Applied Financial Economics ISSN: 0960-3107 (Print) 1466-4305 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rafe20 Project finance loan spreads and disaggregated political risk Claudia Girardone & Stuart Snaith To cite this article: Claudia Girardone & Stuart Snaith (2011) Project finance loan spreads and disaggregated political risk, Applied Financial Economics, 21:23, 1725-1734, DOI: 10.1080/09603107.2011.577006 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/09603107.2011.577006 Published online: 27 Jul 2011. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 655 View related articles Citing articles: 5 View citing articles Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rafe20 Applied Financial Economics, 2011, 21, 1725–1734 Project finance loan spreads and disaggregated political risk Claudia Girardone and Stuart Snaith* Essex Business School, University of Essex, Wivenhoe Park, Colchester, CO4 3SQ, UK This article provides novel evidence on project finance loan pricing using economic and disaggregated political risk determinants. As expected, our findings suggest that the presence of loan guarantees and lower levels of aggregate political risk results in cheaper project finance loans. The evidence in support of disaggregated political risk as a pricing determinant is negligible for developed countries, but significant for developing countries. For the latter we find that loan spreads are negatively related to the effectiveness, quality and strength of a country’s legal and institutional systems whilst lower levels of government stability and democratic accountability are associated with lower loan spreads. Our results are consistent with a risk allocation approach to project finance deals. Keywords: project finance; banking; loan pricing; political risk JEL Classification: F34; G21; G32 I. Introduction In recent years project finance has become an increasingly popular method of funding long-term capital intensive infrastructure projects worldwide. The nature of modern project finance is to use limited or nonrecourse syndicated loans via a Special Purpose Vehicle (SPV), where such debt typically represents the lion’s share of the capital structure. The SPV is a standalone legal entity that usually has one objective such as to build a dam or a pipeline. Project finance lending techniques are often employed in developing countries, typically in assetrich industrial sectors such as oil and gas, mining, and utility and energy. Project finance loans are usually preferred if the economy of a country is poor, the corporate governance system is weak, political risk high and bank influence over the host government is strong (Hainz and Kleimeier, 2007). For developed countries project finance is viewed as one financing alternative among many; for the developing country it can often be one of the few sources of finance available. We therefore posit that developing countries, which tend to have high levels of political risk relative to developed countries, have a weaker negotiating position when entering into contracts with the SPV. This permits higher levels of risk transference in such economies, making project finance investing in such a climate viable.1 The main contribution of this article is to examine the determinants of project finance loan spreads by adopting a disaggregated approach to political risk. To the best of our knowledge this is the first study to explore in detail these issues. The advantage of our *Corresponding author. E-mail: ssnaith@essex.ac.uk 1 There are voluntary standards (Equator Principles) in place to ensure socially and environmentally responsible practices. In the developing country case these principles may help in part to mitigate the stronger negotiating position of the SPV. These principles were first endorsed in 2003, and in January 2011 there were 69 ‘official adopters’. Applied Financial Economics ISSN 0960–3107 print/ISSN 1466–4305 online ß 2011 Taylor & Francis http://www.informaworld.com DOI: 10.1080/09603107.2011.577006 1725 1726 analysis is that it allows the identification of the specific elements of political risk that affect loan pricing, rather than relying on aggregate measures used elsewhere in the literature. This approach yields novel results that dovetail with the notion of risk allocation between the SPV and host government. More specifically, our disaggregated analysis using 1190 project finance loans and controlling for economic determinants yields two main findings. First is that the relationship between disaggregated measures of political risk and project finance loan spreads differs as a function of country development, with little evidence found to support a role for political risk in developed countries. Second is the novel relationship between specific disaggregated measures of political risk and loan price for developing countries. On the one hand, the cost of funds is negatively related to the effectiveness, quality and strength of a country’s legal and institutional systems, and on the other hand, lower levels of government stability and democratic accountability are more likely to be associated with lower loan spreads. We argue that both these findings are consistent with the manner in which project finance is conducted. For the first finding we posit that this is indicative of a difference in host government bargaining power at the contractual stage of the project finance deal. The second finding fits well with the risk transference rationale of the SPV, in this case from the project to the host country. The remainder of this article is organized as follows: Section II provides a brief introduction to project finance; Section III reviews the main literature; Section IV presents the data and the main methodological issues; Section V discusses the main results and a final section concludes. C. Girardone and S. Snaith There are three main distinguishing features that differentiate project finance lending from standard deals in other types of syndicated lending. Firstly, such financing includes the creation, by the project sponsors (equity-holders, who are often large multinational corporations), of a standalone SPV where nonrecourse debt forms the majority of the capital structure. Secondly, the structure of the SPV allocates risk to those participants who are best able to handle it via legally binding contracts. Thirdly, such financing is predominantly used in developing countries.2,3 It is through the formation of the SPV that there is no recourse to the project sponsors, as the debt is held by the newly created SPV. In the event of a project failure this means that the bank has no or at most limited recourse to the project sponsors. Large international banks fund the majority of the loan, often with a smaller contribution from multilateral development banks, such as the International Finance Corporation (IFC, 1999). The participation of such institutions is one method by which political risk is addressed in project finance.4 The importance of contracts to project finance is highlighted by Esty (2004), who finds that a standard project contains 40 or more contracts between the input supplier and the output buyer involving more than 15 different parties in the process. In particular, project finance makes considerable use of political risk guarantees and loan covenants that typically restrict or encourage various actions to enhance the probability of repayment. The contract between the project and the host state is particularly crucial. This host government agreement (concession agreement) will give the right to the SPV to build and operate the project, state the infrastructure the government is required to undertake to ensure the success of the project, as well as have measures to protect against expropriation. II. Project Finance and the SPV III. Literature Review Over the past 20 years project finance has experienced considerable growth that was mainly brought about by the globalization of product markets, an extensive process of deregulation of key industrial sectors worldwide, and the privatization of state-owned entities. Project finance deals tend to be tangibly asset-rich, and are relatively well-diversified across industrial sectors (Esty, 2004). 2 Despite the growing international importance of project finance to fund large-scale projects, there is a paucity of studies in this area. Esty (2004) argues that the field of project finance is ‘relatively unexplored territory for both empirical and theoretical research’. The literature that offers an economic treatment of project finance (Brealey et al., 1996; Esty For more background on the specifics of project finance and the SPV see Brealey et al. (1996) and Esty (2002). Benjamin Esty’s project finance portal is an excellent research tool for project finance research. See Esty (2011). 4 For example, a host country would be less likely to expropriate a project as it would risk losing the future support of the development bank that was a party to the loan. 3 Project finance loan spreads and disaggregated political risk and Megginson, 2003) emphasizes a number of features that make project finance a ‘special case’ compared to alternative methods of financing. This relates to the distinguishing features of project finance mentioned in the previous section, such as the high levels of debt-to-equity (typically averaging around 60–70%), and the use of the SPV and attendant legal contracts. Much of the extant empirical literature has examined project finance lending from three perspectives. The first focuses on the determinants of loan pricing (e.g. Kleimeier and Megginson, 2000; Sorge and Gadanecz, 2008). The second examines what factors might affect the syndicate structure of the SPV (Esty and Megginson, 2003). Lastly, the final approach examines what factors might affect the project finance proportion of syndicated lending (Altunbas and Gadanecz, 2004; Hainz and Kleimeier, 2007). The purpose of this review is not to focus on these latter two perspectives, but rather on the former, the determinants of the loan price with particular emphasis on political risk. An early study by Kleimeier and Megginson (2000) use a standard Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression to identify what factors are important in assessing loan spreads for a sample of 1824 project finance loans. Unexpectedly project finance loans are found to have lower credit spreads over the London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) than any other comparable nonproject finance loans. Moreover, the main results generally suggest that project finance loans should be considered separately from other types of syndicated loans because they have a longer average maturity, are more likely to have third-party guarantees and to be extended to borrowers in riskier countries. In particular they find that higher maturity, the availability of third party guarantees and the presence of collateralizable assets significantly reduce the average project finance loans spreads. Finally, project finance loans involve more participating banks and are more likely to be extended to borrowers in assetrich industries. Kleimeier and Meggison’s results were later confirmed by Altunbas and Gadanecz (2004) who investigate the microeconomic and macroeconomic determinants of bank lending and find that project finance loans have lower spreads than other forms of syndicated lending. The authors use a broad sample of syndicated loans, including project finance, and take into account additional pricing factors such as fees that are typically charged in loan syndications. 5 1727 Overall, the results show an inverse relationship between the cost of borrowing and a country’s economic strength, whereas ceteris paribus higher political risk results in larger loan spreads. In a related study on the nature of credit risk in project finance Sorge (2004) looks at the term structure of loan spreads in project finance using a set of microeconomics variables including maturity, loan guarantees and a measure of corruption as a proxy for political risk. Here the aim is to examine the nature of the relationship between maturity and the cost of the loan, specifically whether it is linear or nonlinear. The main finding is that the relationship between project loan spreads and maturity is humpshaped. As one would expect, Sorge finds that while corruption increases the cost of borrowing, the involvement of multilateral development banks or export credit agencies decreases it. Sorge and Gadanecz (2008) extend the analysis by examining both microeconomic and macroeconomic factors. The main conclusions are that for poorer countries in particular, the presence of political risk and political risk guarantees play an important role in the pricing of project finance, with the latter having a significant impact in reducing credit spreads. Other important factors are the host country’s creditworthiness and the syndicate size. Overall, this review has shown that only a handful of studies have empirically investigated the determinants of spreads specifically for project finance loans. In addition, none of the reviewed studies provides an in-depth analysis of the effects of disaggregate political risk components on spreads. This constitutes the main novelty of this article and the details of our chosen empirical models and variables are described in the following section. IV. Data and Methodology Data We employ the Loan Analytics database (formerly Loanware) from Dealogic which contains extensive information on loans made in the international syndicated loans market signed from January 1980. Specifically, financial information for a panel of 1190 project finance loans worth over $205 billion over 1996–2003.5 All spreads are measured as the margin over LIBOR. Since the chosen time period covers various international financial crises (South-East The sample of 1190 project finance loans represents 49% of the available observations downloadable from the database. Observations can be lost for a number of reasons, including missing information or being based on non-LIBOR rates. C. Girardone and S. Snaith 1728 Asia, Russia, Brazil and Turkey) it is reasonable to expect that spreads have increased over the period of study as the availability of credit decreased particularly for the affected countries. Given the variables included in our model (see below), much of these effects should be captured by the macroeconomic and political risk variables. The dataset is split into three sub-samples: developed, emerging and developing countries, according to the World Bank’s data on country development. Two proxies for disaggregated political risk are used: the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG, 2011) political risk index and the World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Research Indicators Dataset. The span of the dataset is dictated by data availability for both the World Bank’s data on governance and on economic development. The latter uses Gross National Income per capita and defines: ‘high income’ countries as developed; ‘upper middle income’ countries as emerging and finally, ‘low income’ and ‘lower middle income’ countries as developing. The political risk rating included in the ICRG database is calculated for 140 countries and is based on 100 points. It includes 12 weighted variables covering both political and social attributes and can be broadly divided into two levels of risk: low risk (80–100 points) and high to moderate risk (0–79 points). The aim of this political risk rating is to offer a method of measuring the political stability of the countries covered by the ICRG on a comparable basis. Table A1 in the appendix provides definitions of each variable. Also included in Table A1 are the World Bank’s aggregate governance indexes that specify six dimensions of governance that relate to political risk. Data are available for the years 1996, 1998, 2000, 2002 and 2004 for 209 countries and territories.6 As with the ICRG index, high values are associated with low political risk. Methodology Our analysis of the data is based upon applying a statistical model to our sample of project finance loans. The estimation procedure is a simple crosssectional OLS regression that takes the form of Equation 1, where 0 s refer to coefficients on microeconomic variables, 0 s on macroeconomic variables and on the political risk variable.7 Equation 1 treats with one political risk index variable, though when using disaggregated political risk data this will be 6 7 replaced by 12 variables and coefficients in the ICRG case, and six in the World Bank case (see Table A1): LOAN SPREAD ¼ þ 1 MATURITY þ þ þ 2 DEAL VALUE 3 GUARANTEE þ 5 CURR RISK þ 4 BANKS CLUB 6 þ 7 ENVIR RISK þ 1 RESERVES þ 2 INVEST þ 3 CREDPRIV þ 4 GDPGR þ 5 ACCBALANCE þ 6 INFLATION þ 7 IMPEXP þ 8 PPP SHARE þ 9 WORLDTR þ 10 USTREAS þ POL RISK ð1Þ Taking each variable in turn, MATURITY is the loan maturity in years. Although one could expect that longer term loans cost more, results on this relationship in the empirical literature are mixed. DEAL VALUE is the loan size in $m: this variable should be negatively related to spreads as only borrowers with a good credit history should be able to obtain large size loans. GUARANTEE is a dummy variable that takes the value of one if there is an implicit or explicit third-party repayment guarantee and zero otherwise. For this variable, the expectation is that the availability of guarantees will reduce the cost of borrowing. BANKS is the number of banks in the syndicate and is included to test to what extent syndicate structure affects the spread; it is reasonable to expect that a higher number of participants might have a significant risk mitigating effect. Whilst this is certainly true in the case of strategic default, Esty and Megginson (2003) offer another possibility. They posit that a weakening of creditor rights, which would result in an increase in risk, would require a greater need for monitoring of cash flows and an increased need for re-contracting resulting from economic distress. This type of risk they argue is best handled by a smaller syndicate. CURR_RISK is a dummy variable measuring currency risk that takes the value of one if a loan is exposed to currency risk and zero otherwise. This specific risk arises when the currency of the loan is different from the currency of the project’s host country, and it is therefore expected to affect the loan spread positively. CLUB is a dummy taking the value of one according to whether the type of deal is in the form of a club of banks or bilateral. A final dummy variable, ENVIR_RISK, takes the value of one if the industry of the borrower is typically perceived to be high risk environmentally and zero otherwise. This factor may be important because it reflects the level Following the extant literature we interpolate to get data for 1997, 1999, 2001 and 2003. White’s (1980) corrected SEs used. Project finance loan spreads and disaggregated political risk of potential or actual environmental risks for each industrial sector included in our sample.8 Turning to the macroeconomic factors: RESERVES is the ratio of international reserves to Gross Domestic Product (GDP); INVEST is the level of investments to GDP; CREDPRIV is the level of domestic credit to private sector as a % of GDP; GDPGR is real GDP growth; ACCBALANCE is the level of current account balance as a % of GDP. INFLATION is the percentage annual inflation rate; IMPEXP is the ratio of imports to exports; PPPSHARE is the Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) share of world GDP and, finally WORLDTR is a proxy for the growth in world trade (in %) and is calculated as absolute sum of imports plus exports for all countries. For all indicators of actual or potential economic strength expectations are for a negative relationship with loan spreads (INVEST, CREDPRIV, GDPGR, ACCBALANCE and PPPSHARE). In contrast, INFLATION should be positively related to spread because it is likely associated with weaknesses associated with the country’s finances. Similarly, high IMPEXP and WORLDTR variables could signal a strong dependence from abroad and more competition for funds, respectively, and are thus expected to be positively related to loan spreads. Expectations for RESERVES are mixed because while on the one hand if high they may signal a strength of a country in the form of a safety net, on the other hand it may mean the contrary as in various instances developing countries have preferred to rebuild their reserves rather than servicing their debts (Altunbas and Gadanecz, 2004). USTREAS is the US Treasury rate calculated at constant maturities three-year middle rate. Altunbas and Gadanecz argue that this variable should control for the price of alternative risk-free investments and gives an indication of the ‘riskier borrowers’ appetite for risk’. Finally, the aggregate political risk variable is POL_RISK; high (low) values for the POL_RISK index are associated with low (high) political risk levels. In line with the extant literature the coefficient on POL_RISK should be negative. With regards to the disaggregated data our a priori view is not uniform. This can be seen by referring to the political risk measures provided in the appendix and the key features of project finance. For example, it is perfectly plausible to expect the quality of law and order to have a negative impact on the loan spread. However, given claims that project finance is often conducted in countries where political risk and influence over the host state is high, for the 8 1729 Table 1. Regression results for economic factors and ICRG political risk index, 1996–2003 Abbr 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Abbreviations Aggregated POL RSK index MATURITY DEAL VALUE GUARANTEE BANKS CURR_RISK ENVIR_RISK CLUB 0.1977 0.0234*** 66.031*** 0.2992 16.942 8.9780 3.9936 RESERVES INVEST CREDPRIV GDPGR ACCBALANCE INFLATION IMPEXP PPP SHARE WORLDTR USTREASURY POL_RISK 0.6167 4.5902*** 0.3843*** 4.3091** 0.8230 0.0038 0.9812*** 1.5145** 2.0142*** 5.5873** 2.3573*** Adjusted R2 15.1% Notes: High (low) levels of the political risk index variable POL_RISK correspond to low (high) levels of risk. ** and *** indicate significance at 5 and 1% levels, respectively. developing country sample the relationship between some of the political risk measures and price may have a positive impact. V. Results and Discussion Loan price determinants: political risk index Table 1 shows the empirical results derived from the estimation of our model described in Equation 1 using the ICRG aggregated measure of political risk. Focusing on microeconomic factors, the most striking result is the significance and magnitude of the variable GUARANTEE. The sign for this variable is negative thereby indicating that the presence of a risk mitigant in the form of a third party repayment guarantee is likely to lower the loan spread. This finding is in line with the main literature: for example, Sorge and Gadanecz (2008) investigate the risk mitigating role of explicit and implicit guarantees from multilateral development banks and export credit agencies. They find that guarantees play an important role in project finance particularly Examples of high environmental risk industries include chemicals, mining and oil and gas. C. Girardone and S. Snaith 1730 Table 2. Political risk ICRG measures 1996–2003 Variables Developed countries Emerging countries Developing countries Government stability Socio-economic conditions Investment profile Internal conflict External conflict Corruption Military in politics Religion in politics Law and order Ethnic tensions Democratic accountability Bureaucracy quality 7.1114 6.7171 24.3193 5.0075 9.4957 2.2667 21.8786 0.1708 8.1726 5.2228 24.5552 0.3251 0.3759 17.4941 7.5226 15.0658 84.5817*** 3.0254 2.8612 30.7002 1.6805 23.3951*** 19.5811 33.8795*** 29.5173** 14.1824 21.1594 14.0646 0.7182 10.9219 2.5245 17.6367 44.8096*** 3.5806 17.7335** 33.2758*** Adjusted R2 9.4% 99.6% 36.7% Notes: Note that for a given country each disaggregated measure of political risk assigns a higher value the lower the risk. ** and *** indicate significance at 5 and 1% levels, respectively. in emerging countries and have a significant impact in reducing credit spreads (by almost one-third on average). Our regression results indicate that the magnitude of the coefficient for GUARANTEE is by far the largest (66.03) among our variables and corresponds to almost 30 times that of political risk. In an attempt to investigate what drives this large coefficient for the repayment guarantees, we have re-estimated the model by taking into account the economic development of the regions using the World Bank’s data on country development. These unreported results yield a significant coefficients of 56.13 for developed countries and to 62.68 for the joint sample of developing and emerging countries, showing the strong risk mitigating effect of these guarantees across all economic groups.9 Focusing on other microeconomic variables, in line with the literature (e.g. Sorge, 2004), no significant linear relationship between MATURITY (the term of project finance loans) and the size of credit spreads has been found. Moreover, we found that the variable DEAL VALUE is significantly negative, thereby confirming our view that banks will tend to lend larger amounts to those who are more creditworthy, hence on average the cost of larger loans would be lower. Concerning the macroeconomic factors, several observations can be made: first, typical indicators of a country’s strength, like GDP growth and domestic 9 credit to the private sector are negatively related to loan spreads and the coefficients are statistically significant.10 These results suggest that, as expected, lenders would charge borrowers less the better the host country’s economic prospects. On the other hand, the positive and statistically significant relationship between the variable INVEST and loan spreads can be interpreted as if high values for investment over GDP increase the borrower’s credit risk.11 The only unanticipated result in Table 2 is the PPPSHARE coefficient that is positively related to loan spreads. One possible explanation could be that lenders charge wealthier borrowers a premium. The IMPEXP variable is positively related to project finance loan prices suggesting that countries that are more dependent from abroad will have to pay a higher spread. This is confirmed by the variable WORLDTR that is also positive and significant. The last macroeconomic coefficient is a proxy for USTREASURY and is found negative and statistically significant. One possible explanation put forward by Altunbas and Gadanecz (2004) is that since USTREASURY is a proxy for the price of alternative investments of banks, in times of tight monetary policy only the less risky developing countries’ borrowers will be able to obtain finance. The last coefficient to consider is the coefficient on the ICRG aggregated political risk index. In line with expectations we find that the coefficient is negative Coefficients are significant at the 1% level. Unreported results are available from the authors upon request. A similar relationship is found by Eichengreen and Mody (2000) who examine the determinants of a syndicated lending, which contrasts with our own study which focuses exclusively on project finance lending. 11 An alternative interpretation considers the variable investments/GDP as a proxy for high potential for future growth, which would imply a positive relationship with loan spread. However for developing countries the high level of debts and a less robust financial environment may result in increased risk. 10 Project finance loan spreads and disaggregated political risk and significant with a value of approximately 2.4. This indicates that a 1% reduction in the overall political risk (i.e. an increase in the index) results in a 2.4 basis point reduction in the loan price.12 Loan price determinants and country development: disaggregated political risk index Building on the results from the previous section, Table 2 illustrates the regression results for the 12 disaggregated ICRG political risk components described in Table A1. The results are presented for each of the three sub-samples based on country development as ranked by the World Bank. Note that in every case the lower the points total, the higher is the risk (and vice versa).13 Based on the developed countries sample, the first point to note is that none of the disaggregated measures of political risk are statistically significant in explaining the loan spread. This is contrasted by the finding of several significant variables in our emerging and developing country sub-samples. This, in conjunction with higher R2 values in the emerging and developing country samples suggests that in determining the loan spread for developed countries the weighting placed on political risk will be substantially less relative to more risky, less developed countries. This is in line with the intuition that developed countries are characterized as countries where there is very little political risk. Take for example the ‘level’ of law and order and the quality of the bureaucracy. For developed countries this has remained broadly constant and of a reasonable standard in recent times, negating the need to attach a premium to the cost of a loan. Turning to the significant coefficients in the emerging country sample, we see some evidence of the anticipated significant negative coefficients, though only for external conflict, ethnic tensions and bureaucracy quality. For the developing country sample we see that law and order and bureaucracy quality are also significantly negative. An incremental improvement in these two measures will on average remove 44.81 and 33.28 basis points from the cost of a loan. These two results dovetail well with our understanding of project finance. In the case of the 12 1731 former, the importance of a reliable recourse to a strong and impartial legal system is crucial for a form of finance that is governed by so many contracts. In the case of the latter, given the reliance of large infrastructure projects on the host country, a lack of institutional strength and quality in the bureaucracy will also attract a risk premium. For the remaining significant coefficients, government stability and democratic accountability, a positive relationship is found with respect to loan spread. This result, prima facie, can be viewed as somewhat puzzlingly, implying that the more stable and democratically accountable the government, the more the loan costs. Taking government stability as an example, the coefficient implies that an increase in stability will result in (on average) an increase in the cost of a loan. Based on the definitions of these two variables (Table A1) we find that in developing countries project finance deals will on average be cheaper if countries exhibit lower levels of government unity and legislative strength and are less responsive to their people. This result offers a clear link between the weakness of a host country government and the cost of a project finance loan. Based upon our results we suggest that projects that are conducted in host countries where governments are in a weaker negotiating position benefit to a larger degree from risk transference. Whilst it is unclear what the ramifications of such transference are upon the host country, for the project we argue the reduction in risk results in a reduction of the loan spread. To better assess this attention would need to be paid to the tool that enables the majority of this risk transference – the host government agreement. The relationship we find bears out the common belief that developing countries will agree to far broader concessions in such agreements as opposed to developed countries at the contractual stage of the project finance deal.14 Our findings complement those of Hainz and Kleimeier (2007) who find that the percentage of syndicated lending that is classified as project finance increases when a country exhibits poor economic performance, weak corporate governance, high political risk and strong bank influence over host Although not shown, we also tested the aggregate measure of political risk for the period 1984 to 2004 (with a total of 1883 observations) and found that the coefficient is also negative (0.7125) and statistically significant with an R2 of 14.1%. 13 For example, a high value for ‘Democratic Accountability’ means the democracy is rated as very accountable. Less intuitively a higher value for corruption is implicit of less corruption. Therefore a low disaggregated value, or index value, is seen as a measure of high risk (say the absence of law and order and the presence of corruption), whilst high values imply the presence of that which is nonrisk-inducing: for example, good quality of democracy, low corruption, the absence of military in politics. 14 This has been confirmed with interviews with leading project finance lawyers. For further discussion of legal aspects see Leader and Ong (2011). C. Girardone and S. Snaith 1732 Table 3. Political risk WB measures 1996–2003 Variables Developed Emerging Developing countries countries countries Voice and 0.2325 accountability Political stability 2.2012 Government 0.4396 effectiveness Regulatory burden 3.4553 Rule of law 7.7329** Control of 4.3546** corruption Adjusted R2 10.4% 0.6080 coefficient is not significant for developing countries and is never found significant using the ICRG definitions (Table 2). 0.5820 3.2212** 4.6744 1.1910 7.2721*** 2.5907 4.0766 4.8294** 3.4694** 5.0770*** 2.3426 25.7% 35.9% Note: See notes to Table 2. governments. One reason for the popularity of project finance in such situations is the lack of other investment alternatives available in such economies. As a consequence this would lead to an increased ability to influence host governments, and thus gain greater concessions for the project and change the risk–return relationship in the manner outlined above. We now validate our results by employing an alternative measure of political risk, the World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Research Indicators Dataset, in place of the ICRG dataset (see Table 3). While we consider this comparison an essential ‘robustness test’, comparative conclusions should be drawn tentatively as the definitions of the indicators differ across the two datasets. Overall, Table 3 appears to confirm two main empirical findings. Firstly, there exists a clear negative relationship between loan spreads and two of the indicators, government effectiveness and the rule of law for the developing country sample. These are associated with the ICRG definition of bureaucracy quality and law and order respectively. This implies that the cost of funds in project finance is strongly related to the effectiveness, quality and strength of a country’s legal and institutional systems. Secondly, based upon the R2 values, measures of political risk seem better able to describe loan spreads of developing countries. The main difference between the results yielded by the second dataset relates to the coefficient for the corruption index that is found significant and positive for developed and emerging countries. This implies that a reduction in corruption (an increase in the measure ‘corruption’) will mean that on average loans will be more expensive. However, the VI. Conclusions In recent years, the relative importance of project finance investments for long-term infrastructure has increased remarkably, and forms an important source of finance for countries that are characterized by a high level of political risk. As expected, our evidence suggests that project finance loan spreads are significantly lower when loan guarantees are present, and that lower levels of aggregate political risk are associated with lower loan spreads. The importance of guarantees is explained by the nonrecourse nature of project finance, and it makes intuitive sense that when, in general, political risk is lower, the cost of a loan should be lower. These findings generally corroborate the extant (albeit scarce) literature on the determinants of spreads in project finance loans. Yet, this article’s main contribution is to examine the disaggregate components of political risk while controlling for the economic determinants of project loan spreads. We also distinguish across groups of countries according to their level of economic development. As far as we are aware such an analysis has not been carried out before and is expected to provide us with a better understanding of the role of political risk in this context. Our results from the developed country sample indicate a limited role for political risk, which is contrasted by the results garnered for developing countries. The findings of developing economies dovetail well with our understanding of project finance risk allocation. They indicate that the quality and strength of a country’s legal and institutional systems help to reduce the cost of project finance loans. Similar evidence is obtained for bureaucracy quality. In the case of the former a project finance deal in such a climate will be reliant on the host country’s legal and institutional systems. In the case of the latter the construction of large infrastructure project requires the extensive cooperation of host governments. A positive relationship between the cost of project finance lending with government stability and democratic accountability is also observed. This implies that the weaker the host country government the lower the loan price. We argue that this is a consequence of risk transference from project to the developing host state. Project finance loan spreads and disaggregated political risk Finding that the cost of project finance loans is reduced when dealing with weak governments, in conjunction with the support of a limited role for political risk in developed countries, suggests that future research should focus on how bargaining power varies between developed and developing host countries, and how this variation manifests itself in the host government agreements of such countries. Acknowledgements The authors thank the ESRC for funding this research under the World Economy and Finance Research Programme (ESRC award reference number: RES-156-25-001), and Jerry Coakley, Sheldon Leader and John Wilson for helpful comments and suggestions. References Altunbas, Y. and Gadanecz, B. (2004) Developing country economic structure and the pricing of syndicated credits, Journal of Development Studies, 5, 143–73. Brealey, R. A, Cooper, I. A. and Habib, M. A. (1996) Using project finance to fund infrastructure investments, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 9, 25–38. Eichengreen, B. and Mody, A. (2000) Lending booms, reserves and the sustainability of short-term debt: inferences from the pricing of syndicated bank loans, Journal of Development Economics, 63, 5–44. Esty, B. C. (2002) Returns on project-finance investments: evolution and managerial implications, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15, 71–86. 1733 Esty, B. C. (2004) Why study large projects? An introduction to research on project finance, European Financial Management, 10, 213–24. Esty B. C. (2011) Project finance portal: research, data and information sources, Harvard Business School. Available at http://www.people.hbs.edu/besty/projfinportal/ (accessed 5 May 2011). Esty, B. C. and Megginson, W. L. (2003) Creditor rights, enforcement, and debt ownership structure: evidence from the global syndicated loan market, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38, 37–59. Hainz, C. and Kleimeier, S. (2007) Project finance as a risk management tool in international syndicated lending, Governance and the Efficiency of Economic Systems Discussion Paper No. 183, University of Mannheim. International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) (2011) A business guide to political risk for international decisions. Available at www.prsgroup.com (accessed 5 May 2011). International Finance Corporation (IFC) (1999) Project Finance in Developing Countries: IFC’s Lessons of Experience, IFC, Washington DC. Kleimeier, S. and Megginson, W. (2000) Are project finance loans different from other syndicated credits?, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 13, 75–87. Leader, L. and Ong, D. (Eds) (2011) Global Project Finance, Human Rights and Sustainable Development, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Sorge, M. (2004) The nature of credit risk in project finance, Bank for International Settlement Quarterly Review, 91–101, December. Sorge, M. and Gadanecz, B. (2008) The term structure of credit spreads in project finance, International Journal of Finance and Economics, 13, 68–81. White, H. (1980) A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity, Econometrica, 48, 817–38. Appendix Table A1. Components of political risk indexes Variables Definitions a ICRG Government stability Socio-economic conditions Investment profile Internal conflict External conflict Government’s ability to carry out its declared programmes and to stay in office. Subcomponents: government unity; legislative strength; popular support Socio-economic pressures at work in society that could constraint government action or fuel social dissatisfaction. Subcomponents: unemployment; consumer confidence; poverty Factors affecting the risk to investment not covered by other political, economic or financial risk components Subcomponents: contract viability/expropriation; profits repatriation; payment delays Political violence in a country and its actual and potential impact on governance Subcomponents civil war/coup threat; terrorism/political violence; civil disorder Risk to the incumbent government from foreign action, from nonviolent to violent external pressures. Subcomponents: war; cross-border conflict; foreign pressures (continued ) C. Girardone and S. Snaith 1734 Table A1. Continued Variables Definitions Corruption Corruption within the political system particularly in the form of excessive patronage, nepotism, job reservations, secret party funding and suspicious ties between politics and business Involvement of military in politics even at peripheral level including the threat of military take over Domination of society or governance by a single religious group that seeks to replace civil law by religious law and to exclude other religions from the political or social process Law is an assessment of the strength and impartiality of the legal system while the order subcomponent is an assessment of popular observance of the law It is an assessment of the degree of tension within a country due to racial, nationality or language divisions How responsive is government to its people on the basis that the less responsive the more likely it is to fall Institutional strength and quality of the bureaucracy refers to the ability to govern without drastic changes in policy or interruption of government services Military in politics Religion in politics Law and order Ethnic tensions Democratic accountability Bureaucracy quality World Bank Worldwide Governance Research Indicators Dataset Voice and accountability Measures various political, civil and human rights e.g. these indicators measure the extent to which citizens of a country are able to participate in the selection of governments and the independence of the media Political stability The likelihood of violent threats to, or changes in, government, including terrorism e.g. acts having direct effect on the continuity of policies, and possibly undermining the ability of all citizens to peacefully select and replace those in power Government effectiveness The competence of the bureaucracy and the quality of public service delivery including the quality of the bureaucracy, the independence of the civil service from politics and the credibility of the government’s commitment to policies Regulatory burden The incidence of market-unfriendly policies, such as price controls or inadequate bank supervision, as well as perceptions of the burdens imposed by excessive regulation in areas like foreign trade and business development Rule of law The quality of contract enforcement, the effectiveness and predictability of the judiciary, the police and the courts, as well as the likelihood of crime and violence. It aims to measure the success of a society in developing an environment in which fair and predictable rules form the basis for economic and social interactions, including property rights protection Control of corruption The exercise of public power for private gain, including both petty and grand corruption and state capture Note: a ß The PRS Group, Inc.