDCs), which forms the subject of Part 5. Yet we will discover that many issues we touch upon here apply to more developed countries (MDCs) as well. Economic growth Defining and calculating economic growth · a percentage change in real GDP (or real GNP) over a specified period of time; or · a percentage change in real GDP per capita (or real GNP per capita) over a specified period of time. The formula for calculating percentage change of a variable, A, is the following: % change in A = final value of A − initial value of A × 100 initial value of A For example, if real GDP in a hypothetical country was $50 billion in 2004 (the initial value) and increased to $51 billion in 2005 (the final value), its rate of growth over this period would be given by % change in real GDP = 51 − 50 × 100 = 2 % 50 Therefore real GDP increased by 2% in the period 2004–05. However, the percentage change representing growth is not always a positive value; if real GDP has fallen it will be negative. Say, for example, that real GDP in a hypothetical country was $60 billion in 2006 and $57 in 2007. Using the same formula, we can calculate its rate of growth to have been − 5%. The negative rate of growth indicates that real GDP fell in the period 2006–07. Let’s now consider economic growth in per capita terms. Say that real GDP has been growing in a hypothetical country, so that is has a positive real GDP growth rate. Does this mean that it also has positive per capita GDP growth? The answer depends on how fast the population has been growing. Remember that real GDP per capita is simply real GDP divided by the number of people in the population; it represents the amount of GDP there is on average for each person. If real GDP is growing faster than the population, then the amount of real GDP that corresponds to each person will get bigger and bigger, and there will be positive growth in real GDP per capita. But if the population is growing faster than real GDP, then the amount of GDP per person on average will be less and less, and the growth rate of real GDP per capita will be negative. It is not uncommon to see countries where total output is increasing but output per capita is falling (as we will see in Table 7.2). If we know the percentage change in real GDP and the percentage change in the population, we can find the percentage change in real GDP per capita in a very simple way: % change in real GDP per capita = % change in real GDP − % change in population For example, if real GDP has grown by 2% in the course of a year, and the population has grown by 1.5%, then real GDP per capita growth is 0.5%. If, however, the population grew by 3%, then the % change in real GDP is − 1%, indicating that output per person fell by 1%. Note that throughout this discussion we are using real as opposed to nominal GDP figures. The real figures have eliminated the impact of price changes, thus permitting meaningful comparisons of output over time. of resources and its productive inefficiency. This means that if the country can make better use of its resources by reducing unemployment and increasing efficiency in production, it will move closer to the PPC and increase the quantity of output it produces. Therefore reductions in unemployment and increases in productive efficiency are two factors that can cause economic growth. In Figure 7.3(a), the movement from point A to point B, which is closer to the PPC, illustrates economic growth. However, reduction of unemployment and inefficiencies can only result in a limited amount of economic growth. As the economy comes closer and closer to its PPC, the possibility for further growth becomes exhausted. In order for further growth to occur, there must occur an increase in production possibilities, illustrated by an outward shift of the economy’s PPC. This is shown in Figure 7.3(b), where the outward shifts of production possibilities are accompanied by outward movements of the economy’s points of production, from A to B, to C. These movements are only possible because the economy’s PPC is shifting outward. What are the factors that cause outward shifts of the PPC? As you may remember from Chapter 1, page 13, these include: · increases in the quantity of one or more factors of production · improvements in the quality of the factors of production · improvements in technology. The sources of economic growth We have seen how economic growth is defined and calculated. The question we now turn to is: what are the sources of economic growth, in other words, what are the causes of growth? We can find the answer to this question in the production possibilities model we studied in Chapter 1 (page 11). You may remember that the production possibilities curve (PPC) shows the maximum attainable combinations of output that can be produced by an economy with fixed resources and technology, provided there is full or maximum employment of resources and productive efficiency. When an economy has fixed (unchanging) quantities and quality of factors of production and fixed technologies, it can achieve some limited economic growth through reductions in unemployment and improvements in productive efficiency. However, sustained economic growth over long periods of time depends crucially on increased resource quantities, improved resource quality, and technological improvements, i.e. increases in production possibilities and outward shifts in the economy’s PPC. As we saw in Chapter 1, page 12, any economy is most likely actually to be situated at some point inside its PPC, as it is very difficult ever to achieve full productive efficiency and maximum employment of all resources. The further away an economy is situated from its PPC, the greater is the unemployment Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 193 (a) Economic growth caused by reductions in unemployment and productive inefficiency. (b) Economic growth caused by increases in production possibilities. Y Y C B B A A 0 0 X X Average annual growth (%) 1990–2005* Growth (%) 2005–06** Middle East and North Africa 2.3 3.6 Tunisia 3.3 4.1 Egypt 2.4 4.9 Jordan 1.6 4.0 Morocco 1.5 6.0 High income countries 1.8 2.3 Greece 2.5 4.2 Figure 7.3 Using the production possibilities model to illustrate economic growth. United Kingdom 2.5 2.6 United States 2.1 2.4 The significance of economic growth Japan 0.8 2.4 Economic growth rates achieved by countries around the world are highly variable. While some countries experience rapid growth, others grow much more slowly. This can be seen in Table 7.2, showing average annual growth rates of real GDP per capita for groups of developing and developed countries, as well as for some specific countries within each group. The groups, and countries within the groups, are listed in order of declining average growth rates over the period 1990– 2005. Switzerland 0.6 2.6 Central and Eastern Europe and former Soviet Union 1.4 5.7 Belarus 2.2 8.1 Kazakhstan 2.0 10.1 Romania 1.6 6.0 Table 7.2 Russian Federation − 0.1 7.3 Latin America and Caribbean 1.2 4.2 Peru 2.2 6.5 Brazil 1.1 2.4 Real GDP per capita percentage growth. Average annual growth (%) 1990–2005* Growth (%) 2005–06** East Asia and Pacific 5.8 8.6 China 8.8 10.1 Colombia 0.6 5.4 Vietnam 5.9 6.9 Venezuela − 1.0 8.5 Thailand 2.7 4.2 0.5 4.7 Indonesia 2.1 4.3 Sub-Saharan Africa South Asia 3.4 6.9 Tanzania 1.7 3.3 India 4.2 7.7 Malawi 1.0 6.2 Sri Lanka 3.7 6.6 Nigeria 0.8 3.4 Nepal 2.0 − 0.1 − 0.6 2.1 Pakistan 1.3 4.1 194 Part 3: Macroeconomics Central African Republic *Data from United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report 2007–08, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/. **Data from World Bank, World Development Report 2008 (World Bank, 2007). Although there are wide differences in growth rates of countries within each group, on average the countries of East Asia and the Pacific have been growing the most rapidly, averaging growth of 5.8% per year in real per capita GDP in the period 1990–2005. By contrast, the countries in sub-Saharan Africa have shown the lowest growth rates, with real per capita GDP on average increasing by 0.5% per year over the same period. We will discover many of the reasons behind these highly variable growth rates in Part 5. It is interesting to note that all the groups in Table 7.2, and most of the countries in each group, have experienced an increase in their rate of growth in 2005–06 compared to the average of the previous 15 years.5 Widely differing growth rates have enormous implications for a country’s economic performance over extended periods of time. To see why this is so, let’s consider what would happen to per capita GDPs of three hypothetical economies that grow at different rates over a period of 25 years. Imagine that each economy starts out in 1990 with a GDP per capita of $1000. The first one grows for 25 years at the high annual rate of 5.8% (the rate of the East Asia and Pacific group); the second country grows for 25 years at the annual rate of 2.3% (the rate of the Middle East and North Africa group). And the third country grows for 25 years at the lower annual rate of 0.5% (the subSaharan African group). The results are presented in Table 7.3. The country that grows at 5.8% per year for 25 years succeeds in more than quadrupling its GDP per capita, while the country that grows at the lowest rate of 0.5% per year for 25 years merely adds $133 to its GDP per capita! The longer the time period during which countries experience relatively high growth rates, the greater is the cumulative impact on their per capita GDPs, and the greater the differences between per capita GDP levels of high-growth and low-growth countries. Very low (or even negative) growth rates in GDP per capita in many sub-Saharan African and other countries over long periods have had profound impacts on the levels of living of their populations. For many developing countries, particularly those with lower average growth rates in the period 1990–2005, the surge in growth in the mid-2000s has been due to rapid increases in the prices of their commodity exports. As of autumn 2008, there are indications that the prices of commodities may 5 The enormous cumulative impact that rates of growth have on levels of real GDP per capita explains why governments around the world focus strongly on factors and policies that will accelerate their rate of growth. We will come back to these issues in Part 5. Table 7.3 Growth of GDP per capita in hypothetical economies. 1990 GDP per capita Annual growth rate 2015 GDP per capita $1 000 5.8% $4094 $1 000 2.3% $1 766 $1 000 0.5% $1 133 Test your understanding 7.8 1 (a) Define economic growth; (b) how is economic growth expressed? 2 How is it possible that a country can experience positive real GDP growth and yet have falling real GDP per capita (negative real GDP per capita growth)? 3 When we calculate economic growth figures, should we use nominal or real values of GDP (or any other measure of output or income)? Why? 4 Say that an economy’s real GDP grew by 5% in 2007, and its population grew by 1.5% during the same year. By how much did its real GDP per capita grow? 5 Use the production possibilities model and a diagram to show how the following can result in economic growth (shift of the PPC or movement of a point within the PPC: (a) a fall in unemployment (b) a discovery of new oil reserves (c) an improvement in levels of health of the population (d) an increase in productive efficiency (e) the widespread use of a new technology. 6 What must be occurring continuously if an economy wants to maintain its growth over long periods of time? Use the concepts of production possibilities and actual output to show why economic growth cannot continue over long periods of time if there is no increase in production possibilities. start to come down again, and this may reduce their high rates of growth. We will discuss these issues in Chapter 14, where we will study the impacts of commodity price changes on growth and development. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 195 Economic development Increasing levels of output and incomes made possible by economic growth mean that societies can better satisfy the needs and wants of their populations and secure improvements in their levels of living. However, while economic growth can make improved levels of living possible, it does not by itself guarantee that this will occur. Persisting poverty and the failure of many countries to secure long-lasting improvements in the well-being of their populations, even if they have achieved respectable rates of growth over extended periods of time, have shown that economic development is a highly complex and sometimes elusive process. Distinguishing between developing and developed countries The World Bank (an international financial institution that lends to developing countries in order to assist them in their development efforts, discussed in Part 5) divides countries into four groups according to their level of GNP per capita. These groups (based on 2006 GNP per capita) are · low income, with GNP per capita of $905 or less · lower middle income, with GNP per capita of $906–$3595 · upper middle income, with GNP per capita of $3596–$11,115 · high income, with GNP per capita of $11,116 or high population growth rates, prevalence of disease and poor health, low life expectancy, limited access to basic services such as health care, education and sanitation, and serious environmental problems. It is important to note, however, that these characteristics do not apply uniformly to all developing countries. For example, whereas many developing countries have relatively low literacy rates, this does not apply to the countries of eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union because of the priority given to education under former communist regimes. Tajikistan (a part of the former Soviet Union), with a very low per capita GNP, has achieved a youth literacy rate that is comparable to many highly developed countries in the world; by contrast, Saudi Arabia with a relatively high per capita GNP has a lower literacy rate than other countries with a comparable per capita GNP level. In fact, classifying countries by level of GNP (or any other output or income measure) does not accurately represent their level of development. The World Bank points out that ‘Classification by income does not necessarily reflect development status.’ As we will see later in this chapter (Section 7.3), a country’s level of development varies widely depending upon what characteristic is used; whereas one country may be quite developed with respect to one characteristic, it may be less so with respect to another. High income, or developed economies, include the countries of North America, western Europe, Australia, Japan and New Zealand, as well as some eastern European and some oil-producing countries in the Middle East. Further, it is important to note that classifying countries as developing or developed with respect to per capita GNP levels or any other characteristic hides the lack of uniformity within countries. The United States, for example, one of the economically most advanced countries in the world, has pockets of poverty, with lack of access to basic services such as health care, low educational attainment, high unemployment and low income levels. Similarly, most less developed countries have pockets of great wealth concentrated in the hands of a small proportion of the population, with good access to health care, high levels of education, lower birth rates and higher life expectancy. Developing countries (LDCs) include most of the countries of Africa, Asia, Latin America and the Middle East, and parts of eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. They tend to be characterized by widespread poverty, use of less advanced production technologies, low levels of industrialization and a correspondingly high dependence on agriculture, highly unequal distribution of income and wealth, relatively high rates of illiteracy, high unemployment, Different countries display the characteristics of being ‘less developed’ or ‘more developed’ to varying degrees. Moreover, there is a lack of uniformity within countries with respect to the level of development; there can be pockets of poverty in very wealthy countries, as there can be pockets of wealth in very poor countries. more. Table 7.4 lists all the countries in these country groups. The first three groups (low, lower middle and upper middle income) comprise the less developed countries or LDCs (‘developing countries’), while the high income economies are the more developed countries or MDCs (‘developed countries’). 196 Part 3: Macroeconomics Table 7.4 World Bank country groups by 2006 GNP per capita. Low income economies Afghanistan Ghana Mauritania Bangladesh Benin Burkina Faso Burundi Cambodia Central African Rep. Chad Comoros Guinea Guinea-Bissau Haiti India Kenya Korea, Dem. Rep. Kyrgyz Rep. Lao PDR Mongolia Mozambique Myanmar Nepal Niger Nigeria Congo, Dem. Rep. Côte d’Ivoire Liberia Eritrea Ethiopia Gambia, The Madagascar Malawi Mali Pakistan Papua New Guinea Rwanda Solomon Islands Somalia Sudan Tajikistan Tanzania Timor-Leste Togo Uganda Uzbekistan Vietnam São Tomé and Yemen, Rep. Principe Senegal Zambia Sierra Leone Zimbabwe Lower middle income economies Albania Algeria Angola Belarus Cuba Djibouti Dominican Republic Ecuador Egypt, Arab Rep. El Salvador Bhutan Fiji Bolivia Bosnia and Herzegovina Cameroon Cape Verde China Colombia Georgia Guatemala Armenia Azerbaijan Congo, Rep. Guyana Honduras Indonesia Iran, Islamic Rep. Iraq Jamaica Jordan Kiribati Philippines Samoa Sri Lanka Lesotho Macedonia, FYR Maldives Suriname Swaziland Marshall Islands Nicaragua Micronesia, Fed. Sts Moldova Morocco Namibia Paraguay Syrian Arab Republic Thailand Tonga Tunisia Turkmenistan Ukraine Vanuatu West Bank and Gaza Upper middle income economies American Samoa Estonia Mayotte Seychelles Argentina Belize Botswana Gabon Grenada Hungary Brazil Bulgaria Latvia Lebanon Mexico Montenegro Northern Mariana Islands Oman Palau Chile Libya Panama Costa Rica Croatia Lithuania Kazakhstan Poland Romania Dominica Malaysia Equatorial Guinea Mauritius Russian Federation Serbia Slovak Republic South Africa St Kitts and Nevis St Lucia St Vincent and Grenadines Trinidad and Tobago Turkey Uruguay Venezuela, RB High income economies Andorra Czech Republic Israel Portugal Antigua and Barbuda Aruba Australia Austria Bahamas, The Bahrain Denmark Italy Puerto Rico Japan Korea, Rep. Kuwait Liechtenstein Luxembourg Qatar San Marino Saudi Arabia Singapore Slovenia Macao, China Malta Monaco Netherlands Netherlands Antilles New Caledonia Spain Sweden Switzerland Taiwan, China United Arab Emirates United Kingdom United States Estonia Faroe Islands Finland France French Polynesia Barbados Germany Belgium Greece Bermuda Greenland Brunei Guam Canada Hong Kong, China Cayman Islands Iceland Channel Islands Cyprus Ireland New Zealand Isle of Man Norway Virgin Islands (US) Peru Defining economic development The meaning of economic development has changed dramatically over the years. In the past 50 to 60 years that economists have been concerned with development, we can distinguish the following main strands of thought: · the 1950s and 1960s: focus on economic growth · the 1970s: redistribution with growth · the 1980s, 1990s and beyond: human development. We will consider each of these in turn. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 197 The 1950s and 1960s: focus on economic growth in 1973 showed that economic growth in the early years benefited only the wealthiest groups, and in a later phase benefited middle income groups, while the position of the poorest 40% of the population grew worse both relatively and absolutely. In other words, the benefits of economic growth were not ‘trickling down’ to the poorest members of society. In the 1950s and 1960s, economists held that economic growth and economic development were virtually synonymous. A prominent development economist, Charles P. Kindleberger, wrote in 1965: Growth and development are often used synonymously in economic discussion, and this is entirely appropriate … In the early stages, any economy that grows is likely to develop, and vice versa … In the less developed parts of the world, i.e. countries that have low incomes or that find difficulty in adapting to the economic opportunities available to them, growth and development go hand in 6 hand. Perceptions about what constitutes economic development, and how this should be pursued, began to change dramatically. Since economic growth, where it did occur, did not work to eliminate widespread poverty, what was needed was an approach that would directly deal with the problems of developing countries, and specifically the problem of persisting poverty. In the new view, less developed countries should combine the older focus on economic growth with new ideas on redistribution of income and wealth, and improved access of the poor to basic goods and services. It was believed that economic growth over long periods of time would automatically provide economic and social benefits for the wider population; larger quantities of goods and services, including health care and education, and employment opportunities and social change would eventually be spread out over most people in an economy, thereby achieving economic development. This notion was termed the trickle-down theory: benefits of growth would eventually trickle down to everyone. Based on this view, developing countries in this period pursued policies that aimed at promoting their economic growth. The work of a number of economists carried out from the late 1940s to the 1960s was highly influential in providing the theoretical grounds for growth-oriented economic policies. (We will consider some of these in Chapter 17.) Economic development, as understood in the 1970s (and beyond), can be defined as a process whereby increases in real per capita incomes are accompanied by improvements in levels of living of the population and reductions in poverty and inequalities, which in turn suggest decreases in the number of persons living below a minimum level of real income, attainment of a certain minimum level of consumption, increased access to goods and services that satisfy basic needs (including food, shelter, health care, education, sanitation and others), increased employment opportunities and reduction of unemployment, and reductions of serious inequalities in wealth and growth of different regions within a country. The 1970s: redistribution with growth By the late 1960s and early 1970s, it was becoming increasingly apparent that many less developed countries were not performing according to expectations. First, it was noted that the GNP per capita gap between rich countries and poor countries had more than doubled on average in the period 1950– 75.7 Growth rates were highly uneven: while some less developed countries were growing rapidly (particularly the oil-rich countries in the Middle East), others were experiencing very low or even negative growth rates (especially in Africa). The 1980s, 1990s and beyond: human development Many people in the development field today would agree with the broad definitions of economic development that appeared in the 1970s. Yet thinking about development has progressed further in more recent years, building on an even broader interpretation of development that was provided by Denis Goulet as early as 1971. Goulet defined three core values of development: life sustenance, selfesteem, and freedom:8 Second, it became apparent that the number of people living in extreme poverty (defined as living on less than US$1 per day) was increasing rather than decreasing. A major study of 43 countries published · Life sustenance refers to access to basic services (merit goods) such as education and health care services, as Charles P. Kindleberger, Economic Development (McGraw-Hill, 1965). David Morawetz, Twenty-Five Years of Economic Development: 1950–1975 (World Bank, 1977). 6 7 198 Part 3: Macroeconomics D. Goulet, The Cruel Choice: A New Concept on the Theory Of Development (Atheneum, 1971). 8 well as satisfaction of basic needs like food, clothing and shelter. · Self-esteem involves the feeling of self-respect; development is desirable because it provides individuals with dignity, honour and independence; self-esteem is related to the absence of exploitation and dominance associated with poverty and dependence. · Freedom involves freedom from want, ignorance and squalor; it is freedom to make choices that are not available to people who are subjected to the conditions of poverty. The economist Amartya Sen, who won the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1998 for his work on poverty and economic development, taking Goulet’s ideas further, sees improvements in human welfare as arising from a process of expanding freedoms: Development can be seen . . . as a process of expanding the real freedoms that people enjoy. Focusing on human freedom contrasts with narrower views of development, such as identifying development with the growth of gross national product, or with the rise in personal incomes, or with industrialization, or with technological advance, or with social modernization. Growth of GNP or of individual incomes can, of course, be very important as a means to expanding the freedoms enjoyed by the members of the society. But freedoms depend also on other determinants, such as social and economic arrangements (for example, facilities for education and health care), as well as political and civil rights (for example, the liberty to participate in public discussion 9 and scrutiny)… Sen’s approach has been crystallized in the concept of human development, introduced in the first Human Development Report of the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) in 1990.10 Human development can be defined as a process of expanding human freedoms: the freedom to satisfy hunger; to be adequately fed; to be free of preventable illnesses; to have adequate clothing and shelter; to have access to clean water and sanitation; to be able to read, write and receive an appropriate education; to be knowledgeable; to be able to find work; to enjoy legal protection; to participate in social and political life; and, in general, to have the freedom to develop one’s potential and lead a full and productive life. Amartya Sen, Development as Freedom (Oxford University Press, 2001), emphasis in the original. 10 The UNDP is an agency of the United Nations designed to foster development in less developed countries. The UNDP’s Human Development Reports are compiled annually and provide statistical and other 9 Based on the concept of human development, the UNDP makes a key distinction between income poverty and human poverty. Income poverty occurs when income falls below a nationally or internationally determined level that defines the poverty line (i.e. anyone with less than this income is considered poor). Human poverty, by contrast, involves deprivations and the lack of opportunities and choices that allow individuals ‘to lead a long, healthy, creative life and to enjoy a decent standard of living, freedom, dignity, selfesteem and the respect of others’.11 To understand the distinction between income poverty and human poverty, consider a villager whose income increases, so that now he or she is able to purchase more goods and services. If there are no schools or health care services in the area, or if the village is infested with malaria, the higher income will be of limited use to the villager in securing a higher standard of living. While income poverty is reduced through the higher income, human poverty cannot be lowered without explicit measures to provide a broad range of social services to the entire population. On the other hand, if people on low incomes have access to education, health services, improved sanitation, improved water supplies, etc., human poverty can be reduced even while income poverty remains. Later in this chapter we will see how economic and human development, income poverty and human poverty are measured. Relating economic growth to economic development Economic growth can occur without economic development. It was this experience for many countries in the 1950s and 1960s that gave rise to a rethinking and redefining of economic development. Can economic development occur without economic growth? Some economic development may be possible in the absence of rapid growth, if appropriate strategies are undertaken to provide access to basic social services for the poor. The production possibilities model we studied in Chapter 1 shows how this can occur. Consider Figure 1.5 on page 15 in Chapter 1, when an economy produces some combination of industrial goods (measured on the vertical axis) and merit goods (measured on the horizontal axis). The merit goods include education, health care services, sanitation, information on numerous issues relating to human development in less developed countries around the world. 11 UNDP, Human Development Report 1997, available at http://hdr.undp. org/en/. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 199 and clean water supplies, which are made available to people on low incomes who would not otherwise have access to them. (For simplicity it is assumed that actual output is at some point on the production possibilities curves). Suppose now that an economy is operating on PPC1, is not experiencing much growth, and therefore remains on PPC1. It can still achieve an improvement in the well-being of its population, i.e. some economic development, simply by cutting back on some of its industrial goods production and increasing merit goods production; this would entail a movement along PPC1 downward and to the right. However, over long periods of time, the possibilities for improving the population’s well-being by moving along the same PPC will be exhausted, and further improvements will depend on outward shifts of the PPC, as shown by the movement from PPC1 to PPC2 in Figure 1.5. Economic growth, made possible by outward shifts of the PPC, is therefore necessary for economic development to be sustained. Growing output per capita translates into higher incomes and an improved ability to provide the goods and services needed by the population. We can therefore conclude that: Economic growth can occur without economic development (or with limited economic development). Some economic development can occur without economic growth (or with limited economic growth), but for limited periods of time and to a limited extent. Sustained economic development over extended periods of time requires economic growth, in combination with policies that result in improvements in quality of life through improved access to basic social services (merit goods). Test your understanding 7.9 1 Define economic development as it has come to be understood since the 1970s. 2 (a) What is the ‘trickle-down theory’? (b) How was it used during the 1950s and 1960s to justify the pursuit of economic growth as the road to economic development? 3 (a) Define human development. (b) Distinguish between income poverty and human poverty. (...continued) Test your understanding 7.9 (...continued) 4 Use the production possibilities model to (a) show how a country can experience growth without economic development (see Chapter 1, page 10); (b) show how it can achieve some economic development without economic growth; (c) explain why economic development over long periods of time requires economic growth. Limitations of the GDP measure in international welfare comparisons Welfare is an expression for the state of well-being of a population. When real per capita GDP of a country increases over time, we might expect that the population of this country achieves greater welfare. Or, if GDP per capita in one country is greater than that of another country, we might expect that the first country enjoys a higher level of welfare. But would these conclusions be valid? The answer is that we cannot be sure. There are two reasons why this is so. One is that GDP statistics do not accurately measure the true value of output produced in an economy. The other is that the welfare of a population is closely related to the many dimensions of economic and human development, which GDP is unable to measure. As we will see in the pages that follow, GDP per capita simply measures the income or output of a country that corresponds to each individual in the country on average; it cannot account for levels of health, education, access to clean water, and the numerous other dimensions of economic and human development. It follows, then, that GDP per capita can be quite misleading when used as the basis for welfare comparisons across countries. The factors limiting the usefulness of per capita GDP for comparison purposes can be divided into those that systematically result in understating society’s welfare, those that systematically result in overstating welfare, and those that result in either understating or overstating welfare. Why GDP figures understate welfare (or why true welfare is greater than indicated by GDP per capita) · GDP does not include non-marketed output GDP, as we know, measures the value of goods and services that are traded in the marketplace and that 200 Part 3: Macroeconomics generate incomes for the factors of production. Yet some output of goods and services is not sold in the market and does not generate any income; this is called ‘non-marketed output’. The work of women inside the home is one such example; one’s own work on repairing and improving one’s own home is another. If the housework and the home repairs were carried out by hired workers, GDP would be greater by the amount of their wages. In less developed countries households are often quite self-sufficient, with a substantial portion of production, such as agricultural production, taking place for a household’s own use and consumption, and never reaching the marketplace. Non-marketed output therefore is likely to be far greater in less developed countries compared to more developed ones. In general, exclusion of non-marketed output from GDP leads to understating GDP and therefore understating society’s welfare. · GDP does not include output sold in underground (informal) markets Here we have the case where goods are traded in markets and do generate incomes, but they go unrecorded and therefore are not included in GDP. An ‘underground market’ (also known as an ‘informal market’) exists whenever a buying/selling transaction is unrecorded. It may involve the provision of legal goods and services (such as when a plumber does repairs in your home and does not report the income received so as to avoid paying taxes), or in transactions involving illegal goods and services. The exclusion of unrecorded output results in understating society’s GDP. · GDP does not take into account quality improvements in goods and services The quality of many products improves over time, yet this is not taken into account in calculating the value of aggregate output. Technological advances often permit improved products to be sold at lower prices (for example, mobile phones and computers). This process offers significant benefits to consumers, which do not show up in GDP figures. The exclusion of quality improvements means that GDP understates society’s welfare. · GDP does not take into account increased leisure In many countries around the world (particularly in more developed ones) the average number of hours worked per week has declined significantly, with the number of hours of leisure correspondingly increasing. This clearly contributes to society’s welfare, yet is not accounted for in measures of GDP. Once again, the neglect of growing leisure understates society’s welfare. · GDP does not take into account increased life expectancy Increased life expectancy (the number of years one can expect to live, on average) is another benefit of technological improvements and higher income levels that has contributed enormously to the welfare of societies, but is not accounted for in GDP figures. Why GDP figures overstate welfare (or why true welfare is smaller than indicated by GDP per capita) · GDP does not account for the value of negative externalities, such as pollution, toxic wastes, and other undesirable by-products of production In this case, GDP overstates society’s welfare. Virtually all countries contribute to environmental degradation (though to varying degrees), as a result of which welfare is reduced, though this is not reflected in GDP figures. · GDP does not take into account the depletion of natural resources The depletion of natural resources (rainforests, the ozone layer, wildlife) around the world reduces welfare yet is also not taken into consideration by standard national income accounting. GDP figures once again overstate welfare. We will come back to this topic in Chapter 19. Why GDP figures understate or overstate welfare (or why true welfare may be greater or smaller than indicated by GDP per capita) · GDP makes no distinctions regarding the composition of output Whether a country produces military goods (weapons, guns, tanks, etc.) or merit goods (education, health care, other social services) or any other type of goods, GDP includes the value of all of without any distinctions regarding the degree to which they contribute to the welfare of the population. We know that economic development and human development involve increasing production of social services and merit goods that contribute to higher levels of living. One country may have a lower per capita GDP than another, but higher levels of social service and merit goods provision than the other. Which has the higher level of welfare? The GDP measure will be inconclusive and misleading if used as the basis for welfare comparisons. · GDP provides no information on the distribution of income and output How equally or unequally income and output are distributed over the entire Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 201 population is another key factor underlying society’s welfare. Is the wealth of a nation highly concentrated in relatively few hands or is it relatively more equally distributed? Are the benefits of a growing GDP concentrated among a small group of beneficiaries or are they widely distributed? Are inequalities increasing or decreasing? Economic development and the reduction of poverty often depend on the reduction of extreme inequalities. The measure of GDP per capita cannot address any of these questions, as it only provides an indication of average output per person, and is therefore in this respect, too, inconclusive and misleading as a basis for international welfare comparisons. · GDP does not account for quality of life factors A society’s welfare depends upon a number of noneconomic factors, such as the crime rate, a sense of security and peace arising from relations with other countries, well-functioning institutions, stress levels from working conditions, the degree of political freedom, and many others. GDP cannot account for any of these. As a result, welfare may be higher or lower depending on the particular situation prevailing with respect to each of these factors. · GDP and differing domestic price levels Goods and services can sell for vastly different prices in different countries. This means that 100 yen (the Japanese currency, after it has been converted into local currencies) will be able to purchase more in a low price country than in a high price country. If international comparisons of GDP do not account for differing price levels across countries, we will get a highly misleading picture of welfare. This issue will be discussed in some more detail in the section that follows. Purchasing power parities and welfare comparisons across countries If we were told that in 2005 India’s GDP per capita was 21,791 Indian rupees and China’s was 11,283 yuan, we would be hard pressed to make a sensible comparison. In order to be able to compare GDP (or GNP, or any other monetary measure) between countries, we must convert different national currencies into a single currency. This conversion may be performed by use of exchange rates, which are the rates at which one currency can be converted into another. In terms of US$, India’s GDP per capita in 2005 was $564 and China’s was $1100. However, expressing GDPs in terms of one common currency does not solve the problem of making international comparisons that measure the welfare 202 Part 3: Macroeconomics of populations, because of differing price levels across countries. Let’s take two hypothetical countries that have an identical GDP per capita of $1000. Imagine that both countries produce only one identical good, which sells for $100 in Country A and for $200 in Country B. The $1000 per person in Country A can buy 10 units of the good, but the same amount of money can buy only 5 units of the good in Country B. In other words, the $1000 of GDP per person in country A, the low price country, has far greater purchasing power. Purchasing power refers to the quantity of goods and services that can be bought with money. Although the two countries have identical GDPs per capita in terms of $, the population of country A can buy double the amount of the good than the population of Country B. Clearly, the population of country A on average has greater welfare than the population of Country B. Therefore, to be able to make comparisons of welfare between two or more countries, we cannot simply rely on exchange rates to convert one currency into another. We need a method of currency conversions that accounts for different price levels, and therefore different purchasing powers across countries. Such a method is provided by special exchange rates called purchasing power parities (PPPs). Purchasing power parity literally means ‘buying power equivalence’. It is defined as the amount of a country’s currency that is needed to buy the same quantity of local goods and services that can by bought with US$1 in the United States. A PPP exchange rate is an exchange rate between currencies that makes their buying power equal to the buying power of US$1, and therefore equal to each other. (Use of the US$ as the basis for the conversions is only a matter of convention, as other currencies would also have been suitable for this purpose.) Table 7.5 shows GDP per capita for selected countries, calculated both by use of exchange rates (in the first column) and by use of purchasing power parities (in the second column). The countries range from some of the poorest to some of the wealthiest in the world, and are listed in order of increasing GDP per capita based on exchange rates. Note that in the second column of figures, showing GDP per capita using PPPs, the same country order no longer holds. A look at Table 7.5 reveals an interesting pattern: for the poorer countries starting at the top of the table, the GDP figures based on PPPs are higher than those based on exchange rates; for the wealthier countries at the bottom of the table, GDP figures based on PPPs are lower than those based on exchange rates. Why is this so? Table 7.5 Comparisons of GDP per capita using exchange rates and purchasing power parities, 2003. Country GDP per capita (exchange rates US$) GDP per capita (purchasing power parities, US$ PPP) Burundi 83 648 Ethiopia 97 711 Sierra Leone 149 548 India 564 2,892 Indonesia 970 3,361 China 1,100 5,003 Russian Federation 3,018 9,230 Chile 4,591 10,274 Latvia 4,771 10,270 Mexico 6,121 9,168 Czech Republic 8,794 16,357 Korea, Republic 12,634 17,971 Greece 15,608 19,954 Australia 26,275 29,632 United Kingdom 30,253 27,147 Sweden 33,676 26,750 Japan 33,713 27,967 United States 37,648 37,648 Ireland 38,487 37,738 Switzerland 43,553 30,552 Source: Data from United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report 2005, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/. It is because prices of goods and services on average tend to be lower in countries with low per capita GDPs, and higher in countries with high per capita GDPs. To understand what this means, consider two countries that produce the identical quantity of output (goods and services), but that have different prices for this output. When the value of this output is calculated in terms of US$ using exchange rates, it will appear to be lower in the lower price country than in the higher price country, even though the quantity of output is the same. This is exactly what happens in the real world. In the first column of figures, the output of lower price countries at the top end of the table appears to be lower than the equivalent output of higher price countries at the bottom end. The second column of figures, using PPPs to convert GDP per capita, eliminates the impact on GDP of differing price levels, and as a result, the differences in per capita GDP between countries shrink enormously. Comparing Switzerland with Burundi, we see that Swiss GDP per capita based on exchange rates is 525 times greater than Burundi’s; based on purchasing power parities, Swiss GDP per capita is 47 times greater than Burundi’s. The second comparison is a much better indicator of the differences in welfare between the Burundian and Swiss populations. In the case of the United States, the two figures are identical, since it is the purchasing power of the US$ within the United States that is used as the basis for the PPP conversions. Welfare comparisons across countries require measures of per capita income or output based on conversions of national currencies into US$ by use of purchasing power parities (PPPs), so as to eliminate the influence of price differences on GDP per capita. Purchasing power parity exchange rates are computed and published on a regular basis by a number of international bodies, including the Organisation for European Co-operation and Development (OECD), European Union, World Bank and United Nations agencies. Test your understanding 7.10 1 Explain why GDP per capita may be inappropriate as the basis for making comparisons of a society’s welfare over time, or for comparisons of welfare between countries. 2 Discuss some factors that cause GDP figures to (a) understate a society’s true welfare; (b) overstate a society’s true welfare; (c) to understate or overstate a society’s true welfare. 3 (a) What are purchasing power parities? (b) Why are they important for making valid comparisons of GDP per capita across countries? Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 203 7.3 Measuring economic development The complexities of measuring economic development Economic development, as we have seen, is a complex and multifaceted process that is not accurately reflected in accounting aggregates like GDP and GNP per capita. Because of its many dimensions, the level of economic development of any one country cannot be reflected in any single measure. Economists therefore consider specific individual attributes or characteristics of an economy that tend to distinguish countries according to their level of economic or human development. Individual attributes and characteristics of economies are measured by use of indicators. An indicator is a measurable variable that indicates the state or level of something that is being measured. For example, GDP per capita is an indicator of the level of output or income per person. The number of years of life expectancy is an indicator of the state of the health of a population. The proportion of a population that can read and write (the degree of literacy) is an indicator of the level of education in the country. All these are attributes of economic or human development. The data comprising economic or human development indicators (such as GDP, or life expectancy, or literacy) are compiled by statistical services in every country over a period of years and are made available to international organizations such as the World Bank and United Nations agencies. Indicators are extremely useful for: · monitoring how a country is changing (developing) over a period of years with respect to the attribute that the indicator measures · making comparisons between countries with respect to the attribute · assessing how well a country is performing with respect to particular goals or targets of development (for example, an increase in the literacy rate indicates an improvement in the educational level of a population) · devising appropriate policy measures to deal with specific problems. In addition to individual attributes and goals of development, measured by individual indicators, economists also use composite indicators. A composite indicator is a summary measure of several dimensions or goals of development. We will consider both individual and composite indicators of development in the sections that follow. Individual and composite indictors, used in combination with per capita GDP (or GNP) statistics, are enormously useful as measures of different aspects and levels of development, but they are also subject to certain limitations: · Each indicator measures only one aspect of development; since development is a multidimensional process, it is often necessary to combine the use of many indicators to obtain an overall picture of a country’s level of development. · Indicators are based on statistical information, and this poses a distinct set of problems: ❍ ❍ ❍ some countries have a limited capacity for collection of statistical data data are not fully available in many countries definitions of variables and methods used by statistical services vary from country to country, despite efforts by international organizations (such as the World Bank and United Nations agencies) to achieve standardization. These statistical problems mean that the indicators cannot always be precise and should therefore be interpreted carefully. Whether they are used to examine how a country is changing over time with respect to some characteristic, or to make comparisons across countries, they should be used as rough guides to provide general trends over time, or as indicative of broad differences between countries, rather than as very precise measures of changes or differences. Test your understanding 7.11 1 Explain why it is easier to measure economic growth than to measure economic development. 2 What are some of the difficulties involved in measuring economic development? 3 How do economists measure economic development? 204 Part 3: Macroeconomics Individual indicators There are many hundreds of indicators that can be used as measures of the different characteristics of an economy and of the dimensions of development. World Development Indicators (World Bank) The World Bank compiles a set of indicators known as the ‘World Development Indicators’ (WDI). As of 2006, there were over 900 indicators, 695 of which were available online in the Bank’s ‘WDI online list of times series indicators’.12 The indicators provide statistical information about the following areas: · People 178 indicators provide information on population and demography, labour, employment, poverty, income, education and health. · Environment 79 indicators provide information on land use and agricultural production, energy production, urbanization and emissions. · Economy 264 indicators provide information on diverse aspects of the economy, including national accounts, trade, government finance, balance of payments and external debt. · States and markets 134 indicators provide information on the investment and business environment, tax and trade policies, defence expenditures, arms trade, transport, power and communications, and information and technology. Millennium Development Goals and indicators In September 2000, the United Nations hosted the largest meeting of world leaders ever to take place in history, at which 147 heads of state and government and 189 countries adopted the Millennium Declaration: a global statement of commitment to eliminating extreme poverty, hunger, disease and environmental damage, through development strategies based on the needs of the poor, human rights and sustainable development. What differentiates the Millennium Declaration from statements of earlier years is that it establishes specific goals and targets to be achieved within a period of 15 years, and specifies indicators to be used to monitor country progress towards achieving the goals and targets. The 8 goals, 18 targets and some of the 48 indicators of the Declaration are listed in Table 7.6. As the table shows, there is one or more target corresponding to each goal, while there are several indicators that have been specified to monitor and measure the progress made in each country with respect to each target. For example, the second target of goal 1, to halve in the 25 years to 2015 the proportion of people suffering from hunger, is measured by two indicators: the proportion of underweight children under five years of age, and the proportion of the population whose dietary energy consumption is below the minimum.13 · Global links 40 indicators on investment and trade, financial flows, development assistance and aid, migration, and travel and tourism. 12 Some (but not all) of these indicators can be accessed free of charge at the World Bank’s website (http://devdata.worldbank.org/wdi2006/contents/ cover/htm). 13 The UNDP’s Human Development Reports, as well as indicators and other information, can be accessed through the UNDP’s website (www.undp.org or http://hdr.undp.org/en/statistics/). Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 205 Table 7.6 Millennium goals, targets and indicators. Goals Targets Indicators 1 Eradicate extreme poverty and hunger. 1 Halve, between 1990 and 2015, the proportion of people whose income is less than $1 a day. 1 Proportion of population below $1 (1993 PPP) per day. 2 Poverty gap ratio (the poverty gap is the amount of income required to raise everyone’s income to at least $1 a day). 3 Share of poorest quintile (i.e. the poorest fifth) in total income 2 Achieve universal primary education. 2 Halve, between 1990 and 2015, the proportion of people who suffer from hunger. 4 Prevalence of underweight children under five years of age. 3 Ensure that by 2015 children everywhere will be able to complete primary schooling. 6 Net enrolment ratio in primary education. 5 Proportion of population below minimum level of dietary energy consumption. 7 Proportion of pupils starting grade 1 who reach grade 5. 8 Literacy rate, 15–24 years old. 3 Promote gender equality and empower women. 4 Eliminate gender disparity in primary and secondary education, preferably by 2005, and in all levels of education no later than 2015. 9 Ratio of girls to boys in primary, secondary and tertiary education. 10 Ratio of literate women to men, 15–14 years old. 11 Share of women in wage employment in the non-agricultural sector. 12 Proportion of seats held by women in national parliament. 4 Reduce child mortality. 5 Reduce by two-thirds, between 1990 and 2015, the under-five mortality rate. 13 Mortality rate of children under five. 14 Infant mortality rate. 15 Proportion of one-year-old children immunized against measles. 5 Improve maternal health. 6 Reduce by three-quarters, between 1990 and 2015, the maternal mortality ratio. 16 Maternal mortality ratio. 6 Combat HIV/AIDS, malaria and other diseases. 7 Have halted by 2015 and begun to reverse the spread of HIV/AIDS. 18 HIV prevalence among pregnant women. 17 Proportion of births attended by skilled health personnel. 19 Condom use rate or the contraceptive prevalence rate. 20 Ratio of school attendance of orphans to school attendance of non-orphans aged 10–14 years. 8 Have halted by 2015 and begun to reverse the incidence of malaria and other major diseases. 21 Prevalence and death rates associated with malaria. 22 Proportion of population in malaria-risk areas using effective malaria prevention and treatment measures. 23 Prevalence and death rates associated with tuberculosis. 24 Proportion of tuberculosis cases detected and cured under internationally recommended TB control strategy. 206 Part 3: Macroeconomics Goals Targets Indicators 7 Ensure environmental sustainability. 9 Integrate the principles of sustainable development into country policies and programmes and reverse the loss of environmental resources. 25 Proportion of land area covered by forest. 26 Ratio of area protected to maintain biological diversity to surface area. 27 Energy use (kg oil equivalent) per $1000 GDP (PPP). 28 Carbon dioxide emissions per capita and consumption of ozone-depleting CFCs. 29 Proportion of population using solid fuels. 8 Develop a global partnership for development. 10 Halve, by 2015, the proportion of people without sustainable access to safe drinking water and sanitation. 30 Proportion of population with sustainable access to an improved water source, urban and rural. 11 By 2020, to have achieved a significant improvement in the lives of at least 100 million slum dwellers. 32 Proportion of households with access to secure tenure. 12 Develop further an open, rule-based, predictable, nondiscriminatory trading and financial system. For targets 12–15: 12 indicators including measures of development assistance, developed country imports from developing countries, tariffs imposed by developed countries on developing country agricultural exports, debt relief, debt service and others. 13 Address the special needs of the least developed countries. 31 Proportion of population with access to improved sanitation, urban and rural. 14 Address the special needs of landlocked developing countries and small island developing states. 15 Deal comprehensively with the debt problems of developing countries through national and international measures in order to make debt sustainable in the long term. 16 In cooperation with developing countries, develop and implement strategies for decent and productive work for youth. 45 Unemployment rate of young people aged 15–24 years, male and female and total. 17 In cooperation with pharmaceutical companies, provide access to affordable essential drugs on a sustainable basis. 46 Proportion of population with access to affordable essential drugs on a sustainable basis. 18 In cooperation with the private sector, make available the benefits of new technologies, especially information and communications. 47 Telephone lines and cellular subscribers per 100 population. 48 Personal computers in use per 100 population and Internet users per 100 population. Source: Data from United Nations Development Programme, at www.undp.org. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 207 Examples of individual indicators We will now consider some examples of individual indicators. The purpose of this discussion is to illustrate some of the attributes that tend to characterize less developed countries; to demonstrate the use of indicators when making comparisons across countries as well as over time (how is one country or region performing relative to another; is a country or region improving its performance over time?); to show that GDP per capita can be a poor indicator of the diverse dimensions of economic development; to show that a country’s level of development can vary enormously with respect to different indicators; to show that development issues apply to developed countries as well as developing ones; and finally, to suggest that a great many countries, both more developed and less developed, can make progress with achieving development goals by making better use of available resources (i.e. through a reallocation of resources towards increased social services provision and merit goods production). Health indicators Health indicators measure attributes of populations related to health. Three commonly used health indicators are life expectancy at birth, infant mortality and maternal mortality. Data for all three are provided in Table 7.7, which lists selected countries in order of declining GDP per capita (in US$ PPP). Life expectancy at birth refers to the number of years one can expect to live, calculated as the average number of years of life in a population. Life expectancy is determined by many factors, and is greater when there are: · adequate public health services (such as populationwide immunization services and provision of health information and education), and control and prevention of communicable diseases (for example, malaria, measles, tuberculosis, HIV/AIDS) · adequate health care services with broad access by the entire population · a healthy environment, including access to safe drinking water and sanitation, and low levels of pollution · an adequate and healthy diet and avoidance of malnutrition · a high level of education of the entire population · healthy lifestyles, including low levels of smoking · absence of serious income inequalities and poverty. 208 Part 3: Macroeconomics All these factors are among the numerous dimensions of economic and human development. Therefore life expectancy at birth is a widely used indicator of development. In 2005, Japan had the highest life expectancy in the world of nearly 82 years and Zambia the lowest, at the shocking number of just under 40 years (see Table 7.7). Table 7.7 shows that lower levels of GDP per capita (US$ PPP) tend to be associated with lower life expectancies and vice versa. This is consistent with what we would expect, since higher income countries generally have more resources at their disposal to provide the necessary services and appropriate living conditions for their populations that will secure them longer lives. However, there are very wide divergences from this broad pattern, indicating clearly that income per capita can explain only a small part of the wide variations in life expectancy. For example, Greece has a higher life expectancy than the United States, though its GDP per capita (in PPPs) is just over half that of the latter. More surprisingly, Costa Rica surpasses the United States in life expectancy, although its GDP per capita is roughly a quarter that of the United States. There are other striking examples of such divergences: Sri Lanka’s and Armenia’s life expectancies are almost as high as Saudi Arabia’s although their per capita GDP is less than one-third of Saudi Arabia’s. Moldova’s life expectancy is substantially higher than Russia’s, yet its GDP per capita is less than one-fifth of Russia’s. How is it possible that some countries have managed to achieve high life expectancies relative to their level of output and incomes, while others are faring less well? The answer to these questions lies in the degree to which countries have addressed the development issues listed above, for example: · The relatively low life expectancy in the United States (compared to other highly developed countries) may be due to inequalities in income and education resulting in pockets of poverty, which in turn are connected to poor housing and living conditions, lifestyles that promote poor health and poor nutrition, and low access to medical care (due to lack of medical coverage). This results in lower life expectancy among low income groups, which lowers the average over the entire American population. · Saudi Arabia’s low life expectancy relative to its income level is due to significant income inequalities and inadequate attention to provision of health care services to lower income groups. Table 7.7 GDP per capita (US$ PPP) and health indicators in selected countries. Country GDP per capita (US$ PPP) 2005 Life expectancy at birth (years) 2000–2005 Infant mortality rate (per 1000 live births) 2005 Maternal mortality ratio (per 100,000 live births) 2005* United States 41,890 77.4 6 11 Norway 41,420 79.3 3 7 United Kingdom 33,238 78.5 5 8 Australia 31,794 80.4 5 4 Japan 31,267 81.9 3 6 Greece 23,381 78.3 4 3 15,711 71.6 21 18 Chile 12,027 77.9 8 16 Russia 10,845 64.8 14 28 Costa Rica 10,180 78.1 11 30 Turkey 8,407 70.8 26 44 Brazil 8,402 71.0 31 110 China 6,757 72.0 23 45 Venezuela 6,632 72.8 18 57 Armenia 4,945 71.4 26 39 Swaziland 4,824 43.9 110 390 Sri Lanka 4,595 70.8 12 58 Indonesia 3,843 68.6 28 420 India 3,452 62.9 56 450 Cambodia 2,727 56.8 98 590 Angola 2,335 41.0 154 1400 Moldova 2,100 67.9 14 22 Zimbabwe 2,038 40.0 81 880 Kyrgyzstan 1,927 65.3 58 150 Tajikistan 1,456 65.9 59 170 Uganda 1,454 47.8 79 550 Zambia 1,023 39.2 102 830 Sierra Leone 806 41.0 165 2100 Tanzania 744 49.7 76 950 Saudi Arabia *Adjusted, based on reviews by the UN Children’s Fund (UNICEF), World Health Organization (WHO) and the UN Population Fund (UNFPA), to account for problems of underreporting and misclassification. Source: Data from United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report, 2007–08, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 209 · Costa Rica’s and Sri Lanka’s high life expectancies are due to government policies that placed a high priority to the provision of health care services for low income groups. · The very low life expectancies in sub-Saharan African countries are due to a very large extent to the disastrous impacts of HIV/AIDS, as well as problems with sanitation, safe drinking water, lack of education and information, poor public health and health care services, and premature deaths due to diseases that are both preventable and treatable (such as malaria). Infant mortality (also appearing in Table 7.7) refers to the number of deaths of infants from the time of birth until the age of one, per 1000 live births. This is indicator 14 corresponding to goal 4 of the Millennium Development Goals (see Table 7.6, page 205). Maternal mortality refers to the number of women who die per year as a result of pregnancy-related causes (per 100,000 live births). This is indicator 16 corresponding to goal 5 in the Millennium Development Goals. Both infant and maternal mortality are determined to some extent by the same factors as life expectancy; however, more than life expectancy, they reflect the quality of and access to health care services. The reason is that very many infant and maternal deaths occur because the infant and mother do not have access to the necessary health care during the mother’s pregnancy and delivery, as well as during early childhood (and additionally to lack of access to sanitation and clean water and poor nutrition of the mother). An examination of infant mortality and maternal mortality figures reveals similar patterns as life expectancy. While the United States has one of the highest GDPs per capita in the world, and while its infant and maternal mortality rates are very low by world standards, still the probability of dying at birth, infancy or during pregnancy or childbirth is higher than in any other developed country. Sri Lanka, with a lower GDP per capita than Swaziland, has about onetenth the number of infant deaths as the latter and about one-seventh the number of maternal deaths. Moldova has a lower GDP per capita than Angola, yet it has less than one-tenth the number of infant deaths compared to Angola; and for every one woman who dies in Moldova due to pregnancy-related causes, there are more than 63 women who die for similar reasons in Angola. A close look at Table 7.7 will show that there are many more examples of some countries faring much better than others, in spite of having a comparable or lower GDP per capita. 210 Part 3: Macroeconomics The discussion of health indicators illustrates the following very important points: · GDP per capita (or any other per capita income or output measure) used on its own is a poor measure of welfare of a population. · Limited resources, due to low GDP per capita, are not always the most important cause of poor health outcomes. The data indicate that most (if not all) countries, both developing and developed, can do more with their available resources to meet economic and human development goals by making better use of these. We will discover in Part 5 that better use of resources involves pursuing policies that reallocate these towards provision of social services and merit goods, improving the institutions through which these services are delivered, as well as improving income distribution. · Some development issues apply not only to developing, but to developed countries as well, because of the presence of pockets of poverty in wealthy societies that make people on low incomes subject to similar deprivations as poor people in developing economies, as well as because of the presence of institutions that do not make the most effective use of available resources. In Table 7.8 we see how infant mortality has developed over time in various country groupings. Whereas significant progress has been made in all regions and groups, infant deaths have been falling less quickly in sub-Saharan Africa, where they still remain at very high levels compared to the rest of the world. Table 7.8 Infant mortality rate (per 1000 live births), 1970 and 2005. 1970 2005 % change East Asia and Pacific 84 25 − 70.2% Eastern Europe and Central Asia 39 22 − 43.6% Latin America and Caribbean 86 26 − 69.8% Arab States 129 46 − 64.3% South Asia 130 60 − 53.8% Sub-Saharan Africa 144 102 − 29.2% OECD (high income countries only) 22 5 − 77.3% OECD (all countries) 41 9 − 78.0% Region OECD is the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, a group of mostly high income countries. Source: Data from United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report, 2007–08, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/. Income poverty You may remember from our earlier discussion that income poverty occurs when income falls below a nationally or internationally determined level that defines the poverty line. Two commonly used poverty lines are: · living on less than $1.25 a day, which is defined as extreme poverty · living on less than $2 a day, which is defined as moderate poverty. Extreme poverty used to be defined for many years as living on less than $1 a day. This was increased to $1.25 a day in 2008, in order to take into consideration more accurate measurements of the cost of living in developing countries. The first millennium development goal (to eradicate extreme poverty and hunger) is thus concerned in part with income poverty. The first of the two targets corresponding to this goal is to halve in the period to 2015 the proportion of people living in extreme poverty, and the first indicator used to measure and monitor progress towards the achievement of this target is the percentage of a population living on less than $1.00 a day. In the summer of 2008, the World Bank published one of the most comprehensive studies on poverty in developing countries ever undertaken. The study estimates that there are 1.4 billion people in the Table 7.9 world living in extreme poverty (using the $1.25 a day poverty line), and that there are 2.6 billion people living in moderate poverty (less than $2 a day), representing nearly half the total population of developing countries. Data on extreme and moderate poverty in developing countries appear in Table 7.9, both in terms of numbers of people (for extreme poverty) and in terms of percentages, by geographical regions, and for two years, 1990 and 2005. Columns 4 and 5 in the table indicate that significant progress was made in reducing the percentage of people in extreme poverty, which fell from about 42% in 1990 to 25% in 2005. Columns 1 and 2 show that there has also occurred a significant decrease in terms of absolute numbers. However, progress has been highly uneven across geographical regions. The greatest declines in extreme poverty occurred in the East Asia and Pacific region, as the percentage of people living on less than $1.25 a day dropped from 60% in 1990 to 16% in 2001. South Asia also made some progress, showing a drop from 52% to 40% (however, note that the number of people in extreme poverty, appearing in columns 1 and 2, has increased, due to population growth). Developments in the other regions look less encouraging. The large increase in eastern Europe and Central Asia (both in absolute numbers and in percentage terms) was due to the collapse of the former Soviet Union and communist regimes in 1990–91, causing huge disruptions to economic Extreme and moderate poverty. Region East Asia and Pacific (of which China) Extreme poverty: millions of people living on less than $1.25 a day Extreme poverty: % of population living on less than $1.25 a day Moderate poverty: % of population living on less than $2.00 a day (1) 1990 (2) 2005 (3) % change (4) 1990 (5) 2005 (6) 1990 (7) 2005 873.4 (683.2) 316.2 (207.7) − 63.8 (− 69.6) 54.7 (60.2) 16.8 (15.9) 79.8 (84.6) 38.7 (36.3) 9.1 17.3 90.1 2.0 3.7 6.9 8.9 Latin America and Caribbean 42.9 46.1 − 7.5 9.8 8.4 19.7 16.6 Middle East and North Africa 9.7 11.0 13.4 4.3 3.6 19.7 16.9 South Asia (of which India) 579.2 (435.5) 595.6 (455.8) 2.8 (4.7) 51.7 (51.3) 40.3 (41.6) 82.7 (82.6) 73.9 (75.6) Sub-Saharan Africa 299.1 390.6 30.6 57.9 51.2 76.2 73.0 1,813.4 1,376.7 − 24.1 41.6 25.2 63.2 47.0 Eastern Europe and Central Asia Total Source: Data from Shaohua Chen and Martin Ravallion, ‘The Developing World Is Poorer than We Thought, But No Less Successful in the Fight against Poverty’, World Bank, Development Research Group, Policy Research Working Paper 4703, August 2008. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 211 activity and resulting in significant unemployment and drops in incomes (though there are signs that poverty in this group of countries has begun to go down). The most worrisome region is sub-Saharan Africa, where half of the total population lives in extreme poverty (column 5), and nearly three-quarters in moderate poverty (column 7). Whereas the share of the total population in extreme poverty fell in the period 1990 to 2005, the actual number of extremely poor people increased because of population growth. The country containing the largest number of extremely poor people is India, with about 456 million people, or 42% of its total population, living on less than $1.25 a day. (India belongs to the South Asia group of countries.) Countries with the largest percentages of extremely poor people are in subSaharan Africa, where in some cases more than 70% of a country’s population live on less than $1.25 a day. The 1.4 billion of extremely poor people in the world, living on less than $1.25 a day, account for nearly one-quarter of the world’s population. The 2.6 billion people living on less than $2 a day (moderate poverty) account for about 47% of the world’s population. Income distribution It is useful to distinguish between absolute poverty and relative poverty. Measures of absolute poverty define a minimum income level, so that the percentage of a population (or the number of individuals) whose income falls below the minimum determines the amount of absolute poverty. Extreme poverty and moderate poverty, discussed above, are both examples of absolute poverty. Measures of relative poverty, by contrast, compare the income of one group in a society with the income of another group. They are useful for determining how equally or unequally society’s income is distributed among its total population. One simple measure of the degree of equality (or inequality) of income distribution is the share of total income of a society that goes to the poorest fifth (or ‘quintile’) of a population.14 This measure corresponds to the first of the Millennium Development Goals (to eradicate extreme poverty and hunger) as indicator number 3. 14 It is also possible to consider the share of income of the top quintile, as well as taking the ratio of the top quintile to the bottom quintile. The analysis can also be carried out in terms of deciles (10% of the population) 212 Part 3: Macroeconomics Some data for this indicator are provided in Table 7.10, column 2. Let’s consider what these figures mean. If income were completely equally distributed, everyone would receive exactly the same income, in which case every quintile (every 20% segment of the population) would receive exactly 20% of income. In this hypothetical situation there would be no relative poverty; since everyone would receive the same income, no one would be poor relative to someone else; everyone would be equally ‘poor’ or equally ‘rich’. If income is unequally distributed, some quintiles receive less than 20% and others more than 20% of income. For example, in the case of Thailand, the poorest 20% of the population receives 6.3% of total income. In Colombia, the poorest 20% of the population receives only 2.5% of total income. The higher the percentage of income received by the poorest 20% of the population, and the closer it is to 20%, the more equal is the distribution of income. The smaller the percentage, and the closer it is to zero, the more unequal the distribution of income. The more unequal is the distribution of income, the greater is the degree of relative poverty. Table 7.10 (column 2) reveals some interesting patterns. Latin America and sub-Saharan Africa tend to have more unequal distributions of income compared to the other regions. In economies with low per capita incomes (such as in sub-Saharan African countries), highly unequal income distributions mean very low incomes for some groups as there is so little total income to be distributed in the first place. Also, it can be seen that there is no clear relationship between GDP per capita levels (in PPPs) and the degree of income inequalities. Among developing countries as a whole, Latin American countries on average have higher GDPs per capita than South Asian countries, and yet their income inequalities tend to be far greater. Moreover, South Asian countries, with very low per capita GDPs, have income shares of the lowest quintile that are comparable to those in countries in East Asia and the Pacific, with higher GDPs per capita. We will discover some reasons behind these patterns in Chapter 16, where we will also see why highly unequal income distributions can pose serious problems in countries that are trying to grow and develop. or quartiles (25% of the population). Other useful measures of income distribution are the Lorenz curve and the Gini coefficient, both of which will be examined in Chapter 11 (at higher level). Table 7.10 Income distribution, literacy, water source and sanitation. (1) GDP per capita (US$ PPP) (2005) East Asia and Pacific 6,604 (2) Share of income or consumption (%) of poorest 20% (latest available year) (3) Adult literacy rate (% ages 15 and above) (1995–2005) (4) % of population with access to improved water source (2004) (5) % of population with access to improved sanitation (2004) – 90.7 79 50 Cambodia 2,727 6.8 73.6 41 17 Philippines 5,137 5.4 92.6 85 72 China 6,757 4.3 90.9 77 44 Thailand 8,677 6.3 92.6 99 99 South Asia 3,416 – 59.5 85 37 Nepal 1,550 6.0 48.6 90 35 Pakistan 2,370 9.3 49.9 91 59 India 3,452 8.1 61.0 86 33 E. Europe and Central Asia 9,527 – 99.0 94 – Tajikistan 1,356 7.9 99.5 59 51 Bosnia and Herzegovina 7,032 9.5 96.7 97 95 Kazakhstan 7,857 7.4 99.5 86 72 10,845 6.1 99.4 97 87 Latin America and Caribbean 8,417 – 90.3 91 77 Colombia 7,304 2.5 92.8 93 86 Brazil 8,402 2.8 88.6 90 75 Mexico 10,751 4.3 91.6 97 9 Middle East and North Africa 6,716 – 70.3 86 71 Russia Yemen 930 7.4 54.1 67 43 Egypt 4,337 8.6 71.4 98 70 Algeria 7,066 7.0 69.9 85 92 Sub-Saharan Africa 1,998 – 60.3 55 37 Malawi 667 7.0 64.1 73 61 Sierra Leone 806 1.1 34.8 57 39 Zambia 1,023 3.6 68.0 58 55 Swaziland 4 824 4.3 79.6 62 48 Source: Data from United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report, 2007–08, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 213 Income distribution will also be discussed further in Chapter 11. The interested student should refer to Table 11.3 (page 318), which compares income distribution by quintiles for a range of countries grouped by income levels (including high income countries). Literacy, improved water source and improved sanitation Table 7.10 contains data for three more indicators: · the adult literacy rate (column 3), or the percentage of people aged 15 and above who can read and write; this is related to indicator 8 of goal 2 of the Millennium Development Goals (which refers to the proportion of people ages 15–24 who can read and write) extremely important factors determining levels of health. A significant proportion of poor levels of health, and much of infant and child mortality (as well as adult mortality) in developing countries is due to limited access to clean water and sanitation services by substantial proportions of populations. We will come back to these issues in Part 5. The data of Table 7.10 illustrate the points made earlier: given their levels of GDP per capita, many countries can do more with their available resources; also, a country’s level of development can vary enormously with respect to different indicators. For example, Tajikistan has achieved a level of literacy that is comparable to the most highly developed countries in the world, yet it fares far less well with respect to access to an improved water source and sanitation. · the percentage of the population with access to an improved source of water (column 4), indicator 30 of goal 7 of the Millennium Development Goals · the percentage of the population with access to improved sanitation (column 5), indicator 31 of goal 7 of the Millennium Development Goals. The data on literacy reveal that there are very wide variations among regions and among countries within regions. Most developed countries (not shown in the table) have literacy rates at or close to 99% of the population. The developing country group with the highest literacy rate is Eastern Europe and Central Asia, and that is due to the very strong emphasis placed on education by former communist regimes. Countries of East Asia and Latin America are also performing well. Literacy rates tend to be far lower in the Middle East and North Africa group, and even lower in some sub-Saharan African countries. The interested student may also examine Table 16.1 (Chapter 16, page 435), which presents further information on literacy rates and school enrolment in developing countries. In Chapter 15 we will see why literacy and education are very important sources of economic growth and development. The data in columns 4 and 5 indicate wide variations among countries with respect to the proportion of their populations that have access to improved water and sanitation. Access to clean water and sanitation are very important factors determining quality of life and standards of well-being in societies, and are 214 Part 3: Macroeconomics Demographic indicators Demographic indicators show how populations change in size, increasing or decreasing according to numbers of births, deaths, and migration. Table 7.11 presents some demographic indicators for different population groups around the world grouped by income levels. Population growth rates have been falling on average in all income categories, though they remain much higher in the low income countries, meaning that the populations in this group of countries are growing more rapidly than elsewhere. The reason for higher population growth rates lies in higher birth rates, also shown in the table. The crude birth rate (defined to be the number of births occurring in one year, per 1000 population) in low income countries was 29 in 2001, compared to 17 and 12 in middle and high income countries respectively. High population growth rates result in a relatively large proportion of children in the population, while the proportion of elderly persons is relatively small. This can be seen in the two ‘Population age composition columns’ of the table. In low income countries, the proportion of the population aged 0–14 is double that of the high income countries, while the proportion aged 65 and above is less than one-third. This means that all the people of working age (above age 14 and less than 65) in low income countries must work for and support proportionately double the number of children as in high income countries. In the high income countries the working population must support a relatively larger elderly population. Table 7.11 Demographic indicators by country income group. Country group Total population (millions) 2001 Average annual population growth rate, 1980–2001 (%) Average annual population growth rate, 2001–2015 (est.) (%) Population age composition 0–14 (%) Population age composition 65 + (%) Crude birth rate, no. births per 1000 Low income 2505.9 2.1 1.5 36.4 4.4 29 Middle income* 2667.2 1.4 0.8 27.1 6.9 17 High income 957.0 0.7 0.3 18.4 14.3 12 *Includes both upper middle and lower middle income groups. Source: Data from World Bank, World Development Indicators 2003 (World Bank, 2003). The proportion of the non-working (dependent) population that must be supported by people of working age is called the dependency burden of the population. It can be seen that, adding together the two dependent age groups (children and the elderly), the dependency burden is far greater for the low income than for the high income countries (40.8% of the population as opposed to 32.7%). A higher dependency burden means that the income of a family must be stretched out to cover the needs of more family members. When the family income is low to begin with, as in the case of most households in many developing countries, the income per person that results is often barely enough to cover basic needs. While there is no birth rate or population growth rate that is considered to be the ‘right’ one for any country, it is believed today that high birth rates, and hence high population growth rates, may hinder economic development. We will consider the reasons for this in Part 5. Relative importance of primary, secondary and tertiary sectors You may remember from Chapter 3, page 78, that whereas most less developed countries tend to have a relatively large primary (mainly agricultural) sector, as they grow and develop the relative share of agriculture shrinks, becoming progressively replaced by industry, and at a later stage by services (in Section 3.3 of Chapter 3, page 78, we explained this phenomenon in terms of elasticities). Table 7.12 (page 216) lists several countries in order of declining GDP per capita (in US$ PPP), and shows the relative shares of GDP in each of the three sectors. We can see that there is a general trend for the share of agriculture to become smaller as per capita GDP becomes larger, and for the share of services to increase. Composite indicators In 1990, under the leadership of Mahbub ul Haq (a highly influential Pakistani development economist), and the strong intellectual influence of Amartya Sen (who won the Nobel Prize for his work in economic development), the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) introduced the concept of human development, explained on page 198. Each year since 1990, the UNDP has produced a Human Development Report which presents analyses of development issues of current interest, as well as statistical information on over 100 ‘human development indicators’ and four composite indicators: the Human Development Index (HDI), the Human Poverty Index (HPI), the GenderRelated Development Index (GDI) and the Gender Empowerment Measure (GEM). Composite indicators are usually expressed as an ‘index’. An index is a set of numbers showing the relative position of a variable in a list. This will become clearer in the consideration of composite indicators below. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 215 Table 7.12 GDP per capita (US$ PPP) and relative shares of primary, secondary and tertiary sectors in selected countries, 2003. Country GDP per capita (US$ PPP) Agriculture, value added (% of GDP) Industry, value added (% of GDP) Services, value added (% of GDP) United Kingdom 27,147 1 26 73 Greece 19,954 7 23 70 Portugal 18,126 4 27 70 Korea, Rep. 17,971 4 41 55 Poland 11,379 3 33 64 Russian Federation 9,230 5 35 60 Brazil 7,790 10 40 50 Colombia 6,702 11 31 58 China 5,003 13 46 41 India 2,892 21 27 52 Vietnam 2,490 22 40 38 1,751 37 21 42 Togo 1,696 41 23 36 Uganda 1,457 32 21 47 Central African Rep. 1,089 56 22 23 Kyrgyzstan Sources: Data from United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report 2005, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/; data from World Bank, World Development Indicators 2005 (World Bank, 2005). The Human Development Index The Human Development Index (HDI) is the bestknown and most widely used index of the UNDP. It is a summary measure of human development and measures average achievement in three dimensions: (i) a long and healthy life, measured by life expectancy at birth (this indicator was discussed above); (ii) knowledge, measured by adult literacy and the combined primary, secondary and tertiary enrolment ratio (or the ratio of the number of students enrolled in a level of education to the total population of school age for that level); and (iii) a decent standard of living, measured by GDP per capita (in US$ PPP). Each dimension is expressed as a value between 0 and 1, with 0 being the lowest possible value for the dimension, and 1 being the highest. The composite index is simply the average over the three dimensions. Each country receives an HDI value from 0 to 1, and the countries are ranked according to their HDI values. 216 Part 3: Macroeconomics HDI ranks and HDIs (i.e. HDI values) for selected countries, together with their corresponding GDP per capita (in US$ PPP), appear in Table 7.13, where countries are listed in order of declining HDIs. Of the 177 countries for which the UNDP calculates HDIs, Norway ranked second in 2005, meaning that it had achieved the second highest level of human development in the world, with an HDI of 0.968 (the first country was Iceland, not shown here). In this table, countries have been selected to show how it is possible to achieve similar levels of human development with very different levels of GDP per capita. For example, Norway and Australia have very similar HDIs, indicating that they have attained approximately the same level of human development. However, Australia has accomplished this high level of human development with a lower GDP per capita. The same can be said for New Zealand and the United Kingdom, Greece and Germany, etc. The most striking pair of countries is Tajikistan and South Africa. Tajikistan’s GDP per capita is roughly one-tenth of South Africa’s, and yet their HDIs are very close. We can conclude that Tajikistan, with about onetenth the income per person of South Africa, has succeeded in almost reaching South Africa’s level of human development! Table 7.13 Human Development Index and GDP per capita (US$ PPP) for selected countries in order of decreasing HDI (increasing HDI rank). Country HDI rank Norway Australia Comparisons between HDIs and GDP per capita confirm the important points made earlier (in connection with health indicators): · GDP per capita used in isolation from other indicators can be a poor measure of the diverse dimensions of development. · Many countries, even with their given levels of GDP per capita, are capable of making significant improvements in the welfare of their populations simply by making different choices regarding the resources that are allocated to health, education and other services or merit goods. In other words, some economic and human development is possible even in low income countries and in the absence of significant growth. Human Development Index (HDI) 2005 GDP per capita (US$ PPP) 2005 2 0.968 41,420 3 0.962 31,749 United Kingdom 16 0.946 33,238 New Zealand 19 0.943 24,996 Germany 22 0.935 29,461 Greece 24 0.926 23,381 Uruguay 46 0.852 9,962 Bahamas 49 0.845 18,380 Russian Federation 67 0.802 10,845 Albania 68 0.801 5,316 Turkey 84 0.775 8,407 Ecuador 89 0.772 4,341 Algeria 104 0.733 7,062 Other composite indicators Vietnam 105 0.733 3,071 Moldova 111 0.708 2,100 Egypt 112 0.708 4,337 South Africa 121 0.674 11,110 Tajikistan 122 0.673 1,356 The United Nations Development Programme has developed three more composite indicators. One of these is the Human Poverty Index (HPI), based on the concept of human poverty as distinct from income poverty. There are actually two human poverty indices: one is for less developed countries, and the other is for more developed countries. Swaziland 141 0.547 4,824 Madagascar 143 0.533 923 Angola 162 0.446 2,335 Malawi 164 0.437 667 Source: Data from United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report, 2007–08, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/. · Economic and human development issues apply not only to developing countries, but to developed countries as well. The HDI is very useful as a tool for countries and governments wishing to devise policies that focus on human development. However, it should be noted that the HDI, too, has its shortcomings as a measure of development. This is because economic and human development are much broader concepts with more dimensions than are reflected in the HDI. The HDI does not provide us with information about income distribution, malnutrition, demographic trends, unemployment, gender inequalities, political participation, etc. As you may remember, income poverty occurs when income falls below a nationally or internationally determined level that defines the poverty line (such as $1.25 a day or $2 a day in developing countries). Human poverty refers to deprivations and the lack of opportunities and choices that allow individuals to lead a long, healthy and creative life with a decent standard of living, freedom, and dignity. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 217 Human poverty is measured in the same three dimensions as the Human Development Index, but with the use of different indicators. The HPI in developing countries uses the following indicators: · deprivation in longevity, measured by the probability at birth of not surviving to age 40 · deprivation in knowledge, measured by the percentage of illiterate adults · deprivations in the standard of living, measured by ❍ ❍ ❍ the percentage of people who do not have sustainable access to safe water the percentage of people who do not have access to health services the percentage of children under age five who are underweight for their age. Indicators used for the HPI of developed countries include: (i) probability at birth of not surviving to age 60; (ii) percentage of adults lacking functional literacy skills; (iii) percentage of people living below the nationally determined poverty line; and (iv) the longterm underemployment rate. Unlike the Human Development Index, which focuses on positive achievements within a country, the Human Poverty Index focuses attention on deprivations (the lack of benefits or basic necessities). In addition, by differentiating itself from income poverty, it draws attention to the point that income does not guarantee the absence of deprivations. Table 7.14 presents the human poverty rank and index for selected developing countries. (The Human Poverty Index is calculated as a number from 1 to 100 and is expressed as a percentage.) The lower the rank and index number of a country, the smaller is its human poverty. The last column indicates whether a country’s human poverty is greater or smaller than income poverty. Income poverty (not shown in the table) is defined as the percentage of the population living on less than $1 a day. If a country’s human poverty rank is larger than its income poverty rank, this means that human poverty is greater than income poverty, therefore the figure in the last column has a positive sign (for example, Turkey and South Africa). If, on the other hand, the human poverty rank is smaller than the income poverty rank, then income poverty is greater than human poverty, and the figure in the last column is negative. Therefore, in Costa Rica, Colombia, China and India there is 218 Part 3: Macroeconomics greater income poverty than human poverty. When a country has greater income poverty, this means that the government is providing social services (education, health care, safe water, etc.) that people have access to and can benefit from even though their incomes may be very low. The Gender-Related Development Index (GDI) is similar to the Human Development Index (HDI) in that it measures the average achievement of the population in the same three dimensions as the HDI, using the same indicators, but adjusted to reflect the inequalities between women and men in each of the three dimensions. As we will see in Part 5 (Chapter 16), gender issues are worthy of special attention because of the special roles of women in economic and human development. The Gender Empowerment Measure (GEM) also measures gender inequalities but in different dimensions: (i) political participation and decision-making, measured by women’s and men’s parliamentary seats; (ii) economic participation and decision-making, measured by women’s and men’s percentage shares of positions as legislators, managers, and professional and technical positions; and (iii) power over economic resources, measured by income earned. Table 7.14 Human and income poverty. Country Human poverty rank* Human Poverty Index (HPI)* HPI rank minus income poverty rank* Costa Rica 4 4.4 − 10 Colombia 10 8.1 − 13 Turkey 19 12.0 12 China 24 13.2 − 14 South Africa 52 31.7 20 India 48 31.4 − 12 Pakistan 71 41.9 24 Ethiopia 92 55.5 20 *A total of 95 countries are in this index, which does not include developed countries. Source: Data from United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report 2005, available at http://hdr.undp.org/en/. Test your understanding 7.9 1 (a) Explain the concept of income poverty. (b) What is the difference between extreme poverty and moderate poverty? (c) How are extreme poverty and moderate poverty related to income poverty? 2 (a) Explain the difference between absolute poverty and relative poverty. (b) How can we measure absolute poverty? (c) How can we measure relative poverty? 3 What is the difference between individual and composite indicators? Can you provide some examples of each? 4 What are the advantages of using the Human Development Index over GDP per capita as a measure of economic and human development? 5 What is the difference between the Human Development Index and the Human Poverty Index? What could be the advantage of using the Human Poverty Index when studying the problems of very low income groups in developing countries? 6 Why do you think the United Nations Development Programme constructs a Human Poverty Index for more developed countries in addition to a Human Poverty Index for less developed countries? 7 Use examples of individual or composite indicators (you may use the information in the text) to illustrate the following points: (a) GDP per capita is a poor indicator of levels of welfare or levels of economic and human development (b) many countries around the world can do more to promote the welfare of their populations through a reallocation of resources, even in the absence of economic growth (c) many economic development issues apply to MDCs as well as LDCs (d) countries may be more developed with respect to some indicators and less developed with respect to other indicators. Chapter 7: Macroeconomic concepts and measurement 219 Questions for review 7.1 [15 marks] (a) Explain the three methods that can be used to measure aggregate output. (b) How does the circular flow of income model help us illustrate the equivalence of the three methods? 7.2 [15 marks] Explain whether you agree or disagree with each of the following: (a) You have just read in the news that GDP in your country increased by 4% this year over last year. You therefore conclude that the quantity of output produced increased by 4%. (b) In the early 1990s, following the collapse of the Soviet Union, many eastern European and former Soviet Union countries experienced negative net investment for a period of time. This means there was a drop in their stock of capital goods. (c) If a government wants a measure of its population’s income per capita it should use GDP per capita; if it wants a measure of the quantity of output produced per capita it should use GNP per capita. (d) GDP per capita is a better indicator of a country’s welfare than total GDP, because it calculates the amount of output produced per person in the population. (e) The average American is 12.5 times richer than the average Russian, since US GDP per capita is 12.5 times greater than Russian GDP per capita, based on the dollar–rouble exchange rate. (The rouble is Russia’s national currency.) 7.3 [10 marks] You are interested in making welfare comparisons (a) across a number of countries, and (b) over time for a single country. What income or output measures could you use in each case? 7.4 [5 marks] Explain what factors can account for different values of GDP and GNP for a single country. 7.5 [10 marks] Why does purchasing power differ across countries? What problem does this pose when we use GDP to make international comparisons of welfare? How can this problem be resolved? 7.6 [15 marks] Evaluate GDP per capita as a measure of a society’s welfare and as the basis for making international welfare comparisons. 7.7 [10 marks] Using the production possibilities model and diagrams, explain the sources of economic growth. 220 Part 3: Macroeconomics 7.8 [15 marks] Using the production possibilities model and diagrams, evaluate the following statements: (a) It is very difficult, if at all possible, for economic development to occur without economic growth. (b) If economic development is to be maintained over a long period of time, economic growth is essential. 7.9 [15 marks] An Economics textbook published in 1998 writes the following: ‘A country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services. Policymakers who want to encourage growth in standards of living must aim to increase their nation’s productive ability by encouraging rapid accumulation of the factors of production and ensuring that these factors are employed as effectively as possible’ (N. Gregory Mankiw, Principles of Economics (Dryden Press, 1998), p. 537). (a) Use the production possibilities model to illustrate the process that this textbook describes. (b) Do you agree with the argument made here, that a rapid accumulation of factors of production together with their effective use will lead to growth in a country’s standards of living? Explain why or why not. 7.10 [10 marks] Compare and contrast the problems involved in measuring economic growth and measuring economic development. 7.11 [10 marks] Both individual indicators as well as the Human Development Index can be used to show that many countries can do more to increase the well-being of their populations even with their given level of GDP per capita. How is this possible? 7.12 [10 marks] Using examples of individual and composite indicators, explain some of the methods used by economists to measure economic development. Chapter 8 Macroeconomics Aggregate demand and aggregate supply In this chapter we will develop the aggregate demand–aggregate supply model of the macroeconomy, an important analytical tool for studying output fluctuations, changes in the price level and unemployment, as well as economic growth. This chapter will lay the foundations for the analysis of macroeconomic policies in Chapter 9 and the problems of unemployment and inflation in Chapter 10. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · distinguish between the phases of the business (trade) cycle explain the difference between actual and potential GDP define aggregate demand and identify the factors that cause it to change distinguish between the short run and long run in macroeconomics define short-run aggregate supply and identify the factors that cause it to change explain short-run equilibrium in the AD-AS model identify the three short-run equilibrium states of the economy, and relate them to inflationary and recessionary (deflationary) gaps identify factors that change short-run equilibrium, and their impacts on real GDP, the price level and the level of employment define long-run aggregate supply, the long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve and long-run equilibrium in the neoclassical perspective identify the factors that cause economic growth and shifts in the LRAS curve understand that in the neoclassical perspective, recessionary and inflationary gaps cannot persist in the long run explain the Keynesian aggregate supply curve in terms of wage and price rigidities identify and explain recessionary (deflationary) and inflationary gaps in the Keynesian perspective analyse less than full employment equilibrium (deflationary gaps) in the Keynesian perspective understand the different policy implications of the neoclassical and Keynesian perspectives. Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 221 8.1 The business (trade) cycle: economic fluctuations time, shown on the horizontal axis. Note that GDP is measured in real terms, so that the vertical axis measures changes in the volume of output produced after the influence of price level changes has been eliminated. Understanding the business (trade) cycle In Chapter 7 we discussed the concept of economic growth, and Table 7.2 (page 194) presented average growth rates in real GDP per capita in selected countries around the world for the period 1990– 2005, indicating that the output per person of most economies usually grows over extended periods. The growth rates in Table 7.2 consist of averages taken over many years. These average growth rates can be highly misleading if they are taken as an indication of what happens on a year-to-year or month-to-month basis. In fact, output growth virtually everywhere in the world is uneven and irregular. In some years (or months) real output may grow rapidly, in other years (or months) more slowly, and in still others it may even decline, indicating negative growth or economic contraction. Fluctuations in the growth of real output, consisting of alternating periods of expansion (increasing real output) and contraction (decreasing real output), are called business cycles, or alternatively trade cycles or economic fluctuations. Each cycle consists of a period of expansion, or growth in real GDP, followed by a period of contraction, or decline in real GDP (negative growth). Let’s consider what these mean in some detail. · Expansion An expansion occurs when there is positive growth in real GDP, and is shown by those parts of the curve in Figure 8.1 that are upward sloping. During periods of growth in real GDP, employment of resources increases, and the general price level of the economy (which is an average over all prices) usually begins to rise more rapidly than before. An increase in the general price level is known as inflation (this will be studied in Chapter 10). · Peak A peak represents the cycle’s maximum level of real GDP, and marks the end of the expansion. When the economy reaches a peak, unemployment of resources has fallen substantially, and the general price level may be rising quite rapidly; in other words, the economy is likely to be experiencing inflation. · Contraction Following the peak, the economy begins to experience falling real GDP (negative growth), shown by the downward-sloping parts of the curve. If the contraction lasts six months or more it is termed a recession, which is characterized by falling real GDP and growing unemployment of resources. Increases in the price level may slow The phases of the business (trade) cycle A business cycle is shown in Figure 8.1, which plots real GDP, measured on the vertical axis, against real GDP actually achieved peak contraction real GDP expansion potential GDP peak trough trough 0 Figure 8.1 The business cycle (trade cycle). 222 Part 3: Macroeconomics time (years) down considerably, and it is even possible that prices in some sectors may begin to fall. (However, this is not always the case; some contractions are accompanied by increasing price levels or inflation.) · Trough A trough represents the cycle’s minimum level of GDP, or the end of the contraction. There may now be widespread unemployment. A trough is followed by a new period of expansion (also known as a recovery), marking the beginning of a new cycle. (The line going through the business cycle, called ‘potential output’, will be discussed below.) The terms ‘business cycle’ and ‘trade cycle’ suggest a phenomenon that is regular and predictable, whereas business cycles are in fact both irregular, as they do not occur at regular time intervals, and unpredictable. For these reasons, many economists prefer to call them ‘economic fluctuations’. While each cycle typically lasts several years, it is not possible to generalize, as there is wide variation in duration (how long the cycle lasts), as well as in intensity (how strong the expansion is and how deep the contraction or recession is). Expansions usually last longer than contractions. These are the reasons why the curve appearing in Figure 8.1 has an irregular shape. The relationship between real GDP and unemployment When real GDP fluctuates, it does so together with a number of other macroeconomic variables. One of the most important of these is the level of employment or unemployment of labour, or how many people in the workforce are working or are unemployed (not working). There is a very close relationship between changes in real GDP and the level of unemployment in the economy. When real GDP grows in the expansion phase, unemployment falls; in the contraction phase, when real GDP falls, unemployment increases. The reason for this relationship is easy to see. In an expansion, real GDP increases because firms increase the quantity of output they produce; in order to do this, they must hire more labour (and other resources), and therefore unemployment falls. In a contraction, when real GDP falls, firms cut back on their production, they lay off workers, and the result is growing unemployment. We can therefore say that: As real GDP increases, unemployment falls, and as real GDP falls, unemployment increases (ceteris paribus). For every economy, there is a level of real GDP at which the economy experiences ‘full employment’. This is known as the full employment level of output, or full employment level of real GDP. However, the term ‘full employment’ is misleading, as it does not mean that all resources, including all labour resources, are employed to the greatest extent possible; it does not mean that unemployment is zero. Whenever the economy produces its ‘full employment level of output’, there is still some unemployment, known as the natural rate of unemployment. We can think of this as unemployment of labour that is normal or ‘natural’ for the economy. There are many reasons why unemployment never falls to zero. At any point in time, there are some people who are in between jobs, some who are moving from one geographical area to another, some people who are training or retraining in order to be able to get a new or better job, and some people who are temporarily out of work. Therefore, even under the best of circumstances for an economy, there will always be some people who will be unemployed. (We will return to these points in Chapter 10 when we discuss unemployment more fully.) To summarize: The full employment level of output or full employment level of real GDP is that level of real GDP at which unemployment is equal to the natural rate of unemployment. The natural rate of unemployment is the unemployment that exists when there is ‘full employment’. Actual and potential GDP Let’s return now to the business cycle shown in Figure 8.1. The cyclical line represents fluctuations in real GDP that is actually achieved by an economy over time. These fluctuations occur over relatively short periods of time, typically lasting several years, and are therefore referred to as ‘short-term economic fluctuations’. The straight line going through the cyclical line represents average growth over long periods of time (many years), and is the economy’s full employment level of output, discussed above, which is also known as potential output or potential GDP. Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 223 Potential GDP represents the level of real GDP that can be produced when there is full employment, meaning that unemployment is equal to the natural rate of unemployment. As you can see in the figure, real GDP actually achieved fluctuates around potential GDP. Figure 8.2 introduces a further concept related to the business (trade) cycle. When actual GDP lies above potential GDP (as at point d), or below potential GDP (as at point e), there results a GDP gap, also known as an output gap. The output gap is simply actual GDP minus potential GDP, and may be positive or negative. When actual GDP is equal to potential GDP (as at points a, b, c) the output gap is equal to zero. As Figure 8.2 illustrates, actual GDP fluctuates around the full employment level of GDP, also known as potential GDP. When the economy’s actual GDP is at points such as a, b and c, actual GDP is equal to potential GDP, and the economy is achieving full employment, which is equal to the natural rate of unemployment. When the economy’s actual GDP is greater than potential GDP, such as at point d, there is an output gap, and unemployment has fallen to less than the natural rate. When actual GDP is less than potential GDP, such as at point e, there is an output gap where unemployment is greater than the natural rate. Why we study the business (trade) cycle Why are we interested in studying the business cycle? Economic growth over long periods of time, represented by an upward-sloping potential output line, is a highly desirable objective (as we know from Chapter 7, page 195). Growth in real output provides opportunities to achieve higher incomes and higher standards of living. But deviations of actual output from potential output over short periods of time are not desirable. When actual output rises above potential output, the economy often experiences a rapidly rising price level, which is not good for the economy (we will see why in Chapter 10). When actual output falls below potential output, the economy experiences falling incomes and growing unemployment, causing hardship for many people and frustrating the objective of economic growth. In an ideal world, every economy would experience economic growth over long periods of time, with continuously low levels of unemployment and a stable or gently rising price level (low inflation). Rapid economic growth, full employment, and price stability are among the key macroeconomic objectives of economies. Figure 8.3 illustrates these objectives in terms of the business cycle. actual GDP > potential GDP; there is an output gap: unemployment < natural rate of unemployment expansion: unemployment falls real GDP d contraction: unemployment increases b a 0 actual GDP e actual GDP < potential GDP; there is an output gap: unemployment > natural rate of unemployment time (years) Figure 8.2 Illustrating actual output, potential output and unemployment in the business (trade) cycle. 224 Part 3: Macroeconomics c potential GDP = full employment GDP; unemployment = natural rate of unemployment Test your understanding 8.1 (a) Reducing the intensity of economic fluctuations: achieving price stability and full employment. real GDP real GDP 1 Using a diagram, (a) identify the phases of the business cycle; (b) explain how they relate to unemployment and inflation; and (c) explain the difference between actual and potential output. 2 Why does unemployment never fall to zero, even when there is ‘full employment’? 0 3 How does the ‘natural rate of unemployment’ time (years) relate to the ‘full employment level of output’ and to ‘potential output’? real GDP (b) Economic growth. potential output 4 What would you conclude about an economy whose business cycle showed (a) a horizontal potential GDP line; (b) a downward-sloping potential GDP line? 5 (a) What are three key macroeconomic 0 time (years) objectives of economies? (b) Use a business cycle diagram to illustrate what it means to achieve these objectives. Figure 8.3 Illustrating three macroeconomic objectives. Using the business (trade) cycle, we can understand macroeconomic objectives to involve: · Reducing the intensity of expansions and contractions: this is aimed at making output gaps as small as possible, shown by the dotted line in Figure 8.3(a). It involves flattening the cyclical curve in order to make actual output come as close as possible to potential output. It would eliminate or lessen the problem of a rising price level in an expansion, by achieving price stability, as well as the problem of unemployment in a contraction. · Increasing the steepness of the line representing potential output (or full employment output), shown by the dotted line in Figure 8.3(b): in effect, this means achieving more rapid economic growth over long periods of time. In this chapter we will develop the analytical tools that will help us understand what causes the business (trade) cycle, and what government can do to achieve the objectives of full employment, price stability and economic growth (to be considered in Chapter 9). 8.2 The aggregate demand and aggregate supply model in the short run Introducing the aggregate demand and aggregate supply (AD-AS) model The analytical tools we will develop in this chapter are based on the aggregate demand and aggregate supply (AD-AS) model of the macroeconomy. The AD-AS model superficially resembles the microeconomic demand and supply model for a single product or industry we developed in Chapter 2; however, care must be taken not to confuse them because they are in many respects very different from each other. The AD-AS model is one of the most controversial areas in macroeconomics, interpreted differently by economists according to differing theoretical perspectives. Most of the disagreements centre on aggregate supply and the shape of the aggregate supply curve. In this section we will focus on a simple interpretation of the model that most economists would find useful as the basis for understanding the macroeconomy. In Sections 8.3 and 8.4 we will enter the area of controversy by studying two Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 225 Defining aggregate demand and the aggregate demand curve Aggregate demand is the total quantity of goods and services that all buyers in an economy want to buy at different possible price levels, ceteris paribus. The total quantity of goods and services is represented by real GDP (real GDP was explained in Chapter 7). The aggregate demand curve shows the relationship between the total quantity of goods and services buyers want to buy, or real GDP demanded, and the economy’s price level, ceteris paribus. Figure 8.4(a) presents an aggregate demand curve. The horizontal axis measures the quantity of goods and services, or real GDP, and the vertical axis measures the general price level in the economy, which is an average over the prices of all goods and services. Aggregate demand is not just the demand of all consumers (as one might think from the study of microeconomics). It consists of all the components of aggregate expenditure that we studied in Chapter 7, page 185. Aggregate demand includes: · · · · the demand of consumers (C), the demand of businesses (firms) (I), the demand of government (G), (a) The downward-sloping aggregate demand curve. price level Aggregate demand and the aggregate demand curve (You may have noticed something odd about the definition of aggregate demand. In Chapter 7, page 186 we defined GDP to be equal to spending by the four components: C + I + G + (X − M). Now we are saying that aggregate demand is also equal to C + I + G + (X − M). Yet aggregate demand is not the same as GDP. The explanation for this apparent oddity is that when we define GDP to be equal to spending by the four components, we are doing so for one particular price level. When the price level changes, the level of spending by the four components also changes. The aggregate demand curve simply plots the amount of real GDP the four components want to buy at different possible price levels.) AD 0 (b) Shifts in the aggregate demand curve. the demand of foreigners for exports (X) minus the demand for imports (M) (X − M or net exports). AD3 0 Aggregate demand is the total amount of real output (real GDP) that consumers, firms, the government and foreigners demand (i.e. want to buy) at each possible price level, over a particular time period, ceteris paribus. The aggregate demand curve shows the relationship between the total amount of real output demanded in an economy by the four components, and the economy’s price level over a particular time period, ceteris paribus. The aggregate demand curve is downward sloping; there is an inverse relationship between the price level and aggregate output demanded. 226 Part 3: Macroeconomics real GDP price level main theoretical perspectives, the neoclassical and the Keynesian. The two perspectives arrive at very different conclusions over what are the most appropriate policies that governments must pursue to achieve the three macroeconomic goals. Figure 8.4 Aggregate demand. real GDP AD1 AD2 The downward slope of the aggregate demand curve (supplementary material) The reasons behind the downward slope of the aggregate demand are very different from demand in a single market that we studied in microeconomics.1 Aggregate demand slopes downward for the following three reasons: · The wealth effect Changes in the price level affect the real value of people’s wealth. (Note that wealth is not the same as income; wealth is the value of assets that people own, including their houses, their stocks and bonds, their jewellery, their works of art, and so on.) If the price level increases, the real value of wealth falls. People feel worse off and cut back on their spending on goods and services. Therefore, as the price level increases, less output is demanded, and there results an upward movement along the aggregate demand curve. If, on the other hand, there is a fall in the price level, the real value of wealth increases, people feel better off and increase their spending, thus more output is demanded, i.e. there is a downward movement along the aggregate demand curve. · The interest rate effect Changes in the price level impact upon rates of interest, which in turn affect aggregate demand. If there is an increase in the price level, consumers and firms need more money to carry out their purchases and transactions. This leads to an increase in the demand for money, which in turn results in an increase in rates of interest.2 But as interest rates rise, there results a decrease in consumer purchases financed by borrowing, as well as in investment spending by firms that must borrow to finance their expenditures. Therefore, increases in the price level lead to decreases in spending and a fall in quantity of output demanded (a downward movement along the AD curve). Similarly, a fall in the price level leads to increases in spending and a rise in quantity of output demanded (an upward movement along the AD curve). · The international trade effect If there is an increase in the price level in the domestic economy while price levels in other countries remain the same, exports Students studying Economics at higher level may note that the substitution effect and income effect explaining the downward slope of the micro demand curve do not hold for aggregate demand. The substitution effect tells as that when the price of a good changes, consumers substitute relatively less expensive goods for more expensive goods. At the macro level, there can be no substitution effect, because since aggregate demand involves demand for all goods and services, it is not possible for consumers to substitute more of lower price goods for higher price goods. Also, according to the income effect in microeconomics, as the price of a good changes, with the consumer’s nominal income held constant, there results a change in real income, which therefore causes a movement along 1 will become more expensive to foreign buyers and the quantity of exports demanded by foreigners will fall. At the same time, domestic buyers will increase their purchases from foreign countries (i.e. imports) since the goods produced in other countries are now relatively cheaper. Therefore, a rising price level produces a fall in exports, X, and a rise in imports, M, so that net exports, X − M, fall. Falling net exports represent a fall in quantity of output demanded (downward movement along the AD curve). A decrease in the domestic price level relative to other countries will give rise to a greater X and a lower M (or an increase in net exports, X − M), and so quantity of output demanded increases (an upward movement along the AD curve). Changes in aggregate demand (shifts in the AD curve) The aggregate demand curve can shift to the right or to the left. It is important to distinguish between movements on the aggregate demand curve, caused by changes in the price level, discussed above, and shifts of the aggregate demand curve, to which we turn next. (This is analogous to microeconomic analysis where we stressed the distinction between a movement along the demand curve and a shift of the curve). Aggregate demand curve shifts are shown in Figure 8.4(b). A rightward shift from AD1 to AD2 means that aggregate demand increases: for any particular price level, a larger amount of real GDP is demanded; a leftward shift from AD1 to AD3 means that aggregate demand decreases: for any particular price level, a smaller amount of real GDP is demanded. Since aggregate demand is composed of consumer spending (C), investment spending (I), government spending (G), and net export spending (X − M), changes in aggregate demand, or shifts in the aggregate demand curve, can be caused by any factor that produces a change in one of the four components. the downward-sloping demand curve. At the aggregate level, when the general price level changes, nominal incomes also change. But if nominal incomes change, there will not result an income effect. 2 Interest rates can be thought of as the ‘price’ of money services. Using standard microeconomic analysis, we can see that as the demand for money increases, while the supply is constant, the interest rate will rise. If, on the other hand, the demand for money falls, while the supply of money is constant, the interest rate will rise. We will examine interest rates briefly in Chapter 10. Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 227 We will now examine what these factors are. But before we do so, you must note the following important point. Income (or national income) is not included among the factors that can shift the aggregate demand curve. The reason is that in the aggregate demand model, changes in income cannot initiate any aggregate demand curve shifts. This will become clearer when we discuss the multiplier effect in Chapter 9 (at higher level). The factors that can shift the aggregate demand curve are grouped below under each of the components of aggregate demand. Changes in consumer spending, as a result of the following · Changes in wealth Wealth refers to the value of assets that households own, such as the value of their homes, the value of stocks they own in the stock market, the value of bonds, valuable paintings, jewellery, and so on. Note that wealth is not the same as income. An increase in consumer wealth (for example, an increase in stock market values, or an increase in the value of homes) makes people feel wealthier; therefore they spend more and the aggregate demand curve (AD) shifts to the right. A decrease in wealth lowers aggregate demand; the AD curve shifts to the left. · Changes in expectations about future income, and expectations about the future of the economy If consumers expect their income to increase in the future, or if they are optimistic about the future of the economy, they are likely to spend more today, and the AD curve shifts to the right. Expectations of falling incomes in the future, as well as pessimistic expectations about the future of the economy, cause decreases in spending in the present, and the AD curve shifts to the left. · Changes in interest rates Some consumer spending is financed by borrowing, and so it is sensitive to interest rate changes. An increase in interest rates makes borrowing more expensive, and so results in lower consumer spending, and therefore a leftward shift in the AD curve. A fall in interest rates makes borrowing less expensive, and results in more consumer spending and a rightward shift in the AD curve. Interest rates can increase or decrease as a result of a type of government policy called ‘monetary policy’ (we will examine this in Chapter 9). Note that this does not in any way contradict the point made above, that changes in income cannot initiate a change in aggregate demand. This is because changes in taxes and after-tax income do not affect national 3 228 Part 3: Macroeconomics · Changes in personal income taxes If the government decides to increase personal income taxes (taxes paid by households), then consumer disposable income, or the income that is left over after personal income taxes have been paid, falls; therefore spending drops, and the AD curve shifts to the left. If personal income taxes are lowered, the result is higher disposable income and a rightward shift in the AD curve. Changes in taxes are the result of a type of government policy called ‘fiscal policy’ (discussed in Chapter 9).3 · Changes in the level of household indebtedness ‘Indebtedness’ refers to how much money people owe from taking out loans in the past. If consumers have a high level of debt from past loans (due to past use of credit cards or taking out loans to finance consumption), then they are under pressure to make high monthly payments in order to pay back their loans plus interest, and so are likely to cut back on their present expenditures. Therefore a high level of indebtedness lowers consumption spending and shifts the AD curve to the left. A low level of indebtedness increases consumption spending and shifts the AD curve to the right. · Changes in the attitude towards spending Over time, or in particular periods of time, households may change their attitudes toward spending. After a war or a major national calamity, households often become cautious in their spending habits. This means that, given their income level, they may decide to spend less (and save more). In different periods of time, households may become more comfortable about spending more (and saving less). Some economists argue that we are currently in an age of ‘consumerism’, in which households want to acquire more and more consumer goods; this would mean that, for a given level of income, consumption increases (while saving decreases) and aggregate demand shifts to the right. Note that this list does not include national income as a factor that changes consumption and therefore shifts the AD curve. As noted above, changes in income cannot initiate a change in aggregate demand. Changes in investment spending, as a result of the following · Changes in expectations about future sales If businesses are optimistic about their sales and economic activity in the future, they spend more on income, as they simply involve a transfer of income from households to the government. National income remains unchanged. investments, and the AD curve shifts to the right. Business pessimism, on the other hand, gives rise to a leftward shift in the AD curve. · Changes (improvements) in technology Improvements in technology stimulate investment spending, thus causing increases in aggregate demand. · Changes in interest rates Increases in interest rates raise the cost of borrowing, and force businesses to reduce their investment expenditures if these are financed by borrowing, and therefore the AD curve shifts to the left. Decreases in interest rates mean that businesses can now finance their investment spending by borrowing at a lower cost, and therefore the AD curve shifts to the right. As noted above, interest rates change as a result of monetary policy (see Chapter 9). · Changes in business taxes If the government increases taxes on profits of businesses as part of its fiscal policy (see Chapter 9), firms’ after-tax profits fall, and therefore investment spending decreases and the AD curve shifts to the left. Decreases in taxes on profits result in increased aggregate demand and a rightward shift. · Legal/institutional changes Sometimes, the legal and institutional environment in which businesses operate can have an important impact on investment spending. This is often the case in many developing and transition economies where laws and institutions do not favour small businesses (we will study these issues in Part 5). For example, small businesses often do not have access to credit; in other words, they cannot borrow easily in order to finance investments. Many developing and transition economies do not have the necessary laws that secure property rights (see Chapter 1, page 25). In such situations, increasing access to credit (the ability to borrow) and securing property rights would result in an increase in investment spending, thereby shifting the AD curve to the right. Changes in government spending, as a result of the following · Changes in political priorities Governments have many expenditures, such as provision of merit goods and public goods, spending on subsidies and pensions, payments of wages and salaries to its employees, purchases of goods for its own use, and so on. It may decide to increase or decrease its own expenditures in response to changes in its priorities. Increased overall government spending shifts aggregate demand to the right, and decreased government spending shifts aggregate demand to the left. · Deliberate efforts to influence aggregate demand The government can use its own spending as part of a deliberate attempt to influence aggregate demand. The impacts of such changes in government spending on aggregate demand are exactly the same as above. This is another aspect of fiscal policy (to be discussed in Chapter 9). Changes in export spending minus import spending, as a result of the following · Changes in real national income abroad Let’s say we are considering aggregate demand in country A, which has trade links with country B. If country B’s real national income increases, it will purchase more goods and services from country A, which means that country A’s exports will increase. Therefore the AD curve in country A shifts to the right. If, on the other hand, country B’s real national income falls, it will buy less from country A, and country A’s aggregate demand shifts to the left. · Changes in exchange rates An exchange rate is the price of one country’s currency in terms of another country’s currency. Let’s again consider country A, and assume that the price of its currency increases, i.e. it appreciates, or becomes more expensive relative to the currency of, say, country B. Country B now finds country A’s output more expensive, and it therefore decreases its purchases from country A; therefore country A’s exports fall, and the AD curve in country A shifts to the left. At the same time, country A now finds country B’s output cheaper, and so it increases its imports from country B. Therefore country A’s currency appreciation has two effects: a fall in its exports, X, and an increase in its imports, M, so that net exports, X − M, fall on both counts, and aggregate demand shifts to the left. In the opposite situation, where the price of country A’s currency decreases (i.e. it depreciates), there results an increase in X and a decrease in M, so that X − M increases, and aggregate demand in country A shifts to the right. (This discussion will become much clearer after we consider exchange rates in Chapter 13.) Table 8.1 summarizes the factors that can cause movements on or shifts of the aggregate demand curve. (If you have read the section on the downward slope of the AD curve, marked as supplementary material, you should take care not to confuse the wealth effect, which results from a change in the price level (and causes a movement along the demand curve), with Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 229 Table 8.1 Distinguishing between movements along and shifts of the aggregate demand curve. Movements along the aggregate demand curve are caused by: Changes in the price level Shifts in the aggregate demand curve are caused by: Changes in consumer spending, arising from · a change in wealth · a change in expectations about future income and prices · a change in interest rates (due to monetary policy) · a change in personal income taxes (due to fiscal policy) · a change in the level of household indebtedness · a change in the attitude towards spending Changes in investment spending, arising from · a change in expectations about future sales · a change (improvement) in technology · a change in interest rates (due to monetary policy) · a change in business taxes (due to fiscal policy) · legal/institutional changes Changes in government spending, arising from · a change in political priorities · deliberate efforts to influence aggregate demand (due to fiscal policy) Changes in foreigners’ spending, arising from · a change in real national income abroad · a change in exchange rates changes in wealth which cause shifts in the aggregate demand curve. The first case refers to a change in the real value of wealth that has resulted from a change in the price level. The second case refers to changes in real wealth that have come about in the absence of a change in the price level. The same must be said about the difference between the interest rate effect that results from a change in the price level (and produces movements along the demand curve), and changes in interest rates that occur in the absence of a change in the price level.) 230 Part 3: Macroeconomics Test your understanding 8.2 1 (a) Define aggregate demand and explain its components. (b) Show aggregate demand diagrammatically, and define the relationship it represents. (c) What causes a movement along the aggregate demand curve? (d) What are the four components of spending that cause shifts of the aggregate demand curve? 2 Using appropriate diagrams, show the impact of each of the following on the aggregate demand curve; explain what happens to aggregate demand in each case; and identify the component of aggregate expenditure involved: (a) Consumers become optimistic about future conditions in the economy (the level of employment, the level of income, expected economic growth, etc.). (b) The government decides to increase taxes on firms’ profits. (c) Firms become fearful that a recession is about to begin. (d) The government decides to increase its spending on heath care services. (e) There is a decline in the real estate market (average house prices fall). (f) The central bank (a government organization) decides to increase interest rates. (g) Real incomes in countries that purchase a large share of country A’s exports fall; examine the impact on aggregate demand in country A. (h) The government lowers personal income taxes (taxes on income of households). (i) New legislation makes property rights more secure. (j) There is an appreciation (an increase) in the value of the euro relative to the US dollar; examine the impact on aggregate demand in eurozone countries (countries that have adopted the euro). (k) There is an appreciation (an increase) in the value of the euro relative to the US dollar; examine the impact on aggregate demand in the United States. (l) A non-governmental organization (NGO) introduces a progamme that provides credit to small farmers, thereby making it easier for small farmers to borrow in order to finance the building of irrigation projects and the purchase of new farm equipment. Aggregate supply and the short-run aggregate supply curve In order to build our AD-AS model, we must now make a distinction between the short run and the long run as it relates to macroeconomics, as these concepts differ from the corresponding distinction in microeconomics. time, perhaps a year or two or more · minimum wage legislation fixes the lowest legally permissible wage · workers and labour (trade) unions resist wage cuts · wage cuts have negative impacts on worker morale, causing firms to avoid them · ideas of fairness may dictate the level of wages. The short run and long run in macroeconomics The short run and long run in macroeconomics are defined as follows: The short run in macroeconomics is the period of time during which the nominal prices of resources, particularly the price of labour (wages), do not change in response to changes in the price level; we can think of resource prices as being constant. (See page 188 for an explanation of nominal.) The long run in macroeconomics is the period of time in which the nominal prices of all resources, including the price of labour (wages), change so as to reflect fully any change in the price level. Simplifying the difference between the two, we can say that in the short run wages are constant, whereas in the long run wages change in response to changes in the price level. Wages, or the price of labour resources, are of particular interest because they account for the largest portion of firms’ costs of production, and therefore strongly affect the quantity of output supplied by firms. In addition, wages are singled out because they do not change very much over relatively short periods of time. Whereas the prices of most resources other than labour usually change quickly in response to changes in demand and supply, the price of labour (wages) is often rigid (unchanging), for the following reasons: (a) The upward-sloping SRAS curve. · labour contracts fix wage rates for certain periods of Defining aggregate supply and the shortrun aggregate supply curve We begin by defining aggregate supply and the shortrun aggregate supply curve. Aggregate supply is the total quantity of goods and services produced in an economy at different price levels, ceteris paribus. The short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve shows the relationship between the price level and the quantity of real GDP produced by firms when resource prices (particularly wages) do not change. Figure 8.5(a) illustrates a short-run aggregate supply curve, indicating that there is a positive (or direct) relationship between the price level and real GDP supplied: a higher price level is associated with a greater quantity of real GDP, and a lower price level with a lower quantity of real GDP. The explanation for this relationship is based on firm profitability: when there is an increase in the price level, this means that output prices have increased; but with nominal 0 price level (b) Shifts in the SRAS curve. price level SRAS Note that the distinction between the short run and the long run in macroeconomics does not affect aggregate demand. It is, however, crucial to our understanding of aggregate supply, to which we turn next. 0 real GDP SRAS3 SRAS 1 SRAS 2 real GDP Figure 8.5 The short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve in the neoclassical perspective. Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 231 resource prices and particularly the price of labour constant since the economy is in the short run, it follows that firms’ profits increase. As production becomes more profitable, firms increase the quantity of output they produce. There is therefore a positive relationship between the price level and the quantity of real GDP supplied. Similarly, a falling price level means falling output prices; with constant nominal wages, firm profitability falls, and output decreases. Once again we have the positive relationship between the price level and the quantity of real GDP supplied. Changes in short-run aggregate supply (shifts in the SRAS curve) A change in the price level, as we have seen, leads to a movement on the SRAS curve. A number of factors (other than the price level) can lead to shifts of the SRAS curve, illustrated in Figure 8.5(b). This distinction is analogous to what we learned in Chapter 2, page 42, in connection with the supply curve for a specific good. A rightward shift from SRAS1 to SRAS2 means that short-run aggregate supply increases: for any particular price level, firms produce a larger quantity of real GDP. A leftward shift from SRAS1 to SRAS3 means that aggregate supply decreases: for any particular price level, firms produce a smaller quantity of real GDP. Important factors that can cause SRAS curve shifts involve changes in firms’ costs of production and sudden events called ‘supply shocks’: · Changes in wages Wage changes can cause significant shifts in the SRAS curve, since wages constitute a major portion of firms’ costs of production. Wages can change for a number of reasons, such as, for example, changes in minimum wage legislation (explained in Chapter 2, page 55), or changes brought about by labour union bargaining with employers. If nominal wages increase, with the price level constant, firms’ costs of production rise, resulting in a leftward shift in the SRAS curve, such as from SRAS1 to SRAS3 in Figure 8.5(b). Such a shift means that for any particular price level, a smaller quantity of real output is produced and supplied. If wages decrease, with the price level constant, firms’ costs drop, 232 Part 3: Macroeconomics giving rise to a rightward shift in the SRAS curve, such as from SRAS1 to SRAS2. · Changes in non-labour resource prices Changes in the price of non-labour resources, such as the price of oil, equipment, capital goods, land inputs, or any other resource, impact upon the SRAS curve in the same way as changes in wages. An increase in the price of a key resource shifts the SRAS curve to the left; a decrease in the price shifts the SRAS curve to the right. · Changes in business taxes Business taxes are taxes on firms’ profits, and are treated by firms like costs of production. Therefore higher taxes on profits are equivalent to increases in production costs and so shift the SRAS curve to the left. Lower taxes on profits are equivalent to lower production costs and shift the SRAS curve to the right. · Changes in subsidies offered to businesses Subsidies have the opposite effect to taxes, as they involve money transferred from the government to firms. If they increase, the SRAS curve shifts to the right; if they decrease, the SRAS curve shifts to the left. · Supply shocks Supply shocks are events that have a sudden and strong impact on short-run aggregate supply. Some supply shocks directly affect aggregate supply. If they are adverse supply shocks, they cause a leftward shift of the SRAS curve. For example, a war or violent conflict can result in the destruction of physical capital and disruption of the economy, leading to lower output produced and a leftward shift in the SRAS curve. Unfavourable weather conditions can cause a fall in agricultural output, also shifting the SRAS curve to the left. Beneficial supply shocks such as a major oil discovery or unusually good weather conditions with a positive effect on agricultural output lead to an increase in aggregate supply and a rightward shift in the SRAS curve. Supply shocks sometimes work by producing sudden changes in firms’ costs of production. For example, a sudden increase in the price of a major input (such as oil) increases firms’ costs. Over short periods of time, the SRAS curve tends to shift to the left or to the right mainly as a result of factors that influence firms’ costs of production (such as changes in wages, changes in non-labour resource prices and changes in business taxes or subsidies), as well as supply shocks, which are sudden events impacting on short-run aggregate supply. Test your understanding 8.3 SRAS 2 (a) Distinguish between the short run and the long run in macroeconomics. (b) What are some of the factors that cause wages to be inflexible (not change very easily and rapidly)? price level 1 Define aggregate supply. Pl1 Ple Pl2 AD 3 (a) Show the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve in a diagram, and explain what relationship it represents. (b) What factors can cause a movement along the SRAS curve? (c) What factors cause shifts in the SRAS curve? 4 Using diagrams, show the impact of each of the following on the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve; explain what happens to SRAS in each case. (a) The price of oil (an important input in production) increases. (b) Below-zero temperatures during a large part of the growing season destroy agricultural output. (c) The government lowers taxes on firms’ profits. (d) The government eliminates subsidies on agricultural products. Macroeconomic equilibrium in the short run Short-run equilibrium level of prices and output We are now in a position to put the aggregate demand curve and the short-run aggregate supply curve together. This will determine short-run macroeconomic equilibrium. The equilibrium level of real GDP occurs where aggregate demand intersects aggregate supply. In the short run, it is given by the point of intersection of the aggregate demand curve and the short-run aggregate supply curve, and determines the price level, the level of real GDP and the level of employment that prevail when the economy is in short-run equilibrium. This is shown in Figure 8.6, where Ple is the equilibrium price level and Ye is the equilibrium level of real GDP. As we know from our earlier discussion, the level of real GDP is closely related to how much unemployment there is in the economy. As real GDP increases, firms hire more labour and unemployment falls; as real GDP decreases, firms need fewer labour 0 Ye real GDP Figure 8.6 Short-run macroeconomic equilibrium. resources, and unemployment rises. Therefore the equilibrium level of real GDP also determines how much unemployment there is in the economy. At any price level and real GDP other than Ple and Ye, the economy is in disequilibrium. At price level Pl1, there is excess quantity of real GDP being supplied, and this exerts a downward pressure on the price level, which falls until it reaches Ple. At a price level lower than Ple, such as Pl2, there is excess quantity of real GDP demanded, exerting an upward pressure on the price level, which will move upward until it settles at Ple. At Ple, the quantity of real GDP demanded is equal to the quantity of real GDP supplied, and the market is in equilibrium. Changes in short-run equilibrium The short-run equilibrium position of an economy changes whenever there is a change in aggregate demand or short-run aggregate supply. Suppose there occurs an increase in aggregate demand (a rightward shift in the aggregate demand curve). This may be due to any of the factors discussed earlier (such as an increase in national income abroad, or an increase in investment spending). The effect is shown in Figure 8.7(a) (page 234), where aggregate demand shifts from AD1 to AD2. An increase in aggregate demand gives rise to a rise in the price level, from Pl1 to Pl2, and a rise in real GDP, from Y1 to Y2. We know, too, that these changes also result in a fall in unemployment. In the event of a decrease in aggregate demand (due, for example, to pessimism among firms or a fall in net exports), the AD curve shifts from AD1 to AD3, with the result that the price level and real GDP fall from Pl1 to Pl3 and from Y1 to Y3, along with increase in unemployment. Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 233 (a) Changes in aggregate demand. (b) Changes in short-run aggregate supply. SRAS3 price level price level SRAS Pl2 Pl1 Pl3 AD2 AD3 0 SRAS1 Pl3 SRAS2 Pl1 Pl2 AD AD1 0 Y3 Y1 Y2 Y3 Y1 Y2 real GDP real GDP Figure 8.7 Changes in short-run macroeconomic equilibrium in the neoclassical perspective. economy, shown in Figure 8.8, all of which are defined in relation to the economy’s potential GDP. As you may remember from our discussion in Section 8.1, potential GDP is the economy’s full employment level of real GDP, where unemployment is equal to the natural rate of unemployment. Potential GDP appears as Yp in the three panels of Figure 8.8, where a vertical line drawn at Yp represents the level of real GDP at which there is ‘full employment’. The three kinds of short-run equilibrium are: · Panel (a): recessionary (deflationary) gap In panel (a), the intersection of the AD and SRAS curves determines a level of equilibrium real GDP, Ye, that lies to the left of potential GDP. When real GDP is less than potential GDP, the economy is experiencing a recessionary gap (also known as a deflationary gap), and unemployment is greater than the natural rate of employment. Why does Recessionary (deflationary) gaps, inflationary gaps and short-run full employment equilibrium We can identify three possible kinds of short-run macroeconomic equilibrium positions for the (a) The economy with a deflationary (recessionary) gap. (b) The economy with an inflationary gap. (c) The economy at the full employment level of output. price level price level SRAS Ple SRAS Ple AD 0 Ye Yp 0 Figure 8.8 Three short-run equilibrium states of the economy. Part 3: Macroeconomics SRAS Ple AD real GDP 234 price level Figure 8.7(b) shows shifts in the short-run aggregate supply curve. A rightward shift in the SRAS curve from SRAS1 to SRAS2 (for example, because of a technological improvement, or if the government decides to lower business taxes) will give rise to a lower price level, Pl2, a higher level of real GDP, Y2, and lower unemployment. On the other hand, a leftward shift in the SRAS curve, from SRAS1 to SRAS3 (say, because of an increase in business taxes or an increase in the price of a key resource) will produce an increase in the price level to Pl3, a fall in real output to Y3, and an increase in unemployment. Yp Ye real GDP AD 0 Yp real GDP this happen? Remember that aggregate demand consists of the demand for real GDP of consumers, firms, the government and foreigners (the four components). The recessionary gap has been created because at the price level (Ple) determined by the intersection of AD with SRAS, the quantity of real GDP that the four components of aggregate demand want to buy is less than the economy’s potential GDP. In other words, with aggregate demand represented by AD, there is not enough total demand in the economy to make it worthwhile for firms to produce potential GDP. With aggregate demand at AD, firms therefore produce a smaller quantity of real GDP than potential GDP. But this also means that they require less labour for their production, and so unemployment is greater than the natural rate of unemployment. · Panel (b): inflationary gap In panel (b), the intersection of the AD and SRAS curves determines a level of equilibrium real GDP, Ye, that lies to the right of potential GDP. When real GDP is larger than potential GDP, the economy is experiencing an inflationary gap, and unemployment is less than the natural rate of unemployment. An inflationary gap arises because with aggregate demand AD, the quantity of real GDP that the four components want to buy at the price level (Ple) determined by the intersection of AD with SRAS is greater than the economy’s potential output. There is too much total demand in the economy, and firms respond by producing a greater quantity of real GDP than potential GDP. To be able to produce more output, firms’ labour needs increase, and unemployment falls to become less than the natural rate of unemployment. · Panel (c): full employment level of real GDP In panel (c), the intersection of the AD and SRAS curve determines a level of equilibrium real GDP that is exactly equal to potential GDP. When the economy is producing its potential GDP, unemployment is equal to the natural rate of unemployment. The full employment level of real GDP is the level of real GDP at which there is no recessionary or inflationary gap. This occurs because at the price level (Ple) determined by the intersection of AD with SRAS, the quantity of real GDP demanded by the four components is exactly equal to the economy’s potential output. Recessionary (deflationary) and inflationary gaps represent short-run equilibrium positions of the economy. A recessionary (deflationary) gap is defined as a situation where real GDP is less than potential GDP (and unemployment is greater than the natural rate of unemployment) due to insufficient aggregate demand; it arises when the AD curve intersects the SRAS curve at a lower level of real GDP than the full employment level. An inflationary gap is defined as a situation where real GDP is greater than potential GDP (and unemployment is smaller than the natural rate of unemployment) due to excessive aggregate demand; it arises when the AD curve intersects the SRAS curve at a higher level of real GDP than the full employment level. When the economy is at its full employment equilibrium level of GDP, the AD curve intersects the SRAS curve at the level of potential (full employment) GDP, and there is no deflationary or inflationary gap. You can see from this discussion that the three shortrun equilibrium states of the economy correspond to the phases of the business cycle that we studied in Section 8.1: Ye of Figure 8.8(a) corresponds to a point such as e in Figure 8.2, where the economy is experiencing recession, unemployment is greater than the natural rate and actual GDP is less than potential GDP. Ye of Figure 8.8(b) corresponds to a point such as d in Figure 8.2, where unemployment is lower than the natural rate and actual GDP is greater than potential GDP. Finally, Yp of Figure 8.8(c) corresponds to points like a, b, and c where the economy is producing actual GDP equal to potential GDP, or full employment GDP, with unemployment at its natural rate. Therefore, recessionary and inflationary gaps are two types of output gaps. Shifts in AD or SRAS: possible causes of the business cycle It is now a simple matter to consider the possible causes of the business cycle studied in Section 8.1. Assume that an economy is in full employment equilibrium producing real GDP Yp in Figure 8.9(a) (page 236), and then experiences a fall in aggregate demand. Aggregate demand shifts leftward from AD1 to AD2, resulting in a recessionary gap, where real GDP, Yrec is less than potential GDP, the price level is lower Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 235 (a) Changes in aggregate demand. (b) Changes in aggregate supply. SRAS2 SRAS1 Pl3 Pl1 Pl2 AD3 AD1 AD2 0 Pl2 SRAS3 Pl1 Pl3 AD Yrec Yp Yinfl recessionary (deflationary) gap price level price level SRAS real GDP inflationary gap 0 recession with inflation ('stagflation') Y2 Yp Y3 real GDP desirable outcome: higher real GDP with lower price level Figure 8.9 Possible causes of the business cycle. at Pl2, and there is an increase in unemployment. If, on the other hand, the economy that initially is in long-run equilibrium experiences an increase in aggregate demand, the rightward shift in the AD curve from AD1 to AD3 will give rise to an inflationary gap, where real GDP, Yinfl is greater than potential GDP, the price level increases to Pl3 and unemployment falls. Shifts in the short-run aggregate supply curve can also contribute to economic fluctuations.4 In Figure 8.9(b), starting from long-run equilibrium once again, a fall in SRAS, shifting SRAS1 to SRAS2, will give rise to an economic contraction, with real GDP falling to Y2 and an increase in unemployment. Note, however, that this contraction differs from the recessionary gap that resulted from the fall in aggregate demand: the fall in aggregate supply gives rise to an increase in the price level, along with the decrease in real GDP. This special set of circumstances is especially undesirable for an economy, as it leads to the simultaneous appearance of two problems: economic contraction with unemployment, and a rising price level. This combination of events has been termed ‘stagflation’ (combining ‘stagnation’ with ‘inflation’) and will be further discussed in Chapter 9. An increase in short-run aggregate supply shifting SRAS1 to SRAS3 gives rise to an economic expansion It may be noted that changes in aggregate supply can cause contractions and expansions; however, these are not called deflationary (recessionary) or inflationary gaps. The reason is that deflationary and inflationary gaps are defined in terms of the level of actual aggregate demand relative to 4 236 Part 3: Macroeconomics as real GDP increases to Y3 and unemployment falls. Note that the expansion set into motion by the increase in short-run aggregate supply is accompanied by a falling price level (in contrast to the rising price level that resulted from an increase in aggregate demand). The rightward shift of the SRAS curve differs fundamentally from the other three shifts considered above, because it does not result in any undesirable effects for the economy. Instead, the economy is now experiencing two desirable developments: economic expansion and increasing employment, with a falling price level. Most economists believe that changes in aggregate demand are more important than changes in aggregate supply as causes of the business cycle. If the economy is initially in a position of full employment equilibrium, a decrease in aggregate demand causes recession while an increase in aggregate demand causes inflation. A decrease in aggregate supply causes both inflation and recession, while an increase in aggregate supply brings about two desirable outcomes: economic expansion accompanied by a falling price level. the aggregate demand that is required to bring about full employment equilibrium. A deflationary gap is therefore caused by insufficient aggregate demand, and an inflationary gap by too much aggregate demand. 1 Explain and use a diagram to show how shortrun equilibrium is determined in the AD-AS model. 2 For each of the events listed below, use an appropriate diagram to show the change in short-run equilibrium, and the impacts on the equilibrium price level, output (real GDP) and unemployment. (a) Firms are pessimistic about the future of the economy. (b) There is a fall in the price of oil, a major input in production. (c) There is a significant rise in stock market prices. (d) A war destroys a portion of an economy’s physical capital. 3 (a) Using the AD-AS model and diagrams, show the three short-run equilibrium states of the economy and illustrate a recessionary gap, an inflationary gap, and full employment equilibrium. (b) Explain how each of the three equilibrium states is related to the natural rate of unemployment. (c) How are the three equilibrium states related to the phases of the business (trade) cycle? 4 Assuming the economy is initially in a position of full employment equilibrium, explain how each of the events in question 2 can contribute to short-term economic fluctuations. 8.3 Macroeconomic controversies: the neoclassical perspective In this section we will study the theoretical perspective of neoclassical economists. Neoclassical economics builds on the work of the classical economists of the 19th century. Some of the key principles of this perspective include the importance of the price mechanism in coordinating economic activities; the concept of perfectly competitive market equilibrium; and the conceptualization of the economy as a harmonious system that automatically tends towards full employment. While economists generally accept these principles in the study of microeconomics, there is significant disagreement over their relevance to the study of economics at the macro level. The AD-AS model in the long run Defining the long-run aggregate supply curve and long-run macroeconomic equilibrium The neoclassical approach to the AD-AS model rests crucially on the distinction we made earlier between the macroeconomic short run and long run. This approach examines what happens to the relationship between real GDP and the price level when the economy moves into the long run. In the long run, as you may remember, all resource prices including wages change so as to match changes in the price level. This has some very important implications for the shape of the long-run aggregate supply curve: the long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve is vertical at potential GDP, or the full employment level of real GDP. A vertical LRAS curve indicates that in the long run a change in the price level does not give rise to any change in the quantity of real GDP produced. Moreover, the economy is in long-run equilibrium when the AD curve and the SRAS curve intersect at a point that is on the LRAS curve, as shown in Figure 8.10. Note that the economy’s long-run equilibrium position is the same as the short-run equilibrium position where the intersection of AD with SRAS occurs at the economy’s potential GDP, shown in Figure 8.8(c). Since the LRAS curve is vertical at potential GDP, it follows that deflationary (recessionary) and inflationary gaps, appearing in Figures 8.8 (a) and (b), can be represented diagrammatically in relation to the economy’s LRAS curve. Simply label the vertical line at Yp in Figures 8.8 (a) and (b) as LRAS, and you can illustrate a deflationary gap and an inflationary gap in relation to the LRAS curve. LRAS SRAS price level Test your understanding 8.4 AD 0 Yp real GDP Figure 8.10 Long-run equilibrium in the neoclassical perspective. Economics for the IB Diploma Figure 8.10 Mac/eps/Illustrator Col s/s Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply Text: Agenda emcdesign Studio: Peters & Zabransky 237 The long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve shows the relationship between real GDP produced and the price level when wages (and other resource prices) change to reflect fully any changes in the price level, ceteris paribus. The LRAS curve is vertical at the full employment level of GDP, or potential GDP, indicating that in the long run the economy produces potential GDP, which is independent of the price level. Why the LRAS curve is vertical There is a very simple explanation for the vertical shape of the LRAS curve. Since nominal wages (and other resource prices) are now changing to match fully any output price changes, firms’ costs of production remain constant even as the price level changes. Therefore, as the price level increases or decreases, with constant real costs, firms’ profits are also constant, and firms no longer have any incentive to increase or decrease their output levels. For example, say the price level increases by 5%. In the short run, with wages (and other input prices) constant, firms’ profits increase, and firms therefore increase the quantity of output produced by moving upward along an upward-sloping SRAS. But in the long run, wages (and other resource prices) also increase by 5%. In effect, nothing has changed from the firms’ point of view, and so they have no reason to increase the quantity of output they produce. Similarly, any price level decrease will be fully matched by the same percentage decrease in nominal wages (and other resource prices), so that firms have no incentive to decrease the quantity of output produced. Why the LRAS curve is situated at the level of potential GDP (or why inflationary and deflationary gaps cannot persist in the long run) In our discussion above, we saw that recessionary and inflationary gaps are two possible short-run equilibrium positions of the economy where the You may be wondering why wages will fall in the long run, thereby causing the shift in the SRAS curve that makes the economy move back to full employment equilibrium. The reason involves adjustments that take place in the labour market. As we know from our earlier discussion, if there is a recessionary gap, aggregate demand is weak and there is unemployment of labour that is greater than the natural rate of unemployment. This means that there is a surplus of labour in the labour market; in other words, the quantity of labour supplied is greater than 5 238 Part 3: Macroeconomics equilibrium level of real GDP differs from potential GDP. But if the LRAS curve is vertical at the level of potential GDP, it follows that recessionary and inflationary gaps are only short-run phenomena that cannot persist in the long run. As soon as the economy moves into the long run, the recessionary and inflationary gaps disappear, and the economy moves automatically towards full employment equilibrium. To see how this occurs, consider Figure 8.11(a), where an economy is initially in long-run equilibrium at point a on SRAS1 and AD1, and real GDP is equal to potential output, Yp. If there is a fall in aggregate demand from AD1 to AD2, the economy will move in the short run from point a to point b, where there arises a recessionary gap; at b, real GDP has fallen to Yrec and the price level has fallen from Pl1 to Pl2. But the economy cannot remain in that position in the long run. In the long run, the fall in the price level will be matched by a fall in wages (and falls in other resource prices), so that the SRAS curve will shift to the right from SRAS1 to SRAS2, until the economy is back on the LRAS curve, at point c. In other words, the assumption of wage and price flexibility in the long run has allowed the economy to automatically come back to its long-run equilibrium position. The recessionary gap was eliminated, and the only thing that changed in response to the fall in aggregate demand was the fall in the price level (from Pl1 to Pl3).5 The case where aggregate demand increases to create an inflationary gap in the short run is shown in Figure 8.11(b). Once again the economy begins from a position of long-run equilibrium at point a. The increase in aggregate demand is shown by the shift from AD1 to AD2; in the short run the economy moves to point b, where real GDP has increased to Yinfl, there is an inflationary gap, and the price level has increased from Pl1 to Pl2. But the economy cannot remain at point b in the long run, because once wages (and other resource prices) increase to match the increase in the price level, SRAS shifts from SRAS1 to SRAS2, and the economy arrives at point c, which is the quantity of labour demanded. This creates pressures on wages to fall, so as to bring about a balance between the quantity of labour demanded by firms and the quantity supplied by workers. Therefore wages fall in the long run, in order to eliminate the labour surplus, and when there is no longer any surplus labour, the economy reverts to long-run equilibrium through the shift in the SRAS curve. (a) Creating and eliminating a deflationary gap. Pl1 Pl2 a SRAS2 b c Pl3 LRAS SRAS1 AD1 price level price level LRAS (b) Creating and eliminating an inflationary gap. Pl3 Pl2 Pl1 c b a 0 Yrec Yp real GDP AD2 AD1 AD2 0 SRAS2 SRAS1 Yp Yinfl real GDP Figure 8.11 LRAS and long-run equilibrium. once again on the LRAS curve. In the long run, the inflationary gap is eliminated and the only thing that changed after the increase in aggregate demand was the increase in the price level (to Pl3).6 unchanged. Similarly in Figure 8.11(b), as aggregate demand increased from AD1 to AD2, the economy in the long run moved from point a to c, indicating a higher price level and unchanging real GDP. In the neoclassical perspective, recessionary (deflationary) and inflationary gaps are eliminated in the long run by flexibility in resource prices. This ensures that in the long run the LRAS curve will be vertical at the level of potential GDP. The economy has a built-in tendency towards full employment equilibrium. In the neoclassical perspective, changes in aggregate demand can influence real GDP only in the short run; in the long run, the only impact of a change in aggregate demand is to change the economy’s price level. Increases in aggregate demand in the long run are therefore inflationary (i.e. cause inflation). Test your understanding 8.5 Why in the long run aggregate demand influences only the price level, leaving real GDP unchanged Our discussion above on the elimination of deflationary and inflationary gaps illustrates another important principle of the neoclassical interpretation of the AD-AS model: changes in aggregate demand can have an influence on real GDP only in the short run; in the long run, they only result in increases in the price level, having no impact on real GDP, as this remains constant at the level of potential output and the LRAS curve. In Figure 8.11(a), when aggregate demand fell from AD1 to AD2, in the long run the economy moved from point a to point c, indicating a fall in the price level with real GDP remaining When there is an inflationary gap, unemployment falls below the natural rate, and there is a shortage in the labour market. Firms have a strong demand for labour (as well as other resources) and workers would like to negotiate higher wages because the price level has increased. In the long run, the wage is free to change in response to the forces of supply 6 1 (a) Define and use a diagram to show the longrun aggregate supply (LRAS) curve. (b) What can we say about the rate of unemployment in the economy that occurs at the level of real GDP determined by the position of the LRAS curve? (c) What does the vertical shape of the LRAS curve tell us about the relationship between the price level and real GDP in the long run? 2 Define and use a diagram to show long-run equilibrium in the AD-AS model (show the relationship between the LRAS, SRAS and AD curves). (...continued) and demand, and moves upward to the point where quantity of labour demanded is brought into balance with quantity of labour supplied. When this occurs, the economy reverts to long-run equilibrium through the shift in the SRAS curve. Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 239 Test your understanding 8.5 (...continued) 3 Draw two diagrams, illustrating recessionary and inflationary gaps in relation to the LRAS curve. 4 Can inflationary or deflationary gaps persist in the long run according to the neoclassical perspective? Explain why or why not. 5 Why do neoclassical economists argue that in the long run aggregate demand can only affect the price level? Use a diagram to illustrate your answer. Changes in long-run aggregate supply (shifts in the LRAS curve) Economic growth in the AD-AS model Real GDP in the long run is determined by the position of the LRAS curve, which in turn is determined by the economy’s potential output. Over a period of time, potential output can change: the LRAS curve shifts to the right or to the left in response to factors that increase or decrease potential output. Potential output is the total quantity of goods and services, or real GDP, that an economy can produce, given its factors of production (resources) and its technology, assuming that there is ‘full employment’ (remember that there is still some unemployment, which is the natural rate of unemployment). A rightward shift of the LRAS curve indicates an increase in potential output; a leftward shift indicates a decrease. This is simply another way of representing economic growth: as the LRAS shifts to the right, there is an increase in real GDP, representing positive economic growth; as it shifts to the left, there is a decrease in real GDP, representing negative growth. It is then a simple matter to see what factors can shift the LRAS curve, as they are similar factors that cause economic growth in the context of the production possibilities model. As we know from Chapter 7 (see Figure 7.3, page 194), an economy can achieve some growth by moving from one point inside its PPC to another point closer to its PPC, if it makes more efficient use of its resources and if it reduces unemployment. Over longer periods of time, the economy can continue to grow if there are increases in the quantities of resources, improvements in their quality and improvements in technology; all these are represented by outward shifts in the PPC. 240 Part 3: Macroeconomics By the same token, the LRAS shifts to the right when there are: · Increases in efficiency When an economy increases its efficiency in production, in effect it makes better use of its scarce resources, and can therefore produce a greater quantity of output (real GDP). Therefore potential output increases, and the LRAS curve shifts to the right. (Decreases in efficiency would shift the LRAS curve to the left.) · Reductions in the natural rate of unemployment The natural rate of unemployment is the unemployment that is ‘normal’ or ‘natural’ for an economy when it is producing its ‘full employment’ level of output. It includes unemployed people who are in between jobs, who are retraining in order to become more employable, and others. The natural rate of unemployment is not fixed or unchangeable. It differs from country to country and it can also change over time within the same country. If the natural rate of unemployment decreases, the economy is making better use of its resources, and can therefore produce a larger quantity of output (real GDP). Therefore potential output increases, and the LRAS curve shifts to the right. (An increase in the natural rate of unemployment would result in a leftward shift in the LRAS curve.) But an economy’s ability to continue to increase its potential output and shift its LRAS curve to the right through increases in efficiency and reductions in natural unemployment will at some point be exhausted. The economy can continue to grow only if there are increases in its production possibilities, resulting from: · Increases in the quantities of the factors of production If one or more factor of production increases, the LRAS curve shifts to the right. This is because an increase in the quantity of a factor of production, such as an increase in the quantity of physical capital, or the quantity of labour, or the quantity of land (such as when there is a discovery of new oil reserves) means that the economy is now capable of producing a larger quantity of real GDP. (If the quantity of factors of production decreases, the LRAS curve shifts to the left.) · Improvements in the quality of factors of production (resources) Improvements in resource quality will shift the LRAS curve to the right. For example, greater levels of education, skills or health constitute an improvement in the quality of labour resources. More highly skilled and educated workers or healthier workers can produce more output than the same number of unskilled or less healthy workers. · Improvements in technology An improved technology of production means that the factors of production using it can produce more output, and the LRAS curve shifts to the right. For example, workers who work with improved machines and equipment that have been produced as a result of technological innovations will produce more output in the same amount of time. Rightward shifts in the LRAS curve illustrate an increase in potential output and economic growth. They result from similar factors that cause economic growth in the production possibilities model. The LRAS curve can shift to the right as a result of increases in efficiencies and reductions in the natural rate of unemployment. Over extended periods of time, rightward shifts in the LRAS curve depend on increases in the economy’s production possibilities, which may arise from increases in quantities of factors of production, improvements in quality of factors of production and technological improvements. The relationship between the SRAS and LRAS curves If an economy is experiencing economic growth, its LRAS curve will be shifting rightward, indicating increases in potential output. But its SRAS curve will be shifting rightward as well because, at any given moment in time, an economy is always producing on an SRAS curve. This is shown in Figure 8.12. Therefore any factor that shifts the LRAS curve must also shift the SRAS curve. LRAS1 LRAS2 SRAS2 SRAS3 price level SRAS1 LRAS3 Are there any factors that can shift the SRAS curve without shifting the LRAS curve? There are certain events that have only a temporary impact on aggregate supply, and these can shift the SRAS curve for a short while, while leaving the LRAS curve unchanged. Consider, for example, adverse weather conditions during one season that cause a drop in agricultural output. The SRAS curve will shift to the left for that season, but will then revert back to the original position when the weather changes back to normal patterns, while the LRAS curve remains unaffected. Changes in firms’ costs of production, such as changes in wages, or changes in the prices of other key inputs (such as oil), may similarly affect only the SRAS curve. This applies to temporary changes that do not have a lasting impact on real GDP produced. Test your understanding 8.6 1 Illustrate diagrammatically the impacts on an economy’s LRAS curve of the following: (a) There is a widespread introduction of a new technology that increases labour productivity. (b) The government provides training programmes for workers to retrain and improve their skills. (c) A developing country receives large amounts of foreign aid, which allows it to purchase a large quantity of capital goods. (d) An extensive nationwide public health campaign undertaken by the government improves levels of health of the population. (e) The government introduces anti-monopoly legislation, reducing the monopoly power of firms and increasing the economy’s productive efficiency. 2 (a) Using an appropriate diagram and the concept of potential output, explain the relationship between the LRAS curve and economic growth. (b) Can you think of some factors that can affect the SRAS curve but not the LRAS curve? 0 Y1 Y2 real GDP Y3 Figure 8.12 Illustrating growth in potential output: shifts in the LRAS and SRAS curves. 8.4 Macroeconomic controversies: the Keynesian perspective In this section we turn to the theoretical perspective of Keynesian economists. Keynesian economists base their ideas on the work of John Maynard Keynes, one of the most famous economists of the 20th century, Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 241 (a) The implications of downwardly inflexible wages and prices. Pl1 d Pl2 Pl3 SRAS1 SRAS2 a b AD1 c Keynesian AS price level price level LRAS (b) The Keynesian AS curve. AD2 AD2 0 Yp real GDP a d 0 AD1 Yp real GDP Figure 8.13 Keynesian analysis. whose work in the first half of that century came to form the basis of modern macroeconomics. Keynes questioned the classical economists’ view of the economic system as a harmonious system that automatically tends towards full employment (on which the neoclassical perspective is based), and instead showed that it is possible for economies to remain in a position of short-run equilibrium for long periods of time. Getting stuck in the short run Wage and price downward inflexibility The long-run aggregate supply curve in the neoclassical perspective depends on the principle that all resource prices and product prices are fully flexible and respond to the forces of supply and demand. But what if resource prices are not free to move in the downward direction even over long periods of time? Keynesian economists argue that there is an asymmetry between wage movements in the upward and downward directions. They note that under conditions of an economic expansion and strong aggregate demand (rightward shifts in the AD curve causing an inflationary gap), with unemployment lower than the natural rate and a rising price level, wages quickly begin to move upward. Yet in a recessionary gap, where aggregate demand is weak and the economy is in recession with unemployment greater than the natural rate, wages do not fall easily, even over long periods of time, because of a variety of factors that we noted earlier (such as labour contracts, which fix wage rates for certain periods of time; minimum wage legislation; worker and union resistance to wage cuts; and so on). Moreover, Keynesian economists argue that not only wages, but also product prices are inflexible in 242 Part 3: Macroeconomics the downward direction, even if an economy is in a recessionary gap. In the event of a recessionary gap, the neoclassical perspective predicts that the price level will fall. Keynesian economists argue that this is unlikely to happen. The line of reasoning is the following: in a recession, if wages won’t go down, firms will resist lowering their prices because that would reduce their profits. Further, large oligopolistic firms may fear price wars; if one firm lowers its price then others may lower theirs more aggressively in an effort to capture market shares, and then all the firms will be worse off. Such factors, it is argued, make prices unlikely to fall even in a recession. According to the Keynesian perspective, both wages and prices are unlikely to fall even if the economy is in a recessionary gap, and even if the recessionary gap persists over long periods of time. The inability of the economy to move into the long run If wages and prices do not fall easily even over long periods of time, this in effect means that the economy may get stuck in the short run, and cannot move into the long run. Let’s see how this happens. Consider Figure 8.13(a), which is similar to Figure 8.11(a). The economy is initially at point a, producing potential output Yp. There occurs then a decrease in aggregate demand, so the AD curve shifts from AD1 to AD2. The neoclassical model predicts that the economy will move to point b in the short run, where there is a recessionary gap and the price level falls from Pl1 to Pl2; in the long run it will move to point c, where there is an even lower price level, Pl3, and the economy is once again producing potential output Yp. The fall in the price level and in wages caused the recessionary gap to disappear. This argument suggests that the SRAS curve has the shape shown in Figure 8.13(b). The horizontal part of the curve is based on the Keynesian perspective of downward inflexibility of wages and prices. Point d in Figure 8.13(a) corresponds to point d in Figure 8.13(b). At this point, the economy is in a recessionary gap, and may stay there indefinitely as it is unlikely to move out of the recession unless the government intervenes with specific policies. In the Keynesian perspective, inflexible wages and prices mean that the economy cannot move into the long run. Inflexible wages and prices are shown graphically by a horizontal segment of the Keynesian aggregate supply (AS) curve. Keynesians would not suggest that wages and prices can never fall. They would agree that if a recession or depression (which is a very severe recession) continues for a long enough period of time (perhaps years) wages and prices would eventually begin to fall. But in the Keynesian view, the period of waiting for this to happen would be far too long. In the meantime a long-lasting recession would be very costly in terms of unemployment, low incomes and lost output. Therefore it would be necessary for the government to intervene with active policies to help the economy come out of the recession. The shape of the Keynesian aggregate supply curve As we can see in Figure 8.14, the Keynesian aggregate supply curve has three segments. In segment I, real GDP is low, and the price level remains constant as real GDP increases. In this range of real GDP, there is a lot of unemployment of resources. This means that if firms want to increase their output they can easily do so by employing the unemployed labour and other unemployed resources, without having to bid up wages and other resource prices. In segment II, as real GDP continues to increase, the AS curve begins to rise, so that real GDP increases are accompanied by increases in the price level. The reason is that as output increases, so does employment of resources, and eventually bottlenecks in resource supplies begin to appear. Firms are forced to use less and less efficient resources, which means that even though wages are held constant (since the economy is in the short run), the cost of production per unit of output increases. The only way that firms will then be induced to increase their output is if they can sell it at higher prices. Therefore growing output gives rise to an increasing price level. At output level Yp, the economy has reached its full employment level of real GDP. This is also its potential output level, and unemployment has fallen to the point where it is now equal to the natural rate of unemployment. However, as we know, the natural rate of unemployment is not maximum employment. It is possible for unemployment to fall further, which is what happens when real GDP continues to increase beyond Yp. Real GDP can continue to increase until it reaches segment III. In segment III, the AS curve becomes vertical at Ymax, indicating that real GDP reaches a level beyond which it cannot increase any more; at this point, the price level rises very rapidly. Why can real GDP no longer increase? The reason is that firms are now using the maximum amount of labour and all other resources that are available in the economy. Since it is not possible for real GDP to increase any more, any efforts on the part of firms to continue to increase their output will only give rise to greater increases in the price level, as shown by the vertical part of the AS curve at Ymax. Keynesian AS segment III price level Now what if the price level and wages do not fall following the decrease in aggregate demand? If the price level cannot fall from Pl1, where it was initially, the economy will move to point d on the new, lower, aggregate demand curve, AD2. Even if the price level succeeds in falling to Pl2, so the economy moves to point b, the economy may get stuck there if wages do not fall (remember that wages must fall in order for the SRAS curve to shift to SRAS2 on the LRAS curve). It follows that if the price level cannot fall, or if wages cannot fall, the economy will be unable to eliminate the recessionary gap. It will be stuck in the short run, and will be unable to move into the long run. segment II segment I 0 Yp Ymax real GDP Figure 8.14 The Keynesian aggregate supply curve. Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 243 The three short-run equilibrium states of the economy in the Keynesian perspective Some key features of the Keynesian perspective Macroeconomic equilibrium in the Keynesian perspective is determined by the point of intersection of the aggregate demand curve and the Keynesian aggregate supply curve. There are three shortrun equilibrium states of the economy, shown in Figure 8.15. Recessionary gaps can persist over long periods of time One of the most important principles arising from the Keynesian interpretation of the AD-AS model is that recessionary gaps can persist over long periods of time. According to Keynes, this happens partly because of the inability of wages and prices to fall so as to bring the economy to its full employment level of output (potential GDP). In addition, and very importantly, the problem is caused by insufficient aggregate demand. Whenever aggregate demand intersects the horizontal segment of the Keynesian AS curve, the economy is in a recessionary gap, because aggregate demand is too low, and the four components of aggregate demand are unable to buy enough output to make it worthwhile for firms to produce real GDP equal to full employment or potential GDP. Therefore the level of equilibrium GDP is lower than potential GDP. Figure 8.15(a) shows the AD curve intersecting the Keynesian AS curve in its horizontal segment, determining Ye, which is less than Yp (potential GDP), indicating that there is a recessionary (deflationary) gap with unemployment greater than the natural rate. In panel (b), the economy is producing at Ye, which is greater than potential output Yp, and is experiencing an inflationary gap. There is strong aggregate demand, unemployment has fallen below its natural rate, and as the economy approaches its maximum capacity, the price level has increased. Panel (c) shows the case where the economy has achieved full employment equilibrium, or potential output, at Yp. These three short-run equilibrium states of the economy can be related to the business cycle we studied in Section 8.1: Ye in Figure 8.15(a) corresponds to a point such as e in Figure 8.2, where there is a recessionary gap; Ye of Figure 8.15(b) corresponds to a point such as d in Figure 8.2, where there is an inflationary gap; and Yp of Figure 8.15(c) corresponds to points like a, b and c in Figure 8.2, where the economy’s actual output is equal to its potential output, or full employment output. (b) Inflationary gap. Keynesian AS price level price level Keynesian AS (c) Full employment equilibrium. Keynesian AS price level (a) Recessionary gap. In Figure 8.15(a), the equilibrium level of real GDP settles at Ye, determined by the intersection of the AD and the AS curves. What differentiates the Keynesian analysis is that, unlike in the neoclassical perspective where the recessionary gap will disappear once the economy moves into the long run, the economy here cannot move into the long run, and will therefore remain at an equilibrium like Ye indefinitely. This has very important implications for economic policy. It means that the government must intervene in the economy with specific measures to help it come out of the recessionary gap. AD AD AD 0 Ye real GDP Yp 0 Yp Ye real GDP Figure 8.15 The three equilibrium states of the economy in the Keynesian perspective. 244 Part 3: Macroeconomics 0 Yp real GDP (a) The neoclassical perspective (b) The Keynesian perspective. Keynesian AS Pl1 Pl2 price level price level LRAS AD3 Pl3 AD2 AD1 0 Yp AD2 AD1 0 real GDP Y1 Y2 AD3 real GDP Y3 Figure 8.16 Impacts of increases in aggregate demand on real GDP and the price level. In the Keynesian perspective, an economy can remain for long periods of time in an equilibrium position where there is less than full employment (i.e. a recessionary or deflationary gap), which is caused by insufficient aggregate demand. Increases in aggregate demand need not cause increases in the price level Another important principle arising from the Keynesian interpretation of the AD-AS model is that increases in aggregate demand need not always cause increases in the price level. In the neoclassical perspective, increases in aggregate demand will always give rise to increases in the price level. In the short run, as AD shifts to the right causing a movement along an upward-sloping SRAS curve, there will result some increase in real GDP as well as an increase in the price level (see Figure 8.7(a)). In the long run, you may remember, increases in aggregate demand give rise only to increases in the price level, while leaving real GDP unaffected. This is shown in Figure 8.16(a). In the Keynesian perspective, by contrast, when the economy is in the horizontal range of the AS curve, increases in aggregate demand lead to increases in real GDP without affecting the price level. This is shown in Figure 8.16(b). It is only when the Keynesian AS curve begins to slope upward that further increases in aggregate demand begin to result in changes in the price level as well. Illustrating economic growth in the Keynesian perspective While Keynesian analysis is a short-run analysis, this certainly does not mean that the model cannot explain economic growth over long periods of time. Economic growth, involving increases in the full employment level of real GDP, or potential GDP, can be illustrated by rightward shifts in the Keynesian AS curve and the AD curve, as shown in Figure 8.17. Any factor causing shifts in the neoclassical LRAS curve will also cause shifts in the Keynesian AS curve. As the AS curve shifts to the right from AS1 to AS2, potential output increases from Y1 to Y2. Figure 8.17 shows AD shifting along with the AS curve, so the economy in this case continues to be in a position of full employment equilibrium as it grows (though it is not necessary that the AD curve will always increase along with the AS curve). Keynesian AS1 Keynesian AS2 price level It follows that Keynesian analysis is essentially a shortrun analysis. There is no such thing as a Keynesian long-run aggregate supply curve. This does not mean that Keynesian economists do not consider what happens over long periods of time; it means only that they do not accept the idea that the economy can move into what neoclassical economists define as the long run (where there is full resource and product price flexibility). It follows then that in the Keynesian perspective the economy does not automatically tend towards full employment equilibrium. AD2 AD1 0 Y1 Y2 real GDP Figure 8.17 Economic growth in the Keynesian perspective. Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 245 Test your understanding 8.7 (a) Neoclassical AD-AS model. LRAS aggregate supply curve if wages and prices are inflexible in the downward direction. Can the economy move into the long run? 2 (a) Use a diagram to show the Keynesian AS 0 the Keynesian perspective? 8.5 Some final observations Illustrating the neoclassical and Keynesian perspectives Figure 8.18 shows how some key concepts we have considered in this chapter relate to each other in the neoclassical and Keynesian theoretical perspectives. Point a in both panels determines full employment equilibrium output, or potential GDP. Note that the LRAS curve in panel (a) is not the same as the vertical segment of the Keynesian AS curve, as the latter vertical segment represents the maximum possible output that the economy can produce if it uses all its resources. 246 Part 3: Macroeconomics AD3 AD2 AD1 potential GDP = full employment GDP real GDP Keynesian AS economic growth c b deflationary gap 4 Using diagrams illustrating the Keynesian 6 How would you illustrate economic growth in b price level show the three short-run equilibrium states of the economy, noting recessionary and inflationary gaps and their relationship to the full employment equilibrium position of the economy (potential output). position where there is less than full employment for long periods of time in the Keynesian perspective? inflationary gap a (b) Keynesian AD-AS model. 3 Using the Keynesian perspective and diagrams, 5 Why can an economy remain in an equilibrium SRAS c deflationary gap curve. (b) What does the flat segment of this curve indicate about the relationship between the price level and real GDP? (c) What does the upward-sloping segment indicate about this relationship? (d) What does the vertical segment indicate about this relationship? perspective, show and explain what happens to the equilibrium level of real GDP and the price level if aggregate demand shifts (a) within the horizontal segment of the Keynesian AS curve; (b) within the upward-sloping segment of the Keynesian AS curve; (c) within the vertical segment of the Keynesian AS curve. economic growth price level 1 Explain what it means for the shape of the 0 a AD2 inflationary gap AD1 AD3 potential GDP = full employment GDP real GDP Figure 8.18 Illustrating the neoclassical and Keynesian AD-AS models. v Point b in both panels represents a recessionary (deflationary) gap, which occurs due to low aggregate demand, given by AD2 in panels (a) and (b). Point c in both panels represents an inflationary gap, which arises due to strong aggregate demand, given by AD3. Finally, economic growth is illustrated in both panels by the rightward pointing arrows. In panel (a) it is represented by a rightward shift of the LRAS curve; in panel (b) by a rightward shift of the Keynesian AS curve. Policy implications of the neoclassical and Keynesian perspectives The business cycle and government policy in the neoclassical perspective In the neoclassical perspective, the economy is conceived of as a stable system that tends towards long-run equilibrium where there is full employment, at the natural rate of unemployment. The system has a built-in tendency to revert to long-run equilibrium by itself. This argument has important implications for the short-run fluctuations of the business cycle and long-term economic growth. Since short-term fluctuations (recessionary and inflationary gaps) are seen to correct themselves automatically, it follows that there is no need for the government to do anything to correct them. What the government must do is ensure that markets work as competitively as possible, so that all resource and product prices will be able to rise or fall as required in order to allow the economy to settle at its point of long-run equilibrium, which occurs at the level of potential GDP. In fact, continues the argument, if governments do intervene with policies intended to correct short-run fluctuations of real GDP, they may well achieve the opposite of the intended results. Rather than reduce the size of fluctuations, they may actually make them bigger. Many neoclassical economists believe that the deviations of real GDP from potential GDP that we observe in real-world business cycles of many countries are as large as they are because governments in the real world do intervene with policies intended to reduce the fluctuations of the business cycle. When it comes to promoting economic growth, aggregate demand cannot affect real GDP in the long run. If aggregate demand increases, in the long run it will only give rise to increasing price levels and inflation. Governments should therefore concentrate on policies that affect the supply side of the economy, or policies that attempt to shift the LRAS curve to the right, thereby aiming to achieve increases in real GDP without causing inflation. Summarizing: In the neoclassical perspective, if the government pursues policies to influence aggregate demand, in the short run these may intensify the business cycle (i.e. make inflationary and deflationary gaps larger); in the long run they will only result in changes in the price level. What governments should do, therefore, is (i) encourage competition so that resource and output prices will respond to the forces of supply and demand, which will allow the economy to automatically correct short-run inflationary and recessionary gaps; and (ii) adopt policies that influence the supply side of the economy, which shift the LRAS curve to the right, thereby achieving longrun economic growth. The business cycle and government policy in the Keynesian perspective In the Keynesian perspective, the economy is viewed as an unstable system because of recurrent shortterm fluctuations that do not have the ability to automatically correct themselves. Such fluctuations are seen as arising mainly due to changes in aggregate demand, or shifts in the AD curve, caused by spontaneous actions of firms and consumers. Keynes himself considered fluctuations of the business cycle to be caused mainly by changes in investment spending, due to variations in firms’ expectations about the future. Optimism about the future increases investment spending, causing a rightward shift in aggregate demand; pessimism about the future decreases investment spending, leading to a leftward shift. Keynes referred to alternating waves of optimism and pessimism as ‘animal spirits’. In the Keynesian view, when there is a recessionary gap, there are many factors preventing the operation of market forces, and so wages and product prices do not fall even over extended periods of time. This means the economy can remain in an equilibrium position with less than full employment (in recessionary gaps) for long periods. Therefore there is an important role for government policy to play in order to restore full employment and raise real GDP to its potential GDP level. Government policy should focus on the demand side of the economy, specifically on policies that increase aggregate demand when there is a recessionary gap, and decrease aggregate demand when there is an inflationary gap; such policies are essential if the economy is to achieve full employment and price stability. Policies to influence aggregate demand are particularly important when aggregate demand is low. Summarizing: In the Keynesian perspective, government policies to influence aggregate demand are imperative in order to deal with the short-term fluctuations of the business cycle. Particularly when the economy is in a less than full employment equilibrium (recessionary or deflationary gap), government must intervene with policies that will increase aggregate demand, as otherwise the economy will remain stuck at low levels of real GDP and high unemployment over long periods of time. Efforts should be made to shift the AD curve to the right, until it intersects the Keynesian AS curve at full employment real GDP. It is only in the upward-sloping and vertical portions of the Keynesian AS curve that further increases in aggregate demand become inflationary. The mainstream economic perspective Our discussion of the two different perspectives has focused on the disagreement over whether Chapter 8: Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 247 the economy can move into the long run, the shape of aggregate supply curves, and their policy implications. In fact, there are disagreements among economists that extend beyond just these points. We will come back to some additional aspects of the debate in Chapters 9 and 10. Most economists today are unlikely to be purely ‘neoclassical’ or purely ‘Keynesian’ in their view of the economy. While they are likely to side more with one or the other of the two perspectives, many would argue that elements of both perspectives have some merit, and that policies attempting to influence both aggregate demand and aggregate supply are important in achieving the goals of reducing short-term fluctuations while promoting economic growth. These points will become clearer in Questions for 8.1 8.2 8.3 the next chapter, where we will examine a variety of demand-side and supply-side policies. Test your understanding 8.8 Explain why (a) use of the LRAS curve to account for economic growth leads to the policy implication that governments should focus on policies that try to influence the supply side of the economy; (b) use of the Keynesian threesegment aggregate supply curve leads to the policy implication that governments should focus on the policies that try to influence the demand side of the economy. review [10 marks] Use a business (trade) cycle diagram to illustrate the following: (a) the phases of the cycle; (b) potential GDP, or full employment GDP; (c) recessionary (deflationary) and inflationary gaps; (d) the level of output at which unemployment is at the natural rate of unemployment. [10 marks] (a) Define aggregate demand, and identify and explain each of its components; (b) Identify some factors that cause changes in each of the components, causing shifts in the AD curve. Keynesian) affect your answers to question 8.3 (a), (f), (g), (i)? 8.5 [15 marks] Using diagrams and the concepts of inflationary and recessionary (deflationary) gaps, show if and how it is possible for the equilibrium level of real GDP to differ from the full employment level of real GDP: (a) in the neoclassical short run; (b) in the long run; (c) in the Keynesian version of the AD-AS model. 8.6 [10 marks] Using diagrams and the AD-AS model, explain how each of the following will impact on the SRAS or LRAS curve of an economy: [3 marks for each part] Using diagrams and the neoclassical AD-AS model, explain the impact each of the following would have on Country A’s shortrun equilibrium price level, real GDP, and level of unemployment: (a) a long-lasting improvement in the technology of production (b) reduction of bureaucratic procedures that increase productive efficiency (c) major educational and retraining programmes for workers (a) consumer and business pessimism about the future of the economy (d) widespread drought, affecting agricultural production (b) a war that restricts supplies of key inputs (c) a drop in interest rates (e) a new discovery of oil reserves (d) a significant rise in stock market values (f) a war that destroys a significant portion of the country’s productive capacity. (e) an increase in wages due to trade union activities (with the price level constant) (f) an increase in personal income taxes 8.7 [10 marks] Use the concepts of AD, SRAS and LRAS to distinguish between short-term economic fluctuations (the business cycle) and economic growth. 8.8 [15 marks] Assume that the economy is in a recessionary (deflationary) gap and there is unemployment of labour. In the absence of government intervention, explain what will happen: (a) in the view of a neoclassical economist; (b) in the view of a Keynesian economist. (g) an increase in defence spending by the government (h) a fall in the price of oil (a major resource) (i) an increase in real GDP in countries that are major trading partners of Country A (j) an increase in the value of Country A’s currency (currency appreciation). 8.4 248 [10 marks] How does the shape of the aggregate supply curve (whether it is neoclassical or Part 3: Macroeconomics Chapter 9 Macroeconomics Demand-side and supply-side policies In this chapter we will use the aggregate demand and aggregate supply (AD-AS) model as the basis for analysing and evaluating a variety of policy alternatives that can be used by governments to achieve the macroeconomic objectives of price stability, full employment and economic growth. OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: · · · · · · · · · · · · · · explain the objectives of demand-side policies distinguish between fiscal and monetary policies analyse the impacts of contractionary and expansionary fiscal and monetary policies on real GDP, the price level and the level of unemployment explain the impacts of demand-side policies on economic growth evaluate (identify strengths and weaknesses of) fiscal and monetary policies explain the objectives of supply-side policies distinguish between market-oriented and interventionist supply-side policies identify a variety of market-oriented supply-side policies analyse the impacts of market-oriented supply-side policies on real GDP and economic growth, the price level and unemployment evaluate (identify strengths and weaknesses of) market-oriented supply-side policies explain supply-side effects of demand-side policies, and demand-side effects of supply-side policies define and calculate the multiplier, and explain its impacts on aggregate demand and real GDP (higher level topic) explain the accelerator theory and multiplier–accelerator interactions (higher level topic) define and explain the crowding-out effect and its impacts on aggregate demand and real GDP (higher level topic). 9.1 Demand-side policies: shifts in the aggregate demand curve Objectives of demand-side policies Demand-side policies focus on changing aggregate demand, or shifting the aggregate demand curve in the AD-AS model, in order to achieve the goals of price stability, full employment and economic growth. They are based on the idea that short-term fluctuations in real GDP of the business cycle are due to actions of firms and consumers that affect aggregate demand and cause inflationary or recessionary (deflationary) gaps (see Figures 8.8 and 8.15 in Chapter 8, pages 234 and 244). Demand-side policies try to counteract the effects of these actions and bring aggregate Chapter 9: Demand-side and supply-side policies 249 demand to the full employment level of real GDP, or potential GDP. In addition, demand-side policies can also impact on economic growth by contributing to increases in potential GDP. Active and purposeful government intervention in the economy in order to pursue macroeconomic objectives is termed discretionary policy, meaning that the policy is at the discretion (or the choice and will) of the government authorities. There are two types of discretionary demand-side policies: · fiscal policy · monetary policy. When discretionary fiscal and monetary policies attempt to reduce the short-run fluctuations of the business cycle, they can be called stabilization policies, because they try to ‘stabilize’ the economy, or eliminate short-run instabilities caused by sharp increases and decreases of aggregate demand. If stabilization policies worked as intended (which they do only in part, as we will see), the business cycle would be flattened out, and the economy’s actual output would be very close to its potential output (see Figure 8.3(a) in Chapter 8, page 225). In practice, the most that stabilization can hope to achieve is to lessen the severities of the business cycle. Fiscal policy Background to government finance Governments have expenditures, involving spending in many areas such as education, health care, provision of public goods, etc., which they finance through tax revenues. If tax revenues are equal to government expenditures over a specified period of time (usually a year), the government is said to have a balanced budget. However, in practice, the government’s budget is rarely if ever balanced, as expenditures are usually larger or smaller than revenues. Governments are therefore likely to have a budget deficit, in which case expenditures are larger than tax revenues, or a budget surplus, where expenditures are smaller than tax revenues. In the event that a government has a budget deficit, it finances (pays for) the excess of expenditures over revenues by borrowing. This is much as in the case of personal finance: if you spend more than you earn, it is likely that you finance your extra spending over your income by borrowing. 250 Part 3: Macroeconomics Over time, the government’s accumulation of deficits minus surpluses is referred to as public debt, or ‘government debt’. In any given year, if the government runs a budget deficit, its debt will become larger; if it runs a budget surplus its debt will become smaller. Fiscal policy refers to manipulations by the government of its own expenditures and taxes in order to influence the level of aggregate demand. You may remember from Chapter 8, page 226, that the components of aggregate demand are consumption (C), investment (I), government spending (G), and net exports (X − M). Fiscal policy can affect three of these four components (see Table 8.1): · the level of government spending, G, can be changed as the government alters the level of its own expenditures · the level of consumption spending, C, can be influenced if the government changes taxes levied on consumers (personal income taxes), thereby altering their level of disposable income, which is the income of consumers after income taxes have been paid · the level of investment spending, I, can also be influenced as the government changes taxes levied on business profits. Expansionary fiscal policy Suppose the economy is experiencing a recessionary gap caused by insufficient aggregate demand. This is shown in Figures 9.1 (a) and (b), where the aggregate demand curve AD1 intersects both the SRAS curve and the Keynesian AS curve at a level of real GDP, Ye, that is below the full employment (potential output) level, Yp. Panel (a) is based on the neoclassical version of the AD-AS model, while panel (b) is based on the Keynesian version. (The impacts of fiscal policy can be illustrated equally well by both.) The government’s objective is to try to increase AD, shifting it from AD1 to AD2, where the economy will achieve full employment output, or potential GDP, Yp, thereby eliminating the recessionary gap. Fiscal policy undertaken to eliminate a recessionary gap is called expansionary policy, because it works to expand aggregate demand and the level of economic activity. Expansionary fiscal policy may consist of: · · · · increasing government spending decreasing personal income taxes decreasing business taxes, or a combination of increasing spending and decreasing taxes. (a) Eliminating a deflationary gap (neoclassical AD-AS model). (b) Eliminating a deflationary gap (Keynesian AD-AS model). Keynesian AS SRAS Pl2 Pl1 price level price level LRAS AD2 Pl2 Pl1 AD1 0 Ye Yp AD2 AD1 0 real GDP Ye potential output Yp real GDP potential output Figure 9.1 Impacts of expansionary policy. If the government increases its spending, there will be a direct impact on aggregate demand, which will increase. If the government decreases taxes, aggregate demand is affected in a two-step process. In the case of personal income taxes, a tax cut first leads to a rise in disposable income, which is then likely to result in an increase in consumption spending, thus causing the aggregate demand curve to shift to the right. In the case of cuts in business taxes, the lower taxes will cause after-tax business profits to increase, which in turn is likely to lead to higher investment spending and therefore increased aggregate demand. In all three cases, aggregate demand is intended to shift to the right from AD1 to AD2 in Figures 9.1 (a) and (b), so that the economy achieves full employment or potential output Yp. Finally, the government may decide to pursue a policy of increasing government spending and lowering taxes simultaneously. How can it increase its own spending while keeping taxes constant or even decreasing them? As explained above, it can do so by borrowing to finance the excess of spending over tax revenues. If initially it has a balanced budget, then by increasing G while keeping taxes constant or lowering them, it will create a budget deficit. If it already has a budget deficit at the outset, then the deficit will become larger. If, on the other hand, it has a budget surplus at the outset, then the surplus will either become smaller, or it will shrink until it eventually turns into a deficit. Note that whether we consider the neoclassical perspective or the Keynesian perspective, the impact of the increase in aggregate demand will be to increase real GDP. However, note that for a given increase in aggregate demand, the size of the increase in real GDP will not be the same in the two cases. The increase in real GDP will be smaller in the neoclassical model than in the Keynesian one, because of the upwardsloping SRAS curve in the neoclassical model. The same is not true, however, for the price level. In the neoclassical perspective, the increase in aggregate demand will bring forth a rise in the price level, because of the upward-sloping SRAS curve. In the Keynesian perspective, the increase in aggregate demand may result in no increase in the price level at all if the AD shift occurs entirely within the horizontal segment of the Keynesian AS curve. If the AD shift is larger, so that it reaches into the upwardsloping part of the Keynesian AS curve, as shown in Figure 9.1(b), there will be only a very small increase in the price level. Contractionary fiscal policy Consider now the case where the economy is experiencing an inflationary gap caused by excessive aggregate demand, shown in Figures 9.2 (a) and (b) (page 252): the aggregate demand curve AD1 intersects the SRAS curve and the Keynesian AS curve at a level of real GDP, Ye, that is greater than the full employment or potential output level, Yp. The government’s objective now is to attempt to lower AD, shifting it from AD1 to AD2, so that AD2 intersects aggregate supply at the full employment level of output, Yp, thereby eliminating the inflationary gap. Fiscal policy undertaken to eliminate an inflationary gap is called contractionary policy, because it works to contract aggregate demand and the level of economic activity. Contractionary fiscal policy consists of: · · · · decreasing government spending increasing personal income taxes increasing business taxes, or a combination of decreasing spending and increasing taxes. Chapter 9: Demand-side and supply-side policies 251 (a) Eliminating an inflationary gap (neoclassical AD-AS model). (b) Eliminating an inflationary gap (Keynesian AD-AS model). Keynesian AS SRAS Pl1 Pl2 0 Ye Pl1 Pl2 AD2 AD1 AD2 Yp price level price level LRAS real GDP 0 AD1 Yp Ye real GDP potential output potential output Figure 9.2 Impacts of contractionary policy. A decrease in government spending has a direct influence on the aggregate demand curve, causing it to shift to the left. An increase in personal income taxes or business taxes is intented to affect aggregate demand in a two-step process. As personal income taxes increase, after-tax income falls, causing consumption spending and aggregate demand to fall. As taxes on profits increase, after-tax profits fall, leading businesses to spend less on investment and causing aggregate demand to fall. In all three cases, the aggregate demand curve is meant to shift to the left. The government can also pursue a combination of decreases in government spending with increases in personal income and business taxes. Depending on the initial conditions that prevail in the government’s budget, such a combination of policies would lead to the creation of a budget surplus, or the shrinkage of a budget deficit, or turning a budget deficit into a surplus. Fiscal policy involves manipulations by the government of its own expenditures and taxes in order to influence aggregate demand. The components of aggregate demand that can be affected are government spending (G), and investment (I) and consumption (C) spending (the latter two through changes in taxes). Expansionary fiscal policy can be used when there is a recessionary gap, and aims to increase aggregate demand, or shift the AD curve to the right so that it intersects the AS curve at the full employment level of real GDP (potential GDP). Contractionary fiscal policy can be used when there is an inflationary gap, and aims to decrease aggregate demand, or shift the AD curve to the left so that it intersects the AS curve at the full employment level of real GDP (potential GDP). 252 Part 3: Macroeconomics Test your understanding 9.1 1 Explain the difference between ‘government budget deficit’ and ‘government debt’. 2 (a) What are the objectives of fiscal policy? (b) Distinguish between expansionary and contractionary fiscal policy. (c) What are the components of aggregate demand that fiscal policy can influence? 3 Using diagrams, show how the government can use fiscal policy when there is (a) a recessionary gap, (b) an inflationary gap. 4 Using diagrams, show and explain how the following policies can impact on real GDP, the price level and unemployment: (a) the government lowers income taxes (b) the government decreases its spending on defence (c) the government increases taxes on business profits (d) the government increases its spending on the country’s road and highway system. Monetary policy Monetary policy is carried out by the central bank of each country. The central bank is a government financial institution whose purpose is to control the supply of money, determine the rate of interest, oversee the banking system, and carry out monetary policy. Every country has a central bank. In the countries of the European Union that have formed the European Monetary Union (those countries that have adopted the euro), the responsibility for monetary policy has been transferred to a single organization, the European Central Bank. Monetary policy impacts indirectly on aggregate demand through the rate of interest. To understand how monetary policy works, we must first consider how the rate of interest is determined. Determination of the rate of interest When we borrow money, we must make a payment for the loan in addition to repaying the principal (the amount of the loan); this payment for a loan is interest. Interest is usually expressed as a percentage of the principal to be paid per year; this percentage is called the rate of interest. For example, let’s say you borrow $1,000 for one year at the rate of interest of 10% per year; at the end of the year you must pay back the principal of $1,000, plus $100 of interest (calculated as 10% of $1,000). In the real world there are many different rates of interest, depending on a number of factors, such as the level of risk of a loan (the greater the risk, the higher the interest rate); the length of the period of time over which the loan must be paid, known as ‘maturity’ (the longer the time period, the lower the interest rate); the size of the loan (the larger the loan, the lower the interest rate); the degree of monopoly power of the lender (the greater the monopoly power, the higher the interest rate), and others. However, when economists analyse the rate of interest in the context of economic models (as we are doing here), they simplify the analysis by adopting the common practice of referring to ‘the rate of interest’ as if there were only one. We can understand how the rate of interest is determined very simply as an application of the familiar concepts of supply and demand in a special market, the money market, shown in Figure 9.3(a). The money market is a market where the demand for money and the supply of money determine the equilibrium rate of interest. The horizontal axis measures the quantity of money in the economy, and the vertical axis measures the rate of interest. The rate of interest can be thought of as the ‘price’ of money services. The demand for money, Dm, shows the relationship between the rate of interest and the quantity of money demanded, and has the familiar downward-sloping shape of a demand curve. As the rate of interest falls, the quantity of money demanded by the public at large (consumers, firms, the government) increases. (To understand better why the demand for money is downward sloping, we must look into what ‘money’ is. Money provides important services because it allows consumers, firms and the government to carry out all their buying and selling exchanges, or their spending. In addition, money can be used as a form of saving when it is used to buy bonds. (A bond is a certificate issued by the government or a firm that promises to pay interest at various intervals until a certain date when the money is repaid to the bond holder.) Since bonds pay interest, this means that the rate of interest is very important in determining how much money people want to hold as money, and how much of it they want to hold in the form of bonds. When people hold money, they sacrifice the interest they could have received if they had bought bonds; in other words, interest is the opportunity cost of holding money. The higher the interest rate, the greater the opportunity cost, in terms of sacrificed interest, and therefore the lower the quantity of money demanded. As the interest rates falls, the opportunity cost of holding money decreases, and therefore the quantity of money demanded rises. This is the explanation behind the downward-sloping demand for money curve.) The supply of money is fixed at a level that is decided upon by the central bank. It appears in Figure 9.3(a) as a vertical line, Sm, because it does not depend on the rate of interest. The point of intersection between Dm, showing the quantity of money demanded, and Sm, showing the quantity of money supplied, determines the equilibrium rate of interest, i, as illustrated in Figure 9.3(a). Monetary policy is carried out by the central bank, through changes in the money supply, which are undertaken in order to influence the rate of interest. (There are several tools that the central bank uses to alter the supply of money; a discussion of these is beyond the scope of this course.) When the money supply changes, this has the effect of shifting the Sm curve. Figure 9.3(b) shows how changes in the money supply affect the equilibrium rate of interest. Say initially the money supply is at Sm1; with demand for money Dm, the equilibrium rate of interest is i1. If the central bank decides to increase the money supply, the supply of money curve shifts to the right from Sm1 to Sm2, and the equilibrium rate of interest falls to i2. If on the other hand the central bank decides to decrease the money supply, the money supply curve shifts to the left, from Sm1 to Sm3, and the equilibrium rate of interest rises to i3. Chapter 9: Demand-side and supply-side policies 253 (a) Equilibrium rate of interest. (b) Changes in the supply of money cause changes in the equilibrium rate of interest. Sm3 rate of interest rate of interest Sm i Dm 0 Qe quantity of money Sm1 Sm2 i3 i1 i2 0 Dm Q3 Q1 Q2 quantity of money Figure 9.3 The money market and determination of the rate of interest. In practice, when the central bank decides to conduct monetary policy, it can target either the money supply or the rate of interest; that is, it can make its decision in terms of changing either the money supply or the rate of interest. (Of course making a decision on one automatically determines the other.) Central banks in many countries used to target the money supply. However, this presupposed having control over the money supply in order to be able to target by how much it should increase or decrease. Growing difficulties in effectively controlling the supply of money prompted central banks in many countries to abandon money supply targeting and switch to interest rate targeting. Interest rate targeting in effect means that the central bank decides upon a target interest rate, and then takes the necessary steps to adjust the money supply so that the actual equilibrium interest rate will become equal to the target interest rate. Changes in interest rates and aggregate demand The point of changing the money supply so as to change interest rates is to ultimately influence aggregate demand. If we refer to our discussion of aggregate demand in Chapter 8, page 228, we will remember that changes in interest rates affect two of the four components of aggregate demand: consumption, C, and investment, I (see Table 8.1). Since some consumer spending is paid for out of borrowing, a change in interest rates is intended to affect the amount of consumer spending (C); similarly, changes in interest rates affect the amount of borrowing by businesses to finance their investment expenditures (I). 254 Part 3: Macroeconomics An increase in interest rates is intended to result in lower consumer and business borrowing and spending (lower C and I), and therefore a leftward shift in aggregate demand. A decrease in interest rates is intended to give rise to greater consumer and business borrowing and spending (higher C and I), and therefore a rightward shift in aggregate demand. Expansionary (easy money) policy Consider the case where the economy is experiencing a recessionary gap due to insufficient aggregate demand, as in Figures 9.1 (a) and (b). The central bank decides to increase the money supply, causing a rightward shift in the supply of money curve (from Sm1 to Sm2 as shown in Figure 9.3(b)). With the demand for money constant, the interest rate falls from i1 to i2. The drop in the rate of interest means a lower cost of borrowing, and therefore consumers and firms are likely to borrow more and spend more. The result is that consumption spending (C) and investment spending (I) increase. The effect will be to increase aggregate demand and cause a rightward shift of the aggregate demand curve. In fact, investment spending is more sensitive than consumption spending to interest rates changes, so that the increase in I is likely to have a greater impact on aggregate demand than the increase in C. The increase in aggregate demand arising from the combined effect of the C and I increases is shown in Figures 9.1 (a) and (b), where the recessionary gap has been eliminated through the shift of the AD curve from AD1 to AD2. Note that, just as in the case of fiscal policy, whereas the increase in AD will serve to increase real GDP, the impact on the price level will be different, and will be greater according to the neoclassical perspective compared to the Keynesian perspective. An increase in the money supply by the central bank is referred to as an easy money policy; it is also an expansionary policy, since the objective is to expand aggregate demand and the level of economic activity. Contractionary (tight money) policy Let’s suppose now that the economy is experiencing an inflationary gap caused by excessive aggregate demand, as in Figures 9.2 (a) and (b). The central bank reduces the money supply; this appears in Figure 9.3(b) as a leftward shift of the Sm curve, from Sm1 to Sm3. With the demand for money constant, there results a higher rate of interest, i3. This means a higher cost of borrowing, and therefore reduced borrowing by consumers and firms (again, the impact will be greater in the case of investment spending). The effect of lower consumer spending (C) and lower investment spending (I) is to lower aggregate demand, i.e. to shift the aggregate demand curve to the right. This is shown in both panels of Figure 9.2, where the inflationary gap has been eliminated through the shift of aggregate demand from AD1 to AD2. A decrease in the money supply by the central bank is referred to as a tight money policy, or contractionary policy, as the objective is to contract aggregate demand and therefore the economy. Table 9.1 provides a summary of fiscal and monetary policy measures, their effects on spending, and their impacts on aggregate demand. The impacts of both types of policies have been illustrated by use of the same diagrams (Figures 9.1 and 9.2). Yet this simple diagrammatical analysis hides important differences between the two types of policies, related to the very different channels that affect the spending of the various aggregate demand components. Fiscal policy works directly through changes in G, C and I spending; monetary policy indirectly through changes in interest rates that affect C and I spending. We will discover some differences between the two types of policies in the next section. Table 9.1 Demand-side policies to correct recessionary and inflationary gaps. Expansionary policy (in recession) Type of policy Measures Effects Fiscal policy increase government spending increase AD lower personal income taxes ➞ increase consumption spending increase AD lower business taxes ➞ increase investment spending increase AD Monetary policy increase supply of money ➞ lower interest rate ➞ (i) increase consumption spending increase AD (ii) increase investment spending increase AD Contractionary policy (in inflation) Monetary policy is carried out by the central bank, which aims at changing interest rates in order to influence aggregate demand. The components of aggregate demand that can be affected are investment spending (I) and consumption spending (C). If the economy is experiencing a recessionary gap, the central bank may pursue an expansionary policy through lower interest rates to encourage I and C spending, the objective being to increase aggregate demand, and shift the AD curve to the right so it will intersect the AS curve at the full employment level of real GDP (potential GDP). In the event of an inflationary gap, the central bank can pursue a contractionary policy though higher interest rates aimed at discouraging I and C spending, causing the AD curve to shift to the left so that it intersects the AS curve at the full employment level of real GDP (potential GDP). Type of policy Measures Effects Fiscal policy decrease government spending decrease AD raise personal income taxes ➞ decrease consumption spending decrease AD raise business taxes ➞ decrease investment spending decrease AD Monetary policy decrease supply of money ➞ raise interest rate ➞ (i) decrease consumption spending decrease AD (ii) decrease investment spending decrease AD Chapter 9: Demand-side and supply-side policies 255 Test your understanding 9.2 1 (a) Explain the importance of the money supply in determining the rate of interest. (b) What is the government authority that is responsible for changing the supply of money and carrying out monetary policy? 2 (a) What are the objectives of monetary policy? (b) Distinguish between expansionary and contractionary monetary policy. (c) Why do you think expansionary monetary policy is also called an ‘easy money policy’; why is contractionary monetary policy also known as a ‘tight money policy’? (d) What are the components of aggregate demand that monetary policy can influence? (e) What is the role of the rate of interest in monetary policy? 3 Using diagrams, show how the government can use monetary policy when there is (a) a recessionary gap, (b) an inflationary gap. 4 Using diagrams, show and explain the impact on real GDP, the price level and unemployment of the following policies undertaken by a country’s central bank: (a) a fall in the rate of interest; (b) an increase in the rate of interest. Strengths and weaknesses of demand-side policies for short-term stabilization The discussion above has focused on illustrating the expected impacts of demand-side policies intended to counteract the fluctuations of the business cycle. However, the complexities of the real world, which are not reflected in the simple AD-AS model, present a number of difficulties that often prevent these policies from achieving the desired and expected impacts. We now turn to consider the strengths and weaknesses of fiscal and monetary policies. output and incomes and high unemployment over an extended period of time, showed that market forces acting alone were inadequate to pull the economy out of the deep recession and restore full employment and output. In the now classic work The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, that made its appearance in 1936, John Maynard Keynes (the originator of ‘Keynesian economics’) argued that wages and prices were inflexible in the downward direction even in the face of steep recession, and that low aggregate demand could keep the economy stuck in a recessionary gap indefinitely if the government did not step in with an active fiscal policy to pull it out. This situation, as we saw in Chapter 8, Figure 8.15(a), page 244, can occur when the AD curve intersects the Keynesian aggregate supply (AS) curve at some point on its horizontal segment, determining a level of real GDP that is less than full employment GDP; it is shown again in Figure 9.1(b) above. The strength of fiscal policy is to pull an economy out of a deep recession, or when the economy finds itself in the horizontal segment of the AS curve. In the autumn of 2008, fears of a major global recession prompted governments around the world to pursue expansionary fiscal policy in the form of increased government spending, as well as tax cuts, in order to stimulate low aggregate demand. · Combating rapid and escalating inflation Inflationary pressures (to be discussed in Chapter 10) arising when there is an inflationary gap, can sometimes get out of hand, resulting in rapid increases in the price level over relatively short periods of time. Contractionary fiscal policy may then be used effectively to help bring the problem under control. Weaknesses of fiscal policy · Problems of timing Fiscal policy is subject to a number of delays in timing called time lags: ❍ Strengths of fiscal policy · Combating a deep recession Until the Great Depression of the 1930s, classical economists believed that short-term economic fluctuations were self-correcting: in the event of a recession, wage and price flexibility would work to correct the problem and the economy would eventually revert to its full employment equilibrium. (This is very similar to the thinking of neoclassical economists, discussed in Chapter 8, page 238, based on the ideas of the classical economists.) However, the experience of the Great Depression, which involved low levels of 256 Part 3: Macroeconomics ❍ ❍ there is a lag until the problem (recessionary or inflationary gap) is recognized by the government authorities and economists there is a lag until the appropriate policy to deal with the problem is decided upon by the government there is a lag until the policy takes effect in the economy. Some months may pass in the case of each of these, and by the time the policy action has taken effect the problem may have become less or more severe, so that the policy action is no longer the appropriate one. · Problems of inadequate information The government bases its policy decisions on statistical information and forecasts about future developments that are often inaccurate. Inaccuracies may lead to inappropriate policies. · Political constraints Government spending and taxation are subject to numerous pressures that are unrelated to fiscal policy considerations. Spending for social services (merit goods such as health care and education) and public goods is undertaken for its own sake and cannot easily be cut if a contractionary policy is required. On the other hand, tax increases are politically unpopular and may be avoided by the government even though they might be necessary. Tax decreases could also be inappropriately enacted because they are politically popular. The upshot is that political factors may sometimes lead to unsuitable fiscal policies. · Crowding-out effect If the government pursues an expansionary fiscal policy involving spending increases in the absence of a corresponding increase in revenues, it must borrow to make up the excess of spending over its revenues. Government borrowing in effect involves an increase in the demand for money, and leads to an increase in the rate of interest. A higher interest rate in turn can lead to lower investment spending by private firms, or a ‘crowding out’ of investment. This means that the government’s expansionary fiscal policy is weakened, since a greater G (government spending) will be offset by a lower I (investment spending). (Crowding out is a higher level topic (see page 275).) • In a recession, tax cuts may not be very effective in increasing aggregate demand Tax cuts are less effective in a recession than increases in government spending because part of the increase in after-tax income is saved. If the proportion of income saved rises due to pessimism about the future, the impacts of tax cuts on aggregate demand will be even weaker. Increases in government spending are more powerful because they work in their entirety to increase aggregate demand. · Inability to ‘fine tune’ the economy Whereas fiscal policy can lead the economy in a general direction of larger or smaller aggregate demand, it cannot ‘fine tune’ the economy, i.e. it cannot be used to reach a precise target with respect to the level of output, employment and the price level. If fiscal policy were successful, it would be possible to use it to keep the economy’s real GDP at or very close to its potential output level. However, experience has shown that this cannot be done, as there are many factors affecting aggregate demand simultaneously that the government cannot control. Strengths of monetary policy The strengths of monetary policy lie chiefly in it not being subject to some of the weaknesses of fiscal policy: · Relatively quick implementation Monetary policy can be implemented more quickly than fiscal policy because it does not have to go through the political process, which is very cumbersome and time consuming (though, as we will see below, monetary policy is also subject to some time lags). · No political constraints Monetary policy is not subject to the same kinds of political pressures, since it does not involve making changes in the government budget, whether in terms of government spending that would affect merit and public goods provision, or government revenues (taxes). Moreover, the central bank in many countries, though a government organization, is independent of the governing political party, and therefore exercises greater freedom in pursuing policies that may be politically unpopular (such as higher interest rates that make borrowing more costly). · No crowding-out effect Monetary policy does not lead to the crowding-out effect, which can result from higher interest rates due to an expansionary fiscal policy. The monetary policy counterpart to an expansionary fiscal policy is an easy money policy, which leads to lower (not higher) interest rates. · Better suited to ‘fine tuning’ of the economy in comparison with fiscal policy The above factors make monetary policy better suited to ‘fine tuning’ the economy, as compared to fiscal policy, in that it may be more accurate with respect to achieving output, price level and employment objectives. However, it should be stressed that it is also subject to limitations, and that there is in fact no policy tool that economists can use to fully ‘fine tune’ an economy. Weaknesses of monetary policy · Problems of timing Unlike fiscal policy, monetary policy can be implemented and changed according to perceived needs relatively quickly, because it does not depend on the political process. However, like fiscal policy, it remains subject to time lags (delays), including a lag until the problem is recognized, and a lag until the policy takes effect. Changes in interest rates can take several months to have an impact on aggregate demand, real output and the price level. By then, economic conditions may have changed such that the policy undertaken is no Chapter 9: Demand-side and supply-side policies 257 longer appropriate. Moreover, if there is pessimism in the economy, this time lag becomes even longer. · Problems of inadequate information As in the case of fiscal policy, the government bases its decisions on statistical information and forecasts about future developments that are often inaccurate. Such inaccuracies may lead to inappropriate policies. · Possible ineffectiveness in recession Whereas monetary policy can work effectively when it restricts the money supply (a tight money policy) to combat inflation, it is less certain to be as effective in a deep recession. An easy money (expansionary) policy is intended to increase aggregate demand by encouraging investment and consumption spending through lower interest rates. This process presupposes that banks will be willing to increase their lending to firms and consumers, and that firms and consumers will be willing to increase their borrowing and their spending. However, in a severe recession, banks may be unwilling to increase their lending, because they may fear that the borrowers might be unable to repay the loans. Moreover, if firms and consumers are pessimistic about future economic conditions, they may avoid taking out new loans, and may even reduce their investment and consumer spending, in which case aggregate demand will not increase (it may even decrease), and monetary policy will be unable to pull the economy out of recession. This is not something that happens often; however, it appears to have occurred during the Great Depression of the 1930s and some economists believe it occurred in Japan in the late 1990s and early 2000s. In the autumn of 2008, many economists expressed the fear that it might be happening again. There was a concern that even as interest rates fell (due to expansionary monetary policy), lending by firms and consumers might not increase as much as would be desirable because banks were fearful that many borrowers might be unable to repay their debts. Inability of fiscal and monetary policies to address supply-side causes of economic contractions In addition to respective weaknesses noted above, both fiscal and monetary policies are unable to deal with a particular combination of undesirable events. We have seen that demand-side (fiscal and monetary) policies undertaken for stabilization purposes attempt to reverse the undesirable shifts in aggregate demand that cause business cycle fluctuations. As we learned 258 Part 3: Macroeconomics in Chapter 8, page 234, if there is a recessionary gap caused by a leftward shift in AD, there results unemployment and a falling price level; these can be potentially corrected by expansionary fiscal and monetary policies that shift the AD curve rightward to the full employment level of real GDP. An inflationary gap, on the other hand, caused by a rightward shift in the AD curve, gives rise to more than full employment and a rising price level (inflation); this can be potentially corrected by contractionary fiscal and monetary policies that shift the AD curve leftward to the full employment level of real GDP. But what if the economy is experiencing a contraction, with falling real GDP and a rising price level simultaneously? This combination of events has been termed stagflation (combining the words ‘stagnation’ and ‘inflation’), and first made its appearance in the mid-1970s. We discussed it briefly in Chapter 8, page 236, where it was illustrated in Figure 8.9(b) by the leftward shift in the SRAS curve, from SRAS1 to SRAS2. Of the many explanations that have been put forward to explain stagflation, the most popular refers to increases in oil prices due to the actions of OPEC (the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries), which cut back on its production of oil, thereby giving rise to increases in the price of oil, a major input in production. As we know from Chapter 8, page 232, an increase in the price of a major input gives rise to a leftward shift in the SRAS curve, resulting in a lower level of real GDP and a higher price level (inflation). Fiscal and monetary policies are unable to resolve both inflation and unemployment at the same time, because inflation requires a contractionary policy, while unemployment that arises in a recession requires an expansionary policy. A contractionary policy could address the problem of the rising price level, but would make the recession worse; an expansionary policy would help get the economy out of recession, but would worsen the problem of inflation. Demand-side policies (fiscal and monetary) are suited to dealing with macroeconomic instability that arises from shifts of the aggregate demand curve. But these policies cannot address instability arising from leftward aggregate supply curve shifts, which give rise to both inflation and unemployment simultaneously. Fiscal or monetary policy? Historically, Keynesian economists have tended to believe that fiscal policy is more effective in achieving stabilization, while neoclassical economists have believed that monetary policy is more effective. Most economists today would adopt a ‘middle of the road’ perspective, according to which both fiscal and monetary policies are able to influence aggregate demand. While some disagreements remain, there tends to be a convergence on the point that fiscal and monetary policies should not be viewed as an either–or choice, but are most effective when used together in order to complement and reinforce each other. Most economists believe that because of its greater speed and flexibility, monetary policy is better suited to dealing with short-term stabilization efforts, particularly when there is an inflationary gap. Fiscal policy, on the other hand, being more cumbersome, inflexible and subject to political constraints, should focus on creating a stable fiscal environment, involving avoidance of very large and persistent budget deficits or surpluses. In addition, many economists believe that fiscal policy should be used to complement monetary policy in the event of strong economic downturns that may require an extra helping hand to prevent a serious recession, or to pull an economy out of a serious recession. In the autumn of 2008, a number of governments turned to expansionary fiscal policies to stimulate their economies as they appeared to be going into recession, particularly since there were fears that monetary policy on its own might be unable to give rise to the necessary increases in aggregate demand. Test your understanding 9.3 1 Discuss the strengths and weaknesses of fiscal policy. 2 Discuss the strengths and weaknesses of monetary policy. 3 Why do decisions on whether or not to use fiscal policy to stabilize the economy sometimes depend on more than just economic considerations? 4 Why do you think in recent decades monetary policy tends to be preferred over fiscal policy as a policy tool to correct the fluctuations of economic activity (the business cycle)? (Refer to the strengths and weakness of each type of policy in your answer.) (...continued) Test your understanding 9.3 (...continued) 5 Explain why both fiscal and monetary policies are not very well suited to dealing with instabilities caused by decreases in aggregate supply. Discretionary policy or a monetary rule? (supplementary material) A quite different debate concerns the question whether discretionary fiscal and monetary policies should be pursued at all by government authorities for macroeconomic stabilization. Some neoclassical economists (namely ‘monetarists’) oppose the active use of such policies, and argue that the weaknesses of fiscal and monetary policies outlined above (time lags, lack of sufficient information, crowding out, etc.) combine to make discretionary policies part of the cause of economic instability rather than its cure. Such policies are destabilizing for the economy and should therefore not be used at all. Demand-side policies are seen to intensify the business cycle rather than smooth it out. In this view, the economy is capable of correcting short-run instabilities on its own without government intervention (this was explained in Chapter 8, pages 238 and 246). Rather than use fiscal policy for the sake of short-term stabilization, the government should concentrate on making long-term decisions about government spending and taxation that reflect social priorities (such as how much to spend and how to finance merit and public goods). In the case of monetary policy, the central bank should avoid changing the money supply in an effort to influence interest rates, and should instead adopt a monetary rule according to which the supply of money will grow steadily each year at some pre-specified rate. One possible monetary rule would be to have the money supply grow at the same rate as the rate of growth in potential GDP. (The reasoning behind such a rule will become clear in Chapter 10 when we study the monetarists’ quantity theory of money.) At the same time, governments should pursue policies that increase wage and price flexibility, which will improve the economy’s self-correcting ability; and they should also pursue policies that focus on the supply side of the economy to promote long-term economic growth. Chapter 9: Demand-side and supply-side policies 259 Economists who favour the use of demand-side policies for short-term stabilization purposes base their arguments on the Keynesian tradition of economic thought, and argue that, left on its own, the economy does not tend towards full employment equilibrium. Cyclical fluctuations in real GDP are due to many possible disturbances to economic activity related to the behaviour of private sector decision-makers (summarized in Table 8.1, page 230), which require government intervention to counteract their impacts on aggregate demand. Discretionary policies, though imperfect, play an important role in preventing large recessionary and inflationary gaps, therefore smoothing out the business cycle. The adoption of rules would make the economy more prone to cyclical fluctuations. Most economists hold the view that discretionary demand-side policies are important for maintaining full employment and price stability. This is the view also held by most governments around the world that use monetary and fiscal policies in pursuit of these economic objectives. There is no country to date that has tried implementing a monetary rule. Some countries have tried a kind of monetary policy based on the adoption of an inflation target, which involves using monetary policy to try to maintain the targeted rate of inflation (for example, Australia, Canada, Finland, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and others). While this has come the closest to the idea of a monetary rule, it is not the same, because the target inflation involves a range of inflation rates (for example 1%–3%), which means that the central bank still has some leeway to conduct discretionary monetary policy, as long as it remains within the range of permissible (targeted) rates of inflation. Moreover, most mainstream economists believe that demand-side and supply-side policies should be used in combination in order to promote long-run economic growth. We will come back to this point later in this chapter. Demand-side policies and long-term economic growth Demand-side policies focus mainly on short-term stabilization; however, they can also contribute to long-term growth of potential GDP. Demand-side policies can do so indirectly, by providing a stable macroeconomic environment, and directly, by leading to aggregate expenditures that result in growth of potential GDP. 260 Part 3: Macroeconomics Consumers and firms need a stable economic environment in order to be able to plan and carry out their economic activities. Firms, in particular, must make plans in many areas, including what capital goods to invest in, and whether, how and in what areas to pursue research and development (R&D) and technological innovations. Investment is the key to the formation of new capital goods, and R&D is the driving force of technological changes, both of which are very important factors in increasing production possibilities and increasing potential GDP (shifting the LRAS curve to the right in the neoclassical context). In order to be in a position to plan over long periods of time, firms need economic stability, consisting of avoidance of sharp economic upturns (inflation) and downturns (recession and unemployment). Demandside policies aiming at economic stabilization are therefore important in creating the macroeconomic environment that encourages activities impacting on long-term economic growth. In addition, demand-side policies can impact directly on the growth of potential GDP: · They can directly encourage investment through lower business taxes (fiscal policy) or lower interest rates (monetary policy), thereby contributing to new capital formation and R&D that promotes technological innovations that increase potential output and long-term economic growth. · They can direct a portion of government spending to the development of infrastructure (roads and transport systems, telecommunications, harbours, airports, etc.), which increases the quantity of capital goods; on research and development, which improves technology; on training and education programmes that increase the quality of the labour force and can also help lower the natural rate of unemployment (we will see how in Chapter 10). All these factors work to increase potential GDP, thus supporting long-term economic growth. In Figure 9.4, suppose an economy is initially in long-run equilibrium on LRAS1. Suppose then that the government pursues a variety of demand-side policies, including increases in government expenditures on infrastructure, R&D and training and education, thereby increasing the quantity of capital goods, and improving the level of technology and the quality of labour force; or alternatively it lowers interest rates, giving rise to increases in investment spending and a greater quantity of capital goods. These demand-side policies produce increases in aggregate demand, so that AD shifts from AD1 to AD2. But these policies also impact on aggregate supply, because of the increase in the quantity of capital goods, the improvements in the quality of labour, etc., so that the LRAS and SRAS curves also shift to the right. What has happened is that the demand-side policies initiated a sequence of events that resulted not only in an increase in aggregate demand, but also in increases in growth in potential output. In the neoclassical model, this shows up as a rightward shift of the LRAS curve, as shown in Figure 9.4; in the Keynesian model, it is a rightward shift of the Keynesian AS curve (see Figure 8.17 in Chapter 8, page 245). price level LRAS1 LRAS2 SRAS1 SRAS2 Pl1 AD1 0 Y1 AD2 Y2 real GDP Figure 9.4 Long-run economic growth: shifts in the AD, SRAS and LRAS curves. Demand-side policies have not only demand-side but also supply-side effects, and can therefore affect long-term economic growth by increasing potential output. Their contribution to economic growth includes creating a stable economic environment, as well as encouraging private investment spending and government spending, which in turn lead to increases in potential output (through new capital formation, increased R&D and technological improvements, and improvements in the quality of the labour force), and to reductions in the natural rate of unemployment. Test your understanding 9.4 Explain how demand-side policies (a) have supply-side effects; (b) can impact on long-term economic growth. Use an appropriate diagram in your answer. 9.2 Supply-side policies: shifts in the aggregate supply curve Objectives of supply-side policies Supply-side policies focus on aggregate supply, and specifically on factors aimed at directly shifting the long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve to the right, in order to achieve long-term economic growth. They do not attempt to stabilize the economy (i.e. to reduce the severity of the business cycle). There are two major categories of supply-side policies: market oriented and interventionist. Market-oriented policies tend to be favoured by neoclassical economists, who emphasize the importance of well-functioning competitive markets in bringing about rightward shifts in the LRAS curve. Interventionist supply-side policies attempt to increase aggregate supply by relying on government intervention rather than the market; these tend to be favoured by economists influenced by Keynesian economic thinking. Market-oriented supply-side policies In the early 1980s, a number of highly influential neoclassical economists in the United Kingdom and the United States began to emphasize the view that growth in real GDP does not depend on aggregate demand, but rather on the supply side of the economy. This view was adopted by the government headed by Margaret Thatche