CHAPTER 5 Introduction to Risk, Return, and the Historical Record INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 5-2 Topics • Discussion of Risk and Risk Premiums – – – – Determinants of the Level of Interest Rates Bills and Inflation, 1926-2009 Risk and Risk Premiums Time Series Analysis of Past Rates of Return • Normality of Returns – The Normal Distribution – Deviations from Normality and Risk Measures – Historic Returns on Risky Portfolios INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-3 Real and Nominal Rates of Interest • Nominal interest rate (R): Growth rate of your money • Real interest rate (r): Growth rate of your purchasing power • Inflation rate (i): Growth rate of the price level • Then, 1 1 1 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-4 Equilibrium Real Rate of Interest • Determined by: – Supply (Households, Government) – Demand (Businesses, Government) INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-5 Figure 5.1 Determination of the Equilibrium Real Rate of Interest INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-6 Equilibrium Nominal Rate of Interest • As the inflation rate increases, investors will demand higher nominal rates of return • If E(i) denotes current expectations of inflation, then we get the Fisher Equation: • Nominal rate = real rate + inflation forecast R r E (i ) INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-7 Taxes and the Real Rate of Interest • Tax liabilities are based on nominal income – Given a tax rate (t) and nominal interest rate (R), the Real after-tax rate is: R(1 t ) i (r i )(1 t ) i r (1 t ) it • The after-tax real rate of return falls as the inflation rate rises. INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-8 Table 5.2 Statistics for T‐Bill Rates, Inflation Rates and Real Rates, 1926‐2009 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-9 Figure 5.2 Nominal and Real Wealth Indexes for Investments in T‐Bills, 1968‐2009 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-10 Figure 5.3 Interest Rates and Inflation, 1926‐2009 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-11 Correlation of Inflation with … Nominal R = Real r + Exp. Inflation INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-12 Bills and Inflation, 1926‐2009 • Moderate inflation can offset most of the nominal gains on low-risk investments. • A dollar invested in T-bills from1926–2009 grew to $20.52, but with a real value of only $1.69. • Negative correlation between real rate and inflation rate means the nominal rate responds less than 1:1 to changes in expected inflation. INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-13 Interest Rates and Inflation in Korea • Source: ECOS (Economic Statistics System: 한국은행 경제통계시스템) Monthly inflation data measured by CPI, YoY basis INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-14 Interest Rates and Inflation in Korea • Source: ECOS (Economic Statistics System: 한국은행 경제통계시스템) Monthly inflation data measured by CPI, YoY basis INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-15 Interest Rates and Inflation in Korea • Source: ECOS (Economic Statistics System: 한국은행 경제통계시스템) INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-16 Interest Rates and Inflation in Korea • Source: ECOS (Economic Statistics System: 한국은행 경제통계시스템) 30.00 무담보콜금리(1일물, 은행간직거래) 25.00 CD유통수익률(91일) 산금채(3년) 회사채(장외3년,AA- 등급) 20.00 소비자물가지수 (전년대비증감률) 15.00 10.00 5.00 0.00 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-17 Holding Period Return Rates of Return: Single Period P 1 P 0 D1 HPR P0 = capital gains yield + dividend yield HPR = Holding Period Return P0 = Beginning price P1 = Ending price D1 = Dividend during period one INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-18 Excess Returns and Risk Premiums • We measure the reward as the difference between the expected HPR and the risk-free rate; we call this difference the risk premium on common stocks. • The difference in any particular period between the actual rate of return on a risky asset and the actual riskfree rate is called excess return. • Therefore, the risk premium is the expected value of the excess return, and STD of the excess return is a measure of its risk. INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-19 The Reward‐to‐Volatility (Sharpe) Ratio • Sharpe Ratio for Portfolios: Risk Premium SD of Excess Returns INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-20 Expected Return (Definition) Expected returns p(s) = probability of a state s r(s) = return if a state s occurs s = state INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-21 Scenario Returns: Example State Excellent Good Poor Crash Prob. of State .25 .45 .25 .05 r in State 0.3100 0.1400 -0.0675 -0.5200 E(r) = (.25)(.31) + (.45)(.14) + (.25)(-.0675) + (0.05)(-0.52) E(r) = .0976 or 9.76% INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-22 Variance and Standard Deviation (Definition) Variance (VAR): Standard Deviation (STD): INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-23 Scenario VAR and STD: Example • Example VAR calculation: σ2 = .25(.31 - 0.0976)2+.45(.14 - .0976)2 + .25(-0.0675 0.0976)2 + .05(-.52 - .0976)2 = .038 • Example STD calculation: .038 .1949 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-24 Estimation of The Sharpe Ratio • The both definitions of expected return (risk premium) and standard deviation (risk or volatility) involve expectation (E[ ]). • Empirically, since we don’t know the true distribution of an asset return, we cannot use the definitions of expected return and standard deviation to estimate the Sharpe ratio of an asset. • In order to estimate an expected value of a random variable, we need something called ‘Law of Large Numbers.’ INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-25 Law of Large Numbers • Idea: If you run many trials in a simulation or experiment, the empirical probability will get closer and closer to the actual or theoretical probability of the event. • Example: Coin flipping • Formal Statement (of a version of LLN): , ,… . . . ⋯ 1 ⋯ ∞, → INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-26 Time Series Analysis of Past Rates of Return The Arithmetic Average of Rate of Return: 1 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-27 Time Series Analysis of Past Rates of Return The Geometric Average Rate of Return ∙ … or, 1 ̅ 1 1 … 1 1 ̅ = geometric average rate of return Example: Terminal Value of the Investment INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-28 Variance and Standard Deviation Estimation • Estimated Variance = expected value of squared deviations _ 2 1 r s r n s 1 ^ 2 where n is the arithmetic average INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-29 Variance and Standard Deviation Estimation • When eliminating the (degrees of freedom) bias, Variance and Standard Deviation become: _ 2 1 r s r n 1 j 1 ^ n INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-30 How Precise is The Estimate? • Once we estimate the risk premium (expected excess return) of an asset, we would naturally be interested in how precise the estimate is. • In order to find out the precision of the estimate, we need something called ‘Central Limit Theorem.’ • The ‘Central Limit Theorem’ gives us the distribution of the sample mean estimated. INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-31 Central Limit Theorem • Idea: The ‘Central Limit Theorem’ says that the distribution of a sample mean , for sufficiently large sample, will be normal, no matter what distribution the original data have. • Formal Statement: , ,… ∞ . . . . , 0, 1 → 0, INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-32 Back to The Estimation Precision… • According to the CLT, the estimated risk premium (sample mean ) will have the following distribution: For large enough n, , , 0,1 • Hence, 1.96 1.96 95% 2.58 2.58 99% INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-33 Figure 5.4 The Normal Distribution INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-34 Back to The Estimation Precision… • However, the problem is that we don’t know the true of ; what we have is a sample variance variance . • Then, if is replaced with its estimate , for large enough n, 1 • Hence, , 0.975 , 0.975 95% , 0.995 , 0.995 99% INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-35 Back to The Estimation Precision… • , 0.975 is the critical value for which makes , 0.975 distribution 0.975 • However, we know that distribution converges to normal distribution as → ∞. • Hence, as far as this course is concerned, we will use – – , 0.975 , 0.995 1.96 2.58 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-36 Student t‐dist’n vs. Normal dist’n INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-37 t‐test for Sample Mean • Now that we know how precise the estimate for the risk premium is, we can test if the risk premium is zero or not. • Let’s assume that the ‘true’ risk premium is zero for an asset. In other words, our null hypothesis is : 0 • Then, under the null hypothesis, 0 1.96 1.96 1.96 95%, 5% INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-38 t‐test for Sample Mean • If we assume that 5% event is a rare/outlier event, we formally say that the level of significance is set at 5%. • Then, if the absolute value of the t-stat is greater than 1.96, we conclude that the observed t-stat is in the rare/outlier region under the null hypothesis. • In other words, we conclude that the observed t-stat cannot be justified by the null hypothesis and we REJECT the null hypothesis; we say the risk premium is statistically significant or statistically different from zero. INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-39 The Normal Distribution • Investment management is easier when returns are normal. – Symmetricity: Standard deviation is a good measure of risk when returns are symmetric. – Stability: If security returns are normal, portfolio returns will be, too. – Simplicity: Future scenarios can be estimated using only the mean and the standard deviation. INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-40 Normality and Risk Measures • What if excess returns are not normally distributed? – Standard deviation is no longer a complete measure of risk – Sharpe ratio is not a complete measure of portfolio performance – Need to consider skew and kurtosis INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-41 Skew and Kurtosis Skew Equation 5.19 _ 3 R R skew average ^ 3 Kurtosis • Equation 5.20 _ 4 R R kurtosis average ^ 3 4 3 3 INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-42 Figure 5.5A Normal and Skewed Distributions INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-43 Figure 5.5B Normal and Fat‐Tailed Distributions (mean = .1, SD =.2) INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-44 Extreme Negative Return Risk Measures • Higher frequency of extreme negative returns may result from negative skew and/or kurtosis (fat tails). • Therefore, we would like a risk measure that indicates vulnerability to extreme negative returns: – Value at Risk – Expected Shortfall – Lower Partial STD INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-45 Value at Risk (VaR) • A measure of loss most frequently associated with extreme negative returns • VaR is written into regulation of banks and closely watched by risk managers. • VaR is the quantile of a distribution below which lies q % of the possible values of that distribution – The 5% VaR , commonly estimated in practice, is the return at the 5th percentile when returns are sorted from high to low. INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-46 Expected Shortfall (ES) • Also called conditional tail expectation (CTE) • More conservative measure of downside risk than VaR – VaR takes the highest return from the worst cases – ES takes an average return of the worst cases INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-47 Lower Partial Standard Deviation (LPSD) and the Sortino Ratio • Issues with STD as a risk measure when the return distribution is nonnormal: – Need to consider negative deviations separately – Need to consider deviations of returns from the risk-free rate. • LPSD: similar to usual standard deviation, but uses only negative deviations from rf (rather than negative deviations from the sample average) • Sortino Ratio replaces Sharpe Ratio INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-48 Historic Returns on Risky Portfolios • Returns appear normally distributed • Returns are lower over the most recent half of the period (19862009) • SD for small stocks became smaller; SD for long-term bonds got bigger • Better diversified portfolios have higher Sharpe Ratios • Negative skew INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-49 Historic Returns on Risky Portfolios INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-50 Historic Returns on Risky Portfolios INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS 5-51 Historic Returns on Risky Portfolios INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS