LH Advanced Macroeconomics (07 33109) Seminar Class 1: Real Business Cycle Theory (Week 3) Q1. Consider the following Cobb-Douglas production function (0< α<1): ππ‘ = πΎπ‘πΌ (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )1−πΌ which shows that output depends upon capital input, labour input and ‘technology’ (A). i) Show that the marginal product of capital is positive (for K,L,A>0) but diminishing in the level of capital employed. ii) Show that the marginal product of labour is positive for (K,L,A>0) but diminishing in the level of labour employed. iii) Provide an economic interpretation for the parameter α. Q2. Consider the one-period RBC model studied in the lecture notes but now suppose the utility function for households is: π’π‘ = ln ππ‘ + π(1 − βπ‘ )1−πΎ ⁄(1 − πΎ) where b>0 and γ>0. How, if at all, does labour supply depend on the real wage under this new functional form for utility? Q3. For the two-period RBC model, show that a logarithmic instantaneous utility function of the form (where b>0 is a leisure preference parameter): π’π‘ = ln ππ‘ + π ln(1 − βπ‘ ) with arguments in consumption (ππ‘ ) and leisure time (1 − βπ‘ ), produces an intertemporal elasticity of substitution of 1 between period 1 and period 2 leisure time. Explain how this is relevant to the labour supply in the two-period RBC model. 1 SOLUTIONS Q1. Recall the Cobb-Douglas production function given in the question: ππ‘ = πΎπ‘πΌ (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )1−πΌ i) To find the marginal product of capital (MPK), take the first derivative of the production function w.r.t. capital, K: πππΎπ‘ = πΌπΎπ‘πΌ−1 (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )1−πΌ > 0 Notice that under a Cobb-Douglas production function the MPK can be conveniently expressed as: ππ‘ πΌπΎπ‘πΌ−1 (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )1−πΌ = πΌ > 0 πΎπ‘ To show that the MPK diminishes as capital input increases, take the second derivative as follows: πΌ(πΌ − 1)πΎπ‘πΌ−2 (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )1−πΌ = πΌ(πΌ − 1) ππ‘ <0 πΎπ‘2 The parameter restriction 0<α<1 is crucial to these results for MPK. ii) To find the marginal product of labour (MPL), take the first derivative of the production function w.r.t. labour, L (chain rule needed here): πππΏπ‘ = (1 − πΌ)πΎπ‘πΌ (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )−πΌ π΄π‘ > 0 Notice that under a Cobb-Douglas production function the MPL can be conveniently expressed as: ππ‘ (1 − πΌ)πΎπ‘πΌ (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )−πΌ π΄π‘ = (1 − πΌ) > 0 πΏπ‘ To show that the MPL diminishes as labour input increases, take the second derivative as follows (chain rule needed again): −πΌ(1 − πΌ)πΎπ‘πΌ (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )−πΌ−1 π΄2π‘ = −πΌ(1 − πΌ) ππ‘ <0 πΏ2π‘ Again, the parameter restriction 0<α<1 is crucial to these results. iii) The parameter α represents capital’s share of output. To see this mathematically, note that under perfect competition and profit maximisation each unit of capital (and labour) is paid an amount equal to its marginal product. The total amount paid to those who own 2 the capital is therefore MPK multiplied by the level of K. Let’s define the share of output paid to those who own the capital as sK: π πΎ ≡ (πππΎπ‘ )πΎπ‘ πΌπΎπ‘πΌ−1 (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )1−πΌ πΎπ‘ = =πΌ ππ‘ πΎπ‘πΌ (π΄π‘ πΏπ‘ )1−πΌ It follows that (1–α) represents labour’s share of output (sL). You can easily check this mathematically. Notice that these shares are constant in the Cobb-Douglas case, even though this may not be consistent with empirical evidence. Also, the shares must sum to 1 because of the parameter restriction on α. In other words, we assume constant returns to scale. We have chosen to adopt a ‘Harrod-neutral’ (labour-augmenting technological progress) form for our Cobb-Douglas production function. Alternatively, the Cobb-Douglas production function could be written with ‘Hicks-neutral’ technological progress as follows: ππ‘ = π΄π‘ πΎπ‘πΌ πΏπ‘ 1−πΌ Or with capital-augmenting (‘Solow-neutral’) technological progress: ππ‘ = (π΄π‘ πΎπ‘ )πΌ πΏπ‘ 1−πΌ However, following Romer’s approach we shall adopt the labour-augmenting specification given in the question. Q2. The utility function is as follows: π’π‘ = ln ππ‘ + π(1 − βπ‘ )1−πΎ ⁄(1 − πΎ) Recall from the lecture slides that the budget constraint in the one-period model is simply π = π€β. The Lagrangian problem is therefore (we can drop time subscripts from this point on since there is only one time period): β = ln π + π(1 − β)1−πΎ ⁄(1 − πΎ) + π(π€β − π) With first order conditions: πβ 1 = −π =0 ππ π πβ = −π(1 − β)−πΎ + ππ€ = 0 πβ For completeness, take the F.O.C. with respect to λ: 3 πβ = π€β − π = 0 ππ Using the budget constraint, the FOC for c can be expressed as: π= 1 1 = π π€β Substitute this result into the FOC for β to obtain: 1 = π(1 − β)−πΎ β This is only an implicit function for β but it is sufficient to show that β does not depend upon the real wage. This gives us the same results as the lecture slides – the income and substitution effects of a change in w exactly offset each other in this one-period model, even though we have used a different utility function in the seminar class. Q3. We need to use the intertemporal elasticity of substitution between period 1 and period 2 leisure time to answer this question. This measures the percentage change in the ratio of leisure time, (1 − β1 )/(1 − β2 ), for a given percentage change in relative wages, w2/w1. Intuitively, an increase in relative wages will make it more attractive to work in period 2, i.e. households want less leisure time in period 2. However, because this elasticity is calculated for a given indifference curve, the household will need to increase leisure time in period 1 to compensate for the reduced leisure time in period 2. Mathematically, we need to calculate the following elasticity: If this elasticity is large, households are willing to substitute a relatively large amount of current leisure for future leisure in response to a rise in the wage ratio w2/w1. This response is relevant to labour supply in the model because households allocate their time endowment between labour and leisure time in each period. An increase in leisure time in period 1, say, implies a decrease in labour time in that same time period. Recall that the first order conditions for current and future leisure time can be combined to obtain (see lecture slides): 4 1 − β1 1 π€2 = −π 1 − β2 π (1 + π) π€1 Therefore: π[(1 − β1 )⁄(1 − β2 )] 1 = −π π[π€2 /π€1 ] π (1 + π) Using this result in the formula for the intertemporal elasticity of substitution for leisure time given above: πΌπΈππΏπππ π’ππ = 1 π −π (1 + π€2 ⁄π€1 π) (1 − β1 )/(1 − β2 ) Using the first order condition presented at the top of this page to substitute out for relative leisure time, we can write this as: = 1 −π π (1 + π) π€2 ⁄π€1 =1 1 π€2 π −π (1 + π) π€1 We can interpret this result as follows: an x% increase in relative wages, w2/w1, leads to an equal % increase in relative leisure time, (1 − β1 )/(1 − β2 ). 5