Uploaded by barbaranazrub

Equilibrium notes

advertisement
CHAPTER 4 Equilibrium - How Supply and Demand Determine Prices
• Market equilibrium - the point where the supply and demand curves cross and the quantity
demanded equals quantity supplied.
The equilibrium point has a price
and quantity, which are the only
ones that are stable in a free
market.
• The price at the meeting point is called the equilibrium price and the quantity at the
meeting point is called the equilibrium quantity.
• At any other point, economic forces push prices and quantities back towards equilibrium.
Adam Smith called this the ‘Invisible hand’.
Surpluses and Shortages
• Surplus - a situation in which the quantity supplied is greater than the quantity demanded.
• Shortage -
a situation in which the quantity demanded is greater than the quantity
supplied
1.A Surplus Drives Prices Down - At
a price of $50 there is a surplus there
is a surplus of oil. When there is a
surplus, sellers have an incentive to
decrease their price and buyers have
an incentive to offer lower prices. The
price decreases until at $30 the
quantity demanded equals quantity
supplied.
2. A Shortage Drives Prices Up At a price of $15 there is a
shortage of oil. When there is a
shortage, sellers have an incentive
to increase the price and buyers
have an incentive to offer higher
prices. The price increases until at
$30 the quantity supplied equals the
quantity demanded and there is no
longer an incentive for the price to
rise.
In general:
• When there is a surplus (a situation in which the quantity supplied is greater than quantity
demanded due to high prices), competition between producers will push the price down until
the market equilibrium is found. If prices decrease, demand will increase, and supply will
decrease.
• When there is a shortage (a situation in which the quantity demanded is greater than the
quantity supplied due to low prices), competition between consumers will push prices up.
When prices rise, supply will increase, and demand will decrease.
• At the market equilibrium the equilibrium price is stable because at the equilibrium price,
the quantity demanded is exactly equal to the quantity supplied. Every buyer can buy as
much as he wants and therefore do not have the incentive to push prices up, and every
supplier can sell as much as he wants and will not have an incentive to push prices down.
Who competes with whom?
Although most people think that buyers compete with sellers, in reality buyers compete with
other buyers and sellers compete with other sellers. Regardless of what sellers want, what
they do when competing is lowering prices, buyers may want lower prices but what they do
when hey compete is raising prices.
A Free Market Maximises Producer plus Consumer Surplus (the Gains from Trade)
Unexploited Gains
• When quantity supplied is below the equilibrium quantity, buyers are willing to pay more
than the minimum that the suppliers accept. In this case, there are unexploited gains.
Wasted resources
• When the quantity supplied is above the equilibrium quantity, there are wasted resources.
In this case, the costs of sellers to produce an extra unit of a product is more than the
worth of this extra unit to buyers. Therefore, the resources could be used better to
produce something buyers are actually willing to pay.
These two problems only exist for a short period of time because the free market will push
the price and quantity to an equilibrium where producer and consumer surplus are maximised.
When we say that a free market maximises the gains from trade, we mean three closely
related things:
1. The supply of goods is bought by buyers with the highest willingness to pay.
2. The supply of goods is sold by the sellers with the lowest costs.
3. Between buyers and sellers, there are no unexploited gains from trade or any wasteful
trades.
Shifting Demand and Supply Curves
1. Increase in Supply
2. Decrease in Supply
3. Increase in Demand
4. Decrease in Demand
Friedrich A. von Hayek (1945), “The Use of Knowledge in the Society
The economic question of what the best way would be to allocate all available resources in
society, is based upon the assumption that those that try to work on this problem possess all
relevant data needed to solve this question through logical economic calculus. The real
economic problem society faces is not merely the question of how to logically solve the
problem of resource allocation, but also how to best utilise the relevant knowledge and bits
of information which are dispersed among society and is impossible for a single mind to
possess.
“Planning” is defined as the decision related to the allocation of available resources. In this
sense, all economic activity is planning. One of the main problems of economic policy is the
question of how to most effectively utilise all this required knowledge which is initially
dispersed among all people. The answer to this problem is closely related to the question of
who should do the planning. The dispute is between whether planning should be done centrally,
by one authority, or if it is to be divided among many individuals. The middle road between
between central planning and decentralised planning by many individuals (competition) is the
delegation of planning to organised industries, a monopoly. The effectiveness of these
systems is to be measured by how well they utilise existing knowledge.
It is often assumed that scientific knowledge is the sum of all knowledge. However, there
exists a large body of very important but unorganised knowledge. This knowledge is not easily
accessible by a central planner, but rather by individuals and can be characterised as
practical knowledge rather than theoretical.
Economic problems are always a product of change. If things continue as they were expected,
there would be no need to form a new plan. Furthermore, small changes happen frequently
and require constant small adjustments to be made by the “man on the spot”. These small
changes and adjustments are not accurately reflected in the statistics which are drawn upon
by the central planners and therefore inadequately considered when making central decisions.
The economic problem of society is one of rapid adaptations to changes in the particular
circumstances of time and place. Ultimate decisions should therefore be left to the people
who are familiar with these circumstances. The problem that arises is making sure that the
“man on the spot” is also aware of the information that will allow him to fit his decisions into
the whole pattern of changes in the larger economic system. The individual does not need to
know all the causes of changes in his immediate surroundings, only the effects. This is where
the price mechanism plays a role. A price can be seen as a numerical index, which
communicates all the necessary knowledge related to its demand and supply, without
overburdening the individual with unnecessary specifics.
The price mechanism allows for information to be spread across the market in a highly
efficient way. When for example a certain raw material becomes scarer, without an order
being issued and without more than perhaps a handful of people knowing the cause of said
scarcity, tens of thousands of people are made to use the material more sparingly, or in other
words, to move in the right direction. The price mechanism extends the span of our
utilisation of resources beyond the span of control of any one mind and allows the individual
to do the desirable things without being told what to do.
This is the concept which solves not only problems of an economic nature, but the central
problem of all social science. Alfred Whitehead once said:
“Civilisation advances by extending the number of important operations which we can perform
without thinking about them”
The price system has made not only the division of labour possible, but also a coordinated
utilisation of resources based on an equally divided knowledge.
Download