Decision & Game Theory Chapter 4: Decision Analysis under Risk with Additional Information Sonia REBAI Tunis Business School University of Tunis • In a risky environment, the probability distribution of the states of nature plays an important role in the choice of the optimal decision. • DMs have preliminary or prior probability assessments that are the best values available at that time. • It would then be of importance to seek additional information before making a final decision. • This new information can be used to revise or update the prior probabilities so that the final decision is based on more accurate probabilities. • The revised probabilities are called posterior probabilities. • Most often, additional information is obtained through experiments, a consulting advice, or a forecast. • Such information is usually acquired at some cost. The question is whether the cost paid is worth. • To answer this question we need to calculate the Expected Value of the additional information. Example 1 A company has the choice between producing itself or buying from a supplier one of the electronic components that it uses in its activity. Net profit depends on the level of demand for the product requiring this component. This demand can be low, medium or high. The a priori distribution is estimated at 0.35; 0.35 and 0.30. Produce buy S1 S2 Low Demand Medium Demand -20 40 10 45 S3 High Demand 100 70 4 The company has the opportunity to test the demand on the market. Two results are possible for this test favorable (F) or unfavorable (U). The following conditional probabilities were estimated: Favorable S1 P(F|S1)=0.10 S2 P(F|S2)=0.40 S3 P(F|S3)=0.60 Unfavorable P(U|S1)=0.90 P(U|S2)=0.60 P(U|S3)=0.40 Find the optimal strategy to adopt. 5 F Pr e c u od Buy Sur v ey e No Su r U duc o r P Buy ve Produce y Bu y S1 S2 S3 S1 S2 S3 S1 S2 S3 S1 S2 S3 S1 S2 S3 S1 S2 S3 -20 40 100 10 45 70 -20 40 100 10 45 70 -20 40 100 10 45 70 Bayes’ theorem Si: State of Nature (i = 1, …, n) P(Si): Prior Probability Ij: Professional Information (Experiment)( j = 1, …, n) P(Ij | Si): Conditional Probability P(IjÇSi) = P(SiÇIj): Joint Probability P(Si | Ij): Posterior Probability P(Si | Ij) P(Si Ç I j ) P( I j | Si ) P(Si ) = = n P( I j ) å P( I j | Si ) P(Si ) i =1 S1 0.35 S2 S3 0.35 0.30 F 0.1 0.4 0.6 U 0.9 0.6 0.4 The sum P(S1│“.”) P(S2│“.”) P(S3│“.”) 0.035 0.14 0.18 0.355 0.09859 0.39437 0.50704 0.315 0.21 0.12 0.645 0.48837 0.32558 0.18605 8 64.51 F (0.355) 43.90 64,51 Pro ce u d 54.23 Buy S ur ve y U (0. 6 45 21.86 ) e c 32,56 Produ 32.56 Buy 43.90 No Su e rve y 37 40.25 Produc Bu y 40.25 S1 (0.09859) S2 (0.39437) S3 (0.50704) S1 (0.09859) S2 (0.39437) S3 (0.50704) -20 40 100 10 45 70 S1 (0.48837) S2 (0.32558) S3 (0.18605) S1 (0.48837) S2 (0.32558) S3 (0.18605) -20 40 100 10 45 70 S1(0.35) S2(0.35) S3(0.30) S1(0.35) S2(0.35) S3(0.30) -20 40 100 10 45 70 • Thus, the optimal strategy is to perform the survey, if the result of the survey is favorable then the company should produce the product, however, if the result is unfavorable, the company should buy the product. • EVII = 43.90 – 40.25 = 3.65 • So if the cost paid for this information is less than 3.65, it will be worthy to acquire. Otherwise, the information will be worthless. • Additional information reduces risk in decision making. It can in some extreme situations completely remove the risk and provide a certainty environment. In General, such information is very expensive. • How to evaluate the value of perfect information (EVPI)? • The idea behind EVPI is that if the state of nature that will occur is known with certainty, then the best alternative can be determined with certainty as well. • The value of EPVI is just simply the expected value under certainty minus the expected value under uncertainty. EVPI = Expected Payoff - Expected payoff under Certainty with no information • To compute the expected value under certainty simply take the best payoff under each state of nature and multiply it by its prior probability and sum these. • EVPI places an upper bound on what one would pay for additional information. • Expected Payoff under certainty = 10*0.35+45*0.35+100*0.30 = 49.25 • EVPI = 49.25 – 40.25 = 9 • This means that we should not be willing to pay more than 9. • The Efficiency of the imperfect information is the ratio of EVII to EVPI. • As the EVPI provides an upper bound for the EVII, efficiency is always a number between 0 and 1. • The efficiency of the survey = EVII/EVPI = (3.65)/(9) = 40.556% Example 2: Marketing a new product Assume that a feasibility study at Getz company of a new product led to encouraging the introduction of this product to the market. The management of Getz is not sure whether a large plant or a small one should be built to manufacture the product. The relevant data is presented in the table below. 1. A marketing research company requests $65000 for a perfect information. How much does this information worth? 15 (0.5) Favorable market (0.5) Unfavorable market Construct a large plant $200,000 -$180,000 Construct a small plant Do nothing $100,000 $0 -$20,000 $0 2. Getz has the possibility to conduct a survey for $10,000. The survey will result in a positive or a negative report. Past experience shows that given a favorable market, there is 0.7 chance of a positive report and a 0.2 chance of a positive report under unfavorable market. What should be the optimal strategy of the company? 3. Calculate the efficiency of the survey 16 Construct a large plant Construct a small plant Do nothing (0.5) Favorable market (0.5) Unfavorable market EMV $200,000 -$180,000 $10,000 $100,000 -$20,000 $40,000 $0 $0 $0 1. EVPI = Expected Value Under Certainty - Max(EMV) = ($200,000*0.50 + 0*0.50) - $40,000 = $100,000 - $40,000 = $60,000 So Getz should not be willing to pay more than $60,000 2. Posterior distribution calculations States Survey Positive Negative FAV 0.5 UNF 0.5 0.7 0.2 0.35 0.3 0.8 0.15 The sum P(FAV│ “.”) P(UNF│ “.”) 0.10 0.45 0.78 0.22 0.40 0.55 0.27 0.73 25 $49,200 Surve y 1 S ur Neg . Res. . (.5 5) No s urv ey $106,400 2 plant e g r La Small $63,600 plant 3 No pla nt -$87,400 $2,400 $49,200 $40,000 es. ) R . 5 r Su s. (.4 Po $106,400 2nd decision point 1st decision point plant e g r a L Small No plant pla nt t plan e Larg Sm all pl an t No p lant 4 $2,400 5 $10,000 6 $40,000 7 Fav. Mkt (0.78) Unfav. Mkt (0.22) $190,000 -$190,000 Fav. Mkt (0.78) $90,000 Unfav. Mkt (0.22) -$30,000 -$10,000 Fav. Mkt (0.27) Unfav. Mkt (0.73) Fav. Mkt (0.27) Unfav. Mkt (0.73) Fav. Mkt (0.5) Unfav. Mkt (0.5) Fav. Mkt (0.5) Unfav. Mkt (0.5) $190,000 -$190,000 $90,000 -$30,000 -$10,000 $200,000 -$180,000 $100,000 -$20,000 $0 Hence, if the survey results are favorable, the company should build a large plant. However, if they are unfavorable, it should build a small plant. The efficiency of the survey = EVII/EVPI = (19,200)/(60,000) = 32% Example 3: Texaco vs. Pennzoil In early 1984, Pennzoil and Getty Oil agreed to the terms of a merger. But before any formal documents could be signed, Texaco offered Getty a substantially better price, and Gordon Getty, who controlled most of the Getty stock, reneged on the Pennzoil deal and sold to Texaco. Naturally, Pennzoil felt as if it had been dealt with unfairly and immediately filed a lawsuit against Texaco alleging that Texaco had interfered illegally in the Pennzoil-Getty negotiations. Pennzoil won the case; in late 1985, it was awarded $11.1 billion, the largest judgment ever in the United States at that time. A Texas appeals court reduced the judgment by $2 billion, but interest and penalties drove the total back up to $10.3 billion. James Kinnear, Texaco’s chief executive officer, had said that Texaco would file for bankruptcy if Pennzoil obtained court permission to secure the judgment by filing liens against Texaco’s assets. Furthermore, Kinnear had promised to fight the case all the way to the U.S. Supreme Court if necessary, arguing in part that Pennzoil had not followed Security and Exchange Commission regulations in its negotiations with Getty. In April 1987, just before Pennzoil began to file the liens, Texaco offered to pay Pennzoil $2 billion to settle the entire case. Hugh Liedtke, chairman of Pennzoil, indicated that his advisors were telling him that a settlement between $3 and $5 billion would be fair. What do you think Liedtke should do? Should he accept the offer of $2 billion, or should he refuse and make a firm counteroffer? If he refuses the sure $2 billion, he faces a risky situation. Texaco might agree to pay $5 billion, a reasonable amount in Liedtke’s mind. If he counteroffered $5 billion as a settlement amount, perhaps Texaco would counter with $3 billion or simply pursue further appeals. Below is a decision tree that shows a simplified version of Liedtke’ s problem. Experts expect that the Supreme Court will keep the fine with only 20% chance, will reduce it to $5 billion with 50% chance or will eliminate it completely with a 30% chance. It was also believed that Texaco accepts a counter-offer of $5 billion with 1/6 chance and would place a counter-offer of $3 billion with 1/3 chance. 1. Find the optimal strategy. 2. Calculate the EVPI regarding Texaco’s reaction to a counteroffer of $5 billion? Can you explain this result intuitively? 3. The timing of information acquisition may make a difference. a. suppose that Penzoil could obtain information about the final court decision before making his current decision (taking the $2 billion or counteroffer $5 billion). What would be the EVPI of this information? b. Suppose that Penzoil knew that it would be able to obtain perfect information only after it has made its current decision but before it would have to respond to a potential Texaco counteroffer of $3 billion. What would be the EVPI in this case? 4. In question 3, EVPI for (b) should be less than EVPI calculated in (a). Can you explain why? 5. What is EVPI if Liedtke can learn both Texaco’s reaction and the final court decision before he makes up his mind about the current $2 billion offer? Can you explain why the interaction of the two bits of information should have this effect?