Financing Payouts Joan Farre-Mensa, University of Illinois at Chicago Roni Michaely, University of Geneva Martin Schmalz, University of Oxford Motivation: An untested assumption Ross, Westerfield, and Jaffe (2013): • “A firm should begin making distributions when it generates sufficient internal cash flow to fund its investment needs now and into the foreseeable future.” • Set level of payouts “low enough to avoid expensive future external financing.” Conventional wisdom in payout lit.: payouts funded w/ free cash flow • Grullon et al. (2002), DeAngelo et al. (2006): lifecycle view of the firm – Young firms raise capital to invest, mature firms pay out excess FCF • dividends when cash flow is permanent, share repurchases when it is temporary Same firm should not raise and pay out capital at the same time RQ1: Do managers follow the textbook advice? As it turns out, they do not: Financed payouts are prevalent 43% of payout payers initiate net debt or equity issues in the same year they pay a dividend or repurchase shares (= “finance” their payouts) 41% of payout payers do not generate enough profits to maintain their investment and payout levels without the proceeds of these issues The economic magnitude of financed payouts is important 31% of aggregate payouts are financed with a security issue initiated by the same firm in the same year; debt is by far the largest financing source Conversely, 37% of aggregate proceeds of security issues are paid out by the same firm in the same year, both via repurchases & dividends Financed payouts are persistent 65% of firms that finance their payouts do it at least once every two years The gap between payouts and free cash flow persists—in fact, widens— over five-year intervals RQ2: Why do firms finance their payouts? A policy of financing payouts is obviously costly—so why do it? • Firms face non-trivial fixed and marginal costs of raising external capital (e.g., Hennessy and Whited 2007) One key reason is firms’ desire to jointly manage their capital structure and cash holdings (increase leverage w/o depleting cash) Tax considerations—both the tax deductibility of interest payments and the avoidance of repatriation taxes—are a key motivating factor Other reasons—which we do not directly study—likely also important: Agency considerations (Easterbrook 1984, Jensen 1986), cross-market arbitrage (Ma 2019), monetary policy (Acharya and Plantin 2020, Elgouacem and Zago 2019) RQ3: What are the consequences of debtfinanced payouts? • Debt-financed payouts appear to increase firms’ exposure to negative shocks, particularly for firms w/o an investment-grade credit rating – • Just 26% of firms that debt-finance their payouts have an investment-grade rating Debt-financed payouts are associated with: – lower investment levels during industry downturns – a deeper stock price decline during the COVID-19 crisis • Of course, the decision to debt-finance payouts is endogenous, so we stop short from claiming causality • That said, our findings suggest that not all payouts are the same when thinking about the consequences of payouts on financial fragility Contributions 1. First systematic analysis of how firms fund their payouts – Earlier evidence that some firms occasionally finance payouts o E.g., Denis and Denis (1993) investigate 39 leveraged recaps. Similarly, Danis, Rettl, and Whited (2014) study large debt-financed payouts, which are “not frequent” o Fama French (2005) & Grullon et al. (2011): some firms simultaneously raise equity & pay out Turns out much of it is driven by equity issues initiated by employees via stockoption exercises, which we conservatively exclude The pervasiveness, magnitude, and persistence of financed payouts that we document indicates that over 40% of firms do not follow the textbook advice of funding payouts internally Contributions 2. Enhance our understanding of motives behind payout policies ─ Firms’ reliance on financed payouts to actively manage capital structure is consistent w/ trade-off theories of capital structure ─ Evidence does not support Myers’ (1984) pecking-order prediction that “an unusually profitable firm will end up w/ unusually low debt ratio, and it won’t do much of anything about it. It won’t go out of its way to issue debt and retire equity to achieve a more normal debt ratio” 3. The COVID-19 crisis has renewed calls from policy makers and public commentators to impose restrictions on corporate payouts, in particular share repurchases (see, e.g., CARES Act, Schumer and Sanders 2019). Our paper suggests that not all payouts are created equal when it comes to their impact on financial fragility—the source of payout financing matters Sample and data • • Sample: Public firms incorporated and located in the U.S., 1989-2019 • exclude financial firms and utilities • exclude firms in year of their IPO Main variables from the statement of cash flows in Compustat – Free cash flow: operating CF + investment CF • investment CF = – capex – acquis + sale PPE – Net debt issues: max {debt issues – debt repurchases, 0} – Equity issues; follow McKeon (2015) and break down in • firm-initiated issues (SEOs and private placements) • employee-initiated issues (employee stock option exercises, warrant exercises) Focus only on “actively financed payouts”: payouts financed with simultaneous net debt or firm-initiated equity issues Payouts and security issues Dollar magnitudes (billions of 2012 $) 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 Total payout 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Repurchases & special dividends 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Regular dividends • We aggregate repurchases and special dividends as they are both part of the discretionary component of payouts (they can be cut w/ little consequence) • Repurchases account for over 97% of repurchases + special dividends • For brevity, sometimes we write “repurchases” to refer to repurch. + spec. dividends • By contrast, cutting (or even failing to increase) regular dividends tends to be perceived as costly (e.g., Brav et al. 2005) Payouts and security issues Dollar magnitudes (billions of 2012 $) 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 Total payout 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Repurchases & special dividends 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 Employee-initiated equity issues 2019 Regular dividends Dollar magnitudes (billions of 2012 $) 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 Net debt issues 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 Firm-initiated equity issues 2007 To what extent do the same firms simultaneously (in the same year) raise and pay out capital? Amount of payout that is financed (FP it) = min { Payout it, Firm-initiated issuance proceeds it } • Firm counts • Dollar magnitudes Simultaneous payouts and issues (counts) 60% % of all payout payers that simultaneously raise capital (avg. = 43%) 40% 20% % of all public firms that simultaneously raise and pay out capital (avg. = 22%) 0% 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Simultaneous payouts and issues ($) Dollar magnitudes (billions of 2012 $) 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 Total payouts financed by net debt issues Reg. dividends financed by net debt issues 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Repurchases & spec. div. financed by net debt issues Total payouts financed by firm-initiated equity issues • On average, 31% of aggregate payouts are simultaneously raised in capital markets • Financed reps are more common than financed divs, particularly in recent years • Debt is by far the most common source of payout financing Simultaneous payouts and security issues are - prevalent (43% of all payout payers) - economically large (31% of aggregate payouts) - strongly procyclical (at least until 2015) 55% are share repurchases & special dividends, 45% are regular dividends They are financed mostly with debt Not surprising: SEOs and private placements are small relative to net debt issues Still, 17% of firm-initiated equity issues are simultaneously paid out vs. 41% of net debt issues o 81% of employee-initiated equity issues are paid out Do firms that finance their payouts need to raise external capital to be able to pay out as much as they do, given their profit and investment levels? – Alternatively, it may be that firms are simply raising capital (while generating enough FCF to fund their payouts) to boost their cash reserves Payout gap (PG it) = min { max {TP it – “internal funds” it , 0}, TP it } where “internal funds” = free cash flow + cash reduction + proceeds of employeeinitiated equity issues Dollar magnitudes (billions of 2012 $) 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 Simultaneous payouts and security issues 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 Aggregate sum of total payout gaps 80% of firms that simultaneously raise and pay out capital have a payout gap, i.e., they could not have funded their payouts using their internal funds • Payout gaps are largely repurchase gaps—firms that repurchase more than they can fund with their internal funds, after paying their dividends Dollar magnitudes (billions of 2012 $) 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 Repurchase & special dividend gap 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 Regular dividend gap 2015 2017 2019 Payout gaps are not the result of timing mismatches between payouts and free cash flow (e.g., due to payout smoothing) Prevalence and magnitude of payout gaps increases if we measure gaps over 5-year intervals payouts gaps are persistent! Why do firms set payout levels above their internal funds, which they need to finance by simultaneously raising costly external capital? – The costs of doing so can be substantial. Hennessy and Whited (2007): “for large (small) firms, estimated marginal equity flotation costs start at 5.0% (10.7%) and [deadweight] bankruptcy costs equal to 8.4% (15.1%) of capital.” Just 26% of firms that debt-finance payouts have investment-grade rating Thus, there must be some offsetting benefit • We begin by examining the characteristics of firms that finance their payouts Focus on firms that finance their repurchases with debt Decision cannot be explained by reluctance to cut dividends, debt is by far the largest source of payout financing Estimate probit model, show marginal effects Firms with high leverage and high cash are less likely to finance their payouts with debt Combining payouts with debt issues allows firms to increase their (net) leverage without depleting their cash reserves (or incurring repatriation taxes) Note: If the firm is investing and growing, leverage will not explode! Regressions include industry and year FE Evolution of median target leverage deviation with and without debt-financed discretionary payouts 2% 0% -1 0 1 2 3 4 -2% -4% -6% -8% Actual target leverage deviation for firms that debt-finance their repurchases Counterfactual target leverage deviation if debt-financed repurchases were set to zero In counterfactual exercise, for debt-financed repurchases, we set – net debt issues (ND) = ND – min{Rep, ND} – repurchases (Rep) = Rep – min{Rep, ND} 5 Evolution of mean target leverage deviation with and without debt-financed discretionary payouts 6% 4% 2% 0% -1 0 1 2 3 4 -2% -4% -6% Actual target leverage deviation for firms that debt-finance their repurchases Counterfactual target leverage deviation if debt-financed repurchases were set to zero In counterfactual exercise, for debt-financed repurchases, we set – net debt issues (ND) = ND – min{Rep, ND} – repurchases (Rep) = Rep – min{Rep, ND} 5 What if firms tried to achieve same leverage increase by simply increasing their repurchases, without simultaneously raising debt? 10% 0% -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 -10% -20% -30% -40% -50% Actual cash over actual assets for firms that debt-finance their repurchases Counterfactual cash over actual assets if firms tried to attain the same leverage increases by only repurchasing more without raising any net debt – Plot shows the median; mean is even starker 81% of firms do not have enough cash to achieve the same leverage increase exclusively through payout increases! What motivates firms’ attempts to jointly manage their capital structure and their cash holdings? Corporate income taxes Repatriation taxes State-level tax increases as exogenous shocks to the demand for leverage • Following Heider and Ljungqvist (2015), we exploit staggered changes in state corporate income taxes as plausibly exogenous shocks to the value of interest tax deductions using a diff-in-diff approach ─ Issuing debt allows firms to minimize their tax bill because interest is tax deductible ─ Paying out the debt ensures that tax savings are not offset by the new taxable interest income that would be generated if firms retained the proceeds as cash • Tax increases play a significant role in explaining debt-financed payouts, but (as expected) only for firms w/ profits to shield from tax Did the 2017 TCJA decrease firms’ incentives to use debtfinanced payouts to avoid paying repatriation taxes? • The Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 (TCJA) eliminated US multinational firms’ incentives to hoard cash overseas to avoid repatriation taxes – Before the TCJA, US corporations were taxed on worldwide income. However, a US corporation could defer foreign income by retaining earnings through a foreign subsidiary – The US corporation would pay US tax on the foreign earnings only when they were repatriated. Upon repatriation, the earnings would be subject to US taxation at a rate up to 35%, with a credit for foreign taxes paid • The repatriation typically resulted in a net US tax obligation because the US tax rate was usually higher than the foreign tax rate – Debt-financed payouts allowed firms to ensure that their net leverage would not fall despite the cash held overseas. Firms could then wait for a repatriation tax holiday (like the one in 2004) to bring back foreign cash and repay debt – Pursuant to the TCJA, the US now exempts from taxation the earnings of a US firm from active foreign subsidiaries, even if the earnings are repatriated • After the TCJA came into effect in 2018, the tax cost of repatriating foreign earnings is no longer associated w/ a higher likelihood to debt-finance payouts • Dynamic results are consistent w/ the parallel trends assumption What are the consequences of debt-financed payouts? Investment reaction to industry downturns Stock price reaction to COVID-19 crisis If anything, repurchasing firms tend to invest more, even during periods of industry distress Regressions include firm and year FE If anything, repurchasing firms tend to invest more, even during periods of industry distress The same is not true for firms whose repurchases are debtfinanced Regressions include firm and year FE If anything, repurchasing firms tend to invest more, even during periods of industry distress The same is not true for firms whose repurchases are debtfinanced Debt-financed repurchases lead to −0.6 p.p. less investment following periods of industry distress Regressions include firm and year FE If anything, repurchasing firms tend to invest more, even during periods of industry distress The same is not true for firms whose repurchases are debtfinanced Debt-financed repurchases lead to −0.6 p.p. less investment following periods of industry distress No significant effect for firms w/ an investment-grade rating Debt-financed repurchases are associated w/ a deeper stock price decline during the COVID-19 crisis This finding is exclusive to debtfinanced repurchases. Cash-flow financed repurchases are not associated w/ deeper stock declines. This likely explains the insignificant findings found by Fahlenbrach, Rageth, and Stulz (2020) Debt-financed repurchases are associated w/ a deeper stock price decline during the COVID-19 crisis This finding is exclusive to debtfinanced repurchases. Cash-flow financed repurchases are not associated w/ deeper stock declines. This likely explains the insignificant findings found by Fahlenbrach, Rageth, and Stulz (2020) Again, no significant effect for firms w/ an investment-grade rating Conclusions • The commonly held view in the payout literature that payouts are first and foremost a vehicle to returns free cash flow to investors payouts should be set “low enough to avoid expensive future external financing” (Ross et al. 2013) is incomplete • • Payouts that are financed with simultaneous debt or equity issues are – prevalent: 43% of payout payers do so – large in magnitude: 31% of aggregate payouts are financed – persistent – take the form of both repurchases (55%) and dividends (45%) Payout financing is an important use of the capital firms raise: – 41% of aggregate proceeds of net debt issues – 17% of aggregate proceeds of firm-initiated equity issues are simultaneously paid out Conclusions • We show that firms use debt-financed payouts to jointly manage their capital structure and cash holdings, motivated, in particular, by tax considerations • We show that not all payouts are created equal when it comes to their impact on financial fragility—the source of payout financing matters Our findings highlight that firms’ liquidity, capital structure, and payout policies are closely related Important to study them jointly!