Strategy T. Kretschmer MN3119 2018 Undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences This subject guide is for a 300 course offered as part of the University of London undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences. This is equivalent to Level 6 within the Framework for Higher Education Qualifications in England, Wales and Northern Ireland (FHEQ). For more information about the University of London, see: london.ac.uk This guide was prepared for the University of London by: T. Kretschmer, Professor of Business Studies, Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität, Munich, Germany. Acknowledgements The author would like to thank Brooke Russell for her excellent assistance on the first edition of the guide and especially her help with the extended activities. Thorsten Grohsjean, Christina Finsterwalder and Sanja Rikanovic were very helpful in the revision of this guide, in particular in putting together the guide to the in-chapter activities and the sample examination questions. This is one of a series of subject guides published by the University. We regret that due to pressure of work the author is unable to enter into any correspondence relating to, or arising from, the guide. If you have any comments on this subject guide, favourable or unfavourable, please use the form at the back of this guide. University of London Publications Office Stewart House 32 Russell Square London WC1B 5DN United Kingdom www.london.ac.uk Published by: University of London © University of London 2013. Reprinted with minor revsions 2018. The University of London asserts copyright over all material in this subject guide except where otherwise indicated. All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced in any form, or by any means, without permission in writing from the publisher. We make every effort to respect copyright. If you think we have inadvertently used your copyright material, please let us know. Contents Contents Chapter 1: Introduction........................................................................................... 1 1.1 Introduction to the subject........................................................................................ 1 1.2 Aims of this course................................................................................................... 1 1.3 Learning outcomes................................................................................................... 1 1.4 The structure of the course........................................................................................ 1 1.5 Use of the guide and hours of study.......................................................................... 2 1.6 Essential reading...................................................................................................... 2 1.7 Further reading......................................................................................................... 3 1.8 Online study resources.............................................................................................. 5 1.9 The examination and examination advice.................................................................. 6 1.10 The syllabus............................................................................................................ 7 Chapter 2: The evolution of strategic management as an interdisciplinary field...... 9 Learning outcomes......................................................................................................... 9 Essential reading............................................................................................................ 9 2.1 Introduction............................................................................................................. 9 2.2 Early theories .......................................................................................................... 9 2.3 Michael Porter and the industrial organisation paradigm......................................... 10 2.4 Organisational economics....................................................................................... 10 2.5 Resource-based view, dynamic capabilities and leadership theory............................ 11 2.6 A consensus definition of the field........................................................................... 11 2.7 Key concepts ......................................................................................................... 12 2.8 A reminder of your learning outcomes..................................................................... 12 Chapter 3: Analysis of market structure................................................................ 13 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 13 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 13 Further reading............................................................................................................. 13 3.1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 13 3.2 Techniques of market definition............................................................................... 13 3.3 Market analysis with many firms............................................................................. 16 3.4 Key concepts.......................................................................................................... 18 3.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes..................................................................... 18 3.6 Sample examination questions................................................................................ 18 3.7 Extended activity: the commercial banking industry in the United States.................. 19 Chapter 4: Introduction to game theory and strategy.......................................... 21 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 21 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 21 Further reading............................................................................................................. 21 4.1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 21 4.2 Static games........................................................................................................... 22 4.3 Dynamic games...................................................................................................... 27 4.4 Key concepts.......................................................................................................... 30 4.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes..................................................................... 30 4.6 Sample examination questions................................................................................ 30 i MN3119 Strategy Chapter 5: Oligopolistic models of competition................................................... 33 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 33 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 33 Further reading............................................................................................................. 33 5.1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 33 5.2 Preliminaries.......................................................................................................... 34 5.3 Bertrand competition.............................................................................................. 34 5.4 Cournot competition............................................................................................... 35 5.5 Comparing Bertrand and Cournot........................................................................... 36 5.6 Stackelberg leadership............................................................................................ 37 5.7 Product differentiation............................................................................................ 38 5.8 Key concepts.......................................................................................................... 39 5.9 A reminder of your learning outcomes..................................................................... 39 5.10 Sample examination questions.............................................................................. 39 Extended activity: articles on Airbus-Boeing competition................................................ 40 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm................................................... 41 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 41 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 41 Further reading............................................................................................................. 41 6.1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 41 6.2 Competitive advantages and resources................................................................... 42 6.3 Some examples of resources as sources of competitive advantage........................... 43 6.4 The dynamics of resource and capability building..................................................... 46 6.5 Key concepts.......................................................................................................... 47 6.6 A reminder of your learning outcomes..................................................................... 48 6.7 Sample examination questions................................................................................ 48 6.7 Extended activity: Dell Computer Corporation ......................................................... 48 Chapter 7: Strategic asymmetries – persistent dominance over time.................. 69 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 69 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 69 Further reading............................................................................................................. 69 7.1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 69 7.2 Firm asymmetries – long- or short-term?................................................................. 69 7.3 Traditional sources of persistent dominance............................................................. 71 7.4 Dynamic capabilities............................................................................................... 75 7.5 Key concepts.......................................................................................................... 76 7.6 A reminder of your learning outcomes..................................................................... 76 7.7 Sample examination questions................................................................................ 76 Extended activity: competition in the wide-body aircraft market..................................... 76 Chapter 8: Organisation design............................................................................. 77 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 77 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 77 Further reading............................................................................................................. 77 8.1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 77 8.2 Strategy and structure............................................................................................ 77 8.3 Organisation design and competitive advantage..................................................... 83 8.4 Key concepts.......................................................................................................... 83 8.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes..................................................................... 83 8.6 Sample examination questions................................................................................ 84 ii Contents Chapter 9: Value chain analysis: vertical relations................................................ 85 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 85 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 85 Further reading............................................................................................................. 85 9.1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 85 9.2 Double marginalisation........................................................................................... 85 9.3 Vertical foreclosure................................................................................................. 88 9.4 Key concepts.......................................................................................................... 89 9.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes..................................................................... 90 9.5 Sample examination questions................................................................................ 90 9.6 Extended activity: outsourcing at Eriksson and Sony and Loews............................... 90 Chapter 10: Vertical integration and transaction cost.......................................... 91 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 91 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 91 Further reading............................................................................................................. 91 10.1 Introduction......................................................................................................... 91 10.2 Purchasing versus production costs....................................................................... 91 10.3 Coordination costs............................................................................................... 92 10.4 Proprietary knowledge.......................................................................................... 93 10.5 Transaction costs.................................................................................................. 94 10.6 Asset specificity.................................................................................................... 95 10.7 Alternatives to ‘make’ or ‘buy’............................................................................... 96 10.8 Key concepts........................................................................................................ 97 10.9 A reminder of your learning outcomes................................................................... 97 10.10 Questions for discussion..................................................................................... 97 Extended activity: athenahealth.................................................................................... 97 Chapter 11: Collusion.......................................................................................... 103 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 103 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 103 Further reading........................................................................................................... 103 11.1 Introduction....................................................................................................... 103 11.2 Stability of cooperation....................................................................................... 103 11.3 Extending the model........................................................................................... 105 11.4 Key concepts...................................................................................................... 107 11.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes................................................................. 107 11.6 Sample examination questions............................................................................ 107 Extended activity: the DeBeers diamond cartel............................................................ 107 Chapter 12: Strategic partnerships..................................................................... 115 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 115 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 115 Further reading........................................................................................................... 115 12.1 Introduction....................................................................................................... 115 12.2 Building capabilities........................................................................................... 115 12.3 Business and strategic partnerships..................................................................... 116 12.4 Equity ownership................................................................................................ 118 12.5 Key concepts...................................................................................................... 120 12.6 A reminder of your learning outcomes................................................................. 120 12.7 Sample examination questions............................................................................ 120 Extended activity: the EU aviation industry.................................................................. 120 iii MN3119 Strategy Chapter 13: Competitive dynamics..................................................................... 123 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 123 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 123 Further reading........................................................................................................... 123 13.1 Introduction....................................................................................................... 123 13.2 A framework to analyse competitive dynamics..................................................... 124 13.3 Key concepts...................................................................................................... 127 13.4 A reminder of your learning outcomes................................................................. 127 13.5 Sample examination questions............................................................................ 127 Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence.............................................................. 129 Learning outcome....................................................................................................... 129 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 129 Further reading........................................................................................................... 129 14.1 Introduction....................................................................................................... 129 14.2 Structural entry barriers...................................................................................... 130 14.3 Strategic entry barriers........................................................................................ 132 14.4 Summary............................................................................................................ 136 14.5 Key concepts...................................................................................................... 136 14.6 A reminder of your learning outcome.................................................................. 137 14.7 Sample examination questions............................................................................ 137 Extended activity: Dubai flowers and internet banking................................................. 137 Chapter 15: Research and development competition......................................... 143 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 143 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 143 Further reading........................................................................................................... 143 15.1 Introduction....................................................................................................... 143 15.2 Terminology........................................................................................................ 143 15.3 Innovation and market structure......................................................................... 146 15.4 Strategic issues in R&D....................................................................................... 151 15.5 Some further thoughts on R&D........................................................................... 155 15.6 Key concepts...................................................................................................... 156 15.7 A reminder of your learning outcomes................................................................. 156 15.8 Sample examination questions............................................................................ 157 Extended activity: discovering DNA............................................................................. 158 Chapter 16: Technology adoption........................................................................ 169 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 169 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 169 Further reading........................................................................................................... 169 16.1 Introduction....................................................................................................... 169 16.2 Adoption dependence......................................................................................... 169 16.3 Strategic technology adoption – option value...................................................... 170 16.4 Technology diffusion models............................................................................... 172 16.5 Key concepts...................................................................................................... 176 16.6 A reminder of your learning outcomes................................................................. 176 16.7 Sample examination questions............................................................................ 176 Extended activity: the adoption of Botox..................................................................... 177 Chapter 17: Network effects............................................................................... 181 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 181 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 181 Further reading........................................................................................................... 181 iv Contents 17.1 Introduction....................................................................................................... 181 17.2 Network market structures.................................................................................. 182 17.3 Technology diffusion with network effects........................................................... 183 17.4 Generic strategies in network markets8................................................................................................................. 186 17.5 Fighting a standards battle................................................................................. 187 17.6 Key concepts...................................................................................................... 188 17.7 A reminder of your learning outcomes................................................................. 188 17.8 Questions for discussion..................................................................................... 188 Extended activity: Skype and digital cinema................................................................. 188 Appendix 1: Sample examination paper............................................................. 191 Appendix 2: Guidance on answering the Sample examination paper................ 193 v MN3119 Strategy Notes vi Chapter 1: Introduction Chapter 1: Introduction 1.1 Introduction to the subject Let us begin this course with a wager: I bet you that, when opening the business section of your local newspaper, you will find the word ‘strategy’ at least once per page. A Google search of ‘strategy’ throws up 1,010,000,000 hits. Narrowing this down to ‘business strategy’ leaves us with 622,000,000 hits. That’s a lot of business strategy! There are a large number of definitions of strategy, and I will not attempt to write my own. There are also entire research fields of ‘business strategy’ ‘corporate strategy’ ‘strategy content’ ‘strategy process’ ‘management strategy’ ‘competitive strategy’ and so on, and I will not get into the fine distinctions between one and the other. Much more, I will try to boil down ‘strategy’ to what most definitions have in common, and more importantly, I will introduce a number of techniques that will be helpful in formulating, analysing and implementing a strategy. 1.2 Aims of this course In this course, you will not learn ‘how-to’ recipes of how to react to specific situations. What you will learn is a way of thinking about such situations. In management, as in economics, the right answer to almost any question is ‘it depends’. What you will learn in this course is what the right answer depends on and, given a particular set of circumstances, how you can analyse the situation. 1.3 Learning outcomes Once you have completed the course and done the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • use tools of strategic analysis and game theory to value and analyse strategic options in real life. In particular, you should be able to: • anticipate the actions of a rational (that is, individually profitmaximising) rival and act accordingly. 1.4 The structure of the course The course is structured in six parts: after this and the following introductory chapter, the basic building blocks of strategic analysis are introduced: market analysis, game theory and oligopoly competition. We will refer back to these chapters often in later chapters, so you are advised to spend a significant amount of time on these and make sure you have understood the basic principles and techniques of these chapters. The third part introduces the sources of competitive advantage – resources and capabilities, strategic asymmetries and organisation design. These chapters will aim to explain why firms are different, in what way and what makes some firms more successful than others. The fourth part will study firms and their relations to other firms. Why are some firms vertically integrated and some not, and what are the implications of this? When do firms cooperate with rivals, and what do partnerships among firms typically look like? The fifth part takes a closer look at competition among firms – over 1 MN3119 Strategy time, and in specific situations like entry or research and development. This is where we will use the tools of game theory we introduced in the second part of the guide very intensively. In the final part we will look at some of the particularities of high-technology industries. This part of the guide may be considerably more demanding technically than the previous ones, but by then you should have had enough opportunity to study, revise and practise the concepts from previous chapters. See this final part as the ‘icing on the cake’ – after you have looked at many techniques and topics in isolation, these last chapters give you an opportunity to look at some of them in combination. 1.5 Use of the guide and hours of study To help you get the most out of this course, you will be given a number of examples and activities throughout each chapter. These will vary in difficulty and style. When you read a chapter, try and do these as you go along, and go back to the ones you had problems with the first time round once you have completed the chapter. At the end of the chapter, you will find a list of questions or exercises designed to challenge you and to check if you have read and understood the chapter. They are titled Sample examination questions. These precise questions are unlikely to come up, but they should give you a general impression of the level that is required in this course. If you are studying this text in a group, you might want to consider discussing these questions in a tutorial-style session at the end of each chapter. As a further test of your skills, most chapters will have an Extended activity in a separate section. This is a longer text, case study, interview, quote etc. that illustrates some of the concepts in the chapter, and gives some concrete questions at the end. These activities will test your overall grasp of the chapter and are often not limited to one chapter or one topic. The advice normally given to University of London students is that if they are studying one course a year, they should allow at least six hours of study every week. Most of the chapters are relatively short compared to regular textbook chapters. Therefore, a chapter should be read all in one go to give you a general idea of what it is about. After that, you should set some time aside to work through the chapter properly. Times will vary for every student and every chapter. Sample examination questions and extended activities will probably take very little time if you just glance over them and sketch them out in your mind. It is recommended, however, that you write out some of your answers as you may find that a casual thought will not look as convincing if you write them out on paper and you need to have a clear, coherent and logical argument. 1.6 Essential reading For many chapters, the Essential reading is: Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) [ISBN 9780262032865]. The chapters in the book will often clarify points and go a little further, but you will find most of the points covered in the subject guide chapter are also covered in Cabral. Reading further often highlights some specific aspects of the chapters or describes some of the research findings 2 Chapter 1: Introduction explained in the chapter. If you would like to get another perspective on strategy from an economics viewpoint, you should have a look at Besanko, D., D. Dranove, M. Shanley and S. Shaefer Economics of Strategy. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2009) fifth edition [ISBN 9780470484838]. or Saloner, G., A. Shepard and J. Podolny Strategic Management. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2006) revised edition [ISBN 9780470009475]. Detailed reading references in this subject guide refer to the editions of the set textbooks listed above. New editions of one or more of these textbooks may have been published by the time you study this course. You can use a more recent edition of any of the books; use the detailed chapter and section headings and the index to identify relevant readings. Also check the virtual learning environment (VLE) regularly for updated guidance on readings. Journals Dierickx, I. and K. Cool ‘Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage’, Management Science 35(12) 1989, pp.1504–511. Dyer, J. and H. Singh ‘The relational view: co-operative strategy and sources of interorganisational competitive advantage’, Academy of Management Review 23(4) 1998, pp.660–79. Haskel, J. and C. Martin ‘Capacity and competition: empirical evidence on UK panel data’, Journal of Industrial Economics 42(1) 1994, pp.23–44. Lexecon Ltd ‘An introduction to quantitative techniques in competition analysis’, Lexecon Ltd. publication, mimeo. www.crai.com/ecp/assets/quantitative_ techniques.pdf Swaminathan, A. ‘Entry into new market segments in mature industries: endogenous and exogenous segmentation in the US brewing industry’, Strategic Management Journal 19(4) 1998, pp.389–404. 1.7 Further reading Please note that as long as you read the Essential reading you are then free to read around the subject area in any text, paper or online resource. You will need to support your learning by reading as widely as possible and by thinking about how these principles apply in the real world. To help you read extensively, you have free access to the VLE and University of London Online Library (see below). For your ease of reference here is a list of all the Further reading for this course. Angelmar, R. ‘Market structure and research intensity in high-technologicalopportunity industries’, Journal of Industrial Economics 34(1) 1985, pp.69–79. Arora, Alfonso Gambardella ‘Complementarities and external linkages: the strategies of large firms in biotechnology’, Journal of Industrial Economics 38(4) 1990, pp.361–79. Barney, J.B. ‘Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage’, Journal of Management, 17 1991, pp.99–120. Barney, J.B. ‘Resource-based theories of competitive advantage: A ten-year retrospective on the resource-based view’, Journal of Management 6(2001a), pp.643–50. Benkard, L. ‘Learning and forgetting: the dynamics of aircraft production’, American Economic Review 90(4) 2000, pp.1034–54. Bryson, A., R. Gomez and T. Kretschmer Catching a wave: the adoption of voice and high-commitment workplace practices in Britain, 1984–1998. CEP discussion 3 MN3119 Strategy paper DP 0676. (London: Centre for Economic Performance, 2005) (http://cep. lse.ac.uk/pubs/download/). Cabral, L. ‘R&D competition when firms choose variance’, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 12(1) 2003, pp.139–50. Cabral, L. and M. Riordan ‘The learning curve, predation, antitrust, and welfare’, Journal of Industrial Economics 45(2) 1997, pp.155–69. Camerer, C. ‘Redirecting research in business policy and strategy’, Strategic Management Journal 6(1) 1985, pp.1–15. Chen, M.-J. ‘Competitor analysis and interfirm rivalry: towards a theoretical integration’, Academy of Management Review 21(1) 1996, pp.100–34. Chen, M.-J. and D. Miller ‘Competitive dynamics: themes, trends, and a prospective research platform’, The Academy of Management Annals 6(1) 2012, pp.135–210. Church, J. and R. Ware Industrial Organisation: A Strategic Approach. (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2000) [ISBN 9780071166454] Chapter 8, Classic Models of Oligopoly Csaszar, F. ‘Organizational structure as a determinant of performance: evidence from mutual funds’, Strategic Management Journal 33 2012, pp.611–32. David, P. ‘Clio and the economics of QWERTY’, American Economic Review 75(2) 1985, pp.332–37. Dixit, A. and S. Skeath Games of strategy. (London: Norton & Company, 2004) second edition [ISBN 9780393924992]. Emmons, W. and R. Prager ‘The effects of market structure and ownership on prices and service offerings in the US cable television industry’, Rand Journal of Economics 28(4) 1997, pp.732–50. Farrell, J. and G. Saloner ‘Standardization, compatibility, and innovation’, Rand Journal of Economics 16(1) 1985, pp.70–83. Ferrier, W.J., K.G. Smith and C.M. Grimm ‘The role of competitive action in market share erosion and industry dynamics: a study of industry leaders and challengers’, Academy of Management Journal 42(4) 1999, pp.372–88. Fudenberg, D. and J. Tirole ‘Preemption and rent equalization in the adoption of new technology’, Review of Economic Studies 52(3) 1985, pp.383–402. Geroski, P. ‘Early warning of new rivals’, Sloan Management Review 40(3) 1999, pp.107–16. Geroski, P. ‘Models of technology diffusion’, Research Policy 29(4–5) 2000, pp.603–25. Geroski, P. ‘Thinking creatively about markets’, International Journal of Industrial Organisation 16(6) 1998, pp.677–95. Gilbert, R. and D. Newbery ‘Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly’, American Economic Review 72(3) 1982, pp.514–26. Griliches, Z. ‘Hybrid corn: an exploration in the economics of technological change’, Econometrica 1957. Reprinted in Z. Griliches (ed.) Technology, Education, and Productivity. (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988) [ISBN 9780631156147] pp.27–52. Hamel, G. and C.K. Prahalad ‘The core competence of the corporation’, Harvard Business Review 68(May–June) 1990, pp.79–93. Hitt, M., H.I.R. Volberda, R. Morgan, R. Hoskisson and P. Reinmoeller Strategic Management: Competitiveness and Globalization. (Hampshire: Cengage Learning EMEA, 2011) [ISBN 9781408019184]. Katz, M. and C. Shapiro ‘Systems competition and network effects’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(2) 1994, pp.93–115. Kay, J. Foundations of Corporate Success: How Business Strategies Add Value. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995) [ISBN 9780198289883], Chapters 5–8. Klette, T. ‘R&D, scope economics, and plant performance’, Rand Journal of Economics 27(3) 1996, pp.502–22. Koski, H and T. Kretschmer ‘Survey on competing in network industries: firm strategies, market outcomes and policy implications’, Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 4(1) 2004, pp.5–31. 4 Chapter 1: Introduction Kretschmer, T. and P. Puranam ‘Integration through incentives within differentiated organisations’, Organization Science 19(6) 2008, pp.860–75. Leonard, R. ‘Reading Cournot, reading Nash’ Economic Journal 104(424) 1994. Lieberman, M. ‘Market growth, economies of scale, and plant size in the chemical processing industries’ Journal of Industrial Economics 36(2) 1987, pp.175–91. McAfee, P., H. Mialon and M. Williams ‘What is a barrier to entry?’, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings (94) 2004, pp.461–65. Monteverde, K. ‘Technical dialog as an incentive for vertical integration in the semiconductor industry’, Management Science 41(10) 1995, pp.1624–38. Ohashi, H. ‘The role of network effects in the US VCR market, 1978–86’, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 12(4) 2003, pp.447–94. Peteraf, M.A. ‘The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view’, Strategic Management Journal 14(3) 1993, pp.179–91. Porter, R. ‘A study of cartel stability: the Joint Executive Committee, 1880–1886’, Bell Journal of Economics 14(2) 1983, pp.301–14. Postrel, S. ‘Competing networks and proprietary standards: the case of quadraphonic sound’, The Journal of Industrial Economics 39(2) 1990, pp.169–85. Sah R.K. and J.E. Stiglitz ‘The architecture of economic systems: hierarchies and polyarchies’, American Economic Review 76(4) 1986, pp.716–27. Saloner, G. ‘Modeling, game theory, and strategic management’, Strategic Management Journal (12) 1991, pp.119–36. Shapiro, C. and H. Varian Information rules. (Cambridge, MA: HBS Press, 1999) [ISBN 97807875848631] Chapter 7 ‘Networks and Positive Feedback’. Smith, K.G., W.J. Ferrier and H. Ndofor ‘Competitive dynamics research: critique and future directions’ in M.A. Hitt, R.E. Freeman and J.S. Harrison (eds), The Blackwell Handbook of Strategic Management. (Oxford: Blackwell Publishing, 2001) pp.314–61. Spence, A. ‘The learning curve and competition’, The Bell Journal of Economics 12(1) 1981, pp.49–70. Wernerfelt, B. ‘The resource-based view of the firm’, Strategic Management Journal 5(2) 1984, pp.171–80. 1.8 Online study resources In addition to the subject guide and the Essential reading, it is crucial that you take advantage of the study resources that are available online for this course, including the VLE and the Online Library. You can access the VLE, the Online Library and your University of London email account via the Student Portal at: http://my.londoninternational.ac.uk You should have received your login details for the Student Portal with your official offer, which was emailed to the address that you gave on your application form. You have probably already logged in to the Student Portal in order to register. As soon as you registered, you will automatically have been granted access to the VLE, Online Library and your fully functional University of London email account. If you have forgotten these login details, please click on the ‘Forgotten your password’ link on the login page. The VLE The VLE, which complements this subject guide, has been designed to enhance your learning experience, providing additional support and a sense of community. It forms an important part of your study experience with the University of London and you should access it regularly. 5 MN3119 Strategy The VLE provides a range of resources for EMFSS courses: • Self-testing activities: Doing these allows you to test your own understanding of subject material. • Electronic study materials: The printed materials that you receive from the University of London are available to download, including updated reading lists and references. • Past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries: These provide advice on how each examination question might best be answered. • A student discussion forum: This is an open space for you to discuss interests and experiences, seek support from your peers, work collaboratively to solve problems and discuss subject material. • Videos: There are recorded academic introductions to the subject, interviews and debates and, for some courses, audio-visual tutorials and conclusions. • Recorded lectures: For some courses, where appropriate, the sessions from previous years’ Study Weekends have been recorded and made available. • Study skills: Expert advice on preparing for examinations and developing your digital literacy skills. • Feedback forms. Some of these resources are available for certain courses only, but we are expanding our provision all the time and you should check the VLE regularly for updates. Making use of the Online Library The Online Library contains a huge array of journal articles and other resources to help you read widely and extensively. To access the majority of resources via the Online Library you will either need to use your University of London Student Portal login details, or you will be required to register and use an Athens login: http://tinyurl.com/ollathens The easiest way to locate relevant content and journal articles in the Online Library is to use the Summon search engine. If you are having trouble finding an article listed in a reading list, try removing any punctuation from the title, such as single quotation marks, question marks and colons. For further advice, please see the online help pages: www.external.shl.lon.ac.uk/summon/about.php 1.9 The examination and examination advice Important: the information and advice given in the following section are based on the examination structure used at the time this guide was written. Please note that subject guides may be used for several years. Because of this we strongly advise you to always check both the current Regulations for relevant information about the examination, and the VLE where you should be advised of any forthcoming changes. You should also carefully check the rubric/instructions on the paper you actually sit and follow those instructions. The examination will be a three-hour unseen written examination covering all aspects of the syllabus. In the examination, you will be asked to: 6 Chapter 1: Introduction • reproduce some knowledge. (This will get you close to a pass grade, although some application is needed). • apply knowledge to new situations. (This will lift you to the high lower second, or low upper second marks (assuming you get all the above questions right)) and • make new connections between topics and/or phenomena. (This will enable you to obtain a first class mark in this course). As with most examinations, try to allocate your time approximately proportional to the marks available. If you are having problems with an analytical question that worth very few points, it’s best to let that one go and avoid losing time that you could use on another question. Remember, it is important to check the VLE for: • up-to-date information on examination and assessment arrangements for this course • where available, past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries for the course which give advice on how each question might best be answered. 1.10 The syllabus Basic game theory: Two-player games. Static and dynamic games and some examples. Equilibrium concepts and solution mechanisms – Nash equilibrium, dominant/dominated strategies, backward induction. Oligopoly competition: Perfect competition and monopoly. Price competition and the Bertrand paradox. Quantity competition. Reaction functions. Bertrand versus Cournot. Analysis of market structure: Describing market structure: C4-ratio, Herfindahl index, Lerner index and market power. Market definition – techniques and interpretation. Collusion: Cartels and antitrust. Cartel stability and the discount factor. Market dynamics and stability of collusion. Strategic alliances: Portfolio test. Strategic and business partnerships. Sources of complementarity. Resource accumulation. Absorptive capacity. Organisation design: Organisational fit, Strategy and structure, Functional organisation, Multidivisional structure, Worldwide structure. Competitive Dynamics: Competitive dynamics, Competitive action, Resource similarity, Market commonality, Awareness, motivation and capability. Strategic asymmetries: Economies of Scale, sources and consequences. Scope Economies: Airline Hubs. Learning or experience curve. Firm strategies with EoScale/Scope/Learning. First-mover advantages. Market structure with increasing returns. Value chain analysis and vertical relations: Double marginalisation and its remedies. Vertical foreclosure. Retailer competition and investment externalities. Vertical integration and transaction cost: Make or Buy. Contracts. RelationSpecific Assets and Hold-Up. Economic Rents and Quasi-Rents. Entry and entry deterrence: Structural determinants of entry. Entry barriers and exit barriers. Entry deterrence. Identifying entrants. Research and Development: Market structure and R&D intensity. R&D rivalry. Monopolists’ and entrants’ R&D incentives. Risk choice of R&D. Benefits of the patent system. Sleeping patents. Spillovers. 7 MN3119 Strategy Technology adoption: Preemption games. Option value and future technological generations. Technology diffusion: Heterogeneity, epidemic, and population ecology approaches. Network effects: Direct and indirect network effects. Systems goods. Excess inertia. Excess momentum. Firm strategies with network effects. Standards Battles. Realising intra-firm synergies: Incentive-setting: Free riding versus cooperation. Interfaces: Modularity, task separation and task similarity. Distinctive capabilities and competitive advantage: Identifying competitive advantage. Sustainability of competitive advantage. Innovation, architecture, strategic assets, reputation. Leveraging distinctive capabilities. All topics are supplemented in the subject guide with specially written case studies. 8 Chapter 2: The evolution of strategic management as an interdisciplinary field Chapter 2: The evolution of strategic management as an interdisciplinary field Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain how the field of strategic management evolved over time • discuss the elements of the shared meaning in the strategic management field. Essential reading Hoskisson, R.E., M.A. Hitt and D. Wan W.P. Yiu, ‘Theory and research in strategic management: swings of a pendulum’, Journal of Management, 25(3) 1999, pp.417–56. Nag, R., D.C. Hambrick and M.-J. Chen, ‘What is strategic management, really? Inductive derivation of a consensus definition of the field’, Strategic Management Journal 28 2007, pp.935–55. 2.1 Introduction Strategic management is a relatively young academic discipline. Among the first publications are Alfred Chandler’s Strategy and structure (1962), H. Igor Ansoff’s Corporate strategy (1965) and Kenneth Andrews’ The concept of corporate strategy (1971). Since then the field has changed its focus from business policy to strategic management and made the transition from being a collection of toolkits developed by consulting firms to a systematic, theory-driven academic field. In addition, right from its beginning the area of strategic management was recognised as an interdisciplinary research field. The field was – and is still – populated by scholars from different disciplines like management, economics, finance, marketing, psychology and sociology. For such a diverse field it might have been difficult to develop a consensual meaning of what the discipline is all about. However, such a shared understanding is important as all academic fields are socially constructed and can only flourish if there is a shared conception of its meaning. Thus, the purpose of this chapter is twofold: first, we will sketch the evolution of the field before analysing the shared understanding of the field. 2.2 Early theories The field of strategic management or, to be more precise, the field of business policy (as it was initially called) did not emerge before the 1960s with the influential work of Alfred Chandler, Igor Ansoff and Kenneth Andrews. These early writings were influenced by the work of Edith Penrose, who developed a theory of the growth of the firm by emphasising the importance of a firm’s resources and managerial capabilities for its growth. Besides Penrose, these researchers were influenced by the work of the Carnegie School, especially Herbert Simon, Richard Cyert and James March, who developed the idea of bounded rationality to study the decision-making process in firms. Deviating from standard economics, Simon and his colleagues assumed that decision makers do not have 9 MN3119 Strategy complete information and that the alternatives they are deciding upon needs to be researched. The last important influence of the early writings was the work by Philip Selznick and his idea on distinctive competences. A distinctive competency is something that is unique to an organisation and superior in some respects when compared with the competencies of other organisations that offers some value to their customers. Influenced by these ideas, Chandler, Ansoff and Andrews developed their theories of strategy by placing an emphasis on the internal characteristics of a firm. In Strategy and structure, for example, Alfred Chandler studied how large organisations develop new administrative structures to accommodate growth and how strategic change influences an organisation’s structure. 2.3 Michael Porter and the industrial organisation paradigm After relabelling the field ‘strategic management’ in the late 1970s, the focus moved towards industrial organisation economics in both theory and method. At this time research was aiming to develop and test hypotheses derived from the structure-conduct-performance (SCP) paradigm. The basic idea of this paradigm is that the performance of a firm is determined by the industry in which it competes. The conduct of a firm is just a reflection of the industry structure, so that the most important decision a firm has to make is in which industry it wants to compete in. The SCP paradigm led to a shift in focus from the firm to the industry or market structure. The most influential scholar from this era is Michael Porter, who is not only well known among researchers but also among practitioners. He developed the so- called ‘five forces’ model that specified different features of an industry and which determines its attractiveness and facilitates competitor analysis. Porter also proposed the idea of generic strategies – low cost leadership, differentiation and focus – to match the characteristics of an industry and achieve a competitive advantage. Besides the SCP paradigm, research at this time developed the idea of strategic groups. Strategic groups are groups of firms in the same industry who follow the same strategy, for example, all suitcase producers in the high-price market like Louis Vuitton or Bottega Veneta. A third important research theme, influenced by industrial organisation economics, is competitive dynamics (which is subject of Chapter 13). The basic interest of competitive dynamics is to investigate how firms are jostling for competitive advantage by carrying out different types of strategic and tactical actions. 2.4 Organisational economics In the 1970s the field of strategic management was not only influenced by the work of industrial economists but also by another subfield of economics: organisational economics. Organisational economics tries to open the ‘black box’ of the firm and looks at its inner structural logic and functioning. Its most prominent theories are transaction cost economics and agency theory. Transaction cost economics, developed by the work of Oliver Williamson, studies the question of why firms exist and which transactions are made inside the market and which inside the firm. Building on the concept of bounded rationality and asset specificity, Williamson argues that transactions are made within the firm (or hierarchy, in the words of Williamson) when the sum of all transaction costs is smaller than the price 10 Chapter 2: The evolution of strategic management as an interdisciplinary field for the transaction in the market. He further argues that firms exit as an efficient alternative to the market. Strategic management scholars have applied transaction cost theory to study the make or buy decision of all firms, including multidivisional and international firms. Agency theory claims that the separation of ownership and control in most organisations lead to a problem of divergence of interest between shareholders (‘principals’ in the words of agency theory) and managers (called agents). The idea is that managers try to maximise their utility, which might not be in line with the maximisation of the long-term profits of the firm. To avoid this problem, firms need contracts that rule the relationship between principal and agents. 2.5 Resource-based view, dynamic capabilities and leadership theory One of the latest steps of the development in the field of strategic management occurred with the emergence of the resource-based view and its dynamic extension – the dynamic capability approach. This stream of research is influenced by the work of Edith Penrose, who viewed the firm as a collection of productive resources. The resource-based view further argues that these resources are heterogeneously distributed among firms. The differences in resources combined with the imperfect mobility of the resources can explain the differences in performance among firms in the same industry. The dynamic capability approach extends this logic and argues that a firm needs dynamic capabilities to modify and extend its resource base to achieve and sustain a competitive advantage or a series of competitive advantages over time. Finally, in 1984 Don Hambrick and Phylis Mason developed the strategic leadership or upper echelons theory. They developed a theoretical framework that proposed senior executives base their strategic choices on their cognitive structures and values. Hence, strategic leadership theory tries to explain differences in firms’ performance by, for example, differences in past performances of their executives, top management team size, composition and tenure. 2.6 A consensus definition of the field As seen in this short historical overview, strategic management has been advanced by researchers from different disciplines, especially economics, organisation science or sociology. Such an interdisciplinary field often lacks a clear understanding of or consensus on the subject. However, without this consensus, a field is limited in its growth. As this is at odds with the great success of the field of strategic management over the last 30 years, Nag et al. conducted a study among strategy scholars from different disciplines asking them about their personal views of the field of strategic management. In their large study among strategy researchers, they found the following implicit definition of the field: The field of strategic management deals with (a) the major intended and emergent initiatives; (b) taken by general managers on behalf of owners; (c) involving utilisation of resources; (d) to enhance the performance; (e) of firms; (f) in their external environments. They therefore concluded that the success of the field emerges from an underlying consensus that enables it to attract multiple perspectives. 11 MN3119 Strategy 2.7 Key concepts • Strategic management • Business policy • Structure-conduct-performance paradigm • Transaction cost economics • Agency theory • Resource-based view • Dynamic capabilities. 2.8 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: 12 • explain how the field of strategic management evolved over time • discuss the elements of the shared meaning of the strategic management field. Chapter 3: Analysis of market structure Chapter 3: Analysis of market structure Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • discuss the most common techniques used to define a market • describe a firm’s market power within a defined market. Essential reading Besanko, D., D. Dranove, M. Shanley and S. Shaefer. Economics of Strategy (New Jersey: Wiley, 2009) pp.205–11. or Lexecon Ltd An introduction to quantitative techniques in competition analysis. Lexecon Ltd. publication, mimeo. Available at: www.crai.com/ecp/assets/ quantitative_techniques.pdf. Saloner, Shepard and Podolny Strategic Management. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2005) Chapter 6. Further reading Emmons, W. and R. Prager ‘The effects of market structure and ownership on prices and service offerings in the US cable television industry’, Rand Journal of Economics 28(4) 1997, pp.732–50. Geroski, P. ‘Thinking creatively about markets’, International Journal of Industrial Organisation 16(6) 1998, pp­.677–95. 3.1 Introduction In this chapter we will first present techniques which are used when defining markets, for instance, for policy or firm strategy analysis. In the second part of this chapter we introduce some methods of analysing markets with many firms. The process of market definition and analysis will be an input for the later chapters in the second part where we will learn how to analyse tightly structured problems, for example, by solving games having identified the players, the strategies, the pay-offs and the rules. 3.2 Techniques of market definition1 Why should we want to define the market for a particular product or firm? Geroski (1998) states that there are three ways of ‘thinking creatively about markets’: trading markets, antitrust markets and strategic markets. Trading markets are defined as geographical areas and a set of products for which the law of one price holds to a certain degree. That is, taking into account transport costs and slight differences in the product offerings, we would expect a similar price to be charged for similar products. Market definition from an antitrust perspective looks at the likelihood that the market can be monopolised by a single firm, or group of firms. That is, if there was some change in the degree of the market’s competitiveness (for example, through mergers or collusive agreements), would it be possible to initiate a ‘small and significant increase in prices’, This section is based mainly on Lexecon Ltd An introduction to quantatative techniques in competition analysis. 1 13 MN3119 Strategy or is market power restricted by other, closely related markets? Finally, strategic market definition concerns itself with market boundaries which are defined by firms’ product offerings. The argument here is that companies not only adapt to but also create or segment markets in order to maximise their profits. We will introduce a number of techniques of market definition: estimating the cross-price elasticity of demand, price correlation analysis, switching or diversion ratio, shock analysis and bidding studies. Example: Sony’s PlayStation 3 (PS3), a video game console The PS3 was introduced in the year 2006 with the express intent of providing a successor to the Playstation 2 and to challenge Microsoft’ s early mover position in the market for 256-bit game consoles. The simple definition of the market would suggest that the PS3’s market is defined by ‘game consoles’. Hence, its main competitors are the Nintendo Wii, the Microsoft X-Box 360, and Sony’s own Playstation 2 to some extent. Is this the whole story? To start with, PCs nowadays have relatively advanced gaming features as well and there is a large library of PC games available, which would suggest that PCs are also a significant competitor also. Going even further, if young people no longer find playing game consoles attractive, they could switch to other ways of entertaining themselves like watching TV, reading books, playing board or ball games, etc. Another way of thinking about the market for the PS3 is by looking at the buyers, who are more often than not parents around Christmas time. What would they be spending their money on if not on the PS3? This could be other consumer electronics as gifts or clothing, etc. 3.2.1 Cross-price elasticity of demand You will recall the (own-price) elasticity of demand (e) from your introductory microeconomics course: it is defined as the ‘relative change in quantity (Q) demanded due to a price (P) change’. We can write the ownprice elasticity as:2 − ∂Qi Qi ∂Pi Pi or − ∂Qi Pi ∂Pi Qi The cross-price elasticity then measures the ‘relative change in quantity demanded of one good, due to a one per cent price change of another good’. We can write the formula as: ∂Qi Pj ∂Pj Qi That is, if the price for another good goes up by one per cent, how will demand for my own product change (in percentage terms)? If a product is a close substitute, we would expect cross-price elasticity to be a large positive number: a price increase of five per cent for a rival product will redirect a lot of customers towards my own product, meaning that demand goes up by more than five per cent. On the other hand, if a price decrease for a potential substitute results in only small quantity losses, cross-price elasticity is low and we can say that the products are distant substitutes. This simple technique cannot be used to define or test a market. However, it is a very powerful tool to assess the relationship of two products if the data is available. 14 2 We leave out the negative sign commonly used in own-price demand elasticity. This is simply because we expect cross-price elasticity to be positive for substitute products. This is however just a convention and nothing should be read into it. Chapter 3: Analysis of market structure Activity 3.1 Give your estimates of the cross-price elasticities of the following product pairs and explain why. a. Two gas stations on opposite sides of the road b. Coffee and tea c. Hotels in Bahrain and New Zealand Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 3.2.2 Price correlation analysis Quite often it is difficult to gather enough data to calculate the cross-price elasticity of demand – in particular, obtaining a time series of quantity and price data containing some small price changes and very little changes in the general market parameters is typically difficult. An (imperfect, but still acceptable) alternative may be tracking movements of prices over an extended period of time. As we will see in Chapter 5, the B and C competition model shows prices as strategic variables are strategic complements, which means that, on the one hand, if one firm increases its price, so will the other. In contrast, if quantities are the strategic variable (and the strategies therefore are strategic substitutes), we expect market prices emerging from the quantities set by the firms to move in unison for related products. In the extreme case of perfect substitutes, the market price for both will be the same, so an increase in price for one product implies a price increase for the rival product. A word of caution on the interpretation of price correlations: it is important to rule out other explanations for the co-movement in prices. For example, if the prices of ice cream and sunscreen are highly correlated, this does not imply that the two are close substitutes – if anything, they are complements, but demand for both of them is affected by the same (seasonal) components, temperature and sun. Similarly, tyres and washing-up liquid are rarely mistaken for substitutes, but changes in their prices are likely to occur at somewhat similar times – both products use oil as a significant input3 and are therefore likely to be affected by oil price changes in a similar way. The point is that price correlations have to be interpreted with care and that potential sources of ‘spurious correlation’ (i.e. correlation that is not down to the reason stipulated) have to be taken into account. It is also important to get a sense of the reasons for the price changes, even if they were not ‘spurious’ in the sense outlined above – were there any product or process innovations (we will cover this later in the guide), was there a significant shift in consumer preferences or did firms simply change their strategies? 3 A more comprehensive list of products made from oil is given on www.anwr.org/features/ oiluses.htm 3.2.3 Switching/diversion ratio analysis If a time series of prices is not available or if for some reason would not be meaningful (for example, if one product is priced at zero, e.g. a software programme available as freeware on the internet), it may be useful to ask consumers directly for the products or services they perceive as the closest substitutes to the products they are currently using. Frequently, this will take the form of a survey of consumers of a particular product or service who are asked a question to the tune of: ‘If the product you have just purchased had not been available today, what other option would you have chosen?’ Clearly, the more ‘votes’ a particular alternative obtains, the closer a substitute it is likely to be. 15 MN3119 Strategy 3.2.4 Shock analysis Another reliable method of determining the closeness of two products or services is their reaction to a ‘shock’. Technically, this is a natural experiment observing a sudden and unexpected change in one market and analysing the reaction in the (possibly) related market. Shocks can take many forms: entry of a new product, technological change, price concessions, a change in input prices, natural crises, etc. For example, when Sony released the Playstation 3 in 2006, board game manufacturers made only limited changes to their strategies (and probably experienced only a limited impact on their sales), whereas Nintendo and Microsoft were hit relatively hard, suggesting that the game consoles market consists of closer substitutes than the broadly defined ‘leisure’ industry. 3.2.5 Bidding studies Finally, there may be cases where prices are not transparent or not publicised, or where the number of transactions is relatively low so that no meaningful correlations can be gathered from the data. Sometimes therefore, the best that can be done is to determine ‘who bids for the same business’ as a proxy of who competes in the same market. For example, when the ‘big four’ accounting firms were still the ‘big six’, the effect of merging PriceWaterhouse and Coopers & Lybrand was assessed using a bidding study. On the one hand, it was found that in addition to PriceWaterhouse and Coopers & Lybrand, the other four accountancy firms were bidding for very similar projects or accounts, which meant that competition was likely to be intense even after the two merged. On the other hand, if the two merging partners had been a duopoly in a submarket, say, large manufacturing accounts in the north-east of England, the merger would have led to a monopoly in the north-east manufacturing sector. So, while bidding studies are a relatively crude way of determining one’s competitors, they are still a useful exercise. 3.3 Market analysis with many firms Suppose now that we have defined the market using one (or multiple) of the techniques introduced above. What next? We need to find some proxies for determining whether the market is competitive or not, in-order to judge, for instance, how attractive the market is likely to be in the near future, how likely it is that antitrust action will be taken, and if entry or exit by rivals can be expected.4 Figure 3.1 gives the four most commonly used measures of competitiveness and concentration in an industry. Their quality and accuracy increase from number one to four: The simplest way to measure the competitiveness of a market is by counting the number of firms in an industry. In a market with many firms, it is less likely that a single firm will have a significant amount of market power. Further, more firms suggest rather low entry barriers (the more firms there are in the industry, the lower the average size or market share per firm), which is another indicator for a competitive market. If there are some firms, however, that do have significantly higher market power than others in the industry, a simple count would not do the trick. 16 4 We will discuss entry in more detail in Chapter 14. For now it is sufficient to know that a less competitive market is likely to be more profitable for potential entrants, which in turn implies that incumbents will try and build barriers to entry to maintain their profitable position. Chapter 3: Analysis of market structure Measures of competitiveness and concentration 1 n 1. #firms C≡ 2. C4/5/8 C4 ≡ ∑ si 4 i =1 3. Herfindahl index n H ≡ ∑ si2 i =1 n 4. Lerner index L ≡ ∑ si i =1 p-MC i p Figure 3.1: Measures of competitiveness and concentration. A more useful method, particularly if there are several larger firms, is to calculate the Cn-ratio (mostly C4, C5 or C8) – the sum of the market shares of the n largest firms. This gives some information about how strong the biggest firms are likely to be. Again, however, this measure is not fully satisfactory: Imagine a market with 4 firms – the C4-ratio will be 100 per cent regardless of the distribution of market shares between the four firms. Similarly, if the n+1th largest firm is almost as big as the nth firm, the Cn-ratio will not pick this up. So even though we can do a little better than simply counting the firms, not all information is utilised in the Cn-ratio. The Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI) takes the market shares of all the firms in an industry into account and sums their squares. This solves a lot of the problems of the previous two concentration indices: first, information of all firms is taken into account,5 and second, larger firms feature more prominently in the index. The HHI is a standard tool for antitrust economists and the US Department of Justice guidelines state that ‘…markets in which the HHI is between 1,000 and 1,800 points are considered to be moderately concentrated, and those in which the HHI is in excess of 1,800 points are considered to be concentrated. Transactions that increase the HHI by more than 100 points in concentrated markets presumptively raise antitrust concerns under the Horizontal Merger Guidelines issued by the US Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission.’6 The one remaining problem with the HHI is that while it says a lot about the size distribution of firms within an industry, it does not say anything about the way and intensity with which these firms compete, or, in economists’ parlance, their conduct. The Lerner index, then, takes the HHI one step further and looks at a firm’s profit margins (i.e. price – marginal cost) and weighs them by the firm’s market share. In other words, if the largest firm charges a high price relative to its marginal cost while smaller ones price relatively aggressively, the Lerner index will be higher than if a small firm charged high mark-ups (e.g. because it operates in a niche market). Note, however, that it is still possible for margins to be high and profits to be low due to fixed costs. The main problem with this measure, however, is that it is almost impossible to gather the necessary information on prices and particularly costs for each firm. In practice, this is often impossible with a large number of very small firms. Antitrust practitioners mostly ignore the market shares of all firms with a market share of <1 per cent. This seems acceptable since they would have a minute effect on the HHI anyway. On the other hand, if the fringe of small firms can be expected to act jointly (or at least to react in the same way to, say, a price increase of a larger firm), there may be a case for squaring the joint market share of all the fringe firms. This will depend on the particular case in question. 5 See www.usdoj.gov/ atr/public/ testimony/ hhi.htm 6 17 MN3119 Strategy 3.4 Key concepts • Cross-price elasticity of demand • Price correlation analysis • Switching/diversion ratio analysis • Shock analysis • Bidding studies • Cn-ratio • Herfindahl-Hirshman index • Lerner index. 3.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • discuss the most common techniques used to define a market • describe firm’ market power within a defined market. 3.6 Sample examination questions 1. You are a product manager for a computer game and have been asked to analyse whether a new game is a competitor and to suggest techniques which could help inform your decision. The game you are in charge of is called ‘Industry Giant’ and has the following product description: ‘Begin in the year 1900 with little money but large ambitions and through skilful decision-making you can build up an enormous business empire. Make critical decisions on which of more than 200 products you should manufacture, where to gather the best raw materials, where to sell them and how to effectively transport them there. Recommended Retail Price (RRP): £29.99’ Industry Giant has a multiplayer option, in other words, you can play it against others on the same PC, but it has no internet capabilities. Your competitors are a combination of computer-controlled teams and (if you play with friends) ‘real’ players. Internet Industry Manager (IIM) is a relatively new computer game where players get to ‘manage’ a firm in an interactive environment by choosing prices, quantities and advertising efforts. It is played over the internet and all players are ‘real’ players, that is, every firm is controlled by somebody on the internet. It is free to download and to play. Is IIM a competitor? Why or why not? What techniques would you use specifically to analyse the degree of competition between the products? 2. You are working for a Japanese firm selling hot coffee in vending machines. You have been asked to identify the market and the potential competitors and substitutes for your product in Europe. a. How would you design and conduct a study to do this (outline your choice of techniques and the reason why you chose this particular set of techniques)? b. What is your first guess of your product’s relevant market? Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. 18 Chapter 3: Analysis of market structure Extended activity: the commercial banking industry in the United States Read the following and answer the questions at the end. The US commercial banking industry consists of independent banks and bank holding companies that provide firms and homes with depository and lending products, as well as a range of other related financial services. Simply put, the difference between the interest paid on deposits and the interest earned on loans determines the profitability of commercial banks. This sector provides a good example of how market structure affects performance by influencing conduct – how the players compete with each other. Most banks are involved in retail banking, serving households and small firms, as opposed to corporate banking, which serves large businesses and offers more sophisticated financial services. The retail banking sector is characterised by having many, relatively small and geographically local markets. People tend to choose banks that are physically close to where they work or live, and, once they become customers, they tend to view their bank as a primary provider of a range of personal finance services. Gaining customer trust and forming strong customer relationships are critical to banks as access to and knowledge about customers enhances the prospects of cross-selling other products and services. Banks operating within markets with a higher concentration – where the market is shared between fewer players – exercise a greater market power, for example in setting fees and prices. Conversely, in local markets with lower concentration – where the market is shared by many competitive players – banks tend to have a lesser market power. Historically, the banking industry has been shaped by regulations that have restricted the geographical scope of operations. Banks, for example, needed to maintain a head office in their local market where deposits were collected and loans originated. Moreover, they were often not allowed to form branches in other regions of their state, and were completely restricted from establishing branches in other states. In the 1990s many of these regulations were relaxed, prompting a significant industry consolidation on a national scale. Forming these larger banks was believed to yield many benefits including the ability to reap greater returns on investments in technology and advertising, to consolidate back-office functions, and to specialise employee functions in conjunction with the diversification of products and services. This merger activity within and across state boundaries had a great impact on the concentration levels of banks on the national scale, where we have seen much fewer – but significantly larger – players. In local markets, however, the concentration levels did not change significantly due to antitrust regulations that continued to restrict mergers between banks in direct local competition. The changes in market structure on the national level, however, do affect the competitive landscape of local markets in that local branch players are often, through their larger bank parents, in competition in several distinct local markets at the same time. Industry consolidation has created a trend of ever-larger banks controlling ever-larger market shares. Evidence shows that small banks are generally less profitable than larger banks, but that there is little difference in profitability within the large bank category. This suggests a threshold on the spectrum of bank size beyond which further gains in efficiency and ability to charge higher prices cannot be sustained. 19 MN3119 Strategy Source Pilloff, S.J. ‘Commercial banking’ in Adams W. and J. Brock (eds) The structure of American industry. (New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 2001), pp.224–54. [ISBN 9780130189166] pp.224–54. Questions 1. How would different market concentration levels affect bank prices and efficiency through the respective levers of market power and competition? Map and describe the relationships between these factors. If you were a bank owner, would you prefer to operate in a market with high or low concentration? Why? 2. Analyse the factors influencing how banks compete in today’s local markets. Consider market concentration levels, bank size, the types of products and services that can be offered, the ‘stickiness’ of the customer relationship, entry barriers. 3. What do you think are the potential implications of national banks competing through branches in several distinct local markets where the conditions and relative competitive positions may differ. How can they exploit their national muscle for local gain, and what might the limitations to this be? 20 Chapter 4: Introduction to game theory and strategy Chapter 4: Introduction to game theory and strategy Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • describe simple games, for instance the prisoner’s dilemma, using the normal form and extensive form • define the concept of Nash equilibrium and find equilibria for a game. Essential reading Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 4. Further reading Camerer, C. ‘Redirecting research in business policy and strategy’, Strategic Management Journal 6(1) 1985, pp.1–15. Dixit, A. and S. Skeath Games of strategy. (London: Norton & Company, 2004) second edition Part II. Saloner, G. ‘Modeling, game theory, and strategic management’, Strategic Management Journal (12) 1991, pp.119–36. Saloner, G., A. Shepard and J. Podolny Strategic management. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2005) Appendix. 4.1 Introduction There are about as many definitions of strategy as there are textbooks on the topic. The definitions often have very little in common and are frequently coloured by the preferences of the author. Instead of advancing another definition with a claim for universal applicability, let us identify a number of features the many definitions have in common. Specifically, strategies are often: • long-term • about securing competitive advantage • coupled with actions, not just a plan. First of all, a strategy is supposed to have a long-lasting effect on a firm – in other words, we are not talking about small, day-to-day transactions (even though these may be in accordance with an overall strategy). Second, a strategy is often aimed at securing an advantageous position relative to other firms in the market. That is, there is an element of competition in many of the definitions of strategy. Finally, strategies are often a set of actions rather than a set of lofty ideas and visions. What would count as a strategy? Surely, the most basic strategy must be whether you want to enter a (geographical or product) market or not. Once you have entered, setting capacities or production volumes will determine the long-term success of your firm. Once this is settled, you have to sell your product. How to sell? Setting prices, choosing (to the extent that you can do this) qualities and advertising levels would 21 MN3119 Strategy be the most obvious levers a firm can pull in order to sell its product. There are other decisions a firm has to make, however: should the firm integrate vertically (i.e. with suppliers or buyers) or horizontally (with competitors), should the firm spend resources on research and development, and if so, what kind of research should be done? Common to these is that the profitability of these actions depends on what your competitors do: lowering your price will only be successful if your competitor does not lower his by the same amount. Introducing a high-quality version of your product will only draw consumers from your competitors if they do not counter this by launching their own high-end version as well. Entering a market on your own is much more profitable than with a competitor, and so on. For formulating a successful strategy, it is therefore important to at least try and anticipate what (actual or potential) competitors are going to do. 4.2 Static games 4.2.1 Anticipating rivals’ moves In strategic analysis, it seems important to be able to figure out what one’s rival is going to do, that is, to anticipate a rival’s moves. How can we do this? Strategists (both professional ones (i.e. managers and consultants) and ‘strategists in the making’ (i.e. students)) often assign probabilities to the different actions a rival might take. But can we do better than this? Game theory tells us we can (most of the time)! Let us use an example to illustrate this. Prisoner’s dilemma – Advertising wars Consider the following situation. P&G and Colgate Palmolive sell competing brands of toothpaste – Crest and Colgate – in a market. The brands share the market equally, that is, both firms have a 50 per cent market share. The overall market for toothpaste is fixed – let’s assume total sales for toothpaste will be €10m per year. Both firms now have the option of launching an advertising campaign for one year at a cost of €2.5m. While advertising does not increase total sales for toothpaste, advertising if the other firm does not advertise would increase market share to 80 per cent. What should both firms do? In fact, can we use the information above to make a prediction of what each of the players is going to do? The first step to take is identifying the players (which is typically a simple but nonetheless important step). In this case, P&G and Colgate Palmolive are the players. The second step is to identify their strategies, that is, what are the choices they have? Here, P&G and Colgate Palmolive decide whether to run an advertising campaign or not. Third, we have to specify the rules of the game. We will go into this in more detail later on, but here the rules are that both players have to decide simultaneously to run or not to run an advertising campaign. Finally, we have to specify the pay-offs for each of the possible outcomes of the game. In this case, both firms not running an ad campaign results in them sharing the market and making sales of €5m. If one of them runs an advertising campaign and the other does not, the first makes sales of €8m (80 per cent of €10m), but has to pay advertising costs of €2.5m, leaving net sales of €5.5m. The other (non-advertising) firm makes sales of €2m. If both firms advertise, their sales will be €5m again (as the market for toothpaste is fixed), but they again incur an advertising cost of €2.5m, resulting in net sales of €2.5m. 22 Chapter 4: Introduction to game theory and strategy We can now represent the game in matrix, or normal form. First, however, a word on convention: The first pay-off (or the leftmost) will be the pay-off of the row player – that is, the player choosing the row (top or bottom), Colgate in this case. The second pay-off (or the pay-off further to the right) will be the column player’s pay-off (i.e. P&G). P&G No Ad €5m No Ad €5m Colgate Ad €5.5m €2m €2m Ad €5.5m €2.5m €2.5m Figure 4.1: Advertising wars. The situation P&G and Colgate are facing is what game theorists call a prisoner’s dilemma: overall profits would be higher if both did not advertise, but both have an individual incentive to go ahead and advertise anyway – regardless of what the other player does (advertise or not advertise). This makes advertising a dominant strategy – a strategy that does better than all others for any strategy chosen by the other player(s). This gives us the first way of predicting our rival’s behaviour: if a strategy always maximises my rival’s pay-offs, he will play it. Eliminating dominated strategies – pizza wars It would be nice if we could always make a clear prediction about our rival’s behaviour. We can often simplify games by finding dominant strategies as demonstrated above. However, consider the following game. There are two restaurants in a small town, Dave’s Deep Dish and Paul’s Pizza Pies. They are in competition with each other for customers and can choose their prices: high (H), medium (M) or low (L). The city has 1,000 customers, of which 300 only ever buy at Dave’s, and 300 only buy at Paul’s. The other 400 are price-sensitive and always buy the cheaper pizza and choose at random if they charge the same price. Both places make a margin of £12 per pizza if they charge high prices, £10 per pizza if they charge medium prices, and £5 for low prices. Both Dave and Paul cannot observe what the other player has chosen before they choose themselves. Can we draw this in a pay-off matrix? We know players, strategies and rules. What about calculating pay-offs? We can calculate profits by multiplying the number of customers with the margin per customer. For example, if Dave charges a medium price and Paul a high price, Dave will sell to his 300 ‘loyal’ customers and the 400 ‘price sensitive’ customers at a margin of £10 each, giving him pay-offs of £7,000. Paul only sells to his 300 loyal customers, but at a margin of £12 per pizza, giving him profits of £3,600. 23 MN3119 Strategy Paul High Medium Low High Dave Medium Low 60/60 36/70 36/35 70/36 50/50 30/35 35/36 35/30 25/25 Figure 4.2: Pizza wars. Can we solve this game by finding dominant strategies? For none of the players can we find one strategy that does better than the other two for all strategies chosen by the rival. For example, M outperforms H if the other price is H or M, but not if it if L. Dominant strategies will not get us very far then. We can, however, find a strategy that never does better than another one – a dominated strategy: charging L is worse than H or M for all strategies chosen by the other player. So if Dave and Paul are (as we assume) trying to maximise their profits, they will never charge lower prices. We combine our outcomes on dominant and dominated strategies for the following set of predictions. Result a. A dominant strategy should always be played. b. A dominated strategy will never be played. Let’s now go one step further. Having simplified the game, we can in fact find a dominant strategy again. Playing M always does better than H, knowing that L will never be played by either of the players. This process is called the iterated elimination of dominated strategies. This makes the game a good deal simpler, and you can now solve the simplified game with just M and H for Dave and Paul. What is the solution? 4.2.2 Nash equilibrium Hopefully you found that the solution to the simplified Pizza game is (M,M) – that is, both players will charge a medium price. Looking for dominant strategies in the simplified game gave you this outcome. This combination of prices is a Nash equilibrium (NE). How did you try to ‘solve’ the game? Assuming that both players are interested in maximising their pay-offs, you tried to predict what they would do given the other player’s strategy. As it turned out, in the simplified game, playing M was the best solution, regardless of the strategy of the other player – a dominant strategy. This means that both players playing M is an equilibrium – none of the players would want to change their behaviour given the other’s strategy. Therefore, a Nash equilibrium can be formally defined as follows. Nash equilibrium – definition A Nash equilibrium is a combination of strategies such that no individual player can deviate unilaterally from his/her current (equilibrium) strategy to improve his/her pay-offs. This means that a game has a solution at a Nash equilibrium in the sense that no player would change given the other player’s strategy. What does this imply about the relationship between Nash equilibrium, dominant and dominated strategies? Here are a few questions to consider. 24 Chapter 4: Introduction to game theory and strategy Activity 4.1 Answer the following questions: a. Is a Nash equilibrium the same as a dominant strategy? b. Can a Nash equilibrium contain dominated strategies? c. Will every Nash equilibrium contain dominant strategies? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Hopefully, your answer to all these questions was ‘No’. Why? As to the first question, a Nash equilibrium refers to a combination of strategies, which by definition means it’s more than just a single strategy by one player. (Another objection is that not every Nash equilibrium must consist of a combination of dominant strategies – as we discuss in c). The second ‘No’ comes directly from the first prediction we made: if a strategy is never played, it cannot be a resting point – there is always something better for the player to do. The final ‘No’ becomes clear when we study the Pizza game. Looking at the full game, we could see that none of the strategies is dominant, but we still found a Nash equilibrium in (M,M). Here are another two questions. Activity 4.2 Answer the following questions: a. Will every game have a Nash equilibrium (in pure strategies)? b. Can a game have more than one Nash equilibrium? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. The answer to the first question is again ‘No’ (Hint: think of a game of ‘matching pennies’, where one player wins if two pennies are both heads or both tails, and the other wins if one is heads and the other is tails.) Let us tackle the second question by using an example: Science and Humanities faculties have to decide on the renovation of an unused lecture hall. Both want something to be done with it, but have their own preferences: Science prefers a laboratory, whereas Humanities prefers a theatre. At the main meeting of all the faculties, both have to endorse one of the projects. At the preliminary meetings within the individual faculties, both have to decide which project to endorse. The meetings take place simultaneously – or, if you are more comfortable with this interpretation, the meetings take place without the faculties knowing what the other faculty has decided. First, let’s represent the game in matrix (or normal) form: Humanities Lab Theatre Lab Science Theatre Figure 4.3: Coordination game. 25 MN3119 Strategy (Try to put in sensible pay-offs in the four quadrants – remember that what’s most important to both players is spending the evening together, even though each of the two players has a preference for one of the activities.) What will be the Nash equilibrium of the game? Well, predicting the other player’s move is tough: putting ourselves in Science’s shoes, if Science thinks that Humanities will endorse the lab, Science will want to vote for the lab as well. But when would Humanities vote for the lab? If it thinks that Science will vote for the lab as well – which will be the case if Science thinks that Humanities will…the story could go on and on, and we could run the same procedure for voting for the theatre! So will this mean that the game has no Nash equilibrium? In fact, there are two: (L,L) and (T,T) – both want to coordinate on one of the projects and they have no incentive to deviate unilaterally (i.e. taking the other player’s strategy as given) if they have coordinated. Note that this does not mean that the faculties are indifferent between the two solutions – Science would rather see a lab built than a theatre, but not at the expense of risking any project being realised. We will deal with ways of solving the conundrum of which of the two equilibria to choose shortly, but for now we know that some games can have multiple Nash equilibria. Activity 4.3 Represent the following situation as a strategic game and solve it, that is, look for the Nash Equilibrium. Two players, Arthur and Bob, drive towards each other in their cars. Both can swerve (i.e. steer to the left or right) or go straight. Whoever swerves first loses and is considered ‘chicken’ (i.e. not very courageous) and the rival wins. If both swerve, they are both chickens (but they do not face the abuse by the winner of the game). If they both go straight, the cars collide and Arthur and Bob are seriously injured.1 Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Some games, as we have seen, have multiple Nash equilibria, with no obvious way of selecting among them. Of course, one might think that Scientists are a stubborn bunch who would only ever vote for a lab anyway, but then who is to say that the Humanities faculty is not just as stubborn? And if that is the case, would the Science faculty not want to compromise instead of seeing the unused lecture theatre go unused for another year? We will now go through a few mechanisms or ways in which games with multiple Nash equilibria can be approached. Note, however, that most of these will imply changing the rules of the game in some way – in other words, you have to make assumptions in addition to the initial specifications of the game. Hierarchy. If there is a ‘junior’ and a ‘senior’ player in a strategic game, the game is played as if the senior player’s preferences are more important. For example, if there is a merger or a takeover, firms will typically try and agree on a common corporate culture (i.e. a coordination game). Although it is possible in principle that either firm’s corporate culture will prevail, it is most common that the larger or more powerful partner will dictate the eventual culture. Commitment. If one of the players commits to playing a certain strategy, it is in the other’s interest to follow, that is, play the game as if the committed player had already moved. For example, in a ‘chicken game’, such as entry into a natural monopoly market, if one firm commits to entering this market (for example, by building production facilities specific 26 1 This is a variant of the 'chicken game' played in James Dean's Rebel without a cause. Chapter 4: Introduction to game theory and strategy to this market or hiring experts for a particular technology on long-term contracts), other firms might be deterred by this and refrain from entering themselves. History. If there has been a ‘traditional way’ of playing a particular game, new versions of the game will automatically ‘converge’ on the historical equilibrium. For example, there is no real method of choosing whether to drive on the right side or the left side of the road – apart from selecting the option others in the country choose.2 Also, if a coordination game between players has traditionally been solved by taking turns of one party’s preferred option and then the other party’s, future versions of the game would take this into account. Mixed strategies. If none of the above work, the best shot players might have of ending up with an acceptable outcome is to randomise their behaviour. We will not go into this in much detail, but the intuition is to take into account the likely actions of the other player and one’s own payoffs and choose accordingly. For the moment, it is sufficient to recognise that sometimes playing ‘randomly’ is the best way of maximising one’s expected pay-offs from a game with multiple equilibria. In fact, mixing behaviour such that each player is indifferent between the possible options is another equilibrium concept – a mixed strategy equilibrium. This is in contrast to the Nash equilibria we have been looking for so far – socalled pure strategy equilibria, which involve non-random behaviour, but deterministic choice of one strategy. 2 Of course, there is also a legal issue here, but even without any legal recourse, no individual driver would have an incentive to choose a different side than all others in the same region. 4.3 Dynamic games In the remainder of this chapter we will briefly discuss dynamic games, and in particular the difference between static and dynamic games. Dynamic games are, put simply, games with a time aspect in them. For example, if one firm acts before the other, this has quite important implications for playing the game: the second firm can play the game knowing what the first firm has done, whereas the first firm has to make its decision without the requisite knowledge about the follower. Some games simply don’t make much sense to play sequentially – paper/scissor/ stones, for example, would not be very exciting if one player knew what the other player has chosen.3 Some games, on the other hand, could be played either simultaneously or sequentially. Setting prices, for example, will be done without knowledge of rivals’ prices some of the time (making it a simultaneous game), but in other situations sequential moves might be more relevant. Representing a sequential game is usually done by drawing a game tree, where the first decision starts the game, and every decision point represents a node from which the decisions of subsequent players branch out accordingly. We illustrate this with an example. Assume that two firms selling mineral water have to decide on their advertising budget. For simplicity, there are only two levels of advertising, High and Low. Harrogate Spa chooses its advertising level first, and Vittel chooses after that. If both firms choose H, profits are zero (because all the money is spent on advertising), if both choose L, their profits are £1m each, and if one chooses H and the other L, the firm running an intensive advertising campaign makes £1,250k, while the other one makes profits of £500k. A game tree (or extensive form) of this situation would then look like Figure 4.4. For those unfamiliar with paper/scissor/ stone, have a look at the website www.netlaputa. ne.jp/~tokyo3/e/ janken_e.html for an explanation and its equivalent in many different cultures. 3 27 MN3119 Strategy Game Tree H L Harrogate Spa: H or L? Vittel: H or L? H 0/0 L H 1,250k/500k 500k /1,250k L 1m/1m Figure 4.4: Game tree. How should one analyse a sequential game? Analysing sequential games has a very similar objective to analysing simultaneous ones: predict sensible behaviour and an eventual outcome of the game. The way to do this in a simultaneous game is by eliminating dominated strategies and/or playing dominant strategies. (While this may enable us to simplify the game, it may still not lead us to a Nash equilibrium. In this case we would have to look for Nash equilibria after having simplified the game as much as we could.) One way of simplifying a sequential game is by backward induction. Backward induction works by eliminating strategies at the final node of the game (i.e. the point when the last player makes a decision, based on the decisions previously taken), and working one’s way forward, that is, closer to the start of the game. The strategies we can eliminate are moves that would not maximise an individual’s profit at that point. A rational player should never select these moves, which means that a player anticipating rivals’ moves should not expect these moves to be chosen. Looking at the game referred to above we can see that Vittel would not choose H if Harrogate Spa plays H, and they would not choose L if Harrogate Spa chose L. This then enables Harrogate Spa to anticipate that playing H gives profits of £1,250k, while playing L yields profits of £500k – Harrogate Spa should then choose high advertising expenses, which Vittel will react to by choosing low expenses. Activity 4.4 Represent the previous game as a normal-form game, if Harrogate Spa and Vittel select advertising expenses at the same time. What is/are the Nash equilibrium/a? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Commitment We already mentioned commitment in the context of selecting among different possible equilibria in a static game. Commitment, however, can also be used by an agent to choose the preferred course of action that he would not otherwise choose. Again, we use an example to illustrate this point. 28 Suppose a monopolist (M) in a market faces a potential entrant (E). The entrant can choose whether to enter (e) or not (ne). If E does enter, the monopolist can choose to fight (f) or to accommodate (a). If E does not enter, M experiences business as usual. Suppose M currently makes profits of PM = 50 (and E makes zero profits in this market), in the case of entry and accommodation the entrant makes PE = 10, the incumbent PM = 20, and if entry is followed up by fight (think of this as the monopolist starting a price war flooding the market), profits are PM = PE = – 10.4 Figure 4.5 represents this game in game tree form. Note that the profits should be considered long-term profits and the entry is a one-off opportunity. 4 Chapter 4: Introduction to game theory and strategy Game Tree e E: e or ne? M: f or a? f -10/-10 ne 0/50 f 10/20 Figure 4.5: Game tree. By backward induction we now find that the Nash equilibrium is for E to enter and for M to accommodate – if entry does occur, M will choose payoffs of 20 over –10, and, knowing this, will prefer entering to not entering. The monopolist will not be particularly happy with this outcome: of course, given the choice, he would rather keep the entrant out – for example, by committing to fight in the case of entry. To this end, M could issue a statement along the following lines: ‘Should entry occur in our market, we will fight aggressively to protect our market position.’ This seems sensible enough, and should go some way towards convincing the entrant not to enter. Or should it? The entrant would have to believe that M would indeed prefer to fight. This would imply, however, that in the case of entry M would choose a sub-optimal action, namely one that gives him pay-offs of –10 rather than 20. In game-theoretic terminology, fighting after entry is not sub-game perfect – a sub-game starts at one player’s decision node and covers all the decisions that follow on from this node, and an action that does not maximise pay-offs at that decision node should not be played. Since post-entry fighting is not sub-game perfect, the entrant should not believe the monopolist if he makes this statement. Let us now consider another strategy by M. Suppose that M sign and publicise a long-term contract with one of suppliers that states: ‘if we, M, ever purchase less than the current quantity, we will incur contractual penalties of 40.’5 This seems like an odd move to begin with, since all that it achieves is to lower pay-offs in some cases, but it never increases pay-offs. However, it changes things around in the particular game we are analysing. Accommodating implies sharing the market, that is, selling less and consequently buying less from one’s supplier. This means that it is now less attractive to accommodate, since M would have to incur contractual penalties, taking down profits from accommodating from +20 to –20. This changes the pay-offs and the way the game is being played – it is now sub-game perfect to fight after entry, which means that the entrant has to choose entering and incurring losses or keeping out and have unchanged profits. The entrant will choose to stay out, leaving the incumbent with profits of PM = 50. We assume here that it is not possible to renegotiate this contract. 5 What happened? By limiting his options, the monopolist was able to commit to playing the game differently, which accordingly made the entrant play the game differently as well, taking M’s expected reaction into account. If we represent this in our game tree (Figure 4.6), the monopolist changed the pay-offs in one game outcome and subsequently the sub-game perfect equilibrium. 29 MN3119 Strategy (New) Game Tree No contract Contract e e ne ne 0/50 f -10/-10 a 10/20 0/50 f a -10/-10 -10/-20 Figure 4.6: (New) Game tree. In this game, committing credibly was worth 30 – the difference between the outcome of the game with commitment and the outcome without. Committing can be done by limiting one’s options, or lowering pay-offs in some (undesired) states of the game. Activity 4.5 What are other examples of credible commitments? Explain how an organisation (or an individual) limits his/her options by lowering pay-offs in one particular state of play. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 4.4 Key concepts • Prisoner’s dilemma • Dominant/dominated strategies • Iterated elimination of dominated strategies • Nash equilibrium • Backward induction • Normal and extensive form games • Sub-game perfect equilibrium. 4.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • describe simple games, for instance the prisoner’s dilemma, using the normal form and extensive form • define the concept of Nash equilibrium and find equilibria for a game. 4.6 Sample examination questions 1. Can you find some examples from business life of coordination games? Of ‘chicken’ games? 2. Simple coordination games have two pure-strategy Nash equilibria. What are ways of selecting among these equilibria? 3. Consider the advertising game in Section 4.3. As you can see, there is a first-mover advantage for Harrogate Spa. Develop an advertising game in which there is a second-mover advantage. 4. Simultaneous games and Nash equilibria. Consider the following games. The first two are zero-sum games in that one player’s 30 Chapter 4: Introduction to game theory and strategy gain is the other’s loss, which is why we can write only player 1’s pay-offs. The other two are non-zero sum. Find all pure-strategy Nash equilibria, and demonstrate if you could identify dominant and dominated strategies. a) b) c) d) 31 MN3119 Strategy 5. Producing cars.6 Consider a normal form game between three major car producers, C, F, and G. Each producer can produce either large cars or small cars, but not both. That is, a car producer’s actions (strategies) are ai = SM or LG. We denote profits for firm i as πi(aC, aF, aG), i.e. they depend on the decisions of all three car producers. The profit function is defined as follows: πi = { γ if all firms play the same strategy (i.e. all SM or all LG) α if i plays a strategy on its own (i.e. ai = SM,aj = LG or vice versa) β if i play a strategy with one other firm, but the remaining firm does not Answer the following questions: i. Does there exist a Nash equilibrium when a > b > g > 0? Prove your answer. ii. Does there exist a Nash equilibrium when a > g > b > 0? Prove your answer. 6. Wage dispute. Consider a situation where an employer and a union are involved in an industrial dispute – a union member is claiming unfair dismissal and demands compensation of £10k. The case has gone to a tribunal which will decide in favour of one or the other with 50 per cent probability. The tribunal can only award the full £10k to either of the parties and cannot propose a compromise. Further, this verdict is binding, that is, both parties have to abide by it. Both parties now can choose a strategy (L) to increase their chances of winning – hiring a lawyer, gathering evidence for or against unfair dismissal, bribing the judge, etc. Playing L comes at a cost of £4k per player. Choosing L gives a success probability of 100 per cent only if the other player does not play L too. If both players choose L, the advantages cancel out and the chances of winning are unchanged at 50 per cent. Represent this game in normal form and find the Nash equilibrium. Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. 32 This exercise is taken from Shy, Industrial organization. (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1995), p. 41. 6 Chapter 5: Oligopolistic models of competition Chapter 5: Oligopolistic models of competition Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • describe and compare the Bertrand and Cournot models of simultaneous, oligopolistic competition • explain the Stackelberg leadership model of sequential competition. Essential reading Besanko, D., D. Dranove, M. Shanley and S. Shaefer Economics of Strategy. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2009) pp.221–29. Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 7. Haskel, J. and C. Martin ‘Capacity and competition: empirical evidence on UK panel data’, Journal of Industrial Economics 42(1) 1994, pp.23–44. Further reading Church, J. and R. Ware Industrial Organisation: A Strategic Approach. (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2000) Chapter 8. Leonard, R. ‘Reading Cournot, reading Nash’, Economic Journal 104(424) 1994. 5.1 Introduction A 1999 Wall Street Journal article said that: …in a strategic shift in the US and Canada, Coca-Cola is gearing up to raise prices by about 5%. The price changes could help boost Coke’s profit…Important to the success of Coke is how Pepsi-Cola responds. The No. 2 soft-drink company could well sacrifice some margins to pick up market share on Coke, some analysts said. It is clear from the preceding quote that the profitability of one firm’s strategy (Coke raising prices) depends crucially on the response of its closest rival (Pepsi reciprocating or not). We can think of many situations like this: capacity expansion and the following production increase will only be profitable if there is sufficient demand, which in turn depends on the strategies of producers of competing products. Lower prices will only generate the expected market share gains if other firms do not simultaneously lower their prices. The list could easily be extended – more interesting, however, is the fact that these problems have a strikingly similar structure to the problems we addressed in the previous chapter: There are players (firms) with a certain set of strategies or actions (prices, capacities, etc.), whose pay-offs (profits) are interdependent, that is, they depend on one’s own actions and those of one’s rivals. In short, such problems of firms interacting in (narrowly defined) product markets could be modelled as a strategic game. Such situations are called oligopolies – loosely translated as markets with few players. That is, they are not monopolies, markets with only 33 MN3119 Strategy a single player, or perfectly competitive markets, where one player’s action has no impact on the profits of others (because every single firm is assumed to be too small to matter in the grand scheme of things). The literature on oligopoly competition is vast, and we cannot hope to cover all the details of the numerous different models. We will focus on the two most basic models – Bertrand and Cournot competition – and then discuss two extensions that are especially relevant for applications in strategy – Stackelberg leadership and product differentiation. 5.2 Preliminaries The first step in any problem of oligopoly competition will be to derive the profit function. Profits are simply Revenues – Costs. Revenues are price x quantity, and costs are average variable cost multiplied by quantity plus fixed cost. For this chapter, we will assume that marginal cost is constant and that there are no fixed costs. Denoting marginal cost as c, this then gives us the following profit function: Pi = piqi – ciqi = (pi – ci)qi Of course, this all seems very simple, but we need to keep in mind that the price a firm can achieve for its product may depend on the overall quantity produced in the market (so that the firm is not a price-setter, but a quantity-setter among other quantity-setters). On the other hand, firms could be setting prices, in which case the quantity they sell would depend on the prices charged by their competitors. Also, to fix ideas, in the first part of the chapter, we will use a simple demand function: Q=5–P Note that this is a market demand function – Q is the total quantity produced and demanded, while we will write q for the quantity an individual firm produces and sells. Where convenient, we will rearrange it to P = 5 – Q (the inverse demand function). For most of our discussions, we will assume marginal costs of MC = 2. 5.3 Bertrand competition When asked about the key strategic variable by firms, most students would opt for prices. After all, product quality is typically given, demand by consumers derives directly from it, so firms can only try and set the price that maximises profits. The basic Bertrand model of competition captures this in a very simple setting: two firms produce identical products and choose the price simultaneously, and then produce to satisfy demand. Since the products are identical, consumers can be expected to purchase purely on the basis of price – whoever charges the lower price will obtain all the market demand Q, and if prices are identical the consumers are distributed evenly across both firms. This gives us a three-part profit function, depending on one’s own price and the rival’s. π1 = 34 { (p1 – c)Q if p1 < p2 (p1 – c)Q/2 if p1 = p2 if p1 > p2 0 If they only interact once, this makes the incentives of the two players quite clear: If player 1’s price exceeds player 2’s, he makes no sales – clearly not desirable. So lowering the price to match player 2’s might be an option as player 1 could take half of the market. However, lowering prices Chapter 5: Oligopolistic models of competition even further by the smallest currency unit available would hardly mean a significant decrease in the price, but an enormous increase in quantity – player 1’s market share would increase from half the market to the full market. Both players will therefore want to undercut their rival by the smallest amount possible for any range or ‘normal’ prices. But what do we mean by normal? Let us determine the upper and lower bound of the ‘undercutting’ regime, that is, the range for which firms will keep on undercutting their rivals by the smallest amount possible. The upper bound is the monopoly price – let us use an extreme example. If firm 2 charges a price of 15, which would lead to zero sales in any case, firm 1 has no incentive to marginally undercut it. In fact, since firm 2 has priced itself out of the market, firm 1 is best off by behaving as a monopolist and charging (for the specific demand functions we have specified) a price of 3.5.1 Activity 5.1 Check that the monopoly price is indeed 3.5. (Hint: derive the profit function and maximise it.) Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. The lower bound is own marginal cost. If firm 2 charges marginal cost and marginal costs are symmetric, undercutting would mean selling to the entire market, but losing money on every unit that sold. Therefore, undercutting will stop at P = MC. We make a distinction here between 'charging lower prices' and 'undercutting'. 'Undercutting' means that a firm charges a price that is lower than the rival's price, but by the smallest possible amount. 1 What does this all mean for the market? We can see that no firm would want to charge a price above the monopoly price, and no firm wants to be undercut in the range between monopoly price and marginal cost – a decrease in price just below the rival’s price would give higher profits. The only sensible Nash equilibrium is for both firms to charge marginal cost: increasing prices (assuming the other firm remains at marginal cost) leads to zero sales and therefore zero profits, while decreasing prices would increase sales but every unit will incur a loss because price is below marginal cost. If both firms charge marginal cost, therefore, there is no incentive to deviate unilaterally – the condition for a Nash equilibrium. We can therefore state the following: Result In a price-setting market with two symmetric firms selling undifferentiated goods, the unique Nash equilibrium is marginal cost, which is the competitive outcome. This is slightly troubling since we quite frequently see two firms active in a market, obviously setting prices but making quite healthy profits. As we will see, changing some of the assumptions means that the competitive outcome need not always emerge in duopolistic markets. For a formal (and very complicated) analysis of this problem, see Kreps, D. and J. Scheinkman 'Quantity precommitment and Bertrand competition yield Cournot outcomes', Bell Journal of Economics 14, 1983, pp. 326–37. 2 5.4 Cournot competition We now look at the same situation (i.e. same demand curve, same symmetric marginal cost), but where firms set quantities rather than prices. We can think of this as a two-step setting: firms set quantities first and then prices. It can be shown that firms will produce the quantity they expect to sell in the second stage, and they set prices in the second stage to clear everything they produced in the first period.2 35 MN3119 Strategy The major difference to the previous model is that there are no ‘jumps’ in the profit function – if my rival produces slightly more than I do, market prices will be slightly lower, but sales or prices will not jump discontinuously as in Bertrand competition. Firm 1’s profit function is determined by the quantity firm 1 produces, but also by firm 2’s quantity (via the market price, which depends on both quantities). π1 = (5 – q1 – q2 – c)q1 We then take the first derivative of the profit function with respect to our decision variable, q1 and set it equal to zero to find the maximum. δ1 δq1 q*1 = = 3 – q2 – 2q1 = 0 3 – q2 2 ;q2* = 3 – q1 2 ⇒ q1* = q*2 = 1 We find that, not surprisingly, my optimal quantity depends on the quantity the other firm sets – after all, every unit of output lowers market price, and if my rival is already producing a lot, high output by two players might depress market price even more. We then have to derive and solve the same problem for firm 2 to find the Nash equilibrium. Recall that the definition of a Nash equilibrium is a situation when both players have no incentive to deviate from their current behaviour given the other player’s behaviour. That is, if player 2 sets quantity q2, player 1’s best response will be to set q1*, and vice versa. After all, if your quantity is a best response to the quantity I set as a best response to your quantity, neither player has an incentive to deviate. As we can see, quantities in the Cournot case are 1 for both players, which implies a price of 3, which exceeds marginal cost. We can conclude the following: Result In a quantity-setting market with two symmetric firms selling undifferentiated goods, prices will be above marginal cost and below the monopoly price. 5.5 Comparing Bertrand and Cournot Perhaps the most striking difference is that despite being based on the exact same demand and cost curves, price competition does not generate any profits, while quantity competition does. This can be interpreted in a number of ways, but the main intuition is that firms react differently to a change in the other firm’s strategy. In the case of price competition, a change in price by firm 1 will lead to a change in price by firm 2 in the same direction. That is, if one firm increases their price, the other will reciprocate by increasing theirs, but possibly by a slightly lower amount. This is called strategic complements – not to be confused with (product) complements, which describes the nature in which the demand of two products are related to each other. On the other hand, if firms compete in quantities, if firm 2 increases its quantity, the best response by firm 1 is to decrease its quantity. Analogous to the previous situation, this is called strategic substitutes. This reaction may seem strange initially, but inspection of the reaction curve 36 Chapter 5: Oligopolistic models of competition q1* = (3 – q2)/2 shows that as q2 goes up, q1 should go down. A more intuitive reason for this is that firms are still trying to maximise their own profit, not market share or anything else. This means that if one firm commits to producing large quantities of a product, competitors will not (should not) be tempted to further lower market price by putting out large quantities of output as well. Instead, their incentive to maximise profits will dictate a decrease in their own quantity. Strategic complements and substitutes – definition If the best response to an increase in the strategic variable of a rival is an increase in one’s own strategic variable, the strategic variables are strategic complements. If the best response to an increase in the strategic variable of a rival is a decrease in one’s own strategic variable, the strategic variables are strategic substitutes. Activity 5.2 Think of the following strategic variables. Which ones are strategic complements or substitutes, and under which circumstances? a. Advertising spend b. Research and development effort c. Entry decisions in small niche markets Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 5.6 Stackelberg leadership Quite frequently, firms do not set prices or quantities (or R&D efforts, advertising efforts, or any other strategic variable) simultaneously, but sequentially. For example, an early entrant in a market will have an opportunity to set production capacities before any potential entrants. We will now analyse oligopoly games with sequential moves, that is, games with so-called Stackelberg leadership. The mechanics of a Stackelberg game are relatively simple: instead of two firms choosing quantities/prices simultaneously and having to infer the other’s actions, Stackelberg games have one leader choosing first, and the leader’s choice will then be observed by the follower, who reacts accordingly (i.e. following her best-response function). We use Cournot competition as an example, so that the Stackelberg leader sets quantities first and the follower reacts to it. We have learned from the previous chapter that sequential games have to be solved by backward induction, that is, by solving the follower’s problem first. The follower’s problem is relatively easy to solve because we have done it before – by finding the best-response function to any quantity by the other player. Therefore, we know that if the leader sets quantity qL, the follower’s best response will be q*F = (3 – q1 ) 2 Now on to the leader’s problem. The leader does not have to secondguess what the follower would do – knowing the reaction function is enough to conjecture that the quantity chosen by the follower will be qF* = (3 – qL)/2. This leaves the leader with a residual (inverse) demand curve of 37 MN3119 Strategy which gives a profit function of: ПL = ( ) 3 qL – q 2 2 L Conveniently, this is a function of just a single variable – the leader’s quantity. This lets us compute the optimum quantities for leader and follower: 3; * 3 qL* = q = 4 2 F Looking at the optimal quantities just derived, we can see that with uniform market prices and symmetric marginal cost, the leader makes higher profits than the follower since it has a higher market share (in fact, twice as much). It is also interesting to note that overall quantities are higher in the Stackelberg case (3/2 + 3/4 = 9/4) than in the symmetric Cournot case (1 + 1 = 2) – in other words, competition is more aggressive with Stackelberg leadership (and prices are lower). This confirms our intuition about strategic substitutes: if one player commits to a high quantity (the leader), the other player would not want to reciprocate with high quantity, but lower quantities to offset the effect to some extent. The offset is not complete however – the follower will not decrease quantities to the same extent that the leader increases its own. With Stackelberg leadership in quantity competition we can therefore say that there are first-mover advantages. In the exercises, you will be asked to show that this does not hold for price competition – but for now we note that first-mover advantages depend on the nature of competition, in particular, if strategic variables are strategic substitutes or complements. 5.7 Product differentiation Finally, we go back to one of the implications that generated the extreme result in the price-setting model, namely that the lower-priced firm takes all the demand. This is a result of the assumption that products offered by the firms are identical. Rational consumers should therefore buy from the lowest-priced firm or choose at random if prices are equal. Realistically, there will always be slight differences, either real or perceived ones. For example, some customers might prefer a certain type of salesperson, or they prefer a closer shop to a more distant shop, or they prefer one package design to the other, even if the product is essentially the same. The important point to note is that the products will not lose all demand if they have a slightly higher price than that of their rival. Suppose for example, that there are different coefficients on ‘own price’ and ‘rival price’ in the case of imperfect substitutes: 40 4 2p q1 = – p + 2 3 3 3 1 This demand function indicates that an increase in own price has a negative effect on demand (the coefficient is – 4/3), while an increase in the rival’s price has a positive effect on demand, which seems intuitive as the two products are assumed to be substitutes. However, the coefficient on own price is larger in magnitude than the rival price coefficient, which indicates that a change in the rival’s price will not have an effect of the same magnitude as a change in own price. In the example above, a one unit increase in own price will decrease the quantity sold by 4/3, while a one unit increase in the rival’s price will increase units sold only by 2/3. Thus, the extent of differences in magnitudes indicate how close substitutes two products are – a zero coefficient on the rival’s price 38 Chapter 5: Oligopolistic models of competition obviously means that demand does not depend at all on the price of another good. We can now solve the game in much the same way as our previous oligopoly games, that is, deriving the profit function for both firms, taking the derivative and setting it equal to zero to find the best-response function, and inserting one best-response function into the other to find the Nash equilibrium. It turns out that for the demand function we specified and zero marginal cost, we obtain the following result: q1 = 40 4 40 4 2 2p – p + 2; q2 = – p + p 3 3 1 3 3 3 2 3 1 δ1 40 8 2p = – p1 + 2; 3 3 3 δq1 p1 = 5 + p2 ; p2 = 5 + P1 4 4 As prices are above marginal cost (20/3 versus 0), profits will be positive, even with price competition. This is because now both firms have an incentive to keep prices high even if the rival undercuts. Consider for example a firm facing a rival setting a price of zero. According to the bestresponse function we have derived, the firm should set a price of 5 since p1* = 5 + p2/4. That is, firm 1 would willingly concede consumers to firm 2 and make positive profits on the ones that remain. To summarise, we can interpret the coefficient on own prices as ‘price sensitivity’ and the relative magnitude of the rival price coefficient as an indicator for the degree of substitution between the two products. 5.8 Key concepts • Bertrand competition • Cournot competition • Bertrand v Cournot • Strategic complements and substitutes • Stackelberg leadership. 5.9 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • describe and compare the Bertrand and Cournot models of simultaneous, oligopolistic competition • explain the Stackelberg leadership model of sequential competition. 5.10 Sample examination questions 1. Consider the demand system in Section 5.7 (Differentiated goods). Solve a game in which firm 1 is a Stackelberg (price) leader and firm 2 a follower. Is there a first-mover advantage? 2. Boeing and Airbus produce more or less homogeneous aircraft for the world market. Let p be the price for a wide-body aircraft. Boeing’s output level is denoted by qB, and Airbus has output level qA. The aggregate industry output is denoted by Q, where Q = qB + qA. 39 MN3119 Strategy The aggregate industry demand curve for this product is given by p = 2000 – Q. Assume that the unit cost of firm 1 is cB = 300 and the unit cost of firm 2 is cA = 500. a. Derive the reaction functions of both firms. Then solve for the Nash equilibrium when firms set quantities (i.e. Cournot) simultaneously. b. Solve a quantity-setting model where Airbus is a Stackelberg leader. Highlight the differences to a). c. Which assumptions do you consider unrealistic in this model? How do you think the model would change if they were incorporated? 4. a. Show that in quantity competition a firm would produce the monopoly quantity if the other firm were to exit the market. b. In a quantity-setting model, show that prices cannot go below the competitive level. Guidance on answering these sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. Extended activity: articles on Airbus-Boeing competition Read the following and then answer the question at the end. Reading ‘For their next trick’, The Economist 25 March 1999. Available at: www.economist.com/node/193875 ‘Mumbo Jumbo’, The Economist, 23 September 1999. Available at: www.economist.com/node/242880 Question Read the two articles on the Boeing/Airbus competition. Airbus is proposing to launch a new aircraft with higher capacity than Boeing’s 747 (Jumbo). How might this affect competition between the two? Frame your answer (also, but not exclusively) in terms of price or cost leadership, cost asymmetries and changes in the demand function. 40 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • link resources and distinctive capabilities • identify some sources of competitive advantage • describe the process of capability building. Essential reading Barney, J.B. ‘Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage’, Journal of Management 17 1991, pp.99–120. Dierickx, I. and K. Cool ‘Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage’, Management Science 35(12) 1989, pp.1504–11. Kay, J. Foundations of Corporate Success: How Business Strategies Add Value. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995) Chapters 5–8. Wernerfelt, B. ‘The resource-based view of the firm’, Strategic Management Journal 5(2) 1984, pp.171–80. Further reading Barney, J.B. ‘Resource-based theories of competitive advantage: A ten-year retrospective on the resource-based view’, Journal of Management 6(2001a), pp.643–50. Peteraf, M.A. ‘The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view’, Strategic Management Journal 14(3) 1993, pp.179–91. 6.1 Introduction Although the field of strategic management is occupied by researchers from different disciplines – like management, economics, psychology or sociology – they all share an interest in answering one question: Why do some firms consistently outperform their competitors? In line with our analysis, a traditional industrial organisation economist, who believes in the structure-conduct-performance paradigm, would answer that firms who picked the ‘right’ industry are able to outperform other firms (where ‘right’ means an industry in which a firm can earn monopoly rents). (Remember that the profit in the monopoly setting is always higher than the profit in a duopoly or perfect competition.) However, if you ask a management scholar interested in strategy, they would probably argue that explaining variation in firm performances by differences in the competitiveness of industries is rather dull and that it is more interesting to study why performance differences exist between firms in the same industry. Thus, to be a bit more precise, management scholars are more interested in the question: Why do some businesses succeed in the same industry environments where others fail? rather than the general question stated above. Over the last 20 years the most prominent management literature dealing with this question has focused on the resource-based view (RBV) of the firm, which is the topic of this chapter. 41 MN3119 Strategy 6.2 Competitive advantages and resources Before we explain the main ideas of the resource-based view of the firm, we will first define what a competitive advantage is. Competitive advantage – definition A firm possesses a competitive advantage if it can consistently outperform other players in the industry. This definition may seem rather obvious, but it is important to note two elements. First, it refers to other players in an industry. That is, competitive advantage is by definition a comparative concept. Second, and most importantly, it refers to consistently outperforming other players. As we have already mentioned, one of the most influential management theories to explain competitive advantage is the resource-based view of the firm. Although some of its ideas can be found in the seminal work of Edith Penrose from the late-1950s, it was not until the mid-1980s that the idea was made popular by the work of Jay Barney and Birger Wernerfelt. The core idea of the RBV is that firms can be seen as a collection of heterogeneous and immobile resources and capabilities and that this heterogeneity of resources and capabilities can explain differences in a firm’s performances. A resource is anything that can be thought of as a strength or weakness of a firm. More formally, a firm’s resources can be defined as the assets that are tied to the firm. Examples of resources include machinery, capital and production facilities as well as brand names, management skills and organisational routines. Resources can be divided into two broad categories: tangible and intangible resources. Tangible resources, on the one hand, are assets that can be observed and quantified, such as financial, organisational, physical and technological resources. Intangible resources, on the other hand, are assets that are deeply rooted in the history of the firm, accumulated over time and which are difficult to quantify or observe. Intangible resources include human resources, innovation or reputational resources. Further capabilities include an organisation’s capacity to deploy resources. As not every resource and capability leads to superior performance, the argument behind the RBV is that a resource must fulfil four different criteria to result in a competitive advantage. Resources and capabilities give sustained competitive advantage when they are: valuable, rare, imperfectly imitable and not substitutable. First, to be valuable, resources must yield a superior product or service or lower costs. Second, they must be rare to ensure that the resource holders cannot compete away the value they create. Third, resources and capabilities must be imperfectly imitable (i.e. competitors must not be able to imitate them). Resources and capabilities are harder to imitate if tacit knowledge is involved in the resource or its application or if they are complex. Fourth, resources and capabilities must be not substitutable (i.e. there are no strategic equivalents, using either the same resource or an equivalent one). The four characteristics mentioned are individually necessary, but do not comprise sufficient conditions for a sustained competitive advantage. In the next section we will talk about four specific examples of resources and how they contribute to a firm’s competitive advantage. Kay (1995) thinks of these resources as the main sources of competitive advantage. 42 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm 6.3 Some examples of resources as sources of competitive advantage 6.3.1 Contractual architecture Architecture – definition Architecture is the set of structure, style and routines which a firm employs in dealings with employees and other firms. The architecture, in other words, is the set of spot, long-term and relational contracts that a firm is involved in. Roughly, we could divide legal contracts (spot and long-term contracts) as defining the structure of the firm, and relational contracts as defining the style and routines of a firm. This is not completely accurate as the choice of contract will also guide the structure of the firm to some extent. Example Volker Finke is the longest-serving football manager in German professional football. He has been manager of SC Freiburg, a team from a mid-sized German city near the French and Swiss border, from 1992 to 2007 – an eternity in professional football. After a few years of signing formal contracts for one or a few years, Volker Finke and the club president, Achim Stocker, stopped signing a formal contract governing Finke’s role in the club, preferring instead a handshake at the start of each season. This absence of a formal (i.e. spot and long-term) contract is indicative of the style of the club, which has for a long time cultivated its image as ‘alternative’, with open, informal structures, no ‘stars’, a relatively flat salary structure and many non-pecuniary perks. On the other hand, Bayern Munich, Germany’s most successful club, is known to insist on formal contracts being signed between player and club. Several years ago, one of their star players, Mehmet Scholl, lost his place in the first team and threatened to leave if he did not get to make more appearances. The response of Uli Hoeness, Bayern’s manager at the time, was that, having signed a contract, Scholl should realise that he was a Bayern player, whether on the field, on the bench or in the stands (i.e. out of the match day squad). We have to distinguish between internal and external architecture. Internal architecture encompasses formal employment relations and career paths, but also in corporate culture and job security – that is, the ‘soft’ factors of working for an organisation. External architecture captures supplier contracts, but also implicit agreements about flexibility over and above what has been agreed in the contract, knowledge sharing arrangements and/or ‘first-point-of-contact’ assurances.1 We should note that even though spot and long-term contracts can secure a firm a superior position in its industry, architecture is likely to be sustainable because that architecture includes a whole set of interdependent contracts that cannot easily be identified and copied by competitors, and the informal or relational contracts a firm has are even more difficult to replicate. ‘First-point-of-contact’ assurances promise that if a new opportunity in a similar field arises, the existing supplier within that field will be approached first. 1 6.3.2 Reputation Reputation – definition Reputation is an aggregate of many personal and collective judgments about a company’s or an industry’s credibility, reliability, responsibility and competence based on a common set of values. 43 MN3119 Strategy It is easy to imagine why reputation might be a source of competitive advantage. It takes a long time to build up an asset stock like reputation, and it might be very difficult, possibly even prohibitively expensive, to try and match the reputation of the market leader. The precarious nature of reputation as a competitive advantage is also reflected in the following quote: If you lose dollars for the firm by making bad decisions, I will be very understanding. If you lose reputation for the firm, I will be ruthless. (Warren Buffet, remarks made to Salomon Brothers managers, 1991) Why is reputation so important and in what markets? It turns out that it is mainly the nature of the product in question that determines how important reputation is. More precisely, reputation is invaluable in markets where product quality is important, and can only be determined through long-term experience. These goods are commonly called ‘experience goods’, and a firm’s or a product’s reputation can serve as a signal for quality without a consumer having to purchase the product in the first place. Similarly, ‘search goods’ are goods where quality is important and can only be ascertained by inspecting the goods personally. This implies that if there are a lot of variants around, ‘searching’ for the right product might prove prohibitively costly and reputation can serve as a substitute for the search. We do this virtually every time we go shopping and choose for a special brand, a specific supermarket, a favourite restaurant, because sampling all options available would be too time consuming. Activity 6.1 Which of these are experience or search goods? •• a cure for baldness •• a hamburger •• stocks •• funeral services •• skirts. 6.3.3 Innovation We distinguish between two concepts here: innovation and innovativeness. Innovation – definition Innovation relates to a new product that is valuable to consumers and provides a firm with an opportunity to outperform others in the market. Innovativeness – definition Innovativeness is a firm’s ability to continuously invest and market new products. At first sight, you would expect that innovativeness is more sustainable than innovation because it refers to a capability that it is possible (although difficult) to build up and copy. However, it might also be the case that a firm with a constant stream of innovations is not able to protect its innovation and consequently will not be able to outperform its competitors consistently. The key, therefore, for both innovation and innovativeness is how to safeguard the value created from an innovation. There are several alternatives. 44 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm First, legal protection through patents and copyrights gives inventors a (usually limited) time period during which they have exclusive rights to bring their invention to the market. Second, building up a reputation as the first or most innovative product on the market can protect the value of an invention. Third, standard-setting can be a very powerful mechanism for securing the benefits of an innovation.2 Finally, if none of these is likely to work for an innovator, another way is to adopt a policy of licensing the innovation. That way, revenues can be generated through license fees instead of own sales. Activity 6.2 Find an example for each of the four mechanisms of protecting the value created by an innovation. However, all the mechanisms mentioned above are risky – they may be circumvented by other firms or simply may not work as well as envisaged. The best way therefore to derive value from an innovation is to support it with other capabilities. For example, supporting innovation with a set of contracts, both internal and external, is likely to generate a sustained advantage. Launching a product with large, concurrent investments in the firm’s reputation will create a first-mover advantage that is hard to copy with another innovation. Finally, strategic assets like patents or the long-term monopoly over a key input for the new product are useful ways to obtain income from innovations. 2 If a firm sets the industry standard, other firms either have to adopt the standard by licensing specific components from the innovator, or they have to engineer around the industry standard, leading to inferior products in comparison with the original. The profits to be gained from innovativeness are often dependent on a firm’s architecture: relational or formal employment contracts that reward ‘innovation from within’, in other words, the workforce, is likely to enable the firm to generate innovations continuously. Similarly, an external architecture consisting either of very flexible spot contracts, which do not tie a firm in to a particular product line or supplier over a long period, or relational contracts, which encourage suppliers to react quickly and constructively to sudden changes in requirements, are complementary to an innovative environment within the firm. 6.3.4 Strategic assets Strategic asset – definition A strategic asset enables a firm to maintain a favourable market position because its competitors must use less productive or profitable substitutes. Firms therefore benefit from the ownership of strategic assets, but in contrast to the other sources of competitive advantage, there is no reason why another firm – if these assets were transferred – would not do equally well. It is therefore not entirely clear if strategic assets should be classed as a capability in the first place, as it does not really describe a capability that is unique to the firm. What it certainly is, however, is a source of competitive advantage, which is why we include it here. There are numerous strategic assets a firm might try to capture. The important point is that once a firm has ownership of the asset, other firms that are otherwise just as capable would be in a worse competitive position than that firm. Activity 6.3 The following are all examples of strategic assets. What would you do as a competitor if one of your rivals had access to such an asset and you did not? 45 MN3119 Strategy •• A patent for a painkilling substance. Assume you do not have a comparable substance ready. •• A taxi licence – all taxi licences are currently allocated (and not traded). •• A prime location for a retail site for which your competitor has signed a long-term lease. •• Your rival has entered a market and is making profits of £100,000 at the moment. It would cost you £70,000 to enter the market, and profits if both firms were active in the market would be £60,000 each. 6.4 The dynamics of resource and capability building We now have a look at the process of capability building. A firm’s capabilities are very much like an asset – in balance sheets, the term ‘goodwill’ often represents the amount of brand equity or intangible assets a firm possesses. In some important ways, however, a firm’s capabilities differ from, say, a piece of production equipment. First, capability cannot be built up immediately. Second, its returns are uncertain. Third, having built up some capabilities, it may become easier to build up even more.3 We now describe the process of capability building (or asset stock accumulation in Dierickx and Cool’s terms) in more detail. An important distinction we have to make is between stocks and flows. While the current stock of a firm’s capabilities will give firms different strategic options, another important goal of strategy has to be the building up of stocks by regulating the flow in and out of the resource pool. Numerous established firms, for example, neglect to replenish their capability pool, which eventually leads them to lose their competitive advantage. On the other hand, young firms that are doing their utmost to catch up with the industry leaders will find it hard to match their capability level immediately. The important distinction to make is the following: Rule While flows can be adjusted immediately, stocks cannot. Hence, the imitability of stocks of resources depends on how resources are accumulated. Bearing in mind that current stock levels affect a firm’s ability to implement some strategies successfully, it is easy to see that a firm’s capabilities may be a sustainable source of competitive advantage – after all, it will take a challenger some time to build up the same capabilities. Asset stock accumulation has a number of special features, which we will discuss in turn. In building up a firm’s capabilities, success often breeds success, which is called asset mass efficiencies by Dierickx and Cool (1989). If you are a successful firm, it is easier to attract good employees, which is likely to make you even more successful, and so on. Similarly, if your technology gathers a sufficiently large following, you will receive user feedback that will enable you to improve your technology further (this is similar to network effects – as you become more successful, you are likely to become even more successful). There is, however, also a flipside to this – when starting from scratch, it is very difficult to get a ‘foot in the door’ since the first step is usually the most difficult and most expensive to make. Asset attrition will work against the stability of an asset stock. As mentioned before, if a firm fails to reinvest in replenishing its current asset stock, it will deteriorate over time and its reputation wanes, employees 46 3 Of course, these properties may still exist for physical assets to some extent, but generally they are regarded as being more common for capabilities or knowledge assets than physical ones. Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm leave, the product goes out of date, and so on. Possessing a competitive advantage cannot be taken for granted; as difficult as it may be for a challenger, it is also crucial to keep up a firm’s own investment. As we have seen before, stocks cannot be immediately adjusted – the reason for this is time compression diseconomies whereby it is less efficient to invest double the amount of resources in one period than it is to spread investment over two periods. This means that a firm trying to catch up with an incumbent will either have to spend considerably more than a firm with an existing asset stock or accept that it is going to take an long time of taking small steps to finally match the incumbent’s asset stock. Anyone who has tried to study for an exam by revising all the material two days before the exam will soon realise that it is much more efficient to study a moderate amount every day or every week, since the knowledge gained has more time to be absorbed. This will also be the case for a firm’s ability to innovate – if all the possible innovation paths are pursued at once, it is most likely to experience some shortages in terms of researchers, coordination problems regarding research findings or perhaps a lack of cross-fertilisation regarding unsuccessful research trajectories that might be duplicated. Also, asset stocks may be interconnected with each other. For example, the ability to innovate will be inextricably linked to the ability to design successful products for the market and the ability to roll out such products to end consumers. If either of the three steps falls short, the value of the others will decrease. For example, an engineering-focused firm might be better off building up marketing capabilities instead of investing yet more in the perfection of the production process for two reasons: first, returns to investment in marketing might be much higher than returns to further investment in the production process, and second, a well-manufactured product is likely to benefit considerably from being sold effectively – that is, the asset stocks are interconnected. Finally, every resource accumulation process has a random element, in particular for cases of capability building – for example, in firms where employees are a large part of a firm’s capabilities, because it is not always possible to predict when employees will leave the firm, this may have a dramatic effect on the firm’s competitiveness. Although this is not something a firm can actively influence, it is at least important for this to be taken into account, for example, by scenario planning or making allowances for periods of high or low asset stock growth. 6.5 Key concepts • Competitive advantage • Resources • Capabilities • Architecture • Reputation • Innovation • Strategic asset • Asset mass efficiency • Asset attrition • Time compression diseconomies. 47 MN3119 Strategy 6.6 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • link resources and distinctive capabilities • identify some sources of competitive advantage • describe the process of capability building. 6.7 Sample examination questions 1. ‘Reputation is hard to build up, but easy to lose.’ Does this mean that reputation is an even stronger source of competitive advantage or a weaker source than we discussed in this chapter? 2. Celebrity endorsements are often used to substitute for consumers’ experience with a particular product. What are the advantages and risks of using celebrities as ‘reputation-builders’? 3. In light of the sources of competitive advantage outlined in this chapter, explain the success of Japanese Keiretsu and Korean Chaebols. Do you think that this source of competitive advantage will be stable over time? Which factors could destabilise it? 4. Firms in network industries can often sustain a long-term advantage over their competitors. Does this imply that network effects are another source of competitive advantage that has been missed? Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. Extended activity: Dell Computer Corporation Read the following and answer the questions at the end. Dell Computer Corporation – an analysis of the PC industry. The personal computer industry: History Electronic computers emerged from military research undertaken during the Second World War. In 1949, the magazine Popular Mechanics predicted that ‘Computers in the future may perhaps only weigh 1.5 tons’. For the following three decades, large mainframe and minicomputers, produced by vertically integrated firms like IBM and Digital Equipment Corporations (DEC) dominated the market. In 1977, Kenneth Olson, founder of mini computer maker DEC, said, ‘There is no reason for any individual to have a computer in their home’ (MacIntyre, 1977). However, electronic hobbyists were already purchasing mail order and retail kits, which allowed them to assemble simple computers at home. Between 1975 and 1981, a group of firms began to offer increasingly integrated, pre-assembled personal computers (PCs) (Das Narayandas and Kasturi Rangan, 1996). Start-ups such as Apple Computer, MITS and Commodore led the early market and were gaining popularity among hobbyists and educational institutions with their easy-to-use machines. Established firms including Texas Instruments, Hewlett-Packard, Zenith, Nec, Xerox, IBM, Toshiba, Sanyo, Sony, Olivetti, Wang and DEC soon joined the entrepreneurs and began to produce PCs. IBM launched its first PC in 1981 and, two years later, held 42 per cent of the market. On the mainframe market, IBM produced many of the components and commanded a 61 per cent market share (Steffens, 48 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm 1994a). In launching its PC, however, IBM purchased many components. It commissioned a start-up software firm Microsoft, to write the operating systems for its PCs and adopted a microprocessor architecture designed by Intel. Most of the industry simply followed the IBM standards and, by 1983, the major alternative standard, a proprietary system by Apple, held only 20 per cent of the market (Steffens, 1994b). IBM used its huge sales force to sell PCs to large corporate accounts. To serve small businesses and individuals IBM turned to retail stores such as Sears and Computerland (Chposky and Leonsis, 1988). These resellers not only sold PCs, they also guided the customers though the purchase of what was still an unfamiliar product. As the demand for IBM PCs grew rapidly, other firms began to offer ‘IBM clones’. Compaq entered the market with a low-priced PC in 1982 and booked a $100 million revenue during its first year. A large number of start-ups followed the Compaq example, and entered the market with IBM clones. Among these entrants was Dell Computer Corporation (Dell), founded in 1984. By 1986, IBM realised that it had set the standard, but that it had outsourced the most valuable components of the PC, the microprocessor and the operating system, to Intel and Microsoft. In 1986, IBM declined to adopt Intel’s third-generation microprocessor, the 386 chip. By introducing its PS/2 line of computers in 1987, IBM tried to make the PC more proprietary. Compaq adopted the 386 chip and led a group of nine clone makers in affirming the existing industry standards (Microsoft, Intel). Though IBM eventually accepted the 386 microprocessor, its market share had fallen from 37 per cent in 1985 to 17 per cent in 1989 (Das Narayandas and V. Kasturi Rangan, 1996). Microsoft released its new operating system Windows 3.0 in 1990, and over the next four years, the user-friendly Windows became the PC standard. ‘Wintel’, the combination of the Windows operating system and Intel’s x86 microprocessor architecture dominated the market. By 1991, between 85 and 90 per cent of computers sold conformed to Microsoft/ Intel standards, with the remainder using the proprietary Apple operating system and a Motorola microprocessor. The initial surge in sales of the PCs slowed down in 1990, just as a recession hit the United States. The result was vigorous price competition. For example, Dell ran advertisements in 1990 showing that its prices were much lower than Compaq’s prices. Compaq usually discounted its PCs well below the list price, but the advertising campaign was highly effective. In response, Compaq slashed its prices by as much as 32 per cent, introduced 41 new products in 1992 and added a new distribution channel (Steffens, 1994). The inevitable price war followed. The demand growth recovered in the mid-1990s, caused by strong economic growth and the emergence of new, popular services involving computer networks. The growing popularity of email and the world wide web gave individual customers new reasons to buy a PC. However, PC prices continued to decline. Compaq offered a powerful personal computer for less than $1000 in 1997. By December 1998, the prices of the least expensive models had dropped below $500. Source Kramer, N. under the supervision of Dr T. Kretschmer ‘Dell Computer Corporation – an analysis of the PC industry’, LSE case study, July 2003. 49 MN3119 Strategy Current situation and trends Hardware components such as housings, keyboards, memory chips, motherboards, disk drives, monitors, modems and connectors can be purchased in highly competitive global markets, served by numerous companies. In contrast, microprocessors and operating systems are supplied by only a handful of companies. Standardisation permits compatibility and interchangeability between different computer and software systems. At the moment the standard is Wintel. Microsoft Windows is installed on 97 per cent of all computer systems (due to Network Effects), compared with just 1.43 per cent for Apple Macintosh and 0.26 per cent for Linux (www.wininformant.com; September 2002). Intel microprocessors are on 82.8 per cent of all PCs (http://news.com). The hardware and software that makes up a PC are often sold as an integrated bundle. PC makers such as IBM, Compaq, and Dell deliver computers with a Microsoft operating system already installed and, in turn, pay a fee to Microsoft. Increasingly, PCs are being delivered with pieces of ‘application software’ already installed. A number of vendors offer application software such as word processors, spreadsheets, database management systems, web browsers and electronic messaging software. In this market Microsoft holds a strong position as well, with a share of 80 per cent of the market for the so-called ‘office productivity applications’ and approximately 10 per cent of the overall market for application software (Microsoft Corporation Annual Report, 2001). As the processing costs decline, the lines between PCs and other devices are becoming blurred. At the lower end of the processing and memory spectrum handheld electronic organisers are beginning to compete with PCs for applications such as email and portable computing. Furthermore, an observer of the distribution channel reported that a number of distributors, resellers and retailers are exploring ‘strategic alternatives’ as the result of the bad availability of certain models of PCs (Anastasi, Johnson, Drennan Lane and Spinner, 1998). MicroAge, one of the resellers that has set up assembly line operations, has established the brand name ‘Pinacor’ for its distribution operation (Lyons, 1998). The retailer CompUSA has started to sell inexpensive computers under its own brand name (Lyons, 1998). Customers PC buyers are usually divided into four categories: large and mid-size businesses and government institutions; small businesses and offices; individual consumers and educational institutions. 1. Large and mid-size businesses and government institutions Large and mid-size businesses and government institutions usually have significant Management Information Systems (MIS) departments that purchase maintain and support PCs in a centralised fashion. Staff members are highly knowledgeable about PCs and are charged with providing a reliable network of high-performance computers while also controlling the information system costs. Once a PC has been purchased, the MIS staff train the users and help the users when they encounter problems. 2. Small businesses and offices Such organisations typically lack MIS staff. However, virtually all businesses have extensive experience with PCs. Reliability, performance, support, service, price, brand and channel recommendations play an important role in the choice of a PC. 50 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm 3. Individual consumers Individual consumers purchase PCs for home or home-office use. Individual buyers are very diverse, but tend to be more sensitive to price and more interested in a computer’s brand name than business buyers (Kay, 1999). Some customers also pay attention to the brand of the microprocessor. This is why Intel has spent an estimated $4 billion on brand advertising for its microprocessors since 1990 (Intel Corporation Annual Reports 1990–2001). Among the individual consumers in the US, 30 per cent of the purchasers were first time buyers in 1998. By 2000 this figure had dropped to 16 per cent (International Data Corporation, 2000). 4. Educational institutions Apple was more successful in selling its PCs to educational institutions, since it was the most user-friendly program in the 1990s. However, more and more educational institutions are purchasing Wintel PCs at the moment, since it is the industry standard. Channels PCs flow from manufacturers to customers via four channels: retail stores, distributors (working with small resellers), integrated resellers and direct distribution (Kasturi Rangan and Bell, 1998). 1. Retail stores Retailers such as Circuit City and CompUSA in the United States and Time Computers in Europe take delivery of PCs directly from manufacturers. Machines then pass through distribution centres owned by the retailers on their way to the stores. In these stores, retail displays and sales people play an important role in helping customers select models and manufacturers. According to a survey 93 per cent of the customers accepted the retailer’s recommendations concerning computer purchases (Fattah, 1998). The distributors and retailers have marked up the hardware by a total of 5–7 per cent in recent years (Fortuna and Pappachan, 2001). Moreover, shelf space is limited and even large superstores carry only three to five brands of PCs. These retailers operate on very thin margins. CompUSA for example had a gross margin of roughly 7–9 per cent on computers (CompUSA Annual Reports, 1998–2001). 2. Distributors (working with small resellers) A handful of large distributors such as Ingram Micro and Tech Data supply a full range of computer hardware and software to nearly 100,000 resellers (Fattah, 1998). The resellers are typically small owner-managed firms. 3. Integrated resellers Integrated resellers such as MicroAge and Vanstar operate distribution centres, field extensive sales and service organisation, and in some cases, manage the PC network of clients on an ongoing basis. 4. Direct distibution A fourth and final channel leads directly from the PC manufacturer to the customer. Only a few PC manufacturers take orders direct from the customers, either over the telephone and internet or by an internal sales force. They then deliver PCs via third party shippers like UPS or TNT Logistics. Most PC manufacturers (HP, IBM, Fujitsu Siemens and NEC) use indirect channels to deliver the PCs to the customers (first three combinations). The general approach to selling PCs through indirect channels is shown in Figure 6.1. 51 MN3119 Strategy Component Component manufacturer Order Forecast PC manufacturer Corporate customer Distributor Product Product Figure 1: PC sales through indirect channels. Manufacturers usually agree to buy back channel inventory that cannot be sold. In addition, they provide price protection to resellers and distributors, which means that if the price of the computer falls while it is in the distribution channel, the manufacturer will reimburse the reseller or distributor accordingly. By one estimate, inventory buy-backs and price protection cost PC manufacturers 2.5 cents on every dollar of revenue (Fortuna and Pappachan, 2001). Dell Computer Corporation – history While a first year undergraduate at the University of Texas at Austin, 18-year-old Michael Dell started a part-time business in his dorm room. He formatted hard disks for PCs and added extra memory, disk drives and modems to IBM clones, selling them for as much as 40 per cent less than the comparable IBM machines. Reluctant to reveal his distraction from his studies, Dell hid his PCs in his roommate’s bathtub when his parents came to visit (www.dell.com). When revenues reached $80,000 per month in 1984, Dell dropped out of college and founded Dell Computer Corporation. Already companies such as Exxon and Mobil were clamouring for 50 to 100 of Dell’s machines at a time (Das Narayandas and V. Kasturi Rangan, 1996). In 1985, Dell shifted from upgrading the machines of other manufacturers to assembling Dellbranded PCs. Revenue rose each subsequent year. Between 1994 and 2003, the revenue of Dell rose from $3.5 billion to $35.4 billion and profits increased from $149 million to $2.1 billion (as can be seen from Exhibit 3, p.162). Between 1994 and 1998, Dell grew twice as fast as its major rivals in the PC market and tripled its market share (www.dell.com). In the 2003 Forbes magazine list of the richest Americans, Michael Dell, the 37-year-old founder of Dell, was ranked 11th with an estimated worth of $11.2 billion (Forbes, 2003). However, the basic elements of Dell’s Direct Model that came together early in the company’s history still remained in place in 2003. The company deals direct with end customers. It serves primarily corporate customers and offers them high-performance PCs at relatively low prices. PCs are customised to buyer specifications and assembly commences only after Dell receives an order. To quote Michael Dell: ‘It was too late to challenge the technical standard and the dealer network had been done already. Compaq was very strong in retail. A new marketing and distribution strategy was something new, however’ (Michael Dell quoted in John R. Halbrooks, How to really deliver superior customer service). The direct business model The core of Dell’s competitive advantage is the direct business model. The underlying principles of the model will be analysed more extensively now. 52 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm Start here with the customer Dell customers communicate and buy from Dell in three ways: www.dell.com Voice-to-voice Face-to-face Kitting Based on the Traveler, all internal parts and components required to make the system are picked and placed into a tote. Just in-time inventory Dell receives only the materials that are immediately ready to use and only those specified as desirable to that particular customer. Custom-designed computers The Traveler is a sheet that contains all of the customer’s unique configuration information. This document travels with the system throughout the assembly and shipping. Built-to-order A team of workers uses the kit to assemble and initally test the entire system Testing and system integration Systems are then extensively tested using Dell diagnostics. Standard or custom hardware is factory installed and tested. Boxing, shipping and delivery The build-to-order cycle takes less than five hours from start to finish. Figure 2: The direct sell and build to customer-model (Ng and Lovelock, 2000). Dell pioneered a new business model that focused on speed of execution and minimum inventory. To this end, the company bypassed the dealer channel, selling products direct to customers over the phone or web (compare Figure 3 with Figure 1). Component Order Dell Computer Corporation Component manufacturer Distributor Corporate customer Product Figure 3: The Dell direct model. 53 MN3119 Strategy The direct model has several key advantages. By eliminating the intermediaries, Dell can dramatically reduce its channel costs. Exhibit 2, p.170, shows that channel costs amount to 2 per cent under the direct model compared with 13–15 per cent for indirect sales. Besides, Dell relies on Information Technology (IT) to tightly control its value chain and achieve a high degree of coordination. Procurement Dell works closely with suppliers to arrange just-in-time delivery of parts. From 1992 to 1998, Dell had reduced the number of suppliers for its Austin facility from 204 to 47 (Kasturi Rangan and Bell, 1998). With the remaining suppliers, Dell maintains close electronic links, communicating replenishment needs to some vendors on an hourly basis (Dell annual report 2001). Most of the suppliers keep the components warehoused less than 20 minutes away from Dell’s factories. Moreover, suppliers assign engineers to Dell’s design teams, who are stationed in Dell plants during new product introductions. The electronic links allow Dell to direct some suppliers’ shipments straight to the customers. Computer monitors supplied by Sony, for instance, never pass through Dell’s facilities (www.dell.com). Dell trusts Sony to provide high-quality monitors, so it is unnecessary to truck them to Round Rock (Austin, Texas), test them and then ship them (with the rest of the PC) to the customer. ‘That’s big waste of time and money, unless we get our jollies from touching monitors, which we don’t’, says Dell (Dell, M., 1998). Dell utilises the information to get its suppliers in line with its highvelocity model. This is achieved either directly, by improving the logistics, or indirectly, by enhancing quality. For example, when a defective part is identified, Dell lets the supplier know what was wrong with the part, so it can quickly redesign the part and the poor-quality problem is fixed immediately. Operations Dell operates facilities in Austin, Texas; Limerick, Ireland; Penang, Malaysia; Alvorada, Brazil and Xiamen, China. Dell puts a strong emphasis on its operations. Every PC manufactured by Dell is specifically configured to a customer’s order. Once received, an order is electronically sent to the appropriate manufacturing facility. In the facilities the Dell PCs are manufactured to order. This means that there are virtually no finished goods in inventory and little work in progress. Since materials move faster in Dell factories, the latest technology is introduced faster than through slow-moving indirect channels. As Dell remarks, ‘If I’ve got 11 days of inventory and my competitor has 80, and Intel comes out with a new microprocessor, that means I’m going to get to market 69 days sooner’ (Dell, M., 1998). The direct model reduces the high risk of obsolescence associated with products in a rapidly changing technological market (Dell annual report 2000). This is very important, since component prices decline very rapidly. The prices of vital components dropped approximately 25 per cent per quarter over the last few years (Aizcorbe, 2002). Components arrive from suppliers just in time for manufacturing through the factory’s cargo doors. Manufacturing is synchronised to avoid storing parts or finished systems. Teams build systems from start to finish. Team members have profit sharing incentives, and hourly data on their performance are posted in large monitors on the factory floor, so each team knows if they are achieving their targets. Since there are no finished goods in inventory a system is taken out of the factory as soon as it is complete. 54 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm Outbound logistics PCs are shipped directly to the consumers. As mentioned above, items such as monitors never pass through Dell facilities. Dell trusts Caliber and UPS to manage the logistics so the PC and the monitor are properly matched even though the former comes from Austin (Texas), and the latter from Sony’s factory in Mexico. Marketing and sales Dell sells direct to the consumers. The direct model eliminates the need to support an extensive network of wholesale and retail dealers. The dealer mark-ups and the higher inventory cost associated with the wholesale and retail channels are avoided. The model also avoids the competition for shelf space. As mentioned before, retail shelf space is limited, and even large superstores typically carry only three to five brands. Segmentation Figure 4 shows Dell’s customer segments. They can be classified as ‘transactional’ or ‘relationship’. Small customers (Business/Customer) Large customer Global enterprises Global enterprises Large companies Mid-size companies Mid-size companies Government Federal State/ Local Education Higher education K-12 Small customers Small business Consumer Figure 4: Dell Customer Segments (2001). Transactional customers are individuals or businesses who make transaction-buying decisions. These customers focus on the economics of the purchase, looking at factors such as performance, specifications, features, reviews and awards. On the lookout for the best PC for a particular application, they shop from a variety of vendors and use an array of information sources, including reviews, advertising and word of mouth when making their purchase decision. Dell does best with more experienced computer buyers. First-time buyers tend to be in the market for low-priced PCs, have more intensive service needs and feel more comfortable with a salesperson. Consequently, Dell focuses on ‘computerliterate’ customers. Relationship customers, in contrast, consider the cost over the life cycle of the PCs. Price is only a secondary concern (several studies have shown that the total cost of ownership of a PC over its life cycle is 5–10 times its purchase cost). Most of them are business, government or education accounts in medium-to-large scale organisations. These customers focus on attributes such as service, reliability, vendor reputation and product standardisation. 55 MN3119 Strategy Forty per cent of customers, mainly large corporate accounts, are classified as relationship customers. Thirty per cent consisting of mainly consumer and small businesses are classified as transactional. The remaining 30 per cent is a mix of the two. This customer segmentation drives the organisational structure of the company. Demand management Dell’s close relationship with its customers improves its demand forecasts. Dell tries to understand the future computing needs of large accounts by discussing their company’s needs and jointly planning the company’s infrastructure. With transaction accounts, the telephone sales representatives try to steer the customer towards product configurations that are readily available. For example, if a customer requests a certain configuration over the phone, the sales representative may suggest that for a small incremental payment, the customer will get a component with significantly higher quality (and faster), because the component is already in stock. Sales representatives’ commissions are based on gross margins. Dell designed its information systems so the gross margin is calculated for each system and displayed on the sales representative’s computer screen. Sales organisation Dell’s sales organisation consists of teams of field account executives and telephone sales representatives. Account executives are responsible for selling products and services tailored to the needs of customers in their geographical area. The telephone sales representatives are responsible for processing orders and handling sales calls. Relationship accounts are assigned to both account executives and telephone sales representatives. Transactional customers are solely handled by telephone sales representatives. The roles of the sales representative varies with the customer segment served. For example, customers in the consumer segment only rely on the sales representative for technical advice, so they can impact the purchase decision. On the other hand, when dealing with large firms, whose purchasing departments predetermine system configurations, the sales representative’s role is reduced to order-entry. www.dell.com Michael Dell got interested in the internet in the early nineties. Listening to industry ‘buzz’ and noting that he could order t-shirts online, it struck him that a customer could order anything over the internet, including a computer. Dell said: ‘We think about internet commerce as a logical extension of our direct model… I’m only half joking when I say that the only thing better than the internet would be telepathy. Because what we’re all about is shrinking the time and the resources it takes to meet customers’ needs. And we’re trying to do that in a world where those needs are changing’ (Dell, 1998). Dell had a number of natural advantages for selling on the internet. Corporations and computer-literate customers that were willing to buy over the phone were among the first to be ready to make purchases on the internet. Further, unlike rivals Compaq, HP, and IBM, Dell did not have an existing indirect channel that would feel threatened by direct internet sales, and the discipline imposed by tracking campaigns and direct telephone sales was applicable to internet as well. Dell’s internet site: www.dell.com, was launched in July 1996. By December 1996, ‘Dell’s direct sales reached $1 million a day. Dell’s webbased sales continued to grow, and by the end of 2002, the company’s 56 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm online sales generated $44 million in daily revenue, about half of the total sales (Bob Kaufman, spokesperson Dell; www.dell.com). The web pages on www.dell.com mirror Dell’s segmentation strategy, with the business unit in charge of each customer segment having the autonomy to deliver the content for its segment. The same applies to international customers. More than three dozen regional Dell websites are customised for particular countries or regions. Dell’s website was initially geared to its transaction customers, who were enthusiastic about making purchases by clicking a button for ordering the configuration they had just put together. The internet proved to be a natural and more efficient extension of Dell’s direct model. ‘I couldn’t imagine a more powerful creation for extending our business’ (Dell, 1999). The internet enabled Dell to decrease the direct cost of configuration, ordering, tracking and support for its transactional business by approximately 15 per cent. Part of these savings come from the increased efficiency of the sales process. Under the traditional direct model, Dell would mail out catalogues to prospective buyers. On average, about 10 per cent of the catalogues mailed would lead to sales calls, with about 20 per cent of calls resulting in actual sales. About 0.5 per cent of the site visits resulted in sales through the internet channel, and about 5 per cent resulted in telephone calls (these statistics are available to Dell, because the website lists separate toll-free numbers, enabling tracking). Because customers who called after browsing the website already have the necessary information and are more inclined to buy, the time to close a sale is shorter and, in addition, the probability of a sale is almost twice as high. As a result, sales representatives working phone orders that originated from web browsers are about 50 per cent more productive than Dell’s pure telephone-based sales representatives. The internet also increases Dell’s service efficiencies. For example, customers who wanted to track their shipments call Dell about three times on average to find order status. Dell’s web-based order tracking system replaced more than two-thirds of these phone calls (www.dell.com). At the beginning, convincing large corporate customers to buy through the web was a challenge and some customers felt Dell was asking them to radically change the way they purchased computers. To overcome this resistance, Dell studied how large customers evaluated and acquired systems, discovering a diversity of practices with no ‘one size fits all’ solution. In autumn 1997, Dell developed ‘Dell Premier Pages’ that could scale by the thousands using software tools that allowed a sales team to develop a new customised Premier site in less than a day. This enabled Dell to extend the program to medium- and small-sized enterprises. These Premier Pages allow the customer to carry out standard transactions such as configuration, price quotes and purchasing, but also track order and inventory in systematic detail and provide him with online asset management support. By September 2000, Dell had more than 50,000 customised Premier sites. After-sales service Dell offers custom-tailored service and support systems (Dell annual report 2000). Dell offers a broad range of service and support programs through its own technical personnel and its direct management of specialised service suppliers. After a sale, Dell supports its products in several ways. Dell uses www.dell.com as an electronic backbone of the after-sales service 57 MN3119 Strategy and offers approximately 60,000 pages of customer support information. A customer with a problem could also reach a technical support staff of 1,500 representatives via a hotline that is manned 24 hours a day. Using the diagnostic software installed in the factory, the customer and the specialist can resolve the problem over the phone in approximately 90 per cent of cases. Dell employs third-party maintenance providers like Unisys, Wang and Decision One Consulting, who send out technicians to tackle problems that require on-site support. These problems are usually solved within 24–48 hours. Even though field service is outsourced, Dell maintains accountability for customer service. This way Dell can provide service somewhat comparable to that of the resellers, but at lower cost. Leaving the direct business model In 1990 Dell departed from its direct business model and entered the retail channel. The move, Michael Dell said, would ‘provide us with the opportunity to generate significant new business and increase Dell’s market penetration’, especially among ‘PC customers – particularly at the entry level – who want to physically “feel and touch” a unit before they buy’ (Dell Press Release, 1990). Accordingly, Dell produced two lines of standard PCs and reached distribution agreements with computer superstores such as CompUSA. Sales through the retail channel were considerable, but Dell soon found out that it was losing money on it. Dell’s operation income was –3 per cent of the revenues through the retail channel (versus a +5 per cent operation income via direct sales (Das Narayandas and Kasturi Rangan, 1996). In 1994, Dell wisely withdrew from retail sales. Surprisingly, last July, Dell started to experiment with kiosks in shopping malls. Since launching the initiative, it has opened more than 60 kiosks in nine states. Recently, Dell announced it is ramping up its kiosk presence by placing them in Sears stores. These kiosks are mini-stores, about 10–12 feet wide, with basic inventory and Dell salespeople. A Dell Spokesman, Bob Kaufman, explains that the kiosks enable mall shoppers to ‘go in and touch and feel some of our product and then either order right there (online of course) or go back home and order’ (Maquire, 2003). Isn’t it ironic that a part of a giant’s expansion effort is geared towards the traditional retail, again? Some call it an odd hybrid: a bricks-and-mortar mini-store with an e-commerce option. Analysts of the sector note that one of the advantages of Sears kiosk placement is that, in comparison to the Dell site, the department store’s foot traffic contains a higher percentage of women and shoppers who are over 55. Competition Exhibit 2, p.60, shows that Dell was the only top five computer manufacturer to grow steadily, in both turnover and market share, in the five years to 2002. Furthermore, Exhibit 3 to 9 pp.61–67, show that Dell reported a higher net profit margin than its major competitors (Apple, Fujitsu Siemens, Gateway, Hewlett-Packard and NEC) over 2001 and 2002. Only IBM performed better than Dell. However, most profits and revenues of IBM are generated in departments other then its Personal and Printing Systems Department. The Personal and Printing Systems Department represented 14 per cent of IBM’s revenues and reported a pre-tax income of $57 million and a pre-tax profit margin of 0.5 per cent in 2002 (IBM Annual Report). Despite the bad performance of the Personal and Printing Systems Department in 2002, the corporate net profit margin was a reasonable 6.6 per cent. 58 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm To summarise, it can be said that Dell outperforms its competitors in the PC industry. Needless to say, Dell’s rapid growth and superior financial results caused its rivals to take both notice and action. Competitors realised that Dell’s sales increase was caused by the explosive growth of the direct and online sales. In October 1998, HP launched a modest effort to set up direct sales on the world wide web. HP Shopping Village (www.hpshopping.com), a web service previously providing refurbished HP computers to individuals, was expanded to allow consumers to buy new PCs direct from HP. Business customers could use a similar website to purchase HP PCs (also similar to IBM’s first website), except HP required businesses to complete purchases though resellers. Lew Platt, former CEO of HP, hinted that business customers might not have to go through resellers in the future ‘You can’t ignore what Dell has done…I could give you a list of names of really large customers who have said to HP: “Either do business with us directly or you are not going to do business with us”.’ (Exhibit 4, p.172, provides financial information for HP). Gateway 2000, founded in an Iowa farmhouse in 1985, is the world’s second largest direct marketer, and like Dell, only sells direct to customers. Gateway takes orders from the customers, produces PCs to their specifications, loads software onto the PCs, and ships the machines to customers. Its sales surged at an annual clip of 39 per cent from 1991 to 1996 and surpassed Dell’s US sales briefly in 1994. In 1997, however, sales growth slowed to 25 per cent, and net income fell by half. Until the year 2000, Gateway’s net revenue grew steadily, but since then sales have dropped sharply in 2001 and 2002 (Exhibit 5, p.173, provides financial information for Gateway). Following the lead of its rivals, IBM introduced its first program to enable businesses to buy a small set of products direct: by the end of 1998, the Netfinity Direct program allowed large enterprises to purchase a particular line of IBM servers without going through resellers. IBM began selling its full line of PCs via the internet in May 1999. In December 1999, IBM’s online sales totalled $38 million, but only 7 per cent of that came from small businesses and consumers. Consequently, IBM planned a direct sales assault in 2000. IBM built up its ‘build-to-order’ manufacturing capabilities, which it considered a crucial element in selling PCs and servers directly and started a huge marketing campaign to promote direct selling. Despite various attempts by competitors to lessen Dell’s position in the direct channel, Dell remains the dominant player. In the US for example, Dell shipped more than half of the PCs sold direct. A strong position considering the fact that for the first time in history direct sales accounted for more than half of the shipments in the US in the second quarter of 2002 (Gartner Dataquest, 2002). Up until now Dell’s senior management appears unconcerned about the efforts of rivals. Concerning competitors’ plans to sell direct, Michael Dell once joked, ‘It is like we’re the best baseball player and Compaq is the best basketball player. Now they want to play baseball’ (Serwer, 1997). 59 MN3119 Strategy Exhibit 1. Channel economics: direct v indirect channels Channel mark-up Indirect Direct 5.0–7.0% 0.0% Co-op marketing 3.0% 0.0% Financing 1.0% 1.0% Price protection* 2.5% 0.0% Obsolescence 1.5% 1.0% Total 13.0–15.0% 2.0% Source: Presentation of Mike Winkler, Senior VP, Compaq Computer, 2001 * Price protection is a scheme whereby the PC manufacturer protects resellers from losses on unsold computers when their price is reduced. Exhibit 2. Wordwide PC market shares (units sold) 2002 Rank Vendor 2002 1999 1998 1997 1 Dell 15.2% 12.9% 10.6% 9.8% 7.9% 5.5% 2 HP* 13.6% 6.9% 7.6% 6.4% 5.8% 5.3% 3 IBM 5.9% 6.2% 6.8% 7.9% 8.2% 8.6% 4 Fujitsu Siemens** 4.3% 4.5% n/a – – – 5 NEC*** 3.3% 3.6% 4.6% 5.2% 4.3% 5.1% Compaq* – 11.1% 12.7% 13.2% 13.8% 13.1% Others 57.7% 54.8% – – – – 136 114 93 81 Total units (millions) 2001 134 2000 127 Source: International Data Corporation, January 2003 * 2002 Data for Hewlett-Packard includes shipments for the new Hewlett-Packard (including Compaq merger) starting in Q2 2002, and only Hewlett-Packard data for Q1 2002. 2001 data includes only Hewlett-Packard data (excluding Compaq). This reflects the legal status of the companies, which merged in Q2 2002 ** The 50–50 joint venture was formed in 1999 through the merger of the European computer operations of global giants Fujitsu and Siemens *** Data for DEC includes Packard Bell Shipments are vendor-branded shipments into distribution channels or direct to end users Data for all vendors are reported for calendar periods 60 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm Exhibit 3. Dell Computer Corp. financial performance (in $; B=Billion, M=Million, K= Thousand) Income statement 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 Net revenue 35.4B 31.2B 31.9B 25.3B 18.2B 12.3B Expenses 32.6B 29.4B 29.2B 23.0B 16.2B 11.0B Income before taxes 3.0B 1.7B 3.2B 2.5B 2.1B 1.4B Income taxes 905M 485M 958M 785M 624M 424M Income after taxes 2.1B 1.2B 2.2B 1.7B 1.5B 944M EPS diluted, incl. 0.8 0.46 0.79 0.61 0.53 0.32 8.9B 7.9B 9.7B 7.7B 5.8B 3.9B Balance sheet Current assets Long-term assets 15.5B 13.5B 13.7B 11.5B 6.9B 4.3B Current liabilities 8.9B 7.5B 6.8B 5.2B 3.7B 2.7B Long-term debt 506M 520M 509M 508M 512M 17M Total liabilities 10.6B 8.8B 8.0B 6.2B 4.6B 3.0B Avg. shares outstanding 2.6B 2.6B 2.6B 2.5B 2.5B 2.6B Shares outstanding 2.6B 2.6B 2.6B 2.6B 2.5B 2.6B Total equity 4.9B 4.7B 5.6B 5.3B 2.3B 1.3B Cash from operations n/a 3.8B 4.2B 3.9B 2.4B 1.6B Cash from investing n/a –2.3B –757M –1.2B Cash from financing n/a –2.7B –2.3B –695M –812M –898M Profit margin (%) 5.99 4.00 7.01 6.59 8.00 7.66 Operating margin (%) 8.55 5.55 10.02 9.70 11.42 11.10 Return on equity (%) 43.55 26.54 39.77 31.39 62.90 73.01 Return on assets (%) 13.72 9.21 16.36 14.52 21.23 22.12 Debt/equity 0.10 0.11 0.09 0.10 0.22 0.01 P/E 34.24 58.68 32.46 42.79 48.72 78.30 Current ratio 1.00 1.05 1.43 1.48 1.57 1.45 –930M –657M Ratios Source: Dell Annual Reports Note: Fiscal year-end January 61 MN3119 Strategy Exhibit 4. Hewlett-Packard Company financial performance (in $; B=Billion, M=Million, K= Thousand) Income statement 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 Net revenue 56.6B 45.2B 48.9B 42.4B 39.4B 35.5B Expenses 57.6B 43.8B 44.8B 38.6B 36.0B 32.1B Income before taxes –1.1B 702M 4.6B 4.2B 3.7B 3.6B Income taxes –129M 78M 1.1B 1.1B 1.0B 1.1B Income after taxes –923M 624M 3.6B 3.1B 2.7B 2.5B EPS diluted, incl. 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.3 0.26 36.1B 21.3B 23.2B 21.6B 18.5B 20.9B Balance sheet Current assets Long-term assets 70.7B 32.6B 34.0B 35.3B 31.7B 31.7B Current liabilities 24.3B 14.0B 15.2B 14.3B 11.9B 11.2B Long-term debt 6.0B 3.7B 3.4B 1.8B 2.1B 3.2B Total liabilities 34.4B 18.6B 19.8B 17.0B 14.8B 15.6B Avg. shares outstanding 2.5B 1.9B 2.0B 2.0B 2.1B 2.1B Shares outstanding 3.0B 1.9B 1.9B 2.0B 2.0B 2.1B Total equity 36.3B 14.0B 14.2B 18.3B 16.9B 16.2B Cash from operations 5.4B 2.6B 4.7B 3.0B 5.2B 3.9B Cash from investing 3.1B –561M –1.4B –628M –608M –2.6B Cash from financing –1.6B –1.2B –5.3B –1.0B –3.7B –1.1B Profit margin (%) –1.63 1.38 7.29 7.33 6.79 7.09 Operating margin (%) –1.86 1.55 9.46 9.90 9.37 10.06 Return on equity (%) –2.55 4.47 25.06 16.97 15.83 15.57 Return on assets (%) –1.31 1.92 10.47 8.79 8.45 7.92 Debt/equity 0.17 0.27 0.24 0.10 0.12 0.20 P/E NA 49.66 8.89 10.40 12.35 13.04 Current ratio 1.48 1.53 1.53 1.51 1.56 1.87 Ratios Source: Hewlett-Packard Annual Reports Note: Fiscal year-end October 62 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm Exhibit 5. Gateway Inc. financial performance (in $; B=Billion, M=Million, K= Thousand) Income statement 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 Net revenue 4.2B 6.1B 9.6B 9.0B 7.7B 6.3B Expenses 4.7B 7.3B 9.1B 8.4B 7.2B 6.1B Income before taxes –475M –1.3B 408M 663M 541M 203.M Income taxes –178M –275M 155M 235M 194M 93M Income after taxes –297M –1.0B 253M 427M 346M 109M EPS diluted, incl. –0.95 –3.2 0.73 1.32 1.09 0.35 2.0B 2.1B 2.3B 2.7B 2.2B 1.5B Balance sheet Current assets Long-term assets 2.5B 3.0B 4.2B 4.0B 2.9B 2.0B Current liabilities 940M 1.1B 1.7B 1.8B 1.4B 1.0B Long-term debt 0 0 0 3M 3M 7M Total liabilities 1.3B 1.4B 1.8B 1.9B 1.5B 1.1B Avg. shares outstanding 324M 323M 321M 314M 311M 307M Shares outstanding 324M 324M 323M 319M 313M 308M Total equity 1.2B 1.6B 2.4B 2.0B 1.3B 930M Cash from operations NA –270M 288M 731M 907M 442M Cash from investing NA 109M –953M –831M –356M –360M Cash from financing NA 405M 20M 54M 23M 153K Profit margin (%) –7.14 –16.69 2.64 4.77 4.50 1.74 Operating margin (%) –11.41 –21.22 4.26 7.40 7.03 3.24 Return on equity (%) –23.88 –64.81 10.64 21.22 25.77 11.81 Return on assets (%) –11.86 –33.96 6.06 10.82 11.98 5.38 Debt/equity 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 P/E NA NA 2.91 1.68 2.06 6.41 Current ratio 2.08 1.85 1.37 1.49 1.56 1.54 Ratios Source: Gateway Annual Reports Note: Fiscal year-end December 63 MN3119 Strategy Exhibit 6. International Business Machines Corp. financial performance (in $; B=Billion, M=Million, K= Thousand) Income statement 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 Net revenue 81.2B 83.1B 85.1B 87.5B 81.7B 78.5B Expenses 74.4B 73.2B 76.0B 77.8B 72.5B 69.4B Income before taxes 7.5B 11.4B 11.4B 11.8B 9.0B 9.0B Income taxes 2.2B 3.3B 3.5B 4B 2.7B 2.9B Income after taxes 5.3B 8.1B 7.9B 7.7B 6.3B 6.1B EPS diluted, incl. 0.59 0.55 0.51 0.47 0.43 0.39 Current assets 41.7B 42.5B 43.9B 43.2B 42.4B 40.4B Long-term assets 96.5B 90.3B 88.3B 87.5B 86.1B 81.5B Current liabilities 34.5B 35.1B 36.4B 39.6B 36.8B 33.5B Balance sheet Long-term debt 20.0B 16.0B 18.4B 14.1B 15.5B 13.7B Total liabilities 73.7B 66.9B 67.7B 67B 66.7B 61.7B Avg. shares outstanding 1.7B 1.7B 1.8B 1.8B 1.9B 2.0B Shares outstanding 1.7B 1.7B 1.7B 1.8B 1.9B 1.9B Total equity 22.8B 23.4B 20.6B 20.5B 19.4B 19.8B Cash from operations 13.1B 14.0B 9.0B 10.1B 9.3B 8.9B Cash from investing –6.9B –5.9B –4.0B –1.7B –6.1B –6.2B Cash from financing –7.3B –5.3B –6.4B –8.6B –5.0B –3.1B Profit margin (%) 6.57 9.81 9.25 8.81 7.75 7.76 Operating margin (%) 9.27 13.78 13.41 13.43 11.07 11.50 Return on equity (%) 23.41 34.74 38.18 37.60 32.56 30.75 Return on assets (%) 5.53 9.02 8.91 8.81 7.35 7.48 Debt/equity 0.88 0.68 0.89 0.69 0.80 0.69 P/E 26.01 17.35 18.29 19.15 24.14 26.38 Current ratio 1.21 1.21 1.21 1.09 1.15 1.21 Ratios Source: IBM Annual Reports Note: Fiscal year-end December 64 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm Exhibit 7. Apple Computer Inc. financial performance (in $; B=Billion, M=Million, K= Thousand) Income statement 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 Net revenue 5.7B 5.4B 8.0B 6.1B 5.9B 7.1B Expenses 5.7B 5.7B 7.5B 5.8B 5.7B 8.2B Income before taxes 87M –52M 1.1B 676M 329M –1.0B Income taxes 22M –15M 306M 75M 20M 0 Income after taxes 65M –37M 786M 601M 309M –1.0B EPS diluted, incl. 0.18 –0.07 2.18 1.81 1.05 –4.14 5.4B 5.1B 5.4B 4.3B 3.7B 3.4B Balance sheet Current assets Long-term assets 6.3B 6.0B 6.8B 5.2B 4.3B 4.2B Current liabilities 1.7B 1.5B 1.9B 1.5B 1.5B 1.8B Long-term debt 316M 317M 300M 300M 954M 951M Total liabilities 2.2B 2.1B 2.7B 2.1B 2.6B 3.0B Avg. shares outstanding 355M 345M 324M 286M 263M 252M Shares outstanding 359M 350M 335M 321M 270M 255M Total equity 4.1B 3.9B 4.1B 3.1B 1.6B 1.2B Cash from operations 89M 185M 868M 822M 775M 154M Cash from investing –252.0M 892M –972M –988M –543M –499M Cash from financing 105M 42M –31M 11M 19M 23M Profit margin (%) 1.13 –0.69 9.85 9.80 5.20 –14.76 Operating margin (%) 1.52 –0.97 13.68 11.02 5.54 –14.76 Return on equity (%) 1.59 –0.94 19.14 19.36 18.82 –87.08 Return on assets (%) 1.03 –0.61 11.55 11.65 7.20 –24.69 Debt/equity 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.10 0.58 0.79 P/E 79.78 NA 6.03 6.96 12.47 NA Current ratio 3.25 3.39 2.81 2.77 2.43 1.88 Ratios Source: Apple Computer Inc. Annual Reports Note: Fiscal year-end September 65 MN3119 Strategy Exhibit 8. NEC Corp. financial performance (in $ Millions) Income statement 2002 2001 2000 Net revenue 38,446 43,099 48,461 Cost of goods sold 27,833 29,725 33,044 Gross profit 10,613 13,375 15,416 Gross profit margin 27.6% 31.0% 31.8% SG&A expense 9,325 9,907 11,811 Depreciation & amortisation 1,769 1,993 2,533 Operating income –481 1,475 1,072 Operating margin –1.25% 3.40% 2.20% Total net income –2,352 451 101 Net profit margin –6.12% 1.5 % 0.21% Cash 2,847.3 3,081.9 3,630.7 Net receivables 7,064.0 8,607.0 8,772.6 Inventories 4,899.4 6,597.3 7,258.3 Total current assets 18,126.8 19,644.8 20,908.1 Total assets 37,767.0 38,429.8 44,747.2 Balance sheet Short-term debt 6,199.3 4,356.8 6,126.7 Total current liabilities 16,659.3 17,508.8 18,991.8 Long-term debt 11,297.0 9,730.1 12,875.1 Total liabilities 3,509.2 31,139.6 35,263.1 Total Equity 4,257.8 7,290.1 9,484.0 Source: NEC Annual Reports Note: Fiscal year-end March 66 Chapter 6: The resource-based view of the firm Exhibit 9. Fujitsu Siemens financial performance (in $ Millions) Income statement 2002 2001 Net revenue 4,728 5,174 Cost of goods sold 3,959 4,441 Gross profit 769 732 Gross profit margin 16.3% 14.2% SG&A expense 734 750 Operating income 35 –18 Operating margin 0.74% –0.35% Total net income -6 –57 Net profit margin –0.13% –1.10% Cash 82.4 134.7 Net receivables 806.1 1,122.1 Inventories 337.7 385.9 Total current assets 1,529.7 1,731.1 Total assets 1,697.5 1,873.0 Short-term debt 133.8 — Total current liabilities 1,044.4 1,212.6 Long-term debt 154.6 158.3 Total liabilities 1,571.1 1,736.3 Total equity 126.3 136.7 Balance sheet Source: Fujitsu Annual Reports Note: Fiscal year-end March Note: The 50–50 joint venture was formed in 1999 through the merger of the European computer operations of global giants Fujitsu and Siemens. References Anastasi, R., N. Johnson, J. Drennan Lane and S. Spinner ‘The computer sales channel: third quarter demand survey’, Robinson-Humphrey 23 September 1998. Aizcorbe, A. ‘Why are semiconductor prices falling so fast, industry estimates and implications for productivity measurement’, Federal Reserve Board March 2002. Chposky, J. and T. Leonsis Blue magic. (New York: Facts of File Books, 1988), pp. 56–66. CompUSA Annual Reports, 1998–2001. Dell, M. ‘An interview with Michael Dell’, Harvard Business Review March/April 1998, pp.72–82. Dell, M. Direct from Dell: strategies that revolutionized an industry. HarperBusiness, 1999. Dell Computer Corporation Annual Report 2000. Dell Computer Corporation Annual Report 2001. Dell Computer Corporation Press Release ‘Dell PCs to be offered through soft warehouse superstores – expands reach to individuals and small businesses’, 10 September 1990. Fattah, H. ‘1998 Forecasts: the channel fights back’, MC Technology Marketing Intelligence January 1998. ‘The Forbes 400: the richest people in America’, Forbes website, 2003. 67 MN3119 Strategy Fortuna, S. and P. Pappachan Compaq Reengineers the Channel; Will It Be Enough to Slow Dell’s Momentum?, Deutsche Morgan Grenfell Technogy Group, 2001. Gartner Dataquest 2002, Most US PC Buyers Purchase Directly from Manufacturers, internal report by Kitagawa and Smulders, 13 August 2002. www.wininformant.com/Articles/Index.cfm?ArticleID=26567 (September 2002). http://news.com.com/2100-1001-947317.html (June 2002). www.dell.com/ Intel Corporation Annual Reports 1990–2001. International Data Corporation, 2000–03. Kasturi Rangan and Bell, M. ‘Dell Online’, 1998, HBS Case 598-116. Kay, R., analyst at International Data Corporation, 22 April 1999. Lyons, D. ‘Games dealers play’, Forbes 19 October 1998, pp.132–34. MacIntyre, J. ‘Fact of life: computers’, Spirit 1997, p.170. Maguire, J. Case Study: Dell.com, 3 March 2003 (http://ecommerce.Internet.com/ news/insights/trends/article/0,,10417_2013731,00.html). Michael Dell quoted in John R. Halbrooks, How to really deliver superior customer service. (Inc Publishing, 1996) [ISBN 1880394286]. Microsoft Corporation Annual Report 2001. Narayandas, D. and Kasturi Rangan ‘Dell Computer Corporation’, 1996, HBS Case 596-058. Ng, P., P. Lovelock and A. Farhoonand ‘Dell selling directly, globally’, 2000, University of Hong Kong Case Study. Serwer, A. ‘Michael Dell turns the PC world inside out’, Fortune 8 September 1997, pp.76–86. Steffens, J. Newgames: strategic competition in PC revolution. (Oxford: Pergamon Press, 1994a), p.181. Steffens, J. Newgames: strategic competition in PC revolution. (Oxford: Pergamon Press, 1994b), p.253. Yoffie, D. ‘Apple Computer 1992’, Harvard Business School Case 792-081, p.4. Questions 1. What are Dell’s distinctive capabilities? 2. Dell has maintained their position of superior profitability for quite some time now. Combining information from the case and the chapter, explain why other firms did not imitate Dell’s business model? 3. List some other industries in which Dell’s business model might also work. Would it make sense for Dell to diversify in other businesses? 68 Chapter 7: Strategic asymmetries – persistent dominance over time Chapter 7: Strategic asymmetries – persistent dominance over time Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain sources of firm asymmetries • describe available strategies firms can employ to increase their industry dominance. Essential reading Besanko, D., D. Dranove, M. Shanley and S. Shaefer Economics of strategy. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2009) Chapter 2. Further reading Benkard, L. ‘Learning and forgetting: the dynamics of aircraft production’, American Economic Review 90(4) 2000, pp.1034–054. Cabral, L. and M. Riordan ‘The learning curve, predation, antitrust, and welfare’, Journal of Industrial Economics 45(2) 1997, pp.155–69. Klette, T. ‘R&D, scope economics, and plant performance’, Rand Journal of Economics 27(3) 1996, pp.502–22. Lieberman, M. ‘Market growth, economies of scale, and plant size in the chemical processing industries’, Journal of Industrial Economics 36(2) 1987, pp.175–91. Spence, A. ‘The learning curve and competition’, The Bell Journal of Economics 12(1) 1981, pp.49–70. 7.1 Introduction Some firms are simply better than others at what they do. There are also firms that play their game better than others or that have been able to secure an advantage over their rivals. This chapter looks at persistent asymmetries among firms and assesses features of a market that might lead to a continuing asymmetric outcome. 7.2 Firm asymmetries – long- or short-term? We have seen in the previous chapter that some firms may possess distinctive capabilities – characteristics that may enable them to outperform their competitors over an extended period of time. There are, however, reasons other than core competencies as to why a firm might be doing better than its rivals at any point in time. The regulatory setting in an industry might allow some firms to be more successful than their rivals. For example, state-owned enterprises might be protected by favourable contracts, licences might protect existing firms from entry and so on. This is similar to the ownership of strategic assets, which might not necessarily be linked to a firm doing anything particularly well, but rather with the firm having been allocated (or having acquired) a particularly scarce asset that gives it market power. 69 MN3119 Strategy Second, firms may also be successful due to historical factors. Having been present at the outset of an industry, for example, will typically give a firm an advantage over latecomers – these are the elusive ‘first-mover advantages’ that might have their roots in consumer habits over branding, technology employed, learning, network effects and lots of other factors. The main point is that in the past, some factors have contributed to a firm maintaining a dominant market position even though the factor as such is no longer a key determinant of success. Third, an advantage may also be down to luck. For example, a firm may get lucky with a new product design – for example, Bart Simpson phones (in the times before there were mobile phones) sold significantly better than other ‘gimmick’ phones in the shape of other popular cartoon characters (see also the example below). Example: Courvoisier and rappers ‘We weren’t expecting cognac to be associated with those type of people,’ said JeanMarie Macoin, a 55-year-old cognac producer after viewing Busta Rhymes’ ‘Pass the Courvoisier’ music video. To the horror of many in the close-knit cognac industry, Busta Rhymes, Jay-Z and the hip-hop community have helped to resurrect this perishing industry with an ongoing obsession for lyrics praising Courvoisier and Hennessy. To most, cognac symbolises getting drunk – a far reach from the ideals of the small French community of approximately 20,000 where hip-hop’s favourite alcoholic drink originates. An economic crisis in 1998 caused cognac’s number one market, Asia, to dramatically reduce demand for the drink – almost wiping out the cognac industry. But it was rappers who eventually brought the bottle back to life. MCs as diverse as Common and Snoop Dogg have long hailed cognac as a drink of choice, with more recent references in last year’s hit single ‘Pass the Courvoisier’ which featured a video showcasing Busta, Pharrell and P. Diddy partying it up in a bar filled with beautiful women and hundreds of gleaming bottles of Courvoisier. Songs like ‘Courvoisier’ have produced a following among urban youths, who have been known to mix the drink for new concoctions such as ‘Thug Passion’ and ‘French Connection’. Jay’s newly opened 40/40 Club even includes a ‘Remy Room’ in homage to Remy Martin, his favorite cognac brand. ‘Cognac is a classy, sophisticated and really smooth thing to drink,’ Jay-Z told The Wall Street Journal. The cognac industry is now prospering thanks to exports to the US which have almost tripled in the last 10 years. Furthermore, Americans spent approximately $1 billion on the French drink last year. Interestingly, cognac’s surging US sales are parallel to hip-hop’s mainstream growth. Americans imported 3.7 million cases of cognac last year, 36 per cent of the worldwide market compared with 1.3 million in 1993. According to The Wall Street Journal, Hennessy, America’s biggest cognac brand with 53 per cent of the market, claims that young black people represent 85 per cent of US sales. Though America’s infatuation with cognac has salvaged this industry, the flip side is that French grape growers responsible for cognac are dumbfounded by rap’s use of the brand. ‘It’s not quite the same world,’ Anne-Sophie Louvet, a 44-year-old woman who cultivates her great-grandfather’s 113-year-old vineyards told The Wall Street Journal. ‘In this region, you don’t show your wealth if you have some, and you don’t talk about money,’ she added. Last April, Courvoisier took steps to educate 900 farmers about the US market, and part of the lesson featured a presentation of the aforementioned ‘Pass the Courvoisier’ video. ‘They didn’t know what to make of it’, a Courvoisier spokewoman told The Wall Street Journal. To further familiarise themselves with their biggest consumers, Hennessy intends to fly half a dozen grape growers to tour New York City night clubs this autumn. where they will get a chance to get lifted hip-hop-style.1 70 1 Source: www.sohh.com/ Chapter 7: Strategic asymmetries – persistent dominance over time The sources of firm asymmetries – core competencies, regulation, luck and history – all help to explain the differences between firms at any point in time. More importantly, however, is to assess which asymmetries can be sustained over a longer period of time. For example, we would expect the current popularity of cognac to be short-lived – after all, the next big drink might just be around the corner. Figure 7.1 shows the evolution of the wide-body aircraft market. In the early half of the 1970s, there was vigorous competition between Boeing (B747), McDonnell Douglas (DC10) and Lockheed (L1011), but after 1975 Boeing surged ahead and strengthened its dominance (until Airbus challenged its position), meaning the market has now become a very competitive duopoly. 100 B747 DC10 L1011 Market share (%) 80 60 40 20 0 65 70 75 Year 80 85 90 Figure 7.1: Market evolution of the wide-body aircraft industry. Source: ‘Competing down the learning curve’. Case Study, Luis Cabral and Tobias Kretschmer. This example is just one of many where firms start out with a relatively modest advantage over their rivals, but then manage to extend their lead over time and end up with vastly superior market shares and profitability. For further details, please see the extended activity for this chapter. 7.3 Traditional sources of persistent dominance We will discuss three of the most important sources of increasing dominance – economies of scale, economies of scope and economies of learning. 7.3.1. Economies of scale The formal definition of economies of scale is as follows. Economies of scale – definition ACQ > ACQ ' , Q < Q ' , AC = FC + VC Q This implies that as more output (Q) is produced, the average cost per unit goes down. As we can see from the definition of average cost (AC), this effect can originate either from FC – fixed cost – or VC – variable cost. Fixed cost degression is the simplest and most intuitive form of economies of scale. If there is some fixed cost that has to be paid as soon as production starts – say, the cost of equipment, a building, some central administration – the more output is produced, the more the cost can be spread over a larger output. Fixed-cost degression is likely to exist 71 MN3119 Strategy in practically any firm as some upfront investments simply have to be made in order to start producing, but the effect of more units and the contribution of fixed cost to overall unit cost will decrease as output increases. The effect is therefore most pronounced in industries where the ratio of fixed cost to variable cost is very high. Activity 7.1 In which industries would you expect fixed cost degression to be especially relevant? Rank them and give an estimated ratio of fixed to variable cost in an average firm in this industry. •• PC software •• Hairdressing •• Handmade candles •• Car production. Ever since Adam Smith’s visit to the pin factory the specialisation of equipment or activities has been regarded as another source of scale economies. Larger quantities will allow workers to split up tasks and concentrate on a single one or will justify the purchase of a specialised piece of production equipment to automate production. (There is a nice link to fixed cost degression here – for smaller production quantities purchasing such a machine would imply a high fixed cost per unit, while large quantities will render such a machine economical.) Some products possess production or inventory economies of scale. For example, to build a pipe with double the capacity, less than twice the material is needed, creating production or technological economies of scale for liquid-based products. Similarly, queuing theory tells us (and intuition hopefully confirms) that to serve twice the number of customers arriving at random times, less than twice the inventory is required. The following example illustrates this: a chip shop will still experience some peaks in demand regardless of how many customers turn up on average. These demand peaks are not twice the size if the average number of customers is twice as high. Advertising can also demonstrate economies of scale – larger firms with more outlets will have two advantages over their smaller counterparts. First, their brand recognition is likely to be higher, so that an advertisement reaching a consumer is more likely to be recognised if it comes from a large firm. Second, even a consumer who recognises the advertisement of the smaller counterpart and would like to purchase the product will have more difficulties finding the product since it will have fewer outlets, less shelf space and so on. Both of these then will translate the same advertising dollar into more sales pounds for a larger firm – advertising economies of scale.2 Purchasing power also increases with the size of the buying firm. That is, if the input purchased by one buyer makes up a significant portion of sales by the supplier, bargaining power is high for the buyer and prices paid are likely to be low. Realising this, buyers have increasingly teamed up to form purchasing consortia – Letsbuyit.com (now defunct) is an example of individual consumers purchasing jointly to achieve better prices, and one of the main benefits of airline alliances is the ability to purchase everything jointly, in particular aircraft. There are other important sources of economies of scale, such as economies of R&D, but most of these will fall under one of the headings 72 2 We should note here that advertising is often regarded as a fixed cost and as such an economy of scale is created by distributing advertising cost over a larger output. Chapter 7: Strategic asymmetries – persistent dominance over time above. In fact, some of the economies of scale will have their roots in several of the factors mentioned above. Activity 7.2 Explain possible causes for economies of scale in the following industries or functions: a. Research and development b. Desktop publishing c. Banking d. Teaching. 7.3.2 Economies of scope In many ways, economies of scope are similar to economies of scale and the distinction is sometimes rather blurry. However, for the sake of clarity we will treat the two concepts separately, but keep in mind that many people will use these two almost interchangeably. The formal definition of economies of scope is as follows. Economies of scope – definition TC(q1,q2) < TC(q10), + TC(0,q2) It is cheaper to produce positive quantities of two different goods (q1 and q2) in the same firm than it is to produce them separately. Again (and this may be where the confusion with economies of scale comes from), this could originate from fixed cost or from variable cost (TC = FC + VC). We will discuss the most important causes in turn. An economy of scope would result from the waste of one production process being the input for another product, or input/output relations. For example, chemical processes often generate waste that can be used for other, unrelated products, thus creating a motive for merging or at least collaborating across different product classes. Similarly, as we will see later, vertical relations between firms are often subject to considerable (direct and indirect) costs, which could be avoided if the supplier and manufacturer were in the same firm. Be aware, however, that these cost savings are not always considered economies of scope as they refer to contractual incompleteness and market inefficiencies rather than technological or logistical economies; the definition of economies of scope still allows for such input/output relations to fall under it. Complementary assets are the key source of economies of scope. Many mergers of two firms from unrelated industries will be justified on the grounds that assets can be used productively in both industries. For example, banking and insurance divisions in the same firm could have access to each other’s client lists and might conceivably make the most of cross-selling opportunities – that is, selling banking clients insurance and insurance clients banking services. Complementary assets can also be physical assets, even buildings. For example, even though academic departments may not necessarily interact much, they would still be using the same lecture theatres and teach the same students. So while not every management student will take an active interest in anthropology lectures, there may be some each year that would like to take a course in anthropology, thus enabling a lecturer to teach a course that might not have been taught with anthropology students alone. 73 MN3119 Strategy Umbrella branding, or reputation stretching in general, is the process of using the reputation built up in one line of business to launch another one. This new line of service may or may not have anything to do with the first. What is important here is that it is offered under the same brand name as the first one, and as such benefits to some extent from the established reputation of the first product, as the following example illustrates. Example: Virgin – king of brands Virgin, a UK-based company, is involved in planes, trains, finance, soft drinks, music, mobile phones, holidays, cars, wines, publishing, bridal wear. What ties all these businesses together are the values of our brand…Virgin stands for value for money, quality, innovation, fun and a sense of competitive challenge.3 A rather specific source of economies of scope is the running of hub-andspoke-networks by airlines. By gathering all consumers from different flights in one ‘hub’, flights originating from that hub are more likely to be fully utilised, and it might even be possible to fly larger planes – which again are subject to economies of scale (it is not twice as expensive to fly 400 passengers as 200). Can you explain why? 7.3.3 Learning economies or the learning curve Again, we start with a definition of economies of learning: Economies of learning – definition MCq > MCq+1 The main difference in comparison with economies of scale and scope is that the decrease in marginal cost here is in response to an increase in cumulative output, while the economies of scale and scope refer to cost decreases in response to production rate. Economies of learning describe the phenomenon where it is cheaper to produce an additional unit – that is, the marginal cost of production decreases. This does not include fixed cost, rather it indicates that having produced q units, it becomes cheaper to produce an additional one. Typically, learning economies materialise over a period of time – a firm cannot decide to produce twice the amount in one go and expect to benefit from learning economies. Learning takes place for a number of reasons. Employees learn the tricks of the trade. For example, they find ways of doing their work more quickly because they leave out unnecessary steps, do not have to think about the process, they produce less waste and/or they redesign the production process to make it more convenient and efficient. Firms get better at staff selection. When a new product is launched, a firm may not know how to identify a successful salesperson for this product or what type of previous experience is helpful. Perhaps most saliently, think of a firm entering a new geographical market. It might have a general idea as to what makes a successful product manager (say, a management degree, an ability to work under pressure and some work experience in a similar industry), but adapting to the local tradition may be something the firm has no expertise in, and it will have a hard time recruiting. Over time, however, these criteria will become more clear, and staff selection will improve once the firm has had some experience in the market. 74 3 Source: www.virgin.com Chapter 7: Strategic asymmetries – persistent dominance over time A similar argument applies to the selection of suppliers and investment choices in general. For a new product, it may be unclear what makes a good supplier, but it will become so over time, so that future ‘batches’ of the product will enjoy lower unit cost simply because the suppliers have been selected more efficiently – thus either achieving lower prices or higher reliability. As much as organisations are able to learn, they can also forget. Organisational forgetting describes the process of a firm’s marginal cost increasing over time. This may have a number of reasons,4 much like the process of individuals forgetting skills. To identify the sources of organisational forgetting, we have to identify the ‘location’ of organisational knowledge (is it the individual, the workgroup, the product, the process, etc.?) and look for reasons why these might not be stable over time. Benkard (2000) analyses the dynamics of organisational forgetting in a particular setting, the wide-body aircraft industry. 4 Activity 7.3 Which industries would be particularly affected by organisational forgetting and why? 7.4 Dynamic capabilities Besides economies of scale, scope and learning, dynamic capabilities are another important explanation of persistent asymmetries of firm performance. Over the past 20 years strategy scholars have devoted considerable effort to developing a coherent theory of dynamic capabilities to complement the rather static perspective of the resource-based view (discussed in Chapter 6). While resources and operational capabilities can be used to explain differences in firms’ performances at certain points in time, they do not explain how firms can cope with changing environments or even create them. Thus, the aim of dynamic capability research is to close this gap and understand how firms can sustain a competitive advantage by responding to and creating environmental change. While many definitions of dynamic capabilities exist, most scholars in the field would agree with the one provided by Helfat and colleagues. They define dynamic capabilities as ‘the capacity of an organisation to purposefully create, extend, or modify its resource base’. This definition makes it clear that the dynamic capabilities approach is an extension of, or complement to, the resource-based view as it answers the question how the resource base of an organisation is created and changed, where the resource base comprises the tangible and intangible assets of the firm. To work on its resource base an organisation must sense, shape and seize opportunities and match these opportunities with its tangible and intangible assets to outperform its competitors. Opportunities are not given (like in a textbook optimisation problem) with given constraints, but they must be discovered and shaped by searching across different technologies and markets. Dynamic capabilities are especially important to organisations working in an international context and firms in industries characterised by fast technological change. The international context provides a firm with the opportunity to explore poorly developed markets and technical change makes it more important to combine different inventions and complement these inventions with the corresponding managerial capabilities (e.g. marketing capabilities). However, not every response of a firm to changes in the environment can be seen as a proof for the existence of an organisation’s dynamic capabilities. A firm can also change in a non-deliberate ad hoc problem-solving way, for example, if a regulation authority forces them to do so. 75 MN3119 Strategy 7.5 Key concepts • Sources of firm asymmetries • Economies of scale • Economies of scope • Hub-and-spoke networks • Complementary assets • Economies of learning • Umbrella branding • Learning curve • Dynamic capabilities. 7.6 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain sources of firm asymmetries • describe available strategies firms can employ to increase their industry dominance. 7.7 Sample examination questions 1. Economies of learning are nothing but economies of scale over time. Do you agree? 2. Most economies of scope have their cause in some form of scale economies – true? 3. Which of the distinctive capabilities discussed in Chapter 6 is most similar to dynamic capabilities? Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found on the VLE. Extended activity: competition in the wide-body aircraft market Read the following and then answer the questions at the end. Reading Cabral, L. and T. Kretschmer ‘Competition in the wide-body aircraft market’. Available at: http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~lcabral/teaching/widebody.pdf Questions 1. Selling aircraft is very intense and often erodes most of the profits from a sale. What could be reasons for that? Would you expect to find this in other industries as well? 2. Currently, the wide-body industry is a duopoly of Airbus and Boeing. Is this a stable long-term market structure? Why or why not? Pay particular attention to the forces against monopolisation. 76 Chapter 8: Organisation design Chapter 8: Organisation design Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain the interaction of organisation design and strategy at different levels • explain how different technological and structural elements of organisation design interact • discuss how organisation design affects organisational decisionmaking. Essential reading Csaszar, F. ‘Organizational structure as a determinant of performance: evidence from mutual funds’, Strategic Management Journal 33 2012, pp.611–32. Further reading Hitt, M., H.I.R. Volberda, R. Morgan, R. Hoskisson and P. Reinmoeller Strategic Management: Competitiveness and Globalization (Hampshire: Cengage Learning EMEA, 2011). Sah R.K. and J.E. Stiglitz ‘The architecture of economic systems: hierarchies and polyarchies’, American Economic Review 76(4) 1986, pp.716–27. 8.1 Introduction A further important source of competitive advantage is the way in which a firm is organised. We could think of this as a form of architecture (as discussed in Chapter 6), but it is really more than that. Organisation design refers to the structure of who knows certain things and who makes decisions about certain things. It determines which of a firm’s actions are supported by the firm’s structure and which ones are hindered. Therefore, one of the key lessons from this chapter will be to recognise that organisation design really does interact with many other elements in the firm. Of particular interest for this course will be the interaction between organisational structure and the firm’s strategy. 8.2 Strategy and structure Strategies are not chosen in a vacuum. Rather, strategies have to fit an organisational structure as it is this that provides the framework within which the strategies will be used and implemented. That is, a good strategy can turn out to be unsuccessful if the structure is not right for it. Note that not all strategies fit equally well with all kinds of structures (which should become obvious the moment you look at the world and see how different firms are, even in the same market). This means that the organisation design has an interesting role: there is not ‘one best’ structure that all firms should aspire to, but managing to align a firm’s structure with strategy can be a source of competitive advantage. 77 MN3119 Strategy The fit between strategy and structure has to be given at different levels, as illustrated by Figure 8.1. Within a business unit, it is important to match business-level strategies and a firm’s functional structure, while the different divisions have to be arranged so they fit within the corporatelevel strategy of the firm, and the worldwide structure has to be aligned with the way a firm wants to operate internationally. We will discuss each of these ‘matches’ in turn later on in this chapter. Of course, over time a firm will undergo an evolution, which will be reflected in the typical organisation structure of a firm for its age and stage in the lifecycle. Most firms start out with a simple structure with little by way of formal organisation. As a firm grows, it becomes increasingly difficult for a single person (often the founder) to manage and implement all aspects of the business. Coordination problems ensue and maintaining control over all subordinates, all with different functions, becomes impossible. This typically creates a need for a functional structure in which a CEO and limited corporate staff lead the firm, but there are functional line managers in the dominant organisational areas – depending on the type of firm, this could be production, R&D, accounting, etc. As the firm continues to grow – and especially continues to diversify into different geographical markets (more on that later) – many firms make the transition into a multidivisional structure. Such a multidivisional structure consists of operating divisions, each of which represent a separate business, and the corporate top officers delegate authority to division managers. Of course, this is an idealised evolution, and if you look around, many firms seem to take this path. Business-Level Strategies Functional Structure Corporate-Level Strategies Multidivisional Structure International Strategies Worldwide Structure Figure 8.1: The fit between strategy and structure. 8.2.1. Matching business-level strategy and functional structure Take the two generic strategies proposed by Porter: cost leadership or differentiation. What structure should an organisation choose if it wants to follow one of these strategies? Figure 8.2 shows a structure a firm with a cost leadership strategy might try and implement. There is a fair number of central staff that coordinate the different functions; operations is the main function because cost-saving potential can be realised most efficiently through streamlining operations. Efforts to improve the firm are focused on process engineering rather than product R&D, and job roles are highly structured so that a low-cost culture can be fostered and slack reduced. This mechanistic structure is most efficient whenever cost leadership is the key aim of the firm. 78 Chapter 8: Organisation design Office of the President Centralised Staff Engineering Marketing Operations Personnel Accounting Figure 8.2: Structure of a firm with a cost leadership strategy. A typical structure for implementing and supporting a differentiation strategy is given in Figure 8.3. Here, most functions are decentralised, with the exception of R&D and marketing, which are most important for the overall strategy of the firm and work together very intensively. There is an emphasis of product R&D rather than process engineering, and this is supported by marketing that does not just sell existing products, but also engages actively in market research to generate and assess new product ideas. Generally, the structure is much less formalised to make sure new ideas are not stifled by formal roles and procedures and change can be realised quickly. This is true both at the organisational level, but also at the level of individuals, whose job roles are not highly structured. Office of the President R&D New Product R&D Operations Marketing Marketing Human Resources Finance Figure 8.3: Structure of a firm with a differentiation strategy. 8.2.2 Matching corporate-level strategy and multidivisional structure There has to be a match between the different types of multidivisional structures and corporate-level strategies. Generally, one can distinguish between the cooperative, the competitive and the strategic business unit (SBU) form of multidivisional structures, which of course can be linked to unrelated or related strategies. We can identify both operational and corporate relatedness: operational relatedness refers to the sharing of activities among different business units, while corporate relatedness describes the transfer of corporate core competencies from the headquarters into different businesses. This distinction leaves us with a 2×2 matrix of possible multidivisional strategies in Figure 8.4. 79 MN3119 Strategy Low High High Related Constrained Diversification Operational and Corporate Relatedness Low Operational Relatedness Corporate Relatedness Unrelated Diversification Related Linked Diversification Figure 8.4: A 2×2 matrix of possible multidivisional strategies. What now are the best multidivisional organisational structures for these strategies? For a related constrained strategy, i.e. high operational relatedness, but low corporate relatedness, the preferred organisational form is shown in Figure 8.5. President Government Affairs Legal Affairs Corporate R&D Lab Strategic Planning Corporate Human Resources Corporate Marketing Corporate Finance Product Division Product Division Product Division Product Division Product Division Figure 8.5: The preferred organisational form for a high operational relatedness, but low corporate relatedness strategy. The emphasis of this structure is on cooperation and sharing across units. Many of the key functions are centralised, especially R&D, and the corporate office emphasises centralised strategic planning, HR and marketing to foster cooperation between divisions. Structural integration devices create tight links among all divisions so that all units are aware of the overall corporation’s goals, and overall contribution as well as divisional performance are rewarded. At the other extreme, there is very little integration in the competitive form shown in Figure 8.6. 80 Chapter 8: Organisation design Headquarter Office President Legal Affairs Division Finance Division Division Auditing Division Division Figure 8.6: The competitive form. Here, the corporate headquarters are very lean, with few staff and almost no input into business-level strategy. Therefore, finance and auditing are the most important functions at headquarters as these are mainly used to manage cash flow and allocate resources to finance, whatever the competing divisions require money for. It is clear that any synergies across divisions are likely to be minimal, which is why this structure is most efficient for an unrelated diversification strategy where the expected synergies across units are fairly low to begin with. Somewhere in between the two extreme is the multidivisional form we see most often – the strategic business unit (SBU) form. Here, SBUs are fairly independent from each other, but integration across functions within each SBU is important and resources may be provided by the corporate headquarters for these functions – which does more than simply allocate funds, however. They develop and implement a strategic plan, and most central functions are strategic in nature. Central staff serve as a consulting unit for the SBUs rather than having direct input in the strategies of the SBUs. They might serve as consultants for general issues, but most importantly they may also advise on how best to implement the centrally developed strategic plan. The SBU form is summarised in Figure 8.7. Headquarter Office President Corporate R&D Lab Corporate Finance Division Corporate Marketing Strategic Business Unit Strategic Business Unit Division Strategic Planning Division Division Division Corporate Human Resources Strategic Business Unit Division Division Division Division Figure 8.7: The strategic business unit (SBU) form. 8.2.3 Matching international strategies and worldwide structure Finally, corporations have to make sure that the structure they give their international operations matches their international strategy. The key determinant here is the degree of autonomy given to the local operations (through organisational structure) and the extent to which a firm’s products in each country are supposed to ‘feel’ like local products. 81 MN3119 Strategy A multidomestic strategy aims at mimicking a local business in each country (or economic area) a firm operates in. That is, products and product mixes will be adjusted and will cater to local tastes, management will most likely be local, and local branches should ideally almost be indistinguishable from a domestic firm. As far as organisation design is concerned, operations are almost completely decentralised, and the corporate headquarters coordinates financial resources among independent subsidiaries. The organisation runs more or less like a decentralised federation. Of course, synergies across geographical areas are low in this case, but in turn there is a great deal of differentiation by local demand and fit to the area and local culture. This is shown in Figure 8.8 below. United States Asia Latin America Multinational Headquarters Europe Middle East/ Africa Australia Figure 8.8: A multidomestic strategy. The polar opposite is a global strategy in which the product offering and product design are identical for all the geographical markets in which a firm operates. In this case, the different product divisions operate worldwide, and there is a fair bit of centralisation to coordinate the information flow among worldwide products. To facilitate global economies of scale and scope, the corporate headquarters uses a series of intercoordination devices and allocates resources in a cooperative way (i.e. it does not encourage competition among business units and/or geographical markets). The organisation effectively runs as a centralised federation, as shown in Figure 8.9. Worldwide Products Division Worldwide Products Division Worldwide Products Division Worldwide Products Division Figure 8.9: A global strategy. 82 Worldwide Products Division Global Corporate Headquarters Worldwide Products Division Europe Chapter 8: Organisation design Finally, a transnational strategy reflects a mixture of the two polar cases above. In such a strategy, the corporation attempts to balance the benefits from the economies of scale and scope accruing from operating on a global scale while granting sufficient autonomy to its local subsidiaries. For example, local subsidiaries might be able to select from a global product portfolio the products they expect to be most profitable in their market, an assessment they may have gathered through extensive (local) market research. Accordingly, performance and success for the local subsidiaries are judged by the profit generated for the overall corporation. There may also be hybrid forms where some business units are structured around a product (or product group), while others reflect geographical markets. Deutsche Telekom may reflect such a hybrid strategy, where T-Systems, T-Home, T-Mobile represent product-oriented organisational units, while Telekom US covers the activities in a particular geographical market. This type of structure is reflected in Figure 8.10. below. Headquarters Product Division A Geographic Area Division 1 Area 1 Product A Area 2 Product B Product Division B Geographic Area Division 2 Area 1 Product A Area 2 Product A Figure 8.10: A hybrid transnational strategy. 8.3 Organisation design and competitive advantage Organisation design is not a means in and of itself. Much rather, it is a tool that can help support and ensure strategies at all levels of the organisation is used correctly. While related to architecture, it is not the same and encompasses more elements. Most importantly, there is no one ‘optimal’ structure, but rather a fitting structure for each strategy a firm might want to follow. As such, competitive advantage can result from using this tool to reinforce successful strategies. 8.4 Key concepts • Strategy and structure • Organisational fit • Functional organisation • Multidivisional structure • Worldwide structure. 8.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain the interaction of organisation design and strategy at different levels. 83 MN3119 Strategy • explain how different technological and structural elements of organisation design interact. • discuss how organisation design affects organisational decisionmaking. 8.6 Sample examination questions 1. Give an example of a firm in which units have low operational relatedness but high corporate relatedness. 2. Which international organisation would you pick for a restaurant chain originating from Asia but operating across the globe? 3. How would a firm following a differentiation strategy in the fastmoving consumer goods industry organise their operations and why? Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found on the VLE. 84 Chapter 9: Value chain analysis: vertical relations Chapter 9: Value chain analysis: vertical relations Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain the concept of double marginalisation and why a vertically integrated monopolist would have made higher profits and charged a lower price • describe and apply to real life/hypothetical situations the concepts of ‘market cornering’, ‘investment externalities’ and ‘market splitting’. Essential reading Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 11. Saloner, G., A. Shepard and J. Podolny Strategic Management. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2006) Chapter 10. Further reading Monteverde, K. ‘Technical dialog as an incentive for vertical integration in the semiconductor industry’, Management Science 41(10) 1995, pp.1624–38. 9.1 Introduction Many of the transactions in the business world are not in the endconsumer market (or B2C, as the dot-com hype has taught us), but are in fact transactions between businesses. A firm selling raw material to a manufacturer, a producer selling goods on to a retailer, or a parts producer delivering products for final assembly are all examples of socalled ‘vertical’ transactions between businesses that do not involve an end consumer. This has a number of important consequences for the analysis of such transactions. First of all, both players often have some degree of market power, that is, firms at both stages of the vertical chain are aware that changes in the price they charge will have an impact on the quantity demanded by the end consumer. That said, both parties also try to maximise their profits in the course of the transaction. In this chapter, we will look at some specific issues arising from the vertical relation between firms and how firms may try and improve their competitive position through them, not only in the vertical transaction, but also in comparison to their direct competitors in the product market. 9.2 Double marginalisation Consider a simple situation with two players: an upstream firm (U) selling a product to a downstream firm (D), which then sells the product to end consumers with a demand function D(p). We assume that both firms are monopolists in their respective market stages. Figure 9.1 illustrates this scenario and the notation. 85 MN3119 Strategy Upstream firm (U) Downstream firm (U) End consumers Figure 9.1: Value chain. We assume that the marginal cost of producing the intermediate good is constant at MCU = c, and the marginal cost of selling the product to end consumers is zero. It may help if you think of U as a manufacturer and D as the retailer – a retailer has no extra incremental cost on top of what he pays the manufacturer.1 What price will the manufacturer set? The retailer? Of course, both will try to set as high a price as possible, but they have to consider the impact this will have on final-good prices as well. As both firms are monopolists in their markets, they will maximise profits by setting MR = MC. We start with the retailer: as its marginal costs are assumed to be zero, he should sell a quantity such that MRD = 0, right? Not quite – we have to take into account that the retailer still needs to purchase the product from the manufacturer. As we can see from Figure 9.2, the transfer price for that is pt. In fact then, the marginal cost the retailer faces is then pt + MCD = pt. Therefore, the quantity sold by an upstream firm with monopoly power will be such that MRD = pt. Double marginalisation MC MR D DD Figure 9.2: Double marginalisation I. What does this imply for the upstream firm? The upstream firm knows that if it sets a transfer price pt, it will sell a quantity (to the downstream firm) determined by the marginal revenue curve for the final goods market. In other words, the downstream marginal revenue curve becomes the demand curve of the upstream firm! This then enables us to analyse the upstream firm’s problem – with a demand curve MRD, the marginal revenue curve for the upstream firm will shift further in (i.e. will be even steeper). The manufacturer will then choose a transfer price that sets MRU = MCU. 86 The assumption of zero marginal cost for the downstream firm is not important for the intuition of our model, but it makes life easier. One of the exercises will ask you to analyse the problem, but with positive marginal sales cost. 1 Double marginalisation Chapter 9: Value chain analysis: vertical relations MC MR U MR D = D U Figure 9.3: Double marginalisation II. The final goods price is then based on a transfer price by the manufacturer that exceeds marginal cost, and the corresponding final goods price further exceeds the price paid by the retailer – both players add their own profit margin; double marginalisation. Activity 9.1 How would the results change if: a. The downstream company had positive marginal cost? b. Marginal cost for the upstream firm was increasing (and MCD = 0)? c. The market for the upstream good was competitive? Illustrate your answers graphically. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. A single (i.e. vertically integrated) monopolist would have made higher profits and would have charged a lower price. To see why, consider the monopolist’s decision rule, which is setting marginal revenues in the final goods market equal to total marginal cost c. In fact, this is often considered one of the main motivations for vertical integration. There are, however, other techniques of getting to the joint-profit-maximising outcome, as illustrated in the following activity. Activity 9.2 Suppose that the upstream firm can charge a transfer price pt and a fixed fee F. Show that this can generate the joint profit-maximising outcome. (Hint: Assuming that the downstream firm has no additional marginal cost, what transfer price would give the best (i.e. profit-maximising) outcome? Given this transfer price what conditions would the fixed fee have to fulfil?) Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Assuming that vertical integration or sophisticated contracting is not possible (or not desired), another way of lowering prices is to encourage competition in the related market. In other words, if a manufacturer manages to sell products via two retailers, they will compete some of the margins in the downstream market away, which is unambiguously good news for the manufacturer, since lower margins imply higher volumes at the same transfer price – and therefore higher profits (the same applies to 87 MN3119 Strategy a retailer purchasing from several competing manufacturers). As a general rule, we can say that the more intense competition in the related market, the higher the profits for the firm on the other side of the market. In the extreme, this brings us back to the situation where a firm is faced by a large number of identical players which do not really have any market power – in other words, the more players there are in the related market, the more the situation resembles a consumer market. 9.3 Vertical foreclosure In the previous section, we considered only a single upstream and downstream firm. In this section, we extend this stylised situation and look at some phenomena that might occur if one stage of the value chain has several firms operating in it. 9.3.1 Market cornering As we have seen in the previous chapter, firms without any obvious capabilities or advantages over their rival can still manage to secure an advantageous position in the market by controlling essential resources or inputs, similar to owning a strategic asset. This is ‘cornering the market’: a product consisting entirely of generic components may still end up being very profitable if one of the components is controlled by a single firm – which can then either sell it profitably to its rivals or monopolise the market altogether. Example: Minnetonka Corporation. One firm that has been very successful with cornering the market in the face of major (potential) competition was Minnetonka Corporation. In 1980 it was the first firm to introduce liquid soap in the US market, but knew that if it were to take off, it would be smothered by Procter & Gamble and Unilever which could spend more resources on marketing and enjoyed a bigger brand reputation. Recognising this, Minnetonka also realised that in order to sell liquid soap, small, plastic pumps would be necessary – a product that had hardly any other use at the time. Consequently, Minnetonka bought up two years’ worth of supply of plastic pumps – much more than it would typically commit to – and therefore cornered the market and forced the major players to build up their own capacity. Minnetonka’s privileged position did not last forever of course, but it was able to enjoy two years undisturbed by major competitors. Ultimately, the liquid soup business was bought by Colgate Company.2 9.3.2 Investment externalities To market a product successfully, investment on different stages of the value chain is necessary. A shop selling luxury products will typically be decorated carefully – which in turn increases the returns to any investment in quality by the luxury goods producers. This is not a problem per se (as both players benefit from investments in quality), but it may get more complicated if there are several competing retailers of the same luxury good. Suppose they are located close to each other, so that an advertisement by either of the two retailers increases demand for the product, but that consumers split up more or less equally between the two retailers. This would imply that whoever bears the cost of the advertisement does not get the full benefit because the other retailer receives a positive externality. The private benefits to advertising therefore are lower than the benefits to the manufacturer, which leads to an inefficient advertising level from the manufacturer’s point of view. 88 Source: http://inventors. about.com/library/ inventors/blsoap.htm 2 Chapter 9: Value chain analysis: vertical relations There are several ways to solve or at least reduce this problem. First, the producer can pick up the bill, which it may be reluctant to do because the investment benefits the retailers as well (in other words, the producer’s private benefits do not include the retailers’ profits). Second, the producers can exert resale price maintenance (RPM) so that retailers have no incentive to compete on price – the worst scenario from a retailer’s point of view would be that it spends money on advertising and the rival retailer lowers its price to pick up the higher demand. Third, a manufacturer can grant exclusive geographical territories to retailers, which would help to minimise the spillovers from one retailer to the other – this will then help align the incentives of retailer and producer. Activity 9.3 Why do Pepsi and Coca-Cola insist on exclusive dealing in most major venues? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 9.3.3 Market splitting Vertical relations are not always a move to weaken direct competitors. In fact, sometimes restricting vertically related markets can help maintain collusion. For example, a firm that has significant switching costs by selling complementary products (i.e. vertically related products like services, software, etc.) may end up creating two monopolies covering half the market rather than with one – a genuinely competitive market. In this case, restricting your competitor’s access (and vice versa) to a vertically related product will create such a market split; neither you nor the competitor has an incentive to steal customers from each other and two cosy monopolies can co-exist side by side (see example below). Example: Fire pumps Hale Products and Waterous jointly hold approximately 90 per cent of the market for fire pumps. Their customers, fire stations in the US, typically have to sign an exclusivity agreement with one of them to use their spare parts and services. While this could potentially lead to a competitive duopoly in which firms compete for new consumers vigorously, it turned out that the ‘duopoly’ was in fact a happy couple of two geographically divided monopolies – Hale Products controlled one half of the market, Waterous the other half, and vertical restrictions (through exclusive dealing agreements) meant that there was no effective competition.3 Source: www.ftc.gov. opa/1996/07/ hale.htm. 3 9.4 Key concepts • Double marginalisation • Intermediate goods • Upstream and downstream firms • Vertical foreclosure • Market cornering • Investment externalities • Market splitting. 89 MN3119 Strategy 9.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain the concept of double marginalisation and why a vertically integrated monopolist would have made higher profits and charged a lower price • describe and apply to real life/hypothetical situations the concepts of ‘market cornering’, ‘investment externalities’ and ‘market splitting’. 9.5 Sample examination questions 1. Exclusive dealing benefits not only the manufacturers (i.e. the upstream firm), but also the retailer. Why is that? 2. Multiple sourcing is the practice of purchasing an input or raw material from several different sources. How does this affect the negative consequences of double marginalisation? 3. Under which circumstances can cornering the market work? When is it likely to be unsuccessful? Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. Extended activity: outsourcing at Eriksson and Sony and Loews Read the following and answer the questions at the end. Reading Baccara, M. et al. ‘Sony and Loews’. NYU, Stern School of Business. Available at: http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~lcabral/teaching/sony.pdf Backus, D. and L. Cabral ‘Outsourcing at Ericsson’. NYU, Stern School of Business. Available at: http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~lcabral/teaching/ericsson.pdf Questions 1. Read the minicase on outsourcing at Ericsson and answer the questions at the end of the case. 2. Read the minicase on Sony and Loews and answer questions (a) and (b). 90 Chapter 10: Vertical integration and transaction cost Chapter 10: Vertical integration and transaction cost Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • comment upon the links between ‘core competencies’ and ‘distinctive capabilities’ to the vertical relations and the value-based strategy literature • describe and explain the sources and types of transaction costs. Essential reading Besanko, D., D. Dranove, M. Shanley and S. Shaefer Economics of Strategy. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2009) Chapters 5 and 6. Further reading Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 3. 10.1 Introduction Building on the previous chapter, the incentives for foreclosure are often only one part of the decision to make or buy a particular input. In fact, many firms are not even in the position to foreclose entry strategically or exploit their market power vis-à-vis competitors and/or suppliers or buyers. Most frequently, the decision to make or buy is governed by cost considerations, although assessing these costs is often more intricate than simply comparing the price of the input on the free market with the cost of producing in-house. In this chapter, we will briefly discuss the different costs and how firms can influence or avoid them. 10.2 Purchasing versus production costs Firms often feel they are paying too high a price for inputs bought externally. However, if the alternative is producing the input at a higher cost than the market price, then buying in still makes economic sense. In other words, if the market price (including a mark-up for the supplier) is still lower than the internal production cost, a firm should ‘buy’ rather than ‘make’. This could be the case if there are significant economies of scale of production that do not apply at the quantities demanded by the firm – as can be seen in Figure 10.1. Firm i would only produce a small amount itself, while the supplier could take advantage of economies of scale, collect a mark-up and still offer the product cheaper than firm i could produce it internally. 91 MN3119 Strategy Ci PM Qi QM Figure 10.1: Cost and demand functions for purchasing versus own production. Activity 10.1 Consider an input with a marginal cost function of MC = 1 + 1/(1 + Q), i.e. marginal costs are decreasing with output. Market demand (including firm i) for the product is Q = 10 – P. a. What is the price a monopolistic supplier would set? b. How much would firm i need to produce for its own use (i.e. not selling to or buying from the external market) for internal production to be more profitable than buying from a monopolistic supplier? c. (Optional:) If supply on the outside market were competitive, how much would firm i need to produce to prefer in-house production? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. These economies of scale could come from ‘true’ benefits to scale, such as production economies, but they could also originate from greater specialisation by the input suppliers. For example, outsourcing of business processes such as payroll services has the advantage that a firm specialising purely in payroll systems will be better at it than a firm with a different focus. As we have established in the previous chapter, the effect will be weakened by the degree of competitiveness of the input market. If it is relatively competitive, market price will be closer to marginal cost, which means that a firm would have to produce even larger quantities to ‘beat the market’. (This can also work the other way if the market is a natural monopoly and the economies of scale are so strong that prices are higher with two smaller operators than with a single monopolist.) 10.3 Coordination costs This cost is often ignored in the calculation of total purchasing cost – informally, we could call it the loss of ‘peace of mind’ when purchasing from an outside supplier. It basically stems from the fact that suppliers will have priorities other than you if the contract does not allow for the cost of delay, or a faulty product, would have for you. Consider a simple example: a restaurant requires its produce and meat to be delivered by 2pm, and the contract it signed with its suppliers states that every hour’s delay will 92 Chapter 10: Vertical integration and transaction cost incur a contractual penalty of $x. Suppose now that the cost of a one-hour delay is $y < $x, but a two-hour delay would mean that the chef has to rush preparations or even purchase meat from another source. The cost of delay therefore increases dramatically, and two hours’ delay means a cost to the chef of $z > $2x. Can this be a problem? If every restaurant requested delivery at 2pm, it might make sense for the supplier to deliver orders along the most convenient (and cost-efficient) route – which could mean that our chef receives the delivery an hour late, which is not a problem as such since the penalty of $x covers the extra cost of $y and, assuming that the supplier obtains a cost saving of at least $x, everybody gains from this rescheduling of deliveries. But suppose that an additional hour’s delay would give the supplier another cost saving (or additional job he can take on) of equal size (> $x), he would be willing to pay another hour’s penalty, which would send the chef into a (costly) panic which would not be covered by the additional penalty payment. In the example above, the problem is that the penalties do not increase according to the real cost to the restaurant – the key insight is that by purchasing externally, it is important to realise that the supplier’s incentives will be different to that of any one individual firm. Of course, a similar argument would also be true for the quality of an input. If the incentives to cut corners for a supplier are not adequately offset by severe enough controls or contractual penalties, it might lead to a situation where a supplier produces with a higher tolerance for small imperfections and willingly takes the penalties into account because they are outweighed by the cost savings achieved. In the extreme, if the cost of delay, faults and so on are prohibitively high, a supplier might not even be willing to enter a contract that would adequately reflect these costs. If the risk is too high, a supplier might prefer not to take the risk, and compensating the supplier for it would be prohibitively costly. 10.4 Proprietary knowledge Frequently, making or buying a particular input is not governed by a calculation of the cost, even if the costs of producing in-house are very high and there is a ready and competitive supply on the market. For example, one might argue that there are plenty of small research laboratories (or at least a number of entrepreneurial scientists) that would be able to offer outsourced research services to larger organisations. (In fact, this is already happening to a certain extent, but the majority of research-intensive firms will still do their research in-house.) The key reason is that the closer an activity is to the core competencies (or is a distinctive capability) of a firm, the more concerned the firm will be to protect this intellectual property. While it is still possible for employees to leave and take company secrets with them, there is a much larger degree of control over in-house activities than outsourced activities, so if the firm wants to protect proprietary knowledge, it is likely to keep activities in-house. A particular case of knowledge kept in-house is the control over the selection of staff – again, companies performing outsourced business functions are often motivated by different performance targets (their own!) than the organisation that outsources. However, keeping knowledge in-house need not be a distinctive capability or crucial to the firm’s success. For example, information about demand for one firm’s product might also be transmitted via supply prices and delivery schedules to rivals. The danger of having rivals learn about the success of a particular market or product then might prompt a firm to produce inputs in-house. 93 MN3119 Strategy 10.5 Transaction costs The term transaction costs defines those costs arising from an exchange relationship – which could be governed by a written contract or an implicit or relational contract. Again, there are direct costs and indirect costs – indirect costs may often affect the value of a transaction more significantly than direct ones. Direct costs are the time spent on specifying a contract, lawyers’ fees for drawing up the contract, writing job descriptions and so on. Most often, these will be much lower within the firm than on the market – predominantly because a contract need not be written. Another direct cost would arise from monitoring the quality of the exchanged product and from the cost of faulty items – if someone has to spend time and effort removing faulty products that the other party has delivered and if this screening process is not perfect, costs arise from completing this specific transaction. Indirect costs are more difficult to quantify, but they often have more bearing on the decision to make or buy – if indirect transaction costs are too high ‘it’s just not worth the effort’. Indirect costs mainly arise from the fact that contracts are incomplete in the sense that they do not specify precisely what should happen (or what both parties are obliged to do) for any possible contingency in the market. If a situation arises that has not been specified in the initial contract this is then subject to haggling and negotiations, and the expected losses from the partners behaving opportunistically. Both parties will have to take into account that incentives are not perfectly aligned and that the other party will try to maximise its own pay-offs if the finer points of the contract allows. Insurance for many types of natural disasters are subject to large uncertainties in the determination of damages and payouts. For example, Hurricane Katrina had (and still has) insurance companies and insured parties in bitter fights because many policies exclude water damage, but include wind damage – it is now a matter of interpretation if the damage to property has been caused by the severe winds or tidal waves – and naturally both parties claim the outcome most favourable to them, which is surely going to generate a significant revenue stream for the legal profession.1 Generally, indirect transaction costs are higher in market transactions because the incentives are less aligned than within the firm. This implies that if a contract cannot be specified well so that a large (and costly) number of contingencies cannot be catered for, relationships are likely to be within one firm. Both elements of transaction costs are important – for example, it is easy to imagine that a homeowner expecting to incur huge legal costs to secure a payout following a natural disaster will decide not to take out insurance despite the direct transaction cost being relatively small, with a standard contract being offered over the phone, for example. Activity 10.2 Using transaction cost arguments, explain why research and development is often kept in-house, while firms purchase options to hedge against currency risk. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 94 For a discussion of the legal conundrum surrounding Hurricane Katrina, see www. insurancejournal. com/news/southeast/ 2005/09/27/60219.htm 1 Chapter 10: Vertical integration and transaction cost 10.6 Asset specificity Closely related to the discussion on vertical relations is the concept of asset specificity. An asset is said to be specific if it has significantly less value outside one particular relationship than it has within it. Activity 10.3 Rank the following four investments in terms of their asset specificity and explain why. Explain who makes the investment and who benefits from it. a. A wind energy turbine is designed and built according to a terrain’s specific features. b. A McDonald’s franchisee builds a ‘Ronald McDonald Playground’ in the back of the restaurant. c. McKinsey offers a mini-MBA to its new employees. d. A firm invests in a high-performance server to improve the productivity of its logistics and distribution. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. A specific investment changes the dynamics of a relationship or transaction quite significantly: the moment the investment has been made, the investor is now vulnerable to opportunistic behaviour by its contractual partner. Basically, before investing, anybody could have entered the same transaction on either side. On the other hand, after the investment, the two parties are bound together – this is what is called the fundamental transformation from a ‘large-numbers bidding (or market) situation’ to a Fundamental ‘small-numbers (bilateral) bargaining scenario’. transformation Firm A B C Supplier(s) 1 2 3 Once the parties invest in relationship-specific assets, the relationship changes from a “large numbers” bidding situation to a “small numbers” bargaining situation. Figure 10.2: Fundamental transformation. Why is this problematic? In a market situation, everybody can walk away from a deal that does not seem favourable. In a situation where an investment has already taken place, this is a lot harder. Contractual parties will take this into account and, if possible, will try to exploit this by holding up their partner: Hold up – definition If a contract is incomplete, party A can hold up B by trying to renegotiate the initial agreement in its favour if leaving the contact unfulfilled would involve significant costs for B and little for A. The important concepts in this definition are the contractual incompleteness and the difference in costs – if the contract is incomplete, there is space for renegotiation, if it is complete, any attempt to change the terms could simply be stopped by insisting on the initial terms of the contract. However, not many contracts are complete. The reasons that we do not fear being held up in all incomplete contracts is that the costs of not fulfilling the contract are often relatively symmetric – a producer stands to gain revenues from selling a product and a consumer stands to enjoy use of a product, which makes trade between the two mutually beneficial. On the other hand, if one party depends on this particular contract while 95 MN3119 Strategy the other has plenty of alternative options (or simply is not that bothered about this transaction) there is some scope for hold up. The term to describe the degree of dependency on this particular transaction is the concept of quasi-rent. Quasi-rent – definition Quasi-rent is the difference between the revenue the seller expects to receive under the initial terms of the contract and the minimum revenues the seller must receive in order not to exit the relationship. Therefore, if one player has high quasi-rent and one has not, the former is typically in danger of being held up. 10.7 Alternatives to ‘make’ or ‘buy’ We increasingly see firms choosing alternatives to pure vertical integration or exclusive market contracting. Described below are a number of alternatives. 10.7.1 Joint ventures and strategic alliances As we will see in Chapter 12, strategic alliances and joint ventures are often initiated over several stages of the value chain – as an alternative to vertical integration. The main difference lies in the nature of contracts between the partners – while vertically integrated firms will typically get by without formal contracts between units, the most important contractual element is the employment contract, which will often include an element of monitoring so that the firm’s interests are secured, and a degree of performance pay so that employees will have their incentives aligned with the firm. A market transaction on the other hand is governed by an exchange contract that specifies the terms of delivery and so on. Strategic alliances and joint ventures are in-between in that they sometimes have an element of joint asset ownership (in the case of joint ventures) and always a degree of (formal or informal) profit sharing, which is used to align incentives. This makes joint ventures and strategic alliances a hybrid form since there is no authority in the same way as in an employment contract, but no fully specified contract as in a market transaction. 10.7.2 Sub-contracting networks and franchising Another alternative is to build and maintain sub-contracting networks and engage in franchising. In some senses, this is similar to a market transaction as the contracts try to specify the terms of sub-contracting and so on, as much as possible with the main difference being that in both cases (sub-contracting network and franchising) there is a relational element to the contract. A franchisee would not enter the relationship and invest accordingly if he did not expect the relationship to continue for some time, very often beyond the end date of the initial franchising contract. The long-term outlook and relational element will make it easier and more attractive to invest in the relationship for both parties. Another reason why such networks do not seem to trigger fears of being held up by the franchiser is that news of opportunistic behaviour would very quickly spread throughout the entire network of franchisees, which would lead to a relatively severe backlash (in the sense of lowered investment by the franchisees), not only by one franchisee, but by many of them. 96 Chapter 10: Vertical integration and transaction cost 10.7.3 Tapered integration Tapered integration involves making some input in-house and buying some on the market. Very often, the rationale given for this is that external demand can be used to ‘buffer’ demand fluctuations of the input, while the stable component of demand is produced in-house. It is important to note, however, that the main difference between tapered integration and the other two alternatives is that there is no attempt to align the incentives of supplier and buyer – if anything, incentives are now even more opposed as the internal input supplier and the external supplier are now in indirect (or direct) competition for business from the downstream unit. Another motivation for tapered integration is to lessen the danger of being held up. If a firm can produce a significant proportion of input demand itself, suppliers will not be able to hold up the firm by threatening to withhold supplies. 10.8 Key concepts • Purchasing versus production cost • Make or buy • Coordination cost • Transaction cost • Asset specificity • Hold-up • Quasi-rent. 10.9 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • comment upon the links between ‘core competencies’ and ‘distinctive capabilities’ to the vertical relations and the value-based strategy literature • describe and explain the sources and types of transaction costs. 10.10 Questions for discussion 1. Discuss the relative advantages and disadvantages of the three alternatives to make or buy compared with vertical integration and/or market transactions. 2. Why do you think outsourcing is more frequent in mature industries than in the early stages of an industry’s life cycle? Extended activity: athenahealth Read the following and answer the questions at the end. Case study: athenahealth, US Healthcare industry Based in Waltham, Massachusetts, athenahealth is an IT provider in the healthcare industry that offers internet-based revenue-cycle management services to physician enterprises – hospitals and doctors in private practice. Founded in 1997 by Jonathan Bush, Chairman and CEO, and Todd Park, Chief Development Officer, athenahealth achieved sales of nearly $40 million in 2005. The company’s mission is to get health care to work the 97 MN3119 Strategy way it should – so that information is conveyed efficiently and accurately to the benefit of both patients and doctors. athenahealth is backed by bluechip venture capital firms in the US, including Venrock Associates, Oak Investment Partners and Draper Jurvetson. athenahealth began not as a technology company but as a women’s health practice focused on improving maternity outcomes for women and babies. The idea for the company took hold when Bush, a recent graduate of Harvard Business School, met Park at the consultancy Booz-Allen & Hamilton where both worked as associates focused on the healthcare sector. With entrepreneurial spirits high, they set out to build this business, but soon found their goals thwarted by something seemingly very basic: getting paid. athenahealth was born from our struggle of actually running a group practice, when the Herculian effort and complexity of getting paid started taking time away from patient care. The practice delivered high-quality patient care, but the mounting red tape from payers meant cash flow was volatile at best. We couldn’t get paid and we didn’t know why. When we started researching solutions, we only found companies selling hardware and software but nothing that could help us get the results we hoped were possible. These companies couldn’t give us back control of our practices. We decided to tackle the problem ourselves and build a true revenue cycle management solution—one that is used by thousands of US physicians today. (athenahealth website) To date, athenahealth has been focused on developing and rolling out an electronic billing solution that, by running back-office processes more efficiently, boosts doctors’ profitability and power, particularly vis-a-vis insurance companies. With this foothold firmly in place, the company is now applying their skills in process control to the clinical side of a medical practice – tracking lab orders, results and prescriptions, and streamlining the medical group’s interface with these players. Talking with Mr Bush reveals his vision of transforming the entire supply chain in the healthcare industry from a flabby and fragmented consortium into a system that ultimately delivers enormous cost savings and vastly improved health care to patients. The company’s strategy remains focused on medical groups as its primary customers, helping them become strategic entities that, through gathering momentum, influence the way every other player in the supply chain acts and interacts. Excerpts from a conversation with Jonathan Bush about athenahealth and the future structure of the supply chain in the US healthcare industry: Everything in health care comes out of an order from a doctor. The order-making engine is the doctor. Associations of physicians create an artificial shortage of their expertise so that they can charge higher prices – and it works. The people who get to decide how many people in the guild there should be are the specialists in that specialty. So the doctor gets to control the original supply of the order-making entity. It’s called great work if you can get it. If you were a taxi driver, you would really like to control how many taxis are competing for fares, right? 98 Chapter 10: Vertical integration and transaction cost When you look at a supply chain, you want to look at where’s the fat, where’s the place where there is extra value created because everything is supposedly getting pushed toward commodity prices all the time. Well the doctor gets to control supply so he doesn’t get pushed so he isn’t forced to merge with other doctors or to get economies of scale in his office, because he can actually make a pretty tidy sum with a lady and a little one-shingle office. When you look at organisational scale in the supply chain, you see that in the first link in the supply chain – the average office has three doctors in it! That’s averaging in the Mayo clinic and all the mega clinics – 55 per cent of medical doctors in the United States are practising in groups of one or two doctors. So there is not a lot of efficiency and scale in the entity that is creating the orders that then flow through the rest of the system. And so our first step is to help doctors in private medical practices go from a guild to an operating entity, helping them to achieve basic efficiencies in the information infrastructure. Our second step is to move medical groups from an operating entity to a strategic entity. So once you – the medical practice, the order-making entity – have basic internal integrity where you know how many orders you sent out, you know how many results came back, you know how many claims you sent out, you know how many got paid, how many didn’t, whether they got paid enough – that basic stuff – then you can use that integrity to move from being an operating to a strategic organisation. You are choosing when to fight and where. A strategic organisation is in the business of looking through the things they do and picking and choosing – I only want to see patients with this or that insurance company versus this other one, or I want to do my own pap smears with my own laboratory because it seems like there’s a lot of money to be made there. So they are making decisions around what in the supply chain around me do I want to control, and what in the supply chain around me do I want to avoid. So that’s the second thing that we want to help medical practices do. And the third thing that medical practices don’t do – but will do some day – is go from being a strategic entity to a system where they actually use their market power to influence what happens elsewhere, in part by coordinating with other medical practices. An example of different entities becoming operating entities, and then strategic entities and then a system is the Visa network. All the different merchandisers in the visa network have agreed to be a system – they have agreed to create this not-for-profit called the Visa association that clears the transaction. Anybody who wants to issue credit on a retail basis can use this really efficient network, where, for pennies a customer can stick her card into any slot in the world and somebody’ll figure it out. Sometimes it’s debit and sometimes it’s credit, all you know is you shove the thing in and the money comes out. So that is the last step in the journey of that order-making entity. Fundamentally we are still stuck at the guild level. We are in the business of moving physicians from guilds to operating entities to strategic entities, and we believe that someone will come along and build a system using athena as an ingredient. And 99 MN3119 Strategy the reason is because we have integrated all of the technology, knowledge and work that go into the mechanics of an order into a solution that doesn’t have any upfront costs. Just like the visa network. When you’re a store and you want to take Visa you don’t have to go buy some software into a computer and install it to capture the Visa network. Visa says, “ok it’s going to cost you 3.5 per cent of all the transactions you do and we’ll show up, we’ll show you how it works, we’ll help you open your account, and we’ll be watching, and as we deliver value to you, we’ll take our piece.” [Indeed, what differentiates athenahealth from competitors is its decision to share risk with customers by charging a percentage fee of a doctor’s collections, rather than a flat fee.] So what athena is doing is for the first time providing a valuebased service like that, which integrates all of the software, hardware, the subject matter knowledge, what type of insurance does this person have, what drug are you ordering, is that something they are allergic to, or is it consistent with other drugs they are already on. We are responsible for what software needs to be written, what hardware it needs to sit on, what knowledge, what resources, insurance or laboratories that are available for the doctor to interact with. We aim to formalise and disaggregate the supply chain so that there is essentially a reliable grid through which orders and results are trafficked. To make a fiduciary platform, a national backbone that makes sure those things are cleared properly. We believe that doing this will create a lot of potential. To begin with, it will create a lot of savings for everybody. Right now we do everything twice. We send out every lab twice, we send out every claim two and a half times, we fill out every prescription 1.8 times. It is all manual and it is all coming out on paper charts in the offices of teeny tiny doctors who don’t have any really strong need to integrate. When a doctor orders something, he or she expects a result to come back, and 30 per cent of the time it doesn’t. That affects patient care pretty dramatically. In the US we killed 96,000 people in the last year by accident by misreading or mis-transcribing information. If the airline industry had the same fatal error rate as the healthcare industry, there would be two jumbo jet airliners crashing into each other every third day of the year killing everyone aboard both planes – by accident! Once we’ve established an information infrastructure, it then becomes possible for doctors to decide their strategic direction. Maybe they want to be their own lab, maybe they don’t, they can figure it out. Once doctors become strategic entities, once all of the complexity is stripped away and it’s reliable, then they can make those decisions; and so that’s our goal. To get all of this tough work to go away and then you’re actually looking at information and you make informed decisions and we’re thinking when that happens, doctors will integrate, will merge, will see the opportunities of doing their own surgeries in their centres, and the supply chain will dramatically reaggregate. It will go from the general store model of a hospital that has a total mishmash of whatever it is that the doctor wants done with no particular idea of whether it works for them or not – to places 100 Chapter 10: Vertical integration and transaction cost that take different parts of the supply chain and do them really well in competition with others. Everybody in this country has always been interested in whether we can cure this or that disease, a new stint, or new device, or a new operation but the truth is we can already do some pretty absurdly elaborate things, we just can’t reliably give each other flu shots. It turns out that the number of lives lost, angst caused, humiliation caused by just doing the things that we already know how to do badly vastly outweighs the lives saved by learning how to do more things. And so there’s this gaping hole. We are going medical group by medical group to grow our business. Remember when you take on the supply chain, the whole supply chain can be included, but if we don’t have this or that insurance company or lab wired up, then we have to replicate the manual work that the lady in the smock used to do in the back office with the fax machine. At athena, we receive two metric tons of paper every week which is the stuff that insurance companies don’t give us electronically, and we run it through scanners to verify the amounts and we run it through the data centre in India and they punch in all the little numbers on all the little pages so that they turn it into the electronic information that we should have gotten in the first place. We have to replicate the experience of everybody operating in a paperless world by actually just handling all the paper. We go to an insurance company and say, dude, you give us 65,000 pages of paper a month! You have to print it, you have to mail it. If you just build an interface, you don’t have to do anything! You got to get there somehow. Imagine trying to start FedEx, when you got a million planes flying every day, the incremental cost of another package is very low…but how do you get to the point where you’ve got a million planes flying? We at athena have been lucky in that with the Internet and India and the evolution of optical character recognition – all those things have converged to allow us to burrow into these very cumbersome pieces of the supply chain without enjoying the luxury of having everybody on the same standard. It has been a kind of solar eclipse that has made us lean enough, and the industry as we walk into it is fat enough, that we can wedge ourselves into the supply chain and still make money. Source This extended activity is based on an in-depth interview with Jonathan Bush conducted by Brooke Russell. Questions 1. Mr Bush talks about how the lack of scale and efficiency in medical practices, the first link in the supply chain, has been a major factor in creating the healthcare supply chain as we know it today. He argues that, with access to information, doctors will become strategic entities that see the benefits of merging and integrating. Analyse this projection. What are some of the likely effects such consolidation would have? Where might the projected sources of economies be? What might some impediments be? Why do you think this has not happened before? 101 MN3119 Strategy 2. Mr Bush speaks about the ‘guild’ culture among medical practitioners. Assuming the restraints on supply of physicians remain in place, what besides empowering through information, could athenahealth be doing to foster a business culture among practitioners in this unique profession? 3. Mr Bush uses the Visa network as analogy of what athenahealth is trying to iniate in the healthcare industry. Do you think this analogy is apt? What are some of the differences between the two systems that might lead to different outcomes? 4. athenahealth is focused on medical practices as its primary customer. Analyse this strategy in light of the company’s vision of building an information infrastructure that includes all players on the supply chain. If you were Todd Park, responsible for business development at athenahealth, what strategies would you propose to fasttrack this process? 5. What other businesses started or could be created as a result of problems or inefficiencies in the supply chain of this or another industry? Brainstorm to find at least one example and discuss. 102 Chapter 11: Collusion Chapter 11: Collusion Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain the factors determining the stability of cartels and other cooperative agreements • discriminate between and explain different motivations for cheating in cooperative agreements. Essential reading Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 8. Further reading Porter, R. ‘A study of cartel stability: the Joint Executive Committee, 1880–1886’, Bell Journal of Economics 14(2) 1983, pp.301–14. 11.1 Introduction Apart from choosing which strategic variables to compete in, firms can also choose not to compete. By behaving to maximise joint profits rather than in a purely self-interested fashion, firms might create a bigger ‘pie’ that they can distribute among themselves and each end up with higher profits than if they were to compete vigorously. So far, so good. From basic microeconomics you know that a monopolist will try to extract as much surplus from consumers as possible, and increase profits accordingly – this is also the reason why antitrust authorities will try to stop collusion, as consumers are commonly assumed to suffer from a collusive cartel. This chapter will present a very simple model of the stability of cooperative agreements and outline some of the factors that will determine the stability of such arrangements – note that we will need this model of cooperation stability in later chapters, since the basic set-up is quite generic. We then discuss some of the factors that will affect the likelihood that cooperation is maintained. 11.2 Stability of cooperation Suppose that two firms compete in a price-setting industry. As we know from Chapter 3, equilibrium prices are at marginal cost, and in equilibrium firms make no profits. Clearly, since the two firms are the only ones in the industry, they feel that they can do better than this. One obvious way of ‘doing better’ would be to agree to set monopoly prices and split the market – as equal prices mean that the players split up the market. If both firms agree to set monopoly prices, therefore, each of them makes half the monopoly profits – quite a step up from zero profits. Suppose now that one firm expects the other one to stick to the agreement. In that case, it has an incentive to undercut the cooperative firm by a small amount, say e, and take the entire market. (Remember that in Bertrand competition whichever firm sets the lowest price takes the entire market.) Taking this further, this means that neither firm would stick to the initial agreement – both will want to undercut, and the situation will resemble a price war. 103 MN3119 Strategy This intuition, however, only holds in a one-shot game. If firms play this game repeatedly, being nice to each other may hold significant pay-offs in the future. Consider this somewhat stylised situation: firms set prices at the monopoly level and share the market at the start. They continue to do so until the other firm has set any price other than the monopoly price, and following that they set competitive prices forever, i.e. P=MC. Activity 11.1 Can you show that this is a sub-game – perfect Nash equilibrium? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. This gives us the following pay-offs: A B Both cooperate: pM/2 pM/2 A cooperates, B cheats 0 pM A cheats, B cooperates pM 0 Both compete pC = 0 pC = 0 Activity 11.2 Draw this as a one-shot game. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Now if firms cooperate forever, they will make half the monopoly profits forever. Recalling the discount factor, we know that tomorrow’s payoffs are worth d (<1) times today’s pay-offs, pay-offs the following day are worth d2 today’s, etc. As this is a geometric progression, this can be simplified to: π π t + δπt + δ 2π t + +δ 3π t ... = t 1− δ You should look up a basic maths textbook to confirm this. What will happen if a firm cheats? Given our strategies, cheating works once in the sense that the cheating firm will take all the market, but it will suffer in the future as a consequence, as from then on firms will compete a la Bertrand and make zero profits. Cooperation is profitable if the profits from cooperating are higher than the profits from cheating. This gives πM > π M , which is shorthand for 1  π M  > π M + δ π C . 2(1 − δ ) (1 − δ ) ï£ 2  (1 − δ ) Solving this for d, the discount factor, gives the following condition: 1 δ >δ = 2 d denotes the critical value of the discount factor such that both sides are exactly equal. As such, it gives a critical value for the time value of money above which cooperation is sustainable and below which it is not. What does this mean? If the future is sufficiently important (i.e. d is close to 1), the two firms will want to cooperate, while if it is not, they will prefer to cheat and cooperation breaks down. The intuition for this is quite clear: cheating gives a one-time pay-off since π πM > M . 2 104 Chapter 11: Collusion On the other hand, the cheating party will expect cooperation to break down from then on, which results in lower profits than under cooperation – basically cheating means sacrificing long-term profits for short-term gains. 11.3 Extending the model The model we considered above was very stylised: Two players, Bertrand competition, eternal cooperation or competition, symmetric firms, etc. We now extend the model in a number of directions – we allow for different types of competition, we increase the number of firms, and we discuss the expected changes if punishment strategies would not be quite so severe. 11.3.1 Different competition models Our assumption of Bertrand competition made life easy for us since competitive profits were zero. Cournot competition, or any other type of competition, is not as nice analytically, but can be solved in the same manner. Basically, think of pM as monopoly profits, pC as non-cooperative profits (whichever competitive model you assume in your specific setting), and pCH as the profit arising from playing the best response to your rival’s cooperative strategy. In matrix form, we can structure any situation in which cooperation would be profitable if both kept to it, but there is an individual incentive to deviate (i.e. a prisoner’s dilemma) as follows: Figure 11.1: A prisoner’s dilemma. The parameters have to be in the following order to constitute a prisoner’s dilemma: pChC > pCC > pChCh > pCCh In words, cheating is better than cooperating if the rival cooperates (and if the rival does not cooperate), but it is better for both players to cooperate than for both to cheat. Activity 11.3 Suppose that two firms with undifferentiated goods competitive in an industry with demand function Q = 5 – P and Marginal Cost MC = 2. Find the threshold value of d, the discount factor, for collusion to be stable if the mode of competition in each round (the stage game) is as follows: a. quantity (i.e. Cournot) competition b. price (i.e. Bertrand) competition. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 105 MN3119 Strategy 11.3.2 More players What happens if we extend our model to allow for n > 2 firms? Although this would also be possible with Cournot competition, we will use Bertrand competition to keep things simple. Our cooperation stability condition πM changes to > π M , since in an industry with n identical firms each n(1 − δ ) firm will get 1/n of overall monopoly profits. Rearranging this and solving n −1 for d, we find δ > δ = . n This expression for d is increasing in n, which implies that the discount factor must be higher for cooperation among more firms to be stable. In the extreme, if we tried to achieve cooperation between n → ∞, all firms would need to have a discount factor of almost 1, that is, all firms would have to value tomorrow’s pay-offs almost as highly as today’s! Therefore the stability of cooperation will decrease with the number of firms included in the cartel. 11.3.3 ‘Forgiving’ punishments We assumed that once cooperation breaks down, it can never be resurrected. This is clearly an extreme assumption and not necessarily a realistic one. If punishment were not eternal but only went on for a limited number of periods, we would expect cheating to become more likely! After all, a cheater does not suffer as much if, say, the other firm(s) only compete non-cooperatively for two periods and then revert to the cooperative agreement. To see how this changes things, consider the following inequality: 3 πM π > π M + δπ C + δ 2π C + M δ 2 (1 − δ ) 2 (1 − δ ) Cooperative profits on the left-hand side are unchanged, but cheating profits are high in the cheating period (as before), zero in the following two periods, and they revert back to cooperation profits in the third period after having cheated. We can rewrite the left hand side as and subtract the last term on both sides. After some algebra, we find the new stability condition to be δ >δ = 5 1 − ≈ .618 2 2 With eternal punishment the minimum value of d was 0.5, so that cooperation has now become less likely (or more difficult to sustain). Of course, if the stability condition is not met at one point in time, this would mean that a cheater who (in our simplest model) found it profitable to cheat one period will want to cheat again two periods from now when the rivals revert back to collusion. So, if punishment is assumed to be of limited length, cooperation may break down completely! This implies that it is also in the best interest of firms to credibly commit to a draconian punishment regime as this makes cooperation more likely – in other words, the range of discount factors that will support cooperation is larger for more draconian punishments. 106 Chapter 11: Collusion 11.4 Key concepts • Stability of cooperation • Cooperation • Finite v single games • Price wars. 11.5 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain the factors determining the stability of cartels and other cooperative agreements • discriminate between and explain different motivations for cheating in cooperative agreements. 11.6 Sample examination questions 1. Why would firms in an industry have periods in which they compete very hard and periods in which they collude? Why does competition not break down once and for all? 2. Which factors will influence the discount factor in an industry? Would you expect collusion to be more likely in a fast-growing industry or in a stable industry? 3. We often see collusion breaking down in the declining stages of an industry lifecycle. Why is that? 4. Would asymmetry between firms make collusion more or less likely? Explain by identifying the incentives to cheat for small and large firms separately. Guidance on answering these sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. Extended activity: the DeBeers diamond cartel Read the following and answer the questions at the end. Reading Kretschmer, T. and L. Cabral ‘De Beers and beyond: the history of the international diamond cartel’. LBS case study. http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~lcabral/teaching/debeers3.pdf De Beers and beyond: an update The need for change [The radical and far reaching changes represent] De Beers’ response to the challenges of a competitive environment and a change from a supply to a demand-driven business.1 – Nicky Oppenheimer. 1 Chairman’s Statement, De Beers Annual Report 2000. De Beers’ traditional role in the diamond market has been to take on the position of the custodian of the entire industry, protecting producers, dealers and cutters through its cartel from the vices of free markets. De Beers’ self-implied obligation to the stakeholders has been to shield the industry from volatility in prices and demand, and to the consumers to secure diamonds as a prestigious and exclusive luxury item. In the 107 MN3119 Strategy last century De Beers managed to do so, by safeguarding its cartel from competitors, by buying off excess supply, storing it in vast stockpiles to protect the prices, and by launching advertisement campaigns on behalf of the entire industry (e.g. A Diamond is Forever). In the late 1990s, however, De Beers realised that the diamond market was getting increasingly competitive, especially with the opening of new diamond mines in Canada, resulting in a decline in market share of DeBeers from nearly 80 per cent in the old days to 65 per cent in 1999 and a general underperformance of its stock.2 The diamond market at that time was characterised by flat demand and excess supply, which caused De Beers to increase its diamond stockpiles from US$2.5 billion in 1990 to US$5 billion in 1998. It became obvious that in an industry where De Beers was no longer the sole supplier of diamonds, the traditional custodian role that De Beers had adopted over the past, could not be sustained. Total percentage of diamonds distributed through the De Beers’ Diamond Trading Company – De Beers share of worldwide production was 44 per cent in 2002. 2 Formal strategic review De Beers decided that it had to change its conventional strategy of an all-embracing stronghold of the diamond industry to one of a highly aggressive competitor. With the announcement of its new chairman, Nicky Oppenheimer, and its new managing director, Gary Ralfe, De Beers seriously considered changing its overall strategy and decided to launch a formal strategic review of the industry, its operations and their future outlook in an increasingly competitive market. With the help of the Strategic Review Report, De Beers identified three main areas that had to be transformed, in order to assure De Beers’ success in the years to come: • First, current operations had to be optimised. This included increasing efficiency and cutting costs by 15 per cent in its operations (As is plus strategy), as well as the restructuring of the organisation into transparent, customer-orientated business units. • Second, De Beers realised the protection of its market leader position demanded long-term measures. However, through it being a publicly listed company on the JSE and LSE, De Beers felt that it had to endure the quick-fix profit demand of its shareholders, instead of focusing on necessary long-term projects. It thus decided to go private in 2001 after its stock had been listed for over 100 years. • Lastly, De Beers claimed there was unrealised potential in decreasing advertisement costs and increasing customer demand by promoting a more competitive environment at the downstream portion of the industry pipeline while binding them closer to their own upstream business (Supplier of Choice strategy). The implementation of the first measure, to decrease costs and to restructure the company, was a fairly standard procedure in the light of the new competitive nature of the global economy. The other two aims, however, express a fundamental change within De Beers as a corporation and the diamond industry as a whole, intended to enable ‘De Beers [to enter] the new century, fitter, leaner and streamlined for success’.3 Going private De Beers realised that a company such as itself could not solely be influenced by the short-termism of the stock market. Throughout history, De Beers had to decrease its profits to balance the market, to prevent excess supply and to sanction competitors. Trying to sustain the market position of the stronghold of the industry, De Beers recognised that it needed to maximise profits, not on an exclusive year-to-year basis, but 108 3 Chairman’s Statement, De Beers Annual Report 1999. Chapter 11: Collusion rather on a long-term view. The only way to implement this was to go private, contradictory to the general trend in the global economy. Preceding the organisational restructuring of the De Beers Group instigated in 1999, De Beers separated its management ties from Anglo American Corporation in 1998, initiating an exclusive refocus on its diamond products. In 1999 De Beers acquired the minority interests in the DTC from Anglo American Corporation, sold most of its non-diamond businesses and two years later announced its proposal to acquire all of the outstanding shares of its shareholders.4 Within less than half a year, 93 per cent of the shareholders accepted the offer by De Beers Investments, comprised of the Oppenheimer Family through Central Holdings Limited (45 per cent), Anglo American plc (45 per cent) and Debswana, the joint-venture between the Government of Botswana and De Beers (10 per cent).5 In June 2001 the trading of De Beers’ shares on the JSE and LSE was thus terminated and De Beers went private. Supplier of choice The rough diamond market is becoming a competitive one and individual producers have to build up a loyal supportive base if they want to be able to sell their output under less buoyant market conditions.6 De Beers’ Supplier of Choice (SoC) marketing strategy, which was finally cleared by the European Commission in 2002, is the attempt to closely bind downstream customers to the upstream business and to foster advertising and branding efforts of the downstream firms, thus growing and encouraging consumer demand and total sales. As part of the SoC strategy, De Beers (re)-evaluates current and potential sightholders through a set of rigid criteria, such as financial standing, market position, distributional and marketing strengths, etc., inviting the most promising of them to benefit from the formalised and closer relationship with De Beers. De Beers guarantees a steady supply of diamonds and the support of marketing activities of its sightholders through its Added Value Services. Of its 120 sightholders, many of them with long-established relationships with De Beers, 25 per cent were disposed of at the end of 2003, creating significant uncertainty in the diamond industry.7 Because of the criteria applied by De Beers, which nobody really seems to understand, [the Antwerp manufacturing] companies have seen their viability come under real threat.8 Closure of the opportunity gap The primary goal of SoC is to initiate growth in the diamond market through downstream advertisement campaigns, driving the consumer demand while allowing De Beers to transfer its advertisement efforts. De Beers aimed to instigate a market where retail firms advertise and establish their own brands, creating more effective, customer-near marketing campaigns. Ultimately, De Beers is seeking to increase total diamond jewellery sales by 4 per cent per year, compounding to a total growth of 50 per cent over 10 years. 4 Previously, Anglo owned 32.2 per cent of De Beers, while De Beers owned 35 per cent of Anglo. See Appendix 1: De Beers Ownership Structure. 5 Chasm Even-Zohor, Tacy Diamond Intelligence, 01.09.2000. 6 See Appendix 2: Official DTC Sightholder List 2004. 7 Peter Meeus, HRD’s Managing Director, Antwerp Focus, September 2003. 8 In the 1990s the diamond market was not growing proportional to worldwide GDPs; compared with sales of similar luxury goods, it was underperforming. The growing divergence between the rate of increase of luxury goods sales and the rather flat rate of increase of the diamond sales is depicted as the Opportunity Gap below: 109 MN3119 Strategy 500 CAGR 1980=100 400 Luxury Goods 300 GDP 200 100 Opportunity Gap Diamonds 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 2000 Figure 11.1: Supplier of Choice, Opportunity Gap (the difference between overall luxury goods sales and diamond sales). Source: www.debeersgroup.com Comparing the amount of money that was spent on advertisement in similar industries, the diamond industry was spending only 1 to 2 per cent of total sales on advertisement, whereas the watch industry was spending 6 per cent and the general luxury industry was spending even up to 10 per cent of total sales. De Beers itself spent the industry’s lion share, allocating about 4 per cent of total sales to advertising. It appeared that the downstream diamond jewellery market and even other upstream competitors were mainly relying (free-riding) on the industry-conducive marketing campaigns launched by De Beers (A Diamond is forever). Determined to end this inbalance, De Beers decided to introduce a new marketing strategy Supplier of Choice, choosing only the best retailers as its sightholders and training them in marketing and advertising. At the official launch of its Supplier of Choice strategy in July 2000, De Beers renamed its Central Selling Organization as Diamond Trading Company (DTC) and introduced the DTC’s new logo the Forevermark, which is inscribed into its stones to ensure its quality. In addition to the Supplier of Choice, De Beers also introduced the Miner of Choice and the Employer of Choice schemes, promoting company culture, equal employment opportunities and such. Vertical integration Many diamond-producing companies have started to build vertically integrated structures, a trend that will strengthen within the next three to five years when we will see quite a different structure of the world diamond market.9 The Supplier of Choice strategy would undoubtedly result in a highly competitive, growth-orientated retailer market, as the removal of De Beers’ industry-wide cloak of protection would force retailers to establish their own differentiated brands. As other diamond suppliers, such as BHP-Billiton and Alrosa, had announced before, De Beers saw a chance to gain from the downstream branding development. It decided to collaborate with the luxury producer LVMH to set up the joint venture Rapids World Ltd. The resulting new retail stores, named De Beers LV, target the very high-end element of the jewellery market, attempting to obtain a 25 to 30 per cent premium over unbranded jewellery. Its first store opened in London at the end of 2002, three more in Tokyo in September 2003. The US launch will take place at the end of 2004 with locations in both New York and Los Angeles. Very recently, Aber Diamond Corporation announced that it would acquire the luxury jeweller Harry Winston Inc., following the trend of vertical 110 Alrosa Vice President Serguei Oulin, Interview with Rapaport Diamond Report, 09.04.2003. 9 Chapter 11: Collusion integration set out by De Beers’ partnership with LVMH. Aber, however, felt that it did not have the name recognition and thus was bound to link up with a well-know brand, such as Harry Winston. Matthew Manson, Aber’s vice president of marketing, explained to the New York Times: We wanted to link up with a well-known brand. The very best brands like Tiffany and Cartier are already out there. You can’t create those overnight. We want to be a more vertically integrated company, not just a producer and a seller. We are looking to attract investors.10 Antwerp Facets News Service, 02.12.2003 10 De Beers had the advantage that it already had established its own name, and thus could rely on sufficient consumer confidence to make De Beers LV a successful brand name. Interestingly, the cartel is effectively profiting from an identical strategy to Intel’s Intel Inside campaign. In each case the companies had already established sufficient brand awareness with the consumer through its upstream activities. Both used their existing reputation to expand downstream and thus to benefit from its own name on various levels of the diamond pipeline. This of course, is intended not simply as a means of obtaining a greater overall return but should be seen as a stark diversification within De Beers’ usual operations. De Beers further expects that the partnership with LVMH will allow the cartel to access the US retail market, a market so far closed to them due to US antitrust regulations. It should be noted that Rapids World is set up as a completely independent company from the rest of De Beers’ operations. De Beers has repeatedly asserted that it would not directly supply Rapids World with stones. However, this would mean that Rapids will have to buy polished stones from the market at regular prices, while De Beers would sell them beforehand to polishers. Cynics argue that this is going to lead inevitably to a conflict of interest. De Beers needs to make certain that the new Rapids World is lucrative, as it would otherwise severely harm De Beers’ reputation as a whole. Thus, one has to explore what options, besides providing cheaper diamonds, De Beers has to ensure the success of its joint venture over other downstream competitors.11 Developments in operations and exploration Canada Following the increase in competition through the split of Argyle from the cartel, De Beers faced a new challenge to its market power. So far three diamond deposits have been discovered in Canada: Snap Lake, Diavik and Etaki. In 2000, De Beers was able to acquire Winspear and is expected to start mining at Snap Lake by 2005, expecting to produce 1.5 million carats per year over 22 years. De Beer’s competitors Rio Tinto and Aber Diamond mines secured ownership of the Diavik Mines, producing 6 million carats per year over 20 years. Another mine, Etaki, is owned by Dia Met along with BHP-Billiton. De Beers has signed a contract to distribute 35 per cent of Diaviks diamonds from 2000 to 2003. It is expected that Canada will be the third largest diamond producer, worth 17 per cent of the total market. To De Beers’ misfortune, it seems that it is having increasing difficulties in establishing itself in this new market. See ‘De Beers and beyond: an update (1997-2003) or ‘Conjecturing about “incredibly hidden” strategies behind dropping of so many US sightholders’ and ‘DTC strategies: a view from the top’ on www. diamondintelligence. com, for a thorough and extremely interesting discussion of De Beers’ potential strategic motives behind the Supplier of Choice implementation. 09.04.2003. 11 Botswana and Namibia De Beers has continued to strengthen ties with Botswana and Namibia, through the joint ventures Debswana and Nambed, held equally between De Beers and the respective governments of both countries. A new mine in each of the countries was opened in 2002; Debswana will have increased its production to 30 million carats per year by the end of 2003 and 111 MN3119 Strategy Namdeb is aspiring to double its value from 2000 by 2005 (as set out in ‘Big Hairy Audacious Goal’12 announced in 2001). Congo and Angola Problem areas such as Angola and the Congo, still torn apart by the consequences of civil war, pose another challenge to the cartel. Because of past civil unrests in Angola, De Beers had cut all operations there. At the moment it is engaged in discussions aiming to organise reconstruction and development in Angola. De Beers plans to return to the Democratic Republic of Congo, as it has regained some stability. The United Nations, however, commenced an investigation against De Beers for allegedly exploiting the natural resources of Congo during the civil war. 12 The goal of growing the value of the diamond business owned by De Beers to US$10 billion by the year 2004 was indeed titled BHAG. The reasons for this curious naming are unknown. Russia Russia has, since the fall of communism, been a concern for De Beers. Only part of Russia’s diamonds are traded through the DTC, while the rest are sold directly to cutters. De Beers had traditionally bought its Russian diamonds through the state-owned supplier Alrosa; however, at the end of 2001 the official contract between Alrosa and De Beers ended. The European Commission has since been reviewing the renewal of the contract, an agreement to sell up to US$4 billion worth of rough diamonds over five years, as it fears that ‘by entering into the agreement, De Beers has abused its dominant position in the rough diamonds market’.13 At the moment, De Beers and Alrosa are trading diamonds on a willing buyer/ willing seller basis, selling US$634 in 2003 – 25 per cent lower than the laid-out contract would provide for. The question is: does Russia gain from a fixed contract with De Beers or is it better off on a willing-buyer/willingseller basis allowing it to explore other opportunities simultaneously? European Commission, January 2003. 13 Challenges to the diamond market Using De Beers’ forecasts, the value of diamonds will grow by 4 per cent per year to US$90 billion in 10 years. A greater demand for diamonds, through the prospect of an accessible US market and expanding developing markets, notably India and China, is likely to result in a shortage of available rough diamonds in the years to come. Industry experts believe that the 50 per cent value increase in the diamond industry will be achieved through vigorous price increases, instead of higher diamonds sales. Despite sluggish economies and uncertain stock markets there is already a shortage of ongoing rough supplies which have only been met from stock.14 James Picton for UK stockbrokers W.H. Ireland, ‘A review of the world’s rough diamond market’, www.minesite. com, 18.07.2003. 14 In the light of this, De Beers’ shift in strategy, targeting a demand-driven rather than a supply-driven diamond market, might have severe consequences for the diamond trade. Industry experts predict that the combination of rising prices and the novel costs of intensified advertisement and branding efforts of the downstream market will lead to a complete re-organisation of the industry. Many retail downstream firms will be forced to consolidate with competitors or at least form joint ventures to avoid bankruptcy. First, there is no guarantee that sufficient rough will be available to support all of these initiatives. Second, the market cannot support 130 different diamond brands. So we are likely to see many companies bankrupted by high costs.15 At present, the retailer market has incurred an extremely high debt of US$8.66 billion in 2002, from US$6.88 the year before. This was a result 112 Moshe Leviev, Leviev International Diamond Group, Gemological Institute of America Newsletter. 15 Chapter 11: Collusion of the general de-stocking activities of the rough suppliers, specifically De Beers, in the last few years. Much of the extra supply was taken up by the extra demand in 2002. The anticipation of a steep rise in prices and the low interest rates caused many downstream firms to buy off a great deal of diamonds, stockpiling them for the future. In 2003 the prices of rough diamonds increased by ca. 10 per cent, while the price of polished stones continued diluting. Retailers are speculating that the inflationary return on their inventory will exceed the cost of holding the diamond stockpiles. However, the transfer of non-debt-financed stockpiles of De Beers to highly debt-financed stockpiles of the retailers is clearly increasing the risk of firms in the downstream market and promoting the expected consolidation trend. These factors will lead inevitably to a shakedown in the market, leaving only the strongest, or better, the ones with the best strategy in the market. Experts predict a major and increasing trend to vertical integration of companies, similar to oil firms, where a small number of firms control the whole of the supply chain (industry pipeline) from mining to cutting to retail. Conclusion It is certain that the diamond market has changed from a tightly-controlled market, in the hands of the market-custodian De Beers, to a increasingly competitive industry, directing De Beers to fundamentally reshape its business proposition. Once upon a time, the key to success in the diamond business was skill…In this new era, skill is still important, but strategy is more important.16 Excerpt from discussion: ‘The past, present and future’ at Rapaport International Diamond Conference 2003, 20.10.2003. 16 The question is whether the radical change of strategy will allow De Beers to hold on to its market share, and whether the Supplier of Choice strategy can defend the De Beers Group from further challenges in the future. Also is there another underlying plan hidden in the Supplier of Choice strategy or is De Beers only optimising its distribution system? Diamonds are forever, but is the De Beers cartel? Source Reichel, M.C. ‘De Beers and beyond: an update’. LSE case study. 113 MN3119 Strategy Appendix 1 – De Beers ownership structure (abridged)17 (following January 2002 restructuring) 11% Anglo American Group Central Holdings Group Debswana Group 89% Central Investments DBI (Lux) 10% 45% 45% 100% DB Investments (Lux) (new company) De Beers sa (formerly DB Investments) 100% De Beers Consolidated Mines (DBCM) 100% De Beers Centenray (DBCAG)) Questions 1. Cabral (2000) gives an overview of factors facilitating or hindering collusion. Which ones are relevant in the diamond industry? Explain how they affect the parameters of the model he outlines on pp.128–30. 2. Why do you think the cartel grew increasingly unstable in recent years? Is there a pattern in the type of attacks on the cartel, or in the type of attacker? If there is, explain what happened on a broad level, and if not, pick two cases and analyse the attackers’ motives for their behaviour. 3. Analyse De Beers’ recent changes in their strategy. Will the ‘Supplier of Choice’ strategy be sufficient to shield De Beers from changes in the diamond industry? Which complementary measures (or alternatives) would you use as a De Beers executive? 114 Group ownership structure, www. debeersgroup.com 17 Chapter 12: Strategic partnerships Chapter 12: Strategic partnerships Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • discuss types of capabilities and motivation for investing or not investing in them • evaluate the benefits and pitfalls of using strategic alliances. Essential reading Dierickx, I. and K. Cool ‘Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage’, Management Science 35(12) 1989, pp.1504–511. Dyer, J. and H. Singh ‘The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganisational competitive advantage’, Academy of Management Review 23(4) 1998, pp.660–79. Further reading Arora, Alfonso Gambardella ‘Complementarities and external linkages: the strategies of large firms in biotechnology’, Journal of Industrial Economics 38(4) 1990, pp.361–79. Kretschmer, T. and P. Puranam ‘Integration through incentives within differentiated organisations’, Organization Science 19(6) 2008, pp.860–75. 12.1 Introduction Strategic alliances combine many of the pros and cons of cooperation between firms as discussed in the previous chapter. Both parties benefit if they collaborate or behave in the manner that they had previously specified. However, each party has an incentive to hold back efforts or resources in the hope that the other one will deliver or there might be policies which restrict collusions but which give firms incentives to enter into alliances; a classic prisoner’s dilemma. This chapter will not dwell on detail regarding the motives of firms to enter strategic alliances, but will look at the mechanics of how such alliances work and at the trade-offs in this context. We will focus on one kind of strategic alliance, namely an alliance to build up capabilities. This type of strategic alliance is a hybrid solution between internal development and external sourcing. 12.2 Building capabilities There are two distinct types of strategic alliances: result-driven and capability-building. Result-driven strategic alliances come about because a specific project, or joint output, needs to be completed, a result needs to be generated, etc. Imagine it as a group of students getting together to prepare a class presentation or a group assignment. This has all the features of a strategic alliance where there are benefits to working hard, but also incentives to let others do the work. Capability-building strategic alliances, on the other hand, may not generate a tangible outcome, but they are aimed at improving the efficiency of the alliance partners in general. Imagine a study group consisting of students taking the course – studying together may not generate a tangible joint output, but it 115 MN3119 Strategy will improve the ability of the students to take their exams (which are individual, so we cannot talk of a joint output). Again each student would like all the others to take charge of topics and be well prepared, but there is still an incentive to listen to others’ explanations and save oneself some work. In this chapter, we will focus on the second type of strategic alliance, capability-building alliances. Building firm capabilities is traditionally considered an ‘inside job’. After all, firm capabilities are what set firms apart from their rivals, and therefore maintaining as much control as possible is preferable (we discussed this in Chapter 6). So how do firms build capabilities? Figure 12.1 gives an overview of the methods of building capabilities. Figure 12.1: Building capabilities. 12.3 Business and strategic partnerships1 One way of building capabilities are strategic partnerships. First, we distinguish between strategic partnerships and business partnerships – not all collaborations, even long-term ones, between firms qualify as strategic partnerships. A strategic partnership can typically be identified by the following. Firms will usually make relation-specific investments, that is, investments that carry most use within a particular partnership. If an investment is generic and not specific to the partnership, it is easy for each party to walk away without losing much money. Strategic partnerships often rely heavily on the voluntary exchange of information among the parties. In a business partnership, all the information that has to be exchanged will either be exchanged up front or it will be written in a formal contract. Strategic partnerships on the other hand will be governed by relatively incomplete contracts (contracts that do not specify what to do in each and every possible situation – but more on that in Chapters 7 and 10), so that information exchange becomes important as the relationship unfolds. Linked to the previous point, strategic partnerships will be much more integrated and interdependent than regular business partnerships. This implies that firms will be interdependent both in their actions (so that one firm’s actions will be more effective if they are coordinated with the other firm’s) and in their pay-offs (so that one firm’s pay-offs from the partnership will depend on the other firm’s pay-offs as well). Finally, the way in which strategic partnerships and business partnerships deal with transaction costs also differs. In a business partnership, the goal is to minimise transaction costs by specifying as much as possible in a contract before launching the partnership. On the other hand, a strategic 116 This section is based on Dyer, J. and H. Singh ‘The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganisational competitive advantage’, The Academy of Management Review 23(4) 1998 pp.660–79. 1 Chapter 12: Strategic partnerships partnership will accept that contracts are incomplete and attempt to build in mechanisms to cope with transaction costs – for example, by joint asset ownership which aligns incentives of the different parties of a strategic partnership. We can therefore finally give a definition of strategic partnerships: Strategic partnership – definition Strategic partnerships are relationships between organisations that involve significant amounts of shared decision making and that may involve equity ownership (economic integration), organisational linkages and coordination mechanisms (organisational integration). Business partnerships score lower on most or all of these dimensions. In particular, the details of investments is typically lower in business partnerships, and business partnerships will often specify as many terms and conditions as possible in the initial contract, thus minimising transaction cost and formalising the exchange of information. In other words, business partnerships are often drawn up as formal contractual propositions, while strategic partnerships will rely on the willingness of the parties or incentives to ‘make a relationship work’. Equity ownership (Economic integration) X% A B Y% Coordination mechanisms (Organisational integration) Figure 12.2: Elements of a strategic partnership. Figure 12.2 illustrates the two elements that typically define a strategic partnership. First, strategic partnerships will require some form of organisational integration – coordination between the two strategic partners, either through communication and coordination efforts or even by forming an entirely new entity (as illustrated in Figure 12.3 – a joint venture). The other element typically found in a strategic partnership is a degree of economic integration, that is joint ownership of assets or crossasset holding. This makes coordinating any actions easier simply because incentives by both partners are aligned – if you do well, so do I (because I have a stake in your own) and vice versa. A particular form of strategic partnership is a joint venture, where a new organisation is set up, and therefore organisational integration takes place within this new unit. This type of strategic partnership is special in the sense that a new entity is created in which the partnership ‘takes place’. The firms can be entirely separate except for the newly-formed joint venture. The advantage of this is that coordinating mechanisms can be realised with less friction since the main activities of the respective partners are not affected. On the other hand of course, the potential for generating synergies originating from the main activities of the partners is lower. 117 MN3119 Strategy Joint Venture Equity ownership (Economic integration) 50+x % 50- x % A B Coordinating mechanisms (Organisational integration) Figure 12.3: Joint venture. Activity 12.1 How would you organise the following and why? a. Two firms, a hardware and a software firm, want to develop a revolutionary new audio technology. b. Two pharmaceutical firms want to enter a new medical sub-class and want to build capabilities in this treatment area. c. The municipality of a large city in an emerging economy has awarded a contract to build a large leisure centre to a local entrepreneur, who will require input from a large number of different parties. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. It is important to note here that strategic partnerships might become useful for two (not mutually exclusive) different reasons. The actions of the strategic partners might be complementary or the actions might require a certain degree of coordination to confer their full benefits. 12.4 Equity ownership Having established that there is some need for organisational integration, where does financial integration come in? In other words, why is equity ownership important in such a situation? As in many cases, the purpose of equity ownership is to enable decision making in the interest of the partnership and not the individual party. Shared decision making is typically difficult since contracts are incomplete (as mentioned before) and there is considerable scope, particularly in open-ended partnerships, for opportunistic behaviour by both parties. Equity ownership, either directly or by setting up a new legal entity through a joint venture, will help align incentives and minimise opportunistic behaviour. As with most things, however, equity ownership does not come without risks and costs, which we will discuss in more detail. The main benefits of equity ownership are the alignment of interests, the retention of control and exclusivity of the partnership, and the feasibility of inter-organisational coordination. There is less risk of one of the strategic partners being exploited by an opportunistic player with no equity stake in the partnership, and it is more likely that the partner will take actions that are inline with the overall success of the undertaking. 118 Chapter 12: Strategic partnerships The key costs are a loss of flexibility and a loss of motivation. Committing to an equity stake in a project lowers the room for manoeuvre if the technology or the market develops in unexpected ways. Locking into a partnership with equity ownership is therefore more risky if there are elements outside the relationship that cannot be taken into account. Also, once equity ownership has been established, motivation to exert maximum effort may decrease since the threat of not continuing a relationship is much lower if equity is involved – if the relationship was governed by a series of spot contracts, anything lower than the optimal outcome (or the agreed level of effort) would lead to the contract not being renewed. Equity ownership and organisational integration are interlinked in that there is a relatively strong positive relationship between the two, as illustrated by Figure 12.4. It is, however, important to note that there can also be cases with high equity ownership but low organisational integration such as pure financial investment or a set of independent ownership and inter-organisational integration business units Equity under the same umbrella (e.g. a holding company). inter-organisational integration High R&D JV’s Collaborative R&D Acquisitions in which target firms are “absorbed” into acquirer Acquisitions in which target firms enjoy intermediate levels of organisational autonomy Contract R&D low Licensing agreements low Minority Equity Equity ownership level Acquisitions in which target firms are managed as autonomous units High Figure 12.4: Equity ownership and inter-organisational integration. Two questions should be asked before engaging in a strategic partnership: first, will a strategic partnership actually create value or should firms extend their firm boundary? Will it actually be beneficial to the two firms to join forces, and is it preferable to integrate to some extent rather than just engage in cross-shareholding without a controlling stake? Is there more value created by a strategic partnership than by a clever investor? Assuming that this is so, the second question should be about the level of organisational and financial integration. Considering the costs of equity ownership, it is therefore advisable to limit ownership so as to sustain the requisite level of shared decision making. 119 MN3119 Strategy 12.5 Key concepts • Result driven • Capability driven • Business and strategic partnership • Strategic partnership • Internal and external development • Asset stock accumulation • Stocks and flows • Equity ownership. 12.6 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • discuss types of capabilities and motivation for investing or not investing to them • evaluate the benefits and pitfalls of using strategic alliances. 12.7 Sample examination questions 1. Business partnerships are relatively loose forms of cooperation among firms. Is this form of cooperation particularly common in specific stages of the industry life cycle and, if so, why? 2. Why would a firm voluntarily choose not to build up capabilities to match those of the market leader? 3. Is equity ownership more useful and important for capability-building alliances than for results-driven alliances? Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. Extended activity: the EU aviation industry Read the following and answer the questions at the end. Strategic alliances – case study: The EU aviation industry The civil aviation industry is defined by a fundamental paradox: it is one of the key instruments of globalisation and is truly international in the scope of its operations; yet it is restricted by arcane regulations and national politics – perhaps more than any other business in the world. Historically, the industry took shape through the creation of national airlines or ‘flag carriers’ by governments eager to propel the economic and social development of their countries. This legacy has created a myriad of vested state interests that result in significant barriers to exit or a political inability to let failing flag carriers go bankrupt. The economic realities of the airline industry are tough. Burdened with high fixed costs and a cyclical problem of overcapacity, airlines also face a declining rate of growth in air travel and stiff competition –particularly from low-cost carriers. In recent years, the industry has seen a marked decline in yields, the average revenue per passenger, due to the persistent pressure on airlines to reduce costs and pass on the savings to customers demanding lower prices in a fiercely competitive market. 120 Chapter 12: Strategic partnerships European civil aviation has undergone significant liberalisation and privatisation over the past 20 years through liberalisation ‘packages’ in 1987, 1990 and 1993. Today the member states of the European Union act as one aviation market, with unlimited traffic rights and rights of establishment, a liberal fare regime, and healthy competition. Airline consolidation, widely believed to be the natural and beneficial follow-on to liberalisation, has been thwarted to date, largely by the ‘open skies’ bilateral treaties governing air traffic between EU states and the US. By imposing ownership and landing restrictions stipulating that designated airlines must be majority owned and controlled by a national of the given state, these treaties place EU airlines at a disadvantage. European airlines are deterred from making ‘cross-border’ acquisitions – even within Europe – because the nationality clauses in the prevailing treaties put into question whether the acquired company would have to forfeit its right to serve foreign (particularly the US) markets. Unable to merge, these carriers cannot fully exploit either the US or European markets. Thus over 20 European carriers divide transatlantic traffic between them, each operating from their individual home base. Many in the EU lament that the ‘open skies’ bilaterals create market asymmetries that give the US an unfair advantage. Unless and until the necessary regulatory changes open the way for significant consolidation of the global market, airlines will continue to forge the next best thing – alliances, which help them achieve some of the economic gains that genuine consolidation would offer: greater economies of scale and the seamless travel services across regions that large multinational corporations – the most lucrative customers – demand. Alliance Members Star Alliance Fourteen, including: United, Lufthansa, SAS, Air Canada, Thai Airways, Varig One World Eight: Aerlingus, American, British Airways, Cathay Pacific, Finn Air, Iberia, LanChile, Qantas SkyTeam Six: Air France, Alitalia, Delta, CSA Czech Airlines, AeroMexico, Korean Air Northwest Northwest –KLM –KLM Founded Countries Destinations Annual served served passengers (m) % share of world traffic Anti-trust immunity? 1997 124 729 289.3 in Year 1999 18.5 Yes for United, Lufthansa, SAS 1999 135 571 238 in Year 2000 11.8 No 2000 120 500 228 in Year 2000 11.1 No 1993 N/A N/A 72.9 in Year 1999 4.7 Yes for NWAKLM, and NWA- Malaysia Source: company websites and AEA 2001 Yearbook Without antitrust immunity from the relevant regulatory bodies – for example, the European Commission and the US Department of Transportation – alliances can do little more than achieve cost savings through joint marketing campaigns and possibly joint purchasing. Those with immunity like Lufthansa and United can align fares and flight schedules, offering customers the much-touted seamless travel experience of one-stop check-in and easy flight connections. Combining operations in this way gives alliance partners access to significant scale economies and allows them to jointly tighten or expand capacity to optimal levels. 121 MN3119 Strategy European airlines fall into two broad categories: the traditional flag carrier and the low cost carriers. The latter have taken the industry by storm following its liberalisation, and continue to gain market share with their winning formula of fleet standardisation, quick turnaround on point–point short-haul routes, and direct sales and marketing practices. Lufthansa, British Airways (BA), and Air France are the three dominant airlines in Europe today. Among these market leaders, however, one sees divergent business strategies. Lufthansa exemplifies the ‘aviation’ or vertically integrated business model in which its passenger and cargo airline businesses sit alongside five independently competitive business groups including catering, ground handling, maintenance and overhaul, IT services, and leisure travel. In contrast, BA pursues a ‘lean’ strategy, focusing mainly on its airline services and outsourcing as many of the related support services as possible. Still this strategy leaves BA competing head-to-head with the low-cost carriers on short-haul routes, and so makes continued cost-cutting a necessity. Airlines that can reduce costs through efficient corporate structures and external alliances will have an advantage in the coming years, where data show that passenger yields, or the average revenue that airlines earn per passenger kilometre, is declining. If airlines acted in concert to lower capacity, they could boost passenger load factors and yields by keeping fares robust. Acting alone, however, airlines that cut costs by cutting capacity might never see concomitant gains in yields for they risk losing significant market share to competitors who might seize the opportunity to expand their own capacity. Industry consolidation would indeed make it easier for airlines to correct any capacity inequalities, and would also make it easier for airlines to deal with the natural cycles in supply and demand, which are an integral characteristic of the industry. But, as we have seen, true consolidation will not happen in Europe until states remove the nationality clauses in their air transport agreements – an issue that governments, not firms, can resolve. For now and the foreseeable future, European airlines must operate within the realities of the market, shaped as it is by regulations. Source Russell, Brooke under the supervision of Dr T. Kretschmer ‘The EU aviation industry’, LSE case study. Questions 1. Outline the costs and benefits of airline consolidation. 2. Compare the relative benefits of airlines consolidating versus forming strategic alliances. 3. If you were CEO of an airline, and there were no nationality clauses, how would you grow your business? 122 Chapter 13: Competitive dynamics Chapter 13: Competitive dynamics Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain the core ideas of competitive dynamics by using the actoraction-response-performance framework • describe how the awareness, motivation and capability of a firm influence its responses towards rivals’ actions. Essential reading Chen, M.-J. ‘Competitor analysis and interfirm rivalry: towards a theoretical integration’, Academy of Management Review 21(1) 1996, pp.100–34. Ferrier, W.J., K.G. Smith and C.M. Grimm ‘The role of competitive action in market share erosion and industry dynamics: a study of industry leaders and challengers’, Academy of Management Journal 42(4) 1999, pp.372–88. Smith, K.G., W.J. Ferrier and H. Ndofor ‘Competitive dynamics research: critique and future directions’ in M.A. Hitt, R.E. Freeman and J.S. Harrison (eds), The Blackwell Handbook of Strategic Management. (Oxford: Blackwell Publishing, 2001) pp.314–61. Further reading Chen, M.-J. and D. Miller ‘Competitive dynamics: themes, trends, and a prospective research platform’, The Academy of Management Annals 6(1) 2012, pp.135–210. 13.1 Introduction Below are three major headlines from The Wall Street Journal: • ‘Alex Trotman’s goal: To make Ford No. 1 in world auto sales.’ • ‘Kellogg’s cutting prices... to check loss of market share.’ • ‘Amoco scrambles to remain king of the polyester hill.’ As we can see from these quotes, at the heart of many a firm’s strategy is competing against its rivals. This is done by carrying out specific actions to become the market leader or to avoid becoming dethroned as the market leader. As already mentioned in Chapter 6, firms seek to gain a competitive advantage in order to consistently outperform other players in the industry. Because firms compete for limited customers and resources, one firm outperforming the other often comes at the cost of the failure of its rival. To compete with each other and to attain market leadership, firms can choose from a wide range of competitive actions like introducing new products, cutting prices or engaging in R&D. Studying which actions specific firms take when they compete with specific rivals is at the core of competitive dynamics, which we discuss in this chapter. Competitive dynamics studies the process of interfirm rivalry in which firms jockey for competitive advantage by exchanging competitive actions. We study competitive dynamics for two main reasons. On the one hand, it complements the traditional perspective on strategy and the wellknown structure-conduct-performance paradigm and five forces analysis in several important dimensions. First, instead of studying competition and strategic decisions from a macro industry level, competitive dynamics 123 MN3119 Strategy looks at an individual firm (or pair of firms) and studies specific actions. Second, competitive dynamics integrates internal (e.g. resources and capabilities) and external (e.g. rivals) concerns instead of just focusing on the external ones. Third, contrary to the rather static perspective often taken, competitive dynamics takes a dynamic perspective on competitive behavioural patterns. Competition is seen as a dynamic market process rather than a static market condition. The focus is on the process by which a market moves away towards the equilibrium but not on the equilibrium per se. On the other hand, unlike game theory models, competitive dynamics is empirically driven. A well-known example of such a set of empirical insights is a case study on the competitive interactions between Kodak and Polaroid to become the leader of the camera industry shown in Figure 13.1. Polaroid 1976 Announces Australian partner for movie camera system Files patent suit against Kodak (instant camera) Reports consumer tests “Kodak has ‘fading’ problem” 01/1976 04/1976 04/1976 11/1976 03/1976 Kodak Introduces tele-instamatic camera (new features) Introduces instant-picture camera and announces attack strategy 12/1976 Announces exchange of patent licenses with Xerox Sets price for motion picture camera at $699 03/1976 09/1977 09/1977 1978 Announces new low-priced instant camera ane other products Announces they’re adding 4 pictures to 20-picture roll for 35mm film ... Figure 13.1: Competitive interactions between Kodak and Polaroid. 13.2 A framework to analyse competitive dynamics Most of the research on competitive dynamics can be integrated into the framework shown in Figure 13.2. The framework is useful because it can help us think about the process of competitive dynamics in a structured way. The first element of the framework is the actors. Here, we are interested in the characteristics of firms initiating actions and their motivation to do so. Second, when studying actions, we look for answers to the question regarding which actions firms use. The next building block are the responses – when and how do rivals respond? And, finally, research on competitive dynamics looks at the performance implications of the actions and responses. In the next paragraphs we will discuss each building block in more detail. Actor (focal firm) Action Response (by competitors) Performance (competitive advantage) Figure 13.2: Competitive dynamics framework. 13.2.1 Actor Firms ‘act’ by initiating competitive actions like price cuts or new product introductions. The timing of the action is crucial for the performance of 124 ... Chapter 13: Competitive dynamics an action. Should firms try to act first or wait and see whether something works? Research shows that late followers usually have a disadvantage, but it is not clear whether it is better to be a first mover or an early follower. On the one hand, a first mover can enjoy monopoly rents from an action (like an increase in sales after a price cut) for a short period until rival firms follow. Second, being first helps the firm to build customer loyalty and branding advantages. Third, early firms can build up market share to benefit from economies of scale. On the other hand, early followers can often still capture a large part of the market while incurring fewer development costs and bearing less technical and market risk. In addition, they have more time to improve the technology to avoid mistakes that can destroy the reputation of the firm. Besides timing, a second important question is who moves first: incumbents who have a long history in the industry or new entrants? Entrants have strong incentives to disrupt the status quo by introducing radical innovations or undercutting prices as they have little to lose and a lot to gain. Their only fear is that the large incumbent might retaliate and drive them out of the market. For incumbents, on the other hand, incentives are mixed. There are some advantages to proactively undertaking actions. First, by engaging in some action, incumbents can use existing (slack) resources to improve their market position. Second, by initiating an action, incumbents can deter market entry or drive out small entrants. Third, they can use actions to fight other incumbents. However, there are also some downsides. First, the introduction of new products can lead to the cannibalisation of the old products. Second, new products might require new capabilities that the firm currently does not possess. Moreover, developing new capabilities might cannibalise resources that might otherwise be used for old products. While there is a lot of research on the question of whether entrants or incumbents initiate more actions, the question is still not fully answered. Incumbents usually face a trade-off between continually engaging in new actions and cannibalising some of their own profits or not engaging and getting some of their profits stolen by rival firms. This idea goes back to the work of Joseph Schumpeter who predicted that industry leaders who do not continually engage in competitive actions would have their market position destroyed by incumbents. Market leaders can only retain their market shares and are ‘dethroned’ less often if they initiate and undertake more actions more quickly than challengers and if they have a broader range of actions. 13.2.2 Action Competitive actions can be defined as ‘externally directed, specific and observable competitive moves initiated by a firm to enhance its relative competitive position’. Broadly speaking there are two types of actions: strategic and tactical actions. Strategic actions are all actions that have a long-term impact on the firm, require a significant commitment of organisational and managerial resources, and are hard to reverse. Examples of strategic actions include mergers and acquisitions, new product development or the appointment of a new CEO. By contrast, tactical actions involve fewer resources, are easier to reverse and have only a short-term effect on the organisation. Typical examples of tactical actions are price cuts or an advertising campaign in a local newspaper. Strategic and tactical actions not only differ in their importance for the firm carrying them out, they also have different impacts on competitors. Besides carrying out individual actions, firms can also engage in action sequences (i.e. combining different single actions like changes in quality 125 MN3119 Strategy and price combined with an increase in the production capacity). However, managers need to be careful when combining different actions. Research has shown that the length and the volume of attack duration has a positive impact on the performance of the focal firm, but more complex attacks reduce the positive effect, as a complex series of actions is harder to conceive and to implement. This means that complex actions are often delayed. 13.2.3 Reactor As already mentioned in the introduction, the competitive dynamics literature does not assume that the relationship between every firm in an industry has to be symmetric. Put differently, not every firm in an industry is fighting with all other firms to the same extent and not every firm is threatened by the action of a rival in the same way. Hence, not every firm might react to an action in the same way and some firms might not even react at all. The question then is which firms react and why do they react? Two distinct features are said to have an influence on a firm to respond to a rival’s action: resource similarity and market commonality. Resource similarity is the degree to which two firms are similar in their resource endowments in terms of both type and time. This idea is rooted in the resource-based view of the firm and the idea of strategic similarity. The notion of market commonality goes back to the literature on multimarket contact. Firms engage in multimarket contact if they compete with a rival in several markets at the same time. When that happens, they have to take all markets into consideration when initiating an action in a focal market. The reason is that an action in one market might also cause retaliation in the other markets. As a result, multimarket competitors may hesitate to attack in one market for the fear of retaliation in other markets. This effect is called ‘mutual forbearance’ and there is some empirical evidence that firms competing in several markets face less fierce competition in these markets. Empirical studies in the telecommunication industry, for example, show that multimarket competitors have higher margins than singlemarket rivals. Firms are more likely to react to a rival’s competitive move if they have a high market commonality, but also if competitors are similar in terms of resources as they have the ability to retaliate. 13.2.4 Response When a firm takes action to gain competitive advantage, rivals often quickly respond so as not to fall behind. Responses can differ in terms of their volume, speed and type. The way rival firms respond to a competitive attack depends on three different factors: awareness, motivation and capability. Awareness means that a firm must perceive and comprehend an action of a rival. In addition, the firm must be motivated and given incentives to react to a rival’s move. For example, if an opponent introduces a new product in a market that is not important enough to the focal firm, it might not be motivated enough to react as losses are limited. The third criterion that must be met is that a firm must be capable to react. An organisation might not possess the required resources or know how to react, even if it is aware of the rival’s action and even if it is motivated enough. Only if all three conditions are met together will a firm react to the competitive actions of a rival. The magnitude and speed of responses not only depend on the characteristics of the respondent in terms of motivation, awareness and 126 Chapter 13: Competitive dynamics capability but also on the kind of action (i.e. strategic or tactical action) that triggered the response. Strategic actions tend to elicit fewer and slower responses by rivals as they require more time and more resources to be effective. On the other hand, tactical actions tend to elicit more and faster responses. 13.2.5 Performance implications Engaging in competitive dynamics can have severe implications for both incumbents and challengers. Research has shown that market leaders can only retain their strong position if they initiate more actions than their challengers, if they use a broader range of actions and if they undertake their actions quicker than rival firms. Maintaining market leadership therefore appears to follow a ‘strategic substitutes’ logic – more actions by an early mover leads to fewer actions and therefore lower performance by rivals. 13.3 Key concepts • Competitive dynamics • Competitive action • Resource similarity • Market commonality • Awareness, motivation and capability. 13.4 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • explain the core ideas of competitive dynamics by using the simple actor-action-response-performance framework • describe how the awareness motivation and capabilities of a firm influences its responses towards rivals’ actions. 13.5 Sample examination questions 1. Give two examples each of a strategic and tactical action in the alcoholic beverages industry. 2. Most experts will argue that responding quickly to a rival’s action leads to higher performance. Explain why and give a counterexample to this expectation. Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. 127 MN3119 Strategy Notes 128 Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence1 Learning outcome By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • define structural and strategic entry barriers and compare the two. Essential reading Swaminathan, A. ‘Entry into new market segments in mature industries: endogenous and exogenous segmentation in the US brewing industry’, Strategic Management Journal 19 1998, pp.389–404. Further reading This chapter is based on a guest lecture given by my former supervisor, Paul Geroski, who died much too young. Hearing Paul talk about entry, and indeed any economic or managerial phenomenon, makes it difficult to think about entry in any different way or structure. My intellectual debt to him goes far beyond this chapter, but I hope to do him and his thoughts justice with this attempt to condense his thoughts on entry. 1 Besanko, D., D. Dranove, M. Shanley and S. Shaefer Economics of Strategy. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2009) Chapter 9. Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 15. Geroski, P. ‘Early warning of new rivals’, Sloan Management Review 40(3) 1999, pp.107–16. McAfee, P., H. Mialon and M. Williams ‘What is a barrier to entry?’, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 94 2004, pp.461–65. Saloner, G., A. Shepard and J. Podolny Strategic Management. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2006) Chapter 9. 14.1 Introduction One of the most ‘strategic’ decisions in the existence of a firm is whether to enter into a particular market or not. It is also obvious that the (anticipated) reaction of firms currently in the market plays an important role in the entry decision. Suppose that an industry currently yields very high profits for the firms operating in it – for arguments sake, operating profits in the pharmaceutical and biotech industry which run close to 20 per cent. Does this mean that a firm should enter it? Not necessarily. First, an additional competitor may disturb a delicate balance achieved by established players after interacting over a long period to reach these profit margins (recall Chapter 11). This need not even be a problem for antitrust authorities, it could simply mean that firms are specialised in particular product classes and as such don’t compete very hard against each other because they produce distant substitutes. A new firm taking on one of these firms in their ‘home market’ would then encounter fierce reprisals and witness a significant drop in these initially enticing profit margins. Plus, it may not even be possible to enter these industries. Pharmaceuticals are again a good example: even if an entrepreneur could raise all the resources to establish a lab and had a good idea for a product, scientists might not be willing to join a start-up, might have invested in other firms or there could simply not be the expertise available to develop and produce a revolutionary new product. Finally, even if there were scientists who could do the job and were available, an entrepreneur might still find it difficult to enter because the incumbent has patented every conceivable innovation even loosely related to its current product, so that an innovation by an entrant would almost inevitably violate some patent or other by the incumbent. 129 MN3119 Strategy MacAfee et al. (2004, p.463) give a list of entry barriers following a review of the history of the concept. In particular, they distinguish between economic and anti-trust barriers to entry: Entry barriers – definitions An economic barrier to entry is a cost that must be incurred by a new entrant but which incumbents do not or have not had to incur. An antitrust barrier to entry is a cost that delays entry and thereby reduces social welfare relative to immediate but equally costly entry. Entry barriers can be said to have two effects, a direct and an indirect one: Entry barriers: i. Make it difficult for firms to enter into a market and earn profits. ii. Enable incumbents in the market to sustain higher levels of profits than under perfect competition. The first effect is obvious and basically defines entry barriers. The second one is more subtle (but also more interesting): if a market has entry barriers, profit levels need not be very low in order to make entry unattractive. To see why, consider the following example. Suppose a newcomer has to purchase a licence at a fixed price to start operating in that market. The entrant will take this into account when making an entry decision – only if the expected profits from entering the market exceed the entry fee will entry take place. The higher the fee (the entry barrier), the higher post-entry profits would have to be to trigger entry – putting it the other way around, the entrant will find entry unattractive for higher current profit levels, because it would still not recoup the entry fee. Of course, this will be different if the licences are freely traded and the price of the licence will settle on the level that lets entrants make a regular rate of return, but for some markets there are fixed costs of entering that cannot be traded. We distinguish between two types of entry barriers: structural barriers or strategic barriers. Structural barriers originate from the structure of the market, the product or the production technology – they arise from external sources. Strategic entry barriers only exist because incumbent firms change their behaviour in the face of (actual or threatened) entry. Some entry barriers will have elements of both structural and strategic entry barriers, but we will keep them separate for clarity. 14.2 Structural entry barriers Cost advantages. If a firm has been operating in a market for a long time, it will have gathered experience about the product and the production process and is likely to realise economies of learning (see Chapter 7). Entrants in the industry would have the same cost structure if they operated in the market for the same length of time, but at the time of entry they are at a disadvantage – the incumbent will be able to produce more cheaply than an entrant, which intrinsically makes entry less attractive. Imagine a Bertrand-type competition with asymmetric cost. A firm with a cost disadvantage will not make any sales, and if future cost in turn depends on past sales, the incumbent will become even more dominant.2 Economies of scale, scope and network effects. Incumbents are typically much larger than entrants. This will give rise to economies of scale (and scope, if they operate in adjacent product classes or markets 130 2 Cabral and Riordan (1990) model such a situation and show that aggressive pricing policies that would seem predatory in other situations are simply attempts to proceed down the learning curve in such a market. Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence as well) which is difficult for entrants to compete with in the early stages of their existence. Similarly, in a market with strong network effects, entrants offer a smaller network and therefore a less enticing alternative to the dominant firm. This problem becomes even more severe if we think about goods with a degree of switching costs – the cost a consumer has to incur if he were to switch from the brand he is currently using to another. If a market is relatively mature and consumers are contractually bound (as for example for mobile phone contracts) or have skills specific to one version of the product (as is the case with end-user software), then at any point in time, an entrant will only be able to compete for the unattached consumers (whose contract is running out, say, or who are about to upgrade from their current software), which makes the process of building up an installed base a long and costly one. Clearly then, entrants will think twice about entering into such a market. Control of essential resources. This was already mentioned in the chapter on vertical relations – if you control an essential input, other firms will find it difficult to compete. This is an important entry barrier and can partly be structural and strategic. For example, Taxi Badges in New York City are limited, as are General Practitioners’ permits in most countries – this has nothing to do with strategic behaviour on the part of the incumbents, it’s the way the market has been structured. On the other hand, DeBeers’ attempt to control most of the world’s diamond mines was (among other things, as we have seen in Chapter 11) a strategic attempt to shut out competition. The main message, however, is that if an entrant has to settle for a less profitable resource (for example, a less central location for a retail shop, a less rich ore mine, or less skilful staff), entry is less attractive, creating a barrier to entry. Marketing and reputation advantages. The first firm in the market will often establish a brand reputation and brand recognition before others enter. Sometimes the first brand on the market even becomes the generic name for the product class. This need not make entry impossible, however – what matters is that consumers make their purchase decisions accordingly (see example below). Example: Kleenex3 Kimberly-Clark manufactures the dominant brand of facial tissue sold to consumers in the United States, a brand so familiar that it is almost synonymous with facial tissues: Kleenex. Nationally, Kleenex brands have a market share (in 1994 revenues) of approximately 48.5 per cent. Scott, which manufactures Scotties facial tissue, is the third-largest producer of branded facial tissue in the United States, with a market share (in 1994 revenues) of approximately 7 per cent. Only one other manufacturer, Procter & Gamble, sells a significant amount of retail facial tissue in the United States. Kleenex and Scott’s combined sales of facial tissue would be nearly twice those of Procter & Gamble, which holds a market share (measured in 1994 revenues) of approximately 30 per cent. Source: Antitrust case United States of America and State of Texas versus Kimberley-Clark Corporation and Scott Company, www.usdoj. gov/atr/cases/f0400/ 0482.htm 3 It would seem that facial tissues are neither a particularly complex product that Kimberley-Clark has a significant advantage in producing, nor would one expect huge differences in quality. The fact that even a major competitor like Procter & Gamble has not been able to challenge the Kleenex brand would seem evidence that ‘old habits die hard’ – consumers choose Kleenex because it is the first brand that comes to mind. Barriers to exit/sunk costs. Entrants might also speculate that their entry will trigger exit by the incumbent – in fact, most entrepreneurs will probably feel they have something to offer that the market currently does not offer, and if the new product is preferred by most (or all) consumers of the existing product, the incumbent might well go out of business. There 131 MN3119 Strategy are, however, reasons why an incumbent might find it profitable to remain in a market even with an inferior technology. One is a classic option value argument – if the entrant turns out to be less efficient than initially expected or if the market could grow to allow for healthy profits for both firms, an incumbent would not exit even in the expectancy of shortterm losses. The other set of exit barriers originates from the real costs of leaving the market – this could be due to asset write-offs, redundancy payments, contractual penalties for long-term contracts with suppliers, a loss in goodwill from existing consumers who will find it difficult to obtain spare parts, for example, or more generally a loss in credibility of being able to compete effectively in a market. 14.3 Strategic entry barriers Strategic entry barriers typically involve some cost on the part of the incumbent. After all, the definition of a strategic entry barrier is that an incumbent takes an action that would not have been taken without the threat of entry. This of course means that is an entry-deterring action does not involve any cost (i.e. if profits are higher with the action than without), it would be part of the equilibrium set of actions anyway – entry or no entry. A threatened monopolist trying to deter potential entrants by choosing specific actions to deter entry will have lower profits. But bluntly, it is always preferable not to have competition, even potential competition. Strategic entry barriers then describe the class of actions that will decrease profits compared to the pure (unthreatened) monopoly or oligopoly case but have the goal of deterring entry. Entry deterrence is profitable if: a. The incumbent earns higher profits (despite deterring) as monopolist than as duopolist (i.e. post-entry). b. The strategy changes the potential entrants’ expectations about the nature of post-entry competition. The first condition states that entry deterrence must not be destructive or too costly – in other words, letting an entrant into the market would decrease profits even further than trying to keep the entrant out. The second condition states that entry deterrence must be successful in the sense that the entrant believes that post-entry profitability would be lower under normal competition (i.e. without entry deterrence). Figure 14.1 illustrates the trade-off. Block entry if NPV(A) > NPV(B) Profits A (block entry) B (allow entry) Time Figure 14.1: The basic trade-off of early deterence. 132 Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence In the early phase – that is, prior to entry, the monopolist’s profits are lower if she deters entry (dotted line) than if she does not, If this succeeds in keeping a potential entrant out of the market after point t* (which is when the entrant would enter the market, if at all), profits will be higher. This illustrates the basic trade-off very clearly: Sacrificing early profits to make higher profits in the future. This trade-off also allows us to make some educated guesses about the factors that will affect the likelihood of entry deterrence taking place. If t* is far into the future (say, because the technology an entrant would enter with is not yet fully developed), the losses from lowering profits are large relative to the higher profits in the future (remember that to get the Net Present Value (NPV), we have to discount future profits as they are worth less than present profits), which makes entry deterrence less likely. Also, the life cycle of a technology has to be taken into account – is it likely that the technology will be replaced relatively soon? If so, entry deterrence becomes less likely. Finally, we also have to take into account the profit differences – how much lower are the incumbent’s profits if it tries to deter entry, and how much lower would it be if it permitted entry? Activity 14.1 Show analytically in a model that the Net Profit Value of both strategies depends on the discount factor. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Activity 14.2 Taking into account the trade-off outlined above, rank these situations in terms of their likelihood and profitability of entry deterrence. a. Old technology about to be replaced b. Stable product with Bertrand competition and new, more efficient technology c. Unrelated products d. Restaurant with long planning permission process Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. On a conceptual level, this seems sensible – sacrificing some profits to avoid the worst case of someone else entering. What now determines this trade-off in practice and what do firms do to deter entry? Limit/predatory pricing. Sometimes even before entry takes place, prices in an industry drop (limit pricing). Incumbents will try to signal to entrants that entry would not be profitable in a market with such low prices. Failing that, incumbents frequently lower their prices after entry in order to drive competitors out of the market (predatory pricing). Both these strategies certainly fulfil the first condition of profitable predatory pricing – profits are lower with competition than with entry deterrence. The problem lies in the second condition – why would a potential (or actual) entrant believe that this is a long-term sustainable price? It could be argued that once entry takes place, the incumbent has an incentive to raise prices again and share the market. This then makes it a non-credible commitment to lower prices in the first place, as the entrant knows that the incumbent knows that keeping prices low forever is not rational (if this does not trigger the concept of ‘sub-game perfection’, now is a good time to reacquaint yourself with it – see Chapter 4). Limit and predatory pricing are therefore promising ways of deterring entry only if the incumbent can somehow convince the entrant that the new, lower price can be sustained indefinitely, for example, by signalling low cost. 133 MN3119 Strategy Example: Ferries v Eurotunnel For several decades, P&O and Stena Line were a stable duopoly offering cross-channel sailings between Calais (France) and Dover (England). There were, however, persistent rumours that a tunnel was going to be built by an international consortium and with significant support by the two governments. As these rumours gathered momentum and a consortium of interested parties started to emerge, P&O and Stena Line took a number of coordinated actions. First, they replaced their current fleet with new, more fuel-efficient ferries. Second, they lowered prices from approximately £120 to £80 per crossing. Third, they announced that the new and upgraded fleet enabled them to lower prices significantly and permanently. All three actions in conjunction suggested that this was an attempt at limiting pricing designed to keep the Channel Tunnel from being built. Sadly, the attempt was unsuccessful, the tunnel was finally built and opened in 1994, and current prices for a regular crossing hover around the £90 mark. Still, this was an illuminating attempt at creating uncertainty about the cost structure of a firm (or a set of firms in this case) to signal the long-term sustainability of low prices. Capacity expansion. Firms typically choose a capacity level approximately equal to the amount they expect to sell. An optimal choice of capacity will of course also include some allowance for unexpected rapid upturns in demand, for expected future growth and so on. Frequently, however, we witness firms in an industry that carry a surprisingly large amount of overcapacity that cannot be explained by any of these factors. Indeed, overcapacity can also serve as an entry-deterring mechanism. Effectively, a firm will signal to potential entrants that they will face a fierce fight with the incumbent who is in a position to flood the market with output. Why would the entrant believe this? This is a valid question which can best be answered by asking what credibility means in a game-theoretic framework. A strategy in the future, as you will remember from Chapter 2, is only credible if it is a sub-game perfect strategy. In other words, if the firm has no incentive to carry through a threat once its bluff is called, there’s no reason to believe the commitment. In this case (as illustrated in Figure 14.2), the threat of utilising one’s overcapacity comes basically from the act itself. In other words, if a firm did not plan to use its overcapacity on a rival entering the market, it would not have built the capacity in the first place. Of course, if a firm’s cost structure is well known and it is obvious to an entrant that increasing output would clearly be sub-optimal even if overcapacity had been built, the entrant should call the incumbent’s bluff. With sufficient uncertainty about the incumbent’s cost, however, overcapacity will successfully serve as an entry deterrent. Enter Normal capacity [2, 1] E not Enter [4, 0] I Enter Excess capacity [1, -1] E not Enter Figure 14.2: Pre-emption with capacity. 134 [3, 0] Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence As we have stated earlier, this might pose some problems because the threat to utilise the overcapacity might not be credible, or sub-game perfect. One argument would run like this: if I was not planning on carrying out my threat, why would I build it in the first place, so it should be credible once I have built it. Another, slightly cleaner argument would involve using the overcapacity even before entry takes place – in other words, producing more than the optimal (monopoly) quantity serves as an even more credible signal to entrants than simply having the capabilities to overproduce in response to entry. This is where theories of overcapacity and limit pricing converge – prices will be lower in both cases, thus making the market less attractive to entrants and creating a belief that these prices or quantities would be upheld even after entry. Endogenous sunk costs.4 We also mentioned the sunk costs of entry in the section on structural entry barriers. That it reappears here illustrates the dual nature of entry costs. On the one hand, some expenses are inherent in the market – building up a brand, say. On the other hand, how much an entrant would have to spend is also to some extent in the hands of the incumbent. For example, if Kleenex had been the first firm to produce, well, Kleenexes (or paper tissues, to be precise), but had not spent a great deal of advertising, Procter & Gamble (P&G) would have had to spend a certain amount on getting their product known and onto the shelves of the major supermarkets. If, on the other hand, Kleenex had invested greatly in building a national brand with strong recognition, then P&G might not have sold much, even if it had made consumers aware of its product and had successfully placed it on supermarket shelves. The problem clearly is that it is just as important in such a context to establish the new product to established brand, which turns out to be a function of the amount the incumbent has invested in branding. (A similar argument also holds for research and development (R&D) – an incumbent might invest in the latest technology and continually improve its existing products not because it expects huge sales growth, but because this makes it almost impossible for a rival to enter this market and match the incumbent’s product in quality, etc.) Thus, incumbents can keep entrants out by ‘overinvesting’ in a brand or technology compared with the level they would invest if there was no threat of entry. Consumer/asset lock-in. Locking-in consumers or assets is also partly external (i.e. structural) and partly internal (i.e. strategic). The important distinction is the way in which lock-in occurs. In other words, if lock-in is part of an equilibrium strategy with or without the threat of entry, it is likely to be exogenous. On the other hand, if consumers are locked-in long-term contracts by aggressive pricing, lock-in is strategic in nature. For example, Nutrasweet succeeded in staving off the threat of Holland Sweetener’s entry by signing Coca-Cola and Pepsi, the world’s largest buyers of artificial sweeteners, on long-term contracts, leaving Holland Sweetener with the leftovers. Nutrasweet, as a consequence of this strategy, was able to maintain a much higher market share than if it had not locked in Coca-Cola and Pepsi.5 Product proliferation. Finally, the number of products that an incumbent sells in a market is also related to the attractiveness of entry. If consumers are differentiated in their preferences and an incumbent chooses to locate products in product space (by choosing a certain set of characteristics appealing to some, but not all consumers), an entrant will choose to locate its products in ‘holes’ left by the incumbent. If these holes are too small for an entrant to profitably sustain a brand (taking into account the cost of launching a new variety, etc.), entry will be This section is based on the work of John Sutton (Sunk costs and market structure, MIT Press 1991 and Technology and market structure, MIT Press 1998), who shows that some sunk costs are endogenous and can have a significant effect on market structure. 4 Source: Brandenburger, A. and B. Nalebuff, Competition. Harper Collins Publishers, 1996. 5 135 MN3119 Strategy deterred. For methodological and data-related reasons, the market for breakfast cereals has been the leading example for academics for this kind of strategy and it is now commonly accepted that Kellogg’s (as the dominant supplier) produces more varieties than it would as a monopoly in order to make it more difficult for entrants to target market niches left by it. Activity 14.3 Which of the above strategies of entry deterrence (if any) are likely to work best in the following industries? a. Airlines b. Pharmaceuticals c. Office furniture d. Breakfast cereals. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 14.4 Summary Entry by new rivals will almost always have a negative effect on the profitability of incumbent firms. Similarly, the prospect of profits in an industry is typically what attracts entrants into a market in the first place. In this chapter, we have discussed and analysed two types of entry barriers that allow incumbents to maintain market share even if newcomers threaten to enter the market. This can either mean that newcomers enter, but are only able to do so on a smaller scale (so that the incumbent maintains a higher market share) or that the entrant succeeds in keeping all entrants out of the market and remains a monopolist. We distinguished between exogenous, or structural, and endogenous, or strategic, entry barriers – structural barriers are a godsend for incumbents as they do not have to change their behaviour at all and entry is still unattractive. Strategic entry barriers are the ones erected by incumbents, sometimes at a considerable cost to them. The reason they do this is frequently to signal to entrants that entry would not be profitable, or to change the structure of the market or the product that entry indeed would either be very expensive or not very profitable. 14.5 Key concepts 136 • Structural entry barriers • Control of essential resources • Marketing and reputation advantages • Barriers to exit • Strategic entry barriers • Entry deterrence • Limit/predatory pricing • Capacity expansion • Endogenous sunk costs • Consumer/asset lock-in • Cost advantages • Product proliferation. Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence 14.6 A reminder of your learning outcome Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • define structural and strategic entry barriers and compare the two. 14.7 Sample examination questions 1. Entry deterrence. How will fixed (entry) cost affect market outcomes in a symmetric Cournot game and in a quantity-setting game with a Stackelberg leader? Discuss separately the cases in which fixed cost are low and high, respectively. 2. Explain how the likelihood and profitability of entry deterrence depends on the degree of substitutability of your product with the product of the potential entrant. 3. What are the major barriers to entry into the brewing industry and how did the microbrewers get around them? Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. Extended activity: Dubai flowers and internet banking Read the following and answer the questions at the end. Dubai threatens Dutch hegemony in global floriculture industry In 2005 the Dubai government opened the Dubai Flower Centre (DFC) with the goal of becoming a global floriculture logistics hub, and grabbing a significant share of the $4.7 billion global floriculture industry, which involves the growth and distribution of cut flowers. The move threatens the incumbent position of the Dutch whose players have for the past 50 years dominated this industry, and now enjoy a 60 per cent share of the global flower trade. Within Dubai’s own business landscape, the DFC supports the growth of Dubai’s flag-carrier Emirates airline by increasing cargo flows, and the state’s business and political leader Sheik Ahmed bin Saeed Al Maktoum has accordingly invested $70 million in the DFC facilities to date, with further expansion planned. The core driver of this industry is the maintenance of a cost-effective and efficient ‘cool logistics chain’ or refrigerated distribution system of these highly perishable products. From a global market perspective, the DFC enjoys several key competitive advantages. Dubai’s tax-free policies and geographic position allow shippers routing through the DFC to save money and shorten delivery times, particularly in linking the producing nations in the Southern Hemisphere – where for example African flower production is growing at a rate of 20 per cent — to the top importing Asian and Middle Eastern consumers. Indeed, the entry of the DFC into the market could change the current distribution pattern whereby an orchid grown in Sri Lanka and sold in Japan must take the intermediary step of travelling north to Amsterdam to be auctioned, packaged and redistributed. In an article published by The Times of India, the managing director of Karuturi Floritech predicts a radical shake-up of the floriculture export business. He cites the 30 137 MN3119 Strategy per cent transaction cost (including import tax and handling fees) associated with trading through Amsterdam as being the golden ‘arbitrage’ opportunity of DFC, who can potentially bring these costs down to below 10 per cent and thereby attract a big share of the market. The impact of Dubai’s entrance in the market remains to be seen. ‘The DFC insists that it is not seeking to take business from the Netherlands but that it will open new trade routes for perishable goods between Africa and Asia,’ reported the Financial Times, which also quoted the CEO of the Flower Council of Holland as saying, ‘It took the Netherlands half a century to build its horticulture export industry…so I don’t believe that can be copied overnight’. Still, Dutch brokers are already investing in overseas facilities to protect their market share. Internet banking – a conversation with Betsy Z. Cohen Betsy Z. Cohen is the Chairman and Chief Executive Officer of The Bancorp, Inc. (NASDQ: TBBK) and its subsidiary, The Bancorp Bank, which provides internet banking and financial services to small and midsized businesses and their principals nationwide in the US. The Bancorp Inc. has a market capitalisation of $264 million. Since 1997 Mrs Cohen has also served as Chairman and Chief Executive Officer of the real estate investment trust, RAIT Investment Trust. A lawyer by training, she has been a leader in the US banking industry for over 30 years, having founded the Jefferson Bank in Pennsylvania in 1974. In 2005 US Banker magazine named Mrs Cohen one of ‘25 Women to Watch’. What is an internet bank? The internet has evolved, and internet financial products and banking have evolved, over the past five years as banks have grown and understood what the medium is all about. The term ‘internet banking’ is not a unitary kind of description. For most banks, it really refers to a distribution mechanism which is very powerful but which is not an end in itself. Internet banking also refers to banks without branches. It is the positioning of an institution in contra-distinction to the recent 10-year trend in the positioning of bricks-and-mortar banks in the US, in which they are creating branches primarily as collection points for deposits, and in order to reinforce their brand. To some extent the branchless internet banks are taking today a different position – that the banking that gets done on the web is supportive of another business or a link to another business. So if you’re taking e-trade, they’ve put together an online brokerage business and now own a range of financial services all of which are internet-based primarily but which support one another. Some ‘Net’ banks, however, simply went on the web and held out a shingle for retail clients. ING does this. ING uses their internet bank, which is very aggressive in granting higher rates of return on deposits in order to pull the customers in. What they’re using those customers for, though, is as a base with which to sell their profitable products, which are their insurance products. ING is another non-bricks-and-mortar-bank, except that they’ve started internet cafes, which are physical spaces. What does Bancorp do? We chose a different path, in part because I would rather be doing wholesale business, which was to provide private-label banking products 138 Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence for companies that are not banks, but that want to provide banking products to their customers. The only way we could really do that effectively is through a web site. We couldn’t do it by physical branches, because our partners are too spread out across the country. So is this like a department store credit card? It is in the nature of that, yes. Bancorp leverages the customers that our partners have, and, from our perspective and from their perspective, it puts a fence around those customers. We’ve chosen lines of business that are in competition with a bank, and have helped our partners avoid exposing their customers to a banking institution in order to get them banking products. So we’ve chosen asset managers that are not banks and not connected with banks – either non-bank trust companies or companies that just manage your assets without regard to other parts of your financial life. For example, one of our partners is a company called SEI which is traded on the New York Stock Exchange. Part of their business is that they administer about $450 million worth of mutual funds, and they have about $30–35 million worth of pure asset management for wealthy families. What they used to do was say to Mrs Smith who was building a second home, ‘We’ll take your portfolio to Smith Barney or we’ll take you to Wachovia and get you a construction loan or a securities-based loan for this project,’ rather than have her sell her stock. Wachovia and Smith Barney each got a look at Mrs Smith’s financial statement and said, ‘Wouldn’t it be nice if we managed her assets. Mrs Smith, if we managed your assets, you wouldn’t have to come to us separately and have all the heartache, we’d just do it!’ So SEI said, ‘This is not working out.’ But they knew it was a product that they had to offer. So we have set up the SEI financial network for them, which offers deposit accounts and the basic banking products their customers need. They do business by having business referred by 9,000 financial advisers, so the financial adviser says to the customer, SEI can provide that through its financial network, and then it’s done. So we have 150 of those partners in three lines of business. Why did you start an internet bank? What opportunities did you seek to exploit? We saw an opportunity to have a different business model. Instead of holding out our shingle and waiting for retail customers to come in, we looked to find an overarching customer who had a need to provide banking products to their customers, and needed a bank involved, but didn’t want to be a bank. So we would become that bank for them. One of the things regulators are so concerned about is maintaining competitive local markets where there are many smaller players, and not just one big bank monopolising things. Let’s say your cohort of 20 Internet banks grows and becomes the dominant model, wouldn’t that change the way regulators would be able to define and determine local market concentration? Yes, it’s counter to the whole community-based model. We applied for an internet charter based in Delaware. But really since we don’t have any branches and we don’t have any branch restrictions, there is no restriction on where our emails can go. 139 MN3119 Strategy So in effect it’s a national charter? Exactly. That’s why they no longer issue something called an internet charter – it would now have to be a national or international charter – because they realised that their whole banking system was based on community need and this is just something very different. Will internet banks change the structure of the banking industry, and the way that regulators look at the industry? Again, let’s differentiate. There are really only 20 charters like ours out there in the country. And the reason is because regulators realised after a bit – and we are fortunate that it was after rather than before – that what they were granting was a national and indeed an international charter, which is not how the US banking system works. So we can talk about those 20 banks, or we can talk about how internet access as a distribution mechanism will change the way in which people do banking. We are just now at the beginning of being able to see that because we are at the end of this 10-year trend where banks were branding. Let’s talk about the 20 banks. They are a pioneering group, doing something different, no? In fact they are. It is a different business model, but it’s a model that began just as the internet boom was fading and about to become a bust and, except for these 15 or 20 banks, has not expanded since that time. In part it’s because people today are still using the standard banking model, which is the branding model. In part it’s because people believe that successful internet businesses must be like JC Penney, which generates the most traffic on the internet of any URL in the world, and which depends on people being able to go into a JC Penney store, touch something and order it over the internet. That model of dual distribution, where you can touch and see and build trust, and then go on and do transactions over the Internet, they believe is essential. So it’s really this model that they haven’t broken away from. It seems that some face-to-face contact would be important in order to build trust. In fact the reason we chose our particular business model is that we wanted someone to know the customer. So SEI has already vetted their customers. They all have to keep $2.5 million or more in assets to be managed by SEI, so that’s easy. Let’s assume that, as time goes on, the internet as a mode of distribution will become more widely accepted. Do you think that this will diminish the need for branches? As banks find their branches less effective gathering points, they will invest more in beefing up their internet access. It’s a combination of things that will occur. We at Bancorp are one of maybe two or three business models that are really different. I don’t know what’s going to happen. I don’t know whether people will come up with different business models or not. So far, they don’t seem to have done that! Sources Lane Fox, H. ‘From catwalk to conveyor belt Amsterdam is to the flower trade what Paris is to the fashion industry’, The Daily Telegraph (London), 14 February 2004. McSheehy, W. ‘Flower power in Dubai could be a thorn in the side of the Dutch’, The Financial Times, 20 October 2005. 140 Chapter 14: Entry and entry deterrence Saifur, R. ‘Dubai flower centre to build complete cool logistics chain’, Gulf News, 27 September 2004. Sujit, J. ‘Floriculture set to bloom’, The Times of India, 7 December 2003. Questions 1. Mrs Cohen makes reference to a number of different banking business models that employ the internet. Enumerate these examples and explore their relative strengths and weaknesses. 2. What are the barriers to market entry a branchless internet bank faces? Are they different from the barriers faced by a traditional bricks-andmortar bank? How did Bancorp navigate these barriers and develop a successful business model in spite of them? 3. The Bancorp Inc. has found a niche in helping wealth management companies retain their customers. What other avenues for growth could Bancorp pursue? 141 MN3119 Strategy Notes 142 Chapter 15: Research and development competition Chapter 15: Research and development competition Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • discuss various types of innovation • explain the concept of replacement and efficiency effect • assess the impact of market structures on R&D activities. Essential reading Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 16. Further reading Angelmar, R. ‘Market structure and research intensity in high-technologicalopportunity industries’, Journal of Industrial Economics 34(1) 1985, pp.69–79. Cabral, L. ‘R&D competition when firms choose variance’, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 12(1) 2003, pp.139–50. Gilbert, R. and D. Newbery ‘Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly’, American Economic Review 72(3) 1982, pp.514–26. 15.1 Introduction Research and development (R&D) is often heralded as one of the key functions within a firm. Even in industries not traditionally thought of as ‘high-tech industries’, development of new products takes centre stage in the considerations of managers and strategists. In the context of R&D, a number of important strategic questions come up consistently. In particular, how do firms choose the intensity and riskiness of their research activities, and how do R&D activities depend on the nature of the innovation and their position in the technological ‘race’ towards an innovation. Of course, a great many innovations come about through a stroke of luck or serendipity,1 but it would seem sensible to assume that the majority of innovations come about because their inventors actively strove towards this particular innovation. 15.2 Terminology What do we mean when we talk about innovation and R&D? There are several distinctions we should make. Closeness to the end user. The closer to the end user an innovation is, the more ‘applied’ it is. That is, research that is applicable to a wide range of potential uses and requires extensive work and market research to make it palatable to the end consumer, is considered basic research. Applied research is defined as ‘the application of scientific knowledge to the solution of a specific, defined problem.’2 This basically means that research is done with a specific application and potentially even end user in mind. Product development is even closer to the end user: an The now-ubiquitous Post-It notes by 3M were discovered in the process of developing a much stickier glue. Similarly, Viagra was only found to have its well-known effects when it was tested as a medication for heart diseases. 1 Source: http://research. uiowa.edu/dsp/main 2 143 MN3119 Strategy end product exists and consumers have been readily identified and the process of product development is about tailoring the product to the target consumers’ needs. Activity 15.1 Categorise the following activities? a. Second-stage drug testing to fulfil FDA (Food and Drug Administration) requirements. b. A celebrity chef combining lemongrass with different cuts of meat to find out about the interaction of flavours and textures. c. Apple developing a hard disk that would double the capacity of its iPod. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Of course, the stage of research also impacts on the way in which firms do research. The outcomes of basic research are often difficult to protect and are subject to knowledge spillovers between firms. That is, one firm’s results are likely to trickle to its competitors, either through personnel movement or because basic research is published in scientific journals (for everyone to read). This creates a free-rider problem: given that we are bound to benefit from other firms’ basic research efforts, we have an incentive to let others do it (and save the costs of setting up a large R&D lab, hiring scientists, etc.). Since of course other firms will think similarly, we expect that commercial firms do less basic research than we would wish. And indeed, we can see that most basic research is done either by universities, public laboratories or even networks of firms. The latter is an effective way of internalising the externalities (or spillovers) from basic research – if everybody contributes and all firms that would benefit from spillovers join such a research network, participating firms will contribute according to their marginal benefit.3 How does this compare to applied research or product development? First of all, new products and processes can often be protect by patent or copyright. This makes it more feasible to stop others from making use of this innovation, meaning that spillovers will be lower. Copyrights and patents also require that an innovation is distinguishable from ‘prior art’. This implies that if two firms are developing very similar products, whoever comes second might not be granted the patent – this has encouraged scholars to compare the process of looking for a patentable innovation to a ‘race’ – only the first to pass the finish line gets the prize. This opens up a new type of competition: what my rival does matters to me – if Bayer Pharmaceuticals has just announced a significant increase in its research budget, should BASF try and match this increase to stay in the race or is it better to just give up? These and similar questions of strategic interaction are what we will focus on most in this chapter. Product versus process innovation. We can think of innovations as an improvement of the existing product – all (or most) existing or potential buyers experience an increase in their willingness to pay. Graphically, this has the effect of shifting out the demand curve for a particular product. Second, an innovation could also be a novel way of producing an existing product – say, a new production process that makes producing the existing product cheaper. Graphically, this implies a lower marginal cost curve. Of course, in real life most innovations will have elements of both, but let’s keep them separate to keep things simple. For most of our analyses we will use process innovations, but this is purely because it is simpler to draw – our results and conclusions would hold for product innovation as well. 144 3 One could argue, however, that this simply pushes the free-rider problem one step back: what are my incentives to join the network if I would benefit from spillovers even I did not join? Chapter 15: Research and development competition Product vs. process innovation DNEW MC MCNEW D D Figure 15.1. Product versus process innovation. Drastic versus incremental innovation. Most people will have an intuitive idea of what drastic and what incremental innovations are. For example, a drastic innovation is often considered one that changes the business model of the industry (whatever that may mean). Without knowing exactly how to define ‘business model’, however, it is difficult to define a threshold of innovativeness that warrants calling an innovation radical. Most will agree that the compact disc was a radical innovation because it revolutionised the audio market, but was Dolby surround sound? The digital audio tape (DAT)? We will give a more precise definition of radical and gradual innovations. Types of innovation – definition An innovation is drastic if an innovator could behave as a monopolist in the market despite the fact that there are substitute products (without access to the innovation) on the market. Conversely, an innovation is incremental if it increases profits for the innovating firm but its strategy is still restricted by the other non-innovating firms. Let us illustrate this with a process innovation. In Figure 15.2 both innovations lower the marginal cost of the innovator somewhat. It is relatively easy to see that the innovation to the left is more radical on the right since marginal cost goes down more significantly. But how will an innovator behave in each of these markets? • Product vs. process innovations • Drastic vs. gradual/incremental innovation p M (i) p M (d) p c = MC OLD MC NEW(i) MC NEW(d) MR D MR D Figure 15.2: Types of innovation. 145 MN3119 Strategy In fact, an innovator in the left panel (i.e. lowering his marginal cost to MCNEW(d)) can price as if he were alone in the market – his monopoly price pM(d) is lower than any price one of the other firms (who still produce at MCOLD) would want to set. On the other hand, if an innovation lowers marginal costs to MCNEW(i) as in the left panel, monopoly pricing would mean that the innovator is pricing himself out of the market – pM(i) is higher than the lowest price his rivals will want to go – MCOLD. Activity 15.2 Given the above definition of radical and incremental innovations, would you still agree that the CD was a radical innovation? What test would you apply to establish if it was or was not? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. So armed with the definitions given above, we will now try to establish some predictions about the effect of market structure and a firm’s relative position on the intensity and character (i.e. the riskiness of a research strategy) of innovation. 15.3 Innovation and market structure In which markets will firms innovate most? On the one hand, firms in competitive markets could be said to have strong incentives to innovate: after all, they are not making huge profits from their existing operations and have every incentive to innovate and differentiate themselves from their competitors. However, firms that have a strong position in their industry will claim that their dominant (or even monopolistic) position is under threat and that they innovate because they have to. Of course, which side of the argument you believe will depend on where you stand – Microsoft’s lawyers will point out that Microsoft’s R&D/sales ratio is well above the industry average and that their dominance stems from their superior ability to come up with innovations that consumers want. In contract, entrepreneurs will stress their role as an ‘engine of innovation’4 and point out that they should be receiving tax breaks, subsidies and other help for their service to society. So which argument is right? Are they both correct? Let’s look at the static efficiency of different market structures for help: any economics textbook will tell you that the most efficient market structure (if there are no notable economies of scale) is a perfectly competitive market: prices will be at marginal cost, and every consumer who is willing to buy above that marginal cost will be served. Monopoly power only introduces deadweight losses. However, consider investing in R&D knowing that the market will remain competitive after the innovation: how much would you invest in such an innovation? Nothing, since you are not expecting any profits from innovating. Scholars therefore agree now that in order to promote innovation, there needs to be some degree of monopoly power (as a carrot), but a sufficient threat of entry (as a stick). This notion is represented in the patent system, where a patent is ‘a set of exclusive rights granted by a government to an inventor or applicant for a limited amount of time’, thus granting the rights to extract the benefits from an innovation, but only for a limited period of time and a restricted range of application so that other innovative firms can ‘invent around’ the patent or freely use the technology after the patent runs out or is not renewed.5 Let us now analyse this conundrum in detail by looking at a very simple situation: a process innovation would lower a firm’s marginal cost from c 146 Kate Barker, Confederation of British Industry. 4 5 A patent holder must choose to renew a patent periodically at a small cost. If a firm decides that the potential profits of keeping the patent are not worth the cost, it goes into the public domain and can be used by other firms (who might have a better idea of what to do with the innovation). Chapter 15: Research and development competition to c. Looking at different market structures, what is a firm’s willingness to pay for this innovation? We first look at a competitive market with no patent protection. Lowering marginal cost is good for consumers, but since the innovating firm would not get any profits from developing the innovation, its willingness to pay is zero (Figure 15.3). • Competitive firm, non-appropriable innovation c ∆ CS c Figure 15.3: Who benefits most from R&D? What if a competitive firm can protect its innovation? Assuming (as we do in the graph) that it is an incremental innovation, they will set a price of (just below) c and make profits of DP. • Competitive firm, proprietary innovation c âˆ†Π c Figure 15.4: Who benefits most from R&D? What incentive will a monopolist have? To start with, profits from innovating are higher if you are guaranteed a monopoly position afterwards – for an incremental innovation, not being limited by any competitors (even less efficient ones) is always preferable. On the other hand, a monopolist also makes significant profits in the first place, that is, before innovating. Figure 15.5 illustrates this. • Monopolist replacement effect p0 p1 Π1 Π1 c c Figure 15.5: Who benefits most from R&D? 147 MN3119 Strategy So if we wanted to compare the incentives to innovate of a competitive firm and a monopolist, we have to take into account two things: profits with the innovation and profits without it – the difference between the two being the incentive, or willingness to pay, to innovate. This might seem trivial, but we will show in the following numerical example that it matters. Example Let us look at the incentives to innovate for a firm in a competitive industry and a monopolist. Suppose that the demand function is P = 5 – Q in both markets, and that marginal cost without the innovation is MC(old) = 3 and MC(new) = 2 after the innovation. The following calculations show that the incentives for a monopolist to innovate are lower than for a competitive firm. (Make sure you know how we derived these numbers!) Comp Industry: P(old) = 3,Q(old) = 2,P(old) = 0 P(new) = 3 – e,Q(new) = 2,P(new) = 2 Monopoly: P(old) = 4,Q(old) = 1,P(old) = 1 P(new) = 3.5,Q(new) = 1.5,P(new) = 2.25 From the example above we can see that a monopolist is less inclined to invest in an innovation because he is replacing old profits with new ones. A monopolist’s lower incentive to innovate because of the higher level of preinnovation profits is summarised in the replacement effect. Replacement effect – definition For a given market structure, a monopolist has less incentive to innovate because of the higher level of pre-innovation profits. So does this mean that monopolists always invest less in R&D? Not necessarily. After all, most of the significant R&D in pharmaceuticals is done by large firms, Microsoft is still considered a pretty innovative company, and firms like IBM, AT&T, Nokia and others are constantly at the top of the pile of patent applications and other measures of innovative activity. Why do they do it, given the replacement effect? They innovate ‘because they have to’ for fear of losing their dominant position. Consider now the following simple scenario: a monopolist and a potential entrant are competing for an innovation that would lower the marginal cost from c0 to c1. It is an ‘innovation race’ in the sense that whoever spends more on the innovation gets the innovation – for example, by being granted a patent or by being first on the market. Again, we are looking for the willingness to pay for the innovation – the belief that whoever is willing to spend more will end up getting it. Post-innovation there are two possible scenarios: either the monopolist gets the innovation and remains a monopolist (but with higher profits because the new product is more efficient) or the market becomes an asymmetric duopoly with the entrant taking more than half of profits because he is using the better technology. Starting from the initial situation, what are the two players willing to invest? The entrant makes zero profits if he does not innovate and would get Pd(c1,c0) if he innovates, which is therefore his willingness to pay. The monopolist defends his monopoly position and gets Pm(c1) if he innovates and gets the smaller share of duopoly profits Pd(c0,c1) – the difference between the two is the monopolist’s willingness to pay. If we want to find out who invests more in innovation, we need to compare the two: 148 Chapter 15: Research and development competition Pm(c1) – Pd(c0,c1) > Pd(c1,c0) is the condition for the monopolist to invest more. Is this the case? Rearranging the inequality gives Pm(c1) > Pd(c1,c0) + Pd(c0,c1) – which is given since monopoly profits are always higher than the sum of duopoly profits! Therefore we can say that if a monopolist knows that he would lose his monopoly position unless he gets the innovation, he will invest more in R&D than the entrant. This has been termed the efficiency effect. Efficiency effect – definition Under the threat of entry, a monopolist has higher incentives to innovate than a potential entrant into the market. Example We will use our standard demand function again, this time allowing for two firms in the market, a monopolist (M) and an entrant (E): P = 5 – Q, where Q = qM + qE. Marginal cost before the innovation is MC(old) = 3, new marginal cost will be MC(new) = 2. A monopolist will make profits of 1 before the innovation. If he innovates, profits increase to 9/4 – the potential entrant’s profits are zero. What happens if the entrant innovates? We have an asymmetric duopoly with the monopolist facing marginal cost of MC(old) = 3, and the entrant MC(new) = 2. This results in quantities of qM = 1/3 and qE = 4/3. Profits will be pM = 1/9 and pE = 16/9. Note that the sum of duopoly profits are pM + pE = 17/9 < 9/4 – competition erodes profits. The monopolist will therefore be willing to pay 9/4 – 1/9 = 77/36 for the innovation, while the entrant only bids 16/9 = 64/36. The monopolist’s willingness to pay is therefore higher because he wants to protect his monopoly position, while the entrant would only be a duopolist. We have looked at two simple, but reasonable models that gave us two very different results: the first one says that a monopolist will invest less in R&D, the second one says he will invest more. We will now extend our models to find one that generates both outcomes. Consider now a situation in which a monopolist does not know for sure if there is a firm trying to enter the industry. If research is secret, for example, or if it is not clear if another firm has the capabilities to develop a technology of sufficient quality, this seems realistic. It seems reasonable, however, to assume that the monopolist has at least some idea if there is a potential rival for an innovation – suppose he thinks that there is a probability r that there is a rival. This changes the situation to that shown in Figure 15.6. •• Model with uncertainty r = probability that rival is doing R&D in this area (‘bids fo the innovation) •• WTP fpr entrant: Πd(c1,c0) •• WTP fpr monopolist: Πm(c1) – (rΠd(c1,c0) + (1 –r)Πm(c0)) Πm(c0) > Πd(c0,c1), so dWTP/dr > 0 → High r: efficiency effect > replacement effect; Low r: vice versa Figure 15.6: Market structure and R&D. 149 MN3119 Strategy We have now integrated both situations: if there is hardly any threat of entry (i.e. low r), the replacement effect will be more important and a monopolist has less incentive to innovate. If the threat is relatively high (high r), the efficiency effect will dominate and the monopolist will have to innovate to stay ahead of the (as yet non-existent) competition. So far we have only looked at incremental innovations – what about drastic ones? If there is at least some chance that there is no rival innovator, a monopolist will have a lower willingness to pay to innovate than an entrant. •• Previous model, but drastic innovation: Pm(c1) for whoever gets the innovation, 0 for the loser •• WTP fpr entrant: Pm(c1) WTP fpr monopolist: Pm(c1) – (1 –r)Pm(c0) → Monopolist is less ‘keen’ on drastic innovations than the entrant, so in real life: •• Incremental innovations: incumbents; •• Drastic innovations: entrants. Figure 15.7: Market structure and R&D Activity 15.3 We use our standard set-up again: Q = 5 – P, MC(old) = 3, MC(new) = 2. Suppose that firms compete in prices and produce identical goods. There is a probability r that an entrant will be actively competing for this innovation. Show that: a. The willingness to pay for an entrant is WTPE = 2 b. The willingness to pay for a monopolist is increasing in r c. WTPM > WTPE for r > 3/4. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Combining all this now suggests that a monopolist may be more innovative in some situations where the threat of entry is quite high and the innovations are incremental, but that an entrant is more likely to implement drastic innovations and (if he is capable of innovating) if the perceived threat of entry is low and the innovation is incremental. Activity 15.4 Interpret the following quote in light of the theories about innovation incentives. Background: Xerox has an early monopoly in the plain paper copies market, but saw its patents run out at some stage. Existing consumers were to some extent locked-in due to service contracts with Xerox, and Xerox had a strong brand name in plain paper copying (people still talk of ‘Xeroxing’ papers to this day!). ‘The transition period saw a great deal of innovation activity from entrants and Xerox... In the monopoly period, Xerox was a highly innovative firm. But the innovations were characterised by being ‘in the copier.’...The innovations by entrants include some of a very different character, those oriented toward the “user interface”...document feed devices, two-sided copying, whole new product markets like the “convenience copier”.’6 Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 150 Bresnahan, T. ‘Postentry competition in the plain paper copier market’, American Economic Review 75 1985, pp.15–19. 6 Chapter 15: Research and development competition 15.4 Strategic issues in R&D The previous model was less strategic in the sense that one player’s behaviour depended on the other player’s actions – we simply derived the willingness to pay for entrants and monopolists. In this section, we will address some of the questions that might arise if multiple firms can select certain aspects of their R&D strategy: the decision to be active in a particular field and the riskiness of an R&D strategy. Throughout this section, we will assume that players are risk-neutral, that is, they only care about expected profits. Let us first look at the question to be active in a particular application field. Consider two firms who have to decide whether to engage in R&D at a fixed cost K. If they engage in R&D, they have a likelihood of r to come up with a successful (marketable) innovation. The profitability of a successful innovation depends on the competition: an innovation that is alone on the market generates profits of pm, an innovation with a competitor in the market generates profits of pd. From this we get the expected profits P for different strategy combinations (Make sure you know how to derive these expected profits!). Firm A does R&D, B does not: P(R,N) = rpm + (1 – r)0 – K (and vice versa) Both firms engage in R&D: P(R,R) = r(1 – r)pm + r2pd + (1 – r)0 – K Firm A does not do R&D: P(N,R) = P(N,N) = 0 You should note that P(R,N) > P(R,R) – it is better to do R&D on your own than with a rival competing for the same market (obvious really, but you should be able to show it using the profit functions). Putting this in a pay-off matrix, we get Figure 15.8. Figure 15.8: A patent race. Let us now derive the Nash equilibrium/–a for different values of r, the likelihood of innovation. We fix the other parameters to the following values: K = 2, pm = 8, pd = 2 What if the likelihood of innovating is very low, say 10 per cent? Generally, we would expect that innovation is not very profitable (because we have to pay the fixed cost anyway, and the likelihood of having an innovation to 151 MN3119 Strategy show for it is quite low) and firms are less inclined to innovate. This also shows in our pay-off matrix, since pay-offs for (R,N) are –1.2 and pay-offs for (R,R) are –1.26. Both are negative, which means that it is better not to do any R&D at all, even if my rival does not do R&D either. Similarly, if the likelihood is very high, say 90 per cent, we would expect both firms to engage in R&D – the Nash equilibrium is (R,R). For intermediate values of r, the situation becomes a little more complicated: If the likelihood of success is r > 25 per cent, not doing R&D is not a dominant strategy anymore. On the other hand, if it is r < 33 per cent, doing R&D is not a dominant strategy. Putting in a number between 25 and 33 per cent will show that there are two Nash equilibria – (R,N) and (N,R): if my rival is not developing, I will develop, but if my rival is developing, I will choose not to develop. Therefore, we now have a pretty good idea of what will happen to R&D activity in relation to the likelihood of success. Low-probability projects with high fixed costs will probably not be undertaken, medium probability projects will be undertaken by whichever firm commits to the project first (and thus pre-empting the others), or whenever two firms compete in a medium-probability field, losses are likely (say both firms play a mixed strategy and end up being active in the same field). High-probability projects will be undertaken by many firms at once, which may turn out to destroy parts of the profits to be made from the innovation in the first place (it is likely that high-r projects will have two innovations and thus competition in the product market, which of course is less profitable than monopoly). Activity 15.5 Using the pay-off functions and the pay-off matrix above, show what happens to the equilibria as the following changes: a. Market size increases by 10 per cent b. Fixed cost decreases by 50 per cent c. Competition becomes more fierce, lowering duopoly profits by 50 per cent Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Now, frequently firms do not decide only if they want to be active in R&D, but also how much risk to take. Taking risk typically comes with a tradeoff: on the one hand, there is a likelihood that I will come up with a better innovation (or innovate faster) if I am successful, but on the other hand, there is a lower probability of being successful in the first place. A stylised situation might look like this: Consider two competing firms having to choose between a safe and a risky strategy. The safe strategy generates an innovation with certainty, the risky one is successful with a probability of x per cent (< 100 per cent). Safe and risky innovations both compete for a patent of value 1, and the risky strategy is faster so that if successful, a risky strategy gets awarded the patent. If both firms innovate at the same time, they have a 50 per cent chance of being awarded the patent. 152 Chapter 15: Research and development competition Figure 15.9: Risk taking in R&D. The pay-off matrix shown in Figure 15.9 gives expected pay-offs for each combination of strategies. Again, we can see that the equilibrium strategies depend on the value of x. In particular, if x is high (>58 per cent), we find that taking risks is a dominant strategy. From a societal standpoint, this may not be the best outcome since there is now a risk of not seeing any innovation as both players try and outpace the other, which includes a risk of not having any successful innovation at all. Consider two competing firms having to choose between a safe and a risky strategy. The safe strategy generates an innovation with x per cent likelihood, the risky one is successful with a probability of y per cent (y < x). The willingness to pay by consumers for a safe innovation is A, and B (B > A) for a risky innovation. If two innovations are of the same quality, they compete against each other on prices (marginal cost is zero). If they are of different quality, the higher-quality firm will be able to charge a price equal to the quality differential A – B (why?). Activity 15.6 Draw a pay-off matrix with the general parameters. For which parameter values will the equilibrium be (R,R)? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. One of the potential outcomes of an R&D race with firms choosing risky strategies is that some firms turn out to be successful and some not. This means that at any one point in time firms will be differently placed in their position in the R&D race. Cabral’s (2003) paper on dynamic R&D competition illustrates under which circumstances firms will choose the risky or safe R&D strategies. We present a very simplified version here. Suppose there are two firms competing for a pharmaceutical innovation. The innovation process can be divided up into four steps, from finding the compound to having it tested by the FDA (Food and Drug Administration). Similar to our previous example, all that matters is getting to the finish line (i.e. coming up with a patentable innovation) first, and if both players arrive simultaneously, they both have a 50 per cent chance of succeeding. One firm has already made some progress and is at stage 2 of the process, while the other is at stage 1. Both have two strategies in each period: Safe R&D will ensure progressing one step further with 100 per cent probability, Risky R&D would propel the firm’s research two steps ahead, but only with 50 per cent probability. Note that no one strategy is inherently ‘better’ – they both have the same expected progress per period. To keep things simple, suppose that the race only has two more periods of play (this is actually not important and the game will end after two 153 MN3119 Strategy periods anyway, but assuming it from the beginning makes things easier to illustrate). A player’s strategy for the entire game now consists of an action in period 1 and an action in period 2, so there are four options for each player: Safe in 1 and Risky in 2 (sr), Risky in 1 and 2 (rr) and so on. This leaves us with the rather daunting-looking pay-off matrix below.7 Figure 15.10: Risk taking in R&D. This matrix looks relatively complicated to solve mechanically, that is, by checking every single cell for a Nash equilibrium. In fact iterated elimination of dominated strategies comes in extremely helpful here – first we will be able to solve the game more quickly and second we will discover some of the intuition behind the firms’ incentives to take R&D risks. Below is an intuitive account of which strategies we can rule out, but you should make sure that you are comfortable with the mechanics of the process as well: • Follower playing (safe, safe): we can immediately rule this out because F will never reach the finishing line with this strategy. • Follower playing (risky, risky): if the first-period gamble was successful, F is one step away from the finish. All that matters is getting there, not getting further than the finishing line. Taking a risk in the second stage is taking an unnecessary risk. • Leader playing (safe, risky): same argument as the previous one – one step away from the finishing line so you don’t want to take any more risks. • Leader playing (risky, safe): if L was successful in the first period, the game is over. If L gambled and failed, taking a safe step would mean that L never gets to stage 4. By eliminating these strategies, we obtain a much simpler matrix (Figure 15.11). 154 The probabilities of winning are derived from the probabilities of successful R&D and getting there first and winning or getting there simultaneously and winning with 50 per cent likelihood. If you feel you need some practice on combinatorial statistics, try retracing these probabilities. 7 Chapter 15: Research and development competition Figure 15.11: Risk taking in R&D. In fact, from inspecting this simplified matrix, we can even see that (risky, risky) is dominated for L, meaning that L’s dominant strategy is to play it safe in both periods, while F will have to try and catch up at some point by taking a risk. This carries an important implication: A firm lagging behind in an innovation race will choose riskier research strategies than a leader. Of course, this may also lead to an outcome where the lagging firm fails to catch up, ends up taking higher and higher risks and finally falls behind too far and gives up – leading to monopolised high-tech markets. Therefore, it could be argued that even though some high-tech firms do not even have potential rivals (which, as we have seen in the earlier part of this chapter, can generate an incentive to engage in R&D), they are only in this position because they have beaten a number of rivals in the R&D stage and are now reaping their reward for their superior research performance. 15.5 Some further thoughts on R&D Sleeping patents. Another strategy that firms often use is creating a thicket of ‘sleeping patents’. These are patents that are relatively minor and that the firm has no intention of ever commercialising. Why would firms do that? After all, patents are preceded by R&D efforts and have to go through an administrative procedure, lawyers are involved and so on. It turns out the incentive is strategic: by patenting an innovation sufficiently ‘close’ to one’s main product, a firm is foreclosing would-be competitors from inventing a close rival to one’s own product. In fact, Xerox has been found guilty of this practice and was subsequently forced to license its sleeping patents to competitors because this practice was found to be hindering technological progress in the copier market. It is not surprising, however, that most firms will try and create a blanket of patents around their main product, which means that again new entrants would be more likely to come up with drastic innovations simply because they are not protected by the incumbent’s intellectual property. R&D spillovers. Spillovers can originate from several sources: employees move from one firm to the other,8 knowledge becomes public because insiders divulge their knowledge, either legally (through academic publications for example) or illegally (through industrial espionage), or firms reverse engineer each others’ products, meaning that they can at least retrace some of the steps that went into an innovation. Formally, spillovers are often expressed as follows: (R&D) = f(X1, bX2), P1 8 Microsoft has hired a large number of Nintendo developers to write games for its nextgeneration Xbox. Part of the motive may be to gain some knowledge of the development process at Nintendo. where b = strength of spillovers and X = R&D effort. 155 MN3119 Strategy That is, the benefits from doing R&D depend partly on your own R&D effort (X1), but also on your rivals’ efforts (X2). Since spillovers are rarely complete (in that everything you learn will be available to others), we use a parameter b to capture the spillover effect – high b means high spillovers and R&D is an almost public good, low b means that knowledge generated stays more or less in-house and is a private good. Studies have shown that typically this parameter is in the order of xx, meaning that 1 hour of someone else’s research time is as productive to your firm as xx minutes of your own time (and you don’t pay for it!). R&D cooperation. Antitrust authorities have often been more lenient about allowing collaboration by rivals in research and development than in product market competition. Why is that? Implicitly, it is recognising the existence and detrimental effect of spillovers: if spillovers are high, we are facing a free-rider problem (as mentioned early on in the chapter). Letting firms cooperate at this stage means that overall more R&D may be done, which is generally considered a good thing. On the other hand, if spillovers are very low, R&D competition may be mutually destructive since double (or even more than double) the resources are spent if two firms compete for the same innovation. Letting firms cooperate may be a way of reducing this duplication of R&D efforts. Of course, one of the challenges is to make sure that firms that collaborate in the R&D stage do not collude in the product market stage. 15.6 Key concepts • Basic research • Applied research • Product versus process innovation • Drastic versus incremental innovation • Replacement effect • Efficiency effect • R&D risk choice • Patenting • Sleeping patents • Spillovers. • Cooperation 15.7 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: 156 • discuss various types of innovation • explain the concept of replacement and efficiency effect • assess the impact of market structures on R&D activities. Chapter 15: Research and development competition 15.8 Sample examination questions 1. It has been said that internal and external R&D are complements, that is, firms are better off doing both simultaneously. Why? 2. The wide-body aircraft industry was a triopoly for a while and eventually evolved into a monopoly (see graph). 100 B747 DC10 L1011 Market share (%) 80 60 40 20 0 65 70 75 Year 80 85 90 Figure 1: Market share development in the wide-body aircraft market. Show and discuss how the willingness to pay for an innovation (i.e. the incentives to innovate) changed through the earlier to later stages in the industry’s evolution. 3. Since the 1990s, the market has developed into a duopoly between Airbus and Boeing and innovation opportunities in the classical wide-body market have been limited. Consequently, Boeing started developing the ‘Sonic Cruiser’, a 250-seater plane that could fly close to the speed of light, and Airbus launched the ‘Superjumbo’, a 550+-seater. Demand for both innovations was uncertain and development costs high, and it was assumed that the two planes would cover different market segments. Using the two stylised representations on the supersonic and highcapacity market below, outline the conditions on development costs under which it was sensible (i.e. an equilibrium strategy) for both firms to locate in different market segments. Figure 2: Normal form representation of ‘Supersonic’ and ‘Superjumbo’ market 157 MN3119 Strategy 4. If a firm believes that it is the only player in a technological field, it may engage in basic R&D in this particular field. On the other hand, if there are many players, R&D tends to be much more applied. Why? 5. It is often said that Microsoft’s operating systems are not truly innovative because they don’t push the boundaries of the state-ofthe art in operating systems. ‘Real’ innovation is likely to come in the shape of other operating systems (e.g. Linux). Outline potential reasons for this. Guidance on answering these Sample examination questions can be found on the VLE. Extended activity: discovering DNA Read the following and answer the questions at the end. The race for the prize – a case study on the discovery of the structure of DNA. The moment that James Watson and Francis Crick walked into the Eagle, their local pub in 1953 and declared that they had ‘discovered the secret of life’, they indelibly etched their names in the history books of science and medicine. Their discovery of the structure of DNA has been widely hailed as the most important scientific discovery of the last 50 years. Indeed as time passes and more discoveries grow out of their original findings, it may simply become one of the greatest discoveries of all time. Background DNA (deoxyribonucleic acid) is a large molecule with the complete set of instructions for making all the proteins a cell needs. DNA consists of two spiralling strands of millions of chemical building blocks or base pairs. DNA is the genetic blueprint that determines such features as body height and skin colour and allows the transmission of genetic information from one generation to the next. What is so well known now, that DNA carries the genetic matter of our forefathers and in fact the secret of how human beings develop from conception, was shrouded in mystery for centuries. Many theories were expounded – one theory was that sperm from the male of the species contained tiny humans that grew into babies in the womb. Another theory suggested that the blood of the mother contained the features of the child and this gave the child the nature that it eventually would have. Many other such theories abounded and as bizarre as these may sound, they were common currency in days past. And it should not be assumed that these were archaic ideas – the realisation that DNA was indeed the bearer of life, only came about in the 1940s and 50s. The people involved Linus Pauling was the most eminent chemist of his generation. He was rightly nominated for the Nobel Prize in chemistry.1 This gave him enormous clout around the world and in his own institution, CalTech where he had significant lab resources at his disposal. Pauling was also known for his intensity and drive when he had a problem he wanted to solve, and would work rapidly and efficiently towards the solution. All this coupled with his encyclopaedic knowledge of chemistry and solid grounding in physics gave him the aura of the man to beat. It was widely perceived that if Pauling was interested in DNA, then he would be the first to unravel its structure. 158 1 Pauling did go on to win the Nobel Prize in Chemistry in 1954. Indeed he also won the prize for Peace in 1962 making him the only person to win two unshared Nobel Prizes. Chapter 15: Research and development competition Perhaps the greatest weakness that Linus Pauling possessed stemmed also from his great strength, his intellect. It was generally acknowledged that Pauling possessed a restlessness which meant that he was only ever content when working on a dozen or so projects simultaneously. He would always have trouble focusing all his attention on just one project. Rosalind Franklin and Maurice Wilkins were researchers at King’s College, London. Rosalind Franklin was an elite researcher and her arrival was considered to be of great value to the research being done at King’s. Maurice Wilkins was highly respected in his field of X-ray diffusion. X-ray diffusion was particularly vital in the search for the DNA structure as it would give the basic shapes and connections that would reveal the underlying structure. In addition, Wilkins was known to be a methodical and rigorous researcher, vital skills that would be required to slowly tease out the mysteries of DNA. In many ways, the team of Franklin and Wilkins were best equipped for the race; their talents and skills were perfect for the task they had set themselves. Unfortunately, Wilkins and Franklin never truly gelled as a team. Franklin especially was seen as a lone worker and although appreciated the skills of her compatriot, she did not trust him enough. This inevitably meant that she would never truly harness his significant talents and abilities and indeed support. Among the many ways in which James Watson and Francis Crick were different from the other researchers in their field, was the stark fact that neither of them were particularly qualified or well versed in the chemistry and physics that would be required for the task they had ahead of them. For much of his time, Watson was bored with his academic work and did not distinguish himself in any particular way. It is with much irony that one of the two people who uncovered the structure of DNA has written, ‘I was principally interested in birds…and managed to avoid taking any chemistry or physics courses which looked of even medium difficulty. Briefly the Indiana biochemists encouraged me to learn organic chemistry, but after I used a Bunsen burner to warm up some benzene,2 I was relieved from further true chemistry. It was safer to turn out an uneducated PhD than to risk another explosion’. Crick had been born in Northampton halfway through the First World War. He had won a scholarship to a small public school and went on to University College London. He also found the courses at university irrelevant and narrow, graduating with a second class degree. However, his maverick mind and his determination to do serious academic work in any subject led on to a PhD working on the design of an apparatus for the study of water viscosity. For the non-chemists, benzene being highly flammable is not generally ‘warmed up’ and especially not with the naked flame of a Bunsen burner. 2 Both Watson and Crick have been called mavericks and perhaps this more than any other factor was the root cause of their success. There was irreverence in their manner, of a refusal to realise that the odds were well and firmly stacked against them. They were both hungry for a problem to solve that they felt worthy of their attention. The decoding of DNA provided a worthy opponent. There was an additional factor that was crucial to their success. Although from very different backgrounds and of very different manner, Watson and Crick hit it off immediately. In a telling excerpt from Crick’s biography, he recounts his first meeting with Watson in the Cavendish Laboratories: ‘Jim and I hit it off immediately, partly because our interests were astonishingly similar and partly I suspect, because a certain youthful arrogance, a ruthlessness, and an impatience with sloppy thinking came naturally to both of us.’ 159 MN3119 Strategy Setting the scene In the early 1950s, James Watson was something of a wanderer. He had tried his hand at various disciplines ranging from bacteriology to zoology to ornithology, the study of birds. He had spent time in academic institutions in the US, Copenhagen and Naples, but had found little satisfaction or enjoyment in his work. In Naples however, he found himself in a lecture by the British biophysicist Maurice Wilkins.3 Maurice Wilkins was describing a procedure to use X-ray diffraction on a substance called DNA. Watson had been pondering the question of how genetic information might pass from generation to generation and how these mechanisms worked. He had not progressed with this thinking, unsure whether it was indeed DNA that carried this information and whether the structure of DNA was simply too complex to decipher. Wilkins’ talk dispelled those doubts because of his confidence in DNA being the conduit of genetic information and the regularity of the patterns that his X-ray diffractions were showing. Within weeks of the lecture, Watson had secured a position with which to follow his new interests. He had managed to find himself a position at the Cavendish Laboratory in Cambridge under the inventor of the X-ray diffraction technique, Sir Lawrence Bragg, then the leading authority on the subject. 3 Who would become on half of the WilkinsFranklin team at King’s College. Bragg instinctively knew to pair Watson up with Crick. Crick’s brilliance was well known, as was his brashness and unwillingness to suffer lesser minds gladly and he would often rub his more old-fashioned English colleagues the wrong way. Not for him were the formality and fustiness that characterised the Cambridge of the 1950s. Bragg’s judgment in this matter was perfect, putting together the impatient Englishman with the confident and extrovert American. Had it not been for Bragg’s insight into the personalities of both men, it is likely that Watson would have passed through Cambridge in the same way as he had his previous institutions, without vigour or any substantial result to speak of. Crick’s path to the question of how information was passed through the generations, was a similarly unusual one. When the Second World War ended, he was preparing to return to his original PhD4 when he became captivated by a book then recently published. What is life? was written by the physicist Edwin Schrödinger, and it approached biology from the perspective of quantum mechanics. Schrödinger was suggesting that the mysteries of genetics might be resolved by applying the laws of quantum theory and building a picture based upon atomic physics and the design of molecular structures. Crick was hooked on the idea and the potential it offered. It is often the case that great discoverers have a ‘Road to Damascus’ experience that illuminates their thoughts and in so doing energises and propels them to the solution of the problem. For Watson, it seems to have been the lecture by Maurice Wilkins and for Crick, Schrödinger’s book. Max Perutz, for whom Crick originally worked when joining the Cavendish Laboratories, recalled that Crick and Watson were clearly exceptionally brilliant and when they first met they were bursting with ideas and energy, although between them they knew almost nothing of the subject they wanted to master. More clearly remembered, however, was Watson’s overwhelming desire for fame and fortune – to win the Nobel Prize. Crick was always hungry for the root answer to the problem and this was his motivation. Crick would often say after they had solved the problem, that Watson never had any doubts about his ability and was preoccupied 160 4 Crick’s original PhD topic, on the design of an apparatus for the study of water viscosity, highlights with startling clarity the giant leap between disciplines that he eventually made. Chapter 15: Research and development competition neither with the means nor the method he used to find the answer, but was principally concerned with finding the answer ‘as quickly as possible’ in order to gain recognition and fame. That James Watson and Francis Crick were unique is without doubt, more so their methods. They conducted very few if any real experiments, instead using ideas from a variety of seemingly disparate disciplines to build an intellectual edifice from the work of others. They would eagerly borrow ideas and carefully make links from various experiments that had been conducted and slowly but surely piece together a picture of what DNA would look like. Being unencumbered by any one discipline or school of science, they took freely from all comers. Watson and Crick had a sort of manifesto of how they would solve the problem first. As Watson would say, their strategy was to imitate the acknowledged and respected leader of the race and then beat him at his own game. Watson and Crick put their efforts into keeping up with the feverish pace of the great chemist himself – Linus Pauling. Events unfolding There were some key requirements in the race towards the structure of DNA. One of them was most obviously the skills and knowledge of various fields of science required to even know what to look for. The second became more important as the work went on – an X-ray picture of DNA would enable any researcher to start to have an insight into the DNA molecule. Finally a model, either physical or mathematical, would be the proof that the structure proposed was indeed coherent and plausible. Any of the teams would realistically need all three to claim victory. Initial situation Linus Pauling started working on DNA at the same time as Watson and Crick. The news of this would have generally defeated most young scientists – Watson and Crick, however, were aware of the fact that if they were to be beaten, it would be unlikely that they would lose any face, indeed, most people would not even know that they had taken on the great Linus Pauling. Additionally they were aware that the field was relatively closed due to the very high investment required to get into it – who was prepared to learn genetics, chemistry, physics, biochemistry and X-ray diffusion? As Wilkins and Franklin were clearly qualified for the task, Watson and Crick were definitely in the worst position for the project. Pauling also had a very poor quality X-ray diffraction picture of DNA which was produced five years earlier. Crick, however, had obtained through his old friend Maurice Wilkins, the latest superior images from Wilkins’ lab at King’s College. This gave Watson and Crick a strong advantage against the more skilled Pauling, however, their position relative to Franklin and Wilkins was unclear. Unexpected help In October 1951, Crick invited Wilkins to visit Cambridge. In the small confines of his flat, Crick, Watson, Wilkins and his wife discussed the progress that Wilkins had made, especially with regard to the improved images of DNA that Wilkins had managed to take. Eventually, Wilkins was to become morose and share that the state of his working relationship with Franklin had deteriorated to such an extent that she was not even sharing her results with him. Instead she would spend long periods locked away in 161 MN3119 Strategy her lab using the newer images that Wilkins had made, in isolation from everyone else. This conversation led to some important insights for Watson and Crick. One was obviously that the King’s pair were not cooperating and this would naturally slow them down. Second, that Franklin was still a long way from a solution. Also they realised that Wilkins was willing to assist them in their quest largely due to his poor relationship with Franklin. Perhaps most importantly they learnt that Franklin would be delivering a seminar which would sum up her year’s worth of research in the coming month. Watson remembered the seminar as being a very dry affair. Franklin talked through various numbers of the different types of chemical groups likely to be in DNA, clues about the potential location of various molecules within DNA and even the shape of the structure. There was a serious problem though, much of the information was wasted as Watson, who never took notes, found he had trouble remembering the finer details of what Franklin had shared, indeed making some crucial mistakes in his recall. For Crick it was very frustrating but they nonetheless began to construct a model of what they thought DNA might look like. Setbacks After a week of slaving away they produced a structure constructed around a central structure of three helices. This was essentially a guess – Franklin in her seminar had suggested somewhere between two and four helices. As soon as they had completed the model, they invited Wilkins to come up and view it – they were surprised when he agreed and indeed that Franklin was also planning to join him. ‘Where are the water molecules?’ the sarcasm in Franklin’s voice was undisguised as she observed the model. Crick pointed them out only to be told that there were nowhere near enough water molecules in their model for it to be viable. With typical steeliness Franklin described her visit to Cambridge as ‘a waste of time’ and in doing so effectively humiliated and embarrassed Watson and Crick. Watson’s failure to make notes in the earlier seminar had cost them dearly. Far worse, however, was the umbrage that Franklin took to the fact that Watson and Crick had attempted to build a model on the back of her research. She duly complained to Lawrence Bragg, the supervisor of the Cavendish Institute. The embarrassment of such an accusation caused Bragg to give both Watson and Crick a severe dressing down. He then forbade them from carrying out any more research on the topic.5 Bragg additionally insisted they hand over their models to the King’s pair and that they stop any further work they may otherwise have done. This was a severe blow to Watson and Crick, perhaps the most significant in their quest. Frustrated and angry, they had no option but to accept Bragg’s demands. The closeknit community at Cavendish meant that it would be impossible to carry on their work modelling DNA without it getting back to Bragg. The setback meant that it became impossible for them to go about obviously working on DNA but they soon realised that they could keep building mental models and talking to each other in private about their progress. Indeed, they even continued borrowing from colleagues and asking questions, albeit in a much more subtle and understated way. In their usual watering hole, the Eagle, their questions were couched in a language that implied that they were working on non-DNA related projects but were always in fact directed towards that goal. 162 This episode highlights what was then a peculiarly British research attitude. Bragg and his peers in powerful positions still cherished the notion of gentlemanly behaviour and did not believe that it was ethical for more than one team to work on a given problem, even when the parties were rival organisations. 5 Chapter 15: Research and development competition That year, 1951, for all their mental efforts, was generally a bleak one and progress was agonisingly slow. Fortunate turn of events In this period, known only to her research assistant, Rosalind Franklin was making great strides forward. Early in 1952, Franklin had obtained the clearest pictures of DNA that had ever been seen. Above all else it began to confirm for the first time that DNA was helical in shape. Picture 51 To the trained eye, ‘Picture 51’, with its broad dark X crossing the centre of the image indicated that the structure of DNA was indeed helical. This was a crucial step forward for Franklin and put her in the best position to progress. Franklin told no one of her results, not even Wilkins. In fact she even went so far as to ridicule his beliefs of helical-shaped DNA by making a public announcement that she had found proof that it was not helical – even though she held the only proof that it was indeed helical. Wilkins was livid and especially after he realised that the announcement had been founded on a lie. Wilkins had been surreptitiously duplicating Franklin’s work and had the same stunning images to prove that DNA was indeed a helix. Spring 1952 came round but brought nothing to lighten the mood at Cambridge. Watson and Crick had not made progress and had not heard anymore of Linus Pauling’s progress. They feared the great man’s powers and were expecting a surprise paper that would shatter their hopes. Throughout this time that had assumed that the work at King’s was also not progressing. Their worst fears were confirmed when Pauling was due to visit the UK to attend a meeting of the Royal Society. They thought that it would be inevitable that he would then meet up with the researchers at King’s, see the X-ray pictures and thereby remove the slender lead they felt they held over him. Convinced the battle would soon be over their spirits sunk to new lows. On the eve of Pauling’s visit they heard shocking news. Pauling’s passport had been withdrawn by US officials fearing that he was too threatening to the capitalist cause and even a potential defector to the Russian side. He had the indignity of being forced to return to California, potentially as a Russian defector. This news was greeted with outrage by the British scientific community. For Watson and Crick, however, it was taken as an omen and they found themselves even more determined to crack the DNA problem. Their efforts over the summer of 1952 quickly bore fruit, in stark contrast with the previous winter. One evening in the Eagle, Crick was to make one of the great breakthroughs in the race. In discussion with John Griffith, a mathematics postgraduate who was applying mathematics to biochemical problems, he told Crick that there was only one consistent arrangement for bases that was plausible for DNA to be bonded together. The proposed structure with the bases in that arrangement meant that two strands of DNA could carry enormous amounts of information. In a moment of dazzling insight, Crick realised that because of the way the bases bonded, the two helices of DNA could unzip, carry the code and pass on instructions during reproduction. The secret of life. It was a giant leap forward. 163 MN3119 Strategy Pauling’s solution In December of 1952, Watson and Pauling were informed through a letter to Pauling’s son who was at Cambridge that he had outlined what he thought to be a promising structure for DNA. No details were given beyond to say that he hoped to publish early in the New Year. In February 1953, the draft paper arrived on their desks. It was a moment of intense despair and apprehension at learning that all was soon to be lost. It was with trepidation that they began to read. They were staggered. The most accomplished mind in chemistry had proposed a structure that Watson and Crick knew to be impossible. He had proposed a triple helix along with many other elementary errors. The structure was too tightly packed, the chemical groups would not fit into the space they had been allotted, the bonding structure was completely wrong. Above all, the structure had nothing to say about how genetic matter passed between generations. It was a stunning revelation that the Pauling that they had so feared had got it so wrong. Watson later declared, ‘The appropriate emotion was pleasure that a giant had forgotten elementary chemistry.’ This emotion quickly gave way to fear. They realised that once Pauling realised his mistake (and perhaps he already had), the humiliation would spur him into a burst of activity that would inevitably culminate in the correct structure. They believed that Pauling could have the structure within weeks. Final burst Flying in the face of Bragg’s authority, Watson made another visit to King’s. He was going to attempt to persuade Wilkins to part with more information, possibly even new X-ray diffraction images. Perhaps as a reflection of the deteriorating relationship between them Wilkins handed over the images that Franklin had made some six months earlier, crucially including a replica of Picture 51. ‘The instant I saw the picture my mouth fell open and my pulse began to race’, Watson recalled. This picture allowed them to leapfrog ahead of the other two teams, giving them a slender but significant lead. For Watson and Crick that data was everything they could have hoped for. It told them that DNA was definitely helical but it also gave them crucial information about the form of the helix and could allow them to calculate the way the chains of the helix were arranged and how far apart the turns of the helix would be. They both realised that this was the vital clue to the structure. Combined with their ideas, it would allow them to elucidate the structure. They had a problem – time was not in their favour and working in a clandestine manner as they had been would slow them up considerably. They decided to come clean and tell Bragg what they were up to. Feeling extremely pessimistic, they came to the interview expecting a stern dressing down. To their astonishment, their boss’s attitude was starkly different from before. Having learnt that Pauling was so clearly in the race, ethical codes and the need for gentlemanly conduct vaporised. Bragg and Pauling were old rivals. Pauling had previously succeeded in overtaking Bragg in the determination of the alpha-helix for proteins, showing up Bragg’s efforts with an elegant and convincing structure and clearly 164 Chapter 15: Research and development competition exerting his superiority. Now facing the spectre of Pauling gaining the greatest biochemical prize in history, his sense of ethics was ditched. Bragg’s approval was absolute. Not only did he give Watson and Crick moral support, he provided them with the full resources of the Cavendish Lab, including the workshop to fashion model parts for them and X-ray diffraction equipment along with technical support. During this period Franklin had decided to leave King’s and was serving out her final weeks. This did not matter to her as she was planning to continue to work on elucidating the structure wherever she went. However, it did mean that her work with Wilkins came to a total stop during this period as her leaving was largely due to the frictions between them. She hence had no inkling that Wilkins had passed on to Crick and Watson the crucial information from her experiments. It is now known from looking at the notebook she kept over that period that she had decided that the double helix was indeed the correct structure and was working on the mathematical analysis to establish a clear proof of the double helix backbone. Watson and Crick were at this stage racing ahead. They had constructed a model of the basic double spiral but were still struggling to position the bases of the molecule in a chemically consistent way. In a casual conversation with Jerry Donahue, a colleague in the chemistry department who specialised in organic bases, Watson described the problems he and Crick were having. Donahue immediately spotted their problem – they had been using the structure of bases that were accepted as standard in chemistry textbooks but had recently been shown to be unlikely to occur in nature. Donahue proposed the structure of the bases that recent research had shown to be naturally occurring. This made all the difference to Watson and Crick as this now allowed the structure to fit together and the bonds to be of the right length within the backbone structure of the helix. Franklin had mathematically and independently come to the same conclusions. Certain crucial aspects still eluded her – however, it is almost certain that in due course she would have cracked these also. Her notes of that period certainly pointed in that direction. Time, however, was something neither she nor Pauling were to have. A few days after discovering the correct bases, the final pieces of the puzzle were falling into place for Watson and Crick. They had a logically consistent theoretical model in which the four bases were fitted into the interior of the helices and bonded correctly together. They then ordered the parts from the workshop and began building their model. A week later on 7 March, their model was completed. Conclusion On an overcast spring morning Linus Pauling is chauffeured to the Cavendish Laboratories. He is met by Sir Lawrence Bragg. Pauling is on his way to the Solvay Conference in Brussels and had been asked to make a detour to inspect the model that Watson and Crick have constructed. For Watson and Crick this is the definitive test along the road to acceptance of their work. All the researchers at the Cavendish Labs, Rosalind Franklin and Maurice Wilkins have inspected the structure and conceded that it was indeed the representation of DNA. Pauling paced the floor in front of the model, peering closely at all its details. It was not pretty to look at by any means. But it consistently and 165 MN3119 Strategy logically showed the bonds between chemicals and displayed how the complex code of the living beings was held between its helices. Perhaps more than any other, Pauling appreciated this. A few days later at the Solvay conference, Linus Pauling beaten to the most important finding of twentieth-century biology, but magnanimous in defeat, announced to the gathering: ‘I think that the formation of the structure by Crick and Watson may turn out to be the greatest development in the field of molecular genetics in recent years’. It was a prescient comment, and an understatement. Wilkins and Franklin were also magnanimous in defeat and asked only that they were allowed also to publish their contribution to the elucidation of the structure when Watson and Crick published theirs. The 25th April 1953 issue of Nature, contained not one but three pieces that announced the elucidation of DNA – one by Wilkins, one by Franklin and the seminal piece by Watson and Crick. Epilogue An extract of the speech by Professor A. Engström, member of the Staff of Professors of the Royal Caroline Institute when awarding the Noble Prize for Physiology or Medicine in 1962 read as follows. ‘Your discovery of the molecular structure of the deoxyribonucleic acid, the substance carrying the heredity, is of utmost importance for our understanding of one of the most vital biological processes. Practically all the scientific disciplines in the life sciences have felt the great impact of your discovery. The formulation of double helical structure of the deoxyribonucleic acid with the specific pairing of the organic bases, opens the most spectacular possibilities for the unravelling of the details of the control and transfer of genetic information.’ An achievement by any standards, but especially for two wanderers. The Nobel award for Physiology or Medicine that year was awarded to Francis Crick, James Watson and Maurice Wilkins, acknowledging the work all three had done. Rosalind Franklin was omitted necessarily as the Nobel Committee does not make posthumous awards. All three scientists continued to work within the field. Rosalind Franklin died in 1958, at the age of 37, through ovarian cancer. It is thought likely that the cancer was brought on in part due to the excessive exposure she had to X-rays in the name of her research – research that was ultimately crucial in finding the structure of DNA. Source Cheryan, D. under the supervision of Dr T. Kretschmer ‘The race for the prize – a case study on the discovery of the structure of DNA’, LSE. Questions 1. The discovery of DNA had the character of an R&D race. Using concepts of R&D efficiency, R&D costs (including opportunity cost) and the riskiness of R&D, introduce the three players (or teams) and their chances of success. 2. Of all the three players, Linus Pauling seemed best equipped to win the race if he set his mind to it. How do you think the other two teams changed their strategies in response to Pauling? Why? Explain using a game-theoretical framework. 166 Chapter 15: Research and development competition 3. Pick one episode from the case where a new discovery was made/ the situation changed significantly/etc. Describe the players’ initial situation and justify how the players reacted to the new situation and the expected responses to the other players. 167 MN3119 Strategy Notes 168 Chapter 16: Technology adoption Chapter 16: Technology adoption Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • describe technology adoption by building game-theoretic models • discriminate between and explain different models of technology diffusion. Essential reading Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 14. Further reading Bryson, A., R. Gomez and T. Kretschmer (2005) ‘Catching a wave: the adoption of voice and high-commitment workplace practices in Britain’, 1984–98. CEP Discussion Paper DP 0676. http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/abstract.asp?index=2154 Fudenberg, D. and J. Tirole ‘Preemption and rent equalization in the adoption of new technology’, Review of Economic Studies 52(3) 1985, pp.383–402. Geroski, P. ‘Models of technology diffusion’, Research Policy 29(4–5) 2000, pp.603–25. Griliches, Z ‘Hybrid corn: an exploration in the economics of technological change’, Econometrica 1957. Reprinted in Griliches, Z. (ed.) Technology, education, and productivity. (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988), pp.27–52. 16.1 Introduction Firms change their technologies all the time – an old one becomes obsolete, a new one is introduced into the market, an existing production process is inadequate for an improved product and so on. In this chapter we will highlight some specific features of new technologies and the effects they have on the adoption process. 16.2 Adoption dependence Benefits from the adoption of new technologies will often depend on previous and future adoption decisions of other users. For example, as more users adopt, information about the technology increases – there are users’ reports, information gets out by word of mouth, and the simple fact that plenty of others are using it may say something about the quality of the technology. Also, a technology may get objectively better or cheaper as more people have adopted it – the learning curve discussed in Chapter 7, or user feedback may make adopting a technology that has been tried and tested by others more attractive. Network effects are also an important feature of many new technologies – adopting a technology with a large network of users is more attractive because there are more people to share, say, software with. We will discuss this in the next chapter. All these phenomena suggest that it is more beneficial to adopt a new technology late, but counteracting this are first-mover advantages that might originate from brand building, occupying crucial market space and so on. First-mover advantages will make it more attractive for users to get in early rather than wait. 169 MN3119 Strategy For the analysis of technology it is important to distinguish between individual and aggregate adoption dependence.1 As mentioned above, the benefits from adoption often depend on other users’ decisions. However, for practical purposes it is important to estimate whether one user’s decision is going to make a large or a small impact on one’s own utility. If the impact is large, game-theoretic analysis is likely to be useful – after all, we want to accurately predict what other adopters will do if their decision may dramatically change our pay-offs. On the other hand, if small changes in the number of other users do not change pay-offs significantly, game-theoretic analysis would be ‘analytical overkill’. After all, trying to predict one player’s adoption decision would not make a big difference so understanding the overall outcome and hence, does not make sense. Situations like these are best analysed using diffusion studies, which we will introduce in the second part of this chapter. 16.3 Strategic technology adoption – option value Consider the following situation: a new technology has just been introduced, and there are two firms considering adoption. The technology can either be ‘Good’ or ‘Bad’ in the sense that their NPV net of adoption cost is positive or negative. Both firms do not know if the technology is ‘Good’ or ‘Bad’, but if one of the firms adopts, the quality of the technology becomes known to both players. The game has two periods, and both firms can adopt in period 1, adopt in period 2 or not adopt at all. Waiting, that is, adoption in period 2, is discounted by d < 1, the discount factor. Let us split our analysis in two parts. First, we assume that the technology is expected to have a negative NPV. That is, the weighted (by their probability of occurring) average of ‘Good’ and ‘Bad’ is negative. By backward induction, we can then conclude that if no player has adopted in period 1, neither of the players will adopt in period 2. After all, the technology is expected to yield negative pay-offs. Pay-offs then for delaying adoption if both delay are (0,0). If firm 1 adopts in period 1, its expected benefit will be P < 0. If firm 2 adopts in 1 and the technology turns out to be successful, firm 1 will adopt in 2 at a pay-off of dpG. On the other hand, if early adoption reveals a bad technology, firm 1 will not adopt and obtain 0. This information can be combined to give the pay-off matrix illustrated in Figure 16.1. Figure 16.1: Technology adoption I. 170 1 You might wonder how network effects and adoption dependence are related. We will discuss network effects in more detail in the next chapter, but basically adoption dependence can originate from network effects as well as learning, information transmission and so on. Chapter 16: Technology adoption Activity 16.1 Show that the Nash equilibrium to the game above is (D, D). Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. The outcome of the game is that a new technology is not even tried out, even though there is a likelihood of (p) that it is successful and gives a positive NPV. Since on average, however, the technology is not profitable, one might argue that ‘no adoption’ is not such a bad outcome. We now analyse a game where the expected value of a technology is positive, i.e. P > 0. This could be either because the likelihood of a technology being ‘Good’ is very high (p ≈ 1), or because the benefit from a ‘Good’ technology is considerably higher than the risk of an unsuccessful one (G > B). The first result we can note is that if no adoption has taken place in period 1, firms 1 and 2 would still adopt the technology in period 2, although they still do not know the technology’s quality and they have delayed adoption. The pay-offs from late adoption under uncertainty are then dP, and the rest of the game remains the same. Figure 16.2: Technology adoption II. The outcome of this game depends crucially on the value of the discount factor. Suppose that the discount factor is close to 1, so that the cost of waiting is very slow. It would seem intuitive that firms will wait and adopt late in the hope that the other player might adopt early. On the other hand, if d is very low, waiting is very costly, and a firm might be willing to take the risk of adopting early to avoid the loss of waiting. The following analysis shows that the dominant strategy for low d is to adopt early and consequently the unique Nash equilibrium is (E,E), and that there are two Nash equilibria (D,E) and (E,D) if d is high. If δpG < pG + (1 − p )B  dominant strategy to adopt early   (1 − p ) B  i.e. δ < δ = 1 −   ï£ p G If δΠ < Π δ > δ , pG > pG + (1 − p )B → NE = (D, E ), (E , D ) The analysis illustrates that there is a cut-off value of the discount factor which determines the choice of strategy. We can see that for low values of d, our intuition of early adoption is correct. On the other hand, for high values of d, even though it is not very costly, there is still an incentive 171 MN3119 Strategy to adopt early, which leaves two Nash equilibria (and possible mixed strategies to solve the game). The option value of waiting until more becomes known about a technology may introduce a number of inefficiencies – either a technology is not even tried out if the perceived risk of a failure is too high (as in the first game we analysed), or adoption takes place late or firms play a waiting game in the hope that the other firm will adopt and reveal information (as in the second game when d is relatively high) Activity 16.2 Consider the situation analysed above. How would the game and its equilibria change in the following situations? a. A new technology following the one currently on the market has been announced and will represent an improvement of D over the current one. b. Adopters are not homogeneous. A firm can be either a high-valuation adopter with valuations G, B, or a low-valuation adopter with valutions g, b. The following parameter restrictions apply: G > g > 0 > B > b. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 16.4 Technology diffusion models As mentioned above, if there is a larger number of adopters of a technology, game-theoretic analysis becomes increasingly difficult and increasingly less useful. There are two alternative approaches to dealing with such situations. Either, the population of potential adopters is divided into consumer groups that are assumed to act more or less the same, which then brings back the possibility of game-theoretic analysis. On the other hand, sometimes it makes more sense to look at aggregate adoption figures, that is, the diffusion of a technology. The first approach borrows heavily from the marketing and market research literature to identify the different consumer groups. We will focus on the second approach and introduce three different models of technology diffusion.2 First, however, we document one of the most robust findings in the economics literature – the s-curve of technological diffusion. Starting with Griliches’ (1957) study on hybrid corn, numerous scholars have identified s-shaped diffusion patterns in the economy (if they are successful at all – the other regular ‘pattern’ is a technology not getting any meaningful level of market penetration). New technologies such as mobile phones and the compact disc have followed a similar pattern. Other ‘technologies’, such as high-performance workplace practices (Bryson, Gomez and Kretschmer, 2005) follow a similar adoption path. The sheer regularity of this pattern throws up two important questions. First, if a new technology is good enough to eventually be adopted by a large number of users, why is adoption not instant? In other words, why wait if it is a good technology? The second puzzle is that these technologies are seemingly very different, and the fact they all display the same diffusion behaviour suggests that they have some common characteristic that drives the diffusion process. 172 2 These models are summarised in more detail in Geroski (2000). Hybrid corn Chapter 16: Technology adoption 100 Per cent 80 Iowa 60 Wisconsin Kentucky Texas Alabama 40 20 10 0 1932 ‘34 ‘36 ‘38 1940 ‘42 ‘44 ‘46 ‘48 1950 ‘52 ‘54 ‘56 Years Figure 16.3: Hybrid corn. Mobile phones in France as a % 70 60 60 62 55 47 50 40 30 24 20 10 11 5 0 Jan 1998 Jan 1997 Jan 1999 June 2000 June 2001 CD players in the UK July 2002 June 2003 Figure 16.4: Mobile phones in France. 97 19 95 19 93 19 91 19 89 19 87 19 85 19 19 19 83 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 81 % of population CD Diffusion UK Figure 16.5: CD players in the UK. As it turns out, there are four dominant models of technology diffusion – the heterogeneity (or probit) approach, the epidemic approach, the population approach model and the network effect approach. We will deal with network effects in the next chapter and introduce the other three now. 173 MN3119 Strategy 16.4.1 Heterogeneous adopters The first approach is based on the notion that adopters are heterogeneous in their propensity to adopt a new technology. If we are dealing with a large number of adopters, it is likely that the distribution of tastes will have one peak in the middle3 – most users will be neither complete enthusiasts for a new technology, nor complete opponents of it, but will be somewhere in between. If a technology now develops over time, either by becoming better or cheaper with time, early adoptions will be made by the enthusiasts, because everybody else will not find it worthwhile to adopt yet. As we have said, enthusiasts are typically few and far between. As it gets more attractive to adopt, more people will, and eventually the mass market – a large ‘spike’ – will adopt. Mass market adoption implies that diffusion speed is much faster than in the early stages. After the mass market has adopted, all that is left are the small numbers of steadfast nonadopters. As the technology becomes even cheaper and more attractive, or the existing technology goes increasingly outmodel) of date, even those unwilling Heterogeneous Adopters ( Probit users will eventually adopt, but at a slow rate, which explains the final adoption slowdown before market saturation see (Figure 16.6). Figure 16.6: Heterogeneous Adopters (Probit model). So far, we simply assume that adopters are heterogeneous in their propensity to adopt. What could be factors that determine the likelihood of adoption? 174 • The size of a firm can have an important effect on the propensity to adopt. For example, if there is a fixed cost of adopting a technology that reduces output costs, it will be more useful (and therefore adopted earlier) by firms who are producing high quantities already and therefore stand to save significantly from a cost-reducing technology. • The indirect adoption cost may differ by firm. Indirect adoption costs include the switching cost from an existing technology, cost of learning to use the new technology or even search cost of identifying the best new technology. • A firm’s absorptive capacity is the ability to cope with new organisational realities and situations. It is plausible to assume that ‘smarter’ firms are more likely to adopt a new technology as the adjustment period will be shorter and less costly. • Use of complementary technologies is another important determinant of a firm’s incentives to adopt a new technology. For example, a firm with an up-to-date computer system is likely to benefit more from a new piece of software than a firm with an outdated system. Conversely, This is called a unimodal distribution. 3 Chapter 16: Technology adoption if a firm is using other software applications that are complementary to the existing generation of software, it will be less inclined to switch to the new generation. These are just a selection of factors that will determine firms’ incentives to adopt. For every technology, it is important to identify the main drivers of adoption and to be able to rank firms according to it. Activity 16.3 What do you think are the main drivers of adopter heterogeneity for the following technologies? a. High-commitment workplace practices (for firms)4 b. Mobile telephony (for end consumers) c. Computer aided design (CAD) (for architecture studios) d. Airbag (for car manufacturers). Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 16.4.2 Epidemic model High-commitment workplace practices cover HR practices like job enrichment, job rotation, incentive pay, internal promotion, etc. - effectively creating a workplace in which employees can learn and improve continuously and are rewarded for good performance. 4 Knowledge about new technologies is often said to spread by ‘word of mouth’. Can this generate an s-curve of diffusion? To simplify things, suppose that everybody who hears about a new technology will adopt it.5 Everybody who has adopted the technology talks about it to a (randomly selected) fraction a of the population. Of this fraction, some will have heard about the new technology already and some will not.6 5 Geroski (2000) also discussed a model in which knowledge does not immediately imply adoption, but it does not make a huge difference in terms of the intuition. This again generates an s-curve: In the early stages, there are very few people who know about the new technology and ‘spread the word’. This implies that only a small number of new users can be recruited in each period. Once the number of existing adopters is higher, ‘word of mouth’ really starts to work – diffusion is very fast. This will only work, however, as long as there are still enough ‘non-users’ in the population. If everybody knows about the technology, it is increasingly likely that users will talk to other users, thus slowing down diffusion. 6 The reason why this model is called the ‘epidemic model’ is that diseases spread in very much the same way throughout populations - infected people come into contact with infected and uninfected people and spread the disease to the uninfected. Activity 16.4 There are N = 1001 potential users in a population and currently one of them is using the internet. He talks to 10 people per day and tells them about the internet. Everybody who hears about it adopts it immediately and talks to 10 people about it. How long will it take for the internet to reach a market penetration of 25 per cent? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 16.4.3 Population ecology model The final model we discuss is that of population ecology. The difference to the previous two is that the population ecology model is based on two competing effects, the legitimisation and the competition effects. Consider a technology that can potentially confer a competitive advantage over non-users. In the early stages of the technology, there is considerable uncertainty about its quality and potential adopters are reluctant to take the risk, so that adoption is slow. As more adopters start using the new technology, non-users grow more confident about the technology and become more likely to use it as well – the technology becomes legitimised. However, as more users adopt it, the competitive advantage that can be derived from it shrinks since everybody is now using it.7 This 7 It may help to think of the new technology as a new market of uncertain size - as more adopters go into the new market, it becomes more competitive and the potential profits decrease. 175 MN3119 Strategy is called competition effect, since competition in the new technology decreases the profitability of the technology and consequently slows down adoption. Again, and not surprisingly, we find that this generates an s-curve, as at first the legitimisation effect causes diffusion to speed after a slow start, while the competition effect slows down diffusion of a fully legitimised technology. Technology diffusion does not come in all shapes and sizes – in fact, the only shape it seems to come in is an S. This does not necessarily mean, however, that all new technologies follow the same diffusion process. We have introduced three approaches to technology diffusion that all generate such a pattern, but are based on very different premises. In the assessment of real-life diffusion processes, it is important to judge which of these processes is most important in the particular case, and what implications can and should be drawn from this in terms of the levers to accelerate diffusion. Activity 16.5 The following technologies have elements of different diffusion models. Discuss the relative importance of the models for each case and outline the diffusion process for each of them. a. E-commerce b. Hybrid corn c. The internet d. Renewable energy sources. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 16.5 Key concepts • Adoption dependence • Individual and aggregate adoption dependence • S-curve • Diffusion models • Heterogeneous adaptors • Epidemic model • Population ecology model 16.6 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • describe technology adoption by building game-theoretic models • discriminate between and explain different models of technology diffusion. 16.7 Sample examination questions 1. The Zip disk drive was never particularly successful, even though it was undoubtedly superior to the then industry standard, the 3.5 inch disk. Using an option value model, how do you think the likelihood that rewriteable CDs would come out relatively soon after the Zip disk affected the Zip disk’s success? 176 Chapter 16: Technology adoption 2. Can the three models of technology also be used to explain unsuccessful technologies? How would you explain a failed technology using the heterogeneity approach, the epidemic approach and the population ecology approach? 3. How would you try and distinguish between the three models of diffusion if you were confronted with a real-life diffusion process? 4. Below are graphs of the diffusion of CD players and CDs (note that the timeframe for CD sales is larger than CD player sales). It seems that while CD player sales have been slowing down in the late 1980s, CD sales growth shows no signs of subsiding. What could be reasons for that? Millions of CD players 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 Figure 16.7.1: CD player sales, 1984–1990. 140 Millions of CDs 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 Figure 16.7.2: CD sales, 1993–1994. Guidance on answering these sample examination questions can be found in the VLE. Extended activity: the adoption of Botox Read the following and answer the questions at the end. Technology Adoption: Botox Population Ecology The United Nation’s demographic projections show that, in the more developed countries, populations across the board are proportionally ageing, with an average of 32 per cent of the population aged over 60 in 2050 versus 20 per cent today. Allergan, Inc. is a $2.2B global healthcare company that plans to profit from this inescapable trend. Among its lines of business in the pharmaceutical and biotechnology industries, the company specialises in aesthetic-related pharmaceuticals and over-the-counter products competing in the anti-ageing sector of the cosmetics market. In the US alone, the demand for R&D based ‘cosmeceutical’ products is expected to increase 11 per cent per year, the market reaching $7 billion in 2008. 177 MN3119 Strategy Based in California, Allergan was arguably optimally positioned for the launch of cosmetic applications of its star product Botox, a treatment based on injections of a purified form of the toxin botulinum, which blocks nerve impulses to muscles. The notion of routinely absorbing a neurotoxin might raise some common sense misgivings, and clinical studies are based only on short-term data and so cannot rule out the possibility of long-term detrimental health effects. At upwards of $300 a session every three to four months, the treatment isn’t cheap. Still, from a market perspective, the technology has been a success story to date. Everybody’s doing it: the treatment is now practically de rigueur among the Hollywood set, where physical beauty rivals talent and personal contacts as the ultimate currency; and from Kansas to Korea, women as young as 30 appear to be following suit. Botox was approved for cosmetic use in the US in 2002, although considerable off-label use for the treatment of facial wrinkles occurred before that time, driving sales to $300 million by 2001. By 2003, total Botox sales reached over $500 million, of which 40 per cent was attributable to its cosmetic application. In 2004, it was cited as becoming America’s fastest growing cosmetics procedure. In 2005 international sales for all applications (medical and cosmetic) of Botox reached more than $800 million. By 2008 analysts predict sales from the cosmetic applications alone to reach $650 million. The patented technology is now Allergan’s main growth driver, delivering a near monopoly in the world market for the unique toxin. The company has recently announced a deal with Glaxo to develop and promote Botox in China and Japan. While Botox sales will continue to grow, the chart below shows how the rate of growth in the numbers of people adopting this new technology has peaked. A 2004 lawsuit brought unsuccessfully against Allergan by Irena Medavoy, the wife of a Hollywood executive, shined a spotlight onto the safety issues raised by the use of Botox. It also brought to light the fact that Allergan has paid Arnold W. Klein, a top celebrity dermatologist, nearly half a million US$ to promote the drug. One year after Botox’s market release, Klein proudly claimed to have personally injected the product into 90,000 patients. Does Botox have the final word in the quest for eternal youth? Vogue magazine has already likened the ‘frozen’ Botox face to frosted hair and too-tight facelifts as examples of commonplace beauty fixes gone awry. Some market analysts predict the rapid acceleration of the market for dermal fillers such as the Swedish Restalyne, which lasts longer and appears to have fewer health risks. Distributors in this segment are already nudging along market acceptance through clever marketing and loyalty schemes that reward customers handsomely for adopting this new technology as part of their beauty regimen. Physician-advocates and marketers of both Botox and Restalyne seem to have consensus in the view that Botox is best for treatment of the upper face, while Restalyne is best for the lower – a convenient supposition that creates two markets from one face. Sources ‘Allergan, Inc. thinking ahead in Botox Glaxo Development Deal’, JP Morgan North America Equity Research, 3 October 2005. ‘Botox getting bigger’, Global Cosmetic Industry, Allured Publishing Corp. 173(6) 2005. ‘Cosmetic dermatology, beyond Botox – the expanding market for dermal fillers’, Deutsche Bank, 27 September 2004. 178 Chapter 16: Technology adoption Gellene, D. ‘“Mr Botox” case raises some brows’, Los Angeles Times 22 August 2004. Gentry, C. ‘Injection for perfection’, Tampa Tribune 3 October 2005. White, J. ‘Fill in the bl’, The Kansas City Star 16 May 2004. Question Interpret the diffusion of Botox as a population ecology case. Calculate a diffusion curve given the data below, assuming a starting point of 787,000 patients receiving Botox in the year 2000. Year YoY growth rate in number of patients receiving Botox 2000E 2001E 9% 2002E 31% 2003E 157% 2004E 27% 2005E 22% 2006E 18% 2007E 13% 2008E 10% Figure 1: Historic and projected growth in numbers of patients receiving Botox from plastic surgeons. 179 MN3119 Strategy Notes 180 Chapter 17: Network effects Chapter 17: Network effects Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • define network effects and network market structures • explain technology diffusion patterns using network theory • discuss the four generic strategies firms can pursue in network markets as described by Shapiro and Varian (1999). Essential reading Cabral, L.M.B. Introduction to Industrial Organization. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000) Chapter 17. Further reading David, P. ‘Clio and the economics of QWERTY’ in The American Economic Review 75(2) 1985, pp.332–37. Farrell, J. and G. Saloner ‘Standardization, compatibility, and innovation’, Rand Journal of Economics 16(1) 1985, pp.70–83. Katz, M and C. Shapiro ‘Systems competition and network effects’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(2) 1994, pp.93–115. Koski, H and T. Kretschmer ‘Survey on competing in network industries: firm strategies, market outcomes and policy implications’, Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 4(1) 2004, pp.5–31. Ohashi, H. ‘The role of network effects in the USVCR market, 1978–86’, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 12(4) 2003, pp.447–94. Postrel, S. ‘Competing networks and proprietary standards: the case of quadraphonic sound’, Journal of Industrial Economics 39(2) 1990, pp.169–85. Saloner, G., A. Shepard and J. Podolny Strategic Management. (New Jersey: Wiley, 2006) Chapter 12. Shapiro, C. and H. Varian Information rules. (Cambridge, MA: HBS Press, 1999) Chapter 7. 17.1 Introduction In earlier chapters, we referred to network effect quite a few times. This chapter will go into more detail and look at some of the aspects specific to markets with strong network effects. To start with, however, we need to define network effect in general, and distinguish between two different types, direct and indirect network effects.1 Network effects – definition A product is said to have network effects if the net benefits from buying and using the product increase with the number of other users using the same. Direct network effects originate from the ability of consumers to directly communicate with other users of the same network, indirect network effects originate from an increased incentive for providers of complementary goods to produce more or a wider variety of them. The literature on network effects is vast and we can only hope to cover a relatively restricted range of topics. For an extensive review of the recent literature, see Koski and Kretschmer (2004). 1 181 MN3119 Strategy The following figures illustrate the mechanics of direct and indirect network effects. In Figure 17.1, we can see that as another user joins the network, the previous two users directly benefit because they can communicate with one more user, which they have not been able to previously. Figure 17.1: Direct network effects. In Figure 17.2, network effects materialise because a complementary good producer has more incentive to produce for a larger network, which in turn makes it more attractive to join a larger network. Figure 17.2: Indirect network effects. Activity 17.1 Which of these products have direct network effects? And indirect? a. Languages b. Telephones c. Diesel cars d. Video games. Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 17.2 Network market structures The general notion of network effects is that a larger network of users is more attractive for new users to join. What does this imply for market structure in industries with significant network effects? We have a look at a number of industries with network effects. 17.2.1 Video cassette recorders (VCRs) Figure 17.3 illustrates market shares of VHS and Betamax in the US.2 In the late 1970s both standards were relatively close in terms of their market shares, but VHS kept on pulling away, so that by the late 1980s Betamax virtually disappeared from the market. Some of the main reasons for VHS’s success was said to be its liberal licensing policy and the support of the largest video rental store, Blockbusters. 182 2 Source: Ohashi (2003). Chapter 17: Network effects Market shares VHS, Beta 100 80 60 VHS 40 BETA 20 0 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 Figure 17.3: VCR by format, 78–86, US. Other successful network technologies include the compact disc, FM stereo radio, eBay auctions, and so on. For almost every success story, however, there is also a story of dismal failure. Quadraphonic sound was a technology that set out to replace stereo in the 1970s, but never caught on,3 the DAT tape never managed to replace the compact cassette, the Dvorak keyboard layout never displaced the ubiquitous QWERTY layout.4 These are just a small number of spectacular failures of technologies that, while some claim they were not significantly better than the successful ones, they were certainly not much worse than them. One of the main points of interest about network markets therefore is how and why technologies fail, and what firms can do to avoid this. 17.2.2 Excess inertia and excess momentum5 One of the reasons for the failure of perfectly acceptable technologies with network effects is that the incumbent technology is superior due to their installed base, which provides users of the incumbent technology with a higher utility than switching to the new technology. It is quite possible that they would prefer the new technology if everybody else switched, but the uncertainty about the switching behaviour of others holds back all but the most enthusiastic adopters of the new technology. Therefore, if a new technology has network effects, is up against an incumbent technology with a significant installed base, and there is some uncertainty about whether other adopters will switch as well, a new technology may suffer from excess inertia, the socially inefficient failure to adopt a new technology. 3 See Postrel (1990). 4 See David (1985). This section is based on Cabral (2000) Chapter 17. 5 Another scenario that might emerge with network effects is the opposite, where the user of an existing technology feels he has to conform to other users who have switched to a new technology, even though the incumbent technology is still perfectly up to date. So if a technology has network effects, and early users have a strong impact on late users through the need for compatibility, excess momentum could emerge, the socially inefficient adoption of a new technology. 17.3 Technology diffusion with network effects In the previous chapter, we discussed three approaches to technology diffusion – the epidemic, heterogeneity and population ecology approach. We now introduce network effects to a story of technology diffusion. Suppose a population of potential users is considering adopting the compact disc. Compact discs are a network product with direct and indirect network effects, so we would expect an early user to obtain relatively low benefit from buying a CD player, while later users, who have 183 MN3119 Strategy access to a large library of CDs, will derive more benefit. Assuming then that adopters could do something else with their money if they did not buy a CD player, every potential user has an incentive to wait and see if the CD catches on. We can see immediately that there are two Nash equilibria among the many potential CD users: either nobody adopts because nobody is expected to adopt, or everybody adopts because everybody is expected to adopt. Which one of these equilibria will emerge is obviously of prime importance to sponsors of the technology, but also to users who are convinced of the value of a new audio system, but would not want to take the risk on their own. If we take the intuition of this story into a dynamic setting, we will find that for low expectations sales will fall short of expected sales, starting a vicious cycle that will end in no sales of the new technology, and that for high expectations sales will exceed expected sales, which in turn generates a virtuous cycle that ends in market success. By continuity, there will be a level of expectations below which the long-term equilibrium will involve zero sales, and above which it involves full market penetration. This threshold level of expectations is called critical mass. Let us look at a numerical example. Suppose that there are N potential adopters in each period and that demand in each period depends on the price charged (p) and the expected demand (Ne) in the following way: N = 1 – p + 2Ne Apart from the last term, this is a well-behaved demand function as demand decreases the price of the product. On the other hand, the higher the expectations are for the product, the more consumers are willing to pay for the product, which captures the assumption of network effects. We look purely at the demand side to begin with. If expectations are updated in some way so that the new expectations (i.e. expected sales in the next period) are some kind of combination of last period’s expectations and last period’s sales, for every price p there will be a point for which actual sales exceed expected sales, which causes expectations to be adjusted upwards and a self-reinforcing process to emerge. Activity 17.2 Find the critical mass point for p = 3/2, p = 7/4 and p = 1. How does critical mass depend on prices? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. We now introduce the supply side of a network technology. Suppose for example that a technology has marginal cost of MC = 1/2 and that a review article states that expected sales of the technology are 1/3.6 At what price should the product be sold? You should be able to derive the profit function for the firm and find the profit-maximising price: 6 We are sidestepping the question of the starting price here – suppose that the review article simply states the starting level of expectations. This is just making things easier for us. We could just as well assume that secondperiod expectations are some combination of last period’s expectations and real sales, i.e. Ne(t+1) = a Ne(t) + (1 – a ) N(t). What effect would this have on the dynamics of the market? 7 N = 1 – p + 2*(1/3) P = (p – 1/2) * (1 – p + 2/3) p* = 13/12, N* = 7/12, P* = 49/144 ≈ 0.34 What is interesting about the optimum prices and sales is that at the optimal price, actual sales exceed expected sales. Suppose now that in the second period, consumers expect sales to be 7/12, that is, the first-period sales level.7 If we derive the optimal price and demand, we find that p* = 4/3 and N* = 5/6. This seems rather counterintuitive since prices have gone up in the second period, yet demand has gone up as well. What 184 Chapter 17: Network effects has happened? As we have established before, the demand function is well behaved, so demand should decrease with price. Indeed it does, but only for constant levels of expected sales. If we let expected sales vary, we are in fact talking about two different demand curves. Activity 17.3 Draw demand curves for the first and second period. Suppose now that expected sales are a linear combination of past expected and real sales, i.e. Ne(t+1) = a Ne(t) + (1 – a) N(t), where a = 50 per cent. What would be the demand curve in the second period? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. The general profit function and optimal prices and quantities (for any level of expectations) are (you should be able to derive this): p* = 3/4 + Ne, N* = 1/4 + Ne, P* = (1/4 + Ne)2 We can see that profits increase in expectations, which makes sense given our assumption of network effects. How can firms use this to their advantage? One way to do it in our simple model is to influence expectations in the first period in order to enjoy higher demand in the second period. Leaving aside marketing activities and other strategies outside the model, the firm could try and price strategically. One strategy would be, for example, to price such that sales in the first period are N(t) = 1, which would raise expectations in the second period to Ne(t+1) = 1. The downside is that profits in the first period would be lower than under optimal (static) pricing, the upside of it is higher second-period profits. To see if this strategy is worth it, we need to solve our model for both periods, assuming our initial demand curve and expectations. First-period prices p1 must be such that: 1 = 1 – p1 + 2/3, i.e. p1 = 2/3. Calculating profits, we find that P1 = 1/6, which is much lower than the first-period profits we found previously (0.34). In the second period, however, we enjoy higher expectations and a demand function of: N=1–p+2 This gives an optimal price of p2 = 7/4, N2 = 5/4, and P2 = 25/16, which is much higher than 0.39, the second-period profits under regular dynamic pricing. Ignoring discounting for a moment, combined first- and secondperiod profits are significantly higher under strategic pricing than under non-strategic dynamic pricing. Activity 17.4 a. Suppose that second-period profits are discounted by a factor d < 1. How low would d have to be in order to render strategic pricing unprofitable? b. Consider the demand function N = 1 – p + (1/10) * Ne. Using our two-period model and initial expectations of Ne = 1/3, would a firm want to set first-period prices strategically so that Ne(t+1) = 1? (That is, is it profitable to do so compared to regular (static) pricing)?) Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 185 MN3119 Strategy 17.4 Generic strategies in network markets8 As mentioned before, entering into a market with an incumbent technology with network effects is not always straightforward and carries the risk of excess inertia. In particular, it makes it difficult to establish a marginally better, but incompatible technology in the market because consumers will be unwilling to switch and abandon their current technology for one with uncertain benefits and small network size. Firms or sponsors of new technologies in general will have to consider two dimensions – the degree of technological improvement and the degree of control over the new technology. Shapiro and Varian (1999) have developed a list of generic strategies in network markets in light of these two dimensions. 17.4.1 Backward compatibility versus performance New technologies that are designed to be backward compatible with the incumbent technology are constrained in their improvements – clearly, if some of the product characteristics need to be shared by the old and the new technologies, improvements in these characteristics is impracticable. A radical new technology on the other hand is not constrained by the existing. However, a technology that is backward compatible will be able to link into the existing network of consumers, thus somewhat lowering the disadvantage of having a small installed base for a new technology. The main trade-off in choosing (assuming of course it can be chosen) the degree of technological improvement is that backward compatibility lowers the installed base problem, but renders the technology less superior to the existing one. 15.4.2 Open standard versus control Choosing the level of control over the new technology has important implications for the ability to appropriate profits from the technology. A closed standard (or ‘control’ strategy) will imply that if it succeeds in replacing the incumbent technology as industry standard, the technology sponsor has monopoly power over the technology. On the other hand, an open standard is attractive to potential users because different suppliers offer slightly differentiated versions of the new technology and prices are likely to be much more competitive, which lowers the risk of being ‘lockedin’ to an all-powerful producer of an industry standard. Here again, both strategies have advantages and disadvantages – control over a technology ensures a larger share of potential future profits, while a relatively liberal licensing policy or even an open standard makes adoption by the market more likely. The combination of these two dimensions yields four generic strategies – controlled migration (control/compatibility), performance play (control/performance), open migration (openness/compatibility), and discontinuity (openness/performance). 186 Control Openness Compatibility Controlled migration Open migration Performance Performance play Discontinuity This section is based on Shapiro and Varian (1999), Chapter 7. The strategies described here are laid out in much more detail there. 8 Chapter 17: Network effects Activity 17.5 The following are all examples of new technology introductions – which of the four generic network strategies do they represent? a. Atari è Nintendo Entertainment System b. Windows 95 è Windows 98 c. 1G (analog) mobile phones è 2G (digital) mobile phones d. 2G mobile phones è 2.5G mobile phones e. 3.5’’ diskettes è Zip disks (by IOmega) f. Vinyl records è Compact discs Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. 17.5 Fighting a standards battle In the previous section, we only considered a single new technology trying to replace an existing one. Quite frequently, however, there is more than one candidate for the next generation of a technology – the VCR battle between VHS and Betamax is just one of the many examples. In a market with network effects, one of the technologies is likely to emerge as the industry standard, as we have seen earlier in this chapter. We now turn to some of the factors that affect the outcome of a standard battle and discuss how firms can influence these factors. First, the price of a technology relative to the rival technology plays an important role. This may not be very surprising, but the consequences of pricing too high may be much more dramatic than in conventional markets. Since future sales are affected by the level of past sales, a small disadvantage early on can translate into a major shortfall in the future – therefore the incentives for strategic pricing will be even higher if there is competition than if there is not. Second, the relative qualities of the technologies play a role. This again is not unexpected, but it should be noted here that a firm faces the trade-off of trying to introduce a technology early to gain an installed base advantage over its rival, but waiting as long as possible to ensure the best possible technology. Pre-emption motives may be important in network industries, but it is always important to maintain a sufficient level of technological quality in order to make switching attractive in the first place. Third, as mentioned previously, backward compatibility may have an impact on the outcome of a standards battle. If one technology sponsor maintains backward compatibility, it can gain a huge advantage over its competitors, but possibly at the expense of a technological advantage over the incumbent technology. Fourth, consumer expectations may play a much more important role in network markets than in regular industries as we have seen, since high expectations are likely to translate into a higher willingness to pay in the future, and consequently even bigger advantages later on. Firms fighting a standards battle will therefore make sure they portray their technology as eventual winners even in the early market stages, for example by highlighting past successes, comparing their technology favourably to their rivals, gaining endorsements from credible ‘lead consumers’, or investing in large production capacities that will only ever be used if the technology becomes the industry standard. 187 MN3119 Strategy Finally, a technology with a sufficient supply of complementary goods can gain a lead over its competitors – the chicken-and-egg problem of producers of complementary goods (why would I produce for no consumers, and why would consumers choose a technology with no complementary goods?) is often solved by the technology sponsor itself. For example, by tapered integration where some of the complementary good is produced in-house and some by outside suppliers. This helps build up expectations and reaching critical mass, while ensuring sufficient variety of complementary goods. 17.6 Key concepts • Direct and indirect network effects • Excess inertia • Excess momentum • Generic strategies in network markets • Compatibility • Standard battles. 17.7 A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and Activities, you should be able to: • define network effects and network market structures • explain technology diffusion patterns using network theory • discuss the four generic strategies firms can pursue in network markets as described by Shapiro and Varian (1999). 17.8 Questions for discussion 1. Postrel (1990) describes the process of the failure of quadraphonic sound to replace stereo sound. Which of the four generic strategies was chosen by quad suppliers and why do you think it failed? 2. Sony and Philips joined forces to develop and market the compact disc standard – what are the advantages and disadvantages of developing jointly with one’s biggest competitor? 3. Excess inertia may occur for technologies with direct or indirect network effects. How can a supplier of a technology with direct network effects try and overcome excess inertia? Can the same techniques be applied for an ‘indirect network effects technology’? Guidance on this activity can be found in the VLE. Extended activity: Skype and digital cinema Read the following and answer the questions at the end. Direct Network Effect ‘caselet’: Skype Technologies SA Founded in 2002, the web-based communications company Skype Technologies has over 60 million users in 225 countries, and has recently been acquired by the online auction site eBay for $2.5 billion. Skype’s aim is to revolutionise the $1 trillion global telecom industry through its service of offering free calls using Voice over Internet protocol (VoIP) technology. 188 Chapter 17: Network effects Skype’s revenue model is distinct from other VoIP players: the company does not charge its users monthly or per-minute fees. Instead, it lets users make free calls to other registered Skype users, and charges them only when calling landlines or users registered with a competing VoIP provider. Network Effects: Digital Cinema in the USA Digital cinema refers to the creation, transmission and projection of film using digital technology – bits and bytes and satellites – instead of physical reels of 35mm film. Universal transition to digital cinema is ultimately expected to benefit all parties on the value chain of this industry – the studios and distributors, the digital technology and hardware developers, exhibitors (movie theatres) and audiences – as more and better films can be made and distributed more cheaply, flexibly and readily than ever before possible. In 2002 the major studios – Disney, Fox, MGM, Paramount, Sony and Warner – formed the Digital Cinema Initiative (DCI) to ‘establish and document voluntary specifications for an open architecture for digital cinema that ensures a uniform and high level of technical performance, reliability and quality control’. The DCI was also committed to facilitating the development of business plans and strategies to help spur deployment of digital cinema systems in movie theatres. The DCI was hailed as being the first bold step towards making digital cinema a reality. It was expected to provide a catalyst for the market transition and hasten its development. Most importantly creating a universal format meant that the technology developers would not be able to offer competing standards at different studios, creating a Betamax/VHS scenario in which purchasers risked investing in the ‘wrong’ technology. In July 2005, the DCI completed its technical specifications for digital cinema, and large-scale rollout of the technology is now widely deemed to be imminent. Sceptics, however, say the transition is still several years off due to lack of infrastructure, ready supply of necessary technology and support, and, finally, the lack of agreement about the economics of the entire endeavour. The chief impediment to progress lies in the fact that the costs of the technology transition fall to the exhibitors, while the cost benefits accrue to the studios/distributors. With installation costing up to $100,000 per screen, say JP Morgan analysts, transferring to a digital cinema system is a major capital expenditure. Conversely, a move to digital saves studios $2,000–3,000 per print of each reel of 35mm film made for distribution, while filming costs go down dramatically. For example, the 220 hours it took to film Star Wars, Episode II: Attack of the Clones digitally cost $16,000, as opposed to the estimated $1.8 million it would have cost using traditional film. Unlike some European countries, where governments are subsidising the digital cinema roll-out, particularly for the independent sector, the US is leaving it to the commercial players to work out between themselves just how the costs are split among them. In between the studios and exhibitors are the companies such as Dolby, Barco, Christie, Technicolor and Access Integrated Technologies, who make the digital cinema systems and projectors. These companies have a clear objective, which is to sell their products, and thus have emerged as ‘brokers’ of the potential cost-sharing agreements between studios/ distributors and exhibitors. As such, the technology providers have created a variety of different business plans that offer exhibitors different financing arrangements. For example, some business plans propose that exhibitors 189 MN3119 Strategy do not pay for initial installation costs but only for ongoing maintenance and support of their new digital cinema systems. Under this arrangement the costs are effectively borne by the studios over time, through the payment to technology providers of ‘virtual print fees’ per film distributed over a given number of years. To date, none of the technology developers appear to have been able to secure the critical mass of participants from either side of the equation – studios or exhibitors – that would push the transition fully into motion. Even once a watershed agreement is secured with one of the big exhibitor chains, there is the issue of a current lack of hardware – for example, there are currently only 85 digital projectors in stock in all of North America. Aligning the supply with demand and getting the timing right will be challenging, so long as there is such uncertainty in this market. What is certain is that the film industry will reach the digital age eventually, however bumpy the road. Sources Coster, P. ‘Digital cinema industry update: near the end of the reel’, JP Morgan North America Equity Research, 20 October 2005. ‘Double Standards’, Media, Haymarket Publishing Services, Ltd, 9 September 2005. Sperling, N. ‘Industry panel discusses 3-D projection’, The Hollywood Reporter 11 October 2005. Sperling, N. ‘Access Integrated Technologies and Christie Digital Systems are learning that rolling out digital cinema can be difficult’, The Hollywood Reporter 2 September 2005. Questions 1. How would you characterise Skype’s business strategy? What is its potential for success versus other VoIP players? 2. Describe and analyse the direct and indirect network effects of digital cinema. What factors are most likely to affect the roll-out of digital cinema? 190 Appendix 1: Sample examination paper Appendix 1: Sample examination paper Important note: The Sample examination paper reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year 2013−2014. The format and structure of the examination may have changed since the publication of this subject guide. You can find the most recent examination papers on the VLE where all changes to the format of the examination are posted. Time allowed: three hours Candidates have to answer a total of eight of the following twelve questions: all four from Section A (12.5 marks each) and four of eight (12.5 marks each) from Section B. Candidates are strongly advised to divide their time accordingly. The maximum length for the answer to each question is 300 words. Section A Answer four questions from this section (50 marks in total). 1. Explain the term ‘time compression diseconomies’. 2. You have been asked to define the market for private financial services, e.g. small credit financing. Which technique(s) would you use and what kind of data would you need to collect to do it? 3. The transition from 2G to 2.5G mobile telephony has been characterised as ‘open migration’. Explain what this means and what advantages or disadvantages it has for owners and consumers of the new technology. 4. What are the major barriers to entry into the brewing industry and how did the microbrewers get around them? Section B Answer four questions from this section (50 marks in total). 5. Explain how some firms might use ‘tapered integration’ to lower the quasi-rents they are facing in the context of a particular transaction. 6. Product introductions in this market come at relatively regular intervals. If consumers expect a new technology to supersede the existing one soon, how will their incentive to adopt the current technology be affected? What, if anything, could a supplier of razor systems do to counter this tendency? 7. The intensity and success of research and development is said to be strongly affected by the present market structure. What are the replacement and efficiency effects for a monopolist? Under what conditions is one stronger than the other? 8. Tapered integration is a way to combine some of the advantages of vertical integration and outsourcing. Which motives for vertical integration still hold when integration is not full, but tapered? Are there advantages that only occur in the case of tapered (but not full) integration? 191 MN3119 Strategy 9. One of the problems Matsushita/JVC faced while working on their own digital audio standard was that they did not have easy access to an affiliated software firm like Sony (in CBS) and Philips (in Polygram). Assuming that their technology was of a similar quality, what strategic options did Matsushita/JVC have? Analyse these options (including the likely reactions by Sony and Philips) and discuss their expected profitability. 10. How can resale price maintenance (RPM) help solve the problem of investment externalities in case of two retailers in the same shopping mall? 11. An industry has a C4-ratio of 80%. a. What is the minimum Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI) for this industry? Show your calculation. b. What is the maximum HHI for this industry? Show your calculation. 12. You are a manager of the (at the moment) only ice-cream parlour in a large shopping mall. Someone told you about how endogenous sunk costs can help your business. How could you use endogenous sunk costs to maximise profits in this case? END OF PAPER 192 Appendix 2: Guidance on answering the Sample examination paper Appendix 2: Guidance on answering the Sample examination paper This course examines your ability to structure situations where there is strategic interdependence between firms (or within firms). Special emphasis is given to the application of concepts introduced in the subject guide to new (real-life) situations. The weighting is such that passing the course is not possible by simply regurgitating facts from the subject guide; you have to give the examiners some evidence that you can transfer the knowledge to new situations. Giving additional evidence of ‘thinking outside the box’, for example by challenging a concept or outlining the limits to its applicability, or giving detailed examples with some of the mechanisms present, will usually be the difference between an upper second and a first-class answer. While there are some questions that have a right and wrong answer, many questions will have cumulative answers where pure repetition gives some credit (but not very much), some transfer of knowledge puts your mark between a pass and a high upper second mark, and a genuinely new concept or connection warrants a first-class mark. In other words, it is possible for students to give a correct, but very ‘thin’ answer and still not get high marks because they did not go far enough in their application of the concept in the examination. It is important that answers are concise and selective. 300 words is not a lot, so candidates will have to make sure to select the most important facts and concepts in their answer. The following notes are guidance on answering the questions on the sample examination paper (Appendix 1). Section A Question 1 This is more or less bookwork – which means it will be something that the subject guide and reading will have described clearly and if you have studied these carefully you should be able to provide a clear and correct definition which will ensure a pass grade. Some examples of time compression diseconomies, limits to the concept’s applicability, a discussion of the implications of time compression diseconomies will cumulatively enable you to get higher marks. Mentioning at least two (better three) of all these factors would warrant a distinction mark. Question 2 The focus in this question is on a competent application of the techniques of market definition for a particular case or scenario. Simply listing all available techniques will at most result in a low passing grade if the techniques are presented very well. Proposing a select set of techniques to this particular situation will get higher marks, and a practical guide of the kinds of data and the method of generating this data (if it needs to be generated) warrants a distinction. 193 MN3119 Strategy Question 3 This question asks you to apply the generic strategy ‘open migration’ to the mobile phone industry. Explaining ‘open migration’ competently is sufficient for a pass mark, but linking it to the specific characteristics of this particular case will be necessary for a higher mark. An informed discussion of the pros and cons will include some mention of the other generic strategies and why open migration has specific advantages or disadvantages over them. The distinction in the pros and cons between owners and consumers is necessary for a first-class mark. Question 4 Barriers to entry have to be defined and applied to the case – indiscriminately listing barriers to entry is not sufficient to pass! Specific application to the case is necessary, and the strategic responses by entrants are necessary for a distinction mark. Section B Question 5 Here, tapered integration must be defined briefly, but this is not enough to pass. An understanding of quasi-rents is essential, and will be needed for a pass mark. Linking these two concepts is relatively challenging, so a good demonstration of how these two are linked will warrant a high upper second class mark. Use of a concrete example with some specific industry (or firm) knowledge then takes an answer up to the distinction or first class level. Question 6 A discussion of the incentives of adopters to purchase a new technology is required here. Factors like uncertainty, network effects, previous usage, pre-announcements by rivals could all be mentioned here. Overall, this question tests your ability to discuss adoption incentives in a novel setting. Question 7 Explaining innovation incentives is necessary here. You should include a discussion on the factors influencing these effects and a sensible assessment of when one of these effects dominate. Question 8 This question is asking for a precise comparison of two scenarios. A list of factors should be produced, with an informed judgment on the direction of the inequality - i.e. are the advantages higher or lower with tapered than with full integration? Question 9 You are asked to be creative here in outlining different strategic options for JVC/Matsushita and their respective advantages and disadvantages. The strategies proposed should be sensible and practical to achieve a pass mark, and they should include a good discussion of the pros and cons for a higher mark. 194 Appendix 2: Guidance on answering the Sample examination paper Question 10 This question requires you to understand the principle of investment externalities – the fact that some of the benefit from an investment into a brand does not accrue to the investor, but other firms. In particular, firms can charge slightly lower prices and benefit from the investment of others. RPM lowers this effect because prices are homogenous. A good answer will detect this link and explain it successfully. Question 11 Candidates have to realise that a C4 of 80% can still hide some heterogeneity among the top 4 firms or the smaller firms. The minimum is an even spread of 20% each of the four largest ((20*20)*4 = 1600) and a mass of atomistic firms (=0), so that the minimum HHI is 1600. The maximum HHI can be derived by knowing that larger firms get increasingly larger weights, so that there could be one firm with 80% market share and the rest of the market being atomistic, giving an HHI of 6400. A good answer will show this and show the workings. Question 12 This question asks for an application of endogenous sunk costs to deter entry. Bookwork of explaining endogenous sunk costs is not sufficient to pass, it is important to show that entry can be deterred through this. Moreover, a very good answer would include a concrete example of what an ice cream parlour in a mall could do by way of endogenous sunk costs. 195 MN3119 Strategy Notes 196 Notes Notes 197 MN3119 Strategy Notes 198 Notes Notes 199 MN3119 Strategy Notes 200