See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/314585222 Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment. Article in Academy of Management Review · October 2004 DOI: 10.5465/AMR.2004.14497675 CITATIONS READS 52 6,262 1 author: William P. Bottom Washington University in St. Louis 93 PUBLICATIONS 4,323 CITATIONS SEE PROFILE All content following this page was uploaded by William P. Bottom on 19 September 2018. The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file. Review Reviewed Work(s): Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment by Thomas Gilovich, Dale Griffin and Daniel Kahneman Review by: William P. Bottom Source: The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 29, No. 4 (Oct., 2004), pp. 695-698 Published by: Academy of Management Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/20159081 Accessed: 19-09-2018 11:51 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Academy of Management is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Academy of Management Review This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Wed, 19 Sep 2018 11:51:21 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 2004 ?ooJc Reviews 695 dangers. But the topic, particularly in light of the consensus that the full impact of the internet will depend on political choices yet to be made, could have had a greater presence than it does. sions. The papers that ultimately made it through the screening process are grouped into three major sections. Eleven papers reflecting New Theoretical Directions are sandwiched be tween twenty-one papers devoted to Theoretical and Empirical Extensions and ten devoted to Real World Applications. Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology o? Intuitive Judgment edited by Thomas Gilovich, Dale Griffin, and Daniel Kahne man. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002. Reviewed by William P. Bottom, Washington Univer sity, St. Louis, Missouri. Individuals cope with the uncertainty and complexity of their personal and professional lives by using a small number of general purpose heuristics for simplifying judgments and making decisions. These tools work reason ably well and save time and effort, but they also lead to predictable errors. In Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, published back in 1982, Daniel Kahneman, Paul Slovic, and Amos Tversky collected a set of papers that re flected the growing body of research exploring That distribution of papers is indicative of the major emphasis and strength of the book? basic psychological theory. Early chapters are devoted to revisiting each of the three major general-purpose heuristics from Judgment Un der Uncertainty. These chapters reinforce the relevance and importance of availability, an choring, and representativeness but also pro vide a very different perspective on their opera tion and interplay. Two broad themes emerge. The first is the recognition that judgment is ul timately the product of the interplay between two distinctive cognitive systems. The "two-systems" concept elaborates on the distinction that Tversky and Kahneman (origi nally 1984, Chapter 1 here) drew between exten sional reasoning based on the logic of probabil ity and intuitive reasoning based on heuristics. Gilovich and Griffin ("Heuristics and Biases: Then and Now"), Kahneman and Frederick ("Representativeness Revisited"), Sloman ("Two this simple yet powerful idea. The papers in Systems of Reasoning"), and Stanovich and extending, and challenging the logic of the tuition and deliberation will be essential to West ("Individual Differences in Reasoning") di rectly address the evidence for this interpreta ability, representativeness, and anchoring and tion. They also show that dual-process theories adjustment. The book proved instrumental in of cognition that treat the individual as a cogni tive miser are not adequate. System One output spreading the application of behavioral deci sion theory to diverse fields such as law, medi is not simply switched off by raising the incen cine, economics, and management. It also gen tives high enough to activate System Two. Un derstanding the dynamic interplay between in erated an outpouring of new research probing, Judgment Under Uncertainty address the opera tion of three general-purpose heuristics: avail "heuristics and biases program." In Heuristics and Biases, Thomas Gilovich, Dale Griffin, and Daniel Kahneman have pulled together a new collection of papers reflecting those develop ments. The Nobel Prize in Economic Science awarded better explaining and predicting judgment. In "Representativeness Revisited," Kahneman and Frederick reinterpret heuristics as a general to Kahneman in 2002 is certainly one indicator of the tremendous impact of heuristics and biases research. The high quality of the papers in this book is another. The still larger number of sig judgment. This attribute substitution is the prod uct of the associative, rapid, and parallel infor mation processing in the intuitive System One. Similarity judgment based on prototype match ing?the process at work in the representative ness heuristic?is but one such attribute substi tution process. Like other System One output, it nificant papers that could have been included may actually be the best measure of all. The editors' task must have been a challenging one, and readers will undoubtedly have varying opinions about particular choices and omis process of "attribute substitution" in which a target judgment is effortlessly and automati cally made by substituting a simpler, natural can sometimes be partially overridden by the controlled, deductive, serial, self-aware, and This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Wed, 19 Sep 2018 11:51:21 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 696 Academy of Management Review October rule-based System Two. Kahneman and Freder accurate. These authors show that a simple rule, operation. Gilbert ("Inferential Correction") elaborates most valid of many available cues, is a form of problem simplification that exceeds the predic tive performance of simple linear rules and even ick reinterpret anchoring not as an intuitive heu ristic but as a much more foundational cognitive on this conclusion, tying anchoring back into the two-systems framework. Rather than serving as an alternative to availability or representative ness, Gilbert sees anchoring as "the process by which the human mind does virtually all its inferential work" (p. 167). That is, the noncon scious System One output forms the anchor, which System Two may or may not subse quently correct. The attribute substitution pro cess generating that anchor could be availabil ity or similarity. This new interpretation is consistent with the review of empirical evidence that Chapman and Johnson report on the impact of experimentally manipulated anchors ("An chors in Judgments of Belief and Value"), which "points to anchors as a type of memory prompt or prime to activate target information similar to the anchor" (p. 133). Mental laziness is not what creates bias from anchoring and adjustment?a commonly held view in the past. It is the biased search (either of memory or external sources) the anchor directs that skews judgment. The second major theme of the selections in this volume is the belated recognition that intu ition can be neither explained nor predicted without considering the role of affect, mood, and emotion. The papers in Judgment Under Uncer tainty are primarily experiments on affect neutral cognition. In "The Affect Heuristic," Slovic, Finucane, Peters, and MacGregor begin to redress this oversight. They review both pre viously neglected and new evidence indicating that a general feeling of goodness or badness associated with a given stimulus automatically substitutes for such target attributes of judg ment as attractiveness, risk, and willingness to pay. Like availability or prototype matching, this automatic response from the intuitive sys tem can generate judgments that may or may not be overridden by rule-based deliberation. The two-systems concept also reconciles the heuristics and biases program with other con ceptions of rationality that appeared as cri tiques of Judgment Under Uncertainty. As Gig erenzer, Czerlinski, and Martignon demonstrate ("How Good Are Fast and Frugal Heuristics?"), many rules-of-thumb for decision making are not only simple and fast but also remarkably such as "take the best," which uses only the some multiple regression models. But these rules-of-thumb and Simon's notion of satisficing constitute System Two heuristics. These are con scious strategies that are deliberately chosen because of self-awareness of one's own mental capabilities. They are not the product of auto matic intuition, although they frequently entail the decision maker's conscious and very clever recruitment and manipulation of intuitive Sys tem One output. Two important parts of the book are less com plete and therefore less satisfactory. In their in troduction to the book, Gilovich and Griffin pro vide a selected history of this field of research. They trace the antecedents of Kahneman and Tversky's work back as far as Meehl's empirical studies of clinical judgment, Edward's labora tory tests of Bayesian updating, and Simon's theoretical work on bounded rationality. This is certainly accurate as to recent influences. But an accurate history of the representativeness and availability heuristics would acknowledge the contribution of Walter Lippmann (1922, 1927) in redefining a term that originally referred to a process in which "a solid plate.. .is used for printing from instead of the forme [sic] itself" (Oxford English Dictionary [2nd ed.]) to mean "the pictures in our heads." The ingenious dem onstrations of the representativeness heuristic, such as "the Linda problem" (is Linda more likely to be "a bank teller" or "a bank teller who is also a feminist"?), amply confirm Lippmann's proposition that we make judgments by noticing "a trait which marks a well known type, and fill in the rest of the picture by means of the stereo types we carry about in our heads" (1922: 59). Lippmann's work, in which he notes that "the opportunities for manipulation open to anyone who understands the process are plain enough" (1922: 158), was based neither on armchair theo rizing nor on laboratory experimentation. This was an inductive theory-building exercise in which the former Army information officer, former foreign policy adviser to Woodrow Wil son, and future adviser to Presidents Hoover, Roosevelt, Truman, Eisenhower, Kennedy, and Johnson described the way in which bounded rationality, representativeness, availability, This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Wed, 19 Sep 2018 11:51:21 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 2004 Book Reviews 697 and egocentric bias had distorted peace negoti work demonstrated, this was never truly an is ations with Germany and the former Ottoman sue. Practice in the field by those who "under Empire (Bottom, 2003a). This process ultimately stood the process well enough" was consider generated a vindictive but unenforceable treaty, ably ahead of theory in 1922 and arguably still which was "not wise, which was partly impos well ahead of it today. Collecting together pa sible, and which threatened the life of Europe" pers on important applied problems that have (Keynes; cited in Bottom, 2003b: 4). Lippmann's drawn on the insights of cognitive heuristics theory was also based on personal practice?his would have shed much needed light on the gen earlier contribution to the propaganda cam eral social, organizational, and policy implica paign that manufactured consent for an Ameri tions of basic theory. can crusade against "the Hun" in Europe. Just before the recent scandal among profes Were the history of these concepts better sional accounting firms broke, Bazerman and known, the authors might have constructed a Loewenstein (2001) used heuristics and biases to more complete section on Real World Applica note the impossibility of truly independent au tions. My initial interpretation of this section led dits. Roll (1986) highlighted the way in which me to believe that the editors had compiled systematic miscalibration of probability has some of the many important social problems fueled the explosive growth of the market in that have been illuminated by research on heu mergers and acquisitions, in spite of the disap ristics. Some of the papers in this section do fit pointing track record of such corporate transac that interpretation. De Bondt and Thaler use tions. Pogarsky and Babcock (2001) showed how heuristics to predict and explain systematic anchoring undermines the intended rationale bias among professional security analysts. The for policies that would cap the size of legal scandals plaguing the industry in recent years claims. And Kuran and Sunnstein (1999) pre mark this paper, originally published in 1990 in sented a series of case studies, including the the American Economic Review, as both pre Alar controversy, on what they call "availability scient and of continuing relevance to policy makers and investors. Koehler, Brenner, and entrepreneurs"?those who capitalize on the workings of the availability heuristic to manip Griffin provide a new and comprehensive re ulate public discourse so they can further a view of studies of the judgmental calibration of given social agenda. Lippmann, a very able professional experts. This study should be es availability entrepreneur, would have recog sential reading for those interested in under nized these as further evidence of the opportu standing when and under what circumstances nities for manipulation open to those who un overconfidence is likely to arise among experi derstand how to manufacture consent. enced professionals. The limitations of historical context and real However, several of the papers might have world application aside, this new collection of been better placed in other sections of the book. Gilovich, Vallone, and Tversky's study of the papers should rapidly become a staple for doc toral courses in cognitive psychology, social misperception of streaks of consecutive made psychology, economics, and various profes shots in basketball is an essential study of rep resentativeness, which the editors could have sional fields, including management. Research ers in those fields who are looking for an ad included in the section Theoretical and Empiri cal Extensions. Medvec, Madey, and Gilovich's vanced reference work on the subject will study of regret among Olympic medallists certainly want to add this to their library. Even would have made an excellent addition to the those who already have a number of the previ section New Theoretical Directions. The under ously published papers will welcome having them in one compact source. They will also wel lying interest in grouping together these papers come the many new and important contributions in the concluding section appears to be in dem to our understanding of the psychology of intu onstrating empirically that heuristics generate itive judgment crafted just for this volume. The bias in a nonlaboratory context. theory building begun by Lippmann, the work The justification would seem to be a perceived need to demonstrate that these biases exist in collected in Judgment Under Uncertainty, and "the real world"?that they are not simply a lab the contributions in this new book have begun to oratory curiosity. As Lippmann's very grounded permit social science to catch up to practice. This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Wed, 19 Sep 2018 11:51:21 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 698 Academy of Management Review October REFERENCES Bazerman, M. H., & Loewenstein, G. 2001. Taking the bias out of bean counting. Harvard Business Review, 79(1): 28. Bottom, W. P. 2003a. Keynes' attack on the Versailles Treaty: An early investigation of the consequences of bounded rationality, framing, and cognitive illusions. Interna tional Negotiation, 8: 367-402. Bottom, W. P. 2003b. Smoke and mirrors: Cognitive illusions and the origins of appeasement at the Paris Peace Con ference. Paper presented at the International Biennale on Negotiation, Paris. De Bondt, W. F. M., & Thaler, R. H. 1990. Do security analysts overreact? American Economic Review, 80(2): 52-57. Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. 1982. Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge: Cam bridge University Press. Kuran, T., & Sunnstein, C. R. 1999. Availability cascades and risk regulation. Stanford Law Review, 51: 683-768. Lippmann, W. 1922. Public opinion. New York: Macmillan. Lippmann, W. 1927. The phantom public. New York: Mac millan. Pogarsky, G.# & Babcock, L. 2001. Damage caps, motivated anchoring, and bargaining impasse. Journal of Legal Studies, 30: 143-159. Roll, R. 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business, 59: 197-216. Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. 1984. Extensional versus intui tive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy in probability judgment. Psychological Review, 91: 293-315. Mind Your Own Business, by Sidney Harman. New York: Random House, 2003. Reviewed by Mustafa ?zbilgin, University of Surrey, Guildford, United Kingdom.1 There has been a proliferation of biographies recounting "leadership and management suc cess" from prescriptive and "best practice" per spectives, promising the replication of such suc cess to their readers. Sidney Harman's Mind Your Own Business is an autobiographical work, which does not fit in this genre. In this text Harman takes us through his journey of key learning events and episodes of epiphany in business, leadership, and life, recounting sto ries from his multifaceted life as an entrepre 11 thank Fin?la Kerrigan for her valuable suggestions on earlier drafts of this review. View publication stats neur, businessman, leader, public servant, so cial agent, citizen, and sportsman. Harman, the founder of a very successful international busi ness, Harman International, which specializes in high-fidelity audio systems, is a self proclaimed business maverick of over sixty years. Playing the devil's advocate, one may ask whether this old maverick has passed his time for learning new tricks. Harman belies the vul gar phrase "You can't teach an old dog new tricks," advocating just the opposite?a way of doing business informed by both academic and practitioner knowledge and sensemaking with entrepreneurial spirit supported by a strong eth ical stance. The book is a tribute to his experi ences of venturing with values, advocating a "new old" (p. 4) business perspective that con siders values an essential ingredient of busi ness conduct. Sidney Harman narrates his experiences in an unpretentious and accessible manner, free from management jargon. The book will appeal to an audience of entrepreneurs, business practitio ners, management biographers, and business studies academics with an interest in biograph ical works and discourse analysis of autobio graphical narratives. Through the successful use of storytelling techniques, the book demon strates that it is possible to envisage a princi pled business life informed by human values. The storytelling technique by which the book is written generates vignettes providing deep un derstanding of many issues. The vignettes in the text are suitable for use as a point of discussion in teaching a wide range of business manage ment subjects. These narratives provide time less insights into some very pertinent issues, including the significance of enterprising and human aspects of employment relations, mar keting, finance, negotiation, and linkages with social life. Reconciling entrepreneurial enthusi asm with a genuine concern for stakeholder welfare appears to be the main stance Sidney Harman takes in this book, and this is, at the same time, the main distinguishing attribute of the book. In the age of corporate greed and scan dals, this book, with its timely call for business with values, is as rare as rain in a desert. The book is based on self-reporting of lived experience. The subjective nature of the ac counts offered and the possibility of post hoc rationalization in presentation of life histories may appear, at first sight, to be the weakness of This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Wed, 19 Sep 2018 11:51:21 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms