British Oil: The Myth of Independence Author(s): Lawrence Freedman Source: The World Today, Vol. 34, No. 8 (Aug., 1978), pp. 287-295 Published by: Royal Institute of International Affairs Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/40395062 Accessed: 07-05-2016 05:54 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Royal Institute of International Affairs is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The World Today This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms British oil : the myth of independence LAWRENCE FREEDMAN lIn thinking of ways and means to enjoy the feast to come, it is important to keep in mind the famine to follow' The purpose of this article is to raise some issues concerning the impact of North Sea oil on Britain's external relations, a matter somewhat less discussed than the impact on domestic economic management. More specifically, the aim is to examine a common presumption that access to substantial indigenous oil and gas supplies and the consequent economic benefits will strengthen Britain's international position. The benefits of North Sea fuels to the British economy are now being put into perspective. The effects are by no means trivial. According to Government figures, by the mid-1980s the help to the balance of payments will be some £8 billion, with about half that amount going to the Government as extra revenue. But for an economy the size of Britain's these figures only represent a few percentage points of GNP. However wisely the extra income is spent it will not create the conditions for an economic 'miracle' in Britain.1 It cannot compensate for weak performances by the rest of British industry or for slow growth in international markets. In what promises to be a difficult period for all members of the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Britain may notice an improvement in its relative position while still failing to achieve the high growth rates that have proved so elusive in the past. Furthermore, the benefits will be most marked during the 1980s, as the level of production will steadily decline in the following decade. In thinking of ways and means to enjoy the feast to come, it is important to keep in mind the famine to follow. If Britain's economy can be strengthened, its international standing will no doubt improve. It will no longer always be the patient at gatherings of bankers and finance ministers nor the first to blush when the hat is passed round to fund some international initiative. The corollary of this 1 For a full discussion of the economic impact, see Sheila Page, 'The value and distribution of North Sea oil and gas, 1970-1985', National Institute Economic Review t No. 82, November 1977. The author is Research Fellow at the Royal Institute of International Affairs. This article is based on a paper first prepared in connexion with Chatham House's current project on 'British Foreign Policy to 1985'. It appears simultaneously in German in Europa- Archiv, Verlag für Internationale Politik, GmbH (Bonn) and in Dutch in Internationale Spectator (The Hague). 287 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE WORLD TODAY August 1978 will also be true. Others will be less impressed by any special pleading on Britain's behalf. The appearance of economic strength, at least relative to past British performance, may contain a long-term danger of over- extension. With more revenue at hand, the Government might be tempted to accept commitments which involve some financial outlay that will be difficult to sustain when the oil wells start to run dry. The recent White Paper on North Sea oil noted how it could put Britain in 'a stronger position to discharge her international responsibilities, not least in relation to developing countries'.2 Dr Luns, Nato's Secretary-General, has already put in a claim for some of the oil revenue on behalf of the defence budget. The major foreign policy benefit normally associated with North Sea oil is the prospect of the release from dependence on the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (Opee). Alone amongst its major partners and allies, Britain will enjoy secure supplies of oil sufficient to meet local demand. This, it is hoped, will spare Britain the need to placate the Arab states and offers the opportunity to avoid the worst ravages of the coming tightness of world oil supply. Because of the importance of these assumptions to estimates of Britain's international strength they need to be examined with care. The coming energy crisis Oil has come to be considered a particularly precious resource because of the existence of a powerful cartel capable of determining its price beyond that justified by production costs or available supplies, because of the considerable role it plays in meeting most countries' energy needs (some 40 per cent in the case of Britain) and because world reserves are finite. In the future there will have to be less reliance on oil. There is concern that alternative energy sources cannot be introduced with sufficient speed to fill this gap. A number of authoritative projections have suggested that well before the end of this century, some would say before 1985, the rate of production of oil will fail to match potential world demand. This will result in energy starvation for those consumers unable to meet the inevitable price increases. If the market mechanism works imperfectly in such a situation there could be severe economic dislocations, as some countries continue to consume more than they can afford. There will be considerable competition amongst those who can pay to secure supplies.3 The timing of such a crisis and the validity of this whole scenario have been the subject of disputes usually bound up with issues in energy 2 Prime Minister and others, The Cliallenge of North Sea Oil (London : HMSO, March 1978), Cmnd. 7143. 3 On some of the political consequences of a severe tightening of oil supply, see Working Paper on International Energy Supply:. A Perspective from the Industrial World (New York: The Rockefeller Foundation, May 1978). 288 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms BRITISH OIL politics. On the production side, much depends on the willingness of Saudi Arabia to sell oil above the levels required for the purposes of its economic development. Uncertainties on the demand side include the degree of American dependence on imported oil, the possibility of the Eastern bloc finding it necessary to purchase oil on the world market, the success of conservation measures, progress with new, alternative energy sources and the speed and scale of world economic recovery. If recovery continues to be slow and if energy conservation measures prove to be effective, the crunch could be postponed. Certainly in the short term, with demand still depressed and new fields coming on stream, in Alaska as well as the North Sea, there is, if anything, a glut of oil. Estimates from the Department of Energy suggest that there will be ample supplies over the next few years, and that by 1985 there will still be 'substantial spare capacity even at the top end of the demand range'. By the late 1980s or early 1990s, however, supplies are liable to be tightening.4 The North Sea oil fields were hurried into production because of the need for a boost to the economy and because of a desire, after the traumas of 1973-4, for a measure of energy self-sufficiency. This was not a response to a long-term supply problem but to a short-term embargo and a well-organized cartel. As things stand, production from the main fields will peak in the early or mid-1980s, and decline steadily from the early 1990s. According to the above projections, this peak is coming too early. If we could (i) delay, and (ii) stretch out production of North Sea oil, the later barrels could be meeting an urgent need and be commanding a much higher premium. (Some expect world energy prices to double or even treble over the next 20 years.) There may therefore be a financial, as well as an energy supply argument for slowing down the depletion rate of our reserves. Tomorrow's gain, of course, will have to be significantly higher than today's gain to compensate for the loss of a long-term boost to the economy and a full return on investment. There might then be doubts over whether it is wise to forgo undoubted and tangible benefits to the balance of payments and potentially the structure of the economy now for the sake of surviving a hypothetical threat in the 1990s. There are also technical factors. Each field has an optimum production profile based on the natural rate of flow of its oil. Excessive interference in order to acceler- ate or restrict production will involve some costs. Though there are a number of tactics available to the Government for delaying some production, its freedom of manœuvre is not great. In 1974, in order to encourage production, a number of assurances were made to 4 Department of Energy, Energy Policy: A Consultative Document (London: HMSO, February 1978), Cmnd 7101, pp. 8-13. US estimates are more pessi- mistic, suggesting that demand might exceed supply as early as 1981 and that a substantial gap could develop by 1 985 . The International Energy Agency ( IE A) has recently forecast a notional demand gap of 4-12 million barrels per day by 1985. 289 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE WORLD TODAY August 1978 the companies, including one that no delays would be imposed on finds made up to the end of 1975. The effect of these assurances removes onehalf to two-thirds of known reserves from imposed delays. It is therefore unlikely that depletion rate controls will be able to shift the period of peak production by a significant amount; it is more likely that they will be used to ease the transition period out of net self-sufficiency. However, in practice, delays caused by bad weather and technical problems are already providing inadvertent depletion controls. In addition, there is now some evidence that wrangles over participation agreements plus new fields taking longer to appraise than did the first 14 'have made it seem less likely than formerly that production will build up to a fairly sharp peak in the early 1980s'.5 Commercial exploitation of new fields will be to a considerable extent determined by developments in the price of oil, and will thus be responsive to the general world supply situation. Though a large proportion of the oil will have been used up before the 'energy crisis' arrives, if it does arrive, Britain can expect a smoother passage than others through its early stages. Energy independence The sense of immunity to serious supply disruption, encouraged by the use of such words as 'energy independence' and 'self-sufficiency' in discussions of North Sea oil, is not justified. That the oil will only be available for a limited period is not particularly relevant. Ten years may be a short time for energy planners, but it is still a long time in politics. By the 1990s, the political demands from the Middle East may have taken on a different character. The main danger is of over-estimating the extent to which Britain can ever be independent. It is too much a part of the international economy not to feel the reverberations of any crisis afflicting its partners. Furthermore, Britain will still need to import substantial amounts of oil from the Middle East. This is because North Sea oil produces 'light' crudes which command a high price on overseas markets but are not particularly suitable for many British refineries unless mixed in proportions of 35:65 with heavier Middle Eastern crude. There is therefore an economic argument for exporting a substantial percentage of North Sea output. The official policy is to refine up to two-thirds of North Sea oil in UK refineries. This has been interpreted with some flexibility: in the past year, over 40 per cent of North Sea oil has been exported. Some of the oil companies are arguing that as much as 50 per cent of the oil should be exported and others would say more. The Government has indicated a desire to enhance genuine selfsufficiency through the expansion of refinery capacity from the current 136 m. tons to 150 m. tons. As with some Opee states, there is an interest in more down-stream processing so as to increase the value of an in5 ibid. , p. 35. 290 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms BRITISH OIL digenous raw material. Unfortunately there is considerable over-capacity in European, let alone world, refineries. In consequence, opportunities in this sphere will be limited. The European Commission has been pressing for a reduction of European refinery capacity, desiring to shut down plants that are elderly, environmentally inadequate and situated in areas of high concentration of refineries. This plan has a number of problems, one of which is the reluctance of the British Government to contemplate cuts, arguing for an entitlement to a greater share of this industry by virtue of the North Sea production. Yet while existing British refineries are only used to the extent of some 60 per cent, to refine the 'light' North Sea crudes properly would require new plants. Furthermore, processing North Sea oil in British refineries could be more expensive than in existing European plants, as there will be a need in costing to ensure a return on capital investment. A final point is that the value added by refining may well be less than the lost premium of 'light* crudes on world markets. One London stockbroking firm has argued that the cost of insisting on a rigid refine-at-home policy could be as much as £163 m. by 1980. Out of recognition of the danger of losing the premium value of North Sea crude there are now signs that the Government accepts the limits on a refine-at-home policy for the medium term. However, the Government still appears to be unwilling to forgo the possibility of an expansion of refinery capacity. In the meeting of EEC energy ministers late in May, British resistance was a factor preventing agreement on refinery cut-backs. This was done for reasons of principle concerning national sovereignty, rather than because of interference with immediate plans. The Commission has indicated that it is not seeking to abort the two new refineries already planned by Britain. One cost incurred by Britain for taking this negative stand was the rejection by Italy, which is anxious to get subsidies to ease cut-backs in its excess refinery capacity, of a scheme to subsidize the use of EEC-produced coal in power stations. This scheme would have benefited Britain. There are other areas where a strict 'refine-at-home' policy will cause conflict with the Community. It could well fall foul of Article 34 of the Treaty of Rome which forbids quantitative restrictions on trade between members. If another EEC member were willing to pay more for available oil, the British would be obliged to let it go.6 Insistence that all North Sea oil must be landed on British territory unless a special waiver is given by the Energy Secretary is currently being investigated by the Commission as an impediment to free trade within the Community. The Government appears to be ready to accept irritated relations with the Commission and its EC partners in the energy field in order to safeguard a principle that economic common sense suggests ought not to be exercised. 6 See N. J. D. Lucas, Energy and the European Communities (London : Europa Publications, 1977), pp. 122-3. 291 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE WORLD TODAY August 1978 Security against embargoes If Britain still has to meet up to half its oil needs by imports, even though exporting an equal or greater amount, then it will not be insensitive to sudden cut-offs of oil from the Middle East. It is only becoming significantly less dependent on those Opee members which produce crude oil of a comparable quality: Libya and Nigeria. Even without dependence on oil supplies there would remain a number of very good reasons, pertaining to trade and investment, why it would want to keep on good terms with the major Opee countries. Some concern has been expressed over the effect of a decline in imports of Nigerian oil, plus competition for markets for light crudes, on Nigerian attitudes towards the large trade surplus in Britain's favour. Under International Energy Agency (IEA) and EEC arrangements Britain is expected to prepare for an embargo. Such preparations involve maintaining emergency stocks and agreeing on distribution of available supplies in the event of a crisis. Emergency stocks are held in the inventories of the companies. These currently involve some 17 million tons of oil stores at an annual cost of some £55 m. With North Sea oil there is an argument for developing a deliberate amount of 'shut-in' production which could be released in an emergency. This would make particular sense in connexion with a depletion rate policy designed to stretch out the life-span of the oil reserves.7 Under the IEA Britain is expected to hold an 'emergency self-sufficiency capability* so as to be able to endure a total denial of net imports for 70 days at a level of 90 per cent of normal demand. IEA rules permit Britain to maintain a considerable amount of this capability in shut-in production. The second important feature of the IEA arrangements concerns the distribution of North Sea oil in the event of a serious disruption of supply from the Middle East. In such a situation it might be possible, for a limited period and inefficiently, to divert to British refineries oil intended for export. Under any circumstances, this would irritate deprived consumers. Under IEA arrangements, there is not even an incentive to consider such an action. With the first 10 per cent of cuts afflicting the IEA countries, Britain would be expected to reduce its own consumption by 10 per cent (though some of this could be avoided by using stockpiles or spare production). In allocating the burden of cuts above the 10 per cent level, credit will be given for the level of Britain's oil production, whether or not the oil produced is being exported from or refined in the UK. The higher the level 7 The political disadvantages of this policy have been pointed out in an unpublished paper by Ed Krapels on 'Oil and Security in Great Britain*. With a conventional stockpile, Britain would not stand out from other IEA members in the response to an embargo. With shut-in production, it would be able to make a distinctive response. By increasing oil production, as would undoubtedly be requested by its partners, Britain could be seen by those imposing the embargo to be making a determined effort to break it and could thus become a target for further attempted sanctions. 292 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms BRITISH OIL of production the greater the supply right. Britain thus has a clear interest in the IEA because, if the IEA allocation scheme works, the fact that so much of North Sea oil will be exported will be discounted in determining its supply right. In return Britain is expected to maintain 'normal supply patterns'. EEC contingency planning has tended to follow the guidelines of the IEA. A Council Directive of February 1977 spoke of the need to maintain traditional trade patterns' in the event of an emergency. The main difference has been in stricter stockpiling requirements. A 1968 Directive requires the maintenance of stocks equivalent to 90 days' consumption. An exemption of 15 per cent was made to take account of indigenous oil production. The British have been pressing for a greater exemption and last December the Commission responded by proposing that this should be increased to 40 per cent, bringing the minimum level of stocks down to 54 days' consumption. However, this concession applies to all member states and is based on a view of North Sea oil as a Community rather than a particularly British resource. In order to justify an all-round reduction of stocks the Commission proposes that 'normal supply flows of these crudes and products between Member States shall be maintained in the event of supply difficulties'. That is, whatever the difficulties Britain was facing in securing its regular imports of crude and products, the volume of exports to member states should be maintained. The only credit Britain would get would be determined by the normal supply of oil to home refineries (so increasing the security argument for building up indigenous refinery capacity). A more serious problem is that the attempt to maintain supply flows to EEC states could well conflict with attempts to maintain supply patterns with all IEA states. In 1977, only 58 per cent of Britain's oil exports went to the EEC, with 29 per cent going to North America and 11 per cent to non-EEC Scandinavia. The EEC proposals require Britain to take a greater share of any Community burden but they raise the prospect of some of this burden being imposed on the rest of the IEA, and in particular the United States. The Commission proposal allows for some flexibility in that 'supplies may be adjusted in accordance with decisions which have been taken at Community level'. It is doubtful that the British Government will be enthusiastic about handing over decision power on the distribution of North Sea oil to the Community. There is a further question as to the wisdom of attempting to make difficult decisions about burden-sharing, which might well involve non-EEC states, in the midst of a crisis rather than rely on the politically less controversial approach of maintaining normal supply patterns. Britain as an oil-exporting state Because of the IEA measures and the growing interest of the oil pro293 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms THE WORLD TODAY August 1978 ducers in the economic health of the West, many people doubt whether the oil weapon will ever be used again as it was in 1973. With progress towards a Middle East settlement still slow, a certain amount of contingency planning would seem to be prudent. Britain has to work out the responsibilities imposed by its status as an exporter in such a scenario. As we have seen, the current economic argument lies strongly with exporting in normal times a substantial proportion of North Sea oil. Under IEA rules, there is no strong counter-balancing security argument in favour of a refine-at-home policy though there could be one if the latest Commission proposals are accepted.8 So long as Britain does have oil to sell it will have some sort of lever in international relations, especially if there is more of a sellers' market during the 1980s. Decisions about who is to get how much of North Sea oil could prove to be quite difficult during the coming decade. For the moment, few firm decisions on either the level or distribution of exports appear to have been made. Oil companies have been discouraged from signing long-term contracts for refining North Sea oil abroad and any contracts have been scrutinized carefully. Some sort of policy is required. How responsive should Britain be to the desire of its European partners for privileged access to North Sea oil? West Germany is already deliberately importing more oil from Britain in the belief that this will be a more 'stable' supply.9 To what extent can the high United States demand for 'light* crude be satisfied at the expense of European demand? Are there any means by which North Sea oil could help Britain gain secure supplies of the oil it will need to import? A proposal by Venezuela has been reported in which Venezuelan 'heavy* crude would be swapped for British 'light* crude. What can the Community offer Britain in return for privileged access? With oil having to sell at a discount at the moment, there is still interest in a guaranteed minimum price. Another possibility might be Community subsidies to help finance the exploitation of the more marginal fields. British ministers have hinted, often in a jocular mood, at future membership of Opee. Already Britain exports as much as some of the smaller members of Opee. There are no self-evident reasons why Britain should 8 However, as explained earlier, an expansion of British refinery capacity would contradict Community attempts to cut back capacity. 8 Some 7 per cent of the Federal Republic s oil needs were satished by British crude in 1977. This percentage could double in 1978 : Financial Times , 5 January 1978. German confidence in the stability of this source may have been dented by the argument over the freedom of the German Deminex consortium to dispose of its oil from the North Sea Thistle Field as it wishes. In June a deal was an- nounced between British Petroleum and the German Veba group (which has a 54 per cent stake in the Deminex consortium) by which British Petroleum agreed to assure Veba of supplies of 3 million tonnes of oil per annum for the next 20 years at competitive prices in return for greater penetration of the German market for products. However, the oil involved is to come from the Middle East and not the North Sea. 294 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms BRITISH OIL want to join the organization. It would merely have a symbolic significance - an identification with one of the world's major power blocs. But, apart from oil matters, Britain does not share many interests with other members of Opee. (In fact, because oil exports are not the predominant source of national wealth Britain would not qualify for membership.) Furthermore, its influence within the organization would be small. Its contribution to world production is too small (at most, it will be about 4 per cent) to make a lot of difference on a global scale, though it could well make a difference on a regional scale. It has been content in the past to accept the international price set by Opee as the basis for its own prices without being seen to be in any way responsible for the level of that price Its major interests lie with the world's oil consumers rather than the oil producers. The British Government has made its belief known that North Sea oil creates distinctive British interests that need careful protection. Such interests do exist, but they are not overriding. The autarchic instincts betrayed by the Government when it comes to oil have resulted in controversy within the Community for stakes that are not particularly large. Some of the economic benefits to be gained by net self-sufficiency would be lost in any attempt to make this self-sufficiency absolute, without there being any compensating security benefits. The most important point is that, even with independence in oil supplies, Britain will still be depen- dent on the rest of the world for trade and other raw materials. If the oil is to be used to regenerate British industry, the regenerated industries will need markets. Though in a crisis it may give satisfaction to be relatively better off than others, if its major trading partners are suffering then Britain will suffer too. Table i Forecast of United Kingdom Continental Shelf Oil Production Year 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 Forecast production (m. tonnes) 38 55-65 80-95 90-110 100-120 105-125 Source: Department of Energy, Development of the oil and gas resources of the United Kingdom 1978 (London : HMSO, April 1978), p. 3. 295 This content downloaded from 130.113.111.210 on Sat, 07 May 2016 05:54:55 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms