Uploaded by Alwaleed104

Richard Brealey, Stewart Myers, Alan Marcus Fundamentals of Corporate

advertisement
SEVENTH EDITION
Fundamentals of
Corporate Finance
THE McGRAW-HILL/IRWIN SERIES IN FINANCE, INSURANCE AND REAL ESTATE
SEVENTH EDITION
Fundamentals of
Corporate Finance
Richard A. Brealey
London Business School
Stewart C. Myers
Sloan School of Management
Massachusetts Institute
of Technology
Alan J. Marcus
Carroll School of
Management
Boston College
OF CORPORATE FINANCE
usiness unit of The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1221 Avenue of the
Americas, New York, NY, 10020. Copyright © 2012, 2009, 2007, 2004, 2001, 1999, 1995 by The McGraw-Hill
y form or
by an
v
The McGraw-Hill
ut not limited to, in any netw
United States.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 QDB/QDB 1 0 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
ISBN 978-0-07-803464-0
MHID 0-07-803464-7
Vice president
Brent Gordon
Douglas Reiner
editor: Michele Janicek
director of development: Ann
Development editor II: Karen L. Fisher
Robin J. Zwettler
director: Brad Parkins
Senior
manager: Melissa S. Caughlin
Sesha
Senior project manager: Dana M. Pauley
Buyer II: Debra R. Sylvester
Designer: Matt Diamond
Senior photo
coordinator: Keri Johnson
Photo researcher: Michelle Buhr
Senior
project manager: Susan Lombardi
project manager: Ron Nelms
Typeface: 10.5/12 Times Roman
Compositor:
Brealey, Richard A.
ed.
Includes index.
ISBN-10: 0-07-803464-7 (alk. paper)
HG4026.B6668 2012
658.15—dc22
2011017399
About the Authors
Richard A. Brealey
Stewart C. Myers
Alan J. Marcus
vi
Preface
Fundamentals and Principles of Corporate Finance
Organizational Design
Routes through the Book
Changes in the Seventh Edition
Assurance of Learning
AACSB Statement
ORGANIZATION
New and
Enhanced
Pedagogy
WALK-THROUGH
Brealey / Myers / Marcus
Your guide through the challenging landscape
of corporate finance.
Chapter Opener
CHAPTER
Key Terms in the Margin
5.4 Level Cash Flows: Perpetuities and Annuities
annuity
How to Value Perpetuities
perpetuity
EXAMPLE 5.8
▲
Numbered Examples
5
Winning Big at the Lottery
PEDAGOGY
What makes Brealey/Myers/Marcus
such a powerful learning tool?
Spreadsheet
Solutions Boxes
Excel Exhibits
Finance in Practice
Boxes
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
Multiple Cash Flows
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e.
Spreadsheet Questions
SPREADSHEET 19.1
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
The Hazards of Secured Bank Lending
Calculator Boxes and
Exercises
F I N A N C I A L CA L C U L ATO R
An Introduction to Financial Calculators
Self-Test Questions
Self-Test 5.5
Global Index
Global Index
A
End-of-Chapter Material
Summary
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe
Quiz, Practice,
and Challenge
Problems
www.mhhe
www.mhhe
SUMMARY
www.mh
Excel Problems
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Web Exercises
WEB EXERCISES
finance.yahoo.com
MINICASE
www
Minicases
Supplements
For the Instructor
Instructor’s Manual
Online Support
Online Learning Center
PowerPoint Presentation System
Print and Online Test Bank
TM
McGraw-Hill
Connect ™ Finance
Less Managing. More
Teaching. Greater Learning.
Solutions Manual
McGraw-Hill Connect ™
Finance Features
DVD
Tegrity Campus:
Lectures 24/7
McGraw-Hill
Customer Care
Contact Information
Acknowledgments
Contents in Brief
Part One
Introduction
1
2
3
4
Part Two
Value
5
6
7
8
9
10
Part Three
Risk
11
Part Four
Financing
14
Part Five
Debt and Payout
Policy
16
Part Six
Financial Analysis
and Planning
18
Part Seven
Special Topics
21
12
13
15
17
19
20
22
23
24
Part Eight
Conclusion
xxii
25
Contents
Part One
Introduction
Chapter 1
Goals and Governance of the
Corporation 2
1.1
Chapter 3
Accounting and Finance
3.1
Investment and Financing Decisions 4
6
3.2
The Financing Decision 6
1.3
1.4
What Is a Corporation? 8
3.3
9
3.4
Accounting Practice and Malpractice 66
Goals of the Corporation 11
3.5
Taxes 68
Corporate Governance
Corporate Tax
Personal Tax
14
Do Managers Really Maximize Value?
Questions
Careers in Finance 20
1.6
Topics Covered in This Book 23
4.1
Summary 25
Value and Value Added
78
80
How Financial Ratios Help to Understand Value
Added 80
Questions 26
Chapter 2
Financial Markets and Institutions
30
4.2
Measuring Market Value and Market Value
Added 81
4.3
Economic Value Added and Accounting
Rates of Return 84
The Importance of Financial Markets and
Institutions 32
Accounting Rates of Return
35
Other Financial Markets
36
Financial Intermediaries
38
4.4
Measuring Efficiency 88
4.5
Analyzing the Return on Assets: The Du Pont
System 90
The Du Pont System
40
Total Financing of U.S. Corporations
42
Measuring Financial Leverage 92
4.7
Measuring
43
4.8
43
4.9
Liquidity 44
95
97
Interpreting Financial Ratios 98
4.10 The Role of Financial Ratios—and a Final Note on
Transparency 101
The Payment Mechanism 45
Information Provided by Financial Markets
90
4.6
94
Functions of Financial Markets and
Intermediaries 43
Risk Transfer and Diversification
86
Problems with EVA and Accounting Rates of Return 87
The Flow of Savings to Corporations 33
Financial Institutions
2.4
71
Chapter 4
Measuring Corporate Performance
23
The Stock Market
68
69
16
19
1.5
2.3
65
Who Is the Financial Manager? 10
The Ethics of Maximizing Value
2.2
60
The Statement of Cash Flows 63
Free Cash Flow
Shareholders Want Managers to Maximize
Market Value 11
2.1
The Income Statement 59
Profits versus Cash Flow
Other Forms of Business Organization
52
54
Book Values and Market Values 57
The Investment (Capital Budgeting) Decision
1.2
The Balance Sheet
45
Transparency
103
The Crisis of 2007–2009 47
Summary 48
Questions
Questions
Minicase 110
49
105
xxiii
Contents
Part Two
Value
Chapter 5
The Time Value of Money 112
7.2
5.1
Future Values and Compound Interest 114
5.2
Present Values 117
Finding the Interest Rate
5.3
Multiple Cash Flows
Price and Intrinsic Value
197
Nonconstant Growth
Inflation and the Time Value of Money 139
Real or Nominal?
202
205
Market-Value Balance Sheets
138
7.6
139
205
There Are No Free Lunches on Wall Street 206
Method 1: Technical Analysis
206
Method 2: Fundamental Analysis
141
Valuing Real Cash Payments
200
Valuing Growth Stocks
Annuities Due 136
Inflation and Interest Rates
199
7.5
133
Real versus Nominal Cash Flows
194
Simplifying the Dividend Discount Model 197
Estimating Expected Rates of Return
127
129
5.6
5.7
192
The Dividend Discount Model with No Growth 197
126
Level Cash Flows: Perpetuities and Annuities 127
Future Value of an Annuity
5.5
7.4
124
Present Value of Multiple Cash Flows
How to Value Annuities
191
The Dividend Discount Model
124
How to Value Perpetuities
Valuing Common Stocks 191
Valuation by Comparables
123
Future Value of Multiple Cash Flows
5.4
7.3
Market Values, Book Values, and Liquidation
Values 189
A Theory to Fit the Facts
143
7.7
144
210
211
Market Anomalies and Behavioral Finance 212
Market Anomalies
212
Summary 144
213
Questions 145
Behavioral Finance
214
Minicase 156
Chapter 6
Valuing Bonds
6.1
Questions
158
The Bond Market
160
Bond Characteristics
6.2
160
Interest Rates and Bond Prices 161
163
Interest Rate Risk
6.3
6.4
165
8.1
8.2
171
172
Using the NPV Rule to Choose
among Projects 234
235
Problem 2: The Choice between Longand Short-Lived Equipment 236
177
Problem 3: When to Replace an
Old Machine 238
Questions 178
8.3
The Payback Rule
Discounted Payback
Chapter 7
Valuing Stocks 184
8.4
239
240
The Internal Rate of Return Rule 240
A Closer Look at the Rate of Return Rule
Stocks and the Stock Market 186
Reading Stock Market Listings
229
230
Problem 1: The Investment Timing Decision
Corporate Bonds and the Risk of Default 174
Summary 178
7.1
228
Valuing Long-Lived Projects
Bond Rates of Return 168
Variations in Corporate Bonds
Net Present Value
A Comment on Risk and Present Value
Nominal and Real Rates of Interest
6.6
Chapter 8
Net Present Value and Other
Investment Criteria 226
166
6.5
217
Minicase 223
187
241
Calculating the Rate of Return for Long-Lived
Projects 241
Contents
A Word of Caution 243
Calculating the NPV of Blooper’s Project
243
8.5
248
Capital Rationing
Soft Rationing
249
249
Hard Rationing
276
Further Notes and Wrinkles Arising
from Blooper’s Project 277
Questions
249
282
Minicase 287
249
8.6
A Last Look 250
Chapter 10
Project Analysis
10.1 How Firms Organize the Investment
Process 292
Questions 252
Minicase 258
Stage 1: The Capital Budget
Appendix: More on the IRR Rule 259
Exclusive Projects
259
Discount Cash Flows, Not Profits
298
NPV Break-Even Analysis
Operating Leverage
298
300
303
10.4
305
The Option to Expand
266
305
A Second Real Option: The Option to Abandon 307
A Third Real Option: The Timing Option
Separate Investment and Financing Decisions
271
270
307
Facilities 308
271
Operating Cash Flow
Questions
271
Changes in Working Capital
9.3
297
Accounting Break-Even Analysis
Discount Nominal Cash Flows by the
Nominal Cost of Capital 269
Calculating Cash Flow
295
10.3 Break-Even Analysis
264
Discount Incremental Cash Flows
293
10.2 Some “What-If” Questions 294
Scenario Analysis
Identifying Cash Flows 264
Capital Investment
292
Problems and Some Solutions
Chapter 9
Using Discounted Cash-Flow
Analysis to Make Investment
Decisions 262
9.2
292
Stage 2: Project Authorizations
Using the Modified Internal Rate of Return when there
are Multiple IRRs 260
9.1
290
273
309
Minicase 315
An Example: Blooper Industries 274
Cash-Flow Analysis
Part Three
274
Risk
Chapter 11
Introduction to Risk, Return, and the
Opportunity Cost of Capital 316
11.2
319
319
The Historical Record
Diversification
330
11.5 Thinking about Risk
334
Message 2: Market Risks Are Macro Risks
Using Historical Evidence to Estimate
Today’s Cost of Capital 322
Message 3: Risk Can Be Measured
11.3 Measuring Risk 324
A Note on Calculating Variance
333
Message 1: Some Risks Look Big and Dangerous
but Really Are Diversifiable 335
319
Variance and Standard Deviation
329
329
Market Risk versus Specific Risk
11.1 Rates of Return: A Review 318
Market Indexes
11.4 Risk and Diversification
324
Questions
327
Measuring the Variation in Stock Returns
327
338
336
336
Contents
Use Market Weights, Not Book Weights
Chapter 12
Risk, Return, and Capital
Budgeting 344
What If There Are Three (or More) Sources of
Financing? 378
12.1 Measuring Market Risk 346
Measuring Beta
346
Wrapping Up Geothermal
Betas for Dow Chemical and Consolidated
Edison 348
Total Risk and Market Risk
Portfolio Betas
Checking Our Logic
379
379
13.3 Measuring Capital Structure 380
350
13.4 Calculating the Weighted-Average Cost of
Capital 382
350
12.2 Risk and Return 352
Why the CAPM Makes Sense
The Expected Return on Bonds
354
355
How Well Does the CAPM Work?
356
Using the CAPM to Estimate Expected Returns
359
12.3 Capital Budgeting and Project Risk 359
Company versus Project Risk
Determinants of Project Risk
382
The Expected Return on Common Stock
382
The Expected Return on Preferred Stock
383
Adding It All Up
384
Real-Company WACCs
384
13.5 Interpreting the Weighted-Average
Cost of Capital 384
359
361
Don’t Add Fudge Factors to Discount Rates
362
When You Can and Can’t Use WACC
Some Common Mistakes
Questions 363
Chapter 13
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and
Company Valuation 370
13.1 Geothermal’s Cost of Capital 372
385
What Happens When the Corporate Tax
Rate Is Not Zero 387
13.6 Valuing Entire Businesses 387
Calculating the Value of the Concatenator
Business 388
13.2 The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital 373
Calculating Company Cost of Capital as a Weighted
Average 374
Questions
390
Minicase 394
Financing
Chapter 14
Introduction to Corporate Financing
398
Classes of Stock
400
Do Firms Rely Too Heavily on Internal
Funds? 403
407
403
Debt Comes in Many Forms
409
Innovation in the Debt Market 414
14.6 Convertible Securities 415
14.3 Common Stock 404
406
407
14.5 Corporate Debt 409
14.2
Are Firms Issuing Too Much Debt?
Voting Procedures
14.4 Preferred Stock 407
14.1 Creating Value with Financing
Decisions 400
Ownership of the Corporation
384
How Changing Capital Structure
Affects Expected Returns 386
Summary 362
Part Four
376
Taxes and the Weighted-Average Cost of
Capital 377
Questions
417
Contents
Chapter 15
How Corporations Raise Venture Capital
and Issue Securities 422
15.3
433
Market Reaction to Stock Issues
15.1 Venture Capital 424
Venture Capital Companies
Arranging a Public Issue
Part Five
Summary 435
427
Other New-Issue Procedures
433
15.4 The Private Placement 434
425
15.2 The Initial Public Offering 426
The Underwriters
431
432
Questions
430
436
Minicase 439
431
Appendix: Hotch Pot’s New-Issue Prospectus 440
Debt and Payout Policy
Chapter 16
Debt Policy 444
Chapter 17
Payout Policy
16.1
17.1 How Corporations Pay Out
Cash to Shareholders 480
in a Tax-Free Economy
MM’s Argument
446
447
Paying Dividends
How Borrowing Affects Earnings per Share
How Borrowing Affects Risk and Return
Debt and the Cost of Equity
448
450
Debt and Taxes at River Cruises
481
17.2 Stock Repurchases 482
Repurchases and Share Valuation
How Interest Tax Shields Contribute
to the Value of Stockholders’ Equity
456
483
484
17.3 How Do Corporations Decide
How Much to Pay Out? 485
Corporate Taxes and the Weighted-Average
Cost of Capital 456
The Information Content of
Dividends and Repurchases
The Implications of Corporate Taxes
for Capital Structure 458
486
17.4 The Payout Controversy 487
16.3 Costs of Financial Distress 458
459
Costs of Bankruptcy Vary with Type of Asset
Financial Distress without Bankruptcy
461
16.4 Explaining Financing Choices 463
463
488
461
The Assumptions behind Dividend Irrelevance 490
17.5 Why Dividends May Increase Value 491
17.6 Why Dividends May Reduce Value 492
464
465
Taxation of Dividends and Capital
Gains under Current Tax Law 493
Summary 494
Questions 468
Questions
Minicase 474
Appendix: Bankruptcy Procedures
481
Why Repurchases Are Like Dividends
454
The Two Faces of Financial Slack
480
Limitations on Dividends
Stock Dividends and Stock Splits
451
16.2 Capital Structure and Corporate Taxes 454
Bankruptcy Costs
478
494
Minicase 499
475
Contents
Part Six
Financial Analysis And Planning
Chapter 18
Long-Term Financial Planning 502
19.5
543
Evaluating the Plan
18.1 What Is Financial Planning? 504
505
An Improved Model
545
Secured Loans
18.2 Financial Planning Models 506
Percentage of Sales Models
545
Bank Loans
Components of a Financial Planning Model
544
19.6
Financial Planning Focuses on the Big Picture 504
Why Build Financial Plans?
543
547
Commercial Paper
506
548
507
508
Questions
18.3 Planners Beware 512
550
Minicase 556
512
The Assumption in Percentage of Sales Models
The Role of Financial Planning Models
513
514
18.4 External Financing and Growth 515
Chapter 20
Working Capital Management
Summary 519
Terms of Sale
Questions 520
Credit Agreements
560
Credit Analysis
Minicase 525
Collection Policy
562
562
The Credit Decision
565
569
Chapter 19
Short-Term Financial Planning 526
20.2 Inventory Management 571
19.1
20.3 Cash Management 573
Check Handling and Float 574
and Short-Term Financing 528
Other Payment Systems
19.2 Working Capital 531
Electronic Funds Transfer
The Components of Working Capital 531
Working Capital and the Cash Conversion Cycle
536
19.3 Tracing Changes in Cash
and Working Capital 537
558
20.1 Accounts Receivable and Credit Policy 560
533
575
576
International Cash Management
578
20.4 Investing Idle Cash: The Money Market 578
Yields on Money Market Investments
The International Money Market
580
580
19.4 Cash Budgeting 539
Forecast Sources of Cash
Forecast Uses of Cash
539
541
Questions
582
Minicase 588
The Cash Balance 541
Part Seven
Special Topics
Chapter 21
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate
Control 590
Economies of Vertical Integration
21.1 Sensible Motives for Mergers 592
Mergers as a Use for Surplus Funds
Economies of Scale
594
594
Combining Complementary
Resources 595
595
595
Contents
The Cost of Capital for Foreign Investment 636
21.2 Dubious Reasons for Mergers 596
Diversification
596
The Bootstrap Game
Avoiding Fudge Factors
596
21.3 The Mechanics of a Merger 598
Questions
The Form of Acquisition 598
Mergers, Antitrust Law, and Popular Opposition
Mergers Financed by Cash
598
Chapter 23
Options 644
599
Mergers Financed by Stock
638
Minicase 642
21.4 Evaluating Mergers 599
A Warning
636
601
23.1 Calls and Puts
602
646
Selling Calls and Puts
Another Warning 602
647
649
21.5 The Market for Corporate Control 602
21.6
Financial Alchemy with Options
603
Some More Option Magic
21.7 Method 2: Takeovers 604
21.8 Method 3: Leveraged Buyouts 607
Barbarians at the Gate?
650
650
23.2 What Determines Option Values? 652
608
Upper and Lower Limits on Option Values
21.9 Method 4: Divestitures,
The Determinants of Option Value
610
Option-Valuation Models
21.10 The Benefits and Costs of Mergers 610
23.3
655
657
Options on Real Assets
Questions 613
652
652
657
Options on Financial Assets
659
Minicase 616
Chapter 22
International Financial Management
22.1 Foreign Exchange Markets 620
Spot Exchange Rates
620
Forward Exchange Rates
624
Real and Nominal Exchange Rates
the Expected Spot Rate
Chapter 24
Risk Management 670
The Evidence on Risk Management
22.2 Some Basic Relationships 623
Inflation and Interest Rates
618
662
24.1 Why Hedge? 672
622
Exchange Rates and Inflation
Questions
24.2 Reducing Risk with Options 674
626
24.3 Futures Contracts 676
626
629
Interest Rates and Exchange Rates
673
The Mechanics of Futures Trading
677
Commodity and Financial Futures
679
Contracts 680
630
24.5 Swaps 681
22.3 Hedging Exchange Rate Risk 631
Transaction Risk 631
24.6 Innovation in the Derivatives Market 683
Economic Risk
24.7 Is “Derivative” a Four-Letter Word? 684
632
22.4 International Capital Budgeting 633
Net Present Values for Foreign Investments
Political Risk
635
633
Questions
686
Contents
Part Eight
Conclusion
Chapter 25
What We Do and Do Not Know about
Finance 690
25.1 What We Do Know: The Six Most Important Ideas
in Finance 692
Net Present Value (Chapter 5)
Efficient Capital Markets (Chapter 7)
692
692
MM’s Irrelevance Propositions (Chapters 16
and 17) 693
693
Agency Theory
696
How Can We Explain Capital Structure?
694
Why Are Financial Systems Prone to Crisis?
25.3 A Final Word 699
Questions
699
Appendix A A-1
Appendix B B
Risk and Return—Have We Missed
Something? 695
697
What Is the Value of Liquidity? 698
25.2 What We Do Not Know: Nine Unsolved Problems in
Finance 694
What Determines Project Risk and Present
Value? 694
697
How Can We Resolve the Payout Controversy?
How Can We Explain Merger Waves?
692
Risk and Return (Chapters 11 and 12)
Are There Important Exceptions to the
696
Credits C-1
Global Index IND
Index IND-5
698
697
CHAPTER
1
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T O N E
Introduction
To grow from small beginnings to a major corporation, FedEx needed to make good investment and financing
decisions.
T
4
Part One Introduction
1.1 Investment and Financing Decisions
as still a
sophomore at Y
guing that deliv
systems were not keeping up with increasing needs for speed and dependability.1 After
lea
deliv
ef
founded Federal Express.
Like man
w the need for an integrated air and ground
ge number of points more
very system. In 1971, at the age of 27, Smith
w million dollars, but this was far from
enough. The young compan
Dassault Falcon jets, build a central-hub facility, and hire and train pilots, deliv , and
of
f.
company’s shak
wn money.
In
y went liv
out of its Memphis hub. By then, the compan
vely
v
ed by a
uy the company. (Today
ver ex
In Nov
ved some financial stability
when it raised $24.5 million from venture capitalists, investment f
vide
wnership share. Eventually, venture capitalists inv
go deregulation allowed private firms to compete with the Postal
very. Federal Express responded by expanding its operations. It
acquired seven Boeing 727s, each with about seven times the capacity of the Falcon
jets. To pay for these new inv
selling shares of stock to the general public in an
The new
wners of the compan
y purchased.
From this point on, success followed success, and the company invested heavily to
e
fedex.com
Web site for online package tracking. It opened several new hubs across the United
States as well as in Canada, France, the Philippines, and China. In 2007 FedEx (as the
company was no
orld’s lar
planes. FedEx also inv
o’s
for $2.4 billion in 2004. By 2010, FedEx had about 270,000 employees, annual reveet value of $28 billion. Its name had become a
verb—to “FedEx a package” was to ship it ov
Even in retrospect, FedEx’s success was hardly a sure thing. Fred Smith’s idea was
inspired, but its implementation was complex and dif
e good
investment decisions. In the beginning, these decisions were constrained by lack of
funds. For example, used Falcon jets were the only option, given the young company’s
ies. As the company grew, its investment decisions became more complex. Which type
of planes should it buy? When should it expand coverage to Europe and Asia? How
many operations hubs should it build?
1
Legend has it that Smith received a grade of C on this paper. In fact, he doesn’t remember the grade.
Chapter 1
5
Goals and Governance of the Corporation
eep up with the increasing package volume and geographic coverage?
Which companies should it acquire as it expanded its range of services?
e
For e
w should it
raise the money it needed for investment? In the be
f
w, its range of choices expanded.
Ev
w questions. Ho
w big a
w man
sell?
As the company grew
wing money
vestors. At each point, it needed
ver potential
y. The
.
competitors, b
y’
ould hav
, but, lik
e good inv
Let’s widen our discussion. Table 1.1 gives an example of a recent investment and
v
our are
2
Santander’s
VMH’s in P
s in Tokyo. We have chosen v
TABLE 1.1
Examples of recent investment and financing decisions by major public corporations
2
LVMH (Moët Hennessy Louis V
w
“Moët Hennessy Louis Vuitton.”
ut “LVMH” really is short for
6
Part One Introduction
you are likely to be f
You have probably traveled on a Boeing jet, shopped
at W
ven a Ford, for example.
T
w. W
sensible—
at least there is nothing ob
why
The Investment (Capital Budgeting) Decision
capital budgeting or
capital expenditure
(CAPEX) decision
Decision to invest in
tangible or intangible
assets.
Investment decisions, such as those shown in Table 1.1, are often called capital
budgeting or capital expenditure (CAPEX) decisions. Some of the investments in
the table, such as W
s new stores or Union P
s new locomotives, involve
tangible assets—assets that you can touch and kick. Others involve intangible assets,
such as research and development (R&D), advertising, and the design of computer
software. For e
acturers invest billions every year on R&D for ne
VMH is estimated to spend
Most of the investments in Table 1.1 have long-term consequences. For example,
Boeing’
ver 30 years or more. Other investments
may pay off in only a few months. For example, with the approach of the Christmas
holidays, W
stores.
ver the following months, the company recovers its
investment in these inv
The world of b
v
v
y can k
v
dev
v
Airbus, has inv
w
v
v
v
smaller
v
.
v
e
v
wn in Table 1.1.
Not all capital investments succeed.
orldwide, soaked up $5 billion
in inv
break even but attracted only a small fraction of that target number. Iridium defaulted
y in 1999.
for just $25 million.
Although the investment in Iridium w
ve been rational given what was kno
as made. It
may have been a good decision thw
The Iridium system may have
been launched too soon and too ambitiously. (The system surviv
y and is
.3)
avor if
vestment analysis and apply them intelligently. We will cover
these tools in detail later in this book.
The Financing Decision
financing decision
The form and amount of
financing of a firm’s
investments.
s second main responsibility is to raise the mone
requires for its investments and operations. This is the
decision. When a
y needs to raise money, it can invite investors to put up cash in exchange for a
vestors’ cash plus a fixed rate
3
v
vestors who took ov
yw
satellite system.
Chapter 1
Goals and Governance of the Corporation
vestors, who contribute
lenders, that is, debt investors,
real assets
Assets used to produce
goods and services.
financial assets
Financial claims to the
income generated by
the firm’s real assets.
7
vestors receive shares of stock and become shareThe inv
. In the second case, the investors are
The choice between debt
capital structure decision. Here “capital” refers
Af
”
v
When
s prodvestment in real assets by issuing
vests, it acquires real
ucts and services.
to investors.
s real assets and on the income that those assets will produce.
cial asset also. It giv
s
operations can’
y and stake a claim on its real assets. Shares of stock and
v
securities.
The f
to borrow. It can issue debt to inv
w for
1 year or 20 years. If it borro
e the right to pay off the debt
all. It can borrow in P
ving and promising to repay
euros, or it can borrow dollars in New York. (As Table 1.1 shows, LVMH chose to borrow Swiss francs, but it could hav
wed euros or dollars instead.)
Self-Test 1.1
volved in many other day-to-day acti
w up in Table 1.1.
For e
y to another. Manuf
decide how much to invest in inventories of ra
Self-Test 1.2
8
Part One Introduction
1.2 What Is a Corporation?
corporation
A business organized as
a separat
owned by stockholders.
limited liability
The owners of a
corporation are not
personally liable for its
obligations.
▲
EXAMPLE 1.1
We hav
” But before going too f
ast, we need
to offer some basic definitions.
A
is a distinct, permanent legal entity. Suppose you decide to create a
4
You would work with a la
articles of incorporation,
ne
which set out the purpose of the business and how it is to be financed, managed, and
gov
ws of the state in which the business is
incorporated. For man
For example, it can enter into contracts, borrow or lend money, and sue or be sued. It
pays its own taxes (but it cannot vote!).
so
shareholders or stockholders.5 The
do not directly o
usiness’s real assets (factories, oil wells, stores, etc.). Instead
they have indirect o
A corporation is legally distinct from the shareholders. Therefore, the shareholders have limited liability and cannot be held personally responsible for the
corporation’s debts. When the U.S. financial corporation Lehman Brothers failed
in 2008, no one demanded that its stockholders put up more money to cover
Lehman’s massive debts. Shareholders can lose their entire investment in a corporation, but no more.
Business Organization
Suppose you buy a building and open a restaurant. You have invested in the building itself, kitchen equipment, dining-room furnishings, plus various other assets. If
you do not incorporate, you own these assets personally, as the sole proprietor of
the business. If you have borrowed money from a bank to start the business, then
you are personally responsible for this debt. If the business loses money and cannot pay the bank, then the bank can demand that you raise cash by selling other
assets—your car or house, for example—in order to repay the loan. But if you incorporate the restaurant business, and then the corporation borrows from the bank,
your other assets are shielded from the restaurant’s debts. Of course, incorporation
also means that the bank will be more cautious in lending, because the bank will
have no recourse to your other assets.6
Notice that if you incorporate your business, you exchange direct ownership of
its real assets (the building, kitchen equipment, etc.) for indirect ownership via
financial assets (the shares of the new corporation).
vately owned by a
small group of investors, perhaps the company’s managers and a few backers. In this
y is closely held. Eventually,
ets such as the New Y
wn as public companies.
vate hands, and many public companies
4
US
” “Incorporated,” or “Inc.,” as in
oup, Inc.
v
Anonyme”).
AG” (“
5
.
6
t have to ask if your b
Chapter 1
9
Goals and Governance of the Corporation
may be controlled by just a handful of investors. The latter cate
atch Group.
v
together own the business. An individual may have 100 shares, receive 100 votes, and
be entitled to a tiny fraction of the f
s income and v
sion fund or insurance company may own millions of shares, receive millions of votes,
and have a correspondingly large stak
s performance.
Public shareholders cannot possibly manage or control the corporation directly.
y elect a board of directors,
monitor their performance. This separation of ownership and control giv
tions permanence. Ev
ves.
Today’
w investors without disrupting the
operations of the b
ve forever, and in practice
they may survive many human lifetimes. One of the oldest corporations is the
Hudson’
y, which was formed in 1670 to profit from the fur trade
The company still operates as one of Canada’s
leading retail chains.
wnership and control can also have a downside, for it
can open the door for managers and directors to act in their own interests rather than in
We return to this problem later in the chapter.
and money
urdensome for small businesses.
s legal machinery.
gal entity, it is tax
ed again when they receive divi-
dends from the compan
by b
ed just once as personal income.7
Other Forms of Business Organization
Corporations do not hav
usinesses such as those
listed in Table 1.1. You can organize a local plumbing contractor or barber shop as a
ger businesses
or businesses that aspire to grow. Small “mom-and-pop” businesses are usually organized as sole proprietorships.
What about businesses that grow too large for sole
ut don’t want to reorganize as corporations? For example, suppose
you wish to pool money and e
usiness associates. You
partnership
w deciface unlimited liability. If the b
responsible for all the business’s debts.
P
ve a tax advantage. P
pay income taxes.
Some b
the limited liability adv
classif
limited partnership, partners are
usiness and have unlimy they
inv
Many states allow
7
giv
ve to
ships (LLPs) or, equivalently, limited
ve limited
To av
10
Part One
Introduction
liability. Another variation on the theme is the professional corporation (PC), which is
commonly used by doctors, lawyers, and accountants. In this case, the business has
limited liability, but the professionals can still be sued personally, for e
malpractice.
Most large investment banks such as Morgan Stanle
v
gre
y reor
tions.
ganization does not work well when ownership is
1.3 Who Is the Financial Manager?
chief financial officer
(CFO)
Sets overall financial
strategy.
treasurer
Responsible for
financing, cash
management, and
relationships with banks
and other financial
institutions.
controller
Responsible for
budgeting, accounting,
and taxes.
ving? That simple question can be answered in
several ways. W
have a chief
(CFO), who oversees the w
f. As
you can see from Figure 1.1, the CFO is deeply involv
y and finanxecutiv
other top management.
inancial v
tion and e
vestors and the media.
Belo
treasurer and a controller.
s cash, raises ne
inv
s securities.
airs. Thus the treasurer’
whereas the controller ensures that the mone
s capital,
iciently.
Self-Test 1.3
In lar
ganizing and supervising the capital budgeting process. However, major capital investment projects are so
v
eting that managers
from these other areas are inevitably drawn into planning and analyzing the projects.
involved in capital budgeting too. For this reason we will use the term
FIGURE 1.1 Financial
managers in large
corporations.
Chapter 1
Goals and Governance of the Corporation
11
FIGURE 1.2 Flow of cash
between investors and the
firm’s operations. Key: (1)
Cash raised by selling
financial assets to investors;
(2) cash invested in the firm’s
operations; (3) cash
generated by the firm’s
operations; (4a) cash
reinvested; (4b) cash
returned to investors.
manager to refer to anyone responsible for an inv
vely for all the managers drawn into such decisions.
Because of the importance of many financial issues, ultimate decisions often rest by
la
or example, only the board has the legal
po
dele
vestment outlays,
but the authority to approv
ge inv
ver delegated.
Now let’s go beyond job titles. What is the essential role of the financial manager? Figure 1.2 gives one answer. The figure traces how mone
ws from investors to the corporation and back again to investors.
raised from inv
The cash could come from banks or
from securities sold to inv
ets. The cash is then used to pay
for the real assets (investment projects) needed for the corporation’s b
w
2). Later, as the b
w 3). That
cash is either reinvested (arrow 4a) or returned to the investors who furnished the
mone
w 4b
ws 4a and 4b
is constrained by the promises made when cash w
w 1. For example,
if the firm borrows money from a bank at arrow 1, it must repay this money plus
w 4b.
You can see examples of arrows 4a and 4b in Table 1.1.
velopment by reinv
w 4a). W
decided
w 4b). It could have chosen instead to pay the money out as additional cash dividends.
Notice ho
vestors.
volv
e good investment decisions. On the other hand, he or she deals
with financial institutions and other inv
ets such as the
New York Stock Exchange. W
markets in the next chapter.
1.4 Goals of the Corporation
Shareholders Want Managers to Maximize
Market Value
F
sity. For example, W
ver 300,000 shareholders. There is no way that these
vely involved in management; it would be lik
New York City by town meetings. Authority has to be delegated.
Ho
fectively delegate decision making when they all have difDelegation can work only if the shareholders have a common goal. Fortunately there
12
Part One
Introduction
inancial objectiv
the current market value of shareholders’ inv
es sense when the shareholders have access to
Access giv
xibility
to manage their own savings and consumption plans, lea
cial managers with only one task, to increase market value. For e
tion’s roster of shareholders will usually include both risk-av
investors. Y
xpect the risk-averse to say
alue, but don’t
touch too many high-risk projects.” Instead, they say, “Risky projects are okay, provided that e
too risky for my taste, I’ll adjust my inv
e it safer.” For examv
such as U.S. gov
f
y investments
increase market v
f than they would be if
y inv
wn.
▲
EXAMPLE 1.2
Value Maximization
Fast-Track Wireless shares trade for $20. It has just announced a “bet the company”
investment in a high-risk, but potentially revolutionary, WhyFi technology. Investors
note the risk of failure but are even more impressed with the technology’s upside.
They conclude that the possibility of very high future profits justifies a higher share
price. The price goes up to $23.
Caspar Milquetoast,
eholder, notes the downside risks
and decides that it’s time for a change. He sells out to more risk-tolerant investors.
But he sells at $23 per share, not $20. Thus he captures the value added by the
WhyFi project without having to bear the project’s risks. Those risks are transferred to
other investors, who are more risk-tolerant or more optimistic.
In a well-functioning stock market, there is always a pool of investors ready to
bear downside risks if the upside pot
iciently attractive. We know that the
upside potential w
icient in this case, because Fast-Track st
acted
investors willing to pay $23 per share.
ws, as the following self-test illustrates.
Self-Test 1.4
Sometimes you hear managers speak as if the corporation has other goals. For
example, they may say that their job is to “maximize profits.” That sounds reasonable. After all, don’t shareholders want their company to be profitable? But taken
literally, prof
ve. Here are two
reasons:
current profits by cutting back on outlays for maintenance or staf
ut that
will not add value unless the outlays were wasteful in the first place. Shareholders
will not welcome higher short-term prof
Chapter 1
Goals and Governance of the Corporation
2. A compan
and inv
13
s dividend
vestment.
In a free economy a f
ve if it pursues goals that reduce the
firm’s value. Suppose, for e
et
share. It aggressively reduces prices to capture new customers, even when this leads to
continuing losses. What w
As losses mount, it will find it
w money, and it may not even have sufficient profits
to repay existing debts. Sooner or later, however, outside investors would see an opportunity for easy money. They could b
e
sv
They
w
ference between the price paid for the f
alue
it would have under new management. Managers who pursue goals that destroy value
often land in early retirement. The natural financial objective of the corporation is
to maximize market value.
The Investment Trade-Off Okay, let’
e the objectiv
et
value, or at least adding market value. But why do some inv
et
value, while others reduce it? The answer is given by Figure 1.3, which sets out the
fundamental trade-off for corporate investment decisions.
posed inv
on hand to finance the project.
ahead. If he or she decides not to inv
holders, say as an extra dividend. (The investment and di
ws in Figure 1.3
ws 2 and 4b in Figure 1.2.)
s ownThe
v
v
inv
vesting
ould v
vestment project. If the investve on their o
holders would v
Figure 1.3 could apply to Union P
s decisions to invest in new locomotives.
Suppose Union Pacific has cash set aside to buy 20 new locomotives. It could go ahead
with the purchase, or it could choose to cancel the investment project and instead pay
invest for themselves.
Suppose that Union P
FIGURE 1.3 The firm can
either keep and reinvest cash
or return it to investors.
(Arrows represent possible
cash flows or transfers.) If
cash is reinvested, the
oppor
expected rate of return that
shareholders could have
obtained by investing in
financial assets.
s new-locomotiv
y as the
vestment in the stock market offers a 10% expected rate
14
Opportunity cost
of capital
Minimum acceptable
rate of return on capital
investment.
Part One
Introduction
of return. If the new locomotives offer a superior rate of return, say 20%, then Union
P
ould be happy to let the company keep the cash and invest it in
the new locomotives. If the new locomotives offer only a 5% return, then the stockinancial manager should turn the project down.
s proposed investments of
et (or in other f
kets), its shareholders will applaud the investments and the market v
will increase. But if the compan
et
value f
y can invest on
their own.
In our e
s
new locomotives is 10%.
hurdle rate or
opportunity cost of capital. It is called an
because it
depends on the alternative investment opportunities available to inv
markets. Whenev
vests cash in a new project, its shareholders lose
the opportunity to invest the cash on their own. Corporations increase value by accepting all inv
Notice that the opportunity cost of capital depends on the risk of the proposed
investment project.
verse. It’
because shareholders hav
y invest on their
own. The safest investments, such as U.S. government debt, offer lo
Investments with higher e
et, for e
ver painful losses. (The U.S. stock market fell 38% in 2008,
for example.) Other investments are riskier still. For example, high-tech growth stocks
ven more v
market overall.
ets to measure the opportunity cost of capital
for the f
s investment projects. The
e the opportunity cost of capital for
safe investments by looking up current interest rates on safe debt securities. F
y
investments, the opportunity cost of capital has to be estimated. W
task in Chapter 11.
Self-Test 1.5
The Ethics of Maximizing Value
Shareholders want managers to maximize the market value of their shares. But
perhaps this begs the question. Is it desirable for managers to act in the selfish
interests of their shareholders? Does a focus on enriching the shareholders mean
that managers must act as greedy mercenaries riding roughshod over the weak and
helpless?
Most of this book is dev
alue. None of
these policies requires gallops over the weak and helpless. In most instances, there is
alue) and doing good. The first step
Chapter 1
15
Goals and Governance of the Corporation
in doing well is doing good by your customers. Here is how Adam Smith put the
case in 1776:
It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, b
wn interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but
to their self-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their advantages.8
ied customers and loyal emplo
orkforce will probably end up with declinalue by
b
Of course, ethical issues do arise in business as in other walks of life. When the
ws and regulations
seek to prev
laws can help only so much. In business, as in other day-to-day affairs, there are also
unwritten rules of behavior. These work because ev
ws that such rules are in
the general interest. But the
w that their
air and
keeping one’s word are simply good business practices.
re
e, and each side knows that the other will not renege
later if things turn sour.
uy a well-known brand in a
et, you can be f
of the quality of what you are buying. Therefore, honest financial f
uild
long-term relationships with their customers and to establish a name for fair dealing
grity
who’s been swimming naked.”9 The tide went out in 2008 and a number of frauds
were exposed. One notorious example w
f.10 Individuals and institutions invested around $20 billion
with Madoff and were told that their investments had grown to $65 billion. That
ictitious. (It’s not clear what Madoff did with all
this money, but much of it was apparently paid out to early investors in the scheme
to create an impression of superior investment performance.) With hindsight, the
investors should not have trusted Madof
money to him.
Madoff’s Ponzi scheme was (we hope) a once-in-a-lifetime event. (Ponzi schemes
pop up frequently, but none has approached the scope and duration of Madoff’s.) It
was astonishingly unethical, ille
xample, at the
volving the investment bank Goldman Sachs. Some
ers believed that Goldman’
orst on Wall Street.
Others see them as simply an e
v
uyers and sellers.
8
Adam Smith,
1937; first published 1776), p. 14.
9
10
investors unbeliev
W
e and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (New York: Random House,
way
vestment company in 1920 that promised
vestors in Ne
v
vided by later investors to pay generous dividends to the original investors, thus promoting
W
prison sentence.
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Goldman Sachs Causes a Rumpus
It is not alw
w what is ethical behavior
y gray
or e
sive government? Should it emplo
veral simple situations that call for an ethically based decision, along with surve
Compare your decisions with those of the general public.
Self-Test 1.6
Do Managers Really Maximize Value?
Owner-managers hav
usiness.
They work for themselves, reaping the rewards of good work and suf
ties of bad work. Their personal well-being is tied to the v
In most lar
wners, and so managers may
be tempted to act in ways that are not in the best interests of shareholders. For example, the
verindulge in expense-account dinners.
16
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Things Are Not Always Fair in Love or Economics
They might shy away from attractive b
in empire-b
y are w
The
yees. Such problems can
agents of the owners, may
agency
agency problems
Managers are agents
for stockholders, but the
managers may act in
their own interests rather
than maximizing value.
have their o
.
problems.
These agency problems can sometimes lead to outrageous behavior. For example,
when Dennis Kozlowski, the CEO of Tyco, thre
his wife, he charged half of the cost to the company. Conrad Black, the boss of
y jet for a trip with his wife to Bora Bora.
These of course were e
xamples. The agency problems encountered in the
normal course of business are less blatant. But agenc
ver
managers think just a little less hard about spending money that is not their own.
y’s net revenue as a pie that is divided among a number of
claimants. These include the management and the workforce as well as the lenders and
y to establish and maintain the business. The gov-
stakeholder
Anyone with a financial
interest in the firm.
stakeholders
but their interests may not coincide.
All the stakeholders are bound together in a complex web of contracts and underor e
contract stating the rate of interest and repayment dates, perhaps placing restrictions
on di
v
rked
17
18
Part One
Introduction
out personnel policies that establish emplo
can’t de
ver every possible future ev
or e
for a fat salary the
xpected to w
s money on
unw
xpect managers always to act
on behalf of the shareholders? The shareholders can’t spend their lives watching
y
funds on the latest executive jet.
A closer look reveals sev
and managers are w
w
Legal and Regulatory Requirements
have a legal duty to act responsibly and in the interests of investors. For example, the
for public companies in order to ensure consistency and transparency.
ve often been portrayed as passive
w
Board of Directors
pendence. In response to Enron, W
y Act, known widely as SOX. SO
no
w meet in sessions without the CEO present. In addivities, SO
s accounting procedures and results.
Blockholders
ve thousands of individual
shareholders, they often also have blockholders, that is, individual investors that hold
individuals and families—for example descendants of a founder—other corporations,
institutional investors, pension funds, or foundations. When a 5% blockholder calls the
CFO, the CFO answers.11
ve become
more activ
vernance. More chief executives have been forced out in recent years, among them the
ucks, AIG, Fannie Mae, and Freddie Mac. Boards outside the
United States, which traditionally have been more management-friendly, have also
includes the heads of Royal Bank of Scotland, Peugeot Citroen, Lenovo, Swiss Re,
and Versace.
y of specialists.
vestors to buy, hold,
Specialist Monitoring
or sell the company’
e
The
vie
ving their loans.
ve schemes that prout little or nothing if they do not. For example,
usiness softw
ved total
y fraction ($250,000) of that
. The lion’
Compensation Plans
amount w
11
Ellison’
v
v
v
v
wner. For e
e in the company
y pretty much as he w
xtreme
ants to.
Chapter 1
19
Goals and Governance of the Corporation
Those options will be w
be highly v
alls from its 2010 level but will
ver, as founder of Oracle, Ellison holds
Ellison would
have worked with a different compensation package. But one thing is clear: He has a
et value.
W
holder wealth. But some schemes are not well designed, and in these cases poorly
v
ge windfall gains. For e
Nardelli’s roughly 6-year tenure as CEO of Home Depot, the stock price fell by more
val, Lowe’s, more than doubled.
as
ved a f well compensation package of about
.
Takeovers
The further a company’
pany to b
W
en over by
alls, the easier it is for another comThe old management team is then lik
eovers in Chapter 21.
v
xt election.
shareholders will attempt to convince the other shareholders to vote for their slate of
candidates to the board. If they succeed, a ne
or e
felt that the directors of Yahoo! were not acting in shareholders’ interest when they
rejected a bid from Microsoft. He therefore invested $67 million in Y
muscled himself and two lik
Y
e the “Wall Street Walk” by selling out and moving on to other investments. The Wall Street Walk can send a po
Shareholder Pressure
v
ment’s reputation and compensation. A lar
from stock options, which pay off if the stock price rises but are w
f
We do not want to leav
volved
to reconcile personal and corporate interests—to keep everyone w
increase the value of the whole pie, not merely the size of each person’s slice.
Agency problems are mitigated in practice in several ways: legal and
regulatory standards; compensation plans that tie the fortunes of the managers to the fortunes of the firm; monitoring by lenders, stock market analysts, and
investors, and ultimately the threat that poor
orming managers will
be fired.
Self-Test 1.7
Corporate Governance
Financial mark
irms that
can inv
ves from inv
only if investors are protected. This creates the need for a system of corporate
20
One
Introduction
governance so that mone
w to the right firms at the right times. Gov
includes well-designed incentives for managers, standards for accounting and disclosure to investors, requirements for boards of directors, and legal sanctions for
fraud or self-dealing by management.
gov
en down.
fectively and ethically
to deliver v
vernance is
w
.
Think, for e
viewed at the
ved and gre
outside investors. That financing was forthcoming because inv
pany to invest wisely. In other words, they had f
governance, and the
shareholder value.
orldwide tour of corporate gov
be aw
v
ws, re
. The dif
y, for example, banks
often o
agement or strategy of poorly performing companies. (Banks in the United States are
prohibited from lar
tions.) Large German f
ve tw
(Aufsichtsrat) and the management board (Vorstand). Half of the supervisory board’s
members are elected by emplo
ve two boards, one
including employee representatives.
1.5 Careers in Finance
Well over 1 million people work in the f
and many others w
We can’t tell you what
, but we can give you some idea of the v
xperience of a small sample of recent
graduates.12
We e
ace tw
inv
Therefore, as a ne
cial analyst, you may help to analyze a major new investment project. Or you may
y to pay for it, perhaps by ne
inancial analysts w
term finance, managing collection and investment of the company’
volved in
or e
s plant and equipment, or they may assist with the purchase and sale of
options, futures, and other exotic tools for managing risk.
Instead of w
The largest employers are banks. Banks collect deposits and
usinesses come to deposit cash or to seek
a loan. You could also work in the head of
to a large corporation.
y things in addition to lending money
y probably provide a
greater v
or example, if you work in the
ge bank, you may help companies to transfer
huge sums of money electronically as wages, tax
12
ut based on the actual e
v
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Working in Finance
Susan Webb, Research Analyst,
Mutual Fund Group
Albert Rodriguez, European Markets Group,
Major New York Bank
Richard Gradley, Project Finance,
Large Energy Company
Sherry Solera, Branch Manager, Regional Bank
also buy and sell foreign e
of those computer screens in a foreign exchange trading room. Another glamorous
vatives group, which helps companies to manage their risk by
b
This is where the mathematicians and
the computer b
ve.
Investment banks, such as Goldman Sachs or Mor
y, help companies sell
their securities to investors. They also have lar
assist f
gers and acquisitions. When f
e over
y is at stak
ve fast. Thus,
w
v
also pay v
The insurance industry is another large employer
involv
s liv
, but
businesses are also major customers. So, if you work for an insurance company or a
large insurance broker
Life insurance companies are major lenders to corporations and to investors in
commercial real estate. (Life insurance companies deploy the insurance premiums received from policyholders into medium- or long-term loans; banks specialize in shorter-term financing.) So you could end up negotiating a $50 million loan
for construction of a new shopping center or investigating the creditworthiness of
a family-owned manufacturing company that has applied for a loan to expand
production.
21
22
Part One
Introduction
Then there is the business of “managing money,” that is, deciding which companies’ shares to invest in or how to balance investment in shares with safer securities,
such as the bonds (debt securities) issued by the U.S. Treasury.
T
y from individuals
and inv
orks with the investment manager to decide
which should be bought and sold. Man
vestor e
ork as a financial analyst in
the inv
y
vest
bank that manages money for retirement funds, univ
vestment management companies and private individuals to invest in securities. They emplo
e the trades.
They also employ f
decide which to buy or sell.
Inv
w York, as
y of the lar
vestment management companies tend to be more scattered. For example, some of the largest insurance
y inv
ve
large businesses outside the United States. Finance is a global business. So you may
spend some time w
v
Tokyo, Hong Kong, or Singapore.
w graduates are
in the region of $45,000, rather more in a major New York investment bank and somewhat less in a small re
Table 1.2 gives you an
ard to when you become a senior
f
.
If you would lik
logging on to www.careers-in-finance.com.
inance, financial planning, insurance, investment banking, money
management, and real estate. F
vailWe have listed several
other useful job Web sites on our book Web site at www.mhhe.com/bmm7e.
TABLE 1.2
Representative
compensation for jobs in
finance
Source: Careers-in-Business, LLC.;
.careers-in-finance.com,
.salary.com.
Chapter 1
Goals and Governance of the Corporation
23
1.6 Topics Covered in This Book
This book covers investment decisions, then financing decisions, and then a variety
of planning issues that require an understanding of both investment and financing.
But first there are three further introductory chapters that should be helpful to
readers making a first acquaintance with financial management. Chapter 2 is an
overview of financial markets and institutions. Chapter 3 reviews the basic concepts of accounting, and Chapter 4 demonstrates the techniques of financial statement analysis.
In P
ferent aspects of the investment decision.
the problem of how to v
alue.
Nine chapters dev
orth
y cost may seem excessive, but that problem is not so simple in practice.
W
w long-liv
y assets are valued, and that requireets. For example:
• Ho
•
measured?
•
•
•
ets?
w can these risks be
v
v
vestors in common stocks reasonably expect to receive?
Intelligent capital b
other questions about ho
Financing decisions occupy P
ets work.
The two chapters in P
y and explain how and when these
vers debt policy and dividend policy. We will also
ind themselv
xcessiv
wing, or both.
P
v
We cov
cial planning and the management of w
Working capital
term assets (such as cash, inv
y due from customers), net of
banks, or other short-term lenders).
P
vers three important problems that require decisions about both investment
and financing. First we look at mergers and acquisitions.
usiness at home are
present overseas, b
aces the additional compligulations
imposed by foreign institutions and gov
hedge or lay off risks.
P
w
irst to solve an
ably f
Snippets of History
Now let’
sions are made today
ets also have an interesting history. Look at
the growth of bacteria anticipated the mathematics of compound interest, and continuWe have keyed each of these episodes to the chapter of the
book that discusses its topic.
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Finance through the Ages
SUMMARY
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
CHAPTER
2
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T O N E
Introduction
The façade of the New York Stock Exchange is imposing.
I
32
One
Introduction
2.1 The Importance of Financial Markets
and Institutions
In the previous chapter we e
v
order to survive and prosper.
v
decisions. But of course those decisions are not made in a vacuum. They are made in a
vironment. That environment has two main segments: financial markets
and financial institutions.
Lar
v
y need to grow. When they hav
y have to invest the cash, for example, in bank accounts or in securities.
Let’s take Apple Computer, Inc., as an example.
Table 2.1 presents a timeline for
tapped by
in 2010. The initial investment in Apple stock was $250,000. Apple was also able to
ment. Apple w
e discuss accounts payable in Chapter 19.)
Then, as Apple grew, it was able to obtain sev
Apple
shares to private venture capital investors. (We discuss venture capital in Chapter 15.)
TABLE 2.1
Examples of
financing decisions by Apple
Computer
Chapter 2
Financial Markets and Institutions
33
1
to public investors. There was also a follo
Once Apple was a public company, it could raise financing from many sources, and
it was able to pay for acquisitions by issuing more shares. We show a few examples in
Table 2.1.
uted
cash to investors by stock repurchases in the early 1990s. But Apple hit a rough patch
in 1996 and 1997, and regular dividends were eliminated. The compan
w
vate investors in order to cov
its recovery plan. Apple was generally profitable, despite the rough years, and it
wth by plo
had cumulated to $37.2 billion by 2010.
wn for its product innovations, including the Macintosh computer,
the iPod, and the iPad.
act, the story of
as vital to Apple’s gro
. Would we have iMac
computers, iPods, or iPads if Apple had been forced to operate in a country with a
primitiv
initely not.
A modern financial system of
y different forms, depending on
the company’s age, its growth rate, and the nature of its business. For example, Apple
relied on v
ets. Still later, as the compan
xamples given in Table 2.1. But the table does not begin to
cov
We will encounter
many other channels later in the book, and new channels are opening up re
. The
v
e
small loans to b
orld.
2.2 The Flow of Savings to Corporations
The money that corporations invest in real assets comes ultimately from savings
by investors. But there can be many stops on the r
een savings and
corporate investment. The road can pass through financial markets, financial
intermediaries, or both.
Let’
e Apple in
ws in Figure 2.1 sho
w of sa
holders in this simple setting. There are two possible paths:
w
v
s operations. Reinv
additional savings by existing shareholders. The reinvested cash could have been paid
out to those shareholders and spent by them on personal consumption. By not
ve reinvested their savings in the corporation.
Cash retained and reinvested in the firm’s operations is cash saved and invested
on behalf of the firm’s shareholders.
e out a
bank loan, for example.
ve raised money by attracting savings
accounts. In this case investors’ sa
No
Apple Computer in 2010.
What’
Apple’
venues in 2010 were $65 billion,
wed total assets of $75 billion. The scope of Apple’s activities
1
allowed the emplo
for Apple.
v
viously held by Apple employees. Sale of these shares
Apple holdings but did not raise additional
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Micro Loans
has also expanded: It no
orldwide. Because of
Apple attracts investors’ savings by a v
can do so because it is a lar
w of sa
2.2. Notice two key
dif
Figure 2.1
w sa
vestors
worldwide. Second, the sa
FIGURE 2.1 Flow of savings
to investment in a closely
held corporation. Investors
use savings to buy additional
shares. Investors also save
when the corporation
reinvests on their behalf.
FIGURE 2.2 Flow of
savings to investment for a
large, public corporation.
Savings come from investors
worldwide. The savings may
flow through financial markets
or financial intermediaries.
The corporation also reinvests
on shareholders’ behalf.
34
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
It’s Not Your Grandfather’s NYSE
or both. Suppose, for example, that Bank of
w issue
vestor b
of
es that $60,000, along with money raised by the rest of the issue, and
Apple.
vestor’s sa
Apple.
Of course our Italian friend’s $60,000 doesn’
ve at Apple in an envelope marked “From L. DaVinci.” Investments by the purchasers of the Bank of
America’s stock issue are pooled, not segregated. Sr. DaVinci would own a share of
all of Bank of America’s assets, not just one loan to Apple. Nevertheless, investors’
sa
wing through the financial mark
Apple’s
capital investments.
The Stock Market
financial market
Market where securities
are issued and traded.
primary market
Market for the sale of
new securities by
corporations.
A
market is a market where securities are issued and traded.
or a corporation, the stock mark
et.
w
xpand dramatically. At some point the f
organized exchange such as the New Y
or IPO. The buyers of the IPO are helping to finance
s inv
uyers become part-owners of the
ailure. (Most investors in the Internet IPOs of
w sorely disappointed, b
. If
only we had bought Apple shares on their IPO day in 1980 . .
tion’s IPO is not its last chance to issue shares. For example, Bank of America went
ut it could make a ne
w.
A ne
y and
wn as a
,
primary market. But in addition to helping companies raise new
ets also allow inv
es. For
e
Apple stock at the same
time that Jones inv
Apple. The result is simply a transfer
35
36
secondary market
Market in which
previously issued
securities are traded
among investors.
Part One
Introduction
of o
fect on the company itself. Such
purchases and sales of existing securities are known as
ansactions, and
they take place in the secondary market.
y for
v
y can sell
their stock in the secondary market when they need the cash.
Stock mark
ets,
wn the
common equity of the firm. Y
ture decision as “the choice between debt and equity financing.”
es place on the NYSE and on
NASDA
, high-tech companies. The busi, however, as the box on page 35 explains.
No
and needs to be f
orld. For e
Apple’s stock is
traded on the NASDAQ mark
y on the Deutsche Börse. China
T
v
y, Toyota, Unilever,
and over 400 other overseas firms have listed their shares on the NYSE. W
Other Financial Markets
fixed-income market
Market for debt securities.
capital market
Market for long-term
financing.
money market
Market for short-term
financing (less than
1 year).
ets. The Apple bond
issue in 1994 was a public issue (see Table 2.1). Table 1.1 in the previous chapter also
gives examples, including the debt issues by Honda and LVMH.
A fe
xchanges, but
over the counter,
ork of banks
and securities dealers. Gov
ver the counter.
A bond is a more complex security than a share of stock. A share is just a proportional ownership claim on the f
. Bonds and other debt
securities can v
, in the degree of protection or collateral offered by
the issuer, and in the lev
e
vel of interest rates. Many can be
“called” (repurchased and retired) by the issuing company before the bonds’ stated
maturity date. Some bonds can be converted into other securities, usually the stock
of the issuing company. You don’t need to master these distinctions now; just be
aware that the debt or
market is a complicated and challenging place.
A corporation must not only decide between debt and equity finance. It must also
consider the design of debt. We return to the trading and pricing of debt securities in
Chapter 6.
The markets for long-term debt and equity are called capital markets. A firm’s
capital
inancing. Short-term securities are traded in the money
markets. “Short term” means less than 1 year. For example, large, creditworthy
commercial paper,
debt issues with maturities of at most 270 days. Commercial paper is issued in the
money market.
Self-Test 2.1
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Prediction Markets
www.intrade.com
www.biz.uiowa.edu/iem
The financial manager re
examples, with references to the chapters where the
• Foreign-exchange markets (Chapter 22). An
trade must be able to transfer mone
oreign exchange is traded ov
largest international banks.
• Commodities markets
exchanges, such as the New Y
Trade. You can b
platinum, and so on.
•
ets. Here are three
ork of the
ganized
, silver,
vativ
or
e
date. The option’
can be traded by a dif
vative security called a futures contract.
37
38
Part One
Introduction
vativ
e
ets where
s exposure to v
usiness risks. For
y may wish to lock in the future price of natu-
w materials.
Wherever there is uncertainty, investors may be interested in trading, either to specveral ne
ets have been created that allow punters to bet on a single event.
ets can reveal people’s
predictions about the future.
Financial Intermediaries
financial intermediary
An organization that
raises money from
investors and provides
financing for individuals,
corporations, or other
organizations.
mutual fund
An investment company
that pools the savings of
many investors and
invests in a por olio of
securities.
A
pro
intermediary is an organization that raises money from investors and
ganizations. F
the road between savings and real investment.
Why is a f
ferent from a manuf
ays, for example, by taking deposits or selling insurance policies. Second, it invests that money in
assets, for example, in stocks,
bonds, or loans to businesses or individuals. In contrast, a manufacturing company’s
main investments are in plant, equipment, or other real assets.
W
pension funds.
Mutual funds raise money by selling shares to investors. The investors’ money is
pooled and inv
vestors can buy or sell shares in
mutual funds as they please, and initial inv
Vans Explorer Fund, for e
ket value of $10 billion at the end of 2010. An investor in Explorer can increase her
stake in the fund’
uying additional shares, and so gain a higher share of
2
s subsequent di
vestment.3
The adv
ery wealthy, you
cannot b
iciently.
er investors low-cost diversification and professional management. For most investors, it’s mor
icient to buy a mutual fund than to assemble
a diversified por olio of stocks and bonds.
et,” that is, to generate
-than-average returns. Whether
they can pick winners consistently is another question, which we will address in
Chapter 7.
In exchange for their services, the fund’s managers take out a management fee.
xpenses of running the fund. For Explorer, fees and expenses
. This seems reasonable, but watch out:
The typical mutual fund charges more than Explorer does. In some cases fees and
e
. That’s a big bite out of your investment return.
2
ut inv
They pay no tax, providing that all income from
di
this income.
3
Explorer, like most mutual funds, is an open-end
w inv
uy back e
depend on the fund’s net asset value (NAV) on the day of purchase or redemption. Closed-end funds have a
ed number of shares traded on an exchange. If you w
vest in a closed-end fund, you must b
Chapter 2
39
Financial Markets and Institutions
Mutual funds are a stop on the road from sa
vestment. Suppose
w issue of shares by Bank of
Again we
sho
w of savings to inv
ws:
hedge fund
A private investment
pool, open to wealthy or
institutional investors,
that is only lightly
regulated and therefore
can pursue more
speculative policies
than mutual funds.
pension fund
Fund set up by an
employer to provide for
employees’ retirement.
There are 7,600 mutual funds in the United States. In fact there are more mutual
funds than public companies! The funds pursue a wide variety of investment stratevidend payouts. Some specialize in high-tech growth stocks. Some “balanced” funds offer mixtures of stocks
gions. For example, the Fidelity Investments mutual fund group sponsors funds for Canada, Japan, China, Europe,
and Latin
Like mutual funds, hedge funds also pool the sa
vestors and
invest on their behalf. But they differ from mutual funds in at least two ways. First,
because hedge funds usually follow comple
v
gies, access is
wledgeable investors such as pension funds, endowment funds, and
wealthy individuals. Don’
vestment b
to attract the most talented managers by compensating them with potentially lucrative,
ed percentage
performance-related fees.4 In contrast, mutual funds usually char
of assets under management.
Hedge funds follow many different investment strate
e a profit
by identifying o
alued stocks or mark
e will not go into
fall.)5 “V
hedge funds take bets on f
volved in merger negotiations, others look for mispricing of conv
e positions in currencies and interest rates.
Hedge funds manage less money than mutual funds, but they sometimes take v
positions and have a lar
et.
vesting savings. Consider a pension plan set
up by a corporation or other organization on behalf of its employees. There are several
types of pension plan.
ution plan.
In this case, a percentage of the employee’s monthly paycheck is contributed to a
pension fund. (The emplo
ute 5%, for example.)
yees are pooled and invested in securities or
mutual funds. (Usually the emplo
inv
gies.) Each employee’
ws over the years as
contributions continue and investment income accumulates. The balance in the plan
can be used to finance living expenses after retirement. The amount available for
retirement depends on the accumulated contrib
on the investments.6
4
ge indeed. For example, The Wall Street Journal estimated that hedge
fund manager John P
5
v
b
wner.
bought back at a lo
as sold for.
6
In a
plan, the emplo
v
the employer invests in the pension plan.
s accumulated investment v
cov
yer must put in more money
giving w
ge enough to
40
Part One
Introduction
vestment. They provide professional
v
They also hav
butions are tax-deductible, and inv
wn.7
ed until
ehicles for savings. Private pension
plans held $5.7 trillion in assets in 2010.
Self-Test 2.2
Financial Institutions
financial institution
A bank, insurance
company, or similar
financial intermediary.
Banks and insurance companies are
institutions.8
vest savings. Institutions raise
ays, for e
cies, and they pro
e a mutual fund, they not
only invest in securities but also loan money directly to individuals, businesses, or
other organizations.
Commercial Banks
States. They v
midgets like the Tightwad Bank with some $20 million.
States, they are generally not allowed to make equity inv
company negotiates a 9-month bank loan for $2.5 million.
w of savings is:
y and, at the same time, provides a
w it as needed.
Investment Banks We hav
from depositors and other inv
9
Inv
Investment banks
7
emplo
employer.
8
We may be dra
y
e loans to businesses and individuals.
y do not
xcept that the employer inv
v
A mutual fund
-
9
accept deposits and sa
uyers. Inv
xcept as bridge loans
merchant banks.
commercial
Savings
y out mostly to individuals, for example, as mortgage
y to b
vidueov
v
Chapter 2
41
Financial Markets and Institutions
usually make loans to companies. Instead, they advise and assist companies in raising
financing. For example, investment banks
stock offerings by purchasing
the ne
y at a ne
to investors. Thus the issuing compan
ed price for the new shares, and the
investment bank takes responsibility for distrib
vestors. W
Investment banks also advise on takeovers, mergers, and acquisitions. The
inv
v
vidual and institutional
investors. The
xchange, commodities, bonds, options,
and derivatives.
Inv
vest their own mone
entures. For
e
v
ays, elecorld.
gest inv
werhouses. They include Goldman
Sachs, Morgan Stanley
the major commercial banks, including Bank of
ve
10
inv
Insurance Companies
for the
financing of business. The
and bonds, and they often mak
Suppose a compan
issue a bond directly to investors, or it could ne
company:
ve inv
The money to make the loan comes mainly from the sale of insurance policies. Say
you b
y on your home. You pay cash to the insurance compan
y) in exchange. You receive no interest payut if a fire does strike, the company is obliged to cover
the damages up to the policy limit.
vestment. (Of course,
vent that you hope to avoid. But if a fire does occur,
you are better off getting a return on your investment in insurance than not having
insurance at all.)
y will issue not just one policy b
verages out,” leaving the company with a predictable obligation to its policyholders as a group. Of course the insurance company must charge enough for its policies to cov
ve costs, pay policyholders’ claims, and generate
a profit for its stockholders.
Self-Test 2.3
10
America o
ynch, one of the largest inv
vestments.
42
Part One
Introduction
Total Financing of U.S. Corporations
Figure 2.3 shows the investors in bonds and other debt securities.
vestors—mutual funds, pension funds, insurvidual inv
the debt pie. The other slices represent the rest of the world (investors from outside the
United States) and v
gories.
Figure 2.4 sho
e a stronger showing, with
36.5% of the total. Pension funds, insurance companies, and mutual funds add up to
48.5% of the total. Remember
other companies. The rest-of-the-world slice is 13.3%.
The aggre
There is $11.4
Figure 2.3 and $21 trillion of equity behind Figure 2.4
($21,000,000,000,000).11
Chapter 14 revie
FIGURE 2.3 Holdings of
corporate and foreign bonds,
third quarter 2010. The total
amount is $11.4 trillion.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Research and Statistics, Flow of Funds
Accounts, Table L.212 (
.federalreserve.gov).
FIGURE 2.4 Holdings of
corporate equities, third
quarter 2010. The total
amount is $21.0 trillion.
Source:
vernors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Research and Statistics, Flow of Funds
Accounts, Table L.213 (
.federalreserve.gov).
11
e
et value of shares issued by U.S.
Chapter 2
43
Financial Markets and Institutions
2.3 Functions of Financial Markets
and Intermediaries
Financial markets and intermediaries provide financing for business. They channel
savings to real investment.
2.2 of this chapter
vious.
Transporting Cash across Time
Individuals need to transport expenditures in time. If you have money now that you
wish to save for a rainy day, you can (for example) put the money in a savings account
at a bank and withdraw it with interest later. If you don’t have money today, say to buy
, you can borrow money from the bank and pay off the loan later
inance
pro
wers
y were forced to spend income as it
ves. Of course, indi
Firms with good inv
wing or selling ne
y gov
Young people sa
years into the future by means of a pension fund. They may ev
y.
viduals or f
e out newspaper
adv
W
v
is not just a matter of av
. Followup is needed. For example, banks don’t just loan money and walk away. They monitor
wer to mak
wer’s credit stays solid.
Risk Transfer and Diversification
Financial markets and intermediaries allow investors and businesses to reduce
and reallocate risk. Insurance companies are an obvious example. When you buy
homeowner’
ire, theft, or accidents. But your policy is not a v
y. It div
by issuing thousands of policies, and it expects losses to average out over the policies.12
wners.
Investors should diversify too. For example, you can buy shares in a mutual fund
that holds hundreds of stocks. In fact, you can buy index funds that invest in all the
stocks in the popular market indexes. For example, the V
x fund holds
et index. (The “S&P 500”
tracks the performance of the largest U.S. stocks. It is the index most used by professional investors.) If you b
x. These risks are averaged out by diversificavel of the stock market as a
whole will fall. In fact, we will see in Chapter 11 that inv
with market risk, not the specific risks of indi
Index mutual funds are one way to invest in widely div
w
cost. Another route is provided by e
of stocks that can be bought or sold in a single trade.
s
12
damage thousands of homes at once.
reinsurance
t always av
uy
44
Part One
Introduction
Poor’
et indexes.
v
benchmark S&P 500 index was about $94 billion by early-2011. Y
uy
DIAMONDS, which track the Dow Jones Industrial Average; QUBES or QQQs,
which track the NASDAQ 100 inde
Vanguard ETFs that track the V
Total Stock Market index, which is a bask
United States. You can also buy ETFs that track foreign stock markets, bonds, or
commodities.
ays more efficient than mutual funds. To b
,
you simply make a trade, just as if you bought or sold shares of stock.13 To invest in an
open-ended mutual fund, you have to send money to the fund in exchange for newly
vestment, you have to notify the fund,
which redeems your shares and sends you a check or credits your account with the
fund. Also, many of the larger ETFs charge lower fees than mutual funds. Vanguard’s
T
. For a $100,000 investment, the fee is only .0007 3 100,000 5 $70.
Financial markets provide other mechanisms for sharing risks. For example, a
wheat f
y are each e
est. The farmer w
er about high
prices. They can both rest easier if the baker can agree with the f
uy wheat in
the future at a fix
ould be dif
er
and the f
e a deal.
Fortunately no dating service is needed: Each can trade in commodity markets, the
f
er as a buyer.
Liquidity
liquidity
T
o sell an asset
on short notice at close
to the market price.
vide liquidity,
vestment back into cash when needed. Suppose you deposit $5,000 in a savings bank on
w deposits to
make a 6-month construction loan to a real estate developer
The bank can giv
thousands of depositors, and other sources of f
, it can make an
illiquid loan to the developer financed by liquid deposits made by you and other customers. If you lend out your money for 6 months directly to the real estate developer,
you will hav
ving it 1 month later.14
y are traded more or less
et.
vestor who puts $60,000 into Bank of
ver that money on short notice. (A $60,000 sell order is a drop
in the buck
olume of Bank of
vest
.
Of course, liquidity is a matter of degree. Foreign exchange markets for major curxceptionally liquid. Bank of America or Deutsche Bank could buy $200
million w
ye, with hardly an
exchange rates. U.S. T
g-
13
ties. ETF issuers mak
14
the real estate dev
ve). But ETFs do not have managers
wn to index
ed bask
x or basket.
t repay all depositors simultaneously. To do so, it would hav
wers.
not liquid.
wals, with each depositor
ed up by the U.S.
Chapter 2
45
Financial Markets and Institutions
Liquidity is most important when you’
w
y all at once, you will probably
wn the price to some extent. If you’re patient and don’
vestors with a large, sudden sell order
terms. It’s the same problem you may face in selling real estate. A house or condoyou’re not going to get full value.
The Payment Mechanism
Think how inconvenient life would be if you had to pay for ev
suppliers. Checking accounts, credit cards, and electronic transfers allow indi
ve payments quickly and safely ov
are the obvious pro
ut they are not alone. For example, if
you buy shares in a mone
et mutual fund, your money is pooled with that of
other inv
Y
on this mutual fund investment, just as if you had a bank deposit.
Information Provided by Financial Markets
ets, you can see
w
v
xpect
ets is often essential to a
vings.
s job
Commodity Prices
v
The catalysts include platinum, which is traded on
the New York Mercantile Exchange.
acturer of catalytic conv
.
How much per ounce should the company budget for purchases of platinum in that
month? Easy: The company’
et price of platinum on the New
Y
v
as the closv
.) The CFO can lock
The details of such a trade are covered in Chapter 24.
Interest Rates
w
financing. She considers an issue of 30-year bonds. What will the interest rate on the
bonds be? T
xisting bonds traded in
f
ets.
The results are shown in Table 2.2. Notice how the interest rate climbs as credit
quality deteriorates:
gest, safest companies, which are rated Aaa (“triple-A”),
The interest rates for Aa, A, and Baa
climb to 5.70%, 5.98%, and 6.32%, respectively
garded as
investment grade, that is, good quality, but the next step do
es the investor into
TABLE 2.2
Interest rates on
long-term corporate bonds,
May 2010. The interest rate is
lowest for t
issuers. The rate rises as credit
quality declines.
Source: Barclays corporate bond indexes.
46
Part One
junk bond
Introduction
. The interest rate for Ba debt climbs to 7.34%. Single-B companies
vestors demand 8.49%.
ho
the interest rate on ne
as a Baa-rated company
to raise ne
ed-income markets to forecast
or example, if Catalytic Concepts can qualify
wn in Table 2.2, it should be able
Company Values How much was Alaska Air Group w
How about Bob Evans Farms, Callaway Golf, Estée Lauder, or GE? Table 2.3 shows
the answers. We simply multiply the number of shares outstanding by the price per
share in the stock market. Investors valued Alaska Air Group at $2,155 million, GE at
$222 billion.
Stock prices and company values summarize investors’ collective assessment
of how well a company is doing, both its curr
ormance and its future prospects. Thus an increase in stock price sends a positive signal from investors to
managers.15 That is why top management’
ed to stock prices. A
manager who o
y’
et value. This reduces agenc
y will be motivated to increase the
This is one important advantage of going public. A private company can’t use its
but the shares will not be v
cost of capital
Minimum acceptable
rate of return on capital
investment.
et.
Cost of Capital Financial managers look to financial markets to measure, or
at least estimate, the cost of capital
s investment projects. The cost of
capital is the minimal acceptable rate of return on the project. Investment projects
of
y
add value; they make both the f
inancially. Projects offering rates of return less than the cost of capital subtract value and should not
en.16
Thus the hurdle rate for inv
the corporation. The e
v
ets determines the cost of capital.
The opportunity cost of capital is generally not
a loan from a bank or insurance company. If the compan
TABLE 2.3
Calculating
the total market values of
Alaska Air Group and other
companies in Febr
(Shares and market values
in millions. Ticker symbols
in parentheses.)
Yahoo! Finance, finance.yahoo.com
15
W
t claim that investors’ assessments of v
w
b
W
es by investors, for e
the gross ov
verage, however
cial mark
. We’
16
v
or e
vest in pollution control equipment for
a factory. The equipment may not generate a cash return, but may still be worth investing in to meet le
ethical obligations.
Chapter 2
47
Financial Markets and Institutions
inv
xpected rate of return that investors
can achiev
ets at the same lev
The e
on risk
v
wing.
We introduced the cost of capital in Chapter 1, b
We cover the cost of capital in detail in Chapters 11 and 12.
Self-Test 2.4
2.4 The Crisis of 2007–2009
y questions, but it settled one question
conclusively: Yes,
ets and institutions are important. When
markets and institutions ceased to operate properly, the world was pushed into a global
recession.
e and other central banks follo
ubble in 2000.
ge balance-of-payments surpluses in
v
This also
helped to push down interest rates and contribute to the lax credit.
Banks took advantage of this cheap money to expand the supply of subprime mortgages to lo
wers. Man
ould-be homeowners with low
initial payments, offset by significantly higher payments later.17 (Some home buyers
were betting on escalating housing prices so that the
ed in.) One lender is even said to have adv
dubbed its “NINJA” loan—NINJA standing for “No Income, No Job and No Assets.”
Most subprime mortgages were then packaged together into mortgage-backed securities
vestors who could
ge quantities of the loans on their own books or
sold them to other banks.
The widespread av
At that point prices
wners began to def
ge inv
vestments
that were held in tw
as on the
ver
y, and the U.S. Federal Reserv
JPMorgan Chase.
v
e
over the giant federal mortgage agencies F
had invested sev
ed securities.
Over the next fe
ynch
and Lehman Brothers were in danger of failing. On September 14, the gov
America to take ov
However
y protection the next day. Two days later the gov
insurance company AIG, which had insured huge v
ed
17
With a so-called
loan
month’
homeowner was burdened by an ever
as often not even suf
ould need to be paid off.
v
48
Part One
Introduction
securities and other bonds against default. The following day, the T
veiled its
ould be next to fall made banks reluctant to lend
to one another, and the interest rate that they charged for such loans rose to 4.6%
above the rate on U.S. T
ve T
than .5%.)
,
orst setbacks since the Great Depression. Unemployment rose rapidly, and b
Few developed economies escaped the crisis. As well as suf
in their o
ets, man
ge investments in U.S.
A roll call of all the banks that had to be bailed out by their governments w
veral pages, b
w members of that unhappy
band: the Ro
Allied
Austria, and
West Lb in Germany.
Who was responsible for the f
e for
its policy of easy money. The U.S. government also must take some of the blame for
encouraging banks to expand credit for low-income housing. The rating agencies were
at fault for pro
ard
went into default. Last but not least, the bankers themselves were guilty of promoting
As we suggested in the last chapter, managers
were probably aw
gy of originating massiv
was likely to end badly. Perhaps they were trying to squeeze in one more fat bonus
before the game ended.
gely an agency
problem—a failure to incenti
y gov
mountains of debt. By 2010 investors were becoming increasingly concerned about
the position of Greece, where for many years gov
well ahead of revenues. Greece’s position was complicated by its membership in the
y euro club.
wing was in euros,
the gov
v
y and could not simply print more euros
to service its debt. Investors began to contemplate the possibility of a Greek gov
ment def
. As we write
Attention
vernment put up
34 billion euros to take over the
SUMMARY
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
WEB EXERCISES
finance.yahoo.com
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
CHAPTER
3
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T O N E
Introduction
Accounting and finance are not the same, but accounting basics are necessary to understand finance.
I
54
One
Introduction
3.1 The Balance Sheet
ter.
company’
pro
balance sheet
Financial statement that
shows the firm’s assets
and liabilities at a
particular time.
vide the investor with information about the
.
s balance sheet, the income statement, and a
1
ws. We will revie
Firms need to raise cash to pay for the many assets used in their businesses. In the
process of raising that cash, they also acquire liabilities to those who provide funding.
The balance sheet
ticular moment. The assets—representing the uses of the funds raised—are listed on
the left-hand side of the balance sheet. The liabilities—representing the sources of that
funding—are listed on the right.
wn as
liquid assets. The accountant puts the most liquid assets at the top of the list and works
down to the least liquid. Look, for example, at Table 3.1
ws the consolidated
balance sheet for Home Depot (HD), at the end of 2009.2 (“Consolidated” simply
means that the balance sheet shows the position of Home Depot and any companies it
owns.) Y
etable securiut had not yet received payment.
These payments are due soon and therefore the balance sheet shows the unpaid bills or
accounts receivable (or simply receivables
The next asset consists of
inv
These may be (1) ra
suppliers, (2) w
aiting to be shipped from the
w
or Home Depot, inv
gely of goods in the w
ventories would be more skewed
toward ra
ork in progress. Of course, there are always some items that
don’
, other current assets.
Up to this point all the assets in Home Depot’
ely to be used or
turned into cash in the near future. They are therefore described as current assets. The
ne
-lived or
and include items
such as buildings, equipment, and vehicles.
alue of Home Depot’
, plant, and
This is what the assets originally cost. But they are
ely to be w
w. For example, suppose the company bought a deliv
2 years ago; that v
alue today of the
van, b
ould be costly and somewhat subjective. Accountants rely instead on
depreciation in the v
xceptions the
or example, in the case of that delivery van the accounalue. So if
ould show that
accumulated depreciation is 2 3 $5,000 5 $10,000. Net of depreciation the value is
only $5,000. Table 3.1 shows that Home Depot’s total accumulated depreciation on
alue
in the accounts is only $37,345 2 $11,795 5 $25,550
1
In addition, the company pro
, which shows how much of the
vidends and how much money has
been raised by issuing new shares or spent by repurchasing stock. We will not review in detail the statement of
shareholders’ equity.
2
We hav
Chapter 3
55
Accounting and Finance
TABLE 3.1
Note: Column sums subject to rounding error.
Source: Derived from Home Depot annual reports.
In addition to its tangible assets, Home Depot also has valuable intangible assets,
Accountants are generally reluctant to record these intangible assets in the balance sheet
unless they can be readily identified and valued.
There is, however
xception.
businesses in the past, it has paid more for their assets than the value sho
accounts.
wn in Home Depot’
” Most
No
where the money to b
y’
ws
yo
. For e
. It also o
.
y
wed
ve been delivered b
wn as accounts
payable (or payables
. The
current liabilities.
Home Depot’
$10,363 million. Therefore the difference between the value of Home Depot’
2 $10,363 5 $3,537 million.
wn as Home Depot’s net current assets or net working capital. It roughly measures
the company’s potential reservoir of cash.
Belo
v
s long.Y
banks and other investors hav
Home Depot’
or example,
when Home Depot buys goods from its suppliers, it has a liability to pay for them;
ws from the bank, it has a liability to repay the loan.
ve f
s assets.
ver after the liabilities
have been paid off belongs to the shareholders.
wn as the shareholders’
56
Part One
Introduction
. For Home Depot the total value of shareholders’ equity amounts to
Table 3.1 shows that Home Depot’
investors. A much lar
Depot has retained and reinvested in the business on the shareholders’ behalf.3 Finally,
ge negative number, 2
This represents the amount
that Home Depot has spent on b
The money to repurchase them
.
Figure 3.1 shows ho
. There
are tw
ixed” assets, which may be either tangible or intangible. There are
also tw
,
and long-term liabilities.
The difference between the assets and the liabilities represents the amount of the
.
W
equity is what is left over when the liabilities of the f
Shareholders’ equity 5
2 total liabilities
(3.1)
Self-Test 3.1
common-size balance
sheet
All items in the balance
sheet are expressed as
a percentage of total
assets.
common-size
balance sheet, which reexpresses all items as a percentage of total assets. Table 3.2 is
Home Depot’s common-size balance sheet.
w
etable
s assets than they did in the
previous year. There may be good reasons for this, but the manager might wish to
By the way, it is easy to obtain the financial statements of almost any publicly
traded f
vailable on the Web. You also can
ey f
Y
finance.yahoo.com)
or Google Finance (finance.google.com).
FIGURE 3.1
3
Y
y has b
ept in the business may have been used to buy new
arehouses, and so on. T
Home Depot’
etable securities.
Chapter 3
Accounting and Finance
57
TABLE 3.2
Note: Column sums subject to rounding error.
Source: Home Depot annual report, 2009.
Book Values and Market Values
e a distinction between the book values
et values.
alued according to generally accepted accounting
principles,
GAAP. These state that assets must be sho
historical cost adjusted for depreciation. Book v
are therefore
“backw
The
or e
Home Depot b
et the building would sell for $40 million.
alue of the building w
et v
s asset.
Or consider a specialized plant that Intel develops for producing special-purpose
The book v
w chip
makes the existing one obsolete. The market value of Intel’s new plant could fall by
50% or more. In this case market value would be less than book value.
The difference between book value and market v
for others. It is zero in the case of cash but potentially v
ed assets where
of the assets sho
generally accepted
accounting principles
(GAAP)
Procedures for preparing
financial statements.
book value
Value of assets or
liabilities according to
the balance sheet.
the asset ov
verning the depreciation of asset values do not
et value.
et v
ed assets usually is much
higher than the book value, but sometimes it is less.
the accountant simply records the amount of money that you hav
.
F
et value of that promise. For e
w, the accounts show a book
liability of $1 million.
the v
58
One
Introduction
repaid for sev
The accounts still show a liability of $1 million, but how
much your debt is worth depends on what happens to interest rates. If interest rates rise
after you have issued the debt, lenders may not be prepared to pay as much as
all, they may be prepared to pay more than
4
et value of a long-term liability may be higher or lower than
the book value. Market values of assets and liabilities do not generally equal their
book values. Book values are based on historical or original values. Market values measure current values of assets and liabilities.
The difference between book value and market value is likely to be greatest for
shareholders’ equity. The book value of equity measures the cash that shareholders
hav
uted in the past plus the cash that the compan
vested
in the business on their behalf. But this often bears little resemblance to the total market value that inv
, don’t try telling the
shareholders that the book value is satisfactory—they won’t want to hear. Shareholdet value of their shares; market value, not book value,
holders happy will focus on market values.
W
market-value balance sheet. Like a conventional balance sheet, a market-value balance sheet lists the
s assets, b
et v
cal cost less depreciation. Similarly, each liability is sho
et value. The
difference between the market values of assets and liabilities is the market value
of the shareholders’
laim. The stock price is simply the market value of
shareholders’
y the number of outstanding shares.
▲
EXAMPLE 3.1
Market- versus Book-Value Balance Sheets
Jupiter has developed a revolutionary auto production process that enables it to
produce cars 20% mor
iciently than any rival. It has invested $10 billion in producing its new plant. To finance the investment, Jupiter borrowed $4 billion and
raised the remaining funds by selling new shares of stock in the firm. There are
currently 100 million shares of stock outstanding. Investors are very excited about
Jupiter’s prospects. They believe that the flow of profits from the new plant justifies a
stock price of $75.
If these are Jupiter’s only assets, the book-value balance sheet immediat
er
it has made the investment is as follows:
BOOK-VALUE BALANCE SHEET FOR JUPITER MOTORS
(Figures in billions of dollars)
Liabilities and
Shareholders’ Equity
Assets
Auto Plant
$10
Debt
Shareholders’ equity
$4
6
Investors are placing a market value on Jupiter’
share times 100 million shares). We assume that the debt outstanding is worth $4
billion.5 Therefore, if you owned all Jupiter’s shares and all its debt, the value of
your investment would be $7.5 1 $4 5 $11.5 billion. In this case you would own
the company lock, stock, and barrel and would be entitled to all its cash flows.
4
5
We will show you how changing interest rates affect the market v
v
Chapter 3
59
Accounting and Finance
Because you can buy the entire company for $11.5 billion, the total value of
Jupiter’s assets must also be $11.5 billion. In other words, the market value of the
assets must be equal to the market value of the liabilities plus the market value of
the shareholders’
.
We can now draw up the market-value balance sheet as follows:
MARKET-VALUE BALANCE SHEET FOR JUPITER MOTORS
(Figures in billions of dollars)
Liabilities and
Shareholders’ Equity
Assets
Auto Plant
$11.5
Debt
Shareholders’ equity
$4
7.5
Notice that the market value of Jupiter’s plant is $1.5 billion more than the plant
cost to build. T
erence is due to the superior profits that investors expect the
plant to earn. Thus, in contrast to the balance sheet shown in the company’s
books, the market-value balance sheet is f
ard-looking. It depends on the
profits that investors expect the assets to provide.
et value generally exceeds book value? It shouldn’t be.
ve to raise money to invest in v
y believe
the projects will be w
Y
find that shares of stock sell for more than the value shown in the company’s books.
Self-Test 3.2
3.2 The Income Statement
income statement
Financial statement that
shows the revenues,
expenses, and net
income of a firm over
a period of time.
If Home Depot’
income statement is like a video. It shows how profitable the f
past year.
Table 3.3. You can see that during 2009
Home Depot sold goods worth $66,176 million and that the total expenses of acquiring and selling these goods were 43,764 1 $15,907 5 $59,671 million. The largest
expense item, amounting to $43,764 million, consisted of the cost of goods sold,
which included the acquisition cost of its products, the wages of its employees, and
other e
Almost all the remaining expenses
ve expenses such as head of
ution.
In addition to these out-of-pocket expenses, Home Depot also made a deduction for
the value of the plant and equipment used up in producing the goods. In 2009 this
charge for depreciation w
Thus Home Depot’s earnings before interwere
EBIT 5 total revenues 2 costs 2 depreciation
5 66,176
2 59,671 2 1,806
5 $4,699 million
60
Part One
Introduction
TABLE 3.3
Source: Derived from Home Depot annual report, 2009.
As we
saw earlier
vestment in plant and equipment by
wing. In 2009 it paid $676 million of interest on this borrowing.
v
es.
lion. The $2,661 million that was left over after paying interest and taxes belonged to
vidends and
reinvested the remaining $1,136 million in the business. Presumably, these reinvested
funds made the company more valuable.
v
w
ings in Table 3.1 increased by $1,136 million in 2009, from $12,452 million to $13,588
million. However
because Home Depot sold some of its treasury stock during the year.
common-size income
statement
All items on the income
statement are expressed
as a percentage of
revenues.
prepare a common-size income
. In this case, all items are expressed as a
percentage of revenues. The last column of Table 3.3 is Home Depot’
income statement. You can see, for e
66.1% of revenues and that selling, general, and administrative expenses absorb a further 24.0%.
Profits versus Cash Flow
pan
1. Depreciation.
o reasons why prof
s accountants prepare the income statement, they
ut then divides these payments into two
xpenditures (such as wages) and capital expenditures (such as the
purchase of ne
wever
purchased, the accountant makes an annual charge for depreciation.
ver its forecast life.
not deduct the expenditure on new
, even though cash is paid out. However
does
deduct depreciation on assets previously purchased, ev
paid out. For example, suppose a $100,000 investment is depreciated by $10,000 a
Chapter 3
61
Accounting and Finance
year.6 This depreciation is treated as an annual e
went out of the door when the asset w
or this reason, the
noncash expense.
To calculate the cash produced by the business, it is necessary to add
back the depreciation charge (which is not a cash payment) and to subtract
the expenditure on new capital equipment (which is a cash payment).
2. Cash versus accrual accounting. Consider a manufacturer that spends $60 to
ut its customers
The following diagram sho
s cash
ws. In period 1 there is a cash
of $60. Then, when customers pay their
bills in period 3, there is an
of $100.
1$100 (collect payment)
1
2
3
Period
2$60 (buy goods)
It w
w was negative) or that it was e
w was positive).
looks at when the sale was made (period 2 in our e
the revenues and expenses associated with that sale. For our company the income
statement would show:
Revenue
less Cost of goods sold
Profit
$100
60
$ 40
This practice of matching revenues and expenses is known as accrual accounting.
Of course, the accountant cannot ignore the actual timing of the cash expenexpense but as an investment in inv
goods are taken out of inventory and sold, the accountant shows a reduction in
inv
T
ws,
we need to subtract the investment in inv
wn in the balance sheet:
Period:
Cost of goods sold (income statement)
1 Investment in inventories (balance sheet)
5 Cash paid out
1
2
0
60
60
60
(60)
0
to collect its bills.
receivable in the balance sheet is increased to show that the company’s customers
owe an extra $100 in unpaid bills. Later, when the customers pay those bills in
vable are reduced by $100. Therefore, to go from the
6
W
62
One
Introduction
revenues sho
investment in receivables:
ws, we need to subtract the
Period:
2
Sales (income statement)
2 Investment in receivables (balance sheet)
5 Cash received
W
the key points as follows: Cash
3
100
0
100 (100)
0 1100
ut for no
low is equal to the cost of goods sold, which is
shown in the income statement, plus the change in inventories. The cash that
the company receives is equal to the sales shown in the income statement less
the change in uncollected bills.
▲
EXAMPLE 3.2
Profits versus Cash Flows
Suppose our manufacturer spends a further $80 to produce goods in period 2. It
sells these goods in period 3 for $120, but customers do not pay their bills until
period 4.
The cash flows from these transactions are now as follows:
$120
ent)
$100
(collect payment)
1
2$60
(buy goods)
2
3
4 Period
2$80
(buy more goods)
How do the new tr
ect the income statement and the balance
sheet? The income statement will match costs with revenues and record the cost of
goods sold when the sales are made in periods 1 and 2. T
erence between
the costs shown in the income statement and the cash flows is recorded as an
investment (and later, disinvestment) in inventories. Thus, in period 1 the accountant shows an investment in inventories of $60 just as before. In period 2 these
goods are taken out of inventory and sold, but the firm also produces a further $80
of goods. Thus there is a net increase in inventories of $20. As these goods in turn
are sold in period 3, inventories are reduced by $80. The following table confirms
low in each period is equal to the cost of goods sold that is
shown in the income statement plus the change in inventories.
Period:
Cost of goods sold (income statement)
1 Investment in inventories (balance sheet)
5 Cash paid out
1
0
60
60
2
60
260 1 80 5 20
80
3
80
280
0
The following table provides a similar r
erence between
the revenues shown in the income statement and the cash inflow:
Chapter 3
63
Accounting and Finance
Period:
Sales (income statement)
2 Investment in receivables (balance sheet)
5 Cash received
2
100
100
0
3
120
2100 1 120 5 20
1100
4
0
2120
1120
In the income statement the accountant records sales of $100 in period 1 and $120 in
period 2. The fact that the firm has to wait for payment is recognized in the balance
sheet as an investment in receivables. The cash that the company receives is equal
to the sales shown in the income statement less the investment in receivables.
Self-Test 3.3
3.3 The Statement of Cash Flows
cash when it buys ne
to the bank and dividends to the shareholders.
to keep track of the cash that is coming in and going out.
We have seen that the f
w can be quite different from its net income.
These dif
o reasons:
1. The income statement does not recognize capital expenditures as e
. Instead, it spreads those expenses over time
2.
revenues and expenses are recognized when sales are made, rather than when the
cash is received or paid out.
statement of cash flows
Financial statement that
shows the firm’s cash
receipts and cash
payments over a period
of time.
The
ws sho
ations as well as from its inv
ws from operw
w
from operations.
usiness activities. Next comes the cash that Home Depot has invested in plant and equipment or in
the acquisition of new businesses.
acti
w debt or stock. W
The f
w from operations, starts with net income but adjusts that
f
volv
going out. Therefore, it adds back the allowance for depreciation because depreciation
w, even though it is treated as an expense in the income statement.
An
subtracted from net income, since these
absorb cash but do not show up in the income statement. Conversely, any additions to
added to net income because these release cash. For
e
vable is added to
income, because the collection of payment on pre
firm. In addition, Home Depot decreased inv
The decrease in
inventory levels freed up cash.
v
w from operations. On the other hand, Home Depot does
vities. Table 3.4
64
One
Introduction
TABLE 3.4
Source: Calculated from data in Tables 3.1 and 3.3.
not pay all its bills immediately. These delayed payments show up as payables. In
2009 Home Depot had fe
decreased by $36
We have pointed out that depreciation is not a cash payment; it is simply the accountant’
wever
uys and pays for new capital
equipment. Therefore, these capital e
w statement. Y
w
capital equipment. Notice that (gross) property, plant, and equipment on Home Depot’s
balance sheet increased by precisely this amount. On the other hand, Home Depot
freed up $141 million by selling off other investments (this amount shows up as the
ed assets plus other assets). Total cash used by
investments was $981 million.
Finally
w statement sho
vities. Home Depot used 74711,005 5
7
pay di
T
w inv
Therefore,
T
7
Y
wever, it is usual to include
This is because, unlike dividends, interest payments
.
business e
Chapter 3
65
Accounting and Finance
In Millions
Cash flow from operations
2 Cash flow for new investment
1 Cash provided by new financing
5 Change in cash balance
$4,788
2 981
22,905
1 902
Look back at Table 3.1 and you will see that cash accounts on the balance sheet did
Self-Test 3.4
Free Cash Flow
free cash flow
Cash available for
distribution to investors
after firm pays for new
investments or additions
to working capital.
s activities. It
shows ho
s day-to-day operations and how much
has come from the issue of new stock or debt. It also shows whether this cash was paid
out to investors or reinvested in new plant and equipment or w
however, you may w
w how much cash the company has available for distribution to investors after it has paid for any new capital investment or additions to
w
s free cash w.
ing operations is equal to
(EBIT) 2 taxes 1 depreciation
Not all of this cash is av
net investments in w
v
s investors, however. As we’ve discussed,
ventory or receivables, soak up cash. So
orking capital e
ed assets, and these investments also use cash. Thus,
Free cash
▲
EXAMPLE 3.3
5 EBIT 2 taxes 1 depreciation
2 change in net working capital
2 capital expenditures
Free Cash Flow for Home Depot
We use both the income statement and the statement of cash flows to compute
Home Depot’s free cash flow. From the 2009 income statement, EBIT was $4,699
million, taxes were $1,362 million, and depreciation expense was $1,806 million.
From the statement of cash flows (Table 3.4), the change in working capital was
2$321 million (representing a net disinvestment in working capital that released
cash), and net capital expenditures were $981 million. Therefore, Home Depot’s
free cash flow was
Free cash flow 5 $4,699 2 $1,362 1 $1,806 2 (2$321) 2 $981 5 $4,483 million
Some of this money was paid out to Home Depot’s investors as interest or dividends.
The remainder was used to buy back stock or repay debt.
66
One
Introduction
3.4 Accounting Practice and Malpractice
y
y focuses
vestors wait to see
whether the company can meet or beat the forecasts.
all, even if it is only a
cent or two, can be a big disappointment. Investors might judge that if you could not
xtra cent or tw
ay.
Managers complain about this pressure, but do they do an
nately
e
eyed about 400 senior managers.8 Most of the managers said that accounting earnvestors. Most admitted to
adjusting their f
v
vestors
. For e
in R&D, adv
gets.
irm’
y can instead
Accounting Standards Board (FASB) and its generally accepted accounting principles
(GAAP). Yet, inevitably
ve room for discretion, and managers
e adv
way to satisfy investors. In more e
y leeway in
accounting rules:
• Revenue recognition. As we saw abov
ways obvious. For
example, suppose that you sell goods today but you give the customer the right to
” Hav
deliv
companies hav
or
example, in 1997 the head of Sunbeam, “Chainsaw” Al Dunlap, allegedly moved
c
. Between 1997 and 2001 Xerox also
took an overly optimistic view of its revenues. Whenever a customer signed a longy machine, Xerox book
as signed instead of spreading them
ov
• Cookie-jar r
W
wth, at least until 2008 when it suddenly collapsed in the
w e of the meltdo
, it emerged in 2003
that Freddie achiev
e accounts.
Normally, such accounts are intended to allow for the likely impact of events that
ailure of customers to pay their bills. But
Freddie seemed to “ov
e” against such contingencies so that it could
“release” those reserves and bolster income in a bad year. Its steady growth was
•
infamous for its special-purpose vehicles, which allo
y, Enron became
ge potential
companies in which it had an ownership stake. To present a f
ve recognized these potential liabilities on its balance sheet. But
8
J
ey
Accounting and Economics 40 (2005), pp. 3–73.
”
Chapter 3
Accounting and Finance
67
ehicles—in the
middle of its transactions. The ambiguity of ownership resulting from these
technically independent entities led Enron to exclude these liabilities from its own
• Mark-to-market accounting. Many assets and liabilities, such as buildings,
emplo
ven some infrequently traded securities, do not
have easily observ
cost. But advocates of mark-to-market accounting believ
would giv
et value of
et prices
may no longer be indicative of fundamental value. This was a contentious issue in
v
mark
y were allo
wns on assets
es it
irm.
▲
EXAMPLE 3.4
Lehman Brothers’ Repurchase Agreements
As the financial crisis of 2007–2009 worsened, Lehman Brothers desperately looked
for a way to improve its apparent financial health. It did so using an arcane
accounting trick that removed about $50 billion from its balance sheet. The trick
was called Repo 105. Lehman sold $50 billion of bonds to several other investment
banks with an agreement that it would repurchase those bonds at a slightly higher
price within a week or so. This arrangement is thus called a repurchase or “repo”
agreement. Everyone knows that a repurchase agreement is not really a sale of
the bonds—it is for all intents and purposes a loan, with the higher repurchase
price the implicit interest payment. The bonds serve only as collateral—if Lehman
defaults on the promised repurchase, it will not get its bonds back. Repurchase
agreements are thus commonly, and properly, treated in U.S. law as loans. But in
this case Lehman entered into the transaction through its Eur
ice, and
pledged bonds worth more than 105% of the cash it received. This loophole
allowed it to obtain an opinion from a British law firm that the repo could qualify
under English law as a true sale of assets. Lehman’s plan was to use the money it
received from selling the bonds to pa
. Then, er it had
filed its quarterly financial reports, it would borrow the funds necessary to repurchase the bonds. But until that time it would look less indebted than it actually
was. The firm (barely) follow
er of the law but used the discretion allowed
to it under accounting practice to paint a misleading picture of its actual condition. By the way, Lehman was not alone in using “window dressing” to pretty up its
balance sheet around a quarterly financial report. For example, Bank of America
ed to similar (though far smaller) transactions at the end of several fiscal
quarters between 2007 and 2009.
Investors w
act that some companies seem particularly prone to
ast and loose with accounting practice. They refer to
such companies as having “low-quality” earnings, and the
lower v
accounting scandals. Firms such as Global Crossing, Qwest Communications, WorldCom, and F
And this was not exclusively a U.S. phenomenon. P
y, was dubbed “Europe’s
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Accounting Convergence?
ev
v
y.
Vivendi Unias accused of accounting fraud.
In response to these and other scandals, in 2002 Congress passed the SarbanesOxley Act, widely known as SOX.
X created the Public Accounting Ov
versee the auditing of public companies, and it requires that
But managers and investors w
SOX and the b
ve gone too far. The costs of
xible regulations are pushing some corvate ownership. Some blame SOX and onerous
re
panies hav
There is also a vigorous debate ov
v
w York.
v
e to v
ve been engaged
ve lob. The
3.5 Taxes
Taxes often hav
how corporations and inv
Therefore, we should explain
ed.
Corporate Tax
Companies pay tax on their income. Table 3.5 sho
w rates of
ut for large companies (those with income over
9
Thus for ev
When f
y are allowed to deduct expenses. These
expenses include an allowance for depreciation. However
venue
9
68
.
Chapter 3
TABLE 3.5
69
Accounting and Finance
Corporate tax
rates, 2011
TABLE 3.6
Firms A and B
both have earnings before
interest and taxes (EBIT) of
$100 million, but A pays out
part of its profits as debt
interest. This reduces the
corporate tax paid by A.
Note: Figur
.
types of equipment.
10
The company is also allowed to deduct interest paid to debtholders when calculatut di
These
di
-tax income. Table 3.6 pro
how interest payments reduce corporate taxes.
The bad ne
venues increases taxable
es. The good ne
xtra
dollar of expense reduces taxable income by $1 and therefore reduces taxes by 35 cents.
For example, if the f
ws money, ev
reduces taxes by 35 cents.
Self-Test 3.5
y pay 35% of the prof
venue
Service. But the process doesn’t work in rev
fers a loss, the IRS
does not simply send it a check for 35% of the loss. However, the f
losses back, deduct them from taxable income in earlier years, and claim a refund of
past tax
ard and deducted from taxable income in
the future.11
Personal Tax
Table 3.7 sho
rate also increases. Notice also that the top personal tax rate is higher than the top corporate rate.
10
If the company assumes a slower rate of depreciation in its income statement than the Internal Revenue Serge sho
s life
than the actual tax payment. This dif
We
will tell you more about depreciation allowances in Chapter 9.
11
70
TABLE 3.7
Part One
Introduction
Personal tax
rates, 2011
marginal tax rate
Additional taxes owed
per dollar of additional
income.
The tax rates presented in Table 3.7 are mar
tax rates. The marginal tax rate
is the tax that the individual pays on each extra
or example, as a
single taxpayer, you w
your income is below $8,500, but once income exceeds $8,500, you would pay
15 cents of tax on each e
xt
$26,000 (ie., 34,500 2 8,500), and 25% of the remaining $5,500:
Tax 5 (.10 3 $8,500) 1 (.15 3 $26,000) 1 (.25 3 $5,500) 5 $6,125
average tax rate
Total taxes owed divided
by total income.
The average tax rate is simply the total tax bill divided by total income. In this
example it is $6,125/$40,000 5 .153 5 15.3%. Notice that the average rate is below
the marginal rate. This is because of the lo
Self-Test 3.6
The tax rates in Table 3.7
The treatment of dividend income in the United States leads to what is commonly
tax
Then, if the company pays a dividend out of this after-tax
es on the distribution. The original
ed first as corporate income and again as dividend income. Suppose
instead that the compan
The dollar escapes
usiness expense that
reduces the firm’s taxable income.
Capital gains are also taxed, but only when the gains are realized. Suppose that you
bought Bio-technics stock when it was selling for 10 cents a share. Its mark
today is $1 a share. As long as you hold on to your stock, there is no tax to pay on your
gain. But if you sell, the 90 cents of capital gain is taxed. The marginal tax rate on
capital gains for most shareholders is 15%.
Financial managers need to w
vestment income
because tax polic
viduals are willing to pay for the company’s stock or bonds. W
xt.
The tax rates in Table 3.7 apply to indi
investors in corporate securities. These institutions often have special tax provisions. For example, pension funds are not taxed on interest or dividend income or on
capital gains.
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SUMMARY
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEM
WEB EXERCISES
finance.yahoo.com
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.irs.gov
moneycentral.msn.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHAPTER
4
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
6
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T O N E
Introduction
When managers need to judge a firm's performance, they start with some key financial ratios.
I
4.1 Value and Value Added
How Financial Ratios Help to Understand Value Added
The good ne
y are usually easy to calculate. The bad
news is that there are so many of them. To make it worse, the ratios are often presented
in long lists that seem to require memorization first and understanding maybe later.
We can mitigate the bad news by taking a moment to preview what the ratios are
measuring and how the ratios connect to the ultimate objective of value added for
Shareholder value depends on good investment decisions.
evaluates inv
veral questions, including: Ho
vestments relative to the cost of capital? Ho
sured?
itability depend on? (We will see that it depends on efficient use
vious
v
av
v
sold for cash)?
xpected setbacks.
Figure 4.1
what more detail. The boxes on the
left are for investment, the boxes on the right for financing. In each box we have posed
a question and given e
manager can use to answer the question. For example, the bottom box on the f
Figure 4.1 asks about ef
iciency are turnover ratios for assets, inventory, and accounts receivable.
FIGURE 4.1
An organization chart for financial ratios. The figure shows how common financial ratios and other measures
relate to shareholder value.
80
Chapter 4
81
Measuring Corporate Performance
The two bottom box
verage (the amount of
debt financing) is prudent and whether the f
.
verage include debt ratios, such as the ratio of
debt to equity, and interest coverage ratios.
quick, and cash ratios.
We will explain ho
Figure 4.1.
For no
ws how they relate to the objectiv
alue.
No
irst task is to measure value. We will
explain market capitalization, market value added, and the market-to-book ratio.
4.2 Measuring Market Value and Market
Value Added
Twenty years hav
You are well into your
w money to Home Depot stock.
You could be an investment
market capitalization
Total market value of
, equal to share
price times number of
shares outstanding.
market value added
Market capitalization
minus book value of
.
bank
Depot’s credit standing. You could be the treasurer or CFO of Home Depot or of one
of its competitors. You want to understand Home Depot’s v
mance. How w
Home Depot’s common stock closed 2009 at a price of $28.72 per share. There
were 1,693 million shares outstanding, so Home Depot’s market capitalization or
et cap” was $28.72 3 1,693 5
big number, of course, but Home Depot is a big company. Home Depot’
have, ov
vested billions in the company. Therefore, you decide to compare Home Depot’s market capitalization to the book value of Home Depot’s equity.
The book v
ve inv
Y
duced in Tables 4.1 and 4.2.1 At the end of 2009, the book value of Home Depot’s
equity was $19,393 million. Therefore, Home Depot’s market value added, the differet v
shareholders have inv
as $48,623 2 $19,393 5 $29,230 million.
TABLE 4.1
Income
statement for Home Depot,
2009
Source: Home Depot annual report, 2009.
1
For conv
W
The
82
Part One
Introduction
TABLE 4.2
Home Depot’s Balance Sheet (millions of dollars)
Source: Home Depot annual reports.
In other w
v
uted about $19 billion and ended
up with shares w
They have accumulated nearly $30 billion in
et value added.
The consultancy firm EVA Dimensions calculates market value added for a
large sample of U.S. companies. Table 4.3 shows a few of the firms from EVA’s
list. ExxonMobil heads the group. It has created $148.5 billion of wealth for
its shareholders. Xerox is near the bottom of the class: The market value of
its shares is $9.1 billion less than the amount of shareholders’ money invested in
the firm.
83
Chapter 4
TABLE 4.3
Stock-market measures of company performance, July 2010. Companies are ranked
by market value added (dollar values in millions).
Source: We are grateful to EVA Dimensions for providing these statistics.
market-to-book ratio
Ratio of market value of
equity to book value of
equity.
Exxon is a large firm. Its managers have lots of assets to work with. A small firm
could not hope to create so much extra value.
analysts also like to calculate how much value has been added for each dollar that
shareholders have invested. To do this, they compute the ratio of market value to
book value. For example, Home Depot’s market-to-book ratio at the end of 2009
was2
5
book value of equity
5
$48,623
5 2.5
$19,393
In other words, Home Depot has multiplied the v
2.5 times.
Table 4.3 also shows mark
much higher market-to-book ratio than Exxon. But Exxon’
ger scale.
vestment
et value added is
Self-Test 4.1
The market-value performance measures in Table 4.3 have three drawbacks.
First, the market value of the company’
vestors’ expectations
about future performance. Investors pay attention to current profits and investment,
of course, but they also avidly forecast investment and growth. Second, market valy risks and ev
ager’s control. Thus, market v
w well the corporation’s
management is performing. Third, you can’t look up the market value of privately
owned companies whose shares are not traded. Nor can you observe the market
value of divisions or plants that are parts of larger companies. Y
et
values to satisfy yourself that Home Depot as a whole has performed well, but you
can’t use them to drill down to compare the performance of the lumber and home
2
viding stock price by book v
84
Part One
Introduction
improvement divisions. T
W
alue added (EVA).
.
4.3 Economic Value Added and Accounting
Rates of Return
w up an income statement, the
venues and then
deduct operating and other costs. But one important cost is not included: the cost of
ys.
alue,
all costs, including
the cost of its capital.
vestment. It is an
the e
cost of capital, because it equals
v
ets. The
inv
economic value
added (EVA)
After-tax operating
income minus a charge
for the cost of capital
employed. Also called
residual income.
vesting on their own.
including the cost of capital, is called the company’s economic value added or EVA. The term “EVA” w
w
& Co., which did much to develop and promote the concept. EVA is also called residual income.
In calculating EVA, it’s customary to take account of all the long-term capital contributed by investors in the corporation. That means including bonds and other longT
total
capitalization, is the sum of long-term debt and shareholders’ equity.
At the end of 2008 Home Depot’s total capitalization amounted to $27,444, the sum
. This w
tive amount that had been invested by Home Depot’s debt and equity investors. Home
Depot’s cost of capital was about 7.5%.3 So we can conv
lars by multiplying total capitalization by 7.5%: .075 3 $27,444
5 $2,058
million. To satisfy its debt and equity inv
income of $2,058 million.
No
vestors. In 2009 debt investors received interest income
TABLE 4.4
EVA and ROC,
July 2010. Companies are
ranked by EVA (dollar values
in millions)
er-tax interest.
Note: EVAs do not compute exactly because of rounding in the cost of capital.
Source: We are grateful to EVA Dimensions for providing these statistics.
3
v
WACC.
business. The WA
We will explain WACC and how to calculate it in Chapter 13.
y’s WACC depends on the risk of its
ut with the cost of debt calculated
Chapter 4
85
Measuring Corporate Performance
The after-tax equivalent, using Home Depot’s 35% tax rate, is
4
Net income to shareholders was $2,661 million.
(1 2 .35) 3 676 5 $439
Therefore, Home Depot’s after
1 2,661 5
igure, you can see
that the compan
2 2,058 5
more than investors
required. This was Home Depot’s EVA or residual income:
EVA 5 after-tax interest 1 net income 2 (cost of capital 3 total capitalization)
5 439 1 2,661 2 2,058 5 $1,042 million
The sum of Home Depot’s net income and after-tax interest is its after
operating income. This is what Home Depot w
e
interest as a tax-deductible expense. After-tax operating income is what the company
w
inanced. In that case it would have no (after-tax) interest expense and all operating income w
Thus EVA also equals:
EVA 5 after-tax operating income 2 (cost of capital 3 total capitalization)
5 3,100 2 2,058 5 $1,042 million
Of course Home Depot and its competitors do use debt financing. Nev
EVA comparisons are more useful if focused on operating income, which is not
affected by interest tax deductions.
Table 4.4 shows estimates of EV
ge companies. ExxonMobil again heads the list. It earned over $17 billion more than was needed to cover its
cost of capital. By contrast, AT&T was a laggard. Although it earned an accounting
v
as calculated before deducting the cost of
capital. After deducting the cost of capital, AT&T made an EVA loss of about
$3.8 billion.
Notice ho
Table 4.4. The v
vely safe companies like W
Coca-Cola tend to have lo
e Xerox and especially Google have high costs of capital.
EVA, or residual income, is a better measure of a company’s performance
than is accounting income. Accounting income is calculated after deducting
all costs except the cost of capital. By contrast, EVA recognizes that companies
need to cover their oppor
ore they add value.
EVA makes the cost of capital visible to operating managers.
get:
at least the cost of capital on assets employed. A plant or divisional manager can
improve EVA by reducing assets. Evaluating performance by EV
Therefore, a gro
now calculate EVA and tie managers’ compensation to it.
Self-Test 4.2
4
irm pays interest, it reduces its
will v
T
, equivalently, we look at after-tax interest payments.
This tax saving, or
T
-tax weighted-average cost of
capital (WACC). We will have more to say about these issues in Chapters 13 and 16.
86
Part One
Introduction
Accounting Rates of Return
EVA measures how many dollars a b
tal. Other things equal, the more assets the manager has to work with, the greater the
ge EVA. The manager of a small division may be highly
competent, but if that division has few assets, she is unlik
A
stakes.
s
per dollar of assets.
OC),
OA).
book
rates of return, because the
return on capital (ROC)
er-tax operating
income as a percentage
of long-term capital.
Return on Capital (ROC)
-tax operating income divided by total capitalization. In 2009 Home Depot’s operating income
w
shareholders’ equity) of $27,444 million. Therefore its return on capital (ROC) was5
ROC 5
after-tax operating income
3,100
5
5 .113, or 11.3%
total capitalization
27,444
R
ays. For e
vided Home Depot’s operaty’s
v
. If the additional investment cons operating income, it’s better to divide by the
average of the total capitalization at the be
.6 Home Depot’s
ROC for 2009 would decrease slightly to
ROC 5
after-tax operating income
3,100
5
5 .112, or 11.2%
(
average total capitalization
27,444 1 28,055) /2
, Home Depot’s cost of capital was about 7.5%. This was the
y invested
vestors could have e
their money in other companies or securities with the same risk as Home Depot’s business. So in 2009 the compan
2 7.5 5 3.7% more than investors required.
Think again about how Home Depot creates v
invest in new assets or pay out cash to the shareholders, who can then invest the money
for themselves in financial markets. When Home Depot invests in a new store or warev
v
wn.
ving up by keeping their money in the compan
es its
y could obtain for themselv
es its investors worse off: They
vesting on their own in financial markets. So
ant the company to invest only in projects for which the return on capital is at least as great as the cost of capital.
The last column in Table 4.4 shows R
wn companies.
Notice that Google’
ve
its cost of capital. Although Google had a higher return on capital than ExxonMobil, it
had a lower EVA. This w
y than Exxon and so had a
higher cost of capital, but also because it had f
wer dollars invested than Exxon.
5
sR
pretax interest to calculate operating income.
OC for companies that use difOC with the after
verage cost
of capital (WACC). We cover WACC in Chapter 13.
6
Av
uilds up ov
s conv
Chapter 4
87
Measuring Corporate Performance
ve companies in Table 4.4 with negative EVAs all have ROCs less than their
cost of capital. The spread between R
thing as EVA but e
return on assets (ROA)
er-tax operating
income as a percentage
of total assets.
OA) measures after-tax operat-
Return on Assets (ROA)
s total assets. T
or Home Depot, ROA was
5
after-tax operating income
3,100
5
5 .075, or 7.5%
total assets
41,164
Using average total assets, ROA was slightly higher at 7.6%:
ROA 5
after-tax operating income
3,100
5
5 .076, or 7.6%
(
average total assets
41,164 1 40,877) /2
For both ROA and ROC, we use after-tax operating income, which is calculated by
W
w profitable the company would hav
This what-if calculation is helpful
irms with dif
The tax
deduction for interest is often ignored, however, and operating income is calculated
using pretax interest. Some financial analysts take no account of interest payments and
measure ROA as net income for shareholders divided by total assets. This calculation
is really—we were about to say “stupid,” but don’t w
yone. This calcus assets have generated for debt
investors.
Self-Test 4.3
return on equity (ROE)
Net income as a
percentage of
shareholders’ equity.
Return on Equity (ROE)
We measure the return on equity (ROE)
y have invested. Home Depot had net income
. So Home Depot’s ROE was
Return on equity 5 ROE 5
2,661
net income
5
5 .150, or 15.0%
equity
17,777
Using average equity, ROE was
ROE 5
2,661
net income
5
5 .143, or 14.3%
(
average equity
17,777 1 19,393) /2
Self-Test 4.4
Problems with EVA and Accounting Rates of Return
alue added have some obvious attractions as measures
of performance. Unlik
et-v
y sho
and are not affected by all the other things that move stock market prices. Also, they
vision. However,
88
Part One
Introduction
remember that both EV
sheet) values for assets. Debt and equity are also book values. As we noted in the last
chapter
w ev
take accounting data at face value. For example, we ignored the f
has invested large sums in marketing in order to establish its brand name. This brand
ut its value is not shown on the balance sheet. If it were
shown, the book v
ould increase, and Home Depot
w
EV
Tables 4.3 and 4.4
ea
wever, it is impossible to include the
value of all assets or to judge how rapidly they depreciate. For example, did Google
, because its investment
ov
and cannot be measured exactly.
Remember also that the balance sheet does not sho
et values of
s assets.
y’s books are v
any depreciation. Older assets may be grossly undervalued in today’s market condivestments in the past, b
you could buy the same assets today at their reported book values. Conversely a low
ut it does not always mean that today
the assets could be employed better elsewhere.
4.4 Measuring Efficiency
We began our analysis of Home Depot by calculating how much value that company
has added for its shareholders and ho
deducting the cost of the capital that it employs. We e
equity, capital, and total assets, which were all impressively high. Our next task is to
probe a little deeper to understand the reasons for Home Depot’s success. What factors
contrib
s ov
iciency with which it uses
its many types of assets.
The asset turnover, or sales-to-assets, ratio shows how
w
hard the f
s assets are w
or Home Depot, each dollar of assets produced
$1.608 of sales:
Asset Turnover Ratio
Asset turnover 5
sales
5
66,176
5 1.608
41,164
Lik
(sales ov
cial managers and analysts often calculate the ratio of sales ov
average level of assets over the same period. In this case,
Asset turnover 5
66,176
sales
5
5 1.613
(40,877 1 41,164) /2
average total assets
ver ratio measures how ef
w hard
put to use. Belo
Inventory Turnover
ra
of ra
w measure
usiness is using its entire asset
of assets are being
xamples.
Ef
y need in
They hold only a relatively small level of inv
ver those inv
.
89
Chapter 4
The balance sheet shows the cost of inv
ished goods will eventually sell for
invel of inventories
s case,
cost of goods sold
43,764
5
5 4.1
inventory at start of year
10,673
5
Another way to express this measure is to look at how many days of output are represented by inventories. This is equal to the level of inv
cost of goods sold:
Average days in inventory 5
daily cost of goods sold
5
10,673
5 89 days
43,764/365
You could say that on av
icient inv
ations for 89 days.
In Chapter 20 we will see that man
ve managed to increase their invenver in recent years. Toyota has been the pioneer in this endeavor. Its justin-time inv
vered exactly when they are
needed. Toyota now keeps only about one month’
in inv
ver its inventory about 12 times a year.
Receivables Turnover Receivables are sales for which you have not yet been
paid. The receivables turnover ratio measures the f
s sales as a multiple of its
receivables. For Home Depot,
sales
5
5
66,176
5 68
972
, unpaid bills will be a relatively small proportion of
v
Therefore, a high ratio often indicates
sales and the receiv
an eff
w up on late payers. Sometimes,
however, a high ratio may indicate that the f
ve credit policy
.7
Another way to measure the ef
y of the credit operation is by calculating the
average length of time for customers to pay their bills. The f
ver its
receiv
s customers pay their bills
in about 5.4 days:
Average collection period 5
average daily sales
5
972
5 5.4 days
66,176/365
Self-Test 4.5
The receivables turnover ratio and the inv
ver ratio may help to highy, but they are not the only possible indicators. For
example, a retail chain might compare its sales per square foot with those of its competitors, an airline might look at revenues per passenger-mile, and a law firm might
7
es sense to look only at credit
equiv
, a low av
credit. For e
vables turnov
,
ve a
gardless of an
90
Part One
Introduction
look at revenues per partner. A little thought and common sense should suggest
which measures are likely to produce the most helpful insights into your company’s
ef
y.
4.5 Analyzing the Return on Assets:
The Du Pont System
We have seen that ev
s assets generates $1.61 of sales. But
Home Depot’s success depends not only on the efficiency with which it uses its assets
to generate sales but also on ho
This is measured by Home
Depot’
gin.
Profit Margin The profit mar
way into profits. It is sometimes defined as
Profit margin 5
2,661
net income
5
5 .040, or 4.0%
sales
66,176
This definition can be misleading.
v
We would not w
simply because it emplo
operating profit margin
After-tax operating
income as a
percentage of sales.
s lenders.
vided between the debtholders and the
itable than its rivals
gin, it makes sense to add back the
after-tax debt interest to net income. This leads us again to after-tax operating income
and to the operating pr
margin:
after-tax operating income
sales
2,661 1 (1 2 .35) 3 676
5
5 .047, or 4.7%
66,176
5
The Du Pont System
W
following equation sho
The
of
v
dollar of sales (operating prof
gin):
after-tax operating income
assets
after-tax operating income
sales
5
3
assets
sales
c
c
asset turnover
operating profit margin
5
Du Pont formula
ROA equals the product
of asset turnover and
operating profit margin.
This breakdown of RO
Du Pont formula, after the chemical compan
Home Depot’
ves the follo
v
(4.1)
gin is often called the
wn of ROA:
ROA 5
3 operating profit margin
5 1.61 3 .047 5 .075
e
ay to think about a company’s strategy. For
ve for high turnover at the expense of a low prof
gin
Chapter 4
Measuring Corporate Performance
91
(a “W
gin even if that results in low
ver (a “Bloomingdales strategy”). You would naturally prefer both high profit
gin and high turnover, but life isn’t that easy.
gin strategy will typically result in lo
e tradeoffs between these goals.
gy the
ould lik
ut their ability to do so
is limited by competition. The Du Pont formula helps to identify the constraints that
ace. Fast-food chains, which have high asset turnover, tend to operate on low
gins. Classy hotels have relatively lo
ver ratios but tend to compensate with
higher margins.
▲
EXAMPLE 4.1
Turnover versus Margin
en seek to improve their profit margins by acquiring a supplier. The idea is
to capture the supplier’s profit as well as their own. Unfortunately, unless they have
some special skill in running the new business, they are likely to find that any gain in
profit mar
y a decline in asset turnover.
A few numbers may help to illustrate this point. Table 4.5 shows the sales, profits,
and assets of Admiral Motors and its components supplier, Diana Corporation.
Both earn a 10% return on assets, though Admiral has a lower operating profit margin (20% versus Diana’s 25%). Since all of Diana’s output goes to Admiral, Admiral’s
management reasons that it would be better to merge the two companies. That
way, the merged company would capture the profit margin on both the auto components and the assembled car.
T
om row of the following table sho
ect of the merger. The merged
firm does indeed earn the combined profits. Total sales remain at $20 million, however, because all the components produced by Diana are used within the company. With higher profits and unchanged sales, the profit margin increases.
Unfortunately, the asset turnover is reduced by the merger since the merged firm
has more assets. This ex
it of the higher profit margin. The
return on assets is unchanged.
Figure 4.2 shows evidence of the trade-of
v
gin. You
can see that industries with high average turnover ratios, for e
tend to have lower av
gins. Conversely
gins are typically
associated with low turnover. The classic e
ater utilities,
which hav
ver ratios.
However, they have extremely lo
ginal costs for each unit of additional output
The tw
ver that result in an ROA of either 3% or 6%.
ver, that
v
fsetting, so for most industries the return on assets lies between
3% and 6%.
TABLE 4.5
Merging with
suppliers or customers will
generally increase the profit
margin,
by a reduction in asset
turnover.
92
FIGURE 4.2
One
Introduction
Median ROA, profit margin, and asset turnover for 23 industries, 1990–2004
Source: Thomas I. Selling and Clyde P. Stickney,
ects of Business Environments and Strategy on a Firm’s Rate of Return on Assets.” Copyright 1989,
CFA Institute. Reproduced and republished from Financial Analysts Journal, January–February 1989, pp. 43–52, with permission from the CFA Institute. All
rights reserved. Updates courtesy of Professors James Wahlen, Stephen Baginski and Mark Bradshaw.
Self-Test 4.6
4.6 Measuring Financial Leverage
As Figure 4.1 indicates, shareholder value depends not only on good investment deciW
verage and then at measures of liquidity.
ws money, it promises to make a series of interest payments and
to receiv
course, the rev
pain. If times are suf
pay its debts.
entire investment.
bad times, it is said to create
v
that lenders are happ
wed heavily may not be able to
verage. Leverage ratios measure how much
en on. CFOs keep an eye on leverage ratios to ensure
s debt.
93
Chapter 4
Debt Ratio
Financial leverage is usually measured by the ratio of long-term debt
8
wing but also f
For Home Depot,
Long-term debt ratio 5
1 equity
5
8,662
5 .31, or 31%
8,662 1 19,393
v
Leverage may also be measured by the debt-equity ratio. For Home Depot,
Long-term debt-equity ratio 5
long-term debt
8,662
5
5 .45, or 45%
equity
19,393
o ratios is moderate for Home Depot, 31% versus 45%.
v
y
5 9.
The long-term debt ratio for the average U.S. manufacturing company is about
30%, but some companies deliberately operate at much higher debt levels. For example, in Chapter 21 we will look at leveraged buyouts (LBOs). Firms that are acquired
in a leveraged buyout usually issue lar
verage debt ratios of about 90%. Many of
et v
market value of the company,
ues.9
y’
et v
y covers its debts, then lenders
y back. Thus you would expect to see the debt ratio computed using
et values of debt and equity. Y
versally.
et leverage ratios matter much? Perhaps not;
after all, the market value of the f
alue of intangible assets generated
velopment, adv
f training, and so on. These assets are
yf
gether.
wer keep within a maximum debt ratio,
the
alues and they ignore the intangible
Notice also that these measures of lev
mak
cash, b
y is a re
Total debt ratio 5
That probably
wer, it may be preferable to
21,484
total liabilities
5
5 .53, or 53%
total assets
40,877
equity.10 W
5 1.11.
Managers sometimes refer loosely to a company’s debt ratio, but we have just seen
that the debt ratio may be measured in several different ways. For example, Home
Depot has a debt ratio of .31 (the long-term debt ratio) and also .53 (the total debt
8
e re
ment is just lik
9
In the case of leased assets, accountants estimate the value of the lease commitments. In the case of long-term
debt, they simply show the face value, which can be very different from market value.
10
94
One
Introduction
ratio). This is not the first time we have come across several w
ratio. There is no law stating ho
w it has been calculated.
inancial
Times Interest Earned Ratio
verage is the
extent to which interest obligations are cov
ver interest payments with room to spare. Interest coverage
es (EBIT) to interest payments. For Home Depot,
Times interest earned 5
4,699
EBIT
5
5 7.0
interest payments
676
ativ
tent with coverage ratios as low as 2 or 3.
The re
to avoid default. The coverage ratio measures ho
and hurdler.
, however. For e
t tell us
whether Home Depot is generating enough cash to repay its debt as it becomes due.
Cash Coverage Ratio
e
As we explained in Chapter 3, depreciation is not a cash
v
o
w. We then calculate a cash coverage ratio.11 For Home Depot,
Cash coverage ratio 5
EBIT 1 depreciation
4,699 1 1,806
5
5 9.6
interest payments
676
Self-Test 4.7
Leverage and the Return on Equity
e interest payments to its lenders.
ws instead of issuing equity,
it has fewer equityholders to share the remaining profits. Which effect dominates? An
extended v
wn
after-tax
operating income
net income
assets
sales
net income
ROE 5
5
3
3
3
equity
equity
assets
sales
after-tax
c
c
c
operating income
leverage
asset
operating
c
ratio
profit margin
“debt burden”
(4.2)
11
.
1
1
5
A cov
vered here. Y
ves
Y
Table 4.8 on page 101.
Chapter 4
Measuring Corporate Performance
95
Notice that the product of the tw
fected by
12
However
, which we call the leverage ratio, can be
expressed as (equity 1 liabilities)/equity, which equals 1 1 total-debt-to-equity ratio.
The last term, which we call the “debt b
” measures the proportion by which
interest e
Suppose that the f
inanced entirely by equity. In this case, both the leverage
ws, however, the leverage ratio is greater than 1
its is
absorbed by interest). Thus lev
. In
fact, we will see in Chapter 16 that leverage increases R
assets is higher than the interest rate it pays on its debt. Since Home Depot’
on capital e
on capital.
Self-Test 4.8
4.7 Measuring Liquidity
liquidity
Access to cash or assets
that can be turned into
cash on short notice.
wer’
verage. You w
w whether
y can lay its hands on the cash to repay you. That is why credit analysts and
bankers look at several measures of liquidity. Liquid assets can be conv
quickly and cheaply.
Think, for example, what you w
ge unexpected bill. You might
have some mone
v
ut you would
not f
ewise, own assets
grees of liquidity. For example, accounts receivable and inventories of
As inv
pay their bills, mone
ws into the f
At the other extreme, real estate may be
quite illiquid.
uyer, negotiate a f
Managers have another reason to focus on liquid assets: Their book (balance sheet)
values are usually reliable. The book value of a catalytic cracker may be a poor guide
alue, but at least you know what cash in the bank is w
Liquidity ratios also have some less
assets and liabilities are easily changed, measures of liquidity can rapidly become outdated. Y
er is worth, b
airly
sure that it won’t disappear overnight. Cash in the bank can disappear in seconds.
Also, assets that seem liquid sometimes have a nasty habit of becoming illiquid.
This happened during the subprime mortgage crisis in 2008. Some financial institutions had set up funds known as structured investment vehicles (SIVs) that issued
short-term debt backed by residential mortgages. As mortgage default rates began
to climb, the market in this debt dried up and dealers became very reluctant to
quote a price.
12
Again, we use after
96
One
Introduction
ve plenty of liquid assets.
They know that when the
ways a good thing. For e
not leave excess cash in their bank accounts. They don’t allow customers to postpone
paying their bills, and they don’t leave stocks of ra
inished goods littering the w
. In other words, high levels of liquidity may indicate sloppy
use of capital. Here, EVA can highlight the problem, because it penalizes managers
who keep more liquid assets than they really need.
Net Working Capital to Total Assets Ratio
v
v
liquid. The dif
wn as net
working capital. It roughly measures the company’s potential net reservoir of cash.
Since current assets usually e
orking capital is usually
positive. For Home Depot,
Net wo
5 13,900 2 10,363 5 $3,537 million
Home Depot’s net w
as 9% of total assets:
Net wo
Total assets
5
3,537
5 .09, or 9%
40,877
Current Ratio
liabilities:
5
5
13,900
5 1.34
10,363
v
pany borro
ge sum from the bank and inv
or example, suppose that a cometable securities. Cur-
capital is unaffected but the current ratio changes. For this reason it is sometimes
preferable to net short-term investments against short-term debt when calculating
the current ratio.
Quick (Acid-Test) Ratio
v
ything abov
rouble typically comes because the f
t sell its inv
production cost.) Thus managers often exclude inventories and other less liquid comThey
focus instead on cash, marketable securities, and bills that customers have not yet
paid. This results in the quick ratio:
Quick ratio 5
Cash Ratio
1,421 1 964
cash 1 marketable securities 1 receivables
5
5 .23
current liabilities
10,363
A company’
Cash ratio 5
cash 1
et-
5
1,421
5 .14
10,363
A low cash ratio may not matter if the f
w on short notice.
whether the f
wed from the bank or whether it has a guaranteed
97
Chapter 4
of liquidity takes the f
w whenever it chooses? None of the standard measures
s “reserv
wing power” into account.
Self-Test 4.9
4.8 Calculating Sustainable Growth
Home Depot’s lev
cies are safe and sound. But what about the amount
vailable for
investment and growth? To put it another way, how fast could Home Depot grow?
Would its growth be limited by the av
The answer to the last question is in principle no. In well-functioning financial markets, a company’s gro
ut by limits to
good inv
y has investment projects that add value, it should be
But the window to issue stock may not always be open. For e
manager who believes that inv
stock at what he or she sees as a depressed price.
wing how f
w if it relies only on interThe
s sustainable growth rate.
w mainly by reinv
y grow
ept in the b
the compan
w capital.
vidends. The proportion
of earnings paid out as dividends was, therefore,
Payout ratio 5
1,525
5 .57, or 57%
2,661
The remaining 43% of earnings was reinvested and “plowed back” into the business
s equity capital.13 Thus,
Plowback ratio 5 1 2 payout ratio 5 1 2 .57 5 .43
Home Depot’s return on equity (ROE) was 15%. If it continues to reinvest 43% of
y
increase by .43 3 .15 5 .065, or 6.5% a year:
Sustainable growth rate 5
5
2 dividends
equity
2 dividends
3
equity
5 plowback ratio 3 ROE
5 .43 3 .15 5 .065, or 6.5%
13
We assume that payout to shareholders comes as cash dividends only. Companies also pay out cash by repur-
net income. We discuss repurchases in Chapter 17.
98
Part One
sustainable growth rate
The firm’s growth rate if it
plows back a constant
fraction of earnings,
maintains a constant
r
, and
keeps its debt ratio
constant.
This measure is often known as the sustainable rate of growth.
The sustainable gro
s long-term debt ratio is held
constant. Home Depot could grow its assets at a f
wing more and
more, but that growth strategy would not be sustainable in the long run.
Home Depot’s sustainable growth rate is moderate. But sometimes the formula
for sustainable growth will result in crazy values, for example, sustainable growth
rates above 30% or even 40%. No company could expect to maintain growth rates
like these forever. Often, in such cases, firms are selling products at an early stage
of their life-cycle. Competition in these new markets is scarce, return on equity is
high, and, with ample opportunities for profitable reinvestment, firms respond with
very high plowback ratios. For example, the ROE for computer software firms in
2010 was more than double that of electric utilities. And most software companies
14
paid no dividends at all, but instead plowed all
But eventually, as the industry matures, price competition will increase, ROE will
decline, and with fe
vestment, firms will plow
back less of their earnings. As ROE and the plowback ratio both decline, growth
also must slow.
Introduction
4.9 Interpreting Financial Ratios
We have shown ho
s
Table 4.6.15
Now that you have calculated these measures, you need some w
they are high or low
or example, if
gative v
But what about some of our other measures?
vel for, say, the
ver or profit margin, and if there were, it w
y to company. For example, you would not expect a
acturer to hav
gin as a jeweller or the same levery. All financial ratios must be interpreted in the context of
Table 4.7 presents some financial ratios for a sample of industry groups. Notice
the large variation across industries. Some of these differences, particularly in
profitability measures, may arise from chance; in 2009 the sun shone more kindly
on some industries than others. But other dif
tal factors. For example, notice the comparatively high debt ratios of food product
companies. In comparison, computer and electronic companies tend to borrow far
less, and these differences are true in both good times and bad. We pointed out
earlier that some businesses are able to generate a high level of sales from relatively few assets. Differences in turnover ratios also tend to be relatively stable.
For example, you can see that the asset turnover ratio for beverage and tobacco
firms is more than double that for food product companies. But competition
ensures that beverage and tobacco firms earn a correspondingly lower margin on
their sales. The net effect is that the return on assets in the two industries is
broadly similar.
14
Value Line Inv
If you would like to see ho
spreadsheet available on our Web site at www
ey industry group.
15
ve Excel
.
99
Chapter 4
TABLE 4.6
Summary of Home Depot’
ormance measures
*Authors’ calculation.
You can find this spreadsheet at
.mhhe.com/bmm7e.
TABLE 4.7
Financial ratios f
oups, 2009
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from U.S. Department of Commerce,
March 2010. Available at
.census.gov/econ/qfr/curr
erly Financial R
.
or Manufacturing, Mining and Trade Corporations,
100
Part One Introduction
Self-Test 4.10
v
s major competitors. Table 4.8 sets out some ke
we’s.
y respects.
For e
wever, Home Depot’s ROA
is higher
v
gin. Home Depot relies f
vily on debt than Lowe’s.
its higher leverage ratios as well as its lower coverage ratios. This greater indebtedness
O
OE, Home
we’s. This is because it pays
out a far lar
vidends.
vidends today, but with
lower reinv
vidends may grow more slowly.16
It may also be helpful to compare Home Depot’s financial ratios with its own
equiv
or example, you can see in Figure 4.3 that Home
Depot’
w 10% in 2008
FIGURE 4.3 Home Depot
financial ratios over time
Note: We pointed out earlier in the chapter that there is more than one way to calculate several ratios. Value Line’s
figures do not precisely match the values in Table 4.6.
Source: Value Line Investment Survey, April 2, 2010.
16
lently, average collection period. W
Lowe’
its accounts receiv
will generally hav
y between the tw
v
wer receiv
gy as well as to emerging b
v
ver and lo
ver or, equivawe’s tends to sell
The lesson?
ut you
101
Chapter 4
TABLE 4.8
Selected
financial measures for Home
Depot and Lowe’s, 2009
*Authors’ calculation.
before finally stabilizing. W
w that ROA 5 asset
ver 3 operating profit margin. So what accounted for the fall in ROA? Figure 4.3 shows that the culprit was the
gin from 8.6% in 2005 to 5.7% in 2008. Perhaps Home Depot was
where it may be useful to look at the e
This concludes our canter through Home Depot’
ferent divisions.
4.10 The Role of Financial Ratios—and a Final
Note on Transparency
ver tw
the
usiness and finance, it’s a good bet that
s drop in on two conversations.
Conversation 1
as musing out loud: “Ho
e
W
“I’v
w the full cost of the project, the ratio would be about .45. When we
took out our last loan from the bank, we agreed that we would not allow our debt ratio
to get abov
ouldn’t have much leeway
to respond to possible emergencies.
ve our bonds
102
TABLE 4.9
One
Introduction
Financial ratios and default risk by rating class, long-term debt
Note: EBITDA is earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization. Standard & Poor’s and Moody’s, the two largest credit rating agencies, use
slightl
erent labels for rating classes. For example, S&P’s BBB rating is equivalent to Moody’s Baa, BB is equivalent to Ba, and so on.
Source: Corporate Rating Criteria, Standard & Poor’s, 2006.
an investment-grade rating. They too look at a company’s leverage when they rate its
bonds. I have a table here (Table 4.9), which sho
veraged, their bonds receive a lower rating. I don’
w whether the rating agencies
would downgrade our bonds if our debt ratio increased to .45, but they might. That
wouldn’t please our existing bondholders, and it could raise the cost of any new
wing.”
“We also need to think about our interest cover, which is be
v
interest cover would f
o times. Sure, we e
the new investment, but it could be sev
es short of cash.”
“Sounds to me as if we should be thinking about a possible equity issue,” concluded
the CEO.
Conversation 2 The CEO was not in the best of moods after his humiliating
defeat at the compan
vision: “I
see our stock was down again yesterday,” he growled. “It’s now selling below book
v
ork my socks off for this company; you w
ould show a little more gratitude.”
“I think I can understand a little of our shareholders’ w
” the financial manager replies. “Just look at our return on assets.” It’s only 6%, well below the cost of
ver the cost of the funds
that investors provide. Our economic value added is actually negative. Of course, this
doesn’
where, but we should
y of our divisions should be sold off or the
assets redeployed.
“In some ways we’re in good shape. We have v
s not altogether good
news because it also suggests that we may have more w
I’v
They turn over their inventory 12 times a
Also, their customers take an average
e 67. If we could just match their performance
on these two measures, we would release $300 million that could be paid out to
”
w,” said the CEO. “In the meantime
I intend to have a word with the production manager about our inv
vels and
with the credit manager about our collections policy. You’v
about whether we should sell off our packaging division. I’ve always w
the divisional manager there. Spends too much time practicing his backswing and not
enough w
”
Chapter 4
103
Measuring Corporate Performance
Transparency
ve assumed that financial statements are trustworthy.
We assumed that accountants are following generally accepted accounting principles
(GAAP) and not endorsing misleading numbers. We assumed that managers are not
inancial statements or covering up bad ones. When
transparent, because outsiders
alue and performance.
Unfortunately
vestors.
as in many ways an empty shell. Its stock
price was supported more by inv
usinesses. The compan
wing aggressively
special-purpose entities (SPEs) and hiding these debts. Much of the
wing was improperly excluded from Enron’
The bad ne
, Enron
f of its water and broadband business. In November, it
recognized its SPE debt retroactively
wledged indebtedness
debt was do
y.
y
y could hav
prospects—its problems would have shown up right away in a f
That
ould have generated e
cies, lenders, and investors.
With transparency
ve action. But the
top management of a troubled and opaque compan
price and postpone the discipline of the mark
et discipline caught up with
y.
2002.
y Act (SO
y Accounting Ov
Among other things, the act set up
v
y audit; it prohibits
y indi
y’
statements present a f
All this comes at a price. The costs of SOX and the burdens of meeting detailed
re
vate (versus public) ownership. Some observers also believe that these added re
ve hurt the
v
ets.
Despite periodic accounting breakdowns, transparency in the United States and
other dev
v
and critical even in these countries. Take e
veloping economies, where
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
QUESTIONS
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISE
finance.yahoo.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
MINICASE
TABLE 4.10
TABLE 4.12
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
TABLE 4.11
CHAPTER
5
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
6
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T T W O
Value
Do you truly understand what these figures mean?
C
114
Part Two Value
5.1 Future Values and Compound Interest
You have $100 inv
of $6:
Interest 5 interest rate 3 initial investment
5 .06 3 $100 5 $6
Y
ment will gro
alue of your investValue of investment after 1 year 5 $100 1 $6 5 $106
Notice that the $100 invested grows by the factor (1 1 .06) 5
y
interest rate r, the value of the investment at the end of 1 year is (1 1 r) times the initial
investment:
5 initial investment 3 (1 1 r)
5 $100 3 (1.06) 5 $106
What if you leave this money in the bank for a second year? Your balance, now
5 .06 3 $106 5 $6.36
Y
alue of your account will grow to $106 1 $6.36 5 $112.36.
vestment of $100 increases by a f
second year the $106 again increases by a factor of 1.06 to $112.36. Thus the initial
$100 investment grows twice by a factor 1.06:
5 $100 3 1.06 3 1.06
5 $100 3 (1.06)2 5 $112.36
If you keep your money invested for a third year, your investment multiplies by
future value (FV)
Amount to which an
investment will grow
after earning interest.
compound interest
Interest earned on
interest.
simple interest
Interest earned only on
the original investment;
no interest is earned on
interest.
$100 3 (1.06)3 5
ev
v
where.
, if you invest your $100 for t
interest rate of r
t
will be
ut
w to $100 3 (1.06)t. For an
future value (FV) of your investment
Future value (FV) of $100 5 $100 3 (1 1 r)t
(5.1)
Notice in our e
and in the second year is $6.36 (6% of $106). Your income in the second year is higher
because you no
both
vestment and the $6 of
vious year
compounding
or compound interest. In contrast, if the bank calculated the interest only on your
original investment, you would be paid simple interest. With simple interest the v
of your investment would gro
3 $100 5 $6.
Table 5.1 and Figure 5.1 illustrate the mechanics of compound interest. Table 5.1
sho
vings have been increased by the previous year’s interest. As a result, your interest
income also is higher.
Obviously, the higher the rate of interest, the faster your savings will grow.
Figure 5.2 shows the balance in your savings account after a giv
several interest rates. Even a few percentage points added to the (compound) interest
rate can dramatically af
or example, after 10 years $100
Chapter 5
The Time Value of Money
115
TABLE 5.1
How your savings
grow; the future value of $100
invested to earn 6% with
compound interest
FIGURE 5.1 A plot of the
data in Table 5.1, showing the
future values of an investment
of $100 earning 6% with
compound interest
FIGURE 5.2 How an
investment of $100 grows
with compound interest
erent interest rates
invested at 10% will grow to $100 3 (1.10)10 5 $259.37. If invested at 5%, it will
grow to only $100 3 (1.05)10 5 $162.89.
Calculating future values is easy using almost any calculator. If you have the
vestment by 1 1 r (1.06 in our example) once
vestment. A simpler procedure is to use the power key (the
key) on your calculator. For example, to compute (1.06)10, enter 1.06, press the key,
enter 10, press 5, and discover that the answer is 1.7908. (Try this!)
116
Two
Value
TABLE 5.2
An example
of a future value table,
showing how an investment
of $1 grows with compound
interest
If you don’t have a calculator, you can use a table of future values such as Table 5.2.
Let’s use it to work out the future value of a 10-year inv
row corresponding to 10 years. Now work along that row until you reach the column
for a 6% interest rate.
ws that $1 inv
ws to
$1.7908.
Notice that as you move across each row in Table 5.2, the future value of a $1
investment increases, as your funds compound at a higher interest rate. As you move
down any column
alue also increases, as your funds compound for a lonNow try one more example. If you invest $1 for 20 years at 10% and do not withdraw any money, what will you have at the end? Y
Table 5.2 gives future values for only a small selection of years and interest rates.
Table A.1 at the end of the book is a bigger version of Table 5.2. It presents the future
value of a $1 investment for a wide range of time periods and interest rates.
Future value tables are tedious, and as Table 5.2 demonstrates, they sho
alor example, suppose that
you want to calculate future values using an interest rate of 7.835%. The power key on
your calculator will be faster and easier than future value tables.
ve is to
These are introduced in the next section.
▲
EXAMPLE 5.1
Manhattan Island
Almost everyone’s favorite example of the power of compound interest is the puran Island for $24 in 1626 by Peter Minuit. Based on New York real
estate prices today, it seems that Minuit got a great deal. But did he? Consider the
future value of that $24 if it had been invested for 385 years (2011 minus 1626) at
an interest rate of 8% per year:
$24 3 (1.08)385 5 $177,157,000,000,000
5 $177.16 trillion
Perhaps the deal wasn’t as good as it appeared. The total value of land on Manhattan today is only a fraction of $177.16 trillion.
Though entertaining, this analysis is actually somewhat misleading. The 8% interest rate we’ve used to compute future values is high by historical standards. At a
3.5% interest rate, more consistent with historical experience, the future value of the
$24 would be dramatically lower, only $24 3 (1.035)385 5 $13,560,000! On the other
hand, we have understated the returns to Mr. Minuit and his successors: We have
ignored all the rental income that the island’s land has generated over the last
three or four centuries.
All things considered, if we had been around in 1626, we would have gladly paid
$24 for the island.
Chapter 5
117
The Time Value of Money
The power of compounding is not restricted to money. Foresters try to forecast the
compound growth rate of trees, demographers the compound growth rate of population. A social commentator once observed that the number of lawyers in the United
States is increasing at a higher compound rate than the population as a whole (3.6%
versus .9% in the 1980s) and calculated that in about two centuries there will be more
lawyers than people. In all these cases, the principle is the same: Compound growth
means that value increases each period by the factor (1 1 growth rate). The
value after t periods will equal the initial value times (1 1 growth rate)t. When
money is invested at compound interest, the growth rate is the interest rate.
Self-Test 5.1
Suppose that Peter Minuit did not become the first New York real estate
tycoon but instead had invested his $24 at a 5% interest rate in New
Amsterdam Savings Bank. What would have been the balance in his account
after 5 years? 50 years?
Self-Test 5.2
In 1973 Gordon Moore, one of Intel’s founders, predicted that the number of
transistors that could be placed on a single silicon chip would double every
18 months, equivalent to an annual growth of 59% (i.e., 1.591.5 5 2.0). The first
microprocessor was built in 1971 and had 2,250 transistors. By 2010 Intel
chips contained 2.3 billion transistors, over 1 million times the number of transistors 39 years earlier. What has been the annual compound rate of growth in
processing power? How does it compare with the prediction of Moore’s law?
5.2 Present Values
present value (PV)
Value today of a future
cash flow.
Money can be invested to earn interest. If you are offered the choice between $100,000
now and $100,000 at the end of the year, you naturally take the money now to get a
year’s interest. Financial managers make the same point when they say that money in
hand today has a time value or when they quote perhaps the most basic financial principle: A dollar today is worth more than a dollar tomorrow.
We have seen that $100 invested for 1 year at 6% will grow to a future value of
100 3 1.06 5 $106. Let’s turn this around: How much do we need to invest now in
order to produce $106 at the end of the year? In other words, what is the present value
(PV) of the $106 payoff?
To calculate future value, we multiply today’s investment by 1 plus the interest rate,
.06, or 1.06. To calculate present value, we simply reverse the process and divide the
future value by 1.06:
Present value 5 PV 5
$106
future value
5
5 $100
1.06
1.06
What is the present value of, say, $112.36 to be received 2 years from now? Again
we ask, How much would we need to invest now to produce $112.36 after 2 years? The
answer is obviously $100; we’ve already calculated that at 6% $100 grows to $112.36:
$100 3 (1.06)2 5 $112.36
However, if we don’t know, or forgot the answer, we just divide future value by (1.06)2:
Present value 5 PV 5
$112.36
5 $100
(1.06)2
118
Part Two
Value
In general, for a future value or payment t periods away, present value is
Present value 5
discounted cash flow (DCF)
Another term for the
present value of a future
cash flow.
discount rate
Interest rate used to
compute present values
of future cash flows.
▲
EXAMPLE 5.2
future value after t periods
( 1 1 r) t
(5.2)
To calculate present value, we discounted the future value at the interest rate r. The
calculation is therefore termed a discounted cash-flow (DCF) calculation, and the
interest rate r is known as the discount rate.
In this chapter we will be working through a number of more or less complicated
DCF calculations. All of them involve a present value, a discount rate, and one or more
future cash flows. If ever a DCF problem leaves you confused and flustered, just pause
and write down which of these measures you know and which one you need to
calculate.
Saving for a Future Purchase
Suppose you need $3,000 next year to buy a new computer. The interest rate is 8%
per year. How much money should you set aside now in order to pay for the purchase? Just calculate the present value at an 8% interest rate of a $3,000 payment
at the end of 1 year. To the nearest dollar, this value is
PV 5
$3,000
5 $2,778
1.08
Notice that $2,778 invested for 1 year at 8% will prove just enough to buy your
computer:
Future value 5 $2,778 3 1.08 5 $3,000
The longer the time before you must make a payment, the less you need to
invest today. For example, suppose that you can postpone buying that computer
until the end of 2 years. In this case we calculate the present value of the future
payment by dividing $3,000 by (1.08)2:
PV 5
$3,000
5 $2,572
(1.08)2
Thus you need to invest $2,778 today to provide $3,000 in 1 year but only $2,572 to
provide the same $3,000 in 2 years.
You now know how to calculate future and present values: To work out how much
you will have in the future if you invest for t years at an interest rate r, multiply the
initial investment by (1 1 r)t. To find the present value of a future payment, run
the process in reverse and divide by (1 1 r)t.
Present values are always calculated using compound interest. The ascending lines
in Figure 5.2 showed the future value of $1 invested with compound interest. In contrast, present values decline, other things equal, when future cash payments are
delayed. The longer you have to wait for money, the less it’s worth today.
The descending line in Figure 5.3 shows the present value today of $100 to be
received at some future date. Notice how even small variations in the interest rate can
have a powerful effect on the value of distant cash flows. At an interest rate of 5%, a
payment of $100 in year 20 is worth $37.69 today. If the interest rate increases to 10%,
the value of the future payment falls by about 60% to $14.86.
The present value formula is sometimes written differently. Instead of dividing the
future payment by (1 1 r)t, we could equally well multiply it by 1/(1 1 r)t:
PV 5
future payment
1
5 future payment 3
( 1 1 r) t
( 1 1 r) t
Chapter 5
The Time Value of Money
119
FIGURE 5.3 Present value
of a future cash flow of $100.
Notice that the longer you
have to wait for your money,
the less it is worth today.
discount factor
Present value of a $1
future payment.
The expression 1/(1 1 r)t is called the discount factor. It measures the present value
of $1 receiv
t.
The simplest w
,b
managers sometimes find it convenient to use tables of discount factors. For example,
Table 5.3 shows discount factors for a small range of years and interest rates. Table A.2
at the end of the book provides a set of discount f
interest rates.
Try using Table 5.3 to check our calculations of how much to put aside for that
$3,000 computer purchase. If the interest rate is 8%, the present v
PV 5 $3,000 3
1
5 $3,000 3 .9259 5 $2,778
1.08
which matches the value we obtained in Example 5.2.
Table 5.3
shows that the present value of $1 paid at the end of 2 years is .8573. So the present
value of $3,000 is
PV 5 $3,000 3
1
5 $3,000 3 .8573 5 $2,572
(1.08)2
as we found in Example 5.2.
Notice that as you move along the rows in Table 5.3, moving to higher interest
rates, present values decline. As you move down the columns, moving to longer
discounting periods, present v
e sense?)
TABLE 5.3
An example of a
present value table, showing
the value today of $1
received in the future
120
▲
EXAMPLE 5.3
Part Two Value
Puerto Rico Borrows Some Cash
A few years ago,
o Rico needed to borrow several billion dollars. It did so by selling IOUs.1 Each IOU was a promise to pa
er some number of
years. For example, one of those IOUs matured in 2056. The market interest rate on
o Rican bonds in 2010 was 6.35%. How much would investors have been
prepared to pay for that IOU? Because it matured in 46 years, we calculate its present
value by multiplying the $1,000 future payment by the 46-year discount factor:
PV 5 $1,000 3
1
(1.0635)46
5 $1,000 3 .0589 5 $58.90
Self-Test 5.3
▲
EXAMPLE 5.4
Finding the Value of Free Credit
Kangaroo Aut
ering free credit on a $20,000 car. You pay $8,000 down and
then the balance at the end of 2 years. Turtle Motors ne
er free
credit but will give y
. If the interest rate is 10%, which compan
ering the better deal?
Notice that you pay more in total by buying through Kangaroo, but since part of the
payment is postponed, you can keep this money in the bank where it will continue to
earn interest. To compar
ers, you need to calculate the present value of
your payments to Kangaroo. The time line in Figure 5.4 shows the cash payments. The
first payment, $8,000, takes place today. The second payment, $12,000, takes place at
the end of 2 years. To find its present value, we need to multiply by the 2-year discount
factor. The total present value of the payments to Kangaroo is therefore
FIGURE 5.4 Drawing a time
line can help us to calculate
the present value of the
payments to Kangaroo Autos.
1
we you.
interest or coupon payment.
wn as a zero-coupon bond.
bonds.
, bond investors receive a re
as
xt chapter.
F I N A N C I A L CA L C U L ATO R
An Introduction to Financial Calculators
FV
PV
PV 5 $8,000 1 $12,000 3
1
(1.10)2
5 $8,000 1 $9,917.36 5 $17,917.36
Suppose you start with $17,917.36. You make a down payment of $8,000 to Kangaroo Autos and invest the balance of $9,917.36. At an interest rate of 10%, this will
grow over 2 years to $9,917.36 3 1.102 5 $12,000, just enough to make the final payment on your automobile. The total cost of $17,917.36 is a better deal than the
$19,000 charged by Turtle Motors.
121
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
Excel’s Interest Rate Functions
SPREADSHEET 5.1
SPREADSHEET 5.2
Now let’s solve Example 5.2 in a spreadsheet. We can
type the Excel function 5 PV(rate, nper, pmt, FV) 5
PV(.08, 2, 0, 3000), or we can select the PV function from the
pull-down menu of financial functions and fill in our inputs as
shown in the dialog box below.
Either way, you should get an answer of 2$2,572. (Notice
that you don’t type the comma in 3,000 when entering the
number in the spreadsheet. If you did, Excel would interpret
the entry as two different numbers, 3 followed by zero.)
These calculations illustrate how important it is to use present values when comparing alternative patterns of cash payment. You should never compare cash flows
occurring at different times without first discounting them to a common date. By
calculating present values, we see how much cash must be set aside today to
pay future bills.
Calculating present and future values can entail a considerable amount of tedious
arithmetic. Fortunately, financial calculators and spreadsheets are designed with
present value and future value formulas already programmed. They can make your
work much easier. The two nearby boxes provide a short introduction to each of
these tools.
Finding the Interest Rate
When we looked at Puerto Rico’s IOUs in Example 5.3, we used the interest rate to
compute a fair market price for each IOU. Sometimes, however, you are given the
price and have to calculate the interest rate that is being offered.
For example, when Puerto Rico borrowed money, it did not announce an interest
rate. It simply offered to sell each IOU for $58.90. Thus we know that
PV 5 $1,000 3
1
5 $58.90
(1 1 r)46
What is the interest rate?
There are several ways to approach this. You might use a table of discount factors.
You need to find the interest rate for which the 46-year discount factor 5 .0589.
A better approach is to rearrange the equation and use your calculator:
$58.90 3 (1 1 r)46 5 $1,000
$1,000
(1 1 r)46 5
5 16.978
$58.90
(1 1 r) 5 (16.978)1/46 5 1.0635
r 5 .0635, or 6.35%
123
124
Part Two Value
You can also use a financial calculator or a spreadsheet to find the interest rate. The
inputs would be:
i
▲
EXAMPLE 5.5
Double Your Money
How many times have you heard of an investment adviser who promises to double
your money? Is this really an amazing feat? That depends on how long it will take
for your money to double. With enough patience, your funds eventually will double
even if they earn only a very modest interest rate. Suppose your investment adviser
promises to double your money in 8 years. What interest rate is implicitly being
promised?
The adviser is promising a future value of $2 for every $1 invested today. Therefore, we find the interest rate by solving for r as follows:
Future value (FV) 5 PV 3 (1 1 r)t
$2 5 $1 3 (1 1 r)8
1 1 r 5 21/8 5 1.0905
r 5 .0905, or 9.05%
Self-Test 5.4
5.3 Multiple Cash Flows
So f , we have considered problems inv
w. This is obviously limiting. Most real-world investments, after all, will involve man
ws
over time.
y payments, you’
stream of
Future Value of Multiple Cash Flows
Recall the computer you hope to purchase in 2 years (see Example 5.2). Now suppose
sav
y each year. You might be able to put $1,200 in the bank
now
w much will
you be able to spend on a computer in 2 years?
The time line in Figure 5.5 shows how your savings grow.
o cash
ws into the savings plan.
w will hav
therefore will grow to $1,200 3 (1.08)2 5 $1,399.68, while the second deposit, which
, will be inv
w to
$1,400 3 (1.08) 5 $1,512.
these two amounts, or $2,911.68.
Chapter 5
The Time Value of Money
125
FIGURE 5.5 Drawing a time
line can help to calculate the
future value of your savings.
▲
EXAMPLE 5.6
Even More Savings
Suppose that the computer pur
or an additional year and
that you can make a third deposit of $1,000 at the end of the second year. How
much will be available to spend 3 years from now?
Again we organize our inputs using a time line as in Figure 5.6. The total cash
available will be the sum of the future values of all three deposits. Notice that when
we save for 3 years, the first two deposits each have an extra year for interest to
compound:
$1,200 3 (1.08)3 5 $1,511.65
$1,400 3 (1.08)2 5 1,632.96
$1,000 3 (1.08) 5 1,080.00
Total future value 5 $4,224.61
Our examples show that problems inv
ws are simple extenw analysis. To find the value at some future date of a stream
of cash flows, calculate what each cash flow will be worth at that future date
and then add up these future values.
As we will no
calculations.
FIGURE 5.6 To find the
future value of a stream of
cash flows, you just calculate
the future value of each flow
and then add them.
orks for present value
126
Part Two Value
Present Value of Multiple Cash Flows
When we calculate the present v
w would be w
to w
w would be w
▲
EXAMPLE 5.7
w
w much that
w
alues.
Cash Up Front versus an Installment Plan
Suppose that your auto dealer gives y
een paying $15,500 for a
used car or entering into an installment plan where you pay $8,000 down today
and make payments of $4,000 in each of the next 2 years. Which is the better deal?
Before reading this chapter, you might have compared the total payments under
the two plans: $15,500 versus $16,000 in the installment plan. Now, however, you
know that this comparison is wrong, because it ignores the time value of money.
For example, the last installment of $4,000 is less costly to you than paying out
$4,000 now. The true cost of that last payment is the present value of $4,000.
Assume that the interest rate you can earn on safe investments is 8%. Suppose
you choose the installment plan. As the time line in Figure 5.7 illustrates, the present
value of the plan’s three cash flows is:
Present Value
Immediate payment
Second payment
Third payment
Total present value
$8,000
5
$4,000/1.08 5
$4,000/(1.08)2 5
5
$ 8,000.00
3,703.70
3,429.36
$15,133.06
Because the present value of the three payments is less than $15,500, the installment plan is in fact the cheaper alternative.
The installment plan’s present value is the amount that you would need to invest
now to cover the three payments. Let’s check.
Here is how your bank balance would change as you make each payment:
Year
Initial
Balance
0
1
2
$ 15,133.06
7,703.70
4,000.00
2
Payment
$ 8,000
4,000
4,000
5
Remaining
Balance
$ 7,133.06
3,703.70
0
1
Interest
Earned
$ 570.64
296.30
0
5
Balance at
Year-End
$ 7,703.70
4,000.00
0
If you start with the present value of $15,133.06 in the bank, you could make the
first $8,000 pa
er 1 year, your savings account
would receive an interest payment of $7,133.06 3 .08 5 $570.64, bringing your
account to $7,703.70. Similarly, you would make the second $4,000 payment and
his sum left in the bank would grow with interest to $4,000,
just enough to make the last payment.
The present value of a stream of future cash flows is the amount you need to
invest today to generate that stream.
Self-Test 5.5
Chapter 5
127
The Time Value of Money
FIGURE 5.7 To find the
present value of a stream of
cash flows, you just calculate
the present value of each
flow and then add them.
5.4 Level Cash Flows: Perpetuities and Annuities
Frequently, you may need to v
annuity
Equally spaced level
stream of cash flows,
with a finit
.
perpetuity
Stream of level cash
payments that never
ends.
ws. For example, a home
e equal monthly payments for the life
of the loan. For a 30-year loan, this w
loan might require 48 equal monthly payments. Any such sequence of equally spaced,
lev
ws is called an annuity. If the payment stream lasts forever, it is called a
perpetuity.
How to Value Perpetuities
Some time ago the British gov
wn as consols.
ords, instead of repaying these loans, the British
gov
v
ver).
How might we v
vest $100 at an
interest rate of 10%. You w
3 $100 5
could withdraw this amount from your investment account each year without ev
ning down your balance. In other words, a $100 investment could pro
. In general,
Cash payment from perpetuity 5 interest rate 3 present value
C 5 r 3 PV
W
ve the present v
interest rate r and the cash payment C:
PV of perpetuity 5
cash payment
C
5
r
interest rate
, given the
(5.3)
Suppose some worthy person wishes to endo
versity.
If the rate of interest is 10% and the aim is to provide $100,000 a year forever
amount that must be set aside today is
Present value of perpetuity 5
C
$100,000
5 $1,000,000
5
r
.10
Two w
confuse the formula with the present value of a single cash payment. A payment of $1
at the end of 1 year has a present value 1/(1 1 r).
alue of 1/r.
These are quite different.
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
Multiple Cash Flows
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e.
Spreadsheet Questions
alue of a regular stream of payments
w. Thus our endowment of $1 million would provide the
univ
w
vide the univ
she would need to put aside $1,100,000.
Sometimes you may need to calculate the v
e payments for sev
or example, suppose that our philanthropist decides
to provide $100,000 a year with the f
w. We know that in
year 3, this endo
end of 1 year
wment will be
w
r. But it is not w
w. To find today’s v
multiply by the 3-year discount factor.
$100,000 3
Self-Test 5.6
128
1
1
1
5 $1,000,000 3
5 $751,315
3
3
r
( 1 1 r)
(1.10)3
Chapter 5
129
The Time Value of Money
How to Value Annuities
Autos for (almost) the last time. Most installment plans call
w of
xt 3 years.
A lev
wn
as an
.
. Figure 5.8 sho
ws and calculates the present value of each
year’
w assuming an interest rate of 10%. You can see that the total present value of
the payments is $19,894.82.
Y
ways v
w
and finding the total. However, it is usually quick
states that if the interest rate is r, then the present value of an annuity that pays C dolt
for lev
Present value of t
annuity factor
Present value of a
$1 annuity.
5 CB
1
1
R
2
r
r ( 1 1 r) t
(5.4)
The expression in brackets shows the present value of a t
t-year annuity factor. Therefore, another way to
alue of an annuity is
Present value of t
5 payment 3 annuity factor
You can use this formula to calculate the present value of the payments to Kangaroo.
C
r
(t) is 3. Therefore,
Present value 5 C B
1
1
1
1
R 5 8,000B
2
R 5 $19,894.82
2
t
r
r ( 1 1 r)
.10
.10 (1.10)3
This is e
w. If
the number of periods is small, there is little to choose between the two methods, but
when you are v
If you are w
Figure 5.9. It
sho
vestments.
Row 1 The investment in the first row pro
the end of the first year. We hav
of 1/r.
FIGURE 5.8 To find the
value of an ann
, you can
calculate the value of each
cash flow. It is usually quicker
to use the ann
ormula.
130
Part Two Value
FIGURE 5.9
The value of an ann
er
een the v
o
perpetuities.
Row 2 Now look at the investment shown in the second row of Figure 5.9. It also
pro
ut these payments don’
This stream of payments is identical to the payments in row 1, except that the
v
orth 1/r
To
alue today, we simply multiply this f
actor. Thus
PV 5
1
1
1
5
3
r
(
( 1 1 r) 3
r 1 1 r) 3
Row 3 Finally, look at the investment shown in the third row of Figure 5.9. This
provides a lev
annuity. Y
en together, the investments in rows 2 and 3 provide
exactly the same cash payments as the investment in row 1. Thus the value of our
annuity (row 3) must be equal to the value of the ro
alue of the
delayed ro
5
1
1
2
r
r ( 1 1 r) 3
icult as remembering other people’
valent to the difference
, you shouldn’t have any dif
.
You can use a calculator or spreadsheet to work out annuity factors (we show you
ho
Table 5.4 is an abridged
annuity table (an extended version is shown in Table A.3 at the end of the book).
actor for an interest rate of 10%.
Compare Table 5.4 with Table 5.3, which presented the present value of a single
w. In both tables, present values f
v
ws to higher discount rates. But in contrast to those in Table 5.3, present values in Table 5.4 increase
as we move do
longer annuities.
TABLE 5.4
An example of
an ann
able, showing the
present value today of $1 a
year received for each of t
years
Chapter 5
131
The Time Value of Money
Self-Test 5.7
▲
EXAMPLE 5.8
Winning Big at the Lottery
In A
ers from Nebraska pooled their money to buy
Powerball lottery tickets and won a record $365 million. We suspect that the winners
received unsolicited congratulations, good wishes, and requests for money from
dozens of more or less worthy charities, relations, and newly devoted friends. In
response, they could fairly point out that the prize wasn’t really worth $365 million.
That sum was to be paid in 30 equal annual installments of $12.167 million each.
Assuming that the first payment occurred at the end of 1 year, what was the present value of the prize? The interest rate at the time was about 6%.
The present value of these payments is simply the sum of the present values of
each annual payment. But rather than valuing the payments separately, it is much
easier to treat them as a 30-year ann
. To value this annuity, we simply multiply
$12.167 million by the 30-year annuity factor:
PV 5 12.167 3 30-year annuity factor
5 12.167 3 B
At an interest rate of 6%, the ann
B
1
1
2
R
(
r
r 1 1 r)30
actor is
1
1
2
R 5 13.7648
.06
.06(1.06)30
(We could also look up the ann
actor in Table A.3.) The present value of the
cash payments is $12.167 3 13.7648 5 $167.5 million, much less than the muchadvertised prize, but still not a bad day’s haul.
L ery operators generally make arrangements for winners with big spending
plans to take an equivalent lump sum. In our example the winners could either
take the $365 million spread over 30 years or receive $167.5 million up front. Both
arrangements have the same present value.
▲
EXAMPLE 5.9
How Much Luxury and Excitement Can $53 Billion Buy?
Bill Gates is one of the world’s richest persons, with wealth in 2010 reputed to be
about $53 billion. Mr. Gates has devoted a large part of his fortune to the Bill and
Melinda Gates Foundation; but suppose that he decides to allocate his entire
remaining wealth to a life of luxury and entertainment (L&E). What annual expenditures on L&E could $53 billion support over a 30-year period? Assume that Mr. Gates
can invest his funds at 6%.
The 30-year, 6% annuity factor is 13.7648. We set the present value of Mr. Gates’s
spending stream equal to his total wealth:
Present value 5 annual spending 3 annuity factor
53,000,000,000 5 annual spending 3 13.7648
Annual spending 5 3,850,400,000, or about 3.85 billion
132
Part Two Value
Using a financial calculator or spreadsheet, the inputs would be:
PMT
Inputs
Compute
Excel
30
6
0
253000000000
3,850,392,309
=PMT(rate, nper, PV, FV) =PMT(.06, 30, -53000000000, 0)
The answer is identical except for a little rounding error.
Warning to Mr. Gates: We haven’t considered inflation. The cost of buying L&E
will increase, so $3.85 billion won’t buy as much L&E in 30 years as it will today. More
on that later.
Self-Test 5.8
▲
EXAMPLE 5.10
Home Mortgages
Sometimes you may need to find the series of cash payments that would provide a
given value today. For example, home purchasers typically borrow the bulk of the
house price from a lender. The most common loan arrangement is a 30-year loan
that is repaid in equal monthly installments. Suppose that a house costs $125,000
and that the buyer puts down 20% of the purchase price, or $25,000, in cash, borrowing the remaining $100,000 from a mortgage lender such as the local savings
bank. What is the appropriate monthly mortgage payment?
The borrower repays the loan by making monthly payments over the ne
years (360 months). The savings bank needs to set these monthly payments so that
they have a present value of $100,000. Thus
Present value 5
3 360-month annuity factor
5 $100,000
Mortgage payment 5
$100,000
360-month annuity factor
Suppose that the interest rate is 1% a month. Then
Mortgage payment 5
$100,000
1
1
B
2
R
(
.01
.01 1.01)360
5
$100,000
5 $1,028.61
97.218
amortizing loan. “
Table 5.5 illustrates a 4-year amortizing
. The
annual payment (annuity) that w
yourself.) At the end of the f
, the interest payment is 10% of $1,000, or $100.
So $100 of your first payment is used to pay interest, and the remaining $215.47 is
Chapter 5
The Time Value of Money
133
TABLE 5.5
An example of
an amortizing loan. If you
borrow $1,000 at an interest
rate of 10%, you would need
to make an annual payment
of $315.47 over 4 years to
repay the loan with interest.
Next year, the outstanding balance is lower, so the interest charge is only $78.45.
Therefore, $315.47 2 $78.45 5
Amortization
irst, because the amount of the loan has
en up in interest. This procedure continues until the last year
ing balance on the loan to zero.
vely paid off, the fraction of each payment devoted to
interest steadily falls ov
zation) steadily increases. Figure 5.10
Ev
ulk of the monthly payment is interest.
Self-Test 5.9
Future Value of an Annuity
You are back in savings mode again. This time you are setting aside $3,000 at the end
of ev
. If your sa
, how much will they be w
at the end of 4 years? We can answer this question with the help of the time line in
Figure 5.11. Y
s sa
FIGURE 5.10
Mortgage
amortization. This figure
shows the breakdown of
mortgage payments between
interest and amortization.
Monthly payments within
each year are summed, so
the figure shows the annual
payment on the mortgage.
134
Part Two Value
FIGURE 5.11
Calculating
the future value of an
ordinary annuity of $3,000
a year for 4 years
(interest rate 5 8%)
vings in year
The sum of the future values of the four payments is
($3,000 3 1.083) 1 ($3,000 3 1.082) 1 ($3,000 3 1.08) 1 $3,000 5 $13,518
But w
We hav
ity
W
v
ws—an annuity.
present v
e value of a level
ws.
$3,000 in each of the ne
equal to
vings is w
.Y
The present value of this 4-year annuity is therefore
PV 5 $3,000 3
1
1
2
R 5 $9,936
5 $3,000 3 B
.08
.08(1.08)4
No
w much you would have after 4 years if you invested $9,936 today.
Simple! Just multiply by (1.08)4:
Value at end of year 4 5 $9,936 3 1.084 5 $13,518
We calculated the future v
alue and
then multiplying by (1 1 r)t. The general formula for the future value of a stream of
t years is therefore
(FV) of annuity of $1 a year 5
of $1 a year 3 (1 1 r) t
(1 1 r) t 2 1
1
1
t
5B 2
t R 3 (1 1 r ) 5
r
r
r (1 1 r)
(5.5)
If you need to find the future v
ws as in our example, it is a
toss-up whether it is quicker to calculate the future v
w separately
(as we did in Figure 5.11
aced with a stream
ws, there is no contest.
Y
alue of an annuity in Table 5.6 or the more extensive Table
A.4 at the end of the book. You can see that in the ro
t 5 4 and the
r 5 8%, the future v
Therefore, the future value of the $3,000 annuity is $3,000 3 4.5061 5 $13,518. In
alues.
Chapter 5
135
The Time Value of Money
TABLE 5.6 An example of
a table showing the future
value of an investment of
$1 a year for each of t years
▲
EXAMPLE 5.11
Saving for Retirement
In only 50 more years, you will retire. (That’s right—by the time you retire, the retirement age will be around 70 years. Longevity is not an unmixed blessing.) Have you
started saving yet? Suppose you believe you will need to accumulate $500,000 by
your retirement date in order to support your desired standard of living. How much
savings each year would be necessary to produce $500,000 at the end of 50 years?
Let’s say that the interest rate is 10% per year. You need to find how large the annuity in the following figure must be to provide a future value of $500,000:
We know that if you were to save $1 each year your funds would accumulate to
Future value (FV) of
f $1 a year 5
(1.10)50 2 1
(1 1 r)t 2 1
5
r
.10
5 $1,163.91
We need to choose C to ensure that C 3 1,163.91 5 $500,000. Thus C 5
$500,000/1,163.91 5 $429.59. This appears to be surprisingly good news. Saving
$429.59 a year does not seem to be an extremely demanding savings program.
Don’t celebrate yet, however. The news will get worse when we consider the
impact of inflation.
Self-Test 5.10
136
Part Two
Value
5.5 Annuities Due
annuity due
Level stream of cash flows
starting immediately.
Remember that our annuity formulas assume that the first cash flow does not occur
until the end of the first period. The present value of an annuity is the value today of a
stream of payments that starts in one period. Similarly, the future value of an annuity
assumes that the first cash flow comes at the end of one period.
But in many cases cash payments start immediately. For example, when Kangaroo
Autos (see Figure 5.8) sells you a car on credit, it may insist that the first payment be
made at the time of the sale. A level stream of payments starting immediately is known
as an annuity due.
Figure 5.12 depicts the cash-flow streams of an ordinary annuity and an annuity
due. Comparing panels a and b, you can see that each of the three cash flows in the
annuity due comes one period earlier than the corresponding cash flow of the ordinary
annuity. Therefore, each is discounted for one less period, and its present value
increases by a factor of (1 1 r). Therefore,
Present value of annuity due 5 present value of ordinary annuity 3 (1 1 r) (5.6)
Figure 5.12 shows that bringing the Kangaroo loan payments forward by 1 year
increases their present value from $19,894.82 (as an ordinary annuity) to $21,884.30
(as an annuity due). Notice that $21,884.30 5 $19,894.82 3 1.10.
FIGURE 5.12
The cash
payments on the ordinary
annuity in panel a start in
year 1. The first payment on
the annuity due in panel b
occurs immediately. The
annuity due is therefore more
valuable.
3-year ordinary annuity
$8,000
$8,000
$8,000
1
2
3
Year
0
Present value
8,000
1.10
5
$7,272.73
8,000
(1.10)2
5
$6,611.57
8,000
(1.10)3
5
$6,010.52
Total
$19,894.82
(a)
3-year annuity due
$8,000
$8,000
$8,000
0
1
2
Year
3
Present value
$8,000.00
8,000
1.10
5
$7,272.73
8,000
(1.10)2
5
$6,611.57
Total
$21,884.30
(b)
Chapter 5
137
The Time Value of Money
By the way, it is easy to deal with annuities due in your calculator or spreadsheets.
Your calculator will have a “begin” key, possibly labeled BEG or BGN. If you push that
key
ginning of each
e
1 at the end of a present v
the annuity as an annuity due. For example, the present value of Kangaroo Auto’s 3-year
as 5PV(rate, nper, PMT, FV) 5PV(.10, 3, 8000, 0) 5 $19,894.82.
For an annuity due, we w
5PV(.10, 3, 8000,
0, 1) 5 $21,884.30.
Self-Test 5.11
You may also want to calculate the
ev
w comes immediately
w stream is greater, since each
w has an extra year to earn interest. For example, at an interest rate of 10%, the
future value of an annuity due would be exactly 10% greater than the future value of
. More generally,
Future value of annuity due 5
▲
EXAMPLE 5.12
3 ( 1 1 r)
(5.7)
Future Value of Annuities versus Annuities Due
In Example 5.11, we showed that an annual savings stream of $429.59 invested for
50 years at 10% w
vings goal of $500,000. Suppose that you put
aside the same annual amounts but you invested the money at the beginning
rather than the end of each year. Your savings plan now looks as follows:
How much would these annual savings provide by the end of year 50?
Easy. We know that the future value of an ann
o the future value
of an ordinary annuity 3 (1 1 r). Therefore, if you make the first of your 50 annual
investments immediately, then by the end of the 50 years your retirement savings
will be 10% higher, $550,000.
138
Part Two Value
5.6 Effective Annual Interest Rates
Thus f
v
annual interest rates to v
annual
ws. But interest rates may be quoted for days, months, years, or any
convenient interval. How should we compare rates when the
periods, such as monthly v
Consider your credit card. Suppose you have to pay interest on any unpaid balances
at the rate of 1% per month. What is it going to cost you if you neglect to pay off your
effective annual
interest rate
Interest rate that is
annualized using
compound interest.
Don’t be put off because the interest rate is quoted per month rather than per year.
The important thing is to maintain consistency between the interest rate and the number of periods. If the interest rate is quoted as a percent per month, then we must define
the number of periods in our future value calculation as the number of months. So if
w $100 from the credit card company at 1% per month for 12 months, you
will need to repay $100 3 (1.01)12 5 $112.68. Thus your debt grows after 1 year to
$112.68.
v
effective annual interest rate, or annually compounded rate, of 12.68%.
In general, the effectiv
money grows, allo
1 1 effective annual rate 5 (1 1 monthly rate)12
ved ov
annual percentage
rate (APR)
Interest rate that is
annualized using simple
interest.
ve annual rates. This comws for possible
alized by multiplying the rate per period by the number of periods in a year. In fact,
ws in the United States require that rates be annualized in this manner
annual percentage rates (APRs).2 The interest rate on your
, the APR on
the loan is 12 3 1% 5 12%.
If the credit card company quotes an APR of 12%, ho
fective
annual interest rate? The solution is simple:
Step 1. Take the quoted APR and divide by the number of compounding periods in
a year to recover the rate per period actually charged. In our example, the
interest was calculated monthly. So we divide the
interest rate per month:
Monthly interest rate 5
12%
APR
5
5 1%
12
12
Step 2. Now conv
1 1 effective annual rate 5 (1 1 monthly rate)12 5 (1 1 .01)12 5 1.1268
The effective annual interest rate is .1268, or 12.68%.
In general, if an investment is quoted with a given
m compounding periods in a year, then $1 will grow to $1 3 (1 1 APR/m)m after 1 year.
The effective annual interest rate is (1 1
m)m 2 1. For example, a credit card
APR of 12% b
ve
ective
annual interest rate of (1.01)12 2 1 5 .1268, or 12.68%. To summarize:
annual rate is the rate at which invested funds will grow over the course of a
year. It equals the rate of interest per period compounded for the number of
periods in a year.
2
small businesses.
ws apply to credit card loans, auto loans, home improv
Chapter 5
TABLE 5.7
139
The Time Value of Money
These investments all have an APR of 6%, but the more frequently interest is compounded, the
ective annual rate of interest.
▲
EXAMPLE 5.13
The Effective Interest Rates on Bank Accounts
Back in the 1960s and 1970s federal regulation limited the (APR) interest rates banks
could pay on savings accounts. Banks were hungry for depositors, and they
searched for ways to increase the ective rate of interest that could be paid within
the rules. Their solution was to keep the same APR but to calculate the interest on
deposits more frequently. As interest is compounded at shorter and shorter intervals, less time passes before interest can be earned on interest. Therefore,
ective annually compounded rate of interest increases. Table 5.7 shows the
calculations assuming that the maximum APR that banks could pay was 6%. (Actually, it was a bit less than this, but 6% is a nice round number to use for illustration.)
You can see from Table 5.7 how banks were able to incr
ective interest
rate simply by calculating interest at more frequent intervals.
The ultimate step was to assume that interest was paid in a continuous stream
rather than at fixed intervals. With 1 year’s continuous compounding, $1 grows to
e APR, where e 5 2.718 (a figure that may be familiar to you as the base for natural
logarithms). Thus if you deposit
ered a continuously compounded rate of 6%, your investment would grow by the end of the year to
(2.718).06 5 $1.061837, just a hair’s breadth more than if interest were compounded daily.
Self-Test 5.12
5.7 Inflation and the Time Value of Money
fers to pay 6% on a sa
for ev
doesn’t provide an
inv
you actually lose ground in terms of the goods you can buy.
ut it
uy. If the value of your
Real versus Nominal Cash Flows
inflation
Rate at which prices as
a whole are increasing.
Textbooks may become more expensive (sorry) while computers become cheaper. An ov
known as
.
, then goods that cost $1.00 a
Chapter 5
▲
EXAMPLE 5.14
141
The Time Value of Money
The Outrageous Price of Gasoline
Motorists in 2010, who were paying about $2.80 for a gallon of gasoline, may have
looked back longingly to 1981, when they were paying just $1.40 a gallon. But how
much had the real price of gasoline changed over this period? Let’s check.
In 2010 the consumer price index was about 2.5 times its level in 1981. If the
price of gasoline had risen in line with inflation, it would have cost 2.5 3 $1.40 5 $3.50
a gallon in 2010. That was the cost of gasoline in 1981 but measured in terms of
2010 dollars rather than 1981 dollars. Thus over this time period the real price of
gasoline actually declined 20%, from $3.50 a gallon to $2.80.
Self-Test 5.13
Consider a telephone call to London that currently would cost $5. If the real
price of telephone calls does not change in the future, how much will it cost
you to make a call to London in 50 years if the inflation rate is 5% (roughly its
average over the past 30 years)? What if inflation is 10%?
Economists sometimes talk about current or nominal dollars versus constant
or real dollars. Current or nominal dollars refer to the actual number of dollars of
the day; constant or real dollars refer to the amount of purchasing power.
Some expenditures are fixed in nominal terms and therefore decline in real terms
when the CPI increases. Suppose you took out a 30-year house mortgage in 1990. The
monthly payment was $800. It was still $800 in 2010, even though the CPI increased
by a factor of 1.64 over those years (219.2/133.8 5 1.64).
What’s the monthly payment for 2010 expressed in real 1990 dollars? The answer
is $800/1.64, or $488 per month. The real burden of paying the mortgage was much
less in 2010 than in 1990.
Self-Test 5.14
If a family spent $250 a week on their typical purchases in 1950, how much
would those purchases have cost in 1980? If your salary in 1980 was $30,000
a year, what would be the real value of that salary in terms of 1950 dollars?
Use the data in Table 5.8.
Inflation and Interest Rates
nominal interest rate
Rate at which money
invested grows.
Whenever anyone quotes an interest rate, you can be fairly sure that it is a nominal, not
a real, rate. It sets the actual number of dollars you will be paid with no offset for
future inflation.
If you deposit $1,000 in the bank at a nominal interest rate of 6%, you will have
$1,060 at the end of the year. But this does not mean you are 6% better off. Suppose
that the inflation rate during the year is also 6%. Then the goods that cost $1,000 last
year will now cost $1,000 3 1.06 5 $1,060, so you’ve gained nothing:
Real future value of investment 5
5
$1,000 3 (1 1 nominal interest rate)
(1 1 inflation rate)
$1,000 3 1.06
5 $1,000
1.06
142
Two
real interest rate
Rate at which the
purchasing power of an
investment increases.
Value
In this example, the nominal rate of interest is 6%, but the real interest rate is zero.
The real rate of interest is calculated by
1 1 real interest rate 5
1 1 nominal interest rate
11
(5.8)
In our e
1.06
51
1.06
Real interest rate 5 0
1 1 real interest rate 5
What if the nominal interest rate is 6% b
the real interest rate is 1.06/1.02 2 1 5
of bread is $1, so that $1,000 would buy 1,000 loaves today. If you invest that $1,000
ve $1,060 at the end of the year. However,
if the price of loav
y will buy you
1,060/1.02 5 1,039 loaves. The real rate of interest is 3.9%.
Self-Test 5.15
Here is a useful approximation. The real rate approximately equals the difference
5
Real interest rate < nominal interest rate 2
(5.9)
Our e
rate of 3.9%. If we round to 4%, the approximation gives the same answer:
Real interest rate < nominal interest rate 2
< 6 2 2 5 4%
The approximation w
When they are not small, throw the approximation away and do it right.
▲
EXAMPLE 5.15
Real and Nominal Rates
In the United States in mid-2010, long-term high-grade corporat
yield of about 5.1%. If inflation is expected to be about 1%, the real yield is
1 1 real interest rate 5
ered a
1 1 nominal interest rate
1.051
5
5 1.0406
1 1 inflation rate
1.01
Real interest rate 5 .0406, or 4.06%
The approximation rule gives a similar value of 5.1 2 1.0 5 4.1%. But the approximation would not have worked in the German hyperinflation of 1922–1923, when the
inflation rate was well over 100% per month (at one point you needed 1 million
marks to mail a letter), or in Zimbabwe in November 2008, when prices rose an average of 98% per day.
5
The squiggle (≈) means “approximately equal to.”
Chapter 5
143
The Time Value of Money
Valuing Real Cash Payments
w to v
learned how to v
est rate. For e
w much do you
need to invest now to produce $100 in a year’s time? Easy! Calculate the present value
of $100 by discounting by 10%:
PV 5
$100
5 $90.91
1.10
You get exactly the same result if you discount the real payment by the real interest
rate. For example, assume that you e
ver the ne
. The real
value of that $100 is therefore only $100/1.07 5 $93.46. In one year’s time your $100
will buy only as much as $93.46 today.
interest is only about 3%. We can calculate it exactly from the formula
11
11
Real interest rate 5 .028, or 2.8%
1 1 real interest rate 5
5
1.10
5 1.028
1.07
If we now discount the $93.46 real payment by the 2.8% real interest rate, we have
a present value of $90.91, just as before:
PV 5
$93.46
5 $90.91
1.028
The two methods should always give the same answer.
Remember: Current dollar cash flows must be discounted by the nominal
interest rate; real cash flows must be discounted by the real interest rate.
ws) is an unforgiv
ws and real discount rates (or real rates and nominal
w man
Self-Test 5.16
▲
EXAMPLE 5.16
How Inflation Might Affect Bill Gates
We showed earlier (Example 5.9) that at an interest rate of 6% Bill Gates could, if he
wished, turn his $53 billion wealth into a 30-year ann
ear of
luxury and excitement (L&E). Unfortunately, L&E expenses inflate just like gasoline
and groceries. Thus Mr. Gates would find the purchasing power of that $3.85 billion
steadily declining. If he wants the same luxuries in 2040 as in 2010, he’ll have to
spend less in 2010 and then increase expenditures in line with inflation. How much
should he spend in 2010? Assume the long-run inflation rate is 3%.
Mr. Gates needs to calculate a 30-year real annuity. The real interest rat
less than 3%:
1 1 real interest rate 5
1 1 nominal interest rate
1 1 inflation rate
5
1.06
5 1.029
1.03
144
Two
Value
so the real rate is 2.9%. The 30-year ann
actor at 2.9% is 19.8562. Therefore,
annual spending (in 2010 dollars) should be chosen so that
$53,000,000,000 5 annual spending 3 19.8562
Annual spending 5 $2,669,000,000
Mr. Gates could spend that amount on L&E in 1 year’s time and 3% more (in line
with inflation) in each subsequent year. This is only about 70% of the value we
calculated when we ignored inflation. Life has many disappointments, even for
.
Self-Test 5.17
Real or Nominal?
Any present value calculation done in nominal terms can also be done in real terms,
and vice v
nominal rates. However
ws are easier to deal with. In
our example of Bill Gates, the real e
ed. In this case, it was
w stream is fixed in
nominal terms (for example, the payments on a loan), it is easiest to use all nominal
quantities.
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
www.smartmoney.com
www.smartmoney.com
www.bloomberg.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
i
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.bls.gov/cpi/home.htm
PMT
PMT
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO SPREADSHEET QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
MINICASE
CHAPTER
6
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T T W O
Value
I
Bondholders once received a beautifully engraved
certificate like this one issued by a railroad.
6.1 The Bond Market
bond
Security that obligates
the issuer to make
specified payments to
the bondholder.
Gov
w money by selling bonds to investors. The market for these bonds is huge. In 2011 public holdings of U.S. gov
1
Companies also raise v
ge sums of money by
selling bonds. For e
wed $17 billion by an issue of
bonds. The market for bonds is sophisticated and active. Bond traders frequently make
massive trades motivated by tin
v
e.
For e
ed interest payment, b
may go up or do
v
w for only a fe
ve been
a few occasions when bonds hav
Bond Characteristics
face value
Pa
of the bond. Also called
principal or par value.
coupon
The interest payments
paid to the bondholder.
In May 2003 the U.S. gov
Treasury bond. It auctioned
off to investors $18 billion of 3.625% bonds maturing in 2013. The bonds have a
face value
principal or par value
matures, the bondholder receives an interest payment of 3.625% of the face value, or
$36.25. This 3.625% interest payment is called the bond’s coupon. In the old days, most
bonds used to hav
v
claim their payment. When the 3.625% coupon bond matures in 2013, the government
must pay the $1,000 face v
ferent T
buy and sell each of these bonds are sho
Web. Table 6.1, which is compiled from The Wall Street Journal’s Web page, shows
May 2013 is highlighted.
Thus for the 3.625%
bond, the asked price
vestors need to pay to buy the bond—is
shown as 107:01.
ace
value. Therefore, each bond costs $1,070.3125. An investor who already owns the
bond and wishes to sell it would receiv
bid price, which is shown as 106:31. Just
as the used-car dealer earns a li
them, so the bond dealer needs to charge a spread between the bid and the asked price.
Notice that the spread for these 3.625% bonds is only 2/32, or about .06% of the
bond’s value. Don’
ws the ask
. This measures the
vestors if they buy the bond at the ask
2013. Y
T
1.23%. We will e
w this figure was calculated.
Self-Test 6.1
1
160
T
Chapter 6
161
Valuing Bonds
TABLE 6.1
Sample Treasury
bond quotes for May 14, 2010
Source: The Wall Street Journal Web site,
.wsj.com.
FIGURE 6.1 Cash flows to
an investor in the 3.625%
coupon bond maturing in the
year 2013
Y
t buy T
xchange. Instead, the
netw
y are prepared to
buy and sell. For example, suppose that in 2010 you decide to buy the “3.625s of
2013,” that is, the 3.625% coupon bonds maturing in 2013. You approach a broker who
your broker will contact a bond dealer and the trade is done.
If you plan to hold your bond until maturity, you can look forw
ws
shown in Figure 6.1. F
payment. Then, when the bond matures in 2013, you receive the $1,000 face value of
Self-Test 6.2
6.2 Interest Rates and Bond Prices
In Figure 6.1
the bond is the present v
ws from your 3.625% Treasury bond. The value of
ws. To find this value, you need to dis-
The 3.625s were not the only Treasury bonds that matured in 2013. Almost identical bonds maturing at the same time of
ould have been willing to hold
them. Equally, if they had offered a higher
v
ould hav
162
Part Two Value
their other bonds and buy the 3.625s. In other words, if investors were on their toes,
the 3.625s had to offer the same 1.25% rate of interest as similar T
You
v
discussed in Chapter 1. This is the rate that inv
in similar securities rather than in this bond.
We can now calculate the present value of the 3.625s of 2013 by discounting the
ws at 1.25%:
$1,036.25
$36.25
$36.25
1
1
( 1 1 r)
( 1 1 r) 2
( 1 1 r) 3
$36.25
$1,036.25
$36.25
5
1
5 $1,069.51
1
(1.0125)
(1.0125)2
(1.0125)3
PV 5
Bond prices are usually expressed as a percentage of their face value. Thus we can
say that your 3.625% Treasury bond is worth 106.951% of face value.2
Did you notice that your bond is like a package of two investments?
vides a level stream of coupon payments of $36.25 a year for each of 3 years. The
ace value. Therefore, you can use
alue the coupon payments and then add on the present value of
the final payment of face value:
PV 5 PV(coupons) 1 PV(face value)
5 (coupon 3 annuity factor) 1 (face value 3 discount factor)
(6.1)
1
1
1
2
R 1 1,000 3
3
(
)
.0125
.0125 1.0125
1.01253
5 $106.09 1 $963.42 5 $1,069.51
5 $36.25 3 B
If you need to v
, it is usually easiest
to value the coupon payments as an annuity and then add on the present value of the
Self-Test 6.3
Y
The trick is to recognize that the bond provides its owner both
(the coupons) and
w (the face value). For this bond, the
ace value is $1,000.
The interest rate is 1.25%. Therefore, the inputs would be
PV
Inputs
Compute
3
1.25
36.25
1000
21069.51
Now compute PV, and you should get an answer of 21069.51, which is the initial cash
w required to purchase the bond.
F
2
alue of $1,069.51 (106.951%) is a little lo
Table 6.1. We discounted at 1.25%, which is rounded up slightly from the ask
Also, the bond’
, but $18.125 ev
show ho
xt example, we’ll
Chapter 6
▲
EXAMPLE 6.1
163
Valuing Bonds
Bond Prices and Semiannual Coupon Payments
When we valued our Treasury bond, we assumed that interest payments occur
annually. This is the case for bonds in many European countries, but in the United
States most bonds make coupon payments semiannually. So when you hear that
a bond in the United States has a coupon rate of 3.625%, you can generally assume
that the bond makes a payment of $36.25/2 5 $18.125 every 6 months. Similarly,
when investors in the United States refer to the bond’s interest rate, they usually
mean the semiannually compounded interest rate. Thus an interest rate quoted at
1.25% really means that the 6-month rate is 1.25/2 5 .625%.3 The actual cash flows
on the Treasury bond are illustrated in Figure 6.2. To value the bond a bit more
precisely, we should have discounted the series of semiannual payments by the
semiannual rate of interest as follows:
PV 5
1
$18.125
$18.125
$18.125
$18.125
1
1
1
(1.00625)
(1.00625)4
(1.00625)2
(1.00625)3
$18.125
$1,018.125
1
(1.00625)5
(1.00625)6
5 $1,069.72
Thus, once we allow for the fact that coupon payments are semiannual, the value
of the 3.625s is 106.972% of face value, which is slightly higher than the value that
we obtained when we assumed annual coupon payments.4 Since semiannual
coupon payments just add to the arithmetic, we will stick for the most part to our
simplification and assume annual interest payments.
How Bond Prices Vary with Interest Rates
Figure 6.3
T
ho
or example, interest rates climbed steeply after
1979 when the Federal Reserve instituted a policy of tight mone
W
v
this with 2008, when nervous inv
v
T
or e
vestors
demanded an interest rate of 3.625% on 3-year T
What would be the
price of the T
rate of r 5 .03625:
PV at 3.625% 5
$1,036.25
$36.25
$36.25
1
5 $1,000.00
1
(1.03625)
(1.03625)2
(1.03625)3
the bond sells for its face value.
3
You may hav
s APR,
vestors. To find the effective rate, we can use a formula that
we presented in Section 5.6:
Effective annual rate 5 ¢ 1 1
where m is the number of payments each year
E
5 ¢1 1
4
payment is receiv
received earlier, its present value is higher.
2
m
APR
≤ 21
m
T
.0125
≤ 2 1 5 1.006252 2 1 5 .01254, or 1.254%
2
164
Part Two Value
FIGURE 6.2 Cash flows to
an investor in the 3.625%
coupon bond maturing in
2013. The bond pays
semiannual coupons, so
there ar
o payments of
$18.125 each year.
FIGURE 6.3 The interest rate
on 10-year U.S. Treasury
bonds, 1900-2010
W
alued the Treasury bond using an interest rate of 1.25%, which is lower
than the coupon rate. In that case the price of the bond was higher than its face value.
We then valued it using an interest rate that is equal to the coupon and found that bond
price equaled face value. You hav
ws
are discounted at a rate that is higher than the bond’s coupon rate, the bond is w
less than its face value. The following e
▲
EXAMPLE 6.2
Interest Rates and Bond Prices
Investors will pay $1,000 for a 3.625%, 3-year Treasury bond when the interest rate is
3.625%. Suppose that the interest rate is higher than the coupon rate at (say) 8%.
Now what is the value of the bond? Simple! We just repeat our calculation but with
r 5 .08:
PV at 8% 5
$36.25
$36.25
$1,036.25
1
1
5 $887.25
(1.08)
(1.08)2
(1.08)3
The bond sells for 88.725% of face value.
This is a general result. When the market interest rate exceeds the coupon
rate, bonds sell for less than face value. When the market interest rate is below
the coupon rate, bonds sell for more than face value.
Chapter 6
Valuing Bonds
165
FIGURE 6.4 The value of
the 3.625% bond falls as
interest rates rise.
ws, bond investors appear disconsolate. Why? Don’t they lik
,
look at Figure 6.4, which shows the present value of the 3.625% Treasury bond for
or example, imagine yields soar from 1.25% to 8%. Our bond
would then be w
versely, bondholders hav
et interest rates fall. You can
see this also from Figure 6.4. For instance, if interest rates fall to .5%, the value of our
3.625% bond would increase to $1,092.82.
Figure 6.4 illustrates a fundamental relationship between interest rates and bond
prices: When the interest rate rises, the present value of the payments to be
received by the bondholder falls and bond prices fall. Conversely, a decline in
the interest rate increases the present value of those payments and results in a
higher price.
Aw
coupon rate
Annual interest payment
as a percentage of face
value.
payment on the bond
interest rate
vestors require. The $36.25 coupon
payments on our T
when the bond is issued. The coupon rate,
3.625%, measures the coupon payment ($36.25) as a percentage of the bond’s face
v
ed. However, the interest rate changes from
day to day. These c
ect the present value of the coupon payments but
not the payments themselves.
Interest Rate Risk
interest rate risk
The risk in bond prices
due to fluctuations in
interest rates.
We hav
ords,
bonds exhibit interest rate risk. Bond inv
et interest
rates will f
y are unlucky and the market interest rate rises, the value of their investment falls.
A change in interest rates has only a modest impact on the value of near-term cash
ws but a much greater impact on the v
ws. Therefore any
or e
es in Figure 6.5. The green line shows
how the v
, 3.625% coupon bond varies with the interest rate. The blue
line shows how the price of a 30-year, 3.625% bond varies. You can see that the 30-year
bond is more sensitiv
This should
bad deal—you could have got a better interest rate if you had waited. However
how much worse it would be if the loan had been for 30 years rather than 3 years. The
166
Two
Value
FIGURE 6.5 Plot of bond
prices as a function of the
interest rate. The price of
long-term bonds is more
sensitive to changes in the
interest rate than is the price
of short-term bonds.
v
w
interest rate. This shows up in a bigger decline in the price of the longer-term bond. Of
Figure 6.5.
interest rates fall, the longer
Self-Test 6.4
6.3 Yield to Maturity
Your investment adviser quotes a price for the bond. How do you calculate the rate of
return the bond offers?
For bonds priced at face value the answer is easy.
rate. W
ws on your investment:
Cash Paid to You in Year:
You Pay
$1,000
1
2
3
Rate of Return
$100
$100
$1,100
10%
y ($100/$1,000). In the final year
vestment of $1,000.
10%, the same as the coupon rate.
No
et price of the 3-year bond is $1,136.16. Y
are as follows:
Cash Paid to You in Year:
You Pay
1
2
3
Rate of Return
$1,136.16
$100
$100
$1,100
?
ws
Chapter 6
167
Valuing Bonds
Notice that you are paying out $1,136.16 and receiving an annual income of $100. So
5 .088, or 8.8%.
This is sometimes called the bond’s current yield.
However, your total
y capital gains or
losses.
v
bond’s price must fall. The price today is $1,136.16, but when the bond matures 3
years from now, the bond will sell for its face value, or $1,000.
capital loss) of $136.16 is guaranteed, so the overall return over the ne
current yield
Annual coupon
payments divided by
bond price.
Let us generalize. A bond that is priced above its face value is said to sell at a premium. Investors who b
ver the life of the
bond, so the return on these bonds is alw
A bond
w face value sells at a discount. Investors in discount bonds face a capital gain
ov
greater
Because it focuses only on current income and ignores prospective price increases
or decreases, the current yield does not measure the bond’s total rate of return. It
overstates the return of premium bonds and understates that of discount bonds.
yield to maturity
Interest rate for which
the present value of the
bond’s payments equals
the price.
W
change in a bond’s value over its life. The standard measure is called yield to maturity.
wing question: At what interest rate
The yield to matur
ined as the discount
w
rate that makes the present value of the bond’s payments equal to its price.
If you can buy the 3-year bond at face v
rate, 10%. W
the present value of the bond is equal to its $1,000 face value:
PV at 10% 5
ws at 10%,
$1,100
$100
$100
1
5 $1,000.00
1
2
(1.10)
(1.10)
(1.10)3
But suppose the price of the 3-year bond is $1,136.16. In this case the yield to
At that discount rate, the bond’s present value equals its actual
et price, $1,136.16:
PV at 5% 5
▲
EXAMPLE 6.3
$100
$1,100
$100
1
5 $1,136.16
1
(1.05)
(1.05)2
(1.05)3
Calculating Yield to Maturity for the Treasury Bond
We found the value of the 3.625% coupon Treasury bond by discounting at a 1.25%
interest rate. We could have phrased the question the other way around: If the
price of the bond is $1,069.51, what is the bond’s yield to maturity? To calculate the
yield, we need to find the discount rate r that solves the following equation:
Price 5
$36.25
$36.25
$1,036.25
1
1
5 $1,069.51
(1 1 r)
(1 1 r)2
(1 1 r)3
To compute the yield to maturity, most people use either a financial calculator or
a spreadsheet. For this bond, the inputs would be:
i
Inputs
Compute
3
21069.51 36.25
1.25
Now compute i, and you should get an answer of 1.25%.
1000
168
Part Two Value
income and capital gain. If you buy the bond today and hold it to maturity
. Bond investors often refer loosely to a bond’s “yield.” It’s
a safe bet that the
The only general
. You
s payments. If the present v
ve been too low, so
wer PV). Conversely, if PV
▲
EXAMPLE 6.4
Yield to Maturity with Semiannual Coupon Payments
Let’s redo Example 6.3, but this time we recognize that the coupons are paid semiannually. Instead of three annual coupon payments of $36.25, the bond makes
six semiannual payments of $18.125. Therefore, we can find the semiannual yield
to maturity as follows:
i
Inputs
Compute
6
21069.51 18.125
1000
.6284
This yield t
, of course, is a 6-month, not an annual, rate. Bond dealers
w
ualize the semiannual rate by doubling it, so the yield to maturity would be quoted as .628 3 2 5 1.256%. The nearby box shows how to use
spreadsheets to find bond prices and yields.
Self-Test 6.5
6.4 Bond Rates of Return
The yield to maturity is defined as the discount rate that equates the bond’
present v
. However, as interest
yield to maturity
your bond will f
rity. Conversely, if rates f
higher. This is emphasized in the following example.
▲
EXAMPLE 6.5
, the price of
wer than the yield to matu-
Rate of Return versus Yield to Maturity
On May 15, 2008, the U.S. Treasury sold $9 billion of 4.375% bonds maturing in
February 2038. The bonds wer
ered a yield to
Chapter 6
rate of return
Total income per period
per dollar invested.
169
Valuing Bonds
maturity of 4.60%. This was the return to anyone buying at the issue price and
holding the bonds t
. In the months following the issue the financial crisis
reached its peak. Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy with assets of $691 billion,
and the government poured money into rescuing Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, AIG,
and a host of banks. As investors rushed to the safety of Treasury bonds, their prices
soared. By mid-December the price of the 4.375s of 2038 had reached 138.05% of
face value and the yield had fallen to 2.5%. Anyone fortunate enough to have
bought the bond at the issue price would have made a capital gain of $1,380.50 2
$963.80 5 $416.70. In addition, on August 15 the bond made its first coupon payment of $21.875 (this is the semiannual payment on the 4.375% coupon bond with
a face value of $1,000). Our lucky investor would therefore have earned a 7-month
rate of return of 45.5%:
Rate of return 5
5
coupon income 1 price change
investment
$21.875 1 $416.70
5 .455 5 45.5%
$963.80
Suddenly, government bonds did not seem quite so boring as before.
Self-Test 6.6
Is there any
a particular period? Yes: If the bond’s yield to maturity remains unchanged during
the period, the bond price changes with time so that the total return on the bond is
equal to the yield to maturity.
rates fall.
Self-Test 6.7
The solid curve in Figure 6.6
ov
, 6% coupon bond
The
ace value. In
e in Figure 6.6 sho
bond with a 2% coupon that sells at a discount to face v
income would pro
v
w
face v
ace value, however, and the price gain each
et interest rate.
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
Bond Valuation
FIGURE 6.6 How bond
prices change as they
approach maturity, assuming
an unchanged yield. Prices
of both premium and
discount bonds approach
face value as their matur
date approaches.
170
6.5 The Yield Curve
yield curve
Plot of relationship
between bond yields to
o
.
When you buy a bond, you b
ment of face value. But sometimes it is inconvenient to buy things in packages. For
example, perhaps you do not need a regular income and would prefer to buy just the
final repayment. That’s not a problem. The T
es a single payment. These single-payment
bonds are called strips.
wn re
Web. For
example, in May 2010 it would have cost you $962.67 to buy a strip that just paid out
$1,000 in May 2013.
as 1.28%. In other words,
$962.67 3 1.01283 5 $1,000.
Bond investors often draw a plot of the relationship between bond yields and matu. This is known as the yield curve. T
vide a convenient way to
measure this yield curve. For example, if you look at Figure 6.7, you will see that in
vided a yield of about 4.6%. In this case, the yield curve sloped
171
172
Part Two Value
FIGURE 6.7 Treasury strips
are bonds that make a single
payment. The yields on
Tr
ips in May 2010
show that investors received
a higher yield on longer-term
bonds.
upw
5
fer lower
e slopes downward.
But that raises a question. If long-term bonds offered much higher yields, why
didn’t everyone buy them? Who were the (foolish?) investors who put their money
T
w yields?
Even when the yield curve is upward-sloping, inv
way
from long-term bonds for tw
We saw in Figure 6.5
prices are more sensitive to shifting interest rates.
vestors don’t lik
y will inv
y receive a
v
w, when the bond matures, you can reinvest the proceeds
and enjoy whatever rates the bond market offers then. These rates may be high enough
to of
s relatively lo
Thus you often see an
upw
Self-Test 6.8
Nominal and Real Rates of Interest
T
v
v
v
y will b
or e
,b
The real
w what
T
ws:
11
11
Real interest rate 5 .0385 5 3.85%
1 1 real interest rate 5
5
ages. For e
5
1.08
5 1.0385
1.04
v
Table 6.1
.
Chapter 6
173
Valuing Bonds
T
You can nail down a real rate of interest by b
xed bond, whose payxed bonds have been av
many years, but the
wn in the United States until 1997 when the
U.S. Treasury be
x
wn as Tr
ws on
ed, but the nominal
Protected Securities, or TIPS.6
x increases.
For example, suppose the U.S. T
TIPS. The real cash
Year 1
Year 2
$30
$1,030
Real cash flows
The nominal
ws on
or example, suppose
Then the nominal cash
ws would be:
Nominal cash flows
Year 1
Year 2
$30 3 1.05 5 $31.50
$1,030 3 1.05 3 1.04 5 $1,124.76
real
vestment will allow you to buy.
T
The 1.2% real yield on
v
v
Real interest rates depend on the supply of savings and the demand for new investment. As this supply-demand balance changes, real interest rates change. But they do
so gradually. W
v
ment has issued indexed bonds since 1982. The red line in Figure 6.8 shows that the
v
w range.
FIGURE 6.8
om line
shows the real yield on longterm indexed bonds issued
by the U.K. government. The
top line shows the yield on
U.K. government long-term
nominal bonds. Notice that
the real yield has been much
more stable than the nominal
yield.
6
x
Rev
or e
ve b
x
-sev
sw
.”
174
Part Two Value
Suppose that investors revise upw
w will
this affect interest rates? If investors are concerned about the purchasing power of their
money
fect the real rate of interest. The nominal
interest rate must therefore rise by 1% to compensate inv
prospects.
The blue line in Figure 6.8 sho
dom since 1985. You can see that the nominal rate is much more variable than the real
rate. For e
vestors were w
as about 7 percentage points above the real rate. Notice how
low the real interest rate has been recently. By the fall of 2010 the yield on index bonds
had fallen below zero.
6.6 Corporate Bonds and the Risk of Default
ar has been on U.S. T
v
the only issuer of bonds. State and local gov
w by selling bonds.7 So do
y foreign gov
w in the United
States.
issuing their bonds in other countries. For example, they may issue dollar bonds in
London that are then sold to investors throughout the world.
default (or credit) risk
The risk that a bond
issuer may default on its
bonds.
default premium
The additional yield on
a bond that investors
require for bearing
credit risk.
investment grade
Bonds rated Baa or
above by Moody’s or
BBB or above by
Standard & Poor’s.
junk bond
Bond with a rating
below Baa or BBB.
issued by the U.S. Treasury. National governments don’
y just print
T
ault on its
more money.8 So investors rarely w
bonds. However
inancial dif
ties and may default on their bonds.
v
ws, but in hard times it may pay less.
The risk that a bond issuer may default on its obligations is called default risk (or
credit risk). Companies need to compensate for this def
rate of interest on their bonds.
T
called the default premium. The greater the chance that the company will get into
trouble, the higher the def
vestors.
vided by
Moody’s, Standard & Poor’
Table 6.2 lists the possible
bond ratings in declining order of quality. For example, the bonds that receive the
highest Moody’
wn as Aaa (or “triple A”) bonds. Then come Aa (“double A”), A, Baa bonds, and so on. Bonds rated Baa and above are called investment
grade, while those with a rating of Ba or belo
speculative grade,
high-yield, or junk bonds.9
Table 6.2 shows how the chances of default v
You can see that it is
ault. For e
bonds have def
wever
vestment-grade bond
7
municipal bonds enjoy a special tax adv
vestors are ex
coupon payments on state and local gov
As a result, inv
wer yields
on this debt.
8
But the
Therefore, when a foreign gov
vestors w
vernment may not be able to come up with enough dollars to repay
the debt. This w
vestors demand on such debt. For example, in 2002, the gentine government defaulted on over $100 billion of debt. In Chapter 2 we saw also ho
v
s
indebtedness caused investors to w
v
ault on their
wings.
9
or example, the most secure A-rated bonds
would be rated A1 by Moody’
A1 by Standard & Poor’s. The least secure bonds in this risk class would
be rated A3 by Moody’
A2
s.
Chapter 6
175
Valuing Bonds
TABLE 6.2
Key to Moody’s
and Standard & Poor’s bond
r
bonds are rated triple A, then
come double-A bonds, and
so on.
is do
2001 W
e
v
def
Table 6.3 sho
most hea
aults, the shock waves can be considerable. For example, in May
vestment-grade rating. W
W
y
vestment. For low-grade issues, def
or
s at issue have
10
T
you would e
T
As
You can
alls off.
Investors also prefer liquid bonds that the
v
uy and sell. So additionally
fer lower yields
et for
vestors found it almost impossible to
sell their holdings.
Figure 6.9 sho
Treasuries since
or example, as w
TABLE 6.3
Prices and yields
of a sample of heavily traded
corporate bonds, June 1,
2010
Source:
10
Rating T
.wsj.com.
s, “Default, T
v
” www.standardandpoors.com.
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Insuring against Default
6% above the yield on T
You might have been tempted by the higher promised yields on the lower-grade bonds. But remember, these bonds do not always keep
their promises. By the way
ault.
xplains how.
FIGURE 6.9
Yield spreads
een corporate and
ear Treasury bonds
176
Chapter 6
▲
EXAMPLE 6.6
Valuing Bonds
177
Promised versus Expected Yield to Maturity
Bad Bet Inc. issued bonds several years ago with a coupon rate (paid annually) of
10% and face value of $1,000. The bonds are due to mature in 6 years. However, the
firm is currently in bankruptcy proceedings, the firm has ceased to pay interest, and
the bonds sell for only $200. Based on promised cash flow, the yield to maturity on
the bond is 63.9%. (On your calculator, set PV 5 2200, FV 5 1,000, PMT 5 100,
n 5 6, and compute i.) But this calculation is based on the very unlikely possibility
that the firm will resume paying interest and come out of bankruptcy. Suppose that
the most lik
er 3 years of litigation, during which no interest will
be paid, debtholders will receive 27 cents on the dollar—that is, they will receive
$270 for each bond with $1,000 face value. In this case the expected return on the
bond is 10.5%. (On your calculator, set PV 5 2200, FV 5 270, PMT 5 0, n 5 3, and
compute i.) When default is a real possibility, the promised yield can depart considerably from the expected return.
Variations in Corporate Bonds
T
chapter. In other words, the
, at which point they also promise to repay the face value.
However
W
ut here are a fe
that you may encounter.
Zero-Coupon Bonds Corporations sometimes issue zero-coupon bonds. In
this case, investors receive $1,000 face value at the maturity date but do not receive a
regular coupon payment. In other words, the bond has a coupon rate of zero. The
bonds are like T
The
w face value, and the
investor’s return comes from the difference between the purchase price and the payment of face v
.
Floating-Rate Bonds
e
et rates.
Treasury rate plus 2%. So if the T
coupon rate ov
coupon rate always approximates current market interest rates.
ver time. For
s
s
Conver tible Bonds If you buy a convertible bond, you can choose later to
exchange it for a specified number of shares of common stock. For example, a convertible bond that is issued at face value of $1,000 may be conv
s stock. Because conv
y
price appreciation of the company’s stock, investors will accept lower interest rates on
convertible bonds.
Bond issuers are alw
vise new types of bonds that they hope will
vestors. Just to giv
vor of the inventiveness of f
xample of one innovative bond.
Managers of life insurance companies agonize about the possibility of a pandemic
insurance company
€350 million of
Axa’s bonds offered a tempting yield, but the bondholders will lose their entire investment if death rates for 2 consecutive years are 10%
or more above expectations.
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SUMMARY
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
www.investopedia.com
www.wsj.com
finance.yahoo.
com
www.federalreserve.gov
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHAPTER
7
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T T W O
Value
Share prices on the New York Stock Exchange.
A
186
Part Two Value
7.1 Stocks and the Stock Market
common stock
Ownership shares in a
publicly held corporation.
initial public offering (IPO)
ering of stock
to the general public.
primary offering
The corporation sells
shares in the firm.
primary market
Market for the sale of
new securities by
corporations.
secondary market
Market in which
previously issued
securities are traded
among investors.
In Chapter 1 we saw how FedEx was founded and how it grew and prospered. To fund
this growth, FedEx needed capital. Initially, that capital came lar
wing,
but in 1978 FedEx sold shares of common stock
Those
inv
initial public
or IPO,
owners of the b
y shared in the company’s future successes and setbacks.1
A company’s initial public of
raised more capital by selling additional shares.
y
primary offerings
primary market.
Owning shares is a risky occupation. For e
the misfortune to b
vie company
RHI Entertainment, you would have lost 95% of your money by the year-end. You
can understand, therefore, why investors would be reluctant to b
y
y forever
ge companies
xchange so that investors can trade shares among themselves. Exchanges are really markets for secondhand stocks, but they prefer to describe themselves as secondary markets, which
sounds more important.
The two principal stock markets in the United States are the New York Stock
y computer networks
ASDAQ.2
called electr
that connect traders with each
other. All of these markets compete vigorously for the business of traders and just as
vigorously tout the advantages of their own trading venue. The volume of trades in
these mark
or example, ev
et value exceeding $70 billion.
xchanges in man
y, such
as the Dar es Salaam exchange in Tanzania, which trades shares in just 10 companies.
Others, such as the London, T
xt exchanges,
, no longer wishes to hold
y. She can sell them via a stock exchange to Mr. Brown, who
wishes to increase his stake in the f
wnership of the f
vestor to another. No ne
usually will neither care nor even be aw
en place.3
Ms. Jones and Mr. Brown do not b
es. Instead,
each must hire a brokerage f
vile
transaction for them. Not so long ago, such trades would have involved hands-on
negotiation. The broker would hav
in the stock or would hav
xchange where a specialist in FedEx would have coordinated the transaction. But today the vast majority
of trades are executed automatically and electronically, even on the more traditional
exchanges.
When Ms. Jones and Mr. Brown decide to buy or sell FedEx stock, they need to give
their brok
y are prepared to transact.
, might give her broker a market order to sell
1
We use the terms “shares,” “stock,
”
2
as an acron
now is simply known as the NASDAQ market.
3
Ev
, FedEx must know to whom it should send dividend checks, b
example, if a large investor is b
, as we do “shareholders” and
Automated Quotation system, but
Chapter 7
187
Valuing Stocks
FIGURE 7.1 A portion of the
limit order book for Federal
Express from the NYSE/
Archipelago exchange
stock at the best av
. Brown might give his broker a
price limit at which he is willing to b
xecuted
, it is recorded in the exchange’s limit order book until it can be executed.
Figure 7.1 shows a portion of the limit order book for FedEx from the Archipelet run by the NYSE. The bid prices on the left are
the prices (and numbers of shares) at which investors are willing to buy. The Ask
column presents offers to sell. The prices are arranged from best to worst, so the
highest bids and lowest asks are at the top of the list. The broker might electronically
enter Ms. Jones’
et order to sell 100 shares on the Archipelago Exchange,
where it would be automatically matched or crossed with the best offer to buy, which
at that moment was $83.23 a share. Similarly, a market order to buy would be crossed
with the best ask price, $83.27. The bid-ask spread at that moment was therefore
4 cents per share.
Reading Stock Market Listings
Until recently, you probably would have look
The Wall Street
Journal
wspaper. But those pages contain less
and less information about individual stocks, and most inv
or example, if you go to finance.yahoo.com, enter
FedEx’s ticker symbol, FDX, and ask to “Get Quotes,” you will find recent trading
data such as that presented in Figure 7.2.4
August 3 was $83.75 per share,
which was $.85 lower than its closing price the previous day, $84.60. The range of
, as well as over the previous 52 weeks, is proY
v
volume over the last 3 months was 3,821,760 shares. Trading as of 9:47 a.m. on this
4
v
Wall Street Journal at www.wsj.com
or the online edition of
et Data tabs).
188
Two
Value
FIGURE 7.2 Trading
information for FedEx
0.85 (1.00%)
Source: Yahoo! Finance Web site, finance.yahoo.com
P/E ratio
Ratio of stock price to
earnings per share.
s market cap
et capitalization)
is the total value of its outstanding shares of stock, $26.34 billion. You will frequently
venient way to
y.
. (The abbre
theses stands for trailing 12 months.)
wn as the price-earnings multiple or, equivalently,
ratio, is
83.75/3.76 5 22.24.
e
et analysts, and we will
have much to say about it later in the chapter.
The dividend yield tells you how much dividend income you would receive for
every $100 invested in the stock. FedEx paid annual dividends of $.48 per share, so its
yield was .48/83.75 5 .6%. For ev
vested in the stock, you would have
received $.60 in dividends. Of course, this would not be the total rate of return on your
investment, as you would also hope for some increase in the stock price. The dividend
yield is thus much lik
ve
capital gains or losses.
The price at which you can b
alues will wax or wane with investors’ perceptions of the prospects for the company.
Figure 7.3 sho
ver a 6-month period in 2010. The price
FIGURE 7.3
hist
Share price
or FedEx
Source: Yahoo! Finance Web site, finance.yahoo.com
Chapter 7
189
Valuing Stocks
fell by over 25% in just 10 weeks, from $95 at the end of
.
Why w
v
denly? And for that matter
y willing on August 2 to pay $84.60 a share
for FedEx but only $26.25 a share for Microsoft? To answer these questions, we need
alue.
7.2 Market Values, Book Values,
and Liquidation Values
book value
Net worth of the firm
according to the
balance sheet.
Finding the value of FedEx stock may sound lik
, the
compan
alue of the f
ities. The simplified balance sheet in Table 7.1 shows that in May 2010 the book value
of all FedEx’
, inv
and so on—was $24,902 million. FedEx’s debt and other liabilities—money that it
owes the banks, taxes that are due to be paid, and the lik
lion.
alue of the assets and the liabilities was $13,811
million. This was the book value
s equity.5 Book value records all the
mone
ve been
plowed back on their behalf.
Book v
. But does the stock price equal book
v
ut as Table 7.2 shows,
its book v
as only $43.98. So the shares were worth about 1.9 times
book value. This and the other cases shown in Table 7.2 tell us that investors in the
stock market do not just buy and sell at book value per share.
TABLE 7.1
Note: Shares of stock outstanding: 314 million. Book value of equity (per share): 13,811/314 5 $43.98
TABLE 7.2
Market values
versus book values, August
2010
Source: Yahoo! Finance Web site, finance.yahoo.com.
5
ord for stock.
vestors.
190
Part Two Value
Investors know that accountants don’t even try to estimate market values. The value
liquidation value
Net proceeds that could
be realized by selling
the firm’s assets and
pa
editors.
cal”) cost less an allowance for depreciation. But that may not be a good guide to what
the f
.
W
liquidation value
cash per share a compan
ets
and paid off all its debts. Wrong again. A successful company ought to be w
than liquidation value.
The difference between a company’s actual value and its book or liquidation value
is often attributed to
, which refers to three factors:
1. Extr
. A company may hav
alue of those assets will be higher than
alue.
y assets that accountants don’t put on the balance
xtremely valuable. Take Johnson & Johnson, a health
y.
Table 7.2, it sells at 3
times book v
Where did all that extra v
gely from
v
eted. These
v
wn to
v
don’t put it on the company’s balance sheet. Nev
their book v
2. Intangible assets.
3. V
e investments. If investors believ
y will hav
to make v
vestments in the future, they will pay more for the
company’s stock today. When eBay
irst sold its stock
to investors in 1998, the book value of shareholders’ equity w
Yet 1 day after the issue investors valued the equity at over $6 billion. In part, this
dif
ver the Internet. But investors also judged that eBay was a growth
company. In other words, they were betting that the company’s know-how and
brand name would allow it to e
e it easier for
billion and had a market capitalization of $36 billion.
Market price is not the same as book value or liquidation value. Market value,
unlike book value and liquidation value, treats the firm as a going concern.
ver sell at book or liquidation values.
Investors buy shares on the basis of present and future
wer. Two key features
determine the prof
generated by the f
vest in lucrativ
▲
EXAMPLE 7.1
Amazon.com and Consolidated Edison
Amazon.com, is a growth company. In 2010, its profit was $1,152 million. Yet investors in December 2010 were prepared to pay about 70 times that amount, or $81
billion, for Amazon’s common stock. The value of the stock came from the company’s market position, its highly regarded distribution system, and the promise of new
related products that will generate increased future earnings. Amazon was a
growth firm, because its market value depended so heavily on intangible assets
and the anticipated profit
w investments.
Contrast this with Consolidated Edison (Con Ed),
New Y
ea. Con Ed is not a growth company. Its market is limited, and it is
e
ery deliberate pace. More important, it is a regulated
Chapter 7
191
Valuing Stocks
, so its returns on present and future investments are constrained. Con Ed’s
value derives mostly from the stream of income generated by its existing assets.
Therefore, while Amazon shares in 2010 sold for 10.1 times book value, Con Ed
shares sold at only about 1.3 times book value.
Investors refer to Amazon as a growth stock and Con Ed as an income stock. A few
stocks, like Microsoft, offer both income and gro
es the stock attractive to investors. In addition, inv
y’s ability to inv
ably in new ventures that will increase future earnings.
Let’
• Book value records what a company has paid for its assets, less a deduction for
alue of a business.
• Liquidation value is what the company could net by selling its assets and repaying
alue of a successful going concern.
• Market value is the amount that investors are willing to pay for the shares of the
wer of today’s assets and the expected
future investments.
The next question is,
et value?
Self-Test 7.1
7.3 Valuing Common Stocks
Valuation by Comparables
alue a business, the
They then e
w much investors in these companies
This is often called valuation
by comparables. Look, for example, at Table 7.3.
ws,
for some well-kno
et value of the equity to the
book v
et v
alue.
ws the market-to-book ratio for competing
or example, you can see from the second row of the table that the stock of the
typical lar
alue. If you did not
have a mark
it would also sell at three times book value. In this case your estimate of J&J’s market
price would have been almost spot on.
ve would be to look at how much inv
The second row of Table 7.3
sho
would have gotten a value for the stock of $51, somewhat lo
$58.29 in August 2010.
192
Part Two Value
TABLE 7.3
Market-to-bookvalue ratios and priceearnings ratios for selected
companies and their
principal competitors,
August 2010.
*Figures are median ratios for competing companies.
v
example, infant f
or
ve an
1990s, when dot-com companies were growing rapidly and losing lots of money, multiples were often based on the number of subscribers or Web-site visits.
Valuation
by comparables work
wer). However, that is not the case for all the companies shown
in Table 7.3. For example, if you had naïvely assumed that Amazon stock would sell
ould have been out by a wide
mar
ably from stock to stock even for f
usiness. To unders
market value.
Price and Intrinsic Value
In the previous chapter, we saw that the value of a bond is the present value of its coualue of its final payment of face value. Y
ay. Instead of receiving coupon payments, investors may
receive dividends; and instead of receiving face value, they will receiv
at the time the
Consider, for example, an investor who buys a share of Blue Skies Inc. today and
plans to sell it in 1 year
P1, the expected divis expected cash
ver the year DIV1
ws r. Remember
have higher discount rates. Then the present v
ws the investor will
receiv
V0 5
intrinsic value
Present value of future
cash pay
om a
st
.
DIV1 1 P1
11r
(7.1)
We call V0 the intrinsic value
alue is just the present value of
the cash payoffs anticipated by the investor in the stock.
To illustrate, suppose investors expect a cash dividend of $3 over the next year
P1 5 $81). If the dis(DIV1 5 $3) and e
alue is $75:
V0 5
3 1 81
5 $75
1.12
Chapter 7
193
Valuing Stocks
Y
vestors buy the
stock for $75, their expected rate of return will precisely equal the discount rate—in
other words, their investment will just compensate them for the opportunity cost of
their money.
To confirm this, note that the expected rate of return over the next year is the
expected dividend plus the expected increase in price, P1 2 P0, all divided by price
at the start of the year, P0. If the investor buys the shares for intrinsic value, then
P0 5 $75 and
Expected return 5
DIV1 1 P1 2 P0
3 1 81 2 75
5
5 .12, or 12%
P0
75
ain:
5 expected dividend yield 1 expected capital gain
DIV1
P0
3
5
75
5
5 .04
1
1
1
P1 2 P0
P0
81 2 75
75
.08 5 .12, or 12%
investors expect. For example, in 2009, as the economy seemed to be emerging from a
exceeding 100%. This was almost certainly better than investors expected at the start
. At the other e
ve energy
verage by more than 10%. No inv
ould
hav
ver confuse the actual outcome with the expected outcome.
The dream of every investor is to buy shares at a bargain price, that is, a price
less than intrinsic value. But in competitive markets, no price other than intrinsic
value could survive for long. To see why, imagine that Blue Skies’ current price
were above $75. Then the expected rate of return on Blue Skies stock would be
lower than that on other securities of equivalent risk. (Check this!) Investors
would bail out of Blue Skies stock and move into other securities. In the process
they would force down the price of Blue Skies stock. If P 0 were less than $75,
Blue Skies stock would offer a higher expected rate of return than equivalentrisk securities. (Check this, too. ) Everyone would rush to buy, forcing the price
up to $75. When the stock is priced correctly (that is, price equals present value),
the expected rate of return on Blue Skies stock is also the rate of return that
investors require to hold the stock. At each point in time all securities of the
same risk are priced to offer the same expected rate of return. This is a fundamental characteristic of prices in well-functioning markets. It is also common sense.
Equation 7.1 is just a
Now we can go be
all securities at a given lev
e
alue:
orks for any discount rate r.
r as the e
P0 5
DIV1 1 P1
11r
Thus today’s price will equal the present value of di
w we need to tak
v
P1?
w do we estimate the
194
Part Two Value
Self-Test 7.2
vidends. Investors in a young,
gro
y may have to w
P0 still applies to such f
vidend DIV1 equal to zero. In this case value depends on the
subsequent dividends. But let’s be
vidends now.
We will say more about gro
.
The Dividend Discount Model
dividend discount model
Discounted cash-flow
model which states that
today’s stock price
equals the present
value of all expected
future dividends.
s dividend and
1 1 P1, that is, ne
next period’s price. Suppose you have forecast the dividend. How do you forecast the
price P1? We can answer this question by moving our stock-price equation forw
The equation then says that P1 depends on the
P2. The second-period
s dividend DIV2
price P2 in turn depends on the third period’s dividend DIV3
P3, which depends on DIV4 . . . you can see where this logic is going.
xpress a stock’
present value of all
This is the dividend discount model:
P0 5 present value of (DIV1, DIV2, DIV3, c, DIVt, c)
DIV3
DIVt
DIV1
DIV2
5
1
1
1 c1
1c
( 1 1 r) 2
( 1 1 r) 3
( 1 1 r) t
11r
How f
wever, f -distant dividends will not
hav
alues. For example, the present value of $1 received in 30
years using a 10% discount rate is only $.057. Most of the value of established companies comes from dividends to be paid within a person’s w
How do we get from the one-period formula P0 5 (DIV1 1 P1)/(1 1 r) to the dividend discount model? We look at increasingly long investment horizons.
Let’s consider inv
v
vestor will v
xpects to receive
plus the present v
ventually sold. Unlike bonds,
however
” Moreover, both di
vestor, the v
e this:
P0 5
DIV1 1 P1
11r
A 2-year investor would value the stock as
P0 5
DIV1
DIV2 1 P2
1
( 1 1 r) 2
11r
vestor would use the formula
P0 5
DIV3 1 P3
DIV1
DIV2
1
1
2
( 1 1 r)
( 1 1 r) 3
11r
Chapter 7
195
Valuing Stocks
In fact we can look as far out into the future as we lik
date H. Then the stock v
ould be
P0 5
DIV1
DIV2
DIVH 1 PH
1
1 c1
( 1 1 r) 2
( 1 1 r) H
11r
(7.2)
In words, the value of a stock is the present value of the dividends it will pay over
the investor’s horizon plus the present value of the expected stock price at the
end of that horizon.
Does this mean that inv
sions about the v
v
value will be the same. This is because the stock price at the horizon date is determined by expectations of dividends from that date forw
Therefore, as long as
inv
s prospects, they will also agree on its present value. Let’s
xample.
▲
EXAMPLE 7.2
Valuing Blue Skies Stock
Take Blue Skies. The firm is growing steadily, and investors expect both the stock
price and the dividend to increase at 8% per year. Now consider three investors,
Erste, Zweiter, and Dritter. Erste plans to hold Blue Skies for 1 year, Zweiter for 2, and
er for 3. Compare their pay
Year 1
Erste
Zweiter
DIV1 5 3
P1 5 81
DIV1 5 3
Dr er
DIV1 5 3
Year 2
DIV2 5 3.24
P2 5 87.48
DIV2 5 3.24
Year 3
DIV3 5 3.50
P3 5 94.48
Remember, we assumed that dividends and stock prices for Blue Skies are expected
to grow at a steady 8%. Thus DIV2 5 $3 3 1.08 5 $3.24, DIV3 5 $3.24 3 1.08 5 $3.50,
and so on.
Each investor requires the same 12% expected return. So we can calculate present value over Erste’s 1-year horizon:
PV 5
DIV1 1 P1
$3 1 $81
5
5 $75
11r
1.12
or Zweiter’s 2-year horizon:
PV 5
5
DIV1
DIV2 1 P2
1
11r
(1 1 r)2
$3
$3.24 1 $87.48
1
1.12
(1.12)2
5 $2.68 1 $72.32 5 $75
er’s 3-year horizon:
PV 5
5
DIV3 1 P3
DIV1
DIV2
1
1
11r
(1 1 r)2
(1 1 r)3
$3
$3.24
$3.50 1 $94.48
1
1
1.12
(1.12)2
(1.12)3
5 $2.68 1 $2.58 1 $69.74 5 $75
196
Two
Value
All agree the stock is worth $75 per share. This illustrates our basic principle: The
value of a common stock equals the present value of dividends received out to the
investment horizon plus the present value of the forecast stock price at the horizon.
Moreover, when you move the horizon date, the stock’s present value should not
change. The principle holds for horizons of 1, 3, 10, 20, and 50 years or more.
Self-Test 7.3
Look at Table 7.4, which continues the Blue Skies example for v
zons, still assuming that the di
xpected to increase at a steady 8% compound rate. The expected price increases at the same 8% rate. Each row in the table
represents a present v
. Note that total present value does not depend on the inv
7.4 presents the same data
ws the present value of the di
and the present v
As the horizon recedes, the dividend
alue but the total present
value of di
ways equals $75.
TABLE 7.4
Value of Blue
Skies
FIGURE 7.4
Skies f
Value of Blue
erent horizons
Chapter 7
197
Valuing Stocks
ar away, then we can for
price—it has almost no present value—and simply say,
Stock price 5 PV(all future dividends per share)
This is the dividend discount model.
7.4 Simplifying the Dividend Discount Model
The Dividend Discount Model with No Growth
ya
company could not grow because it could not reinvest.6
vidend, but the
ard to higher future dividends.
y’s stock would offer a perpetual stream of equal cash payments,
DIV1 5 DIV2 5 c5 DIVt 5 c .
The dividend discount model says that these no-growth shares should sell for the
present v
vidends. W
w to do that
ment by the discount rate.
vestors
P0 5
DIV1
r
Since our compan
vidends, di
are the same, and we could just as well calculate stock value by
Value of a no-growth stock 5 P0 5
where EPS1 represents next year’
loosely say
EPS1
r
Thus some people
” and calculate value
Self-Test 7.4
The Constant-Growth Dividend Discount Model
The dividend discount model requires a forecast of dividends for every year into
the future, which poses a bit of a problem for stocks with potentially infinite lives.
Unless we want to spend a lifetime forecasting dividends, we must use simplifying assumptions to reduce the number of estimates. As we have just seen, the
simplest simplification assumes a no-growth perpetuity, which works only for nogrowth shares.
Here’
casted dividends gro
vidends grow at
vidends, we need to
forecast only the next dividend and the dividend growth rate.
6
W
y by issuing ne
198
Part Two Value
Recall Blue Skies Inc. It will pay a $3 dividend in 1 year. If the dividend grows at a
constant rate of g 5 .08 (8%) thereafter, then di
5 $3.00
DIV1 5 $3
DIV2 5 $3 3 (1 1 g) 5 $3 3 1.08 5 $3.24
DIV3 5 $3 3 (1 1 g)2 5 $3 3 1.082 5 $3.50
Plug these forecasts of future dividends into the dividend discount model:
DIV1(1 1 g)
DIV1(1 1 g)2
DIV1(1 1 g)3 c
DIV1
1
1
1
1
P0 5
2
3
( 1 1 r)
( 1 1 r)
( 1 1 r) 4
11r
$3
$3.24
$3.50
$3.78
5
1
1
1
1c
2
3
(
)
(
)
(
1.12
1.12
1.12
1.12)4
5 $2.68 1
$2.58
1
$2.49
1
$2.40
1c
constant-growth dividend
discount model
Version of the dividend
discount model in which
dividends grow at a
constant rate.
▲
EXAMPLE 7.3
than the preceding one as long as the dividend growth rate g is less than the discount
rate r. Because the present value of far-distant dividends will be ever closer to zero, the
sum of all of these terms is finite despite the fact that an infinite number of dividends
will be paid. The sum can be shown to equal
P0 5
DIV1
r2g
(7.3)
This equation is called the constant-growth dividend discount model, or the
7
Gordon growth model
Using the Constant-Growth Model to Value Aqua America
Aqua America (ticker symbol WTR) is a wat
ving parts of 14 states from
Maine to Texas. In August 2010 its stock was selling for $19 a share. Since there were
137 million shares outstanding, investors were placing a total value on the stock of
137 million 3 $19 5 $2.6 billion. Can we explain this valuation?
In 2010 Aqua America could point to a remarkably consistent growth record. For
each of the past 15 years it had steadily increased its dividend payment (see
Figure 7.5), and, with one minor hiccup, earnings had also grown steadily. The constant-growth model therefore seems tailor-made for valuing Aqua America’s stock.
In 2010 investors were forecasting that in the following year Aqua America would
pay a dividend of $.63 (DIV1 5 $.63). The forecast gro
as about
3.5% a year over the foreseeable future (we explain later where this figure comes
from). If investors required a return of 6.8% from Aqua America’s stock, then the
constant-growth model gives a share value in 2010 (P0) of just over $19:
P0 5
DIV1
$.63
5
5 $19.09
r2g
.068 2 .035
The constant-gro
alue of a
. Suppose you forecast no growth in dividends (g 5 0). Then the dividend
stream is a simple perpetuity
aluation formula is P0 5 DIV1/r. This is
precisely the formula you used in Self-Test 7.4 to value Moonshine, a no-growth common stock.
7
vidend is assumed to come at the end of the first period and is discounted for a full
vidend DIV0, then next year’s dividend will be (1 1 g) times the dividend
P0 5
DIV0 3 (1 1 g)
DIV1
5
r2g
r2g
Chapter 7
199
Valuing Stocks
FIGURE 7.5 Aqua
America's dividends have
grown steadily
growth in dividends. Notice that as g
wever, the
constant-gro
alid only when g is less than r. If someone forecasts perpetual dividend gro
v
r, then two
things happen:
1. The formula explodes. It gives crazy answers. (Try a numerical example.)
2. Y
w the forecast is wrong, because f
vidends would have incredibly
high present v
xample. Calculate the present value of
a di
1 5 $.63, r 5 .068, but g 5 .20.)
Estimating Expected Rates of Return
We argued earlier, in Section 7.3, that in competitiv
ets, common stocks with the
out what that expected rate of return is?
It’s not easy. Consensus estimates of future dividends, stock prices, or overall rates
The Wall Street J
or reported by TV newscasters.
Economists argue about which statistical models give the best estimates. There are
nev
ve sensible numbers.
vidend discount model, which
forecasts a constant growth rate g in both future di
That
means expected capital gains equal g
.
W
wth
DIV1
1g
P0
5 dividend yield 1 growth rate
(7.4)
r5
For Aqua
growth rate is 3.5%. W
vidend is $.63 and the
DIV1
1g
P0
$.63
5
1 .035 5 .033 1 .035 5 .068, or 6.8%
$19.09
r5
200
Two
Value
Suppose we found another stock with the same risk as Aqua America. It ought
to offer the same expected total rate of return even if its immediate dividend or
expected growth rate is very different. The required rate of return is not the unique
property of Aqua America or any other company; it is set in the worldwide market
for common stocks. Aqua America cannot change its value of r by paying higher
or lower dividends or by growing faster or slower, unless these changes also affect
the risk of the stock. When we use the rule-of-thumb formula, r 5 DIV1/P0 1 g,
we are not saying that r, the expected rate of return, is determined by DIV1 or g.
It is determined by the rate of return offered by other equally risky stocks. That
return determines how much investors are willing to pay for Aqua America’s forecast future dividends:
DIV1
1g
P0
5r5
expected rate of return offered
Given DIV1
g, investors set
▲
EXAMPLE 7.4
so that Aqua
adequate expected rate of
r
Aqua America Gets a Windfall
Suppose that a shift in water usage allows Aqua America to generate 5% per year
future growth without sacrificing immediate dividends. Will that increase r, the
expected rate of return?
This is good news for the firm’s stockholders. The stock price will jump to
P0 5
But at the new price the st
DIV1
$.63
5
5 $35
r2g
.068 2 .05
er the same 6.8% expected return:
r5
5
DIV1
1g
P0
$.63
1 .05 5 .068, or 6.8%
$35
Aqua America’s good news is reflected in a higher stock price today, not in a higher
expected rate of return in the future. The unchanged expected rate of return corresponds to the firm’s unchanged risk.
Self-Test 7.5
Nonconstant Growth
Water companies and other utilities tend to have steady rates of gro
fore natural candidates for application of the constant-growth model. But many companies gro
v
wn.
Obviously in such cases we can’
wth model to estimate value.
However
v
investment horizon
future year by which you expect the company’s growth to settle down. Calculate the
present value of dividends from no
.F
Chapter 7
201
Valuing Stocks
alue. Then add up to get the total present
value of di
P0 5
DIV1
DIV2
DIVH
PH
1
1 c1
1
2
H
( 1 1 r)
( 1 1 r)
( 1 1 r) H
11r
PV of dividends from
at horizon
terminal value.
▲
EXAMPLE 7.5
Estimating the Value of McDonald’s Stock
In mid-2010 the price of McDonald’s stock was nearly $70. The company earned
about $4.50 a share and paid out about 40% of earnings as dividends. Let’s see how
we might use the dividend discount model to estimate McDonald’s intrinsic value.
Investors in 2010 were optimistic about the prospects for McDonald’s and were
forecasting that earnings would grow over the ne
ears by 10% a year.8 This
growth rate is almost certainly higher than the return, r, that investors required from
McDonald’s stock, and it is implausible to suppose that such rapid gro
continue indefinitely. Therefore, we cannot use the simple constant-gro
ormula
to value the shares. Instead, we will break the problem down into three steps:
Step 1: Value McDonald’s dividends over the period of rapid gro
Step 2: Estimate McDonald’s stock price at the horizon year, when gro
should hav
wn.
Step 3: Calculate the present value of McDonald’s stock by summing the present value of dividends up to the horizon year and the present value of
the stock price at the horizon.
Step 1: Our first task is to value McDonald’s dividends over the ne
ears. If dividends keep pace with the growth in earnings, then forecast earnings and dividends are as follows:
Year
1
Earnings
Dividends (40%
of earnings)
2
3
4
5
4.50 4.95 5.45 5.99 6.59
1.80 1.98 2.18 2.40 2.64
In 2010 investors required a return of about 9% from McDonald’s stock.9 Therefore, the present value of the forecast dividends for years 1 to 5 was:
PV of dividends years 1–5 5
$1.80
$1.98
$2.18
$2.40
2.64
1
1
1
1
1.09
(1.09)4
(1.09)5
(1.09)2
(1.09)3
5 $8.41
Step 2: The trickier task is to estimate the price of McDonald’s stock in the horizon
year 5. The most lik
er year 5 gro
wn
to a sustainable rate, but to keep life simple, we will assume that in year 6 the gro
rate falls immediately to 6% a year.10 Thus the forecast dividend in year 6 is
DIV6 5 1.06 3 DIV5 5 1.06 3 2.64 5 $2.80
8
9
The
For now
and
e this v
vailable on the Web at
.
w you how to estimate
s
10
We will sho
return on these new inv
investment.
R
v
y plo
vidends will grow by g 5 plowback ratio 3
ard McDonald’s continues to reinv
vidends will grow by .6 3 .10 5 .06, or 6%.
w
202
Two
Value
and the expected price at the end of year 5 is
P5 5
DIV6
$2.80
5
5 $93.33
r2g
.09 2 .06
Step 3: Remember, the value of McDonald’s today is equal to the present value
of forecast dividends up to the horizon date plus the present value of the price at
the horizon. Thus,
P0 5 PV(dividends years 1–5) 1 PV(price in year 5)
5 $8.41 1
$93.33
5 $69.07
1.09 5
A Reality Check Our estimate of McDonald’s value looks reasonable and
almost matches McDonald’s actual mark
e you nervous to note
that your estimate of the terminal price accounts for such a large proportion of the
stock’s value? It should. Only v
wth
be
In the case of McDonald’s we know what the mark
of 2010, but suppose that you are using the dividend discount model to value a compan
uy Blue
Skies’ concatenator division. In such cases you do not have the luxury of looking up
the market price in The Wall Street J
Av
serious money. Wise managers, therefore, check that their estimate of value is in the
usinesses.
For e
growth prospects today roughly match those projected for McDonald’s at the investment horizon. You look back at Table 7.3 and discover that their stocks typically sell at
Then you can reasonably guess that McDonald’s value in
, that is,
18.8 3 $6.59 5 $123.89, some
alue that we
vidend discount model.
application of the valuation by comparables method introduced earlier in the chapter.
Self-Test 7.6
7.5 Growth Stocks and Income Stocks
W
vestors speak of growth stocks and income stocks. They buy growth
xpectation of capital gains, and they are interested in the future
gro
s di
y buy
income stocks principally for the cash di
make sense.
Think back once more to Aqua America. It is expected to pay a dividend in 2011 of
vidend is expected to grow at a steady rate of 3.5% a
$.63 (DIV1 5
year (g 5 .035). If inv
(r 5
Aqua
America should be
P0 5 DIV1 / (r 2 g) 5 .63/ (.068 2 .035) 5 $19.09
Chapter 7
203
Valuing Stocks
vidend growth? Let’s check. Aqua
OE)
Then
, matching its av
earnings per share in 2011 will be
5
3 return on equity
5 $8.35 3 .11 5 $.919
payout ratio
Fraction of earnings
paid out as dividends.
plowback ratio
Fraction of earnings
retained by the firm.
The forecast dividend in 2011 is DIV1 5
wed back in ne
company’s payout ratio
.63/.919 5 .686, and its plowback ratio
5 .314.
After reinv
additional equity per share equal to its plo
2011. W
equity. Therefore:
ves $.919 2 $.63 5 $.289
vestments. The
vidends) is, therefore,
vested in the
y will start year 2012 with
5 plowback ratio 3
5 plowback ratio 3
3 return on equity]
5 .314 3 [$8.35 3 .11] 5 $.288
T
wth rate in book equity we simply divide this increase in equity by the
Growth rate 5
5 plowback ratio 3
3
5 plowback ratio 3
5 .314 3 .11 5 .035, or 3.5%
If Aqua
sustainable growth rate
The firm’s growth rate if it
plows back a constant
fraction of earnings,
maintains a constant
r
, and
keeps its debt ratio
constant.
ws back
vidends will
also continue to grow by 3.5%.
y’s sustainable growth rate,
because it is the rate of growth that the company can sustain from reinv
verage. (The sustainable growth rate is an old friend
from Chapter 4.)
If a company earns a constant return on its equity and plows back a constant
proportion of earnings, then the gro
ate g is
g 5 sustainable gro
ate 5 retur
What if Aqua America did not plow back any
equipment? In that case it w
forgo any further gro
vidends:
3 plowback ratio
(7.5)
w plant and
ut would
g 5 sustainable growth rate 5 return on equity 3 plowback ratio 5 .11 3 0 5 0
We could recalculate the value of Aqua
y growth:
DIV1
EPS1
$.919
5 $13.51
5
5
r2g
r
.068
Thus, if Aqua America did not reinvest an
ould be
not $19.09 but $13.51. The $13.51 represents the v
already in place.
2 $13.51 5 $5.58) is the net present value of the future investments that Aqua
xpected to make.
P0 5
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Valuing Growth Opportunities
What if the company kept to its policy of reinvesting 31.4% of its profits but the
w investments was only 6.8%? In that case the sustainable growth
rate would also be lower:
g5
5 return on equity 3 plowback ratio
5 .068 3 .314 5 .0214, or 2.14%
w figure into our v
of $13.51 for Aqua America stock, no different from the value it would have if it chose
not to grow at all:
P0 5
DIV1
$.63
5 $13.51
5
r2g
.068 2 .0214
Plowing earnings back into new inv
esult in gro
nings and
dividends, but it does not add to the current stock price if that money is expected to
earn only the return that investors r
. Plowing earnings back does add value if
investors believe that the reinvested earnings will earn a higher rate of return.
present value of growth
opportunities (PVGO)
Net present value of a
firm’s future investments.
204
To repeat, if Aqua America did not reinv
alue of its stock
w
ve from the stream of earnings from the existing assets. The price of
its stock would be $13.51. If the company did reinv
vestors require, then those new investments w
y value. The
price of the stock would still be $13.51. F
, investors believe that Aqua Amerw investments, somewhat above the 6.8%
vestors require.
v
to pay for the stock. The total value of Aqua America stock is equal to the value of its
assets in place plus the present value of its growth opportunities, or PVGO:
Value of assets in place
1 Present value of growth opportunities (PVGO)
5 Total value of Aqua America’s stock
$13.51
5.58
$19.09
Chapter 7
205
Valuing Stocks
The superior prospects of Aqua
W
5 20.8. If the company had no gro
ould be $13.51/$.919 5 14.7.
cator of Aqua’
Does this mean that the f
The answer is usually yes.
wever
ould be only
s stock sells
v
v
Af
nothing
ve an
Of course, valuing stocks is always harder in practice than in principle. Forecasting
The
e Google or
value comes largely from growth opportunities rather than assets that are already in
place. As the nearby box shows, in these cases there is plenty of room for disagreement about value.
Self-Test 7.7
Valuing Growth Stocks
We used the dividend discount model to value Aqua
value of its gro
Aqua
as an easy
tar
as stable and its growth moderate. What about young,
y, and rapidly growing companies? These companies usually pay no cash dividividend discount model still works logically—we could project dividends as zero out
to some distant date when the firm matures and payout commences. But forecasting
f
vidends is more easily said than done. In these cases, it’s more helpful to
think about the value of a stock as the sum of the value of assets in place plus PVGO,
the present value of gro
The v
s av
does not grow, that is, EPS/r. So we can express the value of a growth stock as
P0 5 EPS/r 1 PVGO
Market-value balance
sheet
Balance sheet showing
market rather than book
values of assets, liabilities,
and stockholders’
.
If you can observe P0 and calculate EPS/r, you can subtract and see how much value
investors are assigning to growth.
Market-Value Balance Sheets
Financial managers are not bound by generally accepted accounting principles.
Sometimes they construct a market-value balance sheet to help identify sources of
value. Table 7.5 sho
206
Part Two Value
TABLE 7.5
A Market-Value
Balance Sheet (All entries at
current market, not book
values.)
market-v
assets. The market and book v
recall that book v
amiliar, for e
. In contrast,
alue, that
do not appear at all on the company’s books.
The present value of gro
GO) never appears on a book balance sheet but belongs on a market-value balance sheet. For successful growth companies like Google, PVGO is f
aluable than assets in place. For mature companies
like Con Ed, PVGO is relativ
et value depends on assets in place.
That is why Con Ed is an income stock.
The dif
et and book values on the asset side of the balance
sheet sho
et-to-book
ratio.
aluable future inv
7.6 There Are No Free Lunches on Wall Street
We have explained ho
ve just
given the game away and told you how to mak
et?
W
et, and even highly
ind it very dif
y consistency.
icult to beat the market consistently? Let’s look at two possible
ways that you might attempt to do so.
Method 1: Technical Analysis
technical analysts
Invest
empt to
identify undervalued
stocks by searching for
erns in past stock
prices.
Some inv
v
xploiting patterns in
stock prices. These inv
wn as technical analysts.
Technical analysis sounds plausible. For example, you might hope to beat the market by buying stocks when the
ay
down. Unfortunately
t work.
ge price rise
in one period may be followed by a further rise in the ne
ut it is just as likely
to be followed by a fall.
Look, for example, at Figure 7.6a. The horizontal axis sho
New York Composite Index in one week (5 business days), while the vertical axis
shows the return in the follo
ferent
week ov
et rise one week tended to be followed
xt week, the points in the chart would plot along an upward-sloping
line. But you can see that there was no such tendency; the points are scattered
Chapter 7
Valuing Stocks
207
these changes by the coefficient of correlation. In our example, the correlation
et movements in successive weeks is 2.022—in other words, effectively zero. Figure 7.6b sho
usiness-day) moves.
FIGURE 7.6a Each dot
shows the returns on the New
York Composite Index on two
successive weeks between
September 1970 and
September 2010. The circled
dot shows a weekly return of
13.1%, followed by 15.2% in
the next w
er
diagram shows no significant
r
een returns
on successive weeks.
FIGURE 7.6b This scatter
diagram shows that there is
also no r
een
market returns in successive
months.
208
Part Two Value
Again you can see that this month’s change in the index gives you almost no clue as
to the likely change next month. The correlation between successive monthly changes
is 2.004.
Financial economists and statisticians who hav
vements
have concluded that you won’
This seems to be so re
et as a whole (as we did
in Figure 7.6) or at individual stocks. Prices appear to wander randomly. They are
equally likely t
er a high or low return on any particular day, regardless of
what has occurred on previous days. In other words, prices seem to follow a
random walk
Security prices change
randomly, with no
predictable trends or
erns.
random walk.
alk,” consider the following
example: Y
ven $100 to play a game. At the end of each week a coin is
tossed. If it comes up heads, you win 3% of your investment; if it is tails, you lose
2.5%. Therefore, your payoff at the end of the first week is either $103 or $97.50. At
the end of the second week the coin is tossed again. Now the possible outcomes are
as follows:
Heads $103.00
Heads $106.09
Tails $100.43
$100
T
Heads $100.43
Tails $ 95.06
This process is a random walk because successive changes in the value of your
air coin. That is, the odds of
making money each week are the same, re
or the pattern of heads or tails in the previous weeks.
If a stock’
ws a random w
any day, month, or year do not depend at all on the stock’s previous price moves. The
ves no useful information about the future—just as a long
v
xt toss.
FIGURE 7.7 One of these
charts shows the Standard &
Poor’s Index f
ear
period. The other shows the
results of playing our coin-toss
game for 5 years. Can you tell
which is which? (The answer
is given in footnote 11.)
Chapter 7
209
Valuing Stocks
FIGURE 7.8 Cycles selfdestruct as soon as they are
recognized by investors. The
stock price instantaneously
jumps to the present value of
the expected future price.
ficult to believ
game, then look at the tw
ve like our coin-tossing
ws the outcome
ws the actual performance of the S&P
500 Index for a 5-year period. Can you tell which one is which?11
Does it surprise you that stocks seem to follow a random walk? If so, imagine that
it were not the case and that changes in stock prices were expected to persist for several months. Figure 7.8 provides a hypothetical example of such a predictable cycle.
Y
x was 1,100 and is
e
xt month.
vestors
perceive this bonanza? Since stocks are a bar
vel, investors will
uy and, in so doing, will push up prices. They will stop buying only when
Figure 7.7
Thus, as soon as a cycle becomes apparent to investors,
they immediately eliminate it by their trading.
Don’t confuse randomness in price changes
If a stock is f
ve only if ne
perception of its f
level of prices.
et
Self-Test 7.8
11
Figure 7.7 sho
s Inde
The botas generated by a series of random numbers. You may be among the 50% of our readers who guess
right, but we bet it was just a guess.
210
Part Two Value
FIGURE 7.9
The
ormance of the stocks of
target companies compared
with that of the market. The
prices of target stocks jump up
on the announcement day, but
from then on there are no
unusual price mov
announcement of the takeover
empt seems to be fully
reflected in the stock price on
.
Source: Arthur J. Keown and John M. Pinkerton, “Merger Announcements and Insider Trading Activity,” Journal of
Finance 36 (September 1981); pp. 855–869. Used with permission of Wiley-Blackwell.
Method 2: Fundamental Analysis
fundamental analysts
Invest
empt to
b
al
information, such as
ormance
and earnings prospects.
You may not be able to earn superior returns just by studying past stock prices,
but what about other types of information? After all, most investors don’t just
look at past stock prices. Instead, they try to gauge a firm’s business prospects by
studying the financial and trade press, the company’s financial accounts, the president’s annual statements, and other items of news. These investors are called
fundamental analysts, in contrast to technical analysts who focus on past stock
price movements.
Fundamental analysts are paid to uncover stocks for which price does not equal
intrinsic value. If intrinsic value exceeds price, for example, the stock is a bargain
and will offer a superior expected return. But what happens if there are many
talented and competitive fundamental analysts? If one of them uncovers a stock
that appears to be a bargain, it stands to reason that others will as well, and there
will be a wave of buying that pushes up the price. In the end, their actions will
eliminate the original bargain opportunity. To profit, your insights must be different from those of your competitors, and you must act faster than they can. This is a
tall order.
To illustrate the challenge facing stock market analysts, look at Figure 7.9, which
shows ho
ws—the announcement of a
takeover. In most takeovers the acquiring compan
get company to give up their shares. You can see
from Figure 7.9
get compan
day that the public becomes aw
eover attempt (day 0 in the graph). However
wnw
made public, it is too late to buy.
Researchers have look
y other types of news,
repurchase existing stock.
e superior returns by buying or selling after the announcement.
Chapter 7
211
Valuing Stocks
A Theory to Fit the Facts
efficient market
Market in which prices
reflect all available
information.
Economists often refer to the stock market as an
market. By this they
mean that the competition to find misvalued stocks is intense. So when new
information comes out, investors rush to take advantage of it and thereby eliminate any profit opportunities. Professional investors e
they say that there are no free lunches on Wall Street.
grees of ef
y.
et, share price changes are
alueless.
et
Figure 7.6, which looked at successiv
index, is evidence in fav
ficiency.
Semistr
describes a mark
the information contained in past prices but all publicly available information. In
such a market it is impossible (or exceptionally difficult) to earn consistently superior returns simply by reading the financial press, studying the company’s financial statements, and so on. Figure 7.9, which looked at the market reaction to
merger announcements, was just one piece of evidence in favor of semistrong efficiency. As soon as information about the mergers became public, the stock prices
jumped.
Finally, str
refers to a mark
vailable
et no investor, howev
xpect to earn
In f
ven professional investors, such as managers of mutual
et consistently. Look, for example, at Figure 7.10, which shows the average performance of equity mutual funds over
three decades. Y
et,
but as often as not (in fact, in 24 of the 40 years since 1970) it was the other way
ones, and the top-performing managers one year have about an average chance of
falling on their face the ne
.
FIGURE 7.10
Annual returns
on the Wilshire 5000 Market
Index and equity mutual
funds, 1971–2010. The market
index provided a higher return
than the average mutual fund
in 24 of the 40 years.
212
▲
EXAMPLE 7.6
Two
Value
Performance of Money Managers
Forbes, a widely read investment magazine, publishes annually an “honor roll” of
the most consistently successful mutual funds. Suppose that every year starting in
1975, you invested an equal sum in each of these successful funds when Forbes
announced its honor roll. You would hav
ormed the market in only 5 of the
following 16 years, and your average annual return would have been more than 1%
below the return on the market.12
y investors have given
y simply buy and hold index
et. We disy provide maximum diversi-
up the search for superior inv
funds or e
cussed inde
w management fees.
et” but can’
now invest ov
x funds.
Self-Test 7.9
7.7 Market Anomalies and Behavioral Finance
Market Anomalies
Almost without e
f
et
hypothesis was a remarkably good description of reality. But eventually, cracks in its
ed with evidence of
vestors hav
ailed to
exploit. We will look at just a few examples.
The Earnings Announcement Puzzle In an ef
et, a company’s stock price should react instantly at the announcement of unexpectedly good or
ws typically outperform the
stocks with the w
ws. Figure 7.11 shows stock performance following
the announcement of une
2001.
with the worst news by about 1% per month ov
wing the
v
become aw
ves.
The New-Issue Puzzle
uy. On av
wever
v
e
and then held that stock for 5 years. Ov
ould hav
12
v
w
v
or
verage annual
-sized stocks.13
vesting in Equity Mutual Funds 1971 to 1991,” Journal of Finance
50 (June 1995), pp. 549–572.
13
bear
s Web page,
.
Chapter 7
213
Valuing Stocks
FIGURE 7.11
Average stock
returns over the 6 months
following announcements of
quarterly earnings. The 10%
of stocks with the best
earnings news (por olio 10)
outperformed those with the
worst news (por olio 1) by
about 1% per month.
Source: Tarun Chordia and Lakshmanan Shivakumar, "Inflation Illusion and Post-Earnings-Announcement Dr
Journal of Accounting Research 43 (2005), pp. 521–556. Used with permission of John Wiley and Sons via
Copyright Clearance Center, Inc.
W
t be sure
There
xplanations. T e, for example, the new-issue puzzle. Most new issues
ve involv
et v
y had just been issued
b
ve gro
poorly ov
W
Bubbles and Market Efficiency
individual stocks may occasionally get out of line. But are there also cases in which
prices as a whole can no longer be justified? In the last few decades, we have witnessed several e
et bubbles when prices rose to levels
hard to reconcile with reasonable outlooks for di
Between 1985 and 1989, for e
ei inde
as down 80% from its
peak v
.
The boom in Japanese stock prices was matched by an even greater explosion in
land prices. For example, Ziemba and Schw
w hundred acres
of land under the Emperor’s Palace in Tokyo, evaluated at neighborhood land prices,
was worth as much as all the land in Canada or California.14 But then the real estate
bubble also b
just 13% of their peak.
The dot-com bubble in the United States was almost as dramatic. The technologyheavy NASDAQ stock inde
ventual high in
March 2000. But then, as rapidly as it began, the boom ended, and by October 2002
the index had fallen 78% from its peak.
ve that expected future
ws could ever have been suff
the case, we have tw
xceptions to the theory of ef
ets.
14
See W. T. Ziemba and S. L. Schw
Invest Japan (Chicago: Prob
214
Two
Value
But bew
w
cious. First, most bubbles become ob
y have burst. At the time,
there often seems to be a plausible e
boom, for example, man
ers rationalized stock-price gains as
w and more profitable economy
ven by technological advances.
Here’s another conclusion not to jump to: Don’t assume that anyone can know
intrinsic value with confidence. Security valuation is intrinsically dif
imprecise. Consider this example: Suppose that in September 2010 you wanted to
check whether the stocks forming the S&P 500 were fairly priced.
you might have used the constant-growth dividend discount model. In 2010, the
annual dividends of the 500 companies in the index came to about $228 billion.
Suppose investors expected these dividends to grow at a steady rate of 4.0% and
that they required a rate of return of 6.3%. Then the value of the stocks in the index
would have been
PV 5
$228 billion
5 $9,913 billion
.063 2 .04
which was roughly their value in September 2010. But what if the dividend growth
rate was only 3.5%? Then the value of the stocks would decline to
$228 billion
5 $8,143 billion
.063 2 .035
In other words, a reduction of just half a percentage point in the expected rate of dividend growth would reduce the value of common stocks by about 18%. Given this
sensitivity of value to assumed growth rates, it is easy for investors to justify price
run-ups when the
bubbles—except of course in retrospect, at which point all bubbles seem to have been
obvious.
PV 5
Behavioral Finance
alues?
ve that the
vioral psychology
100% of the time. This shows up in two broad areas—their attitudes to risk and the
way that they assess probabilities:
1. Attitudes toward risk. Psychologists hav
y
v
small. Losers are liable to re
es for having been
so foolish. To avoid this unpleasant possibility, individuals will tend to shun those
actions that may result in loss.
The pain of a loss seems to depend on whether it comes on the heels of earlier
losses. Once investors hav
y may be even more cautious not to
risk a further loss. Conversely, just as gamblers are known to be more willing to
take large bets when the
vestors may be more prepared to run the
et dip after they have e
If they do then suffer a small loss, they at least have the consolation of being up on
.
You can see ho
vior could lead to a stock-price bubble. For
example, early inv
bubble were big winners. They may have stopped w
They may have thrown caution to the winds and piled even more investment into
ving stock prices f
ve fundamental values. The day of
reckoning came when investors woke up and realized how far above fundamental
value prices had soared.
Chapter 7
215
Valuing Stocks
2. Beliefs about probabilities. Most investors do not have a Ph.D. in probability
outcomes. Psychologists have found that, when judging the possible future
outcomes, individuals commonly look back to what has happened in recent periods
and then assume that this is representative of what may occur in the future. The
temptation is to project recent e
get the lessons
or example, an investor who places too much
weight on recent events may judge that glamorous growth companies are very
likely to continue to grow rapidly, even though v
wth cannot
persist indefinitely.
A second common bias is overconfidence. Most of us believ
than-av
vers, and most investors think that the
-than-average
stockpickers. We know that tw
e money from the deal; for every winner there must be a loser. But
presumably inv
.
You can see how such behavior may have reinforced the dot-com boom. As the
bull market dev
vestors rack
y became in their views and the more willing they
xt month might not be so good.
Now it is not difficult to believe that your uncle Harry or aunt Hetty may have
become caught up in a scatty whirl of irrational exuberance,15 but why didn’t hardheaded professional investors bail out of the overpriced stocks and force their
prices down to fair value? Perhaps they felt that it was too difficult to predict when
the boom would end and that their jobs would be at risk if they moved aggressively
into cash when others were raking up profits. In this case, sales of stock by the
pros were simply not large enough to stem the tide of optimism that was sweeping
the market.
w far beha
of the puzzles and e
vents like the dot-com boom. One thing, however, seems
clear: It is relativ
sight and for psychologists to provide an explanation for them. It is much more difficult for inv
v
.
15
as coined by
, Irrational Exuberance (New York City: Broadway Books, 2001).
SUMMARY
e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
finance.yahoo.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
TABLE 7.6
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
MINICASE
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
TABLE 7.7
CHAPTER
8
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T T W O
Value
High tech businesses often require huge investments.
T
●
●
●
●
●
●
8.1 Net Present Value
value. We now apply these ideas to evaluate a simple investment proposal.
Suppose that you are in the real estate business. You are considering construction of
ice block. The land w
$300,000. Y
w you
will be able to sell the building for $400,000. Thus you would be investing $350,000
no
. Therefore, prows:
$400,000
0
Y
1
–$350,000
You should go ahead if the present value of the $400,000 payoff is greater than the
investment of $350,000.
Assume for the moment that the $400,000 payoff is a sure thing. The of
uilding is not the only way to obtain $400,000 a year from now. You could invest in 1-year
U.S. T
T
fer interest of 7%. How much would
you have to invest in them in order to receive $400,000 at the end of the year? That’s
easy: You would have to invest
$400,000 3
1
5 $400,000 3 .9346 5 $373,832
1.07
Let’s assume that as soon as you have purchased the land and laid out the money for
construction, you decide to cash in on your project. How much could you sell it for?
, investors would be willing to pay
at most $373,832 for it now. That’s all it would cost them to get the same $400,000
payoff by investing in gov
ways sell your
Therefore, at an interest rate of 7%, the present value of the $400,000 payoff from
uilding is $373,832.
228
Chapter 8
The $373,832 present v
opportunity cost
of capital
Expected rate of return
given up by investing in
a project.
229
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
uyer and seller. In
alue of the prop-
erty is also its market price or market value.
To calculate present value, we discounted the expected future payoff by the rate of
vestment alternatives. The discount rate—7% in our
example—is often known as the opportunity cost of
. It is called the opportubecause it is the return that is being given up by investing in the project.
The building is w
off. You committed $350,000, and therefore your net present value (NPV) is $23,832.
Net present value is found by subtracting the required initial investment from the present v
ws:
net present value (NPV)
Present value of cash
flows minus investment.
NPV 5 PV 2 required investment
5 $373,832 2 $350,000 5 $23,832
(8.1)
In other w
ice development is w
es a net
ution to value. The net present value rule states that managers increase
shareholders’ wealth by accepting all projects that are worth more than they
cost. Therefore, they should accept all projects with a positive net present value.
A Comment on Risk and Present Value
In our discussion of the of
v
w the v
completed project. Of course, you will never be certain about the future values of
office buildings. The $400,000 represents the best forecast, but it is not a sure thing.
Therefore, our initial conclusion about how much investors would pay for the building is premature. Since they could achiev
vesting in $373,832
worth of U.S. T
y would not buy your building for that amount. You
would have to cut your asking price to attract investors’ interest.
orth less than a
Here we can invoke a basic financial principle: A r
safe one.
Most investors avoid risk when the
wever,
the concepts of present v
inv
fered by a
comparable investment. But we have to think of expected
expected
vestments.
Not all investments are equally risky. The office development is riskier than a
Treasury note but is probably less risky than investing in a start-up biotech company. Suppose you believe the office development is as risky as an investment in the
stock market and that you forecast a 12% rate of return for stock market investments. Then 12% w
That is what
you are giving up by not investing in comparable securities. You can now recompute NPV:
1
5 $400,000 3 .8929 5 $357,143
1.12
NPV 5 PV 2 $350,000 5 $7,143
PV 5 $400,000 3
If other investors agree with your forecast of a $400,000 payoff and with your
orth
$357,143 once construction is under way. If you tried to sell for more than that, there
w
ers, because the property would then offer a lower expected rate of
return than the 12% av
et. The of
uilding still makes a
net contribution to value, but it is much smaller than our earlier calculations
indicated.
230
Two
Value
Self-Test 8.1
Valuing Long-Lived Projects
The net present v
orks for projects of any length. For example, suppose that
you are approached by a possible tenant who is prepared to rent your of
ed annual rent of $25,000. You would need to expand the reception area
-made features. This w
vestment to
$375,000, but you forecast that after you have collected the third year’s rent the building could be sold for $450,000.
w (denoted
shown belo
selling the building).
C3 = $475,000
C1 = $25,000
C2 = $25,000
1
2
0
Y
3
C0 = –$375,000
Notice that the initial investment shows up as a negativ
w.
w,
ws are cerC0, is 2$375,000. For simplicity
r 5 7%.
Figure 8.1 sho
ws and their present values. T
present v
ws at the 7% opportunity cost
of capital:
PV 5
5
C3
C2
C1
1
1
2
( 1 1 r)
( 1 1 r) 3
11r
$25,000
$25,000
$475,000
1
1
5 $432,942
2
1.07
1.07
1.073
The net present value of the revised project is NPV 5 $432,942 2 $375,000
5
and renting it for 3 years makes a greater
.
v
s present
value, you could calculate NPV directly, as in the following equation, where C0
w required to build the of
NPV 5 C0 1
C3
C1
C2
1
1
( 1 1 r) 2
( 1 1 r) 3
11r
5 2$375,000 1
$25,000
$25,000
$475,000
1
1
5 $57,942
2
1.07
1.07
1.073
Let’s check that the owners of this project really are better off. Suppose you put up
$375,000 of your own money, commit to b
uilding, and sign a lease that
Chapter 8
231
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
FIGURE 8.1 Cash flows
and their present values for
ice block project. Final
cash flow of $475,000 is the
sum of the rental income in
year 3 plus the forecast sales
price for the building.
will bring in $25,000 a year for 3 years. Now you can cash in by selling the project to
other investors.
ws are certain, and the interest rate
vestments is 7%, investors will v
per
5
$25
$475
$25
1
1
5 $432.94
1.07
1.072
1.073
Thus you can sell the project to outside investors for 1,000 3 $432.94 5 $432,940,
which, save for rounding, is exactly the present value we calculated earlier. Your net
gain is
Net gain 5 $432,942 2 $375,000 5 $57,942
which is the project’s NPV. This equiv
value calculation is designed to calculate the v
the capital markets.
ws to investors in
w. In that case we would discount C1 by r1, the discount rate for
ws; C2 would be discounted by r2; and so on. Here we assume that the
cost of capital is the same re
w. We do this for one
reason only—simplicity. But we are in good company: W
ws from
the project.
each period’
▲
EXAMPLE 8.1
Valuing a New Computer System
Obsolete Technologies is considering the purchase of a new computer system to
help handle its warehouse inventories. The system costs $50,000, is expected to last
4 years, and should reduce the cost of managing inventories by $22,000 a year.
The oppor
al is 10%. Should Obsolete go ahead?
Don’
y the fact that the computer system does not generate any
sales. If the expected cost savings are realized, the company’s cash flows will be
$22,000 a year higher as a result of buying the computer. Thus we can say that the
232
Two
Value
computer increases cash flows by $22,000 a year for each of 4 years. To calculate
present value, you can discount each of these cash flows by 10%. However, it is
smarter to recognize that the cash flows are level, and therefore you can use the
annuity formula to calculate the present value:
PV 5 cash flow 3 annuity factor 5 $22,000 3 B
1
1
2
R
.10
.10(1.10)4
5 $22,000 3 3.1699 5 $69,738
The net present value is
NPV 5 2$50,000 1 $69,738 5 $19,738
The project has a positive NPV of $19,738. Undertaking it would increase the value
of the firm by that amount.
The first tw
ws and estimating
y, and we will have a lot more to say about
them in later chapters. But once you have assembled the data, the calculation of present value and net present value should be routine. Here is another example.
▲
EXAMPLE 8.2
Calculating Eurotunnel’s NPV
One of the world’s largest commercial investment projects was construction of the
Channel Tunnel by the Anglo-French company Eurotunnel. Here is a chance to put
yourself in the shoes of Eurotunnel’s financial manager and find out whether the
project looked like it would be a good deal for shareholders. The figures in column
C of Table 8.1 are based on the forecasts of construction costs and revenues that
the company provided to investors in 1986.
The Channel Tunnel project was not a safe investment. Indeed, the prospectus
to the Channel Tunnel share issue cautioned investors that the project “involves
significant risk and should be regarded at this stage as speculative. If for any reason the Project is abandoned or Eurotunnel is unable to raise the necessary finance,
it is lik
vestors will lose some or all of their money.”
To be induced to invest in the project, investors needed a higher prospective rate
of return than they could get on safe government bonds. Suppose investors
expected a return of 13% from investments in the capital market that had a degree
of risk similar to that of the Channel Tunnel. That was what investors were giving up
when they provided the capital for the tunnel. To find the project’s NPV we therefore
discount the cash flows in Table 8.1 at 13%.
Since the tunnel was expected to take about 7 years to build, there are 7 years of
negative cash flows in Table 8.1. To calculate NPV, you just discount all the cash
flows, positive and negative, at 13% and sum the results. Call 1986 “year 0,” call 1987
“year 1,” and so on. Then
NPV 5
52
1
C1
C2
1
1c
(1 1 r)2
11r
2
£17,781
2
1
1 c1
5 £249.8 million
1
2
(
)
(1.13)24
1.13
1.13
We present the calculations in column D. (The nearby box provides additional discussion of how to calculate present values by using spreadsheets.) The net present
value of the forecast cash flows is £249.8 million, making the tunnel a worthwhile
project, though not by a wide margin, considering the planned investment of
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
Present Values
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Spreadsheet Questions
TABLE 8.1
Forecast cash
flows and present values in
1986 for the Channel Tunnel
project. The investment at the
time appeared to have a
positive NPV of £249.8 million.
You can find this spreadsheet at
.mhhe.com/bmm7e.
Note: Cash flow for 2010 includes the value in 2010 of forecast cash flows in all subsequent y
. Some of these figures involve guesswork because the prospectus
reported accumulated construction costs including interest expenses.
Source: Eurotunnel Equity II Prospectus, October 1986. Reprinted with permission.
233
234
Two
Value
w forees
ve. As the law predicted, the
tunnel proved much more expensive to build than anticipated in 1986, and the opening
was delayed by more than a year. Revenues also were below forecast, and Eurotunnel
did not ev
Thus, with hindsight, the tunnel was a costly negative-NPV venture. By 2007, Eurotunnel was operaty law and had to be restructured. Eventually, the f
as
reorganized into a new company called Groupe Eurotunnel.
casts.
wn Pentagon Law of Lar
8.2 Using the NPV Rule to Choose
among Projects
So far, the simple projects that we have considered involv
e-it-or-leave-it decisions. But almost all real-world decisions entail either-or choices. You could use that
vacant lot to b
You could build a
7-story of
You could heat it with oil or with natural gas.
You could build it today or w
mutually exclusive.
When choosing among mutually exclusive projects, calculate the NPV of
each alternative and choose the highest positive-NPV project.
▲
EXAMPLE 8.3
Choosing between Two Projects
It has been several years since y
ice last upgr
ice networking software. Two competing systems have been proposed. Both have an expected useful
life of 3 years, at which point it will be time for another upgrade. One proposal is for
an expensive,
em, which will cost $800,000 and increase firm cash
flows by $350,000 a year through increased productivity. The other proposal is for a
cheaper, somewhat slower system. This system would cost only $700,000 but would
increase cash flows by only $300,000 a year. If the cost of capital is 7%, which is the
better option?
The following table summarizes the cash flows and the NPVs of the two
proposals:
In both cases,
are systems are worth more than they cost, but the faster
system would make the greater contribution to value and therefore should be your
preferred choice.
o netw
did not affect an
e. But sometimes the
choices that you make today will have an impact on future opportunities.
but often challenging, problems:
• The investment timing problem. Should you buy a computer now or wait and think
about it again ne
s investment is competing with possible
vestments.)
Chapter 8
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
235
• The c
Should the company save
mone
today’s decision would accelerate a later investment in machine replacement.)
• The replacement problem. When should e
vestment in more modern equipment.)
W
Problem 1: The Investment Timing Decision
In Example 8.1 Obsolete Technologies is contemplating the purchase of a new computer system. The proposed investment has a net present value of almost $20,000, so it
vings would easily justify the expense of the system. However,
the f
tinually f
guing that the NPV
of the system will be ev
. Unfortunately
gument for 10 years, and the company is
steadily losing b
w in
her reasoning?
This is a problem in investment timing.
ve-NPV
investment? Investment timing problems all involve choices among mutually exclusive investments. You can either proceed with the project now or do so later. Y
t
do both.
Table 8.2 lays out the basic data for Obsolete. You can see that the cost of the computer is expected to decline from $50,000 today to $45,000 ne
The
new computer system is expected to last for 4 years from the time it is installed. The
present value of the savings at the time of installation is expected to be $70,000. Thus,
if Obsolete invests today, it achieves an NPV of $70,000 2 $50,000 5 $20,000; if it
invests next year, it will have an NPV of $70,000 2 $45,000 5 $25,000.
Isn’t a gain of $25,000 better than one of $20,000? W
may prefer to be $20,000 richer today than $25,000 richer next year. Your decision
should depend on the cost of capital.
Table 8.2 shows the value
today (year 0) of those net present values at a 10% cost of capital. For example, you
can see that the discounted v
5 $22,700.
The financial manager has a point. It is w
vestment in the computer: Today’s NPV is higher if she waits a year. But the investment should not be
postponed indefinitely. You maximize net present value today by buying the comNotice that you are involved in a trade-off. The sooner you can capture the $70,000
savings the better, but if it costs you less to realize those savings by postponing the
investment, it may pay for you to w
, the gain
from b
Since this is less than the cost of capital, this postponement would not make sense. The
decision rule for investment timing is to choose the investment date that produces the highest net present value today.
Self-Test 8.2
236
Part Two Value
TABLE 8.2
Obsolete Technologies: The gain from purchase of a computer is rising, but the NPV today is highest if
the computer is purchased in year 3 (figures in thousands of dollars).
Problem 2: The Choice between Longand Short-Lived Equipment
o machines, A and B. The two
machines are designed differently but have identical capacity and do exactly the same
job. Machine
Machine B is an “economy” model, costing only $10,000, but it will last only 2 years
Because the two machines produce exactly the same product, the only way to
choose between them is on the basis of cost. Suppose we compute the present value of
the costs:
Should we tak
. All we have sho
wer present value of costs? Not necwer total
A. But is the annual cost of using B lower
than that of A?
uy machine A and pay for its operating
costs out of her b
of the machine.
equivalent annual annuity
The cash flow per period
with the same present
value as the cost of
buying and operating a
machine.
viously, the
e sure that the present value of these payments equals
the present value of the costs of machine A, $25,690. When the discount rate is 6%,
the payment stream with such a present v
. In other
words, the cost of buying and operating machine A over its 3-year life is equivalent to
This figure is therefore termed the
equivalent annual annuity of operating machine A.
Ho
w that an annual charge of $9,610 has a present value of $25,690?
. So we calculate the value of this annuity and set
it equal to $25,690:
Equivalent annual annuity 3
5 PV of costs 5 $25,690
Chapter 8
237
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
If the cost of capital is 6%, the 3-year annuity factor is 2.6730. So
present value of costs
Equivalent annual annuity 5
5
(8.2)
$25,690
$25,690
5
5 $9,610
3-year annuity factor
2.6730
We see now that machine A is better, because its equivalent annual annuity is less
($9,610 for A versus $11,450 for B). In other w
afford to set a lower annual
ge for the use of A. We thus have a rule for comparerent lives: Select the machine that has the lowest equivalent
annual ann
.
Think of the equivalent annual annuity as the level annual char
1
The annual
to recover the present value of inv
charge continues for the life of the equipment. Calculate the equivalent annual annuity
by dividing the present value by the annuity factor.
▲
EXAMPLE 8.4
Equivalent Annual Annuity
You need a new car. You can either purchase one outright for $15,000 or lease one
for 7 years for $3,000 a year. If you buy the car, it will be worth $500 to you in 7 years.
The discount rate is 10%. Should you buy or lease? What is the maximum lease payment you would be willing to pay?
The present value of the cost of purchasing is
PV 5 $15,000 2
$500
5 $14,743
(1.10)7
The equivalent annual cost of purchasing the car is therefore the annuity with this
present value:
Equivalent annual annuity 3 7-year annuity factor at 10% 5 PV costs of buying
5 $14,743
Equivalent annual annuity 5
$14,743
7-
r
5
$14,743
5 $3,028
4.8684
Therefore, the annual lease payment of $3,000 is less than the equivalent annual
ann
. You should be willing to pay up to $3,028 annually to lease.
▲
EXAMPLE 8.5
Another Equivalent Annual Annuity
Low-energy lightbulbs typically cost $3.50, have a life of 9 years, and use about
$1.60 of electricity a year. Conventional lightbulbs are cheaper to buy, for they cost
only $.50. On the other hand, they last only about a year and use about $6.60 of
energy. If the real discount rate is 5%, which product is cheaper to use?
1
We hav
vactor.
238
Two
Value
To answer this question, you need first to convert the initial cost of each bulb to
an annual figure and then to add in the annual energy cost.2 The following table
sets out the calculations:
It seems that a lo
5 $5.03.
gy bulb provides an annual saving of about $7.12 2 $2.09
Problem 3: When to Replace an Old Machine
ed. In
collapse. We usually decide when to replace. For example, we usually replace a car not
wn but when it becomes more expensive and troublesome to
keep up than a replacement.
Here is an example of a replacement problem: Y
ves up the ghost. It costs $12,000 per year to operate.
You can replace it now with a ne
machine no
We calculate the NPV of the new machine and its equivalent annual annuity in the
following table:
ws of the ne
valent to an annuity of $13,930 per year.
So we can equally well ask whether you would want to replace your old machine,
w one costing $13,930 a year.
question is posed this way, the answer is obvious. As long as your old machine costs
only $12,000 a year, why replace it with a ne
Self-Test 8.3
2
Our calculations ignore any environmental costs.
Chapter 8
239
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
8.3 The Payback Rule
payback period
Time until cash flows
recover the initial
investment in the project.
A project with a positive net present value is worth more than it costs. So whenever a
v
f.
These days almost ev
vestments, b
vestment
decisions. W
x. As we describe these measures, you will see
that payback is no better than a very rough guide to an investment’s w
x lead
to the same decisions as net present value.
We suspect that you hav
versations that go something like this: “A
w
, at the laundromat. So the washing machine should pay for itself in
less than 3 years.” You hav
A project’s payback period is the length of time before you recover your initial
The
investment. For the washing machine the payback period w
payback rule states that a project should be accepted if its payback period is
less than a specified cut
iod. For e
w
t.
ut it is easy to see that
it can lead to nonsensical decisions. For example, compare projects E and F. Project E
ge positive NPV
ut
a negative NPV
,b
.
This is because payback does not consider an
ve after the payback
period.
f of 2 or more years would
accept both E and F despite the fact that only E would increase shareholder wealth.
Cash Flows (dollars)
Project
C0
C1
C2
E
F
G
22,000
22,000
22,000
11,000
11,000
0
11,000
11,000
12,000
C3
110,000
0
0
Payback
Period,
Years
NPV
at 10%
2
2
2
$7,249
2264
2347
A second problem with payback is that it giv
ving before
ws are less valuable. For e
ut it has
an even lower NPV than project F.
ve later within the
payback period.
T
f period. If it
gardless of project life, it will tend to accept too many shortlived projects and reject too many long-lived ones.
ve after the payback
Earlier in the chapter we evaluated the Channel Tunnel project. Lar
vitably have long payback periods.
ws that we
240
Two
Value
presented in Table 8.1
v
that employ the payback rule use a much shorter cutoff period than this. If they used
, long-lived projects like the Channel Tunnel wouldn’t
have a chance.
. But remember that
v
tic. Today’
vial exercise. Therefore, the payback
v
We hav
y companies continue
to use it? Senior managers don’t truly believ
ws after the payback
vant. It seems more lik
ves because the def
vely unimportant or because there
are some offsetting benefits. Thus managers may point out that payback is the simplest
way to communicate an idea of project desirability. Investment decisions require disto have a measure that ev
avor quick
payback projects even when the projects have lower NPVs because they believe that
quicker profits mean quicker promotion.
es us back to Chapter 1, where we
discussed the need to align the objectives of managers with those of the shareholders.
In practice payback is most commonly used when the capital investment is small or
.
For example, if a project is e
ws for 10 years and
the payback period is only 2 years, the project in all likelihood has a positive NPV.
Discounted Payback
Sometimes managers calculate the discounted-payback period. This is the number of
alue of prospectiv
ws equals or exceeds the initial
investment. The discounted-payback measure asks, How long must the project last in
order to offer a positive net present value? If the discounted payback meets the company’
The discounted-payantage that it will never accept a negative-NPV project. On the
other hand, it still tak
ws after the cutoff date, so a company
y project with a long discounted-payback
y managers simply use the measure as a w
These managers
don’
the
s ability to genws into the distant future. They satisfy themselves that the equipment
truly has a long life or that competitors will not enter the market and eat into the
project’
ws.
Self-Test 8.4
8.4 The Internal Rate of Return Rule
Instead of calculating a project’s net present v
whether the project’
wer than the opportunity cost of capital. For
example, think back to the original proposal to build the of
You planned to
Chapter 8
241
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
inv
w of C1 5 $400,000 in 1 year. Therefore, you
forecast a profit on the venture of $400,000 2 $350,000 5
project lik
vested in the project:
profit
C1 2 investment
$400,000 2 $350,000
5
5
investment
investment
$350,000
5 .1429, or about 14.3%
Rate of return 5
The alternative of investing in a U.S. Treasury note would pro
Thus the return on your of
This suggests tw
project:
3
vestment
1. The NPV rule. Invest in any project that has a positiv
ws are
discounted at the opportunity cost of capital.
2. The rate of return rule. Inv
y project offering a rate of return that is higher
An inv
NPV of zero will also hav
Suppose that the rate of interest on Treasury notes is not 7% but 14.3%. Since your
of
no
ving your money in T
notes.
The NPV rule also tells you that if the interest rate is 14.3%, the project is evenly
C1
$400,000
5 2$350,000 1
50
11r
1.143
The project would make you neither richer nor poorer; it is worth what it costs. Thus
ve the same decision on accepting the
project.
NPV 5 C0 1
A Closer Look at the Rate of Return Rule
W
w that if the of
ws are discounted at a rate of 7%, the project has a net present value of $23,832. If they are discounted at a rate of 14.3%, it has
an NPV of zero. In Figure 8.2 the project’s NPV for a v
ted. This is often called the NPV pr
of the project. Notice tw
about Figure 8.2:
1. The project rate of return (in our example, 14.3%) is also the discount rate that
The rate of
would give the project a zero NPV. This giv
return is the discount rate at which NPV equals zero.
2.
your project is positiv
then NPV is negative.
valent.
Calculating the Rate of Return for Long-Lived Projects
There is no ambiguity in calculating the rate of return for an investment that generates
a single payof
w do we calculate return when the project prows in sev
3
uilding is risk-free.
vestments.
242
Part Two Value
FIGURE 8.2
The value of
ice project is lower
when the discount rate is
higher. The project has a
positive NPV if the discount
rate is less than 14.3%.
internal rate of return (IRR)
Discount rate at which
project NPV 5 0.
introduced above—the project rate of return is also the discount rate that gives the
project a zero NPV. W
y
ws. The discount rate that gives the project a zero NPV is known as the
project’s
, or IRR. It is also termed the discounted cashflow (DCF) rate of return.
Let’
vised of
ws are as follows:
Year:
Cash flows
0
1
2
3
2$375,000
1$25,000
1$25,000
1$475,000
ws would have zero NPV. Thus,
NPV 5 2$375,000 1
$25,000
$25,000
$475,000
1
1
50
2
(1 1 IRR)
(1 1 IRR)3
1 1 IRR
There is no simple general method for solving this equation. You have to rely on a little
This gives an NPV of
$150,000:
NPV 5 2$375,000 1
$25,000
$25,000
$475,000
1
1
5 $150,000
2
(
)
(1.0)3
1.0
1.0
With a zero discount rate the NPV is positive. So the IRR must be greater than zero.
The ne
2$206,481:
NPV 5 2$375,000 1
$25,000
$25,000
$475,000
1
1
5 2$206,481
(1.50)2
(1.50)3
1.50
NPV is now negative. So the IRR must lie somewhere between zero and 50%. In
Figure 8.3 we have plotted the net present values for a range of discount rates. You can
see that a discount rate of 12.56% gives an NPV of zero. Therefore, the IRR is 12.56%.
You can alw
Figure 8.3, but it is
quick
The nearby boxes illustrate how to do so.
You can see from Figure 8.3
es sense. Because
the NPV profile is downward-sloping, the project has a positive NPV as long as the
Chapter 8
243
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
FIGURE 8.3 The internal
rate of return is the discount
rate for which NPV equals
zero.
opportunity cost of capital is less than the project’s 12.56% IRR. If the opportunity
cost of capital is higher than the 12.56% IRR, NPV is negative. Therefore, when we
v
whether the project has a positive NPV. This w
ice project. We conclude that the rate of return
rule will give the same answer as the NPV rule as long as the NPV of a project
declines smoothly as the discount rate increases.4
The usual agreement between the net present v
should not be a surprise. Both are
methods of choosing between
better off, and both recognize that companies always have a choice: They can invest in
a project, or if the project is not suf
ve, they can give the money back to
vest it for themselv
et.
Self-Test 8.5
A Word of Caution
Some people confuse the internal rate of return on a project with the opportunity cost
of capital. Remember that the project IRR measures the profitability of the project. It
internal rate of return in the sense that it depends only on the project’s own cash
ws. The opportunity cost of capital is the standard for deciding whether to accept
the project. It is equal to the return offered by equiv
vestments in the
capital market.
Some Pitfalls with the Internal Rate of Return Rule
Many firms use the internal rate of return rule instead of net present value. We
think that this is a pity. When used properly, the two rules lead to the same decision, but the rate of return rule has several pitfalls that can trap the unwary. Here
are three examples.
4
In Chapter 6 we showed ho
A bond’s yield to maturity is simply
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
Internal Rate of Return
Pitfall 1: Lending or Borrowing?
to work: The project’s NPV must fall as the discount rate increases. Now consider the
following projects:
Cash Flows (dollars)
Project
C0
C1
IRR, %
NPV at 10%
H
I
2100
1100
1150
2150
150
150
1$36.4
2 36.4
Each project has an IRR of 50%. In other w
ws at
50%, both projects would have zero NPV.
Does this mean that the two projects are equally attractive? Clearly not. In the case
of H we are paying out $100 now and getting $150 back at the end of the year. That is
better than an
w
but we hav
. That is equiv
wing
money at 50%.
If someone asked you whether 50% was a good rate of interest, you could not
answer unless you also knew whether that person was proposing to lend or borrow at
that rate. Lending mone
country), b
wing at 50% is not usually a good deal (unless, of course, you plan
y, you want a high
borrow, you want a low rate of return.
e Figure 8.2
(T
Obviously
Project I is a fairly obvious trap, but if you want to make sure you don’t fall into it,
calculate the project’s NPV. For example, suppose that the cost of capital is 10%. Then
the NPV of project H is 1$36.4 and the NPV of project I is 2$36.4.
correctly warns us away from a project that is equiv
wing money at 50%.
When NPV rises as the interest rate rises, the rate of return rule is reversed:
A project is acceptable only if its internal rate of return is less than the opportual.
Pitfall 2: Mutually Exclusive Projects We have seen that f
dom f
e-it-or-leave-it projects. Usually they need to choose from a number of mutually exclusiv
ves. Given a choice between competing projects,
the higher NPV.
Would it make sense to just choose the proj, no. Mutually exclusive proj5
ects involve an additional pitf
5
ve considered, payback, giv
v
xclusive projects.
244
F I N A N C I A L CA L C U L ATO R
Using Financial Calculators to Find NPV and IRR
Think once more about the two of
You initially intended to invest $350,000 in the building and then sell it at the end of the
year for $400,000. Under the revised proposal, you planned to invest $375,000, rent
out the offices for 3 years at a fixed annual rent of $25,000, and then sell the building for $450,000. The following table sho
ws, their IRRs, and
their NPVs:
vestments; both offer a positive NPV. But the revised pro,
vised proposal doesn’t sho
The
IRR rule seems to say you should go for the initial proposal because it has the higher
IRR. If you follow the IRR rule, you have the satisf
return; if you use NPV
.
Figure 8.4 sho
ves the wrong signal.
NPV of each project for different discount rates. These tw
w, is the superior investment. If the cost of
capital is lower than 11.72%, then the re
245
246
Part Two Value
FIGURE 8.4 The initial
pr
ers a higher IRR
than the revised proposal, but
its NPV is lower if the discount
rate is less than 11.72%.
discount rate, either proposal may be superior. For the 7% cost of capital that we have
assumed, the re
Now consider the IRR of each proposal. The IRR is simply the discount rate at
which NPV equals zero, that is, the discount rate at which the NPV profile crosses the
horizontal axis in Figure 8.4.
and 12.56% for the revised proposal. However, as you can see from Figure 8.4, the
.
In our e
volv
, but the revised proposal had
the longer life.
enly favored the quick payback project with the
high percentage return but the lower NPV. Remember, a high IRR is not an end in
itself. You want projects that increase the value of the firm. Projects that earn a
good rate of return for a long time often have higher NPVs than those that offer
high percentage rates of return but die young.
Self-Test 8.6
Pitfall 2a: Mutually Exclusive Projects Involving Different Outlays
ves
but different outlays. In this case the IRR may mistakenly favor small projects with
high rates of return but low NPVs. When you are faced with a straightforward
either-or choice, the simple solution is to compare their NPVs. However, if you are
determined to use the IRR rule, there is a way to do so. We explain how in the
appendix.
Chapter 8
247
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
Self-Test 8.7
Pitfall 3: Multiple Rates of Return
Here is a tricky problem. King Coal
The project requires an invest-
uilding up to $175 million in years 3 and 4. However, the company is
At a 20% opportunity
T
s project, we have calculated the NPV for various
discount rates and plotted the results in Figure 8.5. Y
discount rates at which NPV5 0. That is, each of the following statements holds:
NPV 5 2210 1
125
175
175
400
$125
1
1
1
2
50
2
3
4
1.03
1.03
1.03
1.03
1.035
NPV 5 2210 1
$125
125
175
175
400
1
1
1
2
50
2
3
4
1.25
1.25
1.25
1.25
1.255
and
In other words, the investment has an IRR of both 3% and 25%. The reason for this is
ws.
y dif
w stream.6
FIGURE 8.5 King Coal’s
project has two internal rates
of return. NPV 5 0 when
the discount rate is either
3% or 25%.
6
fewer
is no IRR. For e
1, and 1
ect ever have a ne v
You may ev
ws of 1
t believ
2
248
Part Two Value
Is the coal mine worth developing?
greater than the cost of capital—won’t help. For e
Figure 8.5
gative NPV. It has a
positive NPV only if the cost of capital is between 3% and 25%.
e King Coal’s f
w negative, can sometimes be huge. Phillips Petroleum has estimated that it will need to
spend $1 billion to remove its Norwe
ver $300
wer plant. These are obvious examples where
ws go from positive to negative, but you can probably think of a number of
other cases where the company needs to plan for later expenditures. Ships periodically
it, hotels may receive a major f
Whenev
w stream is expected to change sign more than once, the
rate of return (MIRR). We explain how to do so in the appendix to this chapter.
However, it would be much easier in such cases to abandon the IRR rule and just
calculate project NPV.
8.5 The Profitability Index
profitability index
Ratio of net present
value to initial investment.
The pr
of investment:
index measures the net present value of a project per dollar
Profitability index 5
net present value
initial investment
For e
(8.3)
uilding involved an investx7 was
23,832
5 .068
350,000
Any project with a positive profitability index must also have a positive NPV, so it
w
Why go to the trouble of calculating the profitability index? The answer is that whenever there is a limit
on the amount the company can spend, it makes sense to concentrate on getting the
biggest bang for each investment buck. In other words, when there is a shortage of
v
x.
Let us illustrate.
aced with the following investment
Cash Flows ($ millions)
Project
J
K
L
C0
C1
C2
210
25
25
130
15
15
15
120
115
NPV at 10%
Profitability Index
21
16
12
21/10 5 2.1
16/5 5 3.2
12/5 5 2.4
All three projects are attractive, b
million. In that case, you can invest either in project J or in projects K and L, but you
can’t inv
7
required inv
example, the of
uilding’
net present value) to
xes calculated belo
or
x would be PV/investment 5373,832/350,000 5 1.068. Note
Chapter 8
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
249
y. In our example, K provested, followed by L. These two projects exactly
use up the $10 million budget. Between them the
wealth. The alternative of investing in J would have added only $21 million.
Capital Rationing
capital rationing
Limit set on the amount
of funds available for
investment.
Economists use the term capital rationing
vailable for
inv
x can provide a
measure of which projects to accept.8
tions can obtain v
ge sums of money on fair terms and at short notice. So why
does top management sometimes tell subordinates that capital is limited and that they
may not e
o reasons.
Soft Rationing
For many f
rationing is not imposed by inv
ment. For e
ager. Y
een to e
overstate the inv
man
” By this we mean that the capital
usiness, and as a result you tend to
This limit
forces you to set your o
Even if capital is not rationed, other resources may be. For example, v
gro
A somewhat rough-and-ready response to this problem is to ration the amount of capital that
Hard Rationing
Soft rationing should never cost the f
vestment become
more money and relax the limits it has imposed on capital spending. But what if there
is “hard rationing,
cannot raise the money it needs? In
that case, it may be forced to pass up positive-NPV projects. W
may still be interested in net present value, but you now need to select the package of
projects that is within the company’s resources and yet gives the highest net present
value.
x can be useful.
Pitfalls of the Profitability Index
x is sometimes used to rank projects even when there is no soft
or hard capital rationing. In this case the unwary user may be led to favor small projects over larger projects that have higher NPVs.
x was designed
to select projects with the most bang per buck—the greatest NPV per dollar spent.
That’
ve when bucks are limited. When they are not, a bigger bang is
always better than a smaller one, even when more b
est 8.8 is a
xample.
8
other resources are rationed in addition to capital, it isn’t alw
x. T
ming methods may be used.
, or
250
Two
Value
Self-Test 8.8
8.6 A Last Look
We’ve covered several inv
wn nuances. If your head is
spinning, you might want to take a look at Table 8.3, which gives an overview and
, NPV is the gold standard. It is designed to tell you whether an investment
will increase the v
xclusive investments.
aces
capital rationing. In this case, there may not be enough cash to take ev
positive NPV, and the f
x, that is,
net present v
vested.
F
w analysis is in f
for project evaluation. Table 8.4 pro
ge survey of
w
ways use NPV or IRR to
evaluate projects. The dominance of these criteria is even stronger among larger, preantages of discounted cashw methods, however
v
valuate projects. For
example, just ov
ways or almost always compute a project’s
What e
to the chapter
TABLE 8.3
A comparison of investment decision rules
To some extent,
As we noted in the introduction
ant to consider some simple ways to describe project
Chapter 8
Net Present Value and Other Investment Criteria
251
TABLE 8.4
Capital
budgeting techniques
used in practice
Source: Reprinted from the Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 60, Issue 2–3, J. R. Graham and C. R. Harvey, “The
Theory and Practice of Corporate Finance: Evidence from the Field,” May 2001, pp. 187–243. © 2001 with permission
from Elsevier Science.
, even if they present obvious pitfalls. For example, managers talk casually
ay that inv
stocks. The fact that the
verns their decisions.
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
FIGURE 8.6
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO SPREADSHEET QUESTIONS
MINICASE
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
APPENDIX
More on the IRR Rule
Using the IRR to Choose between
Mutually Exclusive Projects
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Using the Modified Internal Rate of Return
when there are Multiple IRRs
CHAPTER
9
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T T W O
Value
A working magnoosium mine.
T
9.1 Identifying Cash Flows
Discount Cash Flows, Not Profits
Up to this point we hav
We hav
about the problem of what you should discount. The f
this: To calculate net present v
ws, not accounting
W
w ho
They
ws.
If the f
ge amount of money on a big capital project, you do not
, even though a lot of cash is going
out the door. Therefore, the accountant does not deduct capital expenditure when
calculating the year’s income but, instead, depreciates it over several years.
its, but it could get you into trouble
when working out net present value. For e
investment proposal. It costs $2,000 and is e
w of $1,500
You think that the opportunity cost of capital
ws as follows:
PV 5
$500
$1,500
1
5 $1,776.86
(1.10)2
1.10
The project is w
gative NPV:
NPV 5 $1,776.86 2 $2,000 5 2$223.14
The project costs $2,000 today, but accountants would not treat that outlay as an
xpense. They would depreciate that $2,000 over 2 years and deduct the
w to obtain accounting income:
Cash inflow
Less depreciation
Accounting income
Year 1
Year 2
1$1,500
2 1,000
1 500
1$ 500
2 1,000
2 500
Thus an accountant would forecast income of $500 in year 1 and an accounting loss of
$500 in year 2.
Suppose you were giv
vely discounted them.
Now NPV looks positive:
NPV 5
spending mone
264
2$500
$500
1
5 $41.32
(1.10)2
1.10
w that this is nonsense. The project is ob
w), and we are simply getting our money
W
vesting our mone
et.
Chapter 9
265
Using Discounted Cash-Flow Analysis to Make Investment Decisions
The message of the example is this: When calculating NPV, recognize investment expenditures when they occur, not later when they show up as depreciation. Projects are financially attractive because of the cash they generate, either
for distribution to shareholders or for reinvestment in the firm. Therefore, the focus
of capital budgeting must be on cash flow, not profits.
We sa
w and accounting profits in Chapter 3.
compan
or example, an income
statement will recognize rev
v
months. This practice also results in a difference between accounting profits and cash
w.
w comes later.
▲
EXAMPLE 9.1
Sales before Cash
Your firm’s ace computer salesman closed a $500,000 sale on December 15, just in
time to count it toward his annual bonus. How did he do it? Well, for one thing he
gave the customer 180 days to pay. The income statement will recognize the sale
in December, even though cash will not arrive until June.
The accountant takes car
erence by adding $500,000 to
accounts receivable in December and then reducing accounts receivable when
the money arrives in June. (The total of accounts receivable is just the sum of all
cash due from customers.)
You can think of the increase in accounts receivable as an investment—it’s
ectively a 180-day loan to the customer—and therefore a cash outflow. That
investment is recovered when the customer pays. Thus f
en find
it convenient to calculate cash flow as follows:
December
Sales
Less investment in
accounts receivable
Cash flow
June
$500,000
2500,000
0
Sales
Plus recovery of
accounts receivable
Cash flow
0
1$500,000
$500,000
Note that this procedure gives the correct cash flow of $500,000 in June.
It is not alw
w
the dollars going out.
Self-Test 9.1
e away
266
Two
Value
Discount Incremental Cash Flows
A project’s present value depends on the extra
ws that it produces. So you need
Then forecast
ws if you don’t accept the project. T e the difference and you have the
extra (or incremental
ws produced by the project:
Incremental
▲
EXAMPLE 9.2
5
with project
2 without project
Launching a New Product
Consider the decision by Sony to develop Playstation 4. If successful, the PS4 could
lead to several billion dollars in profits.
But are these profits all incremental cash flows? Certainly not. Our with-versuswithout principle reminds us that we need also to think about what the cash flows
would be without the new system. By launching the new console, Sony will reduce
demand for Playstation 3. The incremental cash flows therefore are
Cash flow with PS4
(including lower cash flow)
from PS3)
2
The trick in capital b
project. Here are some things to look out for.
cash flow without PS4
(with higher cash flow
from PS3)
ws from a proposed
Include All Indirect Effects The decision to launch a ne
w products often damage sales of an existing product. Of
w products anyway, usually because they
believe that their e
en if you
don’t go ahead with a ne
xisting product line will continue at their present level. Sooner or later they will decline.
Sometimes a new project will help the f
s existing business. Suppose that you
inancial manager of an airline that is considering opening a new short-haul
s O’Hare
When considered in isolation, the new route may have a negative NPV. But once you allow for the additional
business that the ne
ery
w
vestment. To forecast incremental cash flow, you must trace out all
indir
ects of accepting the project.
Some capital investments have very long lives once all indirect ef
nized. Consider the introduction of a new jet engine. Engine manufacturers often offer
attractive pricing to achiev
Also, since airlines prefer to limit the
number of dif
ves sales
w model engine can
Forget Sunk Costs
The
versws. Sunk costs remain the same whether or not you accept the project.
Therefore, the
ect project NPV.
Unfortunately
velopment of the T
gued that it would be
foolish to abandon a project on which nearly $1 billion had already been spent. This
Chapter 9
267
Using Discounted Cash-Flow Analysis to Make Investment Decisions
w
gument, however, because the $1 billion was sunk. The relevant questions
were how much more needed to be inv
ranted the incremental investment.
pect of a satisf
This argument too was faulty. The $1
billion was gone, and the decision to continue with the project should have depended
vestment.
opportunity cost
Benefit or cash flow
forgone as a result of an
action.
Include Oppor tunity Costs Resources are almost never free, even when no
or example, suppose a ne
acturing operation uses land
This resource is costly; by using the land,
you pass up the opportunity to sell it. There is no out-of-pocket cost, but there is an
opportunity cost, that is, the v
gone alternative use of the land.
This example prompts us to w
ersus after”
rather than “with versus without.”
assign any v
wns it both before and after:
Before
Take Project
Firm owns land
Cash Flow,
Before versus
er
er
Firm still owns land
0
ersus without, is as follows:
Before
Take Project
Firm owns land
Before
Firm owns land
Cash Flow, with
Project
er
Firm still owns land
Do Not Take
Project
0
Cash Flow,
without Project
er
Firm sells land for $100,000
$100,000
ws with and without the project, you see that $100,000 is given
v
The oppor
ing the land now and therefore is a relevant cash flow for project evaluation.
et
price.1 However
you go ahead with a project to develop Computer Nouveau, pulling your software
team off their work on a new operating system that some e
so-patiently awaiting. The e
to calculate, but you’
ving the software
team to Computer Nouveau.
net working capital
Current assets minus
current liabilities.
Recognize the Investment in Working Capital Net working capital
working capital) is the difference between a company’s
short-term assets and its liabilities.
receivable (customers’ unpaid bills), and inventories of ra
inished
you have
es that
hav
ut have not yet been paid).
1
If the v
xceed the cost of buying an equiv
replace it.
268
Two
Value
Most projects entail an additional investment in w
or example,
vest in inventories of raw materials.
Then, when you deliv
accounts receiv
9.1. It required a $500,000, 6-month investment in accounts receivable.) Next year, as
business b
ger stock of ra
ve
even more unpaid bills. Investments in working capital, just like investments in
plant and equipment, r
lows.
W
ws.2 Here are the most common mistakes:
1. Forgetting about working capital entirely. We hope that you never fall into that trap.
2. Forgetting that working capital may change during the life of the project. Imagine
that you sell $100,000 of goods per year and customers pay on average 6 months
late. You will therefore have $50,000 of unpaid bills. Now you increase prices by
10%, so revenues increase to $110,000. If customers continue to pay 6 months late,
e an additional
investment in w
3. Forgetting that working capital is recovered at the end of the project.
comes to an end, inv
wn, an
ver your investment in w
This generates a cash
.
Remember Terminal Cash Flows The end of a project almost always
ws. For e
as dedicated to it. Also, as we just mentioned, you may
recover some of your investment in w
ventories of
vable.
xpenses to shutting down a project. For e
sioning costs of nuclear po
v
Similarly, when a mine is e
vironment may need rehabilitation.
ed ov
ver the future
closure and reclamation costs of its New Me
t forget to include these
ws.
Beware of Allocated Overhead Costs We hav
the accountant’s objectiv
ways the same as the project analyst’s. A case in point is the allocation of ov
.
v
ut they must be paid for
nev
s projects, a
charge for ov
ws says
v
extra expenses of the project.
A project may generate extra overhead costs, but then again it may not. We
should be cautious about assuming that the accountant’s allocation of overhead costs represents the incremental cash flow that would be incurred by
accepting the project.
Self-Test 9.2
2
w
why w
w, look back to Chapter 3, where we gav
xamples.
Chapter 9
Using Discounted Cash-Flow Analysis to Make Investment Decisions
269
Discount Nominal Cash Flows by the
Nominal Cost of Capital
Interest rates are usually quoted in nominal
of
es no promises about what that $106 will buy.
vest $100 in a bank deposit
. It
uy you only 4% more
goods at the end of the year than your $100 could buy today. The nominal rate of interest is 6%, but the real rate is about 4%.3
If the discount rate is nominal, consistenc
ws be estimated in
w
some slower. For example, perhaps you have entered into a 5-year fixed-price contract
with a supplier
v
ed in nominal terms.
ws at the real interWe sa
ws
discounted at the real discount rate give e
alues as nominal
ws discounted at the nominal rate.
It should go without saying that you cannot mix and match real and nominal
quantities. Real cash flows must be discounted at a real discount rate, nominal
cash flows at a nominal rate. Discounting real cash flows at a nominal rate is a
big mistake.
y may seem like an obvious point, analysts
sometimes forget to account for the ef
ws. As a result, the
This can grossly understate project values.
▲
EXAMPLE 9.3
Cash Flows and Inflation
vices is considering moving into a ne
ice building. The cost
of a 1-year lease is $8,000, paid immediately. This cost will increase in future years at
the annual inflation rate of 3%. The firm believes that it will remain in the building for
4 years. What is the present value of its rental costs if the discount rate is 10%?
The present value can be obtained by discounting the nominal cash flows at
the 10% discount rate as follows:
3
Remember from Chapter 5,
Real rate of interest < nom
2
The e
1 1 real rate interest 5
11
11
Therefore, the real interest rate is .0392, or 3.92%.
5
1.06
5 1.0392
1.02
270
Two
Value
Year
Cash Flow
0
1
2
3
8,000
8,000 3 1.03 5 8,240
8,000 3 1.032 5 8,487
8,000 3 1.033 5 8,742
Present Value at
10% Discount Rate
8,000
8,240/1.10 5
7,491
8,487/(1.10)2 5
7,014
8,742/(1.10)3 5 6,568
$29,073
Alternatively, the real discount rate can be calculated as 1.10/1.03 2 1 5 .06796 5
6.796%.4 The present value can then be computed by discounting the real cash
flows at the real discount rate as follows:
Year
Real Cash Flow
0
8,000
1
8,000
2
3
8,000
8,000
Present Value at
6.796% Discount Rate
8,000
8,000/1.06796
5
7,491
8,000/(1.06796) 5
7,014
2
3
8,000/(1.06796) 5
6,568
$29,073
Notice the real cash flow is a constant, since the lease payment increases at the rate
of inflation. The present value of each cash flow is the same regardless of the method
used to discount it. The sum of the present values is, of course, also identical.
Self-Test 9.3
Separate Investment and Financing Decisions
w should you treat the proceeds
from the debt issue and the interest and principal payments on the debt? Answer: You
should neither subtract the debt proceeds from the required investment nor recognize
ws. Regardless of the
actual financing, you should vie
ws as going to them.
This procedure focuses exclusively on the project
ws
ve financing schemes. It, therefore, allo
vestment decision from that of the financing decision. First, you ask
whether the project has a positive net present v
Then you can undertak
gy
xt.
4
W
void confusion from rounding. Such precision is
Chapter 9
Using Discounted Cash-Flow Analysis to Make Investment Decisions
271
9.2 Calculating Cash Flow
It is helpful to think of a project’
(9.1)
5
1
1
W
Capital Investment
To get a project off the ground, a compan
e considerable up-front
inv
eting, and so on. For example, development of a ne
volves e
This
e
gativ
w—negative because cash goes out the door.
y can either sell the
plant and equipment or redeploy the assets elsewhere in the business. This salvage
v
y taxes if the equipment is sold) represents a positiv
w to the
wever
ws can be negative if
wn costs.
▲
EXAMPLE 9.4
Cash Flow from Capital Investment
Slick Corporation plans to invest $800 million to develop the Mock4 razor blade.
The specialized blade factory will run for 7 years until it is replaced by more
advanced technology. At that point the machinery will be sold for $50 million.
Taxes of $10 million will be assessed on the sale.
The initial cash flow from Slick’s investment is 2$800 million. In year 7, when
the firm sells the land and equipment, there will be a net inflow of $50 million
2 $10 million 5 $40 million. Thus, the initial investment involves a negative cash
flow, and the salvage value results in a positive flow.
Operating Cash Flow
w consists of revenues from the sale of the new product less the costs of production
and any taxes:
5 revenues 2 costs 2
Undoubtedly, the revenues are expected to outweigh the costs, and therefore operating
ve.
Many investments do not result in additional revenues; they are simply designed to
reduce the costs of the company’s existing operations. For example, a new computer
system may provide labor savings, or a new heating system may be more energyef
ute to the operating cash
w of the f
venues but by reducing costs. These cost savings
therefore represent a positiv
w.
▲
EXAMPLE 9.5
Operating Cash Flow of Cost-Cutting Projects
Suppose a new heating system costs $100,000 but reduces heating costs by
$30,000 a year. The firm’s tax rate is 35%. The new system does not change rev
nues, but, thanks to the cost savings, income increases by $30,000. Therefore, incr
mental operating cash flow is:
272
Part Two Value
Increase in (revenues less expenses)
$30,000
2 Incremental tax at 35%
5 Operating cash flow
2 10,500
1$19,500
Notice that because the cost savings increase profits, the company must pay more
tax. The net increase in cash flo
er-tax cost savings:
(1 2 .35) 3 $30,000 5 $19,500
w.
es a deduction for depreciation.
ge is an accounting entry
y
pays, but it is not a cash expense and should not be deducted when calculating operatw. (Remember from our earlier discussion that you want to discount cash
When you work out a project’
with depreciation.
ays to deal
Method 1: Dollars In Minus Dollars Out Take only the items from the
ws.
cash revenues and subtract cash expenses and taxes paid. You do not, however, subtract a charge for depreciation because this does not involve cash going out the door.
Thus,
5 revenues 2 cash expenses 2 taxes
(9.2)
Method 2: Adjusted Accounting Profits
vely, you can start
with after-tax accounting profits and add back any depreciation deduction. This
gives
5
1 depreciation
(9.3)
Method 3: Add Back Depreciation Tax Shield Although the depreciation deduction is not a cash e
s tax payment, which cer-
s tax bracket is 35%, tax payments f
depreciation tax shield
Reduction in taxes
attributable to
depreciation.
w
ving as the
depreciation tax shield. It equals the product of the tax rate and the depreciation
charge:
Depreciation tax shield 5 tax rate 3 depreciation
This suggests a third w
w. First, calculate net profit,
assuming zero depreciation. This is equal to (revenues 2 cash expenses) 3 (1 2 tax
rate). No
w:
5 (revenues 2 cash expenses) 3 (1 2
1 (tax rate 3 depreciation)
The following e
w.
v
)
(9.4)
Chapter 9
▲
EXAMPLE 9.6
Using Discounted Cash-Flow Analysis to Make Investment Decisions
273
Operating Cash Flow
A project generates revenues of $1,000, cash expenses of $600, and depreciation
charges of $200 in a particular year. The firm’s tax bracket is 35%. Net income is
calculated as follows:
Revenues
2 Cash expenses
2 Depreciation expense
5 Profit before tax
2 Tax at 35%
5 Net profit
1,000
600
200
200
70
130
Methods 1, 2, and 3 all show that operating cash flow is $330:
Method 1: Operating cash flow 5 revenues 2 cash expenses 2 taxes
5 1,000 1 600 2 70 5 330
Method 2: Operating cash flow 5 net profit 1 depreciation
5 130 1 200 5 330
Method 3: Operating cash flow 5 (revenues 2 cash expenses)
3 (1 2 tax rate) 1 (depreciation 3 tax rate)
5 (1,000 2 600) 3 (1 2 .35) 1 (200 3 .35) 5 330
Self-Test 9.4
Changes in Working Capital
W
y builds up inv
w
y’s cash is reduced; the reduction in cash
irm’s investment in inv
, cash is reduced when customw to pay their bills—in this case, the f
vestment in accounts
receivable. Investment in working capital, just like investment in plant and equipment,
represents a negativ
w. On the other hand, later in the life of a project, when
inv
f and accounts receiv
s investment in
w
verts these assets into cash.
▲
EXAMPLE 9.7
Cash Flow from Changes in Working Capital
Slick makes an initial (year 0) investment of $10 million in inventories of plastic and
steel for its blade plant. Then in year 1 it accumulates an additional $20 million of
raw materials. The total level of inventories is now $10 million 1 $20 million 5 $30
million, but the cash expenditure in year 1 is simply the $20 million addition to inventory. The $20 million investment in additional inventory results in a cash flow of 2 $20
million. Notice that the increase in working capital is an investment in the project.
Like other investments, a buildup of working capital requires cash. Increases in the
level of working capital therefore show up as negative cash flows.
Later on, say, in year 5, the company begins planning for the next-generation
blade. At this point, it decides to reduce its inventory of raw material from $30
274
Two
Value
million to $25 million. This reduction in inventory investment frees up $5 million of
cash, which is a positive cash flow. Therefore, the cash flows from inventory investment are 2$10 million in year 0, 2$20 million in year 1, and 1$5 million in year 5.
These calculations can be summarized in a simple table, as follows:
Year:
0
1
2
3
4
5
1. Total working capital, year-end ($ million)
2. Change in working capital ($ million)
3. Cash flow from changes in working capital
10
10
210
30
20
220
30
0
0
30
0
0
30
0
0
25
25
15
In years 0 and 1, there is a net investment in working capital (line 2), corresponding
to a negative cash flow (line 3), and an increase in the level of total working capital
(line 1). In years 2 to 4, there is no investment in working capital, so its level remains
unchanged at $30 million. But in year 5, the firm begins to disinvest in working capital, which provides a positive cash flow.
In general: An increase in working capital is an investment and therefore
implies a negative cash flow; a decrease in working capital implies a positive
cash flow. The cash flow is measured by the change in working capital, not the
level of working capital.
9.3 An Example: Blooper Industries
No
ve e
them together into a coherent whole. As the ne
ven the forecasts shown in the
deposit of high-grade magnoosium ore.5 Y
spreadsheet in Table 9.1. We will walk through the lines in the table.
Cash-Flow Analysis
Investment in Fixed Assets P
assumptions. Panel B details investments and disinv
ed assets. The project requires an initial investment of $10 million, as shown in cell B14. After 5 years,
the ore deposit is e
When you sell the equipment, the IRS will check to see whether any taxes are due
on the sale. Any dif
alue of
the equipment will be treated as a taxable gain.
W
alue of zero. Therefore, the book v
will be subject to taxes on the full $2 million proceeds. Your sale of the equipment will
land you with an additional tax bill in year 6 of .35 3 $2
5 $.70
The
Salvage value 2 tax on gain 5
2 $.70 million 5 $1.30 million
This amount is recorded in cell H15.
5
Readers hav
stool.” We forget the company, but the blooper really happened.
w
acts: Magnoosium was
w by saying,
Chapter 9
Using Discounted Cash-Flow Analysis to Make Investment Decisions
TABLE 9.1
Financial projections f
275
s magnoosium mine (figures in thousands
of dollars)
You can find this spreadsheet at
.mhhe.com/bmm7e.
Ro
ws from inv
The entry in each cell equals the after-tax proceeds from asset sales (ro
inv
ed assets (row 14).
Operating Cash Flow
ed assets.
y expects to be able to sell 750,000 pounds
venues
of 750,000 3 $20 5
venues by 5%.
5%, and so on. Row 19 in Table 9.1 shows rev
The sales forecasts in Table 9.1
straight-line depreciation
Constant depreciation
for each year of the
asset’s accounting life.
v
That makes sense if the ore
should include them in your forecasts. We hav
agers who assume a project life of (say) 5 years, even when the
xpect
rev
When ask
y explain that forecasting
beyond 5 years is too hazardous. We sympathize, but you just have to do your best. Do
s life.
We assume that the expenses of mining
and refining (ro
.
We also assume for now that the company applies straight-line depreciation to the
ver 5 years.
276
Two
Value
million inv
deduction is $2 million.
Pretax profit, shown in ro
(ro
Thus row 21 shows that the annual depreciation
venues 2 expenses 2 depreciation). Taxes
or e
Tax 5 .35 3 3,000 5 1,050, or $1,050,000
Profit after tax (ro
The last ro
sum of after
sum of rows 24 and 21.
Changes in Working Capital
es.
w. W
w as the
ve). Therefore, row 25 is the
Row 28 shows the level of w
ut later in the
project’s life, the investment in working capital is recovered and the level declines.
Row 29 shows the change in w
1 to 4 the change is positiv
vestment in w
gative; there is a disinvestment as w
v
w associated with investments in
w
w 30) is the negative of the change in working capital. Just like
investment in plant and equipment, investment in w
gative
w, and disinvestment produces a positiv
w.
Total Project Cash Flow T
w from inv
w.
16, 25, and 30.
ws from each
ed assets and working capital,
w in row 33 is just the sum of rows
Calculating the NPV of Blooper’s Project
You have no
ved (in ro
ws from Blooper’s magnoosium
mine. Suppose that investors expect a return of 12% from investments in the capital
This is the opportunity cost of
the shareholders’ money that Blooper is proposing to invest in the project. Therefore,
to calculate NPV
ws at 12%.
Ro
v
t you can di
w by (1 1 r)t or you can mult
tiply by a discount factor that is equal to 1/(1 1 r) . Row 34 presents the discount factors for each year, and row 35 calculates the present v
w by
w (row 33) times the discount factor.
ws are
discounted and added up, the magnoosium project is seen to offer a positive net present v
Now here is a small point that often causes confusion: To calculate the present
v
w, we divide by (1 1 r) 5
es sense only if all the sales and all the costs occur exactly 365 days, zero hours,
w
s sales don’
e place on the
stroke of midnight on December 31. However
udgeting deciws occur at 1-year interv
They pretend this for one reason only—simplicity.
sometimes little more than intelligent guesses, it may be pointless to inquire how the
sales are lik
.6
6
of June.
v
v
.
late in the year, as the holiday season approaches.
v
ws are distributed ev
w comes
Chapter 9
277
Using Discounted Cash-Flow Analysis to Make Investment Decisions
Further Notes and Wrinkles Arising
from Blooper’s Project
Before we leave Blooper and its magnoosium project, we should cover a few extra
wrinkles.
Forecasting Working Capital
magnoosium mine to produce rev
But Blooper will not actually receiv
Table 9.1 shows that Blooper expects its
. We have assumed that, on average, customers pay with a 2-month lag, so that 2/12 of each year’
follo
. These unpaid bills show up as accounts receivable. For example, in
year 1 Blooper will have accounts receivable of (2/12) 3 15,000 5 $2,500.7
Consider now the mine’s expenses.
Blooper must produce the magnoosium before selling it. Each year, Blooper mines
magnoosium ore, b
. The ore is
put into inv
, and the accountant does not deduct the cost of its production until it
is taken out of inv
W
s expenses represent an investment in inv
. Thus the investment in inv
3 10,000 5 $1,500 in year 0 and at
.15 3 $10,500 5 $1,575 in year 1.
We can now see ho
ves at its forecast of w
0
1
2
3
4
5
1. Receivables (2/12 3 revenues) $
0 $2,500 $2,625 $2,756 $2,894 $3,039
2. Inventories (.15 3 following
year’s expenses)
1,500 1,575 1,654 1,736 1,823
0
3. Working capital (1 1 2)
1,500 4,075 4,279 4,493 4,717 3,039
6
0
0
0
Note: Columns may not sum due to rounding.
Notice that w
Y
ye
receivables also fall to zero.
e
uilds up in years 1 to 4, as sales of magnoosium increase.
v
.
w. For
ferent assumptions for w
capital. For example, you can adjust the level of receivables and inventories by changing the values in cells B8 and B9.
A Fur ther Note on Depreciation We w
ws are lik
The depreciation tax shield is a case
in point, because the Internal Revenue Service lets companies depreciate only the
amount of the original investment. For example, if you go back to the IRS to explain
vestment and you should be allowed
on’t listen. The nominal
ed,
wer the real value of the depreciation that you can claim.
W
vestment in
mining equipment by $2 million a year. That produced an annual tax shield of
7
For conv
s customers pay with a lag, Blooper pays all its bills on
ould be recorded as accounts payable. Working capital would be
278
Part Two Value
TABLE 9.2
Tax
depreciation allowed under
the modified accelerated
cost recovery system
(figures in percent of
depreciable investment)
Notes:
1. T
eciation is lower in the first year because assets are assumed to be in service for 6 months.
2. Real property is depreciated straight-line over 27.5 years for residential property and 39 y
or nonresidential
property.
modified accelerated cost
recovery system (MACRS)
Depreciation method
that allows higher tax
deductions in early
years and lower
deductions later.
$2 million 3 .35 5 $.70 million per year for 5 years. These tax shields increase cash
ws from operations and therefore increase present value. So if Blooper could get
those tax shields sooner
y would be w
tions, tax law allows them to do just that. It allows accelerated depreciation.
wn as the
ecovery system, or MACRS. MACRS places assets into
one of six classes, each of which has an assumed life. Table 9.2 shows the rate of
depreciation that the company can use for each of these classes. Most industrial equipment falls into the 5- and 7-year classes. To keep life simple, we will assume that all of
Blooper’
Thus Blooper can depreciate
v
tion of .32 3 10 5 $3.2 million, and so on.8
How does MA
the magnoosium project? Table 9.3 gives the answer. Notice that MACRS does not
as before. But MACRS allo
,
which increases the present value of the depreciation tax shield from $2,523,000 to
$2,583,000, an increase of $60,000. Before we recognized MACRS depreciation, we
calculated project NPV as $4,223,000. When we recognize MACRS, we should
eep two sets of books, one for stockvenue Service. It is common to use straight-line
CRS depreciation on the tax books.
Only the tax books are relevant in capital budgeting.
8
You might w
.
also explains why the depreciation allowance is lo
This is
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
MidAmerican’s Wind Power Project
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
TABLE 9.3
The switch from straight-line t
ear MACRS depreciation increases the value of Blooper’s depreciation tax
shield from $2,523,000 to $2,583,000 (figures in thousands of dollars).
Note: Column sums subject to rounding error.
Self-Test 9.5
es on the
More on Salvage Value
difference between the sales price and the book value of the asset. The book value in
ve charges for depreciation. It is common
when figuring tax depreciation to assume a salvage value of zero at the end of the
asset’s depreciable life.
F
wever, positive expected salvage v
recognized. For e
vestment in mining equipment would be w
ould be based on the difference
between the investment and the salvage value, that is, $8 million. Straight-line depreciation then would be $1.6 million annually.
279
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
The Blooper Spreadsheet Model
Spreadsheet Questions
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
finance.yahoo.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO SPREADSHEET QUESTIONS
MINICASE
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
TABLE 9.4
CHAPTER
10
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T T W O
Value
When undertaking capital investments, good managers maintain maximum flexibility.
I
292
Two
Value
10.1 How Firms Organize the Investment Process
In the pre
w to evaluate a proposed investment such as the
w forecasts don’t fall
. Promising inv
ve to be identified, and they must
s strategic goals. To evaluate these opportunities properly
w forecasts that have not been skewed to “sell” a
project to upper management. Lar
facilitate effective communication across dif
F
vestments are evaluated in two separate stages.
Stage 1: The Capital Budget
capital budget
List of planned
investment projects.
Once a year, the head of
list of the investments that they would like to make.1
a proposed capital budget.
This budget is then revie
visions and plants to provide a
f specialgotiations between the
visional management, and there may also be special analyses of major outlays or ventures into ne
udget has been
approved, it generally remains the basis for planning over the ensuing year.
Many investment proposals bubble up from the bottom of the organization. But
sometimes the ideas are likely to come from higher up. For example, the managers of
plants A and B cannot be e
w plant C. We expect divisional management to
, divisions 1 and 2 may not be eager to give up their own
data processing operations to a large central computer. That proposal would come
s
strate
forts in areas
where it has a real competitive advantage.
fort, management must also
identify declining businesses that should be sold or allowed to run down.
s capital inv
do
udgeting and strategic planning, respectively. The two processes should complement each other
vision managers, who do most of
the work in bottom-up capital budgeting, may not see the forest for the trees. Strategic
planners may hav
en view of the forest because they do not look at the trees.
Stage 2: Project Authorizations
The annual b
ws everybody to exchange ideas before
attitudes hav
ve been made. However, the fact
that your pet project has been included in the annual budget doesn’t mean you have
At a later stage you will need to draw up a detailed
w forecasts, and present value calculations. If your project is large, this proposal may have to
ved.
category. For e
wn:
1. Outlays required by law or company policy, for example, for pollution control
equipment.
The main
1
plants.
vided into several divisions. For e
, packaging, and forest products. Each of these divisions may be responsible for a number of
Chapter 10
293
Project Analysis
west possible cost. The decision
is therefore lik
ve technologies.
2. Maintenance or cost reduction, such as machine replacement. Engineering analysis
ut new machines have to pay their own
way. Here the f
aces the classical capital budgeting problems described in
Chapters 8 and 9.
3.
xpansion in existing businesses. Projects in this category are less
in technology, and the reactions of competitors.
4. Investment for new products. Projects in this cate
ely to depend on
gic decisions.
w area may not have positive NPVs if
considered in isolation, but they may giv
aluable option to undertake
follow-up projects. More about this later in the chapter.
Problems and Some Solutions
Valuing capital inv
wever
brings with it some challenges.
udgeting is a cooperative ef
Ensuring That Forecasts Are Consistent Inconsistent assumptions often
creep into investment proposals. For example, suppose that the manager of the furniture
division is b
vivision look more attractive than those of the appliance division.
To ensure consistency, man
gin the capital budgeting process by establishwth in national
s busiThese forecasts can then be
Eliminating Conflicts of Interest In Chapter 1 we pointed out that while
managers w
y are also concerned about their own futures. If the
ely to be poor
investment decisions. For example, new plant managers naturally want to demonstrate
good performance right away. So they might propose quick-payback projects even if
, man
w
agers in ways that encourage such behavior
ways demands quick results,
it is unlikely that plant managers will concentrate only on NPV.
Reducing Forecast Bias Someone who is keen to get a project proposal
accepted is also lik
s cash
ws. Such ov
or example,
think of large public expenditure proposals. How often hav
w missile, dam, or highway that actually cost less than w
Think back
to the Eurotunnel project introduced in Chapter 8.
as f
higher than initial forecasts. Overoptimism is not altogether bad. Psychologists stress
tence.
for each project.
Sometimes a head of
verstate
their case. For example, if middle managers believe that success depends on having
gest di
y will propose large expansion projects that they do not believe have the largest possible net present value. Or if
divisions must compete for limited resources, the
294
Two
Value
those resources. The fault in such cases is top management’s—if lower-lev
are not rew
alue and contrib
alue, it
where.
v
avorite
projects. As the proposal travels up the or
Thus once
a division has screened its own plants’ proposals, the plants in that division unite in
competing against outsiders.
ice may receive several
thousand investment proposals each year, all essentially sales documents presented by
united fronts and designed to persuade. The forecasts have been doctored to ensure
ve.
Since it is dif
v
an investment proposal, capital inv
vely decentralized
whatev
f to check
capital investment proposals.
Sor ting the Wheat from the Chaff
Senior managers are continually bom-
wing that the projects have positive NPVs. How then
can managers ensure that only w
e the grade? One response of
senior managers to this problem of poor information is to impose rigid e
vidual plants or divisions. These limits force the subunits to choose
The f
2
tainable but as a w
Senior managers might also ask some searching questions about why the project
has a positive NPV. After all, if the project is so attractive, why hasn’t someone already
undertaken it? W
itable? Positiv
sible only if your company has some competitive advantage.
Such an advantage can arise in several ways. Y
y enough to
et with a new or improved product for which customers will pay
Your competitors eventually will enter the market and squeeze out
excess profits, b
e them sev
ve a propriantage that competitors cannot easily match.
You may have a contractual advantage such as the distrib
region. Or your advantage may be as simple as a good reputation and an established
customer list.
Analyzing competitive adv
ve a negative NPV. If you are the lo
product in a growing market, then you should invest to e
et.
w a negativ
have made a
e.
10.2 Some “What-If” Questions
“What-if ” questions ask what will happen to a project in v
or
example, what will happen if the economy enters a recession? What if a competitor
enters the market? What if costs turn out to be higher than anticipated?
You might wonder why one w
or instance,
suppose your project seems to have a positiv
vailable forecasts,
in which you have already f
ve and negative surWon’
later don’t work out as you had hoped, that is too bad, but you don’t hav
2
W
Chapter 10
Project Analysis
295
In fact, what-if analysis is crucial to capital b
w
estimates are just that—estimates. You often have the opportunity to improve on those
or example,
if you wish to improve the precision of an estimate of the demand for a product, you
v
vel
production process. But ho
w when to k
where it is best to dev
What-if analysis can help identify the inputs
that are most worth refining before you commit to a project. These will be the ones
that have the greatest potential to alter project NPV.
Moreover
e
w
ws roll in.
w
where to undertake contingenc
Sensitivity Analysis
sensitivity analysis
ects on
project profit
changes in sales, costs,
and so on.
fixed costs
Costs that do not
depend on the level of
output.
variable costs
Costs that change as
the level of output
changes.
TABLE 10.1 Cash-flow
forecasts for Finef
s
superstore
You can find this spreadsheet at
.mhhe.com/bmm7e.
Uncertainty means that more things can happen than will happen. Therefore, whenever
managers are giv
w forecast, the
and the implications of those possible events.
sensitivity analysis.
w superstore in Gravenstein, and your staff members hav
wn in Table 10.1. To keep
the example simple we hav
We have also assumed that the
entire inv
ve neglected
the w
ve ignored the fact that at the end of the
12 years you could sell off the land and buildings.
et are fixed. For e
the level of output, you still hav
.
These
costs
.
Other costs v
v
, the lower the sales, the less
food you need to buy.
number of checkouts and reduce the staff needed to restock the shelves. The new
superstore’s v
Thus variable costs
5 .8125 3
5
The initial inv
ov
are taxed at a rate of 40%.
296
TABLE 10.2
Two
Value
Sensitivity analysis for superstore project
Given these inputs, we add after
w in
As an e
, you recws constitute an annuity, and therefore you
calculate the 12-year annuity factor at a discount rate of 8% (cell C14). The net present
v
NPV 5 2$5,400,000 1 $780,000 3 12-year annuity factor 5 $478,141
ve net present value. Before
you agree to go ahead, however, you want to delve behind these forecasts and identify
the key v
ails.
You seem to hav
en account of the important factors that will determine success
or failure, but look out for things you may have forgotten. Perhaps there will be delays
e costly landscaping.
unknown unkno
” as
scientists call them.
Having found no unk-unks (no doubt you’
w NPV
may be affected if you have made a wrong forecast of sales, costs, and so on. To do
Table 10.2.
Next you see what happens to NPV under the optimistic or pessimistic forecasts for
each of these v
You recalculate project NPV under these v
determine which v
.
▲
EXAMPLE 10.1
Sensitivity Analysis
The right-hand side of Table 10.2 shows the project’s net present value if the variables are set one at a time to their optimistic and pessimistic values. For example,
suppose fixed costs are $1.9 million rather than the forecast $2 million. To find NPV
in this case, we simply substitute $1,900,000 in cell C5 of the spreadsheet, and discover that NPV rises to $930,306, a gain of approximately $452,000. The other entries
in the three columns on the right in Table 10.2 similarly show how the NPV of the
project changes when an input is changed.
Your project is by no means a sure thing. The principal uncertainties appear to
be sales and variable costs. For example, if sales are only $14 million rather than
the forecast $16 million (and all other forecasts are unchanged), then the project
has an NPV of 2$1.217 million. If variable costs are 83% of sales (and all other forecasts are unchanged), then the project has an NPV of 2$787,920.
Self-Test 10.1
Chapter 10
Project Analysis
297
Value of Information No
w the project could be thrown badly
of
e to see whether it is possible to
resolve some of this uncertainty. Perhaps your w
ail to attract
wns. In that case, additional survey data and
vel times may be worthwhile.
On the other hand, there is less value to gathering additional information about
ed costs. Because the project is marginally profitable ev
ed costs, you are unlikely to be in trouble if you hav
mated that variable.
Limits to Sensitivity Analysis Y
fodder’s
new superstore is an example of sensitivity analysis. Sensitivity analysis expresses
wn variables and then calculates the consequences of
misestimating those v
actors,
ould be most useful, and helps to expose confused or inappropriate forecasts.
Of course, there is no law stating which v
sitivity analysis. For e
rate tax rate, you may wish to look at the ef
s NPV.
One drawback to sensiti
ves somewhat ambiguous results.
For example, what exactly does optimistic or pessimistic
ferent way from another. T
w, after
hundreds of projects, hindsight may sho
as
exceeded twice as often as the other’s; but hindsight won’t help you now while you’re
making the investment decision.
Another problem with sensiti
ely
or example, if sales exceed expectations, demand will likely be
stronger than you anticipated and your profit margins will be wider. Or, if wages are
higher than your forecast, both v
ely to be at the
upper end of your range.
Because of these connections, you cannot push one-at-a-time sensitivity analysis
too f
alues for total project
ws from the information in Table 10.2. Still, it does give a sense of which variables should be most closely monitored.
Scenario Analysis
scenario analysis
Project analysis given a
particular combination
of assumptions.
simulation analysis
Estimation of the
pr
erent
possible outcomes, e.g.,
from an investment
project.
w their
project would fare under dif
Scenario analysis allows them to look at
ut consistent combinations of v
orecasters generally prefer to give
an estimate of rev
ve some
alue.
Suppose that you are w
f (S&S) may decide to build a new
That would reduce sales in your Gravenstein store by 15%,
ar to keep the remaining b
be reduced to the point that v
venue. Table 10.3 shows that
both lo
gins your new venture would
no longer be w
A bit more research into S&S’
called for.
An e
simulation analysis. Here, instead of
specifying a relativ
veral hunutions specified by the analyst. Each combination of v
298
Part Two Value
TABLE 10.3 Scenario
analysis comparing NPV of
superstore with and without
competing store
You can find this spreadsheet at
.mhhe.com/bmm7e.
combination of v
ution of outcomes can be
Self-Test 10.2
10.3 Break-Even Analysis
break-even analysis
Analysis of the level of
sales at which the
project breaks even.
e a sensitivity analysis of a project or when you look at alternative
ould be if you hav
w far off the
estimates could be before the project begins to lose money. This ex
wn as
break-even analysis.
For many projects, the make-or-break v
olume. Therefore, managers
most often focus on the break-even level of sales. However, you might also look at other
v
ay. Most often,
the break-ev
,
however
alue. W
ing break-even, show that it can lead you astray, and then show how NPV break-even
can be used as an alternative.
Accounting Break-Even Analysis
The accounting break-even point is the level of sales at which prof
equivalently
venues equal total costs. As we hav
fixed regardless of the level of output. Other costs vary with the level of output.
,
wing
estimates:
Sales
Variable costs
Fixed costs
Depreciation
$16
million
13
million
2
million
0.45 million
Chapter 10
Project Analysis
299
TABLE 10.4 Income
statement, break-even sales
volume
Notice that variable costs are 81.25% of sales. So for each additional dollar of sales,
costs increase by only $.8125. We can easily determine how much business the supervoid losses. If the store sells nothing, the income statement
will sho
ed costs of $2 million and depreciation of $450,000. Thus there will be an
accounting loss before tax of $2.45 million. Each dollar of sales reduces this loss by
$1.00 2 $.8125 5 $.1875. Therefore, to cov
ed costs plus depreciation, you need
sales of 2.45
5 $13.067 million. At this sales lev
even. More generally,
fixed costs
including depreciation
(10.1)
Break-even level of revenues 5
additional profit
from each additional dollar of sales
Table 10.4 sho
Figure 10.1 shows ho
ven point is determined. The blue 45-degree line
shows the store’s accounting revenues. The dashed cost line shows how costs v
with sales. If the store doesn’
ed costs and depreciation
amounting to $2.45 million. Each e
When sales are $13.067 million, the two lines cross, indicating that costs equal revenues. For lower sales, revenues are less than costs and the project is in the red; for
venues e
v
Is a project that breaks even in accounting terms an acceptable investment? If you
, here’s a possibly easier question: Would you be happy
about an inv
v
We hope not. Y
ven on such a stock, but a zero return does not compensate you for the time value of money or the risk that you have taken.
FIGURE 10.1
Accounting
break-even analysis
300
Part Two Value
A project that simply breaks even on an accounting basis gives you your money
back but does not cover the oppor
al tied up in the project.
A project that breaks even in accounting terms will surely have a negative NPV.
Let’s check this with the superstore project. Suppose that in each year the store has
sales of $13.067 million—just enough to break ev
What
w
w?
Operating cash
5 profit after tax 1 depreciation
5 0 1 $450,000 5 $450,000
The initial investment is $5.4 million. In each of the ne
y back:
ves a
Total operating cash
5 initial investment
12 3 $450,000 5 $5.4 million
But revenues are not suf
ment. NPV is negative.
of that $5.4 million invest-
NPV Break-Even Analysis
A manager who calculates an accounting-based measure of break-even may be
tempted to think that an
igure will help shareholders. But projects that break ev
y
ailing to cover the costs of capital employed. Managers who accept such projects
NPV break-even point
Level of sales at which
project net present
value becomes positive.
produce an accounting profit, it is more useful to focus on the point at which NPV
switches from negative to positive.
NPV break-even point.
ws of the superstore project in each year will depend on sales as
follows:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
Variable costs
Fixed costs
Depreciation
Pretax profit
Tax (at 40%)
Profi
er tax
Cash flow (3 1 6)
81.25% of sales
$2 million
$450,000
(.1875 3 sales) 2 $2.45 million
.40 3 (.1875 3 sales 2 $2.45 million)
.60 3 (.1875 3 sales 2 $2.45 million)
$450,000 1 .6 3 (.1875 3 sales 2 $2.45 million)
5 .1125 3 sales 2 $1.02 million
12-year annuity factor. With a discount rate of 8%, the present value of $1 a year for
each of 12 years is $7.536. Thus the present v
ws is
PV(
) 5 7.536 3 (.1125 3 sales 2
The project breaks even in present v
ent v
break-even occurs when
)
vestment. Therefore,
) 5 investment
PV(
7.536 3 (.1125 3 sales 2 $1.02 million) 5 $5.4 million
.8478 3 sales 2
5 $5.4 million
Sales 5 (5.4 1 7.69) /.8478 5 $15.4 million
vestment to have a zero
NPV.
Figure 10.2 is a plot of the present v
ws from the superstore as a function of annual sales. The two lines cross when sales are $15.4 million.
Chapter 10
FIGURE 10.2
301
Project Analysis
NPV break-
even analysis
This is the point at which the project has zero NPV. As long as sales are greater than
this, the present v
ws exceeds the present v
ws and the
project has a positive NPV.3
Self-Test 10.3
▲
EXAMPLE 10.2
Break-Even Analysis
We have said that projects that break even on an accounting basis are really making a loss—they are losing the oppor
vestment. Here is a dramatic example. Lophead Aviation is contemplating investment in a new passenger
aircraft, code-named the Trinova. Lophead’s financial st
ed together
the following estimates:
1. The cost of developing the Trinova is forecast at $900 million, and this investment
can be depreciated in six equal annual amounts.
2. Production of the plane is expected to take place at a steady annual rate over
the following 6 years.
3. The average price of the Trinova is expected to be $15.5 million.
4. Fixed costs are forecast at $175 million a year.
5. Variable costs are forecast at $8.5 million a plane.
6. The tax rate is 50%.
7. The cost of capital is 10%.
Lophead’s financial manager has used this information to construct a forecast
of the profitability of the Trinova program. This is shown in rows 1 to 7 of Table 10.5
(ignore row 8 for a moment).
How many aircr
ophead need to sell to break even? The answer
depends on what is meant by “break even.” In accounting terms the venture will
break even when net profit (row 7 in the table) is zero. In this case,
(3.5 3 planes sold) 2 162.5 5 0
Planes sold 5 162.5/3.5 5 46.4
3
present value basis will have a positiv
just cover all
alue added (EVA) in Chapter 4.
ven on a
ut zero economic value added. In other words, it will
302
Two
Value
TABLE 10.5 Forecast
profit
or production
of the Trinova airliner
(figures in millions of dollars)
Thus Lophead needs to sell about 46 planes a year, or a total of 280 planes over the
6 years to show a profit. With a price of $15.5 million a plane, Lophead will break even
in accounting terms with annual revenues of 46.4 3 $15.5 million 5 $719 million.
We would have arrived at the same answer if we had used our formula to calculate the break-even level of revenues. Notice that the variable cost of each plane is
$8.5 million, which is 54.8% of the $15.5 million sale price. Therefore, each dollar of
sales increases pretax profits by $1 2 $.548 5 $.452. Now we use the formula for the
accounting break-even point:
Break-even revenues 5
5
fixed costs including depreciation
additional profit from each additional dollar of sales
$325 million
5 $719 million
.452
If Lophead sells about 46 planes a year, it will recover its original investment,
but it will not earn any return on the capital tied up in the project. Companies
that earn a zero return on their capital can expect some unhappy shareholders. Shareholders will be content only if the company’s investments earn at least
the cost of the capital invested. True break-even occurs when the projects have
zero NPV.
How many planes must Lophead sell to break even in terms of net present value?
Development of the Trinova costs $900 million. If the cost of capital is 10%, the 6-year
ann
actor is 4.3553. The last row of Table 10.5 shows that net cash flow (in millions of dollars) in years 1–6 equals (3.5 3 planes sold 2 12.5). We can now find the
annual plane sales necessary to break even in terms of NPV:
4.3553(3.5 3 planes sold 2 12.5) 5 900
15.2436 3 planes sold 2 54.44 5 900
Planes sold 5 954.44/15.2436 5 62.6
Thus, while Lophead will break even in terms of accounting profits with sales of 46.4
planes a year (about 280 in total), it needs to sell 62.6 a year (or about 375 in total)
to recover the opportunity cost of the capital invested in the project and break
even in terms of NPV.
Our e
anciful, but it is based loosely on reality. In 1971 Lockheed w
T
.
This program w
ailure, and it tipped Rolls-Royce
(supplier of the T
v
ving evidence to Congress, Lockheed argued that the T
ve and that sales would
eventually exceed the break-even point of about 200 aircraft. But in calculating this
break-ev
v
Chapter 10
303
Project Analysis
capital inv
to reach a zero net present value.4
Self-Test 10.4
Operating Leverage
A project’s break-even point depends on both its
costs, which do not v
sales, and the profit on each extra sale. Managers often face a trade-off between these
v
or e
ed costs. But superet companies sometimes rent stores with contingent rent agreements. This means
that the amount of rent the company pays is tied to the level of sales from the store.
alls along with sales. The store thus replaces a fixed cost with a variable cost that is link
y’s
expenses will fall when its sales fall, its break-even point is reduced.
ed costs is not all bad. The f
gely fixed f
w, b
operating leverage
Degree to which costs
are fixed.
degree of operating
leverage (DOL)
Percentage change in
profits given a 1%
change in sales.
Finefodder has a polic
yees who will not be laid off
except in the most dire circumstances. F
val, Stop and Scof
uses expensiv
ver demand requires e
A greater proxpenses are therefore v
Suppose that if Finefodder adopted its rival’s policy
ed costs in its new superstore would f
ut variable costs would rise from
81.25% to 84% of sales. Table 10.6 sho
vel of sales, the two
policies fare equally
its costs fall along with revenue. In a boom the reverse is true, and the store with the
ed costs has the advantage.
If Finefodder follo
y of hiring long-term employees, each e
2 $.8125 5 $.1875. If it uses tempo, an extra dollar of sales increases profits by only $1.00 2 $.84 5 $.16. As a
ve high operating leverage. High
operating lev
We can measure a business’s operating lev
for each 1% change in sales. The degree of operating leverage, often abbreviated as
DOL, is this measure:
DOL 5
percentage change in profits
percentage change in sales
(10.2)
TABLE 10.6 A store with
high operating leverage
orms relatively badly in a
slump but flourishes in a
boom (figures in thousands
of dollars).
4
sT
ven point for the T
Application of Financial
en
,” Journal of Finance 28 (September 1973), pp. 821–838.
304
Part Two Value
For example, Table 10.6 shows that as the store mov
y with high
Therefore,
DOL 5
102.2
5 5.45
18.75
The percentage change in sales is magnified more than fivefold in terms of the percentage impact on profits.
Now look at the operating leverage of the store if it uses the policy with lo
ed
costs but high v
As the store moves from normal times to boom, profits
Therefore,
DOL 5
87.3
5 4.65
18.75
ge percentage
ut the degree of operating leverage is lower.
In fact, one can show that degree of operating leverage depends on fixed charges
(including depreciation) in the following manner:5
DOL 5 1 1
▲
EXAMPLE 10.3
fixed costs
profits
(10.3)
Operating Leverage
Suppose the firm adopts the high-fixed-cost policy. Then fixed costs including
depreciation will be 2.00 1 .45 5 $2.45 million. Since the store produces profits of
$.55 million at a normal level of sales, DOL should be
DOL 5 1 1
fixed costs
2.45
511
5 5.45
profits
.55
This value matches the one we obtained by comparing the actual percentage
changes in sales and profits.
Some companies hav
Table 10.7, which shows the av
ple of lar
A 1% change in sales has on av
ed costs than others. Look, for example, at
ve relativ
ve lo
ed costs.
ed costs.
6
5
ved as follo
its will increase by .01 3 (sales 2 v
DOL 5
percentage change in sales
5 100 3
change in profits
level of profits
5
5 100 3
costs) 5 .01 3 (profits 1
ed costs). Now
/level of profits
.01
.01 3 (profits 1 fixed costs)
level of profits
fixed costs
511
profits
6
Y
reason for this conclusion.
ery low v
ed costs) but use f
f
xhibiting low operating leverage. But there is a good
wer, which have very
wer to be brought online
xpensive to b
wer
xpensive energy sources (with high v
acilities.
Chapter 10
Project Analysis
305
TABLE 10.7 Estimated
degree of operating leverage
(DOL) for large U.S.
companies b
Note: DOL is measured as the median ratio of the change in
profits to the change in sales for firms in Standard & Poor’s
Composite Index, 1998–2008.
Notice that operating lev
The greater the degree
Risk
of operating leverage, the greater the sensitivity of profits to v
depends on operating leverage. If a large proportion of costs is fixed, a shor all
in sales has a magnif
ect on profits.
We will have more to say about risk in the ne
Self-Test 10.5
10.4 Real Options and the Value of Flexibility
w (DCF) to v
vely
they have invested in a new project, they do not simply sit back and w
y go badly, the project may
. Most tools for project analysis ignore these opportunities. For e
w end of your forecasts.
It w
y to close do
ays are more valuable than those that
don’t pro
xibility.
aluable this
xibility becomes.
The Option to Expand
The scientists at MacCaugh have developed a diet whiskey
ahead with pilot production and test-marketing. The preliminary phase will take a year
and cost $200,000. Management feels that there is only a 50–50 chance that the pilot
et tests will be successful. If the
uild
a $2 million production plant that will generate an e
w in perpetuity of $480,000 after taxes. Given an opportunity cost of capital of 12%, project
NPV in this case will be 2$2
1 $480,000/.12 5 $2 million. If the tests are not
successful, MacCaugh will discontinue the project and the cost of the pilot production
will be wasted.
Notice that MacCaugh’s e
uys a valuable manageThe f
ut it has the option to do
so depending on the outcome of the tests. If there is some doubt as to whether the project will tak
void a
e. Therefore, when it proposed the expenditure, MacCaugh’
ment was simply follo
w the water
temperature (and depth) dive in; if you don’
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
FedEx Buys an Option
decision tree
Diagram of sequential
decisions and possible
outcomes.
When faced with projects like this that involve future decisions, it is often helpful to
draw a decision tree as in Figure 10.3. Y
y.
Each circle represents an outcome revealed by f
left-hand square. If it decides to test, then fate will cast the enchanted dice and decide
wn, MacCaugh faces a second decision:
Should it wind up the project, or should it invest $2 million and start full-scale
production?
The second-stage decision is obvious: Invest if the tests indicate that NPV is positive
gative. So now MacCaugh can move back
to consider whether it should invest in the test program. This first-stage decision boils
down to a simple problem: Should MacCaugh invest $200,000 now to obtain a 50%
At any reasonable discount
rate the test program has a positive NPV.
Y
y other investments that take on added value
because of the options they provide to expand in the future. For example:
• When designing a f
, it can make sense to provide e
reduce the future cost of a second production line.
• When building a four-lane highway, it may pay to build six-lane bridges so that the
road can be conv
ves higher than expected.
• An airline may acquire an option to buy a ne
how Federal Express bought options on the Boeing 777 freighter).
In each of these cases you are paying out money today to give you the option to
invest in real assets at some time in the future. Managers therefore often refer to such
FIGURE 10.3
Decision tree
for the diet-whiskey project
306
Chapter 10
Project Analysis
307
options as real options. These options do not show up in the assets that the company
lists in its balance sheet, but investors are v
ware of their existence. If a company
has valuable real options that allow it to inv
et
value will be higher than the value of its physical assets now in place. We consider the
valuation of options in Chapter 23.
real options
Options to invest in,
, or dispose of a
capital investment
project.
A Second Real Option: The Option to Abandon
If the option to expand has value, what about the decision to bail out? Projects don’t
just go on until assets expire of old age. The decision to terminate a project is usually
taken by management, not by nature. Once the project is no longer profitable, the
company will cut its losses and exercise its option to abandon the project.
T
to sell than intangible ones. It helps to have active secondhand markets, which really
e
ely to be relatively easy to sell. On the other hand, the knowledge accumulated by a software company’s research and development program is a specialized
intangible asset and probably would not hav
alue. (Some
assets, such as old mattresses, even have negative abandonment value; you have to pay
wer plants or to reclaim land
▲
EXAMPLE 10.4
Abandonment Option
Suppose that the Widgeon Company m
o technologies for
the manufacture of a new product, a Wankel-engined outboard motor:
1. Technology A uses custom-designed machinery to produce the complex shapes
required for Wankel engines at low cost. But if the Wankel engine doesn’t sell, this
equipment will be worthless.
2. Technology B uses standard machine tools. Labor costs are much higher, but
the tools can easily be sold if the motor doesn’t sell.
Technology
er in an NPV analysis of the new product, because it is
designed to have the lowest possible cost at the planned production volume. Yet
you can sense the advantage of technology B’s fle
ou are unsure whether
the new outboard will sink or swim in the marketplace.
Self-Test 10.6
A Third Real Option: The Timing Option
Suppose that you have a project that could be a big winner or a big loser. The project’s
upside potential outweighs its downside potential, and it has a positive NPV if undertaken today. However, the project is not “now or never.” So should you inv
away or wait? It’
. If the project turns out to be a winner, waiting means the
ws. But if it turns out to be a loser, it would have
been better to w
ely demand.
Y
y project proposal as giving you the option to invest today. You
don’t have to exercise that option immediately. Instead, you need to weigh the value of
308
Two
Value
v
velopment of a
ne
vestment has a small positive NPV. But oil
prices are highly volatile, occasionally halving or doubling in the space of a couple
be better to wait a little before investing.
Our e
wn apparently profitable
projects. For example, suppose you approach your boss with a proposed project. It
involv
You explain to him ho
fully you have analyzed the project, but nothing seems to convince him that the company should inv
wn a positive-NPV project?
Faced by such mar
es sense to w
may hav
become clear whether it is really a winner or a loser. In the former case you can go
ut if it looks like a loser, the delay will have helped you to
av
e.7
A Fourth Real Option: Flexible Production Facilities
acility. It produces mutton and wool in roughly
ed proportions. If the price of mutton suddenly rises and that of wool falls, there is
little that the f
y manuf
y have b
xibility to v
changes. Since we hav
case in which manuf
ashion changes hav
riously dif
ve increasingly invested in computer-controlled
vide an option to v
void becoming dependent on a single source of raw materials. For e
ate than oil-fired ones. Yet many companies prefer to buy boilers that can use either oil
v
.
The reason is ob
v
ired boiler gives
the company a valuable option to e
Self-Test 10.7
7
ve-NPV
vestment timing problem involves a choice among mutually exclusiv
tives. Y
uild the project today or next year, but not both. In such cases, we hav
choice is the one with the highest NPV. The NPV of the project today, even if positive, may well be less than
vestment and keeping alive the option to invest later.
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISE
finance.yahoo.com
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
MINICASE
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
FIGURE 10.4
Chapter 11
335
Message 1: Some Risks Look Big and Dangerous
but Really Are Diversifiable
Managers confront risks “up close and personal.” They must make decisions about
vestments. The failure of such an investment could cost a promotion,
bonus, or otherwise steady job. Yet that same inv
y to an
investor who can stand back and combine it in a div
y other
assets or securities.
▲
EXAMPLE 11.2
Wildcat Oil Wells
You have just been promoted to director of exploration, Western Hemisphere, of
MPS Oil. The manager of your exploration team in far
aguana has appealed
for $20 million e a to drill in an even steamier part of the Costaguanan jungle. The
manager thinks there may be an “elephant” field worth $500 million or more hidden
there. But the chance of finding it is at best 1 in 10, and yesterday MPS’s CEO sourly
commented on the $100 million already “wasted” on Costaguanan exploration.
vestment? For you it probably is; you may be a hero if oil is found
and a goat otherwise. But MPS drills hundreds of wells worldwide; for the company
as a whole, it’s the average success rate
ers. Geologic risks (is there oil or
not?) should average out. The risk of a worldwide drilling program is much less than
the apparent risk of any single wildcat well.
Back up one step, and think of the investors who buy MPS stock. The investors
may hold other oil companies too, as well as companies producing steel, computers, clothing, cement, and breakfast cereal. They naturally—and realistically—
assume that your successes and failures in drilling oil wells will average out with the
thousands of independent bets made by the companies in their por olio.
Therefore, the risks you face in Cost
ect the rate of return they
demand for investing in MPS Oil. Diversified investors in MPS stock will be happy if
you find that elephant field, but they probably will not notice if you fail and lose your
job. In any case, they will not demand a higher average rate of return for worrying
about geologic risks in Costaguana.
▲
EXAMPLE 11.3
Fire Insurance
Would you be willing to write a $100,000 fire insurance policy on your neighbor’s
house? The neighbor is willing to pay you $100 for a year’s protection, and experience shows that the chance of fire damage in a given year is substantially less than
1 in 1,000. But if your neighbor’s house is damaged by fire, you would have to pay up.
Few of us have deep enough pockets to insure our neighbors, even if the odds of
fire damage are very low. Insur
ou think policy by
policy. But a large insurance company, which may issue a million policies, is concerned only with average losses, which can be predicted with excellent accuracy.
Self-Test 11.6
336
Part Three Risk
Message 2: Market Risks Are Macro Risks
We have seen that div
vidual stocks b
v
market and the entire economy. These are macroeconomic, or “macro,” factors such as
xchange rates, and
energy costs. These f
fect most f
relevant macro risks turn generally fav
vestors do well;
when the same variables go the other way, investors suffer.
You can often assess relative
xposures to the
business cycle and other macro v
The following businesses have substantial
macro and mark
• Airlines. Because b
vel f
viduals postpone
v
v
of the business cycle. On the positive side, airline prof
b
• Machine tool manufacturers. These b
xposed to the
business cycle. Manufacturing companies that have excess capacity rarely buy new
machine tools to expand. During recessions, excess capacity can be quite high.
Here, on the other hand, are tw
verage macro exposures:
• Food companies. Companies selling staples, such as breakf
, and dog
v
• Electric utilities.
wer v
what across the
business cycle, b
vel or machine tools. Also,
man
gulated. Re
but also giv
Remember, investors holding diversified por olios are mostly concerned with
macroeconomic risks. They do not w
oeconomic risks peculiar to
a particular company or investment project. Micro risks wash out in diversified
portfolios. Company managers may worry about both macro and micro risks,
but only the for
ect the cost of capital.
Self-Test 11.7
Message 3: Risk Can Be Measured
Delta Airlines clearly has more exposure to macro risks than food companies such as
Kellogg or General Mills. These are easy cases. But is IBM stock a riskier investment than ExxonMobil? That’s not an easy question to reason through. We can,
however, measure the risk of IBM and ExxonMobil by looking at how their stock
We’ve already hinted at how to do this. Remember that diversified investors are
concerned with market risks. The movements of the stock market sum up the net
effects of all relevant macroeconomic uncertainties. If the mark
traded stocks is up in a particular month, we conclude that the net effect of
Chapter 11 Introduction to Risk, Return, and the Opportunity Cost of Capital
337
macroeconomic news is positive. Remember, the performance of the market is
barely affected by a f
vent. These cancel out across thousands of stocks
et.
How do we measure the risk of a single stock, like IBM or ExxonMobil? We do not
re up close to a
v
s sensiti
verall stock market. We will show you how this
works in the next chapter.
SUMMARY
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
finance.yahoo.com
www.fidelity.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHAPTER
12
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T T H R E E
Risk
I
Professor William F. Sharpe receiving the Nobel Prize
in Economics.
346
Part Three Risk
12.1 Measuring Market Risk
v
v
market portfolio
Por olio of all assets in
the economy. In
practice a broad stock
market index is used to
represent the market.
macro ev
We
market
, then the net impact of macve. W
v
verage out when we
orld economy—
not just stocks but bonds, foreign securities, real estate, and so on. In practice, however
e do with index
et, such as the Standard
& Poor’s Composite Index (the S&P 500).1
Our task here is to define and measure the risk of individual
You
can probably see where we are headed. Risk depends on exposure to macroeconomic
events and can be measured as the sensitivity of a stock’
et portfolio. This sensitivity is called the stock’s beta. Beta is often
b.
beta
ock’s
return to the return on
the market por olio.
Measuring Beta
v
you had held Do
much as they would hav
et:
v
ould have v
vestors don’
v
Div
ggs
v
vidual stocks but not the
v
agers talk about “defensive” and “aggressive” stocks. Defensive stocks are not v
sensitive to mark
ve low betas. In contrast, aggressive
et mov
v
et goes up, it
is good to be in aggressive stocks; if it goes down, it is better to be in defensive stocks
(and better still to have your money in the bank).
Aggressive stocks have high betas, betas greater than 1.0, meaning that their
returns tend to respond more than one for one to changes in the return of the
overall market. The betas of defensive stocks are less than 1.0. The returns of
these stocks v
or one with market returns. The average beta of
all stocks is—no surprises here—1.0 exactly.
Now we’ll show you how betas are measured.
▲
EXAMPLE 12.1
Measuring Beta for Turbot-Charged Seafoods
Suppose we look back at the trading history of Turbot-Charged Seafoods and pick
out 6 months when the return on the market portfolio was plus or minus 1%.
1
W
et indexes in Section 11.2.
Chapter 12
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting
347
FIGURE 12.1
This figure is a
plot of the data presented in
the table in Example 12.1.
Each point shows the
ormance of TurbotCharged Seafoods stock
when the overall market is
either up or down by 1%. On
average, Turbot-Charged
moves in the same direction
as the market, but not as far.
Therefore, Turbot-Charged’s
beta is less than 1.0. We can
measure beta by the slope of
a line fitted to the points in
the figure. In this case it is .8.
Look at Figure 12.1, where these observations are plotted. We’ve drawn a line
through the average performance of Turbot when the market is up or down by 1%.
The slope of this line is Turbot’s beta. You can see right away that the beta is .8,
because on average Turbot stock gains or loses .8% when the market is up or down
by 1%. Notice that a 2-percent
erence in the market return (21 to 11)
generates on average a 1.6-percent
erence for Turbot shareholders
(2.8 to 1.8). The ratio, 1.6/2 5 .8, is beta.
In 4 months, Turbot’s returns lie above or below the line in Figure 12.1. The distance
from the line shows the response of Turbot’s stock returns to news or events that
ected Turbot but did not ect the overall market. For example, in month 2, investors in Turbot stock benefited from good macroeconomic news (the market was up
1%) and also from some favorable news specific to Turbot. The market rise gave a
boost of .8% to Turbot stock (beta of .8 times the 1% market return). Then firm-specific
news gave Turbot stockholders an e a 1% return, for a total return that month of 1.8%.
As this example illustrates, we can break down common stock returns into two
parts: the part explained by market returns and the firm’s beta, and the part due
to news that is specific to the firm. Fluctuations in the first part reflect market risk;
fluctuations in the second part reflect specific risk.
Of course, div
That’s why wise investors, who don’t put all their eggs in one basket, will look to Turbot’
verage
beta and call its stock “defensive.”
Self-Test 12.1
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
Calculating Risk
Spreadsheet Questions
Real life doesn’t serve up numbers quite as convenient as those in our examples so
far. However, the procedure for measuring real companies’ betas is exactly the same:
1.
2. Plot the observations as in Figure 12.1.
3. Fit a line showing the av
et.
This may sound like a lot of work, but in practice computers do it for you. The
nearby box shows how to use the SLOPE function in Excel to calculate a beta. Here
o real e
Betas for Dow Chemical and Consolidated Edison
Each point in Figure 12.2a sho
the market index in a different month. For example, the circled point shows that in
w Chemical’
et index
rose by 8.5%. Notice that more often than not Do
348
Chapter 12
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting
349
FIGURE 12.2
(a) Each
point in this figure shows the
returns on Dow Chemical
common stock and the
overall market in a particular
month between June 2005
and May 2010. Do s beta is
the slope of the line fitted to
these points. Dow has a v
high beta of 2.28. (b) In this
plot of 60 months’ returns for
Con Ed and the overall
market, the slope of the fitted
line is much less than Dow’s
beta in (a). Con Ed has a
relatively low beta of .32.
inde
et when the index fell. Thus Dow was a relatively aggressive, high-beta stock.
2
The slope of this
We have dra
line is 2.28. For each e
et, Dow’
ved on average
an e
or each extra 1% f
et, Dow’
xtra
2.28%. Thus Dow’s beta was 2.28.
Of course, Dow’
The company w
ws up in the scatter of points around
the line. Sometimes Do
w south while the mark
ersa.
Figure 12.2b sho
In contrast to Do
as a defensive, low-beta stock. It was not
highly sensitive to market movements, usually lagging when the market rose and yet
doing better (or less badly) when the market fell.
ws
that on average an extra 1% change in the inde
price of Con Ed stock. Thus ConEd’s beta was .32.
Estimates of beta can be accessed easily, for example, at finance.yahoo.com, but
Table 12.1, which shows ho
et movements hav fected sev
lowest beta: Its stock return was .32 times as sensitive as the average stock to market
movements. Dow Chemical was near the other e
as 2.28 times as
sensitive as the av
et movements.
2
wn as a regression line.
least squares regression. The dependent v
v
et index, in this case the S&P 500.
or
w Chemical). The independent
350
Three
Risk
Total Risk and Market Risk
Ford and Do
Table 12.1. They were also at the top
of Table 11.6, which showed the total variability of the same group of stocks. But
et risk. Some of the most variable stocks have belowaverage betas, and vice versa.
Consider, for example, Newmont Mining. Newmont is the world’
gest gold producer. The company cites the man
y faces as “gold and other
metals’ price volatility, increased costs and v
v
countries in which we operate and gov
returns on Newmont’s stock (see T
gulation and judicial outcomes.”
viation of the
When the
wmont stock
has above-average volatility, it has a relatively low beta.
Portfolio Betas
Div
et risk. The
v
weighted by the investment in each security. For e
two stocks would have a beta as follows:
Beta of portfolio 5 (
1(
3 beta of second stock)
3 beta of first stock)
(12.1)
vested 50–50 in Dow Chemical and Consolidated Edison would
have a beta of (.5 3 2.28) 1 (.5 3 .32) 5 1.30.
A well-div
e Dow Chemical,
would still have a portfolio beta of 2.28. However, most of the individual stocks’
specif
ould be diversified away.
et risk would remain, and such a
ould end up 2.28 times as v
et. For e
et
TABLE 12.1 Betas for
selected common stocks,
May 2005–April 2010
Note: Betas are calculated from 5 years
of monthly data.
Chapter 12
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting
351
viation of 20%, a fully div
viation of 2.28 3 20 5 45.6%.
ve in the same direction as the
w-beta stocks like Consolidated
v
et movements. Such a portfolio is .32 times as v
et.
Of course, on average stocks have a beta of 1.0.
v
verage beta of 1.0, has the same variability as the
et index.
et but not as far. A well-div
Self-Test 12.2
▲
EXAMPLE 12.2
How Risky Are Mutual Funds?
You don’t have to be wealthy to own a diversified por olio. You can buy shares in
one of the more than 8,000 mutual funds in the United States.
Investors buy shares of the funds, and the funds use the money to buy por olios
of securities. The returns on the portfolios are passed back to the funds’ owners in
proportion to their shareholdings. Therefore, the funds act like investment cooperatives, ering even the smallest investors diversification and professional management at low cost.
Let’s look at the bet
o mutual funds that invest in stocks. Figure 12.3a plots
the monthly returns of Vanguard’s Explorer mutual fund and of the S&P index for 5
years ending in April 2010. You can see that the stocks in the Explorer fund had
above-average sensitivity to market changes: They had on average a beta of 1.15.
If the Explorer fund had no specific risk, its portfolio would have been 1.15 times
as variable as the market por olio. But the fund manager wanted to beat the market, not to hold it. So the fund had not diversified away all the specific risk; there is
still some scatter about the line in Figure 12.3a. As a result, the variability of the fund
was somewhat more than 1.15 times that of the market.
FIGURE 12.3a
The slope
of the fitted line shows that
investors in the Vanguard
Explorer mutual fund bore
market risk greater than that
of the S&P 500 por olio.
Explor s beta was 1.15. This
was the average beta of the
individual common stocks
held by the fund. Investors
also bore some specific risk,
however; not
er of
Explor s returns above and
below the f ed line.
352
Part Three Risk
FIGURE 12.3b
The
Vanguard 500 Portfolio is a
fully diversified index fund
designed to track the
ormance of the market.
Note the fund’s beta (1.0)
and the absence of specific
risk. The fund’s returns lie
almost precisely on the f ed
line relating its returns to
those of the S&P 500 por olio.
Figure 12.3b shows the same sort of plot for Vanguard’s Index Trust 500 Por olio
mutual fund. Notice that this fund has a beta of 1.0 and only a tiny residual of specific risk—the f ed line fits almost exactly because an index fund is designed to
track the market as closely as possible. The managers of the fund do not attempt
to pick good stocks but just work to achieve full diversification at very low cost. The
index fund is fully diversified. Investors in this fund buy the market as a whole and
don’t have to worry at all about specific risk.
Self-Test 12.3
12.2 Risk and Return
market risk premium
Risk premium of market
por olio
erence
between market return
and return on risk-free
Treasury bills.
In Chapter 11 we looked at past returns on selected investments.
y investment was U.S. T
T
ed, it is unafet. Thus the beta of Treasury bills is zero. The most
y investment that we considered w
This
has av
et risk: Its beta is 1.0.
Wise investors don’t run risks just for fun. They are playing with real money and
therefore require a higher return from the market portfolio than from Treasury bills.
The dif
et and the interest rate on bills is
termed the market risk premium. Over the past century the average market risk
premium has been 7.4% a year. Of course, there is plenty of scope for argument as to
ut we will just assume here
that the normal risk premium is a nice round 7%, that is, 7% is the additional return
that an investor could reasonably expect from investing in the stock market rather
than T
bills.
Chapter 12
353
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting
FIGURE 12.4
(a) Here we
begin the plot of expected
rate of return against beta.
The first benchmarks are
Tr
a 5 0) and
the market portfolio
(beta 5 1.0). We assume a
Tr
ate of 3% and a
market return of 10%. The
market risk premium is
10 2 3 5 7%. (b) A por olio
split ev
een Treasury
bills and the market will have
beta 5 .5 and an expected
return of 6.5% (point
portfolio invested 20% in the
market and 80% in Treasury
bills has beta 5 .2 and an
expected rate of return of
4.4% (point
e that the
expected rate of return on
any portfolio mixing Treasury
bills and the market lies on a
straight line. The risk premium
is proportional to the portfolio
beta.
In Figure 12.4a we hav
T
and the mark
You can see that T
v
free return; we’ll assume that return is 3%. The mark
3
an assumed e
Now, given these two benchmarks, what e
vestor
vided between T
et?
Halfway between, of course. Thus in Figure 12.4b we have drawn a straight line
through the T
xpected market return.
ed
with an
ould have a beta of .5 and an e
premium of 3.5% above the T
You can calculate this return as follo
ference between the
rf. This is the expected mark
expected mark
rm and the T
premium:
5 rm 2 rf 5 10% 2 3% 5 7%
ve to the market. Therefore, the expected risk premium
premium 5 r 2 rf 5 b(rm 2 rf)
3
W
mark
et is about 7%. With a 3% T
ould be 3 1 7 5 10%.
xpected
354
Part Three Risk
For e
Risk
5 b(rm 2 rf) 5 .5 3 7% 5 3.5%
The total expected rate of return is the sum of the risk-free rate and the risk premium:
5
1
r 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf)
5 3% 1 3.5% 5 6.5%
(12.2)
You could have calculated the e
Expected return 5 r 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf)
5 3% 1 (.5 3 7%) 5 6.5%
capital asset pricing
model (CAPM)
Theory of the
relationship between risk
and return which states
that the expected risk
premium on an
equals its beta times the
market risk premium.
This basic relationship should hold not only for our portfolios of T
market, but for any asset.
wn as the capital asset pricing model,
or CAPM.
The expected rates of return
demanded by investors depend on two things: (1) compensation for the time
value of money (the risk-free rate rf) and (2) a risk premium, which depends on
beta and the market risk premium.
Note that the expected rate of return on an asset with b 5
W
et
r 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf)
5 3% 1 (1 3 7%) 5 10%
Self-Test 12.4
Why the CAPM Makes Sense
The CAPM assumes that the stock market is dominated by well-div
vestors
et risk. That is reasonable in a stock market where
ge institutions and even small fry can diversify at v
w
cost. The following example shows why in this case the CAPM makes sense.
▲
EXAMPLE 12.3
How Would You Invest $1 Million?
Have you ever daydreamed about receiving a $1 million check,
ached,
from an unknown benefactor? Let’s daydream about how you would invest it.
We hav
o good candidates: Treasury bills,
er an absolutely safe
return, and the market por olio (possibly via the Vanguard index fund discussed
earlier in this chapter). The market has generated superior returns on average, but
those returns have fluctuated a lot. (Look back to Figure 11.4.) So your investment
policy is going to depend on your tolerance for risk.
If you’re a wimp, you may invest only part of your money in the market portfolio
and lend the remainder to the government by buying Treasury bills. Suppose that
you invest 20% of your money in the market por olio and put the other 80% in U.S.
Treasury bills. Then the beta of your por olio will be a mixture of the beta of the market (bmarket 5 1.0) and the beta of the T-bills (b T-bills 5 0):
Chapter 12
355
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting
Beta of por olio 5 a
proportion
beta of
proportion
beta of
b 1 a
b
3
3
in market
market
in T-bills
T-bills
b 5 (.2 3 bmarket)
1 (.8 3 bT-bills)
5 (.2 3 1.0)
1 (.8 3 0) 5 .20
The fraction of funds that you invest in the mark
ects your expected
return. If you invest your entire million in the market por olio, you earn the full market risk premium. But if you invest only 20% of your money in the market, you earn
only 20% of the risk premium.
Expected
proportion
market risk
proportion
risk premium
b1 a
b
risk premium 5 a
3
3
in market
premium
in T-bills
on T-bills
on portfolio
5 (.2 3 expected market risk premium) 1 (.8 3 0)
5 .2 3 expected market risk premium
5 .2 3 7 5 1.4%
The expected return on your portfolio is equal to the risk-free interest rate plus the
expected risk premium:
Expected portfolio return 5 rpor
olio
5 3 1 1.4 5 4.4%
In Figure 12.4b we show the beta and expected return on this por olio b
er Y.
The Security Market Line
security market line
Relationship between
expected return and
beta.
Example 12.3 illustrates a general point: By inv
y
in the mark
wing)4 the balance, you can obtain any
combination of risk and expected return along the sloping line in Figure 12.5. This line
is generally known as the security market line.
Self-Test 12.5
The secur
ket line describes the expected returns and risks from investerent fractions of your funds in the market. It also sets a standard for other
investments. Investors will be willing to hold other investments only if the
er
4
et line extends abov
, b 5 2.0? It’s easy, but it’
ves you $2 million inv
b 5 1.0. How would you generate a
w $1 million and inv
.Y
w
has a beta of 2.0:
5 (proportion in market 3 beta of market) 1 (
b 5 (2 3 b et) 1 (21 3 b )
5 (2 3 1.0) 1 (21 3 0) 5 2
gativ
ay
er w
3 beta of loan)
wing, not lending money.
xpensive as long as you
vest strategy?
356
Part Three Risk
FIGURE 12.5
The security
market line shows how
expected rate of return
depends on beta. According
to the capital asset pricing
model, expected rates of
return for all securities and all
portfolios lie on this line.
equally good prospects. Thus the required risk premium for any investment is
given by the secur
ket line:
Risk premium on investment 5 beta 3 expected market risk premium
Look back to Figure 12.4b, which suggests that an indi
b 5 .5 must offer a 6.5% expected rate of return when T
et risk premium is 7%. You can now see why this has to be so. If that stock
offered a lower rate of return, nobody would buy even a little of it—they could get
6.5% just by investing 50–50 in T
et. And if nobody wants to
hold the stock, its price has to drop. A lower price means a better buy for investors, that
The price will fall until the stock’s expected rate of return is
pushed up to 6.5%.
If, on the other hand, our stock offered more than 6.5%, div
vestors would
want to buy more of it. That would push the price up and the e
wn to
the levels predicted by the CAPM.
This reasoning holds for stocks with any beta. That’s why the CAPM makes sense,
and why the e
v
Self-Test 12.6
How Well Does the CAPM Work?
The basic idea behind the capital asset pricing model is that investors expect a rew
for both w
The greater the w
you inv
T
ve the rate of interest. That’s the
reward for waiting. When you invest in risky stocks, you can expect an e
is equal to the stock’
Therefore,
5 risk-free interest rate 1 (beta 3
r 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf)
How well does the CAPM w
.5 on average lie halfw
)
Chapter 12
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting
357
FIGURE 12.6
The capital
asset pricing model states
that the expected risk
premium from any investment
should lie on the secur
market line. The dots show
the actual average risk
premium from portfolios with
erent betas. The high-beta
portfolios generated higher
returns, just as predicted by
the CAPM. But the high-beta
portfolios plotted below the
market line and the low-beta
portfolios plotted above. A
line f ed to the 10 por olio
returns would be “flatter” than
the secur
ket line.
Source: This material is reprinted with permission from Institutional Investor, Inc. It originally appeared in the Fall
1993 issue of the Journal of P olio Management 20. It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article. For
more information please visit www.iijournals.com. All Rights Reserved.
rate on T
, the e
s look back to
vestors in low-beta stocks and in high-beta stocks.
Imagine that in 1931 ten investors gathered together in a W
to establish inv
vestor decided to follow a
gy. Investor 1 opted to buy the 10% of the New York Stock Exchange
stocks with the lowest estimated betas; investor 2 chose the 10% with the next-lowest
vestor 10, who proposed to buy the stocks with the highest
betas. They also planned that at the end of each year they would reestimate the betas of
And so the
ality and good wishes.
In time the 10 investors all passed away, but their children agreed to meet in early
Figure 12.6
shows how they f
vestor 1’
y than the
market; its beta was only .49. However, investor 1 also realized the lo
abov
At the other extreme, the beta of investor 10’s portfolio w
vestor 1’
vestor 10 was
rew
v
ve the interest rate. So
ov
As you can see from Figure 12.6
et portfolio ov
pro
verage return of 11.8% above the interest rate5 and (of course) had a beta
of 1.0.
et
line in Figure 12.6. Since the market provided a risk premium of 11.8%, investor 1’s
ve pro
vestor 10’
ve given a premium of 18.1%. You can
see that, while high-beta stocks performed better than low-beta stocks, the difference
was not as great as the CAPM predicts.
Figure 12.6 pro
v
CAPM. For e
vested their cash in 1966 rather than
1931, there would have been v
beta.6 Does this imply that there has been a fundamental change in the relation between
5
In Figure 12.6
pro
v
alue-weighted index.
Figure 12.6 and the 7.4% premium reported in Table 11.1.
6
irst seven investors increased in line with beta. However
.
ve
x is
et risk
358
Part Three Risk
FIGURE 12.7
The blue line
shows the cumulative
difference between the
returns on small-firm and
lar
irm stocks from 1926 to
September 2010. The orange
line shows the cumulative
difference between the
returns on high-book-tomarket-value stocks and
low-book-to-market-value
stocks.
Source: mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/k
Kenneth R. French.
w
h/data_library.html. Used by permission of
vestors expected? It is hard to be sure.
v
et. For example, look at Figure 12.7. The orange line shows the cumula-
tive dif
gest capitalizations, this is how your wealth would have changed. You can see that
small-cap stocks did not always do well, but over the long haul their owners have made
v
ference between
o groups of stocks has been 3.8%. Now look at the blue line in
Figure 12.7, which shows the cumulativ
alue stocks
and gro
Value stocks
alue
et v
Growth stocks
et. Notice that
value stocks have pro
wth stocks. Since 1926 the
av
wth stocks has been 4.9%.
with the CAPM, which predicts that beta is the only reason that e
fer.
If investors expected
et ratios, then
the simple v
What’s going on here? It is hard to say. Defenders of the capital asset pricing model
emphasize that it is concerned with expected
e only
actual returns.
xpectations, but they also embody lots of
verage investors have
receiv
y expected.
e that in the past smallfirm stocks and value stocks have pro
t be sure
whether this was simply a coincidence or whether investors have required a higher
Such debates have prompted headlines like “Is Beta Dead?” in the business press. It
is not the first time that beta has been declared dead, but the CAPM remains the leadve more than
one funeral.
The CAPM is not the only model of risk and return. It has several brothers and sisters as well as second cousins. However, the CAPM captures in a simple way two
veryone agrees that investors require some extra
vestors appear to be concerned principally with the
market risk that the
v
.
Chapter 12
TABLE 12.2
359
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting
Expected rates
of return
Note: Expected return 5 r 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf) 5 3% 1 b 3 7%.
Using the CAPM to Estimate Expected Returns
T
vestors are e
three numbers—the risk-free interest rate, the expected market risk premium, and
beta. Suppose that the interest rate on T
et risk
premium is about 7%. Now look back to Table 12.1, where we gave you betas of several stocks. Table 12.2 puts these numbers together to give an estimate of the expected
s take Dell Computer as an example:
Expected return on Dell 5
1 ¢ beta 3
≤
r 5 3% 1 (1.33 3 7%) 5 12.3%
Of our sample of companies, Ford had the highest beta. Investors in Ford required
xtra market risk. Table 12.2 suggests that Ford’s
e
s.
12.3 Capital Budgeting and Project Risk
We hav
aces a trade-off. It can either buy new plant and equipment
vest the money for themselves in the
et.
y invests the cash, shareholders can’t invest these
funds in the capital market.
ve up by keeping their
money in the company is therefore called the
need the compan
vestments.
We hav
vestors could e
vestors can buy.
company cost of capital
Expected rate of return
demanded by investors in
a company, determined
by the average risk of the
company’s securities.
r,
vel of
Company versus Project Risk
Man
company cost of capital
v
ws on all new projects. Because
360
Three
Risk
inv
y
ve a
w investment
or e
e
project cost of capital
Minimum acceptable
expected rate of return
on a project given its risk.
Table 12.2). According to the company cost of
This is a step in the right direction, but we must tak
irm has issued
securities other than equity.7 Moreover
new projects do not hav
xisting business. Dell’
investors’ estimate of the risk of the computer hardware business, and its company
cost of capital is the return that inv
xpansion of its re
xpected cash
ws by the company cost of capital. But suppose Dell is w
project cost
of capital.
shareholders require from investing in such a business.
Self-Test 12.7
The project cost of capital depends on the use to which that capital is put. Therefore, it depends on the risk of the project—not on the risk of the company. If a company invests in a lo
low cost of capital. If it inv
ws should be discounted at a high cost of capital. Many companies use the company cost of capital as
y require on a “typical” capital investment. They then
Self-Test 12.8
▲
EXAMPLE 12.4
Estimating the Opportunity Cost of Capital for a Project
Suppose that Dell is contemplating investment in a new project. You have forecast
the cash flows on the project and calculated that the internal rate of return is 11%.
We assume that Treasur
er a return of 3% and that the expected market risk
premium is 7%. Should Dell go ahead with the project?
To answer this question, you need the oppor
al, r. You start with
the project’s beta. For example, if the project is a sure thing, its beta is zero and the
cost of capital equals the interest rate on Treasury bills:
r 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf) 5 3 1 (0 3 7) 5 3%
7
Therefore, the
Chapter 12
361
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting
If the pr
ers an expected return of 11% when the cost of capital is 3%, Dell
should obviously go ahead.8 But if you had compared this project’s return with
Dell’s 12.3% company cost of capital, you would have wrongly concluded that it
was not worthwhile.
Surefire projects rarely occur outside finance texts. So let’s think about the cost of
capital if the project has the same risk as the market por olio. In this case beta is
1.0, and the cost of capital is the expected return on the market:
r 5 3 1 (1.0 3 7) 5 10%
The project appears less attractive than before but still worth doing.
lies abov
reasonably expect else
NPV investment.
ve because, as Figure 12.8 shows, its e
et line. The project offers a higher return than investors can
vestments. Therefore, it is a positive-
The security market line provides a standard for project acceptance. If the
project’s expected return lies above the security market line, then it is higher
than investors could expect to earn by investing their funds in the capital market,
and the project is an attractive investment oppor
.
Determinants of Project Risk
We hav
that hav
y’s existing business but not for those projects
y’s average. Ho
w whether a
y? Estimating project risk is never going to be an exact science,
but here are two things to bear in mind.
First, we sa
v
y change in rev
ve a
Therefore, projects that involv
ed costs tend to hav
Second, many people intuitiv
much of this v
v
look forward to e
ut whether the
e it rich is
not lik
. These investments
(like Newmont Mining) hav
viation but a low beta.
FIGURE 12.8
The expected
return of this project is more
than the expected return one
could earn on stock market
investments with the same
market risk (beta). Therefore,
the project’s expected return
lies above the secur
market line, and the project
should be accepted.
8
fer a lower internal rate
W
w ones.
362
Three
Risk
What matters is the strength of the r
een the firm’s earnings
and the aggregate earnings of all firms. Cyclical businesses, whose revenues
and earnings are strongly dependent on the state of the economy, tend to have
high betas and a high cost of capital. By contrast, businesses that produce
essentials, such as food, beer, and cosmetics, ar
ected by the state of the
economy. They tend to have low betas and a low cost of capital.
Don’t Add Fudge Factors to Discount Rates
Risk to an investor arises because an investment adds to the spread of possible portfoTo a diversified investor
et risk. But in everyday
usage risk
” People think of the “risks” of a project as the
things that can go wrong. For example,
•
• A pharmaceutical manufacturer w
reverses balding may not be approved by the F
• The o
xpropriation.
w drug which
Administration.
orld w
Managers sometimes add fudge factors to discount rates to account for w
these.
v
ould not affect the e
inv
managers fail to giv
w forecasts. The
e by adding a fudge factor to the discount rate. For example, if a manager is w
xploration, he or she may reduce the value of the project by using a higher discount rate. That’s
not the w
v
Then the expected
lion. Y
ut (.5 3 0) 1 (.5 3 20) 5 $10
Expected cash-flow forecasts should already reflect the probabilities of all
possible outcomes, good and bad. If the cash-flow forecasts are prepared properly, the discount rate should reflect only the market risk of the project. It should
not be fudged t
ors or biases in the cash-flow forecast.
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
FIGURE 12.9
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
FIGURE 12.10
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISE
finance.yahoo.com
finance.yahoo.com
www.fidelity.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
SOLUTIONS TO SPREADSHEET QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
FIGURE 12.11
CHAPTER
13
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T T H R E E
Risk
Geothermal Corporation was founded to produce electricity from geothermal energy trapped under the
earth.
I
372
Part Three Risk
13.1 Geothermal’s Cost of Capital
Jo Ann Cox, a recent graduate of a prestigious eastern business school, poured a third
w about project
hurdle rates. Why hadn’t she paid more attention in Finance 101? Why had she sold
her finance te
Costas
valuation of a proposed e
s production.
She w
Thermopolis, whose background was geoxpected a numerical analysis but also expected her to
explain it to him.
mal energy trapped deep under Nevada.
y had pioneered this business and
av
U.S. government.
ve up ener
orldy. It w
.
Now, in 2012, production rights were no longer cheap. The proposed expansion
w
w of $4.5
.
as 4.5/30 5 .15, or 15%, much less
s existing assets. However, once the new project
was up and running, it w
s present business.
Jo Ann realized that 15% w
would have been better. Fifteen percent might still exceed Geothermal’s cost of capital, that is, exceed the e
vestors would demand to
invest money in the project. If the cost of capital w
xpected
xpansion would be a good deal and would generate net v
Jo Ann remembered how to calculate the cost of capital for companies that used
gument.
“I need the expected rate of return investors w
s real
assets—the wells, pumps, generators, etc.
wever
et, so I can’
e how risky
they hav
s common stock.
wning the stock means
owning the assets, and the e
vestors in the stock must
also be the cost of capital for the assets.” She jotted down the following identities:
of business 5 value of stock
Risk of business 5
Rate of return on business 5 rate of return on stock
Investors’ required return from business 5 investors’ required return from stock
capital structure
The mix of long-term
debt and equity
financing.
If there were no company debt, this would be the right discount rate for Geothermal’s
expansion plan.
Unfortunately, Geothermal had borrowed a substantial amount of money; its stockholders did not have unencumbered ownership of Geothermal’s assets. The expansion
project would also justify some e
ould have
to look at Geothermal’s capital structure—its mix of debt and equity financing—and
consider the e
vestors.
w trading at $20 each. Thus shareholders valued Geothermal’s equity at $20 3 22.65 million 5 $453 million. In addition, the compan
et v
et
value of the company’s debt and equity was therefore $194 1 $453 5 $647 million.
Debt was 194/647 5 .3, or 30% of the total.
Chapter 13
373
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
sw
vestors than either its debt or its equity,” Jo Ann
verall v
s business by
adding up the debt and equity.” She sketched a rough balance sheet:
Assets
Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity
Market v
5v
of Geothermal’s existing business
$647
Total value
$647
Market value of debt
Market value of equity
Total value
$194
453
$647
(30%)
(70%)
(100%)
“Holy Toledo, I’ve got it!” Jo Ann exclaimed. “If I bought all
Geothermal, debt as well as equity, I’d own the entire business. That means . . .” She
jotted again:
Value of business 5
value of portfolio of all the firm’s
debt and equity securities
Risk of business 5
Rate of return on business 5 rate of return on portfolio
Investors’ required return on business
(company cost of capital) 5 portfolio
“All I have to do is calculate the e
irm’s
securities. That’s easy. The debt’s yielding 8%, and Fred, that nerdy banker, says that
equity investors want 14%. Suppose he’s right.
ould contain 30% debt
and 70% equity, so . . .”
Portfolio return 5 (.3 3 8%) 1 (.7 3 14%) 5 12.2%
It was all coming back to her now.
y cost of capital is just a weighted
average of returns on debt and equity, with weights depending on relative market values of the two securities.
“But there’s one more thing. Interest is tax-deductible. If Geothermal pays $1 of
s tax bill drops by 35 cents
(assuming a 35% tax rate). The net cost is only 65 cents. So the after-tax cost of debt
is not 8%, but .65 3 8 5 5.2%.
“No
verage cost of capital:
WACC 5 (.3 3 5.2%) 1 (.7 3 14%) 5 11.4%
“Looks like the e
a break.”
s a good deal. Fifteen’s better than 11.4. But I sure need
13.2 The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital
Jo Ann’
vious by now that the choice of
volves large capital
expenditures or is long-lived.
w a major investment in a
power station—an investment with both a large capital e
y cost of capital is, and what it is used for. We
se
use it to v
it as
w assets
that hav
xpands by investing in av
We f
v
v
ets. If
vest their money only if it
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Choosing the Discount Rate
Shortly before the British government began to sell off the
electricit
y to private investors, controversy er ed
ov
y’s proposal to b
awatt
n
wer station known as Hinkley Point C. The government ar
ation w
ersify the
ces of electricity generation and r
xide
and carbon dioxide emissions. Protesters emphasized the
dangers of n
tacked the proposal as
“bizarre, dated and irrelevant.”
y held to consider the proposal, opponents pr
w
vidence that the n
ation was also a very high cost option. Their principal witness,
Professor Elroy Dimson, ar
vernment-owned
power company had employ
ealistically low fi e
for the oppor
y cost of capital. Had the compan
mor
le fi e, the cost of b
ating the
n
ation w
ve been higher than that of a comparable station based on f
.
The reason wh
ate was so important was that n
ations are expensive to b
cheap to operate. If capital is cheap (i.e
ate is
lo
ont cost is less ser
.
of capital is high, then the high initial cost of n
ations
Evidence pr
constr
ed that the
ation was £1,527 million (or
able nonn
clear station was only £895 million. However, power stations
ears, and, once b
ations cost
m
o operate than nonn
ations. If operated
etical capacity, the r
n
ation w
ear, compared with r
68 million a year for the nonn
ation.
The following table shows the cost advantage of the
n
wer station at different (r
ates. At a
ate, which was the fi
y the government, the present v
as
own. Therefore, the e
nearly £1 billion lower than that of a station based on fossil
.
ate of 1
as the fi e
favored by Professor Dimson, the position was almost exactly
reversed, so the gover
ve nearly £1 billion by
r
wer company permission to b
y
Point C and relying instead on new f
wer stations.
Eight years aft
y, the proposal to constr
kley Point C contin
og
itish Energy, the
privatized electr
y, declared that it had no plans to b
a new n
wer st
e.
8
10
12
14
16
18
0.9
0.2
0.1
0.4
0.7
0.9
1.2
Technical Notes:
1. Present v
ed at the date that the power station comes into
operation.
2. The above tab
or simplicity that constr
or n
stations are spread evenly over the 8 years before the station comes into
operation, while the costs for f
ations ar
o be spread
evenly over the 4 years before operation. As a r
esent v
the costs of the two stations may differ slightly from the more precise estimates pr
y Professor Dimson.
Adapted from Elroy Dimson,
,V
from Elsevier Science.
. 175–180.
ate for a Power Station,”
989 with permission
fer higher rates of return than investors could achieve on their
v
ets detervestments.
y as a
y cost of capital in Chapter 12, b
whole. W
ho
or how to adjust it for the tax-deductibility of interest payments. The weighted-average
cost of capital formula handles these complications.
Calculating Company Cost of Capital
as a Weighted Average
y cost of capital is
ways easy. For e
pricing model (CAPM). This would be the expected rate of return investors require on
the company’s e
xpected return they will
require on new investments that do not change the company’s mark
374
Chapter 13
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
375
But most companies issue debt as well as equity. The company cost of capital is
a weighted average of the returns demanded b
vestors. The
weighted average is the expected rate of return investors would demand on a
portfolio of all the firm’s outstanding securities.
Let’s review Jo Ann Cox’s calculations for Geothermal. To avoid complications,
we’ll ignore tax
xt two or three pages.
et value of Geothermal, which we denote as V, is the sum of the values of the outstanding debt D and the
equity E.
alue is V 5 D 1 E 5 $194 million 1 $453 million 5 $647 million. Debt accounts for 30% of the v
If you held all the shares and all the debt, your investment in Geothermal would be
V 5 $647 million. Between them, the debt- and equityholders own all
s assets.
So V is also the value of these assets—the v
s existing business.
s equity inv
investment in the stock. What rate of return must a new project provide in order that all
inv
air rate of return? The debtrdebt 5 8%. So each year the f
interest of rdebt 3 D 5 .08 3 $194 million 5 $15.52 million. The shareholders, who
have invested in a riskier security, require an e
requity 5 14% on their
investment of $453 million. Thus in order to k
y
y
5 $63.42
To
needs additional income of requity 3 E 5 .14 3 $453
lion 1 $63.42 million 5 $78.94 million. This is equiv
rassets 5 78.94/647 5 .122, or 12.2%.
Figure 13.1 illustrates the reasoning behind our calculations. The figure shows the
vestors. Notice that debtut receive less than 30% of
its expected income. On the other hand, the
they hav
y’s income and also first claim on its assets if the company gets in trouble. Shareholders expect a return of more than 70% of Geothermal’s
income because the
However, if you buy all
s debt and equity, you own its assets lock,
You receiv
The expected rate
of return you’
d require
from unencumbered ownership of the business. This rate of return—12.2%, ignoring
taxes—is therefore the compan
equal-risk expansion of the business.
FIGURE 13.1
Geothermal’s
debtholders account for
30% of the company’s capital
structure, but they get a
smaller share of income
because their return is
guaranteed by the company.
Geothermal’s stockholders
bear more risk and receive,
on average, greater return. Of
course, if you buy all the debt
, you get all
the income.
376
Part Three Risk
The bottom line (still ignoring taxes) is
Company cost of capital 5
The underlying algebra is simple. Debtholders need income of (rdebt 3 D), and the
The total income that is needed
equity investors need expected income of (requity 3
The amount of their combined existing investment in the
is (rdebt 3 D) 1 (requity 3
y is V.
vide
the income by the investment:
rassets 5
5
total income
value of investment
(D 3 rdebt) 1 (E 3 requity)
V
5 ¢
D
E
3 rdebt ≤ 1 ¢ 3 r
V
V
≤
F
rassets 5 (.30 3 8%) 1 (.70 3 14%) 5 12.2%
This figure is the e
v
s assets.
Self-Test 13.1
Use Market Weights, Not Book Weights
The company cost of capital is the expected rate of return that investors demand from
The cost of capital must be based on what
the company’
investors are actually willing to pay for the company’s outstanding securities—
that is, based on the securities’ market values.
Market values usually differ from the values recorded by accountants in the company’s books. The book v
y raised in the past
from shareholders or reinvested by the f
vestors recognize
Geothermal’s e
et value of equity may be much higher than
et values rather
than book values.
Financial managers use book debt-to-value ratios for v
times they unthinkingly look to the book ratios when calculating weights for the company cost of capital. That’s a mistake, because the company cost of capital measures
what investors want from the company, and it depends on how they value the company’
That v
ws, not on accounting
. Book values, while useful for man
ve
inancings; they don’t generally measure market values accurately.
Self-Test 13.2
Assets (book v
Debt
y
50
Chapter 13
377
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
Taxes and the Weighted-Average Cost of Capital
So f
xamples hav
es. When you calculate a project’s NPV, you need
ws after
That is exactly the approach that we used in Chapter 9, when we valued Blooper’s
inv
ws before
discount rate. It doesn’t work; there is no simple adjustment to the discount rate that
ws.
Tax
debt. The interest payments on this debt are deducted from income before tax is calculated. Therefore, the cost to the company is reduced by the amount of this tax saving.
s debt is rdebt 5 8%. However
The
rate of Tc 5 .35, the gov
gov
t send the firm a check for this amount, but the income tax that the
xpense.
-tax
cost of debt is only 100 2 35 5 65% of the 8% pretax cost:
After-tax cost of debt 5 (1 2 tax rate) 3 pretax cost
5 (1 2 Tc) 3 rdebt
5 (1 2 .35) 3 8% 5 5.2%
We can no
s cost of capital to recognize the
Company cost of capital, after-tax 5 (.3 3 5.2%) 1 (.7 3 14%) 5 11.4%
weighted-average cost of
capital (WACC)
Expected rate of return
on a portfolio of all the
firm’s securities, adjusted
for tax savings due to
interest payments.
Now we’re back to the weighted-average cost of capital, or WACC. The general
WACC 5 B
D
E
3 (1 2 Tc)rdebt R 1 ¢ 3 requity ≤
V
V
(13.1)
Self-Test 13.3
▲
EXAMPLE 13.1
Weighted-Average Cost of Capital for Dow Chemical
In Chapter 12 we showed how the capital asset pricing model can be used to estimate the expected return on Dow Chemical common stock. We will now use this
estimate to figure out the company’s weighted-average cost of capital.
378
Part Three Risk
Step 1. Calculate the value of each security as a proportion of firm value.
The company has outstanding 1,150 million shares, which in mid-2010
had a market value of about $26.50 each. The total market value of
Dow’
as E 5 1,150 3 $26.50 5 $30,475 million. The company’s
latest balance sheet showed that it had borrowed D 5 $19,152 million.
So the total value of Dow’s securities is V 5 D 1 E 5 $19,152 1 $30,475 5
$49,627 million. Debt as a proportion of the total value is D/V 5
$19,152/$49,627 5 .39, and equity as a proportion of the total is
$30,475/$49,627 5 .61.
Step 2. Determine the required rate of return on each security. In Chapter 12 we
estimated that Dow’s shareholders required a return of 19.0%. The average yield on Dow’s debt was about 6.3%.
Step 3. Calculate a weighted aver
er-tax return on the debt and
the r
.2 The weighted-average cost of capital is
WACC 5 B
D
E
3 (1 2 Tc)rdebt R 1 ¢ 3 requi ≤
V
V
5 3 .39 3 (1 2 .35)6.3% 4 1 (.61 3 19.0%) 5 13.2%
Self-Test 13.4
What If There Are Three (or More)
Sources of Financing?
We hav
two classes of securities: debt and equity. Ev
securities, our general approach to calculating WACC remains unchanged. We simply
calculate the weighted-average after-tax return of each security type.
For e
Lik
dends. Unlike bonds, however
ven, usually level, stream of diviThe
usiness. Moreover, a failure to come up with the cash to pay the di
y. Instead, any unpaid dividends simply cumulate; the common stockholders do not receiv
vidends have been
paid. Finally, unlik
vidends are not considered
tax-deductible expenses.
How would we calculate WA
stock and bonds outstanding? Using P to denote the v
ply generalize Equation 13.1 for WACC as follows:
WACC 5 B
P
E
D
3 (1 2 Tc)rdebt R 1 ¢ 3 rpreferred ≤ 1 ¢ 3 r
V
V
V
2
(13.1a)
v
W
common stock.
≤
r
xpected return on the
Chapter 13
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
379
Wrapping Up Geothermal
We now turn one last time to Jo
want to mak
capital.
Remember that the proposed e
s proposed expansion. We
w how to use the weighted-average cost of
.
w worksheet might look
like this:3
Revenue
2 Operating expenses
5 Pretax operating cash flow
2 Tax at 35%
After-tax cash flow
$10.00 million
2 3.08
6.92
2 2.42
$ 4.50 million
s
managers and engineers forecast rev
all-equity financed. The interest tax shields generated by the project’s actual debt
gotten, however. They are accounted for by using the after-tax
cost of debt in the weighted-average cost of capital.
Project net present v
w (which is a perpetuity) at Geothermal’s 11.4% weighted-average cost of capital:
NPV 5 230 1
4.5
5 1$9.5 million
.114
s owners.
Checking Our Logic
Any project of
ect of
ve a positive NPV, assums business. A projxactly 11.4% would just break even; it would generate just enough cash
Let’
million and after
xpansion had revenues of only $8.34
ws of $3.42 million:
Revenue
2 Operating expenses
5 Pretax operating cash flow
2 Tax at 35%
After-tax cash flow
$8.34 million
2 3.08
5.26
2 1.84
$3.42 million
With an inv
exactly 11.4%:
Rate of
5
3.42
5 .114, or 11.4%
30
and NPV is exactly zero:
3.42
50
.114
s weighted-average cost of capital, we recognized
that the company’s debt ratio was 30%.
s analysts use the
NPV 5 230 1
3
F
xample we ignore depreciation, a noncash but tax-deductible expense. (If the project were really
380
Part Three Risk
weighted-average cost of capital to evaluate the new project, they are assuming that
vestment w
to 30% of the investment, or $9 million.
vided by the
shareholders either in the form of reinv
tional shares.
The following table shows ho
ws would be shared between the debt.W
Cash flow before tax and interest
2 Interest payment (.08 3 $9 million)
5 Pretax cash flow
2 Tax at 35%
After-tax cash flow
v
pay tax. Taxes equal .35 3 4.54 5 $1.59
just enough to giv
(Note that 2.95/21 5 .14, or 14%.)
$5.26 million
2 .72
4.54
2 1.59
$2.95 million
y must
vestment.
v
If a project has zero NPV when the expected cash flows are discounted at the
weighted-average cost of capital, then the project’s cash flows ar
icient
to give debtholders and shareholders the returns they require.
13.3 Measuring Capital Structure
We have e
We will no
verage cost of capital.
s weightedaverage cost of capital. Your first step is to work out Big Oil’s capital structure. But
where do you get the data?
Financial managers usually start with the company’s accounts, which show
the book value of debt and equity, whereas the weighted-average cost of capital formula calls for their market values. A little work and a dash of judgment are
needed to go from one to the other.
Table 13.1 shows the debt and equity issued by Big Oil.
wed
These bonds hav
, there
alue of $1. But
wed back into the f
The total book value of the equity shown in the
accounts is $100 million 1 $300 million 5 $400 million.
wn in Table 13.1
en from Big Oil’s annual accounts and are
therefore book v
et
values are negligible. For example, consider the $200 million that Big Oil owes the
ed to the general level of interest
rates. Thus if interest rates rise, the rate charged on Big Oil’s loan also rises to
TABLE 13.1 The book
values of Big Oil’s debt and
igures in
millions)
Bank debt
erm bonds (12-y
ity
Common stock (100 million shares, par v
Retained earnings
Total
200
100
300
25.0
12.5
37.5
1
Chapter 13
TABLE 13.2 The market
values of Big Oil’s debt and
igures in
millions)
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
Bank debt
erm bonds
Total debt
Common stock (100 million shar
Total
2)
185.7
385.7
1,200.0
381
1
11.7
24.3
75.7
1
maintain the loan’s value. As long as Big Oil is reasonably sure to repay the loan, it is
w
accept the book v
air approximation of its market value.
term interest rates have risen to 9%.4 We can calculate the value today of each bond as
3 200 5 $16
follows.5
ment of face v
million. All the bond’
ws are discounted back at the current interest rate of 9%:
PV 5
16
16
216
16
1
1
1 c1
5 $185.7
2
3
(1.09)
(1.09)
(1.09)12
1.09
ace value.
If you used the book value of Big Oil’s long-term debt rather than its market value,
you would be a little bit off in your calculation of the weighted-average cost of capital,
b
alue of equity rather
than its market value.
alue of Big Oil’s equity measures the
vested on their behalf. But perhaps Big Oil has been able to find projects that were w
alue of the assets
vestors see great future investment opportuniy. All these considerations determine what inv
pay for Big Oil’s common stock.
Big Oil’s stock price is $12 a share. Thus the total market value of the stock is
Number of shares 3
5 100 million 3 $12 5
In Table 13.2 we show the market values of Big Oil’s debt and equity. You can see
that debt accounts for 24.3% of company value (D/V 5 .243) and equity accounts for
75.7% (E/V 5 .757).
average cost of capital. Notice that if you looked only at the book values shown in the
company accounts, you would mistakenly conclude that debt and equity each
accounted for 50% of value.
Self-Test 13.5
Debt
Preferred stock
Common stock
Total
4
2.2
2.8
24.2
30.8
1
If Big Oil’
s value using the rate of interest offered by
similar bonds.
5
W
.
382
Part Three Risk
13.4 Calculating the Weighted-Average
Cost of Capital
To calculate Big Oil’s weighted-average cost of capital, you first need the rate of return
that investors require from each security.
The Expected Return on Bonds
We kno
y
does not go belly-up, that is the rate of return investors can expect to earn from holding
Big Oil’s bonds. If there is any chance that the f
however, the yield to maturity of 9% represents the most fav
expected
wer than 9%.
For most lar
y is suf
w
as a measure of the e
w
fered on the
vestors could expect to receive.
The Expected Return on Common Stock
Estimates Based on the Capital Asset Pricing Model In the last
chapter we showed you how to use the capital asset pricing model to estimate the
e
The capital asset pricing model tells us that
investors demand a higher rate of return from stocks with high betas.
on stock
5
interest rate
1 ¢
stock’s
3
beta
≤
Financial managers and economists measure the risk-free rate of interest by the
yield on T
To measure the expected mark
y usually
look back at capital mark
vestors have received about
an extra 7% a year from inv
Treasury bills. Yet
vidence with considerable humility, for who is to
say whether inv
v
y expected or whether
investors today require a higher or lower rew
Let’s suppose Big Oil’
rm 2 rf) is 7%. Then the CAPM
rate (rf) is 6%, and the e
would put Big Oil’s cost of equity at
Cost of equity 5 r
5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf)
5 6% 1 .85(7%) 5 12%
Self-Test 13.6
Estimates Based on the Dividend Discount Model Whenever you are
given an estimate of the expected return on a common stock, always look for ways
to check whether it is reasonable. One check on the estimates provided by the
CAPM can be obtained from the dividend discount model (DDM). In Chapter 7 we
Chapter 13
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
383
showed you how to use the constant-growth DDM formula to estimate the return
that investors expect from different common stocks. Remember the formula: If divixpected to gro
g, then the price of the
stock is equal to
P0 5
where P0
requity is the e
provide an estimate of requity:
1
DIV1
requity 2 g
is the forecast di
W
requity 5
,
DIV1
1g
P0
(13.2)
In other words, the e
vidend yield (DIV1/P0)
plus the e
wth rate in dividends (g).
This constant-growth dividend discount model is widely used in estimating expected
ve a f
gro
-made for the constant-growth formula.
Remember that the constant-gro
ormula will get you into trouble if you
apply it to firms with very high current rates of gro
h gro
sustained indefinitely.
ver-
estimate of the expected return.
Beware of False Precision Do not expect estimates of the cost of equity to
t know whether the capital asset pricing model fully
explains e
vidend discount model
hold exactly. Even if your formulas were right, the required inputs would be noisy and
subject to error.
in a band of 2 or 3 percentage points is doing pretty well. In this endeavor it is perfectly okay to conclude that the cost of equity is, say, “about 15%” or “somewhere
”6
Sometimes accuracy can be improved by estimating the cost of equity or WACC for
This cuts down the “noise” that
plagues single-company estimates. Suppose, for e
Ann Cox is able to
v
s.
The average WACC for these three companies would be a valuable check on her
estimate of WA
Or suppose that Geothermal is contemplating investment in oil refining. For this
v
s existing WA
usiness. It could therefore try to estimate WACC
available—most oil companies invest in production and marketing as well as refining—
WA
ge oil companies could be a useful check or
The Expected Return on Preferred Stock
alued from the perpetuity
formula:
of
6
rounding.
5
dividend
r
ve been done to one or two decimal places just to avoid confusion from
384
Three
Risk
where r
Therefore, we
aluation
r
5
dividend
For e
(13.3)
vidend of $2 per
rpreferred 5 $2/$20 5
simply the dividend yield.
Adding It All Up
Once you have worked out Big Oil’s capital structure and estimated the expected
average cost of capital. Table 13.3
do is plug the data in Table 13.3 into the weighted-av
w all you need to
E
D
3 (1 2 Tc)rdebt R 1 ¢ 3 requity ≤
V
V
5 3 .243 3 (1 2 .35) 9% 4 1 (.757 3 12%) 5 10.5%
WACC 5 B
Suppose that Big Oil needs to ev
ness. If the project w
xisting busiverage
ws.
Real-Company WACCs
Big Oil is entirely hypothetical.
Table 13.4, which gives some estimates of the weighted-av
sample of real companies. As you do so, remember that any estimate of the cost of
capital for a single company can be way of
You should always check
7
13.5 Interpreting the Weighted-Average
Cost of Capital
When You Can and Can’t Use WACC
The weighted-average cost of capital is the rate of return that the firm must
expect to earn on its average-risk investments in order to provide a fair expected
return to all its secur
ictly speaking, the weighted-average cost of
capital is an appropriate discount rate only for a project that is a carbon copy
TABLE 13.3 Data needed to
calculate Big Oil’s weightedaverage cost of capital
(dollar figures in millions)
Debt
Common stock
Total
385.7
/
/
.243
.757
debt
y
.12, or 1
Note: Corporate tax rate 5 Tc 5 .35.
7
v
ord’s WACC is about average despite its v
ord use a WACC of 8% when v
.
y’s
The
v
WACC
Chapter 13
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
385
of the firm’s e
en it is used as a companywide benchmark
discount rate; the benchmark is adjusted upward for unusually r
ojects
and downward for unusually safe ones.
There is a good musical analogy here. Most of us, lacking perfect pitch, need a
ey. But anyone
relative pitches right. Businesspeople have good intuition
about relative
ut not about absolute risk or
Therefore, they set a company- or industrywide cost of capital
verything the company does, but
y ventures.
Some Common Mistakes
One danger with the weighted-average formula is that it tempts people to make logical
errors. Think back to your estimate of the cost of capital for Big Oil:
E
D
3 (1 2 Tc)rdebt R 1 ¢ 3 requity ≤
V
V
5 3 .243 3 (1 2 .35) 9% 4 1 (.757 3 12%) 5 10.5%
WACC 5 B
Now you might be tempted to say to yourself: “Aha! Big Oil has a good credit rating.
It could easily push up its debt ratio to 50%. If the interest rate is 9% and the required
verage cost of capital would be
WACC 5 3 .50 3 (1 2 .35) 9% 4 1 (.50 3 12%) 5 8.9%
At a discount rate of 8.9%, we can justify a lot more investment.”
wing,
the lenders would almost certainly demand a higher rate of interest on the debt. Secwing increased, the risk of the common stock would also increase and
There are actually two costs of debt finance. The explicit cost of debt is the
rate of interest that bondholders demand. But there is also an implicit cost,
TABLE 13.4 Calculating
the weighted-average
cost of capital for selected
companies
Dow Chemical
Starb ks
Dell
Boeing
Disney
Microsoft
ord
IBM
McDonald’s
Newmont Mining
Johnson & Johnson
Heinz
Pfizer
ExxonMobil
C
Consolidated Edison
Walmart
19.0
12.5
12.3
12.0
11.1
9.8
20.7
8.3
7.3
7.1
7.0
7.3
7.8
5.9
5.6
5.2
4.7
6.30
6.30
4.60
4.60
4.60
3.50
7.25
4.55
4.65
6.25
3.50
6.25
4.55
3.50
4.60
6.20
4.20
.61
.97
.88
.79
.86
.98
.21
.88
.87
.85
.92
.74
.70
.98
.85
.55
.84
Notes:
1. Expected return on equity is taken from Table 12.2.
2. Interest rate on debt is calculated from yields on similarly rated bonds.
3. D is the book value of the firm’s debt, and E is the market value of equity.
4. WACC 5 (D/V) 3 (1 2 .35) 3 rdebt 1 (E/V) 3 requity.
.39
.03
.12
.21
.14
.02
.79
.12
.13
.15
.08
.26
.30
.02
.15
.45
.16
13.2
12.3
11.2
10.1
9.9
9.7
8.0
7.7
6.8
6.7
6.6
6.4
6.4
5.8
5.2
4.7
4.4
386
Part Three Risk
because borrowing increases the required return to equity. When you jumped to
the conclusion that Big Oil could lower its weighted-average cost of capital to 8.9% by
wing more, you were recognizing only the explicit cost of debt and not the
implicit cost.
Self-Test 13.7
How Changing Capital Structure
Affects Expected Returns
We will illustrate how changes in capital structure affect expected returns by focusing
Tc is zero.
,
has the following market-value balance sheet:
Assets
Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity
Assets 5 v
existing business
mal’s
Total value
$647
$647
Debt
Equity
Value
$194
453
$647
(30%)
(70%)
(100%)
Geothermal’
average cost of capital is simply the e
s assets:
WACC 5 rassets 5 (.3 3 8%) 1 (.7 3 14%) 5 12.2%
ould expect if you held all Geothermal’
fore o
Now think what will happen if Geothermal borrows an additional $97 million and
uses the cash to buy back and retire $97 million of its common stock. The revised
market-value balance sheet is
Assets
Assets 5 v
existing business
Total value
Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity
mal’s
$647
$647
Debt
Equity
Value
$291
356
$647
(45%)
(55%)
(100%)
ws. Therefore, if investors require a return of 12.2% on the total package of debt and equity before the financing, they must require the same 12.2% return
The weighted-average cost of capital is therefore unaffected
After all, the required return on debt is lo
wing to reduce the weightedaverage cost of capital.
y has more debt than before, the debt is
Chapter 13
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
387
ely to demand a higher return. Increasing the amount of
W
What Happens When the Corporate Tax
Rate Is Not Zero
We have sho
capital is unaf
es, the weighted-average cost of
, taxes can compli8
For the moment, just remember:
• The weighted-average cost of capital is the right discount rate for averagerisk capital investments.
• The weighted-average cost of capital is the return the company needs to
ear
er tax in order to satisfy all its security holders.
• If the firm increases its debt ratio, both the debt and the equity will become
more r
. The debtholders and equityholders require a higher return to
compensate for the increased risk.
13.6 Valuing Entire Businesses
free cash flow
Cash flow that is not
required for investment
in fixed assets or working
capital and is therefore
available to investors.
Investors routinely b
uy
and sell entire b
ter 7 to value Blue Skies’ stock also work for entire businesses?
Sure! As long as the company’s debt ratio is expected to remain fairly constant, you
can treat the compan
ws by the weightedaverage cost of capital. The result is the combined value of the company’s debt and
equity. If you w
w just the v
, you must remember to subtract
the value of the debt from the company’s total value.
uying Establishment Industry’s concatenator
manuf
Table 13.5 sets
out your forecasts for the ne
w 8 shows the e
w from
operations. This is equal to the e
,
w, and therefore you need to add it back when calculatw. Row 9 in the table shows the forecast inv
and w
w less investment expenditures is the amount of cash that the
b
vestors after paying for all inv
wth.
This is the concatenator division’s free cash w (row 10 in the table). Notice that the
w is negative in the early years. Is that a bad sign? Not really. The business
ut because it is growing so fast.
Rapid growth is good news, not bad, as long as the b
cost of capital on its investments.
ws in Table 13.5 did not include a deduction for debt interest.
But we will not forget that acquisition of the concatenator b
tional debt. We will recognize that f
ws by the
weighted-av
the tax deductibility of its interest payments.
8
doesn’t change the aggre
provided
vestors. However
adjusted formulas showing how WA
. Allen, Principles of Corporate Finance,
wY
vings from deducting
v
y,
w-Hill, 2011).
388
Part Three Risk
TABLE 13.5 Forecasts of operating cash flow and investment for the concatenator manufacturing division (thousands of
dollars). Rapid expansion means that free cash flow is negative in the early years, because investment outstrips the cash
flow from operations. Free cash flow turns positive when gro
ws down.
1. Sales
2. Costs
3. Earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation,
and amortization (EBITDA) 1 2
4. Depreciation
5. Profit before tax 3 4
6. T
7. Profit after tax 5 6
8. Operating cash flow 4 7
9. Investment in plant and working capital
10. ree cash flow 8 9
1,189
1,070
119
45
74
25.9
48.1
93.1
166.7
73.6
1,421
1,279
1,700
1,530
142
59
83
29.1
54.0
113.0
200.0
87.1
170
76
94
32.9
61.1
137.1
240.0
102.9
2,020
1,818
202
99
103
36.1
67.0
166.0
200.0
34.1
2,391
2,152
239
128
111
38.9
72.2
200.2
160.0
40.2
2,510
2,260
250
136
114
39.9
74.1
210.1
130.6
79.5
Suppose that a sensible capital structure for the concatenator operation is 60%
equity and 40% debt.9 You estimate that the required rate of return on the equity is
12% and that the b
w at an interest rate of 5%. The weightedaverage cost of capital is therefore
E
D
3 (1 2 Tc)rdebt R 1 ¢ 3 requity ≤
V
V
3
(
)
4
(
5 .4 3 1 2 .35 5% 1 .6 3 12%) 5 8.5%
WACC 5 B
Calculating the Value of the Concatenator Business
The value of the concatenator operation is equal to the discounted value of the free
alue of the b
horizon, also discounted back to the present. That is,
PV 5
FCF1
FCF2
FCFH
1
1 c1
1
2
(11WACC)H
11WACC (11WACC)
PV (
)
PVH
(11WACC)H
1PV (horizon value)
usiness will continue to gro
ut it’s
w year by year to infinity. PVH stands in for the
v
H 1 1, H 1 2, and so on.
. Sometimes the boss tells everybody to
s a nice round number. We have pick
year because the business is expected to settle down to steady growth of 5% a year
from then on.
v
alue.
Let’s try the constant-growth formula that we introduced in Chapter 7:
value 5
r2g
9
et-value weights to compute WA
5
79.5
5 $2,271.4 thousand
.085 2 .05
present value of the business by debt. Remember
book value may be more or less
Chapter 13
The Weighted-Average Cost of Capital and Company Valuation
389
We now have all we need to calculate the value of the concatenator business today.
W
alue:
)
PV (business) 5 PV (
–5) 1 PV (
73.6
87.1
102.9
34.1
40.2
2,271.4
52
2
2
2
1
1
2
3
4
5
(1.085)
(1.085)
(1.085)
(1.085)
(1.085)5
1.085
5
Notice that when we use the weighted-average cost of capital to value a company, we
y’s debt and equity?” If you
need to value the equity
alue of any outstanding debt. Suppose
that the concatenator b
of the overall value of about $1,290,000. Then the equity in the business is w
$1,290,000 2 $516,000 5 $774,000.
Self-Test 13.8
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
million
10 million
50 million
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Debt
Preferred stock
Common stock
8
12
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
Earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation,
and amortization (EBITDA)
Depreciation
Pretax profit
Investment
80
20
60
12
100
30
70
15
115
35
80
18
120
40
80
20
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Cash and short-ter
A
eceivable
Inventories
Total
ities
Bonds
3
7
21
y
ity 10 years
ent yield
t
ity
Preferred stock (par v
share)
Common stock (par v
0)
Additional paid-in stockholders’
y
Retained earnings
Total
0.0
2.0
.1
9.9
10.0
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
WEB EXERCISE
finance.yahoo.com
www.bondsonline.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
Assets
Debt
V
V
Assets
Debt
V
V
y
40
y
24
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
EBIT
Interest expense
Taxable income
Taxes owed
Net income
Total income accr
MINICASE
yholders
0.0
2.0
8.0
2.8
5.2
7.2
0.0
0.0
10.0
3.5
6.5
6.5
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
FIGURE 13.2
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
TABLE 13.6
Working capital
Other assets
Total
Bank loan
360
40
erm debt
Preferred stock
Common stoc
Total
20
etained earnings
80
100
300
1. At year-end 2010, Sea Shore Salt had 10 million common shar
anding.
2. The compan
eferred shares with book v
00 per share. Each share receives
an ann
CHAPTER
14
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T F O U R
Financing
GM and Chrysler went bankrupt, but Ford managed to raise and keep enough financing to survive the recent
financial crisis and recession. It’s time to start learning about financing.
U
400
Part Four Financing
14.1 Creating Value with Financing Decisions
vestment decisions make shareholders wealthier
sions. For example, if your compan
w at 3% when the going rate is 4%, you
hav
The problem is that competition
in financial markets is more intense than in most product markets. In product markets,
companies re
ve advantages that allow positive-NPV investments. For e
y may have only a fe
same line of business in the same geographical area. Or it may be able to capitalize on
patents or technology or on customer recognition and loyalty. All this opens up the
ind projects with positive NPVs.
w protected niches in
markets. You can’t patent the design
of a new security. Moreover, in these markets you always face fast-moving competilocal, and federal gov
and governments that also come to New York, London, or Tok
The
inv
ely, these
inv
w, you would like to pay less than the going rate of intervestors into
ov
securities the
alues.
But what do we mean by true value?
True value
does not mean ultimate future value—we do not expect inv
currently available to investors.
W
capital markets and showed how dif
vestors to obtain consistently supeet all securities are fairly priced given the
v
v
et
price can never be a positive-NPV transaction.
All this means that it’
e or lose mone
strate
e mone
investors who supply the financing demand f
At the same time, it’s harder to
lose money because competition among investors prevents any one of them from
demanding more than f
Just remember as you read the following chapters: There are few free lunches
on Wall Street. . . . and few easy answers for the financial manager who must
decide which securities to issue.
14.2 Patterns of Corporate Financing
internally generated funds
Cash reinvested in the
firm: depreciation plus
earnings not paid out
as dividends
v
They can plo
the
y from e
for example, at Figure 14.1, which shows ho
w Chemical have generated cash. In each panel the green line shows the percentage yearly addition to the
s capital that was pro
The orange line shows the addition that came from ne
ws the
contribution from internally generated funds
vidends1).
1
does not represent a use of cash.
noncash expense.
xpense ev
Chapter 14
Introduction to Corporate Financing
401
FIGURE 14.1
Sources of
funds for FedEx and Dow
Chemical
o examples. Let’s
gest source of cash for both companies came
financial deficit
erence between the
cash companies need
and the amount
generated internally.
from plo
cash that the company needs is called the
. To mak
company must either sell new equity or borrow. Neither FedEx nor Do
w shares. In fact, as often as not they used cash to
buy back shares that had been issued in earlier years. In Figure 14.1 these repurchases
show up as negative issues of common stock. (Dow did mak
stock in 2009. This is not shown in Figure 14.1.).
Instead of issuing equity, both companies have made occasional large new issues
of debt, but they have done so for somewhat different reasons. For example, in 2004
o’s for $2.4 billion in cash. To help pay for this purchase, FedEx
sold $1.9 billion of short-term debt, called commercial paper. It then issued a
402
Part Four
Financing
package of 1-, 3-, and 5-year unsecured notes and used the proceeds to pay off the
commercial paper. Much of this increased borrowing was also subsequently repaid
over the next 4 years. Figure 14.1a shows both the spike in FedEx’s debt issuance in
2004 as well as the negative net debt issues in subsequent years.
FedEx’s debt issue was needed to offset a temporary increase in expenditures. In
contrast, Dow Chemical’s large debt issues in 2001 and 2002 coincided with a
period of operating losses. Thus, the debt issues in those years largely substituted
for internal funds.
Figure 14.2 shows the net effect of these financing decisions on the debt ratios of
the two companies. Debt ratios here are measured in two ways: alternatively using the
book value of the equity or its market value. For most of this period FedEx’s steady
accumulation of internal funds resulted in a fairly continuous decline in the debt ratio.
By contrast, Dow’s periodic large issues of debt to make up for shortfalls in profitability left it with much higher debt ratios.
There is nothing particularly remarkable about the financial structure of either
FedEx or Dow. For example, some companies, such as Google, rely almost entirely on
internal funds and have no debt. Others, such as Ford, are at the opposite extreme. Ford
has $147 billion of debt, and the book value of its equity is negative at 2$8 billion.2
Figure 14.3 shows how corporate America as a whole has financed its investments.
Notice again the importance of internal funds. Over the 15-year period, internally
FIGURE 14.2
Ratio of debt
to debt plus equity for FedEx
and Dow Chemical
(a) FedEx
50
Ratio computed using book values
Ratio computed using market values
Debt ratio (%)
40
30
20
2010
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998
1997
1996
0
1995
10
Year
(b) Dow Chemical
Ratio computed using book values
70
Ratio computed using market values
Debt ratio (%)
60
50
40
30
20
2010
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998
1997
1996
1994
0
1995
10
Year
2
In other words, Ford’s accumulated losses exceed the total cumulative amount that it has raised from shareholders.
Chapter 14
403
Introduction to Corporate Financing
FIGURE 14.3
Sources of
funds for U.S. nonfinancial
corporations, 1995–2010
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Research and. Statistics, “Flow of Funds
Accounts,” Table F.102 at
.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/cur
.
generated cash cov
wing.3
their new cash to buy back stock.
The gap was more than
gativ
Do Firms Rely Too Heavily on Internal Funds?
ers w
They believe that
y if they had to ask inves-
tors for it.
ing of managers, shareholders, debtholders, and so on. The shareholders and
debtholders would like to monitor management to make sure that it is pulling its
et v
vidual investors to keep
check on management, but large financial institutions are specialists in monitoring. So
es a public issue of stock or
w that they had better hav
y want a quiet
life, they will avoid going to the capital market to raise money and they will retain suff
We do not mean to paint managers as loafers. There are also rational reasons for
or example, the costs of issuing new securities
voided. Moreover, the announcement of a new equity issue is usually bad news
4
for investors, who w
v
v
ated with equity issues.
Are Firms Issuing Too Much Debt?
We hav
ve on average
uy back some of their stock. Has this
polic
Figure 14.4 pro
f
3
The
ve on the question. If all U.S. manuould be its ratio
. For e
w up in
4
Managers hav
to them, that is, when the
will buy a ne
the next chapter.
vestors. The outside inv
.
404
Part Four Financing
FIGURE 14.4
The ratio of
debt t
or
the nonfinancial corporate
sector
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Research and Statistics, “Flow of Funds
Accounts,” Table B.102 at
.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/cur
.
book values. This is because the market value of equity is substantially greater than
book v
wever, generally have
et debt ratio in
increased since 1955.5
2008–2009 as equity v
Should we be w
y were
ely to fall
. Undoubtedly GM,
, Washington Mutual, and the many other companies that faced insolvency in
the recent recession would all hav
ways follo
ratio is like f
,
b
its as well as
risks. So does debt, as we will see in Chapter 16.
Self-Test 14.1
14.3 Common Stock
We will now look more closely at the different sources of f
mon stock. We will stick with our example of Do
ge to be owned by one investor. For example,
you would need to lay your hands on about $42 billion if you wanted to own the whole
of Dow. Dow is owned by about 650,000 different investors, each of whom holds a
These inv
wn as shareholders, or stockholders. At the end of 2010 Do
common stock. Thus, if you were to buy one Do
ould own 1/167,000,000,
5
vely
Chapter 14
treasury stock
Stock that has been
repurchased by the
company and held in
its treasury.
issued shares
Shares that have been
issued by the company.
outstanding shares
Shares that have been
issued by the company
and are held by investors.
authorized share capital
Maximum number of
shares that the company
ed to issue.
par value
V
wn in
the company’s accounts.
additional paid-in capital
erence between
issue price and par
value of stock. Also
called capital surplus.
retained earnings
Earnings not paid out as
dividends.
Introduction to Corporate Financing
405
or about .00000009%, of the company. Of course, a large pension fund might hold
many thousands of Do
v
ve been
issued by Dow. The company has also issued a further 5 million shares, which it later
bought back from investors.
y’s treawn as treasury stock. The shares held by inv
issued and outstanding shares.
be issued but not outstanding.
If Dow wishes to raise more money
wever, there is a limit
to the number that it can issue without the approv
The
wn as the authorized share
capital—for Dow
w has already issued 1.172 billion
val.
Table 14.1 shows how the investment by Dow’
in the company’s books.
wn as its par
value. In Dow’s case each share has a par value of $2.50. Thus the total par value of
3 $2.50 per share 5 $2.931 billion. Par value
6
The price at which ne
vestors almost always e
value. The difference is entered into the company’s accounts as additional paid-in
capital, or capital surplus. For e
ould increase by 1 million 3
$2.50 5 $2.5 million and additional paid-in capital would increase by 1 million 3
($20 2 $2.50) 5 $17.5 million. You can see from this example that the funds raised
vided between par v
as immaterial, so is the allocation
alue and additional paid-in capital.
Besides buying ne
ute ne
v
vidends are instead plowed back into
the company. Table 14.1 shows that the cumulative amount of such retained earnings
is $17.736 billion.
Dow’s books also show the amount that the company has spent to repurchase its
own stock. The repurchase of the 5 million shares cost Dow $.239 billion. This is
mone
huge sums repurchasing shares.
The sum of the par v
wn as the net comof the f
uted directly by shareholders
TABLE 14.1 Book value of
common stockholders’
of Dow Chemical, December
31, 2010 (figures in billions)
6
406
Part Four Financing
w stock and indirectly when it plo
The book value of Dow’s net common equity is $17.839 billion. With 1.167 billion
valent to 17.839/1.167 5
et
value of Dow’
alue. Evidently investors believe that Dow’s assets are w
y originally cost.
Self-Test 14.2
Ownership of the Corporation
A corporation is o
As we saw in Chapter 2, over
vidual U.S. inv
ganizations.
The remainder belongs to financial institutions such as mutual funds, pension funds,
and insurance companies.
ain in Figure 14.5.
own
v
ver after the lenders have
received their entitlement. Usually the compan
viw inv
these investments will enable the compan
vidends in the future.
ve the ultimate control over ho
y is run. This
does not mean that shareholders can do whatever they like. For example, the bank that
lends to the company may place restrictions on how much extra borrowing the comy can undertake. However, the contract with the bank can never restrict all the
actions that the compan
e. The shareholders retain the residual
rights of control over these decisions.
Occasionally, the compan
v
e certain
actions. For e
or to merge with another company. On most other matters, shareholder control boils
down to the right to v
FIGURE 14.5
Holdings of
corporate equities, third
quarter, 2010
Board of Governors of the Federal R
e System, Division of Research and Statistics, “Flow of Funds
Accounts,” table L.213 at
.feder
ve.go
r
.
Chapter 14
Introduction to Corporate Financing
407
The board of directors usually consists of the company’s top management as well as
outside directors,
versees the management of the f
to vote on such matters as a ne
vidend. Most of the
time the board will go along with the management, but in crisis situations it can be
v
or e
ailing
chief executive.
Voting Procedures
majority voting
Voting system in which
each director is voted
on separately.
cumulative voting
Voting system in which
all votes that one
shareholder is allowed
to cast can be cast for
one candidate for the
board of directors.
proxy contest
Takeov
empt in
which outsiders compete
with management for
shareholders’ votes.
majority voting. In this
case each director is voted on separately
ote for each
yo
cumulative voting. The
directors are then voted on jointly
y choose, cast all
their votes for just one candidate. For example, suppose that there are five directors to
be elected and you o
You therefore have a total of 5 3 100 5 500 votes.
otes for any one candidate.
With a cumulative voting system you can cast all 500 votes for your favorite candidate.
Cumulative voting mak
That is why minority groups devote so much effort
to campaigning for cumulative voting.
On many issues a simple majority of the v
, but
there are some decisions that require a “supermajority” of, say, 75% of those eligible
to vote. For example, a supermajority vote is sometimes needed to approve a merger.
This makes it dif
en over and therefore helps to protect the
incumbent management.
ote in person or appoint a proxy to vote. The issues on
which they are asked to vote are rarely contested, particularly in the case of large publicly traded f
, however
proxy contests in which outsiders
compete with the f
se
tion. But the odds are stack
pay all the costs of presenting their case and obtaining votes.
Classes of Stock
preferred stock
Stock that tak
over common stock in
regard to dividends.
Most companies in the United States issue just one class of common stock. But a few,
such as Ford Motor and Google, have issued tw
ferent voting rights. For e
ut its management
does not want to give up its controlling interest. The existing shares could be labeled
“class A,
oting rights could be issued to outside investors.
o classes of stock with
That may be a good thing if the controlling shareholders then
v
. However, you can see the dangers here. If
ge block of votes, it may use these votes
e, it may exercise its
ain a business advantage.
14.4 Preferred Stock
net worth
Book value of common
stockholders’
preferred stock.
Usually when investors talk about equity or stock, the
But Dow Chemical has also issued 4 million shares of preferred stock, and this too is
y’s equity. The sum of Dow’
known as its net worth.
408
Part Four Financing
F
However
situations.
Lik
with relatively few e
ixed payments to the investor, and
vergally an equity security. This is because payment of a
vidend is within the discretion of the directors. The only obligation is that
no di
vidend has been
paid.7 If the company goes out of b
after the debtholders b
oting privileges.
antage to f
that want to raise new mone
w shareholders. However, if there is an
vide the holder with some
voting po
Companies cannot deduct preferred dividends when they calculate taxable
income. Like common stock dividends, preferred dividends are paid from aftertax income. For most industrial firms this is a serious deterrent to issuing preferred. However, regulated public utilities can take tax payments into account
when they negotiate with regulators the rates they charge customers. So they can
effectively pass the tax disadvantage of preferred on to the consumer
stock also has a particular attraction for banks, for regulators allow banks to lump
preferred in with common stock when calculating whether they have sufficient
equity capital.
Preferred stock does have one tax advantage. If one corporation buys another’s
stock, only 30% of the dividends it receiv
ed.
vidends on
vidends rather than capital gains.
vest. If it buys a bond, the interest will
y’s tax rate of 35%. If it b
lik
vidends can be viewed as “interest”), but the effective tax
rate is only 30% of 35%, .30 3 .35 5
floating-rate preferred
Preferred stock paying
dividends that vary with
short-term interest rates.
If you invest your firm’
ant to make
sure that when it is time to sell the stock, it won’t have plummeted in value. One
ariety preferred stock that pays a fixed dividend is that the
preferred’s market prices go up and down as interest rates change (because present
values fall when rates rise). So one ingenious banker thought up a wrinkle: Why not
link the di
interest rates rise and vice versa? The result is known as
preferred. If
you o
w that any change in interest rates will be
counterbalanced by a change in the dividend payment, so the value of your investment is protected.
Self-Test 14.3
7
ve. In other w
vidends that hav
Chapter 14
Introduction to Corporate Financing
409
14.5 Corporate Debt
w money, companies promise to make re
wed). However, corporations
have limit
. By this we mean that the promise to repay the debt is not
always kept. If the company gets into deep water, the company has the right to
default on the debt and to hand over the compan s assets to the lenders.
y only if the value of the assets is less than the
ver of assets
is f
or example, when P
as faced with several thousand creditors all
jostling for a better place in the queue. By the time the company had emerged from
y 3 years later, it had agreed to mak
still under dispute.
Because lenders are not re
y don’t normally have
any voting power. Also, the company’s payments of interest are re
Thus interest is paid out of befor
income, whereas di
-tax
income.
vernment pro
which it does not provide on stock.
Debt Comes in Many Forms
ety of debt issues. We will w
Interest Rate
prime rate
Benchmark interest rate
charged by banks.
The interest payment, or coupon,
ed
ues to pay $100 a year re
w interest rates change. You may also encounter zero-coupon bonds. In this case the f
e a regular interest payment.
es a single payment at maturity. Obviously, investors pay less for zerocoupon bonds.
est rate. For
example, your firm may be offered a loan at “1 percent over prime.” The prime rate is
ge customers with good to excellent
credit. (But the largest and most creditw
w at less
than prime.) The prime rate is adjusted up and down with the general level of interest
rates.
Floating-rate loans are not alw
y are tied to the
. This is known as the London
ed Rate, or LIBOR.
Self-Test 14.4
funded debt
Debt with more than
1 year remaining to
.
Maturity
Funded debt is any debt repayable more than 1 year from the date of
debt short-term and a 366-day debt long-term (except in leap years).
410
Part Four Financing
very conceiv
banks hav
extreme we f
sinking fund
Fund established to
retire debt before
.
callable bond
Bond that may be
repurchased by firm
befor
specified call price.
. For example,
ve forever. At the other
wing literally overnight.
Repayment Provisions
regular way, perhaps after an initial grace period. For bonds that are publicly traded,
this is done by means of a sinking fund.
uy back the bonds.
fund, inv
wer rate of interest. They know that they are
more likely to be repaid if the company sets aside some cash each year than if the
.
Suppose that a compan
ve years
later interest rates have fallen to 4%, and the price of the bond has risen dramatically.
If you were the company’s treasurer, wouldn’t you like to be able to retire the bonds
and issue some new bonds at the lower interest rate? W
wn as
callable bonds, the company does have the option to buy them back for the call price.8
y will wish to buy the
issue back if interest rates fall, and therefore the price of the bond will not rise above
the call price.
Figure 14.6 shows the risk of a call to the bondholder. The blue line is the value of
alue of a
bond with the same coupon rate and maturity but callable at $1,060 (i.e., 106% of face
value). At v
y will call the bonds is negAs rates f
bond continues to increase steadily in value, but since the capital appreciation of the
the straight bond.
A callable bond gives the company the option to retire the bonds early. But some
bonds give the investor
y
loans to Asian companies gave the lenders a repayment option. Consequently, when
the Asian crisis struck in 1997, these companies were f
FIGURE 14.6
Prices of
callable versus straight debt.
When interest rates fall, bond
prices rise. But the price of
the callable bond (orange
line) is limited by the call
price.
8
is simply to issue another bond at a lower interest rate.
wed to call the bond if the purpose
Chapter 14
Introduction to Corporate Financing
411
demanding their money back. Needless to say, companies that were already struggling
ve did not appreciate this additional burden.
Self-Test 14.5
subordinated debt
Debt that may be repaid
in bankruptcy only after
senior debt is paid.
secured debt
Debt that has first claim
on specified collateral in
the event of default.
Seniority
Some debts are subordinated. In the event of default the subordinated
s general creditors. The subordinated lender holds a
When you lend money to a f
the debt agreement says otherwise. However, this does not always put you at the front
of the line, for the f
v
tion of other lenders. That brings us to our ne
Security
w to buy your home, the sa
y will
tak
default on the loan payments, the S&L can seize your home.
w, the
loan.
collateral, and the debt is said to be secured. In the event
of def
ve a
s assets but only a junior claim on the collateral.
Default Risk Seniority and security do not guarantee payment. A debt can be
senior and secured but still as risky as a dizzy tightrope walker—it depends on the
v
s assets. In Chapter 6 we showed how the safety of
most corporate bonds can be judged from bond ratings provided by rating agencies
such as Moody’s and Standard & Poor’
default. At the other extreme, many speculative-grade (or “junk”) bonds may be teetering on the brink.
As you would expect, investors demand a high return from low-rated bonds. We
saw e
aultfree U.S. T
arious rating classes. The
lower-rated bonds do in fact offer higher promised yields to maturity.
eurodollars
Dollars held on deposit
in a bank outside the
United States.
Country and Currency These days capital mark
w few national boundy large f
w abroad. For example, an American company may choose to finance a ne
wing Swiss
francs from a Swiss bank, or it may expand its Dutch operation by issuing a bond in
Holland. Also many foreign companies come to the United States to borro
orld.
et
centered mainly in London. Banks from all over the world have branches in London.
The
and BNP P
y are there is to collect deposits in the major
or example, suppose an Arab sheikh has just received payment in dollars
for a large sale of oil to the United States. Rather than depositing the check in the
held in a bank outside the United States came to be known as eurodollars.
yen held outside Japan were termed euroyen, and so on.
,
412
eurobond
Bond that is marketed
internationally.
private placement
Sale of securities to
a limited number
of investors without
ering.
protective covenant
Restriction on a firm to
protect bondholders.
Part Four Financing
y
ay that a bank in the United States
may relend dollars that have been deposited with it.
w
w dollars from a bank in London.9
If a f
e an issue of long-term bonds, it can choose to do so in the
United States.
vely
vestors in several countries.
ve usually been marketed by the London branches
y hav
wn as eurobonds. A eurobond
y other currency. Unfortunately, when the
y was established it was called the euro. It is easy, therefore,
to confuse a eurobond (a bond that is sold internationally) with a bond that is denominated in euros.
Public versus Private Placements
yone who wishes to buy, and once they have been issued, they can be freely traded in
ets. In a private placement, the issue is sold directly to a small
vestment institutions. Privately
placed bonds cannot be resold to individuals in the United States and can be resold
only to other qualified institutional investors. However, there is increasingly active
trading among these investors.
We will have more to say about the difference between public issues and private
placements in the next chapter.
Protective Covenants
vestors lend to a company, the
w that
the
y back. But they expect that the company will use their
money well and not tak
To help ensure this, lenders usually
impose a number of conditions, or protective covenants, on companies that borrow
from them.
ws that
the
w at a reasonable rate of interest.
w in moderation are less likely to get into dif
e
vent others from pushing ahead of them in the queue if trouble occurs. So they will not allow the company
to create ne
ers are not suf
y impose.
Self-Test 14.6
9
Because the Federal Reserv
a tax on dollar deposits in the United States. Ov
wer slightly lower interest rates.
eep interest-free reserv
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Marriott Plan Enrages Holders of Its Bonds
Strong Covenants May Re-Emerge
Price Plunge
A Debt by Any Other Name
lease
Long-term rental
agreement.
The word debt sounds straightforward, but
e
identifiable. For example, accounts payable are simply obligations to pay for goods
that have already been delivered and are therefore lik
or e
wing
money to buy equipment, many companies lease
e a series of payments to the lessor (the owner of the
equipment). This is just lik
e payments on an outstanding loan.
What if the firm can’
e the payments? The lessor can then take back the equipment, which is precisely what w
borrowed money from the
lessor
For e
ord f
sion plan. That is a debt which the company will eventually need to pay.
There is nothing underhanded about these obligations. The
wn on the
company’s balance sheet as a liability. Sometimes, however, companies go to considerable lengths to ensure that inv
w ho
y hav
wed. For
e
special-purpose entities
(SPEs), which raised cash by a mixture of equity and debt and then used that debt to
y. None of this debt sho
s balance sheet.
413
414
Part Four Financing
▲
EXAMPLE 14.1
The Terms of Procter & Gamble’s Bond Issue
Now that you are familiar with some of the jargon, you might like to look at an
example of a bond issue. Table 14.2 is a summary of the terms of a bond issue in
2009 by Procter & Gamble. We have added some explanatory notes.
TABLE 14.2
Procter & Gamble’s Debt Issue
Innovation in the Debt Market
We hav
You might think
ves you all the choice you need. Yet almost ev
advisers dream up new types of debt. Here is one example of a bond that proved popuThe Rise and Fall of Asset-Backed Bonds
wing money
directly, companies sometimes b
ws
wn as an asset-backed bond. For e
bile loans, student loans, and credit card receivables have all been bundled together
and remarketed as asset-backed bonds. However, by f
age lending.
Suppose your compan
uyers of
wever, you don’t want to wait until the loans are
y now, you can sell mortgage pass-through
back
uying
a share of the payments made by the underlying pool of mortgages. For example, if
interest rates f
Chapter 14
Introduction to Corporate Financing
415
. That is not generally popular with these holders, for
they get their money back just when they don’t w
w.
sev
ferent classes of security
wn as collateralized debt obligations (or CDOs).
For example, an
senior inv
, junior
By 2007 over half of the new issues of CDOs involved e
, senior investors in these CDOs
ault on an
wever, even
market that would lead to widespread defaults
v
vealed that two of its hedge funds had invested heavily in CDOs that became
as rescued with help
e, b
There is a great v
inv
As long as you can convince
xisting securities, you may
be able to create an entirely new one. We can imagine a copper mining company issuorld copper price. We
know of no such security, b
ws?—it
might generate considerable interest among investors.
V
ve different tastes, levels of wealth, rates of
tax, and so on. Why not offer them a choice? Of course, the problem is the expense of
designing and marketing ne
w security that
will appeal to investors, you may be able to issue it on especially favorable terms and
thus increase the value of your company.
14.6 Convertible Securities
warrant
Right to buy shares from a
company at a stipulated
price before a set date.
▲
EXAMPLE 14.2
We have seen that companies sometimes have the option to repay an issue of bonds
.
investors have an option. The most dramatic case is provided by a warrant, which is nothing but an option. Companies often
issue w
Warrants
Macaw Bill wishes to make a bond issue, which could include some warrants as a
“sweetener.” Each warrant might allow you to purchase one share of Macaw stock
at a price of $50 any time during the next 5 years. If Macaw’s st
orms well,
that option could turn out to be very valuable. For instance, if the stock price at the
end of the 5 years is $80, then you pay the company $50 and receive in exchange
a share worth $80. Of course, an investment in warrants also has its perils. If the
price of Macaw stock fails to rise above $50, then the warrants expire worthless.
convertible bond
Bond that the holder
may exchange for a
specified amount of
another security
A convertible bond gives its owner the option to exchange the bond for a predeterThe conv
ny’s share price will zoom up so that the bond can be conv
the shares zoom down, there is no obligation to conv
, investors v
eep the bond or e
shares, and therefore a conv
that is not convertible.
416
Part Four Financing
The convertible is rather like a package of a bond and a w
important difference: When the owners of a convertible wish to exercise their options
to buy shares, they do not pay cash—they just e
stock.
Companies may also issue conv
vestor
receiv
ed dividend payments but has the option to exchange
y’s common stock.
Do
v
These examples do not e
.
In f
the
SUMMARY
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
finance.yahoo.com
www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/data.htm
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHAPTER
15
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T F O U R
Financing
Trading opens on NASDAQ for shares in Google.
B
15.1 Venture Capital
venture capital
Money invested to
finance a new firm.
424
You have taken a big step. With a couple of friends, you hav
open a number of fast-food outlets, offering innovative combinations of national
w mein with Yorkshire
ast-food business costs money, but, after pooling your savings and borro
ve raised $100,000 and purchased
1 million shares in the new company.
zero-stage investment, your company’s
assets are $100,000 plus the idea for your new product.
That $100,000 is enough to get the business off the ground, b
es off,
w
with funds provided directly by managers or by their friends and f
ve
using bank loans and reinv
vestment, you will probably need
v
y in return for part of the
wn as venture capital, and it is providuals, and investment institutions such as pension funds.
y. But it is
as hard to convince a v
vest in your business as it is to get a first
novel published. Y
business plan.
et, the production method, and the resources—time, money,
employees, plant, and equipment—needed for success. It helps if you can point to the
f
savings in the company, you signal your faith in the business.
The venture capital compan
ws that the success of a new business depends on
the effort its managers put in.
y deal so that you
have a strong incentive to work hard. For example, if you agree to accept a modest salalue of your investment in the company’s stock), the venture capital company knows you will be committed to w
hard. However, if you insist on a watertight employment contract and a fat salary, you
won’
enture capital.
Y
ely to persuade a venture capitalist to give you all at once as much
money as you need. Rather, the f
xt
vince the venture capital company to buy
w shares for $.50 each. This will give it one-half o
o
the v
usiness. After this st-stage
y’s balance sheet looks like this:
Chapter 15
How Corporations Raise Venture Capital and Issue Securities
425
Self-Test 15.1
usiness has grown to the point at which it needs a
. This second-stage
volve the issue of a
nal backers and some by other v
financing would then be as follows:
The balance sheet after the new
Notice that the v
wned by you and your friends
has no
gin to sound like a money machine?
It was so only because you have made a success of the business and new investors are
uy a share in the business.
asn’
ould catch on. If it hadn’t caught on, the v
f
ve refused to put up more funds.
Y
vestment, b
The
second-stage investors hav
y.
w 3 million shares outstanding, and the second-stage investors hold
was w
ge investment—must have decided that the company
Your one-third share is therefore also w
Venture Capital Companies
Some young companies grow with the aid of equity investment provided by wealthy
indi
wn as angel investors. Many others raise capital from specialist venture
v
nies to invest in, and then work with these companies as they try to grow. In addition,
corporate
venturers by providing capital to new innovative companies.
Most venture capital funds are or
v
ed
v
The
management company
overseeing the investments and, in return, receiv
ed fee as well as a share of the
Y
uy out
whole companies and then take them private. The general term for these activities is
vesting.
V
ve investors. They are usually represented on
each company’s board of directors, the
pany, and they provide ongoing advice. This advice can be very valuable to businesses
et.
426
Part Four Financing
For ev
successful, self-suf
come tw
enture capital inv
ve as
enture capital investment. First, don’t shy away from
w probability of success. But don’t buy into a business unless
chance
et. There’s no
ward is big if you win. Second, cut your losses;
identify losers early, and if you can’
example—don’t throw good mone
Very few new businesses make it big, but those that do can be v
venture capitalists keep sane by reminding themselves of the success stories—those
e Genentech, Intel and FedEx.1
15.2 The Initial Public Offering
For man
y need more capital than can
viduals or venture capitalists. At this
point one solution is to sell the business to a lar
y entrepreneurs do not
ureaucracy and would prefer instead to remain the boss. In
this case, the company may choose to raise mone
initial public offering (IPO)
ering of stock to
the general public.
A firm is said to go public when it sells its first issue of shares in a gener
ering
to investors. This first sale of stock is called an initial public
, or IPO.
An IPO is called a
y. It is a
of
y’
enfer therew investors,
v
y
w cash at the
ve involved gov
f stock
or example, the Japanese government raised $12.6 billion
by selling its stock in Nippon Telegraph and Telephone, and the Italian gov
y Enel. Even
these two issues were dw
We hav
e an IPO to raise new capital or to enable the
existing shareholders to cash out, but there may be other benefits to going public. For
example, the company’s stock price provides a readily available yardstick of perforw
And,
because information about the company becomes more widely av
div
wing cost.
antages to ha
ve
v
for b
vately owned. Even in the United States many f
vate, unlisted companies. They include some v
ge operations,
gill, and Levi Strauss.
cess in the United States as a one-w
verse and
vately owned. For a somewhat extreme e
y
v
in 1960. In 1984 the management bought out the company and took it private, and it
remained private until 2001, when it had its second public offering. But the experiment
did not last long, for 6 years later Aramark was the object of yet another buyout that
took the company private once again.
1
F
, the successes seem to have outweighed the f
v
427
How Corporations Raise Venture Capital and Issue Securities
Chapter 15
volv
y and at the
have become more v
to prev
WorldCom, b
y Act.
urden on small public
vate ownership.
v
Arranging a Public Issue
underwriter
Firm that buys an issue
of securities from a
company and resells it
to the public.
Underwriters are investment banking firms that act as financial midwives to a new
issue. Usually they play a triple role—first providing the company with procedural and financial advice, then buying the stock, and finally reselling it to the
public. A small IPO may hav
, but larger issues usually require
uy the issue and resell it.
spread
er
een
er price and
price paid b
er.
b
receiv
spread—that is, the
wed by the company to sell
y won’
happens, the
y can for
sell as much of the issue as possible b
Before any stock can be sold to the public, the company must register the issue with
This involv
detailed and sometimes cumbersome re
, existing b
The SEC does not evaluate the wisdom of an inv
ut
it does check the registration statement for accuracy and completeness.
also comply with the “blue-sky” la
y seek to
y to investors.2
prospectus
Formal summary that
provides information on
an issue of securities.
v
vestors have jok
y read proy would nev
y new issue.
provides a streamlined version of a possible prospectus for your restaurant business.
The compan
To gauge how
w calculations like
those described in Chapter 7. The
involv
pr
y inv
.
w,”
which giv
potential investors. These inv
y’
yw
ely orders. Although inv
uy.
w that if they w
underpricing
Issuing securities at an
ering price set below
the true value of the
.
xpressions of interest.
stock, b
ely to be cautious because they will be left with any
unsold stock if they overestimate investor demand.
fering. Underpricing, they argue, is needed to
2
Sometimes states go be
issue w
When Apple Computer
v
vestors in the state. The state relented later, after the
vestors ob
”
428
Part Four Financing
tempt investors to buy stock and to reduce the cost of marketing the issue to customers. Underpricing represents a cost to the existing owners since the new investors
are allowed to buy shares in the firm at a favorable price.
Sometimes ne
or example, when the prospectus
y
wever, the enthusi-
w
asm for eBay’s Web-based auction system w
The ne
uy eBay; over
The experience of eBay is not typical, b
wing the sale. For example,
one study of more than 12,000 new issues between 1960 and 2009 found an average
3
vestors
would have been prepared to pay much more than the
▲
EXAMPLE 15.1
Underpricing of IPOs
Suppose an IPO is a secondary issue and the firm’s founders sell part of their holding to investors. Clearly, if the shares are sold for less than their true worth, the founder an opportunity loss.
But what if the IPO is a primary issue that raises new cash for the company? Do
the founders care whether the shares are sold for less than their market value? The
following example illustrates that they do care.
Suppose Cosmos.com has 2 million shares outstanding and no
ers a further
1 million shares to investors at $50. On the first day of trading the share price jumps
to $80, so the shares that the company sold for $50 million are now worth $80 million.
The total market capitalization of the company is 3 million 3 $80 5 $240 million.
The value of the founders’ shares is equal to the total value of the company less the
value of the shares that have been sold to the public—in other words, $240 million 2
$80 million 5 $160 million. The founders might justifiably rejoice at their good fortune.
However, if the company had issued shares at a higher price, it would have needed to
sell fewer shares to raise the $50 million that it needs and the founders would have
retained a larger share of the company. For example, suppose that the outside investors, who put up $50 million, received shares that were wo h only $50 million. In that
case the value of the founders’ shares would be $240 million 2 $50 million 5
$190 million.
T
ect of selling shares below their true value is to transfer $30 million of value
from the founders to the investors who buy the new shares.
v
v
only a small share of these hot issues. If it is ov
w
wn as the winner’s curse.4
ely to receiv
xpensiv
yone can become wealthy by buyant to buy it and the
Y
ely to get
vestors are unlikely to
ge
vesverage.
3
vided on Jay Ritter’s home page, bear
4
.
alue on the auctioned object. Therealue. W
v
ve ov
v
Chapter 15
▲
EXAMPLE 15.2
How Corporations Raise Venture Capital and Issue Securities
429
Underpricing of IPOs and Investor Returns
Suppose that an investor will earn an immediate 10% return on underpriced IPOs
and lose 5% on overpriced IPOs. But because of high demand, you may get only
half the shares you bid for when the issue is underpriced. Suppose you bid for
$1,000 of shares in two issues, one overpriced and the other underpriced. You are
awarded the full $1,000 of the overpriced issue but only $500 worth of shares in the
underpriced issue. The net gain on y
o investments is (.10 3 $500) 2 (.05 3
$1,000) 5 0. Your net profit is zero, despite the fact that, on average, the IPOs are
underpriced (10% underpricing versus 5% overpricing). You hav
ered the
winner’s curse: You “win” a larger allotment of shares when they are overpriced.
Self-Test 15.2
flotation costs
The costs incurred when a
w securities
to the public.
The costs of a ne
costs. Underpricing is not the only
act, when people talk about the cost of a new issue, they
often think only of the direct costs of the issue. For example, preparation of the registration statement and prospectus involves management, legal counsel, and accountants, as well as underwriters and their advisers. There is also the underwriting
spread. (Remember, underwriters make their profit by selling the issue at a higher
price than they paid for it.) For most issues between $20 million and $80 million, the
spread is 7%.
Look at the blue bars (corresponding to IPOs) in Figure 15.1. These show the direct
costs of going public. For all b
istrative costs are likely to absorb 7% to 8% of the proceeds from the issue. For the
gest IPOs, these direct costs may amount to only 5% of the proceeds.
v
FIGURE 15.1
Total direct costs as a percentage of gross proceeds, 2004–2008. The total
direct costs f
erings (IPOs),
erings (SEOs), convertible
bonds, and straight bonds are composed of underwriter spreads and other direct
expenses.
Source: We are grateful to Nickolay Gantchev for undertaking these calculations, which update tables in Immoo Lee,
a
er, and Quanshui Zhao, “The Costs of Raising Capital,” Journal of Financial Research 19
(Spring 1996), pp. 59–74. Used with permission. Updates courtesy of Nickolay Gantchev.
430
▲
EXAMPLE 15.3
Part Four Financing
Costs of an IPO
The largest U.S. IPO was the $19.7 billion sale of stock by the credit card company
Visa in 2008. A syndicate of 45 underwriters acquired a total of 446.6 million Visa
shares for $42.768 each and then resold them t
ering price of
$44. T
ers’ spread was therefore $44 2 $42.768 5 $1.232. The firm also
paid a total of $45.5 million in legal fees and other costs.5 Therefore, the direct costs
of the Visa issue were as follows:
The total amount of money raised by the issue was 446.6 million 3 $44 5
$19,650 million. Of this sum 3% was absorbed by direct expenses (that is,
595.7/19,650 5 .030).
In addition to these direct costs, there was the cost of underpricing. By the end
of the first day’s trading Visa’s stock price had risen to $56.50, so investors valued
Visa shares at 446.6 3 $56.50 5 $25,233 million. In other words, Visa sold stock for
$25,233 2 $19,650 5 $5,583 less than its market value. This was the cost of
underpricing.
Managers commonly focus only on the direct costs of an issue. But, when we
add in the cost of underpricing, the total cost of the Visa issue as a proportion of
the market value of the shares was ($595.7 1 $5,583)/$25,233 5 .24, or 24%.
Self-Test 15.3
Other New-Issue Procedures
Almost all IPOs in the United States use the bookbuilding method. In other words,
uild up a book of likely orders, b
y at
a discount, and then resell it to investors. This method is in some ways like an auction, since potential buyers indicate how man
uy at
given prices. However
The advantage of the bookbuilding method is that it allows
underwriters to give preference to those investors whose bids are most helpful in setfer them a rew
ics of the method point to the dangers of allowing the underwriters to decide who is
allotted stock.
ve way to issue stock is by means of an open auction. In this case, investors are in
w many shares
they wish to buy.
v
5
ve costs. For e
y do not include management time spent
Chapter 15
431
How Corporations Raise Venture Capital and Issue Securities
including the U.S. T
of common stock are fairly rare. However, in 2004 Google simultaneously raised
eyebro
orld’
gest IPO to be sold by auction.
The Underwriters
We hav
new issue from the company, and reselling it to inv
the company to make its initial public of
viding advice, buying a
t just help
ver a company
Successful underwriting requires considerable e
large issue f
veral hundred milery red faces. Underwriting in the United States is therefore
dominated by the major inv
ne
gers.
They include such giants as Citigroup, JPMorgan, Bank of
ynch,
and Goldman Sachs. Lar
vily involv
.
Underwriting is not always fun. In
fered its
shareholders two ne
iv
y currently held.6 The underwriters to the issue guaranteed that at the end of 8 weeks they
would buy any ne
ant. At the time of the offer
y
would not hav
, they reckoned without the turbulent market in bank shares that year. The bank’s shareholders w
money they were asked to provide would largely go to bailing out the bondholders
belo
anted
shares w
Companies get to make only one IPO, b
time. W
not handle an issue unless they believe the facts have been presented fairly to investors. If a ne
ind
themselves v
or example, in 1999 the softw
pany V
The next day trading opened at $299 a
ut then the price began to sag. W
allen belo
tled VA Linux investors sued the underwriters for overhyping the issue. VA Linux
inv
ved. Investment banks soon found themselv
vidence emerged that they had deliberately
oversold many of the issues that the
There w
ged that several well-kno
ers had eng
s seal of approval for a new
issue no longer seemed as valuable as it once had.
15.3 General Cash Offers by Public Companies
seasoned offering
Sale of securities by a
firm that is already
publicly traded.
w
time it will need to raise more money by issuing stock or bonds. An issue of additional
stock by a compan
seasoned
.
An
v
6
wn as a rights issue. W
.
432
Part Four Financing
If a stock issue requires an increase in the company’
fer to
investors at large or by making a rights issue, which is limited to existing shareholders. In the latter case, the company offers the shareholders the opportunity, or
right, to buy more shares at an “attractive” price. For example, if the current stock
price is $100, the company might offer investors an additional share at $50 for each
y hold. Suppose that before the issue an investor has one share worth
$100 and $50 in the bank. If the investor takes up the offer of a new share, that
vestor’s bank account to the company’s. The
investor now has two shares that are a claim on the original assets w
on the $50 cash that the company has raised. So the two shares are worth a total of
$150, or $75 each.
rights issue
Issue of securities
ered only to current
stockholders.
▲
EXAMPLE 15.4
Rights Issues
We have already come across one ex
er by the British
bank HBOS,
ers. Let us look more
closely at another issue.
In May 2010,
y National Grid needed to
raise over £3 billion. It did so b
ering its existing shareholders the right t
o
new shares for every five that they currently held. The new shares were priced at
£3.35 each, some 44% below the preannouncement price of £5.95.
Before the issue, National Grid had about 2.5 billion shares outstanding, which
were priced at £5.95 each. So investors valued the company at 2.5 3 £5.95 5
£14.875 billion. The new issue increased the total number of shares by (2/5) 3
2.5 billion 5 1 billion and therefore raised 1 billion 3 £3.35 5 £3.35
ect,
the issue increased the total value of the company to 14.875 1 3.35 5 £18.225 billion
and reduced the value of each share to £18.225/3.5 5 £5.207.
Suppose that just before the issue you hold five shares of National Grid valued at
5 3 £5.95 5 £29.75. If you decide to tak
er, you would need to lay
out 2 3 £3.35 5 £6.70 and the value of your shareholding would increase by exactly
£6.70 to 7 3
5 £36.45. You would get what you paid for.
stock, but in the United States rights issues are now very rare. We therefore will
concentrate on the mechanics of the general cash offer.
General Cash Offers and Shelf Registration
general cash offer
Sale of securities open
to all investors by an
already-public
company.
es a general cash offer of debt or equity, it essentially
follo
This means that it must first
register the issue with the SEC and draw up a prospectus.7 Before settling on the issue
vestors and build up a book of
likely orders.
y in turn
will of
gistration statement ev
y
issue new securities. Instead, the
cov
sold to the public with scant additional paperwork, whenev
7
, but as long as these
y do not need to be registered with the SEC.
Chapter 15
shelf registration
A procedure that allows
firms to file one
registration statement
for several issues of the
same security.
433
How Corporations Raise Venture Capital and Issue Securities
registration is put “on the shelf,
ve price. This is called shelf registration—the
en do
.
Suppose that your compan
ov
approval to issue up to $200 million of debt, but it isn’
required to w
y particular
w has
y. Nor is it
gistration statement may
.
Now you can sit back and issue debt as needed, in bits and pieces if you like.
Suppose JPMorgan comes across an insurance company with $10 million ready to
inv
s a good
deal, you say OK and the deal is done, subject to only a little additional paperwork.
JPMorgan then resells the bonds to the insurance company
than it paid for them.
w.” You in
ge inv
Thus shelf registration offers several advantages:
1.
2.
3.
xcessive costs.
e advantage of “market conditions” (although
any f
av
et conditions could
make a lot more money by quitting and becoming a bond or stock trader instead).
4. The issuing f
e sure that underwriters compete for its business.
issues. Sometimes they believe the
ge issue
unusual feature or when the firm believes it needs the inv
er’s counsel or
stamp of approval on the issue. Thus shelf registration is less often used for issues of
common stock than for g
Costs of the General Cash Offer
v
, it incurs substantial administrative costs. Also,
price that they expect to receive from investors. Look back at Figure 15.1, which
shows the av
ve costs for several types of
Y
v
additional compensation for the greater risk they take in buying and reselling equity.
Market Reaction to Stock Issues
Because stock issues usually throw a sizable number of new shares onto the market, it
is widely believed that the
issue is v
, it is thought, be so severe as to make it
almost impossible to raise money.
This belief in price pressure implies that a new issue depresses the stock price temalue. However, that view doesn’
ery well with
iciency. If the stock price falls solely because of increased supply, then that stock would offer a higher return than comparable stocks and investors
would be attracted to it as ants to a picnic.
434
Part Four Financing
Economists who have studied ne
ve generally found
that the announcement of the issue does result in a decline in the stock price. For
8
While this
may not sound ov
ge fraction of the money
raised. Suppose that a company with a market value of equity of $5 billion announces
its intention to issue $500 million of additional equity and thereby causes the stock
price to drop by 3%. The loss in value is .03 3 $5 billion, or $150 million. That’s 30%
of the amount of money raised (.30 3
5
the additional supply? Possibly, b
Suppose managers (who hav
tors) kno
price, it will give the ne
ve explanation.
vesy sells new stock at this low
go the new investment
rather than sell shares at too lo
o
the position is reversed. If the company sells ne
xisting shareholders at the
expense of the ne
ven if the new
cash were just put in the bank.
Of course inv
The
ely to
issue stock when the
v alued, and therefore the
stock down accordingly. The tendency for stock prices to decline at the time of an
issue may have nothing to do with increased supply. Instead, the stock issue may
simply be a signal that well-informed managers believe the market has overpriced
the stock.9
15.4 The Private Placement
private placement
Sale of securities to a
limited number of
investors without a
ering.
Whenever a compan
es a public of
gister the issue with the SEC. It
could av
vately.
ast
vate placement, b
gely to knowledgeable investors.
One disadv
v
vestor cannot easily resell the
security.
invest huge sums of mone
ed
uy unre
ge
gistered securities among themselves.
As you would e
vate placement than to make a
public issue.
ge issues where costs are
antage for companies making smaller issues.
Another adv
vate placement is that the debt contract can be customto change the terms of the debt, it is much simpler to do this with a private placement
where only a few inv
volved.
Therefore, it is not surprising that private placements occup
the corporate debt market, namely
These are
8
W. Mullins, “Equity Issues and Of
” Journal of Financial
W. Masulis and A. N. K
ar, “Seasoned Equity
vestigation,” Journal of Financial Economics
W
elson and M. M. P
aluation Ef
Process,” Journal of Financial Economics
9
This explanation was dev
vestment
Decisions
ve Information That Investors Do Not Have,” Journal of Financial Economics
13 (1984), pp. 187–222.
See, for e
Economics
Of
.
Chapter 15
How Corporations Raise Venture Capital and Issue Securities
435
ace the highest costs in public issues, that require the most detailed
inv
W
ge, safe, and conv
vate
or
example, in 2005, Berkshire Hathaway, the investment compan
W
wed $3.75 billion in a private placement. Nev
antages of
private placement—avoiding registration costs and establishing a direct relationship
Of course these advantages are not free. Lenders in private placements have to be
y face and for the costs of research and negotiation. They
also have to be compensated for holding an asset that is not easily resold. All these
f
about the dif
vate placements and public issues,
but a typical yield dif
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
finance.yahoo.com
www.sec.gov/edgar/searchedgar/webusers.htm
bear.cba
.ufl.edu/ritter
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
MINICASE
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
APPENDIX
Hotch Pot’s New-Issue PROSPECTUS10
Prospectus
Silverman Pinch Inc.
April 1, 2012
The Company
Use of Proceeds
Dividend Policy
Certain Factors
Substantial Capital Needs
Competition
Capitalization
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Prospectus Summary
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Selected Financial Data
Management’s Analysis of Results of
Operations and Financial Condition
Business
Management
Executive Compensation
Certain Transactions
Lock-Up Agreements
Description of Capital Stock
Underwriting
Legal Matters
Legal Proceedings
Experts
Financial Statements
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Principal and Selling Stockholders
CHAPTER
16
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T F I V E
Debt and Payout Policy
River Cruises is reviewing its capital structure. More debt would increase the expected return on its shares, but
would it add value?
A
446
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
TABLE 16.1 Median ratios
of debt to total capital for a
sample of nonfinancial
industries, 2009
Note: Debt to total capital ratio 5 D/(D 1
e D and
E are the book values of long-term debt and equity.
Source: Compustat.
16.1 How Borrowing Affects Value
in a Tax-Free Economy
v
Yogi Berra. “Should I cut it
into four slices as usual, Yogi?” asks the pizza man. “No,” replies Yogi, “Cut it into eight; I’m
”
capital structure
The mix of long-term
debt and equity
financing.
If you understand why more slices won’t sate Yogi’s appetite, you will hav
culty understanding when a company’s choice of capital structure does not increase
the underlying v
Think of a simple balance sheet, with all entries e
et values:
Assets
Liabilities and Stockholders’ Equity
Value of cash flows from the firm’s
real assets and operations
Value of firm
Market value of debt
Market value of equity
Value of firm
have to balance!) Therefore, if you add up the market v
s real assets and operations.
In fact, the v
determines the aggregate v
ways equal. (Balance sheets
s debt and
ws from the
ws determines the value of the f
, by using more debt and less equity financ-
ing, overall value should not change.
hand side determines how it is sliced.
y
parts as it likes, but the v
ways sum back to the value of the
w. (Of course, we have to mak
w stream
is lost in the slicing. We cannot say “The value of a pizza is independent of how it is
sliced” if the slicer is also a nibbler.)
The basic idea here (the value of a pizza does not depend on how it is sliced) has
v
Y
v
, always referred to as “MM,” showed in 1958 that the
v
ws are “sliced.” More precisely,
Chapter 16
Debt Policy
447
they demonstrated the following proposition: When there are no taxes and capital
markets function well, the market value of a company does not depend on its
capital structure. In other words, financial managers cannot increase value by
changing the mix of securities used to finance the company.
For example, capital markets have to be “well functioning.” This means that investors can trade securities without restrictions and can borrow or lend on the same
ets are eff
fairly priced giv
vailable to investors. (We discussed market
ef
y in Chapter 7.) MM’
taxes, and it ignores the costs encountered if a firm borrows too much and lands in
financial distress.
if other practical complications are encountered. But the best way to start
s argument. To keep things as simple as
possible, we will ignor
.
MM’s Argument
Cleo, the president of River Cruises, is revie
Antony
. Table 16.2 sho
The company
The
expected earnings and dividends per share are $1.25, b
restructuring
Process of changing the
firm’s capital structure
without changing its real
assets.
TABLE 16.2 River Cruises is
entir
inanced.
Although it expects to have
an income of $125,000 in
per
, this income is not
certain. This table shows the
return to the stockholder
erent assumptions
about operating income. We
assume no taxes.
or e
fall to $.75 in a slump or they could jump to $1.75 in a boom.
xpects to produce a lev
ings and dividends in perpetuity. No gro
xpected
xpected di
vided
5 .125, or 12.5%.
Cleo has come to the conclusion that shareholders w
pan
. She therefore proposes to issue
$500,000 of debt at an interest rate of 10% and to use the proceeds to repurchase
This is called a restructuring. Notice that the $500,000 raised by the
ne
order to repurchase and retire 50,000 shares. Therefore, the assets and investment polic
fected. Only the f
What would MM say about this ne
Operating income is the same, so the v
With
$500,000 in ne
$500,000, that is, 50,000 shares at $10 per share. The total value of the debt and equity
448
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
Since the v
orse
v
The ov
alue of River
alls from $1 million to $500,000, but shareholders have also received
$500,000 in cash.
Antony points all this out: “The restructuring doesn’t mak
y
, Cleo. Why bother? Capital structure doesn’t matter.”
Self-Test 16.1
How Borrowing Affects Earnings per Share
Cleo is unconvinced. She prepares Table 16.3 and Figure 16.1 to show ho
wing
Tables 16.2 and 16.3
sho
Table 16.3 also sho
ersus
$1.75) and more “downside” ($.50 versus $.75).
The orange line in
16.1 shows ho
ould v
of the data in Table 16.2. The blue line shows ho
y mov
data in Table 16.3.
Cleo reasons as follo
ould v
. It is therefore a plot of the
use of debt, b
increased. We could be heading for a recession but it
doesn’t look likely
debt issue.”
As financial manager, Antony replies as follo
wing will
increase earnings per share as long as there’s no slump.” But we’re not really doing
anything for shareholders that they can’t do on their own. Suppose Riv
not
w. In that case an inv
w $10, and then invest
$20 in two shares. Such an investor would put up only $10 of her own money.
Table 16.4 shows how the payoffs on this $10 investment v
v
TABLE 16.3 River Cruises is
wondering whether to issue
$500,000 of debt at an
interest rate of 10% and
repurchase 50,000 shares.
This table shows the return to
the shareholder under
erent assumptions about
operating income. Returns to
shareholders are increased in
normal and boom times but
fall more in slumps.
Chapter 16
Debt Policy
449
FIGUR 16.1 Borrowing
increases River Cruises’
earnings per share (EPS)
when operating income is
greater than $100,000 but
reduces it when operating
income is less than $100,000.
Expected EPS rises from
$1.25 to $1.50.
operating income. Y
vestor
would get by buying one share in the compan
last two lines of Tables 16.3 and 16.4.) It makes no dif
w directly or whether Riv
ws on their behalf. Therefore, if River
ws, it will not allow investors to do anything that they
could not do already, and so it cannot increase the v
“W
gument in reverse and show that investors also won’t be
any worse of
vestor who owns two shares in the
compan
v
ws money, there is some
wer than before. If that possibility is not
to our investor’s taste, he can b
y and also
invest $10 in the firm’s debt. Table 16.5 shows how the payoff on this investment v ies with Riv
You can see that these payof
xactly
the same as the inv
Tables
16.2 and 16.5.) By lending half of his capital (by inv
ver Cruises’ debt), the
investor exactly offsets the company’
wing. So if Riv
ws, it won’t stop investors from doing an
y could previously do.”
TABLE 16.4 Individual
inv
e River
Cruises’
owing by borrowing
on their own. In this example
we assume that River Cruises
has not restructur
wever,
the inv or can put up $10 of
her own money,
w $10
,
same rat
Table 16.3.
n as in
TABLE 16.5 Individual
investors can also undo the
ects of River Cruises’
borrowing. Here the investor
buys one share for $10 and
lends out $10 more. Compare
these rates of return to the
original returns of River
Cruises in Table 16.2.
450
MM’s proposition I (debtirrelevance proposition)
The value of a firm is
ected by its capital
structure.
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
This re-creates MM’s original argument.2 As long as inv
w or lend
on their o
The v
must be the same as before. In other words, the value of the firm must be unaffected by its capital structure.
This conclusion is widely known as MM’s proposition I.
MM debt-irrelevance proposition, because it shows that under ideal conditions
s debt policy shouldn’
Self-Test 16.2
How Borrowing Affects Risk and Return
Figure 16.2
River Cruises. The upper circles represent f
“normal,
vance proposition for
alue; the lower circles, expected, or
Thus if the f
raises $500,000 in debt and uses the proceeds to repurchase and retire shares, the
remaining shares must be w
must
stay at $1 million.
The two bottom circles in Figure 16.2 are also the same size. But notice that the
bottom right circle sho
ver
They get more than half of the expected income
“pie.
f? MM say no.
operating risk
(business risk)
Risk in firm’s operating
income.
financial leverage
Debt financing to
ects of
changes in operating
income on the returns to
stockholders.
Look again at Tables 16.2 and 16.3
regardless of the state of the economy. Therefore, debt f
operating risk or, equivalently, the business risk
fect operating income,
Suppose operating income drops from $125,000 to $75,000. Under all-equity financall by $.50. With 50% debt, there
earnings per share by $1.
You can see no
lever
wn as
leverage and a
The debt increases the uncer, a
Tables
16.2 and 16.3.) In other words, the effect of leverage is to double the magnitude of the
upside and downside in the return on Riv
Whatever the beta of the
ould be twice as high afterw
2
W
Chapter 16
451
Debt Policy
FIGURE 16.2 “Slicing the
pie” for River Cruises. The
circles on the left assume
the company has no debt.
The circles on the right reflect
the proposed restructuring.
The restructuring splits firm
value (top circles) 50–50.
Shareholders get more
than 50% of expected, or
“normal,” operating income
(bottom circles), but only
because they bear financial
risk. Note that restructuring
ect total firm
value or operating income.
$1 million
equity value
$500,000
equity value
Equity income
= operating income
= $125,000
financial risk
Risk to shareholders
resulting from the use of
debt.
Debt f
W
share must double.3
Equity income
= $75,000
ect the operating risk but it does add
.
o absorb the same amount of operating risk, risk per
Consider now the implications of MM’
ver
vi-
dends per share is $1.25. Since inv
v
xpected dividend di
$10. The good news is that after the debt issue, e
$1.50. The bad ne
v
y
5
w doubled. So instead of being
1 5 5 15%.
vidends is e
5 $10, e
Expected earnings per share
Share price
Expected return on share
Current Structure:
All Equity
Proposed Structure:
Equal Debt and Equity
$1.25
$10
12.5%
$1.50
$10
15.0%
Thus leverage increases the e
ut it also increases the
The two effects cancel, leaving shareholder value unchanged.
Debt and the Cost of Equity
ver Cruises’ cost of capital? W
3
leverage.
ed costs increase the v
vide operating leverage. It is e
.
irm’s profits. These
ixed cost,
452
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
5 .125, or
requity, and also rassets, the e
12.5%.
cost of capital for the f
s assets.
alue, it should
es place. Also, by a
grand stroke of luck you simultaneously become a billionaire and buy all the outstanding debt and equity of Riv
What rate of return should you expect on this
investment? Your answer should be 12.5%, because once you own all the debt and
equity, you will effectively own all the assets and receive all the operating income.
You will indeed get 12.5%. Table 16.3 shows e
and a share price that is unchanged at $10. Therefore, the e
rdebt 5 .10). Your
$1.50/$10 5 .15, or 15% (requity 5 .15).
overall return is
(.5 3 .10) 1 (.5 3 .15) 5 .125 5 rassets
There is obviously a general principle here:
rdebt and requity takes you to rassets
assets. The formula is
rassets 5 (rdebt 3 D/V) 1 (r
verage of
y’s
3 E/V)
where D and E
V equals overall
alue, the sum of D and E. Remember that D, E, and V are market values, not
book values.
verage cost of capital (WACC)
formula presented in Chapter 13 because at this point we are still ignoring taxes.4
Don’t w
, we’ll get to WACC in a moment. First let’s look at the implications of
MM’
vance proposition for the cost of equity.
MM’
s operating income or the value of its assets. So rassets, the e
the package of debt and equity, is unaffected.
However, we have just seen that leverage does increase the risk of the equity and the
To see how the expected return on equity v
lev
ws:
requity 5 rassets 1
D
(rassets 2 rdebt)
E
(16.1)
which in words says that
expected
expected
debtexpected
≥S
2
5 return 1 C equity 3 £
assets
on equity on assets
ratio
debt
Expected
MM’s proposition II
The required rate of return
on equity increases as
the firm’
atio
increases.
▲
EXAMPLE 16.1
This is MM’s proposition II.
mon stock of a levered f
expressed in market values. Note that requity 5 rassets if the f
River Cruises’ Cost of Equity
We can check out MM’s proposition II for River Cruises. Before the decision to borrow,
requi 5 rassets 5
5
4
expected operating income
market value of all securities
125,000
5 .125, or 12.5%
1,000,000
Chapter 16
453
Debt Policy
If the firm goes ahead with its plan to borrow, the expected return on assets, rassets,
is still 12.5%. So the expected return on equity is
requi 5 rassets 1
5 .125 1
D
(rassets 2 rdebt)
E
500,000
(.125 2 .10)
500,000
5 .15, or 15%
We pointed out in Chapter 13 that you can think of a debt issue as having an explicit
cost and an implicit cost. The e
s
debt. But debt also increases financial risk and causes shareholders to demand
a higher return on their investment. Once you recognize this implicit cost, debt is
no c
eturn that investors require on their assets is unaffected by the firm’s borrowing decision. Be sure to remember this point whenever
you hear some layperson say “Debt is cheaper than equity.”
Self-Test 16.3
The implications of MM’
ws, the e
unchanged, but the e
wn in Figure 16.3. No matter how
, rassets, is
age are also changing. More debt means that the cost of equity increases, but at the
same time the amount of equity is less.
In Figure 16.3 we have drawn the rate of interest on the debt as constant no matter
ho
ws. That is not wholly realistic. It is true that most large, conservativ
w a little more or less without noticeably affecting the
interest rate that they pay. But at higher debt levels lenders become concerned that
they may not get their money back and they demand higher rates of interest. Figure 16.4 modifies Figure 16.3 to take account of this. Y
rows more, the risk of def
Proposition II continues to predict that the e
FIGURE 16.3
MM’s
proposition II with a fixed
interest rate on debt. The
expected return on River
Cruises’
ises in line
with the debt-equity ratio.
The weighted average of
the expected returns on
debt and equity is constant,
equal to the expected
return on assets.
454
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
FIGURE 16.4 MM’s
proposition II when debt is
not risk-free. As the debtatio increases,
debtholders demand a
higher expected rate of return
to compensate for the risk of
default. The expected return
on equity increases more
slowly when debt is r
because the debtholders
take on part of the risk. The
expected return on the
pack
,
r
, remains constant.
equity does not change. However, the slope of the requity line now tapers off as D/E
increases.
y debt be
As the f
Figures 16.3 and 16.4 wrap up our discussion of MM’s leverage-irrelevance proposition. Because ov
v
s debt and
This
result follows from MM’
ets are well functioning and
tax
w it’
es back into the picture.
16.2 Capital Structure and Corporate Taxes
The MM propositions suggest that debt policy should not matter. Yet financial managers do w
y, and for good reasons. Now we are ready to see why.
If debt policy were completely
vant, actual debt ratios would v
. Yet almost all airlines, utilities, and
real estate development companies rely heavily on debt. And so do many f
capital-intensiv
are company that is not predominantly equitywth companies seldom use much debt, despite rapid expansion and often heavy requirements for capital.
The e
ve so f
of our discussion. No
es.
Debt and Taxes at River Cruises
antage: The interest that the company pays is a
tax-deductible expense, b
To see the advantage of debt finance, let’s look once again at River Cruises.
Table 16.6 shows how e
ed at a rate of 35%.
ver Cruises is f
equity. The right-hand column shows what happens if the f
at an interest rate of 10%.
Notice that the combined income of the debtholders and equityholders is higher by
vered.
deductible. Thus ev
es by $.35. The total amount of
tax savings is simply .35 3 interest payments. In the case of Riv
Chapter 16
455
Debt Policy
TABLE 16.6 Since debt
interest is tax-deductible,
River Cruises’ debtholders
and equityholders expect to
receive a higher combined
income when the firm is
leveraged
interest tax shield
Tax savings resulting
fr
interest payments.
interest tax shield is .35 3 $50,000 5 $17,500 each year. In other words, the “pie” of
after-tax income that is shared by debt and equity investors increases by $17,500 relativ
v
The interest tax shield is a valuable asset. Let’s see how much it could be worth.
Suppose that Riv
y mature and to keep
“rolling ov
tax sa
. These savings depend only on the corporate tax rate
and on the ability of Riv
v
ely to be small. If we wish to compute the present value of
all the future tax sa
est tax shields at a relatively low rate.
But what rate? The most common assumption is that the risk of the tax shields is the
same as that of the interest payments generating them. Thus we discount at 10%, the
e
v
s debt. If the
ard to annual savings of $17,500 in perpetuity. Their present value is
PV tax shield 5
$17,500
5 $175,000
.10
This is what the tax savings are w
v
How does company value change? We continue to assume that if the f
v
pany will be valued at $81,250/.125 5 $650,000.5
s securities increases by the value of the
tax shield to $650,000 1 $175,000 5 $825,000.
Let us generalize.
Tc
wed, or rdebt 3 D. The annual tax sa
times the interest payment. Therefore,
Annual
shield 5
3 interest payment
5 Tc 3 (rdebt 3 D)
alue:
PV
shields 5
Tc 3 (rdebt 3 D)
annual tax shield
5
5 TcD
rdebt
rdebt
(16.2)
5 TcD) in the rest of the River
xample. We do so for simplicity. In fact, the formula almost always overstates the v
.
es. If that happens, there
W
5
as w
as zero (see Table 16.2). It is worth only $650,000
es.
456
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
are no taxes for interest to shield. Third, the formula assumes that the amount of debt
ed re
s more reasonable to assume that
the f
rebalance
ver time to keep its debt ratio more or less
ves and its v
hard times and value decreases, it can gradually pay down debt to a more comfortable
lev
ed
amounts; they v
s performance, and therefore should be discounted at
a rate higher than the cost of debt.
The simple formula nev
Self-Test 16.4
How Interest Tax Shields Contribute
to the Value of Stockholders’ Equity
MM’
how it is sliced.” The pizza is the firm’s assets, and the slices are the debt and equity
claims. If we hold the pizza constant, then a dollar more of debt means a dollar less of
equity value.
But there is really a third slice—the government’s. MM would still say that the
value of the pizza—in this case the company value before taxes—is not changed by
slicing. But anything the f
vernment’s slice obviously leaves more for the others. One w
w money. This reduces
s tax bill and increases the cash payments to the investors. The value of their
investment goes up by the present value of the tax savings.
In a no-tax world, MM’s proposition I states that the v
by capital structure. But MM also modified proposition I to recognize corporate taxes:
Value of levered firm 5
1 present value of tax shield
5
1 TcD
(16.3)
Figure 16.5. It implies that borrowing
increases firm value and shareholders’ wealth.
Corporate Taxes and the Weighted-Average
Cost of Capital
We have sho
v
es, debt provides the company with a
xplicitly calculate the present v
wing policy.
gotten,
however, because they show up in the discount rate used to evaluate capital investments.
Since debt interest is tax-deductible, the government in effect pays 35% of the
interest cost. So to keep its investors happy
after-tax rate of
benefit of debt, the weighted-average cost of capital formula (see Chapter 13 for a
review if you need one) becomes
D
E
≤ 1 requity ¢
≤
WACC 5 (1 2 Tc)rdebt ¢
D1E
D1E
Chapter 16
457
Debt Policy
FIGURE 16.5
The heavy
blue line shows how the
interest t
ect the
market value of the firm.
Additional borrowing
decreases corporate income
tax payments and increases
the cash flows available to
investors. Thus market value
increases.
PV tax
shield
Value if
all equity
financed
Notice that when we allow for the tax advantage of debt, the weighted-average cost of
capital depends on the after-tax rate of interest (1 2 Tc) 3 rdebt.
▲
EXAMPLE 16.2
WACC and Debt Policy
We can use the weighted-average cost of capital formula to see how leverage
ects River Cruises’ cost of capital if the company pays corporate tax. When a
company has no debt, the weighted-average cost of capital and the return
required by shareholders are identical. In the case of River Cruises the WACC with
all-equity financing is 12.5%, and the value of the firm is $650,000.
Now let us calculate the weighted-average cost of capital if River Cruises issues
$500,000 of permanent debt (D 5 $500,000). Company value increases by PV tax
shield 5 $175,000, from $650,000 to $825,000 (meaning that D 1 E 5 $825,000). Therefore the v
ust be $825,000 2 $500,000 5 $325,000 (E 5 $325,000).
Table 16.6 shows that when River Cruises borrows, the expected equity income is
$48,750. So the expected return to shareholders is 48,750/325,000 5 15%
(r equity 5 .15). The interest rate is 10% (r debt 5 .10), and the corporate tax rate is 35%
(Tc 5 .35). This is all the information we need to see how lever
ects River
Cruises’ weighted-average cost of capital:
WACC 5 (1 2 Tc)rdebt ¢
5 (1 2 .35).10 ¢
D
E
≤ 1 requity ¢
≤
D1E
D1E
325,000
500,000
≤ 1 .15 ¢
≤ 5 .0985, or 9.85%
825,000
825,000
We saw earlier that if there are no corporate taxes, the weight
verage cost of
capit
ected by borrowing. But when there are corporate taxes, debt provides
the company with a new benefit—the interest tax shield. In this case leverage reduces
the weighted-average cost of capital (in River Cruises’ case from 12.5% to 9.85%).
Figure 16.6 repeats Figure 16.3 except that now we have allowed f
ect of
taxes on River Cruises’ cost of capital. You can see that as the company borrows
more, the expected r
, but the rise is less rapid than in the absence
of taxes. T
er-tax cost of debt is only 6.5%. As a result, the weighted-average cost
of capital declines. For example, if the company has debt of $500,000,
wor
atio (
5 1.54.
Figure 16.6 shows that with this amount of debt the weighted-average cost of capital is 9.85%, the same figure that we calculated above.
458
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
FIGURE 16.6
Changes in
River Cruises’ cost of capital
with increased leverage when
there are corporate taxes.
The after-tax cost of debt is
assumed to be constant at
(1 2 .35)10% 5 6.5%. With
increased borrowing the cost
ises, but more
slowly than in the no-tax case
(see Figure 16.3). The
weight
verage cost of
capital (WACC) declines as
the firm borrows more.
Again, we must nag and remind you that we have used the simple formula (PV
tax shields 5 TcD). The formula assumes that tax shields are fixed, safe, and permanent. But the message from Figure 16.6 still stands even if these assumptions are
relaxed.6 Interest tax shields increase firm value and reduce the after-tax WACC.
The Implications of Corporate Taxes
for Capital Structure
wing pro
xtreme:
w to the hilt.
verage cost of capital.
MM were not that fanatical about it. No one would e
extreme debt ratios. For example, if a f
ws heavily, all its operating income
es to be paid. There is no
wing any more.
There may also be some tax disadvantages
ve to
pay personal income tax on any interest they receive. The top rate of tax on bond interest
viv
antage that the
taxed until the stock is sold. (The delay reduces the present value of the tax payment.)
All this suggests that there may come a point at which the tax savings from debt
lev
ven decline. But it doesn’t e
with large tax bills often thrive with little or no debt. There are clearly factors besides
tax to consider. One such factor is the lik
v
16.3 Costs of Financial Distress
en or honored with
y. Sometimes it means only
skating on thin ice.
6
xpected rate
WA
however. If you w
WACC, check out Chapter 19
in R. A. Brealey, S. C. Myers, and F. Allen, Principles of Corporate Finance, 10th ed. (New Y
Irwin), 2011.
D/E
et-v
Figure 16.6.
Chapter 16
costs of financial distress
Costs arising from
bankruptcy or distorted
business decisions
before bankruptcy.
459
Debt Policy
. Inv
w that levered f
, and they w
costs of
distress. That
w
et value of the lev
s securities. Even the
most blue-chip f
w their debt is perceived by investors.
The
w that the
ged a lower rate of interest if the probability of default
is minimal, and they are therefore anxious to maintain an investment-grade rating.
Ev
vestors factor the potential for
alue.
verall value
Overall market
value if all-equityPV tax
PV costs of
5
1
2
value
shield
financial distress
The present v
distress and on the magnitude of the costs encountered if distress occurs.
16.7 shows ho
e Riv
ut considers mo
v
At moderate debt levels the pr
inancial distress
is trivial,
ore the tax advantages of debt dominate. But at some point
additional borrowing causes the pr
inancial distress to increase rapidly
and the potential costs of distress begin to take a substantial bite out of firm value.
The theoretical optimum is reached when the present value of tax savings from
further borro
y increases in the present value of costs of distress.
trade-off theory
Debt levels are chosen
to balance interest tax
shields against the costs
of financial distress.
This is called the trade-off theory
The theory says that
vels to the point where the value of additional
interest tax shields is exactly of
Now let’
Bankruptcy Costs
y is merely a le
wing creditors (that is,
e ov
ault
on outstanding debt. If the company cannot pay its debts, the compan
ver to
wo
cause of the decline in the value of the firm. It is the result.
In practice, of course, anything involving courts and lawyers cannot be free. The
fees involv
alue of the
FIGURE 16.7
The tr
al structure.
The curved blue line shows
how the market value of the
firm at first increases as the
firm borrows but finally
decreases as the costs of
financial distress become
more and more important.
The optimal capital structure
balances the costs of
financial distress against the
value of the interest tax
shields generated by
borrowing.
PV costs
of financial
distress
PV tax
shield
Value if
all equity
financed
460
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
s assets. Creditors end up with what is left after paying the lawyers and other
y
et value of the
alue of these potential costs.
It is easy to see how increased lev
expected value of the associated costs.
et v
Creditors foresee the costs and realize that if def
y costs
y demand compensation in advance
fs to
et v
Self-Test 16.5
y, the
Chapter 11.
to face the w
val of a reorganization plan for who gets
what; under the plan each class of creditors needs to give up its claim in exchange for
new securities or a mixture of new securities and cash. The challenge is to design a new
e the business
ves possible to satisfy both demands and the patient emer
. Often, however, the proceedings involve costly delays and legal tangles, and the business continues to deteriorate.
y costs can add up fast. The f
lion in le
y.
ers are forecast to reach a record $1.5 billion.
xceptional cases, for only the largest f
ruptcy costs average only about 3% of the v
ruptcy.7
ge ones; it seems
Thus f
ve discussed only the direct (that is, legal and administrative) costs
y. The indirect
y while it
y.
y in 1989, it
was in severe f
ut it still had some v
acilities. These assets were
more than suf
wever, the bankruptcy judge was determined to k
, Eastern’s losses
continued to pile up.
received less than $900 million. The unsuccessful attempt at resuscitation had cost
Eastern’s creditors $2.8 billion.
We don’
w how much these indirect costs add to the e
y.
We suspect it is a significant number
y proceedings are
7
See, for e
A. W
y Resolution: Direct Costs and V
Journal of Financial Economics 27 (October 1990), pp. 285–314.
”
Chapter 16
Debt Policy
461
prolonged. Perhaps the best evidence is the reluctance of creditors to force a f
y. In principle, they would be better off to end the agony and seize the assets
as soon as possible. But, instead, creditors often overlook defaults in the hope of nursver a dif
The
v
y.
w $1,000 and you’ve got a banker.
Borrow $10,000,000 and you’v
.”
Costs of Bankruptcy Vary with Type of Asset
Suppose your f
ge downtown hotel, mortgaged to the hilt. A
recession hits, occupancy rates f
The
es over and sells the hotel to a new owner and operator. The stock is worthless and you use the f
allpaper.
y? In this example, probably very little. The value of
the hotel is, of course, much less than you hoped, but that is due to the lack of guests,
y
y does not damage the hotel itself.
y
gal and court fees, real estate commissions, and
the time the lender spends sorting things out.
thing is the same, except for the underlying assets. Fledgling is a high-tech going
concern, and much of its v
v
usiness”; its most important
assets go down in the elevator and into the parking lot ev
y to
y should they put up cash which will simply go
to pay off the banks? Failure to invest is likely to be much more serious for Fledgling
than for a company lik
aults on its debt, the lender w
to cash in by selling the assets. In fact, if trouble comes, many of those assets may
driv
ver come back.
Some assets, lik
y and reorgely unscathed; the values of other assets are likely to be considerably
diminished.
, where
company v
velopment. It may also
explain the low debt ratios in man
Do not think only about whether borrowing
labor.
is likely to bring trouble. Think also of the value that may be lost if trouble comes.
Self-Test 16.6
Financial Distress without Bankruptcy
Not ev
y for
462
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
many years. Ev
altogether.
ver
y
y does not
avoided.
y may not be paid, potential
8
and employees
ws.
want it to recover, b
e man
alities but threatened by squabbling on any specific issue. Financial distress is costly
when these conflicts get in the way of running the business. Stockholders are
tempted to forsake the usual objective of maximizing the overall market value of
the firm and to pursue narrower self-interest instead. They are tempted to play
games at the expense of their creditors. These games add to the costs of financial distress.
Think of a compan
y. It has large debts and large losses. Double-R’s assets have little value, and
if its debts were due today, Double-R would default, lea
The
debtholders would perhaps receive a fe
would be left with nothing.
xplains why Double-R’s
ve value. There could be a strok
allo
ver. That’s a long shot—unless f
v
, the stock will be valueless. But the owners have a secret
weapon: They control investment and operating strategy.
The First Game: Bet the Bank’s Money Suppose Double-R has the opportunity to take a wild gamble. If it does not come of
orse
off; the company will probably go under anyway. But if the gamble does succeed, there
will be more than enough assets to pay off the debt and the surplus will go into the
shareholders’ pockets. Y
y, but if Double-R
does hit the jackpot, the equityholders get most of the loot.
This was essentially the situation facing Federal Express while it w
ut needed $24,000 for
ve to gamble literally. He took
s remaining $5,000 and boarded a plane for Las Vegas, where he won $27,000.
When asked ho
ference
did it make? Without the funds for the fuel companies, we couldn’t hav
wn
ves to tak
anyway.” 9 The ef
blatant, b
vestment strategies are costly for the bondholders
y associated with financial distress? Because
the temptation to follo
gies is strongest when the odds of default are high.
ould never invest in Double-R’s lousy gamble, since it would be gambling with its own money, not the bondholders’.
s creditors would not
be vulnerable to this type of game.
The Second Game: Don’t Bet Your Own Money We have just seen how
e on risky
ects.
We will no
8
v
y, the U.S. gov
by backing the w
ehicles.
9
Roger Frock, Changing How the World Does Business, FedEx’s Incredible J
oehler Publishers, 2006).
s customers
The Inside
Chapter 16
463
Debt Policy
Suppose Double-R uncovers a relatively safe project with a positive NPV
nately
vestment. Double-R will need to raise this
extra cash from its shareholders. Although the project has a positive NPV, the profits
may not be suf
y. If that is so, all the profy’
y put up. Although it is in the firm’s interest
to go ahead with the project, it is not in the owners’ interest, and the project will be
passed up. A recent e
man
ailure, discovered that their shareholders were reluctant
to come to the rescue. The shareholders reasoned that any cash that the
uted
would simply be used to get existing debtholders and the gov
These examples illustrate a general point. The value of any inv
s stockholders
bondholders.
ute fresh
equity capital even if that means forgoing positive-NPV opportunities.
These tw
debtholders.
fect all lev
y in the face. If the pr
default is high, managers and stockholders will be tempted to take on excessively r
ojects. At the same time, stockholders may refuse to contribute
mor
al even if the firm has safe, positive-NPV opportunities. Stockholders would rather take money out of the firm than put new money in.
y kno
w
loan covenant
Agr
een
firm and lender requiring
the firm to fulfill certain
conditions to safeguard
the loan.
xpense. So to reassure lenders that its
loan covenants. For examwing and not to pay excessive dividends. Of
ver ev
y might
ve-NPV
course, no amount of f
play. F
investments and reject negative ones.
We do not mean to leav
ways succumb to temptation unless restrained. Usually they refrain v
, not only because
of a sense of f
ut also on pragmatic grounds:
es a
killing today at the expense of a creditor will be coldly received when the time comes
w again. Aggressiv
wing precisely
because they don’t wish to land in distress and be exposed to the temptation to play.
Self-Test 16.7
We have now completed our review of the b
cov
.
16.4 Explaining Financing Choices
The Trade-Off Theory
troversy about how v
464
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
Thus
Figure 16.7
get debt ratios will v
have high target ratios. Unprofitable companies with risky, intangible assets ought to
. It avoids
extreme predictions and rationalizes moderate debt ratios. But what are the facts? Can
xplain how companies actually behave?
f theory successfully explains
many of the industry dif
Table 16.1.
For example, high-tech gro
y and mostly intangible, normally use relativ
w heavily
because their assets are tangible and relatively safe.
f theory cannot explain. It cannot
e
ve with little debt. Consider,
for e
s
most v
velopment. We
kno
ative capital structures should go together. But
Microsoft also has a v
w enough to save tens of millions of tax
er of concern about possible financial distress.
Our e
The most
ails, for it
predicts exactly the reverse. Under the trade-of
, high profits should mean more
in a higher debt ratio.
Self-Test 16.8
A Pecking Order Theory
ve theory which could e
w
less. It is based on asymmetric information
w more than outside investors about the prof
Thus investors may not be able to
assess the true value of a ne
They may be especially
reluctant to buy ne
yw
w shares
verpriced.
Such w
ve down
10
If managers know more than outside investors, they will be tempted
to time stock issues when their companies’ stock is overpriced—in other words, when
v
see their companies’ shares as underpriced and decide not to issue. You can see why
investors w
wn the stock price accordingly. You can also see why
are
ould view a
vely expensive source of financing.
10
W
Chapter 16
pecking order theory
Firms prefer to issue debt
rather than equity if
internal finance is
icient.
Debt Policy
465
All these problems are avoided if the compan
vested. But if e
inancing is required, the path
of least resistance is debt, not equity. Issuing debt seems to hav
fect on
stock prices.
alued and therefore a debt issue is
a less w
vestors.
These observations suggest a pecking order theory
like this:
1.
vesting internally generated cash does not send
adverse signals that could lower the stock price.
2. If e
ely than an
equity issue to be interpreted by investors as a bad omen.
In this story
o kinds of
equity
, and the second
is at the bottom.
w less; it is not because they have low target debt ratios but because they don’t
need outside money
y do not have suf
v
external
y that taxes and f
actors in the choice of capital structure. However, the theory says that these
f
ver e
ver new issues of common stock.
F
w investment,
and most external financing comes from debt. These aggre
.Y
ork best for
ast-gro
vestments. Of course you wouldn’t e
xtremely valuable growth opportunities. Such f
ve good
reasons to issue stock; the
wth f
The Two Faces of Financial Slack
financial slack
Ready access to cash
or debt financing.
ve worked down the pecking order and need e
living with excessive debt or bypassing good inv
t be sold
at what managers consider a fair price.
ed about what f
y
s credit rating. But they place even greater emphasis
y has access to funds for pursuing new
11
In other words, they place a high value on
projects when the
slack. Ha
ative
y’s debt as a safe investment.
y’s v
v
Therefore, you w
v
v
slack is most v
ve-NPV gro
That is
another reason why gro
ativ
11
ey, “The
Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2001), pp. 187–243.
”
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
How Sealed Air’s Change in Capital Structure Acted
as a Catalyst to Organizational Change
However, there is also a dark side to financial slack. Too much of it may encourage
e it easy, expand their perks, or empire-b
paid back to stockholders. Michael Jensen has stressed the tendency of managers with
w too much cash into
mature businesses or ill-advised acquisitions. “The problem,” Jensen says, “is how to
motivate managers to disgorge the cash rather than investing it below the cost of capital or wasting it in organizational inef
”12
If that’
pal payments are contractual obligations of the f
cash. Perhaps the best debt level would leave just enough cash in the bank, after debt
ve-NPV projects, with not a penny left over.
We do not recommend this de
ut the idea is valid and important. F
ve a good effect on managers’ incentives.
es the skater
concentrate. Likewise, managers of highly lev
ely to work
harder
y spend money.
The nearby box tells the story of how Sealed
$300 million, using the proceeds of the loan to pay a special cash dividend to shareholders. The net effect w
vial level to fully 65% of the
12
M. C. Jensen, “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance and Takeovers,” American Economic
Review 26 (May 1986), p. 323.
466
Chapter 16
Debt Policy
total v
ge sums of money as interest, lea
aw
ef
SUMMARY
467
Air showed great improvements in
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
finance.yahoo.com
finance.yahoo.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
MINICASE
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
APPENDIX
workout
bankruptcy
liquidation
reorganization
Bankruptcy Procedures
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
The Choice between Liquidation and Reorganization
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
Appendix Questions
CHAPTER
17
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T F I V E
Debt and Payout Policy
In 2010 Union Pacific paid out $600 million in dividends and used $1.2 billion to repurchase stock.
S
480
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
17.1 How Corporations Pay Out
Cash to Shareholders
o ways. They can pay a cash
dividend or repurchase some outstanding shares. Figure 17.1 shows annual repurchases
and dividends in the United States since 1980. You can see that stock repurchases were
rare before the mid-1980s but have since become f
the more active stock repurchasers included W
lion), and Microsoft ($8.2 billion). The repurchase champion, however
2009. In 2009, repurchases and dividends in the United States were just about equal,
vidends. The no-dividend group includes household
names such as Sun Microsystems, Oracle, Amazon, and Google. The no-dividend
group also includes companies that used to pay dividends but have f
and been forced to cut back dividends to conserve cash. An e
ord Motor
Company
vidends for decades but cut its dividend to zero in 2006.
Paying Dividends
cash dividend
Payment of cash by the
firm to its shareholders.
In May 2010, Union P
s board of directors met and decided to authorize a regular
cash dividend of $.33 per share, an increase of $.06 from the pre
s
vidend of $.27.
regular
xpected to
maintain or increase the dividend in the future. Instead of increasing the regular
dividend, they could have kept it at $.27 and authorized a special dividend. Investors
realize that special dividends probably won’t be repeated.
Some of Union P
ve welcomed the cash, but others prevest the dividend in the company. To help these investors, Union P
offered an automatic dividend reinvestment plan, or DRIP
to this plan, his or her dividends were automatically used to buy additional shares.1
Who receives the Union P
vidend? That may seem an obvious question, but
s records of who owns its shares are never fully
FIGURE 17.1
Dividends
and stock repurchases in the
United States, 1980–2008
(figures in $ billions).
Source: Capital IQ Compustat, www.compustat.com.
1
Often the new shares in an automatic dividend inv
v
v
Chapter 17
481
Payout Policy
FIGURE 17.2
The key dates
for Union Pacific’s quarterly
dividend.
ex-dividend
Without dividend. Buyer
of a st
er the
ex-dividend date does
not receive the most
recently declared
dividend.
Union Pacific
declares regular
quarterly dividend
of $.33 per share.
Shares start to
trade ex-dividend.
Dividend will be
paid to shareholders registered
on this date.
Dividend checks
are mailed to
shareholders.
v
who qualify to receive each dividend. Union P
ould send a
dividend check on July 1 (the payment date) to all shareholders recorded in its books
on May 28 (the record date).
On May 26, two days before the record date, Union P
gan to trade
ex-dividend. Inv
ve their
purchases re
vidend. Other
things equal, a stock is w
vidend. So when a stock
“goes ex-dividend,” its price falls by about the amount of the dividend.
Figure 17.2
ey dividend dates.
same whenever companies pay a dividend (though of course the actual dates will
differ).
Self-Test 17.1
Limitations on Dividends
ute the
money as dividends. That would not leav
s debts.
State la
s creditors against excessive dividend payments.
For example, most states prohibit a company from paying dividends if doing so would
wed to pay a dividend if
make the company insolvent.2
it cuts into le
Legal capital
outstanding shares.3
y
wer’
orthiness. We mentioned that F
its dividend in 2006. F
w heavily
very plan. Its loan agreements prohibit dividends. Thus Ford’s
get about dividends until the company’
ves and its
gotiated.
stock dividends and splits
Distributions of
additional shares to a
firm’s stockholders.
Stock Dividends and Stock Splits
Union P
For e
2
3
s dividend was in cash, b
enc
Where there is no par value, le
stock di
.
ould send
wns.
ays. In some cases, it just means an inability to meet immediate
ed liabilities.
482
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
A stock dividend is v
e a stock split.
giv
ed number of ne
or e
o-for-one
stock split, each investor would receiv
held. The investor ends up with two shares rather than one. A two-for-one stock split
is therefore like a 100% stock dividend. Both result in a doubling of the number of
outstanding shares, but the
y’
alue.4
More often than not, however
et price of the stock, even though investors are aw
y’s
business is not affected. Perhaps lo
avored by investors, or maybe investors take the decision as a signal of management’
the future.5
▲
EXAMPLE 17.1
Stock Dividends and Splits
Amoeba Products has issued 2 million shares currently selling at $15 each. Thus
investors place a total market value on Amoeba of $30 million. The company now
declares a 50% stock dividend. This means that each shareholder will receive one
new share for ever
o shares that are currently held. So the total number of
Amoeba shares will increase from 2 million to 3 million. The company’s assets are
not changed by this paper transaction and are still worth $30 million. The value of
each shar
er the stock dividend is therefore $30/3 5 $10.
If Amoeba split its stock three for two,
ect would be the same.6 In this case
two shares would split into three. (Amoeba’
o is “Divide and conquer.”) So
each shareholder has 50% more shares with the same total value. Other things
equal, share price must decline by a third.
17.2 Stock Repurchases
Another way for the f
or example, when Union P
stock repurchase
Firm buys back stock
from its shareholders.
vidend increase in
ver the
following 2 years. The company can keep these reacquired shares in its treasury and
resell them if it needs money later.
exercise stock options.
ays to implement a stock repurchase:
1. Open-market repurchase.
et, just like any other investor. This is by far the most common
4
b
could use a six-for
v
wn into a more conv
vidual investors may favor stocks with lo
er. R. Greenwood, and J. Wurgler
”J
inance
reverse split
or e
a 1-for-10 rev
xchange for ev
5
See E. F. F
, M. Jensen, and R. Roll, “The
or e
stock have above-av
. Asquith, P
, and K. P
Splits,” Accounting Review
6
, say
w stock
”
vidend is shown on the
A split is shown as a
.
Chapter 17
483
Payout Policy
method. There are limits on how many of its o
given day
ver several months or years.
2. T
.
fers to b
ed price.
, the deal is done.
3. Auction.
fers declaring how many shares they are prepared to sell at
each price, and the f
west price at which it can buy the desired
4. Direct negotiation.
.
which the tar
gotiate repurchase of a block of shares from a
xamples are greenmail transactions, in
eover buys out the hostile bidder. “Greenmail”
es the bidder
happy to leave the target alone.
Why Repurchases Are Like Dividends
T
A of Table 17.1,
which shows the market value of Hewlard Pocket’s assets and liabilities. Shareorth in total $1 million, so the price per share equals
$1 million/100,000 5 $10.
vidend is paid.
Pocket is proposing to pay a di
With 100,000 shares outstanding, that amounts to a total payout of $100,000. Panel B shows the effect of this dividend payment.
et value of the
s assets f
price falls to $9. Suppose that before the dividend payment you owned 1,000 shares of
Pocket w
After the payment you would hav
orth $9,000.
Rather than paying out $100,000 as a dividend, Pocket could use the cash to buy
anel C shows what happens. The firm’s assets fall to
$900,000, just as in panel B, b
share remains at $10. If you o
ould own
1% of the company
et, you would still
own 1% of the company. Your sales w
TABLE 17.1 Cash dividend
versus share repurchase.
Hewlard Pocket’s marketvalue balance sheet.
484
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
would keep 900 shares w
Your position is exactly the same with the share
repurchase (panel C of Table 17.1) as with the cash di
It’
vidend and a share repurchase are equivalent transallets.
reduced by repurchases, however
cash is paid out as dividends.
Self-Test 17.2
Repurchases and Share Valuation
Now here is a question that often causes confusion. We stated in Chapter 7 that the
value of a share of stock is equal to the discounted v
repurchases, does our simple dividend discount model still hold? The answer is yes, but
we need to explain why.
w you would value the stock of He
et. We’ll suppose
that it has just paid a di
The stock is ex-dividend. The next
dividend is in year 1.7 Pocket is expected to continue to pay annual dividends of
orks out to
a di
alue of this
dividend stream is $1/.111 5 $9.
Pocket now announces that it will not pay a dividend in year 1 but will instead use
the $100,000 it would hav
year 2 onward it will resume paying annual dividends of $100,000.8 The new policy
does not change the aggregate amount of cash going out to shareholders. Therefore,
s
check that the dividend discount model continues to give a present value of $9 a share.
After the company has repurchased the stock in year 1, the number of outstanding
all to 90,000. Therefore, there is no di
ut the
dividend per share from year 2 onward will be $100,000/90,000 5 $1.11. The present
v
in year 1 is $1.11/.111 5 $10, and its value in year 0 is
$10/1.11 5 $9.9
So our dividend discount model still holds.
dividends per share. The only trick is to remember that share repurchases reduce the
number of shares and increase future di
You can also calculate PV
s overall mark
on the total cash paid out to both present and future shareholders, and then dividing by
7
W
vidends for simplicity. Most cash di
Have we cheated by assuming a $100,000 dividend forever? No.
but it doesn’t matter. Y
8
.
wer,
xpectedly well ov
xt
e Table 17.1 to sho
f with $111,000 in repurchases as $111,000 of cash dividends. In f
vidends at any level of payout, at least in the simple examples that
we’re doing now. Some complications come later in the chapter.
9
checks.
Chapter 17
485
Payout Policy
17.3 How Do Corporations Decide
How Much to Pay Out?
ey asked senior executiv
xecutives’ responses.
vidend policies.
1.
e dividend changes that may have to be reversed, and
the
wf
2. Managers “smooth” dividends and hate to cut them back. Dividends tend to follow
the gro
T
vidend payouts.
3. Managers focus more on dividend changes than on absolute levels. Thus paying a
$2 di
inancial decision if last year’s dividend was $1, but it’s
no big deal if last year’s dividend was $2.
gular dividends sometimes act as though they have a target
payout ratio,
get ratio does not
s
di
wever. Dividends in that case would
be just as volatile as earnings. We know
, that dividends are smoothed.
target dividend as a percentage of expected or normal
or e
casts average income of $5 per share over the next 2 or 3 years. If the target payout
ratio is 40%, the target dividend is 40% of $5, or $2.
get, then the dividend is increased gradually toward the tar
all,
lea
vidend higher
get dividend? In this case, the dividend
w
,b
t
cut regular dividends unless the cut is forced by hea
Financial managers do not have to choose between cash dividends and repurchases.
The
ge, mature corporations that pay cash dividends also repurchase
re
. Man
vidends b
chase, either regularly or sporadically.
dividends but never repurchase is tiny.10
FIGURE 17.3
ey of
financial executives
suggested that their firms
were reluctant to cut the
dividend and tried to
maintain a smooth series of
payments.
Source: A. Brav, J. R.
. R.
nomics 77 (September 2005), pp.
10
ey, and R. Michaely, “Payout Policy in the 21st C
,” J
Financial Ecomission of Elsevier Science via Copyright Clearance Center, Inc.
v
Journal of Financial Economics 87 (March 2008), pp. 582–609.
vidends but never
vidends and Stock Repurchases,”
486
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
vidends stabilize the dividends. Cash dividends evolve
,e
same way.
ar more volatile
than dividends. The
xcess cash,
but wither in recessions. Look back at Figure 17.1, and you will see that repurchases
fell far more dramatically than dividends in the f
The Information Content of
Dividends and Repurchases
information content
of dividends
Dividend increases send
good news about future
cash flow and earnings.
Dividend cuts send bad
news.
vide. Secrecy
xt to meaningless. Some say that creative accounting makes the situation in the United States
.
If transparency is limited, dividends can provide clues about a company’
prospects.
vidend, it
is putting its mone
ut
di
w cannot back up
its dividend payout, it will ultimately have to reduce its investments or turn to investors
This can be costly. W
therefore, why investors believe in the information content of dividends.
vidend increases are good
ne
en as bad news (stock
alls). For example, Healy and Palepu found that the announcement of a
company’
verage.11 Such
viously good news for investors. The news is good not because
inv
e dividends.” It is good because announcements of dividend
increases send positive signals about future income. Managers don’t increase dividends unless they are confident that income will be high enough to cover the
dividend with room to spare. A dividend increase conveys that confidence to
investors. A dividend cut, on the other hand, conveys a lack of confidence. Even
investors who otherwise prefer lo
is unwelcome ne
s prospects.
xceptions. Not all di
vidend
ws; if investors are convinced
or example,
xplains how investors endorsed a drastic di
2009 by J.P. Morgan.
Of course, dividend cuts don’t convey bad news when the news is already out and
inv
vidend cut is coming.
▲
EXAMPLE 17.2
BP’s Dividend Suspension
BP announced on June 16, 2010, that it planned to suspend dividends at least
through the end of the year. The suspension freed up roughly $7.8 billion in cash,
which could be used for the $20 billion compensation fund that BP agreed to set
up in the wake of the Gulf oil spill. Yet the announcement of the dividend cut barely
moved BP’s stock price. This cut was widely anticipated, so it wasn’t new information. It was a response to a bad event that had already happened and knocked
down BP’s stock price. It was not interpreted as a signal of new bad news about BP.
ws for investors.
But repurchase programs may not be repeated, unlike dividend increases, which imply
11
See P
veyed by Dividend Initiations and Omissions,”
Journal of Financial Economics 21 (1988), pp. 149–175.
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Good News: J.P. Morgan Cuts Its Dividend to a Nickel
a longer
Therefore, the information content of a repurchase program
vidends.12
y have accumulated more cash than they can
inv
often relieved to see companies paying out the e
way
vestments. Of course, investors w
av
gro
y suddenly announced a repurchase program because its managers could
17.4 The Payout Controversy
s
confidence in the f
would happen anyway as the information ev
Can payout policy itself change the underlying value of the f
s common stock, or is
it just a signal about underlying value?
This can be a dif
vestment decisions. Some f
w dividends
because management is optimistic about the f
ings for e
s capital budgeting decision.
xpenditures largely by
wing.
wing decision.
We wish to isolate payout polic
The precise question we should ask is,
fect of a change in dividend
policy,
s capital budgeting and borrowing decisions?
Suppose that the firm proposes to increase its dividend. The cash to finance that
dividend increase has to come from somewhere. If we fix the f
s investment outlays
wing, there is only one possible source—an issue of stock or a reduction in
stock repurchases. Suppose instead that the f
vidend. In that
case it would have extra cash. If investment outlays and borro
ed, there is
only one possible way that this cash can be used—to increase repurchases or reduce
een higher or lower
stock issues. Thus dividend policy involves a trade-of
cash dividends and the issue or repurchase of stock.
12
irm’
y’s stock is w
Of
vestors, believe that
et’s current assessment.
et stock repurv
ve Signaling Power of Dutch-Auction and Fix
ender
”J
inance 46 (September 1991), pp. 1243–1271.
487
488
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
o but three
opposing points of view. And so it is with payout policy
believ
vidends increase v
ves payout polic
ves
alue. And in the center there
es no difference. Let’
Why Dividends Are Irrelevant in Perfect
and Efficient Capital Markets
MM’s dividend-irrelevance
proposition
Under ideal conditions,
the value of the firm is
ected by dividend
policy.
v
t matinancial mark
y also
proved that dividend policy doesn’
ets.13 We have
already seen the common sense of MM’ gument in Table 17.1, which shows that
investors should not care whether a firm distributes cash by dividends or share
repurchases.
y may matter
content of dividends and repurchases but also because of tax
e a more thorough look at MM’s dividend-irrelevance proposition.
We can illustrate MM’s views about payout policy by considering the Pickwick
Paper Company
w paper
mill. But Pickwick’s directors now propose to use the $100 million to increase the
dividend payment. If Pickwick is to continue to build its new mill, that cash needs to
ed, the money must come from the sale of new
The combination of the dividend payment and the new issue of shares leaves
Pickwick and its shareholders in exactly the same position that the
All
that has happened is that Pickwick has put an extra $100 million in investors’ pockets
(the dividend payment) and then taken it out again (the share issue). In other words,
Pickwick is simply recycling cash. T
es investors better off is
lik
After Pickwick pays the additional dividend and replaces the cash by selling new
yv
w have an extra $100
million of cash in their pockets, but they have given up a stak
investors who buy the ne
The ne
million and therefore will demand to receive shares worth
value of the compan
e in the company falls by this $100 million. Thus the extra di
receive just offsets the loss in the v
y hold.
e an
y receive an e
vidend payment plus an of
ay they
could get their hands on the cash. But as long as there are ef
ets,
the
Thus Pickwick’s old shareholders can “cash in”
either by persuading the management to pay a higher dividend or by selling some of
their shares. In either case there will be the same transfer of value from the old to the
investors do not need dividends to convert their shares
ne
to cash, they will not pay higher prices for firms with higher dividend payouts. In
other words, payout policy will have no impact on the value of the firm. This is
MM’s argument.
The e
shareholders better of
aper Company sho
gument also works in reverse: If inv
y reduction in di
13
M. H. Miller and F. Modigliani, “Dividend Policy, Gro
e
vipurchase of stock. For
Valuation of Shares,” Journal of Business
Chapter 17
489
Payout Policy
e
w decides
uy back some of the comvidend payments but
pany’
they receive $100 million from the sale to the compan
Thus MM’
v
gument holds both for increases in dividends and for
een
reductions. As these examples illustrate, payout policy is a tr
cash dividends and the issue or repurchase of common stock. In a perfect
capital market, the payout decision would have no impact on firm value.
These e
a stock issue with ev
ef
vidends
They could av
lower dividends and retaining more funds in the firm. Man
anted
cash to repurchase shares. They could instead use the cash to increase the dividend.
v
ve ignored tax
v
orld complications. W
, but
actually be w
uys for $100,000 must also be
w
ords, di
v
ets.
If you’d like another example, look back at Table 17.1
same amount of money to repurchase shares. Pocket’
with one payout policy as the other
wever: Lower cash divie were implicitly holding inv
wing policy constant.) W
ay, too, with higher dividends
Again shareholders would not care.
▲
EXAMPLE 17.3
Dividend Irrelevance
The columns labeled “Old Dividend Plan” in Table 17.2 show that Consolidated
Pasta is currently expected to pay annual dividends of $10 a shar
.
Shareholders expect a 10% rate of return from Consolidated stock, and therefore
the value of each share is
PV 5
10
10
10
10
1
1
1 c5
5 $100
(1.10)2
(1.10)3
1.10
.10
Consolidated has issued 1 million shares. So the total forecast dividend payment in each year is 1 million 3 $10 5 $10 million, and the total value of Consolidated Past
million 3 $100 5 $100 million. The president, Al Dente, has
read that the value of a share depends on the dividends it pays. That suggests an
TABLE 17.2 Consolidated Pasta is currently expected to pay a dividend of $10 million in per
. However, the
president is proposing to pay a one-time bumper dividend of $20 million in year 1. To replace the lost cash, the firm will
need to issue more shares, and the dividends that will need to be diverted to the new shareholders will ex
ect of the higher dividend in year 1.
Note: New shareholders ar
0 million of cash at the end of year 1. Since they require a return of 10%, the total dividends paid to the new shares
(starting in year 2) must be 10% of $10 million, or $1 million.
490
Part Five Debt and Payout Policy
easy way to keep shareholders happy—increase ne
ear’s dividend to $20 per
share. That way, he reasons, share price should rise by the present value of the
increase in the first-year dividend to a new value of
PV 5
20
10
10
10
10
1
1
1 c5
1
5 $109.91
(1.10)2
(1.10)3
1.10
1.10
.10
The president’s heart is obviously in the right place. Unfortunately, his head isn’t.
Let’s see why.
Consolidated is proposing to pay out an e a $10 million in dividends. It can’t
do that and earn the same profits in the future, unless it also replaces the lost cash
by an issue of shares. The new shareholders who provide this cash will require a
return of 10% on their investment. So Consolidated will need to pay $1 million a year
of dividends to the new shareholders ($1 million/$10 million 5 .10, or 10%). This is
shown in the last line of Table 17.2.
As long as the company replaces the e a cash it pays out, it will continue to
earn the same profits and to pay out $10 million of dividends each year from year
2. However, $1 million of this total will be needed t
w shareholders,
leaving only $9 million (or $9 a share) for the original shareholders. Now recalculate
the value of the original shares under the revised dividend plan:
PV 5
20
9
9
11
9
1
1
1 c5
1
5 $100
(1.10)2
(1.10)3
1.10
1.10
.10
The value of the shares is unchanged. The extra cash dividend in year 1 is exactly
y the reduction of dividends per share in later years. This reduction is necessary because some of the money paid out as dividends in later years is diverted to
the new shareholders.14
The Assumptions behind Dividend Irrelevance
Man
icult to accept the suggestion that
dividend polic
vant.
aced with MM’ gument, they often reply that
di
ush. It may be true,
they say, that the recipient of an extra cash dividend forgoes an equal capital gain, but
if the dividend is safe and the capital g
, isn’
It’
stabilize dividends but they cannot control stock price. From this it seems a small step
to conclude that increased di
e the f
.15 But the important point
is, once again, that as long as investment polic
s overall
ws are the same regardless of payout policy.
all the f
e
ed by its inv
wing policies
vidend policy.
If we really believed that e
cash, then we w
v
gue that the ne
e sense:
w
14
will be $9/.10 5 $90. So the ne
Table 17.2
ve total di
e
15
suggestion?
vidend is e
ve $10,000,000/$90 5
ve total dividend payments of 111,111 3 $9 5
3 $9 5
and
ven more predictable, so a company’s risk would
w would you respond to that
Chapter 17
491
Payout Policy
ut the
The
uy
MM’s ar
vance of dividend policy does not assume a world of
et. Market efficiency means that the
transfers of ownership created by shifts in dividend polic
And since the overall value of (old and ne
fected,
nobody gains or loses.
17.5 Why Dividends May Increase Value
MM’s conclusions follo
ets. However, nobody claims their model is an exact description of the so-called
real world. Thus the impact of payout policy finally boils down to arguments about
Those who believe that di
preference for high-payout stocks. For e
gue that some investors have a natural
gally
vidend records. T
wment funds may prefer high-dividend stocks because di
able “income,
” which may not be
spent.
In addition, there is a natural clientele of investors, including the elderly, who look
v
be generated from stocks paying no dividends at all; the investors can just sell off a
small fraction of their holdings from time to time. But that can be inconvenient and
lead to hea
Behavioral psychology may also help to explain why some investors prefer to
receive regular dividends rather than sell small amounts of stock. W
succumb to temptation. Some of us may hanker after fattening foods, while others
We could seek to control these cravings by willpower, but
es
(“cut out chocolate,” or “wine only with meals”). In just the same way, we may welcome the self-discipline that comes from limiting our spending to dividend income.
ut it does not follow that you can increase the value of
your
ve recognized
that there is a clientele of investors who w
payout stocks. There are natural clienteles for high-payout stocks, but it does not
follow that any particular firm can benefit by increasing its dividends. The highdividend clienteles already have plenty of high-dividend stocks to choose from.
Suppose that the CEO of a software company announces at a press conference a
plan to enter the market for mint toothpaste. When you ask why, the CEO points out
that millions of people buy mint toothpaste. You would doubt the CEO’s business sanity. So why should you believe that because there is a clientele of investors who like
high payouts, your company can increase value by manufacturing a high payout? That
clientele w
Perhaps the most persuasive argument in favor of a high-payout policy is that it
prevents managers from wasting funds. Suppose a company has plenty of cash but few
profitable inv
y will be
plowed back into b
cases, generous dividends or share repurchases deprive the managers of excess cash
alue-oriented investment policy.
ution in
. By 2004, the company’s inv
and investors were, therefore, happ
ute its cash mountain.
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Microsoft’s Payout Bonanza
Self-Test 17.3
17.6 Why Dividends May Reduce Value
The low-dividend creed is simple. Companies can conv
vidends into capital gains
by shifting their dividend policy. If dividends are taxed more heavily than capital
vestor
should pay the lo
y can get aw
used to repurchase shares.
Table 17.3 illustrates this. It assumes that dividends are taxed at a rate of 40% but
ed at only 20%.
,
and investors demand an expected after-tax
vestors
expect A to be w
.
xpected to
be only $102.50, but a $10 di
same, $112.50.
Both stocks of
f. Yet B’s stock sells for less than A’s.
The reason is obvious: Inv
A because its return
w-taxed capital gains.
10% e
act that B’s pretax
.
vidend and uses the cash
to repurchase stock instead. We saw earlier that a stock repurchase is equivalent to a
cash dividend, but now we need to recognize that it is treated differently by the tax
TABLE 17.3 ects of a shift
in dividend policy when
dividends are taxed more
heavily than capital gains.
The high-payout stock (firm B)
must sell at a lower price in
order to provide the same
er-tax return.
492
Chapter 17
493
Payout Policy
y capital
vidend, B’s new policy
16
would reduce the tax
Self-Test 17.4
Taxation of Dividends and Capital
Gains under Current Tax Law
If di
ed more hea
ver pay a
cash di
uted to stockholders, isn’t share repurchase the
best channel for doing so?
In the United States, the case for low dividends was strongest before 1986. The top
rate of tax on dividends was then 50%, while realized capital gains were taxed at 20%.
However, the top rates of tax on both dividends and capital gains were later reduced to
v
vidends. Late in 2010,
Congress agreed to extend these rates through 2012, so at least for the immediate
future, the tax case for low dividends has been weakened.
There is, however, one w
w still favors capital gains. Taxes on dividends hav
, but taxes on capital gains can be deferred until
17
The longer they wait, the less
capital gains tax
the present value of the capital gains tax liability. Thus the
rate can be less than the statutory rate.
The distinction between dividends and capital gains is less important for pension
funds, endo
taxes and therefore have no reason to prefer capital gains to dividends or vice versa.
Only corporations have a tax reason to prefer dividends. They pay corporate income
tax on only 30% of any dividends received.19 Thus the effective tax rate on dividends received by large corporations is 30% of 35% (the marginal rate of corporate
income tax), or 10.5%. But they have to pay a 35% tax on the full amount of any
18
y are pretty simple. Capital gains
have advantages to many investors, but the
antageous than they were
30 or 40 years ago. Consequently, it is less easy today to make con
guments
in fav
.
16
17
v
vent tax avoidance by substitution of repurchases for dividends.
v
vidends and
vidends for tax purposes.
If the stock is willed to your heirs, capital gains escape taxation altogether.
Suppose the discount rate is 6%, and an inv
et has a $100 capital gain.
If the stock is sold today
, the tax due on that $100
gain still will be $15, b
, the present value of the tax falls to
$15/1.06 5 $14.15.
ve tax rate falls to 14.15%.
wer the
effective tax rate.
19
so
company paying the di
vidends received.
18
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SUMMARY
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
finance.yahoo.com
www.earnings.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
MINICASE
TABLE 17.4
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
TABLE 17.5
TABLE 17.6
CHAPTER
20
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After reading this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T S I X
M
Financial Analysis and Planning
Amazon's warehouses are stacked with over $3 billion of inventory.
560
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
20.1 Accounts Receivable and Credit Policy
trade credit
Bills awaiting payment
from one company to
another.
consumer credit
Bills awaiting payment
from final customer to a
company.
W
s accounts receivable. When one company sells goods to another, it does not usually e
. The
unpaid bills, or trade credit, compose the b
vable. The remainder
is made up of consumer credit, bills awaiting payment by the final customer.
volves the follo
ve steps:
1. Y
or
example, how long will you give customers to pay their bills? W
discount for immediate payment?
2. You must decide what evidence you require that the customer owes you money. For
e
3. Y
ely to pay their bills. This is called
credit analysis.
4. You must decide on credit policy. How much credit will you extend to each
customer? Ho
e on marginally creditw
prospects?
5. Finally, you have to collect the money when it becomes due. What do you do about
reluctant payers or deadbeats?
We discuss these topics in turn.
Terms of Sale
terms of sale
Credit, discount, and
payment t
ered
on a sale.
ver you sell goods, you need to set the terms of
. For e
plying goods to a wide v
very
(COD).
heavy deliv
v
In many other cases, payment is not made until after deliv , so the buyer receives
credit. Each industry seems to have its o
ments have a rough logic. For e
goods are perishable or quickly resold.
When you buy goods on credit, the supplier will state a final payment date. To
encourage you to pay before the final date, it is common to of
prompt settlement. For example, a manufacturer may require payment within 30 days
but offer a 5% discount to customers who pay within 10 days. These terms would be
5
10,
net 30
percent discount
for early payment
number of days that
discount is available
number of days
before payment is due
ve a 2%
voice date
Self-Test 20.1
561
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
For many items that are bought re
, it is inconv
ment for each deliv .
in fact occur at the end of the month (EOM). Thus goods may be sold on terms of 8/10,
EOM, net 60. This allo
the invoice date.
A firm that buys on cr
ect borrowing from its supplier. It saves cash
today but will have to pay later. This is an implicit loan from the supplier. Of
course, if it is free, a loan is always worth having. But if you pass up a cash discount,
ve to be v
xpensive. For example, a customer who buys on
day. The customer obtains an e
30 days after the sale but pays about 3% more for the goods. This is equivalent to borrowing mone
. To see why, consider an order of $100. If the
aits the full
30 days, it pays $100. The extra 20 days of credit increase the payment by the fraction
3/97 5 .0309, or 3.09%.
ged to extend the trade
credit is 3.09% per 20 days. There are 365/20 5
, so
ve annual rate of interest on the loan is (1.0309)18.25 21 5 .743, or 74.3%.
The general formula for calculating the implicit annual interest rate for customers
who do not take the cash discount is
Effective annual rate 5 ¢ 1 1
365/extra days credit
discount
≤
21
discounted price
(20.1)
The discount divided by the discounted price is the percentage increase in price
paid by a customer who forgoes the discount. In our example, with terms of 3/10,
net 30, the percentage increase in price is 3/97 5 .0309, or 3.09%. This is the
implicit rate of interest per period. The period of the loan is the number of extra
days of credit that you can obtain by forgoing the discount. In our example, this is
20 days. To annualize this rate, we compound the per-period rate by the number of
periods in a year.
Of course an
yond day 30 gains a cheaper loan but
damages its reputation for creditw
▲
EXAMPLE 20.1
Trade Credit Rates
What is the implied interest rate on the trade credit if the discount for early payment
is 5/10, net 60?
The cash discount in this case is 5% and customers who choose not to take the
discount receive an e a 60 2 10 5 50 days cr
ective annual interest is
ctive annual rate 5 ¢1 1
5 ¢1 1
365/extra days credit
discount
≤
21
discounted price
5
≤
95
/50
In this case the customer who does not tak
money at an annual interest rate of 45.4%.
Y
2 1 5 .454, or 45.4%
ectively borrowing
onder why the effective interest rate on trade credit is typically so high.
v
v
discount. Those who don’t are probably strapped for cash. It mak
ge
562
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
Self-Test 20.2
Credit Agreements
open account
Agreement whereby
sales are made with no
formal debt contract.
ine the amount of any credit but not the nature of the contract.
Repetitiv
ways made on open account and involve only an implicit
contract. There is simply a record in the seller’s books and a receipt signed by the
buyer.
Sometimes you might w
uyer before you deliver
commercial draft. This is
gon for an order to pay.1 It works as follows: The seller prepares a draft
sight dr
otherwise, it is known
as a time draft. Depending on whether it is a sight or a time draft, the customer either
ord “accepted” and
a signature. Once accepted, a time draft is like a postdated check and is called a trade
acceptance. This trade acceptance is then forwarded to the seller, who holds it until the
payment becomes due.
If your customer’
y
s debt, and the
draft is called a banker’s acceptance.
er’
verseas
trade. They are actively bought and sold in the mone
et for shortIf you sell goods to a customer who proves unable to pay, you cannot get your
goods back. You simply become a general creditor of the company
You can av
conditional sale, so that
ownership of the goods remains with the seller until full payment is made. The condibought on installment. In this case, if the customer f
e the agreed number of
payments, then the equipment can be immediately repossessed by the seller.
Credit Analysis
credit analysis
Procedure to determine
the likelihood a
customer will pay its bills.
There are a number of w
ely to pay their debts,
credit analysis. The most obvious indication is whether they have
paid promptly in the past. Prompt payment is usually a good omen, but beware of the
If you are dealing with a new customer, you will probably check with a credit
agency. Dun & Bradstreet, which is by far the largest of these agencies, provides credit
vice, Dun & Bradstreet pro
customer.
ve had with your
customer, b
through a credit bureau.
Y
e a credit check. It will contact the customer’
s average bank balance, access to bank credit, and
general reputation.
1
For e
a payment.
xample of a draft. Whenev
e
563
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
In addition to checking with your customer’
e sense to discover
what ev
s credit
xpensive? Not if your customer is a public company. You
just look at the Moody’s or Standard & Poor’s rating for the customer’s bonds.2 You
irms’ bonds. (Of course
, coupon, and so on.)
If you don’t wish to rely on the judgment of others, you can do your own homework. Ideally this would involve a detailed analysis of the company’s business prosinancing, b
xpensive.
concentrate on the company’
ratios. Chapter 4 described ho
Numerical Credit Scoring Analyzing credit risk is like detective work. You
hav
. You must weigh these clues to come up with an overall judgment.
When the f
gular clientele, the credit manager can easily handle
the process informally and mak
credit:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
The customer’s character.
The customer’s
to pay.
The customer’s capital.
The collateral provided by the customer.3
The condition of the customer’s business.
When the company is dealing directly with consumers or with a large number of
small trade accounts, some streamlining is essential. In these cases it may make sense
to use a scoring system to prescreen credit applications.
If you apply for a credit card or a bank loan, you will probably be asked to complete a questionnaire that pro
4
If you do not make
This information is then used to calculate an ov
the grade on the score, you are likely to be refused credit or subjected to a more
ay
f
potential customers.
Suppose that you are given the task of dev
es sense to e
s customers. Y
v
period with those of surviving firms. Figure 20.1 shows what you find. Panel a illusmuch lo
O
ved. Panel b sho
average they also had a high ratio of liabilities to assets, and panel c shows that
EBITD
es, and depreciation) was low relative to the
f
w ROA), were more
highly leveraged (high ratio of liabilities to assets), and generated relatively little cash
(low ratio of EBITDA to liabilities). In each case, these indicators of the f
inany approached.
William Beaver, Maureen McNichols, and Jung-Wu Rhie studied these f
concluded that these v
elihood of
2
W
For e
customer f
3
These bonds can then be seized by the seller if the
.
4
data provided by any one of three credit b
veloped by F
Trans Union, or Equifax.
564
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
FIGURE 20.1
Financial
ratios of failing and nonfailing
firms
Source: W. H. Beaver, M. F. McNichols, and J.-W. Rhie, “Have Financial Statements Become Less Informative?
Evidence from the Ability of Financial Ratios to Predict Bankruptcy,” Review of Accounting Studies 10 (2005),
pp.
22.
565
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
y. The chance of f
xt year relative to the odds of not failing was best estimated by the following equation:5
Log(
) 5 26.445 2 1.192 3 ROA 1 2.307 3
2.346 3
liabilities
assets
EBITDA
liabilities
Av
ve been used to develop credit-scoring systems.
The model that we have just described uses the technique of hazard analysis. An early,
amous Z-score model developed by Edward
multiple discriminant analysis
s financial ratios could be
the impecunious goats.6
combined as follo
wn as a Z score:7
market value of equity
EBIT
sales
Z 5 3.3 3
1 1.0 3
1 .6 3
1
total assets
total assets
total book debt
retained earnings
1.4 3
1 1.2 3
total assets
total assets
Z scores below 2.7 before they went bankZ scores above this level.
▲
EXAMPLE 20.2
The Z-Score Model
Consider a firm with the following financial ratios:
EBIT
5 .12
Total assets
Sales
5 1.4
Total assets
Retained earnings
Total assets
5 .4
Market value of equity
5 .9
Total book debt
Working capital
Total assets
5 .12
The firm’s Z score is
(3.3 3 .12) 1 (1.0 3 1.4) 1 (.6 3 .9) 1 (1.4 3 .4) 1 (1.2 3 .12) 5 3.04
This score is above the cut
vel for predicting bankruptcy, and it would therefore
be considered favorably in an evaluation of the firm’s cr
orthiness.
cut estimates of creditw
These assessments can streamline the credit decision and free up labor for other, less mechanical tasks.
The Credit Decision
You have tak
ward an effective credit operation. In other words,
you have fixed your terms of sale; you have decided whether to sell on open account
5
See W. H. Beaver, M. F. McNichols, and J.-W. Rhie, “Hav
ve?
Evidence from the
y,” Review of Accounting Studies 10 (2005),
pp. 93–122.
6
See E. I.
y,” J
inance
23 (September 1968), pp. 589–609.
7
es. E. I.
y,” J
inance 23 (September 1968), pp. 589–609.
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Credit Scoring: What Your Lender Won’t Tell You
credit policy
Standards set to
determine the amount
and nature of credit to
extend to customers.
or to ask your customers to sign an IOU; and you have established a procedure for
estimating the probability that each customer will pay up. Your next step is to decide
on credit policy.
If there is no possibility of repeat orders, the credit decision is relatively simple.
Figure 20.2
e neither profit nor loss.
v
credit. If you of
it margin on
the sale. If the customer defaults, you lose the cost of the goods delivered. The decision t
er credit depends on the pr
yment. You should grant
credit if the expected profit from doing so is greater than the profit from
refusing.
Suppose that the probability that the customer will pay up is p. If the customer
does pay, you receive additional revenues (REV) and you deliver goods that you
FIGURE 20.2 If you refuse
credit, you make neither profit
nor loss. If y
er credit,
there is a pr
p that
the customer will pay and you
will make REV 2 COST and
there is a pr
2 p)
that the customer will default
and you will lose COST.
566
567
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
alue of REV 2 COST. Unfortunately, you can’t be certain that the customer will pay; there is a probability (1 2 p)
of default. Default means you receive nothing but still incur the additional costs of
the delivered goods. The expected pr 8 from the two sources of action is therefore
as follows:
You should grant credit if the e
▲
EXAMPLE 20.3
ve.
The Credit Decision
Consider the case of the Cast Iron Company. On each nondelinquent sale Cast
Iron receives revenues with a present value of $1,200 and incurs costs with a present value of $1,000. Therefore, the company’s expected prof
ers credit is
p 3 PV(REV 2 COST) 2 (1 2 p) 3 PV(COST) 5 p 3 200 2 (1 2 p) 3 1,000
If the probability of collection is 5/6, Cast Iron can expect to break even:
Expected profit 5 5/6 3 200 2 (1 2 5/6) 3 1,000 5 0
Thus Cast Iron’s policy should be to grant credit whenever the chances of collection ar
er than 5 out of 6.
In this last example, the net present value of granting credit is positive if the probability of collection exceeds 5/6. In general, this break-even probability can be found
by setting the net present value of granting credit equal to zero and solving for p. It
ven probability is simply the ratio of the present value of costs to revenues:
p 3 PV(
2 COST) 2 (1 2 p) 3 PV(COST) 5 0
Break-even probability of collection, then, is
p5
PV(COST)
PV(REV)
ven probability of default is
(1 2 p) 5 1 2 PV(COST) /PV(REV) 5 PV(PROFIT) /PV(REV)
In other words, the break-even probability of def
each sale. If the default probability is lar
extend credit.
gin on
gin, you should not
w prof
gins should be
cautious about granting credit to high-risk customers. Firms with high margins can
afford to deal with more doubtful ones.
8
“e
v
venues.
venues generated. Also, while we follow conv
As we emphasized in Chapter 1, the manager’s task is to add value, not to
568
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
Self-Test 20.3
So f
of
ve ignored the possibility of repeat orders. But one of the reasons for
.
Suppose Cast Iron has been asked to extend credit to a new customer. Y
ve that the probability of payment is no
Expected profit on initial order 5 p 3 PV(REV 2 COST) 2 (1 2 p) 3 PV(COST)
5 (.8 3 200) 2 (.2 3 1,000) 5 2$40
You decide to refuse credit.
if
. But now consider
future periods. If the customer does pay up, there will be a reorder next year. Having
paid once, the customer will seem less of a risk. For this reason, any repeat order is
v
Think back to Chapter 10, and you will recognize that the credit decision bears
man
w, the
repeat sales. This option can be v
aluable and can tilt the decision tow
credit. Even a dubious prospect may w
the company will dev
.
▲
EXAMPLE 20.4
Credit Decisions with Repeat Orders
To illustrate, let’s look at an extreme case. Suppose that if a customer pays up on
the first sale, you can be sure you will have a regular and completely reliable customer. In this case, the value of such a customer is not the profit on one order but
an entire stream of profits from repeat purchases. For example, suppose that the
customer will make one purchase each year from Cast Iron. If the discount rate is
10% and the profit on each order is $200 a year, then the present value of an indefinite stream of business from a good customer is not $200 but $200/.10 5 $2,000.
There is a pr
p that Cast Iron will secure a good customer with a value of
$2,000. There is a pr
2 p) that the customer will default, resulting in a
loss of $1,000. So, once we recognize the benefits of securing a good and permanent customer, the expected profit from granting credit is
Expected profit 5 (p 3 2,000) 2 (1 2 p) 3 1,000
This is positive for any probability of collection above .33. Thus the break-even probability falls from 5/6 to 1/3. If one sale may lead to profitable repeat sales, the firm
should be inclined to grant credit on the initial purchase.
Self-Test 20.4
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
569
Of course, real-life situations are generally far more complex than our simple
e
y pay late consistently; you get
your money, but it costs more to collect and you lose a few months’ interest. And estimating the probability that a customer will pay up is f
xact science. Then
There may be a good chance that the customer
will give you further business, but you can’
w for
how long she or he will continue to buy from you.
Lik
volves a strong dose of judgment. Our e
volved rather than as
1. Maximize pr
As credit manager your job is not to minimize the number of bad
accounts; it is to maximize profits. You are f
The best that can
happen is that the customer pays promptly; the worst is default. In the one case the
f
ves the full additional revenues from the sale less the additional costs; in
the other it receives nothing and loses the costs. You must weigh the chances of
v
ied in a
liberal credit policy; if it is low
y bad debts.
2. Concentrate on the dangerous accounts. You should not expend the same ef
analyzing all credit decisions. If an application is small or clear
gely routine; if it is large or doubtful, you may do better to move
straight to a detailed credit appraisal. Most credit managers don’
e credit
decisions on an order-by-order basis. Instead, they set a credit limit for each
customer. The sales representative is required to refer the order for approval only if
the customer e
3. Look beyond the immediate order. Sometimes it may be w
vely
elihood that the customer will grow into a regular
and reliable buyer
ge
students even though fe
.) New
businesses must be prepared to incur more bad debts than established businesses
because they hav
w-risk customers. This is
uilding up a good customer list.
Collection Policy
It w
y don’t, and
since you may also “stretch” your payables, from time to time, you can’t altogether
blame them.
Slow payers impose tw
resources in collecting payments. They also force the f
vest more in w
capital. Recall from Chapter 4 that accounts receiv
verage
wn as days’ sales in receivables):
Accounts receivable 5 daily sales 3 average collection period
collection policy
Procedures to collect
and monitor receivables.
aging schedule
Classification of
accounts receivable by
time outstanding.
and a greater investment in accounts receivable. That’s why you need a collection
policy.
The credit manager keeps a record of payment e
. In
addition, the manager monitors ov
wing up a schedule of the
aging of receivables. The aging schedule classifies accounts receivable by the length
of time the
This may look roughly like Table 20.1. The table shows
that customer A, for e
than a month. Customer Z, however
bills that hav
570
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
TABLE 20.1 An aging
schedule of receivables
Self-Test 20.5
statement of account
w this at interv
ax
messages. If none of these has an
ver to a collection agency or an attorney.
Large f
eeping, billing, and so on, but
the small f
wever, it
can obtain some scale economies by f
factor. The factor
sf
ies
each customer that the factor has purchased the debt (i.e., the trade credit). The factor
then takes on the responsibility (and risk) of collecting the bills and pays the invoice
value to the client minus a fee of 1% or 2%. Aside from gaining the economies that
ge number of manufacturers, factors see
many more transactions than any single f
creditw
.
There is alw
v
y no sooner win
ne
ters. The collection manager
quently paid for.
y problem introduced in
Chapter 1. Good collection policy balances conflicting goals. The company wants
cordial relations with its customers. It also wants them to pay their bills on time.
agers who w
or e
vision of a
major pharmaceutical company actually made a b
tomer that had been suddenly cut off by its bank. The pharmaceutical company bet that
company was right.
v
y, and became an even more loyal customer. It was a nice
e
e business loans in this way, but they lend
money indirectly whenever they allow a delay in payment. Trade credit can be an
e sense
for you, the supplier, to continue to e
o possible reasons
e sense: First, as in the case of our pharmaceutical company, you may
571
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
have more information than the bank about the customer’s business. Second, you need
to look be
lose some prof
usiness.9
20.2 Inventory Management
. Inv
w matew
ventories. For example, they could b
,
as needed. But then they would pay higher prices for ordering in small lots, and they
w
vered on time. They can
av
,f
could do away with inv
y expect
w
gy. A producer with only a
small inv
orders if demand is unexpectedly high. Moreover
ge inv
may allow longer
v
These are called
For example, money tied up in inventories does
in
spillage or obsolescence.
e a sensible
ventory and the costs.
▲
EXAMPLE 20.5
Inventory Management
Here is a simple inventory problem. Akron Wire Products uses 255,000 tons a year of
wire rod. Suppose that it orders Q tons at a time from the manufacturer. Just before
delivery, its inventories of wire have run down to zero. Just
er delivery, it has an
inventory of Q tons. Thus, Akron’s inventory of wire rod roughly follo
ooth
pattern in Figure 20.3.
There ar
o costs to holding this inventory. First, there are carrying costs, such
as the cost of storage, and the cost of the capital that is tied up in inventory. Suppose these costs work out to an annual figure of about $55 per ton. The second
type of cost is the order cost. Each order that Akron places with the manufacturer
involves a fixed handling and delivery charge of $450.
FIGURE 20.3
A simple
inventory rule. The company
waits until inventories of
materials are exhausted and
then reorders a constant
quantity.
9
ve a greater
Theories and Evidence,” Review of Financial Studies 10 (F
. For some evidence on
rade Credit:
572
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
FIGURE 20.4
As the
inventory order size increases,
order costs fall and invent
ise. Total costs
are minimized when the
saving in order costs equals
the incr
.
Here, then, is the kernel of the inventory problem: As Akron increases its order size,
the number of orders falls but average inventory rises. Figure 20.4 shows that cost
related to the number of orders declines, though at a decreasing rate, while carrying cost related to inventory size rises. It is worth increasing order size as long as the
decline in order cost outweighs the rise in carrying cost. The optimal inventory polects ex
. In our example, this
occurs when the firm places about 250 orders a year (roughly one order every
working day) and the size of each order is Q 5 2,043 tons. The optimal order size
(2,043 tons in our example) is known as the economic or
, or EOQ.10
In
the
order
for
Wire, we made several unrealistic assumptions. For instance, most firms do not use up their inventory of raw
y would not w
of inv
• Optimal inv
•
in inv
.
•
vels involve a trade-of
v
aiting until they reach some minimum level
.
•
w
es sense to place more
frequent orders and maintain higher levels of inv
will w
ger and therefore less frequent orders.
• Inventory levels do not rise in direct proportion to sales. As sales increase, the
optimal inventory level rises, b
.
10
Optimal order size 5 Q 5
In our example, Q 5
Å
Å
2 3 sales 3 cost per order
2 3 255,000 3 450
5 2,043 tons.
55
573
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
wer levels of inv
y used to.
v
just-in-time approach
System of inventory
management that
requires minimal
inventories of materials
and very frequent
deliveries by suppliers.
Today
ay that companies have reduced inv
vels is by
moving to a just-in-time approach. Just-in-time was pioneered by To
Toyota keeps inv
y
Thus deliv
interv
. Toyota is able to operate successfully with such low invenes, traf
hazards don’
y
v
Toyota’s example and hav
their investment in inventories.
Firms are also finding that they can reduce their inv
producing their goods to order. For example, Dell Computer discovered that it did not
need to k
ge stock of f
net to specify what features they want on their PC. The computer is then assembled to
order and shipped to the customer.11
20.3 Cash Management
viduWhy, for example, don’t you
e all your cash and inv
The answer of course is
that cash gives you more
than do securities. You can use it to b
w York cab drivers to give you change for a $20 bill, but try
asking them to split a Treasury bill.
When you hav
xtra can be
extremely useful; when you hav
y additional liquidity is not
worth much.
point where the marginal value of the liquidity is equal to the value of the interest
forgone.
aces a
task like that of the production manager. After all, cash is just another raw material that
you need to do b
ge “inv
of cash. If the cash were invested in securities, it w
hand, you can’
s bills. If you had to sell them every
time you needed to pay a bill, you could incur hea
manager must trade off the cost of keeping an inventory of cash (the lost interest)
against the benefits (the saving on transaction costs).
For v
ge f
uying and selling securities are trivial
interest rate is 4% per year, or roughly 4/365 5 .011% per day. Then the daily interest
3 $1,000,000 5 $110. Even at a cost of $50 per transaction, which is generous, it pays to buy T
w
rather than to leave $1 million idle ov
A corporation such as W
verw of $400,000,000,000/365 5
up buying or selling securities once a day, ev
, unless by chance they have only
a small positive cash balance at the end of the day.
Banks have developed a v
ays to help such firms invest idle cash. For
example, they may provide sweep programs,
11
These examples of just-in-time and b
Isn’t Good Enough,” Ward’s Auto World,
World, May 1999, pp. 73–77; “
en from T
, “JIT
, “Aliv
Well,” Ward’s Auto
” The Economist, July 14, 2001, pp. 63–65.
574
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
surplus funds into a higher-interest account. Why then do these large firms hold
any significant amounts of cash in non-interest-bearing accounts? For two reasons:
First, cash may be left in accounts to compensate banks for the services they
provide. Second, large corporations may have literally hundreds of accounts with
dozens of different banks. It is often less expensive to leave idle cash in some of
these accounts than to monitor each account daily and make daily transfers between
them.
One major reason for the proliferation of bank accounts is decentralized management. If you giv
airs, you must
also giv
ve cash. Good cash management nev
implies some degree of centralization. You cannot maintain your desired inv
wn private pools of
cash.
v
vesting
that even in highly decentralized companies there is generally central control over
cash balances and bank relations.
Check Handling and Float
concentration account
Customers make
payments to a regional
collection center, which
then transfers funds to
an account at a
principal bank.
lock-box system
System whereby
customers send
payments to a postice box, and a local
bank collects and
processes checks.
T
ve been paid with checks. But
check handling is a cumbersome and labor-intensiv
e several days
for a check to clear. Suppose, for example, that you renew your auto insurance by writy.
insurance company receives your check and deposits it in its bank account. But this
money isn’t available to the company immediately. The company’s bank won’t actually have the mone
ves payment. Since the bank has to wait, it makes the insurance company wait too—usually 1
or 2 business days. Until the check has been presented and cleared, that $600 will continue to sit in your bank account.
Checks that have been mailed b
wn as
In our examvided you with an extra $600 in your bank account while the check went
y, then to the company’
inally to your own
bank.
elous invention, but unfortunately it can
also work in reverse. Ev
you a check, you have to wait several
days after depositing it before you may spend the money.
However
w in the last sev
ve helped to speed up collections.
wn as “Check 21,”
allo
es. So fe
e bundles of checks from one bank to another.
v
ge volume of checks have devised a number of ways to
ensure that the cash becomes av
or e
concentration
account at one of the company’
o reasons that concentration banking allows the company to gain quicker use of its funds. First, because the
s
check is likely to be dra
reduced.
Concentration banking is often combined with a lock-box system. In this case the
ice box.
The local bank then takes on the administrative chore of emptying the box and depositing the checks in the company’s local deposit account.
575
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
▲
EXAMPLE 20.6
Lock-Box Systems
Suppose that you are thinking of opening a lock box. The local bank shows you a
map of mail delivery times. From that and knowledge of your customers’ locations,
you come up with the following data:
Average number of daily payments to lock box
Average size of payment
Rate of interest per day
Saving in mailing time
Saving in processing time
5 150
5 $1,200
5 .02%
5 1.2 days
5 .8 day
On this basis, the lock box would reduce collection float by
150 items per day 3 $1,200 per item 3 (1.2 1 .8) days saved 5 $360,000
Invested at .02% per day, that gives a daily return of
.0002 3 $360,000 5 $72
The bank’s charge for operating the lock-box system depends on the number of
checks processed. Suppose that the bank charges $.26 per check. That works out
to 150 3 $.26 5 $39 per day. You are ahead by $72 2 $39 5 $33 per day, plus whatever your firm saves from not having to process the checks itself.
Self-Test 20.6
Other Payment Systems
ger purchases or
set out in Table 20.2.
Figure 20.5 compares use of these payment systems around the world. Payment
patterns v
or example, look at the bottom (blue) portion
or Germany
fer. By contrast,
v
, U.S. indi
e about 27 billion payments by check. But even in the United States, check writing
is steadily giving way to electronic payments. Over 50% of U.S. households now use
paid by direct deposit.
In f
of credit and debit cards continues to grow
orld as the market share
576
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
TABLE 20.2 Small faceto-face purchases are
commonly paid for in cash,
but here are some of the
other ways that you can pay
your bills.
FIGURE 20.5
How
purchases are paid for:
Percentage of total volume
of cashless transactions.
(Data exclude small usage
of card-based e-money.)
Source: Bank for Inter
.bis.or
l, December 2009.
, “Statistics on Pa
ystems in Selected Countries,”
the Internet are encouraging the development of new inf
just two examples:
•
ws companies to bill
customers and receive payments through the Internet. Already in Finland, two out
gard the Internet as the most typical medium for paying bills.
• Stored v
pretty much as electronic cash.
Electronic Funds Transfer
As we’ve just noted, throughout the world payments are increasingly being made electronically. The most f
ays that mone
v
. It
can do so by direct payment, direct deposit, or wire transfer. Figure 20.6 shows the
577
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
FIGURE 20.6
Methods used
by companies to make and
receive electronic payments
Source: A Treasurer’s Guide to U.S. Cash Management, Association for Financial Professionals, Report of Survey
Results, August 2000.
xpenditures, such as utility bills,
or example, if you hav
en
out a student loan, you may hav
e the payment directly
from your bank account each month. The student loan company simply needs to prowing details of each student, the amount to be debited, and
the date. The payment then trav
Automated Clearing
House (ACH) system. You are saved from the chore of writing regular checks, and the
ws exactly when the cash is coming in and avoids the labor-intensive process
of handling thousands of checks.
The
ws mone
w in the reverse
direction. Thus, while a direct payment
vides an automatic debit, a
direct deposit
e bulk
payments such as wages or dividends. Again the company pro
The bank then debits the company’
the
s employees or shareholders. ACH transactions have grown dramatically in recent years. You can see from
Table 20.3 that the total value of these transactions in the United States has ov
en
that of checks.
The third method of electronic payment is wire transfer. Most large-value payments
Direct payment
Automated Clearing
House (ACH)
An electronic network
for cash transfers in the
United States.
e and
.12 CHIPS,
the other electronic payment system, is owned by the banks and used mainly for crossborder payments. Wire transfers allow f
vement of very large sums of
money. For example, suppose bank A wires the Fed to transfer $10 million from its
TABLE 20.3 Use of
payment systems in the
United States, 2009
Source:
12
.federalreserve.gov,
.nacha.com, and
.chips.org.
Fedwire is a real-time, gross settlement system, which means that each transaction over Fedwire is settled
indi
.W
als.
578
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
A’s account is immediately
reduced by $10 million, and bank B’
Table 20.3 shows
that although the number of payments by Fedwire and CHIPS is relatively small, the
average v
alue of payments
o systems is ov
Thus, while these systems account for a far smaller number of transactions than do
checks, the
value.
These electronic payment systems have several advantages:
• Record keeping and routine transactions are easy to automate when money moves
electronically.
•
ery low. For e
typically costs about $20, while it costs only a few cents to make each ACH
payment.
• Float is reduced. For e
one plant was paying out about $8 million a month several days early to avoid any
risk of late fees if checks were delayed in the mail. The solution was obvious: The
ay they could
ved exactly on time.
International Cash Management
ge multinational corporations operating in dozens of different countries, each with its own
y
A single centralized cash management system is an unattainable ideal for these
companies, although the
ward it. For example, suppose that you are
treasurer of a large multinational company with operations throughout Europe. You
could allow the separate businesses to manage their own cash, but that would be costly
and w
The
solution is to set up a re
y establishes a local
concentration account with a bank in each country. Any surplus cash is swept daily
.
This cash is then invested in mark
that hav
Payments can also be made out of the regional center. For example, to pay wages in
, the compan
inds the least costly way
to transfer the cash from the company’
.
ge multinationals have sev
,b
they use, the less control they have over their cash balances. So development of
regional cash management systems favors banks that can offer a worldwide branch
network.
ford the high costs of setting up computer systems for
handling cash payments and receipts in different countries.
20.4 Investing Idle Cash: The Money Market
money market
Market for short-term
financial assets.
ve excess funds, they can inv
the money market,
invest directly in these securities. However
a money mark
y market investments.
et. In fact, however, most instruments in the money market have
o advantages for the cash
579
Chapter 20 Working Capital Management
manager
maturity. V
it is f
v
ault ov
inancial strength ov
ver the 30-year
life of a bond.
y are conv
Most money market securities are also highly marketable or liquid, meaning that it
is easy and cheap to sell the asset for cash.
, too, is an attractive feature of
vestments until cash is needed.
y market are:
Tr
T
vernment and mature
The
safest and most liquid money mark
Commercial paper.
wn companies.
ge and well-
than 2 months. Because there is no active trading in commercial paper, it has low
etability. Therefore, it w
vestment for a firm that
could not hold it until maturity. Both Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s rate comault risk of the issuer.
greater than $100,000. Unlik
its cannot be withdra
The bank pays interest and
wever, short-term CDs (with
maturities less than 3 months) are activ
Repurchase agreements.
wn as repos,
A gov
T
investor, with an agreement to repurchase them at a later date at a higher price.
es as implicit interest, so the investor in effect is lending
money to the dealer, first giving money to the dealer and later getting it back with
interest. The bills serve as collateral for the loan: If the dealer fails, and cannot
buy back the bill, the investor can keep it. Repurchase agreements are usually
very short-term, with maturities of only a few days.
Interest rates on short-term loans (loans of less than 1 year) are often quoted on a
so-called discount basis. For e
. On a discount basis, the rate would be quoted as the discount from
face value, in this case 5%. The actual interest rate is a bit higher than this. You pay
interest of $5,000 on a $95,000 loan, so the interest rate is $5,000/$95,000 5 .0526, or
5.26%. You should be aw
on a discount basis.
▲
EXAMPLE 20.7
Money Market Rates
A Treasury bill with face value $100,000 and maturity 6 months is sold for $98,000.
The rate on this bill on a discount basis would be quoted as 4%. The actual discount from face value is 2% semiannually, or 4% on an annualized basis. Notice
also that money market rates are annualized using simple, not compound, interest.
The ective annual rate on this half-year investment can be found by solving
98,000 3 (1 1 r)1/2 5 100,000
which implies that r 5 .0412, or 4.12%.
580
Part Six Financial Analysis and Planning
Yields on Money Market Investments
e account of def
Almost anyy may get into
ven today’
trouble ev
.
T
ven companies
. They included Lehman Brothers, which
defaulted on a record $3 billion of paper. F
, such examples are exceptions; in
general, the danger of default is less for money mark
o reasons for this. First, as we pointed out
abov
vestments. Even
ve for at least the ne
well-established companies can borrow in the money market. If you are going to lend
money for just a few days, you can’
valuating the
Thus, you will consider only blue-chip borrowers.
Despite the high quality of money market inv
icant
differences in yield between corporate and U.S. gov
Why is this?
One answer is the risk of default. Another is that the investments have different degrees
of liquidity, or “moneyness.” Investors like Treasury bills because they are easily
verted so quickly and
cheaply into cash need to offer relatively high yields.
et turmoil investors may place a higher value on having ready
access to cash. On these occasions the yield on illiquid securities can increase dramatically. This happened in 2007, when banks across the world revealed huge losses in the
their positions, inv
ity.”
Treasury bills increased
to over 100 basis points (1.00%), four times its level at the be
.
The International Money Market
In addition to the domestic money market, there is also an international market for
vestments, which is known as the eurodollar mark
hav
(EMU). The
or example, suppose
American auto producer buys 1,000 ounces of palladium from Xstrata, the
European mining giant. It pays for the purchase with a check for $1.5 million drawn
on JPMorgan Chase. Xstrata then deposits the check with its account at Barclays Bank
in London.
account with JPMorgan Chase. It also has an of
deposit. Since that dollar deposit is placed in Europe, it is called a eurodollar deposit.13
Just as there is both a domestic U.S. mone
et, so
et and a market in London for euroyen.
vestment in yen, it can deposit
the yen with a bank in Tok
e a euroyen deposit in London. Similarly,
there is both a domestic money market in the euro area as well as a money market for
euros in London. And so on.
London
ed Rate
, the
LIBOR interest rate, and they lend euros at the euro interbank offered rate, or Euribor.
in the United States and in other countries. For e
13
would still hav
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
L I S T I N G O F E Q U AT I O N S
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
finance.google.com
finance.yahoo.com
www.wellsfargo.com
www.bankofamerica.com
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
MINICASE
TABLE 20.4
QUESTIONS
CHAPTER
21
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
5
6
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T S E V E N
Special Topics
Panasonic, a consumer electronics giant, acquired rival Sanyo for around $9 billion.
T
592
Seven
Special Topics
FIGURE 21.1
The number of
mergers in the United States,
1962–2009
Source:
.mergerstat.com.
21.1 Sensible Motives for Mergers
Mer
mer
horizontal, vertical, or conglomerate. A
es place between tw
usiness; the merged
gers have been of this type. For e
ynch and between Wells Fargo and Wachovia. Other
gers hav
W
A vertical merger involves companies at different stages of production. The buyer
expands back tow
ard in the direction of the
ultimate consumer.
acturer might b
(expanding backward) or a fast-food chain as an outlet for its product (expanding forward). A recent example of a vertical merger is the acquisition of Tele Atlas by its
fello
Tom Tom. Tom T
orld’
gest mak
vigation
devices, plans to use Tele Atlas’s digital map data to provide real-time updates to its
sat-nav systems.
TABLE 21.1
Some important
recent mergers
Chapter 21
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
593
A conglomerate merger involves companies in unrelated lines of business. For
y Tata Group is a huge, widely diversif
y. In
ve been as div
Steel, Jaguar Land Rover, and the Ritz Carlton, Boston. No U.S. company is as diverTata, but in the 1960s and 1970s it w
unrelated businesses to merge. The number of U.S. conglomerate mergers declined in
the 1980s. In f
.
e
Self-Test 21.1
Many mergers and acquisitions are motiv
y from
combining operations. These mergers create synergies. By this we mean that the two
It would be conv
gers are more likely
to result in syner
no such simple generalizations. Many mer
e sense nevertheless
fail because managers cannot handle the complex task of integrating tw
different production processes, pay structures, and accounting methods. Moreover, the
v
usinesses depends on human
orkers, scientists, and engineers. If these people are not happy in their new roles in the mer
the best of them will leave. Bew
wn in the
elev
usiness day.
Consider the $38 billion merger between Daimler
. Although it
w
bede
ov
ferent cultures:
German management-board members had executiv
papers on any number of issues. The
t hav
orked
y for final approval at the top. Then it was set in stone. The
vel employees to proceed on their own initiativ
waiting for executive-level approval.
. . . Cultural integration also was proving to be a slippery commodity. The yawning gap in
The
xpenses of U.S. workers
-side employees thought
w York for a half-day meeting, then capping the visit with a
fanc
xpensive hotel.
xtravagance.1
its way through the b
w in the towel and announced that
veraged-b
it was of
care liabilities and agreed to inv
These observations illustrate the dif
ger does achiev
1
Bill Vlasic and Bradley
The McGra
yee health
.
ger.
gies, but
aken for a Ride,” BusinessWeek, June 5, 2000. Reprinted with special per-
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Those Elusive Synergies
the buyer nev
or example, the buyer may
overestimate the value of stale inv
vating old
plant and equipment, or it may overlook the w
ve product.
With these caveats in mind, we will now consider some possible sources of
synergy.
Economies of Scale
Just as most of us believe that we would be happier if only we were a little richer, so
ways seem to believ
ould be more competitive if only it were
just a little bigger. They hope for economies of scale, that is, the opportunity to spread
ed costs across a larger volume of output.
vides many
examples. As a result of bank re
y small, local
banks. When these regulations were relaxed, some banks grew by systematically buying up other banks and streamlining their operations. When Bank of New York and
ged in 2007, management forecast annual cost savings of $700 million, or ov
pated that the merger would allow the two companies to share services and technology
and w
savings involved senior management. For e
o chief f
icers before the merger and only one afterward.) Bew
verly optimistic predictions of cost savings, however.
ger that
gies.
These economies of scale are the natural goal of horizontal mergers. But they have
gers, too.
gers have
vel management.
Economies of Vertical Integration
Large companies commonly like to gain as much control and coordination as possible
over the production process by expanding back toward the output of the raw material
and forward to the ultimate consumer. One way to achieve this is to merge with a supplier or a customer.
594
Chapter 21
595
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
V
gration has fallen out of fashion recently. Man
icient to outsource many of their activities. For e
and 1960s, General Motors was thought to have a cost advantage over its competitors
because it produced a greater fraction of its components in-house. By the 1990s Ford
antage. They could b
suppliers. This w
.
But it also appears that manufacturers hav
gaining power when the
amily. In 1998 GM decided to spin off Delphi, its automotiv
vision, as a separate
company.
ge volumes,
but it ne
s length.
Combining Complementary Resources
s success.
ve a unique product b
could dev
to mer
resources
the mer
ut it may be quick
ve
e sense for them to merge.
ve faced the loss of patv
of promising new compounds. This has prompted an increasing number of acquisior example, in 2008 Eli Lilly acquired ImClone Systems. Lilly
ver the company’s earlier
market value. But Lilly’s CEO claimed that the acquisition would “broaden Lilly’s
eted cancer therapies and boost Lilly’s oncology pipeline with up to
geted therapies in Phase III in 2009.”
et.
Mergers as a Use for Surplus Funds
but it has fe
v
ute the
, ener
ay.
wn shares, it can instead purchase someone else’s.
vestment opporgers
as a way of deploying their capital.
Firms that have excess cash and do not pay it out or redeploy it by acquisition often
es targets for takeov
y the cash
y cash-rich oil companies
found themselves threatened by takeover. This was not because their cash was a unique
asset. The acquirers w
w to make sure it was
not frittered away on negative-NPV oil exploration projects. W
freemotiv
eovers later in the chapter.
Eliminating Inefficiencies
Cash is not the only asset that can be wasted by poor management. There are always
some instances “better management” may simply mean the determination to force
y’
ve for such acquisitions has nothing to do with benefits from combining tw
Acquisition is simply
the mechanism by which a new management team replaces the old one.
596
Seven
Special Topics
A merger may not be the only way to improve management, but sometimes there is
no simple and practical alternativ
ge public firms do not usually have much direct
If this motive for merger is important, one would expect to observe that acquisitions
get f
This seems to be the
case. For e
xecutive is four times
2
The
more likely to be replaced in the year after a takeov
y studied had generally been poor performers.
y of these
ger.
21.2 Dubious Reasons for Mergers
ve described so far all mak
sometimes given for mergers are more dubious. Here are two.
guments
Diversification
We have suggested that the managers of a cash-rich company may prefer to see that
cash used for acquisitions.
tries mer
ay into fresh woods and pastures new. But what about diversification as an end in itself? It is obvious that div
t that a gain
from merging?
gument is that div
A buy f
versify when
A can b
versify their o
It is f
vidual investors to div
combine operations.
The Bootstrap Game
v
sev
▲
EXAMPLE 21.1
vive strategy produced
To see ho
wn conglomerate W
The Bootstrap Game
The position before the merger is set out in the first two columns of Table 21.2.
Notice that because Muck and Slurry has relatively poor growth prospects, its stock
sells at a lower price-earnings ratio than World Enterprises (line 3). The merger, we
assume, produces no economic benefits, so the firms should be worth exactly the
same together as apart. The value of World Ent
er the merger is therefore
equal to the sum of the separate v
o firms (line 6).
Since World Enterprises stock is selling for double the price of Muck and Slurry
stock (line 2), World Enterprises can acquire the 100,000 Muck and Slurry shares for
50,000 of its own shares. Thus World will have 150,000 shares outst
er the
merger.
World’s total earnings double as a result of the acquisition (line 5), but the number
of shares increases by only 50%. Its earnings per share rise from $2.00 to $2.67.
We call this a bootstr
ect because there is no real gain created by the merger
and no incr
o firms’ combined value. Since World’s stock price is
unchanged b
,
atio falls (line 3).
2
J
T eovers, and Management Turnover,”
inance
Chapter 21
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
597
TABLE 21.2 Impact of
merger on market value and
earnings per share of World
Enterprises
Note: When World Enterprises purchases Muck and Slurry, there are no gains. Therefore, total earnings and total
market v
ected by the merger. But earnings per share increase. World Enterprises issues only
50,000 of its shares (priced at $40) to acquire the 100,000 Muc
es (priced at $20).
Before the merger, $1 invested in World Enterprises bought 5 cents of current
earnings and rapid gro
ospects. On the other hand, $1 invested in Muck
and Slurry bought 10 cents of current earnings but slower growth prospects. If the
total market value is not altered by the merger, then $1 invested in the merged firm
gives World shareholders 6.7 cents of immediate earnings but slower growth than
before the merger. Muck and Slurry shareholders get lower immediate earnings
but faster growth. Neither side gains or loses provided that everybody understands
the deal.
Financial manipulators sometimes try to ensure that the market does not understand the deal. Suppose that investors are fooled by the exuberance of the president of World Enterprises and mistake the 33% postmerger increase in earnings per
share for sustainable gro
y do, the price of World Enterprises stock rises
and the shareholders of both companies receive something for nothing.
You should now see ho
company enjo
vestors
anticipate rapid growth in future earnings. You achieve this growth not by capital
investment, product improvement, or increased operating ef
y but by purchasing
slow-gro
The long-run result will be slower
growth and a depressed price-earnings ratio, b
increase dramatically. If this fools investors, you may be able to achieve the higher
to keep fooling investors, you must continue to expand by merger at the same compound rate. Obviously you cannot do this forever; one day expansion must slow down
or stop.
all. Buying a
firm with a lower P/E ratio can increase earnings per share. But the increase
should not result in a higher share price. The short-term increase in earnings
y lower future earnings gro
Self-Test 21.2
598
Part Seven Special Topics
21.3 The Mechanics of a Merger
Buying a company is a much more complicated aff
uying a piece of machinery. We are not going to get into the tax or accounting complexities here, but we will
describe the dif
e and the way that an acquisi-
The Form of Acquisition
merger
Combination of two
firms into one, with the
acquirer assuming
assets and liabilities of
the target firm.
tender offer
Takeover attempt in
which outsiders directly
er to buy the stock of
the firm’s shareholders.
acquisition
Takeover of a firm by
purchase of that firm’s
common stock or assets.
There are three w
. One possibility is to merge
two companies into one, in which case the acquiring company assumes all the assets
and all the liabilities of the other. The acquired f
v
y mergers
there is a clear acquiring company
Sometimes a merger is presented as a “merger of equals,” but even in these cases one
s management usually comes out on top.
3
A merger must have the approval of at least 50% of the shareholders of each f
Approval is not always guaranteed. For example, when Charles River Laboratories in
W
price slumped and some major institutional shareholders voiced their opposition to the
deal. With a week to go before its shareholders’ meeting, success for CRL w
v
s stock in
exchange for cash, shares, or other securities.
xist
, but it is now owned by the acquirer. The approval and cooperation
ut even if they resist, the acquirer
uy shares
irm can bypass the tar
s management altogether.
tender offer.
is successful, the buyer obtains control and can, if it chooses, toss out incumbent
management.
, the tar
ut
occasionally it sells all
xist as an
independent entity, b
usiness activity.
The terminology of mergers and acquisitions (M&A) can be confusing. These
phrases are used loosely to refer to an
eover. But
strictly speaking, merger means the combination of all the assets and liabilities of two
The purchase of the stock or assets of another f
acquisition.
Mergers, Antitrust Law, and Popular Opposition
Mergers may be blocked by the federal gov
y are thought to be anticompetitiv
et power. Thus, when the video-rental giant Blockbuster proposed to mer
val Hollywood Video, the Federal Trade
ould likely block the deal. In the face of this
agement.
Companies that do business outside the United States also have to w
ws. For e
eover bid for Honeywell was
block
y
would have too much power in the aircraft industry.
3
ws sometimes specify a higher percentage.
Chapter 21
div
F
pan
Mer
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
599
usters will object to a merger but then relent if the companies agree to
or instance, when the organic grocer
et acquired its closest rival, W
ets, the FTC required the comW
ven
or example, the news in 2005 that Pepsi Cola
added his support to opponents of the merger and announced that the French gov
ment was drawing up a list of strate
ownership. It w
gic
fwhat it described as “unprecedented political opposition” in Congress. The following
year Congress voiced its opposition to the takeov
s P&O by the Dubai
y, DP World.
s ports in the United
States were excluded from the deal.
21.4 Evaluating Mergers
ven the responsibility for evaluating a proposed merger, you must think
wing two questions:
1. Is there an overall economic gain to the merger? In other words, is the merger
v
Are the tw
2.
e my compan
f? There
is no point in mer
other company.
vely simple questions is rarely easy
can be nearly impossible to quantify, and complex mer
valuating mer
Mergers Financed by Cash
W
xample. Your company, Cislunar Foods, is
considering acquisition of a smaller food company, Tar
T getco’
o companies is given in the left and center columns of Table 21.3.
TABLE 21.3 Cislunar Foods
is considering an acquisition
of Targetco. The merger
would increase the
companies’ combined
earnings by $4 million.
Note: Figures in millions except price per share.
600
Seven
Special Topics
Question 1
Why w
Targetco be w
ution, and administration. Rev
Targetco’s
Table 21.3 contains projected revenues, costs, and
ger will
be $2 million less than the sum of the separate companies’ costs, and revenues will be
4
We will
$2 million more.
gy to be generated by the merger.
ger is the present value of the e
v
k
region.
Economic gain 5 PV(increased earnings) 5
4
5 $20 million
.20
This additional value is the basic motivation for the merger.
Question 2
ger?
shareholders?
Targetco’s management and shareholders will not consent to the merger unless they
receive at least the stand-alone value of their shares. The
ne
. In this case we are considering a cash offer of $19 per
Targetco share, $3 per share ov
T
ve to pay out $47.5 million, a premium of $7.5 million
over T getco’
et v
T
$7.5 million out of the $20 million gain from the merger. That ought to leave $12.5
.
Table 21.4
bottom of
the column, where the total market value of the merged f
This is
ved as follows:
Cislunar market value prior to merger
Targetco market value
Present value of gain to merger
Less Cash paid out to Targetco shareholders
Postmerger market value
$480 million
40
20
247.5
$492.5 million
The postmer
alue of CisNow let’
The merger mak
ger adds $20 million of overall v
only $7.5 million of that $20 million overall gain to Targetco’
. You could say that the cost
ference between the cash payment and the v
rate company:
o reasons. First,
ger give
ving
T getco is $7.5
T getco as a sepa-
Cost 5 cash paid out 2 Targetco value 5 $47.5 2 40 5
Of course, the T
cost. As we’v
is the merger’
NPV 5
Their gain is your
This
2 cost 5 $20 2 7.5 5 $12.5 million
Writing do
ger in this way separates the
motive for the merger (the economic gain, or value added) from the terms of the
merger (the division of the gain between the two merging companies).
4
To k
also ignore the interest income that could hav
We
v
ger.
Chapter 21
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
601
TABLE 21.4 Financial
for
er the CislunarTargetco merger
column assumes a cash
purchase at $19 per
Targetco share. The right
column assumes Targetco
stockholders receive one new
Cislunar share for ev
ee
Targetco shares.
Note: Figures in millions except price per share.
Self-Test 21.3
Mergers Financed by Stock
e its cash for other investments and therefore decides
T getco
v
v
T
It’s the same merger, but the f
The right column of Table 21.4
works out the consequences.
bottom of the column. Note that the
market v
ger is $540 million, $47.5 million
higher than in the cash deal, because that cash is kept rather than paid out to Targetco
w
ve to be issued in exchange for the 2.5 million Targetco shares (a 1-to-3
ratio). Therefore, the price per share is 540/10.833 5 $49.85, which is 60 cents higher
than in the cash offer.
to pay for the T
gain from the merger is the same, but the Tar
They
ver
T getco’s prior market value:
Cost 5 value of shares issued 2 Targetco value
5 $41.5 2 40 5
The merger’s NPV to Cislunar’s original shareholders is
NPV 5 economic gain 2 cost 5 20 2 1.5 5 $18.5 million
Note that Cislunar stock rises by $1.85 from its prior value. The total increase in value
for Cislunar’
Evaluating the terms of a mer
y when there is an e
The target company’s shareholders will retain a stake in the mer
ve
s shares will be worth after the mer
v
et v
Cislunar and Targetco postmerger, took account of the mer
w
orked back to the postmerger share price. Only then could we
work out the division of the merger gains between the two companies.
There is a key distinction between cash and stock for financing mergers. If cash
ered, the cost of the mer
ected by the size of the merger gains. If
stoc
ered, the cost depends on the gains because the gains show up in the
postmerger share price, and these shares are used to pay for the acquired firm.
602
Seven
Special Topics
Stock f
fects of over
Suppose, for e
A overestimates B’s v
, perhaps
because it has overlooked some hidden liability. Thus A makes too generous an offer.
Other things equal, A’
offer. With a stock offer, the inevitable bad news about B’s value will f
s
Self-Test 21.4
A Warning
The cost of a mer
ver its value
as a separate company. If the target is a public company, you can measure its separate
v
Watch out,
though: If investors e
get to be acquired, its stock price may overstate the
company’
alue.
get company’
ve risen in
Another Warning
Some companies begin their merger analyses with a forecast of the tar
s future
ws. Any revenue increases or cost reductions attributable to the mer
included in the forecasts, which are then discounted back to the present and compared
5 DCF valuation of target including merger benefits
2 cash required for acquisition
This is a dangerous procedure. Ev
e
lar
aluing a business. The estimated net gain may come up positive not
because the merger makes sense, but simply because the analyst’
w forecasts
f
get’s potential as a stand-alone business.
A better procedure starts
get’
et value and
changes
w that would result from the merger.
Always ask why the two firms should be worth more together than apart. Remember, you add value only if you can generate additional economic benef
some competitive edge that other firms can’t match and that the target firm’s
managers can’t achieve on their own.
es sense to keep an eye on the value that investors place on the gains from
merging. If A’s stock price f
v
message that the mer
or that A is paying too much for these
21.5 The Market for Corporate Control
e the
boss, and with good reason. Try b
yee, the chief executive of
.
Chapter 21
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
603
The ownership and management of lar
ways separated.
s managers. The
board of directors, who act as their agents in choosing and monitoring the managers of
ve a direct say in v
v
This system of gov
agency costs. Agency costs occur when
managers or directors take actions adverse to shareholders’ interests.
e such actions may be ever-present, b
y forces
and constraints w
As we
pointed out in Chapter 1, managers’ paychecks in lar
ways
tors tak
y may face lawsuits if they don’t—and
therefore are reluctant to rubber-stamp obviously bad financial decisions.
What
What if the board of directors is derelict in moniut
These are all questions about the market for corporate control, the mechanisms by
e the
most of the firm’s resources. Y
agement for granted. If it is possible for the v
ing management or by reorganizing under new owners, there will be incentives for
someone to mak
There are four ways to change the management of a firm. These are (1) a
successful proxy contest in which a group of stockholders votes in a new group
of directors, who then pick a new management team; (2) the purchase of one
firm by another in a merger or acquisition; (3) a leveraged buyout of the firm by
a private group of investors; and (4) a divestiture, in which a firm either sells part
of its operations to another compan
irm.
We will revie
21.6 Method 1: Proxy Contests
Shareholders elect the board of directors to keep watch on management and replace
unsatisf
-cut. Ownership in lar
dispersed. Usually even the largest single shareholder holds only a small fraction of
v
bers stand for
personal relationship with its members. In man
v
proxy contest
Takeover attempt in
which outsiders
compete with
management for
shareholders’ votes. Also
called proxy fight.
When a group of investors believ
be replaced, they can launch a proxy contest. A proxy is the right to vote another
enough proxies to elect their o
in control, management can be replaced and company policy changed.
w board is
y can cost millions of dollars. Dissidents
who engage in them must use their own money, but management can draw on the
604
Seven
Special Topics
Giv
gister their discontent
simply by voting against the reelection of existing directors. This can send a powerful
signal.
y shareholders voted 43% of the shares against the reelection of
Michael Eisner, the company’
xt day.
In 2010 the SEC adopted a pr
e it easier for dissident shareholders to put their o
ote.
This rule would have greatly reduced the cost of a proxy contest. However, proxy
access w
This initiative promises to be an
ongoing controversy.
Institutional shareholders, such as large hedge funds, have become more aggressive
ve been able to gain concessions by
or example, in 2008 shareholder activist Carl Icahn indicated his intention to put himself forw
otes and failed to prevent the reelection of the
existing board. Nevertheless, the pressure from Icahn had an effect: Motorola agreed
to nominate two ne
of
y’
vision.5
21.7 Method 2: Takeovers
ing in the best interests of inv
and make a
ves that another company’s management is not actver the heads of that f
s management
fer and sell their shares, or it may fight the
fer or walk away from the deal.
If the tender offer is successful, the new owner can then install its own management
team.
eov
often fought.
Of course, these battles for corporate control don’t always result in the intended
improv
xcessive belief in one’s own ability, has led
man
T
,
Viv
turn Vivendi into “the world’
vider of entertainment, education and personalized services to customers, at any time, and across all distribution
vices.” Vivendi entered into a series of major acquisitions, including
wned Universal Studios. Messier’s ambitions
,
moi-même, maitre du monde
orld.” Unfortunately, however,
prof
y, and Messier was ousted.6
ve a near-monopoly on hostile takeovers. That is
no longer the case. T eover activity in Europe now exceeds that in the United States,
and in recent years some of the most bitterly contested takeovers have involved European companies. For example, Mittal’s $27 billion takeover of fellow steel-producer
Arcelor used
every defense in the book—including inviting a Russian company to become a leading
shareholder.
5
In Chapter 1 we saw that, in the same year
board of Y
6
all of Viv
Jean-Marie Messier and Vivendi Universal
The Man Who Tried to Buy the World:
Chapter 21
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
605
Mittal is now based in Europe, but it began operations in Indonesia. This illustrates
another change in the mer
et:
They now include Brazilian, Russian, Indian, and Chinese
companies. We have already encountered some of the recent acquisitions of U.S. and
British companies by the Indian conglomerate Tata Group. Other e
IBM’s personal computer business, which w
y
Lenovo, and Inco, the Canadian nickel producer, which is now owned by Brazil’s Vale.
ger w
. We will
laws,7
look at one recent contest that illustrates the tactics and weapons employed.
▲
EXAMPLE 21.2
poison pill
Measure taken by a
target firm to avoid
acquisition; for example,
the right of existing
shareholders to buy
additional shares at an
attractive price if a
bidder acquires a large
holding.
Oracle Bids for PeopleSoft
Hostile takeover bids are relatively uncommon in high-tech industries where an acrimonious takeov
y cause many of the target’s most valued st
o leave.
Investors were therefore startled in J
are giant Oracle Corp.
announced a $5.1 billion cash t
er for its rival PeopleSoft. T
er price of
$16 a share was only a very modest 6% above the recent price of P
ock.
PeopleSoft’s CEO angrily rejected the bid as dramatically undervaluing the business and accused Oracle of trying to disrupt PeopleSoft’s business and to thwart its
recently announced plan to merge with its smaller rival J.D. Edwards & Co. PeopleSoft immediately filed a suit claiming that Oracle’s management had engaged in
“acts of unfair trade practices” and had “disrupted PeopleSoft’s customer relationships.” In another suit J.D. Edwards claimed that Oracle had wrongly “int ered with
its proposed merger with PeopleSoft” and demanded $1.7 billion in compensatory
damages.
Oracle’s bid was the opening salv
as to last 18 months. Some
of the key dat
e set out in Table 21.5. P
veral
defenses at its disposal. First, it had in place a poison pill, which would allow it to
flood the market with additional shares if a predator acquired 20% of the stock.
Second, the company instituted a customer-assurance progr
ered customers money-back guarantees if an acquirer were to reduce customer support. At
one point in the takeov
ential liability under this program reached
nearly $1.6 billion. Third, elections to the P
d were staggered,
erent directors came up for r
erent years. This meant that it would take
two annual meetings to replace a majority of PeopleSoft’s board.
Oracle not only had to overcome PeopleSoft’s defenses but also had to clear
possible antitrust roadblocks. Connecticut’
orney general instituted an antitrust
action to block Oracle’s bid, in part to protect his state’s considerable investment in
P
are, and announced that he was seeking to assemble a coalition
of other states and customers as well. Then an investigation of the deal by the U.S.
Department of Justice ruled that the deal was anticompetitive. Normally such an
objection is enough to kill a deal, but Oracle was persistent and successfully
appealed the ruling in a federal court.
While these battles were being fought out, Oracle re
er four times. It
er first to $19.50 and then to $26 a share. Then,
ort to put pressure on P
eholders, Oracle reduced
er to $21 a share, citing a
drop of 28% in the price of PeopleSoft’s shares. Six months later it r
er
again to $24 a share, warning investors that it would walk awa
er was not
accepted by P
s board or a majority of the P
eholders.
cent of P
s shareholders indicated that they wished to
er, but before Oracle could gain control of P
it still
7
eovers is the Williams Act of 1968.
606
Part Seven Special Topics
TABLE 21.5 Some key dates
in the Oracle/PeopleSoft
takeover battle
needed the company to get rid of the poison pill and customer-assurance scheme.
That meant putting pressure on PeopleSoft’s management, which had continued
to reject every approach. Oracle tried two tactics. First, it initiated a proxy fight to
change the composition of P
s board. Second, it filed a suit in a Delaware
court alleging that PeopleSoft’s management had breached its fiduciar
y
trying to thwart Oracle’
er and not giving it “due consideration.” The lawsuit
asked the court to require that PeopleSoft dismantle its takeover defenses, including the poison-pill plan and the customer-assurance program.
P
s CEO had at one point said that he “could imagine no price nor
combination of price and other conditions to r
er.” But
with 61% of PeopleSoft’s shareholders wishing to take up Oracle’s lat
er, it was
becoming less easy for the company to keep saying no, and many observers were
starting to question whether P
s management was acting in the shareholders’ interest. If management showed itself deaf to shareholders’ interests, the
court could well rule in favor of Oracle or disgruntled shareholders might vote to
change the composition of the PeopleSoft board. P
s directors therefore
decided to be less intransigent and testified at the Delaware trial that they would
consider negotiating with Oracle if it were t
er $26.50 or $27 a share. This was
the breakthrough that Oracle was looking for
er immediately to
$26.50 a share, P
ed its defenses, and within a month 97% of PeopleSoft’s shareholders had agreed t
er 18 months of punch and counteror P
as over.
shark repellent
Amendment to a
company charter made
to forestall takeover
attempts.
xample illustrates some of the stratagems of
merger w are. Firms lik
en over usually
prepare their defenses in advance. Often they will persuade shareholders to agree to
shark-repellent
. For e
y merger must be approved by a
of 80% of
e the
y unappetizing. For example, the poison pill may give e
the right to buy the company’
The bidder is not entitled to the discount. Thus the bidder
Chapter 21
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
607
resembles Tantalus—as soon as it has acquired 15% of the shares, control is lifted
away from its reach.
eover
defenses. Oracle’s offensive still gained ground, but with great expense and at a v
slow pace. But eventually the pressure on PeopleSoft’s management became overas acting in the shareholders’ interests,
it risked having the poison pill remov
The second reason that the company caved in was the increasing pressure from its shareholders, including some large
institutions, who wished to accept Oracle’s offer.
21.8 Method 3: Leveraged Buyouts
leveraged buyout (LBO)
Acquisition of the firm by
a private group using
substantial borrowed
funds.
management buyout
(MBO)
Acquisition of the firm by
its own management in
a leveraged buyout.
▲
EXAMPLE 21.3
Leveraged buyouts, or LBOs,
o ways. First, a
lar
w inv
on the open market. The remaining equity in the LBO is privately held by a small
group of (usually institutional) investors and is known as
. When this
group is led by the company’s management, the acquisition is called a management
buyout (MBO). Many LBOs are in fact MBOs.
anted
di
v
main lines of business often lacked top management’s interest and commitment, and
di
ureaucracy. Many such divisions
wered when spun off as MBOs. Their managers, pushed by the need to generate
e in the business,
found ways to cut costs and compete more effectively.
vate-equity activity shifted to buyouts of entire businesses,
including large, mature public corporations. The largest, most dramatic, and bestdocumented LBO of them all was the $25 billion takeover of RJR Nabisco in 1988 by
Kohlber
versies of LBOs are
writ large in this case.
RJR Nabisco8
On October 28, 1988, the board of directors of RJR Nabisco revealed that Ross
Johnson, the company’s chief executiv
icer, had formed a group of investors
prepared to buy all the firm’s stock for $75 per share in cash and take the company
private. Johnson’s group was backed up and advised by Shearson Lehman Hutton,
the investment bank subsidiary of American Express.
RJR’s share price immediately moved to about $75, handing shareholders a 36%
gain over the previous day’s price of $56. At the same time RJR’s bonds fell, since it
was clear that existing bondholders would soon have a lot more company.
Johnson’
er lifted RJR onto the auction block. Once the company was in play,
its board of directors was obliged t
ers, which were not long
coming. Four days later, a group of investors led by LBO specialists Kohlberg Kravis
Roberts bid $90 per share, $79 in cash plus preferred stock valued at $11.
The bidding finally closed on November 30, some 32 da
er
was revealed. In the end it was Johnson’s gr
ered $109 per
share, er adding $1 per share (roughly $230 million) at the last hour. The KKR bid
8
The Fall of RJR Nabisco (New Y
w
Barbarians at the Gate:
vie with the same title.
608
Seven
Special Topics
was $81 in cash, convertible subordinated debentures valued at about $10, and
preferred shares valued at about $18. Johnson’s group bid $112 in cash and
securities.
But the RJR board chose KKR. True, Johnson’s gr
ered $3 per share
more, but its security valuations were viewed as “softer” and perhaps overstated.
Also, KKR’s planned asset sales were less drastic; perhaps their plans for managing
the business inspired more confidence. Finally, the Johnson group’s proposal contained a management compensation package that seemed e emely generous
and had generated an avalanche of bad press.
But where did the merger benefits come from?
ering $109
per share, about $25 billion in all, for a company that only 33 days previously had
been selling for $56 per share?
KKR and other bidders were betting on two things. First, they expected to generate billions of additional dollars from interest tax shields, reduced capital expenditures, and sales of assets not strictly necessary to RJR’s core businesses. Asset sales
alone were projected to generate $5 billion. Second, they expected to make those
core businesses significantly more profitable, mainly b
xpenses
and bureaucracy. Apparently there was plenty to cut, including the RJR “Air Force,”
which at one point operated 10 corporate jets.
In the year after KKR took over, new management was installed. This group sold
assets and cut back operating expenses and capital spending. There were also
lay
. As expected, high interest charges meant a net loss of $976 million for 1989,
but pretax operating income actually increased, despite extensive asset sales,
including the sale of RJR’s European food operations.
While management w
, prices in the junk bond
market were rapidly declining, implying much higher future interest charges for RJR
and stricter terms on any refinancing. In mid-1990 KKR made an additional equity
investment, and later that year the compan
er of cash and new
shares in exchange for $753 million of junk bonds. By 1993 the burden of debt had
been reduced from $26 billion to $14 billion. For RJR, the world’s largest LBO, it
seemed that high debt was a temporary, not permanent, virtue.
Barbarians at the Gate?
The buyout of RJR crystallized vie
et, and the takeover business. For many it exemplified all that w
e up established companies, leaving
urdens, basically in order to get rich quick.
There was plenty of confusion, stupidity, and greed in the LBO business. Not all the
people involved were nice. On the other hand, LBOs generated enormous increases in
market v
or example, the biggest winners in the RJR Nabisco LBO were the company’
W
ve come from before
veral possibilities.
The Junk Bond Markets
eovers may have been
v
ets. With hindsight it
seems that investors in junk bonds underestimated the risks of default. Default rates
climbed painfully between 1989 and 1991, yields rose dramatically, and new issues
Leverage and Taxes As we e
wing money saves
taxes. But taxes were not the main driving force behind LBOs. The value of interest
tax shields was just not big enough to explain the observed g
et value.
Chapter 21
609
Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control
Of course, if interest tax shields were the main motive for LBOs’ high debt, then
LBO managers would not be so concerned to pay off debt. We saw that this was one of
s ne
Other Stakeholders
just someone else’s loss and that no value is generated overall. Therefore, we should
look at the total gain to all inv
Bondholders are the obvious losers. The debt they thought was well-secured may
We noted ho
fer was announced.
But again, the v
ge
enough to explain stockholder g
Leverage and Incentives Managers and employees of LBOs work harder
. They have to generate cash to service the extra debt. Moreover,
managers’ personal fortunes are riding on the LBO’s success. They become owners
rather than organization men or women.
ves, but there is some evidence of
improv
uyouts
verage increases in operating income of 24% over the
follo
ut not in employved incentives rather
”9
Free Cash Flow
eovers is basically that mature
firms with a surplus of cash will tend to waste it.
theory
ve-NPV inv
ties should give the cash back to investors through higher dividends or share repurchases. But we see f
questionable capital inv
w theory predicts that mature, “cash cow” companies will be the
most lik
gets of LBOs. We can find many e
, including RJR Nabisco. The theory says that the gains in market value generated by LBOs
are just the present v
ws that would otherwise have been
frittered away.10
W
have mentioned sev
v
w theory as the sole explanation for LBOs. We
v
y mistakes and a good many LBOs hav
icial. On the
y,
, Tropicana, Chicago
e issue with those who
Tribune, Wick
wever
portray LBOs simply as W
corporate America. In many cases LBOs hav
The b
ger boom of the 1980s
even v
val management team.
as the ability of the bidder to f
eover
9
Value,” J
inancial
Economics 24 (October 1989), pp. 217–254.
10
w theory’
”
d Business Review 67 (September–October 1989), pp. 61–74, and “The Agency Costs of
w
T eovers,” American Economic Re
76 (May 1986), pp. 323–329.
610
Seven
Special Topics
ger environment had changed. Many of the obvious targets had disappeared and the battle for RJR
. Institutions were reluctant to
increase their holdings of junk bonds. Moreover, the market for these bonds had
depended to a remarkable extent on one indi
en, of the investment
x
en and his employer were in
en was indicted by a grand jury on 98 counts and was subsequently sentenced to jail. Drex
y, but by that time the junk bond market was
und and the finance for highly leveraged buyouts had largely dried up.11 Finally,
in reaction to the perceived excesses of the merger boom, the state le
courts be
eovers.
Eventually, LBO activity began to recover, encouraged by low interest rates and
(until August 2007) easy access to debt f
gets, hav
vate ownership. In addition, for public companies the costs
of meeting the requirements of the Sarbanes-Oxley
gulations
hav
vate (rather than public) ownership.
21.9 Method 4: Divestitures,
Spin-Offs, and Carve-Outs
publicity
2007, F
vestiture of assets or entire businesses—can be just as
or example, in
, for $924
a business
the newly independent company. For example, in 2009 Time W
investment in AOL. Time W
v
w company
A
wn Time W
.
xcept that shares in the new company are not
given to existing stockholders b
y to establish a market in the
f the remainder of the shares.
w the computer company, Palm, w
ed and then spun.
The most frequent motive for spin-offs is improved ef
y. Companies sometimes refer to a b
” By spinning of
y can concentrate on its main activity. If each business must
stand on its o
f from one in order
vestments in the other. Moreover, if the tw
usiness are independent, it is easy to see the value of each and to reward managers
accordingly.
21.10 The Benefits and Costs of Mergers
Merger activity comes in waves and is concentrated in a relatively small number of
industries. This urge to merge frequently seems to be prompted by deregulation and by
Take the merger wave of the 1990s,
11
F
en in the dev
edator’s
Ball: The Junk Bond Raiders and the Man Who Staked Them (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1988).
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
How Palm Was Carved and Spun
for example. Dere
of mergers in both industries that has continued to the present. Elsewhere, the decline
gers between defense companies
the prospective adv
ers between such giants as AOL and Time W
ution led to merg.
on balance. In general, sharee a healthy gain. For example, one study found that follo
get company jumped by
16% on average.12 On the other hand, it appears that investors e
companies to just about break ev
The value
uyer plus seller—increased by 1.8%. Of course, these are averxample, have sometimes obtained much higher returns.
When Hewlett-Packard won its takeover battle to buy data-storage company 3Par, it
s stock.
Since buyers roughly break ev
there are positive ov
gers. But not everybody is convinced. Some
believe that investors analyzing mer
xpense of long-term prospects.
Since we can’
e how companies would have fared in the absence of a merger,
. However, several studies of merger
activity suggest that mergers do seem to improve real productivity. For example,
Healy, Palepu, and Ruback examined 50 large mergers and found an average increase
13
The
gue that this gain
get f
12
See G.
w Evidence and Perspectives on Mergers,” Journal of
Economic Perspectives
13
See P
, K. P
v
gers?” Journal of
Financial Economics 31 (April 1992), pp. 135–175. The study e
ged
v
verages.
611
612
Seven
Special Topics
came from generating a higher level of sales from the same assets. There was no
e
vestments; expenditures on capital equipment and research and development tracked the industry average.
y toward mergers, you do not want to look
or instance, we
hav
was at the e
venue Service (through the
ged interest tax shield). The acquirer’s shareholders may also gain at the expense
of the target firm’s employees, who in some cases are laid of
e pay
cuts after takeovers.
fect of acquisition is felt by the managers of companies that are not taken over. For example, one effect of LBOs was that the managers of
ev
eov
, we don’t
w whether on balance the threat of merger makes for more active days or more
sleepless nights.
eover may be a spur to inef
ut it is also costly.
The companies need to pay for the services provided by the investment bankers, lawyers, and accountants. In addition, mer
ge amounts of management
time and ef
When a compan
eover, it can be dif
ve as
s existing business.
Ev
xceed these costs, one wonders whether the
v
ay. For example, are leveraged b
e managers work harder? Perhaps the problem lies in
the way that man
w
y of
the gains from takeov
SUMMARY
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISE
finance.yahoo.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
MINICASE
CHAPTER
22
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T S E V E N
Special Topics
Coca-Cola does business around the world.
T
620
Part Seven Special Topics
22.1 Foreign Exchange Markets
An American compan
xchange
its dollars for euros in order to pay for its purchases. Another company e
France will probably receive euros, which it then sells in exchange for dollars. Both
e use of the foreign exchange mark
The foreign exchange mark
etplace. All business is conducted
via computer terminals and telephone.
ge commercial
ants to b
commercial bank.
T
ver in the foreign e
y changes hands each day.
v
v
wY
ver per day
olume of the New Y
where about $70 billion of stock typically changes hands on any given day.
Spot Exchange Rates
uy two
loaves for a dollar, or he may say that one loaf costs 50 cents. If you ask a foreign
e
exchange rate
Amount of one currency
needed to purchase
one unit of another.
pesos that you can b
wn as an indirect quote of the exchange rate.
uy 1 peso) is known as a direct
quote. Of course, both quotes pro
uy 100 pesos
, then you can easily calculate that the cost of buying 1 peso is 1/100 5 $.01.
v
y
xactly 100 pesos per U.S. dollar. W
veral
examples below.)
Table 22.1 shows the exchange rate for several actual countries on September
17, 2010. The second column of the table shows the name of the currency and its
common abbreviation. For example, the Mexican peso is usually abbreviated as
expressed as indirect quotes. Thus the third column of Table 22.1 shows that
TABLE 22.1 Exchange rates
in September 2010
* Direct quotes (number of U.S. dollars per unit of foreign currency). Other quotes are indirect (units of foreign
currency per U.S. dollar).
Source: Financial Times, September 17, 2010, available at
Chapter 22
621
International Financial Management
you could buy 12.8344 Mexican pesos for 1 dollar. This is sometimes written as
MXN12.8344 5 USD1.
To complicate matters, there are two currencies whose prices are generally
expressed as direct quotes. These are the euro and the British pound. For example, you
can see that it cost $1.3044 to buy 1 euro. We therefore write the euro exchange rate as
USD1.3044 5 EUR1.
Self-Test 22.1
▲
EXAMPLE 22.1
A Yen for Trade
How many yen will it cost a Japanese importer to purchase $10,000 worth of
oranges from a California farmer? How many dollars will that farmer need in order
to buy and import a Japanese tractor priced in Japan at 4.5 million yen?
The exchange rate is JPY85.6600 5 USD1. The $10,000 of oranges will require the
Japanese importer to come up with 10,000 3 85.66 5 856,600 yen. The tractor will
require the American importer to come up with 4,500,000/85.66 5 $52,533.
The e
spot rate of exchange
Exchange rate for an
immediate transaction.
Table 22.1
y for
wn as spot rates of exchange. For example, the
spot rate of e
5
ords, it
costs 1.71550 Brazilian reals to buy 1 dollar for immediate deliv .
Exchange rates are generally quoted against the dollar. For example, Table 22.1
sho
uy either 85.66 Japanese yen or 1,160 Korean won. This implies
that 85.66 yen are equivalent to 1,160 won and, therefore, that 1 yen is equivalent to
1,160/85.66 5 13.54 won. An exchange rate between tw
wn as a cross-rate. In our example, the cross-rate of exchange
between the Japanese yen and the South Korean w
W13.54 5 JPY1.
Cross-rates between any tw
ed down by the exchange rate for
y versus the U.S. dollar. Otherwise, inv
e an easy
or example, suppose that a (really stupid) bank quotes a rate of
W10 5 JPY1. Here’s what you do: You take $1 and exchange it for 1,160 Korean
won, which you then use to buy 1,160/10 5 116 Japanese yen.
exchanged back to U.S. dollars for 116/85.66 5 $1.354. You have just taken advantage
1
Of course, in real life you
and other investors w
time.
ould be forced to revise its quote in short order.
v
.
Self-Test 22.2
.
so the e
y increases in v
1
In practice foreign e
y
a major cost for small transactions by indi
The spread is very small on lar
uy and
ut it is
622
Part Seven Special Topics
y to b
y to b
y is said to appreciate.
depreciate.
Self-Test 22.3
v
ed e
y and seek
ed rates seldom last forever. If ev
y, ev
w the currency to depreciate. When this happens, exchange rates can change dramatically. In
December 2001, when Argentina gav
ed exchange rate versus the
U.S. dollar, the value of the Argentinian peso fell by over 70% in a few months.
Forward Exchange Rates
Fluctuations in exchange rates can get companies into hot water. For example, suppose
you have agreed to b
will be deliv
(R
uys 100 pesos (RUP100 5 USD1). So, if the exchange
forward exchange rate
Exchange rate for a
future transaction.
appreciates? For example, suppose that when you come to buy the pesos at the end of
the year
uys only 80 pesos (RUP80 5 USD1). Then the dollar cost of
5 $1.25 million).
You can avoid this exchange rate risk and fix your dollar cost by b
d,
now to buy pesos at a prespecified price on a future date. This
xchange
d contract. Suppose you enter into a
ard contract with a bank to buy 100 million pesos 12 months from no
of RUP105 5 USD1. You don’t pay an
w; you simply fix today the price that
you will pay in the future.
2
you hand over in exchange $.952 million (100 /105 5
The spot e
y today. The
exchange rates in Table 22.1
xchange rates.
y for
delivery at a future date is called the forward exchange rate. The forw
xchange
rate is not usually the same as the spot rate. In our example 1 dollar bought 100 Ruritanian pesos in the spot market b
et. In this case, the
peso is said to trade at a forw
discount relativ
. It’s a discount because
pesos are cheaper—more pesos per dollar—if purchased forward rather than spot. If
fewer pesos in the forward market, the peso would trade at a forw
premium relativ
.
ard purchase or sale is a made-to-order transaction between you and the bank.
It can be for an
y, any amount, and any deliv
. You could buy, say, 99,999
V
There is also an organized mark
y for
future deliv
wn as the currency
es
et. Futures contracts are highly stanye
y
v
2
xchange rate is R
5 USD1, then 1 peso will cost you 1/105 5
3 $.00952 5 $.952 million.
Chapter 22
International Financial Management
623
easy on futures exchanges—you don’t have to negotiate a one-off contract with a bank.
Almost ev
futures. We will describe futures markets in greater detail in Chapter 24.
Self-Test 22.4
22.2 Some Basic Relationships
exchange rates and must be aw
exchange rates. She must also recognize that tw
rates. To dev
needs to understand how e
have a lower interest rate than another.
To k
b
consider:
ve different interest
y, the financial manager
y doing
inancial manager needs to
1.
2.
expected exchange rate at some future date?
3. How do dif
s interest rate and the exchange rate?
4. What e
the spot rate?
These are complex issues, but as a f
ward e
Figure 22.1.
FIGURE 22.1
Some simple
theories linking spot and
f
ard exchange rates,
interest rates, and inflation
rates
fect each
ard exchange rate for the peso and
ed as shown in
624
Part Seven Special Topics
Exchange Rates and Inflation
(the two boxes on the right of Figure 22.1). The idea here is simple: If one country suf, then the v
y
will decline.
But let’s slow down and consider why
linked. Suppose you notice that gold can be bought in New Y
law of one price
Theory that prices of
goods in all countries
should be equal when
translated to a common
currency.
transport of gold, you could be onto a good thing. You b
e it
on the first plane to Ruritania, where you sell it for 130,000 pesos.
e
UP100 5 USD1. So you can e
130,000 pesos for 130,000/100 5 $1,300. You hav
ounce. Of course, you hav
ut there should
ver for you.
Y
its rarely exist,
and when they do exist, they don’t last long.
price of gold in Ruritania and the price in New York, the price will be forced down in
wY
This ensures that
the dollar price of gold is the same in the two countries.
Our conclusion that gold is w
y is an example of
the law of one price. Just as the price of goods in W
Target, so the prices of goods in Ruritania when conv
Dollar price of goods in U.S. 5
Number of pesos per dollar
, but the same forces push the
. Those goods that can
wn the price of
the domestic product. Those goods that can be produced more cheaply at home will be
e
w
believes that the law of one price holds exactly. Look at Table 22.2, which shows the
v
You can see that
or example, in Norway Big Macs cost
almost twice as much as in the United States, but in China the
U.S. price.3
TABLE 22.2
Mac hambur
countries
Price of Big
erent
“When the Chips Are Down: The Latest Big Mac Index Suggests the Euro Is Still Overvalued,” The Economist, July
22, 2010.
3
ay
e with like.
urgers
Chapter 22
625
International Financial Management
This suggests a possible way to make a quick buck. Why don’t you buy a
hamburger
e it for resale in Norway
in dollars is $7.20? The answer, of course, is that the gain would not cover the costs.
The law of one price works very well for commodities like gold, where transportation
orks f
purchasing power
parity (PPP)
Theory that the cost of
erent
countries is equal and
that exchange rates
adjust t
lation
erentials across
countries.
W
er version of the la
w that captures the
main idea but allows for exceptions.
er version is purchasing power parity,
or PPP. PPP states that although some goods, such as Big Macs and haircuts, may cost
ferent countries, the overall cost of li
.
PPP implies that the relative costs of living in two countries will not be affected by
will be offset by changes in exchange rates.
If purchasing po
rates is also your best forecast of the change in the spot rate of exchange. For example,
suppose you need a forecast of the exchange rate for the Ruritanian peso. Purchasing
po
xchange rate for the peso is RUP100 5 USD1. If the cost of living is
undle of
6% in Ruritania and 1% in the United States.
buy the same quantity of goods as $1.01, and $1 will have the same purchasing power
as RUP100 3 (1.06/1.01) 5 R
expected exchange rate at the end of the year is RUP105 5
e
Look back at the tw
es in Figure 22.1. We can no
4
box
11e
5
11
1.06
5 1.05
1.01
equals
Expected change in spot exchange rates
Expected peso exchange rate 105
5
5 1.05
xchange rate
100
Now we have some helpful advice for the U.S. company doing business in Ruritaxchange rate for Ruritanian pesos, he or she can use the difference in e
versus in the United States.
4
Aw
indirect e
v
T
v
626
Seven
Special Topics
Real and Nominal Exchange Rates
Financial managers distinguish nominal exchange rates from real exchange rates.
Nominal exchange rates tell you how many euros or yen or pounds you can buy for
your dollar. Real exchange rates measure the quantity of goods you can b
or e
alue of the
Ruritanian peso declines, you will be able to purchase more pesos for your dollar, but
if Ruritania e
uy you only the same
nominal exchange rate has declined b
real
exchange rate is unchanged. Purchasing po
y change
in the nominal exchange rate will be offset by a change in the relativ
o countries, leaving the real exchange rate unaffected.
Figure 22.2
For e
ws that in 2010 one pound (£1) bought only 33% of the
. But this decline in the nominal value of the pound
w
The plot shows that just
ov
xchange rate was little changed.
.
Of course, purchasing po
term real e
. For example, the real
value of the pound fell by more than one-quarter between the end of 2007 and the
end of 2008. U.S. tourists to Britain found that their dollar bought more than it had
in earlier years. Such changes in real exchange rates can be a major headache for
an
called on to make a long-term forecast of an exchange rate, you probably can’t do
much better than to assume that changes in the nominal v
y will
offset the dif
That is the message of purchasing po
ity theory.
Self-Test 22.5
Inflation and Interest Rates
Ruritania.
W
xplain such a difference?
they don’
est rate of 3%, you will hav
ix
ut
y will buy. If you invest $100 for a year at an interould be needed to compen-
In our example, the nominal rate of interest is higher in Ruritania than in the United
States, b
, then the real rates of interest may be much
closer than the nominal rates. For example, suppose that the e
1% in the United States and 6% in Ruritania. Then
Chapter 22
International Financial Management
FIGURE 22.2
Nominal versus real exchange rates in (a) the United Kingdom, (b) France, and (c) Italy.
December 1899 5 1. (Values are shown on log scale.)
Source: E. Dimson, P. R. Marsh, and M. Staunton, Triumph of the Optimists: 101 Years of Global Investment Returns (Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 2002) Updates courtesy of Triumph's authors.
627
628
Part Seven Special Topics
Real U.S. interest rate 5
5
1 1 nominal interest rate
21
11
1.03
2 1 5 .0198, or 1.98%
1.01
and
11
21
11
1.081
5
2 1 5 .0198, or 1.98%
1.06
The nominal interest rates in the tw
ferent, but the real
interest rates are the same.
Now you can see why we drew the top two boxes in Figure 22.1:
5
ence in interest rates
1 1 Ruritanian
interest rate
Expected differ
11e
5
1 1 U.S.
interest rate
1.081
1.03
5 1.05
equals
rate
1 1 U.S.
rate
5
1.06
5 1.05
1.01
If e
international Fisher effect
Theory that real interest
rates in all countries
should be equal, with
erences in nominal
rates reflecting
erences in expected
inflation.
v
ferences in the nomferences in e
This conclusion is
often called the
Fisher effect,
. As long
w unimpeded across national borders, capital mark
requires that real
y two countries. Just as water always
ws downhill, so capital alw
wing only when expected returns are the same.5 But it is the real returns that concern
investors, not the nominal returns. Tw
ve different nominal interest
rates but the same expected real interest rate.
How similar are real interest rates around the world? It is hard to say, because we
e expected
wever, in Figure 22.3 we have plotted
the av
act
You can see that the countries with the highest interest rates generally had
Self-Test 22.6
5
Here we assume aw
y.
, pound, euro, Swiss franc, and yen.
not acceptable for some dev
We hav
vestors w
ault or e
gov
y may demand a higher real interest rate on peso loans.
Chapter 22
629
International Financial Management
FIGURE 22.3
Countries
with the highest interest rates
generally have the highest
inflation. In this diagram
each of the 65 points
represents the experience of
er
.
The Forward Exchange Rate and
the Expected Spot Rate
expectations theory of
exchange rates
Theory that expected
spot exchange rate
equals the f
ard rate.
If you buy Ruritanian pesos forw
you buy them spot. So the peso is selling at a forw
w let us think how
this discount may be related to expected changes in spot rates of exchange.
The spot rate for the peso is RUP100 5
ard rate is
RUP105 5 USD1. Would you sell pesos forw
alue?
Probably not. You would be tempted to w
price (more pesos) in the spot market. If other traders felt the same way, nobody would
ould want to buy, so the number of pesos that you
et would f
expected the peso to f
alue, they might be reluctant to buy
in order to attract buyers, the number of pesos that you could b
the forw
et would need to rise.6 Trading would stabilize when the forw
adjusts to equal the expected future spot rate.
This is the reasoning behind the expectations theory of exchange rates, which
xchange rate. Put another
way, we can say that the percentage dif
s
spot rate is equal to the expected percentage change in the spot rate:
g of our quadrilateral in Figure 22.1.
Difference between forward and
spot exchange rates
Forward peso
exchange rate
105
5
5 1.05
rate
100
equals
Expected change in spot
exchange rate
Expected peso
exchange rate
105
5
5 1.05
100
rate
6
forw
, you might
ven if you e
, if a forw
ard even if you expected to receive less as a result.
uy
might be
630
Seven
Special Topics
The e
ve the previous
forw
all below
that on average
This prediction is roughly
8
e a long enough average,7 b
Because of the exceptions and anomalies, the expectations hypothesis is not much
help to foreign e
usiness. F
exchange exposure, the e
fers some reassurance. A company that
always covers its foreign exchange commitments by b
y in the
forw
et does not have to pay a premium to avoid e
On average, the forw
y will equal the eventual
spot exchange rate, no better but no worse.
Interest Rates and Exchange Rates
Now let’s mov
av
xchange rates, known as covered
interest r
, almost always works, ev
Y
vestor with $1 million to invest for 1 year.
vest your money in
Ruritania or in the United States?
The answer seems obvious: Isn’
v
v
When the loan is repaid at the end of the year, you need to
convert your pesos back into U.S. dollars. Of course, you don’t know what the
e
,b
alue of your
pesos by selling them forw
ard rate of exchange is suf
w, you
may do just as well keeping your money in the United States.
Let’s check which loan is the better deal:
• U.S. dollar loan. The rate of interest on a U.S. dollar loan is 3%. Therefore, at the
3 1.03 5 $1.03 million.
• Ruritanian peso loan.
UP100 5 USD1.
Therefore, you can conv
UP100 million. The interest
ve R
3 1.081 5 R
You don’
w what the e
, but that doesn’t matter. You can nail down the rate at which you
conv
RUP105 5 USD1.
will get RUP108.1/105 5 $1.03 million.
Thus the two investments offer exactly the same rate of return. They have to,
because the
“covered” foreign rate, you would have a money machine: You could borrow in the
market with the lower rate and lend in the market with the higher rate.
7
times the
v
ve up return in order to buy
sell forw
y.
ard rate overstates the likely
understates the likely spot rate. The over- and
v
8
ve studied exchange rates hav
ov
fall. There is even e
rise. F
Exchange,” J
xaggerate the lik
v
ely to f
Thaler, “Anomalies: Foreign
olitical Economy 4 (1990), pp. 179–192.
Chapter 22
631
International Financial Management
We now hav
Figure 22.1:
ence in interest rates
11
1.081
interest rate
5
5 1.05
1.03
1 1 U.S.
interest rate
interest rate parity
Theory that f
ard
premium equals interest
rat
erential.
called interest rate parity.
equals
Difference between forward
and spot exchange rates
F
ard peso
exchange rate 105
5
5 1.05
100
rate
wn in
tend to
ways holds with great precision.
whenev
You can’t
w in a currency with a low nominal rate of interest. If
you hedge or “cover” your exchange rate e
y.9 If you don’t cover, exchange
rate mov
antage of a low interest rate.
Interest rate parity means that covered interest rates are the same in all major
currencies. A f
empts to borrow in currencies with low
interest rates can profit only by taking a bet on future exchange rates.
Self-Test 22.7
22.3 Hedging Exchange Rate Risk
Transaction Risk
As exchange
alue of their revenues or e
ful to distinguish two types of exchange rate risk: transaction risk and economic risk.
T
v
wn amount of
y. For example, our importer of machinery w
RUP100 million at the end of 12 months. If the value of the peso appreciates rapidly
ov
xpected.
T
or ev
committed to pay, she can buy 1 peso forward. If she buys R
ard,
v
appreciation of the peso.
Of course, it is possible that the peso will depreciate
v
,10 in
ould regret that she did not wait to buy the peso more cheaply
9
A cov
y contract. In our e
with 8.1% interest to R
You therefore would sell R
dollar value of your year-end proceeds.
10
By this we mean that the peso f
y and hedge the exchange
UP100 million, which grows
632
Seven
Special Topics
et. Unfortunately, you cannot have your cak
dollar cost of the machinery
Is there any other w
xchange rate loss? Think
again how cov
orks. The f
w
vert them into pesos today, put the proceeds in a Ruritanian bank deposit,
and withdra
wing dollars, b
et, and leaving them on
deposit is e
uying pesos forw
What is the cost of protection against currency risk? You sometimes hear managers say that it is equal to the difference between the forward rate and today’s spot
rate. This is wrong. If our importer did not hedge, she would pay the spot price for
pesos when the payment is due at the end of the year. Therefore, the cost of hedging
is the difference between the forward rate and the expected spot rate when payment
is due.
Should companies hedge, or should the
tions? We generally vote for hedging. First, it makes life simpler for the f
allows it to concentrate on its own business. Second, it does not cost much. (In fact, the
cost is zero if the forw
xpected spot rate, as our simple theories
imply.) Third, the foreign exchange mark
icient, at least for the
ely case
market.
Economic Risk
Ev
wes nor is owed foreign currency, it still may be affected by
, for example, the competitive position of foreign auto
producers such as Volkswagen and Toyota when the v
matically in 2006 and 2007. These f
aced a difficult choice between maintaining
y,
ve against U.S. producers such
as Ford and GM. Economic exposure to the exchange rate arises because exchange
fect competitive positions.
y to undertake operational hedging
production closely with sales. For example, 38% of Ford’s sales are outside North
America, b
y risks
v
Japanese auto manufacturers have less operational hedging. For example, Toyota
produces 63% of its output in Japan b
Toyota than for Ford. On the other hand,
the Japanese auto companies operate in a wider range of mark
They
have therefore diversified aw
y risks.
y risk. Think again of Toyota. It is
a net e
America and is therefore exposed to a decline in the
v
. So, in addition to its operational hedging, Toyota also mitigates
exchange rate risk by using
es. For e
ws large amounts in
Toyota’s prof
Self-Test 22.8
Chapter 22
International Financial Management
633
22.4 International Capital Budgeting
Net Present Values for Foreign Investments
ve risen to the point
that it is considering establishing a small manufacturing and sales operation overseas
in Ruritania. Ecsy-Cola’s decision to invest overseas should be based on the same
vest in the United States. The company needs to forecast the
ws at the opportunity
cost of capital, and accept those projects with a positive NPV.
Suppose Ecsy-Cola’s Ruritanian facility is expected to generate the following cash
ws in Ruritanian pesos:
The interest rate in the United States is 3%. Ecsy’
the company requires an additional e
1 10 5 13%.
Notice that Ecsy’s opportunity cost of capital is stated in terms of the return on a
vestment b
ven in pesos. A project that
offers a 13% e
all f
fering the required
alue of the peso is expected to decline. Conversely, a project
that offers an expected return of less than 13% in pesos may be w
is likely to appreciate.
You cannot compare the project’s return measured in one currency with the
return that you require from investing in another currency. If the oppor
of capital is measured as a dollar-denominated return, cash flows should also
be forecast in dollars.
T
Where does this come from? Forw
ard exchange rate.
ut they can be estimated using interest rate par-
ity. For e
xchange rate is RUP100 5 USD1 and that the interest rate is 3% in
the United States and 8.1% in Ruritania. Thus, the manager sees right away that the
peso is likely to sell at a forw
. For e
forw
1 1 peso interest rate
11
1.081
5 RUP100/USD1 3
5 RUP104.95/USD1
1.03
5 Spot rate in year 0 3
The implied forw
similarly, as follows:11
11
W
634
Seven
Special Topics
ard exchange rates to convert the peso
ws into dollars:
No
capital:
.9528
1.1348
1.2976
1.4424
1.5707
1
1
1
1
2
3
4
1.13
1.13
1.13
1.13
1.135
5 $.568 million, or $568,000
NPV 5 23.8 1
ws at 13%, not at the U.S. risk-free interest
rate of 3%.
ws are risky, so a risk-adjusted interest rate is appropriate. The
positive NPV tells the manager that the project is w
shareholder wealth by $568,000.
not hav
xchange
ws into dollar equiv
ard
e
y
forecast is needed, because the company can hedge its foreign exchange exposure.
If it does hedge, for example, by selling pesos forw
ws will
xchange rates implied by the interest rate
differential. In other w
ws
that we have just calculated. The decision to accept or reject the project therefore is
w about the future e
What if the management actually expects the peso to appreciate rather than depreciate? Should it use its own forecasts of the future exchange rate instead of the forw
e
ve, it
must be able to stand on its own, based on hedged
ws. It would be foolish for
xchange rate appreciation. If
ould be better
y directly rather than use a negative-NPV project to gain
e
y. (Of course, before it speculates, management ought to think
v
ves its e
ket’s. After all, Ecsy’s comparative advantage is presumably in manuf
xchange rate speculation.)
Self-Test 22.9
Chapter 22
635
International Financial Management
Political Risk
So far we have focused on the management of e
w
political risk. They w
v
ut managers also
vestment is made. Of course,
verseas investments. Businesses in ev
are exposed to the risk of unanticipated actions by gov
the w
Consultancy services of
w up
12
For example, Table 22.3 is an e
cal risk rankings pro
verall, while
Somalia languishes at the bottom.
Some managers dismiss political risk as an act of God, lik
quak
usiness to
reduce political risk. Foreign gov
ely to e
usiness if it cannot operate without the support of its parent. For example, the foreign
American computer softw
ould have
relatively little value if they were cut off from the know-how of their parents. Such
ely to be expropriated than, say, a mining operation that
enture.
W
er mine into a pharmaceutical
company, but you may be able to plan your overseas manuf
improv
vernments. For example, Ford has
integrated its overseas operations so that the manufacture of components, subassemblies, and complete automobiles is spread across plants in a number of countries. None
of these plants would have much value on its own, and Ford can switch production
TABLE 22.3
Political risk scores for a sample of countries - January 2010
Source: PRS Group, “International Country Risk Guide, July 2007,”
12
F
(www.duk
.prsgroup.com.
ey, and T. V
” Financial Analysts J
vey) is also a useful source of information on political risk.
ey’s Web page
636
Seven
Special Topics
Multinational corporations have also de
eep
foreign governments honest. For e
inv
Tomé silver mine in Costaguana with
modern machinery, smelting equipment, and shipping facilities.13 The Costaguanan
government agrees to inv
e 20% of the
silv
es.
The project’s NPV on these assumptions is quite attractive. But what happens if a
new government comes into po
w and imposes a 50% tax on “any
precious metals exported from the Republic of Costaguana”? Or changes the government’s share of output from 20% to 50%? Or simply takes ov
air
compensation to be determined in due course by the Minister of Natural Resources of
the Republic of Costaguana”?
No contract can absolutely restrain sovereign power
e these acts as painful as possible for the foreign government. For
e
ws a
large fraction of the required investment from a consortium of major international
e sure the guarantee stands only if the
Costaguanan government honors its contract. The government will be reluctant to
break the contract if doing so causes a default on the loans and undercuts the country’s
The Cost of Capital for Foreign Investment
We did not say ho
project.
ved at a 13% dollar discount rate for its Ruritanian
verseas investment and the reward that investors
, there is no tidy theory of risk and return in
xt.14
Remember that the risk of an investment cannot be considered in isolation; it
v
or example,
suppose Ecsy-Cola’s shareholders inv
usiness in the
United States. They could vie
et, though v
ven by
different forces and therefore a div
ets is relatively low, an inv
business w
vely low-risk project to Ecsy-Cola’
That w
y
e
et.15
Avoiding Fudge Factors
We don’
foreign investment. But we disagree with the practice of automatically increasing the
domestic cost of capital when foreign investment is considered.
inv
13
14
citizens hav
and taxes?
15
Tomé mine is described in Joseph Conrad’s Nostromo.
ve never been able to agree on
y have dif
y are subject to different regulations
ferent countries.
grated w
vestors diversify worldwide, re
vestors would vie
s investment identically. But
in reality investors’ portfolios are strongly weighted tow
“home bias.” We do not yet have an integrated w
et.
Chapter 22
International Financial Management
637
because they w
xpropriation, foreign e
unfavorable tax changes. In other words, they add a fudge factor to the discount rate to
of
Those managers should leave the discount rate alone and reduce expected cash
ws instead. For example, let’s go back to Ecsy-Cola’
w forecast of
100 million Ruritanian pesos in year 1. Now the company gets word of a proposed 100 million peso “incorporation fee” to be imposed in “the first year of
operations for all new foreign investments.” The odds that the fee will be imposed
are judged at 5%.
No
expected
ut .95 3
100 million 5 95 million pesos. Ecsy should recalculate NPV using this forecast. It
should mak
s assumptions about political risks out in
the open for scrutiny and sensitivity analysis. There may be some discount rate fudge
factor that giv
,b
ve no practical way of
wing what the fudge f
lated. Once the adjusted NPV is in hand, the fudge factor is not needed.
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
www.prsgroup.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
MINICASE
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHAPTER
23
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
After studying this chapter, you should be able to:
1
2
3
4
R E L A T E D W E B S I T E S F O R T H I S C H A P T E R C A N B E F O U N D A T W W W. M H H E . C O M / B M M 7 E .
PA R T S E V E N
Special Topics
Just another day on the options exchange.
W
646
Part Seven Special Topics
23.1 Calls and Puts
A call option giv
ed exercise price (also
called the strike price
xpiration date.1 For example, if you buy
a call option on Google stock with an e
x
of $460, you hav
.
You need not ex
xceeds the exercise price. If it does not, the option will be left unexercised and
will be valueless. But suppose that when the option expires, Google shares are selling
above the exercise price, say, at $520. In this case you will choose to exercise your
orth $520. Y
call option
Right to buy an asset at
a specified exercise
price on or before the
expiration date.
you exercise the option. More generally, when the stock price is greater than the exercise price, the payof
xercise price.
, the value of the call option at expiration is as follows:
Stock Price at Expiration
Value of Call at Expiration
Greater than exercise price
Less than exercise price
Stock price 2 exercise price
Zero
Of course, that payof
You have to pay for the option.
wn as the option premium. Option b
exercise later. Your pr
equals the ultimate payoff to the call option (which may be
zero) minus the initial premium.
▲
EXAMPLE 23.1
Call Options on Google
In July 2010 a call option on Google stock with a January 2011 expiration and an
exercise price of $460 sold for $42.50. If you bought this call, you gained the right
to purchase Google shares for $460 at any time until the option expired the following January. The price of Google stock in July was $460. If the stock price did not
rise by January, the call would not be worth exercising and you would lose your
investment of $42.50. On the other hand, even a relatively modest rise in the stock
price could give you a rich profit on your option. For example, if Google sold for
$520 in January, the proceeds from exercising the call would be
Proceeds 5 stock price 2 exercise price 5 $520 2 $460 5 $60
and the net profit on the call would be
Profit 5 Proceeds 2 original investment 5 $60 2 $42.50 5 $17.50
In 6 months, you would have earned a return of $17.50/$42.50 5 .41, or 41%.
put option
Right to sell an asset at
a specified exercise
price on or before the
expiration date.
Whereas a call option giv
uy a share of stock, a put option
giv
sell it for the exercise price. If you o
xercise price, you will not want
to exercise your option to sell the shares for the exercise price. The put will be
left unex
xpire v
than the ex
uy the share in the market at the low price and
then exercise your option to sell it for the exercise price. The put would then be w
the difference between the ex
1
European call;
x
xercised on or before that day
, and it is then conventionally known as a
wn as an American call.
Chapter 23
▲
EXAMPLE 23.2
647
Options
Put Options on Google
In July 2010 it cost $41 to buy a put option on Google stock with a January 2011
expiration and an exercise price of $460. Suppose that Google is selling for $400
when the put option expires. Then if you hold the put, you can buy a share of stock
in the market for $400 and exercise your right to sell it for $460. The put will be worth
$460 2 $400 5 $60. Because you paid $41 for the put originally, your net profit
is $60 2 $41 5 $19. As a put buyer, your worry is that the stock price will rise above
the $460 exercise price. If that happens, you will let the put option expire worthless
and you will lose the $41 that you originally paid for it.
In general, the value of the put option at expiration is as follows:
Stock Price at Expiration
Value of Put at Expiration
Greater than exercise price
Less than exercise price
Zero
Exercise price 2 stock price
Table 23.1 shows how the v
vel
of the stock price on the expiration date. You can see that once the stock price is
above the ex
w the ex
dollar decrease in the stock price. Figure 23.1 plots the values of each option on the
expiration date.
Table 23.2 shows the prices of nine options on Google stock in July 2010. Notice
that for an
orth more when the exercise
price is lower, while puts are worth more when the ex
. This
makes sense: You would rather have the right to buy at a low price and the right to sell
at a high price. Notice also that for an
xercise price the longer-dated
aluable.
es sense. An option that expires in Januves you ev
-dated option offers and more. Naturally,
you w
eep your options open for as long as
possible.
Self-Test 23.1
Selling Calls and Puts
panies themselves but by other investors. If one investor buys an option on Google
TABLE 23.1 How the value
of a Google option on its
expiration date varies with
the price of the stock on that
date (exercise price 5 $460)
648
Part Seven Special Topics
FIGURE 23.1
Values of call
options and put options on
Google stock on option
expiration date (exercise
price 5 $460)
stock, some other inv
gain. We will look now
at the position of the investor who sells an option.2
We have already seen that the Google calls that e
ex
Thus if you sell
Google stock, the buyer pays you $42.50. However, in return you promise to sell
Google shares at a price of $460 to the call buyer if he decides to exercise his option.
The option seller’s obligation to sell Google is just the other side of the coin to the
option holder’s right to buy
The b
to exercise; the seller receives the premium but may be required at a later date to
deliver the stock for an ex
w the exercise price of $460 when the option e
,
holders of the call will not exercise their option and you, the seller, will hav
liability. However, if the price of Google is greater than $460, it will pay the buyer to
exercise and you must give up your shares for $460 each. You lose the difference
between the share price and the $460 that you receive from the buyer.
Suppose that Google’s stock price turns out to be $520. In this case the buyer will
exercise the call option and will pay $460 for stock that can be resold for $520. The
buyer therefore has a payoff of $60. Of course, that positive payoff for the buyer means
a negative payoff for you the seller, for you are obliged to deliver Google stock w
$520 for only $460.
nally paid for selling the option.
In general, the seller’s loss is the buyer’s gain, and vice versa. Figure 23.2a shows
the payoffs to the call option seller
Figure 23.1a drawn
upside down.
The position of an investor who sells the Google put option can be shown in just the
same w
Figure 23.1b on its head. The put buyer has the right to sell a
seller
b
TABLE 23.2 Examples of
options on Google shares in
July 2010 when Google stock
was selling for $460
2
wn as the writer.
Chapter 23
Options
649
FIGURE 23.2
Pay
o
sellers of call and put options
on Google stock (exercise
price 5 $460)
ve $460 but his payoff will be negativ
alls belo
The worst thing that can happen to the put seller is for the stock to be w
The seller would then be obliged to pay $460 for a w
The payoff to the
seller would be 2$460. Note that the advantage alw
uyer
the obligation lies with the seller. Therefore, the buyer must pay the seller to acquire
the option.
Table 23.3
uyers and sellers of calls
and puts.
Self-Test 23.2
Payoff Diagrams Are Not Profit Diagrams
23.1 and 23.2 show only
possible
xpires; they do
not account for the initial cost of buying the option or the initial proceeds from selling it.
or example, the payoff diagram in
23.1a
es purchase of a call look like a sure thing—the payoff is at worst
zero, with plenty of upside if Google’s stock price goes abov
pr
gram in Figure 23.3, which subtracts the $42.50
xpiration.
uyer loses money
1 $42.50 5 $502.50.
Take another example: The payoff diagram in Figure 23.2b makes selling a put look
like a sure loser—the best payof
Figure 23.4, which
ved by the seller, sho
ve
$460 2 $41 5 $419.
Profit diagrams like those in Figures 23.3 and 23.4 may be helpful to the options
beginner, but options e
w that you’ve graduated from the
on’t draw them either. We will stick to payoff diagrams,
because you have to focus on payoffs at expiration to understand options and to value
.
TABLE 23.3 Rights and
obligations of various option
positions
650
Part Seven Special Topics
FIGURE 23.3
Pay
profit for a purchaser of a call
option on Google with
exercise price of $460
Financial Alchemy with Options
e
s prospects but you perceive
enough risk that a large investment in the stock would cause you sleepless nights. Here
is a strate
ut also buy a put option on the
stock with ex
vel of $460,
ut you win on your investment in the stock. If the
alls, your losses are limited, since the put gives you the right to sell your
stock for the $460 exercise price. Thus the value of your stock-plus-put position cannot be less than $460.
ay to view your overall position. You hold the stock and the put
option. The ultimate value of each component of the portfolio is as follows:
Value of stock
Value of put option
Total value
Stock Price < $460
Stock Price ê $460
Stock price
$460 2 stock price
$460
Stock price
0
Stock price
No matter how f
alls, the total v
all
below the $460 exercise price.
The value of your position when the option expires is graphed in Figure 23.5. You
have downside protection at $460, but still share in an
This strategy is called a protective put, because the put option gives protection against
losses. Of course, such protection is not free. Look again at Table 23.2 and you will
vel of $460 between
as the price of a put option with
ex
xpiration.
Some More Option Magic
Look again at Figure 23.5, which sho
look somewhat f
FIGURE 23.4
Pay
profit for a seller of a put
option on Google with
exercise price of $460
T
xpiration from holda of Figure 23.2, which shows
Chapter 23
651
Options
FIGURE 23.5
Payo to
protective put strategy. If the
ultimate stock price exceeds
$460, the put is valueless but
you own the stock. If it is less
than $460, you can sell the
stock for the exercise price.
the payoffs from holding a call option on Google stock with an ex
The only difference between the tw
stock and put option always provides exactly $460 more than the call option. In other
words, re
v
same payof
ve strategy of buying a call option plus investing the present
value of $460 in a bank deposit.
w this second strategy. If the stock price is below
$460 when the option expires, your call option will be valueless but you will still have
ve $460, you will take
your money out of the bank, use it to exercise the call, and own the stock. The followvestment package gives you exactly the same
payoffs as you get from holding the stock and a put option:
Pay
Stock price < $460
Call option
Bank deposit paying $460
Total value
0
$460
$460
ation
Stock price > $460
Stock price 2 $460
$460
Stock price
If you plan to hold each of these packages until the options expire, the packages must
. This gives us a fundamental relationship between the
value of a call and the value of a put:3
Value of stock 1 value of put 5 value of call 1
This basic relationship between share price, call and put values, and the present value
of the exercise price is called
.
Self-Test 23.3
3
o options hav
present value of the ex
order to receiv
xercise price at expiration.
xercise price and e
652
Part Seven Special Topics
23.2 What Determines Option Values?
In Table 23.2 we set out the prices of different Google options. But we said nothing
about ho
et v
Upper and Lower Limits on Option Values
W
w what an option is w
xpires. Consider, for example, the option to
buy Google stock at $460. If the stock price is belo
xpiration date, the
call will be worthless; if the stock price is above $460, the call will be w
alue
xercise price. The relationship is depicted by the heavy
Even before expiration, the price of the option can never remain below the heavy
orange line in Figure 23.6. For e
at $520, it would pay any investor to buy the option, exercise it for an additional $460,
and then sell the stock for $520. That would give a “mone
$520 2 ($20 1 $460) 5 $40. Money machines can’t last. The demand for options
from investors using this strategy w
the hea
The heavy orange line is therefore a lo
et price of the option. Thus
Lower limit on value the greater of zero or
5 (stock price 2 exercise price)
of call option
The diagonal blue line in Figure
upper
ves a higher final payoff
whatever happens. If when the option expires the stock price ends up above the exerless the ex
ends up below the ex
ut the stock’s owner still has
av
. Thus the e
as follows:
Stock Price at Expiration
Stock Pay
Option Pay
Extra Pay
om
Holding Stock
rather than Option
Greater than $460
Less than or equal to $460
Stock price
Stock price
Stock price 2 $460
$0
$460
Stock price
The Determinants of Option Value
23.6. In fact,
ed, upward-sloping line like the dashed curve shown in the
This line begins its trav
wer bounds meet (at zero).
Then it rises, gradually becoming parallel to the lower bound. This line tells us an
act about option values: Given the exercise price, the value of a call option
increases as the stock price increases.
y when the
xercise price and are willing to pay more
y.” If you look back at the prices of the Google
ve
the exercise price. But let us look more carefully at the shape and location of the
dashed line.
A, B, and C,
ed on the dashed line. As we explain
Chapter 23
Options
653
FIGURE 23.6
Value of a
call before its expiration date
(dashed line). The value
depends on the stock price.
The call is always worth more
than its value if exercised
now (hea
ange line). It is
never worth more than the
stock price itself (blue line).
each point, you will see why the option price has to behave as the dashed line
predicts.
Point A When the stock is worthless, the option is worthless. A stock price of zero
means that there is no possibility the stock will ever have any future value.4 If so, the
option is sure to expire unex
.
Point B When the stoc
oaches the
stock price less the present value of the exercise price. Notice that the dashed line rep23.6 ev
heavy orange line representing the lo
The reason is as
follows:
ventually
be exercised. If the stock price is high enough, ex
the probability that the stock price will fall below the exercise price before the option
expires becomes trivial.
If you own an option that you know will be exchanged for a share of stock, you
vely own the stock now.
t have to pay for the
stock (by handing over the exercise price) until later, when formal exercise occurs. In
uying the call is equivalent to buying the stock now with
v . The value of the call is therefore equal to the stock
price less the present value of the exercise price.5
vestors who acquire
stock by way of a call option are buying on “installment credit.” They pay the
, but they do not pay the exercise price until
they actually exercise the option.
aluable if
interest rates are high and the option has a long maturity. Thus the value of a call
option increases with both the rate of interest and the time to expiration.
4
If a stock can be worth something in the future, then investors will pay something for it today, although possibly a very small amount.
5
W
vidends until after the option expires. If dividends were paid, you
would
wn the stock because the option holder misses out on any dividends.
654
Part Seven Special Topics
Self-Test 23.4
Point C The option price always exceeds its minimum value (except at expiration
or when the stock price is zero). We have seen that the dashed and heavy lines in
23.6
A), but elsewhere the lines diverge;
xceed the minimum value given by the heavy orange
line. You can see why by examining point C.
At point C, the stock price exactly equals the ex
The option therefore
would be worthless if it expired today. However, suppose that the option will not
e
w what the stock price will be at
the expiration date. There is roughly a 50% chance that it will be higher than the exerwer. The possible payof
are therefore:
Outcome
Pay
Stock price rises
(50% probability)
Stock price falls
(50% probability)
Stock price 2 exercise price
(option is exercised)
Zero
(option expires worthless)
ve payof
orst payoff is zero, then the
option must be valuable.
C exceeds its lower
bound, which at point C
xceed the lower
bound as long as there is time left before expiration.
height of the dashed curve (that is, of
the difference between actual and lower-bound value) is the likelihood of substantial
mov
by more than 1% or 2% is not w
halve or double is very valuable.
For e
x
xpires. The possible payoffs to the
option are as follows:
Stock price at expiration
Call value at expiration
$400
$520
0
$ 60
No
The average
greater. In this case the payof
Stock price at expiration
Call value at expiration
option is valueless re
the option is w
ut the volatility is
$340
$580
0
$120
.
w the exercise price when the option expires, the
. However,
its of stock price advances. Thus in our example
ut it is w
Therefore, volatility helps the option holder.
Chapter 23
Options
655
TABLE 23.4 What the price
of a call option depends on
The probability of large stock price changes during the remaining life of an option
depends on two things: (1) the v
per unit of time and (2) the
length of time until the option expires. Other things equal, you would like to hold an
option on a volatile stock. Given volatility, you would like to hold an option with a
long life ahead of it, since that longer life means that there is more opportunity for the
The value of an option increases with both the v
xpiration.
It’
Therefore, we have summed them up in Table 23.4.
Self-Test 23.5
Option-Valuation Models
If you want to value an option, you need to go beyond the qualitative statements of
Table 23.4
xact option-valuation model—a formula that you can plug
alue.
Valuing complex options is a high-tech business and well beyond the scope of this
book. Our aim here is not to make you into instant option whizzes, but we can illustrate the basics of option valuation by w
xample. The trick to
option valuation is to f
wing and an investment in the stock
that exactly replicates the option. The nearby box illustrates a simple version of one of
these option-valuation models.
This model achiev
e on only
two values at the expiration date of the option. This assumption is clearly unrealistic,
b
ge number
o values in our example.
which showed that ev
, you can still
replicate an option by a series of levered investments in the stock. The Black-Scholes
v
ers to value a wide v
6
The box on page 657
in economics for their work on the dev
shows you how to set up a Black-Scholes calculator in Excel.
Today
y ever-more-sophisticated v
ets. As computer power continues to increase, these models can be made more complex and increasingly
accurate.
6
Fischer Black passed away in 1995.
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
A Simple Option-Valuation Model
TABLE 23.5
Self-Test 23.6
656
SPREADSHEET SOLUTIONS
Using the Black-Scholes Formula
www.numa.com
Spreadsheet Questions
23.3 Spotting the Option
In our discussion so far we may have giv
to recognize the dif
Unfortunately, they rarely come with a lar
the problem is to identify the option.
W
Y
options in earlier chapters.
uy or sell shares. But once you hav
ind that the
v
v
y of these
Options on Real Assets
In Chapter 10 we pointed out that the capital investment projects that you accept today
ve tomorrow. Today’s capital budgeting decisions
more v
real options
Options to invest in,
, or dispose of a
capital investment project.
v
t.
gy—is more v
xible or generates ne
If you look out for real options, you’
xible one.
real options.
v
udgeting decision. In Chapter 10 we looked at several
ways that companies may b
of two types of real options that we introduced in that chapter.
657
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Allegheny Acquires a Real Option
The Option to Expand Many capital investment proposals include an option
to expand in the future. For instance, some of the world’s largest oil reserves are found
, in many cases the cost of e
ing oil is higher than the current mark
s estimate
of the likely price in the future. Yet oil companies hav
ves
the companies an option. If prices remain below the cost of extraction, the Athabasca
sands will remain undeveloped. But if prices rise above the cost of extraction those
land purchases could prove very valuable. Thus, ownership giv
option—a call option to extract the oil.
The Option to Abandon Suppose that you need a ne
turboencab
You have a choice of designs. If design A is chosen con. Design B is more expensive but you can wait a year
A. But suppose that there is some possibility that demand for turboencabulators will
fall of
s time you will decide the plant is not required. Then design
B may be preferable because it giv
y time
xt 12 months.
Y
x
v
mak
v
wnside exposure.
Self-Test 23.7
658
Chapter 23
659
Options
Options on Financial Assets
vestors to
. The
y’
ws. However, f
issue options to their managers or investors, and these do have a potential impact on
ws. Here are a few examples.
Executive Stock Options
as
as dw
w
and shares w
s compensation is
unusual, but these days the chief executiv
gely with stock options.
These stock options are valuable and therefore are an expense just lik
wages. The Financial
ASB) now requires companies to
air
value of option grants and to recognize this value when calculating expenses. For
example, in fiscal 2010 Oracle granted options to its directors, management, and
employees to b
y’s stock. Oracle’s accounts showed
that according to the Black-Scholes model the total value of these options was $375
million.
compensation. There is nothing wrong with that if the options encourage managers to
work hard to increase the value of their companies’ stock. However, in recent years
gally boosted the value of the stock options that they have given to
managers by backdating the grant of their executive stock options. The nearby box
discusses the backdating scandal.
warrant
Right to buy shares from
a company at a
stipulated price before a
set date.
Warrants
convertible bond
Bond that the holder
may exchange for a
specified amount of
.
Conver tible Bonds The convertible bond is a close relative of the bondw
ws the bondholder to exchange the bond for a given number of
Therefore, it is a package of a straight bond and a call option.
The exercise price of the call option is the value of the “straight bond” (that is, a bond
that is not conv
vert if the value of the stock to which
the investor is entitled exceeds the value of the straight bond.
The owner of a conv
s stock.
So does the owner of a package of a bond and a w
wever
ferences, the most important being that a conv
s owner must give up the bond
to exercise the option. The owner of a package of bonds and w
xercises the
w
eeps the bond.
A warrant is a long-term call option on the company’s stock. For examTreasury
receiv
T
buy one share in the bank for $13.30 at an
In March 2010 the T
vestors for $8.35 each. At that
time the price of Bank of America stock was $16.40 a share. So investors who bought
the w
ould realize a profit if the stock price rose above $13.30 1 $8.35 5 $21.65.
W
y
s bondholders warrants in the reorganized company as part of the
settlement. At other times w
v
y issues a bond, it will
occasionally add some w
.” Since these warrants are valuable to
investors, the
than for the bond on its own. Managers sometimes look with delight at this higher
price, for
the w
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
The Options Backdating Scandal
▲
EXAMPLE 23.3
Convertible Bonds
In March 2009, the giant aluminum company Alcoa issued $575 million of 5.25%
convertible bonds maturing in 2014. Each of these bonds can be converted before
maturity into 155.49 shares of Alcoa stock. In other words, the owner of the convertible has the option to return the bond to Alcoa and receive 155.49 shares in
exchange. The number of shares that are received for each bond is called the
bond’s conversion ratio. The conversion ratio of the Alcoa bond is 155.49.
In order to receive 155.49 shares of Alcoa stock, you must surrender bonds with a
face value of $1,000. Therefore, to receive one share, you have to surrender a face
amount of $1,000/155.49 5 $6.43. This figure is called the conversion price. Anybody who originally bought the bond at $1,000 in order to convert it into 155.49
shares paid the equivalent of $6.43 a share.
As we write this in July 2010, Alcoa’s stock price is $10.40. So, if investors were
obliged to convert their bond today, their investment would be worth
155.49 3 $10.40 5 $1,617. This is the bond’s conversion value. Of course, investors
do not need to convert in 2010. They obviously hope that Alcoa’s stock price will
zoom up, making conversion even more profitable. But they have the comfort of
knowing that if the stock price zooms down, they can choose not to convert and
simply hold on to the bond. The value of the bond if it could not be converted is
known as its bond value. If Alcoa’s bond could not be converted, it would probably
sell in July 2010 for about its face value of $1,000.
660
Chapter 23
661
Options
Since the owner of the conv
establishes a lo
ways has the option not to conv
, to the price of a conv
orth much.
In the extreme case where the f
orthless.
When the firm does well, conversion value exceeds bond value. In this case the
investor would choose to conv
alue
exceeds conversion value when the firm does poorly
vestor would hold on to the bonds if forced to choose. Conv
ve to
make a now-or-never choice for or against conversion. They can wait and then, with
e whatev
ve them the highest payoff. Thus a convertible is always worth more than both its bond value and its conversion value (e
W
v
straight bond and an option to b
xchange for the straight
bond. The v
v
s
mark
alue.
Self-Test 23.8
callable bond
Bond that may be
repurchased by the
issuer befor
specified call price.
Callable Bonds Unlike w
v
ve the investor an
option, a callable bond gives an option to the issuer. A company that issues a callable
uy the bond back at the stated exercise or “call” price. Therefore, you can think of a callable bond as a package of a straight bond (a bond that is
not callable) and a call option held by the issuer.
viously attractiv
. If interest rates
decline and bond prices rise, the compan
a fix
Therefore, the option to call the bond puts a ceiling on the bond price.
y issues a callable bond, inv
w
The
alue of the call option that investors have giv
y:
Value of callable bond 5 value of straight bond 2 value of the issuer’s call option
Self-Test 23.9
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SUMMARY
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
FIGURE 23.7
FIGURE 23.8
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHALLENGE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe
.com/bmm7e
FIGURE 23.9
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
WEB EXERCISES
finance.yahoo.com
finance.yahoo.com
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
SOLUTIONS TO EXCEL SPREADSHEET QUESTIONS
673
Chapter 24 Risk Management
a 50% decline in profits when the dollar unexpectedly strengthens against other
w much of that decrease is due to the exchange rate shift and how much
fect of exchange
s probably bad management. If it wasn’t protected, you have
ea
ve been if the
xchange rate movements?”
Finally, hedging e
vents can help focus the operating manager’s attention. We know we shouldn’t w
vents outside our control, but most of us do
anyway. It’s naive to expect the manager of the e
vision not to w
e
vements if his bottom line and bonus depend on them. The time spent
w
y hedged itself against such movements.
wing questions:
• What are the major risks that the company faces and what are the possible
consequences?
y.
• Is the company being paid for taking these risks?
void all
ut if they can reduce their e
compensating rew
y can af
ger bets when the odds are
stacked in their favor.
• Can the company take any measures to reduce the pr
to limit its impact? For example, most b
to prev
ire and invest in backup f
occur.
• Can the company purchase fairly priced insur
Insurance
companies have some adv
, they may be able to
ferent insurers.
• Can the company use derivatives, such as options or futures, to hedge the risk? In
the remainder of this chapter we explain when and how derivatives may be used.
The Evidence on Risk Management
There are three principal w
uildxibility into its operations. For example, a petrochemical plant that is designed
to use either oil or natural gas as a feedstock reduces the threat of an unfavorable shift
y that reduces the risk of a disaster
by test marketing a new product before launching it nationally
real options
A second way to reduce risk is to buy an insurance
polic
derivatives
Securities whose payo
are determined by the
values of other financial
variables such as prices,
exchange rates, or
interest rates.
known collectively as derivatives, and they include options, futures, and swaps.
A survey of the world’
gest companies found that almost all the companies
2
Eighty-five percent employ them to
vatives in some w
v
Risk policies differ. For example, some natural resource companies w
hedge their e
ander as they may. Explaining why some hedge and others don’t is not
easy
y had
high debt ratios, no debt ratings, and low dividend payouts.3 It seems that for these
and to improve
2
3
International Swap Dealers Association (ISDA), “2003 Derivatives Usage Survey,” www.isda.org.
G. D. Haushalter, “Financing Policy, Basis Risk and Corporate Hedging,” J
2000), pp. 107–152.
inance
674
Seven Special Topics
24.2 Reducing Risk with Options
In the last chapter we introduced you to put and call options. Managers re
Man
v
Petrochemical P
hea
Petrochemical b
exercise price of $90.
uy
xchanges, but often the
To protect itself against such increases
ve the $90 exercise price when the options expire,
Petrochemical will exercise the options and will receive the difference between the oil
x
alls below the exercise price, the options
will expire w
The net cost of oil will therefore be:
You can see that by b
in the oil price while continuing to benef
discard its call option and buy its oil at the mark
can ex
an attractive
of the options.
Consider now the problem of Onne
all, it can
wever, it
Therefore, options create
s; it loses when oil prices fall and
Onnex w
put options that give it the right to sell oil at an exerall, it will exercise the put. If the
et price:
If oil prices rise, Onne
the payoff of the put option exactly offsets the rev
v
option.
all belo
all. As a result, Onnex
xercise price of the put
Once again, you don’t get something for nothing. The price that Onnex pays
for insurance against a fall in the price of oil is the cost of the put option. Similarly, the price that Petrochemical paid for insurance against a rise in the price
of oil was the cost of the call option. Options provide protection against adverse
price changes for a fee—the option premium.
Notice that both Petrochemical and Onnex use options to insure against an adverse
move in oil prices. But the options do not remove all uncertainty. For example, Onnex
may be able to sell oil for much more than the ex
675
Chapter 24 Risk Management
rev
24.1
v
As prices f
x’
gy. P
a shows the
xposed to oil
s revenue. But, as panel b
s exposure. P
c sho
venues after it buys
the put option. F
venues are $90,000. But revenues rise
$1,000 for ev
ve $90.
c should be
f
Think back to the protective
In both cases, the put pro
alue of the overall position.
Self-Test 24.1
FIGURE 24.1
Onnex can
buy put options to place a
floor on its overall revenues.
676
Seven Special Topics
24.3 Futures Contracts
futures contract
Exchange-traded
promise to buy or sell an
asset in the future at a
prespecified price.
Suppose you are a wheat f
. You are optimistic about next year’s wheat crop, but
still you can’t sleep. You are w
may have f
. The cure for insomnia is to sell wheat
es. In
this case, you agree to deliver so many bushels of wheat in (say) September at a price
that is set today. Do not confuse this futures contract with an option, where the holder
has a choice whether to make deliv
deliv
xed selling price.
buy
est. If she
would lik
buying wheat
futures. In other w
e deliv
xed today. The miller also does not have an option; if she still holds the futures
contract when it matures, she is obliged to take deliv .
Let’s suppose the f
e a deal. They enter a futures contract.
What happens? First, no money changes hands when the contract is initiated.4 The
uy wheat at the futures price on a stated
e date (the contract
maturity date). The f
contract is a binding obligation, not an option. Options give the right to buy or sell if
b
The futures contract requires the f
Just remember, no
sell and the miller to buy re
money changes hands when a futures contract is entered into. The contract is a
binding obligation to buy or sell at a fixed price at contract matur .
ference between the initial futures price
and the ultimate price of the asset when the contract matures. For example, if the
futures price is originally $7 and the market price of wheat turns out to be $7.50, the
f
vers and the miller receives the wheat for a price $.50 below market value.
The f
ushel as a result of the
locked in turns out to exceed the price that could have
rity. Conversely, the b
et price of the
5 initial futures price 2 ultimate market price
5 ultimate market price 2 initial futures price
Now it is easy to see how the f
hedge. Consider the f
s ov
ws:
The profits on the futures contract offset the risk surrounding the sales price of wheat
and lock in total rev
, the miller’s all-in cost
xed at the futures price. Any increase in the cost of wheat will be
offset by a commensurate increase in the profit realized on the futures contract.
4
Actually
y do
need not suf
gin account.
677
Chapter 24 Risk Management
Both the f
ve
The f
uying
wheat futures.5
▲
EXAMPLE 24.1
Hedging with Futures
Suppose that the farmer originally sold 5,000 bushels of September wheat futures
at a price of $7 a bushel. In September, when the futures contract matures, the
price of wheat is only $6 a bushel. The farmer buys back the wheat futures at $6
just befor
, giving him a profit of $1 a bushel on the sale and subsequent
repurchase. At the same time he sells his wheat at the spot price of $6 a bushel. His
total receipts are therefore $7 a bushel:
You can see that the futures contract has allowed the farmer to lock in total
proceeds of $7 a bushel.
Figure 24.2 illustrates how the futures contract enabled the farmer in Example
24.1 to hedge his position. Panel a shows how the value of 5,000 bushels of wheat
v
The v
very dollar increase
in wheat prices. Panel b is the profit on a futures contract to deliver 5,000 bushels of
wheat at a futures price of $7 per bushel. The profit will be zero if the ultimate price
The profit on the contract to deliver at
$7 rises by $5,000 for every dollar the price of wheat falls below $7. The exposures
to the price of wheat depicted in panels a and b obviously cancel out. Panel c shows
that the total value of the 5,000 bushels plus the futures position is unaffected by the
ultimate price of wheat, and equals $7 3 5,000 5 $35,000. In other words, the farmer
has locked in proceeds of $7 per b
The Mechanics of Futures Trading
In practice the f
ould not sign the futures contract face-to-face.
Instead, each would go to an organized futures exchange such as the Chicago Board of
Trade.
Table 24.1 shows the price of wheat futures at the Chicago Board of Trade in August
very was about $7 a bushel. Notice that there is
a choice of possible deliv
xample, you were to sell wheat for deliv
in March 2011, you w
TABLE 24.1
The price of
wheat futures at the Chicago
Board of Trade on August 16,
2010
Source: The Chicago Board of Trade Web site, www.
cmegroup.com.
5
or e
many bushels of wheat he will produce.
w for sure how
678
Seven Special Topics
FIGURE 24.2
The farmer
can use wheat futures to
hedge the value of the crop.
See Example 24.1.
The miller w
deliv
or example, in the case
v
ushels of wheat of a
Toledo, or Burns Harbor.
When you b
xed today, but payment is not
made until later. However, you will be asked to put up some cash or securities as
margin
gain.
marked to market. This means that each day any
prof
xchange any losses and
receive an
or e
ver 5,000 bushels of wheat
at $7 a bushel. Suppose that the next day the price of wheat futures increases to $7.05
a bushel. The f
w has a loss on his sale of 5,000 3 $.05 5 $250 and must pay
679
Chapter 24 Risk Management
spot price
Price that is paid for
immediate delivery.
this sum to the exchange. Y
uying back his futures
position each day and then opening up a new position. Thus after the first day the
f
ushel and now has an obligation to
deliver wheat for $7.05 a bushel.
Of course our miller is in the opposite position. The rise in the futures price leaves
her with a pr
of 5 cents a bushel. The exchange will therefore pay her this profit. In
ef
w contract to take
delivery at $7.05 a bushel.
The price of wheat for immediate deliv
spot price. When the
f
e for his wheat may be very
different from the spot price. But the future eventually becomes the present. As the
date for deliv
e a spot
The f
ait until the futures contract matures and then deliver
wheat to the buyer. But in practice such deliv
venient for
the f
.6
Self-Test 24.2
Commodity and Financial Futures
We have shown how the f
their risk. It is also possible to trade futures in a wide v
such as sug , soybean oil, pork bellies, orange juice, crude oil, and copper.
Commodity prices can bounce up and down like a bungee jumper. For example, in
w
or a large user of copper
reduces its exposure to mov
A number of copper producers have also found that hedging
increases their debt capacity
y Equinox needed to
borro
Equinox reduce its e
For man
use
xchange rates have
You can
es
Financial futures are similar to
es, but instead of placing an
order to
e date, you place an order to buy or
sell a financial asset at a future date. You can use financial futures to protect
yourself against fluctuations in short- and long-term interest rates, exchange
rates, and the level of share prices.
Figure 24.3 shows the explosive growth of w
6
simply receiv
purchase the asset.
, you cannot deliver the asset.
Table 24.2
uyer
680
Part Seven Special Topics
Self-Test 24.3
FIGURE 24.3
Worldwide
turnover in futures contracts
has expanded sharply.
Source: Bank for Inter
,
.bis.org.
TABLE 24.2
Some financial
futures contracts
Key to abbreviations:
CBT Chicago Board of Trade
CME Chicago Mercantile Exchange
24.4 Forward Contract
Each day billions of dollars of futures contracts are bought and sold. We have seen that
contract in Table 24.1), and the contract size is standardized. For example, a contract
may call for delivery of 5,000 bushels of wheat, 100 ounces of gold, or 62,500 British
forward contract
Agreement to buy or sell
an asset in the future at
an agreed price.
able to buy or sell a forward contract.
Forward contracts are custom-tailored futures contracts.7 You can write a
forward contract with any matur
e for delivery of an
For
e
Y
to buy yen forw
At the end of the 3 months, you pay the agreed sum and take
delivery of the yen.
7
ed to market. Thus
Chapter 24 Risk Management
▲
EXAMPLE 24.2
681
Forward Contracts
Computer Parts Inc. has ordered memory chips from its supplier in Japan. The bill
for ¥53 million must be paid on July 27. The company can arrange with its bank
today to buy this number of yen forward for delivery on July 27 at a f
ard price of
¥110 per dollar. Therefore, on July 27, Computer Parts pays the bank $53 million/
(¥110/$) 5 $481,818 and receives ¥53 million, which it can use to pay its Japanese
supplier. By committing f
ard to exchange $481,818 for ¥53 million, its dollar costs
are locked in. Notice that if the firm had not used the forward contract to hedge
and the dollar had depreciated over this period, the firm would have had to pay a
greater amount of dollars. For example, if the dollar had depreciated to ¥100/dollar, the firm would have had to exchange $530,000 for the ¥53 million necessary to
pay its bill. The firm could have used a futures contract to hedge its foreign
exchange exposure, but standardization of futures would not allow for delivery of
precisely ¥53 million on precisely July 27.
The most active trading in forw
ut in recent years
ve
ard rate agreements that allow them to
ance the interest rate at which they borrow or lend.
24.5 Swaps
Suppose Computer P
bonds to help f
w plant. (Recall from Chapter 14 that
e interest payments that go up and down with the general level
of interest rates.
swap
Arrangement by two
counterparties to
exchange one stream
of cash flows for another.
more volatile, and she would lik
s interest expenses. One approach
would be to b
w issue of
xed-rate debt. But it is costly to issue ne
uying back
the outstanding bonds in the market will result in considerable trading costs.
A better approach to hedge out its interest rate e
interest rate swap.
x
that is tied to the level of interest rates.
s interest e
w from the swap agreement will rise as
well, offsetting its exposure.
LIBOR, or London Interbank Offer Rate, is the interest rate at which banks borrow
interest rate in the swap market.)
s interest expense each year therefore equals
ould like to transform this obligation into one
aps mark
xed.”
ap agreement to pay 5% on “notional
ap dealer and receive payment of the LIBOR rate on
counterparties in the swap.
3 $100 million and receives LIBOR 3 $100
million.
s net cash payment to the dealer is therefore (.05 2 LIBOR) 3 $100
million. (If LIBOR e
ves mone
y to the dealer.) Figure 24.4
ws paid
by Computer P
ap dealer.
means that Computer P
682
Part Seven Special Topics
FIGURE 24.4
Interest rate
swap. Computer Parts
currently pays the LIBOR rate
on its outstanding bonds (the
arrow
irm
enters a swap to pay a fixed
rate of 5% and receive a
floating rate of LIBOR, its
exposure to LIBOR will cancel
low
will be a fixed rate of 5%.
Table 24.3 shows Computer P
s net payments for three possible interest rates.
The total payment on the bond-with-swap agreement equals $5 million regardless of
the interest rate. The sw
xedrate debt with an effective coupon rate of 5%.
way its interest rate exposure without actually ha
fixed-rate bonds. Swaps offer a much cheaper w
”8
There are many other applications of interest rate swaps. A portfolio manager who
ut is w
xed rate
and receive
v
rate portfolio (see Self-Test 24.4). Or a pension fund manager might identify some
mone
xcellent yields compared with other
wever, the manager might believe that shortThe fund can receive the interest rate on
these high-yielding securities and enter a swap in which it receiv
xed rate and
wer-yielding money market security. It thus captures
the benefit of the advantageous relative yields on its securities but still establishes a
portfolio with the fix
Self-Test 24.4
yv
ap. For example, currency swaps
xed
y (which also may be tied
allo
TABLE 24.3
An interest rate
swap can transform floatingrate bonds into synthetic
fixed-rate bonds.
8
You might wonder what’
wishes to receive
x
.
it by charging a bid-ask
xed rate and pay LIBOR.
xed rate and receiv
xed and equal to .1% of notional principal.
ves
Chapter 24 Risk Management
x
683
These swaps can therefore be used to manage exposure to
e
▲
EXAMPLE 24.3
Currency Swaps
Suppose that the Possum Company wishes to borrow Swiss francs (SFr) to help
finance its European operations. Since Possum is better known in the United States,
the financial manager believes that the company can obtain more attractive terms
on a dollar loan than on a Swiss franc loan. Therefore, the company borrows
$10 million for 5 years at 5% in the United States. At the same time Possum arranges
with a swap dealer to trade its futur
or Swiss francs. Under this
arrangement the dealer agrees to pay P
icient dollars to service its dollar
loan, and in exchange Possum agrees to make a series of annual payments in
Swiss francs to the dealer.
Possum’s cash flows are set out in Table 24.4. Line 1 shows that when Possum
takes out its dollar loan, it promises to pay annual interest of $.5 million and to repay
the $10 million that it has borrowed. Lines 2a and 2b show the cash flows from the
swap, assuming that the spot exchange rate for Swiss francs is $1 5 SFr2. Possum
hands over to the dealer the $10 million that it borrowed and receives in exchange
2 3 $10 million 5 SFr20 million. In each of the next 4 years the dealer pays Possum
$.5 million, which it uses to pay the annual interest on its loan. In year 5 the dealer
pays Possum $10.5 million to cover both the final year’s interest and the repayment
of the loan. In return for these future dollar receipts, Possum agrees to pay the
dealer SFr1.2 million in each of the ne
ears and SFr21.2 million in year 5.
T
ect of Possum’
o steps (line 3) is the conversion of its
5% dollar loan into a 6% Swiss franc loan. The device that makes this possible is the
currency swap.
Self-Test 24.5
24.6 Innovation in the Derivatives Market
Almost every day some new derivative contract seems to be invented.
may be just a few private deals between a bank and its customers, but if the contract
proves popular, one of the futures exchanges may try to muscle in on the business.
Derivativ
ace businesses and then
design a contract that will allow them to lay off these risks. For example, a major hazge customer will get into
dif
ault on its debts. Credit default swaps offer a way for the lender to
TABLE 24.4
Cash flows from
Possum’s dollar loan and
currency swap (figures in
millions)
684
Seven Special Topics
insure against such a default. The pro
wer defaults on its debts and in return char
We
ault swaps in Chapter 6.
olatile. W
roughly doubled in 2008 and halved in 2009 before surging again in early 2010. The
futures exchanges reasoned that both producers and users might welcome a contract
vements. Therefore, in July 2010 the New
York Mercantile Exchange (part of the CME Group) introduced a futures contract
Real estate b
uilders w
wouldn’t it be nice if they could stop w
es against these
Well, now they can do so by dealing in real estate futures or options on the
participants to protect themselv
It seems to be v
ficult to predict which new contracts will succeed and which
will bomb. By the time you read this, iron ore contracts may have been forgotten, and
ev
w gro
et in
vatives.
ord.
24.7 Is “Derivative” a Four-Letter Word?
xamples of the f
wed how derivatives—futures,
options, or swaps, for example—can be used to reduce business risk. However, if you
were to copy the f
fsetting holding of wheat,
you would not be reducing risk; you would be speculating.
A successful futures market needs speculators who are prepared to tak
provide the f
y need. For example, if an
excess of f
ould be forced
down until enough speculators were tempted to b
uy wheat futures, the reverse will happen.
wn in to sell.
ving derivatives market, but it can get comor e
y,
per; its chief trader
wn in the business simply as “Mr. Copper,” was lauded for his
utions to f
its. However, in June 1996 the copper market was battered by
the revelation that the man with the Midas touch had managed to hide losses amounting to about $2 billion.
Sumitomo has plenty of company.
merchant bank, became insolvent. The reason: Nick Leeson, a trader in its Singapore
of
et index.
The same year Daiwa Bank reported that a bond trader in its New York of
managed to hide losses over 11 years of $1.1 billion. In 2008 the French bank Societé
Generale joined the billion-dollar club when it reported that one of its derivativ
ers had lost a record $7.2 billion on unauthorized trades.
aged to lose well over $1 billion.
matter that is subject to debate.
ets to hedge, but it still manas hedging, however, is a
vatives? Of course
not. But they do illustrate that derivatives need to be used with care. Speculation is
foolish unless you have reason to believe that the odds are stacked in your favor.
If you ar
er informed than the highly paid professionals in banks and
other institutions, you should use derivatives for hedging, not for speculation.
FINANCE IN PRACTICE
Meltdown at Metallgesellschaft
SUMMARY
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
PRACTICE PROBLEMS
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.wsj.com
CHALLENGE PROBLEM
WEB EXERCISES
www.cmegroup.com
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.bis.org
SOLUTIONS TO SELF-TEST QUESTIONS
FIGURE 24.5
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
CHAPTER
25
PA R T E I G H T
Conclusion
W
Too bad Einstein didn’t tackle the unsolved problems
of finance.
692
Eight
Conclusion
25.1 What We Do Know: The Six Most Important
Ideas in Finance
What would you say if you were ask
Here is our list.
Net Present Value (Chapter 5)
et. Similarly
w the value of a used car, you look at prices in the second-hand
w the v
w, you look
(remember, those highly paid investment bank
w dealers). If you can b
ws for your shareholders at a cheaper price than they would
hav
et, you have increased the value of their investment.
This is the simple idea behind net present value (NPV). When we calculate a
project’s NPV
orth more than it costs. W
estimating its v
ws would be worth if a claim on
v
ets.
cost of capital—that is, at the e
ving the
v
fer the same e
vestors in the project could expect
Like most good ideas, the net present v
ers, who may have v
They giv
vious when you think about it.
ws thousands of shareholdvels of wealth and attitudes tow
gate its operation to a professional manager.
alue.”
Risk and Return (Chapters 11 and 12)
That’s
nonsense. If the capital asset pricing model had never been inv
ould be essentially the same. The attraction of the model is that it
giv
vestment.
vely simple idea.
can diversify away and those that you can’t. The only risks people care about are the
ones that they can’t get rid of—the nondiversifiable ones.
You can measure the nondiver
, or market,
vestment by the extent
to which the value of the investment is affected by a change in the aggregate value of
all the assets in the economy. This is called the beta of the investment. The required
return on an asset increases in line with its beta.
y people are w
iculties of estimating a
project’s beta. The
, we will have
w, b
ticated theories will retain the tw
• Investors don’t lik
•
vestors cannot get rid of.
Efficient Capital Markets (Chapter 7)
v
tion and respond rapidly to ne
available. This
Chapter 25
693
What We Do and Do Not Know about Finance
v
“av
initions of
”
licly av
Don’
or costs; it doesn’
ficient-market idea. It doesn’t say that there are no taxes
t some clever people and some stupid ones. It
ets is v
y
alues of assets on the basis
of the best information available to investors.
The ef
et hypothesis has been extensiv
ve
revealed several pricing “anomalies,
it opportunities with simple
investment strategies. We showed you just a few examples of these anomalies in
these puzzles. Does this mean that inv
ving easy money on the table?
Unfortunately for all of us, this body of evidence has not translated into easy money.
Superior returns are elusive, and only a few mutual-fund managers have been able to
y consistency
k
MM’s Irrelevance Propositions (Chapters 16 and 17)
vance propositions of Modigliani and Miller (MM) imply that you can’t
increase v
w available to investors. Financing decisions that simply repackage the same
ws don’t add value.
Financial managers often ask how much their company should borrow. MM’s
wing does not alter the total
w generated by
s assets, it does not af
alue.
gument to show that dividend policy does
alue unless it af
w available to present and future
shareholders.
vidend and gets the cash back by
.
The same ideas can be run in rev
ws doesn’t add
value, neither does combining dif
w streams. This implies that you can’t
increase v
o whole companies together unless you thereby increase
w.
gers solely for diversification.
Y
v
ation of value.”
You can’t increase value simply by putting two companies together, nor can you create
v
w into several pieces, for example, into debt and
equity claims.
Option Theory (Chapter 23)
In ev
v
versation we often use the word “option” as synonymous with “choice”
having a number of options. In f
an option
ed today
w that it is often w
b
w.
We saw in Chapters 10 and 23 that companies are willing to pay e
projects that giv
xibility. Also, many securities provide the company or
the investor with options. For e
v
ves the owner an option to
e
y used to. This is
y increasingly use options to help limit risk.
694
Eight
Conclusion
ware that man
great f
v
or examver its salvage value is a put option.
v
w how to value them. One of the
as the discov
alue options. We revie
value in Chapter 23.
Agency Theory
fort involving many players, including management,
emplo
y pull
together.
F
v
and ho
v
v
wn
as ag
.
Consider, for e
ers. The shareholders (the principals) want managers (their agents
irm
value. T
alue they have added. Moreover
interests f
en over and they will be turfed out.
Although we didn’t allocate a separate chapter to agency theory
helped us to think about such questions as these:
• How can an entrepreneur persuade venture capital investors to join in his or her
•
•
ine print in bond agreements? (Chapter 16)
do they change management’s incentives to maximize company value? (Chapter 21)
will, the
s job. If after reading this book you really
w how to apply them, you hav
25.2 What We Do Not Know: Nine Unsolved
Problems in Finance
wn is never e
could go on forever
research.
ed problems that seem ripe for productive
What Determines Project Risk and Present Value?
A good capital investment is one that has a positive NPV. We have talked at some
length about how to calculate NPV, but we have given you very little guidance about
ho
ve-NPV projects, except to say in Chapter 10 that projects have positiv
ve advantage. But why do some compaall gains, and when can the
created, and planned for? What is their source, and how long do they persist before
competition wears them away? V
wn about an
questions.
Here is a related question:
vely safe?
In Chapter 12 we suggested a fe
ferences
Chapter 25
695
What We Do and Do Not Know about Finance
in operating leverage, for e
xtent to which a project’
ws
.
ut we
have as yet no general procedure for estimating project betas. Assessing project risk is
.
Risk and Return—Have We Missed Something?
w
ws of value which
” Econor example, the capital asset pricing model is
fect of risk on the value of an asset, but
prove or disprove conclusively. It appears that av
w-beta stocks
w. But this could be a problem with the way the tests
are conducted and not with the model itself.
We also described the puzzling discovery that e
alue of the stock to its market value. Of
course, these findings could be just a coincidence—an accidental result that is
unlikely to be repeated. But if they are not a coincidence, the capital asset pricing
model cannot be the whole truth. Perhaps firm size and the book-to-market ratio are
related to some other v
x
xpected
returns demanded by investors. But we cannot yet identify v
x
ve that
it matters.
Meanwhile, work is proceeding on the theoretical front to relax the simple assumpyou love f
e sense for you to b
ev
ge fraction of your personal wealth and leaves you with a
relatively undiv
wever
hedged against a rise in the price
Your hobby will cost you more in a bull market for wine, b
e
in the chateau will mak
.
vely
undiv
We would not expect you to demand a
s undiv
In general, if two people have different tastes, it may make sense for them to hold
different portfolios. You may hedge your consumption needs with an investment in
vest in Baskin-Robbins.1 The
capital asset pricing model isn’t rich enough to deal with such a world. It assumes that
all investors have similar tastes; the “hedging motive” does not enter, and therefore
the
Merton has e
motive.2 If enough investors are attempting to hedge against the same thing, this
wever, it is not yet
clear who is hedging against what, so the model remains difficult to test. Given the
rich possibilities for these extra hedging motives, there are many plausible alternative
risk measures beyond beta and many potential competitors to the simple capital asset
pricing model.
In the meantime, we must recognize the CAPM for what it is: an incomplete but
extremely useful w
message, that div
t matter
v
1
2
Asset Pricing Model,” Econometrica 41 (1973), pp. 867–887.
696
Eight
Conclusion
Are There Important Exceptions to the
Efficient-Market Theory?
The ef
exceptions.
ve, but no theory is perfect—there must be
xceptions could simply be coincidences, for the more that
ely to
or example, there is e
w moons have been
ve that this is anyroughly double those around full moons.3 It seems dif
thing other than a chance relationship—fun to read about b
inv
. We
sa
believ
et is inef
vestors have consistently been slo
t expect
investors never to mak
es. If they have been slo
interesting to see whether they learn from their mistak
ciently in the future.
v
of human behavior. For e
emphasis on recent events when they are predicting the future. We don’t yet know how
far such beha
vels.
ASDAQ Composite Index rose 580% from the beginning of 1995 to its peak in
xtreme price mov
e
aluation techniques. However
liable to speculative bubbles, where inv
xuberance. No
verexcited, but
why don’t professional investors bail out of the ov
y would
do so if it were their own money at stake, but maybe there is something in the way that
w
ve a full
understanding of why asset prices sometimes seem to get so out of line with what
fs.
Is Management an Off-Balance-Sheet Liability?
In Chapter 7, we ar
et v
alue,
alue. For e
e here, yet the
alue of the fund’s portfolio.
Other examples abound. For instance, real estate stocks often appear to sell for less
et v
et values of
et values of their oil reserves. Analysts joked that you could buy oil cheaper on Wall Street than in west Texas.
v
et v
with the value of its underlying assets.
alue is
harder to measure.
One possibility is that gaps between market v
alue
added of management. Of course, if market value is less than the value of assets, then
3
K. Yuan, L. Zheng, and Q. Zhu, “
v
Empirical Finance, 13 (2006), pp. 1–23.
” Journal of
Chapter 25
What We Do and Do Not Know about Finance
697
the market seems to view managers’ value added as negative. Perhaps inv
w
w for their own interests
fully e
v
yees coinv
vestors. So far, we know very little about
how this coinvestment works.
How Can We Explain Capital Structure?
Modigliani and Miller’
alue of a
ges, and the
costs that it incurs. Financing decisions merely affect the w
ws are
packaged for distribution to investors. What goes into the package is more important
than the package itself.
Does it really not matter ho
ws? We have come across several reasons why it may matter. T
. Debt provides a corporate tax
shield, and this tax shield may more than compensate for any e
the inv
y costs. Perhaps dif
relativ
, none of these possibilities has
been either proved relevant or definitely excluded.
The upshot of the matter is that we still don’t hav
gument on the subject.
How Can We Resolve the Payout Controversy?
We spent all of Chapter 17 on dividend policy without being able to resolve the
dividend controversy. Many people believe di
ve they are
v
s investfected, the payout decision is lar
vant. If pressed, we
e the middle view, but we can’t be dogmatic about it.
whether di
when
es sense
to pay out high or low dividends. Investors in mature f
w investment opportunities may welcome the financial discipline imposed by a high dividend payout,
The w
small high-gro
ute cash has changed over the last few decades. An
y dividends, while the volume of stock
vestment opportunities, b
y may help
us to understand how that policy affects f
alue.
How Can We Explain Merger Waves?
There are many plausible reasons why two firms might wish to merge. If you single
out a particular merger, it is usually possible to think up a reason why that merger
could make sense. But that leaves us with a special hypothesis for each merger.
What we need is a general hypothesis to explain merger waves. For example, nobody
seemed to be merging in 2002, yet only 4 years later, mergers were back in fashion.
Why?
W
ashions. For example, from time to
698
Eight
Conclusion
speculative ne
have been developing new theories of speculative b
help to e
ashions.
What Is the Value of Liquidity?
Unlike Treasury bills, cash pays no interest. On the other hand, cash provides more
T
The value of this liquidity declines as you hold increasing
amounts of cash. When you hav
extra can be extremely useful; when you hav
y additional
liquidity is not w
, we don’
w to value
t say how much cash is enough or
ho
orking capital management we lar
aguely of the need to ensure
an “adequate” liquidity reserve.
wledge of liquidity would also help us to understand how corporate
We already kno
lower prices than T
. However
T
ge to be
e
y will default. It seems likely that the
Treaw how to price differences in liquidity, we can’t really say
Investors seem to value liquidity much more highly at some times than at others.
ind it v
w. This hapv
rising default lev
et. Many banks that had sold these
inancial
institutions both in the United States and abroad. As the music began to stop, no one
w
reluctant to quote a price for buying or selling bonds, and banks became w
lending to each other.
w at
.1% above the Federal Reserve’s target interest rate found that they now needed to pay
a spread of over 4%—if they could borrow at all.
Why Are Financial Systems Prone to Crisis?
Financial markets work well most of the time, but we don’t understand why they
sometimes shut do
vely little advice to managers
as to how to respond.
cial systems. One moment ev
k
When the bubbles b
deep recession follows.
xt moment marW
w that
ubbles.
all, often precipitously, and
We need to know what causes
them, how they can be prevented, and how they can be managed when they do occur.
Crisis prevention will have to incorporate good gov
compensation schemes, and ef
inancial crises
will occup
inancial regulators for many years to come. Let’s hope
that the
.
That concludes our list of unsolved problems. We have given you the nine upper-
Chapter 25
What We Do and Do Not Know about Finance
699
25.3 A Final Word
We titled this chapter “What We Do and Do Not Know about Finance.” We should
perhaps have added a third section, “What We Know about Finance but Haven’t Told
You.”
that we hav
ver. Here are some examples:
• Investment decisions always hav
v
w. Sometimes these side ef
or instance, if
the project allows the company to issue more debt, it may bring with it valuable tax
shields. How can companies allo
valuating
new investment projects? We touched on this issue in Chapter 13 when we showed
you how to calculate the weighted-average cost of capital, but there is a huge body
wledge about how best to allo
aluation.
• We stressed in Chapter 14 the wide v
raise money. W
ut there are others that we largely
ignored. Leasing is an example. Companies lease assets rather than buy them
because it is conv
advantages. A lot is no
wn about how to value leases.
• Treasurers of large corporations w
xchange rates, interest
rates, and commodity prices. V
ards,
and swaps—have been invented to help managers hedge against these risks. Many
ve been applied to devising and valuing these new
instruments. We only touched on the problem of option valuation and said nothing
at all about valuing futures. It’s an exciting area and there is no shortage of books
QUESTIONS
QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
ANSWERS TO QUIZ
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
www.mhhe.com/bmm7e
APPENDIX A
Present Value and Future Value Tables
A-1
A-2
Appendix A
APPENDIX TABLE A.1
t years = (1 + r)t
A-3
Appendix A
APPENDIX TABLE A.2
t years = 1/(1 + r)t
A-4
Appendix A
APPENDIX TABLE A.3
t years = 1/r 2 1/[r (1 + r)t ]
Appendix A
APPENDIX TABLE A.4
Annuity table: Future value of $1 per year for each of t years 5 [(1 1 r)t 2 1]/r
A-5
APPENDIX B
Solutions to Selected End-of-Chapter Problems
CHAPTER 1
1.
CHAPTER 3
1.
shares of stock to raise funds; buy or lease a new machine.
2.
Liabilities and
Shareholders’ Equity
Assets
Cash
$ 10,000
Receivables
22,000
Inventory
financial
financial
real
real
real
financial
real
financial
12.
over defences, it is more likely that managers will act in their
own best interest, rather than in the interests of the firm and its
22.
yer and the client.
170,000
Total assets
100,000
Shareholders’ equity
145,000
$332,000
Liabilities and shareholders’ equity
$332,000
5. a. Taxes 5 $2,575
Average tax rate 5 12.88%
Marginal tax rate 5 15%
b. Taxes 5 $8,625
Average tax rate 5 17.25%
5 25%
c. Taxes 5 $83,897
Average tax rate 5 27.97%
5 33%
d. Taxes 5 $1,027,314
Average tax rate 5 34.24%
5 35%
12. Dividends 5 $600,000
13. Total taxes are reduced by $2,000.
27. a.
14. a. Book
b.
5 $200,000
value 5 $50,200,000
b.
5 $25.10
Book value per share 5 $0.10
investment unless the expected return on the project is
greater than 20%.
32. If you know that you will engage in business with another
15.
Sales
arise.
CHAPTER 2
4.
$10,000
Cost of goods sold
6,500
G & A expenses
1,000
Depreciation expense
1,000
EBIT
1,500
Interest expense
markets, money market.
500
Taxable income
5.
1,000
Taxes (35%)
Net income
10.
pare it to $2,500/6 5 $416.67/ounce.
13. a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
f.
$ 17,000
Long-term debt
200,000
Store and property
6. a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
f.
g.
h.
Accounts payable
False
False
True
False
False
False
18. These funds collect money from small investors and invest
Cash
350
$
650
5 net income 1 depreciation 5 $1,650
18.
20. a. Cash
5 $3.95 million
Net income 5 $1.95 million
b. CF increases by $0.35 million
NI decreases by $0.65 million
c. Positive impact. Investors should care more about cash
d.
tages of mutual funds for individuals are diversification,
professional investment management, and record keeping.
23. a. 2010: Equity 5 $890 2 $650 5 $240
2011: Equity 5 $1,040 2 $810 5 $230
B-1
Appendix B
b. 2010: NWC 5 $90 2 $50 5 $40
2011: NWC 5 $140 2 $60 5 $80
c. Taxable income 5 $330
Taxes
5 $115.50
d.
5 $174.50
e. Gross investment 5 $450
f. Other current liabilities increased by $45.
25.
27.
5 $1.70
5 $1.52
31.
14.
16. Days’ sales in inventory 5 2
18. a.
5 1.25
b. Cash coverage ratio 5 1.5
c. Fixed payment coverage 5 1.09
20. Total sales 5 $54,750
Asset turnover 5 0.73
ROA 5 3.65%
22.
5 $13.70
CHAPTER 4
1. a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
f.
g.
h.
i.
j.
k.
l.
m.
5 0.42
5 0.65
5 3.75
Cash coverage ratio 5 7.42
ratio 5 0.74
Quick ratio 5 0.52
5 12.64%
Inventory
5 19.11
5 19.10 days
5 67.39 days
ROE 5 13%
ROA 5 6%
Payout ratio 5 0.699918
8. a. ROE 5 13.41%
after-tax operating income
Assets
3
3
Equity
assets
net income
3
after-tax operating income
13,193
1,223 1 685(1 2 .35)
27,503
3
3
5
9,121
27,503
13,193
1,223
3
5 .129796 5 13%
1,223 1 685(1 2 .35)
long-term debt
11. a. Debt-equity ratio 5
b. Ret
ty 5
net income
average equity
c. Operating profit
d. Invent
e.
tu
ratio 5
n5
5
after-t
cost of goods sold
average inventory
current assets
current liabilities
f. Average collection period 5
g. Quick ratio
cash 1
5
ing income
sales
average receivables
average daily sales
etable securities 1 accounts receivable
cu
t liabilities
Book debt
5 0.5
Book equity
Market equity
52
Book equity
0.5
Book debt
5
5 0.25
Market equtiy
2
24.
perhaps it pays a higher interest rate on its debt.
26. a.
b. United Foods
c.
d.
CHAPTER 5
1. a.
b.
c.
d.
$46.32
$21.45
$67.56
$45.64
3. $100 3 (1.04)113 5 $8,409.45
$100 3 (1.08)113 5 $598,252.29
5. PV 5 $548.47
9. PV 5 $796.56
10. a. t 5 23.36
b. t 5 11.91
c. t 5 6.17
11. Effective annual rate
a. 12.68%
b. 8.24%
c. 10.25%
13. n 5
5 52%; EAR 5 67.77%
20. The PV for the quarterback is $11.37 million. The PV for the
24. a. EAR 5 6.78%
b. PMT 5 $573.14
5 19.188%; EAR 5 20.97%
30.
34. a. PMT 5 $277.41
b. PMT 5 $247.69
B-2
Appendix B
35. $66,703.25
37. $79,079.37
46. $100 3 e0.10 3 8 5 $222.55
$100 3 e0.08 3 10 5 $222.55
47. n 5
48.
value of your receipts is $930.66. This is a good deal.
22. a.
b.
c.
25. a.
b.
c.
d.
9.89%
8%
6.18%
4.902%
2.885%
0.9434%
20.926%
CHAPTER 7
50. r 5 8%
53. a.
good deal.
b. PV is $771.09. This is a bad deal.
60. $3,230.77
68. a.
b.
c.
d.
5 12%
6. a. 14%
b. P0 5 $24
62. $2,964.53
66. a.
b.
c.
3. a. $66.67
b. $66.67
c. Capital gains yield 5 0
Dividend yield 5
rate 5 3%
rate 5 7.12%
rate 5 9.18%
$79.38
$91.51
Real interest rate 5 4.854%
$91.51/(1.04854)3 5 $79.38
11. a. DIV1 5 $1.04
DIV2 5 $1.0816
DIV3 5 $1.1249
b. P0 5 $13
c. P3 5 $14.6237
d. Your payments are:
Year 2
Year 3
$1.04
Year 1
$1.0816
$ 1.1249
70. a. $228,107
b. $13,950
DIV
71. Approximately 24 years. Purchasing Power increases by
57.84%
Total cash flow
$1.04
$1.0816
$15.7486
PV of cash flow
$0.9286
$0.8622
$11.2095
Sales price
77. FV 5 $1.188; PV 5 $0.8418
78. $2,653.87
CHAPTER 6
1. a. Coupon rate remains unchanged.
b. Price will fall.
c.
d.
3. Bond
5 $1,333.33
4. Coupon rate 5 8%
5 9.119%
9. Rate of return on both bonds 5 10%
10. a. Price will be $1,000.
b.
5 21.82%
c. Real
5 24.68%
11. a. Bondholder receives $80 per year.
b. Price 5 $1,065.15
c. The bond will sell for $1,136.03.
12. a. 8.971%
b. 8%
c. 7.18%
16. 20
18. a. Price 5 $641.01
b. r 5 12.87%
19. a.
b.
5 5.165%
5 30.61%
$14.6237
Sum of PV 5 $13
13. a. P0 5 $31.50
b. P0 5 $45
16. P0 5 $33.33
18. a. (i)
g 5 0; P0 5 $40
(ii)
g 5 6%; P0 5 $40
(iii) Reinvest 60% of earnings.
g 5 9%;P0 5 $40
b. (i)
g 5 0; P0 5 $40
PVGO = $0
(ii)
g 5 8%; P0 5 $51.43
PVGO 5 $11.43
(iii)
g 5 12%; P0 5 $80
PVGO 5 $40
c.
the discount rate.
19. a.
b.
21. a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
f.
than the discount rate.
P0 5 $18.10
DIV1/P0 5 5.52%
6%
$35
$10
11.667
5
5 8.333
B-3
Appendix B
23. a.
b.
5 33.33/4 5 8.33
25. a. P0 5 $125
b. Assets in place 5 $80
PVGO 5 $45
29. a.
b.
5 $800/$200 5 4
ratio 5 ½
30. a. The equiv
wning and operating
Econo-cool is $252.53.
valent annual cost of
Air is $234.21.
b. Luxury Air.
c. Econo-cool equivalent annual cost is $229.14. Luxury Air
equivalent annual cost is $193.72.
33. a.
machine is $4,465.82. The old machine costs $5,000 a
30. $16.59
b. If r 5
5 $5,539.68.
41. a. P0 5 $52.806
b. P1 5 $57.143
c. Return 5 0.1200
43. a. Expected
5 8%
b. PVGO 5 $16.67
c. P0 5 $106.22
CHAPTER 9
3. $2.3
5.
5
6.
CHAPTER 8
Revenue
$160,000
Rental costs
1.
3.
A
5 $23.85 and NPVB 5 $24.59. Choose B.
5. No.
50,000
Depreciation
10,000
Pretax profit
$ 70,000
Taxes (35%)
7.
11. 0.2680
A 5 25.69%
B 5 20.69%
24,500
Net income
Project B has a payback period of 2 years.
$ 45,500
8. Cash
5 $3,300
10. Cash
5 $56,250
11. a.
14. NPV 5 2$197.7. Reject.
MACRS(%)
Depreciation
1
20.00
$ 8,000
$32,000
2
32.00
12,800
19,200
3
19.20
7,680
11,520
4
11.52
4,608
6,912
5
11.52
4,608
2,304
6
5.76
2,304
0
17. NPV9% 5 $2,139.28 and NPV14% 5 2
11.81%.
20. NPV must be negative.
Project
Payback
A
3 years
B
2 years
C
3 years
b. Only B
c. All three projects
d.
b.
17. Cash
5 $3.7055 million
18. a. Incremental operating CF 5
5 2$4,800
b. NPV 5 2$4,800 1
5 2$9.84
c. NPV 5 $137.09
21. a.
b.
investment 5 $53,000
Year
Cash Flow ($000)
A
2$1,010.52
1
20.9
B
$3,378.12
2
17.3
C
$2,404.55
3
13.7
4
10.1
Project
NPV
e. False
26. a. If r 5 2%, choose A.
b. If r 5 12%, choose B.
27. $22,637.98
29. b. At 5% NPV 5 2$0.443
c. At 20% NPV 5 $0.840
At 40% NPV 5 2$0.634
Book Value
(end of year)
Year
15. a. r 5 0 implies NPV 5 $15,750.
r 5 50% implies NPV 5 $4,250.
r 5 100% implies NPV 5 0.
b. IRR 5 100%
22. a.
30,000
Variable costs
c. NPV 5 2 $4,377.71
d.
5 7.50%
23. NPV 5 2$10,894.31. Don’t buy.
24.
$1.891
Choose Do-It-Right.
Appendix B
26. NPV 5 2$349,773.33
19.
30. a. $71.75 million
b.
c. NPV 5
21. a. General Steel
b. Club Med
5 31.33%
23. Sassafras is not
CHAPTER 10
2.
costs 5 $0.50 per burger
Fixed costs 5 $2.5 million
5. a. $1.836 million
2$5.509 million
b. $544,567
6. a. NPV 5
b. NPV 5
c. NPV 5
d.
5
CHAPTER 12
1. a. False
b. False
c. False
d.
e.
3. It is not well diversified.
7. Required return 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf) 5 14.75%
9. $1.50
Expected
12.
13.
5 16%
11. a. bA 5 1.2
bD 5 0.75
b. rm 5 12%
rA 5 14%
rD 5 9%
c. r 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf)
rA 5 13.6%
rD 5 10%
d. Stock A
15. a.
b.
$7,578.
16. a.
b.
c.
18. NPV will be negative.
5 2$25.29
21. DOL 5 1
24. a. Average CF 5 $0
b. Average CF 5 $60,000
15. P1 5 $52.625
27. a. NPV 5 2
b. NPV 5
23. b 5 4/7 5 0.5714
19. $400,000
25. a. False
b.
c. False
d.
e. False
CHAPTER 11
1.
5 15%
Dividend yield 5 5%
Capital gains yield 5 10%
26. r 5 rf 1 b(rm 2 rf) 5 12%
3. a. Rate of return 5 0
rate 5 23.85%
b. Rate of return 5 5%
rate 5 0.96%
c. Rate of return 5 10%
Real rate 5 5.77%
5.
CHAPTER 13
1. 4.88%
4. 13.75%
Asset Class
Real Rate
Treasury bills
0.87%
Treasury bonds
2.04%
Common stock
8.05%
8. The cost of equity capital is 11.2%.
WACC 5 8.74%
11. WACC 5 12.42%
16.
15.
Dollars
Bonds
17. b. r stock 5 13%
r bonds 5 8.4%
5 9.8%
5 3.2%
$ 9.36 million
Percent
30.3%
Preferred stock
1.50 million
4.9
Common stock
20.00 million
64.8
Total
$ 30.86 million
100.0%
B-5
Appendix B
17. 11.36%
18.
19. a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
r 5 16%
Weighted-average beta 5 0.72
WACC 5 10.56%
Discount rate 5 10.56%
r 5 18%
CHAPTER 14
1. a.
b. Outstanding
5 58,000
c. 40,000
3. a. funded
b. Eurobond
c. subordinated
d. sinking fund
e. call
f. prime rate
g.
rate
h. private placement, public issue
i. lease
j.
k.
6. a. 100 votes
b. 1,000 votes
7. a. 200,001 shares
b. 80,000 shares
9.
5 $400,000
Additional paid-in capital 5 $1,600,000
Retained
5 $500,000
12.
b. The public issue
c.
terms can be more easily renegotiated.
15. a. $12.5 million
b.
17. a.
b.
c.
d.
$10
$18.3333
$8.3333
200
CHAPTER 16
4. $280 million
5 10/1.25 5 8 (no leverage)
5 10/1.33 5 7.5 (leveraged)
14. a. Low-debt plan: D/E 5 0.25
High-debt plan: D/E 5 0.67
b.
Low-Debt Plan
EPS
Expected EPS
c.
EPS
3. a.
b. A bond issue
c.
placements
4.
to value.
7. a. 10%
b. Average return 5 3.94%
c.
10. No
12.
14. a. Net proceeds of public issue 5 $9,770,000
5 $9,970,000
$8.33
$11.25
$15.00
$11.67
Low-Debt
High-Debt
$10.00
$10.00
22. a. 11.2%
b.
3 $800 5
Assets
$2,420
1. a. Subsequent issue
b. Bond issue
c. Bond issue
High-Debt Plan
$13.75
16. r equity 5 14%
deductible expenses.
CHAPTER 15
$8.75
Debt
Equity
$0
$2,420
24. Distorted investment decisions, impeded relations with other
firms and creditors.
31. a.
b.
c.
d.
CHAPTER 17
1. a. May 7:
June 6:
June 7:
Ex-dividend date
June 11: Record date
July 2:
Payment date
b.
c. Dividend yield 5 1.11%
d. Payout ratio 5 15.79%
B-6
Appendix B
2. a.
b.
c.
13. a.
b.
5 $64
5 $64
5 $80, unchanged
15. a.
10. a. No effect on total wealth.
b.
5 5.56%
5 8.33%
Income Statement
Revenue
$2,400
$2,100
2,160
1,890
240
210
Cost of goods sold
12. With a repurchase, shareholders will own fewer shares at
EBIT
Interest expense
dividend.
Earnings before taxes
14. a.
b. Same effect as the stock dividend.
State and federal taxes
Net income
Dividends
16. a. $50; $45
b. $48.50
19. a.
b.
Balance Sheet
A
10.00%
6.500%
9.00%
B
10.00
7.725
8.75
C
10.00
8.950
8.50
Corporation
Individual
B
$ 81.25
C
$ 62.50
80
68
120
102
40
68
$
34
20% Growth
$ 240
$ 210
Fixed assets
960
840
Total assets
$1,200
$1,050
$ 400
$ 400
Liabilities and
Shareholders’ Equity
Long-term debt
Price
$100
$
Net working capital
Pension
A
170
Assets
Stock
Stock
40
200
80
Retained earnings
18. a.
5 $19.45
b. Before-tax return 5 13.11%
c.
5 $20.09
d. Before-tax return 5 14.48%
40
b.
640
634
Total liabilities and
shareholders’ equity
$1,040
$1,034
Required external financing
$ 160
$
Second-Stage Pro
Forma Balance Sheet
16
5% Growth
Assets
Net working capital
23. a.
b.
5 $2. If the firm does the
repurchase, EPS 5 $2.105.
c.
5 9.5. If the stock is
840
Total assets
$1,200
$1,050
$ 560
$ 416
Long-term debt
CHAPTER 18
6.
to output. Costs and assets will increase as a proportion of
sales.
9. The balancing item is dividends. Dividends must be $200.
11. a. Internal growth rate 5 10%
b. Sustainable growth rate 5 15%
$ 210
960
Liabilities and
Shareholders’ Equity
5 9.5.
1. a.
b.
c.
d. False
e.
f.
g. False
$ 240
Fixed assets
Total liabilities and
shareholders’ equity
640
634
$1,200
$1,050
17. a. g 5 2.5%
b. Issue $1,000 in new debt.
c. 1.5%
19. a.
b.
c.
d.
5 10%
financing 5 $200,000
5 25%
5 $50,000
21.
5 10%
25. g 5 12%
27.
29. Higher
B-7
Appendix B
22.
CHAPTER 19
1.
a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
f.
Cash
Net Working Capital
$2 million decline
$2 million decline
$2,500 increase
Unchanged
$5,000 decline
Unchanged
1. Cash required for
operations
Unchanged
$1 million increase
2. Interest on bank loan
Unchanged
Unchanged
$5 million increase
Unchanged
3. Interest on stretched
payables
0
0
4. Total cash required
$50.00
$15.90
$45
$ 0
First
Third
Cash requirements
$50
$15
0.00
0.90
2$26
0.90
0.8
2$35
0.73
0
2$24.30
2$34.27
Cash raised in quarter
2. a.
5. Bank loan
b.
5.
$ 0
$ 0
6. Stretched payables
0
15.9
0
0
7. Securities sold
5
0
0
0
$ 0
$ 0
8. Total cash raised
7. a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
f.
Second
9. Of stretched payables
10. Of bank loan
$270
2
$252
3
$288
4
$288
18.
0
0.00
0.00
11. Addition to cash balances $ 5
$ 0
$ 0
$ 0
$ 0
$45
$45
$36.6
$45.00
$45.00
$36.60
$2.33
Sources of Cash
Sale of marketable securities
$ 2
Increase in bank loans
1
Increase in accounts payable
5
Cash from operations:
$348
Net income
6
2
$368
Depreciation
2
3
$352
4
$352
Total
$16
Uses of Cash
Increase in inventories
20.
Increase in accounts receivable
First
Second
Third
$40
$10
$15
2$14
230
15
229
241
5 Cash at end of period
10
15
214
255
Minimum operating
cash balance
30
30
30
30
$20
$15
$44
$85
Cumulative financing
required (minimum cash
balance minus cash at end of
period)
0
34.27
13.
1
1 Net cash inflow
(from Problem 18)
8.40
12.
23.
Collections
Cash at start of period
$15.9
Bank loan
16.
1
0
Bank loan
Cash conversion cycle increases.
Order
$15.9
Repayments
Cash conversion cycle falls.
Cash conversion cycle increases.
Cash conversion cycle falls.
Cash conversion cycle increases.
Quarter
$50
Fourth
$ 6
3
Investment in fixed assets
6
Dividend paid
1
Total
Change in cash balance
$16
0
B-8
Appendix B
5 $1,200
PV(COST) 5 $1,000
24.
February
March
April
$ 100
$ 110
$ 90
expected profit of a sale to a slow payer is therefore 0.70($1,200
2 $1,000) 2 0.30($1,000) 5 2$160.
Expected savings 5 $16. The credit check costs $5, so it is
cost effective.
Sources of cash
Collections on current sales
Collections on
accounts receivable
Total sources of cash
90
100
110
$ 190
$ 210
$ 200
26.
CHAPTER 21
Uses of cash
Payments of accounts payable
$ 30
$ 40
$ 30
Cash purchases
70
80
60
Labor and administrative
expenses
30
30
30
Capital expenditures
100
0
0
10
10
10
$ 240
$ 160
$ 130
2$ 50
1$ 50
1$ 70
$ 100
$ 50
$ 100
Taxes, interest, and dividends
Total uses of cash
Net cash inflow (sources 2 uses)
1 Net cash inflow
250
150
170
5 Cash at end of period
$ 50
$ 100
$ 170
1 Minimum operating cash balance
$ 100
$ 100
$ 100
5 Cumulative short-term
financing required (minimum
cash balance minus cash at
end of period)
1. a. Economies of scale is a valid reason.
b. Diversification is not a valid reason.
c. Possibly a valid reason.
d.
2.
4. LBO: 5
Poison pill: 3
Tender offer: 4
Shark repellent: 2
6.
$ 50
$
0
2$ 70
12. a.
b.
c.
d.
CHAPTER 20
1. a. $10
b. 40 days
c. 9.6%
6. Available balance with bank 5 $275,000
8. Extra cash available 5 $22,000.
Interest 5 .06 3 $22,000 5 $1,320.
11. a. 20 days
b. $1.096 million
c. Average days in receivables will fall.
13. a. The e
2$3. Do not extend
credit.
b. p 5 0.96
c. The present value of a sale is positive, $365.28.
d. p 5 0.1935%
14. a. The expected profit of a sale is positive, $90.
b. p 5 0.875
20. a. $30,000
b. $6
c. $180
22. Yes
23. Cash balances fall relative to sales.
NPV 5 $10,000
SCC will sell for $53.33; SDP will sell for $20.
Price 5 $52.63
NPV 5 $7,890
13. a.
4. a. Due lag and pay lag fall.
b. Due lag and pay lag increase.
c.
19. a. Yes
b. Credit should not be advanced.
c.
8. a. $6.25
b. $4
c. NPV 5 $2.25 million
5
1
5
Total
5 $200,000 1 $500,000 5 $700,000
Number of shares 5 262,172
5 $9,000,000/262,172 5 $34.33
Price-earnings ratio 5 $34.33/$2.67 5 12.86
b. 0.81 shares
c. $567,365
d. 2$567,365
CHAPTER 22
1. a. 76.66 euros; $130.44
b. 100.94 Swiss francs; $99
c.
rate will increase.
d. U.S. dollar is worth more.
3. a.
fx/$
1 1 rx
5
s
1 1 r$
x/$
b.
fx/$
E(sx/$)
5
sx/$
sx/$
c.
E(sx/$)
1 1 ix
5
sx/$
1 1 i$
d.
1 1 r$
1 1 rx
5
(
)
E 1 1 ix
E(1 1 i$)
5 $50.
B-9
Appendix B
6. a
6. Advantages: liquidity, no storage costs, no spoilage.
8.
holding asset in portfolio.
7.
Gold Price
1000
10. a. 4%
b. 14%
c. 26%
a. Revenues
Futures contract
gain
1400
$1,400,000
80,000
2120,000
2320,000
$1,080,000
$1,080,000
$1,080,000
c. Revenues
$1,400,000
18. a.
b.
c.
$1,000,000
$1,200,000
1 Put option payoff
80,000
0
0
2 Put option cost
12,000
12,000
12,000
$1,068,000
$1,188,000
$1,388,000
Total revenues
CHAPTER 23
1200
$1,200,000
b. Total revenues
14.
16. Net present value 5
$1,000,000
9.
for 1 year at 6%.
1.
Payoff
Profit
211.20
a. Call option, X 5 430
30
b. Put option, X 5 430
0
211.05
c. Call option, X 5 460
0
222.50
d. Put option, X 5 460
0
222.20
e. Call option, X 5 490
0
210.10
f. Put option, X 5 490
30
2 9.36
11. The futures price for oil is $90 per barrel. Petrochemical will
take a long position to hedge its cost of buying oil. Onnex
oil.
Oil Price ($ per barrel)
$80
$90
$100
Cost for Petrochemical:
Cash flow to buy
1,000 barrels
5. Figure 23.7a represents a call seller; Figure 23.7b represents a
call buyer.
1 Cash flow on
long futures position
7. a.
b. The value of the stock.
Net cost
10.
280,000
290,000
2100,000
210,000
0
10,000
290,000
290,000
290,000
$80,000
$90,000
$100,000
10,000
0
210,000
$90,000
$90,000
$ 90,000
Revenue for Onnex:
cise price, whichever is greater. The upper bound is the stock
Revenue from 1,000
barrels
14.
1 Cash flow on
16. a. Call option to pursue a project.
b.
Net revenues
18. Put option with exercise price equal to support price.
20. a. Option to put (sell) the stock to the underwriter.
b.
22.
deposits owed to bank customers.
12.
24. a. Buy a call option for $3. Exercise the call to purchase
stock. Pay the $20 exercise price. Sell the share for $25.
of the gold without tying up your money now. The differcompensation for the time value of money. Another way to
put it is that the spot price must be lower than the futures
b.
profit equals $1.
opportunity cost of their funds until the futures maturity
date.
CHAPTER 24
14.
1.
diversify away.
4. No
another currency. An interest rate swap is an exchange of a
Credits
CHAPTER 1
Page 3
CHAPTER 10
© The McGraw-Hill
Companies, Inc./Jill Braaten,
Photographer
Page 291
Stockbyte
Page 31
Page 317
© Brand X Pictures/
Page 53
Polka Dot Images/
Jupiterimages
CHAPTER 12
CHAPTER 3
Page 345
CHAPTER 13
Michael/Corbis
Page 79
Page 371
CHAPTER 19
Page 527
The K
CHAPTER 20
Page 559
Ingram
CHAPTER 4
Page 503
LLC
CHAPTER 11
CHAPTER 2
CHAPTER 18
V
CHAPTER 21
Page 591
Photodisc/Getty Images
Images
CHAPTER 5
Page 113
AP
CHAPTER 22
vid
CHAPTER 6
Page 159
Courtesy of T
CHAPTER 7
Page 185
© Alan Schein Photography/
Corbis
CHAPTER 8
Page 227
Photodisc/Getty Images
CHAPTER 9
Page 263
CHAPTER 14
Page 399
Getty Images
CHAPTER 15
Page 423
Page 619
© Reuters New Media Inc./
Corbis
CHAPTER 23
Page 645
Getty Images
Getty Images
CHAPTER 24
CHAPTER 16
Page 445
Page 671
© Corbis
©
CHAPTER 25
CHAPTER 17
Page 470
Page 691
©
© Medioimages/Superstock
T
C-1
Global Index
A
C
B
D
E
F
I
G
H
J
N
R
K
L
O
S
M
P
V
U
W
Y
T
Z
Subject Index
Page numbers followed by n refer to notes.
A
Abandonment option, 307, 658
Abandonment value, 307
Accelerated depreciation, 278
Accounting
cash, 61–62
conver
gray areas
es, 66
mark-to-market
accounting, 67
liabilities, 66–67
rev
Adobe Systems, 221
Af
Inc., 660
After-tax company cost of
capital, 377
After-tax cost of debt, 371, 377
After-tax income, 409
di
After-tax operating income, 85
calculating, 87
After
Agency costs, 603
Agency problems, 48
and board of directors, 18
and compensation plans, 18–19
, 67
et, 67
legal/re
requirements, 18
Annuity
versus annuity due future
value, 137
B
er, M., 482n
Balance sheet
present v
v
alue, 137
present v
Annuity factor, 129
for Bill Gates, 131–132
in lottery winnings, 131
assets on, 189
book vs. market v
57–59, 206
common-size, 56–57
et value
excluded, 88
Home Depot, 54–57, 82
future value, A-5
present value, A-4
w, 598–599
main items of, 56
market-value, 205–206
Apple Inc., 34, 35
vidends, 33
ven analysis,
298–300
adjusted, 272
w, 265
and stakeholders, 17–18
and takeovers, 19
Agenc
, 694
Agents, 17, 694
Aggressive gro
Aggressive stocks, 346
Aging schedule, 569–570
problems with, 87–88
go deregulation, 4
, 87
see
Accounting standards, 66
Accounts payable, 532
Accounts payable period
definition, 534
estimating, 535
Accounts receivable, 265
on balance sheet, 54
collection period, 569
collections, 539–541
credit policy, 560–571
et risk, 336
negativ
, 445n
Alaska Air Group, 46
Alcoa, 660, 661
Allegheny Corporation, 658
Allen, F., 387n, 458n
Allen, Paul, 423
Vegetable Oil
Refining Company, fraud
at, 547
Altman, Edw
Altria Group, 368, 393, 492
founding of, 423
and Massachusetts law, 427n
Aqua
204, 205
window dressing, 67
Balancing item, 507–508
, J., 660
see also Banks and
Archipelago Exchange, 35, 187
Asked yield to maturity, 161
Asquith, P., 434n, 482n
Asset-back
ubbles, 698
Assets
on balance sheet, 54–57, 189
y costs, 461
et value, 57–59
leasing vs. buying, 699
liquid, 54, 95–96
et accounting, 67
matching maturities, 529–530
needed by corporations, 3
negative-risk, 332
of pension plans in 2010, 40
ve interest rates, 139
proliferation of, by
time deposits, 531
er’s acceptance, 562
48, 329
ed interest rate, 546
line of credit, 545–546
secured loans, 547–548
self-liquidating, 546
67, 176, 431, 546, 586, 592
America w
w York, 594
329, 480, 667
level divisions, 534n
payment of, 541
types of, 559
Accounts receiv
Accounts receivable period
definition, 534
estimating, 534
Accrual accounting, 61–62
on income statement, 63
Acid-test ratio, 96
Acquisitions, 598; see also
Mergers
ve expenses, 541
wer, 189,
192, 221, 524
relative liquidity, 96, 530n
ved, 236–238
ver ratio, 88
Chapter 7, 475
America Online, 610
Andrade, G., 611
Angel investors, 425
486
Ann Taylor Stores, 586
Annual percentage rate
of bonds, 163n
y, 24
ATMs, 576
AT&T, 83, 84, 85
Auction, 428n
for stock repurchase, 483
system, 577
Av
Average risk, 371
Average tax rate, 70
duration of proceedings, 477
460
Enron, 460
L.
, 532
IND-5
IND-6
Subject Index
y—Cont.
P
postpetition creditors, 477
prepackaged, 475n
as protection from litigation, 477
recent examples, 476
for selected companies, 359
spreadsheet solutions, 347
of T
Bid-ask spread, 187
coupon, 160
expected rate of return, 382
face value, 160
Break-even sales volume, 299
Brealey, R. A., 387n, 458n
Brin, Sergey, 423
Bristol Myers Squibb, 410
Brokers, in stock trading, 186–187
Foundation, 131
WorldCom, 175
y costs
Black, Fischer, 357, 655, 694
indexed, 173
examples, 460
indirect, 460–461
model, 659
Blockbuster, 598
and v
varying by type of assets, 461
y procedures
asset liquidation, 475
liquidation vs. reor
Bloomingdale strategy, 91
ws, 427
junk bonds, 46, 174–175, 411
Business organizations
alue, 160
present value calculation, 162
relativ
y problems, 18
v
yield curve, 171–174
yield on, 142
yield to maturity, 166–168
Bond valuation, 159
spreadsheet solution, 170–171
Bookb
reor
workout, 475
Act of
1978, 475
y Act, 18
Bob Ev
y, 4, 6, 45, 306,
329, 350, 359, 385
574–575
credit checks by, 562
di
inv
decisions, 5
Bondholders, 126
with conv
Book value, 83
and capital structure, 380–381
and company cost of capital,
376–377
, 88
and debt ratios, 93
equities, 406
es, 412n
lock-box system, 574–575
merger activity, 594
Buffett, W
Build-to-order production, 573
Bureau of Labor Statistics, 140n
losers in LBOs, 609
sole proprietorships, 9
best-case, 504
normal gro
Business risk, 450
C
Callaway Golf, 46
Call options
v
Google Inc., 646
v
versus market v
189–191
reliability of, 95
et, 36
sweep programs, 573–574
junk bonds, 608–610
size of, 160
versus put options, 646–647
Booms, 330–332
selling, 647–649
Base period, 140
asked yield to maturity, 160, 161
Beaver, William H., 563–565
Bechtel, 426
Before-tax income, 409
Behavioral f
w
beliefs about probabilities, 215
Behavioral psychology, 491
way, 435, 592
ogi, 446
Best-case plan, 504
alue of,
652–653
value at expiration, 646
calculating, 162
,
170
corporate bonds, 175
cash balance and need for, 541
effect on value
debt and cost of equity,
discount, 167
premium, 167
Beta(s)
T
of cyclical businesses, 362
quotations, 175
v
Dell Inc., 360
Do
348–349
fate of, 358
measuring, 346–348
Borders Group, 586
wing
by Apple Inc., 33
163–165
w
vestors, 322
Bonds, 159; see also
bonds; Treasury bonds
asset-back
conv
pros and cons, 697
tax disadv
Bradshaw
Brav, A., 485
Break-even analysis
accounting break-even point,
298–300
in credit decision, 567
and economic value added, 301n
e
at Lockheed, 302–303
net present value, 300–303
sales volume, 298
Call provisions, 645
y, 189, 192,
329, 350, 359, 385, 593
Capacity e
Capacity to pay, 563
Capital, 7, 36
Capital asset pricing model, 371
basis of, 356
to calculate company cost of
capital, 374–375
critique of, 358
expected return based on, 382
expected vs. actual returns, 358
prediction of risk premium, 357
et line, 355–356
IND-7
Subject Index
value and drawbacks, 695
v
358
Capital budget, 292
Capital budgeting, 10–11, 227;
see also
w, 263–264
w, 265
ws,
266–268
and options, 645
problems and solutions
analyze competitive
advantage, 294
interest, 292
ensuring consistent forecasts,
292
reducing forecast bias,
293–294
and project risk, 359–362
proposed budget, 292
in strategic planning, 504
what-if questions, 295
Capital budgeting decisions, 6
Allegheny Corporation, 658
and capital rationing, 249
case, 258–259
choosing between two projects,
234
investment timing problem, 234,
235–236
ved equipment,
235, 236–238
xclusive projects, 235
and payout policy, 487
real options
option to abandon, 658
option to expand, 658
replacement problem, 235,
238–239
Capital investment projects, 228
decision rules
net present v
Capital surplus, 405
CAPM; see Capital asset pricing
model
gill, 426
for long-lived projects,
241–243
pitfalls, 243–248
xclusive, 244–246
net present v
selecting
ved
equipment, 236–238
replacement of equipment,
238–239
timing decision, 235–236
Pentagon La
ge Projects,
234
v
ved projects
new computer system,
231–232
spreadsheet solutions,
233–234
estimating cost of capital from
, 322–324
et indexes, 319
ets, 36
I, 447
icient, 692–693
Capital rationing, 249
Capital structure
e
e-outs, 610
Cash
advantage of holding, 530
calculating, 60–61
components, 531
disadv
forecasting uses of, 541
liquidity of, 574
mer
changes in, 445
and corporate taxes
v
tracing changes in., 537–539
transported across time, 43
uses of
accounts receivable
payments, 541
capital expenditures, 541
ve
costs, 541
vidends,
541
v
Cash before deliv
Cash budgeting
payment date, 481
record date, 481
regular vs. special, 480
in U.S. 1980–2008, 480
w(s), 263–264; see also
ws;
w
, 599–601
vested, 33
antage,
240–241
steps, 263
vidend date, 481
from bonds, 166–167
from collections, 539–541
calculating, 64–65
v
requirements, 541–543
example, 541
minimum operating cash
balance, 541
w, 541
changes at Sealed Air
Cash coverage ratio, 94
Cash dividends, 479
adv
from Apple Inc., 33
date, 123
discounting
by real interest rate, 143
equivalent annual annuity,
236–238
expected forecasts, 362
forecasting, 387–388
w, not
profits, 264–265
w,
266–270
inv
incremental, 266–269
from investment in w
capital, 268
level, 127–135
vention, 276n
versus net income, 63
from new computer system,
231–232
, 560
v
used in practice, 251
Capital e
Capital e
w, 65
on income statement, 63
w, 64
Capital gain, 193
versus dividends in taxation, 493
Capital gains tax, 70
Capital investment, 271
Capital investment decisions
equity, 456
weighted average cost of
xpected
539–541
forecasting uses of cash, 541
means of producing, 539
Cash conversion cycle, 533–536
return, 386–387
industry differences, 446, 464
L. A. Gear, 523
accounts receivable period, 534
calculating, 535
estimating accounts payable
measuring, 380–381
vable
, 464–465
in mergers, 591
net present value analysis,
228–239
v
x, 248–250
usinesses,
387–389
ventory period, 534
inventory period, 534
net w
production cycle dates, 534
230–231
and payout policy
v
spreadsheet solution, 233
on TIPS, 173
and value of the firm, 446
w analysis
changes in working capital, 276
inv
ed assets,
274–275
w, 275–276
w, 276
w estimates, 291
w forecasts, 295
w for new investments,
63–65
IND-8
Subject Index
w from operations, 63–65
w, 61
Cash management
centralization of, 574
574–575
concentration accounts, 574
,
576–578
reasons for holding cash, 573
Collateral, 411
accounts receiv
547
inv
Collateralized debt obligations,
415
Collection policy
aging schedule, 569–570
definition, 569
factors for, 570
growth stock, 191, 202–205,
358
holders of, in 2010, 406
income stock, 191, 202–205
incremental risks, 332
405
issued but not outstanding, 405
no-growth dividend discount
model, 197
alue,
192–194
Companies; see also
countercyclical, 330
credit scoring for, 563–565
e
vatives use, 673
fair behavior by, 17
liquidation value, 190
573
types of payment systems,
575–578
Cash on deliv , 560
ws, 61, 62, 541
Cash payments
, 127–128
v
Cash ratio, 96–97
, 368, 393
593n
ing, 66
y, 460
L. A. Gear, 532
y, 475
Character
Char
v
statement of account, 570
Collections of accounts receivable,
539–541
Comcast, 592, 703
Comment, R., 487n
see also
48
functions, 40
markets, 186
market value, 189–191
et risk, 346–352
327–329
vestment, 352
net common equity
overv
and o
2010, 42
holdings of equities 2010, 42
number of, 40
Commercial draft, 562
Commercial paper, 36, 401–402,
531
defaults, 549
definition, 548
, 548
in money market, 579
recent problems with, 549
par value, 405
ets, 37–38, 44
Commodity prices, 45
viation of returns,
328
total risk and market risk, 350
et,
et listings,
187–189
risk in mutual funds, 351–352
risks, 320
viation, 334
574
Chevron, 5
Trade, 35,
37, 677
Chicago Board Options Exchange,
645
Common-size income
statement, 60
Common stock, 185
35, 684
Chicago T une Company, 609
, 10
CHIPS; see
ayment System
Chordia, T., 213
593n, 595, 609
staving of
y, 462n
Cisco Systems, 175, 530
Citicorp, 411
Citigroup, 176, 431
Class
ayment
System, 577–578
Closed-end fund, 38n, 696
CME Group, 684
y, 83, 84,
85, 473
bid-ask spread, 187
book value, 189–191
classes of, 407
y cost of capital,
374–375
and conv
definition, 186
dividend yield, 188
e
based on CAPM 382
based on dividend discount
model, 382–383
f
e
323
e
olatility,
330
insolvency, 404
wth rate, 518
investment decisions, 6
inv
investments by, 113
leasing vs. buying, 699
line of credit, 545–546
liquidity choice, 530
loan cov
tw
value stocks, 358
v
v
aluation
case, 332–334
wth dividend
discount model, 197–199
dif
dividend discount model,
et hypothesis,
211–212
paying for investments, 113
payout ratio, 203
plowback ratio, 203
proliferation of bank accounts,
574
reasons for holding cash, 573
203–204
y, 103
Compan
after-tax, 377
et value of
securities, 376–377
calculated as weighted average,
374–377
calculating, 371
and investors, 376
Company values, 46
Compensation plans
for managers, 18–19
ets,
400
Competitive advantage
ets, 400
Competitiveness, 6
combined by merger, 595
Compound growth, 24, 117
continuous, 139
effective annual interest rate,
138–139
Compound interest
growth stocks, 205
et-v
205–206
present v
118–119
IND-9
Subject Index
Concentration accounts, 574
Conditional sales, 562
decision, 563
companies, 175
promised vs. expected yield to
, 177
speculativ
eliminating, 293
463
Conglomerate merger
bootstrap game, 596–597
Consistenc
505
Consolidated balance sheet, 54
Consolidated Edison, 190–191,
206, 329, 346, 348–350,
359, 368, 385, 554
yield on, 142
yield spread vs. T
176
zero-coupon bonds, 177
ays of
changing, 591; see also
Mark
control
and value of shareholders’
equity, 456
weighted average cost of
387
e
interest deductions, 69
rate v
Corporate v
Corporations
agenc
Cost-cutting projects, 271–272
Cost of capital, 31; see also
Compan
Opportunity cost of
capital
of c
usinesses, 362
,
in economic value added,
84–85
ef
excluded from income
assets needed by, 3
xample, 372–373
investment timing
decision, 235
y
Constant-growth dividend discount
model, 383
closely held, 8
def
interest rates, 409
project, 360–361
example, 198
ve covenants, 412
public vs. private placement,
412
repayment provisions, 410
security, 411
required forecasting, 197–198
Consumer credit, 531
Consumer price index, 141–142
subordinated debt, 411
476
s tasks,
10–11
w of savings to, 33–42
goals of
and agency problems,
16–19
v
value maximization, 11–14
,8
means of payout
RJR Nabisco, 412n
, 10
Conversion v
Conv
direct costs, 429
options on, 645
valuation, 661
Conv
Conv
conv
conv
w
es, 66
vidence to
estimate, 322–323
Cost of debt, after-tax, 377
Cost of equity, 371
f
Cost of goods sold, 62
Cost reduction, 392
case, 439–440
conv
Alcoa, 661
conversion value, 661
and taxes, 371
general cash of
open auctions, 430–431
commercial paper
debt ratios, 402
400
32–33
net common equity
net w
no-dividend group, 480
o
payout decisions
cash dividend advantages,
486
in context of dividends and
ws, 485
get dividend, 485
get payout ratio, 485
vately held, 426
403
y
ef
eholders, 462
investor assessment, 459
v
Counterc
Coupon, 160, 509
Coupon rate, 165
ve Cs of, 563
banker’s acceptances, 562
wnership and
callable, 410–411, 661
call provisions, 645
Treasury bonds, 174
conv
def
def
v
v
v
agency costs, 603
see also Fraud
ault, 176
investment grade, 174–175
liquid, 175
prices vs. T
in United States, 25
es
debt adv
implications of decisions, 458
shareholders, 8
stock betas for, 350
stock issues, 185
tax disadvantage, 9
threat of takeover, 612
open account, 562
sight draft, 562
time draft, 562
Credit analysis, 560
wildly dispersed ownership,
603–604
Cost(s)
of general cash offer, 433
of inv
of proxy contests, 603–604
563–565
Z-score model, 565
Credit booms, 698
Credit bureaus, 563n
IND-10
Subject Index
Credit decision
bases of
336
Demand deposits, 531, 573
458–463
Cutof
usinesses, 362
looking beyond immediate
order, 569
y for, 566
with repeat orders, 568
without repeat orders, 566–567
Credit-default swaps, 176,
683–684
, 566
Credit management steps, 560
iciency, 89
Creditors
y costs, 460
preference for liquidation, 477
y
aging schedule, 569–570
collection policy, 569–571
consumer credit, 560
448–450
Deposit insurance, 44n
Depreciation
accelerated, 278
D
Dangerous accounts, 569
Davidson, S. M., 16
DeAngelo, H., 532
DeAngelo, L., 532
Debit cards, 575–576
Debt; see also
verage
book value, 88
collateral for, 411
and cost of equity
explicit cost, 453
60–61
and cash coverage ratio, 94
w, 64
,
estimating, 54
loan covenants, 463
ws, 465–467
as noncash expense, 400n
w, 272
ed-rate, 681, 682
implicit cost, 453
402
increase in, 404
issue costs, 433
in trade-of
w
Depreciation deduction, 272
, 464
wth rate, 518
open account, 562
terms of sale, 560–562
trade credit, 560
Credit rating agencies, 48
return, 450
see also
structure
in calculating company cost of
models, 566
for small businesses, 566
softw
, 566
Credit transfer, 576
Debt-to-v
Decision making
delegated by shareholders,
11–12
for assets with different lives,
237
Debt-equity ratio, 93
for inv
net present v
, 36,
Cumulativ
requirements, 541–543
Cumulative voting, 407
y swaps, 682–683
Declaration date, 481
Default
over
, 549
inv
in junk bond market, 608
gin, 90
accounts receivable, 531
cash, 531–532
components, 96
inv
, 531
liquidity of, 530n
w,
63–64
types of, 559
277–279
Dere
go, 4
vatives, 671
credit-default swaps, 683–684
futures contracts, 676–680
innovations, 683–684
iron ore futures, 684
problems caused by
Debt-equity trade-off, 459,
Debt financing, 7
bonds, 36
68
recovery system, 278
two costs of, 385–386
, 432
Debtholders; see also Bondholders
income vs. shareholders, 92
, 375–376
Debt investors, 7
Debt issues, 401
et; see also Bond
et; Mone
et
asset-back
collateralized debt obligations,
415
Def
Default risk, 102, 159, 411
in money market, 580
Defensive stocks, 346
40n
ution pension
plans, 39
speculation problem, 684
swaps, 681–683
vatives groups, in banks, 21
vativ
et, 37–38
DIAMONDS, 44
Dimon, James, 487
Dimson, Elroy, 319, 320, 321, 324,
325, 327, 328
Direct costs
y, 460
Direct debit, 576
Direct deposit, 577
Direct negotiation for stock
repurchase, 483
Direct payment, 576, 577
Discount basis interest rate
quotes, 579
Discount bonds, 167
price changes, 170
w, 118
by company cost of capital, 360
w, 143
Degree of operating leverage,
v
Debt policy
and net working capital, 96
w,
63–64
in w
es,
Dell Inc., 191, 329, 350, 359,
573, 593, 616, 667
Delphi, 595
263–264
w
vestment, 271
changes in w
273–274
w,
271–273
IND-11
Subject Index
case, 287–288
examples
276
depreciation tax shield,
277–279
orking capital,
277
salvage value, 279
ws, 264–268
spreadsheet solution, 280
w methods,
243
w rate of
return, 242
ws, 263
Discount factors, 119
present value table, A-2
Discounting
w, not profits, 264–265
ws,
266–269
ws, 269–270
ws, 269
Discount rate, 118
w, 143
choosing, 373–374
fudge factors, 362
345
and macro risks, 336
333–334
as reason for merger, 596
to reduce v
, 329–330
et risk,
346
Div
Dividend cuts, 486, 487
Dividend discount model
for common stock valuation,
194–197
constant-growth, 197–199
definition, 194
estimating expected rate of
return, 199–200
e
382–383
inv
194–197
required forecasting, 197–198
y measures
ver ratio, 88
inv
ver, 88–89
receiv
ver, 89–90
Ef
ets, 400,
692–693
Ef
et, 211
Ef
et hypothesis, 693
exceptions to, 696
and inv
211–212
and mark
, 94–95
E
wer, 190
of cyclical businesses, 362
plowback ratio, 203
reinvested, 97
y of, 66
et bubbles,
213–214
212, 213
es,
Dividend reinv
Dividends, 541
es,
, A., 537n
Eight O’Clock Coffee, 593n
691
Eisner, Michael, 604
59, 94
w, 65
verage macro risk,
336
compared to repurchases,
483–484
wth,
203–205
ef
ef
income, 450
impact of merger on, 597
vestment, 479
networks, 186
, 576–578
advantages, 578
, 577–578
w, 192
wildcat oil wells, 335
Div
Ef
get dividend, 485
get payout ratio, 485
vance proposition,
488–491
payout ratio, 203
242–243
for stock’
Div
Dividend policy
advantage of cash dividends,
486
cash di
es, 492, 493
y
low payout policy, 492–493
ws, 485
Microsoft, 491–492
vance proposition,
488–491, 693
in percentage of sales models,
507–508
resolving, 697
stock di
383–384, 408
197–198
stock, 481–482
stock splits, 481
suspended by BP, 486
in U.S. 1980–2008, 480
Dividend yield, 188, 193, 318, 383
ubble, 213, 215,
329, 696
Dow Chemical, 83, 84, 189, 192,
329, 346–350, 359, 385,
Eastern
y, 460
Eastman K
Easy-money policy, 47
eBay, 190, 428
EBIT; see
es
EBITDA; see
es,
depreciation, and
Economic gain from mergers, 600
Economic order quantity, 572
Economics of v
594–595
Economic v
and accounting rates of return,
86–88
ven analysis, 301n
as performance measure, 85
problems with, 87–88
weighted av
377–378
Do
Average, 44
low in 1932, 321
percentage changes, 1900–2010,
328
Dow Jones Wilshire 500 index, 319
Drex
Due lag, 582
w” Al, 66
Economies of scale, gained in
mergers, 594
Economists, disagreements among,
695
Economy
330–332
v
on bank accounts, 139
of bonds, 163n
Eli Lilly, 595
, 18–19, 659
103, 427
y, 460, 477
Equifax, 563n
Equipment
required by law or policy,
292–293
age value, 279
Equity, 425
book value, 88
general cash offer, 432
wth rate, 517
issue costs, 433
holders of, 406
and leverage ratio, 95
Equity investors, 7
Equity issues, 401
ets, 36
Equiv
examples, 237–238
of new equipment, 238
Estée Lauder, 46
European call, 646n
IND-12
EVA; see Economic value added
EVA Dimensions, 82, 88
Excess funds, 559; see also Idle
cash
Subject Index
Federal Deposit Insurance
426, 462
xpansion, 306
hedging, 679
Ex-dividend date, 481
Executive stock options
backdating scandal, 660
calculating, 659
Exercise price, 646–647
Google stock, 648
Expansion option, 305–307, 658
w forecasts,
362
options on
callable bonds, 661
conv
executive stock options,
659
w
v
4–5
386–387
on common stock, 193
based on CAPM, 382
based on dividend discount
model, 382–383
false precision, 383
on common stock 1981, 323
y cost of capital,
359–360
vidend discount model,
199–200
from inv
return, 228
on preferred stock, 383–384
for selected companies, 359
Expenses, tax-deductible, 68–69
Expiration date, 646, 647
Explicit cost of debt, 385–386,
453
161–166
investment decisions, 4, 5
alue, 246
interest rates, 123–124
operation of, 121
present value calculations, 121
xplaining, 698
Federal funds rate, 546n
Federal Reserve System,
415, 699
and Fedwire, 577–578
crisis, 48
tight money policy 1979, 163
Federal Trade Commission
and Blockbuster, 598
and Whole F
et, 599
Fedwire, 577–578
Fernandez, P., 323n
FICO score, 563n
Fidelity, 368
Fidelity Investments, 39
Field warehousing, 548
Finance
careers in, 20–22
agenc
ef
ef
et, 175
and gov
investor fear of default, 698
and mone
origin of, 47
et, 580
responsibility for, 48
385, 480, 592
v
dividend discount model,
194–202
price and intrinsic value,
192–194
Financial leverage
see also Costs of
y, 461–463
and capital investment
strategies, 462
costs of, 672
ets,
692–693
vance propositions,
693
net present value, 692
, 693–694
unsolved problems
463
ef
verage,
460
ef
eholders, 462
investor assessment, 459
Financial environment, 32
et
f
merger waves, 697–698
payout policy, 697
present v
694–695
gro
202–206
technical analysis, 206–210
, 580
f
, 694
e
yield curve, 171–174
, 166–168
common stock
beha
ef
et hypothesis,
211–212
403n
and asset-backed bonds,
, 696
wth rate, 515–518
required, 515–516
ExxonMobil, 82–83, 84, 85, 86,
vestment criteria
bonds
def
annuity present v
2007–2009, 47
on bonds, 382
hedge funds, 39
factors, 547
measuring, 92–95
cash coverage ratio, 94
debt ratio, 93
Financial managers, 3, 6–7, 503
, 10
controller, 10
essential role of, 11
inv
ets, 31
in lar
treasurer, 10
use of shelf re
ets, 31
et, 36
ets, 36
ets, 37
competition in, 400
w of sa
derivatives market, 37–38
694–695
F
Face value, 160
and yield to maturity, 167
Factor
y, 570
F
F
F
F
, Isaac & Company, 563n,
566
., 482n
v
valuing liquidity, 698
Finance companies, 545
Finance.yahoo.com, 187
Financial Accounting
Board, 66
on option v
models, 659
functions
div
payment mechanism, 45
providing liquidity
risk transfer
et, 36
w of sa
foreign e
ets, 37
time, 43
v
32–33
insurance companies, 41
inv
pro
Financial assets, 38
see Hedging
43
, 44–45
IND-13
Subject Index
information provided by
on commodity prices, 45
on company values, 46
mone
et, 36
et, 37–38
over
et, 36
et, 35–36
Financial plan, 503
balancing item, 507–508
depreciation in, 512–513
see also
payout ratio, 97
plowback ratio, 97
Fraud; see also
role of, 101–102
default risk, 102
y, 103
alue added,
80–81
Financial risk
increased by debt, 453
Financial slack
and debt policy
at L.
ve business plans, 504
to av
big-picture focus, 504
case, 525
to establish goals, 504
e
wth,
515–518
long-term focus, 504
528–531
planning horizon, 504
reasons for
contingency planning, 505
forcing consistency, 505
, 505
gic plans, 504
, 532
466–467
v
Financial statements; see also
508–512
pro forma, 506, 507
users of, 53
websites for, 56
Financial system, 33
Financing
y options, 33–35
composition of, 371
by corporations, 3
debt vs. equity, 7
effects of investment decisions
on, 699
of Federal Express, 4–5
508
danger of complexities, 515
and gro
improved model, 508–512
by Home Depot, 60
for investment and growth, 97
vance propositions,
693
WACC 378
and v
Financing decisions, 3
Apple Inc., 32–33
role of, 514–515
cash payments at different
dates, 113
100
case, 110–111
comparisons with past, 100–101
in credit analysis, 563–565
Vegetable Oil
y, 547
and payout policy, 487
priv
separate from investment
decisions, 270
10–11
trade-of
value creation with, 400
v
Fire insurance, 335
Firm commitment, 427
First Call, 201n
compared to investment
decisions, 7, 399
conv
corporate debt, 409–415
First-stage f
Fisher, L., 482n
Five Cs of credit, 563
Fixed assets, 56
on balance sheet, 54
investment in, 274–275
Fixed costs, 295
and operating leverage,
303–305
antages, 303
Fixed-income market, 36
Fixed-income securities, 578–579
Fixed-rate debt, 681, 682
Flexible production facilities, 308
, 580
Float
reducing, 578
Floating interest rates, 36, 409
Floating-rate bonds, 177, 681, 682
F
Forbes, 212
F
y, 6, 330,
332–333, 336, 347, 350,
359, 365, 369, 384n, 385,
399, 402, 413, 480, 481,
548–549, 586, 610
inv
decisions, 5
Forecast bias, resolving, 293–294
Forecasting
ensuring consistency in, 293
at Home Depot ov
leverage ratios, 92–94
w, 387–388
ef
e
by Federal Express, 5
liquidity ratios, 95–97
, 24–25
98, 99
Freddie Mac, 18, 47, 66, 169
w
definition, 65, 387
for Home Depot, 65
managers with, 466
motive for takeover, 595
in v
usinesses,
388–389
eovers, 609
Free credit, v
Frock, Roger, 462n
Fudge factors, 362
cross-border, 68
assumption in percentage of
sales models, 513–514
components
functions, 506
inputs, 506
outputs, 506
consistency between
percentage of sales models,
507–508
pitfalls in design, 512–513
inv
v
uses of cash, 541
Forelle, C., 660
F
Funded debt, 409
Futures, 676
Futures contracts
characteristics, 676–677
commodity futures, 679–680
definition, 676
for iron ore prices, 684
gin account, 676n
gin requirement, 678
et, 678–679
spot price, 679
versus options, 676
real estate, 684
for risk reduction, 676–680
standardized, 680
et
24, 35, 684
New Y
37, 46, 684
ets, 37
requirements for success, 684
Future value
of annuity, 133–135
of annuity due, 137
calculating, 115–116
and compound interest,
114–117
definition, 114
ws, 124–125,
128
in present v
117–118
vings, 135
spreadsheet solution, 122–123
Future value tables, 116, 135, A-2,
A-5
IND-14
G
Gantchev, Nickolay, 429n
Gates, Bill, 131–132, 143–144,
423
Genentech, 426, 592
costs of, 433
seasoned of
and shelf registration,
432–433
319, 598
Generally accepted accounting
Subject Index
balance sheet, 54–57
cash coverage ratio, 94
Growth
from e
515–518
Gro
Gro
internal, 517
sustainable, 518
Growth stocks, 191, 358
determining dividend growth,
203–205
reasons for buying, 202
valuing, 205
Gro
y,
190–191
Gulf oil spill of 2010, 486
H
General Mills, 336
General Motors, 18, 160, 179, 336,
404, 487, 548, 595
cost of capital, 372–373
WACC, 379–380
economic v
y measures, 88–90
f
63–64
w, 65
income statement, 59–60
et capitalization, 81
market value added, 81–82
y, 190
y, 350, 359, 385
ey, C. R., 66, 323n, 465n, 485,
530n
Haushalter, G. D., 673n
Healy, P., 482n, 486, 611
w, 63–64
sustainable growth rate, 97–98
Hone
ger, 592
alue, 388–389
Hostile takeovers, 591
e
poison pills, 605–607
shark repellent, 606
2010, 42
holdings of equities 2010, 42,
406
founding of, 423
204
Gordon, Myron, 198
Gordon growth model, 198
Government, Troubled Asset Relief
Program, 487
Government bonds
amount publicly held, 160
maturity, 168–169
sales of, 159
Gradley
485, 530n
Grand Union, 476
Greenbacks, 24
Greenmail transactions, 483
Greenspan, Alan, 215n
Greenwood, R., 482n
problems with derivatives,
684–685
reasons for, 672–673
gy for, 673
aps, 681–683
v ves, 673
v
, 699
as zero-sum game, 672
Helyar, J., 607n
Hewlett-P
Hickey, Robert, 413
gin
strategy, 91
High-yield bonds, 174–175
Histogram, 324, 325
Historical cost, 57, 190
v
et
accounting, 67
Hollywood Videos, 598
Home Depot, 19, 81, 83, 85, 86,
87–88, 90, 91, 93, 94, 95,
96, 97, 98, 100, 101, 106,
107, 368, 393
Index funds, 43
Inde
y,
460–461
Individual investments, 113
iciencies, eliminated by
mergers, 595–596
base period, 140
and consumer price index, 140
effect on Bill Gates, 143–144
ef
w, 269–270
effect on depreciation, 277
, 671
innov
vatives,
683–684
versus investor choices, 672
recognizing investment in
w
w, 268
Indexed bonds
Revolution,
173n
Households
vulture funds, 39
Hedging
alue, 190
Goldman Sachs, 10, 15, 21, 41,
175, 431
and housing crisis, 16
and SEC, 16
Goodwill, 55
Google Finance, 56
Google Inc., 37, 83, 84, 85, 86, 88,
205, 206, 368, 402, 480,
646, 647–648, 650–651,
656, 657, 666
w, 60–63
pro forma, 508–512
Income stocks, 191
vidend gro
203–205
reasons for buying, 203
ws
allocated overhead costs, 268
forecasting, 266
rates, 172–174
and time value of money
I
IBES, 201n
IBM, 37, 318, 329, 335, 336–337,
350, 359, 385, 480, 593,
602, 616, 667
Idle cash, 574
invested in mone
et,
578–580
Illiquid assets, 95
ImClone Systems, 595
Implicit annual interest rate, 561
Implicit cost of debt, 385–386, 453
Income
subject to personal tax, 69–70
Income statement
real or nominal present value
calculations, 144
ws,
139–141
valuing real cash payments,
143–144
xed debt, 25
and interest rates, 142
in U.S. 1900–2010, 140
Information content of dividends,
486–487
Information value in sensitivity
analysis, 297
Initial public of
Apple Inc., 35–36
Apple IPO and Massachusetts,
427n
xpenditures on, 63
bookb
xcluded, 84
expense items, 59
Home Depot, 69–70
426
direct costs, 429–430
Federal Express, 4, 186
IND-15
Subject Index
information on, 45–46
Google Inc., 204, 423
issue price, 427
Microsoft, 423
et vs. coupon, 164
per period, 561
present v
123–124
ov
prospectus, 427
v
owned, 426
and SEC re
v
v
and market v
Inventories
v
70
vestment management
composition of, 571
costs of holding, 571
vately
Visa, 430
vation
by Apple Inc., 33
in derivativ
et, 683–684
Insolvency, 404, 481n
Installment plan, 126
vestors, 18–19, 42
proxy contests, 604
Insurance companies
174, 269
TED spread, 546
ten-year Treasury bonds,
1900–2009, 164
on trade credit, 561
v
Interest rate sw
Interest tax shield, 85n, 456–457,
609
as v
value of shareholders’ equity,
456
Internal growth rate
2010, 42
holdings of equities in 2010, 42,
406
, 41
, 43
Intangible assets, 3, 6
Internally generated funds, 465
companies relying on, 402
reliance on, 403
Internal rate of return
alue, 307
types of, 559
Inv
e
arehousing, 548
Inv
composition of inventories, 571
, 572
319–322
, 352
, 97
just-in-time systems, 573
and production to order, 573
storage costs, 571
Inventory period
wing, 159
paying for, 113
estimating, 534
Inv
ver
v
gin, 91
relativ
y, 12, 14
Inv
Inv
alue, 190
inv
and economic value added,
537
level divisions, 534n
relative liquidity, 530n
v
and dispersion of possible
outcomes, 324
measures of dispersion,
324–325
vestments
annuities, 128–130
compound interest, 114–117
costs of, 227
vidends, 113
w of, 34
future value, 190
ver ratio, 88–89
245
for long-lived projects, 241–243
v
gies of hedge
v
235, 236
v
425, 426, 530
Interest
versus coupon rate, 165
simple, 114
tax-deductible, 69
Interest coverage, 94
es, 412n
Interest payments, 64n, 509, 541
on before-tax income, 409
f
v
capital, 243
pitfalls
cost of capital, 244
247–248
xclusive projects,
investments by, 41
largest, 41
underwriters, 427, 431
underwriting, 41
Investment decisions, 3; see also
Capital budgeting
xclusive projects
and value maximization,
13–14
vestors, 6–7
464
beha
attitudes tow
inv
215
y laws, 427
verage, 94
decisions, 7
on T
Interest rate quotes, 138
Interest rates
and bond prices, 126
choices without hedging, 672
and company cost of capital,
376
e
v
for choosing between mutually
exclusive projects,
259–260
f, 13–14
, 24–25
new, 503
and compound interest, 114–117
discount basis quotes, 579
discount rate, 118
discount rate, 241, 242
deceiv
differing time horizons,
194–197
div
and payout policy, 487
decisions, 270
Internal Rev
274, 277, 612
408
on gov
Internet, bill payment by, 575–576
effect of dividend change,
,6
w
Investment e
fear of default, 698
in initial public of
IND-16
Subject Index
Investors—Cont.
xuberance, 215, 696
ov
ycles, 209
required return, 371
senior vs. junior, 415
L
valuing liquidity, 698
v
wide choice of securities, 319
w
Iow
ets, 37
IPO; see
ailure, 6
358
Lazard, 41
LBO; see Leveraged buyouts
Lease, 413
Leasing, 699
Lee, Dorothy K., 413
Le
Le
Issue costs, 433
405
Issued but not outstanding stock,
405
J
J. D. Edwards & Company, 605
JCPenney, 83, 84
Jensen, Michael C., 466, 482n,
609n
Jinghua Y 210
Jobs, Steven, 423
Johnson, J., 516, 604n
Johnson, Ross, 607–608, 609
Johnson & Johnson, 83, 84, 189,
190, 191, 192, 350, 359,
385, 425
Jorwar, A. N., 434n
JPMorgan Chase, 40, 47, 175, 176,
431, 580
dividend cut, 486, 487
Junior investors, 415
et
default rates, 608
x
610
eover business, 608
Just-in-time systems, 573
K
Kahn, V. M., 566
Kaplan, S., 609
Kellogg, 336
Keown, A., 210
o’s, 4, 401
K
Nabisco LBO, 607–608,
609–610
Kolasinski, Adam, 357
Kozlo
oods, 592
Liquidation
creditor preference for, 477
L. A. Gear, 530
y, 532
Labor costs, 541
A., 611
y, 460, 477, 549
default by, 580
repo agreements, 67
Lev
ws
alue of annuities,
133–135
valuing annuities, 129–133
v
Leveraged buyouts, 93
case, 616
cash co
gets, 609
607
decline and recov
versus reor
alue, 190, 191
Liquid bonds, 175
Liquidity
adv
of assets, 95
of cash holdings, 574
v
T
698
e
alue of, 698
measures of, 95–97
of mone
et, 579
pro
institutions, 44–45
v
vehicles, 95
Liquidity ratios
cash ratio, 96–97
net w
and incentives, 609
et, 608
management buyouts, 607
private equity, 607
M
Macro risks; see Mark
Madoff, Bernard, 15
Maintenance, 392
Majority voting, 407
e, 32
cost of mer
e-outs, 610
div
leveraged buyouts, 607–610
proxy contests, 603–604
takeovers, 604–607
assets, 96
quick ratio, 96
Litigation
, 609–610
y, 609
, 609
Loss of degree of freedom, 328n
Lotteries, 131
Lowe’s, 19, 83, 100, 106
477
malpractice suits, 10
Live Nation, 703
Loan cov
,
696–697
replacing, 595–596
uyouts
definition, 607
payoff from incentives, 609
adding v
agency problems, 16–19
see also
dishonest, 103
Lock-box system, 574–575
609–610
and stakeholders, 609
es, 608–609
Leverage ratios
cash coverage ratio, 94
debt equity ratio, 93
debt ratio, 93–94
293
ethics of value maximization,
302–303
w, 466
eover, 612
use of WACC, 371
and sustainable growth rate, 98
see also
function, 92
times interest earned ratio, 94
Levi Strauss & Company, 426
Liabilities
on balance sheet, 54–57, 189
et value, 57–58
Lie, E., 660
Life insurance companies, 20
, 8, 10
v
, 465
views of debt policy, 465–467
views on dividends, 485
focus of, 504
xible production
advantage of liquidity,
530–531
total capital requirements,
528–530
f
Margin account, 676n
Marginal tax rates, 70
Mar
Marked to market, 678–679
etable securities, 531
decisions, 527
9–10
venture capitalists, 425
Line of credit, 545–546
Liquid assets, 54, 95–96
212, 213
new issue puzzle, 212–213
repayment pro
T
definition, 81
ved equipment
for selected companies, 84
IND-17
Subject Index
Mark
mechanics of
602–610
agency costs, 603
for selected companies, 189
et value added
w, 598–599
return, 248
260
wnership and
management, 603
e
598–599
, 598
w
et-v
205–206
et vs. coupon rate, 164
o
, 702
et accounting, 67
v
leveraged buyouts, 607–610
proxy contests, 603–604
takeovers, 604–607
Market index, 319
Market order, 186–187
Mark
problems, 413
aul R., 319, 320, 321, 324,
325, 327, 328
e
353–354
Masonite, 609
et line,
355–356
calculating, 353–354
definition, 352
measuring, 382
, 352
et risks, 43, 692
Apple IPO,
427n
Massachusetts Bay Colony, 24
MasterCard, 576
Masulis, Ronald W., 434n, 472
, 548
y market,
578–579
matching, 529–530
, 595
recent, 591, 592
RJR Nabisco, 24–25
sensible motives for
commercial paper, 579
vernment
resources, 595
to create synergies, 593–594
ertical
inte
595–596
takeovers, 604–607
in U.S., 1962–2009, 591, 592
vertical, 592
ynch, 25, 41n, 47, 431,
592
Michaely, R., 485
336
measuring
betas, 346–349
portfolio betas, 350–352
div
see Value
maximization
McCain, John, 37
McConnell, J. J., 596
McDonald’s, 189, 192,
201–202, 329, 350,
359, 385, 524
McGuire, William W., 660
McNichols, Maureen F., 563–565
v
345
spreadsheet solution, 348
et-to-book ratio, 206
e
for selected companies,
191–192
et value, 229
y cost of capital,
376–377
versus book value, 57–59,
189–191
in calculating WACC,
company examples, 46
and debt ratios, 93
, 404
e
sheet, 88
594
Memorex, 476
Merck & Company, 554, 592
Mergers
gulation, 611
wav
case, 616
conglomerate, 593
Daimler
, 593
versus divestitures, 610
dubious reasons for
693, 696
Money; see also Time value of
money
greenbacks, 24
in 17th century America, 24
Money management, 22
Mone
et, 36
191, 329, 350, 359, 385,
437, 445, 446, 480, 530
cash dividend, 491–492
founding of, 423
MidAmerica Energy, 279
Middle-of-the-road policy for
f
w convention,
276n
elson, W. H., 434n
en, Michael, 610
Miller
696, 702
541
Minuit, Peter, 116, 117
Mitchell, M., 611n
v
450
MM di
vance
proposition
def
definition, 578
578–579
interest rates, 579
liquidity of, 579
recent mark
repurchase agreements, 579
T
yields, 580
Moody’s Inv
174, 411, 413, 563, 579
Moore, Gordon, 117
Mor
y, 10, 21
A. D., 16
alue analysis,
132–133
Motorola, 604
Mullins, D. W., 434n
ws
future value, 124–125
present v
spreadsheet solution, 128
analysis, 565
260
, T., 573n
closed end, 38n, 696
consistently successful, 212
versus exchange traded
funds, 44
functions, 38–39
holders of corporate bonds in
2010, 42
description, 488–490
MM proposition I, 693
cost of equity, 452
div
evaluation of
and v
406
impact of merger on, 597
alue, 696
w
e
aves of, 697–698
v
LBOs, 607–610
system, 278
number of, 39
open end, 38n
IND-18
Subject Index
Mutually exclusive projects,
to choose between two projects,
234
O
calls and puts, 646–649
on convertible bonds, 645
ferent outlays, 246
,
vs. payback rule, 239
liabilities, 66–67
259–260
Myers, S. C., 387n, 434n, 458n
value of, 692
valuing long-lived projects,
230–234
Net w
see also W
capital
entries
N
Najluf, N. S., 434n
NASDAQ, 35, 36, 186
number of stocks traded, 319
NASDAQ Composite Index, 696
NASDAQ 100 index, 44
NASDAQ stock index, rise and
decline of, 213
Dealers Automated
Quotation system, 186n
, 703
v
Negativ
Net asset value, 38n
Net income
v
function of sales, 513–514
Net w
New issue puzzle, 212–213
Newmont Mining, 329, 332–333,
350, 351, 359, 365, 385
New products
development of, 6
effect on existing products, 266
investment in, 293
Ne
New York Mercantile Exchange,
37, 45, 684
New York Stock Exchange, 8–9,
11, 36, 185, 186
changes since 2007, 35
w, 63
Net present v
break-even point, 300
examples, 228–229
to measure w
negative, 265
negative in accounting
break-even analysis, 300
new computer system, 232
of
229
x, 248
vestment
e
Net present v
ven
Net present v
and IRR, 242–243
Net present v
olume, 620
New York Stock Exchange
Composite Index, 206–207
New York Stock Exchange stocks,
357
No-di
No-growth dividend discount
model, 197
No-gro
, 197
ws, 139–141,
269–270
Nominal cost of capital, 269–270
Nominal dollars, 141
Nominal interest rate, 141–142,
172–174, 269
Nonconstant growth stocks
estimating McDonald’s v
201–202
inv
v
value of di
Nondiversifiable risks, 692
Non-profit organizations
to choose among projects
inv
235–236
ved
equipment, 236–238
replacement of old
equipment, 238–29
NPV; see Net present v
One-at-a-time sensitivity analysis,
297
Open account, 562
entries
, 563–565
ve Cs of credit, 563
Z-score model, 565
versus payoff from holding
stock, 652
protective put, 650
, 651
on real assets, 657–658
Open-end fund, 38n
Open-mark
w, 275–276
of cost-cutting projects,
271–272
dealing with depreciation, 272
example, 273
forecasting, 387–388
Operating income
after-tax, 85
calculating, 87
ef
uyouts, 609
for risk reduction, 674–675
et, 37–38
, 693–694
xpand, 305–306, 658
aluation models
Black-Scholes model, 655, 657,
659
simple model, 656
Option values
verage, 303–305, 451n
and project risk, 361
gin, 90
Operating risk
models for, 655–657
upper and lower limits, 652
659
effect of debt, 450–451
in accounting break-even
of holding cash, 573
692; see also Cost of
ws,
263
ef
estimating, 263
versus internal rate of return,
243
and project risk, 317
445, 459
Option(s)
406
convertible bonds, 659–661
ex
ve stock options, 659
w
505
to expand
decision tree, 306
e
Option
Option premium, 646, 648
Options
annual volume, 645
backdating scandal, 660
gression,
349n
Outputs of f
Outside directors, 407
Outsourcing vs. v
integration, 595
Ov
Overhead costs, 268
Ov
Over
et, 36
Overv
P
P
P
Page, P
, 423
P
Palm, 611
Pandora, Inc., 438
Partch, M. M., 434n
P
definition, 9
types of, 9–10
,9
P
alue
of bonds, 160
Paulson, John, 39n
IND-19
Subject Index
P
holdings of equities in 2010,
42, 406
y
discounted, 239
Positive-NPV projects, 694–695
plausibility, 294
P
adv
, 240
cutof
definition, 239
length of payback periods,
239–240
problems with, 239
reasons for using, 240
Pay lag, 582
Payment date, 481
Payment mechanism, 45
Payment systems
checks, 574–575
,
576–578
United States, 576
Payoff
on hedging instruments, 671
on options, 649, 650–561
Payof
Payout policy, 479
and capital budgeting, 487
case, 499–500
controversy
assumptions behind MM
ef
MM di
not taxed, 70
Pension plans
assets in 2010, 40
it, 39n, 40n
ution, 39
Pensions, 413
ge Projects, 234
PeopleSoft, 605–607
PepsiCo, 189, 192, 473, 599
Percentage of sales models
assumptions in, 513–514
Postpetition creditors, 477
its, 413
Po
, 131, 137
Po
ets, 37
191–192
no-growth, 197
vidends as, 378
present value, 198
v
w
v
455–456
actor, 119
effect of interest rates, 165
e
decisions on, 485–487
average rate, 70
high vs. low
implication of tax rates, 493
vestment decisions, 487
ws, 485
on dividend income, 70
121
Petersen, M. A., 571n
cash dividends, 480–481
stock di
385, 473, 592, 667
gers,
stock splits, 482
v
w, 490–491
reasons for dividend value
reasons for dividend value
increase, 491–492
Payout ratio, 97
definition, 203
595
erton, J., 210
owitz, L., 530–531
ood, 476
and future value, 117–118
in future value of annuity, 134
as intrinsic value, 192
investment timing decision, 235
ws, 126–127,
128
new computer system, 232
Plowback ratio, 97, 518
alue), 160
Principles-based accounting, 68
Priv
Privately owned businesses, 426
Private placement, 412
adv
and Rule 144a (SED), 434
Probabilities, beliefs about, 215
, 215
Procter & Gamble, 204
debt issue, 414
ycle, 534
, 573
Product life cycle, 98
ve
advantages in, 400
Products, sales of new vs. e
266
v
w, 60–63,
264–265
determining factors, 190
economic value added, 84
expected, 567
of perpetuities, 127–128, 198
Ponzi scheme, 15
Portfolio betas, 350–352
e
macro risks, 336
Portfolios
div
performance of, 320–322
2010, 42
Prime rate, 509
Plug; see
Poison pill, 605–607
Tea, 586
Pension funds
def
et, 35–36
61–62
, 79
structure
definition, 465
e
inancing, 465
and company prospects, 205
and mergers, 597
dividends, 408
expected rate of return, 383–384
Present value
, 129–130, 136–137
calculating, 117–123
w, 264
, 236
Permanent w
requirement, 530n
T
of gasoline, 141
conv
lack of v
vileges, 408
and net worth, 407
tax advantage, 408
complications, 513–514
Price(s)
of assets, 692
650
spreadsheet solution, 122–123,
233
126–127
of Treasury bonds, 162, 163
using compound interest, 118
Present value of growth
et-v
206
Present value tables, 119, A-3, A-4
Present value tax shield, 455
x, 228, 248–250
with capital rationing, 249
pitfalls, 249
positive net present value, 248
inv
receiv
ver ratio, 88
ver, 88–89
ver, 89–90
, 87
IND-20
gin, 90
versus inv
ver, 91
low vs. high, 90–91
for selected industries, 92
Pro forma balance sheet, 507, 508
Pro forma income statement, 507
Pro formas, 506
second-stage, 509–510
Project analysis
break-even analysis
accounting, 298–300
net present value, 300–303
verage, 303–305
case, 315
inv
ve
advantage, 294
capital budget, 292
consistent forecasts, 293
interest, 293
Subject Index
and capital budgeting,
359–362
v
359–360
and company cost of capital,
359–360
contemplating
v
335
336
,
361–362
operating leverage, 361
Q
QQQs, 44
QUBES, 44
Quick ratio, 96
xible production facilities,
308
option to abandon, 307, 658
option to expand, 305–307,
658
R
timing, 307–308
Real rate of return, 318
693
577n
Rates of return, 14; see also
and div
322–323
for bonds, 168–171
calculated for bonds, 166–168
in capital mark
,
319–322
333–334
ault, 463
with debt-equity mix, 375–376
Receiv
ver ratio, 89–90
Recession, 330–332
Recession of 2007–2009, 48
Record date, 481
Re
Regression line, 349n
Regular dividends, 480
Re
362
estimating, 322–323
estimating cost of capital from
, 322–323
Ford Motor Company, 365
Geothermal e
government bonds, 1900–2010,
321
histogram, 324, 325
calculating v
viation, 324–327
v
v
327–329
sensitivity analysis, 295–297
w, 271–273
age value, 279
spreadsheet solution, 280
with zero net present v
Real estate bubble, 213
Real estate futures, 684
Real interest rate, 142, 172–174,
269
Real options
Alleghen
Receivables, 89
aging schedule, 569–570
xible production facilities,
308
option to abandon, 307
option to e
timing, 307–308
277–279
and financing, 270
forecasting w
identifying, 264–268
allocated overhead costs, 268
ws,
266–268
w, 268
y vs. safe, 694–695
ws, 139–141
selling, 647–649
Puttable bonds, 661
, 208–209,
329–330
273–274
protective put, 650
Rajan, R. G., 571n
Rajgopel, S., 66
292–293
reducing forecast bias,
293–294
capacity expansion, 293
maintenance cost reduction, 293
new product investments, 293
outlays required, 292–293
Project betas, 694–695
ws, 263
alue,
276
capital investment, 271
w analysis, 274–276
Real assets, 38
Project cost of capital
estimating, 360–361
et line, 361
e
Ne
Reinsurance, 43n
Reinvestment, 33
Relaxed approach to f
529, 530
Rent, contingent, 303
Reorganization
v
procedures, 475–476
Repayment pro
Replacement problem, 235,
238–239
Repurchase agreements
ve covenants
in mone
47
percentage return, 318
real, 318
ve put, 650
costs of, 603–604
et, 579
transactions, 15
Required e
515–516
capital, 240–241
et risk, 345
at PeopleSoft, 606
T
T
y Accounting
Residual income, 84, 537
323–323
Ov
T
v
Walt Disney Company, 365
v
,
167–169
, 651
ve f
, 595
y, 529
Ra
payof
and operating income, 450
IND-21
Subject Index
Sa
derivatives, 673
evidence on, 673
with forw
vings, 135
xpected, 358
e
with futures contracts, 676–680
innovations in derivatives,
683–684
on T
vatives,
reasons for hedging, 672–673
with sw
value of tools for, 699
at Home Depot, 87
Home Depot vs. Lowe’s,
100–101
gin, 90
for selected industries, 92
and beta, 353–354
297–298
Schiller
Scholes, Myron, 655, 694, 702
Schref
Schw
Schwed, Fred, 702
Sealed
direct costs, 429
et, 36
net present value, 296
one-at-a-time, 297
for project analysis, 295–296
wns, 296
v
v
wnership and
control
y problems, 16–19
and agency theory, 694
downside of, 9
and agency theory, 694
y, 477
versus bondholders, 463
x,
fering, 426
357n
for Home Depot, 85–86
et line, 356
, 517, 518
see also Risk
management
verage, 94–95
for Home Depot, 87
for software firms, 98
Revenue recognition, 66
Revenues, examples of, 5
Rhie, Jung-Wu, 563–565
y, 660
Rieker, M., 487
Rights issue, 431n, 432
Risk(s)
w
div
hedging, 671
market, 692
mark
measurable, 336–337
of New York Stock Exchange
stocks, 334
verage, 305
alue, 229
selection of, 671
of v
CAPM, 354–359, 692, 695
wing on,
investments, 352
et line, 355–356
Risk-averse, 12
Risk-free rate, 354
measuring, 382
Risk-free return on T
353
Second-stage pro formas, 509–510
Secured debt, 411
Secured loans
accounts receiv
547
cost of mergers to, 600–601
dele
11–12
dividend reinvestment plan,
479
verage, 451
versus speculation, 684
, 43–44
, Jay, 212n, 428n, 429n
hazards of, 548
inv
Securities, 7; see also Bonds;
, 36
607–608, 609–610, 612
Road shows, 427
Rockefeller, John D., 702
21
Roll, R., 482n
Ruback, R., 611
Rules-based accounting, 68
ed-income, 578–579
ed, 47
priv
relativ
shelf registration, 433
at true value, 400
v
iculties, 214
wide choice for investors, 319
Securities and Exchange
S
Safeway, 593
Sales
conditional, 562
credit agreements, 562
of new vs. e
266
on open accounts, 562
Sales-to-assets ratio, 88
Sales volume, 298
break-even, 299
break-even point, 300
Salvage value, 274, 279
Sarbanes-Oxley Act, 18, 103, 427,
610
urden of, 68
Savings
capital, 373–374
and ethics of value
income vs. debtholders, 92
inv
81–83
ge number of, 9
no-growth stock, 197
o
605–606
proxy contests, 603–604
, 375–376
, 87
verse, 12
654
on private placement, 434
and proxy access, 604
re
Rule 144a, 434
et line
and project acceptance, 361
Security prices, 692–693
Self-liquidating loans, 546
Selling, Thomas I., 92
y, 211,
693
Senior investors, 415
Sensiti
pooled in hedge funds, 39
vidends, 481–482
v
11–14
voting procedures
ve
voting, 407
proxy contests, 407
Shareholders’ equity
on balance sheet, 55–56
book vs. market value, 58
created at Home Depot, 86
vestment decisions, 80–81
maximizing, 79
ed costs, 295
William F., 345, 702
IND-22
Subject Index
Shelf registration
advantages, 433
v
, L., 213
Short sellers, 39
Spin-offs, 610
by 3Com, 611
Staunton, Mike, 320, 321, 324,
325, 327, 328
w
y, 84, 537
y A., 593n
Stew
y, Clyde P., 92
Stock, 7; see also Common stock;
Spread, 160, 176, 427
Spreadsheets
annuity present v
model, 657
bond valuation, 170–171
cash budget, 540
case, 556–557
cash budgeting, 539–543
decisions, 527
future value calculation,
122–123
ws, 128
time horizons, 528
528–530
commercial paper, 548–549
tracing changes in cash and
w
w
line of credit, 545–546
sources
commercial paper, 548–549
re
secured loans, 547–548
ev
e
present v
122–123
present v
542–544
Squared deviations, 326
effect of financial distress, 462
in LBOs, 609
relation to companies, 17–18
s, 174–175,
329, 411, 563, 579
s
Composite/500 Index,
viation, 334
calculating, 326
Consolidated Edison, 346
103, 413–414
, 601–602
Stock di
Stock exchanges
electronic communications
networks, 186
limit order book, 187
NASDAQ, 186
New York Stock Exchange, 186
number of stocks traded, 319
see also
entries
Stock market, 31
consolidation, 33
crash of 1929, 24, 329
crash of 2007–2009, 24, 322
decline in 2002, 322
decline in 2008, 14
336–337
viation of returns, 328
ucks, 18, 330, 350, 359, 385
b
capital requirements, 423
Federal Express, 4
211–212
as equity market, 36
functions, 35–36
venture capital for
State laws
ws, 427
di
Statement of account, 570
w
puzzle, 212, 213
new issue puzzle, 212–213
and market risk, 43
, 186
et, 35–36
reaction to stock issues,
, 186
et, 36
v
345
ve bubbles, 696, 698
Speculative grade bonds, 174–175
Spinning, 431
211–212
ex-dividend, 481
w, 65
of Home Depot, 63–64
items on, 63–65
Statement of shareholders’ equity,
54n
Google Inc., 423
Home Depot, 81
alue, 192–194
liquidation value, 190
Microsoft, 423
aluation models,
655–657
ov
par value, 405
and put options, 647
random w
reactions to news, 210
wing, 185
in selling calls or puts, 647–649
speculative bubbles, 696
trading range, 482n
alue of call option,
652–653
yardstick for performance, 426
Stock repurchase, 405
by Apple Inc., 33
vidends,
483–484
e
mark
Soft rationing, 249
Sole proprietorships, 9
, 21
Special dividends, 480
Specialist in stock trading, 186
y values, 46
ws, 611
w issues, 433–434
et value, 42n
Dow Chemical, 346
, Douglas, 485n
Small Business
475n
Small b
566
ge-firm stocks,
358
bid-ask spread, 187
et value, 189–191
et, 186
eholders
s Depository
Simple interest, 114
Simulation analysis, 297–298
defensive, 346
ex
factors af
measuring v
327–329
mergers f
464
vioral f
ws, 233
351–352
versus cash, 573
Sidel, R., 487
aggressive, 346
amount traded in e
319
fect, 486
Apple Inc., 423
v
Stock market bubbles, 213–214
Stock market listings, 187–189
Stock options, 426, 660
means of
auction, 483
gotiation, 483
greenmail transactions, 483
open-market repurchase,
482–483
tender offer, 483
aluation, 484
in U.S. 1980–2008, 480
Stock splits, 482
Storage costs, 571
275–276
udgeting, 504
IND-23
Subject Index
Strategy matched with capital
budget, 292
ws, 124
Taxation
adv
T
Treasurer, 10
T
of investors, 194–197
504
e,
171–172
yield in May 2010, 172
iciency, 211, 693
Structured investment v
Stuyvesant, Peter, 24
Subordinated debt, 411
et, 698
depreciation deduction, 272
depreciation tax shield,
277–279
disadvantage for
415
Time line for future value, 125
T
Time value of money
annuity due, 136–137
effective annual interest rate,
138–139
future value of annuity, 133–135
future values, 114–117
disadv
wing,
458
vidend policy, 492, 493
et accounting, 67
least risky investment, 352
in mone
et, 579
320–322
safety of, 320
standard de
328
T
auction in 2003, 160
auction sales, 431
and interest rates, 141–142
174
Sunk costs, ignoring, 266–267
on individual income, 70
Sun Microsystems, 480
ger as use for,
595
wth rate, 203–204,
518
calculating, 97
variability in, 98
Swaps
credit-def
y swaps, 682–683
144
interest rates, 161–166
ws,
139–141
320–322
v
vidends,
408
ACC, 377
Tax payments, 541
Tax rates
T
personal taxes, 70
see also
143–144
ws, 127–135
ws, 124–126,
128
present values, 114–124
Time W
, Inc., 175, 610
T
TIPS; see T
lev
maturity, 168–169
real interest rate, 172–173
standard de
328
trading of, 126
, 167
Total capitalization, 84
T
interest rate swaps, 681–682
Synergies
elusive, 594
mergers to create, 593–594
T
Takeovers, 19
case, 616
612
, 609
Oracle and PeopleSoft,
605–607
poison pills, 605–607
by proxy contests, 603–604
shark repellent, 606
tender offer, 604
unsuccessful, 604
Tangible assets, 3, 6
on balance sheet, 54
easy to sell, 307
hea
v
inv
Tar
vidend, 485
Tar
Target Stores, 536, 624
Taxable income, 70
toxic mortgage-backed
T
T
TED spread, 546
T
, 483, 604
10K reports, 54
10Q reports, 54
T
w vs. incremental
w, 268
T
alue, 201
T
T
cash before deliv , 560
cash on delivery, 560
credit sales, 560–561
due lag, 582
Total capital requirements
vel of
advantages of liquidity, 530
529–530
permanent working capital
requirement, 530
seasonal v
T
T
w, 276
on bonds, 167
yield to maturity as measure
of, 168
T
et risk, 350
T
Trade credit, 531
credit scoring for, 563–565
561
pay lag, 582
Trade-off theory of capital
trade credit interest rates, 561
Tesla Motors, 440n
Te
, R. H., 611
3 Com, 611
Tick
, 703
T an
y, 536
Tight money policy, 163
Time deposits, 531
T
Trading range, 482n
Transaction costs, 573
T
ef
effect on income statement,
62–63
T
y, 103
T
T
World
A), 476
T
T
T
Tropicana, 609
Troubled Asset Relief Program,
487
T
alue, 400
T
inancial transactions, 15
T
ws, 138n
T
U
disadvantage, 428
and inv
reasons for
Underwriters
best ef
,
433
gest in U.S., 431
road shows, 427
, 431
spinning by, 431
w
, 659
IND-24
Subject Index
acific, 6, 13–14
dividend dates, 481
dividend reinv
inv
decisions, 5
V
697
components, 93
destroying, 79
dividends/stock repurchase
1980–2008, 480
dot-com bubble, 213
impact of payout decisions,
489
and liquidation value, 190
market capitalization, 81–84
market-to-book ratio, 83
et vs. asset values,
696–697
mergers 1962–2009, 591, 592
payment systems, 576
ubble, 213
v
,9
Unocal, 599
US Airways Group Inc., 8n
U.S. Robotics, 611
V
VA Linux, 431
V
191–192, 202
V
V
see also
alue
xpiration, 646
400
of entire businesses, 387–389
of no-growth stock, 197
of put option at e
of real cash payments,
143–144
Value added
Value stocks, 358
V
V
x, 43
V
x fund, 354
V
xT
V
T
et
index, 44
V
V
linked to sales, 303
and operating leverage,
303–305
V
in sensitivity analysis, 297
Wall Street Journal, 160, 185, 199,
202, 204, 660
et listings, 187
W
W
W
192, 329, 350, 359, 385,
456, 480, 573, 624
inv
decisions, 5
W
gy, 91
Walt Disney Company, 329,
350, 359, 365, 385, 604,
703
W
Washington Mutual, 404
W
iciency, 211, 693
Webb, Susan, 21
Weighted average cost of capital,
84n, 85n, 373–380
accuracy of, 379–380
e
function of, 294
sensiti
295–297
Whole F
et, 599
Wick
Wildcat oil wells, 335
W
ets, 599
Wilhelm, W. J., Jr., 16
Williams Act of 1968, 605n
Williamson, R., 530–531
Wilshire 5000 Market Index,
211
Window dressing, 67
Wind power project, 279
Winner’s curse, 428
W
, 577–578
W
additional investment in,
268
version cycle,
533–536
382
273–274
e
stock, 382–383
components
changing with cycle of
operations, 533–534
e
stock, 383–384
, 384
using market value,
380–381
y cost of
capital, 374–377
case, 394–396
y,
forecasting, 277
530n
recognizing inv
267–268
tracing changes in, 537–539
V
calculating, 327
Dow Chemical, 377–378
Ford Motor Company, 384n
V
and business plan, 424
Geothermal Corporation,
379–380
V
425–426
V
V
504, 505
gration
V
es, 385–386
corporate taxes, 387
ef
386–387
W
536
accounts receivable credit
policy, 560–571
case, 588
cash management, 573–578
inv
571–573
inv
et, 578–580
W
f
managerial use of, 371
V
V
vestment Survey, 98n
ethics of, 14–16
goal of shareholders, 11–14
and investment trade-off, 13–14
agency problems, 16–19
vestment
v
V
V
ger, 592
Vlasic, Bill, 593n
Voting procedures
with common stock, 407
408
V
18–19
le
gulatory requirements,
18
W
380–381
multiple sources of capital,
378
y, 384
for selected companies, 385
and taxes, 377–378
valuing entire businesses,
387–389
Weiss, L. A., 460n
Wells-Fargo, 586, 592, 703
Wendy’
in, 536–537
Workout, 475
WorldCom, 18, 67, 175, 427
W
ven, 423
Wurgler, J., 482n
Wyeth, 592
W
X
WACC; see Weighted average cost
eholders, 17–18
takeovers, 19
udgeting,
Wachovia, 25, 592, 703
295
83, 84
XTO Energy, 592
IND-25
Subject Index
Y
Y
Y
Yield
on corporate bonds, 142, 175
on mone
et investments
corporate vs. gov
securities, 580
default risk, 580
et turmoil, 580
Z
on TIPS in 2010, 173
Yield curve
168
172–174
upw
Yield spread, Treasury vs.
corporate bonds, 175–176
Y
, 160, 161
168
promised vs. expected, 177
v
168–169
selected corporate bonds, 175
for T
Zack’s, 201n
Zero-coupon bond, 120n, 177
Zero net present value, 242, 247
ws, 380
Zero-stage investment, 424
Zero-sum game, hedging as, 672
Zhao Quanshui, 429n
Ziemba, W. T., 213
Z-score model, 565
Download