BUSINESS FINANCE 12e PEIRSO N BROW N EASTON HOW ARD PINDER BUSINESS FINANCE Monash University L University of Melbourne University of Newcastle Monash University — Graw Hill Education Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education (Australia) Pty Ltd Additional owners o f copyright are acknowledged in on-page credits. Every effort has been made to trace and acknowledge copyrighted material. The authors and publishers tender their apologies should any infringement have occurred. Reproduction and communication for educational purposes The Australian Copyright Act 1968 (the Act) allows a maximum o f one chapter or 10% o f the pages o f this work, whichever is the greater, to be reproduced and/or communicated by any educational institution for its educational purposes provided that the institution (or the body that administers it) has sent a Statutory Educational notice to Copyright Agency Limited (CAL) and been granted a licence. For details o f statutory educational and other copyright licences contact: Copyright Agency Limited, Level 15, 233 Castlereagh Street, Sydney NSW 2000. Telephone: (02) 9394 7600. Website: www.copyright.com.au Reproduction and communication for other purposes Apart from any fair dealing for the purposes o f study, research, criticism or review, as permitted under the Act, no part o f this publication may be reproduced, distributed or transmitted in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the written permission o f McGraw-Hill Education (Australia) Pty Ltd, including, but not limited to, any network or other electronic storage. Enquiries should be made to the publisher via www.mcgraw-hill.coin.au or marked for the attention o f the permissions editor at the address below. National Library o f Australia Cataloguing-in-Publication Data Author: Peirson, Graham, author. Title: Business finance / Graham Peirson, Rob Brown, Steve Easton, Sean Pinder, Peter Howard. Edition: 12th edition ISBN: 9781743078976 (paperback) Notes: Includes index. Subjects: Business enterprises-Finance. Cash management. Corporations-Finance. Other Authors/Contributors: Brown, Rob, author. Easton, Stephen Andrew, author. Pinder, Sean, author. Howard, Peter, author. Dewey Number: 658.15 Published in Australia by McGraw-Hill Education (Australia) Pty Ltd Level 2, 82 Waterloo Road, North Ryde NSW 2113 Publisher: Jillian Gibbs Senior product developer: Jane Roy Production editor: Tami Rex Permissions editor: Haidi Bernhardt Copyeditor: Jess Ni Chuinn Proofreader: Anne Savage Indexer: Russell Brookes Cover design: Christabella Designs Internal design: David Rosemeyer Typeset in Chapparal Pro 10/12 pt by diacriTech, India Printed in China on 70gsm matt art by China Translation and Printing Services Ltd PUBLISHER'S FOREW ORD When this endeavour began 44 years ago, few could have foreseen the success of this publication, and few could have imagined how proud we would be to have published a resource that has guided well over 2 0 0 0 0 0 undergraduate students through their introduction to business finance. This title has become one of McGraw-Hill Education Australia's longest-standing and most successful textbooks. It is with the greatest pleasure that McGrawHill Australia now presents the twelfth edition of Business Finance by Graham Peirson, Rob Brown, Steve Easton, Peter Howard and Sean Pinder. This text is an original work—not an adaptation of US material. The founding authors, Graham Peirson and Ron Bird, embarked on an ambitious undertaking: to write a meaningful introduction to the fascinating field of business finance, specifically for students in Australia and New Zealand. They succeeded, and the first edition was published in 1972. As a testament to the consistent value of the work and its ongoing relevance for generations of students and instructors, Business Finance continues to sell thousands of copies each year. In a market increasingly crowded with competitive texts, it is a credit to our author team that Business Finance continues as the market leader in its field. To our authors and the academic community who have so staunchly supported this publication we say thank you. Quality content is clearly the key. The twelfth edition author team has worked hard, in consultation with instructors across Australia and New Zealand, to ensure that the text and its digital resource package provide recent data and up-to-date thinking in an accessible format that will engage students and instructors alike. This twelfth edition has done just that, demonstrating the authors, commitment to refining their text and ensuring that Business Finance not only retains a reputation for currency, but emerges once again as the standard setter. Our focus at McGraw-Hill is wholly on providing superior content. W ith Business Finance twelfth edition we are confident we offer you the best there is. M c G ra w -H ill Education A u stra lia , 2 0 1 4 v ^1 ■ BRIEF C O N TEN TS CHAPTER 1 Introduction CHAPTER 2 Consumption, investment and the capital market 10 CHAPTER 3 The time value o f money: on introduction to financial mathematics 28 CHAPTER 4 A pplying the time value o f money to security valuation 74 CHAPTER 5 Project evaluation: principles and methods 103 CHAPTER 6 The application o f project evaluation methods 129 CHAPTER 7 Risk and return 772 CHAPTER 8 The capital market 210 CHAPTER 9 Sources o f finance: equity 232 CHAPTER 10 Sources o f finance: debt 275 CHAPTER 11 Payout policy 315 CHAPTER 12 Principles o f capital structure 3 56 CHAPTER 13 C apital structure decisions 3 93 CHAPTER 14 The cost o f capital 417 CHAPTER 15 Leasing and other equipment finance 450 CHAPTER 16 C apital market efficiency 477 CHAPTER 17 Futures contracts and swops 507 CHAPTER 18 Options and contingent claims 5 63 CHAPTER 19 Analysis o f takeovers 605 CHAPTER 2 0 Managem ent o f short-term assets: inventory 646 CHAPTER 21 Managem ent o f short-term assets: liqu id assets and accounts receivable 666 1 C O N TEN TS Publisher's foreword V Preface X X V // About the authors x x v iii Acknowledgments Chapter 1 Digital resources xxx i Highlights o f this edition xxx ii How to use this book xxxiv XXX Introduction Learning objectives ID FINANCE AS AN AREA OF STUDY 2 IB FINANCIAL DECISIONS 2 IB BUSINESS STRUCTURES 3 1.3.1 Sole proprietorship 3 1.3.2 Partnership 3 1.3.3 Company 4 IQ THE COMPANY'S FINANCIAL OBJECTIVE 5 IB FUNDAMENTAL CONCEPTS IN FINANCE 5 ID 1.5.1 Value 5 1.5.2 The time value of money 5 1.5.3 Risk aversion 6 1.5.4 Nominal and real amounts 6 1.5.5 Market e仟iciency and asset pricing 6 1.5.6 Derivative securities 7 1.5.7 Arbitrage 7 1.5.8 Agency relationships 7 OUTLINE OF THE BOOK Summary 8 8 Key terms 8 Questions 9 Chapter 2 Consumption, investment and the capital market 10 Learning objectives JO m INTRODUCTION 11 ^ FISHERY SEPARATION THEOREM: A SIMPLIFIED EXAMPLE 11 2.2.1 11 Introduction to the example 2.2.2 Assumptions 11 2.2.3 The shareholders7 consumption opportunities and preferences 12 2.2.4 Solution: introduce a capital market 12 2.2.5 An analysis using rates of return 13 2.2.6 A solution requiring borrowing 13 C ontents Q | B | 2.2.7 Fisher's Separation Theorem and net present value 13 2.2.8 Fisher’s Separation Theorem: summary 14 FISHERS SEPARATION THEOREM: A FORMAL APPROACH 14 2.3.1 14 Assumptions 2.3.2 The company 15 2.3.3 The shareholders 15 2.3.4 The company’s decision 16 2.3.5 Solution: introduce a capital market 16 2.3.6 Proving there is an optimal policy 19 2.3.7 Identifying the optimal policy 21 2.3.8 Implications for financial decision making 22 INVESTORS'REACTIONS TO MANAGERS' 2.4.1 DECISIONS Certainty 24 25 2.4.2 The introduction of uncertainty 25 Summary 26 Key terms 26 Questions 26 Problems 26 References 27 The time value of money: an introduction to financial mathematics 28 Learning objectives 28 m INTRODUCTION 29 |B FUNDAMENTAL CONCEPTS OF FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS 29 3.2.1 Cashflows 29 3.2.2 Rate of return 29 3.2.3 Interest rate 30 3.2.4 Time value of money 30 SIMPLE INTEREST 31 3.3.1 The basic idea of simple interest 31 3.3.2 Formula development: future sum 31 3.3.3 Formula development: present value 32 3.3.4 Applications of simple interest 32 COMPOUND INTEREST 33 3.4.1 The basic idea of compound interest 33 3.4.2 Formula development: future sum and present value 34 3.4.3 Nominal and effective interest rates 37 3.4.4 Compound interest: two special cases and a generalisation 40 VALUATION OF CONTRACTS WITH MULTIPLE CASH FLOWS 46 3.5.1 46 IQ IB Introduction 3.5.2 Value additivity 46 ix C ontents |Q IB |Q 3.5.3 Formula development: valuation as at any date 48 3.5.4 Measuring the rate of return 49 ANNUITIES 50 3.6.1 50 Definition and types of annuity 3.6.2 Formula development: present value of an ordinary annuity 51 3.6.3 Formula development: present values of annuities-due, deferred annuities and ordinary perpetuities 52 3.6.4 Future value of annuities 56 PRINCIPAL-AND-INTEREST LOAN CONTRACTS 58 3.7.1 58 Basic features of the contract 3.7.2 Principal and interest components 59 3.7.3 Balance owing at any given date 60 3.7.4 Loan term required 61 3.7.5 Changing the interest rate 62 GENERAL ANNUITIES 63 Summary 66 Key terms 66 Self-test problems 66 Questions 67 Problems 67 References 73 Applying the time value of money to security valuation 74 Learning objectives 74 ED INTRODUCTION 75 IQ FINANCIAL ASSET VALUATION UNDER CERTAINTY 75 m VALUATION OF SHARES 76 4.3.1 Valuation of shares assuming certainly 76 4.3.2 Valuation of shares under uncertainty 77 4.3.3 Share valuation and the price-earnings ratio 79 |Q VALUATION OF DEBT SECURITIES 80 EB INTEREST RATE RISK 81 ED THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES 4.6.1 EB W hat is the term structure? 82 82 4.6.2 Using the term structure to price a bond 83 4.6.3 Term structure theories: expectations and liquidity (risk) premium 85 4.6.4 Empirical evidence 88 4.6.5 Inflation and the term structure 89 THE DEFAULT-RISK STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES 89 C ontents W ED OTHER FACTORS AFFECTING INTEREST RATE STRUCTURES 91 Summary 92 Key terms 92 Self-test problems 92 Questions 93 Problems 93 References 96 APPENDIX 4.1 DURATION AND IMMUNISATION 97 Introduction 97 Bond duration 97 Duration and interest elasticity 99 Duration and bond price changes 100 Duration and immunisation 100 I Project evaluation: principles and methods 103 Learning objectives 103 m INTRODUCTION 104 Q THE CAPITAL-EXPENDITURE PROCESS 104 E 9 METHODS OF PROJECT EVALUATION 104 5.3.1 107 0 3 Q Q Discounted cash flow methods THE DISCOUNTED CASH FLOW METHODS COMPARED 108 5.4.1 108 Net present value 5.4.2 Internal rate of return 109 5.4.3 Choosing between the discounted cash flow methods 112 5.4.4 Benefit-cost ratio (profitability index) 1 17 OTHER METHODS OF PROJECT EVALUATION 118 5.5.1 1 18 Accounting rate of return 5.5.2 Payback period 120 5.5.3 Economic value added (EVA) 121 PROJECT EVALUATION AND REAL OPTIONS ANALYSIS 123 5.6.1 123 Real options analysis 5.6.2 W ho uses real options analysis? 124 Summary 125 Key terms 125 Self-test problems 125 Questions 125 Problems 126 References 128 xi C ontents Chapter 6 The application of project evaluation methods 129 Learning objectives 129 INTRODUCTION 130 APPLICATION 〇 F THE NET PRESENT VAUJE METHOD 130 6.2.1 130 Estimation of cash flows in projectevaluation 6.2.2 Illustration of cash-flow information in project evaluation 133 TAX ISSUES IN PROJECT EVALUATION 134 6.3.1 134 Effect of taxes on net cash flows 6.3.2 Illustration of cash-flow information inproject evaluation with taxes 137 COMPARING MUTUALLY EXCLUSIVE PROJECTS THAT HAVE DIFFERENT LIVES 139 DECIDING WHEN TO RETIRE (ABANDON) OR REPLACE A PROJECT 146 6.5.1 146 Retirement decisions 6.5.2 Replacement decisions 147 ANALYSING PROJECT RISK 149 6.6.1 149 Sensitivity analysis 6.6.2 Break-even analysis 151 6.6.3 Simulation 152 DECISION-TREE ANALYSIS 153 QUALITATIVE FACTORS AND THE SELECTION OF PROJECTS 156 PROJECT SELECTION WITH RESOURCE CONSTRAINTS 157 Summary 159 Key terms 159 Self-test problems 159 Questions 160 Problems 161 References 171 Chapter 7 Risk and return 172 Learning objectives 172 INTRODUCTION 173 RETURN AND RISK 173 THE INVESTORS UTILITY FUNCTION 176 THE RISK OF ASSETS 179 PORTFOLIO THEORY AND DIVERSIFICATION 179 7.5.1 180 Gains from diversification 7.5.2 Diversification with multiple assets 184 7.5.3 Systematic and unsystematic risk 186 7.5.4 The risk of an individual asset 187 7.5.5 The efficient frontier 189 C ontents m THE PRICING OF RISKY ASSETS 190 7.6.1 191 The capital market line 7.6.2 The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) and the security market line 192 7.6.3 Implementation of the CAPM 195 7.6.4 Risk, return and the CAPM 197 ■ ADDITIONAL FACTORS THAT EXPLAIN RETURNS 197 Q PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE APPRAISAL 198 7.8.1 Alternative measures of portfolio performance 203 Key terms 204 Self-test problems 204 Questions 204 Problems 205 References 208 The capital market Learning objectives 211 21 1 8.1.2 The capital market 211 8.1.3 Types of financial market 212 8.1.4 Developments in Australia's financial markets 212 FINANCIAL AGENCY INSTITUTIONS 8.2.1 Brokers and the stock exchange FINANCIAL INTERMEDIARIES 8.3.1 IQ 210 8.1.1 The flow of funds 8.2.2 Investment banks HI 210 INTRODUCTION 8.1.5 Business funding ■ 199 Summary Banks 214 215 216 217 220 220 8.3.2 Money market corporations 223 8.3.3 Finance companies 223 8.3.4 Securitisation 223 INVESTING INSTITUTIONS 8.4.1 Insurance companies and superannuation funds 224 225 8.4.2 Unit trusts and investment companies 228 8.4.3 Overseas sources and markets 229 Summary 230 Key terms 230 Questions 230 References 231 C ontents I Sources of finance: equity Learning objectives BD INTRODUCTION Q THE CHARACTERISTICS OF ORDINARY SHARES 9.2.1 Fully paid and partly paid shares 9.2.2 Limited liability d 233 234 234 234 234 9.2.4 The rights of shareholders 235 9.2.5 Advantages and disadvantages of equity as a source of finance 235 PRIVATE EQUITY 236 9.3.1 236 W hat is private equity? 9.3.2 Information problems and new ventures 237 9.3.3 Sources of finance for new ventures 237 9.3.4 Finance from business angels 238 9.3.5 Finance from private equity funds 238 INFORMATION DISCLOSURE Offers of unlisted securities 240 240 9.4.2 Offers of listed securities 241 9.4.3 Offers that do not need disclosure 241 FLOATING A PUBLIC COMPANY 9.5.1 242 Public versus private ownership 242 9.5.2 Initial public offering of ordinary shares 243 9.5.3 Pricing a new issue 243 9.5.4 Underwriting and managing a newissue 244 9.5.5 Selling a new issue 246 9.5.6 The costs of floating a company 246 9.5.7 Long-term performance of IPOs 250 SUBSEQUENT ISSUES OF ORDINARY SHARES 252 9.6.1 253 Rights issues 9.6.2 Placements (private issues) 260 9.6.3 Contributing shares and instalment receipts 262 9.6.4 Share purchase plans 262 9.6.5 Company-issued share options 262 9.6.6 Choosing between equity-raising methods 263 m EMPLOYEE SHARE PLANS B 3 INTERNAL FUNDS 9.8.1 ® 232 9.2.3 No liability companies 9.4.1 Q 232 Dividend reinvestment plans MANAGING A COMPANY'S EQUITY STRUCTURE 9.9.1 Bonus issues and share splits 9.9.2 Share consolidations 265 266 267 268 268 269 C ontents Summary 270 Key terms 270 Questions 271 Problems 272 References 273 Chapter 10 Sources of finance: debt Learning objectives 275 275 BT8B1 INTRODUCTION 276 1BH GENERAL CHARACTERISTICS OF DEBT 277 10.2.1 The interest cost of debt 278 10.2.2 Effect of debt on risk 279 10.2.3 Effect of debt on control 279 10.2.4 Security for debt 280 10 3 ■ SHORT-TERM BORROWING FROM BANKS AND OTHER FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS 282 10.3.1 Bank overdraft 282 10.3.2 Debtor finance 283 10.3.3 Inventory loans 284 10.3.4 Bridging finance 284 10 4 ■ LONG-TERM BORROWING FROM BANKS AND OTHER FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS 285 10.4.1 Long-term loan choices available to borrowers 285 10.4.2 Variable-rate term loans 286 10.4.3 Fixed-rate term loans 287 10.4.4 Other features of term loans 287 10.4.5 288 W hy do borrowers use term loans instead of security issues? 10 5 ■ DEBT SECURITIES 289 10.5.1 Debt securities: the general principles 289 10.5.2 Commercial paper 290 10.5.3 Bills of exchange 292 10.5.4 Debentures 295 10.5.5 Unsecured notes 297 10.5.6 Corporate bonds 297 10 6 ■ PROJECT FINANCE 301 10.6.1 The main features of project finance 301 10.6.2 When is project finance attractive? 302 10 7 ■ HYBRIDS OF DEBT AND EQUITY 302 10.7.1 Convertible notes and convertible bonds 303 10.7.2 Preference shares 305 Summary 309 Key terms 309 C ontents Self-test problems 310 Questions 310 Problems 311 References 313 Chapter 1 1 Payout policy Learning objectives 3 75 INTRODUCTION 316 11.1.1 Dividend declaration procedures 317 11.1.3 317 IS Legal and tax considerations PAYOUT POLICY IMPORTANT TO SHAREHOLDERS? 11.2.1 Alternative payout policies 318 319 319 1 1.2.2 Managers and payout decisions 320 11.2.3 321 The irrelevance of payout policy 1 1.2.4 The importance of full payout 323 11.2.5 324 Payout policy in practice TRANSACTION COSTS AND FLOTATION COSTS 324 | 1 1.3.1 Transaction costs 324 1 1.3.2 Flotation costs 325 DIVIDENDS AND TAXES 325 1 1.4.1 Dividends and the imputation tax system 325 1 1.4.2 Imputation and capital gains tax 327 1 1.4.3 Dividend policy with imputation and capital gains tax 328 gl 1 1.4.4 The market value of franking credits 329 INFORMATION EFFECTS AND SIGNA山 NG TO INVESTORS 332 AGENCY COSTS AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 335 BEHAVIOURAL FACTORS AND CATERING THEORY 339 SHARE BUYBACKS 339 11.8.1 340 W hy do companies repurchase shares? 1 1.8.2 Share repurchases in Australia 343 DIVIDEND REINVESTMENT PLANS AND DIVIDEND ELECTION SCHEMES 346 PAYOUT POLICY AND COMPANY LIFE CYCLE 347 I DD DD 316 11.1.2 Types of dividend 11.1.4 Repurchasing shares DD 315 Summary 349 Key terms 349 Questions 350 Problems 351 References 353 C ontents Chapter 12 Principles of capital structure 356 Learning objectives 356 INTRODUCTION 357 12.2 THE EFFECTS OF FINANCIAL LEVERAGE 357 12.3 THE MODIGLIANI AND MILLER ANALYSIS (NO TAX CASE) 361 12.3.1 |B | 12.4 12.5 12.6 12.7 Modigliani and Miller's Proposition 1 361 12.3.2 Modigliani and Miller's Proposition 2 365 12.3.3 368 Modigliani and Miller's Proposition 3 12.3.4 W hy is the M M analysis important? 369 THE EFFECTS OF TAXES ON CAPITAL STRUCTURE UNDER A CLASSICAL TAX SYSTEM 369 12.4.1 Company income tax 369 12.4.2 Company tax and personal tax 371 12.4.3 373 Miller's analysis 12.4.4 The scope of Miller's analysis 374 THE EFFECTS OF TAXES ON CAPITAL STRUCTURE UNDER AN IMPUTATION TAX SYSTEM 374 12.5.1 374 W hat is an imputation tax system? 12.5.2 The effects of tax on capital structure decisions under an imputation tax system 376 THE COSTS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS 377 12.6.1 Bankruptcy costs 377 12.6.2 Indirect costs of financial distress 378 AGENCY COSTS 379 12.7.1 Conflicts of interest between lenders and shareholders 379 12.7.2 Conflicts of interest between shareholders and company managers 380 12.8 OPTIAAAL CAPITAL STRUCTURE: THE STATIC TRADE-OFF THEORY 381 12.9 CAPITAL STRUCTURE WITH INFORMATION ASYMMETRY 382 12.9.1 Pecking order theory 382 12.9.2 Information asymmetry and the undervaluation of a company's assets 383 12.9.3 Information asymmetry and the overvaluation of a company's assets 385 12.9.4 Implications of information asymmetry for financing policy 386 Summary 387 Key terms 387 Self-test problems 387 Questions 388 Problems 389 References 392 Capital structure decisions 13.1 393 Learning objectives 393 INTRODUCTION 394 13.1.1 394 Company financing: some initial facts XVII C ontents 13.2 13.3 EVIDENCE ON CAPITAL STRUCTURE 395 13.2.1 Evidence on taxes 395 13.2.2 Evidence on the costs of financial distress 397 13.2.3 Evidence on agency costs 399 13.2.4 Evidence on information costs and the pecking order theory 401 13.2.5 Evidence from dual issues and spin-offs 403 13.2.6 Evidence on the choice of maturity and priority of debt 404 13.2.7 Evidence from surveys 405 ASSESSING THE THEORIES OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE 406 13.3.1 How useful is the static trade-off theory? 406 13.3.2 How useful is the pecking order theory? 407 13.4 FINANCING AS A MARKETING PROBLEM 408 13.5 DETERMINING A FINANCING STRATEGY 409 13.5.1 Business risk 409 13.5.2 Asset characteristics 410 13.5.3 Tax position 410 13.5.4 Maintaining reserve borrowing capacity ('financial slack') 411 13.5.5 411 Other factors Summary 412 Key terms 412 Questions 413 References 414 The cost of ca pital Learning objectives 417 |Q | INTRODUCTION 418 B 〇 RISK, RETURN AND THE COST OF CAPITAL 418 14.2.1 Risk independence 419 14.3 TAXES AND THE COST OF CAPITAL 419 14.4 ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO ESTIMATION OF THE COST OF CAPITAL 421 14.4.1 421 14.5 14.6 Direct use of the CAPM 14.4.2 The weighted average cost of capital (WACC) 422 ESTIMATION OF THE COST OF CAPITAL: AN EXTENDED EXAMPLE 423 14.5.1 424 The cost of debt 14.5.2 The cost of preference shares 427 14.5.3 The cost of ordinary shares 427 14.5.4 The company's cost of capital 429 14.5.5 430 Issue costs and the cost of capital PROJECT AND COMPANY COST OF CAPITAL 431 14.6.1 432 Calculating the cost of capital for divisions using the 'pure play7 approach 14.6.2 Calculating the cost of capital for divisions using the direct estimation approach x v iii 417 434 [ED EVALUATION TECHNIQUES 436 USING CERTAINTY EQUIVALENTS TO ALLOW FOR RISK 437 Summary 440 Key terms 440 Self-test problems 441 Questions 441 Problems 442 References 446 APPENDIX 14.1 THE COST OF CAPITAL UNDER ALTERNATIVE TAX SYSTEMS Introduction 447 Deriving cost of capital formulae 447 Summary 449 Chapter 15 [Q l 447 Leasing and other equipment finance 450 Learning objectives 450 INTRODUCTION 451 451 15.2.1 Finance leases 15.2.2 Operating leases 452 453 15.2.3 Sale and lease-back agreements 453 15.2.4 Leveraged leasing 454 15.2.5 Cross-border leasing 455 [ Q | ACCOUNTING AND TAXATION TREATMENT OF LEASES 15.3.1 Accounting for leases 455 455 15.3.2 Taxation treatment of leases 456 15.4 SETTING LEASE RENTALS 456 15.5 EVALUATION OF FINANCE LEASES 458 15.5.1 Leasing decisions and investment decisions 460 15.5.2 The value of leasing in competitive capital markets 461 15.5.3 462 Establishing an advantage for leasing 15.5.4 Taxes and the size of leasing gains 463 15.5.5 464 Leasing and the imputation tax system 15.6 EVALUATION OF OPERATING LEASES 465 15.7 ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES OF LEASING 466 15.7.1 Possible advantages of leasing 466 15.7.2 Leasing policy 469 15.8 CHATTEL MORTGAGES AND HIRE-PURCHASE 471 15.8.1 471 Equipment finance and the goods and services tax C ontents Summary 472 Key terms 472 Self-test problems 472 Questions 473 Problems 474 References 475 Chapter 16 Capital market efficiency 477 Learning objectives 4 77 16.1 INTRODUCTION 478 16.2 THE EFFICIENT AAARKET HYPOTHESIS 478 16.2.1 479 16.3 16.4 A non-instantaneous price reaction 16.2.2 A biased price reaction 479 16.2.3 480 Categories of capital market efficiency 16.2.4 Market efficiency and the joint test problem 480 TESTS 〇 F RETURN PREDICTABILITY 481 16.3.1 481 The relationship between past and future returns 16.3.2 The presence of seasonal effects in returns 482 16.3.3 483 Predicting future returns on the basis of other forecast variables EVENT STUDIES 487 16.4.1 487 The methodology of event studies 16.4.2 Evidence: profit and dividend announcements in Australia 491 16.4.3 Other events 493 TESTS FOR PRIVATE INFORMATION 493 16.6 MARKET EFFICIENCY AT THE MACRO LEVEL 495 16.7 BEHAVIOURAL FINANCE AND MARKET EFFICIENCY 495 16.8 IMPLICATIONS OF THE EVIDENCE WITH RESPECT TO MARKET EFFICIENCY 497 16.8.1 Implications for investors in securities 497 16.8.2 Implications for financial managers 499 Summary 501 Key terms 501 Questions 501 References 503 Chapter 17 Futures contracts and swaps 507 Learning objectives 5 07 17.1 INTRODUCTION 508 17.2 WHAT IS A FUTURES CONTRACT? 509 17.2.1 Forward contracts and futures contracts 509 17.2.2 How a futures market is organised 509 C ontents 17.2.3 Deposits, margins and the mark-to-market rule 51 1 17.2.4 The present value of a futures contract 512 17.3 THE AUSTRALIAN SECURITIES EXCHANGE 512 17.4 DETERMINANTS OF FUTURES PRICES 513 17.5 FUTURES MARKET STRATEGIES: SPECULATING AND HEDGING 515 17.5.1 Introduction 515 17.5.2 Speculating 516 17.5.3 Hedging 517 17.6 17.5.4 Some reasons why hedging with futures is imperfect 518 17.5.5 521 17.5.6 Selecting the number of futures contracts 522 FINANCIAL FUTURES ON THE AUSTRALIAN SECURITIES EXCHANGE: THE 90-DAY BANK-ACCEPTED BILL FUTURES CONTRACT 525 17.6.1 A brief review of bank bills 525 17.6.1 Specification of the bank-accepted bill futures contract 526 Uses of the bank bill futures contract 527 17.6.2 17.7 Hedging and regretting FINANCIAL FUTURES ON THE AUSTRALIAN SECURITIES EXCHANGE: THE 10-YEAR TREASURY BOND FUTURES CONTRACT 532 17.7.1 A brief review of bond pricing 532 17.7.2 Specification of the 10-year bond futures contract 533 17.7.3 Uses of the 10-year bond futures contract 533 FINANCIAL FUTURES ON THE AUSTRALIAN SECURITIES EXCHANGE: THE 30-DAY INTERBANK CASH RATE FUTURES CONTRACT 535 FINANCIAL FUTURES ON THE AUSTRALIAN SECURITIES EXCHANGE: THE SHARE PRICE INDEX S&P/ASX 200 (SPI 200) FUTURES CONTRACT 536 17.9.1 A brief review of Australian Securities Exchange indices 536 17.9.2 Specification of the S&P/ASX 200 futures contract 537 17.9.3 Uses of the S&P/ASX 200 futures contract 537 17.10 VALUATION OF FINANCIAL FUTURES CONTRACTS 540 17.8 17.9 Valuation of bank bill futures contracts 540 17.10.2 Valuation of share price index futures contracts 541 FORWARD-RATE AGREEMENTS 542 SWAPS 544 17.10.1 17.12.1 17.1 W hat is a swap? 2.2 Interest rate swaps 544 544 CURRENCY SWAPS 551 Summary 556 Key terms 557 Self-test problems 557 Questions 557 Problems 558 References 562 C ontents Chapter 18 (E D Options and contingent claims 563 Learning objectives 563 INTRODUCTION 564 564 18.2.1 W hat is an option? 1 8.2.2 How options are created and traded 565 1 8.2.3 Option contracts and futures contracts 566 1 8.2.4 Payoff structures for calls and puts 566 1 8.2.5 Factors affecting call option prices 567 1 8.2.6 Some basic features of put option pricing 571 18.2.7 573 Put-call parity 1 8.2.8 The minimum value of calls and puts B H ^ 1 564 576 BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING 577 1 8.3.1 The basic idea: pricing a single-period calloption using the binomial approach 577 1 8.3.2 Risk neutrality as a solution method 579 1 8.3.3 Binomial option pricing with many time periods 579 1 8.3.4 Applying the binomial approach to other option problems 582 THE BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL OF CALL OPTION PRICING 582 18.4.1 Assumptions 1 8.4.2 The Black-Scholes equation 1 8.4.3 A brief assessment of the Black-Scholes model 582 583 587 OPTIONS ON FOREIGN CURRENCY 588 18.5.1 589 W hat is an option on foreign currency? 1 8.5.2 Combinations of options on foreign currency 590 18.6 OPTIONS, FORWARDS AND FUTURES 591 18.7 OPTIONS ON FUTURES 593 1 8.7.1 W hat is an option on a futures contract? 593 Uses of options on futures 593 1 8.7.2 18.8 18.7.3 Pricing options on futures 594 18.7.4 Specification of the SPI 200 futures options contract 594 CONTINGENT CLAIMS 595 18.8.1 W hat is a contingent claim? 595 18.8.2 Rights issues 595 18.8.3 Convertible bonds 596 1 8.8.4 Valuation of levered shares and risky zero-coupon debt 596 1 8.8.5 Valuation of levered shares and risky coupon-paying debt 596 1 8.8.6 597 Project evaluation and Veal’ options Summary 599 Key terms 599 Self-test problems 599 C ontents Questions 600 Problems 601 References 604 .; , 19.2 19 3 19 4 19 5 1 Analysis of takeovers I Learning objectives 605 INTRODUCTION 606 19.1.1 606 Fluctuations in takeover activity 19.1.2 Types of takeover 607 REASONS FOR TAKEOVERS 608 19.2.1 Evaluation of the reasons for takeovers 609 19.2.2 Survey evidence of the motives for takeovers 613 19.2.3 The roles of takeovers 613 ■ECONOMIC EVALUATION OF TAKEOVERS Comments on estimation of takeover gains 615 19.3.2 Comparing gains and costs 616 19.3.3 Estimating cost for a share-exchange takeover 617 ■ALTERNATIVE VALUATION APPROACHES 618 19.4.1 Valuation based on earnings 618 19.4.2 Valuation based on assets 619 ■REGULATION AND TAX EFFECTS OF TAKEOVERS 7 | 614 19.3.1 619 19.5.1 Off-market bids 620 19.5.2 Market bids 621 19.5.3 Disclosure requirements 621 19.5.4 Creeping takeover 622 19.5.5 Partial takeovers 622 19.5.6 Schemes of arrangement 622 19.5.7 Other controls on takeovers 623 19.5.8 Tax effects of takeovers 623 19.5.9 624 Break fees, takeovers and corporate governance 1 1 9 . 6 1 TAKEOVER DEFENCES W 605 625 19.6.1 Poison pills 625 19.6.2 Acquisition by friendly parties 625 19.6.3 Disclosure of favourable information 625 19.6.4 Claims and appeals 626 19.6.5 The effects of takeover defences 626 CORPORATE RESTRUCTURING 627 19.7.1 Divestitures 627 19.7.2 Spin-offs 627 19.7.3 Buyouts 628 XXIII C ontents EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON TAKEOVERS 630 19.8.1 631 The target company 19.8.2 The acquiring company 631 19.8.3 Are takeovers poor investments? 633 19.8.4 Distinguishing between good and bad takeovers 636 19.8.5 The net effects of takeovers 636 19.8.6 The sources of gains from takeovers 637 Summary 639 Key terms 639 Self-test problems 640 Questions 640 Problems 642 References 643 Chapter 20 B Q Management of short-term assets: inventory 646 Learning objectives 646 INTRODUCTION 647 THE IMPORTANCE OF SHORT-TERM FINANCIAL DECISIONS 647 TYPES OF SHORT-TERM ASSET 648 20.3.1 Inventory 648 20.3.2 Liquid assets (cash and short-term investments) 648 20.3.3 Accounts receivable (debtors) 648 B Q THE NEED FOR SHORT-TERM ASSET MANAGEMENT 648 Q fl SHORT-TERM ASSETS AND SHORT-TERM LIABILITIES 649 E H OVERVIEW OF INVENTORY MANAGEMENT 650 B Q E 0 INVENTORY COSTS: RETAILING AND WHOLESALING 650 20.7.1 Acquisition costs 650 20.7.2 Carrying costs 651 20.7.3 Stockout costs 651 INVENTORY COSTS: MANUFACTURING 651 20.8.1 Inventories of raw materials 651 20.8.2 Inventories of finished goods 652 in v e n t o r y MANAGEMENT UNDER CERTAINTY 652 20.9.1 The economic order quantity (EOQ) model 652 20.9.2 Cost estimation 655 20.9.3 The EOQ model with positive lead time 656 20.9.4 The EOQ model with quantity discounts 657 E S S INVENTORY MANAGEMENT UNDER UNCERTAINTY 20.10.1 658 Specifying an acceptable probability of stockout 660 20.10.2 Specifying an acceptable expected customer service level 660 20.11 INVENTORY MANAGEMENT AND THE 'JUST-IN-TIME' SYSTEM 661 Summary 662 Key terms 663 Self-test problems 663 Questions 663 Problems 664 References 665 Chapter 21 Management of short-term assets:丨 iquid assets and accounts receivable 666 Learning objectives 666 O H INTRODUCTION 667 w xn OVERVIEW OF LIQUIDITY MANAGEMENT 667 21.2.1 W hat are liq u id ' assets? 667 21.2.2 Liquidity management and treasury management 667 21.2.3 Centralisation of liquidity management 668 Q Q Q Q 21.2.4 Motives for holding liquid assets 669 21.2.5 669 Major issues in liquidity management CASH BUDGETING 670 21.3.1 Forecasting cash receipts 670 21.3.2 Forecasting cash payments 671 THE CHOICE OF SHORT-TERM SECURITIES 673 TYPES OF SHORT-TERM INVESTMENT 674 21.5.1 Deposits of funds with financial institutions 674 21.5.2 Discounting of commercial bills 674 21 6 | THE CORPORATE TREASURER AND LIQUIDITY MANAGEMENT Q Q Q Q 675 OVERVIEW OF ACCOUNTS RECEIVABLE MANAGEMENT 675 21.7.1 675 What are accounts receivable? CREDIT POLICY 677 21.8.1 The decision to offer credit 677 21.8.2 Selection of credit-worthy customers 677 21.8.3 Limit of credit extended 680 21.8.4 Credit terms 680 COLLECTION POLICY 681 EVALUATION OF ALTERNATIVE CREDIT AND COLLECTION POLICIES 682 Summary 686 Key terms 687 Self-test problems 687 Questions 687 C ontents Problems 688 References 689 APPENDIX 21.1 FINANCIAL STATEMENT ANALYSIS xxvi 690 Introduction 690 Measurement and interpretation of several financial ratios 690 Usefulness of financial ratio analysis 695 Financial ratios and short-term asset management 696 Appendix A Numerical tables 698 Appendix B Solutions to self-test problems 709 Glossary 725 Index 736 PREFACE W This book is designed primarily for use in a first subject in the principles and practice of finance. Our main objectives are to introduce readers to finance theory and to the tools of financial decision making in the context of the Australian institutional environment. Nevertheless, it is also suitable for students who have completed an introductory subject on capital markets and financial institutions. It also contains sufficient material for two subjects in finance. Readers who are familiar with previous editions of the book will notice changes that go well beyond the updating that might be expected from a new edition. New finance theories and new empirical evidence are presented with each edition. For example, in this edition both new theoretical material and related empirical evidence have been incorporated on the determinants of payout policy (Chapter 1 1), the capital structure decision (Chapter 13) and the analysis of takeovers (Chapter 19). Some of this new material provides more detailed coverage, compared with previous editions, of the expanding area of behavioural finance—an area where investor psychology is incorporated into research design. Theories and evidence with respect to market efficiency (Chapter 16) are also updated. Since the eleventh edition, Eugene Fama and Robert Shiller have each been awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for their work examining market efficiency. Both have made a fundamental contribution to our understanding of market efficiency yet they have different views as to the extent that markets are efficient. Like the Nobel Prize Committee, the approach we take is to highlight the range of evidence in this area. Practice in finance also necessitates updates. For example, since the last edition there have been on-going developments in financial markets, including in Australia, and changes in the functions of banks. M any of these developments result from the Global Financial Crisis and are incorporated in Chapter 8. Rather than distort the coherent flow of the book by altering its structure to reflect these changes in principles and practice, new material is embedded into the existing structure. Indeed, the major structural change in this edition is the omission of international finance as a separate chapter and instead embedding material where appropriate into relevant chapters; in particular into Chapter 17, which now incorporates a detailed discussion of swaps. Finally, we wish to express our special thanks to Graham Peirson and Peter Howard who have both retired from active authorship but have made a substantial contribution to the foundations of the book. Graham deserves particular mention. Having been central to the book from the first edition, he continues to make a great contribution to each new edition by providing valuable comments on the draft of each chapter. Graham brings not only a deep knowledge but also an uncanny ability to detect flaws in logic and in writing style. His thoroughness has again prevented many such flaws from appearing in print. ROB BROWN ♦ STEVE EASTON ♦ SEAN PINDER August 2014 x x v ii ABO U T THE AUTHORS G rah am Peirson Graham Peirson is Emeritus Professor of Accounting and Finance at Monash University. He has published widely in academic and professional journals and is also coauthor of Issues in Financial Accounting; Accounting: An Introduction; Financial Accounting: An Introduction; and Financial Accounting Theory. Graham is a graduate of Adelaide University, and has taught at Adelaide University, the University of California (Berkeley), the University of Illinois, the University of Florida and the University of Washington. He has also taught short courses for a range of clients, including the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission and the National Australia Bank. Rob Brown Rob Brown is Emeritus Professor of Finance at the University of Melbourne. He has published many research papers in international journals, including Economica, the Journal o f Banking and Finance, the Journal o f Multinational Financial Monogementand \he Journal o f Fixed Income. He is a former associate editor (finance) of Accounting and Finance, the research journal of the Accounting and Finance Association of Australia and New Zealand. Rob has taught at the University of Sydney, Lancaster University and Monash University, and been a visiting scholar at the University of British Columbia (Canada) and the University of Manchester (UK). His current research interests are analysts' investment recommendations. Steve Easton Steve Easton is Professor of Finance at the University of Newcastle, where he previously served as Head of the Department of Accounting and Finance and Dean of the Faculty of Economics and Commerce. His research work has been accepted for publication in a wide range of journals, including the Journal o f Futures Markets, Economico and the Journal o f Banking and Finance. Steve has taught at Adelaide University, Lancaster University and Monash University. He has also provided short courses for a range of private and public sector organisations, including Australia Post, Macquarie Generation, State Forests of New South Wales and the Tasmanian Chamber of Commerce and Industry. His current research interests are in asset pricing, portfolio management and corporate governance. XXVIII Peter H o w a rd Peter Howard taught finance at Monash University for more than 25 years. Before this he worked for eight years as an engineer in the petrochemical and mining industries. He has extensive experience in project evaluation and has taught on short courses for a range of clients, including BHP Billiton and the National Australia Bank. Peter has published in academic and professional journals on lease evaluation and the effects of imputation on payout and financing decisions. He has extensive teaching experience at both postgraduate and undergraduate levels. Since retiring from Monash University he has maintained a strong interest in the finance literature and the operation of Australian financial markets. Sean Pinder Sean Pinder is an Associate Professor in the Department of Finance at the University of Melbourne. Prior to this he held positions at Monash University and the University of Newcastle and taught at the postgraduate level at Lancaster University in England and the Melbourne Business School. He has undertaken a range of consulting activities for international firms and has developed and delivered professional short courses on treasury risk management, derivatives and capital budgeting issues for major Australian and international companies. Sean has an extensive research profile, with his work appearing in leading Australian and international journals. He has received a number of prizes for his research and teaching. A C K N O W LE D G M E N T S We have received valuable assistance from a number of people, including Philip G. Brown, Chris Deeley, Paul Docherty, Stefan Petry and Michael Seamer. We would like to join McGraw-Hill in thanking academic colleagues who provided their valuable time and expertise in aligning the learning resources with this edition of our book. They include: ♦ Mariya Yesseleva-Pionka, Monash University ♦ Neil Hartnett, University of Newcastle ♦ Damian Bridge, Macquarie University ♦ Md Akhtaruzzaman, University of Newcastle We also owe a debt of thanks to the following reviewers of earlier editions who have helped us shape the text you hold today: John Ablett (University of Western Sydney), David Allen (Edith Cowan University), Vicki Baard (Macquarie University), Robert Bianchi (Griffith University), Barry Burgan (University of Adelaide), Nicholas Carline (Lancaster University, UK), Meena Chavan (Macquarie University), Andrew Child (Monash University), Scott Dobbs (University of Wollongong), Samson Ekanayake (Deakin University), Don Geyer (Charles Sturt University), Abeyratna Gunasekarage (Monash University), Neil Hartnett (University of Newcastle), Darren Henry (La Trobe University), Ben Jacobsen (James Cook University), Sian Owen (University of New South Wales), Judy Paterson (University of Canberra), Alex Proimos (Macquarie University), Boyd Scheuber (University of Southern Queensland), Chander Shekhar (University of Melbourne), Jing Shi (Australian National University), Yew Lee Tan (Victoria University), Madhu Veeraraghavan (Monash University) and David W oodliff (University of Western Australia). In addition, we thank publisher Jillian Gibbs and senior product developer Jane Roy. Thanks also to Kate Easton for her suggestions for the cover design of this book. Finally, and most importantly, we thank our wives—Chris, Rayna, Diane, Dawn and Debra—for their support during this project. Get Connected. Get Results. 圓 mHi McGraw-Hill Connect is a digital teaching and learning environm ent th a t improves perform ance over a variety o f critical outcomes; it is easy to use and proven to be effective. Higher Pass Rates M connect 83. 7 % Proven effective With Connect, you can complete your coursework anytime, anywhere. Connect can give you access to your assignments, eBook (within Connect Plus), videos, animations and more. Millions of students have used Connect and the results are in: research shows that studying with McGraw-Hill Connect will increase the likelihood that youll pass your course and get a better grade. Connect support t Connect includes animated tutorials, videos and additional embedded hints w ithin specific questions to help you succeed. The Connect Success Academy for Students is where you’ll find tutorials on getting started, your study resources and completing assignments in C O N N E C T 100 - Connect. Everything you need to know about Connect is here! Visual progress Connect provides you with reports to help you identify what you should study and when your next assignment is due, and tracks your 1_1丨 performance. Connects Overall Performance report allows you to see all of your assignment attempts, your score on each attempt, the date you started and submitted the assignment and the date the assignment was scored. To find out more about Connect and Connect Plus visit www.mheducation.com.au/digital/connect HIGHLIGHTS OF THIS EDITION CHAPTER 1 CHAPTER 8 ► ► Delivers a simple, concise overview of the essential Update on developments in Australian financial markets. concepts of corporate finance. ► Expanded discussion of the functions of banks. CHAPTER 2 ► Provides detailed coverage of Fisher’s Separation Theorem and the company’s objective to maximise CHAPTER 9 ► Provides greater detail on the various accelerated rights issue structures that have developed in the current value. Australian market and recent evidence on the CHAPTER 3 popularity of, and costs associated with, the main ► methods of raising equity capital. Introduces simple interest, compound interest and the time value of money in one logically structured chapter. CHAPTER 10 ► ► Greater emphasis on zero-coupon rates and the zero-rate curve. ► ► New section on pricing off the zero curve. Features a new Finance in action piece on the failure of the Banksia Financial Group. CHAPTER 4 ► ► Updating of discussion of debtor finance. Expanded overview of the growth of the debenture and corporate debt markets in Australia. Includes estimates of the Australian zero-rate curve. ► Updates Australian corporate and government ► ratings. Expanded explanation of liquidity (risk) premium approach to the term structure. BRIEF CONTENTS CHAPTER 1 CHAPTER 2 CHAPTER 3 CHAPTER 5 ► Provides international survey evidence of capital CHAPTER 4 budgeting practices. ► Features an in-depth discussion of the application CHAPTER 5 of real options analysis as well as evidence of the extent of usage of the technique. CHAPTER 6 ► Is dedicated specifically to applying methods of project evaluation. ► Includes a new section dealing specifically with how taxes should be incorporated into project evaluation techniques. CHAPTER 7 ► Updates empirical evidence concerning the market risk premium in an international and domestic context. ► Includes a detailed discussion of models that incorporate factors other than systematic risk in explaining expected returns. ► CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER CHAPTER 16 17 18 19 20 Updates estimates of the systematic risk of Australian firms. ► CHAPTER 6 Addresses alternative methods of appraising the performance of an investment portfolio. CHAPTER 21 Introduction ...................................... 1 Consumption, investment and the capital market ................................ 10 The time value of money: an introduction to financial mathematics....................................28 Applying the time value of money to security valuation ...................... 74 Project evaluation: principles and methods ......................................103 The application of project evaluation methods.................... 129 Risk and return ........................... 172 The capital market .......................210 Sources of finance: e q u ity ...........232 Sources of finance: debt ............. 275 Payout policy ...............................315 Principles of capital structure ...... 356 Capital structure decisions ..........393 The cost of capital ...................... 417 Leasing and other equipment finance ..........................................450 Capital market efficiency ............477 Futures contracts and swaps........ 507 Options and contingent claims ..563 Analysis of takeovers ..................605 Management of short-term assets: inventory .....................................646 Management of short-term assets: liquid assets and accounts receivable..................................... 666 H ighlights ^ ► Expanded discussion of convertible securities and ► of this edition Features a new Finance in action piece illustrating why they are issued. the impact of expectations in share market reaction Restructure of the discussion of preference shares. to announcements. CHAPTER 1 1 CHAPTER 17 ► Includes changes in the legal requirements for payment of dividends. ► Includes updated exchange contracts values and ► Emphasises the importance of a 'full payout' policy ► exchange indices throughout. The chapter now includes a detailed discussion ► ► and de-emphasises the dividend irrelevance theorem. of swaps, including a comprehensively revised Highlights recent evidence on the market value of discussion of interest rate swaps which emphasises franking credits. the different uses of swaps. Discusses recent research on the growing importance of share buybacks and the substitution of buybacks for dividends. 於 CHAPTER 1 8 ► relationship between an option's market price Includes an explanation of behavioural factors that and characteristics such as its term-to-expiry and may affect payout policy. ► exercise price. Features a new Finance in action piece on ANZ Bank’s dividend announcement. Includes updated examples illustrating the ► Features a Finance in action piece describing how CHAPTER 12 options written on a share price index are used to create a Volatility Index (VIX), which then provides ► useful information to investors about the level of Updates of examples. uncertainty in the market. CHAPTER 13 ► Features a new Finance in action piece on the benefits of the no-debt decision of a company that CHAPTER 19 ► ► Includes recent Australian evidence on surveys of ► activity. Includes recent empirical evidence on the costs of ► ► financial distress. Includes recent empirical evidence with respect to agency costs. ► Updates the discussion of the regulation of takeover activity. Extensively updates the empirical evidence presented on the wealth effects of alternative forms CHAPTER 14 ► Includes a new section providing survey evidence of the motives of acquiring managers for takeover chief financial officers. ► ► Updates empirical evidence on the fluctuations in takeover activity over time. had previously experienced a financial collapse. of takeovers and corporate restructuring including Updates empirical evidence on the value of the role of investor psychology in determining what imputation tax credits in Australia. an appropriate bid price may need to be in order A streamlined discussion of the impact of taxes on to ensure success of a bid. the process of project evaluation. ► Features a new Finance in action piece dealing with CHAPTER 2 0 the new approach taken by the Australian Energy ► CHAPTER 15 ► ► or advanced student. ► A new Finance in action piece on inventory management problems at Treasury W ine Estates. Updated evidence on the use of lease finance by Australian companies. CHAPTER 21 Includes a discussion of the proposed changes to the ► by the International Accounting Standards Board CHAPTER 16 Provides concise but thorough coverage of short­ term assets, focusing on liquid assets and accounts receivable, for the curious or advanced student. accounting standards relating to leases as put forward ► Provides concise but thorough coverage of short­ term assets, focusing on inventory, for the curious Regulator to estimate an appropriate weighted average cost of capital for energy distributors. ► Provides, in the appendix, a completely updated Incorporates a range of new evidence with respect comprehensive example demonstrating the application of financial statement analysis to the extent to which markets are efficient. techniques in practice. XXXIII H O W TO USE THIS B O O K L e arn in g objectives list the information you will learn by studying the chapter. They are restated in the margins in appropriate locations and so become useful revision tools. LEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: 1 understand how assets are valued under conditions of certainty m 2 use the tools of financial mathematics to value equity securities 3 explain the main differences between the valuation of ordinary shares based on dividends and on earnings 4 use the tools of financial mathematics to value debt securities 5 explain the nature of interest rate risk 6 understand the theories that are used to explain the term structure of interest rates 7 understand the effect of default risk on interest rates 8 apply the concept of duration to immunise a bond investment. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Understand how assets are valued under conditions of certainty C h ap fe r introductions give you an overview of the chapter's most important points and contextualise the topics to the wide area of business finance. Introduction I n C h a p t e r 1 w e d is c u s s e d b r ie f ly t h e im p o r t a n t c o n c e p t o f t h e t im e v a lu e o f m o n e y . I n C h a p te r 3 w e p r e s e n te d s o m e m a t h e m a t ic a l to o ls u s e f u l i n a n a ly s in g p ro b le m s in v o lv in g t h e t im e v a lu e o f m o n e y . I n p a r t i c u la r , w e s h o w e d h o w p ro m is e d s tre a m s o f f u t u r e ca sh flo w s c a n b e v a lu e d , p r o v id e d t h a t th e r e q u ir e d r a te o f r e t u r n is k n o w n . I n t h i s c h a p te r w e a p p ly th e s e to o ls t o t h e v a lu a t io n o f d e b t a n d e q u it y s e c u r itie s . I n i t i a l l y w e a s s u m e t h a t t h e s e c u r it y s f u t u r e c a s h flo w s a re k n o w n w i t h c e r ta in ty . L a t e r in t h e c h a p te r w e in tr o d u c e u n c e r t a in t y , b u t o n ly i n a lim it e d w a y . A m o re f o r m a l a n d d e ta ile d t r e a t m e n t o f u n c e r t a in t y is g iv e n in C h a p te r 6 . K e y term s are defined in the margins beside the term's first appearance in the text. These terms are then listed in the glossary at the end of the book. T h e le a s t c o m p lic a te d m e a s u re o f t h e t e r m s tr u c tu r e o f in t e r e s t ra te s is t h e m a r k e t y ie ld o n a g o v e r n m e n t b o n d t h a t p a y s n o in t e r e s t d u r in g it s lif e , b u t p a y s a fix e d s u m a t m a t u r it y . S u c h a b o n d is ZERO-COUPON BONDS (ze r o s ) bonds that pay only one cash flow, the payment at maturity k n o w n as a z e r o - c o u p o n b o n d ( o f te n a b b r e v ia te d ju s t t o a z e r o ) . T h e p ric e o f a z e ro w i t h a fa c e v a lu e o f F d o lla r s a n d a t e r m o f n y e a rs is s im p ly : P〇 = (l+z„)n Example 4. Rankine Ltd is currently paying a dividend of 90 cents per share. If investors expect this dividend to be maintained and require a rate of return of 15 per cent on the investment, what is the value of Rankine’s shares? SOLUTION The value of Rankine's shares is calculated as follows: 0 歷0 .1 5 = $ 6.00 xxxiv E x a m p le s are provided throughout the text to illustrate the practical application of the theory and working providing guidance for students. How TO USE THIS BOOK Finance in action F,NANCE ON GUARD AGAINST A BOND FALL IN ACTION ----------------------------- ------------ ------- ---- ----------------- ---------------------- ------------------- -----------In an artide published in 2013, financial journalist Christopher Joye reminds readers of interest rate risk, which flows from the connection between interest rates and bond prices. Bond traders have been making out like bandits since the global financial crisis. A portfolio of Australian government bonds with maturities longer than 10 years has delivered annual total returns of over 12 per cent since December 2007. Yet the preconditions for the mother-of-all bond market reckonings are sliding into place. This contingency, which AM P^ Shane O liver believes is a 'significant risk', could result in wiping more than $60 billion off Aussie bond values, with steep capital losses. To properly understand these risks, one needs to appreciate how extraordinary current circumstances are. W hen doing so, it helps to keep in mind a key principle: bonds that pay fixed, a$ opposed to variable, rates hove prices that are inversely related to external interest rates. If you invested in a bond paying an annual fixed coupon of, say, 3 per cent, and market interest rates surge to 5 per cent, that bond would be worth substantially less than when you bought it. The converse is also true: if market rates decline ... it would be worth more. This is why Australian government bond prices have soared since 2007: market yields have fallen sharply as global central banks have floored policy rates close to zero and printed unprecedented amounts of money to fund public and private debt. is a feature containing interesting items from the business media that relate the theory to real-world practice. Source: 'O n guard against a bond fall', Christopher Joye, Australian Financial Review, 5 January 2013, p. 39. S u m m a rie s give students a checklist of the topics covered in the chapter and SUMMARY • Financial assets such as bonds and shares can be valued by discounting their future cash flows to present values and summing these present values. The discount rate used is the required rate of return or opportunity cost of capital. • If the future cash flows from an asset are certain, the required rate of return will reflect only the effect of time on the value of money. • If the future cash flows are uncertain, investors will also require compensation for risk and the rate will be increased by the inclusion o f a risk premium. serve as a useful revision tool when preparing for exams. • • and a price-earnings ratio. The value of this ratio depends mainly on risk and expected growth in earnings. Debt securities (bonds) are priced by discounting their future coupon interest payments and face value. For any company, the interest rate required by lenders will be less than the required rate of return on the company's ordinary shares. The price of a debf security is inversely related to the interest rate required by investors. Interest rates at any given time will usually be different for different terms to maturity. This pattern is known Self-test p ro b le m s f jt at the end of selected SELF-TEST PROBLEMS 1 Richards Ltd pays annual dividends on its ordinary shares. The latest dividend was 75 cents per share and was paid yesterday. Dividends are expected to grow at 8 per cent per annum for the next 2 years, after which a growth rate of 4 per cent per annum will be maintained indefinitely. Estimate the value of one share if the required rate of return is 14 per cent per annum. 2 A government bond with a face value of $100 and a coupon interest rate of 11 per cent per annum matures in 3 years, time. Inferest payments occur twice each year and a payment has just been made. If the current market yield on the bond is 13 per cent per annum, what is the current price of the bond? 3 The current interest rates (yields) on zero-coupon government bxinds are as follows: 1 13.90 2 11.70 3 10.50 chapters cover all the topics within the chapter for thorough exam preparation. Assume that the term structure can be explained purely by expectations of future interest rates, and therefore there is no liquidity (or risk) premium. Calculate the expected 1-year rates for the next 2 years. Solutions to self-test p r o b lem s a r e a v a ila b le in A p p e n d ix B. Additional e n d -of-ch ap te r q u e stio n s a n d p ro b le m s provide further practice and cA Valuation under certainly [LO 1] A promise to pay $10000 in 4 years, time is certain to be kept. If the risk-free rate for a 4-year term is 5.5 per cent per annum, what is the value of this promise today? Do we know what the value will be in a year's time? Why or why not? 2 Valuation of shares [LO 2] Assume that today is the last day of 2014. Rednip Ltd is expected to pay annual dividends of 64 cents in 2015 (Year 1). Assume that this dividend is expected to grow at an annual rate of 10 per cent and investors require a rate of return of 20 per cent per annum, develop deeper understanding of the topics covered. They are linked back to the learning objectives for each chapter. PROBLEMS 1 a) Estimate Rednip Ltd's share price today. XXXV CHAPTER CONTENTS m Finance as an area of study 2 m The company's financial objective m Financial decisions 2 KB Fundamental concepts in finance KQ Busi门 ess structures 3 IB Outline of the book LEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: 1 describe the structure of finance as an area of study 2 identify the major decisions made by financial managers and investors 3 identify the major types of business entities 4 specify the objective of the company 5 identify and explain the fundamental concepts in finance. B usiness finance Finance as an area of study LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Describe the structure of finance as an area of study This book introduces the reader to the area o f study know n as finance. Although financial issues have been studied fo r centuries, i t is only relatively recently— in the last 50 years or so— th a t finance has emerged as an area o f study in its own rig ht, w ith a well-established body o f theory and evidence. In the chapters th a t follow, we w ill introduce you to the m ajor issues in finance. Finance can be described as having tw o m ain components, which are:1 • • corporate finance investments. Corporate finance takes the view point o f the company. The m ain issues involved are the choice o f assets, the financing decision and the dividend decision. Imagine th a t a group o f investors has set up a new company. The investors are the shareholders (that is, the owners) o f the company. The company must decide2 w hat assets i t w ill buy and how i t w ill fund the purchase o f these assets. The company may use its own m oney— th a t is, the money contributed by the shareholders— to fund the purchase, or i t may borrow the money. O r it may use b oth shareholders* funds and borrowed funds. When the company has been operating fo r a tim e, it may have made a p ro fit. I f so, it may decide to d istribute some or all o f the p ro fit to the shareholders. Such a d istrib u tio n is called a dividend. I f the dividend paid is less than the p ro fit, then some o f the p ro fit is retained w ith in the company, and w ill be used to fu nd asset acquisitions and/or debt repayment. Corporate finance is also concerned w ith corporate governance issues. For example, should the Board o f Directors include some outsiders*? Should senior managers be granted shares to encourage them to make decisions th a t are in the best interests o f the shareholders? Investments takes the view point o f the investor rather than the company. Investors are concerned about the re tu rn they w ill earn on an investm ent — the more the better. But unless investors are w illin g to take a risk, they cannot expect to earn a high return. A ll investors dream o f fin d in g an investm ent th a t produces high returns at low risk— b u t m ost w ill never fin d one. So, investors m ust make a trade­ o ff between retu rn and risk. In investm ents, this balancing o f risk and re tu rn is a m ajor issue. A large p art o f the solution is fo r investors to choose a diversified set o f assets in w hich to invest. Investments is also about the pricing o f securities such as shares and bonds. These securities are traded in financial markets, many o f which are very active, w ith transactions ru n n in g in to the m illions o f dollars every day. How does the risk o f a security affect the price at which i t w ill trade in these financial markets? W hat factors, other than risk, m ig ht also be im portant? And how m ig h t the price be expected to change in the future? Financial decisions LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 In this book we focus on financial decisions made by companies and investors. Some o f these decisions are: Corporate (or company) decisions: Identify fhe major decisions made by financial managers and investors Asset management: W hat new assets should the company acquire? How much should i t pay fo r these assets? W orking capital management: How much cash should the company hold? How much inventory? Capital structure: How much should the company borrow? Payout policy: How much should the company pay out to its shareholders? Mergers and acquisitions: Should the company take over another company? 1 2 A third component, financial markets and institutions, overlaps to some extent with corporate finance and investments. The focus o f this component is on the markets for various securities and the design of financial instruments. It also considers the financial issues faced by banks and other financial institutions. Strictly speaking, a company is just a legal structure, and hence cannot have any personal qualities, such as the ability to make decisions. Company decisions are in fact made by people such as the company s directors. However, for ease of exposition, we attribute personal qualities to companies. C hapter o ne Introduction Investor decisions: • • Portfolio theory: How can an investor achieve a better trade-off between risk and return? Asset pricing: How much is a particular security w orth? W hat is the relationship between long-term interest rates and short-term interest rates? Busi门ess structures When a business is being established, one o f the firs t decisions th a t has to be made concerns the type o f business structure th a t is to be used. In Australia, although many small businesses are sole proprietorships or partnerships, nearly all large businesses, and many thousands o f small businesses, are companies. Hence, in this book, our focus is on companies. But to place the corporate (company) form in context, we firs t discuss the advantages and disadvantages o f sole proprietorships and partnerships. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Identify the major types of business entities 1.3.1 I Sole proprietorship A sole proprietorship is a business owned by one person. M any small service businesses, retail stores and professional practices are operated as sole proprietorships. SOLE PROPRIETORSHIP business owned by one person Advantages The advantages o f a sole proprietorship structure include: • • • Control o f the business rests w ith the owner, so it is relatively easy to make decisions and there is no scope fo r disagreements between owners. I t is easy and inexpensive to form , and to dissolve. It is n o t treated as a separate e n tity fo r tax purposes. Therefore, any business p rofits belong to the owner and are taxed only once as p art o f the owner s assessable income. Disadvantages The disadvantages o f a sole proprietorship structure include: • • • It is n o t a separate legal e n tity and therefore the owner has unlim ite d lia b ility fo r debts incurred by the business. In other words, all obligations o f the business are personal obligations o f the owner. The size o f the business is lim ite d by the wealth o f the owner and by the am ount th a t can be borrowed. I t can be d ifficu lt to raise funds fo r expansion because lenders are usually reluctant to lend large amounts to individuals. Ownership o f a sole proprietorship can be transferred only by selling the business to a new owner. I f a sole proprietorship is n o t sold, then i t w ill cease to exist when the owner retires or dies. 1 .3.2! Partnership A partn ersh ip is a business owned by tw o or more people acting as partners. M any small service PARTNERSHIP businesses, retail stores and professional practices are operated as partnerships. business owned by two or more people acting as partners Advantages The advantages o f a partnership structure include: • • I t is easy and inexpensive to fo rm because there are no legal requirements th a t need to be met. A ll th a t is necessary is an agreement, preferably in w ritin g to avoid future disagreements, by those form ing the partnership. A partnership can combine the wealth and talents o f several individuals, and employees can be offered the prospect o f becoming partners (owners) in the future. B usiness finance Disadvantages There are also im p o rta n t disadvantages o f a partnership structure, including: • • • Partnerships are n o t separate legal entities and the partners are therefore personally liable for obligations (including debts) entered in to by the partnership. It can be d ifficu lt fo r partners to w ithdraw th e ir investm ent because the partnership w ill term inate i f a p artne rs interest in the partnership is sold or a partner dies. In either case, a new partnership w ill have to be formed. Disputes between partners or form er partners can be very damaging. .3 .3 1Company COMPANY separate legal entity formed under the Corporations Act 2001; shareholders are the owners of a company A com pany is a separate legal e n tity form ed under the Corporations A ct 2001. The owners o f a company are called shareholders because th e ir ownership interests are represented by shares in the company s capital. Companies vary greatly in size. They range from large companies listed on a stock exchange w ith many thousands o f shareholders to small fam ily companies carrying on a relatively small-scale business. In a large company, the shareholders and the managers are usually separate groups. The shareholders elect the Board o f Directors, which appoints managers to run the company on behalf o f the shareholders. Advantages Companies have several advantages, including: • LIMITED LIABILITY legal concept that protects shareholders whose liability to meet a company’s debts is limited to any amount unpaid on the shares they hold • • A company is a legal e n tity d istin ct from the owners, which enables it to conduct its operations in its own name. A company can buy, own and sell property; it can sue or be sued in its own name; and i t can enter into contracts w ith other entities. The shareholders o f m ost companies have lim ited liability. This means th a t i f the company fails and i t is unable to pay its debts, the owners o f fu lly paid shares are n o t obliged to contribute fu rth e r funds to meet the company s debts. However, if shares are p a rtly paid, then shareholders can be obliged to contribute any unpaid amount. A company has an indefinite life, which means that, unlike a sole proprietorship or partnership, its existence and operations are unaffected by the death or retirem ent o f its owners. The Corporations Act 2001 distinguishes between public companies, which may in vite members o f the public to invest in them, and proprietary companies, which have no such power. Public companies may be listed on a stock exchange, which facilitates trading in the company s shares. Ownership o f shares in a listed public company can be transferred very easily w ith o u t any effect on the company s operations, which are conducted by employees. Stock exchange lis tin g also makes it relatively easy fo r public companies to raise capital by issuing additional shares th a t are sold to existing shareholders or to new investors. Disadvantages The corporate form o f ownership also has some disadvantages, which include: • • • • • A company is more expensive to establish than a sole proprietorship or a partnership. A company is subject to more onerous regulation. For example, there are extensive reporting requirements, p articularly fo r listed public companies. Capital raising by companies is also highly regulated. For example, shares and other securities can be issued only i f investors are provided w ith info rm a tio n to make inform ed decisions about whether to invest in those securities. It can be d ifficu lt to m otivate managers and staff who are employees o f a company. In comparison, sole proprietorships and partnerships are managed by people who are also owners o f the business and who w ill see a direct lin k between th e ir efforts and the rewards they receive. Because a company is owned by one group (the shareholders) b ut may be run by a d ifferent group (the managers), there can be conflicts o f interest between those who own the company and those who make decisions on th e ir behalf. These conflicts result in agency costs1which are discussed fu rth e r in Section 1.5.8. The taxation treatm ent o f companies can be a disadvantage. Company profits are subject to income tax and shareholders may also be taxed when they receive dividends paid o ut o f the profits. C hapter o ne Introduction Therefore, the use o f a company structure can involve double taxation. However, the extent o f this problem depends on the type o f taxation system imposed by the government. Under Australian tax law, many shareholders are n ot subject to double taxation. Much o f this book concerns listed public companies. However, m ost o f the concepts in this book are also relevant to other form s o f business entity. There w ill, o f course, be differences in the details, depending on the e n tity s size and the nature o f its business. In addition, many o f the ideas considered in this book can be applied to n o t-fo r-p ro fit entities, including public sector entities. Rational solutions to investm ent and financing problems can only be achieved i f the company s objective is clearly specified. The objective assumed in m ost o f this book is th a t management seeks to maximise the m arket value o f the company s ordinary shares. Because an alternative term fo r shares is equityt this objective is often expressed as the m axim isation o f the m arket value o f shareholdersJequity. I t is consistent w ith the economists assumption th a t companies seek to maximise economic p ro fit. I f the m arket value o f a company s ordinary shares is maximised, then the opportunities open to the shareholders are also maximised— greater wealth implies more choices. For example, i f a shareholder wishes to sell his or her shares in order to finance greater consumption, the higher the share price, the greater are his or her consumption opportunities. In Section 1.4 we stated th a t we assume th a t management seeks to maximise the m arket value o f shareholders’ equity. To achieve this objective, the financial manager m ust understand how financial markets work. To finance a company s investments, securities, such as shares and debt securities, w ill need to be issued— th a t is, these securities w ill need to be sold to investors. Subsequently, investors may choose to sell th e ir securities to other investors in financial markets. The actions o f buyers and sellers in financial markets w ill determ ine the prices o f the securities and therefore the m arket value o f the company. The m arket value, V, o f a company may be expressed as: LEARNING OBJECTIVE 4 Specify the objective of the company LEARNING OBJECTIVE 5 Identify and explain the fundamental concepts in finance V= D+ E where D = the m arket value o f the company s debt E = the m arket value o f the company s equity (shares) The value th a t the financial markets place on a company s debt and equity securities w ill depend on the risk and expected return on investments in those securities. In tu rn , the risk and retu rn o f the securities w ill depend on the risk and return th a t the company achieves on the investments it makes in its assets. In finance, the success o f an investm ent is judged by its a b ility to generate more cash than originally outlaid on the investment. This w ill enable the company to make interest payments to lenders and repay the amount borrowed, and to make payouts, such as dividends, to shareholders. The tim e value o f money principle is based on the proposition th a t an individual w ill always prefer to receive a dollar today rather than receive a dollar at any later date. Even i f the individual does n ot want to spend the dollar today, he or she would rather receive the dollar today and then invest it, rather than receive the dollar at a later date. Therefore, a dollar is w o rth more Qess), the sooner (later) i t is to be received, all other things being equal.This principle is discussed and applied in Chapter 3. Some fu rth e r applications are considered in Chapter 4. TIME VALUE OF M ONEY principle that a dollar is worth more (less), the sooner (later) it is to be received, all other things being equal B usiness finance 1 .5 .3 1 Risk aversion RISK-AVERSE INVESTOR an investor who dislikes risk and who will only choose a risky investment if the expected return is high enough to compensate for bearing the risk In finance, i t is usually assumed th a t investors display risk aversion, which means th a t they do not like risk. Given a choice between tw o investments th a t have the same expected return, b u t one has lower risk, a risk-averse investor w ill choose the one w ith the lower risk. Risk aversion does n o t im ply that an investor w ill reject all risky investments. Rather, it implies th a t an investor w ill choose a risky investment only i f the expected retu rn on the investm ent is high enough to compensate the investor fo r bearing the risk. Because investors are risk averse, we expect th a t in the long term , the average re tu rn on high-risk investments w ill exceed the average retu rn on low -risk investm ents— i f this were n o t so, no-one would invest in the high-risk investments. For example, in the long term , shares produce higher returns than bank deposits because shares are riskier than bank deposits. The relationship between ris k and expected return is discussed in Chapter 7. The purchasing power o f money changes as a result o f price increases (inflation) and price decreases (deflation). D uring a period o f in fla tio n there is an increase in the general level o f prices, w ith a consequent decrease in the purchasing power o f money. In contrast, during a period o f deflation there is a decrease in the general level o f prices, w ith a consequent increase in the purchasing power o f money. I t is necessary, therefore, to distinguish between the nominal or face value o f money and the real or inflation-adjusted value o f money. For example, i f the annual rate o f in fla tio n is 3 per cent, the real value o f a dollar is decreasing annually by 3 per cent— th a t is, relative to the purchasing power o f a dollar today, a dollar next year w ill be w orth only 97 cents in real term s.3 Returns on investments may be measured in either nom inal or real terms. In m ost financial markets, trading is conducted in nom inal terms. Similarly, m ost financial contracts are w ritte n in nom inal terms. For example, the interest rate agreed to in a loan m ust be paid whatever the future in fla tio n rate turns out to be. Such an interest rate is called a nominal interest rate. An interest rate may also be expressed in real terms, w hich is equal to the nom inal interest rate after taking out the effect o f infla tion . I f the nom inal rate o f retu rn on an investm ent exceeds the in fla tio n rate, then the real rate o f return is positive— th a t is, the investm ent w ill increase the investors purchasing power. An efficient financial market is one composed o f numerous w ell-inform ed individuals whose trading activities cause prices to adjust instantaneously and w ith o u t bias in response to new inform ation. Price changes are therefore caused by new inform a tion becoming available. The concept o f m arket efficiency means th a t we should expect securities and other assets to be fa irly priced, given th e ir risk and expected return. In Section 1.5.3 we explained that, because investors are risk averse, higher-risk investments w ill need to offer investors higher expected returns— th a t is, in the long term , risk and expected return w ill be positively related. But w hat are the details o f this relationship? The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) provides one answer to this question. According to the CAPM, risk can be a ttributed to tw o sources: a b market-wide factors, such as changes in interest rates and foreign exchange rates— this is called systematic risk (also referred to as non-diversiftable or market risk) factors th a t are specific to a p articular company, such as the possible discovery o f a new m ineral deposit by a m ining company— this is called unsystematic risk (also referred to as diversifiable or unique risk). W hile unsystematic risk can be largely elim inated by the investor holding a well-diversified portfolio, systematic risk cannot be eliminated. A nother model th a t has been developed to measure the riskiness o f an investm ent and to establish the trade-off between risk and expected retu rn is the Fama-French model. According to the CAPM and 3 This result is an approximation. With a rate of inflation of 3 per cent per annum, $1 today is equivalent to $1.03 next year and it follows that a dollar next year is worth $1/1.03 = $0.970874 today. This issue is discussed further in Chapter 3. C hapter one Introduction the Fama-French model, risk-averse investors can diversify th e ir investments to elim inate unsystematic risk. Consequently, the m arket w ill only reward investors by offering a higher expected retu rn fo r bearing systematic or m arket risk. Both models are discussed in Chapter 7. M arket efficiency is considered in detail in Chapter 16. Derivative securities include forward contracts, futures contracts, options and swaps. In each case, the value o f the derivative security depends on the value o f some underlying security. For example, the value o f an option to buy a share in Wesfarmers Ltd depends heavily on the m arket value o f a Wesfarmers share. In this case, the option is the derivative, while the Wesfarmers share is the prim ary security, or underlying asset. Real assets, like a coal m ine or an idea fo r a new product, may also have features that resemble derivatives. For example, the owner o f a coal m ine has the option to close the m ine and reopen it later. Derivative securities are considered in Chapters 17 and 18. Arbitrage plays a central role in finance. I f two identical assets were to trade in the same market at different ARBITRAGE prices, and i f there were no transaction costs, then an arbitrage opp ortu nity would exist. A risk-free p ro fit could be made by traders simultaneously purchasing at the lower price and selling at the higher price. This situation could n ot persist because competition among traders would force up the price o f the lowerpriced asset and/or force down the price o f the higher-priced asset u n til the prices o f the two assets were the same. Arbitrage therefore precludes perfect substitutes from selling at different prices in the same market. I t follows th a t the financial prices we observe m ust be set by the financial markets in such a way th a t arbitrage is n ot possible. This idea is simple yet remarkably powerful. It has applications throughout finance in such diverse areas as the capital structure decision (how much should a company borrow?), payout policy, interna tion al finance, option pricing and the term structure o f interest rates. simultaneous transactions in different markets that result in an immediate risk-free profit In Section 1.3.3 we m entioned th a t one o f the disadvantages o f the corporate structure is the p ossibility th a t managers may pursue th e ir own objectives rather than the interests o f the shareholders. For example, a company th a t operates in a mature ind ustry where there are few grow th opportunities may have surplus cash th a t cannot be invested p rofitably in its usual fields o f operation. The company s shareholders would benefit i f the surplus were paid to them as a dividend or used to buy back shares. But the managers may decide instead to use the cash to acquire another company th a t operates in a different industry. This investm ent may benefit managers by giving them greater opportunities fo r prom otion and higher pay justified by the increase in company size. However, the acquisition may n o t increase shareholders* wealth. There can therefore be a conflict o f interest between shareholders and managers. M aking an unprofitable takeover is only one way in which managers may pursue th e ir own interests at the expense o f the shareholders. O ther examples include managers w orking less energetically than they could and managers directly diverting the company s resources to th e ir own benefit, such as by acquiring expensive company cars, taking unnecessary business trips to exotic locations, and so on. The relationship between shareholders and managers is an example o f an agency relationship. In an agency relationship, one party, the principal, delegates decision-making a u th o rity to another party, the agent. In a company run by managers, the managers are the agents and the shareholders are the principals. Shareholders are aware o f the possibility th a t managers may pursue th e ir own objectives and w ill try to lim it this behaviour by monitoring the behaviour o f managers and by in s titu tin g contracts designed to align the interests o f managers and shareholders. For example, a Board o f Directors th a t includes a significant number o f non-executive directors can be effective in m on itoring managers on behalf o f shareholders. In addition, many companies employ management remuneration schemes designed to give managers an incentive to maximise shareholders* wealth. For example, these schemes often provide senior executives, particularly the chief executive, w ith options to purchase shares in the company at an attractive price. Finally, i f agency costs are high, the company w ill probably be poorly run and, in B usiness finance consequence, its share price w ill be low and it may become a target fo r takeover. Existing managers generally fare badly when such a change o f control occurs, so the desire to avoid being taken over can also lim it the self-interested behaviour o f managers. Agency theory has been used to examine various corporate financial decisions including capital structure, dividend and share repurchase decisions, and leasing decisions. The application o f agency theory to these decisions is discussed in Chapters 1 1 ,1 2 ,1 3 and 15. O utline of the book The ideas introduced in this chapter are developed in the remainder o f the book. • • • • • • • In Chapters 2 to 7, fundam ental concepts underlying finance theory are developed. Chapters 8, 9 and 10 consider sources o f finance fo r companies, and the in s titu tio n a l framework in which financing decisions are made. In Chapters 1 1,12 and 13, payout decisions and financing decisions are discussed. Chapter 14 then considers the measurement o f the cost o f capital to be used in project evaluation, while Chapter 15 provides an analysis o f leases. Chapter 16 reviews the literature on m arket efficiency, while Chapters 17 and 18 consider futures contracts and options respectively. Chapter 19 reviews the theory and evidence on takeovers. In Chapters 20 and 21 the principles outlined earlier in the book are applied to short-term asset management, including inventory, cash and accounts receivable. awldvHu M3IA3W 3M〇 SUMMARY In this chapter, we have introduced the key themes to be addressed in the book. • The two main components of finance are corporate finance and investments. This book focuses on financial decisions made by companies (corporate decisions), w hich include asset and w orking capital management decisions, capital structure and borrow ing decisions, payout policy and merger and acquisition decisions; and financial decisions made by investors (investor decisions), including portfolio and risk decisions and asset pricing decisions. KEY TERMS arbitrage 7 company 4 limited liability 4 partnership 3 8 The objective assumed in most of this book is that management seeks to maximise the market value of the company's ordinary shares (shareholders' equity). To do this, the financial manager must understand how financial markets work. The fundamental concepts in finance include value, the time value of money, risk aversion, nominal versus real values, market efficiency and asset pricing, derivative securities, arbitrage and agency relationships. The market value (V) of a company can be expressed as the market value of the company's debt (D) plus the market value of the company's equity (£). risk-averse investor 6 sole proprietorship 3 time value of money 5 C hapter o ne Introduction QUESTIONS 1 [LO 2】Distinguish between investment decisions and financing decisions. 2 [LO 3] Explain the following: a) a sole proprietorship b) a partnership c) a company. 3 [LO 3] Outline the advantages and disadvantages of a sole proprietorship. 4 [LO 3] Outline the advantages and disadvantages of a partnership. 5 [LO 3] W hat advantages does a company have over a sole proprietorship and a partnership? 6 [LO 3] W hich types o f investors have limited liability? Explain your answer. 7 [LO 5] W h y do people usually prefer to receive $1 today instead of in a year's time? 8 [LO 5 】 Comment on this statement: A company should borrow during times o f high inflation because it con repay the loan in cheaper dollars. 9 [LO 5] W h a t is the relationship between diversifiable and non-diversifiable risk? How does this distinction affect the reward that investors receive for bearing risk? CHAPTER O N E REVIEW itu 10 [L0 5] W h a t is meant by the term 'efficient market'? How does competition between traders promote efficiency? 11 [LO 5] W h a t is meant by the term 'arbitrage7? 12 [L0 5] W h a t is meant by the term 'agency relationships'? 9 CHAPTER TWO Consumption, investment and the capital market CHAPTER CONTENTS HI Introduction Fisher’s Separation Theorem: a sim plified exam ple 11 ii BS m Fisher's Separation Theorem: a form al a pproach 14 Investors' reactions to m anagers' decisions 24 LEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: 1 explain how a com pany's m anagers can, in principle, make financial decisions that w ill be supported by all shareholders 2 explain how the existence o f a capital m arket makes it possible for the com pany to make decisions acceptable to all shareholders 3 命 identify a com pany's optim al investm ent/dividend p olicy under conditions o f certainty. C hapter t w o C o n s u m p t io n , investment a n d the capital market ^ ^ J ~ ln t r o d u c t io n In this chapter we present a theoretical fram ework, know n as ‘Fisher’s Separation Theorem’,th a t shows im p orta nt relationships between companies, th e ir shareholders and the capital m arket. We use this fram ework to make some observations on investm ent decisions, financing decisions and dividend policy. Although the fram ework we present is simple and rather abstract, it provides im p o rta n t insights into some fundam ental issues in finance. To introduce the framework, we present in Section 2.2 a sim plified numerical example th a t captures many o f the m ain lessons o f the theorem. Readers who do n o t wish to develop a detailed technical understanding o f the theorem may wish to read only Section 2.2. Fishers Separation Theorem can be traced to the w ork o f Irv in g Fisher1 2 and is widely regarded as laying a foundation fo r many fundam ental results o f finance theory. The theorem considers the follow ing situation. Suppose th a t a company has to decide how much it should pay to its shareholders in dividends and how much it should retain fo r investm ent in the company. The more the company pays out in dividends, the less there is available fo r investm ent; the more the company invests, the less there is available to pay out as dividends. M ig h t some shareholders want high dividends (and therefore low investment), while other shareholders w ant ju s t the opposite? I f so, w ill the company be forced to make a decision that w ill disappoint some o f its shareholders? Fishers answers are, yes, there may be this type o f disagreement among the shareholders b ut, no, i f there is a capital m arket then there is a way to please all shareholders. In this section, we outline a sim plified example o f Fishers Separation Theorem th a t preserves much o f its flavour b u t is based on in tu itio n rather than a rigorous, technical approach. Assume th a t a company is operating under conditions o f certainty, th a t there are tw o tim e dates (‘now, and ‘later’)and th a t there are tw o equal shareholders (‘A ’ and ‘B’). The company m ust decide3 how much o f its current resources i t should invest and how much it should pay out as a current dividend. An investm ent now generates a retu rn later, and the company then pays out all its resources as a final dividend. Shareholders can use th e ir dividends to finance consumption. In itially, there is no capital m arket b ut at a later stage in the analysis i t is assumed th a t transactions in a capital m arket are possible. The existence o f the capital m arket enables individuals (including the shareholders A and B) to borrow and lend fo r one period at a fixed interest rate. It is fu rth e r assumed th a t the company has $8000 in resources and has identified tw o possible investm ent projects called ‘Project Small’ and ‘Project Upgrade’. • • Project Small requires an in itia l outlay o f $5000 now and w ill produce a cash inflow o f $5700 later. Project Upgrade requires a further outlay o f $2000 now and w ill produce a further cash inflo w o f $2200 later. I t is also assumed th a t it is impossible to invest only in Project Upgrade. Together, projects Small and Upgrade constitute P roject Large*. Clearly, Project Large requires an outlay o f $5000 + $2000 = $7000 now and w ill produce a cash inflo w o f $5700 + $2200 = $7900 later. I f the company invests only in Project 1 2 3 This section is drawn from Brown (1996). Fisher (1930). See also Hirshleifer (1970). In fact, decisions are made by managers rather than by an inanimate company* but for ease of expression we frequently refer to a company making a decision. We have assumed that managers will seek to maximise the interests of the shareholders. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Explain how a company's managers can, in principle, make financial decisions that will be supported by all shareholders B usiness finance Small, it can pay a dividend o f $8000 - $5000 = $3000 now b u t i f it invests in Project Large, i t can pay a dividend o f only $8000 - $7000 = $1000 now. This situation is summarised in Table 2.1. TABLE 2.1 Investment/dividend opportunities facing the company Project Investment outlay now ($) Dividend now (equals $8000 minus outlay) ($) Dividend later ($) Small 5000 3000 5700 Upgrade 2000 n.a.(a) 2200 Large 7000 1000 7900 Not applicable because Project Upgrade is not a stand-alone project. 2 .2 .3 1 The shareholders' consumption opportunities and preferences Recalling th a t Shareholders A and B hold equal shares, the consumption opportunities each faces are equal to h a lf the to ta l dividends paid by the company as shown in Table 2.1. For sim plicity, i t is also assumed th a t a dividend paid now cannot be stored in order to finance consumption later.4 The consumption o pportunities facing each shareholder are shown in Table 2.2. TABLE 2.2 Consumption opportunities facing each shareholder Project selected by the company Consumption per shareholder now ($) Consumption per shareholder later ($) Small 1500 2850 Large 500 3950 Suppose th a t Shareholder A wishes to consume $1500 now, w hile Shareholder B wishes to consume only $500 now. Thus, Shareholder A wants a relatively high dividend now and therefore wants the company to invest in Project Small. Shareholder B, o f course, is in the opposite position. Desiring only a low level o f consumption now, Shareholder B wants the company to adopt a high level o f investm ent and thus wants the company to invest in Project Large. Clearly, the company cannot make a decision that w ill satisfy b oth shareholders simultaneously and therefore i t is n o t possible to say which investm ent is optim al. The company w ill be forced to make a decision th a t w ill be opposed by one o f its tw o shareholders. 2 .2 .4 1 Solution: introduce a capital market LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Explain how the existence of a capital market makes it possible for the company to make decisions acceptable to all shareholders 命 A solution can be found i f there is a capital m arket in which the shareholders can borrow and lend on th e ir personal accounts. In this example, it is assumed th a t the interest rate in the capital m arket is 12 per cent per period. I t is now possible to state th a t there is an optim al decision th a t w ill be supported by b oth shareholders. This decision is th a t the company should invest in Project Small and should reject the o pp o rtu n ity to invest in the upgrade th a t w ill convert Project Small to Project Large. In other words, allowing Shareholder B access to the capital m arket has caused B to change his or her support from w anting the company to invest in Project Large to w anting the company to invest in Project Small. 4 This assumption simplifies the analysis but is not necessary. It is a simple matter to permit resources to be carried from one period to the next. In the absence of a capital market, resources can be carried forward in time at an interest rate of zero. However, any consumption opportunities opened up by allowing resources to be carried forward at an interest rate of zero will be more restricted than the opportunities that become available when a capital market is introduced and interest rates are positive. C hapter t w o C o n s u m p t io n , investment a n d the capital market How do we know Shareholder B w ill react in this way? The answer is th a t the capital m arket allows Shareholder B to make financial arrangements that, from Bs view point, provide an even better outcome than is possible i f the company invests in Project Large. This result can be proved as follows. When the company invests in Project Small, Shareholder B w ill receive a current dividend o f $1500. This w ill finance Bs desired current consum ption o f $500, w ith $1000 le ft over. This sum o f $1000 can be le n t in the capital m arket fo r one period at an interest rate o f 12 per cent, thus producing a later cash in flo w to B o f $1000 x 1.12 = $1120. This sum can then be added to the future dividend o f $2850. Therefore, on the later date, Shareholder B can consume resources to the value o f $1120 + $2850 = $3970. If, instead, Project Large were undertaken, Shareholder B could consume only $3950 on the later date (see Table 2.2). Therefore, provided there is a capital market, the shareholders w ill be unanimous and the company can make investm ent and dividend decisions confident th a t these decisions are optim al from the view point o f all shareholders. 2 .2 .5 1 An analysis using rates of return The analysis can be recast in terms o f rates o f return. The rates o f retu rn on the projects are: Project Small: $5700-5000 Project Upgrade: $5000 $2 2 0 0 -2 0 0 0 $2000 14% = 10% Comparing these rates o f retu rn w ith the interest rate o f 12 per cent, the optim al decision is to accept Project Small (because 14 per cent exceeds 12 per cent) and to reject Project Upgrade (because 10 per cent is less than 12 per cent). In effect, the cost o f investing is the o pp o rtu n ity cost o f forgoing the capital m arket return o f 12 per cent. For Project Small, the benefit (14 per cent) exceeds the o pp o rtu n ity cost (12 per cent), while fo r Project Upgrade the benefit (10 per cent) is lower than the o pp o rtu n ity cost (12 per cent). Note also th a t while the apparent rate o f retu rn on Project Large is ($7900 - $7000)/$7000 = 12.86 per cent, this rate o f retu rn is in fact a weighted average o f the rates o f retu rn on the component projects Small and Upgrade. I t is not valid to suggest th a t the company should invest in Project Large merely because 12.86 per cent exceeds 12 per cent. 2.2.61 A solution requiring borrowing In Section 2.2.4, the interest rate (12 per cent) fell between the rates o f retu rn on Project Small (14 per cent) and Project Upgrade (10 per cent). Therefore, Project Small was accepted and, in tu rn , this decision required Shareholder B to lend in the capital m arket. I f the interest rate had been lower than the rate o f return on both projects— say i t had been 9 per cent— then the optim al decision would have been to invest in both projects. In other words, Project Large would have been accepted. Therefore, the current dividend would have been only $500 per shareholder. W hile this decision would clearly have won the support o f Shareholder B, who wishes to consume only $500 now, a current dividend o f $500 per shareholder w ill be insufficient fo r Shareholder A to finance his or her desired current consumption o f $1500. In this case, Shareholder A m ust borrow $1000 from the capital m arket. A t an interest rate o f 9 per cent per period, the required repayment later is $1000 x 1.09 = $1090. This am ount is paid out o f the later dividend o f $3950, thus leaving Shareholder A w ith $3950 - $1090 = $2860 to finance later consumption. This level exceeds the $2850 o f later consum ption th a t would have been available to Shareholder A i f the company had invested in only Project Small. Therefore, Shareholder A w ill also support the decision to invest in Project Large and there is again a unanimous decision. 2 .2 .7 1 Fisher's Separation Theorem and net present value The problem facing the company s manager can also be solved by calculating a measure know n as a projects *net present value* (NPV). This measure is extremely im p o rta n t and is referred to in a num ber o f later chapters. It is discussed in detail in Chapter 5. A t this p o in t we provide only a very b rie f introduction. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Identify a company's optimal investment/ dividend policy under conditions of certainty B usiness finance To calculate a projects net present value, we firs t use the projects required rate o f retu rn to convert future cash flows to th e ir equivalent values today. We then subtract the in itia l outlay required. I f the result is a positive number, then the project is an acceptable investm ent; i f the result is a negative number, then the project is n o t acceptable. In the in itia l example o f Project Small and Project Upgrade presented in Section 2.2.4, the interest rate in the capital m arket is 12 per cent. In this example, it is also the required rate o f retu rn on the project. The net present value calculations are: iV W o f Project Small = ---------- $5000 = $89.29 > 0 1.12 N P V o f Project Upgrade = 1.12 - $2000 = -$35.71 < 0 Project Small is an acceptable investm ent because its NPV is positive, while Project Upgrade is not an acceptable investm ent because its NPV is negative. Thus, use o f the NPV rule has led to the same investm ent decision as we discussed earlier in Section 2.2.4. N ot only does an optim al decision exist, it can also be found by applying the NPV rule. 2 .2 .8 | Fisher’s Separation Theorem: summary LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Explain how a company’s managers can, in principle, make financial decisions that will be supported by all shareholders In the absence o f a capital market, the shareholders disagreed on what decisions the company should make on th e ir behalf. This problem could be solved* only by imposing a solution to the detrim ent o f one o f the shareholders. But i f there is a capital m arket, the shareholders are sure to reach a unanimous decision. Thus, there is an optim al investm ent/dividend decision. This resolution is possible because the existence o f the capital m arket enables one o f the shareholders to achieve a result th a t fo r h im or her was indisputably b etter than the result th a t the company alone could provide, given the investm ent o pportunities available. An o ptim al decision exists, and can be identified by the company s managers i f they use the net present value (NPV) rule to analyse investm ent proposals. 2.3 Fisher’s Separation Theorem: a formal approach The conclusions th a t we reached largely by in tu itio n in Section 2.2 are reached in a more rigorous fashion in this section. 2.3.1 | Assumptions The assumed objective o f a company is to maximise the m arket value o f its ordinary shares. A company s managers, therefore, have to make investment, financing and dividend decisions consistent w ith that objective. The managers* job would be easier i f there were a consistent set o f decision rules th a t could be employed in m aking investm ent, financing and dividend decisions. The w ork o f Irv in g Fisher provides a fram ework in which such rules can be developed. In itia lly these decision rules are developed in a very sim plified setting. However, the decision rules are applicable even when more realistic assumptions are made. The assumptions in Fishers analysis are: a b C d e 命 There are only two points in tim e: the present (Time 1) and a later tim e (Time 2). There is no uncertainty, and hence the outcome o f all decisions is know n now to everybody. There are no imperfections in the capital market, A ll decision makers are rational. The company s managers wish to use the company s resources according to the wishes o f the shareholders. C hapter t w o C o n s u m p t io n , investment a n d the capital market 2 .3 .2 |T h e company The company is endowed w ith a fixed am ount o f resources at Time 1 and the managers have to decide how much o f these resources should be invested and how much should be paid out as dividends. Any resources not paid out at Time 1 are invested, and the level o f this investm ent determines the resources available to pay dividends at Time 2. The opportunities available to the company are summarised in a production p o ssib ilities curve (PPC) as illustrated in Figure 2.1. Figure 2.1 Production possibilities curve PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES CURVE curve that displays the investment opportunities and outcomes available to the company; its shape therefore determines the combinations of current dividends, investments and future dividends that a company can achieve l^l s8Jno 0s EJ 9J (N l— The horizontal axis measures resources available to the company at Time 1. Assume th a t the company has 200 units o f resources available to it. It could pay this am ount as a dividend at Time 1. In this case, investm ent would be zero and dividends at Time 2 w ould also be zero. The p oint (200, 0) represents this extreme decision. A t the other extreme, the company could pay no dividend at Time 1 and invest the whole o f the company s resources. This decision would result in 250 units being available fo r d is trib u tio n as a dividend at Time 2 and is represented by the p o in t (0, 250). Point Q is an interm ediate case in which a dividend o f 150 units is paid at Time 1, leaving 50 units to be invested. The PPC shows th a t an investm ent o f 50 units at Time 1 can be transform ed in to 160 units o f resources at Time 2. Therefore the dividend at Time 2 is 160 units. INDIFFERENCE CURVE 2 .3 .3 |T h e shareholders Shareholders forgo current consumption by investing in the company at Time 1 in order to receive a retu rn th a t then increases th e ir consum ption o pportunities at Time 2. A persons preference fo r consumption at Time 1 (Cj) or at Time 2 (C2) is represented by indifference curves as depicted in Figure 2.2. The term indifference indicates th a t the person derives equal u tility from the bundles o f C and C2 represented curve showing a set of combinations such that an individual derives equal utility from (and thus is indifferent between) any combinations in the set A B usiness finance by all points on a single curve; fo r example, equal u tility is derived from points X and Y in Figure 2.2. However, any p o in t on a higher indifference curve is preferred to all points on lower curves; fo r example, Z is preferred to X and Y. The slope o f an indifference curve at any p o in t shows the consumer s willingness to trade o ff Cx fo r C2. I t can be seen from Figure 2.2 th a t the indifference curves are convex; they approach the horizontal as the level o f C1 increases and approach the vertical as the level o f C2 increases. The im plication is th a t a consumers desire to increase consumption fu rth e r at a given tim e decreases as the level o f consumption at th a t tim e increases. :igure 2.2 Indifference curves of a representative shareholder 2 .3 .4 1 The company’s decision We now b ring together the company and the shareholders in an attem pt to id e n tify the decision the company should make. We assume th a t there are two shareholders, and (B\ In Figure 2.3, indifference curves fo r Shareholder A are labelled A v A 2 and A 3 and indifference curves fo r Shareholder B are labelled Bv B2 and B3. I f the company chooses p o in t A — th a t is, a current dividend o f 90 and investm ent o f 110, yielding a dividend o f 228 at Time 2— then shareholder As u tility is maximised. However, Shareholder Bs u tility is n o t maximised at this point; i t is maximised only i f the company chooses p o in t B. This requires a current dividend o f 160 and investm ent o f 40, yielding a dividend o f 144 at Time 2. In short, the company is unable to reach a decision th a t w ill lead simultaneously to m axim um u tility fo r both shareholders. This situation poses a severe dilemma fo r the company because i t means th a t the company m ust consider the preferences o f each o f its shareholders when m aking investm ent decisions. In other words, there is no simple decision rule th a t w ill satisfy all shareholders. Such a rule does exist, however, i f there is a capital market. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Explain how the existence of a capital market makes it possible for the company to make decisions acceptable to all shareholders 命 2.3^5| Soluti on: introduce a capital market In this simple model, the capital m arket can be thought o f as a place where current resources may be transform ed into future resources and vice versa. The rate at which these transform ations may be made is in effect an interest rate. We assume th a t the capital m arket is frictionless, and therefore the interest rate fo r borrowers is equal to the interest rate fo r lenders. For example, i f the interest rate is 10 per cent C hapter t w o C o n s u m p t io n , 90 160 investment a n d the capital market 200*2 0 5 Time 1 resources ( q i per period, and 100 u nits o f current resources are placed w ith the capital m arket fo r one period, then 100 x 1.1 = 110 units o f resources become available at Time 2. In effect, this is lending to the capital market. Similarly, i f a person has a claim to receive 110 units o f resources at Time 2, the capital m arket may be used to transform this claim in to 110/1.1 = 100 units o f resources at Time 1. This transaction corresponds to a person borrow ing 100 units at Time 1 and repaying the loan w ith a payment o f 110 u nits at Time 2. Suppose th a t a person has claims on resources in both periods. For example, a person may have an income o f 100 units at Time 1 and an income o f 165 units at Time 2. W hat consumption opportunities are available i f the interest rate is 10 per cent per period? A t one extreme, the person may choose to consume only at Time 2. In this case, consumption at Time 1 is zero and consumption at Time 2 is 165 + 100 x 1.1 = 275 units. A t the other extreme, the person may choose to consume only at Time 1. In this case, consum ption at Time 2 is zero and consum ption at Time 1 is (165/1.1) + 100 = 250 units. Therefore, this persons claim on current resources is 250 units. In short, this persons wealth at Time 1 is 250 units. Figure 2.4 illustrates this case. The line join in g these tw o extreme positions is shown in Figure 2.4 and may be called a m arket opportunity line as i t defines all combinations o f consumption possibilities at the tw o Times, consistent w ith an in itia l wealth level o f 250 units. I f a person can reach any one p o in t on this line, then by borrow ing or lending, all other points on the line are also available to the person. For example, i f a person can reach point A (100 units at Time 1 and 165 units at Time 2), then the person can also reach p o in t (140 units at Time 1 and 121 units at Time 2), by borrow ing 40 units today and repaying 44 units at Time 2. The equation o f a m arket o pp o rtu n ity line can be derived as follows. I f a persons income at Time 1 is Cx and at Time 2 is C2, and the interest rate is i per period, then the persons wealth W1 at Time 1 is: … ^ C2 MARKET OPPORTUNITY LINE line that shows the combinations of current and future consumption that an individual can achieve from a given wealth level, using capital market transactions B usiness finance Figure 2.4 Market opportunity line Equivalently, this equation can be w ritte n as: W \(l + /) = C“ 1 + /) + C2 or C2 = - ( l + i)C 1 + Wl ( l + i) This is a linear equation w ith slope -(1 + 〇 and intercept ^ ( 1 + i). W ith a current wealth level o f 250 and an interest rate o f 10 per cent per period the equation is: C2 = - ( 1 + 0.1)C1 + 250(1.1) and therefore C2 = - l . l C 1 + 275 To illustrate fu rth e r the interpretatio n o f m arket o pp o rtu n ity lines, suppose th a t the person is offered a choice o f two income streams, A or B. Stream A consists o f 100 units at Time 1 and 165 units at Time 2, w hile Stream B consists o f 120 units at Time 1 and 55 units at Time 2. I t has already been shown that i f the interest rate is 10 per cent, Stream A corresponds to a wealth level o f 250 units at Time 1 and the equation o f the m arket o pp o rtu n ity line is C2 = -1.1C 1 + 275. The wealth level corresponding to Stream B is 120 + 55/1.1 = 170 units. The equation o f the m arket o pp o rtu n ity line fo r Stream B is C2 = -1.1C1 + 187. These lines, together w ith the persons indifference curves, are shown in Figure 2.5. Figure 2.5 shows th a t this person w ill maximise u tility by accepting income Stream A and then use a capital m arket transaction to convert Stream A to Stream A \ As we have seen, Stream A provides an income o f 100 units at Time 1 and 165 units at Time 2, and a wealth level o f 250 units. The person then enters the capital m arket and borrows 40 units at Time 1, achieving a consumption level o f 140 units at Time 1. In return, the persons claim on Time 2 resources is reduced by 44 units (fro m 165 units to 121 units). The loan repayment required at Time 2 is, o f course, 44 units (since 40 x 1.1 = 44). 命 C hapter t w o C o n s u m p tio n , investment a n d the capital market Figure 2.5 Consumption opportunities offered by two wealth levels Had Stream B been accepted, the optim al p o in t would have been B \ which could have been achieved by lending 120 - 80 = 40 units at Time 1 and consuming 55 + (40)(1.1) = 99 units at Time 2. However, p o in t is on a lower indifference curve than p o in t A / and therefore yields lower u tility . To summarise: Stream A should be chosen because i t corresponds to a higher wealth level, which, in tu rn , ensures th a t higher u tility can be achieved, given access to a capital market. 2 .3 .6 1 Proving there is an optimal policy Fishers Separation Theorem provides the optim al solution and involves all three elements: the company, the shareholders and the capital market. Suppose th a t the company has E units o f resources and is considering three investm ent/dividend policies, shown in Figure 2.6 as points Pv P2 and P. A m arket o pp ortu nity line w ith slope -(1 + z) has been drawn through each o f the three points. The line through P1 shows th a t i f policy P1 were adopted, the shareholders* wealth would increase from E to Wv Similarly, i f policy P2 were adopted, the shareholders* wealth would increase to W2i and i f policy P were adopted, the shareholders’ wealth would be PV. Because the u tility o f shareholders depends directly on th eir wealth, they w ill unanim ously prefer policy P because the resulting wealth level W is the maximum achievable. Relative to policy P, i t is clear th a t represents too little investm ent by the company, whereas P2 represents too much investm ent by the company. Policy P, which occurs at the p o in t o f tangency between the PPC and the m arket o p p o rtu n ity line, is the optim al policy fo r the company and w ill receive the support o f all shareholders. This result may be shown more form ally by superimposing representative indifference curves fo r shareholders A and B on Figure 2.6. This is shown in Figure 2.7. The company chooses policy P; th a t is, i t invests (E - C p and pays dividends o f C* at Time 1 and C*2 at Time 2. Shareholder A enters the capital m arket and lends resources so th a t this shareholders personal optim al p oint PA is reached. Shareholder B borrows from the capital m arket in order to reach PB, which B usiness finance Figure 2.6 Effect of company policy on shareholder wealth Figure 2.7 Fisher’s Separation Theorem: two shareholders with access to a capital market is Bs personal optim al p oint. A ny policy other than P w ill result in lower u tility fo r both shareholders. For example, i f the company were to choose policy Pv then Shareholder As m axim um u tility would occur at p o in t P^, which is on a lower indifference curve than p o in t PA, w hile Shareholder Bs m axim um u tility would occur at p o in t P^, which is on a lower indifference curve than p o in t PB. The same conclusion holds i f the company were to choose policy P2. There is, therefore, just one policy P th a t w ill maximise the u tility o f all shareholders simultaneously. Regardless o f differences in th e ir u tility functions (preferences), all shareholders w ill support the company s decision to choose policy P. In this sense, the company and its shareholders are separate. The company does not need to consult each shareholder before it makes its decision because it knows in C hapter t w o C o n s u m p tio n , investment advance th a t all shareholders, regardless o f differences in th e ir personal preferences, w ill support the choice o f policy P. Since policy P does n o t require knowledge o f any shareholders u tility function, it follows th a t P m ig ht be identifiable using data directly available to the company. That this is in fact the case is proved in the follow ing section. 2 .3 .7 | Identifying the optimal policy Suppose th a t a company is endowed w ith E units o f current resources and is considering a num ber o f small investm ent projects, each requiring an outlay o f A units o f resources. I t has compiled a lis t o f these projects, ranked from the highest rate o f return to the lowest. The project w ith the highest rate o f retu rn w ill return C2 units at Tim e 2. The company proposes the follow ing decision rule: accept the project i f and only if: R e tu m a tT im e 2 _ A > 〇 This is illustrated in Figure 2.8. Figure 2.8 I t is clear from Figure 2.8 th a t C; > △ (1 + f) and therefore: Under the proposed rule, the project is accepted. Fishers Separation Theorem also recommends acceptance since policy P has n ot yet been achieved. Now consider the second project, w hich also requires an outlay o f A and which returns Cf, 2 at Time 2. Reading from Figure 2.8, it is found that: C2 + C2 〉 C*2 + △(!■ + /) and therefore Both Fishers Separation Theorem and the decision rule recommend acceptance o f this second project. Projects w ill continue to be accepted u n til policy P is reached. Beyond th a t point, both the theorem and the rule recommend rejection o f all fu rth e r projects on the list. This is shown in Figure 2.9. B usiness finance Reading from Figure 2.9 it is found that: C2 " + A(1 + i) > C2 " + C2 " and therefore -△ < 0 Therefore, both the proposed rule and the theorem recommend rejection o f this project. The proposed rule and the theorem are completely consistent. A ll projects th a t are acceptable according to the theorem are also acceptable according to the rule. A ll projects rejected by the theorem are also rejected by the rule. Therefore, a company th a t always applies this rule to its investm ent decisions w ill be able to locate the optim al investm ent/dividend policy and w ill maximise the wealth o f its shareholders. In tu rn , the shareholders can use the capital m arket to achieve th e ir preferred consum ption patterns and thereby maximise u tility. The name given to this rule is the net present value rule. The retu rn next period is divided by the factor (1 + z) to convert the future retu rn in to a present value. The investm ent outlay is then subtracted from the present value to give the net present value (iVPV). I f the iVPVis positive, the project w ill increase the wealth o f the shareholders and should therefore be accepted. I f the NPV is negative, the project w ill decrease the wealth o f the shareholders and should therefore be rejected. The NPV rule is frequently used in practice and is considered fu rth e r in Chapter 5. 2 .3 .8 1 Implications for financial decision making A num ber o f im plications fo r investm ent, financing and dividend decisions can be drawn from Fishers analysis. These im plications w ill hold where there are perfect markets fo r both capital and inform ation. However, Fishers analysis is unaffected by the intro du ction o f uncertainty, provided it is assumed that all participants have the same expectations.5 Further, although the presentation o f Fishers analysis has 5 Fama and Miller (1972, pp. 301-4). C hapter t w o C o n s u m p t io n , investment a n d the capital market been confined to a case involving only tw o periods, its im plications are unaffected by extension to the m ultiperiod case.6 The investment decision Fishers Separation Theorem means th a t a company can make investm ent decisions in the interests o f every shareholder,regardless o f differences between shareholders’ preferences— th a t is, a company can make an investm ent decision w ith which every shareholder w ill agree. Moreover, there is a rule th a t w ill ide ntify th a t decision: a company should invest up to the p o in t where the net present value o f the marginal u n it o f investm ent is zero. In this simple model, an equivalent rule is to invest up to the p o in t where the rate o f retu rn on the m arginal u n it o f investm ent equals the m arket interest rate. These tw o rules and other commonly implem ented investm ent evaluation techniques are considered in Chapter 5 in the context o f certainty. This discussion is extended in Chapter 6 to investm ent evaluation where there is uncertainty. The financing decision In Fishers analysis there is a single m arket interest rate. In effect, there is no d istinction between debt and equity securities, and the cost to the company o f acquiring funds is independent o f the type o f security issued. I t follows th a t the value o f the company and the wealth o f its shareholders are independent o f the company’s capital structure. As a result, the financing decision can be described as ‘irrelevant’. When the financing decision is discussed in Chapter 12 this result is confirm ed in a less restrictive framework. The dividend decision In Fishers analysis, all resources n ot invested at Time 1 are distributed to shareholders as dividends, and all returns at Time 2 are also distributed as dividends_ th a t is, it is assumed th a t the company does not borrow or lend in the capital market, although its shareholders may do so. Suppose, however, that the company is perm itted to borrow o r lend in the capital market. In th a t case, the company has greater choice in its dividend policy, while m aintaining the same level o f investm ent. For example, the company could pay a higher dividend at Time 1 and borrow the resources needed to m aintain investm ent at the optim al level given by the p o in t o f tangency between the PPC and the m arket o p p o rtu n ity line. This is illustrated in Figure 2.10. ure 2.10 6 ibid” pp. 64-7. B usiness finance Compared w ith the basic Fisher analysis (Fig. 2.7), the company in Figure 2.10 pays a larger dividend at Time 1 (C**> C^) and a smaller dividend at Time 2 (C^* < C*2). To m aintain the company s investment level at E - C*, the company borrows C** - C\ from the capital m arket. A t Time 2 the company s gross retu rn is b u t the loan repayment reduces the net retu rn at Time 2 to C^. In short, the company、 investm ent decision is unchanged b ut its dividend decision is different. The im p o rta n t p o in t to note is th a t the new policy Pr lies on the same m arket o pp o rtu n ity line as the original *Fisher policy* P and therefore the wealth o f shareholders is unchanged. The ability o f shareholders to maximise th e ir u tility is also unchanged. As explained previously, i f any one p o in t on a m arket o p p o rtu n ity line is attainable, then, by borrow ing or lending, all other points on the line are also attainable. From the shareholders’ p o in t o f view, therefore, p o in t Pr is no b etter or worse than p o in t P. In summary, provided th a t the company does n o t alter its investm ent decision, the dividend decision does n o t affect shareholders* wealth. In this sense dividend policy is irrelevant. This proposition is discussed fu rth e r in Chapter 11. 2.4 Investors' reactions to managers/ decisions The lin k between decisions made by a company s managers and the resultant actions by investors is illustrated in Figure 2.11. Figure 2.11 supplies funds to transact in A company s managers may, on behalf o f the company, make an investm ent decision, a financing decision o r a dividend decision. In fo rm atio n about this decision is transm itted to investors. On the basis o f this inform ation, investors may adjust th e ir expectations o f future returns from an investm ent in the company, and revise th e ir valuation o f the company s shares. Investors w ill then compare the current m arket price o f the company s shares w ith th e ir revised valuation and either buy or sell shares in the company. Investors* actions in the share m arket w ill determ ine the new m arket price o f the company s shares. 令 C hapter t w o C o n s u m p t io n , investment a n d the capital market Pursuing a goal o f m axim ising the m arket value o f a company s shares is easy when there are no m arket imperfections and no uncertainty. Managers know w ith certainty an investm ents cash flows and its net present value. Therefore, they w ill know whether acceptance o f the investm ent w ill increase the m arket value o f the company s shares. As all investors also know the investm ents net present value, there w ill be an immediate increase in the price o f the company s shares to reflect the resulting increase in the wealth o f the company. Further, managers and investors know th a t financing and dividend decisions are irrelevant and therefore these decisions w ill have no effect on the m arket value o f the comp any s shares. In practice there is uncertainty. W hat effect w ill the acceptance o f an investm ent proposal have on the m arket value o f a company s shares? As is illustrated in Figure 2.11, any change in the company s share price w ill depend on the reaction o f investors to the decisions made by the managers. Obviously there can be no reaction unless investors obtain inform a tion about th a t decision. When there is uncertainty, the effect on the share price o f decisions made by managers is no longer perfectly predictable. A sim plification is to assume that everyone agrees about the probability d istrib u tio n o f the outcomes o f all decisions. This means th a t although there is uncertainty, the exact nature o f th a t uncertainty is agreed on by all. In this case, when investors obtain inform ation, the share price w ill adjust im m ediately to reflect the new best estimate o f the ‘tru e ’ value o f the company. Sufficient conditions fo r this to arise are: *... a m arket in which (i) there are no transaction costs in trading securities, (ii) all available inform a tion is costlessly available to all m arket participants and (iii) all agree on the im plications o f current inform a tion fo r the current price and d istrib u tio n o f future prices o f each security’.7 As these conditions are n o t satisfied in existing capital markets, it is fortunate th a t they are sufficient b ut not necessary conditions.8 For example, managers* decisions may s till have an impact on share prices even though there are transaction costs and/or there are only a lim ite d number o f investors who have access to inform a tion about these decisions. I t is true th a t departures from the sufficient conditions give rise to the problem th a t managers are unable to predict w ith certainty the impact th a t a particular decision w ill have on a company s share price. Fortunately there is a great deal o f empirical evidence on the reaction o f share prices to the release o f inform ation. This evidence is reviewed in Chapter 16. A t this p o in t we sim ply note th a t there is evidence in well-developed capital markets (such as the Australian capital market) th a t there are investors who react quickly to the receipt o f new inform ation, w ith the result th a t this in fo rm a tio n w ill be reflected in security prices. In general, therefore, managers should n o t depart from a course th a t they expect w ill increase the value o f the company’s shares. 7 8 Fama (1970, p. 387). ibid” pp. 387-8. B usiness finance SUMMARY • • • A company's shareholders are likely to be a diverse group, with different preferences regarding current and future consumption. Therefore, it might be thought that when making decisions on investments and dividends, a company’s managers would find it impossible to meet the wishes of all shareholders. Fisher showed that, provided there is a capital market through which shareholders can borrow and lend, a company can make decisions that w ill be supported by all shareholders. The company should invest up to the point where the return on the marginal investment equals the • interest rate in the capital market. Therefore, the optimal decisions can be identified using net present value (NPV) analysis. These decisions will maximise the wealth of the shareholders. In this sense, the company and its shareholders are 'separate7; the company's managers can make optimal decisions without having to discover the preferences of individual shareholders. Although the w orld of business is considerably more complicated than Fisher's simple model, the central messages of his theorem remain a useful guide for company managers. KEY TERMS indifference curve 15 market opportunity line tu production possibilities curve 15 17 QUESTIONS 1 [LO 2] Outline the roles played by companies, shareholders and the capital market in Fisher's analysis. 2 [LO 3] Fisher's Separation Theorem ties together many o f the basic notions that underlie much o f modern finance theory: wealth maximisation, utility maximisation and net present value. Discuss. 3 [LO 3] W h a t is Fisher's Separation Theorem? W h a t are its major implications for financial decision making? 4 [LO 3] Financial decision making is a trivial task in a w orld o f certainty. Discuss. 5 [LO 3 】W hat are the implications for financial decision making when the interest rate on borrowing is greater than the interest rate on lending? PROBLEMS 1 Calculating consumption possibilities with and without a capital market [LO 2] Assume a three-date model in which a rational person has an endowment of $ 2 0 0 0 now, $ 1 0 0 0 in Year 1 and $50 0 in Year 2. If the person wishes to consume $40 0 now and $ 12 00 in Year 2, what could she consume in Year 1 if: a) there is no capital market b) there is a capital market in which the interest rate is 5 per cent per year? 2 Investment decisions: applying Fisher's Separation Theorem [LO 3] A company faces a similar situation to the one described in Section 2.2. It has two equal shareholders (A and B)x is operating under conditions of certainty in a two-period framework ('now7 and later') and is considering an investment in Project Small, which can be upgraded to Project Large. Project Small requires an outlay of $1 1 0 0 0 0 today and will return $121 0 0 0 later. Project Upgrade requires an outlay of $ 6 0 0 0 0 today and will return $ 6 5 0 0 0 later. The company has $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 in resources. There is a capital market in which the interest rate for both borrowing and lending is 5 per cent per period. a) 26 Using the net present value rule, show that the company should invest in Project Large (that is, it should invest in both Project Small and Project Upgrade). C hapter t w o C o n s u m p t io n , investment a n d the capital market c) Suppose that Shareholder A wishes to consume $ 4 0 0 0 0 today. What does she do? How much will she be able to consume later? Show that this outcome is better for Shareholder A than if the company had invested only in Project Small. d) Suppose instead that Shareholder A wishes to consume equal amounts now and later, and the company invests in Project Large. What does she do? Show that this action will deliver the desired outcome for Shareholder A. Investment decisions: applying FisheKs Separation Theorem [LO 3] Consider exactly the same situation as in Problem 2, except that the interest rate is 9 per cent per period. a) Using the net present value rule, show that the company should invest only in Project Small. b) How much will the company pay each shareholder in dividends today, and how much will it pay each shareholder in dividends later? c) Suppose that Shareholder A wishes to consume $ 4 0 0 0 0 today. What does she do? How much will she be able to consume later? d) Compare Shareholder A's consumption in Problem 2(c) with her consumption in Problem 3(c). Investment planning [LO 3] CHAPTER T w o REVIEW b) How much will the company pay each shareholder in dividends today, and how much will it pay each shareholder in dividends later? Consider the following situation: • A company starts with $12 million in cash. • The interest rate is 15 per cent. • The optimal policy for the company is to invest $6 million in assets. • The net present value of this investment is $2 million. Answer the following questions: a) In 1 year’s time, how much will the company receive from the investment? b) Draw, to scale, the Fisher diagram that represents this case. c) What are the marginal and average rates of return on the investment? d) What is the total wealth of the company's shareholders immediately after the investment plan is announced? Effect of an interest rate decrease [LO 3] Redraw your diagram for Problem 4 to show the effect of an interest rate decrease on the company's investment plan. Show the net present value of the revised investment plan. Would all investors be made better off by the decrease in interest rates and the consequential revision in the investment plan? Give reasons for youranswer. Effect of higher investment [LO 3] Return to the diagram you have drawn for Problem 4. Suppose that the company decides to invest $7.5 million— that is, $1.5 million more than before. Redraw the market opportunity line consistent with this new level of investment. What effect has the increased level of investment had on the company's shareholders? REFERENCES Brown, R.L., 'Fisher’s Separation Theorem: an alternative approach^ Accounting Research Journal, 1996, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 7 8 -8 1 . Fama, E., 'Efficient capital markets: a review o f theory and empirical w ork', Journal of Finance, M a y 1970, pp. 3 8 3 -4 1 7 . Fama, E. & Miller, M .; The Theory of Finance, Holt, Rinehart & Winston, N ew York, 1972. Fisher, I., The Theory of Interest, M acm illan Company, N e w York, 1930. Hirshleifer, J.; Investment, Interest a n d Capital, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N e w Jersey, 1970. 27 CHAPTER CONTENTS ED HH Introduction 29 H3 Valuation of contracts with multiple cash flows 46 Annuities 50 Fundamental concepts of financial mathematics 29 HH Simple interest 31 田 Principal-and-interest loan contracts 58 m Compound interest 33 BH General annuities 63 LEARNING OBJECTIVES Z After studying this chapter you should be able to: 1 understand and solve problems involving simple interest and compound interest, including accumulating, discounting and making comparisons using the effective interest rate 2 value, as at any date, contracts involving multiple cash flows 3 distinguish between different types of annuity and calculate their present value and future value 4 apply your knowledge of annuities to solve a range of problems, including problems involving principal-and-interest loan contracts 5 distinguish between simple and general annuities and make basic calculations involving general annuities. C hapter THREE T he TIME VALUE 〇F MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL /sAATHEMATICS Financial mathematics provides the finance specialist w ith some extremely useful tools w ith which to solve financial problems. In this chapter, we present the m ajor tools o f financial mathematics and indicate some o f th e ir im p o rta n t applications. You w ill fin d th a t a thorough understanding o f these tools, and how they may be used, w ill be very valuable when you study later chapters. Although you w ill fin d a large number o f formulae in this chapter, you w ill n ot master financial mathematics i f you sim ply try to memorise the formulae. I f you fu lly understand the approach and the logic th a t are embodied in the formulae, you w ill n o t need to memorise them. 3.2 Fundamental concepts of financial mathematics In this section, we explain four fundam ental concepts used in financial mathematics: cash flows, rate o f return, interest rate and tim e value o f money. 3 .2 .1 1 Cash flows Financial mathematics concerns the analysis o f cash flows between parties to a financial con tract.1 For example, when money is borrowed there is an in itia l flow o f cash from the lender to the borrower, and subsequently one (or more) cash (re)payment(s) from the borrower to the lender. In financial mathematics, as in finance generally, we are concerned w ith the cash flow consequences o f a decision or a contract. How much cash w ill flow between the parties? When w ill these cash flows occur? These are the basic questions th a t m ust firs t be answered when analysing a financial contract using the tools o f financial mathematics. We are n o t concerned w ith the possible non-cash consequences o f a contract, such as effects on reported p ro fit; nor are we concerned w ith effects on parties outside the contract. CASH FLOW payment (cash outflow) or receipt (cash inflow) of money FINAN C IAL CONTRACT arrangement, agreement or investment that produces cash flows 3 .2 .2 ! Rate of return Financial decision makers usually fin d it convenient to relate the cash inflows th a t result from a contract to the cash outflows th a t the contract requires. Typically, this inform a tion is presented as a rate of return. Where there are only tw o cash flows in a financial contract— one at the sta rt o f the contract and another at the end— the rate o f retu rn is usually measured by:2 Ci - C 〇 C〇 where C1 = cash in flo w at Time 1 C〇= cash outflow at Time 0 r = rate o f retu rn per period The value o f C1 - C〇measures the dollar return to the investor. D ividing the dollar return by C〇 , which is the investm ent outlay, measures the rate o f return. Example 3.1 illustrates the calculation o f a rate o f return. Note th a t a rate o f retu rn is always measured over a tim e period. In Example 3.1 the tim e period is 1 year. It is meaningless to state th a t an investm ent has returned, say, 20 per cent w ith o u t also specifying the tim e period involved. 1 2 We use the term contract* broadly. For example, we include depositing money in a bank as an act carried out as part of the contract between the depositor and the bank. There are other measures. For example, under some circumstances it is convenient to measure the rate of return by EnCCj/Cg) [natural logarithm]. This measure is discussed further in Section 3.4.4. RATE OF RETURN calculation that expresses the ratio of net cash inflows to cash outflows B usiness finance Example 3.1 bB On 1 January 2014, Paul buys an antique clock for $ 2 00 00. On 1 January 2015, the clock is sold for $2 4 0 0 0 . What rate of return has been achieved? SOLUTION Using Equation 3.1, the rate of return is: r= Ci ~ C 〇 C〇 _ $24 0 0 0 -$ 2 0 0 0 0 $20000 $4000 _ $20000 4 = 20% per annum 3 2 3 | Interest rate INTEREST RATE rate of return on debt DEBT financial contract in which the receiver of the initial cash (the borrower) promises a particular cash flow, usually calculated using an interest rate, to the provider of funds (the lender) TIME VALUE OF MONEY principle that a dollar is worth more (less), the sooner (later) it is to be received, all other things being equal The term in te r e st ra te 1 is an im p o rta n t special case o f the more general term 4rate o f return* and is used when the financial contract is in the fo rm o f debt. A lthough a precise defin itio n o f debt is difficult, the general principle involved is th a t one party (the borrower) provides a specific promise regarding the future cash flow(s) payable to the other party (the lender). Debt may be contrasted w ith agreements where no particular promise is made regarding the future cash flows. For example, when Paul purchased the antique clock in Example 3.1 he was n ot promised any particular future cash inflow. Similarly, where an investm ent is made in ordinary shares, the shareholder is n o t promised any p articular cash inflow(s) from the investment. 3 .2 .4 |T im e value of money One o f the m ost im p o rta n t principles o f finance is th a t money has a tim e value. This principle means th a t a given sum o f money (say, a cash flow o f $100) should be valued differently, depending on when the cash flow is to occur. Suppose you have the choice o f receiving $100 either today or in 1 years tim e. As a rational person you w ill choose to take the money today. Even i f you do n ot plan to spend the money u n til 1 year later, you w ill s till choose to take the money today rather than in 1 years tim e because you w ill be able to earn interest on the money during the coming year. Because o f the interest you w ill earn, you w ill have more than $100 in 1 year’s tim e. Obviously, from your p o in t o f view this is better than receiving only $100 in 1 year’s time. By choosing to take the $100 today, rather than $100 in 1 years tim e, you are in effect saying th a t $100 received today is more valuable to you than the promise o f $100 to be received in 1 years tim e. To p ut this another way, you have im plied th a t $100 to be received in 1 years tim e is w o rth less than $100 today. You have recognised th a t money has a tim e value.3 An im p o rta n t consequence o f the fact th a t money has a tim e value is th a t we cannot validly add cash flows th a t w ill occur on different dates. Suppose you are offered $100 today and a fu rth e r $100 in 1 years time. How much is this offer w o rth to you? A t this stage we cannot answer this question, except to say th a t the value today is less than $200. The value today o f the cash flow o f $100 in 1 years tim e is less than 3 Other reasons for taking the money today, rather than later, are risk (you are not certain that the future cash flow will be paid) and e x p ected in flation (you fear that in a years time the purchasing power of $100 will be lower than it is today). While these reasons are valid, note that money has a time value, even in the absence of these reasons—that is, even if the risk is zero (you are certain that the future cash flow will be paid) and you expect that the inflation rate next year will be zero or negative (purchasing power either will not change or will increase), you will s till take the $100 today, in preference to $100 later, simply because interest rates are positive. C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction t o financial mathematics $100, so the to ta l value today o f the tw o cash flows m ust be less than $200. In financial mathematics it is extremely im p o rta n t never to attem pt to add cash flows th a t w ill occur on different dates. 3.3 Simple interest 3.3.1 | The basic idea of simple interest Many financial contracts specify the interest rate to be paid, rather than specifying explicitly the cash payment(s) required. Suppose, fo r example, th a t you borrow $1000, and agree to repay the loan by making a lum p sum payment in 1 years tim e at an interest rate o f 12 per cent per annum. Then: Interest owed = 0.12 x $1000 = $120 Lump sum payment = $1000 + $120 = $1120 This example is, o f course, very straightforw ard. O nly one tim e period is involved— in this case it happens to be 1 year— and the interest rate is quoted on a m atching (annual) basis. There is little scope fo r confusion in this case. But suppose the contract had specified a lum p sum repayment after 2 years, but the interest rate was quoted as 12 per cent per annum. How do we apply an annual rate to a period that is n ot equal to 1 year? To answer this question we need a rule or convention to enable us to apply an annual interest rate to a period o f 2 years. There are several ways in which this can be done, one o f which is sim ple in terest. A distinguishing feature o f simple interest is that, during the entire term o f the loan, interest is computed on the original sum borrowed. For example, suppose th a t a loan o f $100 m ust be repaid in a lum p sum after 2 years. Simple interest is to be charged at the rate o f 12 per cent per annum. Because simple interest is being used, interest in both years is charged on the sum o f $100. The interest in each year is thus $12, so the lum p sum repayment is $124. Therefore, the interest rate payable at the m a tu rity (term ination) o f the loan w ill in fact be 2 x 12 per cent = 24 per cent. Similarly, i f payment was instead due after h a lf a year, a simple interest rate o f 12 per cent per annum means that, in fact, interest w ill be paid at the rate o f V2 x 12 per cent = 6 per cent per half-year. Example 3.2 illustrates simple interest. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Understand and solve problems involving simple interest and compound interest, including accumulating, discounting and making comparisons using the effective interest rate SIMPLE INTEREST method of calculating interest in which, during the entire term of the loan, interest is computed on the original sum borrowed Example 3.2 Molly's Bakeries Ltd borrows $ 1 0 0 0 0 and agrees to repay the loan by a lump sum payment in 6 months7 time. The interest rate is 8 per cent per annum (simple). Calculate the lump sum payment. 6 SOLUTION Interest rate per half-year = - x 8% 2 =4% Interest payable = $10000 x 0.04 =$400 Lump sum payable = $ 1 0 0 0 0 + $400 = $10400 3 .3 .2 | Formula development: future sum Suppose an am ount P— also know n as the principal — is borrowed and w ill be repaid in a lum p sum. The interest rate is r per period (for example, per annum) and repayment is required after t periods. Using simple interest, the interest payable is based on the original principal, so the interest owing after one PRINCIPAL amount borrowed at the outset of a loan B usiness finance FUTURE SUM amount to which a present sum, such as a principal, will grow (accumulate) at a future date, through the operation of interest period is P x r. A fte r t periods the interest payable is sim ply P x r x t. Therefore, the required future sum 5, th a t w ill repay the am ount borrowed, is given by: S = principal and interest = P + P rt S = P (l + rt) I 3.2 Example 3.3 illustrates the use o f Equation 3.2 to calculate a future sum using simple interest. Example 3.3 a) Use Equation 3.2 to calculate Molly’s repayment of a loan of $ 1 0 0 0 0 after 6 months if simple interest is used and the interest rate is 8 per cent per annum. b) W hat would be the repayment if the lump sum repayment were instead required after 15 months? SOLUTION a) S = P(1 + rt) = $10000 $10000 1+0.08 X 6 、 ,T2, 1.04 $10400 b) S = P(1 + rt) =$10000 = $10000 1+0.08 $ 10000x '1 5 、 .T2, 1.10 $11000 3 .3 .3 1 Formula development: present value PRESENT VALUE amount that corresponds to today's value of a promised future sum In many practical cases, we know the future repayment S, the interest rate r and the tim e period t, and our problem is to fin d the principal P (or presen t value) th a t is implied. In this case we simply rearrange Equation 3.2 to find: 1 + rr 3.3 The present value P is the sum o f money th a t corresponds to today s value o f the future sum promised. The fact th a t P is n ot equal to S follows from the fact th a t money has a tim e value. Im portantly, P in Equation 3.3 can also be thought o f as a price. I f a prospective borrower promises to pay a sum S in t years* time, then given the interest rate r, we can calculate the price (value) o f the borrowers promised future payment o f S. In other words, i f we view the loan from the lenders perspective, the principal represents the price (or present value) paid by the lender, to secure from the borrower, the promise to pay the future cash flow required by the contract. Looked at from the borrow ers view point, the promised future cash flow has been sold by the borrower to the lender fo r its present value, which is the loan principal. 3.3.4 | Applications of simple interest There are many commercial applications o f simple interest. For example, simple interest is used for Treasury notes, bills o f exchange and many bank deposits. Because large sums o f money are often C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction t o financial mathematics involved, there m ust be clear rules or conventions used in applying simple interest. These conventions can differ between countries. Using bills o f exchange as an example, the Australian conventions are: a b C d Interest rates are quoted on an annual basis. The tim e period t is calculated as the exact num ber o f days divided by 365. In a leap year, 29 February is included in the num ber o f days, b ut the year is s till assumed to consist o f 365 days. Calculations are made to the nearest cent. Bills o f exchange are discussed in detail in Section 10.5.3. The conventions used in Australia are illustrated in Examples 3.4 and 3.5. Example 3.4 Stars Ltd borrows $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 on 20 January 201 2, to be repaid in a lump sum on 2 March 2012. The interest rate is 8.75 per cent per annum. Calculate the lump sum repayment. SOLUTION The time period involved is 42 days, consisting of 1 1 days in January, 29 days in February and 2 days in March; note that we do not count both 20 January and 2 March but we d o count 29 February because 2012 is a leap year. Using Equation 3.2 and the conventions explained in this section the lump sum repayment is: S = P(1 +rf) =$10 00 0 0 1 + (0 .0 8 7 5 )( 盖 ) =$10 00 0 0 x 1.010068493 $101 006.85 Example 3.5 Moon Ltd promises to pay $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 in 6 0 days’ time. For a company with M oon’s credit standing the market interest rate for a loan period of 6 0 days is 14.4 per cent per annum. How much can Moon borrow? SOLUTION Using Equation 3.3 and the conventions explained in this section, Moon can borrow the sum of: P=丄 1 + rt $500000 = 1 + ( 0 .144)(盛 ) $500000 _ 1.023 671 232 =$488 438.07 3.4 Com pound interest COM PO U N D INTEREST 3 .4 .1 1 The basic idea of compound interest When interest is received by a lender, the interest can then be le n t to another borrower and, in due course, w ill earn fu rth e r interest. The basic idea o f com p ou n d in te r e st is th a t interest is periodically interest calculated each period on the principal amount and on any interest earned on the investment up to that point B usiness finance added to the principal. Thus interest generates fu rth e r interest, which then generates s till more interest, and so on. This process is illustrated in Example 3.6. Example 3.6 i s On 31 December 2013, Kee Saw deposited $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 in a bank account that paid interest at the rate of 5 per cent per annum. How much was in the account after 4 years? SOLUTION The history of Kee Saw ’s account is as follows: Balance 31 December 2013 Account opened $100000.00 31 December 2014 Interest 0.05 x $100000.00 = $5000.00 $105000.00 Interest 0.05 x $105000.00 = $5250.00 $110250.00 Interest 0.05 x $110250.00 = $5512.50 $115762.50 Interest 0.05 x $115762.50 = $5788.13 $121550.63 31 December 2015 31 December 2016 31 December 2017 As the growth in Kee Saw 's account balance makes clear, with compound interest, the amount of interest each year increases. For example, in the first year the interest received was $ 5 0 0 0 .0 0 but in the fourth year the interest received was $5788.13. After 4 years, Kee Saw ’s account balance is $ 1 2 1 5 5 0 .6 3 but had the account been paid interest at the fixed amount of $ 5 0 0 0 per annum — that is, if Kee Saw had not been able to reinvest interest to earn further interest— the balance would have been only $ 1 2 0 0 0 0 . Therefore, in 4 years, Kee Saw earned $1 55 0 .6 3 of 'interest on interest'. 3 .4 .2 1 Formula development: future sum and present value ACCUMULATION process by which, through the operation of interest, a present sum becomes a greater sum in the future Assume th a t a principal o f P dollars is deposited— th a t is, lent to a bank o r o ther financial in s titu tio n — fo r a term o f n periods, w ith interest paid at the rate i per period at the end o f each period. O ur task is to develop a form ula fo r the future sum 5 th a t w ill be accum ulated after m periods, allowing fo r compound interest. A fte r one period the interest earned is iP, so the account balance at the end o f the firs t period is P + iP = P(1 + 〇. In fact the balance (or accumulated sum) at the end o f any given period is simply the balance a t the sta rt o f th a t period m ultiplie d by (1 + 〇. D uring the second period interest w ill be earned on the am ount P(1 + 〇. So: Balance at end o f Period 2 = = = = 命 (balance at start o f Period 2) x (1 + /) (balance at end o f Period 1) x (1 + /) P(1 4- i) x (1 + i) P(1 + 〇2 CHAPTER THREE T he TIME VALUE 〇F MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS Similarly: Balance at end o f Period 3 = (balance at start o f Period 3) x (1 -h /) = (balance at end o f Period 2) x (1 + /) = P(1 + i)2 x (1 + i) = P(1 + 〇3 Generalising from this discussion, the sum accumulated after n periods is given by P(1 + i)nf so the form ula fo r the future sum S is: 3.4 S = P ( l + i) n The corresponding form ula to find the present value P o f a future sum S is: ^ S 3.5 where 5 = future sum a fter n periods P = principal (or price or present value) i = interest rate per period n = num ber o f periods To illustrate Equation 3.4 we use the inform a tion in Example 3.6. The value o f Kee Saws deposit after selected terms is shown in Table 3.1. TABLE 3.1 Accumulated value (future sum) of $100000 at 5 per cent per annum Date Number of years completed 31 December 2014 1 $100000 (1.05) 105000.00 31 December 2015 2 $100000(1.05)2 110250.00 31 December 2016 3 $100000 (1.05)3 115 762.50 31 December 2017 4 $100000(1.05)4 121550.63 31 December 2018 5 $100000 (1.05)5 127628.16 31 December 2023 10 $100000 (1.05)10 162889.46 31 December 2033 20 $100000 (1.05)20 265 329.77 31 December 2063 50 $100000 (1.05)50 1146739.98 Calculation Accumulated value ($) The effect o f compound interest becomes more pronounced as the number o f periods becomes large. For example, after 50 years, the value o f Kee Saws account is nearly $1.15 m illion, or more than 10 times the amount w ith which he opened the account. £ 6000 DEBT GREW TO £116 000_____________________________ If you don't repay a loan, and a lot of time passes, the debt can grow to unmanageable proportions, as happened to an unfortunate borrower in Manchester in the United Kingdom. A grandmother has been forced to put her house up for sale after she ended up owing a massive £1 16 0 0 0 — on a £ 6 0 0 0 loan. Esther 〇sei, 57, borrowed the money in 1 9 8 8 to pay for her father's funeral and to buy a new cooker for her Clayton home. continued Finance in ACTION B usiness finance continued But she could not meet the cost of the loan and 1 8 years later, the amount she owed had grown to £1 16 0 0 0 . .. Esther said: 1 borrowed the money when I was grieving for my father. I just signed the papers/ W h en the lender applied to take possession of her home, Esther sought help by going to the North Manchester Law Centre. Lawyers negotiated a deal at Manchester County Court . . . A law centre spokesperson said Esther should never have entered into the loan agreement. 'It was a very high rate of interest/ / 5 、 l/n Autnors7 note: Equation 3.4 can be rearranged to: /= f - J - 1. Substituting S = £1 16 000, P = £ 6 0 0 0 and n = 1 8 years into this equation, gives / = 17.89 per cent per annum. However, this may not have been the contract interest rate because the final debt may have included unpaid fees. Source: '£ 6 0 0 0 debt grew to £116 0 0 0 7, Jo Rostron, Manchester M etro News, 21 July 2006. To illustrate Equation 3.5, which gives the present value o f a future sum promised, suppose th a t an individual is offered the sum o f $100 000 to be received after 5 years. I f the relevant interest rate is 5 per cent per annum, compounded annually, the present value o f this promised sum is: (1 + /广 _ $100 000 一 (1.05)5 $100 000 _ 1.276281563 =$78352.62 DISCOUNTING process by which, through the operation of interest, a future sum is converted to its equivalent present value That is, looking ahead 5 years to the receipt o f this promised sum o f $100000, it is w orth, in todays terms, only $78 352.62. The logic underlying this result is th a t i f one wished to set aside money today to accumulate a sum o f $100000 in 5 years* tim e, the am ount needed to be set aside today is $78352.62. A fte r 5 years, this sum w ill accumulate to $78 352.62 x (1.05)5 = $100 000. Clearly, all o ther things being equal, the longer the w aiting period— th a t is, the later the promised sum is to be received— the lower is the value today. The process by which a future sum is converted to its equivalent present value is called discounting. This process is illustrated in Table 3.2, which shows the present value o f $100 000 to be received at selected future dates, discounted using an interest rate o f 5 per cent per annum. Again, the effect o f compound interest becomes more pronounced when the num ber o f periods is large. A promise to be paid $100000 in 50 years* tim e is w o rth only $8720.37 in todays terms i f the discount rate is 5 per cent per annum. TABLE 3.2 Present value of $100000 at 5 per cent per annum Number of years to wait Calculation Present value ($) 1 $100000/1.05 95 238.10 2 $100000/(1.05)2 90702.95 3 $100000/(1.05)3 86383.76 4 $100000/(1.05)4 82270.25 C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to financial mathematics Table 3.2 continued Number of years to wait Calculation Present value ($) 5 $100000/(1.05)5 78352.62 10 $100000/(1.05)10 61391.33 20 $100000/(1.05)2° 37688.95 50 $100000/(1.05)so 8720.37 3 .4 .3 1 Nominal and effective interest rates Many financial contracts specify th a t a loan shall be repaid by a series o f payments made on various future dates, rather than by a lum p sum at the end o f a single tim e period. For example, a so-called interestonly loan requires payments o f interest at regular intervals followed by the repayment o f the principal in a lum p sum on the loan’s m a tu rity date. In m ost loans, the interest rate specified is a nom inal in terest rate, which is an interest rate where interest is charged more frequently than the tim e period specified in the interest rate. To sim plify matters, we assume th a t interest is charged (and therefore compounded) on the same dates as payments are required.4 Examples o f nom inal interest rates are: 15 per cent per annum w ith quarterly payments, and 1.5 per cent per quarter w ith m on thly payments. Where a nom inal interest rate is used in a loan contract, a convention is needed to decide how an interest rate quoted fo r one tim e period w ill be applied to a different tim e period. The convention adopted is to take a simple ratio. So, fo r example, *15 per cent per annum payable quarterly* means th a t interest w ill be charged each quarter at the rate o f 3.75 per cent per quarter— th a t is, the annual rate o f 15 per cent is simply scaled down to one-quarter o f this rate because there are fo ur quarters in a year. Similarly, *1.5 per cent per quarter payable m o n th ly * means th a t interest w ill be charged each m on th at 0.5 per cent per m onth because a m on th is one-third o f a quarter and one-third o f 1.5 is 0.5. Conversely, an effective in terest rate is one where the frequency o f charging (payment) does match the tim e period specified by the interest rate. Examples o f effective interest rates are: 15 per cent per annum w ith annual payments and 0.5 per cent per m onth w ith m on thly payments. W hile few financial contracts specify an effective interest rate, i t is an im p o rta n t concept because it provides a consistent basis on which to compare interest rates. This use is illustrated later in Example 3.8. From the lender s view point i t is preferable to have interest paid more frequently, all other things being equal. To illustrate th is fact, suppose th a t a bank is w illin g to lend $100 000 fo r 1 year at 15 per cent per annum on an in te re s t only, basis b u t has the choice o f receiving either annual or quarterly interest payments. Thus, the bank faces a choice between the cash inflows shown in Table 3.3. INTEREST-ONLY LOAN loan in which the borrower is required to make regular payments to cover interest accrued but is not required to make payments to reduce the principal. On the maturity date of the loan, the principal is repaid in a lump sum N O M IN A L INTEREST RATE quoted interest rate where interest is charged more frequently than the basis on which the interest rate is quoted. The interest rate actually used to calculate the interest charge is taken as a proportion of the quoted nominal rate. Note: The term 'nominal interest rate7 also has another meaning (see Section 3.4.4) TABLE 3.3 Cash inflows at 15 per cent per annum EFFECTIVE INTEREST RATE Cash inflow at Hme t At f = 1 quarter Annual interest Quarterly interest 4 A t t = 2 quarters A " = 3 quarters At f = 4 quarters $0 $0 $0 $115000 $3750 $3750 $3750 $103750 This assumption is relaxed in Section 3.8. interest rate where interest is charged at the same frequency as the interest rate is quoted I f we sim ply add up the two streams o f cash flows shown in Table 3.3 we would, o f course, find that both to ta l $115000 but, as we explained earlier, this procedure is n o t valid because i t involves adding cash flows th a t occur on different dates. Because earlier cash inflows are preferred to later cash inflows, the quarterly interest stream is w o rth more to the bank. I t is w o rth more because the early* cash inflows o f $3750 can be re-lent to earn fu rth e r interest later in the year. Exactly how much more valuable the quarterly stream w ill prove to be w ill depend on the level o f interest rates during the year, b u t because interest rates are always positive, the bank cannot lose by accepting the quarterly payments rather than the annual payment. An im p o rta n t special case can be developed by assuming th a t during the coming year the bank can continue to lend money at 3.75 per cent per quarter. Thus the firs t quarterly inflow o f $3750 can be re-lent fo r the rem aining three quarters, generating fu rth e r quarterly interest payments o f 0.0375 x $3750 = $140.63, together w ith the repayment o f $3750 at the end o f the fo u rth quarter. A quarterby-quarter analysis is shown in Figure 3.1. As shown in Figure 3.1, taking in to account the future opportunities fo r re-lending, the bank can secure a to ta l cash inflow, at the end o f the fo u rth quarter, o f $115 865.06, which fo r the bank is clearly preferable to a cash in flo w (on the same date) o f only $115 000. In effect, w ith interest paid quarterly, the bank has earned at an annual rate o f retu rn given by: $115 865.06 - $100 000 $100 000 » 15.865% Cash flows re-lent at 3.75 per cent per quarter 0 1 2 $3 750.00 1— 3 4 $3 750.00 $3 750.00 $103 750.00 ,► $ 140.63 $ 140.63 $ 3 890.63 $ 145.90 $ 4 036.53 $ 4 187.90 Quarters $3 890.63 1----------- ► $4 036.53 $115 865.06 W ith only an annual interest payment, the bank would have had to specify an interest rate o f 15.865 per cent per annum to equal this rate o f return. Therefore, this example has established that there is a sense in which the nom inal interest rate o f 15 per cent per annum, which is payable quarterly, is equivalent to an effective interest rate o f 15.865 per cent per annum, payable annually. But the sum o f $115865 is simply the future sum that would result from lending $100000 to earn compound interest at the rate o f 3.75 per cent per quarter for four quarters. This is easily seen by noting that: $100000 x (1.0375)4 = $100000 x 1.158 65 = $115865 Generalising from this example, i f a lender advances a principal o f P and specifies a nom inal interest rate o f; per period, w ith interest payments required every subperiod, and there are m subperiods in every period, then the future sum at the end o f one period is given by: The effective interest rate i per period is: . S -P i = -----P p { x+ i ) P ~p C hapter THREE T he TIME VALUE OF MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS therefore Equation 3.6 is the form ula fo r calculating the effective interest rate zper period fo r a nom inal interest rate;, compounding m times per period. The use o f this form ula is illustrated in Examples 3.7 and 3.8. Example 3.7 Calculate the effective annual interest rates corresponding to 12 per cent per annum, compounding: a) semi-annually 6 b) quarterly c) monthly d) daily. SOLUTION Using Equation 3.6, the calculations are shown in Table 3.4. TABLE 3.4 Compounding frequency Calculation Effective annual interest rate (%) (a) Semi-annually (1.06)2- 1 12.3600 (b) Quarterly (1.03)4 - 1 12.5509 (c) M onthly ( l. 〇l ) 12- l 12.6825 (d) Daily (1.000 328 767)365- l 12.7475 These calculations illustrate the fact that, all other things being equal, more frequent compounding produces a higher effective interest rate. Example 3.8 Lake Developments Ltd wishes to borrow money and is offered its choice of the following nominal interest rates: a) 15.00 per cent per annum, payable annually b) 14.50 per cent per annum, payable semi-annually c) 14.00 per cent per annum, payable quarterly d) 13.92 per cent per annum, payable monthly. Which of these nominal interest rates provides the lowest cost of finance in terms of the corresponding effective annual interest rate? SOLUTION Using Equation 3.6, the effective annual interest rates are: a) /= 15 per cent per annum b) / = (1.0725)2 - 1 = 1 5 . 0 2 6 per cent per annum c) / = (1.035)4 - 1 = 14.752 per cent per annum d) / = (1.01 16)12 - 1 = 14.843 per cent per annum. Thus option (c), which is a nominal interest rate of 14.00 per cent per annum with quarterly compounding, provides the lowest effective annual interest rate. 6 In some problems it is necessary to fin d out w hat nom inal interest r a te ,m u s t be charged in order to achieve a target effective interest rate, z. Answering a problem o f this type requires th a t Equation 3.6 be rearranged so th a t; appears on the left-hand side o f the equation. This is shown below. Equation 3.6 is: 1 + 丄 m Adding 1 to b oth sides, and raising to the power 1/m: ( l + /)1/m = l + 丄 m Subtracting 1 from b oth sides, and m u ltip lyin g by m: 7 = /7?[(l + /)1/m- l ] 3.7 The use o f this form ula is illustrated in Example 3.9. Example 3.9 A financial institution raises funds from several different types of deposits but all its loans to borrowers require monthly repayments. The effective annual interest rate that it pays depositors is 7.5 per cent per annum. To cover its other costs and make a profit, the institution adds a margin of 3 per cent per annum. Therefore, its target effective interest rate is 10.5 per cent per annum. W hat nominal annual interest rate must it charge borrowers? 6 SOLUTION Using Equation 3.7, the nominal annual interest rate is: / = m[(l + i)]^m- 1] = 12W.10511/ 12- 1] = 1 2 x 0.008355155 = 1 0% per annum The financial institution would need to charge a nominal annual interest rate of 10 per cent on the loans it makes. 3.4.41 Compound interest: two special cases and a generalisation In this section we discuss real interest rates, continuous interest rates and geometric rates o f return. To understand the remainder o f the chapter, knowledge o f these issues is not required, so some readers may wish to o m it this section. Special case no. 1: the real interest rate REAL INTEREST RATE interest rate after taking out the effects of inflation N O M IN A L INTEREST RATE interest rate before taking out the effects of inflation. Note: the term 'nominal interest rate' also has another meaning (see Section 3.4.3) A real in te re st rate is an interest rate after taking out the effects o f infla tion . Hence, the word Veal1 in this context is used in the same sense as i t is used in phrases such as ‘real GDP’ and ‘real wages’. An interest rate before taking out the effects o f in fla tio n is usually referred to as a nom inal in terest rate. The phrase ‘nom inal interest rate’ in this context should n o t be confused w ith its use in Section 3.4.3. In th a t section, the phrase N om inal interest rate* referred to an interest rate where the frequency o f payment o r compounding did n ot match the basis on which the interest rate was quoted. Suppose th a t a representative basket o f goods th a t a consumer m ig ht buy costs $500 today. I f the in fla tio n rate in the coming year is expected to be 20 per cent per annum, the price o f the basket at the end o f the year is expected to be $500 x 1.2 = $600. Suppose also th a t a lender currently has $2000 th a t w ill be lent at a nom inal interest rate fo r 1 year. By lending this sum the lender forgoes the consumption now o f four representative baskets o f goods. I f a real interest rate o f 5 per cent per annum is to be achieved, C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to financial mathematics then the lender requires th a t at the end o f the year the sum generated w ill be sufficient to purchase 4 x 1.05 = 4.2 baskets o f goods— th a t is, the sum required in 1 year is: 4.2 baskets x $600 per basket = $2520 Therefore, the nom inal annual interest rate required is: $2520 - $2000 $2000 =26% Generalising from this example, let: B = the price today o f a representative basket o f goods P = principal p = expected in fla tio n rate z* = required real interest rate z = nom inal interest rate ^ ^ Thus the lender forgoes consumption o f — baskets today, to be able to consume ~ ^ + baskets in a years tim e. The expected price o f one basket in a years tim e is B(1 + p ). Therefore, the sum required in p 1 years tim e is —(1 + i*) x B(1 + p). Therefore, the nom inal interest rate required is: i = ^ ------------------------------P On sim plifying, this gives: 3.8 / = (1 + i*) (1 + / ? ) - l Equation 3.8 shows the lin k w ith the idea o f compounding: the nom inal interest rate i is n o t sim ply the sum o f the real interest rate i* and the expected in fla tio n rate p t b u t rather is in the form o f the real interest rate compounded, by the expected in fla tio n rate. Rearranging Equation 3.8 gives: 3.9 l + P Equation 3.9 gives the real interest rate corresponding to a nom inal interest rate z i f the expected infla tion rate is p. Expansion o f Equation 3.9 gives the result: •氺 . •幸 i = i- p - p i 士 i- v That is, the real interest rate i* is not simply the difference between the nom inal interest rate i and the expected infla tion rate p. However, where the rates are ^m a ir, pi* w ill also be small and the approximation i* ^ i - p w ill be close. The calculation o f a real interest rate is illustrated in Example 3.10. E xample 3.10 If the inflation rate is expected to be 2 0 per cent per annum and the nominal interest rate is 30 per cent per annum, calculate the corresponding real interest rate. SOLUTION Using Equation 3.9: r = 上^ - 1 1 +P 1.30 = ---------l 1.20 . =8.33% per annum 6 Special case no. 2: continuous interest rates CONTINUOUS INTEREST method of calculating interest in which interest is charged so frequently that the time period between each charge approaches zero As we showed in Section 3.4.3, the more frequently compounding occurs, the higher is the effective interest rate, other things being equal. In the lim itin g case, compounding becomes so frequent th a t the tim e period between each interest charge approaches zero. This is know n as continuous in terest and it can be shown th a t continuous interest is an example o f exponential growth. Using continuous interest, the fu tu re sum S is S where 3.10 = P eJn S = future sum P = principal j = continuously compounding interest rate per period n = number o f periods e = 2.71828182846 The calculation o f a future sum using continuous interest is illustrated in Example 3.11. E xample 3.11 If the interest rate is 12 per cent per annum, compounding continuously, how much will a principal of $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 be worth after 1 year? After 2 years? SOLUTION Using Equation 3.10, the future sum after 1 year is: S = Pein =$100000 x e (012) ( 1) =$100000 X 1.127496852 =$112 749.69 Again using Equation 3.10, the future sum after 2 years is: S = Pein x e (012)( 2) =$100000 x e 0-24 =$100000 =$127124.92 The effective interest rate th a t results from continuous compounding is found by setting n equal to 1 period and solving: . S -P i = -----P _ Pef - P — i h where P Kill i = effective interest rate per period j = continuously compounding interest rate per period e = 2.71828182846 The calculation o f an effective annual interest rate th a t is equivalent to a continuously compounding interest rate is illustrated in Example 3.12. 命 C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to finan c ial mathematics E xample 3.1! W hat is the effective annual interest rate corresponding to a nominal interest rate of 12 per cent per annum, compounding continuously? SOLUTION Using Equation 3.11, the effective annual interest rate / is given by: /= - 1 = e°-,2 - l = 1 2 .7 4 9 6 9 % per annum Of course, this is the interest rate implicit in Example 3.1 1. Although continuous compounding is rarely used in loan contracts, i t is frequently used in other contexts. In particular, academic studies o f security prices often assume th a t returns compound continuously between the dates on which the prices are observed. Consider the security prices P〇, Px and P2 observed on dates 0 ,1 and 2 respectively. These dates are assumed to be equally spaced. For example, the prices may be observed at weekly intervals. Assuming th a t returns accrue continuously through time, we can apply Equation 3.10 to assert th a t in the firs t week: P i = P〇eri and in the second week: P2 = P\eri where r1 is the continuously compounding weekly rate o f retu rn in the firs t week and r2 is the continuously compounding weekly rate o f retu rn in the second week. Solving fo r r1 and r2 gives: n = in (P i/P 〇 ) and r2 = in {P2/P l ) where in means logarithm to the base e (usually referred to as the natural logarithm ). More generally, we can w rite th a t the rate o f retu rn in period t is: rt = £n {P t/P t-i) An expression o f the fo rm £n (P t/P t-i) is called a lo g p ric e re la tiv e and, when calculated this way, r t is called a logarithm ic rate o f retu rn or a continuous rate o f return. There are two reasons fo r choosing to measure rates o f retu rn in this way. First, the correct way to compound logarithm ic rates o f return is sim ply to add them. Thus, fo r example: LOG PRICE RELATIVE That is: natural logarithm of the ratio of successive security prices. Implicitly, it is assumed that prices have grown (or decayed) in a continuous fashion between the two dates on which the prices are observed. Also known as a logarithmic rate of return and a P2 = P0eri+r2 continuous rate of return P2 = P\er2 But P\ = P〇 eri Substituting, we find: P2 = P〇 en er2 The last equation shows that, using logarithm ic rates o f return, the to ta l rate o f retu rn over the two tim e periods is sim ply the sum o f the rates o f retu rn in each o f the tw o constituent periods. Thus calculations such as finding an average rate o f retu rn are simpler when using logarithm ic rates o f return. 命 B usiness finance As discussed in Section 3.4.5, i t is not valid to add rates o f retu rn i f they are measured using the simple a rith m e tic1d efin itio n that: The second reason fo r using logarithm ic rates o f retu rn is a statistical one. The greatest loss an investor can suffer is when the security price falls to zero. Using the simple arithm etic definition, the rate o f return associated w ith this event is - 1 — th a t is, the rate o f retu rn is -1 0 0 per cent. Using logarithm ic rates o f return, the same event w ill register as a rate o f retu rn o f - 〇〇. Given th a t there is no upper lim it to the rate o f retu rn th a t m ight be achieved, i t follows th a t while arithm etic rates o f retu rn fa ll in the range -1 to +〇〇, logarithm ic rates o f retu rn fa ll in the range - 〇〇to +〇〇. Thus, w hile the statistical d istribution th a t describes logarithm ic rates o f retu rn might have the convenient property o f symmetry, and thus might fo llo w the norm al d istribution, arithm etic rates o f retu rn w ill not be sym metric and thus cannot be norm ally distributed. A generalisation: geometric rates of return GEOMETRIC RATE OF RETURN average of a sequence of arithmetic rates of return, found by a process that resembles compounding Compound interest is a special case o f a geom etric rate o f return. In the case o f compound interest, the interest rate is the same in each period. In the more general case o f geometric rates o f return, the rate o f retu rn can be different in each period. W hile the sum invested is s till subject to the compounding process, the rate at which compounding occurs w ill differ from period to period. Suppose th a t $1000 is invested fo r 4 years and each year the investm ent earns a different rate o f return, as follows: • • • • In In In In Year 1: 10 per cent per annum Year 2: 5 per cent per annum Year 3: 8 per cent per annum Year 4 :1 5 per cent per annum. The value o f this investm ent therefore grows as follows: 1 A t the 2 A t the 3 A t the 4 A t the end o f Year 1: $1000.00 end o f Year 2: $1100.00 end o f Year 3: $1155.00 end o f Year 4: $1247.40 x 1.10 = $1100.00 x 1.05 = $1155.00 x 1.08 = $1247.40 x 1.15 = $1434.51. O f course, this result could have been found more quickly and conveniently by calculating, in one step: $1000 x 1.10 x 1.05 x 1.08 x 1.15 = $1434.51 W ritin g the calculation in this way emphasises the sim ilarity between compound interest and the more general case o f geometric rates o f return. I t is natural to ask: w hat annual compound interest rate would have produced the same result? In other words, w hat single rate o f retu rn zper year would need to be earned in each o f the 4 years, to produce the same future sum? To answer this question we need to solve: $1000 x 1.10 x 1.05 x 1.08 x 1.15 = $1000(1 + 〇 4 th a t is, i = [(1.10)(1.05)(1.08)(1.15)]1/4_ i =(1.434 S l) 1^ - ! =9.440% per annum In fact, i in this calculation is the mean (or average) geometric rate o f return. I t is the rate o f return which, i f earned in every period, and allowing fo r the effects o f compounding, would produce the same outcome as th a t actually observed. In the general case, the mean geometric rate o f retu rn is: i = [ ( l + r i ) ( l + r2) . . . ( l + 〇 ] V " - l where 命 rk = the rate o f retu rn in period k /c = 1, 2, n n = the num ber o f completed periods K1H CHAPTER THREE T he TIME VALUE 〇F MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS I f the rate o f retu rn is calculated each period from security prices P〇, Pl t then: Pk ~ Pk-\ Pk-l Pk Pk-l Substituting in Equation 3.13 gives: 3.14 It is im p o rta n t to understand th a t the mean rate o f retu rn is not (rx + r2 + ... + rn)/ri— th a t is, i t is not correct simply to sum the rates o f retu rn and divide by the number o f periods. This fact is illustrated in Example 3.13. E xample 3.1 An investment of $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 produces rates of return as follows: In Year In Year In Year In Year 1: 2: 3: 4: a a a a gain of 10 per cent loss of 5 per cent loss of 8 per cent gain of 3 per cent Calculate the value of the investment at the end of the fourth year and calculate the mean annual rate of return. SOLUTION The value of the investment at the end of the fourth year is: $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 x 1.10 x 0.95 x 0.92 x 1.03 = $ 9 9 0 2 4 .2 0 Using Equation 3.14, the mean annual rate of return is: _ /$ 9 9 0 2 4 .2 0 \1/4 —V $100000 ) 1 一 = -0.002 448 = -0.2 448% This small negative mean rate of return is consistent with the outcome that the final value ($99024.20) is less than the sum invested ($ 1 0 0 0 0 0 )— that is, the investment has produced a loss after 4 years. Note that the incorrect calculation of the mean as: 10% - 5 % - 8 % + 3 % 4 =0% clearly gives a nonsensical answer because in this example the mean rate of return must be negative.5 5 Note that we are discussing here the correct measurement of p a s t returns. We are not discussing the forecasting of fu tu re returns. B usiness finance 3.5 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Value, as at any date, contracts involving multiple cash flows Valuation of contracts with multiple cash flows 3.5.1 | Introduction Many loan contracts stipulate th a t more than one cash flow is required to repay the loan. For example, a housing loan may require m on thly repayments over a period o f 20 years— a to ta l o f 240 repayments. In this section we consider the valuation o f contracts th a t involve m ultiple cash flows. We do n o t assume th a t the am ount or tim in g o f the cash flows follows any particular pattern. Some im p o rta n t special cases involving equal amounts at equally spaced tim e intervals are considered in Section 3.6. 3.5_2| Value additivity W hile i t is not valid to add cash flows th a t occur at different times, i t is valid to add cash flows th a t occur at the same tim e. Therefore, i f a contract requires cash payments to be made on, say, 1 A p ril and 1 May, we should n o t sim ply add these cash flows. However, i f we firs t value the 1 A p ril cash flow as i f i t were to occur on 1 May, we could then add the two cash flows, since one is actually a May cash flow and the other has, so to speak, been converted to the equivalent o f a May cash flow. Alternatively, we could firs t value the 1 May cash flow as i f it were to occur on 1 A p ril; sum m ation o f these tw o cash flows then provides the to ta l value o f the tw o cash flows as at 1 A pril. For th a t m atter we could choose any date at all, value the two cash flows as i f they were to occur on that date, and thus produce a valuation as at th a t date. To im plem ent this approach we need to decide how we can value, as at any given date, a cash flow that occurs on some earlier or later date. For example, we need to decide how a 1 A p ril cash flow can be valued as at 1 May. The answer is provided by the interest rate. Using our knowledge o f compound interest we can use Equation 3.4 to carry forw ard in tim e (‘accumulate’)the value o f any cash flow, provided we know the interest rate to use. Similarly, we can use Equation 3.5 to carry backward in tim e (‘discount’) the value o f any cash flow i f we know the interest rate to use. The process o f valuation as at any given date is illustrated in Example 3.14. Example 3.14 On 1 February 2 0 1 4 you sign a contract that entitles you to receive two future cash flows, as follows: On 1 February 2016: $ 1 0 0 0 0 On 1 August 2017: $6 00 0 Assuming that the relevant interest rate is 5 per cent per annum (effective), value this contract as at: a) 1 February 2 0 14 b) 1 February 2 0 16 and c) 1 August 2017. The following time line shows the timing of the cash flows in this problem. t= 0 years I 1 1 February 2014 t= 2 years I 1 1 February 2016 $10000 t= 3.5 years I 1 1 August 2017 $6000 C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to finan c ial mathematics SOLUTION a) Valuation as at 1 February 2 0 14 Both cash flows must be discounted to 1 February 2014. This requires that the $ 1 0 0 0 0 to be received on 1 February 2016 be discounted for 2 years and the $6 0 0 0 to be received on 1 August 20 1 7 be discounted for 3.5 years. The equation we need to use in each case is Equation 3.5. The valuation as at 1 February 2 0 1 4 is: $10000 ° $6000 (1.05)2 + (1.05)3.5 = $9070.2948+ $5058.1151 = $ 1 4 128.41 Because this valuation is made as at the start of the contract, Va is called the present value of the contract. b) Valuation as at 1 February 20 1 6 The cash flow of $ 6 0 0 0 on 1 August 2 0 1 7 must be discounted for 1.5 years to calculate an equivalent amount as at 1 February 2016. Therefore, the valuation as at 1 February 2 0 1 6 is: $6000 Vb = $10000 + PRESENT VALUE OF A CONTRACT the value today that is equivalent to the stream of cash flows promised in a financial contract (1 .0 5 )15 = $ 1 0 0 0 0 + $5576.57 $15 576.57 c) Valuation as at 1 August 2 0 1 7 The cash flow of $ 1 0 0 0 0 on 1 February 2 0 16 must be accumulated for 1.5 years to calculate an equivalent amount as at 1 August 2017. The equation we need to use is Equation 3.4. Therefore, the valuation as at 1 August 2 0 1 7 is: ^ = $1 〇〇〇〇(1.〇5)15 + $6000 =$10759.30 +$6000 = $16759.30 Because 1 August 2 0 1 7 is the date of the final cash flow of the contract, Vc is called the terminal value of the contract. In Example 3.14, the three valuations VQf Vb and Vc are all valuations o f the same financial contract. They d iffer because the date o f valuation differs. There should, therefore, be logical connections between the three valuations. For example, the contracts present value (Vai the valuation as at 1 February 2014) should be the same as taking the contracts term inal value (Vct the valuation as at 1 August 2017) and discounting fo r 3.5 years. In fact, the mathematics underlying the valuation process guarantees this result, as the follow ing calculation confirms: Vc (1.05)3*5 $16759.30 (1.05)3*5 =$14128.41 =Va In effect, the valuation process consists o f using compound interest to discount and accumulate cash flows to calculate value equivalents at a common date. The valuation as at th a t date is then found sim ply by adding the value equivalents fo r th a t date. TERMINAL VALUE OF A CONTRACT the value, as at the date of the final cash flow promised in a financial contract, that is equivalent to the stream of promised cash flows 3 .5 .3 1 Formula development: valuation as at any date Where a cash flow o f C dollars occurs on a date t, the value o f th a t cash flow as at a valuation date t* is given by: V r = Ct( l + I f date t* occurs after date t, then t* is greater than t and, in Equation 3.15, the power (t* - t) is positive, and the equation correctly indicates th a t an accumulation o f Ct is required. Conversely, i f date t* occurs before date t, then t* is less than t and, in Equation 3.15, the power (t* - t) is negative, and the equation correctly indicates th a t a discounting o f Ct is required. Where there is more than one cash flow to be valued, the to ta l value o f the contract is the sum o f the values o f each cash flow. The calculation o f a contracts value at various dates is illustrated in Example 3.15. E xample 3.15 Confirm that Equation 3.15 is correct by using it to recalculate the valuations made in Example 3.14. In each case, / = 5 per cent per annum, C 2 = $ 1 0 0 0 0 and C3 5 = $6000. The valuation date t * , however, differs in each case. SOLUTION a) Valuation as at 1 February 20 1 4 In this case, t* = 0. Using Equation 3.15: V〇= $ 10 0 0 0 (1,05)°-2 + $ 6 0 0 0 (1.05)°-3-5 = $ 10 0 0 0 11.05 厂2 + $ 6 0 0 0 (1 _05 广3 5 = $10000 $6000 (1.05)2 (1.05)3"5 = $ 9 0 7 0 . 2 9 4 8 + $5058.1151 = $ 1 4 1 2 8 .4 1 = Va as calculated in Worked example 3.14 b) Valuation as at 1 February 2016 In this case, t* = 2. Using Equation 3.15: V2 = $ 10 0 0 0 (1.05)2-2 + $6 0 0 0 (1,05)2-3-5 = $ 10 0 0 0 (1.05)0 + $ 6 0 0 0 (1.05 广1 5 = $10000+ ^ 〇 (1.05)1-5 = $ 1 0 0 0 0 + $5 576.57 = $ 1 5 576.57 = c) as calculated in Worked example 3.14 Valuation as at 1 August 2 0 17 In this case, t* = 3.5. Using Equation 3.15: V3 5 = $10 0 0 0 (1,05)3-5- 2 + $ 6 0 0 0 (1.05)3-5- 3-5 = $ 10 0 0 0 (1.05)1 5 + $6 0 0 0 (1.05)° = ($ 10 0 0 0 x 1.075 92 9 83) + $6 00 0 = $ 1 6 7 5 9 .3 0 = Vc as calculated in Worked example 3.14 C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to finan c ial mathematics 3 .5 .4 1 Measuring the rate of return When there are m ultiple cash flows in an investm ent, there are also m ultiple tim e periods. Inevitably the question arises: For a given set o f cash flows extending over tw o or more tim e periods, how can we measure the rate o f retu rn per period? There are a num ber o f d ifferent answers to this question, b ut the answer most frequently offered is to employ a measure know n as the internal rate o f return. In this section we outline this method. I t is discussed in greater detail in Section 5.4.2. First, however, we review the measurement o f the rate o f retu rn over a single period. Consider a oneperiod investm ent th a t costs $1000 and promises a cash inflo w o f $1120 a year later. Such an investm ent would usually be described sim ply as a 1-year loan o f $1000 at an interest rate o f 12 per cent per annum. We would infer th a t the interest rate is 12 per cent per annum by observing th a t the interest component o f the cash flow after 1 year is $120, so the interest rate is $120/$1000 = 12 per cent. This is, o f course, the result given by the simple defin itio n o f *rate o f return* in Equation 3.1. Equally, we could have said that the rate o f return is the value o f r th a t solves the follow ing equation: $1120 -$1000 = 0 The calculation $1120/(1 + r) is the present value o f $1120 using a discount rate o f r. On solving this equation we would, o f course, fin d th a t r = 0.12, or 12 per cent. The advantage o f th in kin g about the rate o f retu rn in this way is th a t we can readily see how to extend this approach to the case o f many cash flows and tim e periods. Consider the follow ing investm ent. An in itia l investm ent o f $1000 is made and, as before, a cash flow o f $1120 is to be received after 1 year but, in addition, a fu rth e r cash flow o f $25 is to be received 2 years after making the in itia l investm ent. In tabular form , the cash flows o f this investm ent are shown in Table 3.5. TABLE 3.5 Year Cash flow ($) 0 -1 0 0 0 1 + 1120 2 + 25 Obviously this investm ent promises a rate o f retu rn o f more than 12 per cent per annum, since the firs t cash inflo w alone is sufficient to produce a rate o f retu rn o f 12 per cent per annum. As an investor, however, we would prefer the $25 inflo w to have been promised fo r Year 1 rather than Year 2. Had this occurred, the cash inflow after 1 year would be $1145, representing a rate o f retu rn o f 14.5 per cent per annum. P utting these observations together, the investm ent s annual rate o f retu rn m ust be more than 12 per cent, b u t less than 14.5 per cent. The internal rate o f return measure proposes th a t the rate o f retu rn in this case is the value o f r th a t satisfies the follow ing equation: $1120 $25 1+ r (1 + r)2 -$1000 = 0 The term $25/(1 + r)2 can be thought o f as the present value o f $25, discounted fo r 2 years at the rate r per annum. Solving this equation, we find r = 14.19 per cent per annum.6 We can confirm this result by noting that: $1120 1.1419 $25 -$1000 (1.1419)2 = $980.821438 + $19.172 725 - $1000 = -$ 0 .0 0 5 8 3 6 «$0 6 In this particular case, r can be found by solving the resulting quadratic equation. In more general cases, numerical methods are usually required. B usiness finance The figure o f 14.19 per cent falls w ith in the range o f 12 per cent to 14.5 per cent, as suggested earlier by our in tu itiv e reasoning. Where there are n cash inflow s Ct (where t = 1, n), follow ing an in itia l cash outflow o f C〇, the internal rate o f return is th a t value (or values) o f r th a t solves the equation:7 c. , c2 r\ 1+ r (1 + r)2 I ••• l Cn (1 + r)1 or X: Ct t 3.6 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Distinguish between different types of a 门nuity and calculate their present value and future value AN N U ITY series of cash flows, usually of equal amount, equally spaced in time Co = 0 3.16 A n n u itie s 3.6.1 I Definition and types of annuity In Section 3.5 we explained how to analyse contracts th a t require more than one cash flow to be paid. We considered a general case th a t can be used to deal w ith a wide range o f contracts. There is, however, a special case th a t is found in a large num ber o f financial contracts and hence requires fu rth e r discussion. This is the case o f the annuity. An annuity is a series o f cash flows, usually o f equal amount, equally spaced in tim e. Thus, fo r example, $500 paid each m onth fo r a year is an annuity. Similarly, $600 per week fo r 12 weeks is an annuity; so is $20 000 per annum fo r 10 years. Annuities are involved in many personal loans and commercial loans, and in certain kinds o f financial instrum ents such as bonds. In itia lly we consider fo ur types o f annuity: ordinary annuity, annuity-due, deferred annuity and ordinary perpetuity. The o rd in a ry annuity ORDINARY ANNUITY annuity in which the time period from the date of valuation to the date of the first cash flow is equal to the time period between each subsequent cash flow Like many annuities, the cash flow pattern o f the ordinary annuity consists o f equal amounts, equally spaced in tim e. The distinguishing characteristic o f the ordinary annuity is that the tim e period fro m the date o f valuation to the date o f the firs t cash flow is equal to the tim e period between each subsequent cash flow. Diagrammatically, the cash flow pattern o f the ordinary annuity, using six cash flows as an example, is: 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 $C $C $C $C $C $C AN NUITY-DUE annuity in which the first cash flow is to occur 'immediately' (i.e. on the valuation date) The annuity-due The distinguishing feature o f the annuity-due is th a t the firs t cash flow occurs on the valuation date 一 th a t is, immediately. Diagrammatically, the cash flow pattern o f the annuity-due, using six cash flows as an example, is: DEFERRED AN N U ITY annuity in which the first cash flow is to occur after a time period that exceeds the time period between each subsequent cash flow 0 1 2 3 4 5 $C $C $C $C $C $C The deferred annuity The distinguishing feature o f the deferred annuity is th a t the firs t cash flow is to occur after a tim e period th a t exceeds the tim e period between each subsequent cash flow. 7 If the cash flows are produced by a bond, it is conventional to call the internal rate of return the bonds y ie ld -to -m a tu rity (or 'yield1for short). For further discussion, see Sections 4.4 and 4.7. The Microsoft Excel* function IRR uses numerical methods to calculate the internal rate of return for a given initial outlay and set of cash flows. C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to finan c ial mathematics Diagrammatically, the cash flow pattern o f the deferred annuity, using as an example six cash flows, the firs t to occur after three tim e periods, is: 0 1 2 3 4 $C 5 $C 6 $C 7 $C 8 $C $C The ordinary perpetuity The ordinary perpetu ity is an ordinary annuity w ith the special feature th a t the cash flows are to continue forever.8 Diagrammatically, the cash flow pattern o f the ordinary perpetuity is: 0 1 2 3 4_____________ $C $C $C $C ----------------- > where the arrows indicate continuing forever. 3 .6 .2 1 Formula development: present value of an ordinary annuity The form ula fo r the present value o f an ordinary annuity is one th a t we w ill use frequently. This form ula can then be adapted to apply to the other types o f annuity. The cash flow pattern o f an ordinary a nnuity o f n cash flows o f C dollars each is shown below: 0 1 2 $C 3 $C $C n -1 n $C $C The present value P o f this stream o f cash flows is given by the sum o f the present values o f the individual cash flows: C P- + i C C C C ( i + iy ( i + iy ( l + i) " - 1 ( l + i) n K IH where z = the interest rate per period. M u ltip lyin g both sides o f Equation 3.17 by (1 + 〇 gives: n/1 .x ^ P(1 + z) = C + C + / C C C ( l + i)2 ( l + 〇n_2 ( l + i) n~l B f lU Subtracting Equation 3.17 from Equation 3.18, we fin d th a t all terms on the right-hand side cancel out, except the last term o f Equation 3.17 and the firs t term o f Equation 3.18, giving: P (l + / ) - P = C - C (1 + 0 " C Pi = C- (1 + i)n which, on rearrangement gives: P. C 1 (1 + ^ I t is often convenient to consider an annuity o f $1 per period— th a t is, we set C = 1 and Equation 3.19 becomes: P = A(n, i) (i + 0n Equation 3.20 is the form ula fo r the present value o f an ordinary a nnuity consisting o f n cash flows, each o f $1 per period. The functional notation A{ny i) is sim ply a shorthand way o f referring to 8 We could, of course, also consider the categories p e rp e tu ity -d u e and d eferred p e rp e tu ity but have not done so because the purpose at this stage is simply to introduce the idea of a perpetuity, as distinct from an annuity of finite life. ORDINARY PERPETUITY ordinary annuity with the special feature that the cash flows are to continue forever this equation.9 Values o f A(n, 〇 fo r different values o f n and i are provided in Table 4 o f Appendix A. The valuation o f ordinary annuities is illustrated in Example 3.16. Example 3. Find the present value of an ordinary annuity of $ 5 0 0 0 per annum for 4 years if the interest rate is 8 per cent per annum by: a) using a calculator to discount each individual cash flow b) using a calculator to evaluate the formula given in Equation 3.19 c) using the Microsoft Excel® function PV (rate, nper, pmt) d) using Table 4 of Appendix A to evaluate the formula given in Equation 3.20. SOLUTION a) Discounting each individual cash flow: P= — + C + i + ; (i =$5000 1.08 C + +/)2 C (i +/]3 $5000 $5000 $5000 (1.08)2 (1.08)3 (1.08)4 (i +/)4 =$4629.6296 + $4286.6941 + $3969.1612 + $3675.1493 = $16560.63 b) Using Equation 3.19: $5000 0.08 (1.08)4 $ 5 0 0 0 x3 .3 1 2 122 684 $16560.63 c) Using the Microsoft Excel® function PV (rate, nper, pmt): The Microsoft Excel® function PV returns -1 x the present value of an ordinary annuity. The required inputs are the interest rate (as a decimal), the number of periods and the amount of each cash flow. Using a Microsoft Excel® spreadsheet, we find that-PV(0.08, A, 5000) = $16560.63. d) Using Table 4 of Appendix A: P= CA[n, i) =$5000 x 3.3121 =$16560.50 Except for the relatively small rounding error when using Table 4 of Appendix A, the four answers are identical. 3.6.31 Formula development: present values of annuities-due, deferred annuities and o rdinary perpetuities Present value of an annuity-due The cash flow pattern o f an annuity-due w ith n cash flows o f C dollars each is shown below: 0 $C 9 1 $C 2 3 $C n -2 $C $C n -1 $C The notation sometimes read as 'A angle n at rate i \ is also used to indicate this equation. There is no special significance in this notation: it is simply a different convention. Mathematically, the functional notation A {n ,i) serves equally well. C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to It is im p o rta n t to be aware th a t in an annuity-due consisting o f n cash flows, there are only {n - 1) tim e periods involved.10 Inspecting the annuity-due diagram, i t is clear th a t an annuity-due o f n cash flows is sim ply an immediate cash flow plus an ordinary a nnuity o f (n - 1) cash flows. The present value o f an annuity-due is therefore: P = C + -4 i 1 ^ 13.21 ( l + £•广 1 or 13.22 P = C[1 + y 4 ( n - l, 〇l where P = present value C = cash flow per period z = interest rate per period n = num ber o f cash flows The valuation o f annuities-due is illustrated in Example 3.17. E xample 3.17 Kathy's rich uncle promises her an allowance of $ 1 0 0 0 0 per month, starting today, with a final payment to be made 6 months from today. If the interest rate is 0.5 per cent per month, what is the present value of the promised allowance? SOLUTION Kathy has been promised seven payments of $ 1 0 0 0 0 with the first being due immediately. Thus, she has been promised $ 1 0 0 0 0 today, plus an o rd in a ry annuity of six payments. This is the logic embodied in Equation 3.21. Using this equation with n set equal to 7, gives: p= c + ^ [ i - - L _ ] = $10000+ i M ° ° [ l 0.005 = $ 1 0 0 0 0 + $ 10000 0.005 (1.005)7-1 1 (1.005)6 = $ 1 0 0 0 0 + $58 963.84 =$ 68 963.84 Present value of a deferred annuity The cash flow pattern o f a deferred annuity is as follows: 0 1 2 k -1 k k+1 k + n -2 k + n -1 $C $C $C $C In this case, there are n cash flows and the firs t cash flow occurs on date k. To find the present value o f this series o f cash flows, imagine th a t the valuation was to be made as at date (k - 1) instead o f date zero. Looking ahead from date ( k - 1 ) , the cash flow pattern is th a t o f an ordinary a nnuity o f n cash flows. Thus, at date (/c - 1), the present value is given by the present value o f an ordinary annuity: 10 This is frequently a source of confusion. For an ordinary annuity, it makes no difference whether n is defined as the number of cash flows or the number of time periods, since these are equal. For an annuity-due, we must choose whether to use n to represent the number of cash flows or the number of time periods. We have chosen to develop the formula with n representing the number of cash flows. c Pk-l 1 3.23 (1 + i) n where _ 丄= the present value at date (/c - 1) To s h ift the valuation date back from date (k - 1) to date zero, we sim ply discount the value given by Equation 3.23 fo r (k - 1) periods. Thus the required form ula is: 」 ____C P= (1 + 〇fc_1 i 3.24 (1 + i) n or C P= A{n, i) 3.25 (1 + 〇fc_1 where C = cash flow per period z = interest rate per period n = num ber o f cash flows k = num ber o f tim e periods u n til the firs t cash flow Alternatively, the present value o f a deferred a nnuity can be found by firs t im agining th a t cash flows are to occur on all (k + n - 1 ) dates. The present value o f such a stream is, o f course, given by the present value o f an ordinary annuity consisting o i (k + n - 1) cash flows. The effect o f the deferral period is accounted fo r by subtracting the present value o f the firs t (k - 1) h is s in g 1cash flows, because these cash flows w ill n o t occur. That is: present value o f an p = present value o f an ordinary annuity of less (k-\- n - l ) cash flows ordinary annuity o f (A: - 1) cash flows That is: C !_ 1 i ( l + i) k+n- \ c 1 1 i 3.26 = C[A(k+ n - l J ) - A ( k - l , i ) ] The valuation o f deferred annuities is illustrated in Example 3.18. Example 3. Jason will be starting a 6-month live-in training course in 4 months, time. His father, Sam, has promised him a living allowance of $ 2 0 0 0 per month to help support him during this time. If the simple interest rate is 9 per cent per annum, payable monthly, how much money will Sam need to set aside today to finance Jason's allowance? SOLUTION Sam needs to set aside the present value of the promised allowance. The allowance is an annuity of six payments, the first payment to be made 4 months from today. Diagrammatically, the cash flows are: 0 1 2 3 4 $2000 5 6 $2000 7 $2000 8 $2000 9 $2000 $2000 Using the logic developed in this section, we can approach this problem in two stages. First, w hen v ie w e d from the s ta n d p o in t o f d ate 3, the cash flows form an ordinary annuity of six payments. W e therefore value this stream, as at date 3, using Equation 3.19, which gives the present value of an ordinary annuity. Second, we find the value as at date zero by discounting for three periods. The calculations are shown below. Note that the interest rate is 0.09/1 2 = 0.75 per cent per month. G h APTER THREE T he TIME VALUE OF MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS As at date 3 the value is: $2000 0.0075 (1.0075)° $11 691.195 260 As at date zero, the value is thus: p _ $11 691.195 260 (1.0075)3 =$11 432.04 This is, of course, the logic embodied in Equation 3.24, as we now show. In this case, n = 6, k = 4 and /' = 0.09/1 2 = 0.75 per cent per month. Using Equation 3.24: n 1 (1+/) C k-] (1 $2000 1 0.0075 (1.0075)°. (1.0075) r 1 x $ 2 0 0 0 x5 .8 4 5 59763 1.022 669172 =$11 691.195260 ~ 1.022 669172 = $11432.04 Alternatively, using Equation 3.26, and again using n = 6 , k = 4 and / = 0.75 per cent per month, the required sum is: c ! i L 1 ( i+ ^ ' J $2000 i 0.0075 L C , 1 i i (1.0075)9 J $2000 , 0.0075 L 1 ( i. 〇〇75)3 J =($2000 x 8.671 5 76 42 3)-($ 20 00 x 2.955 556 237) = $ 17343.1 5 2 9 -$ 5 9 1 1 .1125 = $11432.04 Present value of an ord ina ry perpetuity The cash flow pattern o f an ordinary perpetuity o f C dollars per period is shown below: 0 1 2 3 4 5 ---------------------------------------------------------------► $C $C $C $C $ C --------------------► The ordinary p erpe tu ity is an ordinary annuity where the num ber o f cash flows n becomes in d e fin ite ly large. Therefore, to fin d its present value, we need to consider the form ula fo r the present value o f an ordinary annuity and allow n to become indefinitely large. Thus the problem is to value: P = lim — (1 + i) n Because the interest rate z is positive, (1 + i)n becomes ind efin itely large as n becomes ind efin itely 1 large. This means th a t (丄 + becomes very small because the denom inator o f this fraction becomes very large. In the lim it, the value o f this fraction approaches zero and thus the present value o f an ordinary p erpetuity is:11 C 3.27 where C = cash flow per period i = interest rate per period The valuation o f ordinary perpetuities is illustrated in Example 3.19. E xample 3.19 A government security promises to pay $3 per annum forever. If the interest rate is 8 per cent per annum and a payment of $3 has just been made, how much is the security worth? SOLUTION Using Equation 3.27: $3 0.08 =$37.50 The value of the security is $37.50. 3 .6 .4 ! Future value of annuities I t is frequently necessary to calculate the value o f an annuity as at the date o f the final cash flow. Such a calculation is required if, fo r example, regular savings are being made towards a target fu tu re sum. To derive the form ula fo r the future value o f an ordinary annuity, we use a two-stage process. First, the present value o f the annuity is calculated. Second, the future value is calculated by accumulating the present value fo r the n periods from the valuation date to the date o f the final cash flow. In effect we use the compound interest form ula S = P(1 + i)n where, in this case, P is given by the present value o f an ordinary annuity. That is: 1 (1 + i) n (1 + i) n = f [ ( i + On - i ] 3.28 I f C = $1, Equation 3.28 may be w ritte n as:12 S(n, i) = (1 + 〇 n-1 i 3.29 Values o f S(«, z) fo r different values o f n and i are given in Table 3 o f Appendix A. Alternatively, the M icrosoft Excel4 fu nctio n - FV(rate, nper, pm t) m aybe used. The FV fu nctio n returns the value o f- 1 x the future value o f an ordinary annuity, where 'rate* means the interest rate as a decimal, 'nper* means the number o f periods and pint* means the am ount o f each periodic cash flow. The calculation o f the future value o f an annuity is illustrated in Example 3.20. 11 • _ . . . c Similarly, it is a simple matter to show that the present value of a perpetuity-due is C + —, and the present value of a deferred 1 C i perpetuity, where the first cash flow occurs after k periods, i s ------- -- x (1 + i)K 12 The notation can also be used. CHAPTER THREE T he TIME VALUE 〇F MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS Example 3.20 Starting with his next monthly salary payment, Harold intends to save $ 2 00 each month. If the interest rate is 8.4 per cent per annum, payable monthly, how much will Harold have saved after 2 years? SOLUTION The monthly interest rate is 8.4/12 = 0.7 per cent. Using Equation 3.28, Harold's savings will amount to: s = y [ii+ - r - i] = ^ ° ° f(1.007)24- l l 0.007 L' J = $ 2 0 0 x2 6 .0 3 4 9 2 5 07 =$5206.99 Alternatively, using Microsoft Excel®, we find that - FV(0.007, 24, 200) = $5206.99. We could use this two-stage approach to derive formulae fo r the future values o f annuities-due and deferred annuities. In practice, however, i t is usually ju s t as easy to apply this approach using the numbers o f the particular problem. As we said at the sta rt o f this chapter, rather than learning a lis t o f formulae, i t is preferable to learn the approach and then apply th is approach to the particular problem. This is illustrated in Example 3.21. Example 3.21 Harold's sister Janice can also save $ 2 0 0 per month, but whereas Harold takes 1 month to save his first $200, Janice will start by setting aside $ 2 0 0 immediately. With an interest rate of 0.7 per cent per month, how much will she have in 2 years' time? Reconcile this amount with the savings achieved by Harold in the previous example. SOLUTION This problem requires the future value of an annuity-due. W e first calculate the present value, then accumulate this amount for 24 months: Step 1 n ^ C 1 (1 + /) $200. $200 0.007 (1.007)24 $4604.321 714 Step 2 S=P(1 +/)n =$4604.321 714(1.007)24 =$5443.43 Janice is thus able to save $5443.43 after 2 years, compared with Harold's savings of $5206.99. That is, Janice will save $236.44 more than Harold. Logically, this amount should equal the future value of the initial $ 2 0 0 Janice set aside at the start, accumulated for 24 months at 0.7 per cent per month. This is in fact the case, because $ 2 00 x (1.007)24 = $236.44. 6 B usiness finance 3.7 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 4 Apply your knowledge of annuities to solve a range of problems, including problems involving principaland-interest loan contracts Principal-and-interest loan contracts Basic features of the contract An im p o rta n t application o f annuities is to loan contracts, where the principal is gradually reduced by a series o f equal repayments. This type o f loan is often called a prin cipal-an d-in terest loan or a credit foncier loan. M any commercial loans, consumer loans and housing loans are in this category. The promised repayments form an annuity and the present value o f the repayments is equal to the loan principal. Therefore, i f the promised future repayments are made on tim e the debt should reduce gradually during the loan term , so th a t when the final promised repayment is made the debt should be extinguished. This pattern is illustrated in Example 3.22. Example 3.22 On 31 December 2014, Pennant Ltd borrows $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 from Z N A Bank. Annual repayments are required over 5 years at a fixed interest rate of 11.5 per cent per annum. How much is each annual repayment? Show the year-by-year record of the loan account for the 5 years ended 31 December 2019. SOLUTION PRIN CIPAL-AND INTEREST LOAN loan repaid by a sequence of equal cash flows, each of which is sufficient to cover the interest accrued since the previous payment and to reduce the current balance owing. Therefore, the debt is extinguished when the sequence of cash flows is completed. Also known as a credit fonder loan The annual repayments of C dollars form an ordinary annuity with a present value of $ 100000. Using Equation 3.19: $100000 C = 0.115 (1.115 广 C x 3.649 877 84 So c= $100000 _ 3.649 877 847 =$27398.18 The annual repayment required is $27398.1 8. Alternatively, we could use the Microsoft Excel® function PMTjrate, nper, pv). Using the spreadsheet, we find that -PM T(0.115,5, 100000) returns $27398.1 8. The year-by-year record o f the loan account is shown in Table 3.6. TABLE 3.6 Entry Date 31 December 2014 31 December 2015 31 December 2016 31 December 2017 Principal borrowed interest 0.115 x $100000.00 = $11500.00 Balance owing $100000.00 $111500.00 Less repayment $27398.18 $84101.82 Arfrf interest 0.115 x $84101.82 = $9671.71 $93 773.53 Less repayment $27398.18 $66375.35 AcW interest 0.115 x $66375.35 = $7633.17 $74008.52 Less repayment $27398.18 $46610.34 C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to finan c ial mathematics Table 3.6 continued Date Entry 31 December 2018 31 December 2019 Balance owing interest 0.115 x $46610.34 = $5360.19 $51970.53 Less repayment $27398.18 $24572.35 ^ i n t e r e s t 0.115 x $24572.35 = $2825.83 $27398.18 Less repayment $27398.18 $0.00 The year-by-year record shows th a t annual repayments o f $27398.18 are just sufficient to repay the loan over the 5-year term . 3 .7 .2 1 Principal and interest components As shown by the loan account in Example 3.22, the required repayments are ju s t sufficient to extinguish the debt at the required date. This is achieved by a series o f repayments, each o f which is sufficient to cover interest accrued since the previous repayment and to reduce the principal. As the principal decreases, so also does the interest accruing and thus, as tim e passes, a larger p roportion o f each repayment goes to reducing the principal. The principal and interest components o f the repayments in Example 3.22 are shown in Table 3.7. TABLE 3.7 Year ended 31 December Interest component ($) Principal component ($) Repayment ($) 2015 11500.00 15898.18 27398.18 2016 9671.71 17726.47 27398.18 2017 7633.17 19765.01 27398.18 2018 5 360.19 22037.99 27398.18 2019 2825.83 24572.35 27398.18 This pattern is more marked where the num ber o f repayments to be made is large. This is shown in Example 3.23. Example 3.23 Phantom Ltd borrows $1 0 0 0 0 0 at an interest rate of 1 1.5 per cent per annum, repayable by equal monthly instalments over 2 0 years. Calculate the principal and interest components of the first and last repayments. SOLUTION In this example, the monthly interest rate is 0 .1 1 5 /1 2 = 0 .0 0 9 5 8 3 3 3 3 and the loan term is 20 x 12 = 2 40 months. W e use Equation 3 .19 to calculate the monthly repayment: $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 = --------- ---------0.009583 333 1- ________ 1________ (1.009583 333)240 = C x 93.77084022 continued continued So c= $100000 ~ 93.770 840 22 = $1066.43 The interest accrued during the first month of the loan is 0 .0 0 9 5 8 3 333 x $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 = $958.33. Therefore, when the first monthly repayment of $ 1066.43 is made, $958.33 (or nearly 90 per cent of the repayment) is required to meet the interest accrued during the first month and only $108.10 (just over 10 per cent of the repayment) is available to reduce the principal. At the end of the loan term this pattern is reversed. Only a small amount of interest will accrue during the last month, so almost the whole of the final monthly repayment will be available to reduce the principal. The component of principal in the final repayment is $ 1 0 6 6 .4 3 / 1 .0 0 9 5 8 3 333 = $1056.31; therefore, the interest component is only $10.1 2. One aspect of this pattern is that the balance owing decreases slowly in the early stages of repayment, but decreases rapidly as the maturity date is approached. This pattern is considered in more detail in the next section. 3 .7 .3 ] Balance owing at any given date The balance owing at any given date is the present value o f the then rem aining repayments. We explained earlier how the principal is the present value o f all promised repayments. O f course, the principal is sim ply the balance owing at the tim e the loan is made. Similarly, the balance owing at any given date is the present value o f the repayments s till to be made as at th a t date. The calculation o f the balance owing on a loan is illustrated in Example 3.24. E xample 3.24 Consider again Phantom Ltd's loan of $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 at an interest rate of 1 1.5 per cent per annum, repayable by equal monthly instalments over 20 years. As shown in Example 3.23, the required monthly repayment is $1066.43. W hat is the balance owing when: a) one-third of the loan term has expired? b) two-thirds of the loan term has expired? SOLUTION a) The loan term is 2 4 0 months. Therefore, when one-third (or 80 months) of this term has expired, 160 monthly repayments are still to be made. The balance owing at the end of month 80 is the present value of the then remaining 16 0 repayments: $1066.43 0.009583 333 (1.009583 333)*160. = $87087.85 b) When two-thirds (or 160 months) of the loan term has expired, 80 monthly repayments still have to be made. Therefore, the balance owing at the end of month 160 is: $1066.43 ________1________ ■ 0.009583 333 (1.009583 333)80. =$59394.64 C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction t o financial mathematics In the previous section we explained that, in these types of loans, the balance owing reduces slowly at first and more rapidly towards the end of the loan term. This pattern is clearly evident in this example. When one-third of the loan term has expired, the balance owing is still more than $ 8 7 0 0 0 out of an original loan of $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 . That is, the passing of one-third of the loan term has seen the principal fall by less than 13 per cent. When two-thirds of the loan term has expired, only about 4 0 per cent of the debt has been repaid. A more detailed presentation of this pattern is provided in Figure 3.2. Figure 3.2 Balance owing as a loan is repaid o o o o o o o o 0 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 o o o - $ lM O cr) .E 9UUDID CQ 10 220 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 Months remaining 3 .7 .4 1 Loan term required In some applications it is necessary to solve fo r the required loan term n given the principal, interest rate and periodic repayment. For example, in order to plan future expenditure, a borrow er may wish to know when an existing loan w ill be repaid. Solving fo r the loan term requires us to rearrange Equation 3.19 so th a t n appears on the left-hand side: C (i + 0" c (1 + i) n ( i + O77 c C -P i and therefore: n = log[C/(C-P/)] i 〇g (i + 〇 _ _ E E 3 Logarithms to any base (such as base 10 or base e) w ill give the correct answer. The calculation o f a required loan term is illustrated in Example 3.25. A B usiness finance E xample 3.25 One year ago, Canberra Fruit Ltd borrowed $ 7 5 0 0 0 0 at an interest rate of 12 per cent per annum. The loan is being repaid by monthly instalments of $ 1 6 6 8 3 .3 4 over 5 years. As a result of making the promised repayments over the past year, the balance owing is now $ 6 33 532 .48 . The company can now afford repayments of $ 2 0 0 0 0 per month and the company manager wishes to know when the loan will be repaid if repayments are increased to that level. The manager also wishes to know the amount of the final repayment. SOLUTION Using Equation 3.30: n _ log [C /(C -P i] lo g (l + /) _ log { $ 2 0 0 0 0 / [ $ 2 0 0 0 0 - ($633 5 3 2.481(0.011]} = log(l.Ol) _ lo g ( $ 2 0 0 0 0 / $ l3 6 6 4 .6 7 5 2 ) = l〇g(i. 〇 i) _ log (1 .4 6 3 6 2 7 9 1 ) = log(l.Ol) Using 'common' logarithms (logarithms to the base 10):13 = 0 .1 6 5 4 3 0 6 8 2 0 .0 0 4 321 373 = 3 8 .2 8 2 months The loan will be repaid after a further 39 months; for the first 38 months the repayment will be $ 2 0 0 0 0 per month, while the last (39th) repayment will be a smaller amount. The amount of the last repayment must be such that the present value of all 39 repayments equals the balance owing of $633 532.48. Using R to represent the amount of the last repayment, we therefore require that: $ 6 3 3 5 3 2 .4 8 = $20000 0.01 R (1.01)38 (1.01)39 = $ 6 2 9 69 3 .2 6 6 1 + — (1.01)39 $ 3 8 3 9 .2 1 3 9 = R (1.01)39 which gives R = $5659.47. The amount of the last (39th) repayment is $5659.47. 3 .7 .5 1 Changing the interest rate VARIABLE INTEREST RATE LOAN loan where the lender can change the interest rate charged, usually in line with movements in the general level of interest rates in the economy In some loan contracts, usually called variable in terest rate loans, the interest rate can be changed at any tim e by the lender, although, in practice, changes are norm ally made only when there has been a change in the general level o f interest rates in the economy. Such a change may be signalled or caused by the Reserve Bank o f Australia changing the cash rate. In Australia, many housing loans, and many commercial loans, are in this category. Typically, the parties to the contract w ill at the outset agree on a notio na l loan term — say, 15 years fo r a housing loan— and the lender w ill then require a regular repayment th a t is calculated as i f the current interest rate is fixed fo r 15 years. If, as is always the case, the general level o f interest rates subsequently changes, the interest rate charged on the loan w ill then be changed. The lender w ill then set the new required repayment, which w ill be calculated as i f the new interest rate is fixed fo r the remaining 13 令 Use of natural logarithms (logarithms to the base e) must give the same answer. In this case the calculation is n = 0.380918223/0.00995033 = 38.282. C hapter THREE T he TIME VALUE OF MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS loan term. Alternatively, the lender may allow the borrower to continue m aking the same repayment and, instead, alter the loan term to reflect the new interest rate.14 O f course, a com bination o f b oth responses is also a possibility. These choices are illustrated in Example 3.26. E xample 3.26 Three years ago Andrew and Jane borrowed $ 8 0 0 0 0 , repayable by equal monthly instalments over 15 years. At the time they borrowed the money, the interest rate was 9.6 per cent per annum calculated monthly. Following standard procedures, the lender correctly calculated the required monthly payment to be $840.21. Andrew and Jane have made all repayments on time and the balance owing is now $71 685.05. The general level of interest rates has been rising and the lender has now decided to increase the interest rate to 10.8 per cent per annum calculated monthly. What will be the new monthly repayment if the loan term is to remain unchanged? If, instead, the monthly repayment is left at $840.21, by how many months will the loan term increase? SOLUTION The new monthly repayment C must be set so that the present value, calculated using the ne w interest rate, of the remaining 144 repayments equals the balance outstanding of $71 685.05. The new interest rate is 10.8 per cent per annum or 0.9 per cent per month. Therefore, using Equation 3.19: $ 7 1 6 8 5 .0 5 = — ^ 1 --------- — 0.009 L (1.009)144. = 80.531 669 39 C C = $890.15 The new repayment is $890.15 per month. Alternatively, if the loan term is extended, and the monthly repayment is left at $840.21, the new loan term may be found using Equation 3.30: n log [C /(C -P f)] log(l + /) log {$8 40.21/[$840.21 -($71 685.05)(0.009)]} log( 1.009) _ log(4.307785 068) = log( 1.009) =162.998 months w 163 months The remaining loan term is now 163 months, which is 19 months longer than the 144 'expected7 at the time of the interest rate increase. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 5 Distinguish between simple and general annuities and make basic calculations involving general annuities SIMPLE A N N U IT Y 3.8 G eneral annuities In our discussion o f annuities, the frequency o f compounding has coincided w ith the frequency o f the cash flows. An a nnuity w ith this feature is called a sim ple annuity. For example, we have considered cases where interest is calculated and charged annually, and the borrow er is required to make annual repayments. In practice, however, this is n ot always the case. Situations arise where loan repayments are required more frequently, o r less frequently, than interest is charged (compounded). An a nnuity w ith this feature is called a general annuity. 14 Note, however, that if the interest rate is increased to a level where the monthly repayment is less than the monthly interest accruing (that is, C < P i), then the loan term becomes infinite. In these circumstances lenders will usually require a higher monthly repayment. annuity in which the frequency of charging interest matches the frequency of payment GENERAL A N N U IT Y annuity in which the frequency of charging interest does not match the frequency of payment; thus, repayments may be made either more frequently or less frequently than interest is charged In a general annuity, the frequency o f compounding does n o t match the frequency o f repayment. There are thus two cases to consider: a b The frequency o f compounding is greater than the frequency o f repayment. For example, a loan contract may specify an interest rate o f 8 per cent per annum, compounding quarterly, b u t repayments are made annually. The frequency o f compounding is less than the frequency o f repayment. For example, a loan contract may specify an interest rate o f 8 per cent per annum, compounding quarterly, b u t repayments are made m onthly. In b oth cases, to solve the problem we need firs t to adjust the specified interest rate to an interest rate where the compounding frequency matches the repayment frequency.15 This adjustm ent is made using the concept o f the effective interest rate th a t we discussed in Section 3.4.3. This concept was summarised in Equation 3.6, which we reproduce below: / . \ m /=(1 +m) where _1 i = the effective interest rate per period j = the nom inal interest rate, compounding m times per period Note th a t in this equation the tim e dimension o f z is fo r a longer period than the tim e dimension o f m ight be an interest rate per quarter. I t is convenient to restate Equation 3.6 in terms o f an interest rate zs, fo r the shorter tim e period, and an interest rate zL, fo r the longer tim e period. That is, Equation 3.6 is rew ritten as: j/m . For example, z m ig ht be an interest rate per annum while 3.31 where m = the num ber o f ‘short’ periods in one ‘long’ period. The use o f Equation 3.31 is illustrated in Examples 3.27 and 3.28. E xample 3.27 Use Equation 3.31 to express 8 per cent per annum, compounding quarterly, as: a) an effective annual interest rate b) an effective monthly interest rate. SOLUTION a) In this case, interest is compounding quarterly and we wish to calculate an equivalent interest rate in which compounding occurs annually. Thus we are required to calculate iL, where is = 0.08/4 = 0.02, and m = 4. Using Equation 3.31: 彳=(1 + 'S )m _ 1 = (1.02)4 -1 = 0 .0 8 2 4 3 2 16 « 8 .2 4 3 % perannum b) In this case, interest is compounding quarterly and we wish to calculate an equivalent interest rate in which compounding occurs monthly. Thus we are required to calculate is, where iL = 0.08/4 = 0.02 and m = 3. Using Equation 3.31: 0.02 = (1 + /s)3 - l /s = (1 .0 2 )1/ 3 _ l = 0 .0 0 6 6 2 2 71 « 0 .6 6 2 % per month 15 Alternatively, an adjustment can be made to the repayment amount. However, when using a calculator it is generally easier to adjust the interest rate. C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to finan c ial mathematics Example 3.28 A loan is currently being repaid by repayments of $ 5 5 0 0 0 at the end of each quarter. The interest rate is 8 per cent per annum. The borrower wishes to change to a monthly repayment schedule that will pay oft the loan by the same maturity date. Calculate the amount of each monthly repayment. SOLUTION The repayment schedule for a typical quarter is shown in Figure 3.3. :igure 3.3 Monthly and quarterly repayments i :l 3 me)nths $c $C $55 000 $C As shown in Figure 3.3, it is proposed to replace each end-of-quarter cash flow of $ 5 5 0 0 0 with three end-of-month cash flows of C dollars each. Interest is charged quarterly at a nominal rate of 8 per cent per annum— that is, the effective qfuarter/y interest rate is 2 per cent per quarter. As shown in Example 3.27 (b), the equivalent effective m onthly interest rate is 0.662 271 per cent per month. Equating the present values of the quarterly and monthly cash-flow streams gives: $55 000 = 1.02 C (1.006622 71 )3 1.006622 71 Note, however, that although we have included the calculation of (1.006622 71 )3 in this expression, this calculation should by definition equal 1.02 (see the calculation in Example 3.27 (b) for clarification). Therefore, we need to solve: $55 000 = 1.02 which gives C L _ 0.006622 71 L 1 ' 1.02. C = $ 1 8 2 1 2 .4 5 Therefore, monthly repayments of $1 8 2 1 2 .4 5 will pay the loan off at the same maturity date as quarterly repayments of $ 5 5 0 0 0 . Note that 3 x $18 212.45 = $5 46 37.3 5, which is slightly less than the quarterly repayment of $5 5 0 0 0 . This difference reflects the present-value effect of making monthly repayments earlier than the quarterly repayments they replace. B usiness finance SUMMARY • Financial managers frequently make decisions that involve the time value of money. This chapter covered the major tools of financial mathematics needed to support these decisions. These tools include calculating rates of return, present values and future values, and defining and applying interest rates, including simple interest and compound interest. • The definition and valuation of various streams of cash flows were considered in detail, with the present value of an ordinary annuity being used as the basis for dealing with several related problems. Annuity applications, including interest-only loans and principal-and-interest loans, were also discussed. • A wider class of problems, in which interest is charged either more frequently or less frequently than cash flows occur, was also discussed. • Throughout the chapter, emphasis was placed on developing a sound understanding to support the use of the various formulae that were derived. KEY TERMS accumulation 34 annuity 50 annuity-due 50 cash flow 29 compound interest 33 continuous interest 42 debt 30 deferred annuity 50 discounting 36 effective interest rate 37 financial contract 29 future sum 32 general annuity 63 geometric rate of return 44 interes卜 only loan 37 interest rate 30 log price relative 43 nominal interest rate 3 7 , 40 ordinary annuity 50 ordinary perpetuity 51 present value 32 present value of a contract 47 principal 31 principal-and-interest loan 58 rate of return 29 real interest rate 40 simple annuity 63 simple interest 31 terminal value of a contract 47 time value of money 30 variable interest rate loan 62 SELF-TEST PROBLEMS 1 Andrew borrowed $ 6 0 0 0 and repaid the loan 60 days later by a single payment of $6250. What is the implied annual simple interest rate? 2 Angela deposits $ 5 0 0 0 today in a bank account that pays interest annually at the rate of 8 per cent. She then makes 10 more deposits of $ 1 0 0 0 each at annual intervals. a) How much does she have when she has made the last deposit? b) If Angela wished to accumulate the same sum by making a single deposit now, what amount would she need to deposit? 3 Geoff and Gail wish to borrow $ 7 5 0 0 0 to be repaid by equal monthly instalments over 25 years. The nominal annual interest rate is 9.9 per cent. a) What is the effective annual interest rate? b) What is the amount of the monthly repayment? Solutions to self-test problem s ore a v a ila b le in A p p e n d ix B. INTERNATIONAL ARTICLES International articles related to this topic are available on the Online Learning Centre at www.mhhe.com / au /peirso n!2 e 66 C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to finan c ial mathematics 1 [LO 1] Explain the difference(s) between an interest rate and a rate of return. 2 [LO 1] Distinguish between simple interest and compound interest. 3 [LO 1] In financial mathematics, the symbol P can stand for 'present value', 'price' or 'prin cipa l’,but all three terms really hove the some meaning. Discuss. 4 [ L O llT h e term 'nominal interest rate' has two different meanings. Explain these two meanings, distinguishing carefully between them. 5 [LO 1] Rotes o f return should be multiplied, not added. Is this true? Why, or why not? 6 [LO 2] Given a required rote o f return, a set o f cash inflows can be valued os at any date, and the later is the valuation date the higher the value. Is this true? Why, or why not? 7 [LO 3] Distinguish between an annuity-due and a deferred annuity. 8 [LO 4] In any variable interest rote loon, it is possible that the interest rate con be increased to a level where the loan term becomes infinite unless the periodic repayment is increased. Explain how this can occur, and relate your answer to the characteristics of Equation 3.30. 9 [LO 5] Distinguish between a simple annuity and a general annuity. CHAPTER THUEE REVIEW QUESTIONS PROBLEMS 1 Simple interest earned [LO 1] Nicholas deposits $2 0 0 0 in a bank fixed deposit for 6 months at an interest rate of 13.25 per cent per annum. How much interest will he earn? 2 Simple interest earned [LO 1] If Nicholas reinvests the $2000, plus the interest earned (see Problem 1), for a further 6 months, again at 13.25 per cent per annum, how much interest will he earn in this second 6-month period? 3 Implied simple interest rate [LO 1] Jane borrowed $ 1 0 0 0 0 and repaid the loan 30 days later by a single payment of $10400. What is the implied annual simple interest rate? 4 Calculating the loan term [LO 1] Mary borrowed $7250 at an annual simple interest rate of 15.50 per cent. She repaid the loan by paying a lump sum of $7394.70. What was the loan term? 5 Calculating the lump sum repayment [LO 1] On 2 April 2014, Paradise Pencils Ltd borrows $2 00 000 , repaying in a lump sum on 16 M ay 2014. The interest rate is 9.55 per cent per annum. How much is the lump sum repayment? 6 Simple interest earned (harder) [LO 1] On 5 February 2014, Financial Solutions Ltd deposits $ 3 0 0 0 0 0 with Second Street Bank at a simple interest rate of 4.4 per cent per annum. The maturity date of the deposit is 5 M ay 2014. Calculate the amount of interest the deposit will earn. 7 Present value [LO 1] Jupiter Mining Ltd promises to pay $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 in 90 days' time. Taking into account the company’s credit standing, the market interest rate for a loan period of 90 days is 10.65 per cent per annum. How much can Jupiter Mining borrow? 8 Simple and compound interest [LO 1] a) What will be the accumulated value, at the end of 10 years, of $1000 invested in a savings account that pays 8 per cent per annum? Assume that no withdrawals are made from the savings account until the end of the tenth year. What is the interest component of the accumulated value? b) Assume that interest is withdrawn every year. What will be the total interest earnings at the end of the tenth year? W hy does this amount differ from the interest earned in Problem 8 (a)? 67 Compound interest earned [LO 1] If you invest $ 6 5 0 0 0 for 3 years at 14.7 per cent per annum (interest payable annually), how much will you have at the end of the 3 years? Compound interest earned [LO 1] If you invest $ 8 7 0 0 0 at 7.35 per cent per annum (interest paid annually), how much will you have: a) at the end of 3 years? b) at the end of 6 years? Compound interest earned (harder) [LO 1] Frank has invested $ 1 0 0 0 0 for 10 years at 12.4 per cent per annum. He has to pay tax on the interest income each year. a) Calculate the value of the investment at the end of the tenth year if his tax rate is: i) 45 per cent per annum ii) 30 per cent per annum iii) 15 per cent per annum iv) zero per annum. b) Rework your answer to (a)(i) if, instead of having to pay tax each year, Frank must pay in tax 45 per cent of the accumulated interest at the end of the tenth year. Which tax system is better for him? W h y? Compound interest earned [LO 1】 Philip invests $ 1 7 2 0 0 at an interest rate of 2.5 per cent per quarter. How much is the investment worth after 2 years? Compound interest earned [LO 1】 Rhiannyn invests $ 2 5 0 0 0 at an interest rate of 0.6 per cent per month. How much is the investment worth after 3 years? Present value [LO 1] Calculate the following present values: a) $1 00 0 payable in 5 years if the interest rate is 12 per cent per annum b) $ 1000 payable in 10 years if the interest rate is 12 per cent per annum c) $1000 payable in 5 years if the interest rate is 6 per cent per annum d) $ 1 6 2 0 5 payable in 1 year if the interest rate is 1.5 per cent per month e) $1 million payable in 4 0 years if the interest rate is 15 per cent per annum f) $1 million payable in 100 years if the interest rate is 15 per cent per annum. Compound interest [LO 1] Neeta Stoves Ltd borrows $8 00 0 repayable in a lump sum after 1 year. The interest rate agreed to is described as ' 15.0 per cent per annum, calculated monthly’. How much is the repayment? Implied compound interest rate [LO 1] What is the annual interest rate (compound) implied by each of the following future values (FV), present values (PV) and terms (/): a) FV = $9 20 00; PV = $8 20 00; f = 2 years b) FV = $1 6 0 4 6 0 0 ; PV = $1 50 0 0 0 0 ; f= 4 years c) FV = $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 ; PV = $ 1 3 0 7 6 0 0 ; t = 3 years d) FV = $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 ; PV = $ 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 ; t = 6 years e) FV = $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 ; PV = $ 6 0 0 0 0 0 0 ; f = 5.5 years? Effective annual interest rate [LO 1] What is the effective annual interest rate corresponding to each of the following nominal interest rates: a) 18 per cent per annum, payable half-yearly b) 18 per cent per annum, payable monthly c) 18 per cent per annum, payable fortnightly d) 1 8 per cent per annum, payable daily e) 18 per cent per annum, payable continuously? C hapter THREE T he TIME VALUE 〇F MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS Effective annual interest rate [LO 1] What is the effective annual interest rate corresponding to each of the following nominal interest rates: a) 7.5 per cent per annum, payable half-yearly b) 7.5 per cent per annum, payable monthly c) 7.5 per cent per annum, payable fortnightly d) 7.5 per cent per annum, payable daily e) 7.5 per cent per annum, payable continuously? 19 Effective annual interest rate [LO 1] Jerm Ltd buys a bank bill for $91 107 and sells it 5 4 days later for $93 323. What annual effective interest rate did Jerm Ltd earn? 20 Simple interest and effective annual interest rate [LO 1] Liana Ltd bought a bank bill on 7 January 2012 for $976 751 and sold it on 3 March 2012 for $98761 8. a) What simple interest rate did Liana Ltd earn? b) What annual effective interest rate did Liana Ltd earn? 21 Calculating the effective annual interest rate [LO 1] On 16 January 201 2, an investor lent a sum of money to be repaid, with interest, on 1 1 March 2012. The interest rate was 6.15 per cent and was quoted on a simple interest basis. What effective annual interest rate did the investor earn? 22 CHAPTER THUEE REVIEW 18 Effective annual interest rate (harder) [LO 1] Rock Solid Ltd sells, on credit, goods to the value of $8465.95 to University Garden Supplies Ltd. Rock Solid offers a discount of half of 1 per cent for payment within 7 days; otherwise, payment must be made on or before the thirtieth day. What is the effective annual interest rate implicit in the discount being offered? State any assumptions you make. 23 Effective annual interest rate (harder) [LO 1] Since 1 August 201 2, W ing Yin's investment policy has been to lodge fixed (term) deposits at her local bank. The bank pays interest on the maturity date of a deposit and the interest rate is expressed as an annual simple interest rate. When a deposit matures, W ing Yin's policy is to re-lodge the whole sum (principal and interest) immediately for a further period. She chooses the term of each deposit according to her assessment of the interest rates available at that time. W ing Yin's decisions to date are as follows: Date Decision 1 August 2012 8-month deposit at 9.15 per cent per annum 1 April 2013 6-month deposit at 8.45 per cent per annum 1 October 2013 10-month deposit at 8.16 per cent per annum Calculate, as at 1 August 2014, the effective annual interest rate W ing Yin has earned since she began this policy. (Assume that all months are of equal length.) Briefly explain each step. 24 Nominal interest rate [LO 1] A retail chain operates its own credit provision system for customers. Company policy is to set a nominal annual interest rate, and to charge interest monthly. To cover its costs and make a return on capital, the company has a target effective interest rate of 19.5 per cent per annum. What nominal annual interest rate should it set? 25 Nominal interest rate [LO 1] If the real interest rate is 10 per cent per annum, and the expected inflation rate is 25 per cent per annum, what should be the nominal interest rate? 26 Nominal interest rate (harder) [LO 1] George is intending to lend money to his nephew to help him set up a new business. The loan will be made now, and is to be repaid in a lump sum after 3 years. George wishes to earn a real interest rate of 3.5 per cent per annum. He expects the inflation rate in the coming year to be 10 per cent but believes that it will fall steadily thereafter to 6 per cent in the following year and to 4 per cent in the third year. What annual interest rate should George set on the loan? 69 27 Nominal interest rate (harder) [LO 1] Grose Paterson Bank Ltd is intending to lend money to a client. The loan is to be repaid in a lump sum after 7 years. The bank's required real rate of return is 3 per cent per annum. The bank expects the inflation rate in the coming year to be 8 per cent per annum, falling to 5 per cent per annum the following year and 4 per cent per annum thereafter. What annual interest rate should the bank set? 28 Real annual rate of return [LO 1] In Xanadu, the consumer price index (CPI) stood at 147.6 on 1 January 2010. O n that date, SBF Ltd invested $ 5 0 0 0 0 for 4 years at an interest rate of 11.4 per cent per annum (compound). On 1 January 2 0 14 the CPI stood at 193.8. What real annual rate of return has SBF earned? 29 Log price relative [LO 1] An investor purchases 1000 shares at $5.50 per share on 31 M ay 2014. Over the next 6 months the investor notes down the price of the share at the end of each month. The result is shown below: End o f June $5.85 End of July $6.12 End o f August $5.75 End o f September $5.75 End o f October $6.44 End of November $6.60 There were no dividends paid in this period. Calculate, for each month, the log price relative, using natural (base e) logarithms. What does the sum of the log price relatives represent? Compare this sum to ^n($6.60/$5.50). Explain. 30 Average annual rate of return [LO 1] Matthew bought an apartment for $3 64 000 . After 4 years he estimates that its value has changed as follows: In Year 1: an increase of 7 per cent In Year 2: an increase of 2 7 per cent In Year 3: a decrease of 5 per cent In Year 4: an increase of 1 1 per cent. How much is it worth now? What is the average annual rate of return? 31 Present value [LO 1] What is the present value (at 7 per cent per annum) of a contract that provides for the following three payments to be made: After 6 months: $7601 After 2.5 years: $9900 After 7 years: $1 8 5 2 2 ? 32 Present and future values [LO 1] A company is entitled to receive a cash inflow of $8 00 0 in 2 years7 time and a further cash inflow of $ 1 4 0 0 0 in 5 years' time. If the interest rate is 8.5 per cent per annum, how much is this stream of cash inflows worth: a) today b) in 5 years7 time. 33 Internal rate of return [LO 1] An investment costs $ 5 0 0 0 0 and generates cash inflows of $ 4 0 0 0 0 after 1 year and $ 3 0 0 0 0 after 2 years. Show that the internal rate of return on this investment is approximately 27.2 per cent per annum. 34 Valuation of cash flows at any date [LO 2] A contract will produce cash inflows on 4 different dates. These cash inflows are: $1 0 0 0 after 1 year, $8000 after 3 years, $ 1 2 0 0 0 after 7 years and $ 1 0 0 0 0 after 10 years. The required rate of return is 8.5 per cent per annum. a) Calculate the present value. b) Calculate the value as at the start of Year 1. C hapter three T he time value of m o n e y : a n introduction to finan c ial mathematics d) Calculate the value as at the start of Year 7. e) Calculate the terminal value. f) What is the relationship between these successive valuations? 35 Valuing different types of annuity [LO 3] Consider an annuity of 6 cash flows of $5 00 0 payable annually. If the interest rate is 7 per cent per annum, what is the value of this annuity today if the first cash flow is to be paid: a) immediately b) in 1 year’s time c) in 4 years' time? 36 Annuities [LO 3] Today is Stanley's 55th birthday. He plans to retire on his 65th birthday and wants to put aside the same sum of money every birthday (starting today) up to and including his 65th birthday. He then wants to be able to withdraw $ 1 0 0 0 0 every birthday (starting with his 66th) up to and including his 85th birthday. He believes that an interest rate of 10 per cent per annum is a reasonable estimate. How much does he need to put aside each birthday? 37 O rdinary perpetuities [LO 3] How much money would be needed to establish a permanent scholarship paying $1 00 0 at the end of each year, if money can be invested at 8 per cent per annum? 38 CHAPTER THREE REVIEW c) Calculate the value as at the start of Year 3. O rdinary perpetuities (harder) [LO 3] Kevin Oldfellow attended Unicorn High School in the 1960s. After leaving school, Kevin established an advertising agency that proved to be highly successful. Kevin is now very wealthy and wishes to establish a fund that will provide a perpetual scholarship scheme to support students at Unicorn High. At the initiation of the scheme Kevin will award six scholarships— one each to students currently in Years 7 to 12 inclusive. These students keep these scholarships until they leave the school. In subsequent years, one scholarship will be awarded every year to a student entering the school at Year 7 and that student keeps the scholarship through to Year 12. Kevin has sought advice from the school and has been told that it costs about $6 00 0 to keep a student at Unicorn High for 1 year. The current long-term nominal interest rate is 6 per cent per annum. The long-term real interest rate is estimated to be 2.5 per cent per annum. Kevin has been advised that it will cost him $ 6 3 6 0 0 0 to set up the scheme. However, Kevin is not convinced, arguing that, 'The current inflation rate is about 3.5 per cent per annum. If this continues then it won't be long before the real value of a scholarship will not be enough to keep a student at the school for a year. Surely this has to be factored into the calculation somehow'. Kevin has approached you for advice. a) What is the logic behind the advice that a fund of $ 6 3 6 0 0 0 would be sufficient? Show your calculations. b) Suppose that for the next 5 years the annual inflation rate continues to be 3.5 per cent and the annual interest rate continues to be 6 per cent. What will be the real value of an annual scholarship payment after 5 years? c) What amount would you advise Kevin to put into the scholarship fund? Explain. d) Assuming that the forecasts in (b) are correct, show how the amount in the fund and the amount of each scholarship would evolve over the first 2 years. 39 Deferred perpetuities [LO 3] A pine plantation returns nothing to its owner in the first 2 years. In the following 2 years, the returns are $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 and $1 50 000 , respectively, and after that the return is $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 per year in perpetuity. All returns are in cash and occur at year end. a) What is the present value of the constant return stream at the beginning of the fifth year if the returns can be invested at 8 per cent per annum? b) What is the current present value of the whole return stream at the same required rate of return? 40 Deferred perpetuities [LO 3] What is the present value of a perpetual cash inflow of $1 00 0 received at the end of each year, the first inflow occurring 2 years from now, if the interest rate is 5 per cent per annum? This cash flow can be produced by investing $ 1 0 0 0 0 in a business this year and $6 00 0 next year. What is the present value of the investment? Is it profitable? 71 B usiness finance 41 Calculating principal and interest repayments [LO 4] Luke borrows $ 8 0 0 0 0 0 from a bank to set up a medical practice. He agrees to pay a fixed interest rate of 10.2 per cent per annum (calculated monthly) and to repay by equal monthly instalments over 10 years. Calculate the monthly repayment. By how much does Luke's first repayment reduce the principal? If the loan is paid off as planned, by how much will the lost repayment reduce the principal? 42 Calculating principal outstanding [LO 4] After making 21 monthly repayments, Luke (see Problem 41) inherits a large sum of money and decides to repay the (remaining) loan. When the twenty-second repayment is due he asks for the payout figure. How much should it be? 43 Calculating the loan term [LO 4] John decides that he desperately needs a new Italian suit priced at $1999. He borrows the money and agrees to pay $71.07 each month at an interest rate of 16.8 per cent per annum, payable monthly. For how long will he be making repayments? 44 Annual rate of return [LO 4] What is the approximate annual rate of return on an investment with an initial cash outlay of $ 1 0 0 0 0 and net cash inflows of $2 77 0 per year for 5 years? 45 Nom inal interest rate and effective interest rate [LO 4 】 Warren Cameron buys a boat for $30000, paying $5 00 0 deposit. The remainder is borrowed from the Goodfriend Loan Co. to be repaid by 15 monthly payments of $2027.50 each. What is the monthly interest rate being charged? What is the nominal annual interest rate? What is the effective annual interest rate? 46 Calculating the loan term [LO 4 】 Anne Hopewell has just borrowed $ 7 0 0 0 0 to be repaid by monthly repayments over 20 years at an interest rate of 18 per cent per annum. Based on this information, the monthly repayment is approximately $1 08 0 but Anne intends to make higher monthly repayments. She asks you how long it will take to repay the loan if the amount she pays per month is: a) $1100 b) $1200 c) $1500. 47 Annuities [LO 4] Layla borrows $5 00 00, repayable in monthly instalments over 10 years. The nominal interest rate is 12 per cent per annum. What is the monthly repayment? After 3 years have passed, the lender increases the interest rate to 13.5 per cent per annum and Layla is given the choice of either increasing the monthly repayment or extending the term of the loan. What would be the new monthly repayment? What would be the new loan term? 48 Annuities [LO 4] Exactly a year ago, Stephen and Lan Kuan borrowed $ 1 5 0 0 0 0 from a bank, to be repaid in equal monthly instalments over 25 years at an interest rate of 7.8 per cent per annum. Today, the bank told them that it was introducing a monthly fee of $10 but they could continue to repay the loan by making their current monthly payments. However, Stephen and Lan Kuan are worried because if they do this, the loan will take longer to repay. They have asked you to calculate how much longer it will take to repay the loan. 49 Effective annual interest rate, repayments and loan terms [LO 4 】 Don and Jenny wish to borrow $180000, to be repaid over a period of 20 years by monthly instalments. The interest rate (nominal) is 7.8 per cent per annum. The first payment is due at the end of the first month. a) Calculate the effective annual interest rate. b) Calculate the amount of the monthly repayment if the same amount is to be repaid every month for the period of the loan. c) Suppose, instead, that the lender agrees that Don and Jenny will repay $1 10 0 per month for the first 12 months, then $ 1 2 5 0 per month for 出e 12 months after that, then $X per month thereafter. Assuming that the term is to stay at 20 years, how much is $X? d) Alternatively, suppose that Don and Jenny decide to repay $2 50 0 per month from the time the money is borrowed until it is repaid. How long would it take to repay the loan? What would be the amount of the final payment? 72 C hapter THREE T he TIME VALUE 〇F MONEY: AN INTRODUCTION TO FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS Repayments and loan terms [LO 4 】 Peter borrowed $ 8 0 0 0 0 0 to refit his fishing trawler. The loan requires monthly repayments over 15 years. When he borrowed the money the interest rate was 13.5 per cent per annum, but 18 months later the bank increased the interest rate to 15.0 per cent per annum, in line with market rates. The bank tells Peter he can increase his monthly repayment (so as to pay off the loan by the originally agreed date) or he can extend the term of the loan (and keep making the same monthly repayment). Calculate: a) the new monthly repayment if Peter accepts the first option b) the extra period added to the loan term if Peter accepts the second option. 51 Calculating repayments [LO 4] Wahroonga Furniture Ltd (WFL) is planning a large sale of its stock of lounge suites and dining tables. As part of its marketing, WFL will offer customers loans of up to $1 00 00, with no repayment required during the first 6 months. The customer then makes equal monthly repayments. The total loan term (including the first 6 months) is 2 years. The effective interest rate that WFL requires on the loans is 12 per cent per annum. What monthly repayment must WFL charge on a loan of $ 1 0 0 0 0 ? 52 Simple and general annuities [LO 5] A simple annuity of $ 3 00 per quarter is to be replaced by annual payments (the payments to be made at the end of each year). What will be the annual payments if the nominal interest rate is 6 per cent per annum? CHAPTER THREE REVIEW 50 REFERENCES Crapp, H. & Marshall, J., Money Market Maths, Allen & Unwin, Sydney, 1986. M artin, P. & Burrow, M ., Applied Financial Mathematics, Prentice-Hall, Sydney, 1991. Knox, DM., Zima, P. & Brown, R.L., Mathematics of Finance, 2nd edn, M cG raw-H ill, Sydney, 1999. 73 CHAPTER FOUR Applying the time value of money . to security . valuation CHAPTER CONTENTS ED Introduction 75 Financial asset valuation under certainty 75 Valuation of shares 76 HH Valuation of debt securities 80 BH Interest rate risk 81 m m The term structure of interest rates 82 EB The default-risk structure of interest rates 89 BE1 Other factors affecting interest rate structures 91 Appendix 4.1 Duration and immunisation 97 LEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: 命 1 understand how assets are valued under conditions of certainty 2 use the tools of financial mathematics to value equity securities 3 explain the main differences between the valuation of ordinary shares based on dividends and on Gamings 4 use the tools of financial mathematics to value debt securities 5 explain the nature of interest rate risk 6 understand the theories that are used to explain the term structure of interest rates 7 understand the effect of default risk on interest rates 8 apply the concept of duration to immunise a bond investment. C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation In Chapter 1 we discussed b riefly the im p o rta n t concept o f the tim e value o f money. In Chapter 3 we presented some mathematical tools useful in analysing problems involving the tim e value o f money. In particular, we showed how promised streams o f future cash flows can be valued, provided th a t the required rate o f retu rn is known. In this chapter we apply these tools to the valuation o f debt and equity securities. In itia lly we assume th a t the security s fu tu re cash flows are know n w ith certainty. Later in the chapter we introduce uncertainty, b ut only in a lim ite d way. A more form al and detailed treatm ent o f u ncertainty is given in Chapter 6. 4.2 Financial asset valuation under certainty 1 The benefits o f owning an asset are the present and future consumption opportunities attributable to it. For a financial asset, these benefits are in the form o f cash. For example, an investor who holds a government bond u n til m a tu rity receives cash in the form o f interest payments during the bonds life and, at m aturity, in the fo rm o f the payment o f the face value. In the case o f shares, the investor receives cash in the form o f dividends and, on sale o f the shares, in the form o f the price obtained fo r the shares. A decision to buy an asset implies a simultaneous decision to forgo current consumption. It is assumed that, at any time, investors prefer more consumption to less consumption, other things being equal. Application o f this principle between tw o points in tim e implies that, other things being equal, earlier cash inflows are preferred to later cash inflows. As explained in Chapter 3, these observations may be summarised by the phrase ‘money has a tim e value’. To review this principle, suppose th a t a person is given the choice o f receiving $100 now or $100 in 1 years time. A rational person w ill always choose to receive the cash immediately, even i f there is no desire to consume immediately. The reason, o f course, is th a t the earlier cash flow can be invested. This w ill enable even greater consum ption later. I f the interest rate is 12 per cent per annum, the investor (consumer) in this example can invest fo r 1 year the immediate cash flow o f $100, and at the end o f the year have $112 available fo r consumption. Clearly $112 o f consum ption is preferable to $100 o f consumption. In this example the cash flows were, in effect, a g ift. Suppose, however, th a t the investor is offered the chance to buy the rig h t to receive $100 in 1 years tim e. W hat is the m axim um price the investor should offer fo r th is right? We have just seen th a t $100 is ‘w o rth ’ $100 x 1.12 = $112 in 1 year’s time. The rig h t to receive $100 in 1 years tim e is therefore w o rth at present: = LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Understand how assets are valued under conditions of certainty $100 1.12 $89.29 The am ount $89.29 is referred to as the present value o f $100 to be received in 1 years tim e i f the discount rate is 12 per cent per annum. Therefore, the interest rate has tw o functions: it is the rate at which present sums can be converted to equivalent future sums, and i t is also the rate at which promised future sums can be converted to equivalent present values. Therefore the value o f a financial asset is not simply the sum o f the cash th a t it generates in future periods. For example, a financial asset that generates returns o f $100 at the end o f each o f the next 5 years is n o t w o rth $500 today. I t is n o t valid to add together cash flows th a t occur at different times. However, adding together present values is valid because each value relates to the same tim e, the present. Where there are many cash flows from the same asset, the present value o f the asset is the sum o f the present values o f every future cash flow. The present value o f the asset is calculated using the relevant interest rate. I f the cash flows are certain to occur, as we assume here, then the relevant interest rate is the risk-free interest rate, Tr. Thus: P〇 = 1 1+ 7 + —(l +^ rf—2)2 + . . . + — ^ (1 + rf)n In this section we review some of the results explained in Chapter 3. Readers familiar with this material may safely omit this section. 令 A B usiness finance or p〇 = t ^ ED y where P〇 = present value o f the asset Ct = dollar return (cash flow) at tim e t n = term o f the investm ent = risk-free interest rate per tim e period t = 1, 2, n Suppose th a t an asset returns $100 per annum fo r 5 years and th a t an investor requires an annual interest rate o f 3.6 per cent as compensation fo r forgoing current consumption. Substituting in Equation 4.1 we find that: $100 $100 $100 $100 $100 1 + 0.036 (1 + 0 .0 3 6 ) 2 (1 + 0.036” (1 + 0 .0 36)4 (1 -f 0 .0 3 6 )5 n = $ 9 6 ,5 2 5 + $93,171 + $89,933 + $86,808 + $83,792 = $ 4 5 0 ,2 2 9 Therefore, this investor would be prepared to pay $450.23 fo r the asset. In summary, a financial asset is valued in a w orld o f certainty by discounting the known future cash flows at the risk-free interest rate, thus compensating investors fo r th e ir preference fo r current consumption. 4.3 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Use the tools of financial mathematics to value equity securities 4.3.1 [V aluation of shares assuming certainty I f future cash flows are known w ith certainty, Equation 4.1 can be used to value shares.2 The periodic cash flows from an investm ent in shares are called dividends. Unless liqu id atio n o f the company is contemplated, the dividends are assumed to continue indefinitely. Therefore, Equation 4.1 may be rew ritten as: DIVIDENDS periodic distributions, usually in cash, by a company to its shareholders Valuation of shares D, p 〇 = J2 4.2 (1 + rf Y where D t = dividend per share in period t The appropriate discount rate remains the risk-free interest rate, because under conditions o f certainty investors require the same rate o f return on all assets. I t m ig h t appear th a t Equation 4.2 ignores a second potential source o f retu rn from an investm ent in shares— th a t is, the capital gain from selling the shares at a price greater than the price at which they were purchased. This impression is incorrect. Suppose th a t an individual purchases shares w ith the inte n tio n o f selling them in 5 years* time. Equation 4.2 may be expanded as follows: Dt p〇 = E r=l (1 + rf )[ Ps (1 + r /)5 4.3 where P5 = share price at the end o f the fifth year The capital gain (or loss) is the difference between P5 and P〇 . The price o f the shares when they are sold is the discounted value o f all future dividends from Year 6: 〇〇 作 2 令 = Z Dt t=6 (1 + r/ 广 5 4.4 The discussion that follows is directed towards the valuation of ordinary shares. Preference shares are another form of equity capital. The valuation of preference shares is discussed in Chapter 14 and the distinction between ordinary shares and preference shares is discussed in detail in Section 10.7.2. C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation + I I - E 5 3E W x Substituting Equation 4.4 in to Equation 4.3: 5 ( D/ -f/ +/ which is Equation 4.2. Therefore, where a company is assumed to have an in fin ite life, the current m arket price o f its shares can be expressed as the present value o f an in fin ite stream o f dividends. Even in a m arket where investors are seeking capital gains, the valuation form ula remains the same. 4 .3 .2 1 Valuation of shares under uncertainty Valuing a security under uncertainty is d iffic u lt and, in general, few ( if any) people can consistently expect to reach a better valuation than that given by the current m arket price. This statement is discussed fu lly in Chapter 16. However, the statement is unhelpful i f the company is n ot traded on a stock exchange, because there is then no current m arket price to observe. Moreover, to say th a t the best estimate o f a shares ^true* value is its current m arket price provides no insight in to the factors th a t give a share its value. In this section, some o f the fundam ental factors determ ining a share s value are considered. Where there is uncertainty, investors require compensation in the form o f a higher promised rate of return. Equation 4.2 becomes: p 〇= H g (D ') (i + where E(Dt ) = expected dividend per share in period t ke = required rate o f return on the shares The appropriate value o f ke is determ ined using the concept o f the o p p o rtu n ity cost o f capital. The ‘true ’ or economic cost o f investing in a particular security is the retu rn forgone on the next best alternative. For a risky security, this return is greater than the return on the risk-free security (r^). In short, ke > r,. The am ount by which ke exceeds r^is often referred to as the security s risk premium. Further, the riskier the security being considered, the higher the risk premium w ill be and the higher ke w ill be. D eterm ination o f exactly how much higher ke should be requires a measurement o f risk* and a theory lin kin g th a t measure to required rates o f return. These theories are developed in Chapter 7. A t this p o in t we assume th a t all investors reach the same assessment o f risk, and therefore apply the same o p p ortu nity cost o f capital (discount rate) to the same expected dividend stream, therefore a rriving at the same price fo r the company s shares. It may seem unrealistic to assume th a t everyone has the same expectations. However, at the tim e o f making a financial decision, it may be reasonable fo r the company s management to assume th a t its assessment o f the likely impact o f th a t decision on the company s share price w ill prove to be correct. I f this is so, then management should act as i f it is realistic to assume that everyone has the same expectations. The simplest assumption to make when estim ating a share s value is th a t the company w ill m aintain in perpetuity the current dividend per share, D 〇 . In this case the estimate is:3 P〇 A) ke The use o f Equation 4.6 is shown in Example 4.1. 3 This formula treats the dividends as an ordinary perpetuity. For further details, see Section 3.6. ♦ B usiness finance Example 4.1 Rankine Ltd is currently paying a dividend of 90 cents per share. If investors expect this dividend to be maintained and require a rate of return of 15 per cent on the investment, what is the value of Rankine's shares? SOLUTION The value of Rankine's shares is calculated as follows: $0.90 0.15 $ 6.00 G rowth in dividends I t is usually more realistic to assume th a t a company s dividend per share w ill change. For example, it may be assumed th a t the dividend per share w ill grow at a constant rate. In this case, the estimated value is: p 〇 = J2 Q〇( l + g ) f (1 + ke)1 where g = expected grow th rate in dividend per share Where k e is greater thang and the grow th in dividends is assumed to continue indefinitely, Equation 4.7 can be w ritte n as:4 A ) ( l+ g ) P〇 k e -g One approach to estim ating g is to calculate the past grow th rate in dividend per share and use this as the estimate o f the expected grow th rate. This is shown in Example 4.2. Example 4 .: Assume that for the past 10 years the growth rate in Rankine Ltd's dividend per share has been 10 per cent per annum. Assume further that this growth rate is expected to be maintained indefinitely. The latest dividend per share was 90 cents and was paid yesterday. What is the value of Rankine's shares? SOLUTION Using Equation 4.8, the value of Rankine’s shares is: D〇 (l+ g ) P〇 - k e -g $0.90 x 1.1 0 .1 5 -0 .1 0 $19.80 4 The terms in Equation 4.7 form an infinite geometric series, with a common factor (or ratio) between each term of, -8 . Provided that - 1 < + 8 • there will be a limiting sum equal to the first term of the series, divided by 1 ke \ ke (1 - the common ratio). That is: P 〇 \ ke 、 1 K} D〇(l + g ) k e-g 1 + kt> A)(l +g) ke-g ■+ ke If ke < g , the model breaks down. Under these circumstances: - 命 ■ke > 1 and there is no limiting sum (P0 ). 〇〇 C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation A second approach to estim ating g is to assume th a t the grow th in dividend per share is related to the company s retained earnings and to the rate o f retu rn on those earnings. I f the company retains a constant p roportion b o f its earnings each year and reinvests those earnings at a constant rate r, then g = hr, and Equation 4.8 can be rew ritten: If Rankine Ltd retains 4 0 per cent of its earnings each year (jb = 0.4), and these earnings are reinvested to earn a 25 per cent rate of return (r = 0.25), what is the value of Rankine's shares? SOLUTION The value of Rankine’s shares, using Equation 4.9, is as follows: p _ $0.90 x [1 + (0.4 x 0.25)] 0 一 ^ 0 . 1 5 - ( 0 . 4 x 0.25)^ =$19.80 The assumption th a t the past grow th rate is expected to be m aintained indefinitely is unlikely to be realistic, particularly where the company has been experiencing a relatively high growth rate. We m ight therefore assume th a t the current grow th rate w ill be m aintained fo r several years before falling to a level expected to be sustained indefinitely. This is shown in Example 4.4. Example 4.4 Assume that the growth rate will remain at its current level of 10 per cent per annum (gf^ for only a further 3 years, and is then expected to fall to 6 per cent per annum (g) and remain at that level indefinitely. W hat is the share price today? SOLUTION This complication is easily handled by first using Equation 4.8 to estimate the value of the shares as at the end of the third year. The value of the shares today is given by the present value of this estimate, plus the present value of the dividends to be paid in the first 3 years. The value of Rankine's shares is calculated as follows: p 0 D〇 l i + g ,) , P〇 (i ^ g ') 2 , Poll + g ,)3 , (i + M (i + M _ $ 0 .9 0 X 1.10 1.15 2 (l + M $ 0 .9 0 X (1.10)2 + (1.15)2 + 3 1 _ :: P 〇 ( i + g 'l 3(i+ g l (l + M 3 (b-gl $ 0 .9 0 x (1.10 )3 1 $ 0 .9 0 x (1.10)3 x (1.06) (1.15 )3 + (1.15)3 X (0 .1 5 -0 .0 6 ) = $ 1 1 .7 5 Comparing the previous tw o examples, the reduction in the expected dividend grow th rate after Year 3 has resulted in a reduction in the value o f the shares from $19.80 to $11.75. This highlights the sensitivity o f the share value to estimates o f the future grow th rate in dividend per share. The formulae used to estimate a share value may also be used to estimate the required rate o f retu rn on a company s shares, given th e ir current m arket price. This application is discussed fu rth e r in Chapter 14. 4 .3 .3 | Share valuation and the price-earnings ratio The ratio o f a company s share price to its earnings per share— th a t is, its price-earnings ratio _ is often used by security analysts to estimate the value o f the company s shares.5 To illustrate this m ethod o f 5 m LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Explain the main differences between the valuation of ordinary shares based on dividends and on earnings A discussion of the use of the price-earnings ratio to value shares is contained in most texts on investments. See, for example, Brailsford, Heaney and Bilson (2011, pp. 386-93) and Bodie, Kane and Marcus (2011, pp. 601-9). 命 B usiness finance valuation, we again use the example o f Rankine Ltd, and assume th a t Rankines current earnings per share is $2.25. Assume also th a t an analyst estimates th a t the appropriate price-earnings ratio fo r the company is 9.0. Therefore, the value o f each share is estimated at $20.25— th a t is, $2.25 x 9.0. This estimate would then be compared w ith the current market price to determine whether the shares are overvalued or undervalued. However, this leaves unanswered the question: How does an analyst estimate the appropriate priceearnings ratio? In m ost cases where analysts use this m ethod o f valuation, the appropriate price-earnings ratio is determ ined in a way th a t can best be described as judgm ental— th a t is, no form al model is used b ut the analyst tries to take into account the factors considered to be relevant. Two im p o rta n t factors are risk and grow th opportunities. The riskier the analyst believes the investm ent to be, the lower the appropriate price-earnings ratio. To see this, imagine th a t an analyst is try in g to value two companies th a t are equivalent in all respects, including th e ir current and expected earnings, except th a t one company is riskier than the other. Because investors dislike risk, other things being equal, the company th a t is riskier w ill be less attractive to investors and w ill thus have a lower value. Since both companies have the same earnings, the ratio o f price to earnings w ill be lower fo r the riskier company. The other im p o rta n t factor is grow th opportunities. I f an analyst believes a company has substantial opportunities fo r growth, a high price-earnings ratio w ill be assigned. In this case the current earnings level is likely to be surpassed in the future, thereby ju stifyin g a price today th a t appears ‘h igh’ relative to current earnings. O ther factors likely to be considered include the price-earnings ratios o f companies in the same industry, and prospects fo r the ind ustry and the economy as a whole. 4.4 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 4 Use the tools of financial mathematics to value debt securities As we saw in Section 4.3, the returns on an investm ent in shares are dividends and capital gains. In the case o f an investm ent in debt securities (frequently called bonds or debentures), the returns are usually in the fo rm o f interest payments and the repayment o f the face value or principal on the m a tu rity date. As has been explained fo r shares, i f all securities offer certain returns, each security s o p p o rtu n ity cost o f capital is the risk-free interest rate (or yield) r^. Therefore, i f future cash flows are know n w ith certainty, rf \s the appropriate discount rate to apply. Equation 4.1 is rew ritten fo r bonds as follows: n deben tu res) d e b t s e c u ritie s issued w ith a m e d iu m o r lo n g te rm to m a tu rity COUPONS fix e d in te re s t p a y m e n ts m ade on bonds a nd d e b e n tu re s Valuation of debt securities F Q P〇 == E t=\ (1 + rf y (1 + rf )n interest payment (often called coupon payment or just coupon) at tim e i F = face value (principal repayment) at m aturity, which is date n n = num ber o f periods to m a tu rity risk-free interest rate (yield) rf = The use o where Example 4.5 Suppose that Rankine Ltd borrows by issuing 3-year bonds with a face value of $100, and a coupon interest rate of 10 per cent. The cash flows to a bond holder will be interest (/coupon,) payments of $ 1 0 per year for 3 years, followed by payment of $ 1 0 0 at the end of the third year. If the required rate of return is also 10 per cent per year, what is the value of Rankine’s bonds? SOLUTION The value of the bonds is given by Equation 4.10: D 0 $10 $10 $10 $100 1.1 ( l. l) 2 ( l. l) 3 ( l. l) 3 =$9.091 +$8.26 4+ $7.513+ $75.131 = $ 100.00 C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation Once a bond has been issued— th a t is, sold by the borrower to the lender— its promised future cash flows are fixed. Ownership o f the bond entitles the owner to receive from the issuer a fixed schedule o f future cash flows. I f the m arket interest rate changes, it w ill affect the attractiveness o f the bond to potential investors. I f m arket interest rates decrease, the bond w ill become more attractive; i f m arket interest rates increase, the bond w ill become less attractive. O f course, this w ill cause bond prices to change. A decrease (increase) in m arket interest rates w ill cause an increase (decrease) in the prices of existing bonds. This is illustrated in Example 4.6. Example 4.6 Suppose that immediately after Rankine's debt contract is agreed, conditions in the debt market change and the required rate of return falls to 8 per cent per annum. Rankine must still make interest payments of $1 0 each year, but investors now require a return of 8 per cent per annum. W hat is the value of Rankine’s bonds now? SOLUTION Again applying Equation 4.10, the security is now valued more highly, as follows:6 $10 $10 ^ $10 ( $100 0 = h O S + (1.08 )2 + (1 .0 8 )3 + (1.08)3 = $ 1 0 5 ,1 5 4 Similarly, if the required rate of return had risen from 10 per cent to 12 per cent, the price would have fallen as follows: $10 $10 $10 $100 TTTi + (i.i2)2 + (1.12)3 + (i.i2)3 $ 9 5 .1 9 6 4.5 Interest rate risk Example 4.6 shows th a t when interest rates change, so do bond prices. The possibility o f unforeseen price changes means th a t a bond is risky— its future value is uncertain. Thus, even i f a bond is risk-free in the sense th a t the borrower is certain to make the promised cash payments, it is risky in the sense th a t the bond holder (lender) can suffer unforeseen losses i f interest rates increase. When interest rates increase, bond prices fall. For the investor in bonds this is a capital loss, and therefore in this respect the increase in interest rates is undesirable. A benefit m ust be set against that loss: the interest receipts can be reinvested at the new, higher rate o f interest. The opposite occurs when interest rates fall. Investors make capital gains b ut interest receipts can be reinvested only at the new lower rate. These effects are know n as the price effect and the reinvestment effect and are always o f opposite sign fo r a given change in m arket interest rate. The price effect and the reinvestm ent effect are both sources o f interest rate risk. The net effect fo r the investor depends on the size o f the interest rate change and on the period fo r which the bond is held. Appendix 4.1 outlines a m ethod th a t an investor may use to obtain some protection against interest rate risk. A t any given tim e, the m arket-determ ined interest rate (or yield) on a bond w ill depend on the features o f that bond. Two features th a t are usually particularly im p o rta n t to m arket participants are the term o f the security and the risk o f the borrower defaulting on the promised payments. The connection between By convention, bonds in Australia are assumed to have a face value of $100, but in practice bond face values are much higher—often in the millions o f dollars. Therefore, bond prices per $100 of face value are usually taken to more than two decimal places. We follow the Australian convention and use three decimal places. m LEARNING OBJECTIVE 5 Explain the nature of interest rate risk B usiness finance Finance in ACTION O N GUARD AGAINST A BOND FALL__________________________ In an article published in 2013, financial journalist Christopher Joye reminds readers of interest rate risk, which flows from the connection between interest rates and bond prices. TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES relationship between interest rates and term to maturity for debt securities in the same risk class Bond traders have been making out like bandits since the global financial crisis. A portfolio of Australian government bonds with maturities longer than 10 years has delivered annual total returns of over 12 per cent since December 20 07 . Yet the preconditions for the mother-of-all bond market reckonings are sliding into place. This contingency, which A M P ’s Shane Oliver believes is a 'significant risk’, could result in wiping more than $ 6 0 billion off Aussie bond values, with steep capital losses. To properly understand these risks, one needs to appreciate how extraordinary current circumstances are. W hen doing so, it helps to keep in mind a key principle: bonds that pay fixed, as opposed to variable, rates have prices that are inversely related to external interest rates. If you invested in a bond paying an annual fixed coupon of, say, 3 per cent, and market interest rates surge to 5 per cent, that bond would be worth substantially less than when you bought it. The converse is also true: if market rates decline ... it would be worth more. This is why Australian government bond prices have soared since 20 07 : market yields have fallen sharply as global central banks have floored policy rates close to zero and printed unprecedented amounts of money to fund public and private debt. Source: 7On guard against a bond fall', Christopher Joye, The Australian Financial Review, 5 January 2013, p. 39. DEFAULT-RISK STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES relationship between default risk and interest rates term and interest rates is called the term stru ctu re o f in te re st rates, while the connection between default risk and interest rates is called the d efau lt-risk stru ctu re of in te re st rates. These are now considered. 4.6 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 6 Understand the theories that are used to explain the term structure of interest rates ZERO-COUPON BONDS (zero s) bonds that pay only one cash flow, the payment at maturity The term structure of interest rates 4.6.1 | W h a t is the term structure? To consider the effect o f a bonds term on its interest rate, all other factors need to be held constant. Thus, to elim inate the effect o f differences in default risk, the term structure o f interest rates is usually studied by focusing on government bonds since all such bonds have the same risk o f default (assumed to be zero). The least complicated measure o f the term structure o f interest rates is the m arket yield on a government bond th a t pays no interest during its life, b ut pays a fixed sum at m aturity. Such a bond is known as a zero-coupon bond (often abbreviated just to a zero). The price o f a zero w ith a face value o f F dollars and a term o f n years is simply: P〇= ( T ^ f where zn is the yield on the zero, often known as the zero rate fo r a term o f n. The term structure o f interest rates is the set o f zero rates zv z2, ... zn. In practice, except fo r terms o f 6 m onths or less, zerocoupon bonds are relatively rare. However, there are coupon-paying bonds and it is possible to estimate the underlying zero rates from the prices o f coupon-paying bonds. The Reserve Bank o f Australia has made such estimates fo r the Australian m arket. Four examples are shown in Figure 4.1. As shown in Figure 4.1, the shape and level o f the term structure can vary w idely over tim e. For example, i t may be steeply upward sloping, as i t was on 27 June 1994, or almost flat, as i t was on 19 July 2006, or gently downward sloping, as i t was on 27 November 2007. G h APTER FOUR A ure 4.1 The term structure pplying THE TIME VAUJE OF MONEY TO SECURITY VALUATION Australia: various dates 12 . 00 % — 10. 00 % d --------- 19-Jul-06 d 8 .00 % oJ a> OJOZ 6 .00 % P 0 ! D 如SE 4.00% — 27-Jun-94 ——— 27-Nov-07 一 广 ...... 7-Jan-09 LU 2 .00 % 0.00% 0.00 2.00 4.00 6.00 8.00 10.00 12.00 Term to maturity (years) Source: Based on estimates available from the Reserve Bank of Australia website. 4 .6 .2 1 Using the term structure to price a bond I f we know — or have estimated— the current term structure o f zero rates, in principle it is easy to calculate the price o f any coupon-paying bond. This process is illustrated in Example 4.7. When we have the prices, we can then calculate the corresponding yields. These calculations are shown in Example 4.8. Example 4.7 Suppose that the face value of every bond is $ 100 and the current zero rates for terms of 1 ,2 and 3 years are 7 .0 , 8.0 and 8.5 per cent per annum respectively. W hat are the prices of: a 1-year bond paying annual coupons of 5 per cent, a 2-year bond paying annual coupons of 9 per cent and a 3-year bond paying annual coupons of 7.5 per cent per annum? SOLUTION In a year's time, the 1-year bond will make a single payment of $105, consisting of $ 1 0 0 face value and $5 of coupon interest. The required rate of return on a 1-year investment is 7.0 per cent per annum. The price of the bond is therefore D $105 r = ------1.07 =$98.131 The 2-year bond will pay $9 after 1 year and $1 09 after 2 years. In effect, this coupon-paying bond can be decomposed into two zero-coupon bonds. The first is a 1-year zero which pays $9 and the second is a 2-year zero that pays $109. Because we know the 1-year and 2-year zero rates, we know how to price these constituent zero-coupon bonds. The price of the 2-year bond is the sum of the two constituents. D $9 $109 1.07 (1.0812 p = ------- + * =$101.861 Extending the same logic to the 3-year bond, its price is P: $ 7 .5 0 _______ $7.5 〇 + $ 1 〇7.5 〇 1.07 + (1.08)2 $97.602 (1.085)J B usiness finance Given the price o f a coupon-paying bond, its in te rn a l rate o f return, know n as the bonds yield, can be calculated. For fu rth e r details, see Sections 3.5.4 and 5.4.2. Example 4.8 What are the yields on the three bonds described in Example 4.7? SOLUTION For the 1-year bond, the yield is the value of r which solves the following equation: $98,131 = $ 1 0 5 0 0 1+r We know from the previous example that the solution to this equation is r = 7.0 per cent per annum. For the 2-year bond, yield is the value of r which solves the following equation: $101,861 l^ + $10900 n + r|2 This equation is solved when r is approximately 7.957 per cent per annum. For the 3-year bond, yield is the value of r which solves the following equation: $ 9 7 ,6 0 2 $ 7 .5 0 $ 7 .5 0 $ 1 0 7 .5 0 1 + r + (1 + r ) 2 + (1 + r)3 This equation is solved when r is approximately 8.438 per cent per annum. Note that the 2-year and 3-year yields are close to, but not equal to, the corresponding zero rates. YIELD CURVE graph of yield to maturity against bond term at a given point in time The pattern o f yield against term is called the yield curve. Data fo r the Australian yield curve at 10 different dates are given in Table 4.1. TABLE 4.1 Australian yield curve data Term to maturity Date of yield curve 3 months 6 months 2 years 5 years 10 years June 1998 4.93 4.98 5.18 5.38 5.58 June 2000 5.87 5.96 5.89 6.05 6.16 June 2002 5.21 5.32 5.44 5.78 5.99 June 2004 5.61 5.65 5.34 5.67 5.87 June 2006 6.09 6.16 5.78 5.78 5.79 June 2008 7.81 8.04 6.97 6.69 6.59 June 2009 3.25 3.30 3.90 5.10 5.56 June 2010 4.89 5.01 4.57 4.97 5.33 June 2011 4.99 5.10 4.75 4.89 5.16 June 2012 3.49 3.41 2.40 2.49 3.00 Source: Compiled from Reserve Bank of Australia data (www.rba.gov.au). See tables Interest Rates and Yields— Money Market and Capital Market Yields— Government Bonds. For 1998 and 2000 yields for 3(6) months are issue yields for 13-(26)-week Treasury notes. From 2002 to 201 2 these yields are yields for 90-(l 80)-day bank accepted bills. Yields for 2, 5 and 10 years are bond yields. Like the closely related concept o f the term structure, yield curves can have a wide range o f shapes. For example, the yield curve in Australia was upward sloping in June 2002 and June 2009 b ut m ostly downward sloping in June 2012. Typical yield curve shapes are illustrated in Figure 4.2. C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation Figure 4.2 Alternative yield curves 4 .6 .3 1 Term structure theories: expectations and liquidity (risk) premium Obviously the term structure at any given tim e is no accident. Presumably, participants in the debt markets do n ot set the interest rate for, say, a term o f 2 years7 w ith o u t in some way considering the 1-year and 3-year interest rates. In other words, the interest rate fo r a particular term w ill be determ ined by the m arket in the context o f interest rates fo r other terms. The exact id e n tity o f the factors th a t explain the term structure is controversial, w ith different theories proposing different mechanisms. There is, however, broad agreement th a t expectations o f the future course o f interest rates are central to explaining the term structure. The core o f the e x p e c ta tio n s th e o ry o f the term structure is th a t interest rates are set such that investors can expect, on average, to achieve the same retu rn over any future period, regardless o f the term o f the zero-coupon bond in which they invest. For example, suppose th a t in the current term structure the interest rate fo r a 2-year term to m a tu rity is 8 per cent per annum, while the interest rate fo r a 3-year term to m a tu rity is 9 per cent per annum. Suppose, fu rthe r, th a t $1000 is invested fo r 3 years. A fte r 3 years, the investor w ill have $1000 x (1.09)3 = $1295.03. Alternatively, suppose the same investor invests $1000 fo r 2 years. A fte r 2 years, the investor w ill have $1000 x (1.08)2 = $1166.40. I f the investor can re-lend this sum fo r the th ird year at an interest rate o f 11.028 per cent per annum, then at the end o f the th ird year the investor w ill have $1166.40 x 1.11028 = $1295.03, which is the same as the retu rn from the 3-year investm ent. This is shown in Figure 4.3. Figure 4.3 Return from the 3-year investment 0 1 2 3 years <<--------------------------------------------- 9% p . a . --------------------------------------------- > < --------------8% p.a. -----------------------------1.028% p .a .-----------------------------> As shown in Figure 4.3, the current term structure is 8 per cent per annum fo r a term o f 2 years and 9 per cent per annum fo r a term o f 3 years. According to expectations theory, the factor th a t explains the 7 For ease of exposition, in this section we use the term interest rate for a term of n years* to mean the yield per annum on a zero-coupon bond with a term o f n years. EXPECTATIONS THEORY of the term structure is that interest rates are set such that investors in bonds or other debt securities can expect, on average, to achieve the same return over any future period, regardless of the security in which they invest B usiness finance current term structure is the m arkets expectation th a t the 1-year interest rate on the day 2 years from now w ill be 11.028 per cent per annum. In th a t case investors w ill earn 9 per cent per annum over the coming three years, regardless o f whether they invest fo r three years, by: a b buying the 3-year bond today; or buying the 2-year bond today and buying a 1-year bond in 2 years* time. Therefore, the expectation o f the future interest rate determines today s term structure. This process is extended in Figure 4.4. Suppose th a t today s 1-year interest rate is 6.5 per cent per annum. Then the m arket m ust expect next years 1-year interest rate to be 9.521 per cent per annum, because (1.08)2 = 1.065 x 1.095 21 = 1.1664. The economic interpretatio n is th a t the same return is expected over the next 2 years, regardless o f whether an investor: a b buys a 1-year bond today and buys a fu rth e r 1-year bond in 1 years tim e; or buys the 2-year bond today. Figure 4.4 Return from the 3-year investment (extended) years - 9% p.a. 8% p.a. -6.5% p .a .- -> < r -11.028% p.a. 9.521% p.a.- -11.028% p.a. As a final illu stratio n o f the expectations mechanism, consider again the in fo rm a tio n shown in Figure 4.4 and imagine th a t there is an investor who intends to lend $1000 fo r a 2-year period. Consider the follow ing three ways in which such an investm ent could be made: a b c Buy the 2-year bond now and hold i t u n til i t matures. A t the end o f the 2-year period, this investm ent w ill have accumulated to $1000 x (1.08)2 = $1166.40. Buy a 1-year bond now and, after 1 year, reinvest in a fu rth e r 1-year bond, which is then held u n til m aturity. A t the end o f the 2-year period, this investm ent is expected to have accumulated to $1000 x 1.065 x 1.095 21 = $1166.40. Buy the 3-year bond now and sell i t after 2 years. A t the end o f the 2-year period, th is investm ent is expected to be w o rth $1000 x (1.09)3/1 .1 10 28 = $1166.40. As these calculations show, the expected outcome is the same, regardless o f the investm ent strategy. The m arket has set today s term structure in such a way th a t it reflects the m arkets expectations o f the future course o f interest rates. To formalise our discussion o f expectations theory, we w ill use the notation zt t+k to mean the interest rate per annum fo r a period beginning on date t and ending on date t + k. For example, z3 4 means the interest rate fo r the year starting 3 years from now and ending 4 years from now. We make the follow ing assumptions: a b fu tu re 1-year interest rates (zx 2, z2 3, and so on) are known w ith certainty8 there are no transaction costs. Given these assumptions, com petition in the bond m arket w ill result in a term structure th a t ensures th a t the sum to which a dollar accumulates over n years i f invested at today s long-term interest rate z 〇n m ust equal the sum to which it accumulates over n years when invested in the sequence o f present and future 1-year interest rates z12, z2 3, . . . , zn_^ n. As a consequence, an investor who wants to invest for, say, 10 years is indifferent between investing in a 10-year bond and investing in a sequence o f 1-year bonds over the next 10 years. Hence, today s 2-year interest rate, z〇2, is determ ined from today s 1-year interest rate and the 1-year interest rate in a years time. That is, (1 + z 〇 ,2)2 = (1 + 2〇 .i)(l +<2l ,2) 命 8 Alternatively, we could assume that investors are risk neutral. The concept of risk neutrality is explained in Section 7.3. C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation Similarly, today s 3-year interest rate, z 〇3, is determ ined from today s 1-year interest rate, the 1-year interest rate in a years tim e and the 1-year interest rate in the year after that. That is, (1 + 2 〇,3)3 = (1 + z 〇,i ) ( l + 2 1?2)(1 + 之 2,3) Generalising, fo r any given term o f t years, today s t-year interest rate z〇t is set by the m arket such that: (1 + 20,f ) ’ = (1 + 20,1)(1 + 21,2)(1 + Q j ) . . . (1 + 2 f- l ,f ) Rearranging this equation, today’s t-year interest rate z 〇t is given by: z〇 ,t = [(1 + 2〇a ) x (1 + z i, 2) x (1 + z 2,3) x ... x (1 + z M .f) ]1/r- l E U I Thus, in our earlier discussion, using Equation 4.11 gives the 2-year interest rate as: z 〇,2 = (1.065 x 1.095 21)1/2- 1 = 8% oer annum and the 3-year interest rate is: z〇,3 = (1.065 x 1.095 21 x 1.11028)1/3 - 1 = 9% per annum The essence o f expectations theory is th a t the term structure is determ ined by investors’ expectations o f short-term rates w ith in the m a tu rity o f the competing long-term security.9 Expectations theory can help to reconcile the existence o f the differing shapes o f the term structures shown in Figure 4.1 and the yield curves shown in Figure 4.2. In general, an upward-sloping term structure implies th a t investors expect future short-term interest rates to increase.10 In th a t case, investors are n ot prepared to invest in long-term securities unless the yield is greater than th a t on short-term securities, because otherwise the investors would be better o ff investing in short-term securities and reinvesting the proceeds at m aturity. In general, a downward-sloping term structure implies th a t investors expect future short-term interest rates to decrease— th a t is, investors are prepared to purchase long-term securities yielding less than short-term securities because they expect th e ir retu rn to be no larger i f they adopted an investm ent strategy requiring continual reinvestm ent in short-term securities. In short, i f expectations about the level o f future short-term rates change, then actual long-term yields on existing securities w ill tend to adjust in the same direction. A fla t term structure means th a t investors expect future short-term interest rates to be the same as the current short-term rate. Consequently, the long-term rates w ill equal the short-term rates.11 Commentators on the expectations theory o f the term structure have suggested th a t interest rates are not formed solely on the basis o f expectations. For example, the liquidity prem ium (risk prem ium ) theory suggests th a t although expectations are a foundation fo r the term structure, there is in addition a premium due to uncertainty about the future level o f interest rates. Suppose, fo r example, th a t an investor has an investm ent target o f $10000 to be achieved in 2 years* tim e — th a t is, the investm ent horizon is 2 years. The easiest and safest way to achieve this target is to invest today the present value o f $10000, where the present value is calculated using todays 2-year zero rate. Alternatively, the investor could invest the same sum today fo r 1 year at today s 1-year interest rate and, when this investm ent matures in 1 years tim e, reinvest the proceeds fo r a fu rth e r year. O f course, this reinvestm ent is made at next years 1-year interest rate, which today is n ot known. Hence, the outcome o f this alternative is risky, whereas the previous approach is risk-free.12 This fact is illustrated in Example 4.9. LIQUIDITY PREMIUM ( r is k p r e m i u m ) THEORY of the term structure is that although future interest rates are determined by investors' expectations, investors require some reward (liquidity premium) to bear the increased risk of investing long term INVESTMENT HORIZO N the particular future date on which an investor intends to liquidate (sell) their investment It is convenient to think of short-term rates as determining long-term rates, but in fact the market determines all rates simultaneously. 10 That this is not always the case may be seen from the following example. If the current term structure is: 1 year: 6 per cent; 9 2 years: 10 per cent; and 3 years: 11 per cent, then the 1-year interest rate, 1 year hence, is expected to b e :--------- 1 = 14.15% ( l. ll) 3 (I.IO)2 while the 1-year interest rate, 2 years hence, is expected to be: —------ - 1 = 13.03%. l 〇6 11 This result holds even if there is a large difference in the number of bonds outstanding with different maturities. One of the implications of the expectations theory is that interest rates are independent of the relative supply of bonds across the range of maturities. 12 A third possibility would be to buy today a 3-year bond and sell it after 2 years, at which time it has become a 1-year bond. The price obtained at the end of 2 years will depend on the 1-year interest rate at the time of the sale. Because this interest rate is not known today, the price that will be achieved is also unknown today—that is, the investment is risky. 令 Example 4 .9 Freya wishes to have $ 1 0 0 0 0 in 2 years7 time. The current interest rate on a 2-year zero-coupon bond is 7.5 per cent per annum and Freya decides to invest in this bond. a) How much should Freya invest today? How much will she have after 2 years have passed? b) The current interest rate on a 1-year zero-coupon bond is 6.5 per cent per annum. It turns out that during the coming year interest rates fall steeply and at the end of the year the interest rate on a 1-year zero-coupon bond is only 4.2 per cent per annum. If Freya had chosen to invest the same amount in 2 sequential 1-year investments, how much would she have after 2 years have passed? c) The current interest rate on a 3-year zero-coupon bond is 8 per cent per annum. It turns out that the 1-year interest rate at the end of 2 years is 9.5 per cent per annum. If Freya had chosen to invest the same amount in a 3-year bond and then sell that bond after 2 years, how much would she have after 2 years have passed? SOLUTION a) Freya should invest today the present value of $ 1 0 0 0 0 at today's 2-year interest rate. The amount to invest is therefore $ 1 0 0 0 0 / (1 .075)2, which equals $8653.33. • That is, Freya will today pay $8653.33 for a 2-year zero-coupon bond with a face value of $10000. • This investment is guaranteed to produce $ 1 0 0 0 0 after 2 years because on the bond's maturity in 2 years7 time, the face value of $ 1 0 0 0 0 will be paid to Freya. b) After 1 year, Freya will have $8653.33 x 1.065, which is equal to $9215.80. Reinvesting this amount for a further year at 4.2 per cent per annum produces a final amount of $9 215.80 x 1.042, which is equal to $9602.86. Freya therefore does not achieve her target of $1 00 00. c) The face value of the 3-year zero-coupon bond must be $8653.33 x (1.08)3, which is equal to $1 09 00.7 0. At the end of the second year, the bond has become a 1-year bond and the interest rate at that time is 9.5 per cent per annum. Therefore, the price of the bond when it is sold is $1 0900.70/1.095, which equals $9954.98. Freya therefore does not achieve her target of $10000. As Example 4.9(a) illustrates, an investor who buys a zero-coupon bond w ith a term to m a tu rity that matches the investm ent horizon is guaranteed to achieve th e ir target. As Examples 4.9(b) and 4.9(c) illustrate, a different choice may lead to the target n ot being achieved. In other cases, the target could be exceeded. For example, in p a rt (c), i f the 1-year interest rate at the end o f the second year had been anything lower than 9.007 per cent Freya would have ended up w ith more than $10 000 at the end o f the th ird year.13 In other words, any choice other than investing in the m aturity-m atching bond involves risk: the target m ig ht be exceeded or i t m ight n o t be achieved. To induce an investor to depart from investing in the m aturity-m atching bond w ill require a higher interest rate— th a t is, a risk prem ium . In Freyas case, she w ould require a higher interest rate on either the 1-year or the 3-year bonds. However, proponents o f the liq u id ity (risk) prem ium theory believe that, in general, the investm ent horizons o f bond investors (lenders) are shorter than the investm ent horizons o f bond issuers (borrowers).14 Therefore, on balance, the prem ium tends to be higher, the longer the term o f the bond, causing an upward bias in the term structure. Such a bias w ill tend to cause yield curves to be upward sloping. This means th a t compared w ith the yield curves th a t would be observed i f only expectations mattered, an upward-sloping yield curve w ill become steeper, a downward-sloping yield curve w ill become less steep (or perhaps even fla t o r upward-sloping) and a fia t yield curve w ill become upward sloping.15 4 .6 .4 | Empirical evidence The empirical evidence on the theories we have discussed presents a rather complex picture. In the US, Fama (1984), McCulloch (1987) and Richardson, Richardson and Sm ith (1992) found evidence 13 Because $10 900.70/1.09007 is equal to $10 000. 14 Proponents could, for example, point to the fact that investors rarely lodge fixed deposits at a bank with a term exceeding 5 years. But banks often offer mortgage loans with terms of 20 or 30 years. 15 In June 2009 the yield curve was steeply upward sloping. This yield curve is consistent with short-term interest rates having been reduced by central banks to stimulate growth in response to the global financial crisis. Higher yields for longer term securities are consistent with expectations of increasing future short-term interest rates and an increase in the risk premium. C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation supporting the existence o f a premium. But Longstaff (2000) found no evidence o f a prem ium at the very short end o f the yield curve. The evidence in Australia is also mixed. In a test at the short end o f the term structure (90-day interest rates, compared w ith 180-day interest rates), Tease (1988) found that the data quite strongly supported the expectations theory in various forms. Similarly, studies by Robinson (1998), and Young and Fowler (1990) found support fo r the expectations theory using 90-day and 10-year interest rates. However, studies by Alles (1995) and Heaney (1994), in both cases using more thorough statistical analyses, found little support fo r the expectations theory. In a study o f 14 countries, Beechey, Hjalmarsson and Osterholm (2009) found that, consistent w ith the expectations hypothesis, in 10 countries (including Australia) the m arket appeared to set short-term interest rates and long-term interest rates simultaneously. However, fo r all 10 o f these countries there appeared to be risk premiums, suggesting th a t expectations alone do n o t determine the term structure. 4 .6 .5 1 Inflation and the term structure One issue yet to be considered is the relationship between the in fla tio n rate and the term structure o f interest rates. In general, we w ould expect lenders to require the nom inal interest rate to compensate them fo r expected in fla tio n .16 Therefore, the higher the expected in fla tio n rate, the higher w ill be the observed nom inal interest rate. As a consequence, i f the in fla tio n rate is expected to increase over tim e, the nom inal interest rate on sh ort-term bonds w ill also be expected to increase over tim e. According to the expectations th eo ry we w ill therefore see an upward-sloping yield curve. In addition, unexpected changes in the in fla tio n rate are also like ly to have an im pact on the term structure. Such unexpected changes w ill cause a change in the level o f interest rates. As explained earlier, the p ossibility o f such changes gives rise to interest rate risk, and the liq u id ity prem ium th eo ry suggests th a t this in tu rn w ill give rise to the tendency fo r interest rates on long-term bonds to be higher than those on short-term bonds. 4.7 The default-risk structure of interest rates As explained in Section 4.3.2, the presence o f uncertainty causes the o p p o rtu n ity cost o f capital to exceed the risk-free interest rate. For debt o f a given term , the higher the m arkets assessment o f the p robability o f default, the higher w ill be kdi the required rate o f return (or expected yield) on the debt. However, because debtholders rank ahead o f shareholders, it is expected th a t the required rate o f retu rn on a company s debt w ill be less than the required rate o f return on its shares. In short, fo r any given company, rf <kd <ke. Similarly, fo r debt o f a given term and fo r a given company, the required rate o f return, kd, w ill be less than the yield to m aturity, r, where yield to m a tu rity is the rate o f retu rn earned by an investor i f the company does n o t default. This relationship is shown in Example 4.10. Services have existed fo r many years th a t supply ratings on the Quality* o f debt securities issued by both public and private sector borrowers. There is evidence to suggest th a t there is a high correlation between these ratings and the p robability o f default and i t is n o t surprising, therefore, th a t the yields are related to the quality rating. In Australia, ratings are supplied by Fitch Ratings (www.fitchratings.com .au), M oody s Investors Service (www.moodys.com.au) and by Standard & Poors (w w w .standardandpoors.com .au). Issuers o f long-term debt are rated by M oody s on a 21-point scale, ranging from Aaa (of the highest quality, w ith m inim al credit risk) down to C (typically in default, w ith little prospect fo r recovery o f principal or interest).17 The inform a tion in Table 4.2 is indicative o f the ratings supplied by M oody s. 16 See Equation 3.7 and the discussion in Section 3.4.4. 17 Standard & Poors rates issuers o f long-term debt on a 23-point scale ranging from AAA (extremely strong capacity to pay interest and repay principal) to D (the borrower is expected to fail to pay all or substantially all of its obligations as they come due). Fitch uses a 21-point scale, ranging from AAA (exceptionally strong capacity for payment of financial commitments) to D (has entered into bankruptcy filings, administration, receivership, liquidation or other formal winding-up procedure, or which has otherwise ceased business). All three companies also rate short-term debt. Both Fitch and Standard & Poors use an 8-point scale, while Moody’s uses a 4-point scale. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 7 Understand the effect of default risk on interest rates |www j Example 4 . 1 0 Bonds issued by the Red Vines Company mature in 1 year's time with a maturity value of $110. There is no cash flow during the year. Investors believe that there is a 90 per cent chance that the full payment of $ 1 10 will be made and a 10 per cent chance that no payment will be made. Calculate: a) the price of Red Vines' bonds b) the yield to maturity of the bonds. SOLUTION a) The expected payment at the end of the year is 0.90 x $ 1 1 0 + 0 . 1 0 x $ 0 = $99. Assuming that the market requires an expected rate of return, kd, of 10 per cent on these bonds, they will have a price of: =$90 b) The yield, r, is therefore found by solving: $ 9 0 = ili 〇 1+ r Therefore, the yield to maturity is: $110 , r = ----------1 $90 = 22 . 22 % That is, an investor who purchases the bonds for $9 0 and holds them to maturity will earn a rate of return of 22.22 per cent per annum if Red Vines does not default. TABLE 4.2 Moody's ratings for long-term <obligations of selected Australian companies and government entities Aaa Aa Aal Of the highest quality; minimal credit risk Government o f Australia New South Wales Treasury Corporation Treasury Corporation o f Victoria Western Australian Treasury Corporation High quality; subject to very low credit risk Queensland Treasury Corporation South Australian Government Financing Authority Tasmanian Public Finance Corporation Aa2 Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Ltd Australian Rail Track Corporation Ltd Commonwealth Bank of Australia Macquarie University Rabobank Australia Ltd National Australia Bank Ltd University o f Newcastle (Australia) Westpac Banking Corporation Aa3 Toyota Finance Australia Ltd A Upper-premium grade; subject to low credit risk A1 BHP Billiton Ltd HSBC Bank Australia Ltd SPI Electricity Pty Ltd Suncorp-Metway Ltd A2 AMP Group Finance Services Ltd Bendigo and Adelaide Bank Ltd Macquarie Bank Ltd Telstra Corporation Ltd Westfield Group A3 Baa Baal Coca-Cola Am atil Ltd Heritage Bank Ltd Jemena Ltd Members Equity Bank Pty Ltd Rio Tinto Ltd Volkswagen Financial Services Australia Ltd Wesfarmers Ltd Woolworths Ltd Subject to moderate credit risk; medium grade; may possess certain speculative characteristics Bank of Queensland Ltd Brambles Ltd C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation Table 4.2 continued Baa2 Baa3 Dexus Property Group Victoria Teachers Mutual Bank Alcoa of Australia Ltd Brisbane A irport Corporation Pty Ltd Goodman Group Origin Energy Ltd Ansell Ltd Lend Lease Group Premier Finance Trust Australia Transurban Finance Company Pty Ltd Woodside Petroleum Ltd Amcor Ltd Envestra Ltd Leighton Holdings Ltd Sydney A irport Finance Company Pty Ltd Boral Ltd Newcrest M ining Ltd Qantas Airways Ltd Ba Speculative elements; subject to substantial credit risk Bal Ba2 Ba3 Aus drill Ltd Fortescue Metals Group Ltd B Speculative; subject to high credit risk B1 B2 B3 Barminco Holdings Pty Ltd Atlas Iron Ltd Cristal Mining Australia Ltd Caa Of poor standing; subject to very high credit risk Investec Bank (Australia) Ltd Nufarm Ltd Genesee & Wyoming Australia Pty Ltd Caal Caa2 Caa3 Ca C Highly speculative; in or very near default; some prospect of recovery of principal and interest Typically in default; little prospect for recovery of principal or interest Source: www.moodys.com, accessed 9 September 2013. 4.8 O ther factors affecting interest rate structures Yield differentials on securities may also result from differences in m arketability— th a t is, the investors ability to convert the securities in to cash w ith o u t a price penalty. O ther things being equal, an investor w ill buy a security o f low m arketability only i f the yield is greater than th a t on a security o f high m arketability. For example, a life insurance company would usually require a higher interest rate to lend mortgage funds to a company than to lend the same am ount by purchasing the company s debt securities th a t are traded in an active m arket. Similarly, it is conceivable th a t tax effects w ill give rise to differences in yields on bonds. Finally, we refer briefly to the relationship between the yield on bonds and the required rate o f retu rn on ordinary shares. In Section 4.3, we suggested th a t the required rate o f return on ordinary shares may be expressed as the rate o f discount th a t equates the present value o f the expected future dividends w ith the current m arket price o f the shares. Clearly, i f dividends are expected to grow over tim e, the required rate o f return on an investm ent in ordinary shares w ill be greater than the current dividend yield (D 〇/P 〇). Therefore, it is n ot valid to directly compare the yields on debt securities w ith the dividend yields on ordinary shares. N ot surprisingly, the evidence suggests th a t the required returns on ordinary shares exceed those on debt securities.18 This evidence is consistent w ith the idea th a t investors require a higher expected rate o f return to invest in ordinary shares than to invest in, say, debentures because ordinary shareholders are exposed to greater risk. Their risk exposure is greater because ordinary shareholders are the residual claimants on the cash flows o f the company. Therefore, th e ir returns are the firs t to be affected by a dow nturn in the company s prospects and, in the event o f the company being wound up, ordinary shareholders have the last claim on its assets. 18 For international evidence, see Dimson, Marsh and Staunton (2003) and for Australian evidence, see Brailsford, Handley and Maheswaran (2008) and Brailsford, Handley and Maheswaran (2012). 命 B usiness finance SUMMARY • Financial assets such as bonds and shares can be valued by discounting their future cash flows to present values and summing these present values. The discount rate used is the required rate of return or opportunity cost of capital. • If the future cash flows from an asset are certain, the required rate of return will reflect only the effect of time on the value of money. • If the future cash flows are uncertain, investors will also require compensation for risk and the rate will be increased by the inclusion of a risk premium. • The value of an ordinary share is the present value of a dividend stream that can, in principle, continue forever. The calculation of a share’s value can be simplified by assuming that dividends are constant or grow at a constant rate over time. Shares can also be valued using the company’s current earnings and a price-earnings ratio. The value of this ratio depends mainly on risk and expected growth in namings. • Debt securities (bonds) are priced by discounting their future coupon interest payments and face value. For any company, the interest rate required by lenders will be less than the required rate of return on the company’s ordinary shares. The price of a debt security is inversely related to the interest rate required by investors. • Interest rates at any given time will usually be different for different terms to maturity. This pattern is known as the term structure of interest rates. Expectations of future interest rates, together with a risk premium have been suggested as explanations of the shape of the term structure. • The interest rate or yield on debt also depends on the probability that the borrower will default. KEY TERMS bonds (or debentures) 80 coupons 80 default-risk structure of interest rates dividends 76 duration 98 expectations theory 85 82 immunisation 97 investment horizon 87 liquidity premium (risk premium) theory term structure of interest rates 82 yield curve 84 zero-coupon bonds 82 87 SELF-TEST PROBLEMS 1 Richards Ltd pays annual dividends on its ordinary shares. The latest dividend was 75 cents per share and was paid yesterday. Dividends are expected to grow at 8 per cent per annum for the next 2 years, after which a growth rate of 4 per cent per annum will be maintained indefinitely. Estimate the value of one share if the required rate of return is 14 per cent per annum. 2 A government bond with a face value of $ 1 00 and a coupon interest rate of 1 1 per cent per annum matures in 3 years7 time. Interest payments occur twice each year and a payment has just been made. If the current market yield on the bond is 13 per cent per annum, what is the current price of the bond? 3 The current interest rates (yields) on zero-coupon government bonds are as follows: Interest rate [% 13.90 11.70 10.50 Assume that the term structure can be explained purely by expectations of future interest rates, and therefore there is no liquidity (or risk) premium. Calculate the expected 1-year rates for the next 2 years. Solutions to self-test problems are available in Appendix B. 92 C hapter four A pplying the time value of m o n e y to security valuation 1 [LO 1] Assuming certainty, the rates o f return on a ll financial assets w ill be identical. Outline why this statement is correct and indicate the factors on which this market rate of return depends. 2 [LO 2] The valuation o f a share using the dividend growth model is very sensitive to the forecast o f the dividend growth rate. This feature is a serious limitation on its usefulness to a share analyst. Discuss. 3 [LO 3] A company's share price reflects the discounted value o f either its future dividends or its future earnings. Discuss. 4 [LO 4] W h y are bond prices and yields inversely related? Doesn't a higher yield make a bond more attractive to investors and hence make it worth more, not less? 5 [LO 5] Government bonds are not riskless. Do you agree with this statement? W h y? 6 [LO 6] Differences between the current yields on different bonds con be explained by their relative riskiness 7 [LO 6] What is the term structure of interest rates? Discuss the various theories that try to explain the term structure of interest rates. 8 [LO 6 】Given an upward-sloping term structure, it is preferable for a company to raise debt by issuing shortterm debt securities. Discuss. 9 [LO 6 】 If the term structure is downward sloping, does this mean that liquidity preferences are not having any influence on interest rates? 10 [L0 7] How can both the Government of Australia and the Treasury Corporation of Victoria have a credit rating of A a a? Wouldn't the Treasury Corporation of Victoria have a higher credit risk than the Australian government? 11 [LO 8] What is 'immunisation7? (See Appendix 4.1, Introduction.) How may duration matching help? What are the problems of duration matching? and different terms to maturity. Discuss. cA PROBLEMS 1 Valuation under certainty [LO 1] A promise to pay $ 1 0 0 0 0 in 4 years' time is certain to be kept. If the risk-free rate for a 4-year term is 5 .5 per cent per annum, what is the value of this promise today? Do we know what the value will be in a year's time? W hy or why not? 2 Valuation of shares [LO 2] Assume that today is the last day of 2014. Rednip Ltd is expected to pay annual dividends of 64 cents in 2015 (Year 1). Assume that this dividend is expected to grow at an annual rate of 10 per cent and investors require a rate of return of 20 per cent per annum. a) Estimate Rednip Ltd's share price today. b) What is Rednip Ltd's share price expected to be at the end of 2 0 1 5 ? 3 Valuation of shares [LO 2] The required rate of return on the shares in the companies identified in (a) to (c) below is 15 per cent per annum. Calculate the current share price in each case. a) The current earnings per share of Zero Ltd are $1.50. The company does not reinvest any of its earnings, which are expected to remain constant. b) Speedy Ltd's current dividend per share is 80 cents. This dividend is expected to grow at 5 per cent per annum. c) Reduction Ltd's current dividend per share is 60 cents. The dividend of the company has been grow­ ing at 12 per cent per annum in recent years, a rate expected to be maintained for a further 3 years. It is envisaged that the growth rate will then decline to 5 per cent per annum and remain at that level indefinitely. CHAPTER F O U R REVIEW QUESTIONS 4 Required rate of return on a bond [LO 4] A 10 per cent $ 1 00 government bond that pays interest annually, and currently is 5 years from maturity, is selling for $103.29. What is the required rate of return (yield) on this bond? What is the implied real interest rate if the expected inflation rate is 5 per cent per annum? 5 Valuation of bonds [LO 4] A 12 per cent $ 1 00 government bond pays coupon interest twice yearly and matures in 5 years7 time. The current market yield on the bond is 10 per cent per annum. If a coupon payment has just been made, what is the current price of the bond? 6 Bond prices and interest rate changes [LO 5] Consider two 1 2 per cent $100 government bonds that differ only in that one matures in 2 years7 time and the other in 5 years7 time. Both bonds are currently selling for $1 00 and pay coupon interest annually. a) What will be the price of each bond, given an immediate fall in the required yield to 10 per cent per annum? b) What will be the price of each bond, given an immediate increase in the required yield to 14 per cent per annum? c) Explain the relative price movements in response to interest rate changes as evidenced by parts (a) and (b). 7 Bond prices and interest rate changes [LO 5] Welshpool Investments Ltd has a portfolio of 5 bonds (A, B, C, D and E). Their terms to maturity are 2, 3, 5, 10 and 25 years respectively. Each of the bonds has a coupon interest rate of 8 per cent per annum and a yield of 6 per cent per annum and each has just made a coupon payment. All 5 bonds pay annual coupons. a) Calculate the price of each bond. b) Re-calculate the price of each bond if the required yield on each bond increases to 7 per cent per annum. c) Comparing your answers to (a) and (b), what patterns are evident? Explain. 8 Using the term structure to price a bond [LO 6] The government currently has on issue zero-coupon bonds with terms of 1, 2 and 3 years. Their yields are, respectively, 6, 9 and 10 per cent per annum. The government proposes to issue a 3-year bond paying annual coupons and wishes to issue the bond at a price close to its face value of $100. To two decimal places, what coupon interest rate should the government choose? 9 Expectations theory of the term structure [LO 6] The current risk-free zero-coupon interest rates are as follows: 1 6.00 2 6.50 3 6.90 4 7.20 5 7.40 a) Assume that the term structure can be explained purely by expectations of future interest rates, and there­ fore there is no liquidity or risk premium. Calculate the expected 1-year interest rates for the next 4 years. b) Explain why it is not possible in this market for the 6-year zero-coupon interest rate to be 6 per cent per annum. 10 Liquidity premium theory of the term structure [LO 6 】 The current zero-coupon interest rates for terms of 4 and 5 years are 8.4 and 8.5 per cent per annum respectively. Jane Chan wishes to invest today and has an investment horizon of 4 years. Specifically, her target is to have $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 in 4 years' time. She is considering two investment strategies: (i) buying the 4-year bond and (ii) investing the amount calculated for the first strategy but instead buying the 5-year bond and selling the bond after 4 years have passed. CHAPTER FOUR APPLYING THE TIME VALUE 〇F MONEY TO SECURITY VALUATION b) Suppose Jane decides to implement strategy (ii). What 1-year interest rate on the horizon date will see Jane exceed her target? c) How would proponents of the expectations hypothesis interpret this result? How would proponents of the liquidity premium hypothesis interpret this result? 11 Pricing with default risk [LO 7] Waverton Foundry Ltd has just issued a 1-year zero-coupon bond with a face value of $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 . It is known that there is a 3 per cent chance that the company will default on this payment and that, if it does, investors in the bond will receive nothing. The market requires an expected rate of return of 8.6 per cent per annum. a) How much is the bond issue worth today? What is the implied promised yield? b) Suppose instead that, in the event of default, there is a 2 per cent chance that investors would receive $ 7 0 0 0 0 0 0 and a 1 per cent chance that they would receive nothing. How much is the bond issue worth today? What is the implied promised yield? Compare this with your answer to (a) and comment. 12 Duration and interest rate elasticity [LO 8] Consider the following four bonds: Bond Term to maturity (years) Coupon rate [% p.a.) A 2 10 B 3 12 C 3 10 D 3 8 芝 C H A P T EF R oan HEVIE a) How much will Jane need to invest today if she implements strategy (i)? Each bond has a face value of $100 and the current yield is 9 per cent per annum. All bonds pay annual coupons. a) Calculate the current price of each bond. b) Calculate the duration of each bond. (See Appendix 4.1.) c) Calculate what the price of each bond would be if the market interest rate increased to 11 per cent per annum. d) What would be the percentage capital loss on each bond? 13 Duration and immunisation [LO 8] An investor is considering the purchase of a 10-year bond that pays a single annual interest payment at the rate of 10 per cent. The bond's face value is $1 00 0 and its current price is $1 134.19. Determine whether the investor can ensure a particular rate of return over a 7-year time horizon. (See Appendix 4.1 14 Duration and immunisation [LO 8] If you wish to 'lock in’ the current yield of 8.5 per cent per annum for 3 years, which of the following bonds should you invest in? Coupon rate (% p.a.) 1 Bond Term to maturity (years) A 2.0 10 B 3.0 10 C 3.5 10 D 4.0 10 E 4.0 18 Each bond has a face value of $100. Assume that coupon payments are made at the end of each year. 95 B usiness finance REFERENCES Alles, L, 'Time varying risk premium and the predictive power of the Australian term structure of interest rates ’, /Accounf/ng one/ F/'nance, November 1995, pp. 7 7 —96. Beechey, M w Hjalmarsson, E. & Osterholm, P., Testing the expectations hypothesis when interest rates are near integrated', Journal of Banking and Finance, M ay 2009, pp. 9 3 4 -4 3 . Bodie, Z., Kane, A. & Marcus, A.J., Investments, 9th edn; M cG raw-H ill, N ew York, 20 1 1 . Brailsford, Tw Heaney, R. & Bilson, C., Investments, 4th edn, Cengage, M elbourne, 20 11 . Brailsford, T., Handley, J.C. & Maheswaran, K., 'Re-examination of the historical equity risk premium in Australia7, Accounting and Finance, M arch 20 08 , pp. 7 3 -9 7 . 96 Fama, E.F., 'Term premiums in bond returns', Journal of Financial Economics, December 1984, pp. 5 2 9 -4 6 . Heaney, R., 'Predictive power of the term structure in Australia in the late 1980s: a note', Accounting and Finance, M a y 1994, pp. 3 7 -4 6 . Longstaff, F.A., The term structure of very short-term rates: new evidence for the expectations hypothesis', Journal of Financial Economics, December 20 00 , pp. 3 9 7 -4 1 5 . Macaulay, Fw Some Theoretical Problems Suggested by the Movements of Interest Rates, Bond Yields and Stock Prices in the US Since 1856, N ational Bureau o f Economic Research, N ew York, 1938. McCulloch, J., 'The monotonicity o f the term structure: a closer look', Journal of Financial Economics, M arch 1987, pp. 1 8 5 -9 2 . Brailsford, T.; Handley, J.C. & Maheswaran, K., 'The historical equity risk premium in Australia: post-GFC and 128 years o f da ta', Accounting and Finance, M arch 20 12 , pp. 2 3 7 -4 7 . Richardson, M ., Richardson, P. & Smith, T., 'The monotonicity of the term structure: another look', Journal of Financial Economics, M arch 1992, pp. 9 7 -1 0 5 . Cox, J.C., Ingersoll, J.E. & Ross, S.A., 'Duration and the measurement o f basis risk', Journal of Business, January 1979, pp. 5 1 -6 1 . Robinson, E.S., 'The term structure of Australian interest rates: tests of the expectations hypothesis', Applied Economics Letters, July 1998, pp. 4 6 3 -6 7 . Dimson, E., Marsh, P.R. & Staunton, M ., 'G loba l evidence on the equity risk premium', Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Fall 2 0 0 3 , pp. 2 7 -3 8 . Tease, W.J., The expectations theory of the term structure of interest rates in Australia7, The Economic Record, June 1988, pp. 1 2 0 -7 . Elton, EJ. & Gruber, M J ., Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis, 5th edn, John W ile y and Sons, N ew York, 1995. Young, I. & Fowler, D., 'Some evidence on the term structure of interest rates: how to find a black cat when it's not there', Accounf/’ng one/ F/nance, M a y 1990, pp. 2 1 -6 . A ppendix 4 .1 A p p e n d ix 命 D uration a n d im m u n isatio n Duration and immunisation Introduction In S ection 4.5 it w as sh ow n that h old ers o f b o n d s are su bject to in terest rate risk. A change in th e level o f interest rates affects b o th the m arket price o f an existing b o n d an d th e in terest rate at w hich in terest receipts can be reinvested. For exam ple, an increase in in terest rates m eans an im m ed ia te capital loss to holders o f b o n d s becau se th e price o f th eir secu rities w ill fall. H ow ever, th ere is th en th e o p p o r tu n ity to reinvest in terest receipts at th e h igh er in terest rate. The reverse applies i f in terest rates fall. The possib ility o f ch a n g in g in terest rates p resen ts difficulties fo r in vestors. Su ppose, fo r exam ple, that an in vestor w ishes to h ave a target su m o f m o n e y in 3 years* tim e. The challenge is to c h o o s e a b o n d LEARNING OBJECTIVE 8 Apply the concept of duration to immunise a bond investment in vestm en t that w ill achieve th is target, regardless o f in terest rate changes du ring the 3 years. A strategy to achieve such an ob jectiv e is called im m unisation. If p ossib le, the in vestor sh ou ld bu y a 3-year b o n d that m akes n o in terest p a ym en ts (k n ow n as c o u p o n s) du ring its life. Such secu rities are usually called z e r o -co u p o n b o n d s .19 The in v e s to r k n ow s w ith certain ty the price o f the b o n d at th e en d o f th e 3 years because th e b o n d w ill th en b e w o rth exactly its face value, as it m atu res at th at tim e. Since there are n o cou p on in terest paym en ts, th e in vestor also has n o d ou b ts arising fr o m u n certain ty a b ou t the in terest rate that w ill b e earn ed o n rein vested cou p on s. Th erefore, the in vestor k n ow s p recisely w hat th e in vestm en t IM M U N IS A TIO N strategy designed to achieve a target sum of money at a future point in time, regardless of interest rate changes w ill b e w orth at the en d o f th e 3 years, an d thus ach ievem en t o f the target is guaranteed. The p rob lem is that alth ough z e r o -c o u p o n b o n d s exist, c o u p o n b o n d s are m u ch m ore co m m o n . Im m u n isation u sing cou p on -p a y in g b o n d s is m ore difficu lt to achieve. A tech n iqu e certain to im m u n ise an in v estm en t in c ou p on -p a y in g b o n d s against all p ossib le changes in in terest rates has n ever b e e n achieved. H ow ever, there is a tech n iq u e th at w ill im m u n ise a b o n d in vestm ent in a relatively sim ple en v iro n m e n t in w hich the yield curve is fiat, b u t m a y m ake a single parallel sh ift up o r d o w n .20 This tech n iq u e is b a sed o n th e co n c e p t o f b o n d d u ra tion an d its origin s can be traced to research u n derta k en b y M acaulay (1 9 3 8 ). Bond duration M acaulay realised th at a b o n d payin g a lo w c o u p o n rate is in a sen se a lon ger* in v estm en t th an a h igh er c o u p o n b o n d w ith the sam e term to m aturity. For exam ple, con sid er tw o 5-y ear b o n d s , b o th o f w h ich have a face value o f $ 1 0 0 0 , pay in terest annually an d are cu rren tly p riced to yield 10 p er cen t p er annum . They differ, h ow ever, in that o n e has a c o u p o n rate o f 5 p e r cen t per an n u m and the o th e r a c o u p o n rate o f 15 p er cen t p er annum . The cash flow s and th eir p resen t values are sh ow n in Table A 4.1. Table A 4 .1 5% coupon cash flow Present value 15% coupon cash flow Present value ($) t$) ($) ($) 1 50 45.45 150 136.36 2 50 41.32 150 123.97 3 50 37.57 150 112.70 50 34.15 150 102.45 5 50 31.05 150 93.14 5 1000 620.92 1000 620.92 Year 4 Total 8 1 0 .4 6 1189.54 19 With zero-coupon bonds, an investor receives no regular interest payments during the bonds life. A zero-coupon bond is purchased at a discount from its face value and it is either held to maturity, when the investor receives the face value, or sold before maturity at a price determined in the market. 20 For a discussion of techniques appropriate to several, more complex, environments, see Elton and Gruber (1995). 令 T h erefore, th e price o f the 5 per cen t c o u p o n b o n d is $ 8 1 0 .4 6 and th e price o f th e 15 p er cen t cou p on b o n d is $ 1 1 8 9 .5 4 . For th e lo w -c o u p o n b o n d , th e face value p a ym en t ($ 1 0 0 0 ) represents a b ou t 77 per cent o f its p rice (becau se $ 6 2 0 .9 2 /$ 8 1 0 .4 6 = 0 .7 7 ). For the h ig h -c o u p o n b o n d , th e face value represents on ly a b o u t 52 p er cen t o f its p rice ($ 6 2 0 .9 2 / $ l 1 8 9 .5 4 ~ 0 .5 2 ). Conversely, the first in terest paym en t con trib u tes on ly a b ou t 5.6 p er cen t to the value o f th e lo w -c o u p o n b o n d ($ 4 5 .4 5 /$ 8 1 0 .4 6 = 0 .0 5 6 ) bu t c on trib u tes nearly 11 .5 p er cen t to the value o f th e h ig h -c o u p o n b o n d ($ 1 3 6 .3 6 /$ 1 1 8 9 .5 4 = 0 .1 1 5 ). It is clear th a t the lo w -c o u p o n b o n d brin gs returns to th e in vestor later in its life, relative to the h ig h -co u p o n b on d . In this sense, the lo w -c o u p o n b o n d is longer*. DURATION M acaulay p r o p o s e d that this tim in g feature cou ld be in co rp o ra te d in to a d u r a t io n m easure by measure of the time period of an investment in a bond or debenture that incorporates cash flows that are made prior to maturity w eigh tin g th e n u m ber o f p eriod s that w ill elapse b e fo r e a cash flo w is received b y th e fraction o f the b o n d s p rice th at the p resen t value o f th at cash flo w represents. In this w ay th e tim e p e r io d is w eigh ted by th e ‘relative im p o rta n ce ’ o f the cash flo w that w ill occu r at th at tim e. Table A 4 .2 sh ow s th e calculation o f d u ra tion fo r the tw o b o n d s discu ssed above. T able A 4 . 2 鲁 ~ 'f Time 5% coupon weight Weight x time 15% coupon weight Weight x time 1 4 5 .4 5 /8 1 0 .4 6 = 0 .0 5 6 0 8 0.056 08 1 3 6 .3 6 /1 1 8 9 .5 4 = 0 .1 1 4 6 3 0.1 14 63 2 4 1 .3 2 /8 1 0 .4 6 = 0 .0 5 0 9 8 0.101 96 1 2 3 .9 7 /1 1 8 9 .5 4 = 0 .1 0 4 2 2 0.208 44 3 3 7 .5 7 /8 1 0 .4 6 = 0 .0 4 6 3 6 0.139 08 1 1 2 .7 0 /1 1 8 9 .5 4 = 0 .0 9 4 7 4 0.2 84 22 4 3 4 .1 5 /8 1 0 .4 6 = 0 .0 4 2 1 4 0.168 56 1 0 2 .4 5 /1 1 8 9 .5 4 = 0 .0 8 6 1 3 0.344 52 5 3 1 .0 5 /8 1 0 .4 6 = 0 .0 3 8 3 1 0.191 55 9 3 .1 4 /1 1 8 9 .5 4 = 0 .0 7 8 3 0 0.391 50 5 6 2 0 .9 2 /8 1 0 .4 6 = 0 .7 6 6 1 3 3.830 65 6 2 0 .9 2 /1 1 8 9 .5 4 = 0 .5 2 1 9 8 2.609 90 T otal = d u ra tion 4 .4 8 7 88 3.9 5 3 21 As su ggested earlier, the du ration o f the lo w -c o u p o n b o n d (4 .4 8 8 years) is lon g er th an the du ration o f th e h ig h -c o u p o n b o n d (3 .9 5 3 years). D u ration an d term to m a tu rity are equal on ly fo r a z e r o -co u p o n b on d . The du ration o f a co u p o n -p a y in g b o n d is always less th an its term to m aturity. The steps u sed to calculate d u ra tion D are su m m arised in th e form u la: rm 〇) if D = f A4.1 台 卜 。J w here Ct = cash flo w (c o u p o n in terest o r p rin cip al) at tim e PV(Ct) = p resen t value t o f Ct Q ~ (i + 0 f N ow P 〇 = price o f the b o n d _ y - Q , " t t (i + 0 f w here Pn (1 + Ct = c o u p o n in terest at tim e t Pn = face value pa ym en t at m atu rity z = required yield p er p e rio d n = n u m ber o f p eriod s to m atu rity E qu ation A 4 .1 can be rew ritten in its m ore usual form : y ' Ct x t D: f t i (1 + 〇r f Q r t i (1 + iY A4.2 A ppendix 4 .1 D uration Example A4.2 includes a duration calculation th a t follows Equation A4.2. First, however, we provide a b rie f mathematical analysis to h ig hligh t the importance o f the duration measure. Readers who are n ot interested in this analysis can o m it this section. Duration and interest elasticity As explained in Section 4.4, i f interest rates increase (decrease), then bond prices decrease (increase). When there is a change in interest rates, all bond prices respond in the opposite direction, b u t they do not all respond to the same extent. In other words, different bonds have different interest elasticities. It is im p orta nt fo r a bond investor to know the interest elasticity o f the bond because this w ill be a good indicator o f the interest rate risk being borne. The n otio n o f elasticity is prom inent in economics. Perhaps the best known example is the price elasticity o f demand fo r a particular good. This is expressed as follows: QdP where rj = price elasticity o f demand P = price o f the good Q = q uantity o f the good demanded ^ = derivative o f q ua ntity demanded w ith respect to price Price elasticity indicates the response o f the q ua ntity demanded to a change in price. W hat m atters fo r a bond investor is the interest elasticity o f the bond price; in other words, what matters is the response o f the bond price to a change in the interest rate. The elasticity E is given by: i dP〇 E: A4.3 P〇 d i The form ula fo r bond price is: Ci P〇 Pn Cn C2 (1 + (i + v i) n (1 + /广 and therefore: Q 2C2 (1 + 0 2 (1 + i f dP〇 di ~ (-1 ' f 2 〇2 nCn (1 + 〇2 (1 + i) n C\ \\-\- i ) \ l + i nPn nCn (l + i) ^ 1 (l + O^ . 1 nPn ( l + i) n Substituting in to Equation A4.3: E ^ i \ f l \ f C{ 2C2 nCn nPn (1 + i y (1 -f i) n (1 + i) n : P〇 I \ l + i ) D .1 + / \ l + i A4.4 where duration, D, is as defined in Equation A4.2. Equation A4.4 shows th a t the interest elasticity o f a bonds price is proportional to its duration. The longer the duration, the greater (in the sense o f being more negative) is the interest elasticity. For example, i f the interest rate is 10 per cent per annum and the duration is 4.5 years, the interest elasticity is: 3.10 ( 1r 10 , . :-0.409 (4.5) , a n d im m unisation I f the duration is 9 years, the interest elasticity is: /0.10、 E V I . 10, ⑼ - 0 .8 1 8 Duration and bond price changes Given th a t duration is related to interest elasticity, it follows th a t i t is possible to use duration to work out the approximate percentage price change th a t w ill occur fo r a given change in interest rate. Using Equations A4.3 and A4.4: i dP〇 = _ f P〇 d i ~ D VI I t follows that: dP〇 _ f \ P〇" ~ ~ V l T / Ddi Therefore, fo r 'small* discrete changes in interest rates and bond prices we have the follow ing approxim ation: AP〇 (it DAi A4.5 An application o f Equation A4.5 is shown in Example A4.1. Example A 4 .1 Consider the 5-year 15 per cent coupon bond priced to yield 10 per cent per annum. As shown in Tables A4.1 and A4.2, the price of this bond is $1 189.54 (per $1 0 0 0 face value) and its duration is 3.953 years. What is the percentage price change if the interest rate falls to 9.5 per cent per annum? SOLUTION In this case the interest rate change is -0.5 per cent = -0.005. Equation A4.5 gives the approximate answer as: 1 V I . 10 0.01797 (3.953)(-0.005) In other words, the result will be a capital gain of approximately 1.797 per cent. (The exact answer is close to 1.819 per cent.) Duration and immunisation Suppose th a t the yield curve is flat, b ut i t may make a parallel s h ift up or down. If, at the tim e o f a parallel sh ift, an investor is holding a bond whose duration matches the rem aining investm ent period, the investm ent is im m unised against the s h ift— th a t is, the investm ent w ill achieve at least the target yield, notw ithstanding the yield shift. This can be seen in Example A4.2. Managing risk by matching Macaulay s duration to the investm ent horizon is an im p o rta n t idea but the procedure we have described has a num ber o f lim ita tion s. In particular, it is im p o rta n t to investigate w hat happens i f there is more than one yield s h ift during the investm ent period. Consider again Example A4.2 and suppose th a t the yield had shifted down to 8 per cent imm ediately after date 0.0, but then shifted up to 12 per cent just before date 3.0 (the end o f the investm ent period). In th a t case, the investor w ill hold 1.229 37 bonds after 3 years have passed, b ut the price w ill be only $1022.578 per bond, which gives a value o f 1.229 37 x $1022.578 = $1257.127. This falls short o f the target o f having at least $1275.312. A ppendix 4 .1 D uration Example A4.2 Suppose that there is a flat yield curve at an interest rate of 10 per cent per annum. An investor wishes to lock in7 this yield for a 3-year investment period. Bond A has a term of 3.4 years, a face value of $1000, a coupon rate of 7 per cent and pays interest annually. Table A4.3 shows the calculation of Bond A 7s duration using Equation A4.2. n $2877.402 Duration = —--------------- $958,161 =3.003 years Table A4.3 Bond A Time (years) Cash flow ($) Present value of cash flow ($) Time x present value ($) 0.4 70 67.382 26.953 1.4 70 61.256 85.758 2.4 70 55.687 133.649 3.4 1070 773.836 2631.042 958.161 2877.402 Total According to the immunisation strategy, Bond A should provide an immunised investment because its duration matches the investment period— that is, an investment of $958,161 in Bond A will be worth at least $958,161 x ( l. l) 3 = $127 5.31 2 in 3 years7 time, regardless of an interest rate shift. To demonstrate this, it is assumed that: a) immediately after buying Bond A, the yield curve makes a parallel shift from 10 per cent to 8 per cent, and remains at that level for the next 3 years b) as each coupon interest payment is received, the investor reinvests in— that is, buys more of— the same bond c) bonds and dollars are infinitely divisible, thereby allowing the investor to purchase or sell any fraction of Bond A. After 0.4 years have passed, the investor receives a coupon payment of $70. The bond is now a 3-year bond. The yield curve has shifted down to 8 per cent, so the price of one bond is then: $70 $70 $1070 hOS + (1.08)2 + (1.08)3 =$974,229 Therefore, the investor can purchase the fraction 70.00 /97 4.2 29 of one bond. This fraction is 0.071 852, so the investor now holds 1.071 852 bonds. After 1.4 years, the investor receives a further coupon payment of $70 per bond; therefore the cash received is $70 x 1.071 852 = $75.0296. The bond is now a 2-year bond and its price is: $70 $1070 L08 + (1.08)2 =$982,167 The investor can now purchase a further 75 .02 9 6 / 9 8 2 .1 6 7 = 0 .0 7 6 3 9 of a bond. This type of cycle is repeated after 2.4 years and the investment in bonds is then sold after 3 years. Table A4.4 summarises the progress of the investment. continued a n d im m unisation continued Table A4.4 Date = investment period expired (years) Item 0.0 0.4 M 2.4 3.0 3.40000 3.00000 2.00000 1.00000 0.40000 70.00000 75.02960 80.37700 958.16100 974.22900 982.16700 990.74100 Bonds purchased (no.) 1.00000 0.07185 0.07639 0.08113 N il No. of bonds held 1.00000 1.07185 1.14824 1.229 37 1.22937 958.16100 1044.22700 1127.76400 1217.98700 1275.54900 Bond term remaining (years) Coupon interest received ($) Price o f one bond ($)(fl) Value o f bonds held ($) N il Nil 1037.56300 (°) Present value of remaining cash flows per $ 1000 face value. Yield used is 10 per cent per annum for the price at date zero. Yield used is 8 per cent per annum for prices calculated after date zero. As can be seen in the bottom right-hand corner of the table, the sum received from the sale after 3 years is $1275.549. This amount exceeds the target sum after 3 years of $ 1 27 5.31 2 and the investment has therefore achieved the target rate of return of at least 10 per cent per annum. What if the interest rate had risen to 12 per cent (instead of falling to 8 per cent)? In that case, the progress of the investment would be as shown in Table A4.5. Table A4.5 Date = investment period expired (years) Item 0.0 Bond term remaining (years) Coupon interest received ($) 3.40000 Nil 0.4 3.00000 1.4 2.000 00 2.4 1.00000 3.0 0.40000 70.00000 75.56880 81.34680 958.16100 879.90800 915.49700 955.35700 Bonds purchased (no.) 1.00000 0.07955 0.08255 0.08515 No. of bonds held 1.00000 1.07955 1.16210 1.24725 1.24725 958.16100 949.905 00 1063.89700 1191.56500 1275.40600 Price o f one bond ($)(a) Value o f bonds held ($) N il 1022.57800 N il Present value of remaining cash flows per $ 1000 face value. Yield used is 10 per cent per annum for the price at date zero. Yield used is 12 per cent per annum for prices calculated after date zero. Again, therefore, the investment has achieved the target yield of 10 per cent per annum, notwithstanding the shift in yield after the investment was made. In principle, this problem can be solved easily. W hen the yield changes, so too does the duration o f the bond held. W hen the yield shifts on the firs t occasion, the investor should change the bond holding so that, once again, duration matches the investm ent period. The investor is then imm unised against the next yield shift. This is simple in principle b ut in practice there are difficulties because it implies that a rebalancing o f the investm ent— buying and selling bonds— is needed every tim e the duration o f the investm ent changes. Because duration is a function o f the current yield and future coupon payments, this means th a t a bond transaction is needed every tim e the yield shifts, and every tim e a coupon payment is received. This can be costly and cumbersome. Only a fla t yield curve subject to parallel shifts has been considered. It may be shown th a t i f a sloped yield curve shifts in parallel fashion the investor s till matches duration and investm ent period, b ut the duration form ula is slightly more complex. I f a sloped yield curve shifts in some non-parallel way then the im m unisation strategy w ill depend on the type o f non-parallel s h ift assumed to occur. For an example, see the article by Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1979). ▼ CHAPTER CONTENTS ED Introduction 104 m The discounted cash flow methods compared 108 m The capital-expenditure process 104 EB Other methods of project evaluation 118 BH Methods of project evaluation 104 Project evaluation and real options analysis 123 LEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to: 1 explain the importance of each of the steps in the capital-expenditure process 2 outline the decision rules for each of the main methods of project evaluation 3 explain the advantages and disadvantages of the main project evaluation methods 4 explain why the net present value method is preferred to all other methods 5 understand the relationship between economic value added (EVA) and net present value (NPV) 6 understand the relationship between real options, managerial flexibility and firm value. B usiness finance Introduction In Chapter 1 we described the p rim ary financial functions o f a financial manager as raising funds and allocating them to investm ent projects so as to maximise shareholders’ wealth. In this chapter, we consider how such projects should be selected to ensure the m axim isation o f shareholders’ wealth. The term investment project is interpreted very broadly to include any proposal to outlay cash in the expectation th a t future cash inflow s w ill result. There is, therefore, a wide range o f such projects. These include proposals fo r the replacement o f plant and equipment, a new advertising campaign, research and development activities, and proposals to take over competing firm s. In th is book, investm ent and financing decisions are discussed in the order in which they are usually considered in practice. In general, management w ill firs t examine the alternative investm ent projects available to it. A fte r the acceptability o f these projects has been determined, management w ill, i f necessary, set about raising the funds to im plem ent them. It is logical, therefore, to discuss the evaluation and selection o f proposed investm ent projects before discussing the methods o f financing them. In this chapter, we examine the principles and methods o f project evaluation. In Chapter 6, the application o f these principles and methods is discussed. The evaluation and selection o f investm ent projects is only one element o f the capital-expenditure process. Before discussing the methods o f project evaluation, therefore, we outline the capital-expenditure process. 5.2 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Explain the importance of each of the steps in the capital-expenditure process * LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Outline the decision rules for each of the main methods of project evaluation ^0^ The capital-expenditure process Capital-expenditure management involves the planning and control o f expenditures incurred in the expectation o f deriving future economic benefits in the fo rm o f cash inflows. Consider the follow ing possible proposals: a m anufacturer is considering b uilding a new plant; an airline is considering the replacement o f several o f its aircraft; a pharmaceutical company is considering a new research and development program. Each proposal involves m aking current outlays in the expectation o f future cash inflows and, therefore, each can be analysed as a capital-expenditure proposal. This is the case even though, fo r example, the costs o f research and development are usually recognised fo r accounting purposes as expenses in the period in which they are incurred. Capital expenditures are very im p o rta n t fo r a company because freq ue n tly the am ounts o f m oney involved are large and th e ir effects extend w ell in to the fu tu re . A fte r capital expenditures have been made, i t is lik e ly th a t th e ir effects w ill continue fo r some tim e as m any projects are n o t easily m odified. I f there is e ithe r no second-hand m arket or, at best, o nly a <th in , m arket fo r capital assets, management may have to abandon a project i f i t proves to be unprofitable. Because o f the longevity and frequent irre v e rs ib ility o f many investm ents, they are lik e ly to com m it a company to a p articula r technology and to have a considerable influence on the p a tte rn o f its fu tu re operating cash flows. The im portance o f these decisions, therefore, can extend w ell beyond the period in w hich the in itia l capital outlay is made. The tasks involved in the capital expenditure process, as well as the associated outcomes from their im plem entation, are outlined in Table 5.1. 5.3 Methods of project evaluation In th is section we consider the evaluation and selection o f investm ent projects. F irst, we consider the net present value and the in te rn a l rate o f re tu rn m ethods, w hich were explained in a one-period se ttin g in Chapters 2 and 3. We then consider o the r m ethods th a t have been employed in project evaluation. C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods TABLE 5.1 Tasks and outcomes of the capital expenditure process | Tasks Outcomes Stage 1 Generation of investment proposals Systematic processes are established to ensure members of the organisation may contribute ideas to enhance firm value Incentives may be provided to reward employees who contribute ideas Investment proposals are forwarded to management - employees dealing in production processes w ill typically contribute ideas relating to eliminating operating inefficiencies - proposals by upper-level managers w ill mostly relate to wider issues such as product development or expansionary opportunities Stage 2 Evaluation and selection of investment proposals Data about each investment proposal are • collected. Data include: 一 a description of the proposal - the reasons for its adoption - estimates of amount and tim ing of cash inflows and outflows - an estimate o f the time u ntil the proposal w ill come into operation and the economic life o f the proposal once it is adopted All proposals are then evaluated using standard uniform procedures to ensure that assessments are conducted objectively The economic evaluation of the projects is conducted using a variety o f techniques (discussed in Section 5.3) that take into account the risk of the net cash flows that are expected to be delivered by the project A list o f recommended projects is prepared by responsible management Stage 3 Approval and control of capital expenditures A capital expenditure budget is prepared that • details the estimated capital expenditure requirements on new and existing projects over the next few years: - a short-term budget is prepared that relates to a period ranging from, say, 6 months to 2 years - a longer-term budget is also prepared that provides forecasts of cash requirements over the next 2 to 5 years Processes are established to ensure that the project is properly managed and monitored. These processes typically include: - the appointment of a project manager responsible for the implementation of the project and the preparation of regular progress reports 一 the establishment of a realistic timetable for implementation of the project - the establishment of a separate account for each project to ensure that expenditures are readily observed Systematic processes are established that enable the firm to effectively manage and m onitor the implementation o f new projects continued B usiness finance Table 5.1 continued Tasks Stage 4 Post­ completion audit of investment projects • • Outcomes Projects are regularly re-evaluated via a postcompletion audit to ensure that each project is meeting the expectations o f the firm The audit w ill identify where cash flows are significantly different from budget forecasts and possible reasons for such differences • • In itial investment decisions may be improved as those responsible for investment proposals are aware that they w ill be audited Improvements in the operating perform 芑nee of projects facilitated as new inform ation is regularly provided to managers Unsuccessful projects are identified at the earliest possible time— leading to their abandonment and subsequent savings to the firm M any methods are used to evaluate and compare investm ent projects. The methods outlined in this section are those th a t surveys o f business practice suggest are used most frequently. They are o f two basic types: a b the discounted cash flow methods, such as the internal rate o f return and net present value methods, which discount a projects estimated cash flows to allow fo r the magnitude and tim in g o f the cash flows the non-discounted cash flow methods, such as the accounting rate o f retu rn and payback period methods. Figure 5.1 shows some results from different surveys o f chief financial officers in the US, Australia and Canada. In all three countries, net present value and internal rate o f retu rn are easily the m ost popular, followed by payback period. Figure 5.1 Selected project evaluation methods used by surveyed chief financial officers!0) 80.00% 70.00% < - ui 60.00% 、 !/> 50.00% 40.00% 30.00% f i 20 .00 % s< ^0 o 10.00 % 0.00% Internal rate of return Net present value Payback period Accounting rate Real options of return analysis (a) The aggregated percentage exceeds 100 per cent because most respondents use more than one method of project evaluation Sources: Graham, J.R. & Harvey, C.R., 'The theory and practice of corporate finance: Evidence from the field7, Journal of Financial Economics, May 2001, pp. 187-243; Coleman, L., Maheswaran, K. & Pinder, S.; 'Narratives in managers' corporate finance decisions', Accounting & Finance, September 2010, pp. 6 0 5 -3 3 ; Baker, H., Dutta, S. & Saadi, S., 'Management views on real options in capital budgeting', Journal of Applied Finance, February 2011, pp. 18-29. C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods In this chapter i t is assumed in itia lly th a t investm ent projects are independent. Two projects are said to be independent i f the acceptance o f one project does n o t preclude the acceptance o f the other project. Two conditions are necessary fo r two or more projects to be classified as independent: • • It m ust be technically feasible to undertake one o f the projects, irrespective o f the decision made about the other project(s). The net cash flows from each project m ust be unaffected by the acceptance or rejection o f the other project(s). An example o f independent investm ent projects is where an e n tity is considering whether to purchase new machinery fo r its factory and whether to commission a new advertising campaign. As these investments are independent, management can make an accept/reject decision on each investm ent w itho ut considering its relationship to other investments. Problems caused by the existence o f projects that are n ot independent are considered in Section 5.4.3. INDEPENDENT PROJECT a project that may be accepted or rejected without affecting the acceptability of another project DISCOUNTED CASH FLOW (DCF) METHODS 5.3.1 I Discounted cash flow methods It can be seen from Figure 5.1 th a t the two m ost frequently employed discounted cash flow (DCF) m ethods are the net present value and internal rate o f retu rn methods.The net presen t value (NPV) o f a project is equal to the difference between the present value o f its net cash flows and its in itia l cash outlay.1 Assuming a cash outlay at the beginning o f the projects life, and a series o f net cash flows in the following periods, the net present value o f the project is calculated as follows: which can be w ritte n more conveniently as: npv = y ^ c, ?- c 〇 (1 + k)( + — ^ (1 + r) (1 + r)2 + + (1 + r)n 5.3 This can be w ritte n more conveniently as: n Ct Q = E t=\ (1 + r )' 5.4 where C〇= the in itia l cash outlay on the project Ct = net cash flow generated by the project at tim e t n = the life o f the project r - the internal rate o f return 1 2 NET PRESENT VALUE (N P V ) the difference between the present value of the net cash flows from an investment discounted at the required rate of return, and the initial cash outlay on the investment 5.2 where C〇= the in itia l cash outlay on the project Ct = net cash flow generated by the project at tim e t n = the life o f the project k = required rate o f retu rn The in tern al rate of retu rn (IRR) o f a project is the rate o f return th a t equates the present value o f its net cash flows w ith its in itia l cash outlay.2 Assuming a cash outlay at the beginning o f the projects life and a series o f net cash flows in the follow ing periods, the internal rate o f retu rn is found by solving fo r r in the follow ing equation: C〇 = - ^ - methods which involve the process of discounting a series of future net cash flows to their present values The cash flows could be discounted and/or compounded to equivalent values at any point in time. It is usual to discount the cash flows to the present; hence the use of the term n e t p r e se n t value. An alternative would be to calculate a n et terminal value. This is equal to the difference between the accumulated value of the net cash flows generated by a project, and the accumulated value of the initial cash outlay. Use of the net terminal value method gives the same decision as for the net present value method. Other terms used to describe the same concept include ‘the DCF return on investment’,‘yield’ and ‘the marginal efficiency of capital’. INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN (IRR) the discount rate that equates the present value of an investment’s net cash flows with its initial cash outlay; it is the discount rate at which the net present value is equal to zero 5.4 The discounted cash flo w methods com pared The assumed objective o f a company is to maximise shareholders* wealth. Consistent w ith this objective, projects should be accepted only i f they are expected to result in an increase in shareholders’ wealth. Therefore, the m ethod o f project evaluation m ust be consistent w ith m axim ising shareholders* wealth. O ther things being equal, this w ill occur where a project generates more cash, rather than less cash, and generates cash sooner, rather than later. The ability o f the net present value and interna l rate o f return methods to result in decisions th a t are consistent w ith this objective is considered in the follow ing sections. 5.4.1 | Net present value The net present value o f a project is found by discounting the projects future net cash flows at the required rate o f return and deducting from the resulting present value the in itia l cash outlay on the project. Therefore: n npv =J2 t= l Ct (1 + 吖 -C o 5.5 Where the investment outlays occur over more than one period, C〇in Equation 5.5 refers only to the in itia l cash outlay. A ll subsequent outlays are included in the calculation o f the net cash flows o f future periods. O f course, this may result in subsequent negative net cash flows in addition to the in itia l cash outiay. Management should select projects w ith a positive net present value and reject projects w ith a negative net present value. The am ount o f any positive net present value represents the imm ediate increase in the company s wealth th a t w ill result from accepting the project— th a t is, a positive net present value means th a t the projects benefits are greater than its cost, w ith the result th a t its im plem entation w ill increase shareholders1wealth. Conversely, projects th a t have a negative net present value would reduce shareholders’ wealth. The m agnitude o f a projects net present value depends on the projects cash flows and the rate used to discount those cash flows. I t follows th a t the estim ation o f a projects future cash flows is an im p o rta n t step in project evaluation. This involves deciding w hat cash flow data are relevant fo r project evaluation and then estim ating those data. W hile both aspects are im p orta nt, the mechanics o f estim ation, which is the job o f engineers, m arket research analysts and others, is beyond the scope o f this book. We focus on the firs t aspect— th a t is, the principles involved in defining and measuring project cash flows. There are essentially tw o approaches to measuring a projects net cash flows. The most popular m ethod is to forecast the expected net p ro fit from the project and adjust i t fo r non-cash flow items, such as depreciation. The second method, and the approach used in this book, is to estimate net cash flows directly. The cash inflow s w ill comprise receipts from the sale o f goods and services, receipts from the sale o f physical assets, and other cash flows. Cash outflows include expenditures on materials, labour, indirect expenses fo r m anufacturing, selling and adm inistration, inventory and taxes. W hile the measurement o f a projects net cash flows may seem to be straightforw ard, there are some aspects th a t w arrant fu rth e r consideration. These are discussed in Chapter 6. In addition to estim ating a projects future cash flows, i t is also necessary to estimate the life o f the project and determine the required rate o f retu rn to be used in discounting the cash flows. The correct discount rate to apply is the o p p o rtu n ity cost o f capital.3 This is the rate o f retu rn required on the next 3 Estimation of the required rate of return, or discount rate, is discussed in Chapter 14. It is sufficient at this stage to point out that the required rate of return is simply the rate of return that a project must generate in order to justify raising funds to undertake it. Where there is perfect certainty about the outcome of an investment, the risk-free rate, such as the current yield on government securities of the same maturity as the investment, is the appropriate discount rate. However, where there is uncertainty about the outcome of the investment, a risk-adjusted required rate of return must be used. Throughout the remainder of the book we will use the term req u ired rate o f retu rn to indicate the discount rate used in discounted cash flow calculations. C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods best— th a t is, forgone— alternative investment. I f the net cash flows have been estimated on an after-tax basis, then, to be consistent, the appropriate required rate o f retu rn is the after-tax rate. The measurement o f the required rate o f retu rn is considered in Chapter 14. Example 5.1 illustrates the application o f the net present value method. Example 5.1 Bruce Barry is considering an investment of $ 9 0 0 0 0 0 in a project that will return net cash flows of $5 09 000 , $ 4 5 0 0 0 0 and $ 4 0 0 0 0 0 at the end of Years 1, 2 and 3, respectively. Assuming a required rate of return of 10 per cent per annum, what is the net present value of the project? SOLUTION The net present value may be calculated as shown in Table 5.2. TABLE 5.2 Calculating a project’s net present value (NPV) Year Net cash flows ($ ) ! 0 (900 000 )⑷ Discount factor at 10% Present value ($) (900000) 1 509000 0.909 09 462 727 (扮 2 450000 0.826 45 371901^) 3 400000 0.751 31 300 526 (幻 235154 NPV ($) ^T h e amount in brackets represents the initial cash outlay. ^T he sum of $ 4 6 2 7 2 7 + $371 901 + $ 3 0 0 5 2 6 = $1 135 154 is the maximum amount the company would be prepared to pay for the project if the required rate of return is 10 per cent per annum. A t a discount rate o f 10 per cent per annum, the project has a positive NPV o f $235154 and is therefore acceptable. This m ethod is consistent w ith the company’s objective o f m axim ising shareholders’ wealth. I f a company implements a project th a t has a positive net present value, the company w ill be more valuable than before it undertook the project, and therefore, other things being equal, the to ta l m arket value o f the company s shares should increase im m ediately by the same am ount as the net present value o f the new project. In other words, the company is undertaking a project th a t has a net present value in excess o f th a t necessary to leave its share price unchanged. This was shown form ally in Chapter 2 using Fishers Separation Theorem. In summary, the decision rule fo r the net present value m ethod is as follows: Accept a project i f its net presen t value is positive when the p ro je cts net cash flows are discounted a t the required rate o f return. 5 .4 .2 1 Internal rate of return The internal rate o f return fo r a project is the rate o f return th a t equates the present value o f the projects net cash flows w ith its in itia l cash outlay. This means th a t Equation 5.4 can be rew ritten as follows: Ct c〇 = 0 From Equation 5.6, the internal rate o f retu rn is the discount rate th a t results in a zero net present value. However, the interna l rate o f retu rn is n o t only the discount rate th a t causes the net present value o f the projects cash flows to be zero. It also represents: ... the highest rate o f interest an investor could afford to pay, w ithout losing money, i f a ll the funds to finance the investm ent were borrowed, an d the loan (principal an d accrued in terest) w as repaid by using the cash proceeds from the investm ent a s they were earn ed.4 Even i f the investm ent outlays occur in more than one period, C〇in Equation 5.6 refers only to the in itia l cash outlay. Any subsequent investm ent outlays are subtracted from the cash flows o f future periods, which suggests th a t some o f the net cash flows in Equation 5.6 m aybe negative. The effect on the interna l rate o f retu rn o f negative net cash flows in subsequent periods is discussed later in this section. If, as is usual in practice, the projects net cash flows in each period are n o t equal, the internal rate o f retu rn can be found only by tria l and error— th a t is, by varying the discount rate u n til the present value o f the cash flows is equal to the investm ent outlay. I f this process shows th a t the present value o f the net cash flows is greater than the in itia l cash outlay, then some higher discount rate should make them equal, and vice versa. A fte r the interna l rate o f return has been measured, the acceptability o f an investm ent project is determ ined by comparing the internal rate o f return r w ith the required rate o f retu rn k. Any project w ith r > k should be accepted and any project w ith r < k should be rejected. Example 5.2 illustrates the application o f the internal rate o f retu rn method. Example 5.2 If we take the cash flows of Example 5.1, the project's internal rate of return may be calculated using Equation 5.3 as follows: Cn = C l 〇 d - ) _ + C2 d + r + )2 C3 ( l + r )3 Thus: $900 0 0 0 - $509000 + $450000 + $_400000 By trial and error, r = 25 per cent.5 If the required rate of return is, say, 15 per cent, the project’s internal rate of return of 25 per cent exceeds the required rate of return and the project is acceptable. The use o f this method, therefore, appears to be consistent w ith the company s objective o f m aximising shareholders* wealth. I f the required rate o f retu rn is the m inim um return th a t investors demand on investments then, other things being equal, accepting a project w ith an internal rate o f return greater than the required rate should result in an increase in the price o f the company s shares. M ultiple and indeterminate internal rates of return In Example 5.2 the investm ents cash flows consisted o f an in itia l cash outlay, followed by a series o f positive net cash flows. In such cases a unique positive internal rate o f retu rn w ill usually exist. In certain circumstances, however, it is possible fo r the present value o f the future net cash flows to be equal to the in itia l cash outlay at more than one discount rate— th a t is, a project may have more than one internal rate o f return. A necessary condition fo r m ultiple internal rates o f retu rn is th a t one or more o f the net cash flows in the later years o f a projects life m ust be negative. The presence o f negative net cash flows in the later years o f a projects life is n o t a sufficient condition fo r m ultiple interna l rates o f return. In many cases, negative cash flows in the later years o f a projects life are consistent w ith there being only one internal rate o f re tu rn .6 4 5 6 See Bierman and Smidt (1993). In practice, a financial calculator may be used to calculate the internal rate of return and eliminate the time-consuming computations involved in the trial-and-error process. Alternatively, the ^RR1function in Microsoft Excel® might also be used. Descartes* rule of signs states that there can be as many positive roots for 1 + r as there are changes in the sign of the cash flows. Therefore, if, after the initial cash outlay, the net cash flows are always positive, there will be at most one positive root for l + r, and consequendy only one for r itself. However, two sign changes in the cash flow can result in two positive values for 1 + r, so there may also be two positive values for r. For example, if the two positive values for 1 + r are +1.1 and +1.3, there will be two positive values for r: 10 per cent and 30 per cent. In the remainder of this section we use the term in tern al rate o f retu rn to mean p o sitiv e in te rn al r a te o f retu rn . C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods While, in practice, there is little likelihood o f the occurrence o f m ultiple internal rates o f return, i t is im p orta nt to recognise th a t there are circumstances where m ultiple internal rates do occur. Such a set o f circumstances is illustrated in Example 5.3. E xample 5.3 Consider an investment project with the cash flows shown in Table 5.3. TABLE 5.3 Project cash flows Year Cash flow 0 -14545 620 1 34182 000 2 -20000 000 An example of where such a cash flow pattern may occur is where a mining company is obliged, after completion of its mining operations, to restore the mine site to its original condition. If we solve for the internal rate of return of this project, then we find that its net present value is zero at both 10 per cent and 25 per cent— that is, the project has two internal rates of return. The project's net present value profile, which plots the project's net present value as a function of the required rate of return, is shown in Figure 5.2. Figure 5.2 Net present value profile showing two internal rates of return The number o f internal rates o f retu rn is lim ite d to the number o f sign reversals in the cash flow stream. In this case there are tw o sign reversals, which is a necessary, b u t n o t sufficient, condition fo r two internal rates o f return. Three sign reversals is a necessary condition fo r three rates, and so on. Hence, the number o f cash flow sign reversals corresponds to the maximum, b ut n ot necessarily the actual, number o f internal rates o f return. It may be argued th a t m ultiple rates are not a problem because the project may be abandoned at the beginning o f the second year, thereby avoiding the subsequent negative cash flow, and also the m ultiple internal rate o f return problem. I f the project is term inable and has a positive residual value, a unique internal rate o f return may be calculated. However, in some cases, abandonment o f the project may n ot be feasible because it may involve substantial abandonment costs in the early years o f operation, or there may be a legal obligation to continue the project fo r a num ber o f years. In addition to the problem o f m ultiple internal rates o f return, it is possible fo r an investm ent project to have no internal rate o f return. For example, a project w ith the follow ing pattern o f cash flows: -$80 000, +$100 000, -$5 0 000, has no internal rate o f return. 6 ^ B usiness finance Projects w ith a cash flow stream th a t results in either m ultiple internal rates o f return, or no internal rate o f return, are likely to be rare in practice, b ut the possibility o f such occurrences does exist. In what follows, it is assumed th a t a projects cash flow pattern results in a unique internal rate o f return. In summary, the decision rule fo r the internal rate o f retu rn m ethod is: Accept a project i f it h as a unique in ternal rate o f return th at is g reater than the required rate o f return. 5 .4 .3 1 Choosing between the discounted cash flow methods Independent investments LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Explain the advantages and disadvantages of the main project evaluation methods For independent investments, both the IRR and NPV methods o f investm ent evaluation lead to the same accept/reject decision, except fo r those investments where the cash flow patterns result in either m ultiple interna l rates o f retu rn or no internal rate o f return. In other words, i f a project has an internal rate o f retu rn greater than the required rate o f return, the project w ill also have a positive net present value when its cash flows are discounted at the required rate o f retu rn — th a t is, NPV > 0 when r > k, NPV < 0 when r < k, and NPV = 0 when r = k. This is always true, provided th a t the projects cash flows consist o f one or more periods o f cash outlay followed only by positive net cash flows. Such a project is referred to as a conventional project and the net present value profile o f such a project is illustrated in Figure 5.3. Figure 5.3 shows th a t the higher the discount rate, the lower is the net present value. The intercept o f the net present value profile w ith the horizontal axis occurs at the p o in t where k = r, which is the interna l rate o f return because i t is the discount rate at which the net present value is zero. Figure 5.3 Net present value profile for a conventional project Figure 5.3 shows th a t at a required rate o f retu rn o f k1} the net present value is positive and r > k1} while at a required rate o f retu rn o f k2 the net present value is negative and r < /c2. I f management has to decide whether to accept or reject an independent investm ent project, then b o th the internal rate o f retu rn m ethod and the net present value m ethod w ill give results consistent w ith m axim ising shareholders’ wealth. M utually exclusive investments So far it has been assumed th a t investm ent projects are independent, which means th a t management can make an accept/reject decision about each project w ith o u t considering its relationship w ith other C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods projects. In this section, we allow fo r the fact th a t investm ent projects may be interdependent. In this case, the expected benefits fro m one project are affected by a decision to accept or reject another project. In the extreme case, where the expected cash flows from a project w ill completely disappear i f another project is accepted, or i t is technically impossible to undertake the proposed project i f another project is accepted, the projects are said to be m utually exclusive. For example, i f a company owns land on which it can build either a factory o r a warehouse, then these tw o projects are m utually exclusive. I f a decision is made to b uild the factory, the company is unable to build the warehouse. A nother example o f m utually exclusive projects is i f different types o f equipment can be used to manufacture the same product. The choice o f one type o f equipm ent autom atically leads to the rejection o f the other.In the remainder o f this section the discounted cash flow methods w ill be evaluated, assuming th a t investm ent projects are m utually exclusive. Where management has to select from m utually exclusive projects it is necessary to rank the projects in order o f acceptability. This means th a t i t is necessary to determ ine w hether it makes any difference to project selection i f projects are ranked according to th e ir internal rates o f retu rn or th eir net present values. First, we consider in Example 5.4 whether the interna l rate o f retu rn or net present value methods should be used to evaluate m utually exclusive investments. E xample 5.4 Consider the mutually exclusive investments, A and B, in Table 5.4. TABLE 5.4 Project 1 Cash outlay ($) Net cash flow 1 year after the year of outlay ($) IRR (%) N P V @ 10%($) A -1 +10 900 8.09 B -100000 +200000 100 81818.18 The internal rate o f retu rn m ethod ranks a 900 per cent retu rn on $1 ahead o f a 100 per cent return on $100000. A t a required rate o f retu rn o f 10 per cent, both investments are w o rth undertaking, but if a choice has to be made between the tw o investments, then investm ent B w ith the larger net present value is to be preferred. This is because B adds more to the company s value than A. The net present value method w ill ensure th a t the value o f the company is maximised, whereas the use o f the internal rate o f return m ethod w ill n o t ensure th a t result. I t is apparent, therefore, th a t the internal rate o f return and net present value methods can rank m utually exclusive investm ent projects differently. This is now explained. Ranking mutually exclusive investments Although both projects in Example 5.4 had the same life, the in itia l cash outlays were different. However, even if the in itia l cash outlays and the projects* lives had been the same, i t is s till possible th a t the internal rate o f return and net present value methods would rank m utually exclusive investments differently. This is illustrated by Example 5.5. In Example 5.5, the difference in ranking is caused by differences in the magnitude o f the net cash flows. In addition to differences in ranking caused by differences in the cash flow streams, the interna l rate o f retu rn and net present value methods may give a different ranking where the investm ent projects have unequal lives. It may be concluded, therefore, that: … any difference in the m agnitude or tim ing o f the cash flows m ay cause a difference in the ranking o f investm ent projects using the internal rate o f return an d net presen t value methods. MUTUALLY EXCLUSIVE PROJECTS alternative investment projects, only one of which can be accepted Example 5.5 Two projects, C and D, have the same initial cash outlays and the same lives but different net cash flows, as shown in Table 5.5. What are the internal rates of return and net present values for projects C and D? SOLUTION Table 5.6 shows the internal rates of return and the net present values at a required rate of return of 10 per cent for projects C and D. TABLE 5 .6 Internal rate of return (%) Net present value ($) Project C 40 119008 D 50 105 785 Both projects have a positive net present value and an internal rate of return greater than the required rate of return and are therefore acceptable in their own right. In other words, if the projects are independent, both should be implemented. However, if the projects are mutually exclusive and therefore must be ranked, the two methods give different rankings. In this case using the net present value method, C is preferred to D, while using the internal rate of return method, D is preferred to C. This is illustrated in Figure 5.4, which shows the net present value profiles fo r tw o projects, E and F. Assume, as in Example 5.5, th a t the tw o projects have the same cash outlay and lives, and that the pattern o f net cash flows results in the net present value profiles shown in Figure 5.4. In this case, the net present value profiles o f the two projects intersect. A t a discount rate o f rv or at any other discount rate less than r2, the net present value o f E is greater than the net present value o f F, w hile at a discount rate o f r3, or at any other discount rate greater than r2, the net present value o f F is greater than the net present value o f E.7 On the other hand, it has already been shown th a t the interna l rate o f retu rn is found where the net present value is zero and, using this rule, Project F is ranked ahead o f Project E because its internal rate o f return, r5, is greater than r4, which is the internal rate o f retu rn o f E.8 In this case, the tw o methods can provide management w ith different rankings o f projects E and F. 7 For projects such as those in Table 5.5 with the same initial cash outlay, r2 is found by equating the present values of projects E and F as follows: PVe = Y 7. 8 Ce, (1 + r2) f c,:t -E ; ,= 1 (1 + 厂2 ) In this instance, r2 = 18.89 per cent. This means that if the required rate of return is less than 18.89 per cent, the internal rate of return and net present value methods result in conflicting rankings. Remember that discounting of the net cash flows at the internal rate of return will result in a net present value of zero. Therefore: n 〇= E Q ( l + r)f -C 〇 C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods Figure 5.4 Net present value profiles for projects E and F Like Example 5.5, Figure 5.4 shows th a t even where tw o m utually exclusive projects have the same in itia l outlays and the same lives, a difference in the projects* rankings may s till occur as a result o f the projects’ different tim e patterns o f net cash flows. Therefore, fo r m utually exclusive investm ent projects, the net present value m ethod is superior to the internal rate o f retu rn method, because it always gives a wealth-maximising decision. Figure 5.5 Net present value profiles for projects G and Even where the projects are m utually exclusive, the tw o methods could 5deld consistent rankings i f the patterns o f the projects* net cash flows result in net present value profiles th a t do n o t intersect. This is illustrated in Figure 5.5. In this case, the net present value o f Project G at a discount rate o f is greater than the n et present value o f Project H. This is consistent w ith the internal rate o f retu rn m ethod as r3, the interna l rate o f retu rn o f Project G, is greater than r2, the internal rate o f retu rn o f Project H. However, because o f the possibility th a t the internal rate o f retu rn m ethod may give an incorrect ranking o f m utually exclusive investm ent projects, the net present value m ethod is preferred. The incremental internal rate of return approach to ranking mutually exclusive investments The internal rate o f return m ethod can be adapted so th a t i t provides a correct ranking o f m utually exclusive projects. This is shown in Example 5.6. Example 5.6 The cash flows for two projects, I and J, are shown in Table 5.7. Are projects I and J acceptable? TABLE 5.7 " Cash flows ($) Project Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 I -45 000 13 500 13500 13500 13500 13 500 J -30000 9150 9150 9150 9150 9150 SOLUTION If the required rate of return is 8 per cent per annum, both projects are acceptable using either the net present value or the internal rate of return method, as shown in Table 5.8. TABLE 5.8 Project Internal rate of return (%) Net present value ($) I 15.2 8902 J 15.9 6533 If the two projects are mutually exclusive, then, using the net present value method, Project I is preferred to Project J, while using the internal rate of return method, Project J is preferred to Project I. The incremental cash flows from choosing Project I (the project with the lower internal rate of return) rather than Project J (the project with the higher internal rate of return) are presented in Table 5.9. These cash flows may be assigned to the notional project 1 minus J’. TABLE 5.9 Cash flows for notional project Year 1 minus } ' ($) 0 -15000 1 4350 2 4350 3 4350 4 4350 5 4350 C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods The internal rate of return of this notional project is 13.8 per cent. As this internal rate of return is greater than the required rate of return of 8 per cent, the notional project should be accepted. Accepting the notional project 7I minus J7 is equivalent to accepting Project I in preference to Project J. This is the ranking given by the net present value method. The possibility o f conflict between the interna l rate o f retu rn and net present value methods may therefore be avoided by the use o f this ‘increm ental internal rate o f retu rn ’ approach. It results in a ranking o f m utually exclusive projects th a t is consistent w ith the net present value method. However, the net present value m ethod is simpler and is more obviously consistent w ith the objective o f wealth maximisation, which is expressed in absolute dollar term s rather than in percentage terms. 5 .4 .4 1 Benefit-cost ratio (profitability index) Research shows th a t some chief financial officers use the p ro fita b ility index m ethod o f project evaluation. In this m ethod, instead o f showing the net present value as an absolute am ount, the present value o f the n et cash flows is divided by the in itia l cash outlay to give a b e n e fit-c o st ra tio or p ro fita b ility index.A b e n e fit-co st ratio fo r the project in Table 5.2 is calculated as follows: Benefit-cost ratio = present value o f net cash flows 5.7 initia l cash outlay _ $1 135154 $900 000 m LEARNING OBJECTIVE 4 Explain why the net present value method is preferred to all other methods BENEFIT-COST RATIO index calculated by dividing the present value of the future net cash flows by the initial cash outlay (also known as a profitability index) = 1 .2 6 Using the benefit-cost ratio, the decision rule is to accept projects w ith a benefit-cost ratio greater than 1, and to reject projects w ith a benefit-cost ratio less than 1. Clearly, projects w ith benefit-cost ratios greater than 1 w ill have positive net present values, and those w ith benefit-cost ratios less than 1 w ill have negative net present values. In the above example, the net present value is $235154 and the benefit-cost ratio is 1.26. Both methods therefore indicate th a t the project is acceptable and, in general, b oth methods w ill give the same accept/reject decision fo r independent projects. However, the benefit-cost ratio provides no info rm a tio n additional to th a t already provided by the NPV method. Thus, there is little p o in t in using this method. In addition, the benefit-cost ratio can result in a ranking o f m utually exclusive projects th a t differs from the ranking th a t would result from using the NPV method. This is shown in Example 5.7. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Outline the decision rules for each of the main methods of project evaluation Example 5.7 Consider the mutually exclusive investments projects in Table 5.10. TABLE 5.10 Ranking projects using the benefit-cost ratio Project K Project L Present value of net cash flows ($) 260000 100000 Initial cash outlay ($) 180000 50000 80000 50000 260 000 100 000 180 000 1.44 50 000 2.00 Net present value Benefit-cost ratio = In this case, although the net present value of Project L is less than the net present value of Project K, the benefit-cost ratio of L is greater than that of K. 命 B usiness finance Therefore, i f the b e n e fit-co st ra tio is used i t may result in management p re fe rrin g projects w ith low er net present values. The b e n e fit-co st ra tio m ust therefore be rejected as a ranking technique because i t can provide incorrect rankings o f m u tu a lly exclusive projects. Research indicates th a t the p o p u la rity o f the p ro fita b ility index to managers relative to o the r p roject evaluation techniques is low. Further, survey evidence9 suggests th a t the technique tends to be used by managers who face a shortage o f funds available to invest in w ealth-enhancing projects. Faced w ith such constraints, managers have to decide on the m ix o f acceptable projects th a t should be funded in order to m axim ise the w ealth created fo r the firm . This process, know n as capital rationing, is discussed in Section 6.8. 5.5 O ther methods of project evaluation In Figure 5.1, there were two m ajor non-discounted cash flow methods employed by the companies surveyed. They are the accounting rate o f retu rn and the payback methods. These methods are frequently employed in conjunction w ith the discounted cash flow methods o f project evaluation. The accounting rate of return ACCOUNTING RATE OF RETURN earnings from an investment expressed as a percentage of the investment outlay There are many ways to calculate the accounting rate o f return or retu rn on investm ent. The most popular methods are those th a t express a projects average annual earnings as a percentage o f either the in itia l investm ent or the average investm ent in the project. That is: average annual earnings Va = 100 ------------------------------------------------------------ X ------- % initia l investment in a project average annual earnings 1 100 ra = --------------------------------------------------- x ----- % average investment in a project 1 5.8 ■ 5.9 PAYBACK PERIOD the time it takes for the progressive accumulated net cash flows generated by an investment to equal the initial cash outlay Payback period The payback period is the tim e it takes fo r an e n tity to recover a projects in itia l cash outlay. For example, the payback period o f a machine th a t costs $300000 and has net cash flows o f $100000 per annum is 3 years. Sections 5.5.1 and 5.5.2 show th a t the accounting rate o f retu rn and payback methods are in fe rio r to the net present value method. 5.5.1 | Accounting rate of return LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Outline the decision rules for each of the main methods of project evaluation Essentially, the accounting rate o f retu rn is the earnings from a project, usually after deducting both depreciation and income tax, expressed as a percentage o f the investm ent outlay. I t is compared w ith a required rate o f retu rn or cut-off rate to determine the project s acceptability. I f the accounting rate o f return is greater than the required rate o f return, the project is acceptable; i f i t is less than the required rate o f return, the project is unacceptable. The accounting rate o f retu rn has many variants. We w ill calculate only three o f these. To calculate these variants o f the accounting rate o f return, management m ust firs t estimate: a b 9 the average annual earnings to be generated by a project. This is calculated by d ivid in g the to ta l net p ro fit from the project by the num ber o f years d urin g w hich the p ro fit is expected to be received. the investm ent outlay on the project. This is equal to either its in itia l investm ent outlay, including additional and permanent w orking capital requirements, or the average capital employed in the For surveys of capital budgeting practices, see Burns and Walker (2009). C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods project. The average capital employed on a project is calculated either as the average book value o f the investment, or more frequently as the average o f the capital invested in the project at the beginning and the end o f its life. The methods o f calculating the accounting rate o f retu rn are illustrated in Example 5.8. E xample 5.8 Assume that a company is considering an investment project that costs $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 and generates returns in Years 1 ,2 and 3 as shown in Table 5.11. 6 TABLE 5.11 Data for calculating the accounting rate of return Item___________ I Year 2 Year 3 2000000 3000000 4000000 10000000 7000000 4900000 31 December 7000000 4900000 3430000 Average 8500000 5 950000 4165 000 Earnings (after depreciation and income tax) ($) Year 1_____ | Average 3000000 Book value ($)(a) 1 January 6205 000 ^Assuming that depreciation is calculated at 30 per cent on the reducing balance. Using these data, the following accounting rates of return may be calculated: a) Accounting rate of return based on the initial investment is: $3000000 =3〇% $10000000 b) Accounting rate of return based on the average book value is: $3 000000 = 48% $6205000 c) Accounting rate of return based on average investment as measured by the average of the capital invested at the beginning and the end of the project's life is: $3 000000 =44.68% $ 10 000000+ $3 430000 Each variant yields a different rate of return. For example, if the rate of return is calculated by dividing average annual earnings by the a verage investment outlay, then the project's rate of return would be much higher than if it had been calculated by dividing average annual earnings by the in itia l investment outlay. There are two fundam ental problems w ith using the accounting rate o f return, irrespective o f the way it is defined. First, it is arbitrary. This is because i t is based on accounting earnings rather than cash flows. As a result, factors such as the depreciation m ethod employed and the m ethod o f valuing inventories w ill have a substantial bearing on the measurement o f earnings and therefore on the accounting rate o f return. Second, i t ignores the tim in g o f the earnings stream. Equal weight is given to the earnings in each year o f the projects life. This problem is illustrated in Example 5.9. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Explain the advantages and disadvantages of the main project evaluation methods E xample 5.9 A company is considering two projects, M and N. Both projects cost $ 1 000 00 at the beginning of the first year and have a life of 5 years. The residual value of each project at the end of the fifth year is zero. The earnings for each project are shown in Table 5.12. TABLE 5.12 Annual earnings ($) Project Outlay ($1 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Total M 100000 2500 5000 10000 15000 17500 50000 N 100000 17500 15000 10000 5000 2500 50000 The average rate of return for each project is: $50 00 0/5 $10000 $ 10 00 00 /2 $50000 100% 0^ 0/ 1 Project M has increasing earnings while Project N has decreasing earnings. However, both result in the same total earnings, and therefore the same average annual earnings. Consequently, both projects are regarded as equally acceptable if the accounting rate of return method is used. However, the two projects are not equally acceptable because the earnings from Project N are received earlier than the earnings from Project M. Intuition would suggest, therefore, that Project N is preferable to Project M. The accounting rate o f retu rn fails to reflect the advantages th a t earlier returns have over later returns. As a result, this m ethod ranks projects w ith the same in itia l outlay, life and to ta l earnings equally, even though the projects1patterns o f earnings may be different. In addition, i f projects w ith the same in itia l outlay and to ta l earnings have different lives, the accounting rate o f retu rn m ethod w ill automatically favour projects w ith short lives. However, there is no reason w hy such projects should necessarily prove to be the m ost profitable projects. Because o f its significant shortcomings, the accounting rate o f retu rn m ethod should n o t be used to evaluate investm ent projects. However, as we observed earlier, in practice the accounting rate o f return is often used in conjunction w ith the discounted cash flow methods. Because external financial analysts use earnings (profit) to assess a company s performance, management may wish to ensure th a t projects are acceptable according to both accounting and discounted cash flow criteria. 5 .5 .2 1 Payback period The payback period is the tim e it takes fo r the in itia l cash outlay on a project to be recovered from the projects net cash flows. I t is calculated by summing the net cash flows from a project in successive years u n til the to ta l is equal to the in itia l cash outlay. This is illustrated in Table 5.13. TABLE 5.13 Calculation of payback period Project Q Year Initial cash outlay ($) 0 100000 Project R Net cash flow ($) Initial cash outlay ($) Net cash flow ($) 100000 1 20000 20000 2 30000 40000 C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods Table 5.1 3 continued Project Q Year Initial cash outlay ($) Project R Net cash flow ($) Initial cash outlay ($) Net cash flow ($) 3 30000 40000 4 20000 10000 5 70000 10000 Total 170000 120000 Payback period 4 years 3 years To decide whether a project is acceptable, its payback period is compared w ith some maximum acceptable payback period. A project w ith a payback period less than the m axim um w ill be accepted, while a project w ith a payback period greater than the m axim um w ill be rejected. An im p o rta n t question is: W hat length o f tim e represents the correct, payback period as a standard against which to measure the acceptability o f a particular project? In practice a m axim um payback period is set, which is inevitably arbitrary, and may be from , say, 2 to 5 years. A ll projects w ith a payback period greater than this m axim um are rejected. Calculation o f the payback period takes in to account only the net cash flows up to the p o in t where they equal the investm ent outlay. The calculation o f the payback period ignores any net cash flows after that point. As a result, the payback m ethod o f evaluation discriminates against projects w ith long gestation periods and large cash flows late in th e ir lives. The payback period is n o t a measure o f a project s pro fitab ility. I f the m ost profitable projects were always those th a t recovered the investm ent outlay in the shortest period o f tim e, then current assets such as inventory and accounts receivable would yield higher returns than non-current assets, and noncurrent assets w ith short lives would yield higher returns than non-current assets w ith long lives. Mere recovery o f the outlay on a project yields no p ro fit at all. I f there is a p ro fit on the project i t m ust be due to additional cash flows after the investm ent outlay has been recovered. Therefore, the m ajor weakness o f the payback m ethod is its failure to take account o f the magnitude and tim in g o f all o f a projects cash inflows and outflows. Why then is payback popular as a m ethod o f investm ent evaluation? As was shown in Figure 5.1, many companies around the w orld use payback in conjunction w ith other methods. One reason fo r its popularity is th a t i t provides in fo rm a tio n on how long funds are likely to be com m itted to a project. Managers who prefer projects w ith short payback periods are interested in how soon the funds invested in a project w ill be recouped and hence this m ethod provides managers w ith inform a tion th a t w ill facilitate th eir preparation o f cash flow budgets, thereby enabling them to better manage the liq u id ity o f the firm . Another reason is th a t the near-term cash flows considered in calculating the payback period are regarded as more certain than later cash flows. As a result, insistence on a short payback period is a simple b u t imprecise way o f controlling fo r risk. 5 .5 .3 1 Economic value added (EVA) In Section 5.5.1, i t was noted th a t the accounting rate o f retu rn m ethod is often used in addition to the discounted cash flow methods because financial analysts generally use accounting inform a tion to assess performance year by year. To overcome the problems o f measuring the accounting rate o f return discussed in Section 5.5.1, the economic value added (EVA) approach to measuring performance was introduced by consulting firm s in the US.10 10 Economic value added (EVA) is the term used by the US consulting firm Stern-Stewart. This firm has been instrumental in popularising this measure of performance. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Outline the decision rules for each of the main methods of project evaluation m LEARNING OBJECTIVE 5 Understand the relationship between economic value added (EVA) and net present value (NPV) B usiness finance Accounting p ro fit is calculated as the difference between revenues and expenses fo r a reporting period. One o f the costs incurred by a company th a t is n o t deducted in calculating p ro fit is the company s required rate o f return. To calculate the EVA o f an investm ent, i t is sim ply a m atter o f deducting from accounting earnings the p ro fit required from the investm ent, calculated as the required rate o f return m ultiplie d by the capital invested in the project. Thus, using Example 5.9, i f the required rate o f return is 10 per cent, then the returns generated in Years 1, 2 and 3 would be as shown in Table 5.14. TABLE 5.14 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 2000 3000 4000 700 490 $2300 $3510 Earnings (after depreciation and income tax) ($) Capital charge: Am ount invested x 10% ($) 1000(fl) Economic value added (EVA) $1000 In Year 1, the amount invested in the project is $10000, therefore the capital charge is $10000 x 10% = $1000. The EVA in Table 5.14 shows the addition to the company s wealth created by the investment. If the accounting rate o f retu rn were equal to the required rate o f return, then EVA would be zero. EVA, therefore, provides management w ith a simple rule: invest only i f the increase in earnings is sufficient to cover the required rate o f return. EVA makes the required rate o f retu rn an im p o rta n t element in measuring the performance o f an investm ent. The manager o f a plant can improve EVA either by increasing earnings or by reducing the capital employed. Therefore, there is an incentive fo r managers to id e n tify underperform ing assets and dispose o f them. Note th a t this approach to measuring EVA does n ot measure present value. However, it can be shown th a t the present value o f a stream o f future EVAs fo r an investm ent is equal to the net present value of the investm ent. The EVA in each period is equal to the net cash flow plus or m inus the change in the value o f the investm ent less the required rate o f return. Thus: 5.10 E V A ^ C ^ il-I^ -k l^ where Ct = net cash flow in Year t I t = value o f the investm ent at the end o f Year t = value o f the investm ent at the end o f Yeart k = required rate o f return However, there are tw o special cases: a b In Year 0, EVA0 = C〇+ J〇because there is no capital charge u n til Year 1. A t the end o f the project, the investm ent in the project (Jt) is zero because the investm ent is liquidated and therefore EVAt = Ct - (1 + k) 1 ^ . Therefore, the present value o f a stream o f EVAs is: EVA〇 EVAi EVA2 1+ k (1 + k ) 2 EVAT. y EVAt { l + k )T~l ( l + k )T BB1 where EVA0 = C〇+ J〇 EVA1 = C1 + I 1 - ( l + k) I 0 EVA2 = C2 + 12 - (1 + /c) £ \^ 4 了_1 = C t_i + 1"了_1 (1 + /c) 1了_2 EVAj = CT - (1 + /c) I T-1 W hen these values are substituted in to Equation 5.11, we fin d th a t all the I terms cancel out, leaving: C〇 ^ - g j - + — ^ 1 + fc (1 + k f + .,,+ £ r-i (l + k f - 1 _C t (1 + k ) T = NPV That is, the discounted stream o f EVAs is the same as the NPV o f the investment. C hapter five Project 5.6 evaluation : principles a n d methods Project evaluation and real options analysis A key message o f this chapter has been th a t discounted cash flow techniques, such as NPV and IRR, provide the m ost accurate, and m ost popular, approach to project evaluation. However, we know th a t these techniques are answering a very specific question about the lin k between a project and wealth creation th a t may n o t be the question we should be m ost interested in. For example, NPV analysis provides us w ith an estimate o f the wealth created fo r the firm now zfthe firm were to imm ediately invest in the project. That is, the approach treats projects as now-or-never prospects— whereas we know th a t in reality managers often have significant fle xib ility in how they manage a project (including when to begin it). In addition, NPV is lim ite d to a yes-or-no analysis; fo r example, i t im p lic itly gives no recognition to the fact that, after a project has begun, managers may intervene in the project as circumstances develop. Obviously, this significantly understates the role o f managers. These lim ita tion s o f NPV analysis can, in principle, be dealt w ith using an approach known as real options analysis. The follow ing section explains how real options analysis differs from standard discounted cash flow techniques and describes some o f the evidence th a t suggests that, despite its apparent usefulness, it is used by relatively few financial managers.11 5 .6 .1 1 Real options analysis Consider the follow ing scenario: substantial o il reserves have just been discovered in Sydney Harbour and the government has called fo r bids fo r the rig h t to extract the oil. Comprehensive geological reports estimate th a t there are 40 m illio n barrels o f o il th a t could be extracted. Owing to the unique environm ent in which the o il is located, and the need to ensure that any disturbance to the environm ent fro m the invasive extraction process is remedied, the present value o f the expected cost o f extraction is relatively high, at $80 per barrel. The long-run expected sales price o f the o il is estimated to be $70 per barrel in present value terms. How much would an investor bid fo r the rig h t to extract oil? Standard NPV analysis would suggest that no rational investor would bid a positive amount fo r the extraction rig h t as the project has a negative NPV w ith each barrel o f o il extracted decreasing wealth by $10. W hat is wrong w ith this analysis? I t ignores the fact th a t the successful bidder fo r the project obtains the right, b u t n o t the obligation, to commence operations. That is, the successful bidder has the option to extract the oil. Based upon current expectations o f available technology, cost structures and revenues i t is at present unprofitable to extract the o il and the option would n o t be imm ediately taken up. However, it is n ot d ifficu lt to th in k o f circumstances th a t may result in the project having a positive NPV. For example, new technology may be developed to substantially reduce the cost o f extraction or the long-run expected sales price o f o il m ig ht increase. Either way, the successful bidder has purchased the rig h t to exploit any advantageous change in circumstances. Throughout this chapter it has been im p lic itly assumed th a t the problem facing management is lim ited to accepting or rejecting a project fo r immediate im plem entation. In reality o f course, th is is rarely the case. Managers can often choose when to im plem ent a project and can influence the way an ongoing project is managed. These choices* faced by management are often referred to as real option s and problems may arise when the value o f options created (or destroyed) by management decisions is not accounted fo r during the project evaluation stage. Some common examples o f real options include: • O ption to delay investm ent— this option is linked to the a b ility o f the firm to ‘w ait and see’ and collect more inform a tion about the project th a t may alter the final decision. This option is especially valuable to a firm where the level o f uncertainty surrounding a project is high. W hen a firm finally commits to a project, it is giving up the o pp o rtu n ity to collect more info rm a tio n about the project, and hence, it is often argued, the NPV o f a project m ust n o t only be positive, b ut be great enough to compensate the firm fo r the value o f the fle xib ility i t is giving up. 11 For an excellent and accessible discussion of the importance of incorporating real options into project evaluation see Dixit and Pindyck (1995). LEARNING OBJECTIVE 6 Understand the relationship between real options, managerial flexibility and firm value REAL OPTIONS ANALYSIS method of evaluating an investment opportunity that accounts for the value associated with managers having flexibility in their decisions about when to invest, how to manage the investment and when to divest themselves of the investment asset REAL OPTIONS the flexibility that a manager has in choosing whether to undertake or abandon a project or change the way a project is managed B usiness finance • • • O ption to expand operations— when a firm firs t enters a m arket i t quite often does so on unprofitable terms. That is, firm s w ill quite w illin g ly enter in to a project th a t has a negative NPV. One explanation fo r this seemingly irra tion al behaviour is th a t by gaining a presence in the market, the firm is able to acquire valuable expansion options th a t would otherwise be unavailable. An example o f this type o f behaviour was the intro du ction o f V irg in Blue Airlines to the Australian m arket. In itia lly the airline provided only seven daily Brisbane-Sydney return flights. However, follow ing the collapse o f Ansett Airlines (the second largest domestic carrier in Australia at the tim e), V irg in Blue found itse lf in a position where it could rapidly expand to fill the void le ft by Ansett. O ption to abandon operations— once a firm makes the decision to proceed w ith a project, it generally retains the rig h t to abandon operations and sell o ff the assets dedicated to the project at th e ir salvage value. A t the outset, o f course, the firm does n o t expect to make use o f (or exercise) this option, b u t i t is im p orta nt th a t it has the a bility to do so i f m arket conditions were to move significantly against the project. This does not, however, im p ly th a t the firm w ill abandon operations as soon as a project becomes unprofitable, since by doing so the firm gives up the a bility to remain in the m arket were conditions to change back in the project’s favour. Once we accept the notion th a t managerial fle x ib ility is valuable, ide ntifyin g real options is relatively straightforw ard. The d ifficult p art is to tr y to then value them. A discussion o f the general principles underlying option pricing, as well as a more detailed discussion o f real options analysis, is provided in Chapter 18. W hile finance academics have been very enthusiastic about the possible im plications o f real options analysis fo r financial managers, the international evidence in Figure 5.1 suggests th a t the actual usage of the technique has been relatively low over an extended tim e interval beginning at the tu rn o f the century. So who is using real options analysis and why are they doing so? In a survey o f the capital budgeting practices o f Fortune 1000 companies in the US, Block (2007) reports th a t users o f the technique tended to be concentrated in industries such as technology, energy and u tilitie s, where sophisticated analysis* was a standard part o f running the business. In a sim ilar survey o f Canadian firm s, Baker, D utta and Saadi (2011) report th a t the most popular reasons cited fo r using real options analysis were that the approach assists management in form ing th e ir strategic vision, fo r the firm while allowing fo r the impact o f managerial fle x ib ility in the analysis. Also o f interest are the factors th a t impede the im plem entation o f real options analysis. Block (2007) finds th a t the m ost frequently cited reason fo r avoiding the technique is *[a] lack o f top management support*. Baker, D utta and Saadi (2011) provide a helpful glimpse at the reason behind th a t lack o f support: th e ir respondent sample nominates a 'lack o f expertise or knowledge* as the m ost significant reason fo r not using the approach. C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods Of the two discounted cash flow methods of investment evaluation, we recommend the net present value method because it is consistent with the objective of maximising shareholders' wealth. It is also simple to use and gives rise to fewer problems than the internal rate of return method. W e have shown that where mutually exclusive projects are being considered, the internal rate of return method may result in rankings that conflict with those provided by the net present value method. In addition, we have shown that even if investment projects are independent, it is possible that a project's pattern of cash flows may give rise to multiple internal rates of return, or to no internal rate of return at all. If the net present value method is adopted, the rules for making correct investment decisions are straightforward: • Calculate each project's net present value, using the required rate of return as the discount rate. • If the projects are independent, accept a project if its net present value is greater than zero, and reject it if its net present value is less than zero. • If the projects are mutually exclusive, accept the project with the highest net present value, provided that it is greater than zero. • In practice, companies often use one method of project evaluation in conjunction with other methods. For example, one of the discounted cash flow methods may be used to measure a project's profitability, but the payback period may also be used, either as a check on liquidity effects or as a means of monitoring the project's cash flows against expectations. • Whereas the evaluation methods considered throughout the chapter tend to treat projects as 'now-or-never7 prospects, and ignore the ability of management to intervene in an ongoing project, real options analysis considers the value associated with managerial flexibility. KEY TERMS accounting rate of return 1 18 benefit-cost ratio 117 discounted cash flow (DCF) methods independent project 107 internal rate of return (IRR) 107 107 mutually exclusive projects 113 net present value (NPV) 107 payback period 118 real options 123 real options analysis 123 SELF-TEST PROBLEMS The management of a company is considering an investment of $1 8 0 0 0 0 in a project that will generate net cash flows of $101 80 0 at the end of the first year, $ 9 0 0 0 0 at the end of the second year and $ 8 0 0 0 0 at the end of the third year. Assuming a required rate of return of 10 per cent per annum, calculate the project's net present value. Calculate the internal rate of return for the investment in Question 1. Calculate the benefit-cost ratio for the investment in Question 1. Solutions to self-test problems are available in Appendix B. QUESTIONS 1 [LO 1 ] Outline the four steps in the capital-expenditure process. 2 [LO 2 】What factors does the required rate of return of a project reflect? 3 [LO 2] Compare the internal rate of return and net present value methods of project evaluation. Do these methods always lead to comparable recommendations? If not, why not? 4 [LO 2] Distinguish between independent and mutually exclusive investment projects. 5 [LO 3] Evidence suggests that financial managers use more than one method to evaluate investment projects. Comment on this statement. C H A P T E R FIVE R E V I E W SUMMARY B usiness finance 6 [ L 0 3 ] The internal rate o f return m ethod o f p ro je c t evaluation is easier to use because it avoids the need to calculate a re q u ire d rate o f return. C o m m e n t o n th is s ta te m e n t. 7 [L O 3 ] W h a t p ro b le m s a r e a s s o c ia te d w ith th e use o f th e a c c o u n tin g r a te o f re tu rn m e th o d f o r th e e v a lu a tio n o f in v e s tm e n t p ro p o s a ls ? W h y m ig h t m a n a g e rs b e a ttr a c te d to its use? 8 9 [L O 4 ] Even w here projects are independent, the uncritical use o f the internal rate o f return m ethod can seriously m islead management. D iscuss. [L O 4 】D e m o n s tra te , fo r in d e p e n d e n t in v e s tm e n t p ro je c ts , th a t th e in te rn a l ra te o f re tu rn a n d n e t p re s e n t v a lu e m e th o d s o f e v a lu a tio n y ie ld id e n tic a l d e c is io n s . S p e c ify a n y a s s u m p tio n s y o u m a k e . 10 [LO 4 ] U s in g th e N P V p r o file te c h n iq u e , e x p la in w h y th e IRR a n d N P V ru le s w ill a lw a y s re s u lt in th e s a m e a c c e p t o r r e je c t d e c is io n f o r in d e p e n d e n t p ro je c ts . 11 12 [LO 4 The p a y b a c k p e rio d m ethod o f p ro je c t evaluation is b ia se d a g a in st projects w ith lo n g e r developm ental lives, even w here they ultim ately generate g re a t value fo r the firm. Discuss. [L 0 5 ] A s th e p re s e n t v a lu e o f a stre a m o f EVAs f o r a n in v e s tm e n t is th e s a m e a s its n e t p re s e n t v a lu e , w h y d o a n a ly s ts use EVA? 13 [L O 6 ] T h e re is s o m e e v id e n c e th a t w h e n m a n a g e rs e v a lu a te p ro je c ts , th e y s y s te m a tic a lly e m p lo y d is c o u n t ra te s th a t e x c e e d th e ris k -a d ju s te d r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn . H o w is th is o b s e r v a tio n c o n s is te n t w ith th e n o tio n th a t re a l o p tio n s a r e im p o r ta n t in p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n ? 14 [L O 6 ] Real options analysis prom ises to be a ve ry p o w e rfu l to o l fo r fin a n c ia l m anagers. D e s c rib e th e e v id e n c e c o n c e r n in g th e p o p u la r ity o f th e a p p r o a c h — re la tiv e to d is c o u n te d c a s h f lo w t e c h n iq u e s — a n d s u g g e s t p o s s ib le re a s o n s f o r th e se resu lts. cA 1 PROBLEMS Discount rates, IRR and N P V analysis [LO 2] A s s u m e th a t y o u a re a s k e d to a n a ly s e th e fo llo w in g th re e p ro je c ts : A -2 0 0 0 0 0 20000 20000 20000 20000 220000 B -2 0 0 0 0 0 52760 52760 52760 52 760 52760 C -2 0 0 0 0 0 一 一 一 一 322100 C o n s tru c t a s p re a d s h e e t, a n d a s s o c ia te d g ra p h s , th a t w ill e n a b le y o u to a n a ly s e th e im p a c t o f d iffe re n t d is c o u n t ra te s o n th e N P V o f a p r o je c t as w e ll a s c a lc u la te th e IRR fo r a p r o je c t (a n e x a m p le is p r o v id e d in F ig u re 5 .2 ). a) R a nk th e th re e p ro je c ts a s s u m in g th e a p p r o p r ia te d is c o u n t ra te is: i) 6 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m b) 2 ii) 10 per cent per annum iii) 15 p e r ce n t p e r a n nu m . C a lc u la te th e IRR fo r e a c h o f th e p ro je c ts , th e n ra n k th e m . IRR and N P V analysis for independent projects [LO 2] T he fo llo w in g in v e s tm e n t p ro p o s a ls a re in d e p e n d e n t. A s s u m in g a r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn o f 1 0 p e r c e n t, a n d u s in g b o th th e in te rn a l ra te o f re tu rn a n d n e t p re s e n t v a lu e m e th o d s , w h ic h o f th e p ro p o s a ls a r e a c c e p ta b le ? C a s h f lo w ($ ) 126 P ro p o s a l Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 A -4 0 0 0 0 8000 48000 B -4 0 0 0 0 42000 C -4 0 0 0 0 48000 C hapter five Project evaluation : principles a n d methods U s in g th e fo llo w in g d a ta , c a lc u la te th e : a) a c c o u n tin g ra te o f re tu rn b) p a y b a c k p e rio d c) in te rn a l ra te o f re tu rn d) n e t p re s e n t v a lu e . P ro je c t co st: $100000 E stim a te d life : 5 y e a rs E s tim a te d re s id u a l v a lu e : $20000 A n n u a l n e t c a sh f lo w : $30000 R e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn : 10% U se th e s tra ig h t-lin e m e th o d o f d e p r e c ia tio n in y o u r c a lc u la tio n s . H o w w o u ld y o u r a n s w e rs d iff e r if th e n e t c a s h flo w s w e r e a s fo llo w s ? Y e a r 1: $30000 Year 2: $40000 Year 3: $60000 Year 4 : $20000 Year 5: $50000 C H A P T E R FIVE R E V I E W A c c o u n tin g ra te o f r e tu r n , p a y b a c k p e r io d , IRR a n d N P V [L O 2 ] A c c o u n tin g r a te o f re tu r n a n d p a y b a c k p e r io d [L O 3 ] U s in g th e f o llo w in g d a ta , c a lc u la te : a) th e a c c o u n tin g ra te o f re tu rn b) th e p a y b a c k p e r io d . P ro je c t co st: $40000 E stim a te d p r o je c t life : 5 y e a rs E stim a te d re s id u a l v a lu e : $8000 A n n u a l a c c o u n tin g p r o fit (e q u a l to a n n u a l n e t c a s h in flo w ): $ 12000 Use th e s tra ig h t-lin e m e th o d o f d e p r e c ia tio n in y o u r c a lc u la tio n s . H o w w o u ld y o u r a n s w e rs to (a) a n d (b) d iffe r if th e e s tim a te d d o lla r re tu rn s w e r e a s fo llo w s ? Year 1 $12000 Year 2 $16000 Year 3 $24000 Year 4 $20000 Year 5 $8000 IRR a n d N P V a n a ly s is [L O 4 ] E ach o f th e fo llo w in g m u tu a lly e x c lu s iv e in v e s tm e n t p ro je c ts in v o lv e s a n in itia l c a sh o u tla y o f $ 2 4 0 0 0 0 . T he e s tim a te d n e t c a s h flo w s fo r th e p ro je c ts a re a s fo llo w s : C a s h f lo w ($) P ro je ct 1 140000 20000 2 80000 40000 3 60000 60000 4 20000 100000 5 20000 180000 127 B usiness finance T he c o m p a n y 's re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 1 p e r ce n t. C o n s tru c t a s p re a d s h e e t, a n d a s s o c ia te d g ra p h s , th a t w ill e n a b le y o u to a n a ly s e th e im p a c t o f d iffe re n t d is c o u n t rates o n th e N P V o f a p r o je c t as w e ll as c a lc u la te th e IRR fo r a p ro je c t. W h a t is th e N P V a n d IRR fo r b o th p ro je c ts ? W h ic h p r o je c t s h o u ld b e c h o s e n ? W h y ? 6 N P V and IRR analysis for mutually exclusive projects [LO 4 】 A c o m p a n y w is h e s to e v a lu a te th e fo llo w in g m u tu a lly e x c lu s iv e in v e s tm e n t p ro p o s a ls : P ro p o s a l a) A -97400 34000 34000 34000 34000 34000 B -63200 24000 24000 24000 24000 24000 C a lc u la te e a c h p r o p o s a l’s n e t p re s e n t v a lu e a n d in te rn a l ra te o f re tu rn . A s s u m e th e re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 8 p e r ce n t. b) H o w w o u ld y o u e x p la in th e d iffe re n t ra n k in g s g iv e n b y th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e a n d in te rn a l ra te o f re tu rn m e th o d s? 7 N P V a n d IRR a n a ly s is [L O 4 】 You h a v e b e e n a s k e d to e v a lu a te th e f o llo w in g in v e s tm e n t p ro p o s a ls : C a s h f lo w ($ ) P ro p o s a l Year 0 Year 1 A 100000 -140000 60000 B -12000 24000 -20000 Year 2 C a lc u la te th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e (a s s u m in g a re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn o f 1 2 p e r cen t) a n d th e in te rn a l ra te o f re tu rn fo r e a c h p ro je c t. E x p la in y o u r results. REFERENCES Baker, H., Dutta, S. & Saadi, S., 'M anagem ent views on real options in capital budgeting', Journal of A pplied Finance, February 2 0 1 1 , pp. 1 8 -2 9 . Dixit, A.K. & Pindyck, R.S., 'The options approach to capital investment7, Harvard Business Review, M ay-June 1995, pp. 1 0 5 -1 5 . Bierman, H. Jr & Smidt, S., The Capital Budgeting Decision: Economic Analysis of Investment Projects, 8th edn, M acmillan Company, N ew York, 1993. Graham, J.R. & Harvey, C.R., 'The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field', Journal of Financial Economics, May-June 2 0 0 1 , pp. 1 8 7 -2 4 3 . Block, S., 'Are "real options” actually used in the real world?' The Engineering Economist, 2 0 0 7 , pp. 2 5 5 -6 7 . W alker, E.D., Introducing project management concepts using a jewelry store robbery7, Decision Sciences Journal of Innovative Education, Spring 2 0 0 4 , pp. 6 5 -9 . Burns, R.M. & W a lk e r,」•,'C apital budgeting surveys: The future is now ', jo u m a / o f >App//ec/ 尸 /nance, 2 0 0 9 , pp. 7 8 -9 0 Coleman, L , Maheswaran, K. & Pinder, S., 'N arratives in managers7 corporate finance decisions', Accounting and Finance, September 2 0 1 0 ; pp. 6 0 5 -3 3 . 128 ▼ CHAPTER CONTENTS m H H I n t r o d u c tio n 130 A n a ly s in g p r o je c t ris k 149 A p p lic a t io n o f th e n e t p r e s e n t v a lu e m e th o d 130 D e c is io n - tr e e a n a ly s is 153 T a x is s u e s in p r o je c t e v a lu a t io n 134 QQj Q u a lit a t iv e f a c t o r s a n d th e s e le c tio n o f p r o je c ts 156 P r o je c t s e le c tio n w it h r e s o u r c e c o n s tr a in ts 157 C o m p a r in g m u tu a lly e x c lu s iv e p r o je c ts t h a t h a v e d if f e r e n t liv e s 139 H H D e c id in g w h e n to r e t ir e ( a b a n d o n ) o r r e p la c e a p r o je c t 146 LEARNING OBJECTIVES A f te r s tu d y in g th is c h a p t e r y o u s h o u ld b e a b le to : 1 e x p la in th e p r in c ip le s u s e d in e s t im a tin g p r o je c t c a s h f lo w s 2 e x p la in th e e ffe c ts o f t a x e s o n p r o je c t c a s h flo w s 3 c o m p a r e m u t u a lly e x c lu s iv e p r o je c ts t h a t h a v e d if f e r e n t liv e s 4 d e t e r m in e w h e n to r e t ir e ( a b a n d o n ) o r r e p la c e a s s e ts 5 e x p la in h o w s e n s itiv ity a n a ly s is , b r e a k - e v e n a n a ly s is a n d s im u la t io n a s s is t in a n a ly s in g p r o je c t r is k 6 u s e d e c is io n - tr e e a n a ly s is to a n a ly s e s e q u e n tia l d e c is io n s 7 e x p la in th e r o le o f q u a lit a t iv e f a c t o r s in p r o je c t s e le c tio n 8 e x p la in th e e ffe c ts o f r e s o u r c e c o n s t r a in ts o n p r o je c t s e le c tio n . B usiness finance Introduction In C h a p te r 5, m e th o d s o f p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n w e re discussed a n d th e reasons f o r u s in g th e n e t p re s e n t va lu e m e th o d o f p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n w e re o u tlin e d . H o w e ve r, in C h a p te r 5 i t was a ssu m ed t h a t a p ro je c ts cash flo w s a n d th e d is c o u n t ra te a p p lic a b le to th o s e cash flo w s w e re b o th k n o w n . In p ra c tic e , a p ro je c t s cash flo w s a n d re q u ire d ra te o f r e tu r n are n o t k n o w n w it h c e rta in ty b u t m u s t be e s tim a te d . In o th e r w o rd s, p ra c tic a l p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n in v o lv e s im p o r t a n t issues c o n c e rn in g th e e s tim a tio n o f cash flo w s an d ris k . These a n d o th e r issues are th e s u b je c t o f th is c h a p te r. In p a rtic u la r, th e m a tte rs c o n s id e re d in th is c h a p te r in c lu d e : • th e a p p lic a tio n o f th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e m e th o d , in c lu d in g th e e s tim a tio n o f cash flo w s • u s in g th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e m e th o d to solve p ro b le m s , such as c o m p a rin g p ro je c ts w it h d iffe re n t liv e s a n d a sse t-re p la ce m e n t de cisio ns • th e a p p lic a tio n o f te c h n iq u e s t h a t a llo w m an ag ers to analyse th e r is k o f p ro je c ts • th e in flu e n c e o f q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs o n th e s e le c tio n o f in v e s tm e n t p ro je c ts • th e p ro b le m s associated w it h u s in g th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e m e th o d w h e re co m p a n ie s are assu m ed to have o n ly lim ite d access to reso urce s.1 6.2 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Explain the principles used in estimating project cash flows A pp lica tio n of the net present value method A n y a p p lic a tio n o f th e n e t p re s e n t va lu e m e th o d re q u ire s e s tim a te s o f p ro je c t cash flo w s . This s e c tio n discusses issues t h a t are im p o r t a n t in d e fin in g th e re le v a n t cash flo w s. 6.2.1 | Estimation of cash flows in project evaluation Issues t h a t a rise in d e fin in g th e re le v a n t cash flo w s in c lu d e th e : • tre a tm e n t o f fin a n c in g charges • in c lu s io n o f in c re m e n ta l cash flo w s • im p o rta n c e o f e x c lu d in g s u n k costs • tre a tm e n t o f a llo c a te d costs • tre a tm e n t o f a p ro je c ts re s id u a l value • t im in g o f th e cash flo w s • tr e a tm e n t o f in fla tio n . These issues are discussed in tu r n . Financing charges C o m pa nie s s h o u ld use th e re q u ire d ra te o f r e tu r n to d is c o u n t a p ro je c ts n e t cash flo w s . The re q u ire d rate o f r e tu r n is th e r e tu r n t h a t is s u ffic ie n t to co m p e n sa te s h a re h o ld e rs a n d d e b th o ld e rs f o r th e resources c o m m itte d to th e p ro je c t. I t in clu d e s b o th in te re s t p a id to d e b th o ld e rs a n d re tu rn s to sha reh old ers. T h ere fore, fin a n c in g charges such as in te re s t a n d d iv id e n d s s h o u ld n o t be in c lu d e d in th e c a lc u la tio n o f a p ro je c ts n e t cash flo w s . The in c lu s io n o f fin a n c in g charges in a p ro je c t s n e t cash flo w s a n d in th e d is c o u n t ra te w o u ld re s u lt in d o u b le c o u n tin g . Incremental cash flows In c a lc u la tin g a p ro je c t s n e t cash flo w s , i t is th e in c re m e n ta l n e t cash flo w s t h a t are im p o r ta n t. A n a n a ly s t s h o u ld in c lu d e all cash flo w s t h a t change i f th e p ro je c t is u n d e rta k e n . W h e n d e c id in g w h e th e r a p a rtic u la r ite m s h o u ld be in c lu d e d , th e a n a ly s t is in te re s te d in th e an sw e rs to tw o q u e s tio n s : 1 The effects of taxes on discount rates are discussed in Chapter 14. C hapter six T he application of project evaluation methods cash ite m ? a Is i t a b W ill th e a m o u n t o f th e ite m change i f th e p ro je c t is u n d e rta k e n ? I f th e an sw e r to b o th q u e s tio n s is ‘yes’,th e n th e ite m is an in c re m e n ta l cash flo w . I f th e a n sw e r to e ith e r q u e s tio n is ‘n o ’,th e n th e ite m is irre le v a n t to th e an alysis. F o r e xa m p le , assum e t h a t a c o m p a n y is re c e iv in g $ 4 0 0 0 0 p e r yea r fr o m r e n tin g a p o r tio n o f its fa c to ry , a n d t h a t i t is c o n s id e rin g u s in g th a t space to m a n u fa c tu re a p ro d u c t t h a t w i ll r e tu r n n e t cash flo w s o f $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 p e r year. In t h is case, $ 1 0 0 000 o ve rsta tes th e n e t cash flo w s f r o m th e p ro d u c t b y an a m o u n t o f $ 4 0 0 0 0 ; th e cash in flo w fo rg o n e because a p o r tio n o f th e fa c to ry w ill n o t be re n te d . The in c re m e n ta l n e t cash flo w in th is case is $ 6 0 0 0 0 p e r year. The p rin c ip le o f in c lu d in g o n ly in c re m e n ta l cash flo w s m a y seem sim p le , b u t i t s o m e tim e s in v o lv e s d iffic u ltie s such as id e n tify in g s u n k costs a n d a llo c a te d costs. Sunk costs Suppose t h a t th e S p ilt O il C o m p a n y has s p e n t $ 2 0 m illio n e x p lo rin g a p a r tic u la r area w ith o u t success. H a rv e y M ills , th e g e o lo g is t w h o o r ig in a lly id e n tifie d th a t area as p o te n tia lly va lu a b le , argues t h a t th e co m p a n y s h o u ld spe nd a n o th e r $5 m illio n to d r ill an a d d itio n a l w e ll because: ‘I f w e d o n ’t, th e $ 2 0 m illio n th a t we have a lre a d y s p e n t w i ll be lost*. M r M ills s a rg u m e n t is in c o rre c t because th e $ 2 0 m illio n is a sunk SUNK COST cost. cost that has already been incurred and is irrelevant to future decision making S u n k costs are p a s t o u tla y s a n d s h o u ld be ig n o re d in m a k in g de cisio n s a b o u t w h e th e r to c o n tin u e a p ro je c t o r to te rm in a te it . In t h is case, th e $ 2 0 m illio n has a lre a d y b e en s p e n t. T his fig u re w i ll n o t change i f th e p ro je c t is c o n tin u e d o r a b a n d o n e d . A llo w in g s u n k costs to in flu e n c e d e cisio n s can lead to t h r o w in g good m o n e y a fte r b a d 1. R egardless o f w h e th e r $2 o r $2 0 m illio n has a lre a d y be en s p e n t, d e cisio n s o n w h e th e r to c o n tin u e a p ro je c t s h o u ld be based o n ly o n e xp ected future costs a n d b e n e fits . Allocated costs C om panies o fte n a llo ca te costs such as re n t, p o w e r, w a te r, research a n d d e v e lo p m e n t, he ad o ffic e costs, tra v e l an d o th e r ove rh e a d costs to t h e ir d iv is io n s . T h ere fore, w h e n th e p r o fita b ilit y o f a p ro je c t is e stim a te d , th e costs a ttr ib u te d to th e p ro je c t m a y in c lu d e a share o f th e se a llo c a te d costs. The a n a ly s t s h o u ld re m e m b e r t h a t w h e n a p ro je c t is b e in g eva lu ated , o n ly in c re m e n ta l cash flo w s s h o u ld be in c lu d e d . In som e cases, im p le m e n tin g an a d d itio n a l p ro je c t m a y re s u lt in s ig n ific a n tly h ig h e r o v e rh e a d costs, b u t in o th e r cases a n y increase m a y be n e g lig ib le . W h e n e s tim a tin g p ro je c t cash flo w s , a n y a llo c a te d costs s h o u ld be e x a m in e d c a re fu lly to d e te rm in e w h e th e r th e y w o u ld change i f th e p ro je c t w e re to go ahead. I f th e y w o u ld n o t change th e y s h o u ld be exclud ed. Residual value W h e n a p ro je c t is te rm in a te d , i t is lik e ly t h a t a p o r tio n o f th e in it ia l c a p ita l o u tla y w ill be recovered. This is o fte n te rm e d th e p ro je c ts residual value. A p ro je c ts re s id u a l va lu e w ill be th e d isp o sa l va lu e o f th e p ro je c ts assets, less a n y d is m a n tlin g a n d re m o v a l costs associated w it h th e te r m in a tio n o f th e p ro je c t. Timing of the cash flows In som e cases, fin a n c ia l c a lc u la tio n s are based o n th e precise t im in g o f th e re le v a n t cash flo w s . F o r exam ple, such p re c is io n is s ta n d a rd p ra c tic e w h e n c a lc u la tin g th e va lu e o f m a rk e ta b le d e b t s e c u ritie s such as b o n d s a n d b a n k b ills . In the se cases, b o th th e a m o u n t a n d th e t im in g o f th e cash flo w s are k n o w n . H o w eve r, w h e n an in v e s tm e n t p ro je c t is e va lu a te d , th e m a g n itu d e o f th e cash flo w s is ra re ly k n o w n b u t m u s t be e s tim a te d , u s u a lly w it h som e degree o f e rro r. S im ila rly , th e t im in g o f cash flo w s can ra re ly be e s tim a te d p re c is e ly a n d th e s im p lify in g a s s u m p tio n t h a t n e t cash flo w s are rece ive d a t th e e n d o f a p e rio d is u s u a lly a d o p te d . T his a s s u m p tio n reduces th e c o m p le x ity o f th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e c a lc u la tio n s w ith o u t causing a m a rk e d decrease in th e ir re lia b ility , a n d i t is th e a s s u m p tio n a d o p te d in th e re m a in d e r o f th is cha pter. Inflation and project evaluation The A u s tra lia n e co n o m y has a t tim e s e xp e rie n ce d p ro lo n g e d p e rio d s o f in fla tio n . D u rin g a p e rio d o f in fla tio n th e re is an in crea se in th e g e n e ra l le v e l o f p rice s a n d hence a fa ll in th e p u rc h a s in g p o w e r o f m oney. There are tw o a p pro ache s to in c o rp o ra tin g th e e ffe cts o f in fla t io n in to p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n . RESIDUAL VALUE disposal value of a project's assets less any dismantling and removal costs associated with the project's termination B o th ap pro ache s, a p p lie d c o n s is te n tly , w ill g ive th e sam e n e t p re s e n t value . B o th re q u ire th e a n a ly s t to e s tim a te th e f u tu r e ra te o f in fla tio n . O ne a p p ro a ch in v o lv e s m a k in g e s tim a te s o f cash flo w s t h a t are based o n a n tic ip a te d p rice s d u rin g each y e a r o f a p ro je c ts life , a n d d is c o u n tin g th o s e cash flo w s a t th e n o m in a l re q u ire d ra te o f r e tu rn . In th is case, th e e s tim a te d n e t cash flo w s fr o m a p ro je c t in , say, its f o u r t h y e a r o f o p e ra tio n are based on th e p ric e s e xp ected in t h a t f o u r t h year. The presence o f in fla t io n th e re fo re m akes th e jo b o f e s tim a tin g n e t cash flo w s m o re d iffic u lt, esp e cia lly i f p rice s are e xp e cte d to increase a t a ra p id ra te . The use o f th e nominal re q u ire d ra te o f r e tu r n m ea ns t h a t th e d is c o u n t ra te re fle c ts th e m a rk e ts e x p e c ta tio n s a b o u t th e ra te o f in fla tio n . I f i t is e xp e cte d t h a t th e ra te o f in fla t io n w ill increase in th e fu tu re , th e n m a rk e t pressure s h o u ld le a d to an increase in th e n o m in a l re q u ire d ra te o f r e t u r n o n an in v e s tm e n t. T h e re fo re , o b serve d n o m in a l ra te s o f r e tu r n have b u ilt in to th e m e xp ected f u tu r e in fla t io n rates. T his a p p ro a ch is c o n s is te n t, in t h a t n e t cash flo w s based o n a n tic ip a te d f u tu r e p ric e le vels are d is c o u n te d a t th e n o m in a l re q u ire d rate o f r e tu r n , w h ic h also has b u ilt in to i t e xp ected in fla t io n rates. The o th e r a p p ro a ch in v o lv e s e s tim a tin g th e n e t cash flo w s w ith o u t a d ju s tin g th e m f o r a n tic ip a te d changes in p rice s, a n d d is c o u n tin g th o se cash flo w s a t th e real re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn . In o th e r w o rd s, th e n e t cash flo w s are e s tim a te d u s in g e x is tin g (c o n s ta n t) prices. To be c o n s is te n t i t is n e cessa ry to d is c o u n t the se n e t cash flo w s a t th e real re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn , w h ic h excludes e xp e cte d in fla tio n . E xa m p le 6.1 illu s tra te s t h a t th e tw o approaches, a p p lie d c o n s is te n tly , g ive th e sam e re s u lt. Example 6.1 A s s u m e th a t a n in v e s tm e n t o f $ 1 0 0 0 is e x p e c te d to g e n e r a te c a s h flo w s o f $ 5 0 0 , a t c o n s ta n t p ric e s , a t th e e n d o f e a c h o f 3 y e a rs . A s s u m e a ls o th a t p ric e s a r e e x p e c te d to in c re a s e a t th e ra te o f 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m a n d th a t th e n o m in a l r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 5 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . W h a t is th e p r o je c t's n e t p re s e n t v a lu e ? SOLUTION U s in g th e firs t a p p r o a c h , th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e in v e s tm e n t is a s fo llo w s : $]〇〇〇| $500 (1.10 ) f $ 5 0 0 (1 .10)2 ( $ 5 0 0 (1 .10)3 1.15 (1.15)2 (1.15 )3 = $ 1 0 0 0 = $550 + ^ + 1.15 1.3225 1 .5 209 = $ 3 73 U s in g th e s e c o n d a p p r o a c h , th e n e t c a s h f lo w o f $ 5 0 0 p e r a n n u m a t c o n s ta n t p ric e s is d is c o u n te d a t th e re a l r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn . A s d is c u s s e d in S e c tio n s 1 . 5 . 4 a n d 3 . 4 . 4 , th e re a l ra te m a y b e e x p re s s e d in te rm s o f th e n o m in a l ra te a s fo llo w s : 1+p w h e re i* = th e re a l ra te o f re tu rn p e r a n n u m / = th e n o m in a l ra te o f re tu rn p e r a n n u m p = th e a n t ic ip a t e d ra te o f in fla tio n p e r a n n u m T h e re fo re : 1.10 = 4 .5 5 % T he n e t p re s e n t v a lu e is th e n c a lc u la te d a s fo llo w s : $500 $500 $500 1 .0 455 (1.0455)2 (1 .0 4 5 5 )3 -$ 1 0 0 0 + J 5 0 ^ + J 5 0 ^ + J 5 0 ^ 1.0455 = $373 1.0931 1.1428 C hapter six T he application of project evaluation methods In su b se q u e n t exam ples, th e f ir s t a p p ro a ch to in c o rp o ra tin g th e e ffe c t o f in fla t io n in to p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n is g e n e ra lly a d o p te d . U n lik e th e second ap p ro a ch , i t can be re a d ily a p p lie d w h e re th e a n a ly s t w ishes to in c o rp o ra te d iffe re n t rates o f change in p rice s f o r d iffe re n t c o m p o n e n ts o f a p ro je c ts cash flo w s. F o r exam ple, th e ra te o f change in wage rates m a y be fo re c a s t to be d iffe re n t fr o m th e ra te o f change in ra w m a te ria ls prices. In a d d itio n , th e seco nd a p p ro a ch re q u ire s re lia b le e s tim a te s o f th e a n tic ip a te d ra te o f in fla tio n , w h ic h m a y be d iff ic u lt to o b ta in . T h e re fo re , th e f ir s t a p p ro a ch is easier to h a n d le in practice. 6 .2 .2 1 Illustration of cash-flow information in project evaluation The cash flo w in fo r m a tio n t h a t s h o u ld be c o m p ile d f o r p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n is illu s tra te d in E xa m p le 6.2. Example 6.2 T he F ra n k S to n e C o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g th e in tr o d u c tio n o f a n e w p ro d u c t. G e n e r a lly , th e c o m p a n y 's p ro d u c ts h a v e a life o f a b o u t 5 y e a rs , a fte r w h ic h th e y a r e d e le te d fro m th e r a n g e o f p ro d u c ts th a t th e c o m p a n y sells. T he n e w p r o d u c t re q u ire s th e p u rc h a s e o f n e w e q u ip m e n t c o s tin g $ 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 , in c lu d in g f r e ig h t a n d in s ta lla tio n c h a rg e s . T h e u se fu l life o f th e e q u ip m e n t is 5 y e a rs , w ith a n e s tim a te d re s id u a l v a lu e o f $1 5 7 5 0 0 0 a t th e e n d o f th a t p e r io d . T he n e w p r o d u c t w ill b e m a n u fa c tu re d in a f a c t o r y a lr e a d y o w n e d b y th e c o m p a n y . T h e fa c to r y o r ig in a lly c o s t $1 5 0 0 0 0 0 to b u ild a n d h a s a c u r r e n t re s a le v a lu e o f $ 3 5 0 0 0 0 0 , w h ic h s h o u ld re m a in f a ir ly s ta b le o v e r th e n e x t 5 y e a rs . T h is f a c t o r y is c u r r e n tly b e in g re n te d to a n o th e r c o m p a n y u n d e r a le a s e a g r e e m e n t th a t h a s 5 y e a rs to ru n a n d p r o v id e s f o r a n a n n u a l re n ta l o f $ 1 5 0 0 0 0 . U n d e r th e le a s e a g re e m e n t, th e F ra n k S to n e C o m p a n y c a n c a n c e l th e le a s e b y im m e d ia te ly p a y in g th e le ssee c o m p e n s a tio n e q u a l to 1 y e a r 's re n ta l p a y m e n t. It is e x p e c te d th a t th e p r o d u c t w i ll in v o lv e th e c o m p a n y in s a le s p r o m o tio n e x p e n d itu re s th a t w ill a m o u n t to $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 d u r in g th e firs t y e a r th e p r o d u c t is o n th e m a rk e t. A d d it io n s to c u r r e n t a sse ts w ill re q u ire $ 2 2 5 0 0 0 a t th e c o m m e n c e m e n t o f th e p r o je c t a n d a r e a s s u m e d to b e fu lly r e c o v e r a b le a t th e e n d o f th e fifth y e a r. T h e n e w p r o d u c t is e x p e c te d to g e n e r a te n e t o p e r a tin g c a s h flo w s a s fo llo w s : Y e a r 1: $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 Year 2 : $ 2 5 0 0 0 0 0 Year 3: $3 2 5 0 0 0 0 Year 4 : $ 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 Year 5 : $ 1 5 0 0 0 0 0 It is a s s u m e d th a t a ll c a s h flo w s a r e re c e iv e d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r a n d th e r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . W h a t is th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f a d d in g th e n e w p ro d u c t? SOLUTION T he s o lu tio n to th is e x a m p le is se t o u t in T a b le 6 . 1 . TABLE 6.1 Cash flow information for adding the new product C ash Item 1. I n it ia l o u tla y 2. Sale o f e q u ip m e n t Year 0 Year 1 flows ($,_ Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 (4000) 1575 continued B usiness finance T a ble 6.1 3. continued Factory The cost and the c u rre n t resale value o f th e fa c to ry are b o th irre le v a n t (a) Cancel lease (150) (b) N e t cash flo w forgo ne due to re n t forgone (150) 4. M a rk e t research o u tla y (500) 5. A d d itio n s to cu rre n t assets 6. (150) (150) (150) (225) (150) 225 N e t cash flow s fro m operations: Year 1: $2 000 000 2000 Year 2: $ 2 5 0 0 000 2500 Year 3: $ 3 2 5 0 0 0 0 3250 Year 4: $ 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 3000 Year 5: $ 1 5 0 0 0 0 0 T otal 1500 (4375) 1350 2350 3100 2850 3150 1.000 00 0.909 09 0.826 45 0.751 31 0.683 01 0.620 92 Present value o f n e t cash flow s (4375) 1227.3 1942.1 2329.1 1946.6 1955.9 N e t pre sen t value $5026 D is c o u n t fa c to r a t 10% O n th e b a s is o f th is q u a n tita tiv e a n a ly s is th e c o m p a n y s h o u ld a d d th e n e w p r o d u c t to its p r o d u c t lin e . 6.3 Tax issues in project evaluation So fa r in o u r d iscu ssio n o f a lte rn a tiv e m e th o d s o f p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n w e have o u tlin e d th e reasons fo r LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Explain the effects of taxes on project cash flows p r e fe r r in g th e use o f th e n e t p re s e n t va lu e m e th o d . H o w e ve r, th e e ffe cts o f taxes have so fa r b e en ig n o re d . The e ffe c ts o f taxes are c o n sid e re d in th is se ctio n . 6.3.1 | Effect of taxes on net cash flows I f th e re w e re n o taxes, th e m a g n itu d e a n d t im in g o f a p ro je c ts cash in flo w s a n d o u tflo w s w o u ld be th e o n ly re le v a n t cash flo w in fo r m a tio n f o r p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n p u rp o se s. H o w e ve r, u n d e r th e p ro v is io n s o f th e Income TaxAssessmentAct 1936} ta x is assessed o n th e ta x a b le in c o m e o f in d iv id u a ls a n d com p an ies. Taxable in co m e is th e d iffe re n c e b e tw e e n gross in c o m e a n d c e rta in a llo w a b le d e d u c tio n s s p e c ifie d in th e A c t. In c o m e ta x pa yab le is g e n e ra lly c a lc u la te d as a pe rce n ta g e o f ta x a b le in co m e . In c o m e ta x is a m a jo r cash o u tflo w f o r m o s t co m p a n ie s a n d its e ffe c t s h o u ld be co n sid e re d to g e th e r w it h o th e r cash in flo w s a n d o u tflo w s . The ta x re la tin g to a p ro je c t s h o u ld be tre a te d as a cash o u tflo w w h e n th e ta x is p a id . F o r exa m ple, i f ^0^ ta x w ere u s u a lly p a id a t th e en d o f th e y e a r fo llo w in g th e ye a r o f in c o m e , th e n a 1 2 -m o n th la g w o u ld be C hapter six T he application of project evaluation methods a p p ro p ria te f o r c a lc u la tin g a fte r-ta x n e t cash flo w s . H o w e ve r, f o r ease o f c a lc u la tio n , w e assum e t h a t ta x is p a id w h e n th e associated cash in flo w is received. A p ro je c ts a fte r-ta x n e t cash flo w s f o r each p e rio d m a y be c a lc u la te d as: A fte r-ta x n e t cash flo w = n e t cash flo w b e fo re ta x x (1 - tc) m w h ere tc = s ta tu to r y c o m p a n y in c o m e ta x ra te 2 H ow ever, th is e q u a tio n ig n o re s th e e ffe c t o f th e ta x d e d u c tib ility o f expenses t h a t do n o t in v o lv e a cash o u tflo w . In p a rtic u la r, d e p re c ia tio n o f n o n -c u rre n t assets, e x c lu d in g la n d an d, in som e cases, b u ild in g s , is an a llo w a b le d e d u c tio n f o r in c o m e ta x p u rp o se s. D e p re c ia tio n is n o t it s e lf a n o u tflo w o f cash, b u t th e fa ct th a t d e p re c ia tio n is d e d u c tib le f o r ta x p u rp o se s reduces th e in c o m e ta x th a t w o u ld o th e rw is e be payable— a n d in c o m e ta x is d e fin ite ly a cash o u tflo w . The h ig h e r is th e d e p re c ia tio n charge, th e lo w e r is th e in co m e ta x payable b y th e co m p a n y a n d hence th e h ig h e r w ill be th e c o m p a n y s a fte r-ta x n e t cash flow . This increase in a fte r-ta x n e t cash flo w s is re p re s e n te d b y th e ta x savings o n d e p re c ia tio n , w h ic h is calcula ted as fo llo w s : 6.2 Tax savings o n d e p re c ia tio n = d e p re c ia tio n x tc T herefore, th e a fte r-ta x n e t cash flo w s g e n e ra te d b y an in v e s tm e n t p ro je c t m a y be c a lc u la te d b y s u m m in g E q u a tio n s 6.1 a n d 6 .2 as fo llo w s : A fte r - ta x n e t cash flo w = n e t cash flo w x (1 - tc) + d e p re c ia tio n x tc 6.3 E xam p le 6.3 illu s tra te s th e a p p lic a tio n o f E q u a tio n 6.3. Example 6.3 A p ro je c t's b e fo re -ta x n e t c a s h f lo w is e x p e c te d to b e $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 p e r a n n u m . F o r ta x p u rp o s e s th e d e p r e c ia tio n c h a r g e is $ 1 0 0 0 0 p e r a n n u m a n d th e c o m p a n y in c o m e ta x ra te is 3 0 c e n ts in th e d o lla r . The a fte r-ta x n e t c a s h f lo w is c a lc u la te d a s fo llo w s : After-tax net cash flow = $ 1 0 0 000(1 - 0 . 3 0 ) + $ 1 0 0 0 0 (0.30) = $ 7 0 0 0 0 + $7000 =$77000 The e ffe c t o f d e p re c ia tio n o n p ro je c t cash flo w s is m o re co m p le x th a n E xa m p le 6.3 suggests because th e Income Tax A ssessm en t A ct a llo w s tw o m e th o d s o f c a lc u la tin g d e p re c ia tio n : th e straight-line (or prime- cost) method a n d th e reducing-balance (or dim inishing-value) method. I f th e re d u cin g -b a la n ce m e th o d is used, th e a llo w a b le d e p re c ia tio n ra te is g e n e ra lly tw ic e th e s tra ig h t-lin e ra te .3 The d e p re c ia tio n charge c a lc u la te d f o r ta x p u rp o se s m a y b e a r n o re la tio n s h ip to t h a t ca lcu la te d f o r fin a n c ia l r e p o rtin g p u rp o s e s . F o r exa m ple, a co m p a n y m a y use th e s tra ig h t-lin e m e th o d f o r re p o rtin g p u rpo ses a n d th e re d u c in g -b a la n c e m e th o d f o r in c o m e ta x p u rp o se s. S tra ig h t-lin e d e p re c ia tio n in v o lv e s a llo c a tin g th e asse ts co st in e q u a l a m o u n ts o v e r its e s tim a te d u s e fu l life . T h a t is, g iv e n th e a sse ts in it ia l cost, C, a n d its e s tim a te d u s e fu l life o f n years, th e s tra ig h t-lin e d e p re c ia tio n charge in each ye a r o f th e assets life is C /n .4SF o r e xa m p le , i f an asset costs $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 a n d has a 1 0 -y e a r life , th e a n n u a l d e p re c ia tio n charge is $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 / 1 0 = $ 1 0 0 0 0. 2 3 4 As discussed in Section 14.3, under the imputation system that exists in Australia, a company's effective tax rate may be less than the statutory tax rate and in most cases it is appropriate for the effective tax rate to be used. For eligible assets purchased after 10 May 2006, the allowable depreciation rate using the reducing-balance method is twice the straight-line rate. For assets purchased prior to that date, the allowable depreciation rate using the reducingbalance method is 1.5 times the straight-line rate. Taxpayers have at times been able to claim an investment allowance that is essentially an additional depreciation deduction—for example, as part of its economic stimulus package announced in 2009, the Australian Government permitted small businesses to claim a one-off additional 50 per cent tax deduction on the purchase of eligible new assets or the improvement of eligible existing assets. Assets that qualified for the allowance were basically those that could be depreciated for tax purposes. This contrasts with the method of calculating depreciation for financial reporting purposes. In accounting, the straight-line depreciation charge is: (C -S )/n where C = initial cost S = estimated residual value or scrap value n = estimated useful life in years B usiness finance Example 6.4 Table 6.2 shows the calculation of the present value of the tax effects associated with depreciation and disposal of an asset that costs $100000, has an estimated useful life of 5 years and a disposal value of $7776 at the end of the fifth year. The company income tax rate is 30 per cent and the after-tax discount rate is 10 per cent per annum. Table 6.2 shows that the reducing-balance method should be preferred because it results in a higher present value of tax savings and net sale proceeds. TABLE 6.2 Tax effects of depreciation and sale of an asset - I Depreciation method -------------------------------------------------------------------- ------------------------------Straight lin e ^ — Reducing balance⑹ ($) Present value of tax savinqs and proceeds of sale, net of tax ($) 40000 12 000 10909 4959 24000 7200 5 950 6000 4508 14400 4320 3 246 20000 6000 4098 8640 2592 1770 20000 6000 3 726 5184 1555 966 End of year Present value factor 1 0.90909 20000 6000 5454 2 0.82645 20000 6000 3 0.75131 20000 4 0 .6 8 3 0 1 5 0.62092 Disposal Allowable Tax depreciation savings^ expense ($)' ($) Present value of tax savings and proceeds Allowable of sale, net depreciation of tax ($) expense ($) Tax savings — 7 7 7 6 (b ) — 4828 7776 — 4828 — 7776 — — 0 — — — — (2332) (1448) — — 一 26124 一 value G ain on sale Tax on 0 0 gain T o ta l _ 一 27669 (a) Straight-line depreciation is charged at a rate of 20 per cent of acquisition cost, and reducing-balance depreciation is charged at a rate of 40 per cent of the written-down value. (b) It is assumed that at the end of Year 5 the asset is sold for $7776. Under the reducing-balance method of depreciation, this is equal to the written-down value at the end of Year 5 and there is no gain or loss on sale. Consequently, there is no tax effect on the $7776. The present value of the cash inflow is calculated in the usual way and equals $7776 x (0.620 92) = $4828. Under the straight-line method of depreciation, as the whole of the asset's acquisition cost has been written off for tax purposes by the end of Year 5, the $7776 received at that time is regarded as a gain on sale for tax purposes, and increases tax payable by $2332. The present value of this tax payment is $ 1448. (c) Tax savings are equal to allowable depreciation expenses x 0.30. C hapter six T he In c o n tra s t, re d u c in g -b a la n c e d e p re c ia tio n in v o lv e s c h a rg in g a fix e d amount) percentage application of project evaluation methods (ra th e r th a n a fix e d o f th e asse ts w r itte n - d o w n (o r a d ju s ta b le ) v a lu e in each year. The a sse ts w r itte n - d o w n value is equal to its cost o r o th e r v a lu e (such as a re v a lu e d a m o u n t) less a c c u m u la te d d e p re c ia tio n , w h e re a ccu m u la te d d e p re c ia tio n is eq u a l to th e s u m o f th e d e p re c ia tio n charges in p re v io u s years. In c o m p a ris o n w ith s tra ig h t-lin e d e p re c ia tio n , th e re d u cin g -b a la n ce m e th o d o f d e p re c ia tio n re s u lts in la rg e r d e p re c ia tio n charges in th e e a rly years o f a n a s s e ts life a n d s m a lle r charges in la te r years. T h ere fore, co m p a re d w ith th e s tra ig h t-lin e m e th o d , re d u c in g -b a la n c e d e p re c ia tio n re s u lts in lo w e r taxes a n d h ig h e r a fte r-ta x cash flo w s in th e e a rly years. The t o t a l in c o m e ta x p a id is n o t re d u ce d b y u s in g th e re d u cin g -b a la n ce m e th o d . H ow ever, a p o r tio n o f th e ta x payable is p o s tp o n e d in th e e a rly years o f th e p ro je c ts life . G ive n t h a t a d o lla r to d a y is w o r th m o re th a n a d o lla r in a y e a rs tim e , i t fo llo w s t h a t th e use o f th e re d u cin g -b a la n ce m e th o d is g e n e ra lly a d va n ta g e o u s to an asset’s ow ne r. The a fte r-ta x cash flo w s a sso cia te d w it h o w n e rs h ip o f a d e p re cia b le asset also d e p e n d o n th e re la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n th e a s s e ts d isp o sa l v a lu e a n d its w r itte n - d o w n value. I f th e d isp o sa l va lu e is eq ua l to th e w r itte n - d o w n va lu e , th e n sale o f th e asset has n o e ffe c t o n ta x p a id b y th e seller. H o w e ve r, i f th e tw o values d iffe r, th e re are tw o p o s s ib ilitie s : a The asse ts d isp o sa l v a lu e is less th a n it s w r itte n - d o w n value Suppose t h a t an asset is s o ld f o r $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 b u t its w r itte n - d o w n va lu e is $ 2 5 0 00 0. The d iffe re n c e o f $ 1 5 0 0 0 0 is reg ard ed as a loss o n sale, w h ic h is ta x d e d u c tib le . I f t c = 0 .3 0 , th e ta x sa vin g o n th e loss o f $ 1 5 0 0 0 0 is $ 1 5 0 0 0 0 x 0 .3 0 = $ 4 5 0 0 0. T his ta x s a vin g is tre a te d as a cash in flo w , so th e n e t a fte r ­ ta x proceeds are $ 1 4 5 0 0 0. The asset s d is p o s a l va lu e is m o re th a n its w r itte n - d o w n value b Suppose t h a t an asset is s o ld f o r $ 3 0 0 00 0, w h ic h is $ 5 0 0 0 0 m o re th a n its w r itte n - d o w n va lu e . In th is case th e g a in o n sale o f $ 5 0 0 0 0 is re g ard ed as re c o v e ry o f d e p re c ia tio n d e d u c tio n s t h a t w ere p re v io u s ly cla im e d . T h e re fo re , th e g a in is ta xa b le b u t th e ta x m a y be d e fe rre d b y d e d u c tin g th e g a in fro m th e w r itte n - d o w n v a lu e o f a re p la c e m e n t asset o r o th e r de p re cia b le assets.5 I f th e g a in is ta xe d im m e d ia te ly , th e n e t sale pro cee ds are $ 3 0 0 0 0 0 - $ 5 0 0 0 0 x 0 .3 0 = $ 2 8 5 0 0 0 . The ta x e ffe cts o f th e s tra ig h t-lin e a n d re d u cin g -b a la n ce m e th o d s are co m p a re d in E xa m p le 6.4. 6 .3 .2 1 Illustration of cash-flow information in project evaluation with taxes E a rlie r in th is c h a p te r w e co n s id e re d th e c a s h -flo w in fo r m a tio n t h a t s h o u ld be c o m p ile d f o r p ro je c t e va lu a tio n . E xam p le 6.5 illu s tra te s h o w taxes s h o u ld be in c o rp o ra te d in to th e c o m p ila tio n o f cash flo w s. E xample 6.5 The C la r e n d o n C o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g th e in tr o d u c tio n o f a n e w p r o d u c t. G e n e r a lly , th e c o m p a n y 's p ro d u c ts h a v e a life o f a b o u t 5 y e a rs , a fte r w h ic h th e y a r e d e le te d fro m th e ra n g e o f p ro d u c ts th a t th e c o m p a n y sells. T he n e w p r o d u c t r e q u ire s th e p u rc h a s e o f n e w e q u ip m e n t c o s tin g $ 6 0 0 0 0 0 , in c lu d in g f r e ig h t a n d in s ta lla tio n c h a rg e s . T h e u s e fu l life o f th e e q u ip m e n t is 5 y e a rs , w ith a n e s tim a te d r e s id u a l v a lu e o f $ 2 3 6 5 0 0 a t th e e n d o f th a t p e r io d . T h e e q u ip m e n t w ill b e d e p r e c ia te d fo r ta x p u rp o s e s b y th e r e d u c in g - b a la n c e m e th o d a t a ra te o f 2 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . T he n e w p r o d u c t w ill b e m a n u fa c tu re d in a f a c t o r y a lr e a d y o w n e d b y th e c o m p a n y . T h e f a c t o r y o r ig in a lly c o s t $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 to b u ild a n d h a s a c u rre n t re s a le v a lu e o f $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 , w h ic h s h o u ld re m a in f a ir ly s ta b le o v e r th e n e x t 5 y e a rs . T h is f a c t o r y is c u rre n tly b e in g re n te d to a n o th e r c o m p a n y u n d e r a le a s e a g r e e m e n t th a t h a s 5 y e a r s to ru n a n d p r o v id e s f o r a n a n n u a l re n ta l o f $ 2 0 0 0 0 . U n d e r th e continued 5 Replacement decisions are discussed in Section 6.5.2. continued le a s e a g r e e m e n t th e C la r e n d o n C o m p a n y c a n c a n c e l th e le a s e b y p a y in g th e le sse e c o m p e n s a tio n e q u a l to 1 y e a r 's re n ta l p a y m e n t. T h is a m o u n t is n o t d e d u c tib le fo r in c o m e ta x p u rp o s e s . It is e x p e c te d th a t th e p r o d u c t w ill in v o lv e th e c o m p a n y in s a le s p r o m o tio n e x p e n d itu re s , w h ic h w ill a m o u n t to $ 6 0 0 0 0 d u r in g th e firs t y e a r th e p r o d u c t is o n th e m a rk e t. T h is a m o u n t is d e d u c tib le fo r in c o m e ta x p u rp o s e s in th e y e a r in w h ic h th e e x p e n d itu re is in c u rre d . A d d it io n s to c u rre n t a sse ts w ill re q u ire $ 3 2 0 0 0 a t th e c o m m e n c e m e n t o f th e p r o je c t a n d a re a s s u m e d to b e fu lly r e c o v e r a b le a t th e e n d o f th e fifth y e a r. T he n e w p r o d u c t is e x p e c te d to g e n e r a te n e t o p e r a tin g c a s h flo w s (b e fo re d e p r e c ia t io n a n d in c o m e ta x ) a s fo llo w s : • Y e a r 1: $ 3 0 0 0 0 0 • Year 2: $ 3 7 5 0 0 0 • Year 3: $ 4 9 0 0 0 0 • Year 4: $ 4 5 0 0 0 0 • Year 5 : $ 2 2 5 0 0 0 It is a s s u m e d th a t a ll c a s h flo w s a r e re c e iv e d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r a n d th a t in c o m e t a x is p a id a t th e e n d o f th e y e a r in w h ic h th e in flo w o c c u rre d . T h e c o m p a n y in c o m e t a x ra te is 3 0 c e n ts in th e d o lla r . T h e c o m p a n y h a s a r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn o f 1 0 p e r c e n t a fte r ta x . T h e s o lu tio n to th is e x a m p le is se t o u t in T a b le 6 . 3 . SOLUTION TABLE 6 . 3 C a s h - flo w in f o r m a tio n f o r th e e v a lu a tio n o f th e p u r c h a s e o f n e w e q u ip m e n t After-tax cash flows Item Year 0 1. I n itia l o u tla y 2. D e p re c ia tio n Year Year 1 Year 2 ; Year 3 j Year 4 Year 5 (600000) Writtendown value ($) Depreciation 1 600000 20 120000 36000 — 36000 — — — — 2 480000 20 96000 28800 — — 28800 — — — 3 384000 20 76800 23040 — — — 23 040 — — 4 307200 20 61440 18432 — — — — 18432 — 5 245 760 20 49152 14746 — — — — — 14746 ( %) ( $ ) Tax savings at 30c in $ 3. S ale o f e q u ip m e n t Sale $236500 W ritten-down value $196608 Gain on sale $39892 Tax on gain at 30% $11968 Total proceeds $236500 -$ 1 1 9 6 8 — — — — — 224532 C hapter six T he T able 6 .3 application of project evaluation methods continued 4. Factory — — — — — The cost and th e c u rre n t resale value o f the fa c to ry are b o th irre le v a n t a. Cancel lease b. N e t cash flo w forgone due to re n t (2 0 0 0 0 ) forgone $20000 ( 1 -0 .3 0 ) 5. — (1 4 0 0 0 ) (1 4 0 0 0 ) (1 4 0 0 0 ) (1 4 0 0 0 ) (1 4 0 0 0 ) — (4 2 0 0 0 ) (32 000) — — _ — 32000 Market research outlays O u tla y $60000 Less n e t ta x savings a t 30% $18000 $42000 6. Addition to current assets ______ ______________________________ 7. Net cash flows from operations after deducting company income tax Year 1: $ 3 0 0 0 0 0 (1 - 0 .3 0 ) — 210000 — — — — Year 2: $ 3 7 5 0 0 0 (1 - 0 .3 0 ) — — 262500 — — — Year 3: $ 4 9 0 0 0 0 (1 - 0.30) — — — 343000 — — Year 4: $ 4 5 0 0 0 0 (1 - 0 .3 0 ) — — — — 315000 — Year 5: $ 2 2 5 0 0 0 (1 - 0 .3 0 ) — — — — — 157500 -6 5 2 0 0 0 190000 277300 352040 319432 414778 0.90909 0.82645 0.75131 0.68301 0.62092 218176 257544 Total D iscoun t fa c to r a t 10% Present value o f n e t cash flow s 1.0000 -6 5 2 000 172727 229173 264493 N et present value = $ 4 9 0 1 1 4 O n th e b a s is o f th is q u a n tita tiv e a n a ly s is , th e n e w p r o d u c t s h o u ld b e m a n u fa c tu re d . 6.4 C om paring mutually exclusive projects that have different lives In C h a p te r 5 w e c o m p a re d m u t u a lly e xclu sive p ro je c ts t h a t h a d th e sam e life . In p ra c tic e , m a n a g e m e n t w ill fr e q u e n tly have to c o m p a re m u tu a lly e x c lu s iv e p ro je c ts t h a t ha ve d iffe re n t e c o n o m ic liv e s . Such p ro je c ts w i ll o fte n in v o lv e e q u ip m e n t t h a t is o f d iffe re n t q u a lity a n d th e re fo re also o f d iff e r e n t cost. Suppose t h a t a coffee sh o p can b u y e ith e r a T it a n co ffe e m a k e r w it h a life o f 3 yea rs o r th e h ig h e r q u a lity , m o re e xp e n sive , V u lc a n co ffe e m a k e r w it h a lif e o f 5 yea rs to p e r fo r m th e sam e jo b . B o th coffee m a ke rs ge n e ra te th e sam e cash in flo w s , so one w a y to co m p a re th e m w o u ld be to c a lc u la te th e p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e cash o u tflo w s f o r each o f th e m . S uppose t h a t th e p re s e n t v a lu e o f cash o u tflo w s is $ 4 0 0 0 f o r th e T ita n a n d $ 5 0 0 0 f o r th e V u lc a n . T h is does n o t n e c e s s a rily m e a n t h a t th e T it a n s h o u ld be p re fe rre d . I f th e T it a n is p u rc h a s e d , i t w i ll have to be re p la c e d 2 years e a rlie r th a n th e V u lc a n . The a lte rn a tiv e s are n o t d ir e c tly c o m p a ra b le because th e d iffe re n c e in liv e s m e a n s t h a t th e y in v o lv e d iffe re n t f u tu r e cash flo w s , w h ic h have n o t b e e n co n s id e re d . O n e s o lu tio n w o u ld be to assum e t h a t th e V u lc a n is s o ld a fte r 3 years. H o w e v e r, th e d is p o s a l v a lu e m a y n o t re fle c t it s v a lu e in use, a n d i t is u s u a l LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Compare mutually exclusive projects that have different lives B usiness finance to m a ke o th e r a s s u m p tio n s a b o u t w h a t w i ll h a p p e n a t th e e n d o f th e u s e fu l liv e s o f th e e q u ip m e n t. CONSTANT CHAIN C o n s id e r th e fo llo w in g tw o ap pro ache s: OF REPLACEMENT ASSUMPTION may be used to evaluate mutually exclusive projects of unequal lives; in this case, each project is assumed to be replaced at the end of its economic life by an identical project a I t m a y be assum ed t h a t th e co m p a n y w ill re in v e s t in a p ro je c t t h a t is id e n tic a l to t h a t w h ic h is b S pe cific a s s u m p tio n s m a y be m ade a b o u t th e re in v e s tm e n t o p p o r tu n itie s t h a t w ill be com e ava ila ble c u r r e n tly b e in g a n alysed. T his is k n o w n as th e con stan t chain o f replacem ent assum ption, in th e fu tu re . The second ap p ro a ch is th e m o re re a lis tic a n d c o u ld be im p le m e n te d w h e re th e fu tu r e in v e s tm e n t o p p o r tu n itie s are k n o w n . H o w e ve r, in p ra c tic e th is a p p ro a ch is d iff ic u lt to im p le m e n t unless m anagers have co n sid e ra b le fo re s ig h t. T h ere fore, th e f ir s t a p p ro a ch is o fte n used. T his a p p ro a ch is illu s tra te d in E xa m p le 6.6. E xample 6 .6 A s s u m e th a t a c o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g th e p u rc h a s e o f t w o d iffe r e n t p ie c e s o f e q u ip m e n t, A a n d B, th a t w i ll p e rfo rm th e s a m e ta s k a n d g e n e r a te th e s a m e c a s h in flo w s . T h e re fo re , A a n d B c a n b e c o m p a r e d o n th e b a s is o f th e ir c a s h o u tflo w s . T he in fo r m a tio n in T a b le 6 . 4 re la te s to A a n d B. TABLE 6.4 Cash outflows for equipment In itia l a n d o p e r a tin g costs ($ ) E q u ip m e n t Year 0 Year 1 A (life 1 year) 15 000 6000 B (life 3 years) 20000 10000 Year 2 Year 3 10000 10000 A s s u m in g a r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn o f 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m f o r b o th p ie c e s o f e q u ip m e n t, c a lc u la te th e p re s e n t v a lu e s o f th e costs o f A a n d B. SOLUTION T he p re s e n t v a lu e s o f th e co sts o f A a n d B a r e a s fo llo w s : PV of costs for A = $ 15 000 + $ 6 〇〇〇 1.1 = $ 20 45 5 PV of costs for B = $20 000 + $ 10 000 n . i) 3 0.1 =$ 44 869 If m a n a g e m e n t c o m p a re s th e se fig u re s , th e n in v e s tm e n t in E q u ip m e n t A w o u ld a p p e a r to b e m o re d e s ir a b le . H o w e v e r, th is c o m p a r is o n is in v a lid b e c a u s e it ig n o re s th e fa c t th a t A a n d B h a v e d iffe re n t live s. To m a k e a v a lid c o m p a r is o n it is a s s u m e d th a t a t th e e n d o f b o th th e firs t a n d th e s e c o n d y e a rs E q u ip m e n t A w o u ld b e p u rc h a s e d a g a in . If E q u ip m e n t A w e r e r e p la c e d a t th e e n d o f Y e a rs 1 a n d 2 w ith th e s a m e e q u ip m e n t (a c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t), th e co sts w o u ld b e as s h o w n in T a b le 6 . 5 . TABLE 6.5 Costs for chain of replacement over 3i years In itia l a n d o p e r a tin g costs ($) E q u ip m e n t Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 A 15 000 15000 15 000 6000 6000 6000 21000 21000 6000 A T otal 15 000 Year 3 C hapter SIX T he APPLICATION 〇F PROJECT EVALUATION METHODS In th is c a s e , DV/ , ‘ f A ⑴ 識 $21000 $21000 for A = $ 15 0 0 0 + ------------- + ----------- PVof costs 1.1 ( l.l) 2 $6000 ( l. l) 3 = $ 5 5 954 B a s e d o n th is c o m p a r is o n o v e r 3 y e a rs , th e p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e co sts f o r A ( $ 5 5 9 5 4 ) is g r e a te r th a n th e p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e co sts f o r B ( $ 4 4 8 6 9 ) a n d , th e re fo re , B s h o u ld b e p u rc h a s e d . In th e re m a in d e r o f th is s e c tio n i t is assum ed t h a t m a n a g e m e n t a d o p ts th is a p p ro a ch a n d t h a t each p ro je c t is re p lic a te d o v e r th e years. A v a lid c o m p a ris o n o f tw o cha in s o f re p la c e m e n t can be m ade o n ly w h e n b o th cha in s are o f e q u a l le n g th . T his c o m p a ris o n can be ach ie ved in tw o ways: a S uppose t h a t P ro je c t A has a life o f 6 years a n d P ro je c t B has a life o f 9 years. I f A is u n d e rta k e n th re e tim e s a n d B tw ic e , th e re p la c e m e n t c h a in s w i ll be o f eq ua l le n g th — t h a t is, 18 years. In th is exam ple, 18 is th e lo w e s t c o m m o n m u ltip le o f 6 a n d 9, so th is a p p ro a ch is u s u a lly called th e common multiple method. A lth o u g h lowest th e use o f th is m e th o d c o rre c tly ra n k s m u tu a lly e xclusive p ro je c ts w ith d iffe re n t live s, i t can be cu m b e rso m e . F o r e xa m p le , tw o p ro je c ts w ith liv e s o f 1 9 a n d 21 years, resp ective ly, have a lo w e s t c o m m o n m u ltip le o f 3 9 9 years a n d th e cash flo w s f o r each o f these 3 9 9 years w o u ld have to be d is c o u n te d to a p re s e n t value, b A less c o m p le x a p p ro a c h , w h ic h ra n k s p ro je c ts id e n tic a lly to th e lo w e s t c o m m o n m u ltip le m e th o d , is to assum e t h a t b o t h c h a in s c o n tin u e in d e fin ite ly . In t h is case th e ‘le n g th s ’ o f th e c h a in s are ^ q u a r in th e sense t h a t th e y are b o th in fin it e . T his m e th o d is k n o w n as th e constant chain of replacement in perpetuity method. I f th e N P V o f each re p la c e m e n t p ro je c t is N d o lla rs a n d th e life o f each p ro je c t is n yea rs, th e n th e c o n s ta n t c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t is e q u iv a le n t to re c e iv in g a cash in flo w o f N d o lla rs a t tim e s 0, n, 2rz, 377, a n d so o n , fo re v e r. T h e re fo re , th e N P V o f th e c h a in c o n sists o f N d o lla rs a t t im e 0 p lu s a p e r p e tu ity o f N d o lla rs pa yab le a t n, 2n, 3n, a n d so on. T h ere fore: N NPV = N + N (1 + k )n (1 + k) 1 N (1 + 2n 1 k)n (1 + k)2n 1 N 1 ( l + k )n j . k)n + k)n- l (1 + N (1 The n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e in fin it e ch a in , N P V ^ , is th e re fo re : 層 一 6.4 。 w h e re N P V 〇 = n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f each re p la ce m e n t. A v a r ia n t o f t h is m e th o d is th e equivalent annual value m ethod. th e q u e s tio n : W h a t a m o u n t, to be re ce ive d each y e a r f o r p re s e n t v a lu e o f a p ro je c t w h o s e life is value (E A V ), n years? n yea rs, T his m e th o d in v o lv e s a n s w e rin g is e q u iv a le n t to re c e iv in g th e n e t T his a m o u n t, w h ic h is k n o w n as th e equivalent annual is c a lc u la te d f o r each p ro je c t. The p ro je c t w it h th e h ig h e r E A V is p re fe rre d to th e p ro je c t w it h th e lo w e r EAV, p ro v id e d t h a t b o th p ro je c ts have th e sam e r is k , a n d th e re fo re th e sam e re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn . The s tre a m o f EAVs o v e r a n n u ity is g iv e n by: n years is an o rd in a ry a n n u ity a n d th e re fo re th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e EQUIVALENT A N N U A L VALUE METHOD involves calculating the annual cash flow of an annuity that has the same life as the project and whose present value equals the net present value of the project or: (1 + k )n NPV = EAV 〇 k T herefore: NPV 〇 EAV = (1 W 7 k The re la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n th e c o n s ta n t c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t a n d E A V m e th o d s is s tra ig h tfo rw a rd . A ssu m e t h a t a p ro je c t is re p lic a te d in d e fin ite ly . The p re s e n t v a lu e o f an in f in it e s tre a m o f EAVs is: EAV PV-- k NPV 〇 (1 + k )n 1 ■NPV 〇 1 (1 w NPVq (1 + k )u (1 + k )r NPVoo T h a t is, th e p re s e n t v a lu e o f an in fin it e s tre a m o f EAVs is e q u a l to th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e c o n s ta n t c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t in p e rp e tu ity . T h e re fo re , i f th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e in fin it e c h a in c a lcu la te d , th e n th e E AV can be fo u n d b y m u ltip ly in g NPV^ b y NPV^ has been th e re q u ire d ra te o f r e t u r n — t h a t is, th e E A V is g iv e n by: 6.6 EAV=kNPV(X The c o n s ta n t c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t a n d e q u iv a le n t a n n u a l va lu e m e th o d s are illu s tr a te d in E xa m p le 6.7. Example 6.7 S u p p o s e th a t tw o a sse ts, A a n d B, a r e m u tu a lly e x c lu s iv e p ro je c ts a n d h a v e th e c h a r a c te r is tic s s h o w n in T a b le 6 . 6 . TABLE 6.6 Characteristics of two mutually exclusive projects C a sh in flo w s ($ ) A sset Life ( Y r s ) , In itia l cash Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 o u tla y ($ ) A 3 10000 10000 23000 25 000 — — B 5 30000 12000 15000 25 000 30000 30000 It is a ls o a s s u m e d th a t th e r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m fo r b o th p ro je c ts . W h ic h a s s e t s h o u ld b e p u rc h a s e d ? C hapter SIX T he APPLICATION OF PROJECT EVALUATION METHODS SOLUTION The n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f A s s e t A a t tim e z e r o is: N PVAo = -$ 1 0 0 0 0 . ^ 00 + 1.1 + $25000 ( l. l) 2 ( l.l) 3 = $ 3 6 8 8 2 .0 4 T he n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f A s s e t B a t tim e z e r o is: md' / d NPVBr, = $12000 $15000 $25000 $30000 $30000 -$30000 + ----------+ -------- + ------------------------- — + ------- 广 1.1 ( i . i )2 ( i . i )3 ( i . i )4 ( i . i )5 =$51 206.70 U s in g E q u a tio n 6 . 4 , th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e s o f th e in fin ite c h a in s o f re p la c e m e n t a re : NPVAX = ($36 882.04) (1^ — =$148 308.14 N P V B 〇c = ($51 2 0 6 .7 0 )-^ — ' =$135081.98 T h e re fo re , A s s e t A s h o u ld b e a c c e p te d , n o tw ith s ta n d in g th a t its n e t p re s e n t v a lu e (o v e r its 3 -y e a r life ) is less th a n th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f A s s e t B (o v e r its 5 - y e a r life ). U s in g E q u a tio n 6 . 5 , th e e q u iv a le n t a n n u a l v a lu e m e th o d , it is fo u n d th a t: $36 882.04 EAVA = " '1 1 (1 H -0 .1 0 )3 0.10 $14830.81 $51 206.70 EAVb T T T Z Z r ^ r (1 + 0 . 1 0 ) 5 a io $13508.20 T h e re fo re , A s s e t A s h o u ld b e c h o s e n b e c a u s e its E A V is g r e a te r th a n th a t o f A s s e t B. A lte r n a tiv e ly , th e e q u iv a le n t a n n u a l v a lu e s c o u ld h a v e b e e n c a lc u la te d fro m th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e s o f th e in fin ite c h a in s o f r e p la c e m e n t ( N P V ^ ) u s in g E q u a tio n 6 . 6 , E AV = fc N P V ^ a s fo llo w s : EAVA= (0.1)($148 308.14 =$14830.81 EAVB= (0.1)($135081.98 =$13508.20 T hese resu lts a r e id e n tic a l to th o s e o b ta in e d u s in g E q u a tio n 6 . 5 . In s u m m a ry , th e resu lts fo r A s s e t A s h o w th a t a n in v e s to r w o u ld b e in d iffe r e n t b e tw e e n re c e iv in g p a y m e n ts o f $ 3 6 8 8 2 . 0 4 e v e r y 3 y e a rs , o r a s in g le p a y m e n t o f $ 1 4 8 3 0 8 . 1 4 p a y m e n ts o f $ 1 4 8 3 0 . 8 1 fo re v e r. T h e c o r r e s p o n d in g a m o u n ts fo r A s s e t B a r e $ 5 1 2 0 6 . 7 0 e v e ry 5 y e a rs , $ 1 3 5 0 8 1 . 9 8 now , or annual n o w , o r $ 1 3 5 0 8 . 2 0 a n n u a lly f o r e v e r . 〇f th e se th re e p a ir s o f fig u re s , th e s e c o n d a n d th ird p a ir s a d ju s t f o r th e u n e q u a l live s o f th e a sse ts, a n d b o th s h o w th a t A s s e t A s h o u ld b e p re fe rre d . B usiness finance E xa m p le 6 .8 p ro v id e s a m o re d e ta ile d illu s t r a t io n o f th e c o n s ta n t c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t m e th o d . E xample 6 .8 A s s u m e t h a t M a d is o n C o m p a n y , w h ic h o p e ra te s a fle e t o f tru c k s , is c o n s id e r in g r e p la c in g th e m w ith a n e w m o d e l. T h e d a t a in T a b le 6 . 7 a r e a v a ila b le f o r th e o ld a n d th e n e w tru c k s . TABLE 6.7 Data for old and new trucks Item O ld tru cks N e w tru c k s 1. N e t cash flow s $45 000 p.a. $ 5 0 0 0 0 p.a. 2. E s tim a te d life 2 years 4 years 3. D isposal value: (a) at pre se n t $10000 (b) in 4 years, tim e N il $10000 4. Cost o f new tru cks $60000 5. R equired rate o f re tu rn (real) 10% p.a. 10% p.a. M a n a g e m e n t is c o n s id e r in g tw o p r o p o s a ls : a) R e p la c e th e o ld tru c k s n o w a n d a s s u m e th a t th e n e w tru c k s a r e o p e r a te d f o r 4 y e a r s a n d r e p la c e d in p e rp e tu ity . b) R e p la c e th e o ld tru c k s in 2 y e a r s ' tim e a n d a s s u m e th a t th e n e w tru c k s a r e o p e r a te d f o r 4 y e a rs a n d r e p la c e d in p e rp e tu ity . W h ic h o f th e se p r o p o s a ls s h o u ld m a n a g e m e n t a c c e p t? SOLUTION O b v io u s ly th e re a r e o th e r a lte r n a tiv e s th a t m a n a g e m e n t c o u ld c o n s id e r, su ch a s r e p la c in g th e p re s e n t tru c k s in 1 y e a r ’s tim e o r r e p la c in g th e o ld tru c k s n o w a n d th e n e w o n e s in 2 y e a r s ' tim e . H o w e v e r, it is a s s u m e d th a t th e se p o s s ib ilitie s h a v e b e e n c o n s id e r e d a n d r e je c te d b y m a n a g e m e n t. It is a ls o a s s u m e d th a t th e re a r e n o e x p e c te d im p ro v e m e n ts in tru c k d e s ig n th a t w o u ld m a k e th e n e w tru c k o b s o le te . P ro p o s a ls (a) a n d (b) w ill th e re fo r e b e e v a lu a te d a s s u m in g a c o n s ta n t c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t. T he p r o p o s a l w ith th e la r g e r n e t p re s e n t v a lu e , p r o v id e d th a t it is g r e a te r th a n z e r o , w ill b e a c c e p te d , o th e r th in g s b e in g e q u a l. In th e f o llo w in g e v a lu a tio n th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e f o r a s in g le tru c k is c a lc u la te d . If th e re a r e 1 0 tru c k s in th e fle e t, th e n th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e s o f th e t w o p r o p o s a ls w ill b e m u ltip lie d b y 1 0 to f in d th e ir to ta l n e t p re s e n t v a lu e s . a) R e p la c e th e o ld tru c k s n o w , o p e r a te th e n e w tru c k s f o r 4 y e a r s a n d r e p la c e th e m in p e rp e tu ity . T h e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f a n e w tru c k is: NPV0 = - $ 6 0 0 0 0 + $50000 (1 + 0 . 1 0 ) 4 0.10 $10000 ( i.i) 4 = - $ 6 0 0 0 0 + $ 1 5 8 4 9 3 .2 7 + $6 8 3 0 .1 3 = $ 1 0 5 3 2 3 .4 0 T h e p re s e n t v a lu e o f a n in fin ite c h a in o f th e s e tru c k s is th e re fo re : NPV 〇 〇 = ($ 1 0 5 3 2 3 .4 0 ) = $ 3 3 2 265 O ' 1/ C hapter s ix T he application of project evaluation methods In a d d itio n , a t th e s ta rt o f th is c h a in M a d is o n C o m p a n y re c e iv e s a c a s h in flo w o f $ 1 0 0 0 0 fro m th e d is p o s a l o f th e o ld tru c k . T h e re fo re , th e total n e t p re s e n t v a lu e is: $332265 + $10000 = $342265 b) R e p la c e th e o ld tru c k s in 2 y e a r s ' tim e , o p e r a te th e n e w tru c k s f o r 4 y e a rs , a n d r e p la c e th e m in p e rp e tu ity . A s in th e p re v io u s c a lc u la tio n , N P V 00= $ 3 3 2 2 6 5 . H o w e v e r, th e firs t o f th e c h a in o f n e w tru c k s is n o w p u rc h a s e d a t Y e a r 2 in s te a d o f a t Y e a r 0 a s p re v io u s ly . A s a re su lt, NPV 〇 〇m u st b e d is c o u n te d to Y e a r 0 : $332 265 (I.” 2 =$274 599.17 In a d d itio n , M a d is o n C o m p a n y o b ta in s th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f o p e r a tin g th e o ld tru c k s f o r th e firs t 2 y e a rs . T h is is g iv e n b y : $45 000 $45 000 i. i ( i.i) 2 =$78 099.17 The total n e t p re s e n t v a lu e is th e re fo re : $ 2 7 4 5 9 9 .1 7 + $ 7 8 0 9 9 .1 7 = $ 3 5 2 6 9 8 .3 4 T he n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f P ro p o s a l (b) is g r e a te r th a n th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f P ro p o s a l (a) a n d m a n a g e m e n t s h o u ld r e p la c e th e o ld tru c k s in 2 y e a r s 7 tim e . Chain of replacement methods and inflation C h a in o f re p la c e m e n t m e th o d s re ly o n th e a s s u m p tio n t h a t each p ro je c t w ill, a t th e e n d o f its life , be replaced b y an id e n tic a l p ro je c t— t h a t is, each re p la c e m e n t w i ll c o st th e sam e a m o u n t, g e n e ra te th e sam e cash flo w s , a n d la s t f o r th e sam e tim e . C learly, i f th e re is in fla tio n , fu tu r e costs a n d cash flo w s w ill n o t be exp ected to re m a in th e sam e in n o m in a l te rm s , b u t th e y m a y re m a in th e sam e in re a l te rm s . To e n sure t h a t in fla t io n is tre a te d c o n s is te n tly , a ll cash flo w s a n d th e re q u ire d ra te o f r e t u r n s h o u ld g e n e ra lly be expressed in re a l te rm s w h e n a c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t m e th o d is use d .6 Is the chain of replacement method realistic? A possible p ro b le m w ith th e c o n s ta n t c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t m o d e l is t h a t i t em p lo ys u n re a lis tic a s s u m p tio n s a b o u t th e re p la c e m e n t assets in th e ch a in , n a m e ly th a t th e assets a n d th e services th e y p ro v id e are id e n tic a l in e ve ry respect. These a s s u m p tio n s are u n re a lis tic . H o w eve r, th e fa c t t h a t th e re p la ce m e n ts m ay be m a n y years in th e fu tu re , a n d th e fa c t t h a t t h e ir cash flo w s w ill be d is c o u n te d to a p re s e n t value, reduces th e im p a c t o f m a k in g such u n re a lis tic a s s u m p tio n s . I t m a y be even m o re u n re a lis tic to assum e th a t m a n a g e m e n t has s u ffic ie n t fo re s ig h t to be able to p re d ic t such fa c to rs as th e c a p ita l o u tla y, n e t cash flo w s , life a n d re s id u a l value o f re p la ce m e n t assets. H o w eve r, i f such in fo r m a tio n is available, i t is n o t a d iffic u lt m a tte r to in s e rt in to th e a n alysis th e re p la c e m e n t o f an e x is tin g asset w it h an asset o f im p ro v e d d e sig n .7 The m e th o d s discussed in th is se ctio n are v e ry u s e fu l b u t som e p o in ts s h o u ld be n o te d . F irs t, i t is n o t necessary to use the se m e th o d s in a ll cases w h e re p ro je c ts have d iffe re n t lives. F o r in d e p e n d e n t p ro je c ts , th e n e t p re se n t value m e th o d a u to m a tic a lly a llo w s f o r a n y such diffe re nce s. The d iffe re n t lives p ro b le m , arises o n ly f o r m u tu a lly e xclusive p ro je cts. Second, i t is p a rtic u la rly im p o r ta n t, w h e n u s in g c h a in o f re p la ce m e n t m e th o d s, to be c o n s is te n t in th e tre a tm e n t o f in fla tio n . T h ird , in m a n y cases m u tu a lly exclusive p ro je c ts w ill in v o lv e th e same b e n e fits (cash in flo w s ) b u t d iffe re n t costs (cash o u tflo w s ). In these cases th e cash in flo w s can be ig n o re d a nd th e a lte rn a tiv e s can be co m p a re d o n th e basis o f th e ir cash o u tflo w s , as in E xam p le 6.3. 6 7 For a discussion of this issue and presentation of a nominal version of the constant chain of replacement model, see Faff and Brailsford (1992). Brown and Davis (1998) highlight the real options that are ignored in using the constant chain of replacement model. For a discussion of real options, see Chapters 5 and 18. B usiness finance continued SOLUTION If th e m a c h in e is p u rc h a s e d , u s e d fo r o n ly 1 y e a r a n d th e n s o ld , its n e t p re s e n t v a lu e w o u ld b e as fo llo w s : 吟 -$ 2 〇 o〇 〇+ $I ^ 2 1 + i l ^ 1.1 1.1 = $ 5 455 If th e m a c h in e is u se d f o r 2 y e a rs a n d th e n s o ld , th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e w o u ld b e a s fo llo w s : NPV2 = - $ 2 0 0 0 0 + $12000 $11500 $14000 i.i ( i . i )2 ( i . i r $11 983 S im ila rly , n e t p re s e n t v a lu e s c a n b e c a lc u la te d b a s e d o n use f o r 3 , 4 a n d 5 y e a r s . H o w e v e r , th e se n e t p re s e n t v a lu e s c a n n o t b e c o m p a r e d , b e c a u s e th e y a r e b a s e d o n d iffe r e n t liv e s . A s w e n o te d in S e c tio n 6 . 4 , th is d iff ic u lt y c a n b e o v e r c o m e b y a s s u m in g a c o n s ta n t c h a in o f r e p la c e m e n t. If it is a s s u m e d th a t th e m a c h in e is r e p la c e d e v e r y y e a r in p e rp e tu ity , th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e w ill b e a s fo llo w s : NPV(1,〇〇 ) = $5 4 5 4 .5 5 (1 1 ) ( l- l) - l =$60000 If th e m a c h in e is r e p la c e d e v e r y s e c o n d y e a r in p e rp e tu ity , th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e w ill b e a s fo llo w s : NPV(2/X)) = $ 1 1 9 8 3 .4 7 ,2 ( i.ir = $69048 T h e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e s , a s s u m in g th a t th e m a c h in e is r e p la c e d in p e rp e tu ity , a t th e e n d o f th e th ir d , fo u rth a n d fifth y e a rs , re s p e c tiv e ly , a r e a s fo llo w s : NPV[3, ) = $ 1 7 6 9 3 .4 6 (1 .1 ) 3 〇〇 = $ 7 1 148 NPV 〇 〇 ) = (1 -1 )4 ' $ 1 9 9 4 7 -41 = $ 6 2 92 6 NPV(5o〇) = $22 0 5 8 .5 4 (1 .1 ) 5 = $ 5 8 190 T h e se resu lts s h o w th a t th e m a c h in e s h o u ld b e r e p la c e d a fte r 3 y e a rs . In g e n e r a l th e d e c is io n ru le is to c h o o s e th e re p la c e m e n t fr e q u e n c y th a t m a x im is e s th e p r o je c t's n e t p re s e n t v a lu e f o r a p e rp e tu a l c h a in o f r e p la c e m e n t, o r th a t m a x im is e s its e q u iv a le n t a n n u a l v a lu e . Non-identical replacement Suppose t h a t a m a c h in e is p h y s ic a lly s o u n d b u t te c h n ic a lly ob solete. W h e n th e m a c h in e is replaced, its re p la c e m e n t w ill be o f a n e w d e sig n t h a t m a y have th e sam e ca p a c ity b u t costs less to op era te . The q u e s tio n is: W h e n s h o u ld th e o ld m a c h in e be d isca rd e d in fa v o u r o f th e n e w one? The s o lu tio n in v o lv e s tw o steps. F irs t, th e o p tim u m re p la c e m e n t fre q u e n c y f o r th e n e w m a c h in e is d e te rm in e d u s in g th e m e th o d illu s tra te d in E xa m p le 6.1 0. Second, th e e q u iv a le n t a n n u a l va lu e o f th e n e w m a c h in e a t it s o p tim u m re p la c e m e n t fre q u e n c y is c o m p a re d w it h th e n e t p re s e n t va lu e o f c o n tin u in g to o p e ra te th e o ld m a ch in e , C hapter s ix T he application of project evaluation methods as s h o w n in E xam p le 6.9. The d e c is io n ru le is t h a t th e cha n g e o ve r s h o u ld be m ade w h e n th e n e t p re s e n t value o f c o n tin u in g to o p e ra te th e o ld m a c h in e f o r one m o re y e a r is less th a n th e e q u iv a le n t a n n u a l v alue o f th e n e w m a ch in e . 6.6 Analysing project risk The e ffe c t o f r is k o n th e v a lu e o f a p ro je c t is n o r m a lly in c lu d e d in th e e v a lu a tio n b y u s in g a re q u ire d ra te o f re tu r n t h a t re fle c ts th e r is k o f th e p ro je c t. H o w e ve r, th e c a lc u la te d n e t p re s e n t v a lu e is o n ly an e s tim a te th a t relies o n foreca sts o f th e p ro je c ts cash flo w s . In p ra c tic e the se fo re ca sts w ill, a lm o s t c e rta in ly , t u r n o u t to be in c o rre c t, p e rh a p s because th e v o lu m e o f sales tu r n s o u t to be m o re o r less th a n expected, th e p ric e o f th e p ro d u c t is h ig h e r o r lo w e r th a n expected, o r o p e ra tin g costs d iffe r fr o m th e fo re ca st. Therefore, in m a n y cases m a n a g e rs a n a ly s in g p ro p o s e d p ro je c ts w ill ne ed to a n sw e r q u e s tio n s such as: • W h a t are th e k e y v a ria b le s t h a t are lik e ly to d e te rm in e w h e th e r th e p ro je c t is a success o r a fa ilu re ? • H o w fa r can sales fa ll o r costs increase b e fo re th e p ro je c t loses m on ey? LEARNING OBJECTIVE 5 Explain how sensitivity analysis, break­ even analysis and simulation assist in analysing project risk M an ag ers can use v a rio u s te c h n iq u e s to a n s w e r the se a n d o th e r re la te d q u e s tio n s . The te c h n iq u e s we discuss are s e n s itiv ity an alysis, bre a k-e ve n a n a lysis a n d s im u la tio n . 6 .6 .1 1 Sensitivity analysis A p ro je c ts cash flo w s a n d re q u ire d ra te o f r e tu r n are u s u a lly s p e c ifie d as cb e s t e stim a te s* o r exp ected values1 an d th e re s u ltin g n e t p re s e n t value , o fte n re fe rre d to as th e best e s tim a te o r e xp e cte d va lu e . Sensitivity an alysis base-case net present value, is also a in v o lv e s assessing th e e ffe c t o f changes o r e rro rs SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS in th e e s tim a te d v a ria b le s o n th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f a p ro je c t. T his is a ch ie ved b y c a lc u la tin g n e t p re s e n t analysis of the effect of changing one or more input variables to observe the effects on the results values based o n a lte rn a tiv e e s tim a te s o f th e va ria b le s. F o r in sta n ce , m a n a g e m e n t m a y w is h to k n o w th e e ffe ct o n n e t p re s e n t va lu e i f a p ro je c ts n e t cash flo w s are e ith e r 20 p e r c e n t less th a n , o r 20 p e r ce n t g re a te r th a n , th o se e s tim a te d . K n o w le d g e o f th e s e n s itiv ity o f n e t p re s e n t va lu e to changes o r e rro rs in th e va ria b le s places m a n a g e m e n t in a b e tte r p o s itio n to decide w h e th e r a p ro je c t is to o r is k y to accept. A lso , i f m a n a g e m e n t k n o w s t h a t th e n e t p re s e n t va lu e is s e n s itiv e to changes in p a r tic u la r v a ria b le s , i t can e xa m in e th e e stim a te s o f the se v a ria b le s m o re th o ro u g h ly , o r c o lle c t m o re d a ta in an e f f o r t to reduce e rro rs in fo re ca stin g . A s s u m in g t h a t a ll v a ria b le s in th e a n a lysis are u n c e rta in , a s im p le e xa m p le o f s e n s itiv ity a n alysis in vo lve s th e fo llo w in g steps: a P essim istic, o p tim is tic a n d e xp ected e s tim a te s are m ad e f o r each v a ria b le . b N e t p re s e n t va lu e is ca lcu la te d u s in g th e e xp ected e s tim a te s f o r e v e ry v a ria b le exce pt one, th e value fo r w h ic h is, in t u r n , its o p tim is tic a n d p e s s im is tic e s tim a te . This p ro c e d u re is re p e a te d u n t il a n e t p re s e n t va lu e has been ca lcu la te d u s in g an o p tim is tic a n d p e s s im is tic e s tim a te f o r each v a ria b le , in c o m b in a tio n w it h th e e xp ected values o f th e o th e r v a ria b le s. C The d iffe re n c e b e tw e e n th e o p tim is tic a n d p e s s im is tic n e t p re s e n t values is ca lcu la te d f o r each va ria b le . A s m a ll d iffe re n c e b e tw e e n th e n e t p re s e n t value s suggests t h a t th e p ro je c ts n e t p re s e n t value is in s e n s itiv e to changes o r e rro rs in t h a t v a ria b le . A la rg e d iffe re n c e b e tw e e n th e n e t p re s e n t values suggests th e o p p o s ite . F o r exa m ple, suppose t h a t in a p ro je c t in v o lv in g th e use o f a n e w m a c h in e , th e re are o n ly fiv e u n c e rta in variab les: sales p rice , v a ria b le cost, sales v o lu m e , fix e d o p e ra tin g costs a n d th e life o f th e m a c h in e . In th is case, e ig h t n e t p re s e n t v a lu e c a lc u la tio n s are m ade, u s in g th e d a ta in p u ts s h o w n in T able 6 .1 0 . The s y m b o l O in d ic a te s th e o p tim is tic v a lu e o f th e v a ria b le , P in d ic a te s th e p e s s im is tic va lu e o f th e v a ria b le , a n d E in d ic a te s th e e xp ected va lu e o f th e v a ria b le . The a p p lic a tio n o f s e n s itiv ity a n a lysis to p ro je c t e v a lu a tio n in a case such as t h a t s h o w n in Table 6.1 0 is illu s tra te d in E xam p le 6.1 1. The use o f s e n s itiv ity a n a lysis in v o lv e s som e p ro b le m s . O ne is t h a t fr e q u e n tly i t is d iff ic u lt to sp e cify p re c is e ly th e re la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n a p a r tic u la r v a ria b le a n d n e t p re s e n t value . I f th e assum ed re la tio n s h ip is based o n p a s t o u tco m e s, th e re is alw ays th e p o s s ib ility t h a t th is re la tio n s h ip m a y n o t h o ld in th e fu tu re . I t is f u r t h e r c o m p lic a te d b y re la tio n s h ip s b e tw e e n th e v a ria b le s . F o r e xa m p le , i t is TABLE 6.10 Combinations of variable values for sensitivity analysis Estim ates (i) Sales price 0 P E E E Variable cost E E 〇 P Sales vo lu m e E E E Fixed o p e ra tin g E E E E (v ii) (v iii) (ix ) (x) E E E E E E E E E E E E 〇 P E E E E E E E E 〇 P E E E E E E E E 〇 P (iii) N (v) M costs M ach in e life E xample 6.11 A s s u m e th a t a m a n a g e r is c o n s id e r in g w h e th e r to p u rc h a s e a n e w m a c h in e th a t c o sts $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 . It is a s s u m e d th a t th e re a r e o n ly fiv e u n c e rta in v a r ia b le s : sa le s p r ic e , v a r ia b le c o s t, s a le s v o lu m e , fix e d o p e r a tin g co sts a n d th e life o f th e n e w m a c h in e . T he sa le s p r ic e is e x p e c te d to b e $ 7 0 p e r u n it, th e v a r ia b le c o s t is e x p e c te d to b e $ 4 8 p e r u n it, s a le s v o lu m e is e x p e c te d to b e 1 5 0 0 0 u n its p e r a n n u m , w ith fix e d o p e r a tin g co sts o f $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 d u r in g a n e x p e c te d life o f 1 0 y e a rs . A ll o th e r v a r ia b le s a re e x p e c te d to re m a in c o n s ta n t d u r in g th e m a c h in e 's life . T h e r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r annum . T he e x p e c te d a n n u a l n e t c a s h flo w s a r e ( $ 7 0 - $ 4 8 ) x 1 5 0 0 0 - $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 = $ 1 3 0 0 0 0 , a n d th e b a s e -c a s e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e is: Base-case N P V = -$500 000 + $ 130 000 — 1 J 0.1 =$298 794 T he in fo r m a tio n n e e d e d f o r th e s e n s itiv ity a n a ly s is is s h o w n in T a b le 6 .1 1, w h ic h p re s e n ts : • f o r e a c h u n c e rta in v a r ia b le , e x p e c te d (c o lu m n 1), o p tim is tic (c o lu m n 2 ) a n d p e s s im is tic (c o lu m n 3 ) e s tim a te s • th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e (c o lu m n 4 ) w h e n o n e o f th e u n c e rta in v a r ia b le s is set a t its o p tim is tic e s tim a te • th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e (c o lu m n 5 ) w h e n o n e o f th e u n c e rta in v a r ia b le s is se t a t its p e s s im is tic e s tim a te a n d e a c h o f th e o th e r v a r ia b le s is set a t its e x p e c te d v a lu e a n d e a c h o f th e o th e r v a r ia b le s is set a t its e x p e c te d v a lu e • in c o lu m n 6, th e d iffe re n c e b e tw e e n c o lu m n s 4 a n d 5, w h ic h is fr e q u e n tly c a lle d th e 'r a n g e o f th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e ’ . T a b le 6 .1 1 s h o w s th a t th e e s tim a te o f n e t p re s e n t v a lu e is m o re s e n s itiv e to c h a n g e s in s a le s p ric e th a n to c h a n g e s in th e o th e r u n c e rta in v a r ia b le s . In a d d it io n , it s h o w s th a t if th e p e s s im is tic e s tim a te o f e ith e r s a le s p r ic e o r s a le s v o lu m e o c c u rs , th e p u rc h a s e o f th e m a c h in e w i ll g e n e r a te a n e g a tiv e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e . B e fo re d e c id in g to p u rc h a s e th e n e w m a c h in e , m a n a g e m e n t is th e re fo re lik e ly to g a th e r m o re in fo r m a tio n o n s a le s p r ic e a n d s a le s v o lu m e in a n e ffo r t to m in im is e fo r e c a s tin g e rro rs . In c o n tra s t, th e v a lu e o f a d d itio n a l d a ta a b o u t th e m a c h in e 's v a r ia b le co sts, fix e d o p e r a tin g c o sts a n d u s e fu l life is r e la tiv e ly s m a ll. T he p r o je c t is still a c c e p ta b le , b a s e d o n th e p e s s im is tic v a lu e s f o r th o s e v a r ia b le s , a n d th e re fo re th e c o m p a n y is u n lik e ly to m a k e a lo ss o n th e p r o je c t e v e n if th e s e v a r ia b le s h a v e b e e n in c o r r e c tly e s tim a te d . C hapter six T he application of project evaluation methods TABLE 6.11 Sensitivity analysis of the purchase of a new machine, based on optimistic and pessimistic estimates of the values of each variable V a r ia b le E x p e cte d O p tim is tic P essim istic ⑴ ⑵ (31 NPV: NPV: o p tim is tic p e s s im is tic e s tim a te ($1 ⑹ e s tim a te . (4) ($)⑹ R ange o f N P V ($ ) (5 ) —1 6 T Sales price $ 70 76 63 (i) 8 5 1 8 0 5 (ii) 3 4 6 3 8 6 1198191 Variable 48 46 50 (iii) 4 8 3 1 3 1 (iv) 1 1 4 4 5 7 368674 15 000 17000 12500 (v) 5 6 9 1 5 5 (vi) 3 9 1 5 7 608312 200000 190000 205000 (v ii) 3 6 0 2 3 9 (v iii) 2 6 8 0 7 1 92169 10 12 9 (ix) 385 780 (x) 248 673 137107 cost $ Sales volum e Fixed operating costs $ Life o f machine (years) The figures in lower case Roman numerals in these columns indicate the net present value calculation that corresponds to the input shown in Table 6.10. in a p p ro p ria te to e xa m in e th e e ffe c t o n n e t p re s e n t va lu e o f a 20 p e r c e n t re d u c tio n in sales v o lu m e w ith o u t re c o g n is in g t h a t lo w e r sales v o lu m e m a y also m e a n t h a t th e s e llin g p ric e is lo w e r th a n expected. A llo w in g f o r these in te rd e p e n d e n c ie s w i ll c o m p lic a te th e an alysis. A n o th e r p ro b le m is t h a t th e te rm s ‘o p tim is tic ’ a n d ‘p e s s im is tic ’ are su b je c t to in te r p r e ta tio n , a n d th e re s u lts m a y be s o m e w h a t a m b ig u o u s. F o r exa m ple, th e m a rk e tin g d e p a rtm e n t’s ‘o p t im is t ic ’ sales fo re ca sts m a y be so o p tim is tic t h a t th e y are v ir t u a lly u n a ch ie va b le , w h ile a n o th e r d e p a rtm e n ts o p t im is t ic , e s tim a te s o f o th e r v a ria b le s m a y be m o re co n se rva tive . 6 .6 .2 1 Break-even analysis B r e a k - e v e n a n a ly s is is a f o r m o f s e n s itiv ity an alysis. S e n s itiv ity a n a lysis g e n e ra lly in v o lv e s fin d in g BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS answ ers to *w ha t if* q u e s tio n s such as: W h a t w ill be th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e p ro je c t i f sales are 10 p e r analysis of the amounts by which one or more input variables may change before a project ceases to be profitable cen t less th a n expected? In b re a k-e ve n a n alysis th e q u e s tio n is tu r n e d a ro u n d , in t h a t th e m a n a g e r asks: H o w p o o r can sales v o lu m e be co m e b e fo re th e p ro je c t loses m o n e y? The b re a k-e ve n p o in t is th e sales v o lu m e a t w h ic h th e n e t p re s e n t va lu e is zero. B reak-even a n a lysis is illu s tra te d in th e fo llo w in g e xa m ple b y re -e x a m in in g th e in fo r m a t io n in E xa m p le 6.11. Example 6.12 F or e a c h o f th e fiv e u n c e rta in v a r ia b le s , th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e is c a lc u la te d u s in g th e e x p e c te d v a lu e s o f th e o th e r fo u r v a r ia b le s , w ith th e v a lu e s o f th e fifth v a r ia b le b e in g th e o n e th a t re su lts in th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e b e in g z e ro . T h e resu lts f o r a ll v a r ia b le s a r e s h o w n in T a b le 6 .1 2 w ith th e resu lts f o r s a le s v o lu m e a ls o b e in g s h o w n in F ig u re 6 . 1 . T he n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f p u r c h a s in g th e m a c h in e w ill b e p o s itiv e if th e e x p e c te d v a lu e s o f th e o th e r fo u r u n c e rta in v a r ia b le s a r e a c h ie v e d a n d th e s a le s p r ic e is g r e a te r th a n o r e q u a l to $ 6 7 . S im ila rly , th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f p u r c h a s in g th e m a c h in e w ill b e p o s itiv e if th e e x p e c te d v a lu e s o f th e o th e r fo u r u n c e rta in v a r ia b le s a r e a c h ie v e d a n d s a le s v o lu m e is 1 2 7 9 0 o r m o re un its. continued B usiness finance continued TABLE 6.12 Breat:-even analysis of the purchase of a new rnachine Variable Expected Break even Sales p rice $ 70 67 V ariable cost $ 48 51 15000 12 790 Fixed o p e ra tin g costs $ 200000 248627 Life o f m achine (years) 10 6 Sales volum e 6 .6 .3 1 Simulation S e n s itiv ity a n alysis in v o lv e s c h a n g in g one v a ria b le a t a tim e a n d e x a m in in g th e e ffe cts o f th e changes SIMULATION analysis of the effect of changing all of the input variables whose values are uncertain to observe the effects on the results 夺 o n th e p r o f it a b ilit y o f a p ro je c t. O n th e o th e r h a n d , sim ulation a llo w s a m a n a g e r to c o n s id e r th e effects o f c h a n g in g a ll th e v a ria b le s w h ose values are u n c e rta in . The f ir s t ste p in a s im u la tio n is to id e n tify th e re le v a n t v a ria b le s a n d to s p e c ify th e p ro b a b ility d is tr ib u tio n o f each v a ria b le . F o r e xa m p le , in th e case o f th e pu rcha se o f th e n e w m a c h in e in E xam p le s 6 .1 1 a n d 6 .1 2 , th e v a ria b le s c o u ld in c lu d e s e llin g p rice , v a ria b le cost, sales v o lu m e , fix e d o p e ra tin g costs a n d th e u s e fu l life o f th e m a ch in e . The second step is to s p e c ify a n y re la tio n s h ip s b e tw e e n th e va ria b le s. F o r exa m ple, a h ig h e r sales v o lu m e m a y re s u lt in C hapter s ix T he application of project evaluation methods econom ies o f scale in p r o d u c tio n a n d d is tr ib u tio n , w h ic h s h o u ld be re fle c te d in th e v a ria b le costs. The t h ir d step in v o lv e s u s in g a c o m p u te r to s im u la te th e p ro je c t s cash flo w s . E sse n tia lly, th e p ro c e d u re is as fo llo w s: a b The c o m p u te r selects value s ra n d o m ly fr o m th e d is tr ib u tio n o f each o f th e sp e cifie d v a ria b le s, In th e f ir s t ru n o f th e s im u la tio n th e c o m p u te r calcula tes values f o r th e p ro je c ts cash flo w s f o r each year. C The re s u lts o f th e f ir s t r u n are s to re d a n d a n e w s e t o f values is cho sen a n d used in th e seco nd ru n o f th e s im u la tio n , w h ic h gives f u r t h e r re su lts t h a t are also sto re d . T his p ro c e d u re is re p e a te d a t le a s t one h u n d re d an d p e rh a p s th o u s a n d s o f tim e s . d The re s u lts o f a ll th e in d iv id u a l ru n s are c o m b in e d to p ro d u ce a p r o b a b ility d is tr ib u tio n f o r th e p ro je c ts cash flo w s. S im u la tio n is a p o te n tia lly va lu a b le to o l t h a t a llo w s m an ag ers to analyse m a n y aspects o f th e ris k s associated w it h a p ro je c t. I t is g e n e ra lly used fo r la rge p ro je c ts w h e re th e size o f th e in v e s tm e n t can ju s t if y th e cost o f d e v e lo p in g th e s im u la tio n m o d e l. W h ile s p e c ify in g th e m o d e l can be tim e c o n s u m in g , once i t has been d e ve lo p e d i t is re la tiv e ly easy to e xa m in e th e e ffe cts o f c h a n g in g th e p r o b a b ility d is tr ib u tio n f o r one o r m o re va ria b le s. H o w e ve r, users o f th e te c h n iq u e s h o u ld rea lise it s lim ita tio n s . These in c lu d e th e fo llo w in g : • S im u la tio n is a te c h n iq u e f o r p ro ce ssin g in fo r m a tio n a n d p re s e n tin g th e re s u lts o f t h a t p ro ce ssin g in a p a rtic u la r way. T h e re fo re , th e re s u lts o f a s im u la tio n c a n n o t be a n y m o re re lia b le th a n th e in p u t d a ta a n d th e m o d e l t h a t spe cifie s th e re la tio n s h ip s b e tw e e n v a ria b le s. P ro v id in g re a lis tic e s tim a te s o f th e p ro b a b ility d is tr ib u tio n s f o r th e v a ria b le s a n d o f th e re la tio n s h ip s b e tw e e n th e v a ria b le s can be v e ry d iffic u lt. • S im u la tio n re s u lts can be d iff ic u lt to in te r p r e t. The o u t p u t fr o m th e s im u la tio n co n sists o f a p ro b a b ility d is tr ib u tio n f o r th e p ro je c ts cash flo w s f o r each ye a r o f its life . H o w s h o u ld a m a n a g e r use th is data? The o b v io u s f ir s t ste p is to use th e m e a n o r e xp e cte d fo re c a s t cash flo w s f o r each y ea r to e s tim a te th e p ro je c ts n e t p re s e n t v alue . The n e x t ste p m ig h t be to use o th e r p o ssib le v alue s fo r th e cash flo w s to calcula te a d is tr ib u tio n o f n e t p re s e n t values. Suppose t h a t the se steps are c a rrie d o u t a n d th e re s u lts s h o w t h a t th e e xp ected n e t p re s e n t va lu e o f a p ro je c t is $2 m illio n , b u t th e re is a 20 p e r c e n t p ro b a b ility t h a t th e a c tu a l n e t p re s e n t v a lu e w ill be n e g a tive . D iffe r e n t in d iv id u a ls are lik e ly to have d iffe re n t o p in io n s a b o u t w h e th e r th e p ro je c t s h o u ld be accepted— t h a t is, s im u la tio n does n o t p ro v id e an u n a m b ig u o u s a c c e p t/re je c t sig n a l f o r p ro je c ts . • S im u la tio n focuses o n th e to t a l r is k o f a p ro je c t a n d ig n o re s th e p o s s ib ility t h a t m u c h o f th is ris k m ig h t be re m o v e d b y d iv e rs ific a tio n . As discussed in S e ctio n 7.5, i t is th e s y s te m a tic o r n o n d iv e rs ifia b le r is k o f a p ro je c t t h a t is im p o r t a n t in d e te rm in in g its re q u ire d ra te o f r e tu rn . In s u m m a ry, s im u la tio n is a p o te n tia lly va lu a b le te c h n iq u e f o r a n a ly s in g th e ris k s a sso cia te d w ith a p ro je c t, b u t users s h o u ld be aw are o f it s lim ita tio n s . 6.7 Decision-tree analysis M a n a g e m e n t is s o m e tim e s faced w it h th e ne ed to e va lu a te a lte rn a tiv e s in v o lv in g a sequence o f d e cisio n s ove r tim e . D e c is io n -tre e a n a lysis p ro v id e s a m eans o f e v a lu a tin g such d e cisio ns. The d e c is io n -tre e a p pro ach takes in to a c c o u n t th e p ro b a b ility o f v a rio u s e ve n ts o c c u rrin g a n d th e e ffe c t o f th o s e eve nts o n th e expected n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f a p ro je c t. D e c is io n -tre e a n a lysis uses th e c o n c e p t o f ‘ro ll-b a c k ’ to eva lu ate a lte rn a tiv e d e cisio n s. T his is illu s tra te d in E xa m p le 6 .1 3 .8 This ap p ro a ch to e v a lu a tin g a sequence o f d e cisio n s re la tin g to an in v e s tm e n t in a r is k y p ro je c t is o p e ra tio n a l f o r o u r s im p le exa m p le . I t has th e ad van ta ge t h a t i t forces m a n a g e m e n t to c o n s id e r fu tu re in v e s tm e n t d e cisio n s w h e n m a k in g c u rre n t in v e s tm e n t de cisio n s. H o w e ve r, th e c o m p le x ity o f d e c is io n tre e analysis is in crea sed c o n s id e ra b ly since a d d itio n a l a lte rn a tiv e s , such as a llo w in g f o r a m e d iu m -s iz e d p la n t a n d a m e d iu m le vel o f d e m a n d , are in c lu d e d in th e d e c is io n process. 8 For a simple discussion of decision-tree analysis, see Levin, Kirkpatrick and Rubin (1992). m LEARNING OBJECTIVE 6 Use decision-tree analysis to analyse sequential decisions B usiness finance Example 6.13 T he m a n a g e m e n t o f a V ic to r ia n - b a s e d c o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g th e p r o p o s e d c o n s tru c tio n o f a p la n t to m a n u fa c tu r e its p ro d u c ts in C h in a . In itia lly , m a n a g e m e n t is fa c e d w ith th e c h o ic e o f c o n s tru c tin g e ith e r a la r g e o r a s m a ll p la n t. If it c o n s tru c ts a la r g e p la n t, th e in itia l o u tla y w ill b e $ 2 m illio n , w h e r e a s if it c o n s tru c ts a s m a ll p la n t, th e in it ia l o u tla y w ill b e $1 m illio n . If a s m a ll p la n t is c h o s e n , m a n a g e m e n t w ill r e c o n s id e r its d e c is io n a fte r 2 y e a rs . A t th a t tim e , m a n a g e m e n t m a y , if it b e lie v e s th a t fu rth e r e x p a n s io n is w a r r a n t e d , e x p a n d th e s m a ll p la n t to a c h ie v e th e s a m e c a p a c ity a s a la r g e p la n t. The e x p a n s io n w ill c o s t $ 1 . 2 5 m illio n . T he c o m p a n y h a s e s tim a te d th e e x p e c te d n e t c a s h flo w s to b e g e n e r a te d b y a la r g e p la n t, a s m a ll p la n t a n d a n e x p a n d e d p la n t o n th e b a s is o f a tw o - w a y c la s s ific a tio n o f d e m a n d : h ig h d e m a n d a n d lo w d e m a n d . T h e se e x p e c ta tio n s a r e s u m m a ris e d in T a b le 6 . 1 3 . TABLE 6.13 Expected net cash flows for different plants and levels of demand P o s s ib ilitie s E x p e c te d n e t c a sh f lo w p .a . ($ m ) Large p la n t, h ig h dem and 0.8000 Large p la n t, lo w dem and 0.1000 Sm all p la n t, h ig h dem and 0.4000 Sm all p la n t, lo w dem and 0.3500 Expanded p la n t, h ig h dem and 0.5000 Expanded p la n t, lo w dem and 0.0750 M a n a g e m e n t h a s a ls o e s tim a te d th e p r o b a b ilit y o f a c h ie v in g e ith e r h ig h d e m a n d o r lo w d e m a n d d u r in g th e p r o je c t's 1 0 - y e a r life . It h a s e s tim a te d th e lik e lih o o d o f h ig h d e m a n d t h r o u g h o u t th e p ro je c t's life to b e 0 . 6 , th e p r o b a b ilit y o f a c h ie v in g h ig h d e m a n d f o r th e firs t 2 y e a rs a n d lo w d e m a n d fo r th e re m a in in g 8 y e a rs to b e 0 . 2 , a n d th e p r o b a b ilit y o f lo w d e m a n d th r o u g h o u t th e p ro je c t's life to b e 0 . 2 . T he p r o b a b ilit ie s a n d th e e x p e c te d n e t c a s h flo w s a r e s h o w n in F ig u re 6 . 2 in th e fo rm o f a decision tree. T he s q u a re s in F ig u re 6 . 2 re p re s e n t d e c is io n p o in ts a n d th e s m a ll c irc le s re p re s e n t c h a n c e e v e n ts th a t m a y o c c u r d u r in g th e life o f th e p r o je c t. T he b a s e o f a d e c is io n tre e is th e b e g in n in g , D e c is io n p o in t 1. Its b ra n c h e s b e g in a t th e firs t c h a n c e e v e n t. E a ch c h a n c e e v e n t p r o d u c e s tw o o r m o re p o s s ib le o u tc o m e s , s o m e o f w h ic h le a d to o th e r c h a n c e e v e n ts a n d / o r s u b s e q u e n t d e c is io n p o in ts . T h e o p tim u m s e q u e n c e o f d e c is io n s is d e te r m in e d u s in g a ro llb a ck p r o c e d u r e , w h ic h m e a n s th a t th e m o s t d is ta n t d e c is io n — in th is c a s e , th e d e c is io n w h e th e r to e x p a n d th e s m a ll p la n t — is e v a lu a te d firs t. E a c h a lte r n a tiv e is e v a lu a te d o n th e b a s is o f its e x p e c te d n e t p re s e n t v a lu e . T h e r e q u ir e d ra te o f re tu rn is a s s u m e d to b e 9 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . Decision 2: Whether to expand the small plant EXPAND: r, N P V = 0 .7 5 [$0 .5 m ) 1 i (1+0.0918 0.09 [1 + 0.25($0.075m) 1 1 (1+0 .0 9)8 - $ 1.25m 0.09 =$929355 D O N O T EXPAND: 「 NPV= 0.75 ($0.4m) $2 144 743 1- 1 1 [1 (1 +0.09)8 + 0.25($0.035m) 0.09 1 1 |1 +0.09)8 0.09 C hapter s ix T he Demand level Expected cash flo w P robability - Years 0 -2 Demand level P rob ab ility — application of project evaluation methods Expected cash flo w Years 3 - 1 0 0 . 7 5 --------- $0.8rr 0.8 $0.8m 0 .25 ---------- $0.1n 0.2 $0.1 r 0.8 1.0 $0.1 m 0.75 $0.5m 0.25 $0.075m 0.75 $0.4m 0.25 $0.35m 1.0 $0.35m $0.4m Small plant ($lm) 0.2 $0.35rr T h e re fo re , th e o p tim u m c h o ic e is n o t to e x p a n d th e s m a ll p la n t a t th e e n d o f th e s e c o n d y e a r. T he r o llb a c k m e th o d s im p lifie s th e e v a lu a tio n b y e lim in a tin g th e a lte r n a tiv e o f b u ild in g a s m a ll p la n t a n d th e n e x p a n d in g it a fte r 2 y e a rs . O n c e m a n a g e m e n t k n o w s w h a t it o u g h t to d o if fa c e d w ith th e e x p a n s io n d e c is io n , it c a n 'r o ll b a c k 7 to t o d a y 's d e c is io n . T h is d e c is io n is w h e th e r to b u ild a la r g e p la n t o r a s m a ll p la n t to b e o p e r a te d f o r 1 0 y e a rs . Decision 1: Construct either a large plant or a small plant and operate for 10 years LAR G E PLANT: ( 1 + 0 .0 9 〆 Expected NPV = 0 .8 ($0 .8 m ) 0 .0 9 ■ 0 .8 [0 .7 5 ($ 0 .8 m ) (1 + 0 . 0 9 广 (1 .0 9 ) -2 0 .0 9 -0 .2 5 ($ 0 .1 m ) (1 + 0 . 0 9 广 (1 .0 9 )-2] 0 .0 9 1 -0 .2 0 ($ 0 .1 m ) (1 + 0 . 0 9 ) 10 - $2m 0 .0 9 $ 1 5 8 3 0 0 0 (to the nearest thousand dollars) continued B usiness finance continued S M A L L PLA N T: Expected NPV = 0 .8 ($0 .4 m ) (1 + 0 . 0 9 卜 0 .0 9 + 0 .0 8 [$ 2 1 4 4 743 (1 .0 9 )-2 ] 1 •0 .2 ($ 0 .3 5 m ) (1 + O .Q 9 )10 ■$lr 0 .0 9 = $ 1 4 5 6 0 0 0 (to the nearest thousand dollars) In th is c a s e th e e x p e c te d n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f b u ild in g a la r g e p la n t e x c e e d s th a t o f b u ild in g a s m a ll p la n t. 6.8 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 7 Explain the role of qualitative factors in project selection Q ualitative factors and the selection of projects A f te r th e q u a n tita tiv e a n alysis has been co m p le te d , m a n a g e m e n t has to decide w h ic h p ro je c ts to im p le m e n t. W h ile th e a im is to m a x im is e s h a re h o ld e rs , w e a lth , i t does n o t ne ce ssa rily f o llo w t h a t p ro je c t s e le c tio n d e cisio n s s h o u ld be g u id e d o n ly b y th e re s u lts o f th e q u a n tita tiv e an alysis. M a n a g e m e n t s h o u ld also c o n s id e r a n y q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs t h a t m a y a ffe c t th o s e p ro je c ts . E s s e n tia lly , q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs are th o se t h a t m a n a g e m e n t w o u ld lik e to in c lu d e in th e q u a n tita tiv e an alysis b u t is u n a b le to in c lu d e because th e y are d iffic u lt, i f n o t im p o s s ib le , to m ea sure in d o lla rs . F o r th is rea son th e y are assessed separately, a fte r th e q u a n tita tiv e a n a lysis o f th e a lte rn a tiv e s has been co m p le te d . Q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs m a y p la y a v it a l ro le in p ro je c t se le ctio n . F o r e xa m p le , suppose t h a t q u a n tita tiv e a n a lysis sho w s t h a t i t is che ap er f o r a tr a n s p o r t c o m p a n y to c o n tin u e u s in g som e o ld tru c k s f o r a n o th e r ye a r ra th e r th a n re p la c in g th e m no w . H o w e ve r, m a n a g e m e n t m a y decide to replace th e o ld tru c k s n o w because o f q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs such as th e de sire to m a in ta in a m o d e rn im a ge f o r th e c o m p a n y a n d th e im p ro v e d s a tis fa c tio n , a n d c o n s e q u e n tly th e im p ro v e d p ro d u c tiv ity , o f th e d riv e rs re s u ltin g fr o m th e c o m fo rt o f th e n e w tru c k s . Som e f u r t h e r exa m ples o f q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs t h a t m a y a ffe c t m a n a g e m e n ts d e cisio n s a b o u t p ro je c ts are: • The in tr o d u c tio n o f la b o u r-s a v in g m a c h in e ry m a y be d e fe rre d (p e rh a p s in d e fin ite ly ) because o f u n io n o p p o s itio n , even th o u g h o n th e basis o f th e q u a n tita tiv e a n a lysis th e p ro p o s a l to in tro d u c e th e m a c h in e ry has a n e t p re s e n t v a lu e g re a te r th a n zero. • T w o m u tu a lly e xclu sive in v e s tm e n ts m a y have n e t p re s e n t values t h a t are a lm o s t eq ua l, b u t one re q u ire s m u c h m o re m a n a g e m e n t s u p e rv is io n , o r th e use o f som e o th e r scarce h u m a n resource. The use o f th is scarce reso urce in v o lv e s an o p p o r tu n ity cost th a t, w h ile re co g n ise d b y m a n a g e m e n t, is d iff ic u lt to q u a n tify . T h e re fo re , ra th e r th a n a tte m p tin g to m ea sure th e o p p o r tu n it y co st o f u s in g th e scarce h u m a n resources, m a n a g e m e n t m a y s im p ly select th e p ro p o s a l t h a t i t b e lie ve s w ill use fe w e r o f th o s e resources, o th e r th in g s b e in g equal. I t is e s s e n tia l t h a t such q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs be c o n sid e re d b e fo re s e le c tin g a p ro je c t. H o w eve r, th e re c o g n itio n o f q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs is n o t a g e n e ra l p re s c rip tio n f o r ig n o r in g o r re d u c in g th e im p o rta n c e o f th e q u a n tita tiv e a n a lysis. As a ll fa c to rs c a n n o t be in c o rp o ra te d in to th e q u a n tita tiv e an alysis, a c o m p a ris o n o f a lte rn a tiv e in v e s tm e n t p ro p o s a ls is in c o m p le te w ith o u t an asse ssm en t o f th e po ssib le e ffe cts o f th e q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs . Ind e e d , th e in flu e n c e o f q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs m a y be s u ffic ie n tly im p o r ta n t to cause m a n a g e m e n t to select p ro p o sa ls w ith lo w e r c a lc u la te d n e t p re s e n t values. C hapter SIX T he APPLICATION 〇F PROJECT EVALUATION METHODS 6.9 Project selection with resource constraints So fa r i t has been a ssu m ed t h a t m a n a g e m e n t is w illin g a n d able to accept a ll in d e p e n d e n t in v e s tm e n t p ro je c ts th a t have a n e t p re s e n t v a lu e g re a te r th a n zero an d, i f m u tu a lly e xclusive p ro je c ts are b e in g com pared, th o se p ro je c ts w it h th e h ig h e s t p o s itiv e n e t p re s e n t value. H o w e ve r, so m e tim e s a c o m p a n y s LEARNING OBJECTIVE 8 Explain the effects of resource constraints on project selection m anagers be lie ve t h a t th e y are p re v e n te d fr o m u n d e rta k in g a ll acceptable p ro je c ts because o f a sho rta ge * o f fu n d s . C apital ration in g is th e te rm used to de scrib e such a s itu a tio n . I t m a y be c la s s ifie d f u r t h e r in to in te rn a l (o r ‘s o f t ’)c a p ita l ra tio n in g a n d e x te rn a l (o r ‘h a rd ’)c a p ita l ra tio n in g . Internal capital rationing occurs w h e n m a n a g e m e n t lim it s th e a m o u n t t h a t can be in v e s te d in n e w p ro je c ts d u rin g som e s p e c ifie d tim e p e rio d . There are seve ral reasons w h y m a n a g e m e n t m a y im p o s e a li m it o n c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re . O n e is t h a t m a n a g e m e n t is c o n s e rv a tiv e a n d has a p o lic y o f fin a n c in g a ll p ro je c ts fro m in te r n a lly g e n e ra te d cash because i t is u n w illin g to b o rro w . S im ila rly , m a n a g e m e n t m a y be u n w illin g to issue m o re shares because o f p o ssib le e ffe cts o n th e c o n tro l o f th e com p an y. A lte rn a tiv e ly , im p o s in g c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re lim it s can be a w a y o f m a in ta in in g fin a n c ia l c o n tro l. F o r e xa m p le , in a la rg e com p an y, m anagers m a y a tte m p t to e x p a n d t h e ir d iv is io n s b y p ro p o s in g m a n y n e w p ro je c ts , som e o f w h ic h o n ly appear to be p ro fita b le because th e cash flo w fo re ca sts are v e ry o p tim is tic . To a v o id th is p ro b le m , to p m a n a g e m e n t m a y delegate a u t h o r ity f o r c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re d e cisio n s to d iv is io n a l m an ag ers, b u t re ta in o ve ra ll c o n tro l b y g iv in g each d iv is io n a c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re lim it . The a im is to fo rce each d iv is io n a l m an ag er to decide w h ic h o f th e p o ssib le p ro je c ts re a lly s h o u ld be a d op te d. A n o th e r p o s s ib ility is t h a t i t m a y be d e sira b le to li m i t th e ra te a t w h ic h a c o m p a n y exp an ds because o f th e o rg a n is a tio n a l d iffic u ltie s in h e re n t in h ir in g a n d t r a in in g m a n y a d d itio n a l s ta ff. M a n a g e m e n t m a y be con cern ed t h a t ra p id e x p a n s io n w ill le a d to in e ffic ie n c y a n d h ig h e r costs. To a v o id th e se p ro b le m s i t m a y lim it th e n u m b e r o f n e w p ro je c ts t h a t are im p le m e n te d . In th is case, a c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re li m i t is used to im p ose th e d e sire d r e s tr ic tio n , b u t i t is n o t capital t h a t is th e scarce resource. R a th e r, th e scarce resource is m a n a g e m e n t tim e , a n d th e re a l c o n ce rn is t h a t th is c o n s tra in t m a y re s u lt in s u p e rv is io n p ro b le m s . External capital rationing occu rs w h e n th e c a p ita l m a rk e t is u n w illin g to s u p p ly th e fu n d s necessary to fin a n ce th e p ro je c ts t h a t a c o m p a n y s m a n a g e m e n t w ishes to u n d e rta k e . I n th is case, th e c o m p a n y has p ro je c ts t h a t o ffe r p o s itiv e n e t p re s e n t value s b u t c a n n o t raise, a t a co st t h a t m a n a g e m e n t con sid ers acceptable, th e fu n d s necessary to fin a n c e th e m . T h is s itu a tio n can o ccu r i f fin a n c ia l in te rm e d ia rie s are sub je ct to c o n tro ls such as lim it s o n th e v o lu m e o r g r o w th ra te o f t h e ir le n d in g . H o w e ve r, i t is d iffic u lt to see w h y i t s h o u ld o ccu r in d e re g u la te d fin a n c ia l m a rk e ts . A n y c o m p a n y t h a t has a p ro je c t exp ected to be p ro fita b le s h o u ld be able to o b ta in th e necessary c a p ita l, n o m a tte r h o w s m a ll its c a p ita l b u d g e t. F or exam ple, suppose t h a t a s m a ll com p an y, w h ic h p la n s to in v e s t n o m o re th a n , say, $ 5 0 0 0 0 in th e c u rre n t year, discove rs an in e x p e n s iv e w a y o f e x tra c tin g g o ld fr o m th e oceans. R a is in g c a p ita l to b u ild th e e x tra c tio n p la n t s h o u ld n o t be a p ro b le m . E m p iric a l evidence suggests t h a t c a p ita l r a tio n in g is m o re lik e ly to re s u lt fr o m e x p e n d itu re lim it s im p o se d b y m a n a g e m e n t o f its o w n v o lit io n th a n fr o m an u n w illin g n e s s o f th e c a p ita l m a rk e t to s u p p ly fu n d s (P ike 1 9 8 3 ). I f m a n a g e m e n ts de cisio n s re s u lt in th e re je c tio n o f p ro je c ts w it h p o s itiv e n e t p re s e n t values, th e n m a n a g e m e n t is a d o p tin g a p o lic y in c o n s is te n t w it h th e o b je c tiv e o f m a x im is in g th e m a rk e t value o f th e c o m p a n y ’s shares. I f c a p ita l ra tio n in g is e s s e n tia lly an in te r n a l ‘p ro b le m ’, i t m ig h t a p p e a r th a t th e s o lu tio n s h o u ld be sim p le . M a n a g e m e n t s h o u ld re m o ve th e c o n s tra in ts so t h a t a ll p o s itiv e n e t p re s e n t value p ro je c ts can be im p le m e n te d . In som e cases, th is does occur. F o r e xa m p le , in cases w h e re c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re lim it s are used to m a in ta in fin a n c ia l c o n tro l, th e lim it s are lik e ly to be fle x ib le , a n d a d d itio n a l fu n d s w ill be p ro v id e d i f a p ro fita b le in v e s tm e n t o p p o r tu n ity arises u n e xp e cte d ly. H o w eve r, as discussed above, c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re lim it s m a y be im p o s e d f o r v a lid reasons t h a t do n o t re fle c t a sh o rta g e o f c a p ita l. R a th e r, th e re a l c o n s tra in t m a y be a s h o rta g e o f o th e r resources such as m a n a g e m e n t tim e . T h e re fo re , c a p ita l r a tio n in g can be a real p h e n o m e n o n a n d m an ag ers m a y ne ed to choose th e set o f p ro je c ts t h a t m a x im is e s n e t p re s e n t value , s u b je c t to a reso urce c o n s tra in t. O n th e o th e r ha n d , i f e x te rn a l c a p ita l r a tio n in g e xists, a tte m p ts to m a x im is e n e t p re s e n t value , su b je c t to a c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re lim it , in v o lv e a n in h e re n t c o n tra d ic tio n . The p ro b le m is t h a t a p ro je c ts n e t p re s e n t va lu e is ca lcula ted u s in g a re q u ire d ra te o f r e tu r n , b u t th e existe nce o f an e x te rn a l l i m i t o n th e a v a ila b ility o f c a p ita l im p lie s t h a t once th e li m it is reached, th e re q u ire d ra te o f r e tu r n is in fin ite . In th e fo llo w in g CAPITAL RATIO NING a condition where a firm has limited resources available for investment d iscu ssio n , th e re fo re , i t w ill be assu m ed t h a t c a p ita l r a tio n in g e xists o n ly because o f in te r n a lly im p o s e d c o n s tra in ts . A m a n a g e r a tte m p tin g to ‘m a x im is e , th e m a rk e t value o f th e c o m p a n y ’s shares w it h in these s e lf-im p o s e d c o n s tra in ts s h o u ld calcula te th e n e t p re s e n t value o f each p ro je c t b y d is c o u n tin g its cash flo w s a t th e re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn , a n d th e n choose th e c o m b in a tio n o f p ro je c ts t h a t m a xim ise s n e t p re s e n t v a lu e . The fo llo w in g e xa m p le illu s tra te s th is ap pro ach. E xample 6.14 S u p p o s e th a t a c o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g th e p r o p o s a ls lis te d in T a b le 6 . 1 4 . A s s u m e th a t it h a s a c a p it a l e x p e n d itu re lim it o f $ 6 0 0 0 0 0 , a ll p ro je c ts a r e in d e p e n d e n t, th e p ro je c ts a r e n o t d iv is ib le a n d it is n o t e n v is a g e d th a t a n e x p e n d itu re lim it w ill e x is t in fu tu re y e a rs . TABLE 6.14 Ranking of projects under capital rationing Project Initial cash outlay ($) Net present value ($) A 200000 28000 B 200000 20000 C 200000 15 000 D 200000 35 000 E 400000 45 000 F 400000 22000 M a n a g e m e n t m u st f in d th e c o m b in a tio n o f p ro je c ts th a t m a x im is e s n e t p re s e n t v a lu e , s u b je c t to th e e x p e n d itu re lim it o f $ 6 0 0 0 0 0 . SOLUTION In th is e x a m p le , e x a m in a tio n o f a ll p o s s ib le o u tc o m e s s h o w s th a t th e la rg e s t n e t p re s e n t v a lu e w ill b e a c h ie v e d b y th e c o m b in a tio n o f P ro je cts D, A a n d B. T h is c o m b in a tio n resu lts in a n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f $ 8 3 0 0 0 . B y c o m p a r is o n , th e n e x t b e s t a lte r n a tiv e , a c o m b in a tio n o f P ro je cts D a n d E, resu lts in a n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f $ 8 0 0 0 0 . A s a re s u lt o f th e e x p e n d itu re lim it, e v e n th o u g h P ro je c ts C , E a n d F h a v e p o s itiv e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e s , th e c o m p a n y is u n a b le to im p le m e n t th e m th is y e a r . W it h o u t th e e x p e n d itu r e lim it, a ll th e p ro je c ts s h o w n in T a b le 6 . 1 4 c o u ld h a v e b e e n a c c e p te d a n d th e to ta l n e t p re s e n t v a lu e w o u ld h a v e b e e n $ 1 6 5 0 0 0 in s te a d o f $ 8 3 0 0 0 . In re a lity , ra n k in g o f in v e s tm e n t p ro je c ts w h e re th e re is c a p ita l r a tio n in g is m u c h m o re co m p le x because o f th e la rg e n u m b e r o f in v e s tm e n t a lte rn a tiv e s g e n e ra lly a va ila b le to a co m p a n y. To f in d s o lu tio n s to such p ro b le m s , m a th e m a tic a l p ro g ra m m in g m o d e ls have b e en de velope d. W e n o w r e tu r n to th e e a rlie r p o in t t h a t th e im p o s itio n o f c a p ita l r a tio n in g b y m a n a g e m e n t can p re v e n t th e m a x im is a tio n o f s h a re h o ld e rs ’ w e a lth . C a p ita l r a tio n in g is n o t in th e s h a re h o ld e rs ’ b e s t in te re s t i f p ro je c ts w it h p o s itiv e n e t p re s e n t values are rejected . In E x a m p le 6 .1 4 , P ro je cts C, E a n d F, w ith p o s itiv e n e t p re s e n t values t o t a llin g $ 8 2 00 0, are re je cte d because o f a c a p ita l c o n s tra in t. U n less th e c o m p a n y faces a re a l c o n s tra in t, such as a s h o rta g e o f p e rs o n n e l, o r ra p id e x p a n s io n in v o lv e s excessive r is k , m a n a g e m e n t s h o u ld raise th e fu n d s necessary to fin a n c e the se p ro je c ts b y re d u c in g d iv id e n d s , b o rro w in g , is s u in g m o re shares o r som e c o m b in a tio n o f the se a ctio n s. C hapter six T he application of project evaluation methods This c h a p te r h a s d is c u s s e d s e v e ra l im p o r ta n t a s p e c ts c h a in o f p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n , b e g in n in g w ith th e e s tim a tio n o f th e e q u iv a le n t a n n u a l v a lu e o f e a c h p r o je c t. T hese of re p la c e m e n t m e th o d or by c a lc u la tin g c a s h flo w s . m e th o d s a ls o p r o v id e a c o n v e n ie n t w a y o f a n a ly s in g • a s s e t r e p la c e m e n t d e c is io n s . In e s tim a tin g c a s h flo w s , f in a n c in g c h a rg e s s h o u ld b e e x c lu d e d , a s to o s h o u ld a llo c a te d costs a n d su n k • • W h ile th e e ffe c ts o f ris k c a n be in c o r p o r a t e d in p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n b y u s in g a ris k -a d ju s te d d is c o u n t costs. C o n v e rs e ly , a ll in c re m e n ta l c a s h flo w s m ust b e in c lu d e d . T he c o r r e c t tre a tm e n t o f in fla tio n re q u ire s ra te , th e re a r e s e v e ra l m e th o d s o f p r o je c t a n a ly s is th a t c a s h flo w s a n d th e r e q u ir e d ra te o f re tu rn b e th a t c a n b e u se fu l in d e s c r ib in g ris k a n d p r o v id in g d e fin e d in a c o n s is te n t m a n n e r. m a n a g e rs w ith in fo r m a tio n a b o u t th e ris k o f a p r o je c t. In d iv id u a ls a n d firm s a r e T he m e th o d s d is c u s s e d in th e c h a p te r a r e s e n s itiv ity r e q u ire d to p a y in c o m e ta x e s to th e g o v e rn m e n t. H e n c e , it is im p o r ta n t th a t a n a ly s is , p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n m e th o d s ta k e in to a c c o u n t ite m s D e c is io n -tre e th a t q u a lif y as a s s e s s a b le in c o m e a n d e v a lu a tin g s e q u e n tia l d e c is io n s w h e r e p r o b a b ilit ie s q u a lify as a llo w a b le d e d u c tio n s . An ite m s th a t in c re a s e b re a k -e v e n a n a ly s is a n a ly s is can be and a s im u la tio n . u se fu l to o l fo r c a n b e a tta c h e d to th e p o s s ib le o u tc o m e s . in a s s e s s a b le in c o m e resu lts in a h ig h e r ta x p a y m e n t, T he c h a p te r w h ile a n in c re a s e in a llo w a b le d e d u c tio n s re su lts in • P ro je c ts th a t a re a ls o p r o v id e d a d is c u s s io n o f th e im p o r ta n c e o f c o n s id e r in g q u a lita tiv e fa c to rs in p r o je c t a lo w e r t a x p a y m e n t. m u tu a lly e x c lu s iv e and have d iffe re n t liv e s c a n b e c o m p a r e d u s in g th e c o n s ta n t e v a lu a tio n , a n d c o n c lu d e d w ith a d is c u s s io n o f th e e ffe c ts o f re s o u rc e c o n s tra in ts o n p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n . KEY TERMS b re a k -e v e n a n a ly s is c a p ita l r a tio n in g re s id u a l v a lu e 151 131 s e n s itiv ity a n a ly s is 157 c o n s ta n t c h a in o f re p la c e m e n t a s s u m p tio n e q u iv a le n t a n n u a l v a lu e m e th o d s im u la tio n 140 su n k co st 141 149 152 131 SELF-TEST PROBLEMS A c o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g th e p u rc h a s e o f e q u ip m e n t c o s tin g $ 8 4 0 0 0 , w h ic h w ill p e r m it it to re d u c e its e x is tin g la b o u r co sts b y $ 2 0 0 0 0 a y e a r fo r 1 2 y e a rs . T h e c o m p a n y e s tim a te s th a t it w ill h a v e to s p e n d $ 2 0 0 0 e v e r y 2 y e a rs o v e r h a u lin g th e e q u ip m e n t. The e q u ip m e n t m a y b e d e p r e c ia te d f o r t a x p u rp o s e s b y th e s tr a ig h t-lin e m e th o d , o v e r a 1 2 -y e a r p e r io d . T he c o m p a n y ta x ra te is 3 0 c e n ts in th e d o lla r a n d th e a fte r-ta x c o s t o f c a p it a l is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . A s s u m in g a ll c a s h flo w s , in c lu d in g ta x p a y m e n ts , a r e m a d e a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r, s h o u ld th e c o m p a n y p u rc h a s e th e e q u ip m e n t? T he m a n a g e m e n t o f th e T M T C o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g p u r c h a s in g a n e w m a c h in e a n d it h a s g a th e r e d th e f o llo w in g d a ta : a) The c a s h n e e d e d to p u rc h a s e th e n e w m a c h in e is $ 6 4 0 0 0 . b) The re s id u a l v a lu e a n d a n n u a l c a s h o p e r a tin g e x p e n s e s fo r th e n e x t 5 y e a rs a r e e s tim a te d to be: R e sid u a l v a lu e a t e n d A n n u a l ca sh o p e r a tin g Year o f y e a r ($ ) e xp e n se s ($ } 1 50000 11000 2 40000 13000 3 30000 18000 4 23000 24000 5 3500 28000 C H A P T E R SIX R E V I E W SUMMARY B usiness finance c) N o cha ng es in residual values o r a n n u a l cash o p e ra tin g expenses a re exp ected . d) The re q u ire d rate o f return is 15 per cent pe r annum . e) The effects o f c o m p a n y in com e ta x m a y be ig n o re d . W h a t is the o p tim u m re p la ce m e n t p o lic y fo r this m achine? 3 The m a n a g e m e n t o f A B C T ra n sp o rt Ltd, w h ic h is e n g a g e d in interstate tra n s p o rt, is c o n s id e rin g the re p la c e m e n t o f its pre sen t fle e t o f 1 0 CB sem i-trailers w ith six A Z F lexivans. A su rve y has re ve a le d the fo llo w in g estim ates o f costs, a n d so on, p e r vehicle: CB s e m i-tra ile rs R em aining life E stim ate s 3 years A Z F le x iv a n s E stim ates E stim ate d life 5 years 1 Residual value: A t th e p re se n t tim e $5 000 Cost $70000 In 3 years’ tim e $1000 A n n u a l n e t cash flow s $40000 A n n u a l n e t cash flow s $30000 Residual value a fte r $5 000 5 years’ o p e ra tio n O th e r in fo r m a tio n is a s fo llo w s : • N e t c a s h flo w s a r e to b e r e g a r d e d a s re c e iv e d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r. • T he r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . S h o u ld m a n a g e m e n t: a) re ta in th e C B s e m i-tra ile rs f o r 3 y e a rs a n d th e n re p la c e th e m w ith A Z F le x iv a n s ? b) re p la c e th e C B se m i-tra ile rs w ith th e A Z F le x iv a n s n o w ? Solutions to self-test problems ore available in Appendix B. QUESTIONS 1 [LO 1! A p r o p e r ty d e v e lo p m e n t c o m p a n y p la n s to d e m o lis h th e b u ild in g o n a site th a t it a lr e a d y o w n s , a n d th e n b u ild a c o n v e n ie n c e sto re . W h ic h o f th e f o llo w in g ite m s s h o u ld b e in c lu d e d a s in c re m e n ta l c a s h flo w s w h e n th e p r o je c t is e v a lu a te d : 2 a) th e m a rk e t v a lu e o f th e p r o p e r ty b) th e c o s t o f d e m o lis h in g th e o ld b u ild in g c) th e co st o f n e w w a te r a n d e le c tric p o w e r c o n n e c tio n s in s ta lle d 3 m o n th s a g o d) a p o rtio n o f th e c o s t o f le a s in g c a rs use d b y th e c o m p a n y 's e x e c u tiv e s e) m o n e y th a t ha s a lr e a d y b e e n s p e n t o n a rc h ite c tu ra l c o n c e p t p la n s fo r th e n e w b u ild in g ? [L O 1] E x p la in th e re la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n nominal a n d real d is c o u n t ra te s . O u t lin e its a p p lic a t io n to p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n in th e c o n te x t o f a n in fla t io n a r y e c o n o m y . 3 [LO 1] L e a v in g a s id e th e e ffe c t o f ta x e s , w h ic h o f th e f o llo w in g ite m s s h o u ld b e c o n s id e r e d in th e in itia l o u tla y o n a n e w m a c h in e f o r p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n p u rp o s e s ? G iv e re a s o n s . a) T he d is p o s a l v a lu e o f th e o ld m a c h in e , w h ic h is $ 6 0 0 0 . b) T he $ 4 0 0 c o s t o f in s ta llin g th e n e w m a c h in e . 4 5 c) A d d it io n a l in v e s tm e n t o f $ 1 0 0 0 0 in c u rre n t assets th a t w ill b e re q u ire d . d) C o sts o f $ 3 0 0 0 re c e n tly in c u rre d in a sse ssin g th e s u ita b ility o f th e n e w m a c h in e . [L O 2 】It doesn't matter whether the straight-line method or reducing-balance method o f depreciation is used since the total tax b ill over the life o f the project is the some. C o m m e n t o n th is s ta te m e n t. [LO 3 】 O u t lin e tw o m e th o d s o f s o lv in g p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n p ro b le m s w h e r e th e p ro je c ts u n d e r c o n s id e r a tio n d o n o t h a v e c o m m o n te r m in a l d a te s . 160 C hapter six T he [L O 3 ] D e fin e th e te rm 'm u tu a lly e x c lu s iv e p r o je c ts ' a n d p r o v id e a s im p le e x a m p le . O u tlin e a n d ju s tify th e b a s ic n e t p re s e n t v a lu e ru le a p p lic a b le to th e m . H o w s h o u ld th is ru le b e m o d ifie d w h e n such p ro je c ts h a v e u n e q u a l live s? 7 [L O 4 ] H o w s h o u ld th e o p tim u m life o f a p r o je c t b e d e te rm in e d ? 8 [L O 4 ] D is tin g u is h b e tw e e n re p la c e m e n t d e c is io n s a n d re tire m e n t d e c is io n s . 9 [L O 5 ] 10 [L O 5 ] O u tlin e th e w e a k n e s s e s o f s e n s itiv ity a n a ly s is . Sensitivity analysis may be used to identify the variables that ore most important for a project's success. D iscuss. 11 [LO 5 ] 12 [L 0 5 ] Simulation is only useful for large-scale investment projects. D iscuss. Simulation is extremely valuable because it is useful in refining cash flow forecasts and it avoids the need to estimate a project's required rote o f return. D o y o u a g r e e w ith th e se c la im s ? G iv e re a s o n s f o r y o u r a n s w e r. 13 [LO 8 ] D is tin g u is h b e tw e e n in te rn a l a n d e x te rn a l c a p it a l r a tio n in g . G iv e e x a m p le s o f e a c h . 14 [L0 8] a) O u tlin e p o s s ib le re a s o n s fo r th e im p o s itio n b y m a n a g e m e n t o f c a p ita l ra tio n in g . D o e s th e im p o s itio n o f b) If a c o m p a n y is s u b je c t to c a p ita l ra tio n in g , d o e s th is m a k e a n y d iffe re n c e to p r o je c t e v a lu a tio n u s in g th e C H A P T E R SIX R E V I E W 6 application of project evaluation methods in te rn a l c a p ita l r a tio n in g im p ly th a t m a n a g e m e n t is f a ilin g to m a x im is e s h a re h o ld e rs 7 w e a lth ? n e t p re s e n t v a lu e m e th o d ? G iv e re a so n s. CA PROBLEMS 1 Application of the N P V method [LO 1] The fu rn itu re d iv is io n o f P la y fu rn Ltd, a p ro fita b le , d iv e rs ifie d c o m p a n y , p u rc h a s e d a m a c h in e 5 y e a rs a g o fo r $ 7 5 0 0 0 . W h e n it w a s p u rc h a s e d th e m a c h in e h a d a n e x p e c te d use ful life o f 1 5 y e a rs a n d a n e s tim a te d v a lu e o f z e ro a t th e e n d o f its life . T h e m a c h in e c u rre n tly h a s a m a rk e t v a lu e o f $ 1 0 0 0 0 . T he d iv is io n m a n a g e r re p o rts th a t he c a n b u y a n e w m a c h in e fo r $ 1 6 0 0 0 0 (in c lu d in g in s ta lla tio n ) w h ic h , o v e r its 1 0 -y e a r life , w ill re su lt in a n e x p a n s io n o f sa le s fro m $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 to $1 1 0 0 0 0 p e r a n n u m . In a d d itio n , it is e s tim a te d th a t th e n e w m a c h in e w ill re d u c e a n n u a l o p e r a tin g costs fro m $ 7 0 0 0 0 to $ 5 0 0 0 0 . If th e r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m , s h o u ld P la y fu rn b u y th e n e w m a c h in e ? 2 Application of the N P V method [LO 1] T he T w o-B it M in in g C o m p a n y h a s c o n s tru c te d a to w n a t B ig B o re , n e a r th e site o f a ric h m in e ra l d is c o v e r y in a re m o te p a r t o f A u s tr a lia . T he to w n w ill b e a b a n d o n e d w h e n m in in g o p e ra tio n s c e a s e a fte r a n e s tim a te d 1 0 -y e a r p e r io d . T he fo llo w in g e s tim a te s o f in v e s tm e n t costs, sa le s a n d o p e r a tin g e x p e n s e s re la te to a p r o je c t to s u p p ly B ig B o re w ith m e a t a n d a g ric u ltu r a l p ro d u c e o v e r th e 1 0 -y e a r p e r io d b y d e v e lo p in g n e a r b y la n d . a) In v e s tm e n t in la n d is $ 1 0 m illio n , fa rm b u ild in g s $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 a n d fa rm e q u ip m e n t $ 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 . T he la n d is e x p e c te d to h a v e a re a lis a b le v a lu e o f $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 in 1 0 y e a rs ' tim e . T he re s id u a l v a lu e o f th e b u ild in g s a fte r 1 0 y e a rs is e x p e c te d to b e $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 . T he fa rm e q u ip m e n t ha s a n e s tim a te d life o f 1 0 y e a rs a n d a z e r o re s id u a l v a lu e . b) In ve stm e n t o f $ 2 5 0 0 0 0 0 in c u rre n t assets w ill b e re c o v e re d a t th e te rm in a tio n o f th e v e n tu re . c) A n n u a l c a s h sales a r e e s tim a te d to b e $ 2 4 . 8 m illio n . d) A n n u a l c a s h o p e r a tin g costs a r e e s tim a te d to b e $ 2 2 m illio n . Is th e p ro je c t p r o fita b le , g iv e n th a t th e r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m ? 3 Application of the N P V method [LO 1] A s o ftw a re p r o v id e r b u y s b la n k B lu -ra y D V D s a t $ 5 5 0 p e r h u n d re d a n d c u rre n tly uses 2 m illio n D V D s p e r y e a r. The m a n a g e r b e lie v e s th a t it m a y b e c h e a p e r to m a k e th e D V D s ra th e r th a n b u y th e m . D ire c t p r o d u c tio n costs (la b o u r, m a te ria ls , fu e l) a r e e s tim a te d a t $ 2 . 5 0 p e r D V D . T he e q u ip m e n t n e e d e d w o u ld c o s t $ 3 m illio n . T he e q u ip m e n t s h o u ld la s t fo r 1 5 y e a rs , p r o v id e d it is o v e rh a u le d e v e ry 5 y e a rs a t a c o s t o f $ 2 5 0 0 0 0 e a c h tim e . The o p e r a tio n w ill re q u ire a d d itio n a l c u rre n t assets o f $ 4 0 0 0 0 0 . The c o m p a n y 's r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 2 p e r c e n t. E v a lu a te th e p ro p o s a l. 161 B usiness finance 4 Application of the N P V method [LO 1] O z z ie N a tio n w id e In d u strie s Ltd is a la r g e c o m p a n y w ith in te re sts in m in in g , s h ip b u ild in g , e n te rta in m e n t, fo o d p ro c e s s in g a n d in te rs ta te fr e ig h t h a u la g e . Its fo o d p ro c e s s in g d iv is io n is in v e s tig a tin g th e p o s s ib ility o f a d d in g m a n d a rin -fla v o u re d y o g h u r t to its c u rre n t ra n g e o f b a n a n a , s tr a w b e r r y a n d a p p le . C u rre n tly , a ll fla v o u rs a re s o ld a t a p ric e o f $ 1 . 5 0 p e r c a rto n a n d sa le s a re e ve n th ro u g h o u t th e y e a r. O z z ie re c e n tly h ir e d M e lb o u r n e M a r k e t R e se a rch Ltd to s u rv e y co n s u m e rs to ju d g e th e lik e ly p o p u la r ity o f th e n e w fla v o u r. The r e p o r t c o s t $ 4 0 0 0 0 a n d s u g g e s te d th a t th e c o m p a n y s h o u ld b e a b le to sell 4 0 0 0 0 0 c a rto n s o f th e n e w fla v o u r n e x t y e a r, a n d 8 0 0 0 0 0 in e a c h o f th e f o llo w in g 2 y e a rs . A fte r th a t tim e , th e fa d fo r m a n d a r in fla v o u r is e x p e c te d to h a v e run its c o u rs e . O z z ie 's c o s tin g d e p a rtm e n t h a s a d v is e d th a t th e in c re m e n ta l c o s t o f p ro d u c tio n is $ 1 . 2 0 p e r c a rto n . O z z ie 's sales d e p a rtm e n t h a s a d v is e d th a t it is e s s e n tia l th a t a ll fla v o u rs in th e ra n g e s h o u ld b e so ld a t th e s a m e p ric e . O z z ie 's e n g in e e rs h a v e a d v is e d th a t th e re is n o s p a re p ro d u c tio n c a p a c ity a lth o u g h th e re is p le n ty o f s p a re flo o r s p a c e in th e fa c to ry . T h e y h a v e a ls o a d v is e d th a t y o g h u r t p ro c e s s in g m a c h in e s h a v e a p r o d u c tio n c a p a c ity o f 4 0 0 0 0 0 c a rto n s p e r a n n u m a n d th a t th e c o s t o f o n e m a c h in e , fu lly in s ta lle d , is $ 2 3 0 0 0 0 . O z z ie 's fin a n c e d iv is io n ha s a d v is e d th a t th e c o m p a n y 's re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn (n o m in a l) is e s tim a te d to b e 1 5 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . T he m a c h in e s h a v e a life o f 3 y e a rs a n d a t th a t p o in t h a v e o n ly a s c ra p v a lu e , w h ic h is e s tim a te d to b e o n ly $ 1 0 0 0 0 . H o w e v e r, th is a m o u n t u s u a lly o n ly ju st c o v e rs th e costs o f re m o v in g th e m a c h in e fro m th e fa c to ry . O z z ie 's p r o je c t a n a ly s t h a s re c o m m e n d e d a g a in s t p r o c e e d in g w ith th e n e w fla v o u r, b a s in g this r e c o m m e n d a tio n o n a n e t p re s e n t v a lu e a n a ly s is . T he n e t c a s h in flo w s w e r e fo re c a s t to b e $ 1 2 0 0 0 0 in th e firs t y e a r, a n d $ 2 4 0 0 0 0 in th e s e c o n d y e a r a n d th e th ird y e a r. T he in itia l o u tla y w a s $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 . T he N P V w a s c a lc u la te d as: K(m/ $ 1 2 0 0 0 0 $240000 $240000 N P V = --------------- + -------------------1-$ 5 0 0 0 0 0 1.1 50 5 1 .1 5 15 1 .1 5 2-5 一 $ 2 4 2 64 The p r o je c t a n a ly s t's re p o r t c o n ta in e d th e u su al r a n g e o f s e n s itiv ity a n a ly s e s a n d s u p p o rtin g d is c u s s io n a n d d o c u m e n ta tio n b u t th is c a lc u la tio n w a s th e c e n tra l result. You h a v e b e e n a s k e d to r e v ie w th e p r o je c t a n a ly s t’s w o r k a n d re p o r t o n a n y e rro rs y o u d e te c t. P ro v id e re a s o n s. Ig n o re ta x . N o te th a t it is n o t n e c e s s a ry to re d o th e a n a ly s is , o r to s u g g e s t h o w th e a n a ly s is m ig h t b e e x te n d e d . Y o u r ta s k is to id e n tify e rro rs . 5 Application of the N P V method [LO 1] T he B e rtie H a m ilto n F is h in g C o m p a n y (BHF) p u rc h a s e d a tr a w le r 6 y e a rs a g o fo r $ 4 2 0 0 0 0 . A t th e tim e it w a s p u rc h a s e d , th e t r a w le r h a d a use ful life o f 1 0 y e a rs . If BHF w e r e to re ta in th is b o a t, it is a n tic ip a te d th a t u ltra s o n ic d e te c tio n e q u ip m e n t w o u ld h a v e to b e in s ta lle d in th e s e c o n d -la s t y e a r o f its life a t a c o s t o f $ 4 0 0 0 0 . H o w e v e r, th e C o m m e rc ia l T ra w le r C o m p a n y (CT) ha s re c e n tly la u n c h e d a fa ste r, co m p u te r-a s s is te d tr a w le r th a t BHF is c o n s id e rin g a s a re p la c e m e n t. T his tr a w le r w ill c o s t $ 6 0 0 0 0 0 b u t w ill n e e d im m e d ia te re fittin g to s u it th e p u rc h a s e r's s p e c ific a tio n s a t a n a d d itio n a l c o s t o f $ 1 5 0 0 0 . It h a s a n e x p e c te d use ful life o f 1 2 y e a rs . If p u rc h a s e d , th e n e w tr a w le r is lik e ly to in c re a s e c a s h o p e r a tin g costs b y $ 1 0 p e r to n n e o f fish , w h ic h c u rre n tly sells f o r $ 3 0 p e r to n n e . H o w e v e r, fu tu re c a tc h e s a re lik e ly to in c re a s e s ig n ific a n tly b y 6 0 0 0 to n n e s in th e firs t y e a r, a n d the n a t a ra te o f 1 0 0 0 to n n e s p e r a n n u m , s ta b ilis in g a t 1 2 0 0 0 to n n e s fro m Y e a r 7 o n w a r d . O w in g to in te n s iv e u s a g e , it is e x p e c te d th a t to w a r d s th e e n d o f th e fifth y e a r th e n e w tr a w le r w ill re q u ire a m in o r e n g in e o v e rh a u l a t a c o s t o f $ 3 0 0 0 0 . P a rt o f th e p u rc h a s e a g re e m e n t a ls o in v o lv e s a m a in te n a n c e c o n tra c t w ith C T c o v e rin g th e nets a n d t r a w lin g a p p a ra tu s , w h ic h w ill c o s t BHF $ 1 2 0 0 0 , p a y a b le a t th e e n d o f e v e r y fo u rth y e a r. A s a c o m p e titiv e stra te g y, C T o ffe rs a n o p tio n a l fin a n c in g p a c k a g e fo r u p to 8 0 p e r c e n t o f th e in v o ic e p ric e o n a n y b o a t. T h e ra te o f in te re s t o n th is a m o u n t is 1 2 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m , w ith th e firs t p a y m e n t d e fe rre d 1 y e a r. If th e fin a n c in g p a c k a g e is a d o p te d , BHF m ust u n d e rta k e to sell th e tr a w le r b a c k to C T in 1 2 y e a rs ' tim e fo r $ 5 0 0 0 0 . BHF e s tim a te s th a t th e c u rre n t s e c o n d -h a n d p r ic e o f its p re s e n t tr a w le r is o n ly $ 1 4 0 0 0 0 . It is e s tim a te d th a t th e n e w tr a w le r c a n b e s o ld f o r $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 a t th e e n d o f its use fu l life . T h e c o m p a n y 's n o m in a l re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 3 0 p e r ce n t. a) E stim a te th e n e t c a s h f lo w (N C F ) a t th e b e g in n in g o f Y e a r 1. bj E stim a te th e N C F in Y e a r 4 . C hapter six T he M a n a g e m e n t b e lie v e s th a t re la tiv e to to d a y 's p ric e s , th e a v e r a g e in fla tio n ra te is e x p e c te d to b e 8 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m o v e r th e n e x t 1 2 y e a rs . W h a t is th e Y e a r 3 in fla tio n -a d ju s te d N C F ? d) E stim a te th e a p p r o p r ia te d is c o u n t ra te to p e rfo rm a n N P V a n a ly s is in re a l te rm s. Application of the N P V method [LO 1] A c o m p a n y m ust c h o o s e b e tw e e n tw o m a c h in e s . M a c h in e A costs $ 5 0 0 0 0 a n d th e a n n u a l o p e r a tin g e x p e n s e s a re e s tim a te d to b e $ 2 0 0 0 0 , w h ile M a c h in e B costs $ 8 5 0 0 0 a n d ha s e s tim a te d a n n u a l o p e r a tin g e x p e n s e s o f $ 1 5 0 0 0 . B o th m a c h in e s h a v e a 1 0 -y e a r life a n d w ill h a v e a z e ro re s id u a l v a lu e . a) The c o m p a n y h a s a r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn o f 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . W h ic h m a c h in e s h o u ld it p u rc h a s e ? b) R e w o rk th e p ro b le m fo r a 7 p e r c e n t r e q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn . Application of the N P V method [LO 1] A c o m p a n y is c o n s id e rin g th e p u rc h a s e o f e q u ip m e n t c o s tin g $ 1 2 5 0 0 0 th a t w ill p e rm it it to re d u c e its e x is tin g la b o u r costs b y $ 2 0 0 0 0 a y e a r f o r 1 2 y e a rs . T h e c o m p a n y e s tim a te s th a t it w ill h a v e to s p e n d $ 3 0 0 0 e v e r y 2 y e a rs o v e rh a u lin g th e e q u ip m e n t. T h e re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . A s s u m in g a ll c a s h flo w s a re m a d e a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r, s h o u ld th e c o m p a n y p u rc h a s e th e e q u ip m e n t? Explaining the effects of taxes on project cash flows [LO 2 】 The F o u r a n d S ix S tore s Pty Ltd is c o n s id e rin g lo c a tin g a n o th e r o u tle t in a n e a s te rn s u b u rb o f M e lb o u r n e . C H A P T E R SIX R E V I E W c) application of project evaluation methods Estim ates o f sales a n d o p e r a tin g e x p e n s e s h a v e b e e n m a d e a n d a n e s tim a te d p r o fit a n d loss s ta te m e n t fo r the n e w s to re d r a w n u p . T he p r o fit a n d loss s ta te m e n t fo r Y e a r 1 is th o u g h t to b e re p re s e n ta tiv e o f e a c h o f th e 1 0 y e a rs o f th e e x p e c te d life o f th e n e w F o u r a n d S ix s to re . T he in itia l o u tla y to c o n s tru c t th e s to re is $ 4 0 0 0 0 0 0 , w h ile th e o u tla y n e c e s s a ry to sto ck th e s to re is $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 . T h e e s tim a te d s ta te m e n t o f fin a n c ia l p e rfo rm a n c e fo r th e n e w s to re fo r Y e a r 1 is s h o w n in th e fo llo w in g ta b le : Revenue Less sales re tu rn s, discou nts 4000000 400 000 3 600000 N et revenue O pe ra ting expenses Cost o f goods sold 1600000 A d m in is tra tio n costs 600000 D e pre ciatio n 360000 In te re st 240000 2800000 N e t p ro fit before tax 800000 Tax (30% tax rate) 240000 N e t p ro fit a fte r tax 560000 E stim ate th e p ro je c t's a n n u a l a fte r-ta x c a s h flo w . Explaining the effects of taxes on project cash flows [LO 2] A ll- N ig h t C o ffe e S h o p s Ltd is a su cce ssful p r o fita b le c o m p a n y o p e r a tin g s e v e ra l d o z e n c o ffe e sh o p s th ro u g h o u t th e m e tro p o lita n a r e a o f M e lb e r r a . H o w e v e r, th e s h o p in th e s u b u rb o f B u rn a b y h a s n o t b e e n w e ll p a tro n is e d , g e n e ra tin g a b e fo re -ta x n e t c a sh f lo w o f o n ly $ 5 0 0 0 0 in th e p a s t y e a r. T he B u rn a b y s h o p b e g a n tr a d in g 2 y e a rs a g o in p re m is e s le a s e d fro m C B D Ltd. T he le a s e is a b o u t to e x p ir e a n d A ll- N ig h t w ill n o t re n e w it. A c o m p e tito r, B ra z il C o ffe e S h o p s Ltd, h a s o ffe re d to b u y th e fix tu re s a n d fittin g s a n d th e e q u ip m e n t in th e B u rn a b y s h o p fo r $ 4 0 0 0 0 0 . A ll- N ig h t ha s a g r e e d to th is fig u re , e ve n th o u g h it is $ 3 0 0 0 0 0 less th a n th e c o s t o f th e fix tu re s a n d fittin g s a n d th e e q u ip m e n t 2 y e a rs a g o . A s s u m e th a t: a) fo r ta x p u rp o s e s th e fix tu re s a n d fittin g s a n d th e e q u ip m e n t w e re d e p r e c ia te d o n a s tra ig h t-lin e b a s is a t b) th e a fte r-ta x c o m p a n y ta x ra te is 3 0 p e r ce n t. 10 pe r cent pe r annum W h a t is th e a fte r-ta x n e t ca sh f lo w (fo r Y e a r 2 ) a ttr ib u ta b le to A ll- N ig h t's B u rn a b y sh o p ? 163 10 Explaining the effects of taxes on project cash flows [LO 2 】 It doesn't matter whether the straight-line or reducing-balance method o f depreciation is used, since the total tax bill over the life o f the project is the same. D iscuss th e v a lid ity (o r o th e rw is e ) o f this s ta te m e n t in th e c o n te x t o f th e fo llo w in g e x a m p le : A s s e t co st (n o w ) $10000 A sset life 5 years Residual value (in 5 years) $4700 A n n u a l n e t cash in flo w be fore ta x $6000 S tra ig h t-lin e d e p re cia tio n rate (per an nu m ) 10% Reducing-balance de p re cia tio n rate (per a n nu m ) 20% C om pany incom e ta x rate 30% Cost o f cap ital 11 10% p.a. Explaining the effects of taxes on project cash flows [LO 2] A c o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g p u rc h a s in g a n e w m a c h in e a t a c o s t o f $ 9 0 0 0 0 0 to re p la c e a m a c h in e p u rc h a s e d 6 y e a rs a g o f o r $1 m illio n . T h e d is p o s a l v a lu e o f th e o ld m a c h in e is $ 2 5 0 0 0 0 a n d th e a c c u m u la te d d e p r e c ia tio n , w h ic h h a s b e e n a llo w e d fo r ta x p u rp o s e s , is $ 6 0 0 0 0 0 . B oth m a c h in e s w ill h a v e s im ila r o u tp u ts a n d w ill p r o d u c e w o r k o f id e n tic a l q u a lity . T he e s tim a te d y e a r ly costs o f o p e r a tin g e a c h m a c h in e a re as fo llo w s : O ld m a c h in e ($) N e w m a c h in e ($ ) 1 Wages 225 000 75 000 D e pre ciatio n 100000 225000 Supplies, repairs, po w e r 65 000 30000 Insurance and m iscellaneous 36000 20000 426000 350000 B oth m a c h in e s h a v e a n e s tim a te d re m a in in g life o f 4 y e a rs , a t w h ic h tim e b o th m a c h in e s w ill h a v e a n e s tim a te d d is p o s a l v a lu e o f $ 9 0 0 0 0 . A s s u m e th a t: a) th e a fte r-c o m p a n y -ta x c o s t o f c a p ita l is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m b) th e o p e r a tin g co sts o f th e o ld m a c h in e a n d th e n e w m a c h in e a r e in c u rre d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r c) th e c o m p a n y in c o m e ta x ra te is 3 0 ce n ts in th e d o lla r. S h o u ld th e c o m p a n y p u rc h a s e th e n e w m a c h in e ? 12 Mutually exclusive projects with different lives [LO 3] T h e m a n a g e m e n t o f H a r b o u r F e rrie s Ltd is c o n s id e rin g th e re p la c e m e n t o f its e x is tin g fle e t o f s ix ste a m fe rrie s w ith th re e h y d ro fo ils . T he fo llo w in g e s tim a te s o f costs, a n d so o n , fo r e a c h vesse l h a v e b e e n c a lc u la te d : I S te a m fe rrie s E stim ate d re m a in in g life E stim ates 5 years E stim a te d scrap value: N ow $50000 In 5 years’ tim e $10000 A n n u a l n e t cash flow s $100000 H y d ro fo ils E stim ate s Cost $500000 E stim ate d life 10 years E stim ate d scrap value: In 5 years’ tim e $200000 In 10 years’ tim e $100000 A n n u a l n e t cash flow s $200000 C hapter six T he application of project evaluation methods a v a ila b le in 5 y e a rs 7 tim e . T he fo llo w in g e stim a te s o f costs, a n d so o n , p e r h o v e rc ra ft h a v e b e e n p r o v id e d b y th e m a n u fa c tu re r: H o v e rc ra ft E stim ate s Cost $600000 E stim ated life 15 years E stim ate d disposal value: $200000 A fte r 5 years* o p era tion $50000 A fte r 15 years* op e ra tio n $250000 A n n u a l n e t cash flow s C H A P T E R SIX R E V I E W M a n a g e m e n t is a ls o a w a r e o f th e d e v e lo p m e n t o f h o v e rc ra ft, w h ic h th e m a n u fa c tu re r e s tim a te s w ill b e It is c o n s id e re d th a t tw o o f th e n e w h o v e rc ra ft w ill b e a d e q u a te to c a r r y th e e s tim a te d n u m b e r o f p a s s e n g e rs . O th e r in fo rm a tio n is a s fo llo w s : • M a n a g e m e n t c a n n o t fo re s e e a n y fu rth e r d e v e lo p m e n ts b e y o n d th e h o v e rc ra ft. • T he a n n u a l n e t c a s h flo w s a r e re c e iv e d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r. • T he c o m p a n y 's re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . You a re re q u ire d to a d v is e m a n a g e m e n t w h e th e r it s h o u ld : a) re p la c e th e stea m fe rrie s w ith h y d ro fo ils n o w , a n d re p la c e th e la tte r w ith h o v e rc ra ft in 5 y e a r s ' tim e b) re ta in th e ste a m fe rrie s fo r 5 y e a rs , a n d th e n re p la c e th e m w ith h o v e rc ra ft c) re p la c e th e stea m fe rrie s w ith h y d ro fo ils n o w , a n d re p la c e th e la tte r w ith h o v e rc ra ft in 1 0 y e a r s 7 tim e . O th e r a lte rn a tiv e s a re n o t to b e c o n s id e re d . 13 Mutually exclusive projects with different lives [LO 3] H e rm e s Pty Ltd o p e ra te s a c o u r ie r s e rv ic e . A n e w v a n is r e q u ire d to m e e t th e in c re a s e d d e m a n d fo r the c o m p a n y ’s s e rv ic e s . T he c h o ic e h a s b e e n n a r r o w e d d o w n to th re e v a n s , A , B a n d C , e a c h c o s tin g $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 . N e t c a s h f lo w e s tim a te s a r e as fo llo w s : N e t c a sh f lo w e stim a te s ($) Year Van A VanB Van C 1 $47000 $48000 $47000 2 $50000 $40000 $48000 3 $50000 $40000 $48000 4 $58000 $52000 $55000 5 0 $42000 0 20% 20% 20% $30795 $32881 $26801 Required rate o f re tu rn NPV By d is c o u n tin g e a c h n e t c a s h flo w , s h o w th a t th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f V a n A h a s b e e n c a lc u la te d p ro p e rly . W h ic h v a n s h o u ld b e p u rc h a s e d ? G iv e re a so n s. 16 5 14 Mutually exclusive projects with different lives [LO 3] The m a n a g e m e n t o f H u n te r A ir Ltd is c o n s id e rin g th e re p la c e m e n t o f its e x is tin g fle e t o f seve n A 6 1 6 a ir c r a ft w ith th re e B 7 2 7 a ir c r a ft. T he fo llo w in g e s tim a te s fo r e a c h a ir c r a ft h a v e b e e n c a lc u la te d : A 6 1 6 a ir c r a ft E stim ate d re m a in in g E stim ates 5 years B 7 2 7 a e ro p la n e s Estim ates Cost $ 5 00 m illio n E stim ated life 10 years life E stim ated scrap value N ow $50 m illio n E stim ate d disposal value In 5 years’ tim e A n n u a l n e t cash flow s $10 m illio n $100 m illio n In 5 years’ tim e $200 m illio n In 10 years’ tim e $100 m illio n A n n u a l n e t cash flow s $200 m illio n M a n a g e m e n t is a ls o a w a r e o f th e d e v e lo p m e n t o f th e C 8 9 8 , w h ic h th e m a n u fa c tu re r e s tim a te s w ill b e a v a ila b le in 5 y e a rs 7 tim e . T h e fo llo w in g e s tim a te s fo r a C 8 9 8 a ir c r a ft h a v e b e e n p r o v id e d b y th e m a n u fa c tu re r. I C 8 9 8 a ir c r a ft E stim ates Cost $600 m illio n E stim a te d life 15 years E stim ate d disposal value A fte r 5 years’ op e ra tio n $200 m illio n A fte r 15 years’ op e ra tio n $50 m illio n A n n u a l n e t cash flow s $250 m illio n It is c o n s id e re d th a t t w o o f th e n e w C 8 9 8 a ir c r a f t w ill b e a d e q u a te to c a r r y th e e s tim a te d n u m b e r o f p a s s e n g e rs . O th e r in fo rm a tio n is a s fo llo w s : i) M a n a g e m e n t c a n n o t fo re s e e a n y fu rth e r d e v e lo p m e n ts b e y o n d th e C 8 9 8 a ir c r a ft. ii) T he a n n u a l n e t c a sh flo w s a re re c e iv e d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r. iii) T he c o m p a n y 's a fte r-ta x c o s t o f c a p ita l is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . iv) T he c o m p a n y 's ta x ra te is 3 0 cen ts. v) T he A 6 1 6 a ir c r a f t a re a s s u m e d to b e fu lly d e p re c ia te d . vi) S tra ig h t-lin e d e p r e c ia tio n m a y b e a ss u m e d . You a re re q u ire d to a d v is e m a n a g e m e n t w h e th e r it s h o u ld : a) re p la c e th e A 6 1 6 a ir c r a ft w ith B 7 2 7 a ir c r a ft n o w , a n d re p la c e th e la tte r w ith C 8 9 8 a ir c r a f t in 5 y e a r s ' tim e b) re ta in th e A 6 1 6 a ir c r a ft fo r 5 y e a rs , a n d th e n re p la c e th e m w ith C 8 9 8 a ir c r a ft c) re p la c e th e A 6 1 6 a ir c r a ft w ith B 7 2 7 a ir c r a ft n o w , a n d re p la c e th e la tte r w ith C 8 9 8 a ir c r a f t in 1 0 y e a r s ' tim e . O th e r a lte rn a tiv e s a r e n o t to b e c o n s id e re d . 15 Mutually exclusive projects with different lives [LO 3] S p e e d y Pty Ltd o p e ra te s a s u b u rb a n d o c u m e n t d e liv e r y bu sin e ss. It is c o n s id e rin g th e r e p la c e m e n t o f a 2 -to n n e tru c k w ith a 3 -to n n e tru c k . D e ta ils o f th e re s p e c tiv e v e h ic le s a re a s fo llo w s : C hapter six T he Rem aining life 5 years Residual value: N ow $6000 In 4 years $0 C H A P T E R SIX R E V I E W 3 -to n n e tru c k E stim ates 2 -to n n e tru c k application of project evaluation methods E stim ates E stim ate d life 6 years Cost $25 000 Residual value a fte r 6 years’ op e ra tio n $2000 D e pre ciatio n (allow able fo r tax $4000 p.a. purposes) W ritte n -d o w n value (fo r ta x $7500 (before purposes) ta xa tio n ) D e pre ciatio n (fo r ta x purposes) $1200 p.a. N et cash flo w (before ta x a tio n ) $ 1 2 0 0 0 p.a. N e t cash flo w $ 2 0 0 0 0 p.a. O th e r in fo rm a tio n is a s fo llo w s : i) N e t c a s h flo w s a re to b e r e g a r d e d a s re c e iv e d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r. ii) T he e ffe c tiv e a fte r-ta x c o s t o f c a p ita l is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . iii) T he c o m p a n y in c o m e ta x ra te is 3 0 c e n ts in th e d o lla r. M a n a g e m e n t is c o n s id e rin g th e fo llo w in g a lte rn a tiv e s : a) R e p la c e th e 2 -to n n e tru c k w ith th e 3 -to n n e tru c k n o w . b) R e p la c e th e 2 -to n n e tru c k w ith th e 3 -to n n e tru c k in 5 y e a r s ' tim e . A ll o th e r a lte rn a tiv e s m a y b e ig n o r e d . A d v is e m a n a g e m e n t as to w h ic h a lte rn a tiv e it s h o u ld a d o p t, a n d ju s tify y o u r a n a ly s is . 16 Replacement decision [LO 4] A c o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g th e in s ta lla tio n o f a n e w m a c h in e a t a c o s t o f $ 6 0 0 0 0 to re p la c e a m a c h in e p u rc h a s e d 7 y e a rs a g o f o r $ 1 0 0 0 0 0 . T he d is p o s a l v a lu e o f th e o ld m a c h in e is $ 1 5 0 0 0 . B oth m a c h in e s w ill h a v e s im ila r o u tp u ts a n d w ill p ro d u c e w o r k o f id e n tic a l q u a lity . T he e s tim a te d y e a r ly costs o f o p e r a tin g e a c h m a c h in e a re as fo llo w s : O ld m a c h in e ($ ) Wages N e w m a c h in e ($ ) 1 15000 5 000 Supplies, repairs, pow er 5000 3 000 Insurance and m iscellaneous 2000 3000 22000 11000 T otal Both m a c h in e s h a v e a n e s tim a te d re m a in in g life o f 3 y e a rs , a t w h ic h tim e b o th m a c h in e s w ill h a v e a n e s tim a te d d is p o s a l v a lu e o f $ 5 0 0 0 . A s s u m e th a t: a) th e re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m b) th e o p e r a tin g costs o f th e o ld m a c h in e a n d th e n e w m a c h in e a r e in c u rre d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r. S h o u ld th e c o m p a n y p u rc h a s e th e n e w m a c h in e , o r c o n tin u e to o p e r a te th e o ld o n e ? 17 Replacement decision [LO 4] T he m a n a g e m e n t o f N e w W o r ld A irlin e s is c o n s id e rin g th e re p la c e m e n t o f its p re s e n t fle e t o f 1 0 p is to n e n g in e p la n e s w ith fiv e tu rb o p ro p s . A s u rv e y ha s re v e a le d th e f o llo w in g e s tim a te s o f costs, a n d so o n , p e r p la n e : Piston e n g in e R em aining life Residual value: E stim ates 5 years T u rb o p ro p E stim ate s Life 5 years Cost $3430000 j 167 I P iston e n g in e E stim ates T u rb o p ro p E stim ate s A t p resent tim e $10000 In 2 years’ tim e $5 000 In 5 years’ tim e $0 A fte r 2 years’ o p e ra tio n 30% o f purchase price $100000 A fte r 5 years’ o p e ra tio n 5% o f purchase price A n n u a l n e t cash flow s a) A n n u a l n e t cash flow s $1000000 Residual value: S h o u ld re p la c e m e n t b e u n d e rta k e n n o w o r in 5 y e a r s 7 tim e ? Im m e d ia te ly a fte r th e d e c is io n ha s b e e n re a c h e d , m a n a g e m e n t is in fo rm e d o f a s u p e rje t th a t w ill b e c o m e a v a ila b le in 2 y e a r s ' tim e . T he e stim a te s fo r th e n e w p la n e a re : S u p e rje t Estim ates Cost $4500000 A n n u a l n e t cash in flo w s $1200000 Life 5 years Residual value a fte r 3% o f purchase price 5 years’ o p e ra tio n It is c o n s id e re d th a t fo u r o f th e n e w s u p e rje ts w ill b e a d e q u a te to c o v e r th e e s tim a te d p a s s e n g e r lo a d . O th e r in fo r m a tio n is as fo llo w s : • M a n a g e m e n t c a n n o t fo re s e e a n y fu rth e r d e v e lo p m e n ts b e y o n d th e s u p e rje t. • A n n u a l n e t c a s h flo w s a r e a s s u m e d to b e re c e iv e d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r. • T he r e q u ir e d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m , b) S h o u ld m a n a g e m e n t: i) re ta in th e p is to n e n g in e p la n e s fo r 5 y e a rs a n d re p la c e th e m w ith su p e rje ts ii) re p la c e th e m im m e d ia te ly w ith tu rb o p ro p s , o p e ra te th e m fo r 5 y e a rs , a n d th e n re p la c e th e m w ith s u p e rje ts iii) re p la c e th e m n o w w ith tu rb o p ro p s , o p e ra te th e m fo r 2 y e a rs , a n d th e n re p la c e th e m w ith su p e rje ts iv) re ta in th e p is to n e n g in e p la n e s fo r 2 y e a rs a n d th e n re p la c e th e m w ith s u p e rje ts? O th e r re p la c e m e n t d a te s a re n o t to b e c o n s id e re d . 18 Replacement decision [LO 4] A .B . Pty Ltd is c u rre n tly o p e r a tin g a s u b u rb a n ta x i-tru c k b u sin e ss. It is c o n s id e rin g th e re p la c e m e n t o f a 1 .5 to n n e v e h ic le w ith a 2 to n n e v e h ic le . D e ta ils o f th e re s p e c tiv e v e h ic le s a re a s fo llo w s : I 1 .5 -to n n e v e h ic le R em aining life Estim ates 4 years Residual value: N ow $4000 2 -to n n e v e h ic le Estim ates E stim ate d life 7 years Cost $15000 Residual value a fte r $1000 7 years’ op e ra tio n In fo u r years A n n u a l n e t cash flo w $0 $6000 N e t cash flo w $10000 C hapter SIX T he APPLICATION 〇F PROJECT EVALUATION METHODS • N e t ca sh flo w s a r e to b e re g a r d e d as re c e iv e d a t th e e n d o f e a c h y e a r. • T he re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . M a n a g e m e n t is c o n s id e rin g th e f o llo w in g a lte rn a tiv e s : a) re p la c e th e 1 .5 to n n e v e h ic le w ith th e 2 to n n e v e h ic le n o w b) re p la c e th e 1 .5 to n n e v e h ic le w ith th e 2 to n n e v e h ic le in 4 y e a r s 7 tim e . A ll o th e r a lte rn a tiv e s m a y b e ig n o r e d . A d v is e m a n a g e m e n t a s to w h ic h a lte r n a tiv e it s h o u ld a d o p t, a n d ju s tify y o u r a n a ly s is . 19 Retirement decision [LO 4 】 P ulp a n d P a p e r Ltd h a s ju st p la n te d p in e tre e s a t a c o s t o f $ 1 2 0 0 0 p e r h e c ta re o n 5 0 0 h e c ta re s o f la n d , w h ic h it p u rc h a s e d fo r $ 4 0 0 0 0 0 . T he tre e s a r e e x p e c te d to g r o w r a p id ly a n d th e c o m p a n y 's e s tim a te s o f th e n e t fu tu re v a lu e o f th e c u t tim b e r a re : T im e o f h a rv e s t e n d N e t fu tu re v a lu e ($ p e r o f year h e c ta re ) 2 17320 3 20000 4 22360 5 24495 6 26450 C H A P T E R SIX R E V I E W O th e r in fo rm a tio n is as fo llo w s : T he re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m a n d ta x e s c a n b e ig n o r e d . a) C a lc u la te th e o p tim u m tim e to h a rv e s t th e c r o p o f tre e s. A s s u m e th a t th e v a lu e o f th e c le a re d la n d in c re a s e s a t a ra te o f 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . b) E stim a te th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f th e p ro je c t, a s s u m in g s a le o f th e la n d a fte r th e tre e s a re h a rv e s te d . N o te a n y a s s u m p tio n s y o u m a k e . 20 Replacement decision [LO 4] A c o m p a n y is c o n s id e r in g th e re p la c e m e n t o f a n o ld m a c h in e w ith a n e w m a c h in e . T he o ld m a c h in e w a s p u rc h a s e d a y e a r a g o f o r $ 1 2 5 0 0 . A d d it io n a l in fo r m a tio n re la tin g to th e se m a c h in e s (cash flo w s a re in n o m in a l term s) is a s fo llo w s : E stim ates O ld m a c h in e ($) Item N e w m a c h in e ($) M a rk e t value (now ) $7000 $5000 Service life (w hen 6 years 5 years $0 $1000 purchased) Residual value in 5 years’ tim e Cash op e ra tin g receipts - $500 p.a. in excess o f o ld m achine T he re a l re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m , a n d th e a n tic ip a te d in fla tio n ra te is 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . C a lc u la te th e n e t p re s e n t v a lu e o f r e p la c in g th e o ld m a c h in e w ith th e n e w m a c h in e . 169 21 Sensitivity analysis [LO 5] M a n a g e m e n t o f R id e Ltd is c o n s id e rin g th e p o s s ib ility o f m a n u fa c tu rin g a n e w m o to ris e d g o lf b u g g y . The in itia l o u tla y f o r th e n e w p la n t to m a n u fa c tu re th e v e h ic le is $1 m illio n . T h e s ta ff o f R id e Ltd h a v e p r o v id e d th e f o llo w in g e s tim a te s fo r th e p ro je c t: Estim ates Item P essim istic Sales (u n its ) S elling price ($) Fixed o p e ra tin g costs p e r a n n u m ($) M o s t lik e ly O p tim is tic 3000 3500 4000 750 800 850 100000 90000 80000 25 24 23 4 5 6 Variable o p e ra tin g costs pe r a n nu m per u n it o f sales ($) Life o f the p la n t (years) A s s u m in g a re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn o f 1 0 p e r c e n t, c o n d u c t a s e n s itiv ity a n a ly s is . W h a t a re th e m a jo r u n c e rta in tie s if th e p r o je c t is u n d e rta k e n ? 22 Break-even analysis [LO 5] T he m a n a g e r o f A ls p o rts Ltd is c o n s id e rin g a p la n to m a n u fa c tu re a lu m in iu m b a s e b a ll b a ts. E q u ip m e n t to m a n u fa c tu re th e b a ts w ill c o s t $ 8 5 0 0 0 0 a n d is e x p e c te d to h a v e a use ful life o f 3 y e a rs . F ix e d costs a re e s tim a te d to b e $ 8 0 0 0 0 p e r a n n u m a n d th e b a ts a r e e x p e c te d to sell fo r $ 4 0 e a c h , w h ile v a r ia b le costs w ill b e $ 2 8 p e r b a t. A b o u t 5 0 0 0 0 0 b a s e b a ll b a ts a re s o ld e a c h y e a r a n d A ls p o rts h a s a re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn o f 1 0 p e r c e n t. C a lc u la te th e b re a k -e v e n sales v o lu m e . 23 Decision-tree analysis [LO 6] P asha B u lk e r Ltd is c o n s id e rin g p r o d u c in g a n e w p ro d u c t. It e x p e c ts th a t th e p r o d u c t w ill h a v e a life o f 1 0 y e a rs , b y w h ic h tim e th e m a rk e t f o r th e p r o d u c t w ill b e s a tu ra te d a n d fh e assets n e c e s s a ry to p ro d u c e it w ill b e s o ld . T h e c o m p a n y is u n c e rta in a s to w h e th e r th e p r o d u c t s h o u ld b e m a n u fa c tu re d o n a la r g e s c a le in a la r g e p la n t, o r o n a s m a ll s c a le in a s m a ll p la n t. If th e c o m p a n y c h o o s e s a s m a ll p la n t, it w o u ld c o n s id e r e x p a n d in g th e p la n t a fte r 3 y e a rs . T he c o m p a n y e s tim a te s th a t th e re is a 5 0 p e r c e n t p r o b a b ilit y th a t a h ig h le ve l o f d e m a n d w ill b e a tta in e d o v e r th e 1 0 y e a rs d u r in g w h ic h th e p r o d u c t w ill b e m a rk e te d , a 2 5 p e r c e n t p r o b a b ilit y th a t d e m a n d w ill b e h ig h d u rin g th e firs t 3 y e a rs a n d th e n d r o p to a lo w le ve l o v e r th e s u c c e e d in g 7 y e a rs , a n d a 2 5 p e r c e n t p r o b a b ilit y th a t a lo w le ve l o f d e m a n d w ill p e rs is t o v e r th e e n tire 1 0 y e a rs . T he f o llo w in g ta b le in d ic a te s th e e x p e c te d a n n u a l n e t c a s h flo w s a n d re s id u a l v a lu e s a s s o c ia te d w ith e a c h s c a le o f p ro d u c tio n a n d le ve l o f d e m a n d : I P o s s ib ilitie s A n n u a l n e t c a sh f lo w ($ ) R e sid u a l v a lu e ($ ) 1 Large p la n t, h ig h dem and 500000 500000 Large p la n t, lo w dem and 150000 200000 Sm all p la n t, h ig h dem and 200000 200000 Sm all p la n t, lo w dem and 150000 100000 Expanded p la n t, h ig h dem and 300000 400000 Expanded p la n t, lo w dem and 100000 150000 T he in itia l c o s t a s s o c ia te d w ith th e c o n s tru c tio n o f a la r g e p la n t is $ 2 m illio n , a n d th a t a s s o c ia te d w ith a sm a ll p la n t is $1 m illio n . T he e x p e c te d c o s t o f e x p a n d in g fro m a s m a ll p la n t to a la r g e p la n t a fte r 3 y e a rs is $1 m illio n . T h e c o m p a n y 's re q u ire d ra te o f re tu rn o f 1 2 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m is re le v a n t fo r a ll a lte rn a tiv e s . a) W h ic h p o lic y s h o u ld th e c o m p a n y p u rsu e ? b) Is it lik e ly th a t th e s a m e d is c o u n t ra te w ill b e a p p r o p r ia te fo r a ll a lte rn a tiv e s ? G iv e re a so n s. C hapter six T he application of project evaluation methods Brown, C. & Davis, K., 'O ptions in mutually exclusive projects of unequal lives', Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Special Issue 1998, pp. 5 6 9 -7 7 . Levin, R.I., Kirkpatrick, C.A. & Rubin, D.S., Quantitative Approaches to Management, 8th edn, M cG raw-Hill, N ew York, 1992, pp. 2 3 1 -7 . Faff, R. & Brailsford, T., 'The constant chain of replacement model and inflation', Pacific Accounting Review, December 1992, pp. 4 5 -5 8 . Pike, R.J., The capital budgeting behaviour and corporate characteristics of capital-constrained firms', Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, W inter 1983, pp. 6 6 3 -7 . C H A P T E R SIX R E V I E W REFERENCES 171 CHAPTER CONTENTS m R e tu rn a n d ris k EB T h e in v e s to r 's u t ilit y fu n c tio n m T h e ris k o f a s s e ts 3 7 I n t r o d u c t io n 6 7 9 7 m g g 3 7 ED EB P o r t f o lio t h e o r y a n d d iv e r s if ic a t io n 179 T h e p r ic in g o f r is k y a s s e ts 190 A d d it io n a l f a c t o r s t h a t e x p la in re tu rn s 19 7 P o r t f o lio p e r f o r m a n c e a p p r a is a l 19 8 LEARNING OBJECTIVES A f t e r s tu d y in g th is c h a p t e r y o u s h o u ld b e a b le to : 1 u n d e r s ta n d h o w r e tu r n a n d r is k a r e d e f in e d a n d m e a s u r e d 2 u n d e r s ta n d th e c o n c e p t o f r is k a v e r s io n b y in v e s to rs 3 e x p la in h o w d iv e r s if ic a t io n r e d u c e s ris k 4 e x p la in th e c o n c e p t o f e f f ic ie n t p o r t f o lio s 5 u n d e r s ta n d th e im p o r t a n c e o f c o v a r ia n c e b e t w e e n re tu rn s o n r is k y a s s e ts in d e t e r m in in g th e r is k o f a p o r t f o lio 6 e x p la in th e d is tin c t io n b e t w e e n s y s te m a tic a n d u n s y s te m a tic r is k 7 e x p la in w h y s y s te m a tic ris k is im p o r t a n t to in v e s to rs 8 e x p la in th e r e la t io n s h ip b e t w e e n re tu rn s a n d ris k p r o p o s e d b y th e c a p it a l a s s e t p r ic in g m o d e l 9 u n d e r s ta n d th e r e la t io n s h ip b e t w e e n th e c a p it a l a s s e t p r ic in g m o d e l a n d m o d e ls t h a t in c lu d e a d d i t i o n a l fa c to r s 1 0 e x p la in th e d e v e lo p m e n t o f m o d e ls t h a t in c lu d e a d d i t i o n a l f a c to r s 11 d is tin g u is h b e t w e e n a lt e r n a t iv e m e th o d s o f a p p r a is in g th e p e r f o r m a n c e o f a n in v e s tm e n t p o r t f o lio . C hapter seven Risk a n d return Introduction A fin a n c ia l d e c is io n ty p ic a lly in v o lv e s r isk . F o r e x a m p le , a c o m p a n y t h a t b o r r o w s m o n e y f a c e s th e r is k th a t in t e r e s t r a t e s m a y c h a n g e , a n d a c o m p a n y t h a t b u ild s a n e w f a c t o r y f a c e s th e r i s k t h a t p r o d u c t s a l e s m a y b e lo w e r th a n e x p e c te d . T h e se a n d m a n y o t h e r d e c is io n s in v o lv e fu t u r e c a s h flo w s t h a t a r e risk y . In v e s t o r s g e n e r a lly d is lik e r i s k , b u t th e y a re a ls o u n a b le to a v o id it. Th e v a lu a t io n f o r m u la e fo r s h a r e s a n d d e b t s e c u r itie s o u tlin e d in C h a p t e r 4 sh o w e d t h a t th e p ric e o f a r is k y a s s e t d e p e n d s o n i t s e x p e c t e d fu tu r e c a s h flo w s, th e tim e v a lu e o f m o n e y , a n d r isk . H o w ev e r, little a t t e n t i o n w a s p a id to th e c a u s e s o f r i s k o r to h o w r is k s h o u ld b e d e fin e d a n d m e a s u r e d . T o m a k e e ffe c tiv e fin a n c ia l d e c is io n s , m a n a g e r s n e e d to u n d e r s t a n d w h a t c a u s e s r is k , h o w i t s h o u ld b e m e a s u r e d a n d th e e ffe c t o f r is k o n th e r a te o f r e t u r n r e q u ir e d b y in v e s t o r s . T h e se i s s u e s a r e d is c u s s e d in t h is c h a p te r u s in g th e fr a m e w o r k o f p o r t f o lio th e o r y , w h ic h s h o w s h o w in v e s t o r s c a n m a x im is e th e e x p e c te d r e tu r n o n a p o r t f o lio o f r is k y a s s e t s fo r a g iv e n le v e l o f r isk . Th e r e la t io n s h ip b e t w e e n r is k a n d e x p e c te d r e tu r n is fir s t d e s c r ib e d b y th e c a p it a l a s s e t p r ic in g m o d e l (C A P M ), w h ic h lin k s e x p e c t e d r e t u r n to a sin g le so u r c e o f r is k , a n d s e c o n d , b y m o d e ls t h a t in c lu d e a d d it io n a l f a c t o r s to e x p la in r e t u r n s . To u n d e r s ta n d th e m a t e r ia l in t h is c h a p t e r i t i s n e c e s s a r y to u n d e r s t a n d w h a t is m e a n t b y re tu rn a n d risk. T h e re fo re , w e b e g in b y d i s c u s s i n g t h e s e c o n c e p ts . 7.2 Return and risk The re tu r n o n a n in v e s t m e n t a n d th e r i s k o f a n i n v e s t m e n t a r e b a s ic c o n c e p t s in fin a n c e . R e tu r n o n a n in v e s t m e n t is th e fin a n c ia l o u t c o m e f o r th e in v e sto r . F o r e x a m p le , i f s o m e o n e i n v e s t s $ 1 0 0 in a n a s s e t a n d s u b s e q u e n t ly s e lls t h a t a s s e t f o r $ 1 1 1 , th e d o lla r retu rn is $ 1 1 . U su a lly a n i n v e s t m e n t s d o lla r r e t u r n is L E A R N IN G O B JEC TIVE 1 U nde rstand h o w return c o n v e r te d to a ra te o f retu rn b y c a lc u la tin g th e p r o p o r t io n o r p e r c e n ta g e r e p r e s e n t e d b y th e d o lla r r e tu r n . a n d risk are defined F o r e x a m p le , a d o lla r r e t u r n o f $ 1 1 o n a n in v e s t m e n t o f $ 1 0 0 is a r a t e o f r e t u r n o f $ 1 1 / $ 1 0 0 , w h ic h is a n d m easured 0 .1 1 , o r 1 1 p e r c e n t. In th e r e m a in d e r o f t h is c h a p t e r th e w o rd re tu rn is u s e d to m e a n ra te o f re tu rn . R isk is p r e s e n t w h e n e v e r i n v e s t o r s a r e n o t c e r ta in a b o u t th e o u t c o m e s a n in v e s t m e n t w ill p r o d u c e . S u p p o s e , h o w e v e r, t h a t in v e s t o r s c a n a t ta c h a p r o b a b ility t o e a c h p o s s ib le d o lla r r e t u r n t h a t m a y o ccu r. In v e sto r s c a n t h e n d r a w u p a p r o b a b ility d is tr ib u t io n f o r th e d o lla r r e t u r n s fr o m th e in v e s t m e n t . A p ro b ab ility d istrib u tio n is a l is t o f th e p o s s ib le d o lla r r e t u r n s f r o m th e in v e s t m e n t t o g e t h e r w ith th e p r o b a b ility o f e a c h r e tu r n . F o r e x a m p le , a s s u m e t h a t th e p r o b a b ilit y d is t r ib u t io n in T a b le 7 .1 i s a n i n v e s t o r s a s s e s s m e n t o f th e d o lla r r e t u r n s t h a t m a y b e re c e iv e d f r o m h o ld in g a s h a r e in a c o m p a n y fo r 1 year. TABLE 7.1 D o lla r re tu rn , Rt ($ ) P ro b a b ility , P, 9 0.1 10 0 .2 11 0 .4 12 0 .2 13 0 .1 S u p p o s e th e in v e s t o r w is h e s to s u m m a r is e t h is d is t r ib u t io n b y c a lc u la tin g tw o m e a s u r e s , o n e to r e p r e s e n t th e s iz e o f th e d o lla r r e t u r n s a n d th e o t h e r to r e p r e s e n t th e r i s k in v o lv e d . Th e s iz e o f th e d o lla r r e t u r n s m a y b e m e a s u r e d b y th e e x p e c t e d v a lu e o f th e d is t r ib u t io n . Th e e x p e c t e d v a lu e E (R ) o f th e d o lla r r e t u r n s is g iv e n b y th e w e ig h te d a v e r a g e o f all th e p o s s ib le d o lla r r e t u r n s , u s i n g th e p r o b a b ilit ie s a s w e ig h t s — t h a t is: E (R ) = ($ 9 ) (0 .1 ) + ( $ 1 0 ) ( 0 .2 ) + ($ 1 1 ) (0 .4 ) + ($ 1 2 ) (0 .2 ) + ( $ 1 3 ) (0 .1 ) = $11 In general, the expected return on an investment can be calculated as: w h ic h c a n b e w r it t e n a s fo llo w s: n E{R) = Y ^ R iP i i= l The c h o ic e o f a m e a s u r e f o r r is k is l e s s o b v io u s . In t h is e x a m p le , r i s k is p r e s e n t b e c a u s e a n y o n e o f fiv e o u t c o m e s ($ 9 , $ 1 0 , $ 1 1 , $ 1 2 o r $ 1 3 ) m ig h t r e s u lt fr o m th e i n v e s t m e n t . I f th e i n v e s t o r h a d p e r fe c t fo r e s ig h t , th e n o n ly o n e p o s s ib l e o u tc o m e w o u ld b e in v o lv e d , a n d th e r e w o u ld n o t b e a p r o b a b ility d i s t r ib u t io n t o b e c o n s id e r e d . T h is s u g g e s t s t h a t r i s k is r e la t e d to th e d is p e r s io n o f th e d is tr ib u t io n . The VARIANCE m easure of variability; the m ean of the squared deviations from the m ean or expected value m o r e d i s p e r s e d o r w id e s p r e a d th e d is tr ib u t io n , th e g r e a t e r th e r is k in v o lv e d . S t a t i s t i c i a n s h a v e d e v e lo p e d a n u m b e r o f m e a s u r e s to r e p r e s e n t d is p e r s io n . T h e se m e a s u r e s in c lu d e th e r a n g e , th e m e a n a b s o lu t e d e v ia tio n a n d th e v a r ia n c e . H o w e v e r, it is g e n e r a lly a c c e p te d t h a t in m o s t in s t a n c e s t h e i t s s q u a r e r o o t, th e stan d ard deviation, a) is variance (o r th e m o s t u s e f u l m e a s u r e . A c c o rd in g ly , t h is m e a s u r e o f d i s p e r s io n is th e o n e w e w ill u s e to r e p r e s e n t th e r is k o f a s in g le in v e s t m e n t . T h e v a r ia n c e o f a d is tr ib u t io n STANDARD DEVIATION o f d o lla r r e t u r n s is th e w e ig h te d a v e r a g e o f th e s q u a r e o f e a c h d o lla r r e t u r n s d e v ia tio n f r o m th e e x p e c te d square root of the d o lla r r e t u r n , a g a in u s i n g th e p r o b a b ilit ie s a s th e w e ig h ts . F o r th e s h a r e c o n s id e r e d in T a b le 7 .1 , th e varian ce v a r ia n c e is: cr2 = (9-11)2(0.1) + (10-11)2(0.2) + (11-11)2(0.4) + (12-11)2(0.2) + (13 - 11)2(0.1) = 1.2 In g e n e r a l th e v a r ia n c e c a n b e c a lc u la te d a s: 〇2 - [/?, -£(/?)]2p, + [R2 - E ( R ) Y P 2 + ... + [/?„-£(/?)]2p„ w h ic h c a n b e w r it t e n a s fo llo w s: n o2 = J 2 ^ R' ~ E(R^ 2pi i= l In t h is c a s e th e v a r ia n c e is 1 .2 s o th e s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n is: a = \/L 2 = $ 1 .0 9 5 In t h e s e c a lc u la tio n s w e h a v e u s e d d o lla r r e t u r n s r a t h e r t h a n r e t u r n s m e a s u r e d in th e fo r m o f a ra te . T h is is b e c a u s e i t is g e n e r a lly e a s ie r to v is u a lis e d o lla r s t h a n r a t e s , a n d b e c a u s e i t a v o id s c a lc u la tio n s w ith a la r g e n u m b e r o f z e r o s fo llo w in g th e d e c im a l p o in t . H o w e v e r, th e r e is n o d iffe r e n c e in s u b s t a n c e , a s m a y b e s e e n f r o m r e w o r k in g th e e x a m p le u s i n g r e t u r n s in r a te fo r m . I f th e s u m in v e s t e d is $ 1 0 0 , th e n a d o lla r r e tu r n o f $ 9 , f o r e x a m p le , is a r e t u r n o f 0 .0 9 w h e n e x p r e s s e d a s a ra te . T a b le 7 .2 sh o w s r a t e s o f r e t u r n t h a t c o r r e s p o n d to th e d o lla r r e t u r n s in T a b le 7 .1 . TABLE 7.2 R etu rn, P ro b a b ility , P, 0 .0 9 0 .1 0 .1 0 0 .2 0 .1 1 0 .4 0 .1 2 0 .2 0 .1 3 0 .1 U s i n g r a t e s , th e e x p e c t e d r e t u r n E (R ) is: E (R ) = (0 .0 9 ) (0 .1 ) + (0 .1 0 ) (0 .2 ) + ( 0 .1 1 ) ( 0 .4 ) + (0 .1 2 ) (0 .2 ) + (0 .1 3 ) (0 .1 ) = 0.11 = 11% C hapter seven Risk The v a r ia n c e o f r e t u r n s is: a 2 = (0.09-0 .1 1 )2(0.1) + (0 .1 0 -0 .1 1 )2(0.2) + (0.11-0 .1 1 )2(0.4) + (0 .1 2 -0 .1 1 )2(0.2) + ( 0 . 1 3 - 0 . 1 1 ) 2( 0 . 1 ) = 0 .0 0 0 12 The s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f r e t u r n s is t h e r e fo r e : ct= v/0.00012 = 0 .0 1 0 9 5 = 1 .0 9 5 % It is o ft e n a s s u m e d t h a t a n i n v e s t m e n t s d is t r ib u t io n o f r e t u r n s fo llo w s a n o r m a l d is tr ib u t io n . T h is is a c o n v e n ie n t a s s u m p t i o n b e c a u s e a n o r m a l d is t r ib u t io n c a n b e fu lly d e s c r ib e d b y i t s e x p e c t e d v a lu e a n d s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n . T h e r e fo re , a n i n v e s t m e n t s d is t r ib u t io n o f r e t u r n s c a n b e fu lly d e s c r ib e d b y i t s e x p e c te d r e t u r n a n d r is k . A s s u m i n g t h a t r e t u r n s fo llo w a n o r m a l p r o b a b ility d is tr ib u t io n , th e t a b le o f a r e a s u n d e r th e s t a n d a r d n o r m a l c u rv e (s e e T a b le 5 o f A p p e n d ix A ) c a n b e u s e d t o c a lc u la te th e p r o b a b ility th a t th e in v e s t m e n t w ill g e n e r a t e a r e tu r n g r e a t e r t h a n o r l e s s t h a n a n y s p e c ifie d r e tu r n . F o r e x a m p le , s u p p o s e t h a t th e r e t u r n s o n a n in v e s t m e n t in C o m p a n y A a r e n o r m a lly d is tr ib u t e d , w ith a n e x p e c t e d r e tu r n o f 1 3 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m a n d a s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f 1 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . S u p p o s e a n in v e s t o r in th e c o m p a n y w ish e s to c a lc u la te th e p r o b a b ilit y o f a l o s s — t h a t is , th e in v e s t o r w is h e s to c a lc u la te th e p r o b a b ility o f a r e tu r n o f l e s s th a n z e r o p e r c e n t. A r e t u r n o f z e r o p e r c e n t is 1 .3 s t a n d a r d d e v ia t io n s b e lo w th e e x p e c te d r e t u r n (b e c a u s e 0 .1 3 / 0 .1 0 = 1 .3 ). F ig u r e 7 .1 illu s t r a t e s t h is c a s e . Th e s h a d e d a r e a r e p r e s e n t s th e p r o b a b ility o f a lo s s . Th e ta b le o f a r e a s u n d e r th e s t a n d a r d n o r m a l c u r v e (T a b le 5, A p p e n d ix A o r th e N O R M S D IS T f u n c tio n in M ic r o s o ft E x c e l*) in d ic a t e s t h a t th e p r o b a b ility o f a l o s s o c c u r r in g is 0 .0 9 6 8 o r a lm o s t 9 .7 p e r c e n t. T o h ig h lig h t th e i m p o r t a n c e o f th e s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f th e r e t u r n d is tr ib u t io n , a s s u m e t h a t th e s a m e in v e s t o r a ls o h a s th e o p p o r t u n it y o f in v e s t in g in C o m p a n y B w ith a n e x p e c t e d r e t u r n o f 1 3 p e r c e n t a n d a s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f 6 .9 1 p e r c e n t. Th e p r o b a b ility d i s t r ib u t io n s o f th e r e t u r n s o n in v e s t m e n t s in c o m p a n ie s A a n d B a re s h o w n in F ig u r e 7 .2 . B o th in v e s t m e n t s h a v e t h e s a m e e x p e c t e d r e tu r n b u t, o n th e b a s i s o f th e d is p e r s io n o f th e r e t u r n s , a n in v e s t m e n t in C o m p a n y A (w ith a s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f 1 0 p e r c e n t) is r is k ie r t h a n a n in v e s t m e n t in C o m p a n y B (w ith a s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f 6 .9 1 p e r c e n t). S u p p o s e t h a t th e in v e s t o r d e c id e s t h a t a r e t u r n o f z e r o p e r c e n t o r l e s s i s u n s a t is f a c t o r y . A r e tu r n o f z e r o p e r c e n t o n a n in v e s t m e n t in C o m p a n y B is 1 .8 8 s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n s b e lo w th e e x p e c t e d r e tu r n (b e c a u se 0 . 1 3 / 0 .0 6 9 1 = 1 .8 8 ). Th e p r o b a b ilit y o f t h is o c c u r r in g is 0 .0 3 . T h e r e fo re , th e p r o b a b ilit y t h a t a n in v e s t m e n t in o n e o f t h e s e c o m p a n ie s w ill g e n e r a t e a n e g a tiv e r e t u r n is 3 p e r c e n t fo r C o m p a n y B c o m p a r e d w ith 9 .7 p e r c e n t f o r C o m p a n y A . H o w e v e r, w h e n th e i n v e s t o r c o n s id e r s r e t u r n s a t th e u p p e r e n d o f th e d i s t r ib u t io n s i t i s fo u n d t h a t a n i n v e s t m e n t in C o m p a n y A o f f e r s a 9 .7 p e r c e n t c h a n c e o f a a n d return B usiness finance Figure 7.2 RISK-AVERSE INVESTOR an investor who dislikes risk and who will only choose a risky investment if the expected return is high enough to compensate for bearing the risk retu rn in excess o f 26 per cent, compared w ith only a 3 per cent chance fo r an investm ent in Company B. In summ ary the p robability o f both very low returns and very high returns is much greater in the case o f Company A. The fact th a t the investor is more uncertain about the retu rn from an investm ent in Company A does n o t mean th a t the investor w ill necessarily prefer to invest in Company B. The choice depends on the investors a ttitude to risk. A lternative attitudes to risk and the effects o f risk are considered in the next section, which can safely be o m itte d by readers who are prepared to accept th a t investors are generally risk averse. Risk aversion does not mean th a t an investor w ill refuse to bear any risk at all. Rather i t means th a t an investor regards risk as something undesirable, b ut which may be w o rth tolerating i f the expected retu rn is sufficient to compensate fo r the risk. Therefore, a ris k -a v e rs e in v e s to r would prefer to invest in Company B because A and B offer the same expected return, b u t B is less risky. 7.3 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Understand the concept of risk aversion by investors RISK-NEUTRAL INVESTOR an investor who neither likes nor dislikes risk RISK-SEEKING INVESTOR an investor who likes risk and who will choose a risky investment even if the expected return is less than the expected return on a less risky investment The investor’s utility function Consider the decision to invest in either Company A or Company B. As discussed in Section 7.2, both companies offer the same expected return, b ut differ in risk. A preference fo r investing in either Company A or Company B w ill depend on the investors a ttitude to risk. An investor may be risk averse, risk neutral o r risk seeking. A risk-averse investor attaches decreasing u tility to each increm ent in wealth; a risk -n eu tral in vestor attaches equal u tility to each increm ent in wealth; while a risk -seek in g investor attaches increasing u tility to each increm ent in wealth. Typical u tility -to -w e a lth functions fo r each type o f investor are illustrated in Figure 7.3. The characteristics o f a risk-averse investor w arrant closer examination, as risk aversion is the standard assumption in finance theory. Assume th a t a risk-averse investor has wealth o f $ W* and has the o p p o rtu n ity o f p articipating in the follow ing game: a fa ir coin is tossed and i f it falls tails (probability 0.5), then $1000 is won; i f i t falls heads (probability 0.5), then $1000 is lost. The expected value o f the game is $0 and it is, therefore, described as a *fair game*. Would a risk-averse investor participate in such a game? I f he or she participates and wins, wealth w ill increase to $(PV* + 1000), b ut i f he or she loses, wealth w ill fall to $(PV* - 1000). The results o f this game are shown in Figure 7.4. The investors current level o f u tility is U2. The investors u tility w ill increase to U3 i f he or she wins the game and w ill decrease to [7Xin the event o f a loss. W hat is the expected u tility i f the investor decides to participate in the game? There is a 50 per cent chance th a t his or her u tility w ill increase to U3, and a 50 per cent chance th a t i t w ill decrease to Uv Therefore, the expected u tility is 0 . 5 ^ + 0.5U3. As shown in Figure 7.4, the investors expected u tility w ith the gamble (0.5U1 + 0.5U3) is lower than the u tility obtained w ith o u t the gamble (U2). As it is assumed th a t investors maximise th e ir expected u tility , a riskaverse investor would refuse to participate in this game. In fact, a risk-averse investor may be defined as C hapter seven Risk a n d return ure 7.3 Utility-to-wealth functions for different types of investors Risk seeking Risk neutral IM ln ir un Wealth (W ) 1 someone who would n ot participate in a fa ir game. Similarly, it can be shown th a t a risk-neutral investor would be indifferent to participation, and a risk-seeking investor would be prepared to pay fo r the rig h t to participate in a fa ir game. Now consider the preferences o f a risk-averse investor w ith respect to an investm ent in either Company A or Company B. As we have seen, the expected retu rn from each investm ent is the same but the investment in A is riskier. An investm ent in A offers the possibility o f making either higher returns or lower returns, compared w ith an investm ent in B. However, from Figure 7.2, the increased spread o f returns above the expected retu rn tends to increase expected u tility . But this increase w ill be outweighed by the decrease in expected u tility resulting from the greater spread o f returns below the expected return. Therefore, the risk-averse investors expected u tility would be greater i f he or she invests in B. As both investments offer the same expected return, the risk-averse investors choice implies th a t the increased dispersion o f returns makes an investm ent riskier. This suggests th a t the standard deviation o f the return distribu tio n may be a useful measure o f risk fo r a risk-averse investor. Similarly, it can be argued th a t the risk-neutral investor would be ind iffe re nt between these tw o investments. For any given amount to be invested, such an investor w ill always choose the investm ent th a t offers the higher return, 命 B usiness finance irrespective o f the relative risk o f other investm ents— th a t is, the standard deviation is ignored. The risk­ seeking investor would choose to invest in A. I f a given am ount is to be invested, and the investor has the choice o f two investments th a t offer the same expected return, the risk-seeking investor w ill always choose the investm ent w ith the higher risk. An investors preferences regarding expected retu rn and risk can be illustrated using indifference curves. For a given am ount invested, an indifference curve traces out all those combinations o f expected return and risk th a t provide a particular investor w ith the same level o f u tility . Because the level o f u tility is the same, the investor is indifferent between all points on the curve. A risk-averse investor has a positive attitude towards expected retu rn and a negative a ttitude towards risk. By this, we mean th a t a risk-averse investor w ill prefer an investm ent to have a higher expected retu rn (for a given risk level) and lower risk (for a given expected return). Risk aversion does not mean th a t an investor w ill refuse to bear any risk at all. Rather it means th a t an investor regards risk as something undesirable, b u t which may be w o rth tolerating i f the expected return is sufficient to compensate fo r the risk. In graphical terms, indifference curves fo r a risk-averse investor m ust be upward sloping as shown in Figure 7.5. The risk-re tu rn coordinates fo r a risk-averse investor are shown in Figure 7.5 fo r three investments— A, B and C. I t is apparent that this investor would prefer Investment B to Investment A, and would also prefer Investment B to Investment C. This investor prefers a higher expected return at any given level o f risk (compare investments B and A) and a lower level o f risk at any given expected return (compare investments B and C). However, this investor would be indifferent between investments A and C. The higher expected return on investm ent C compensates this investor exactly fo r the higher risk. In addition, fo r a given expected return the expected u tility o f a risk-averse investor falls at an increasing rate as the dispersion o f the distribution o f returns increases. As a result, the rate o f increase in expected return required to compensate for every increment in the standard deviation increases faster as the risk becomes larger. Note that indifference curves for a risk-averse investor are n ot only upward sloping, but also convex, as shown in Figure 7.5. So far we have concentrated on the characteristics and behaviour o f a risk-averse investor. However, there are instances where individuals behave in a way contrary to risk aversion. For example, a risk-averse person w ill never purchase a lo tte ry ticket, as the expected value o f the gamble is less than the price o f the ticket. However, many individuals whose current level o f wealth is quite low relative to the lo tte ry prize are prepared to purchase lo tte ry tickets because, w hile only a small outlay is required, there is the small chance o f achieving a relatively large increase in wealth. In decisions th a t involve larger outlays, risk aversion is much more likely. As the financial decisions considered in this book generally involve Figure 7.5 Increasing utility | 0) EIRB) = EIRC) J I 肌 ) °C aA = aB Risk (o) C hapter seven Risk a n d return large investments and small rates o f retu rn (at least relative to w inning a lo tte ry prize), i t is assumed throughout that investors behave as i f they are risk averse. 7.4 The risk of assets I f investors, expectations o f the returns from an investm ent can be represented by a norm al probability distribution, then the standard deviation is a relevant measure o f risk fo r a risk-averse investor. I f two investments offer the same expected return, b ut differ in risk, then a risk-averse investor w ill prefer the less risky investm ent. Further, it has been shown th a t a risk-averse investor is prepared to accept higher risk fo r higher expected return, w ith the result th a t the required retu rn on a particular investm ent increases w ith the investors perception o f its risk. The standard deviation o f the retu rn from a single investm ent is a relevant measure o f its riskiness in cases where an individual is considering the investm ent o f all available funds in one asset. However, it is exceptional to lim it investm ents in this way. M ost people invest in a num ber o f assets; they may invest in a house, a car, th e ir human capital and numerous other assets. In addition, where they invest in shares, i t is likely th a t they w ill hold shares in a num ber o f companies. In other words, people typically invest th e ir wealth in a p o rtfolio o f assets and w ill be concerned about the risk o f th e ir overall p ortfo lio . This risk can be measured by the standard deviation o f the returns on the p o rtfo lio . Therefore, when an individual asset is considered, an investor w ill be concerned about the risk o f th a t asset as a component o f a p o rtfo lio o f assets. W hat we need to know is how individual p o rtfo lio components (assets) contribute to the risk o f the p o rtfo lio as a whole. An apparently plausible guess would be th a t the co ntribu tion o f each asset is p ro p o rtio n a l to the assets standard deviation. However, p o rtfo lio theory, w hich is discussed in the next section, shows th a t this guess turns o ut to be alm ost always incorrect. 7.5 PORTFOLIO combined holding of more than one asset Portfolio theory and diversification m Portfolio theory was in itia lly developed by M arkow itz (1952) as a norm ative approach to investm ent choice under uncertainty.1 Two im p o rta n t assumptions o f p o rtfo lio theory have already been discussed. These are: a The returns from investments are norm ally distributed. Therefore, two parameters, the expected return and the standard deviation, are sufficient to describe the d istrib u tio n o f returns.2 b Investors are risk averse. Therefore, investors prefer the highest expected retu rn fo r a given standard deviation and the lowest standard deviation fo r a given expected return. Given these assumptions, it can be shown th a t i t is rational fo r a utility-m axim isin g investor to hold a well-diversified p o rtfo lio o f investments. Suppose th a t an investor holds a p o rtfo lio o f securities. This investor w ill be concerned about the expected retu rn and risk o f the p ortfolio. The expected retu rn on a portfolio is a weighted average o f the expected returns on the securities in the p ortfolio. Let E(Rt) be the expected return on the zth security and E(Rp) the expected retu rn on a p o rtfo lio o f securities. Then, using the n otation introduced earlier: n E(R„) = ^ 2 w iE(Ri) i= \ where = the proportion o f the to ta l current m arket value o f the p o rtfo lio constituted by the current m arket value o f the zth security— th a t is, it is the ‘w eight’ attached to the security n = the number o f securities in the p ortfo lio Calculation o f the expected return on a p o rtfo lio is illustrated in Example 7.1. 1 2 For a more extensive treatment, see Markowitz (1959). Other parameters may exist if the distribution is non-normal. In this case it is assumed that investors base decisions on expected return and standard deviation and ignore other features such as skewness. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Explain how diversification reduces risk Example 7.1 A s s u m e th a t th e re a r e o n ly t w o s e c u ritie s (1 a n d 2 ) in a p o r tf o lio a n d E(R}) = 0 . 0 8 a n d E(/?2) = 〇• 1 2 . A ls o a s s u m e th a t th e c u r r e n t m a rk e t v a lu e o f S e c u rity 1 is 6 0 p e r c e n t o f th e to ta l c u rre n t m a rk e t v a lu e o f th e p o r tf o lio (th a t is, w 1 = 0 . 6 a n d w 2 = 0 . 4 ) . T h e n : E(/?p) = ( 0 . 6 ) ( 0 .0 8 ) + ( 0 . 4 ) ( 0 .1 2 ) = 0 . 0 9 6 o r 9 .6 % Example 7.1 illustrates the fact th a t the expected retu rn on a p o rtfo lio is sim ply the weighted average o f the expected returns on the securities in the p ortfo lio . However, the standard deviation o f the return on the p o rtfo lio (c p) is not sim ply a weighted average o f the standard deviations o f the securities in the p ortfo lio . This is because the riskiness o f a p o rtfo lio depends n ot only on the riskiness o f the individual securities b ut also on the relationship between the returns on those securities. The variance o f the return on a p o rtfo lio o f two securities is given by: # = 4 cr| + 2 Cov(/?卜 i?2) where Cov(Rv R2) = the covariance between the returns on securities 1 and 2 The covariance between the returns on any pair o f securities is a measure o f the extent to which the returns on those securities tend to move together or covary*. This tendency is more commonly measured using the correlation coefficient p, which is found by dividing the covariance between the returns on the tw o securities by the standard deviations o f th e ir returns. Therefore, the correlation coefficient for securities 1 and 2 is: Pi,2 = Cov(/?i,/?2) 7.3 The correlation coefficient is essentially a scaled measure o f covariance and it is a very convenient measure because it can only have values between +1 and -1 . I f the correlation coefficient between the returns on two securities is +1, the returns are said to be perfectly positively correlated. This means th a t i f the retu rn on security z is ^ ig h 1(compared w ith its expected level), then the retu rn on se curity; w ill, unfailingly, also be ‘high’ ( compared w ith fts expected level) to precisely the same degree. I f the correlation coefficient is -1 , the returns are perfectly negatively correlated; high (low) returns on security i w ill always be paired w ith low (high) returns on security A correlation coefficient o f zero indicates the absence of a systematic relationship between the returns on the tw o securities. Using Equation 7.3 to substitute for the covariance, Equation 7.2 can be expressed as: = w \ 〇\ -f- W2 O 2 + 2 W \W 2 P \ 2 (J \ (T2 7.4 As may be seen from Equation 7.4, the variance o f a p o rtfo lio depends on: a b c the com position o f the p o rtfo lio — th a t is, the p roportion o f the current m arket value o f the p o rtfo lio constituted by each security the standard deviation o f the returns fo r each security the correlation between the returns on the securities held in the p ortfo lio . The effect o f changing the composition o f a p o rtfo lio o f tw o securities is illustrated in Example 7.2. 7.5.1 I Gains from diversification Example 7.2 shows th a t some portfolios enable an investor to achieve simultaneously higher expected retu rn and lower risk; fo r example, compare portfolios (d) and (f) in Figure 7.6. It should be noted th a t Portfolio (d) consists o f both securities, whereas Portfolio (f) consists o f only Security 1— th a t is, Portfolio (d) is diversified, whereas Portfolio (f) is not. This illustrates the general principle th a t investors can gain from diversification. C hapter seven Risk a n d return E xample 7.2 A n in v e s to r w is h e s to c o n s tru c t a p o r tf o lio c o n s is tin g o f S e c u rity 1 a n d S e c u rity 2 . T h e e x p e c te d re tu rn s o n th e tw o s e c u ritie s a r e E(R}) = 8 % p .a . a n d E(R2) = 1 2 % p .a . a n d th e s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n s a re = 2 0 % p .a . a n d a 2 = 3 0 % p .a . T he c o r r e la tio n c o e ffic ie n t b e tw e e n th e ir re tu rn s is p ] 2 = - 〇.5. The in v e s to r is fre e to c h o o s e th e in v e s tm e n t p r o p o r tio n s w ] a n d w 2/ s u b je c t o n ly to th e re q u ire m e n ts th a t + w 2 = 1 a n d th a t b o th a n d vv2 a r e p o s itiv e .3 T h e re is n o lim it to th e n u m b e r o f p o r tfo lio s th a t m e e t th e se re q u ire m e n ts , s in c e th e re is n o lim it to th e n u m b e r o f p r o p o r tio n s th a t sum to 1. T h e re fo re , a re p re s e n ta tiv e s e le c tio n o f v a lu e s is c o n s id e r e d fo r W ]: 0 , 0 . 2 , 0 . 4 , 0 . 6 , 0 . 8 a n d 1. U s in g E q u a tio n 7 . 1 , th e e x p e c te d re tu rn o n a tw o -s e c u rity p o r tf o lio is: E(/?p) = w .E iR ,) + w 2E(R2) = w ^ O .0 8 ) + w 2( 0 . 1 2 ) U s in g E q u a tio n 7 . 4 , th e v a r ia n c e o f th e re tu rn o n a tw o -s e c u rity p o r tf o lio is: ap = = + w^ + 2w 1vv2Pir2a l °2 w2(〇.20)2 + w2(0.30)2 + 2Wl w2(-0.5)(0.20)(0.30) = 0.04w^ + 0.09w^ - 0.06W] vv2 T he s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n o f th e p o r tf o lio re tu rn s is fo u n d b y ta k in g th e s q u a re r o o t o f a . E a ch p a ir o f p r o p o r tio n s is n o w c o n s id e r e d in tu rn : a) w 1 = 0 and w 2 = 1 q /y = (o .〇 8 i( o ) + ( o .i 2 )⑴ = 0 . 1 2 o r 1 2 % p .a . 〇 p = (〇.〇4)(0)2 + (0.09)(1)2 -(0.06)(0)(1) o2 p = 0.09 〇 b) p - 0.30 or 30% p.a. W! = 0 . 2 a n d w 2 = 0 . 8 E(Rp) = ( 0 . 0 8 ) ( 0 . 2 ) + ( 0 . 1 2 ) ( 0 . 8 ) = 0 . 1 1 2 o r 1 1 . 2 % p .a . o2 p = (0.04)(0.2)2 + (0.09)(0.8)2 -(0.06)(0.2)(0.8) o2 p = 0.0496 .-.〇 p = 0.2227 or 22.27% p.a. c) d) W l = 0 . 4 a n d w 2 = 0 . 6 E[Rp) = ( 0 . 0 8 ) ( 0 . 4 ) + ( 0 . 1 2 ) ( 0 . 6 ) = 0 . 1 0 4 o r 1 0 . 4 % p .a . 〇 p = (〇.〇4)(0.2)2 + (0.09)(0.6)2 -(0.06)(0.4)(0.6) 〇 p = 0.0244 〇 p = 0.1562 or 15.62% p.a. W l = 0 . 6 a n d w 2 = 0 . 4 E(/?p) = ( 0 . 0 8 ) ( 0 . 6 ) + ( 0 . 1 2 ) ( 0 . 4 ) = 0 . 0 9 6 o r 9 . 6 % p .a . 〇 l = (0.04)(0.6)2 + (0.09)(0.4)2 -(0.06)(0.6)(0.4) =0.0144 = 0.12 or 12% p.a. e) vvt = 0 . 8 a n d w 2 = 0 . 2 E(/?p) = ( 0 . 0 8 ) ( 0 . 8 ) + ( 0 . 1 2 ) ( 0 . 2 ) = 0 . 0 8 8 o r 8 .8 % p .a . a2 p = (0.04)(0.8)2 + (0.09)(0.2)2 - (0.06)(0.8)(0.2) =0.0196 〇 p = 0.14 or 14% p.a. continued 3 Negative investment proportions would indicate a short sale', which means that the asset is first sold and later purchased. Therefore, a short-seller benefits from price decreases. ^0^ B usiness finance continued f) vvt = 1 . 0 a n d w 2 = 0 E(/?p) = ( 0 . 0 8 ) ( 1 ) + ( 0 .1 2 ) ( 0 ) = 0 . 0 8 o r 8 % p .a . 〇l = (〇 .〇 4 ) ( l) 2 + (0 .0 9 )(0 )2 - ( 0 . 0 6 ) ( l) ( 0 ) 〇 p = 0.04 〇 p = 0.20 or 20% p.a. T h e se re su lts a r e s u m m a ris e d in T a b le 7 . 3 . TA B LE 7 .3 P o rtfo lio (a) (b) (Cl (d) (e) (f) Proportion in Security 1 (Wj) 0.0000 0.2000 0.4000 0.6000 0.8000 1.0000 Proportion in Security 2 (w2) 1.0000 0.8000 0.6000 0.4000 0.2000 0.0000 Expected return E (Rp) 0.1200 0.1120 0.1040 0.0960 0.0880 0.0800 Standard deviation a 0.3000 0.2227 0.1562 0.1200 0.1400 0.2000 R e a d in g a c ro s s T a b le 7 .3 , th e in v e s to r p la c e s m o re w e a lth in th e lo w -re tu rn S e c u rity 1 a n d less in th e h ig h -re tu rn S e c u rity 2 . C o n s e q u e n tly , th e e x p e c te d re tu rn o n th e p o r tfo lio d e c lin e s w ith e a c h step. T he b e h a v io u r o f th e s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n is m o re c o m p lic a te d . It d e c lin e s o v e r th e firs t fo u r p o rtfo lio s , re a c h in g a m in im u m v a lu e o f 0 . 1 2 0 0 w h e n Nv! = 0 . 6 , b u t th e n rises to 0 . 2 0 0 0 a t th e sixth p o r tfo lio , w h ic h co n sists e n tire ly o f S e c u rity 1 .4 T his is a n im p o rta n t fin d in g a s it im p lie s th a t so m e p o rtfo lio s LEARNING OBJECTIVE 4 Explain the concept of efficient portfolios w o u ld n e v e r b e h e ld b y risk-a ve rse in ve sto rs. F or e x a m p le , n o risk-a ve rse in v e s to r w o u ld c h o o s e P o rtfo lio (e) b e c a u s e P o rtfo lio (d) o ffe rs b o th a h ig h e r e x p e c te d re tu rn a n d a lo w e r ris k th a n P o rtfo lio (e). P o rtfo lio s th a t o ffe r th e h ig h e s t e x p e c te d re tu rn a t a g iv e n le ve l o f risk a re re fe rre d to a s 'e ffic ie n t’ p o rtfo lio s . T he d a ta in T a b le 7 . 3 a re p lo tte d in F ig u re 7 . 6 . A s c a n b e se e n fro m F ig u re 7 .6 , p o r tfo lio s (e) a n d (f) a r e n o t e ffic ie n t. ■ E n J P9p9dx ai uj 4 me minimum value of the standard deviation actually occurs slightly beyond Portfolio (d) at proportions Wj = 0.6333, and = 0.3667. The standard deviation for this portfolio is 0.11.92% p.a. and its expected return is 9.48% p.a. w2 C h apter The magnitude o f the gain from diversification is closely related to the value coefficient, p12- To show the importance o f the correlation coefficient, securities considered. This tim e, however, the investm ent proportions are held constant at and different values o f the correlation coefficient are considered. Portfolio variance is = o f the correlation 1 and 2 are again = 0.6 and w2 = 0.4 given by: o ^ C T j - f 1〇2 〇 2 + 2 W \ W 2 p \ , 2 ^ \ ^ 2 = (0.6)2(0.20)2 + (0.4)2(0.30)2 + 2(0.6)(0.4)pi,2(0.20)(0.30) =0.0144 + 0.0144 + 0.0288pi,2 (Tp = ^/0.0288 + 0.0288^! 2 a Pi,2 = +1.00 (Tp = x/0.0288 4-0.0288pi,2 CTp = 0.2400 b Pi,2 = +0.50 CTp = ^/0.0288 + 0.0288/), i2 (Tp = 0.2079 c Pi,2 = 0.00 〇 "p = ^0.0288 + 0.0288^1^ CTp = 0.1697 d Pi,2 = -0.50 (Tp = ^ 0 .0 2 8 8 + 0.0288p1<2 (Tp = 0.1200 e Pi,2 = -1.00 (Tp = ^0.0288 + 0.0288/?,,2 (Tp = 0 These results are summarised in Table 7.4. TABLE 7.4 Effect of correlation coefficient on portfolio standard deviation C o r r e la tio n c o e ffic ie n t P i S ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n 2= + l. 〇 〇 Pi 2 = +0.50 P i 2 = p i 2 = 〇 .〇 〇 0 .2 4 0 0 0.2 0 7 9 0 .1 6 9 7 -0 .5 0 0.1 2 0 0 P i 2 = - 1 .0 0 0 .0 0 0 0 Table 7.4 shows three im p o rta n t facts about p o rtfo lio construction: a b Combining two securities whose returns are perfectly positively correlated (that is, the correlation coefficient is +1) results only in risk averaging, and does n ot provide any risk reduction. In th is case the p ortfo lio standard deviation is the weighted average o f the two standard deviations, which is (0.6)(0.20) + (0.4)(0.30) = 0.2400. The real advantages o f diversification result from the risk reduction caused by com bining securities whose returns are less than perfectly positively correlated. s e ven Risk a n d return B usiness finance C The degree o f risk reduction increases as the correlation coefficient between the returns on the two securities decreases. The largest risk reduction available is where the returns are perfectly negatively correlated, so the tw o risky securities can be combined to form a p o rtfo lio th a t has zero risk (<Jp = 0). By considering different investm ent proportions w 1 and w 2, a curve sim ilar to th a t shown in Figure 7.6 can be plo tte d fo r each assumed value o f the correlation coefficient. These curves are shown together in Figure 7.7. Figure 7.7 I t can be seen th a t the lower the correlation coefficient, the higher the expected re tu rn fo r any given level o f risk (or the lower the level o f risk fo r any given expected return). This shows th a t the benefits o f diversification increase as the correlation coefficient decreases, and when the correlation coefficient is -1 , risk can be elim inated completely. The significance o f the dotted lines in Figure 7.7 is th a t a risk-averse investor would never hold combinations o f the two securities represented by points on the dotted lines. A t any given level o f correlation these combinations o f the tw o securities are always dom inated by other com binations th a t offer a higher expected retu rn fo r the same level o f risk. 7 .5 .2 1 Diversification with multiple assets LEARNING OBJECTIVE 5 Understand the importance of covariance between returns on risky assets in determining the risk of a portfolio ^0^ W hile the above discussion relates to the tw o-security case, even stronger conclusions can be drawn fo r larger portfolios. To examine the relationship between the risk o f a large p o rtfo lio and the riskiness o f the individual assets in the p ortfo lio , we sta rt by considering tw o assets. Using Equation 7.2, the p ortfo lio variance is: ojj = W y〇 i + U/2〇2 + ^ w l W 2C 〇v (R \ , R 2 ) C hapter seven Risk a n d return The variances and covariances on the right-hand side of this equation can be arranged in a matrix as follows: 1 1 2 C ov(R C〇v(i?2,i?1) 2 v R 2) °2 W ith two assets the variances and covariances form a 2 x 2 m atrix; three assets w ill result in a 3 x 3 m atrix; and in general w ith n assets there w ill be ann x n m atrix. Regardless o f the num ber o f assets involved, the variance-covariance m a trix w ill always have the follow ing properties: The m atrix w ill contain a total o f n2 terms. O f these terms, n are the variances o f the individual assets and the remaining (n2 - n) terms are the covariances between the various pairs o f assets in the portfolio, b The two covariance terms fo r each pair o f assets are identical. For example, in the 2 x 2 m a trix above, a C o v (R v R 2) = C o v (R 2>^ i )- c Since the covariance term s fo rm identical pairs, the m atrix is sym metrical about the m ain diagonal, which contains the n variance terms. Remember th a t the significance o f the variance-covariance m atrix is th a t it can be used to calculate the p ortfo lio variance. The p o rtfo lio variance is a weighted sum o f the terms in the m atrix, where the weights depend on the proportions o f the various assets in the p ortfolio. The firs t property o f the m a trix listed above shows th a t as the number o f assets increases, the number o f covariance terms increases much more rapidly than the number o f variance terms. For a p o rtfo lio o f n assets there are n variances and {n2 - n) covariances in the m atrix. This suggests th a t as a p o rtfo lio becomes larger, the effect o f the covariance terms on the risk o f the p o rtfo lio w ill be greater than the effect o f the variance terms. To illustrate the effects o f diversification and the significance o f the covariance between assets, consider a portfolio o f n assets. Assume th a t each o f these assets has the same variance {cr\). Also assume, initially, that the returns on these assets are independent— that is, the correlation between the returns on the assets is assumed to be zero in all cases. I f we form an equally weighted p o rtfo lio o f these assets, the proportion invested in each asset w ill be (1/n). Given the assumption o f zero correlation between all the asset returns, the covariance terms w ill all be zero, so the variance o f the p ortfo lio w ill depend only on the variance terms. Since there are n variance term s and each such term is the variance o f the p o rtfo lio w ill be: 7.5 aP Equation 7.5 shows that as n increases, the p o rtfo lio variance w ill decrease and as n becomes large, the variance o f the p o rtfo lio w ill approach zero; th a t is, i f the returns between all risky assets were independent, then i t would be possible to elim inate all risk by diversification. However, in practice, the returns between risky assets are not independent and the covariance between returns on most risky assets is positive. For example, the correlation coefficients between the returns on company shares are m ostly in the range 0.5 to 0.7. This positive correlation reflects the fact that the returns on m ost risky assets are related to each other. For example, i f the economy were growing strongly we would expect sales o f new cars and construction o f houses and other buildings to be increasing strongly. In turn, the demand fo r steel and other b uilding materials would also increase. Therefore, the profits and share prices o f steel and b uilding m aterial manufacturers should have a tendency to increase at the same tim e as the p ro fits and share prices o f car manufacturers and construction companies. To reflect the relationships among the returns on individual assets, we relax the assumption th a t the returns between assets are independent. Instead, we now assume th a t the correlation between the returns on all assets in the p o rtfo lio is p*. I f the p o rtfo lio is again equally weighted, the p o rtfo lio variance w ill now be equal to the sum o f the variance terms shown in Equation 7.5, plus (n2 - n) covariance terms 2 where each such term w ill be T + ( 1 ~ n )p^ p*a^- Therefore, the variance o f the p o rtfo lio w ill be: 7.6 40V B usiness finance Equation 7.6 illustrates an im p o rta n t result: w ith identical positively correlated assets, risk cannot be completely eliminated, no m atter how many such assets are included in a p ortfolio. As n becomes large, (1/n) w ill approach zero so the firs t term in Equation 7.6 w ill approach zero, b ut the second term w ill approach p*G^; th a t is, the variance o f the p o rtfo lio w ill approach which is the covariance between the returns on the assets in the p ortfolio. Thus, the positive correlation between the assets in a p ortfolio imposes a lim it on the extent to which risk can be reduced by diversification. In practice, the assets in a p o rtfo lio w ill n ot be identical and the correlations between the assets w ill d iffer rather than being equal as we have assumed. However, the essential results illustrated in Equation 7.6 remain the same— th a t is, in a diversified p o rtfo lio the variances o f the individual assets w ill contribute little to the risk o f the p ortfo lio . Rather, the risk o f a diversified p o rtfo lio w ill depend largely on the covariances between the returns on the assets. For example, Fama (1976, pp. 245-52) found that in an equally weighted p o rtfo lio o f 50 random ly selected securities, 90 per cent o f the p o rtfo lio standard deviation was due to the covariance terms. 7 .5 .3 1 Systematic and unsystematic risk LEARNING OBJECTIVE 6 Explain the distinction between systematic and unsystematic risk UNSYSTEMATIC ( d iv e r s if ia b l e ) RISK that component of total risk that is unique to the company and may be eliminated by diversification SYSTEMATIC (MARKETRELATED OR N O N DIVERSIFIABLE) RISK that component of total risk that is due to economy-wide factors As discussed in Section 7.5.2, i f we diversify by combining risky assets in a p o rtfo lio , the risk o f the p o rtfo lio returns w ill decrease. Diversification is most effective i f the returns on the individual assets are negatively correlated, b u t i t s till works w ith positive correlation, provided th a t the correlation coefficient is less than +1. We have noted that, in practice, the correlation coefficients between the returns on company shares are m ostly in the range 0.5 to 0.7. We also noted th a t this positive correlation reflects the fact th a t the returns on the shares o f m ost companies are economically related to each other. However, the correlation is less than perfect, which reflects the fact th a t much o f the va riab ility in the returns on shares is due to factors th a t are specific to each company. For example, the price o f a company’s shares may change due to an exploration success, an im p o rta n t research discovery or a change o f chief executive. Over any given period, the effects o f these company-specific factors w ill be positive fo r some companies and negative fo r others. Therefore, when shares o f different companies are combined in a p ortfo lio , the effects o f the company-specific factors w ill tend to offset each other, which w ill, o f course, be reflected in reduced risk fo r the p ortfolio. In other words, p a rt o f the risk o f an individual security can be eliminated by diversification and is referred to as unsystem atic risk or diversifiable risk. However, no m atter how much we diversify, there is always some risk th a t cannot be elim inated because the returns on all risky assets are related to each other. This p art o f the risk is referred to as sy stem atic risk or nondiversifiable risk. These tw o types o f risk are illustrated in Figure 7.8. igure 7.8 C hapter seven Risk a n d return Figure 7.8 shows th a t m ost unsystematic risk is removed by holding a p o rtfo lio o f about 25 to 30 securities. In other words, the returns on a well-diversified p o rtfo lio w ill n ot be significantly affected by the events that are specific to individual companies. Rather, the returns on a well-diversified p o rtfo lio w ill vary due to the effects o f market-wide or economy-wide factors such as changes in interest rates, changes in tax laws and variations in com m odity prices. The systematic risk o f a security or p o rtfo lio w ill depend on its sensitivity to the effects o f these market-wide factors. The d istin ction between systematic and unsystematic risk is im p o rta n t when we consider the risk o f individual assets in a p o rtfo lio context, which is discussed in Section 7.5.4, and the pricing o f risky assets, which is discussed in Section 7.6. 7 .5 .4 | The risk of an individual asset The reasoning used above can be extended to explain the factors th a t w ill determine the risk o f an individual asset as a component o f a diversified portfolio. Suppose th a t an investor holds a p o rtfo lio o f 50 assets and is considering the addition o f an extra asset to the p ortfolio. The investor is concerned w ith the effect that this extra asset w ill have on the standard d e la tio n o f the p ortfo lio . The effect is determined by the p o rtfo lio proportions, the extra assets variance and the 50 covariances between the extra asset and the assets already in the portfolio. As discussed above, the covariance terms are the dom inant influence— th a t is, to the holder o f a large p o rtfo lio the risk o f an asset is largely determined by the covariance between the retu rn on th a t asset and the retu rn on the holders existing p ortfolio. The variance o f the return on the extra asset is o f little importance. Therefore, the risk o f an asset when it is held in a large p o rtfo lio is determ ined by the covariance between the return on the asset and the return on the portfolio. The covariance o f a security z w ith a p o rtfo lio P is given by: The holders o f large p ortfo lio s o f securities can s till achieve risk reduction by adding a new security to their portfolios, provided th a t the returns on the new security are n o t perfectly positively correlated w ith the returns on the existing p ortfo lio . However, the increm ental risk reduction due to adding a new security to a p o rtfo lio decreases as the size o f the p o rtfo lio increases and, as shown in Figure 7.8, the additional benefits from diversification are very small fo r portfolios th a t include more than 30 securities (Statman 1987). I f investors are well diversified, th e ir portfolios w ill be representative o f the m arket as a whole. Therefore, the relevant measure o f risk is the covariance between the retu rn on the asset and the return on the m arket or Cov(Ri}RM). The covariance can then be scaled by dividing it by the variance o f the return on the m arket th a t gives a convenient measure o f risk, the b e ta factor, j3{) o f the asset— th a t is, fo r any asset z, the beta is: Cov(i?/, Rm) Beta is a very useful measure o f the risk o f an asset and i t w ill be shown in Section 7.6.2 th a t the capital asset pricing model proposes th a t the expected rates o f retu rn on risky assets are directly related to th e ir betas. Value Line (w w w .valueline.com ) is a US website based on the Value Line Investm ent Survey and contains inform a tion to help determine a share s level o f risk. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 7 Explain why systematic risk is important to investors BETA measure of a security’s systematic risk, describing the amount of risk contributed by the security to the market portfolio ^w w ^J VALUE AT RISK (VaR)-AN O TH ER WAY OF LOOKING AT RISK Finance Since the m id -1990s, a new measure o f risk exposure has become popular. This measure was developed by the investment bank J.P. M organ and is known as value at risk (VaR).5 It is defined as the worst loss that is possible under normal market conditions during a given time period. It is therefore determined by w hat are estimated to be normal market conditions and by the time period under consideration. For a given set o f market conditions, the longer the IN A C T IO N continued 5 * 7.7 Cov{Ri,Rp) = pip(Tiap 。 * A detailed examination of value at risk is provided by Jorion (2006), while an excellent online resource for those interested in the topic is provided at www.gloria-mundi.com. B usiness finance continued VALUE AT RISK tim e h o r iz o n th e g r e a t e r is th e v a lu e a t ris k . T h is m e a s u re o f r is k is b e in g in c r e a s in g ly u s e d b y worst loss possible under normal market conditions for a given time horizon c o r p o r a t e tr e a s u r e r s , fu n d m a n a g e r s a n d f in a n c ia l in s titu tio n s a s a s u m m a r y m e a s u r e o f th e to ta l r is k o f a p o r t f o lio . To illu s tra te h o w v a lu e a t ris k is m e a s u re d , s u p p o s e th a t $ 1 5 m illio n is in v e s te d in s h a re s in G r a d s t a r ts Ltd. S h a re s in G r a d s ta r ts h a v e a n e s tim a te d re tu rn o f z e r o a n d a s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f 3 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . 6 T h e s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n o n th e in v e s tm e n t o f $ 1 5 m illio n is th e re fo r e $ 4 . 5 m illio n . S u p p o s e a ls o t h a t re tu rn s f o llo w a n o r m a l p r o b a b ilit y d is tr ib u tio n . T h is m e a n s th a t th e t a b le o f a r e a s u n d e r th e s t a n d a r d n o r m a l c u r v e (see T a b le 5 o f A p p e n d ix A , o r th e N O R M S D IS T fu n c tio n in M ic r o s o f t E xcel® ) c a n b e u s e d to c a lc u la te th e p r o b a b ilit y th a t th e re tu rn w ill b e g r e a t e r th a n a s p e c ifie d n u m b e r. S u p p o s e a ls o th a t a b n o r m a lly b a d m a r k e t c o n d itio n s a r e e x p e c te d 5 p e r c e n t o f th e tim e . T h e t a b le o f a r e a s u n d e r th e s t a n d a r d n o r m a l c u r v e in d ic a te s t h a t th e re is a 5 p e r c e n t c h a n c e o f a lo ss o f g r e a t e r th a n $ 7 . 4 0 2 5 m illio n p e r a n n u m . T h is f ig u r e is e q u a l to 1 . 6 4 5 m u ltip lie d b y th e s t a n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f $ 4 . 5 m illio n . A s s h o w n in F ig u re 7 . 9 , th e v a lu e a t ris k o f th e in v e s tm e n t in G r a d s t a r ts is th e re fo r e $ 7 . 4 0 2 5 m illio n p e r a n n u m . Figure 7.9 Value of Gradstarts Ltd !l! 2 > OJd -e _Q S u p p o s e t h a t $ 1 0 m illio n is a ls o in v e s te d in s h a re s in C u r z o n C r e a t iv e Id e a s Ltd . T h e s e C u r z o n C r e a t iv e Id e a s s h a re s h a v e a n e s tim a te d re tu rn o f z e r o a n d h a v e a s t a n d a r d d e v ia t io n o f 2 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . T h e s t a n d a r d d e v ia t io n o n th e in v e s tm e n t o f $ 1 0 m illio n is th e r e f o r e $ 2 m illio n p e r a n n u m . It is a g a in a s s u m e d t h a t re tu rn s f o ll o w a n o r m a l p r o b a b il it y d is t r ib u t io n a n d t h a t a b n o r m a lly b a d m a r k e t c o n d it io n s a r e e x p e c t e d 5 p e r c e n t o f th e tim e . A s im ila r c a lc u la t io n to t h a t f o r G r a d s t a r ts p r o v id e s a v a lu e a t r is k o f th e in v e s tm e n t in C u r z o n C r e a t iv e Id e a s o f $ 2 m illio n m u lt ip lie d b y 1 . 6 4 5 o r $ 3 . 2 9 m illio n p e r a n n u m . T h e b e n e fits o f d iv e r s if ic a t io n m a y b e d e m o n s tr a te d b y c a lc u la t in g th e v a lu e a t r is k o f a p o r t f o lio c o m p r is in g a $ 1 5 m illio n in v e s tm e n t in G r a d s t a r t s a n d a $ 1 0 m illio n in v e s tm e n t in C u r z o n C r e a t iv e Id e a s . T h e w e ig h t o f th e in v e s tm e n t in G r a d s t a r t s is $ 1 5 m illio n o f $ 2 5 m illio n o r 0 . 6 o f t h e p o r t f o lio . T h e w e ig h t o f th e in v e s tm e n t in C u r z o n C r e a t iv e Id e a s is 0 . 4 . S u p p o s e t h a t th e c o r r e la t io n b e tw e e n th e re tu rn s o n th e s h a re s is 0 . 6 5 . U s in g E q u a t io n 7 .4 , th e v a r ia n c e o f th e re tu r n s o n th e p o r t f o lio is: a 2= ( 0 . 6 ) 2 ( 0 . 3 ) 2 + ( 0 .4 ) 2 ( 0 . 2 ) 2 + 2 ( 0 . 6 ) ( 0 . 4 ) ( 0 . 3 ) ( 0 . 2 ) ( 0 . 6 5 ) = 0 .0 5 7 5 2 T h e s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f p o r t f o lio re tu rn s , a , is th e r e fo r e 0 . 2 3 9 8 3 3 o r 2 3 . 9 8 3 3 p e r c e n t a n d th e s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n o n th e in v e s tm e n t is $ 2 5 m illio n x 0 . 2 3 9 8 3 3 = $ 5 . 9 9 5 8 m illio n . T h e v a lu e a t ris k o f th e p o r t f o lio is $ 5 . 9 9 5 8 m u ltip lie d b y 1 . 6 4 5 o r $ 9 . 8 6 3 1 6 m illio n p e r a n n u m . It is usual in calculating value at risk to assume an expected return of zero. This is a reasonable assumption where the expected return is small compared with the standard deviation of the expected return. C hapter seven Risk T h e t o t a l v a lu e a t r is k o f t h e in d iv id u a l in v e s tm e n ts in G r a d s t a r t s a n d C u r z o n C r e a t iv e Id e a s w a s $ 7 . 4 0 2 5 m illio n p lu s $ 3 . 2 9 m illio n o r $ 1 0 . 6 9 2 5 m illio n p e r a n n u m . T h e d if f e r e n c e b e tw e e n t h a t a m o u n t a n d th e v a lu e a t r is k o f th e p o r t f o lio o f $ 9 . 8 6 3 1 m illio n is d u e to th e b e n e fits o f d iv e r s if ic a t io n . If, h o w e v e r , th e re tu rn s o n th e s h a re s o f th e t w o c o m p a n ie s w e r e p e r fe c t ly c o r r e la t e d , th e v a lu e a t r is k o f th e p o r t f o lio w o u ld e q u a l th e v a lu e a t r is k f o r th e in v e s tm e n t in G r a d s t a r t s p lu s th e v a lu e a t r is k o f th e in v e s tm e n t in C u r z o n C r e a t iv e Id e a s . V a R is a t e c h n iq u e t h a t is c o m m o n ly u s e d b y f in a n c ia l in s titu tio n s t o m o n it o r t h e ir e x p o s u r e to lo s s e s t h r o u g h a d v e r s e c h a n g e s in m a r k e t c o n d it io n s . A p e r t in e n t e x a m p le o f th e u s e o f V a R is p r o v id e d b y th e J a n u a r y 2 0 0 4 a n n o u n c e m e n t o f a $ 3 6 0 m illio n f o r e ig n e x c h a n g e lo s s b y th e N a t io n a l A u s t r a lia B a n k . W h i l e a n in d e p e n d e n t in v e s t ig a t io n b y P r ic e w a t e r h o u s e C o o p e r s a ttr ib u t e d m o s t o f th e b la m e f o r th e lo s s to d is h o n e s t y o n th e p a r t o f th e c u r r e n c y t r a d e r s in v o lv e d a n d th e la c k o f s u it a b le c o n t r o l m e c h a n is m s in p la c e to u n c o v e r s u c h b e h a v io u r , th e r e p o r t a ls o m a d e s o m e in te r e s t in g c o m m e n ts o n th e b a n k ’s u s e o f V a R . T h e N a t i o n a l A u s t r a lia B a n k 's b o a r d o f d ir e c t o r s h a d a u t h o r is e d a V a R m a r k e t r is k e x p o s u r e lim it o f $ 8 0 m illio n p e r d a y f o r th e b a n k in g g r o u p a s a w h o le . T h is lim it w a s d i v id e d b e t w e e n t h e v a r io u s d iv is io n s o f th e b a n k . T h e c u r r e n c y o p t io n s d e s k h a d a V a R lim it o f $ 3 . 2 5 m illio n p e r d a y . T h is lim it w a s p e r s is te n tly b r e a c h e d o v e r th e 1 2 -m o n th p e r io d p r i o r to th e a n n o u n c e m e n t o f th e $ 3 6 0 m illio n lo s s . In r e la t io n to th e im p le m e n t a t io n o f a f la w e d V a R s y s te m th e P r ic e w a t e r h o u s e C o o p e r s r e p o r t c o m m e n te d th a t: ... m a n a g e m e n t h a d little c o n fid e n c e in the VaR num bers d u e to systems a n d d a ta issues, a n d e ffe ctive ly ig n o re d VaR a n d o th e r lim it breaches. There w a s n o sense o f u rg e n c y in resolving the VoR c a lc u la tio n issues w h ic h h o d been a p ro b le m fo r a p e rio d o f tw o o r m ore ye a rs.7 7 .5 .5 1 The efficient frontier When all risky assets are considered, there is no lim it to the num ber o f portfolios th a t can be formed, and the expected return and standard deviation o f the retu rn can be calculated fo r each p ortfo lio . The coordinates fo r all possible p ortfo lio s are represented by the shaded area in Figure 7.10. Figure 7.10 j E n s ' UJ J Qj p a p a d x LIJ Risk (a) 7 See PricewaterhouseCoopers (2004, p. 4). a n d return B usiness finance Only portfolios on the curve between points A and B are relevant since all portfolios below this curve yield lower expected return and/or greater risk. The curve AB is referred to as the efficient frontier and it includes those portfolios that are efficient in that they offer the m aximum expected return for a given level o f risk. For example, Portfolio 1 is preferred to an internal p oint such as Portfolio 3 because Portfolio 1 offers a higher expected return fo r the same level o f risk. Similarly, Portfolio 2 is preferred to Portfolio 3 because it offers the same expected return for a lower level o f risk. No such <dominance, relationship exists between efficient portfolios— that is, between portfolios whose risk-re tu rn coordinates plot on the efficient frontier. Given risk aversion, each investor w ill want to hold a p ortfo lio somewhere on the efficient frontier. Risk-averse investors w ill choose the p o rtfo lio th a t suits th e ir preference fo r risk. As investors are a diverse group there is no reason to believe th a t they w ill have identical risk preferences. Each investor may therefore prefer a different p oint (portfolio) along the efficient frontier. For example, a conservative investor would choose a p ortfo lio near p o in t A while a more risk-tolerant investor would choose a p ortfo lio near p oint B. In summary, the m ain points established in this section are that: diversification reduces risk the effectiveness o f diversification depends on the correlation or covariance between returns on the individual assets combined into a p o rtfo lio C the positive correlation th a t exists between the returns on m ost risky assets imposes a lim it on the degree o f risk reduction th a t can be achieved by diversification d the to ta l risk o f an asset can be divided in to two parts: systematic risk th a t cannot be elim inated by diversification and unsystematic risk th a t can be elim inated by diversification e the only risk th a t remains in a well-diversified p o rtfo lio is systematic risk f fo r investors who diversify, the relevant measure o f the risk o f an individual asset is its systematic risk, which is usually measured by the beta o f the asset g risk-averse investors w ill aim to hold p ortfolios th a t are efficient in th a t they provide the highest expected retu rn fo r a given level o f risk. a b The concepts discussed in this section can be extended to model the relationship between risk and expected return fo r individual risky assets. This extension o f p o rtfo lio theory is discussed in Section 7.6 and we discuss below an alternative technique to measuring risk th a t focuses on the maximum dollar losses th a t would be expected during norm al trading conditions. 7.6 The pricing of risky assets Section 7.5 focused on investm ent decision making by individuals. We now s h ift the focus from the behaviour o f individuals to the pricing o f risky assets and we introduce the assumption th a t investors can also invest in an asset th a t has no default risk. The return on this risk-free asset is the risk-free interest rate, R^. Typically, this is regarded as the interest rate on a government security, such as Treasury notes. We continue to assume th a t all investors in a particular m arket behave according to p o rtfo lio theory, and ask: How would prices o f individual securities in th a t m arket be determined? In tu itive ly, we would expect risky assets to provide a higher expected rate o f retu rn than the risk-free asset. In other words, the expected retu rn on a risky asset could be viewed as consisting o f the risk-free rate plus a premium fo r risk, and this prem ium should be related to the risk o f the asset. However, as discussed in Section 7.5.3, part o f the risk o f any risky asset— unsystematic risk — can be eliminated by diversification. It seems reasonable to suggest that in a competitive market, assets should be priced so that investors are not rewarded fo r bearing risk that could easily be eliminated by diversification. On the other hand, some risk — systematic risk— cannot be eliminated by diversification so it is reasonable to suggest that investors w ill expect to be compensated fo r bearing that type o f risk. In summary, in tu itio n suggests that risky assets w ill be priced such that there is a relationship between returns and systematic risk. The remaining question is: W hat sort o f relationship w ill there be between returns and systematic risk? The work o f Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), Fama (1968) and Mossin (1969) provides an answer to this question.8 8 Although we have referred to the pricing5of assets, much of this work deals with expected returns, rather than asset prices. However, there is a simple relationship between expected return and price in that the expected rate of return can be used to discount an assets expected net cash flows to obtain an estimate of its current price. 7 .6 .1 1 The capital market line W ith the opp ortu nity to borrow and lend at the risk-free rate, an investor is no longer restricted to holding a p o rtfo lio th a t is on the efficient fro n tie r AB. Investors can now invest in combinations o f risky assets and the risk-free asset in accordance w ith th e ir risk preferences. This is illustrated in Figure 7.11. N % ◦s C J n oJ L U p a p a d x L U Risk [a) The line R^T represents p o rtfo lio s th a t consist o f an investm ent in a p o rtfo lio o f ris k y assets T and an investm ent in the risk-free asset. Investors can achieve any com bination o f ris k and re tu rn on the line RrT by investing in the risk-free asset and P o rtfo lio T. Each p o in t on the line corresponds to different p ro po rtio ns o f the to ta l funds being invested in the risk-free asset and P o rtfo lio T. However, it would n o t be ratio na l fo r investors to hold p o rtfo lio s th a t p lo t on the line RjT, because they can achieve higher returns fo r any given level o f risk by com bining the risk-free asset w ith o the r p o rtfo lio s th a t p lo t above T on the efficient fro n tie r (AB). This approach suggests th a t investors w ill achieve the best possible re tu rn fo r any level o f ris k by holding P o rtfo lio M rather th an any other p o rtfo lio o f risky assets. The line R^MN is tangential at the p o in t M to the efficient fro n tie r (AB) o f portfolios o f risky assets. This line represents p ortfo lio s that consist o f an investm ent in Portfolio M and an investm ent in the risk-free asset. Points on the line to the le ft o f M require a positive am ount to be invested in the risk-free asset— that is, they require the investor to lend at the risk-free rate. Points on the line to the rig h t o f M require a negative am ount to be invested in the risk-free asset— th a t is, they require the investor to borrow at the risk-free rate. It is apparent th a t the line R^MN dominates the efficient fro n tie r AB since at any given level o f risk a portfolio on the line offers an expected return at least as great as th a t available from the efficient fro n tie r (curve AB). Risk-averse investors w ill therefore choose a p o rtfo lio on the line R^MN— th a t is, some combination o f the risk-free asset and Portfolio M. This is true fo r all risk-averse investors who conform to the assumptions o f p o rtfo lio theory. The portfolios th a t m ig ht be chosen by three investors are shown in Figure 7.11. Having chosen to invest in Portfolio M, each investor combines this risky investm ent w ith a position in the risk-free asset. In Figure 7.11, Investor 1 w ill invest p a rtly in Portfolio M and p a rtly in the risk-free asset. Investor 2 w ill invest all funds in Portfolio M , while Investor 3 w ill borrow at the risk­ free rate and invest his or her own funds, plus the borrowed funds, in Portfolio M . A fo u rth strategy, n o t shown in Figure 7.11, is to invest only in the risk-free asset. This is the least risky strategy, whereas the strategy pursued by Investor 3 is the riskiest. B usiness finance MARKET PORTFOLIO portfolio of all risky assets, weighted according to their market capitalisation CAPITAL MARKET LINE efficient set of all portfolios that provides the investor with the best possible investment opportunities when a risk-free asset is available. It describes the equilibrium riskreturn relationship for efficient portfolios, where the expected return is a function of the risk-free interest rate, the expected market risk premium and the proportionate risk of the efficient portfolio to the risk of the market portfolio I f all investors in a particular m arket behave according to p o rtfo lio theory, all investors hold Portfolio M as at least a p art o f th e ir to ta l p o rtfo lio .9 In turn, this implies th a t Portfolio M m ust consist o f all risky assets. In other words, under these assumptions, a given risky asset, X, is either held by all investors as part o f Portfolio M or it is n o t held by any investor. In the la tte r case, Asset X does n o t exist. Therefore, Portfolio M is often called the m arket portfolio because it comprises all risky assets available in the m arket. For example, i f the to ta l m arket value o f all shares in Company X represents 1 per cent o f the to ta l m arket value o f all assets, then shares in Company X w ill represent 1 per cent o f every investors to ta l investm ent in risky assets. The line R^MN is called the capital m arket line because i t shows all the to ta l portfolios in which investors in the capital m arket m ight choose to invest. Since investors w ill choose only efficient portfolios, it follows th a t the m arket p o rtfo lio is predicted to be efficient* in the sense th a t it w ill provide the m axim um expected retu rn fo r th a t particular level o f risk. The capital m arket line, therefore, shows the trade-off between expected return and risk fo r all efficient portfolios. The equation o f the capital m arket line is given b y:10 ' E(Rm ) - R f 、 E(Rp) = Rf + where 〇 7.8 M is the standard deviation o f the retu rn on the m arket Portfolio M The slope o f this line is 丑( 只以)— and this measures the m arket price o f risk. It represents the additional expected retu rn th a t investors would require to compensate them fo r in cu rring additional risk, as measured by the standard deviation o f the p ortfolio. 7 .6 .2 |T h e Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) and the security market line LEARNING OBJECTIVE 8 Explain the relationship between returns and risk proposed by the capital asset pricing model A lthough the capital m arket line holds fo r efficient portfolios, it does n o t describe the relationship between expected return and risk fo r individual assets or inefficient portfolios. In equilibrium , the expected return on a risky asset (or inefficient p ortfo lio ), z, can be shown to be:11 f E(R M) - R f \ E(R i) = Rf + f ^ f j Cow(Rh RM) where 7.9 = the expected retu rn on the zth risky asset C ov(R j} Rm) = the covariance between the returns on the zth risky asset and the m arket p o rtfo lio 9 This ignores the extreme case of investors who hold only the risk-free asset. 10 The fact that Equation 7.8 is the equation for the capital market line can be shown as follows: let Portfolio p consist of an investment in the risk-free asset and the market portfolio. The investment proportions are w f in the risk-free asset and w M = 1 - W fin the market portfolio. Therefore, Portfolio p is, in effect, a two-security portfolio and its expected return is given by: £(Kp) = w R f + (1 - w f ) E (RM) and the variance of its return is: + By definition, a2P _ w)2〇 2m + 2My(! - = 0 so the variance reduces to: = ^ ~ wf)Z〇 2M Therefore: (Tp = ( l - Wf)crM Since the expected return and standard deviation of Portfolio p are linear functions of w^, it follows that R f M in Figure 7.11 is a straight line. This result is not specific to portfolios consisting of the risk-free asset and Portfolio M: rather it applies to a ll portfolios that include the risk-free asset. The equation for a straight line can be expressed as y = m x + c where m is the slope of the line and c is the intercept on the y axis. Referring to Figure 7.11, it can be seen that: n c = Rr 」 and m = E (R M - R f ) --------- — O 'M Therefore, the equation for the line rf M N is Equation 7.8. 11 This is a purely mathematical problem. For a derivation see Levy and Sarnat (1990) or Brailsford and Faff (1993). C hapter seven Risk a n d return Equation 7.9 is often called the CAPM equation. An equivalent version is given in Equation 7.11. The CAPM equation shows th a t the expected return demanded by investors on a risky asset depends on the risk-free rate o f interest, the expected retu rn on the m arket p ortfo lio , the variance o f the retu rn on the m arket p ortfolio, and the covariance o f the return on the risky asset w ith the retu rn on the market portfolio. The covariance term Cov(Rj} RM) is the only explanatory factor in the CAPM equation specific to asset z. The other explanatory factors (R厂,£(RM) and c r^) are the same, regardless o f which asset z. is being considered. Therefore, according to the CAPM equation, i f tw o assets have different expected returns, this is because they have different covariances w ith the m arket p ortfo lio . In other words, the measure o f risk relevant to pricing a risky asset is Cov(Rif RM)t the covariance o f its returns w ith returns on the m arket portfolio, as this measures the contribution o f the risky asset to the riskiness o f an efficient p ortfolio. In contrast, fo r the efficient p o rtfo lio itse lf the standard deviation o f the p o rtfo lio s return is the relevant measure o f risk (see Figure 7.11). As discussed in Section 7.5.4, the measure o f risk fo r an investm ent in a risky asset i is often referred to as its beta factor, where: Cov(i?/, Rm) Pi 7.10 Because Cov(Rj} RM) is the risk o f an asset held as part o f the m arket p ortfo lio , while crM is the risk (in terms o f variance) o f the m arket p ortfolio, it follows th a t J3f measures the risk o f i relative to the risk o f the market as a whole. Using beta as the measure o f risk, the CAPM equation can be rew ritten: £( r ) = v z p (r m) - 〜 ] HD When graphed, Equation 7.11 is called the security m arket line and is illustrated in Figure 7.12. ■ graphical representation of the capital asset pricing model ure 7.12 Security market line Security market line b / )CJ n 4J UJ a} p a p a d x LU 0.5 SECURITY MARKET LINE 1.0 1.5 Risk (A) The significance o f the security m arket line is that in equilibrium each risky asset should be priced so that it plots exactly on the line. Equation 7.11 shows that according to the capital asset pricing model, the expected return on a risky asset consists o f two components: the risk-free rate o f interest plus a premium for risk. The risk premium for each asset depends on the assets beta and on the market risk premium [E(RM) - Rr]. B usiness finance The betas o f individual assets w ill be distributed around the beta value o f the market portfolio, which is l . 12 A risky asset w ith a beta value greater than 1 (that is, higher risk) w ill have an expected return greater than E(Rm), while the expected return on a risky asset w ith a beta value o f less than 1 (that is, lower risk) w ill be less than E(RM). Assuming that the risk-free rate o f interest is 10 per cent and the m arket risk premium [E(Rm) is 5 per cent, the expected return on risky Asset 1 w ith a beta value o f 0.5 w ill be 12.5 per cent. The expected return on risky Asset 2 w ith a beta value o f 1.5 w ill be 17.5 per cent. The capital asset pricing model applies to individual assets and to portfolios. The beta factor fo r a p o rtfo lio p is simply: ^ _ Cov (Rp ,R m) Pp 一 Z2^ 7.12 where Cov(R yRM) = the covariance between the returns on p o rtfo lio p and the m arket p ortfo lio . Equation 7.12 is sim ply Equation 7.10 rew ritten in term s o f a p o rtfo lio pt instead o f a particular asset i. Fortunately there is a simple relationship between a p o rtfo lio s beta (J3p) and the betas o f the individual assets th a t make up the p ortfo lio . This relationship is: n 0p = Y l 7.13 i= \ where n = the num ber o f assets in the p ortfo lio = the proportion o f the current m arket value o f p o rtfo lio p constituted by the zth asset Equation 7.13 states th a t the beta factor fo r a p o rtfo lio is sim ply a weighted average o f the betas o f the assets in the p o rtfo lio .13 One useful application o f Equation 7.13 is to guide investors in choosing the investm ent proportions to achieve some target p ortfo lio beta, /3p. An im p o rta n t special case is to construct such a p o rtfo lio using only the m arket p o rtfo lio (J3 = 1) and a position in the risk-free asset (J3 = 0). In this case, investors place a pro po rtio n wM o f th e ir to ta l funds in the m arket p ortfolio, and a p roportion Wr = (1 - wM) in the risk-free asset. Using Equation 7.13, the target beta is given by: P p = wf 0 f + w m P m Substituting /3f= 0 and j3 m = 1 gives: wM=^*p and W f r = l- J3* For example, if / ^ = 0.75, investors should invest 75 per cent o f their funds in the m arket portfolio and lend 25 per cent o f their funds at the risk-free rate. I f = 1.3, investors should borrow an amount equal to 30 per cent o f their own investment funds and invest the total amount (130 per cent) in the market portfolio. 12 Since Cov (/?,, R m) P i = ----------5-------we have _ C o v (/?a/ ,/? a/) 13 Our discussion has omitted the steps between Equations 7.12 and 7.13. For the interested reader, these steps are as follows. Since: R P = ^ 2 WjRj /=i it follows that: C o v (R r , R m ) = Cov 5 3 ^/C 〇v(/?„ R m) /=i Substituting in Equation 7.12: (^i = = i=i i=l WiCov (/?,, Rm) Wi(3i C hapter seven Risk a n d return 7 .6 .3 1 Implementation of the CAPM Use o f the CAPM requires estim ation o f the risk-free interest rate, the systematic risk o f equity, fie and the m arket risk premium, E(RM) - Rf: . Each o f these variables is discussed in turn. The risk-free interest rate (Rfj The assets closest to being risk free are government debt securities, so interest rates on these securities are norm ally used as a measure o f the risk-free rate. However, as discussed in Section 4.6.1, unless the term structure o f interest rates is flat, the various government securities w ill offer different interest rates. The appropriate risk-free rate is the current yield on a government security whose term to m a tu rity matches the life o f the proposed projects to be undertaken by the company. Since these activities undertaken by the company typically provide returns over many years, the rate on long-term securities is generally used. The share's systematic risk [jSJ The betas o f securities are usually estimated by applying regression analysis to estimate the follow ing equation from tim e series data: Ri t = a i + ^ iRM + eit where ^ = a constant, specific to asset z eit = an error term Equation 7.14 is generally called the m arket model. Its relationship to the security m arket line can MARKET MODEL time series regression of an asset's returns be readily seen by rew riting Equation 7.11 as follows: E (R )= R f + ^ E (R M) - A R f 7.15 Therefore, the m arket m odel is a counterpart (or analogue) o f Equation 7.15. The magnitude o f the betas th a t result from using this model when i t is applied to returns on shares is illustrated in Table 7.5, which contains a sample o f betas fo r the shares o f selected listed companies. The values are calculated using ordinary least squares (OLS) regression. TABLE 7.5 Betas of selected Australian listed companies calculated using daily share price and index data for the period January 2009 - December 2013 N am e o f com pany M a in in d u s tria l a c tiv ity Beta ANZ Banking Group Banking 1.16 Amcor Packaging 0.75 BHP Billiton Minerals exploration, production and processing 1.32 Coca-Cola Amatil Food, beverage and tobacco 0.41 Fairfax Media Media 1.16 Harvey Norman Retailing 1.03 QBE Insurance Insurance 0.95 Woolworths Food and staples retailing 0.46 The m arket model, as specified in Equation 7.14, is often used to obtain an estimate o f ex-post systematic risk. To use the m arket model, it is necessary to obtain tim e series data on the rates o f return on the share and on the m arket p o rtfo lio — th a t is, a series o f observations fo r both Rit and RMt is needed. However, when using the m arket model, choices m ust be made about two factors. First, the model may be estimated over periods o f different length. For example, data fo r the past 1, 2 ,3 or more years may be used. Five years o f data are commonly used, but the choice is somewhat arbitrary. Second, the returns used in the m arket model may be calculated over periods o f different length. For example, daily, weekly, monthly, quarterly or yearly returns may be used. Again this choice is subject to a considerable degree o f judgment. From a statistical perspective, it is generally better to have more rather than fewer observations, because using more observations generally leads to greater statistical confidence. However, the greater the num ber o f years o f data th a t are used, the more likely i t is th a t the company s riskiness w ill have changed. This fact highlights a fundam ental problem o f using the m arket model. The m arket model provides a measure o f how risky a company s equity was in the past. W hat we are seeking to obtain is an estimate of future risk. Therefore, the choice o f both the number o f years o f data and the length o f the period over which returns are calculated involves a trade-off between the desire to have many observations and the need to have recent and consequently more relevant data.14 The market risk premium [E{RM] - Rf] The m arket p o rtfo lio specified in the CAPM consists o f every risky asset in existence. Consequently, it is impossible in practice to calculate its expected rate o f retu rn and hence impossible to also calculate the m arket risk premium. Instead, a share m arket index is generally used as a substitute fo r the m arket p ortfolio. As the rate o f retu rn on a share m arket index is highly variable from year to year, it is usual to calculate the average retu rn on the index over a relatively long period. Suppose th a t the average rate o f return on a share m arket index such as the All-Ordinaries Accum ulation Index over the past 10 years was 18.5 per cent per annum. I f this rate were used as the estimate o f E(RM) and today s risk-free rate is 8.5 per cent, the m arket risk prem ium [E(RM) - R^\ would be 10 per cent. A problem w ith using this approach is th a t the estimate o f ^ re fle c ts the m arkets current expectations o f the future, whereas E(RM) is an average o f past returns. In other words, the two values may n ot match, and some unacceptable estimates may result. For example, [E(RM) - RJ estimated in this way may be negative i f the rate o f in fla tio n expected now, which should be reflected in is greater than the realised rate o f in fla tio n during the period used to estimate E(RM). A better approach is to estimate the market risk prem ium directly, over a relatively long period. For example, Ibbotson and Goetzmann (2005) compare the returns on equities w ith the returns on bonds in the US between 1792 and 1925 and report an average difference o f approximately 3.8 per cent per annum. The Credit Suisse Global Investment Returns Yearbook provides an annual update o f m arket risk premiums across 20 countries. The 2013 yearbook authored by Dimson et al. (2013) reports that over the 113 years from 1900 to 2012 the average prem ium in the US was 5.3 per cent per annum. Over the same period, the country w ith the lowest premium was Denmark, at 2.7 per cent per annum, and the country w ith the highest premium was Australia, at 6.4 per cent per annum. Brailsford, Handley and Maheswaran (2012) provide sim ilar estimates fo r Australia. They report that, over the 128 years from 1883 to 2010, the premium was approximately 6.1 per cent per annum. Using a shorter tim e period during which the quality o f the data is higher, they estimate th a t the premium from 1958 to 2010 was also 6.1 per cent per annum. However, estim ating the m arket risk premium directly also has some problems. R itte r (2002) uses the example o f Japan at the end o f 1989 to illustrate th a t historical estimates can result in nonsensical numbers. He notes th a t estim ating the m arket risk prem ium at the end o f 1989 using historical data starting when the Japanese stock m arket reopened after W orld War II would have provided a m arket risk premium o f over 10 per cent per annum. The Japanese economy was booming, corporate profits were high and average price-earnings (P-E) ratios were over 60. I t was considered th a t the cost o f equity for Japanese companies was low. However, it is n ot possible fo r the cost o f equity to be low and the market risk premium to be high. O f course, it is possible fo r the historical m arket risk premium to be high and the expected m arket risk prem ium (and therefore the expected cost o f equity capital) to be low. In an im p o rta n t theoretical paper, Mehra and Prescott (1985) showed th a t a long-term risk premium such as th a t found in the US, Canada, the UK and Australia cannot be explained by standard models o f risk and return. This fin ding has led to arguments th a t historical measures o f the risk prem ium are subject to errors in th e ir measurement. For example, Jorion and Goetzmann (1999) argue th a t estimates o f the m arket risk premium based solely on data obtained from the US w ill be biased upwards sim ply as a result 14 For a discussion of the issues associated with calculating systematic risk from historical data, see Brailsford, Faff and Oliver ( 1997) . C hapter seven Risk of the outperformance o f the US m arket relative to other equity markets over the tw e ntie th century. Others, such as Heaton and Lucas (2000), argue th a t increased opportunities fo r p o rtfo lio diversification mean th a t the m arket risk prem ium has fallen. These concerns have led to new techniques being employed to estimate the m arket ris k prem ium . Fama and French (2002), among others, use the dividend g ro w th m odel and conclude th a t the m arket risk prem ium is now o f the order o f 1 per cent per annum . Claus and Thomas (2001) use forecasts by security analysts and conclude th a t the m arket risk prem ium is approxim ately 3 per cent per annum. Duke U niversity and CFO magazine have conducted a qua rte rly survey o f chief financial officers since 1996 (see w w w .cfosurvey.org). The average estimated ris k prem ium fo r the US over th a t tim e has been approxim ately 4 per cent per annum . For the fo u rth quarter o f 2013, when asked how much they expect returns in the equity m arket in the US to exceed the returns on governm ent bonds over the next 10 years, the average response was 3.6 per cent per annum . In summary, the d isp a rity o f estimates o f the m arket risk prem ium is considerable, ranging from 1 to in excess o f 6 per cent per annum. a n d return 卜, | 7 .6 .4 | Risk, return and the CAPM The d istin ction between systematic and unsystematic ris k is im p o rta n t in explaining why the CAPM should represent the ris k -re tu rn relationship fo r assets such as shares. This issue was discussed in Section 7.5.3 b ut is reiterated here because o f its importance in understanding the CAPM. The returns on a company s shares may vary fo r many reasons: fo r example, interest rates may change, or the company may develop a new product, attract im p o rta n t new customers or change its chief executive. These factors can be divided in to tw o categories: those related only to an individual company (companyspecific factors) and those th a t affect all companies (m arket-wide factors). As the shares o f different companies are combined in a p o rtfo lio , the effects o f the company-specific factors w ill tend to cancel each other out; this is how diversification reduces risk. However, the effects o f the m arket-wide factors w ill remain, no m atter how many d ifferent shares are included in the p o rtfo lio . Therefore, systematic risk reflects the influence o f m arket-wide factors, w hile unsystematic risk reflects the influence o f company-specific factors. Because unsystematic risk can be elim inated by diversification, the capital m arket w ill n o t reward investors fo r bearing this type o f risk. The capital m arket w ill only reward investors fo r bearing risk that cannot be elim inated by diversification— th a t is, the risk inherent in the m arket p ortfo lio . There are cases when, w ith hindsight, we can id e n tify investors who have reaped large rewards from taking on unsystematic risk. These cases do n ot im p ly th a t the CAPM is invalid: the model sim ply says th a t such rewards cannot be expected in a competitive market. The reward fo r bearing systematic risk is a higher expected retu rn and, according to the CAPM, there is a simple linear relationship between expected return and systematic risk as measured by beta. A d d itio n a l factors that explain returns In 1977 Richard Roll published an im p o rta n t article th a t pointed out th a t while the CAPM has strong theoretical foundations, there is a range o f difficulties th a t researchers face in testing i t empirically. For example, in testing fo r a positive relationship between an assets beta and realised returns, a researcher first needs to measure the correlation between the assets returns and the returns on the m arket p ortfolio. The m arket p o rtfo lio theoretically consists o f all assets in existence and is therefore unobservable in practice— im plying th a t ultim ately the CAPM itse lf is untestable. Aside from the problems associated w ith testing fo r a relationship between estimates o f beta and realised returns, voluminous empirical research has shown th a t there are other factors th a t also explain returns. These factors include a company s dividend yield, its price-earnings (P-R) ratio, its size (as measured by the m arket value o f its shares), and the ratio o f the book value o f its equity to the m arket value o f its equity. This last ratio is often called the company s book-to-m arket ratio. In a detailed study, Fama and French (1992) show th a t the size and book-to-m arket ratio were dom inant and th a t dividend yield and the price-earnings ratio were n o t useful in explaining returns after allowing fo r these more dom inant factors. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 9 Understand the relationship between the capital asset pricing model and models that include additional factors B usiness finance In another im p o rta n t paper, Fama and French (1993) tested the follow ing three-factor model of expected returns: £(Rit) - Rf, = Pm [E{Rm ) - Rf,} + j3 iS £(SMBt) + J3m £(H M Lt) LEARNING OBJECTIVE 10 Explain the development of models that include additional factors B In Equation 7.16, the firs t factor is the m arket risk premium, which is the basis o f the CAPM discussed earlier in this chapter. The next factor, SMB, refers to the difference between the returns o f a diversified p o rtfo lio o f small and large companies, while H M L reflects the differences between the returns o f a diversified p o rtfo lio o f companies w ith high versus low book-to-m arket values. j3iM, j3jS and j3jH are the risk parameters reflecting the sensitivity o f the asset to the three sources o f risk. A ll three factors were found to have strong explanatory power. Brailsford, Gaunt and O b rie n (2012) found th a t in Australia, over the period 1982 to 2006, all three factors provided strong explanatory power. I t is possible th a t both the size and book-to-m arket ratio factors m ig ht be explicable by risk. For example, Fama and French (1996) argue th a t smaller companies are more likely to default than larger companies. Further, they argue th a t this risk is likely to be systematic in th a t small companies as a group are more exposed to default during economic downturns. As a result, investors in small companies w ill require a risk premium. Similarly, Zhang (2005) argues th a t companies w ith high book-to-m arket ratios w ill on average have higher levels o f physical capacity. Much o f this physical capacity w ill represent excess capacity during economic dow nturns and therefore expose such companies to increased risk. However, as discussed in detail in Chapter 16, the relationship between these additional factors and returns may n o t be due to risk. Further, Carhart (1997) added a fo u rth factor to the three described in Equation 7.16 to explain returns earned by m utual funds. In an earlier paper, Jegadeesh and Titm an (1993), using US data from 1963 to 1989, identified better perform ing shares (the winners) and poorer perform ing shares (the losers) over a period o f 6 months. They then tracked the performance o f these shares over the follow ing 6 months. On average, the biggest winners outperform ed the biggest losers by 10 per cent per annum. When Carhart added this m om entum effect to the three-factor model, he found th a t it too explained returns. Unlike the size and book-to-m arket ratio factors, it is d iffic u lt to construct a simple risk-based explanation fo r this factor. W hile the CAPM is clearly an incomplete explanation o f the relationship between risk and returns, it is im p o rta n t to note th a t it is s till widely applied. This p o in t is perhaps best demonstrated by the Coleman, Maheswaran and Pinder (2010) survey o f the financial practices adopted by senior financial managers in Australia. Financial managers employ asset pricing models to estimate the discount rate used in project evaluation techniques such as the net present value approach. Coleman, Maheswaran and Pinder reported that more than twice as many respondents used the trad ition al single-factor CAPM compared w ith models th a t used additional factors. 7.8 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 11 Distinguish between alternative methods of appraising the performance of an investment portfolio S Portfolio perform ance appraisal A fundam ental issue th a t faces investors is how to measure the performance o f th e ir investm ent p ortfolio. To illustrate the problem, assume th a t an investor observes th a t during the past 12 m onths, his or her p o rtfo lio has generated a return o f 15 per cent. Is this a good, bad or indifferent result? The answer to that question depends, o f course, on the expected return o f the p o rtfo lio given the p o rtfo lio s risk. That is, in order to answer the question, we need a measure o f the risk o f the investors p o rtfo lio , and then compare its performance w ith the performance o f a benchmark p o rtfo lio o f sim ilar risk. However, even after accounting fo r the specific risk o f the p ortfo lio , the performance o f a p o rtfo lio may d iffer from that o f the benchmark fo r four reasons: • • Asset allocation. Investors m ust decide how much o f th e ir wealth should be allocated between alternative categories o f assets such as corporate bonds, government bonds, domestic shares, international shares and property. This decision w ill ultim ately affect the performance o f the p o rtfo lio because in any given period a particular asset class may outperform other asset classes on a risk-adjusted basis. M arket timing. In establishing and adm inistering a p ortfo lio , investors need to make decisions about when to buy and sell the assets held in a p ortfo lio . For example, investors m ig h t choose to C hapter seven Risk • • move out o f domestic shares and in to corporate bonds or alternatively sell the shares o f companies that operate in the telecomm unication ind ustry and invest these funds in the shares o f companies operating in the retail industry. Clearly, the performance o f a p o rtfo lio w ill be affected by an investors success in selling assets before th e ir prices fall and buying assets before th e ir prices rise. Security selection. Having made a decision about the desired m ix o f different asset classes w ith in a portfolio, and when that desired m ix should be implemented, investors m ust then choose between many different individual assets w ith in each class. For example, having determined th a t they wish to hold half o f th e ir p o rtfo lio in domestic shares, investors m ust then decide which o f the more than 2000 shares listed on the Australian Securities Exchange they should buy. The a rt o f security selection requires the investors to id e n tify those individual assets th a t they believe are currently underpriced by the m arket and hence whose values are expected to rise over the holding period. Similarly, if investors believe th a t any o f the assets held in the p o rtfo lio are currently overpriced, they would sell these assets so as to avoid any future losses associated w ith a reduction in th e ir m arket value. Random influences. Ultim ately, investing is an uncertain a ctivity and in any given period the performance o f a p o rtfo lio may n o t reflect the skills o f the investor who makes the investm ent decisions. That is, good decisions m ig ht yield poor outcomes and poor decisions m ight yield good outcomes in what we would label as ‘bad luck’ or ‘good luck’, respectively. Over enough time, though, we would expect the influence o f good luck and bad luck to average out. We now consider four comm only used ways o f measuring the performance o f a p ortfo lio . Each o f these measures has a different approach to try in g to determine the ‘expected’ performance o f the benchmark portfolio in order to determ ine whether the p ortfo lio has met, exceeded or failed to meet expectations. Simple benchmark index This is probably the m ost comm only used approach to appraising the performance o f a p o rtfo lio and involves a simple comparison between the p o rtfo lio s retu rn and the retu rn on a benchmark index that has (or is assumed to have) sim ilar risk to the p o rtfo lio being measured. For example, a well-diversified portfolio o f domestic shares m ig h t be benchmarked against the S&P/ASX 200 Index, which measures the performance o f the shares in the 200 largest companies listed on the Australian Securities Exchange. The advantages associated w ith using this approach to performance appraisal are th a t it is easy to implement and to understand. The main problem w ith this approach is th a t i t implies th a t the risk o f the portfolio is identical to the risk o f the benchmark index, whereas, w ith the exception o f so-called passive funds, which are specifically established to m im ic (or track) the performance o f benchmark indices, this w ill rarely be the case. The Sharpe ratio The Sharpe ratio, developed by W illiam Sharpe15, is a measure o f the excess retu rn o f the p o rtfo lio per u n it o f total risk and is calculated using the follow ing formula: where fp is the average re tu rn achieved on the p o rtfo lio over the tim e period, 7y is the average risk-free rate o f return over the same tim e period and crp is the standard deviation o f the returns on the p ortfo lio over the tim e period and is a measure o f the to ta l risk o f the p ortfo lio . I f the Sharpe ratio o f the investors p ortfo lio exceeds the Sharpe ratio o f the m arket p ortfolio, then the investors p o rtfo lio has generated a greater excess return per u n it o f to ta l risk and hence is regarded as exhibiting superior performance to the m arket p ortfolio. Conversely, i f the p o rtfo lio s Sharpe ratio is less than th a t o f the m arket p ortfo lio then the p o rtfo lio has generated less excess return per u n it o f to ta l risk than the m arket p o rtfo lio and the p ortfo lio can be seen as having underperform ed th a t benchmark. 15 See Sharpe (1966). a n d return B usiness finance The rationale behind the use o f the Sharpe ratio is best demonstrated by considering the ratios links w ith the ris k -re tu rn trade-off described by the capital m arket line discussed in section 7.6.1. Consider Figure 7.13, which illustrates the risk and retu rn profile fo r a superannuation fu nd s p o rtfo lio relative to the m arket p ortfolio. Note from Figure 7.13 that the superannuation fu nd s p ortfo lio has generated a lower rate o f return than the m arket p o rtfo lio but has also generated a lower level o f to ta l risk. That is, while fp is less than is also less than The key point, however, is th a t the realised excess retu rn per unit o f risk is higher fo r the fu nd s p o rtfo lio compared w ith the m arket p o rtfo lio and hence the fu n d s p ortfo lio is regarded as having exhibited superior performance. This is illustrated in Figure 7.13 by the fu nd s p ortfolio p lo ttin g above the capital m arket line. I f the fu nd s p o rtfo lio had generated a lower excess retu rn per u n it o f risk than the m arket p ortfo lio , then i t would have plotted below the capital m arket line and this would have im plied th a t the p o rtfo lio had underperformed the benchmark on a to ta l risk-adjusted basis. Note th a t the Sharpe ratio assumes th a t in determ ining the risk-adjusted performance o f a p ortfo lio the appropriate measure o f risk is to ta l risk. Following on from our discussion earlier in the chapter, it is clear th a t to ta l risk is an appropriate measure only when we are dealing w ith well-diversified portfolios rather than individual assets or undiversified portfolios. The Treynor ratio The Treynor ratio, named after Jack T re yn o r16, is a measure th a t is related to the Sharpe ratio of performance measurement, in th a t it measures excess returns per u n it o f risk, b ut differs in th a t it defines risk as non-diversifiable (or systematic) risk instead o f to ta l risk. I t can be calculated using the follow ing form ula: P p where Op and fr are the returns on the p o rtfo lio and the risk-free asset as defined earlier, and f3P is slu estimate o f the systematic risk o f the p o rtfo lio over the period in which the returns were generated, as measured by beta and defined in Section 7.6.2. As w ith the Sharpe ratio, insights in to the rationale behind the use o f the Treynor ratio are provided by considering the lin k between ris k and expected retu rn — b u t this tim e, instead o f considering the trade-off fo r efficient portfolios im plied by the capital 16 See Treynor (1966). C hapter seven Risk market line, we tu rn instead to the security m arket line, which applies to individual assets and inefficient portfolios. In Figure 7.14 we compare the ex-post systematic risk and excess returns o f a superannuation fund relative to the m arket p o rtfo lio over the same period o f time. Recall th a t the security m arket line is sim ply the graphical representation o f the CAPM. The slope o f the security m arket line describes the extra return, in excess o f the risk-free rate, th a t is expected for each additional u n it o f systematic risk (as measured by beta) and is w hat we have previously defined as the m arket risk premium The slope o f the line th a t intersects the realised systematic risk and return o f the funds p o rtfo lio is in tu rn the Treynor ratio. Hence, the decision rule used in assessing the performance o f a p o rtfo lio using this technique requires a comparison o f the Treynor ratio calculated fo r the p ortfolio over a specified interval w ith the market risk prem ium generated over th a t same interval. Example 7.3 illustrates the three approaches to p o rtfo lio appraisal discussed above. E xample 7.3 An investor holds a portfolio that consists of shares in 15 companies and wants to assess the performance using a simple benchmark index as well as calculating the portfolio's Sharpe and Treynor ratios. She estimates the parameters shown in Table 7.6 for the financial year ended 30 June 2014. TABLE 7.6 Realised return (% p.a.) Standard deviation of returns (a) (% p.a.) Systematic risk estimate (p) Portfolio 13 30 1.2 S&P/ASX 200 share price index 11 20 1.0 Government bonds 5 0 0 Based solely on the benchmark index approach, the portfolio appears to have performed well in that it has generated an additional 2 per cent return above the proxy for the market (S&P/ASX 200). a n d return A s d is c u s s e d e a r lie r , h o w e v e r, th is a s s e s s m e n t fa ils to a c c o u n t fo r d iffe re n c e s in th e ris k p ro file s o f th e tw o p o r tfo lio s . T h e S h a r p e r a t io is e s tim a te d u s in g E q u a tio n 7 . 1 7 f o r b o th th e in v e s to r's p o r tf o lio a n d th e A S X 2 0 0 a s fo llo w s : 5 = ^ (7 P 1 3 -5 SPortfolio • 30 ~ 1 1 -5 ^ASX 200 20 0.27 = 0.30 A s th e S h a r p e r a t io f o r th e p o r tf o lio is less th a n th a t o f th e S & P /A S X 2 0 0 , th e in v e s to r c o n c lu d e s th a t th e p o r tf o lio h a s u n d e r p e r fo rm e d th e m a rk e t o n a ris k -a d ju s te d b a s is . A p o s s ib le p r o b le m w ith th is c o n c lu s io n is th a t, a s d e s c r ib e d a b o v e , th e S h a rp e r a t io a ssu m e s th a t th e r e le v a n t m e a s u re o f ris k fo r th e in v e s to r is to ta l ris k , a s m e a s u re d b y th e s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f re tu rn s . T h is is n o t th e c a s e w h e r e , f o r e x a m p le , th e p o r tf o lio o f s h a re s re p re s e n ts o n ly o n e c o m p o n e n t o f th e in v e s to r’s o v e r a ll set o f assets. T h e T re y n o r ra tio s f o r th e p o r tf o lio a n d f o r th e A S X 2 0 0 a r e m e a s u re d a s fo llo w s : rp -'rf Pp 1 3 -5 1.2 1Portfolio T 'A S X 200 • 6.67 1 1 -5 1.0 6 N o te th a t th e T re y n o r r a t io f o r th e S & P /A S X 2 0 0 is s im p ly e q u a l to th e m a rk e t ris k p re m iu m o f 6 p e r c e n t. A s th e T re y n o r r a tio o f th e p o r tf o lio e x c e e d s th is a m o u n t th e in v e s to r c o n c lu d e s th a t th e p o r tf o lio h a s o u tp e r fo r m e d th e m a rk e t o n a s y s te m a tic ris k -a d ju s te d b a s is . W e c a n r e c o n c ile th is re s u lt w ith th e s e e m in g ly c o n t r a r y re su lts p r o v id e d b y th e S h a rp e r a t io b y a c k n o w le d g in g th a t s o m e o f th e p o r tf o lio ris k th a t is a c c o u n te d fo r in th e S h a rp e r a tio m a y a c tu a lly b e d iv e r s ifie d a w a y o n c e w e a c c o u n t fo r th e o th e r asse ts in th e in v e s to r's p o r tf o lio . T h e re fo re , in th is c a s e , th e T re y n o r r a t io p r o v id e s th e m o re s u ita b le a s s e s s m e n t o f th e p e r fo r m a n c e o f th e p o r tf o lio re la tiv e to th e m a rk e t g e n e r a lly , as it c o n s id e rs o n ly th a t ris k th a t c a n n o t b e e lim in a te d b y d iv e r s ific a tio n . Jensen’s alpha Jensens alpha is a measure pioneered by Michael Jensen17 and relies on a m ulti-pe rio d analysis o f the performance o f an investm ent p o rtfo lio relative to some proxy fo r the m arket generally. Recall that the CAPM suggests th a t the relationship between systematic risk and retu rn is fu lly described by the follow ing equation: E iR ^ R f+ m R ^ -R f) The CAPM is an ex-ante single-period model, in the sense th a t it is concerned w ith the returns that m ig ht be expected over the next tim e period. Its conclusion is relatively simple: the retu rn in excess o f the risk-free rate th a t we expect any asset i to generate is determ ined only by the level o f systematic risk reflected in the assets fi. We compute Jensens alpha by im plem enting an ex-post m ulti-period regression analysis o f the returns on the p o rtfo lio and the returns on the m arket and ask the question: Is there any evidence o f systematic abnormal retu rn performance th a t cannot be explained by the p o rtfo lio s systematic risk? The regression equation estimated is as follows: rP ,t _ r f , t= a P + [rM,r_ rfA + e t where t and are the returns from the p ortfo lio , the risk-free asset and the proxy fo r the m arket p o rtfo lio th a t have been observed in period t. /3P is an estimate o f the p o rtfo lio s beta over the entire period in which returns were collected. Qp is an estimate o f Jensens alpha and reflects the incremental 17 See Jensen (1968 & 1969). C hapter seven Risk a n d return performance o f the p o rtfo lio after accounting fo r the variation in p o rtfo lio returns th a t can be explained by market-wide returns. I f 〇 tp is positive, and statistically significant, then this is an indication th a t the p o rtfo lio has outperformed the market, on a risk-adjusted basis, and may be interpreted as evidence o f a p o rtfo lio managers skill in managing the p ortfolio. Conversely, a statistically significant negative estimate o f Qp m ight be interpreted as evidence th a t the p o rtfo lio managers actions in managing the p o rtfo lio are actually destroying value! There are many other techniques th a t have been developed by academics and practitioners to try to assess the performance o f investm ent portfolios and each technique brings w ith it both advantages and disadvantages over the alternative approaches.18 W hile much o f the preceding discussion has been concerned w ith measuring the relative performance o f a p ortfolio, another issue facing managers and investors is how much o f the performance o f a p o rtfo lio may be a ttributed to the different decisions made by the investment manager. Specifically, as described at the beginning o f Section 7.8, an investor may be concerned w ith how the performance has been affected by the managers decisions w ith respect to asset allocation, market tim in g and security selection as well as the possible interactions between each o f these decisions. This c h a p te r d is c u s s e d tw o m a in issues. The • firs t, S y s te m a tic ris k depends on th e c o v a r ia n c e b e tw e e n th e re tu rn s o n th e a sse t a n d re tu rn s o n th e p o r tfo lio th e o ry , c o n c e rn s th e a p p r o a c h th a t c a n b e use d b y ris k -a v e rs e in v e s to rs to s e c u re th e b e s t tr a d e ­ m a rk e t p o r tf o lio , w h ic h c o n ta in s a ll ris k y assets. o ff b e tw e e n risk a n d re tu rn . S e c o n d , th e c h a p te r d e a lt T he s y s te m a tic ris k o f a n a s s e t is u s u a lly m e a s u re d in v o lv e s th e b y th e a s se t's b e ta fa c to r, w h ic h m e a s u re s th e risk r e la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n ris k a n d re tu rn in th e m a r k e t fo r o f th e a s s e t re la tiv e to th e ris k o f th e m a rk e t as ris k y assets. a w h o le . R isk-a ve rse in v e s to rs w ill a im w ith th e p r ic in g • o f ris k y a sse ts, w h ic h T he e s s e n tia l m e s s a g e o f p o r tf o lio d iv e r s ific a tio n re d u c e s ris k . th e o ry It is a ls o is th a t show n h ig h e s t e x p e c te d re tu rn fo r a g iv e n le ve l o f risk. th a t T he set o f e ffic ie n t p o r tfo lio s fo rm s th e e ffic ie n t th e e ffe c tiv e n e s s o f d iv e r s ific a tio n d e p e n d s o n th e c o r r e la tio n o r c o v a r ia n c e in d iv id u a l b e tw e e n assets c o m b in e d in to a fro n tie r, a n d in a m a rk e t w h e r e o n ly ris k y assets re tu rn s o n th e p o r tf o lio . a r e a v a ila b le , e a c h in v e s to r w ill a im to h o ld a T he g a in s fro m d iv e r s ific a tio n a r e la rg e s t w h e n th e re is n e g a tiv e c o r r e la tio n b e tw e e n a s s e t re tu rn s , b u t th e y p o r tf o lio s o m e w h e re o n th e e ffic ie n t fro n tie r. • th a n p e rfe c t. In p r a c tic e , th e p o s itiv e a n d e x p e c te d re tu rn f o r in d iv id u a l ris k y a sse ts. T he is less m a in re s u lt is th e C A P M , w h ic h p ro p o s e s th a t th e re c o r r e la tio n is a lin e a r r e la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n th e e x p e c te d ra te th a t e xis ts b e tw e e n th e re tu rn s o n m o st ris k y assets o f re tu rn o n a n a s s e t a n d its ris k a s m e a s u re d b y its im p o s e s a lim it o n th e d e g r e e o f ris k r e d u c tio n th a t c a n b e a c h ie v e d b y d iv e r s ific a tio n . • T he to ta l ris k o f a n a s s e t c a n b e d iv id e d in to tw o b e ta fa c to r. • u n s y s te m a tic ris k th a t re m a in s in a w e ll- d iv e rs ifie d p o r tf o lio is s y s te m a tic ris k . • T he ris k o f a w e ll- d iv e rs ifie d p o r tf o lio can be m e a s u re d b y th e s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n o f p o r tf o lio re tu rn s . H o w e v e r, a n a ly s is o f th e fa c to rs th a t c o n trib u te to th is s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n s h o w s th a t, asset re tu rn s p r ic in g a re m o d e ls lin e a r ly p ro p o s e re la te d to th a t m u ltip le fa c to rs ra th e r th a n th e s in g le m a rk e t fa c to r p ro p o s e d ris k th a t can b e e lim in a te d b y d iv e r s ific a tio n . It f o llo w s th a t th e o n ly A lte r n a tiv e e x p e c te d p a rts : s y s te m a tic ris k th a t ca n n o t b e e lim in a te d b y d iv e r s ific a tio n , a n d In tro d u c tio n o f a ris k -fre e a s s e t a llo w s th e a n a ly s is to b e e x te n d e d to m o d e l th e r e la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n ris k still e x is t w h e n th e re is p o s itiv e c o r r e la tio n b e tw e e n a s s e t re tu rn s , p r o v id e d th a t th e c o r r e la tio n to h o ld p o r tfo lio s th a t a r e e ffic ie n t in th a t th e y p r o v id e th e b y th e C A P M . • A s s e s s m e n t o f th e p e r fo r m a n c e o f an in v e s tm e n t p o r tf o lio re q u ire s th e s p e c ific a tio n o f th e 'e x p e c t e d ' p e r fo r m a n c e o f a b e n c h m a r k p o r tfo lio . An e x c e lle n t s ite w ith r e la tin g to th is t o p ic is a w e a lth of in fo r m a tio n vsww.wsharpe.com. P ro fe s s o r W illia m S h a rp e 's w o r k w a s r e c o g n is e d w ith a N o b e l fo r in v e s to rs w h o d iv e rs ify , th e re le v a n t m e a s u re P riz e in 1 9 9 0 . F in a n c ia l a d v is o r y in fo r m a tio n c a n a ls o o f ris k f o r a n in d iv id u a l a s s e t is its s y s te m a tic risk. b e fo u n d a t www.moneysmart.gov.au. 18 See Chapter 24 of Bodie, Kane and Marcus (2013) for an excellent review of some of these alternative techniques, and a comprehensive description of other issues faced when assessing portfolio performance. CHAPTER SEVEN REVIEW SUMMARY B usiness finance KEY TERMS b e ta 187 c a p ita l m a rk e t lin e m a rk e t m o d e l s e c u rity m a rk e t lin e 193 s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n 174 s y s te m a tic (m a rk e 卜 re la te d o r n o n -d iv e rs ifia b le ) 195 m a rk e t p o r tfo lio p o r tfo lio 192 192 ris k 179 186 u n s y s te m a tic (d iv e rs ifia b le ) ris k ris k -a v e rs e in v e s to r 176 v a lu e a t ris k ris k -n e u tra l in v e s to r 176 v a r ia n c e ris k -s e e k in g in v e s to r 186 187 174 176 SELF-TEST PROBLEMS 1 A n in v e s to r p la c e s 3 0 p e r c e n t o f h is fu n d s in S e c u rity X a n d th e b a la n c e in S e c u rity Y. T he e x p e c te d re tu rn s o n X a n d Y a r e 1 2 a n d 1 8 p e r c e n t, re s p e c tiv e ly . T he s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n s o f re tu rn s o n X a n d Y a r e 2 0 a n d 1 5 p e r c e n t, re s p e c tiv e ly . a) C a lc u la te th e e x p e c te d re tu rn o n th e p o r tfo lio . b) C a lc u la te th e v a r ia n c e o f re tu rn s o n th e p o r tfo lio a s s u m in g th a t th e c o r r e la tio n b e tw e e n th e re tu rn s o n th e tw o s e c u ritie s is: i) + 1 . 0 ii) + 0 . 7 iii) 0 iv) - 0 . 7 2 A n in v e s to r h o ld s a p o r tf o lio th a t c o m p ris e s 2 0 p e r c e n t X, 3 0 p e r c e n t Y a n d 5 0 p e r c e n t Z . T h e s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n s o f re tu rn s o n X, Y a n d Z a re 2 2 , 1 5 a n d 1 0 p e r ce n t, re s p e c tiv e ly , a n d th e c o r r e la tio n b e tw e e n re tu rn s o n e a c h p a ir o f s e c u ritie s is 0 . 6 . P re p a re a v a r ia n c e - c o v a r ia n c e m a tr ix f o r th e se th re e s e c u ritie s a n d use th e m a tr ix to c a lc u la te th e v a r ia n c e a n d s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n o f re tu rn s f o r th e p o r tfo lio . 3 T he ris k -fre e r a te o f re tu rn is c u r r e n tly 8 p e r c e n t a n d th e m a rk e t ris k p re m iu m is e s tim a te d to b e 6 p e r c e n t. T h e e x p e c te d re tu rn s a n d b e ta s o f fo u r s h a re s a r e a s fo llo w s : Expected return [%) Beta Carltown 13.0 0.7 Pivot 17.6 Forresters 14.0 i.i Brunswick 10.4 0.4 I S h a re 丨 W h ic h sh a re s a re u n d e rv a lu e d , o v e r v a lu e d o r c o rre c tly v a lu e d b a s e d o n th e C A P M ? Solutions to self-test problems are available in Appendix B. t y 1 [LO 1] QUESTIONS F a rm e rs c a n in s u re th e ir c r o p s a g a in s t d a m a g e b y h a ils to rm s a t r e a s o n a b le ra te s . H o w e v e r , th e s a m e in s u ra n c e c o m p a n ie s re fu s e to p r o v id e f lo o d in s u ra n c e a t a n y p r ic e . E x p la in w h y th is s itu a tio n e xists. 2 [LO 2] Is ris k a v e rs io n a r e a s o n a b le a s s u m p tio n ? W h a t is th e re le v a n t m e a s u re o f ris k f o r a ris k -a v e rs e in v e s to r? 204 C hapter seven Risk [L O 3 i W h a t a r e th e b e n e fits o f d iv e r s ific a tio n to a n in v e s to r? W h a t is th e k e y fa c to r d e te r m in in g th e e x te n t o f th e se b e n e fits ? 4 [LO 4 ] E x p la in e a c h o f th e f o llo w in g : a) th e e 仟 ic ie n t fro n tie r b) th e c a p ita l m a rk e t lin e c) th e s e c u rity m a rk e t lin e . Risky assets con be combined to form a riskless asset. D iscuss. 5 [L O 5 ] 6 [L O 5 】Whenever 7 [L O 6 ] an asset is added to a portfolio, the total risk o f the portfolio w ill be reduced p rovided the returns o f the asset and the portfolio ore less than perfectly correlated. D iscuss. Total risk can be decomposed into systematic and unsystematic risk. E x p la in e a c h c o m p o n e n t o f ris k , a n d h o w e a c h is a ffe c te d b y in c re a s in g th e n u m b e r o f s e c u ritie s in a p o r tfo lio . 8 [L O 7 】Diversification is certainly good for investors. Therefore, investors should be prepared to p ay a premium for the shores o f companies that operate in several lines o f business. E x p la in w h y th is s ta te m e n t is tru e o r fa ls e . 9 [L O 7 】M in c o Ltd, a la r g e m in in g c o m p a n y , p r o v id e s a s u p e r a n n u a tio n fu n d fo r its e m p lo y e e s . T he fu n d 's m a n a g e r s a y s : 'W e k n o w th e m in in g in d u s try w e ll, so w e fe e l c o m fo r ta b le in v e s tin g m o s t o f th e fu n d in a p o r tf o lio o f m in in g c o m p a n y s h a re s ’ . A d v is e M in c o ’s e m p lo y e e s o n w h e th e r to e n d o rs e th e fu n d ’s in v e s tm e n t p o lic y . C H A P T E R SEVEN! R E V I E W 3 a n d return An important conclusion o f the CAPM is that the relevant measure o f an asset's risk is its systematic risk. O u tlin e th e s ig n ific a n c e o f th is c o n c lu s io n fo r a m a n a g e r m a k in g f in a n c ia l d e c is io n s . 10 [L O 8 ] 11 [L O 8 】F o r in v e s to rs w h o a im to d iv e rs ify , s h a re s w ith n e g a tiv e b e ta s w o u ld b e v e r y u se fu l in v e s tm e n ts , b u t such s h a re s a r e v e r y ra re . E x p la in w h y f e w s h a re s h a v e n e g a tiv e b e ta s . 12 [LO 8 ] C o m p a r e a n d c o n tra s t th e c a p it a l a s s e t p r ic in g m o d e l a n d m o d e ls th a t in c lu d e a d d itio n a l fa c to rs . 13 [L O 1 1 ] In w h a t s itu a tio n s w o u ld it b e a p p r o p r ia t e to use a s im p le b e n c h m a r k in d e x , such a s th e S & P /A S X 14 [L O ll] 2 0 0 s h a re p r ic e in d e x , to assess th e p e r fo r m a n c e o f a p o r tfo lio ? When assessing the performance o f o set o f portfolios it does not really matter if you choose the Shorpe ratio or the Treynor ratio to do so os both approaches account for the risk inherent in the portfolios. D iscuss. PROBLEMS 1 V a lu e a t r is k [L O 1 ] C o n s id e r a p o r tfo lio c o m p ris in g a $ 3 m illio n in v e s tm e n t in O u tlo o k P u b lis h in g a n d a $ 5 m illio n in v e s tm e n t in Russell C o m p u tin g . A s s u m e th a t th e s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n s o f th e re tu rn s fo r sh a re s in the se c o m p a n ie s a r e 0 . 4 a n d 0 . 2 5 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m re s p e c tiv e ly . A s s u m e a ls o th a t th e c o r r e la tio n b e tw e e n th e re tu rn s o n th e sh a re s in these c o m p a n ie s is 0 . 7 . A s s u m in g a 1 p e r c e n t c h a n c e o f a b n o r m a lly b a d m a rk e t c o n d itio n s , c a lc u la te th e v a lu e a t risk o f th is p o r tfo lio . S tate a n y a s s u m p tio n s th a t y o u m a k e in y o u r c a lc u la tio n s . 2 In v e s tm e n t a n d r is k [L O 2 ] M r B o b N e il is c o n s id e r in g a 1 -y e a r in v e s tm e n t in sh a re s in o n e o f th e f o llo w in g th re e c o m p a n ie s . • C o m p a n y X: e x p e c te d re tu rn = 1 5% w ith a s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n o f 1 5% • C o m p a n y Y: e x p e c te d re tu rn = 1 5 % w ith a s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n o f 2 0 % • C o m p a n y Z : e x p e c te d re tu rn = 2 0 % w ith a s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n o f 2 0 % R a n k th e in ve s tm e n ts in o r d e r o f p re fe re n c e fo r e a c h o f th e ca s e s w h e r e it is a s s u m e d th a t M r B o b N e il is: a) risk a v e rs e b) risk n e u tra l c) risk s e e k in g . G iv e re a s o n s . 205 Portfolio standard deviation and diversification [LO 3] The s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n s o f re tu rn s o n assets A a n d B a r e 8 p e r c e n t a n d 1 2 p e r c e n t, re s p e c tiv e ly . A p o r tfo lio is c o n s tru c te d c o n s is tin g o f 4 0 p e r c e n t in A s s e t A a n d 6 0 p e r c e n t in A sse t B. C a lc u la te th e p o r tfo lio s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n if th e c o r r e la tio n o f re tu rn s b e tw e e n th e tw o assets is: a) 1 b) 0 .4 c) 0 d) -1 G om m ^nt on y o u 「 a n s w e rs . Expected return, variance and risk [LO 3] You b e lie v e th a t th e re is a 5 0 p e r c e n t c h a n c e th a t th e s h a re p r ic e o f C o m p a n y L w ill d e c re a s e b y 1 2 p e r c e n t a n d a 5 0 p e r c e n t c h a n c e th a t it w ill in c re a s e b y 2 4 p e r ce n t. F urther, th e re is a 4 0 p e r c e n t c h a n c e th a t th e s h a re p r ic e o f C o m p a n y M w ill d e c re a s e b y 1 2 p e r c e n t a n d a 6 0 p e r c e n t c h a n c e th a t it w ill in c re a s e b y 2 4 p e r ce n t. T h e c o rre la tio n c o e ffic ie n t o f th e re tu rn s o n sh a re s in th e tw o c o m p a n ie s is 0 . 7 5 . C a lc u la te : a) th e e x p e c te d re tu rn , v a r ia n c e a n d s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n fo r e a c h c o m p a n y 's sh a re s b) th e c o v a r ia n c e b e tw e e n th e ir return s. Variance of return [LO 5] A n in v e s to r p la c e s 4 0 p e r c e n t o f h e r fu n d s in C o m p a n y A 's sh a re s a n d th e r e m a in d e r in C o m p a n y B7s sha res. T he s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n o f th e re tu rn s o n A is 2 0 p e r c e n t a n d o n B is 1 0 p e r c e n t. C a lc u la te th e v a r ia n c e o f re tu rn o n th e p o r tfo lio , a s s u m in g th a t th e c o r r e la tio n b e tw e e n th e re tu rn s o n th e tw o se c u ritie s is: a) + 1 .0 b) + 0 .5 c) 〇 d) -0 .5 Expected return, risk and diversification [LO 5 】 H a r r y Jo n e s h a s in v e s te d o n e -th ird o f his fu n d s in S h a re 1 a n d tw o -th ird s o f his fu n d s in S h a re 2 . H is asse ssm en t o f e a c h in v e s tm e n t is as fo llo w s : Item S h a re 1 S h a re 2 Expected return (%) 15.0 21.0 Standard deviation (%) 18.0 25.0 Correlation between the returns 0.5 a) b) W h a t a re th e e x p e c te d re tu rn a n d th e s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n o f re tu rn o n H a r r y 's p o rtfo lio ? R e c a lc u la te th e e x p e c te d re tu rn a n d th e s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n w h e r e th e c o r r e la tio n b e tw e e n th e re tu rn s is 0 a n d 1 .0 , re s p e c tiv e ly . c) Is H a r r y b e tte r o r w o r s e o ff as a re su lt o f in v e s tin g in tw o s e c u ritie s ra th e r th a n in o n e se c u rity ? Expected return, risk and diversification [LO 5] A 12.5 40 1.00 0.20 0.35 B 16.0 45 0.20 1.00 0.10 C 20.0 60 0.35 0.10 1.00 C hapter seven Risk a n d return a) P o rtfo lio 1 co n sists o f 4 0 p e r c e n t A s s e t A a n d 6 0 p e r c e n t A sse t B. C a lc u la te its e x p e c te d re tu rn a n d s ta n d ­ a r d d e v ia tio n . b) P o rtfo lio 2 co n sists o f 6 0 p e r c e n t A sse t A , 2 2 . 5 p e r c e n t A s s e t B a n d 1 7 .5 p e r c e n t A s s e t C . C a lc u la te its e x p e c te d re tu rn a n d s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n . C o m p a re y o u r a n s w e rs to (a) a n d c o m m e n t. c) P o rtfo lio 3 co n sists o f 4 . 8 p e r c e n t A s s e t A , 7 5 p e r c e n t A s s e t B a n d 2 0 . 2 p e r c e n t in th e risk-fre e asset. C a lc u la te its e x p e c te d re tu rn a n d s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n . C o m p a re y o u r a n s w e rs to (a) a n d (b) a n d c o m m e n t. d) P o rtfo lio 4 is a n e q u a lly w e ig h te d p o r tfo lio o f th e th re e ris k y assets A , B a n d C . C a lc u la te its e x p e c te d re tu rn a n d s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n a n d c o m m e n t o n the se results. e) P o rtfo lio 5 is a n e q u a lly w e ig h te d p o r tfo lio o f a ll fo u r assets. C a lc u la te its e x p e c te d re tu rn a n d s ta n d a r d d e v ia tio n a n d c o m m e n t o n th e se results. 8 Expected return and systematic risk [LO 7 】 The e x p e c te d re tu rn o n th e /th a sse t is g iv e n b y: E L R f+_ R a) M]-R f 、 W h a t is th e e x p e c te d re tu rn o n th e /th a sse t w h e r e Rf = 0 . 0 8 , fi- = 1 . 2 5 a n d f(/?yvi) = 0 . 1 4 ? b) W h a t is th e e x p e c te d re tu rn o n th e m a rk e t p o r tf o lio w h e r e E(Rj) = 0 . 1 1 , c) 9 = 0 . 0 8 a n d p y= 0 . 7 5 ? W h a t is th e s y s te m a tic ris k o f th e /th a sse t w h e re E(Rt ) = 0 . 1 4 , ^ = 0 . 1 0 a n d E(RM) = 0 . 1 5 ? Assessing diversification benefits [LO 7 】 CHAPTER SEVEN REVIEW T h e re is a ls o a risk-fre e A s s e t F w h o s e e x p e c te d re tu rn is 9 . 9 p e r ce n t. You a re a s h a re a n a ly s t e m p lo y e d b y a la r g e m u ltin a tio n a l in v e s tm e n t fu n d a n d h a v e b e e n s u p p lie d w ith th e fo llo w in g in fo rm a tio n : S ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n (%) E x p e c te d re tu rn (%) A sse t BHZ Ltd 9 8 ANB Ltd 13 48 1 You a re a ls o to ld th a t th e c o r r e la tio n c o e ffic ie n t b e tw e e n th e re tu rn s o f th e tw o c o m p a n ie s is 0 . 8 . A c lie n t c u rre n tly h a s a ll o f h e r w e a lth in v e s te d in B H Z s h a re s. S he w is h e s to d iv e r s ify h e r p o r tf o lio b y re d is trib u tin g h e r w e a lth such th a t 3 0 p e r c e n t is in v e s te d in B H Z sh a re s a n d 7 0 p e r c e n t in A N B sh a re s. a) W h a t w ill b e th e e x p e c te d re tu rn o f th e n e w p o r tfo lio ? b) W h a t w ill b e th e s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n o f re tu rn s fo r th e n e w p o rtfo lio ? A fte r c o n s tru c tin g th e p o r tfo lio a n d r e p o r tin g th e results to y o u r c lie n t, she is q u ite u p se t, s a y in g , 7I th o u g h t th e w h o le p u rp o s e o f d iv e r s ific a tio n w a s to re d u c e risk? Yet y o u h a v e ju st to ld m e th a t th e v a r ia b ility o f m y p o r tfo lio h a s a c tu a lly b e e n in c re a s e d fro m w h a t it w a s w h e n I in v e s te d o n ly in B H Z ’ . c) P ro v id e a re s p o n s e to y o u r c lie n t th a t d e m o n s tra te s th a t th e n e w p o r tfo lio d o e s o r d o e s n o t re fle c t th e b e n e ­ fits o f d iv e rs ific a tio n . S h o w a ll n e c e s s a ry c a lc u la tio n s . 10 Portfolio weights systematic risk and unsystematic risk [LO 8 】 T he ta b le p ro v id e s d a ta o n tw o ris k y assets, A a n d B, th e m a rk e t p o r tf o lio M a n d th e ris k-fre e a sse t F. Asset E x p e c te d re tu rn (%) A A 10.8 324 60 48 0 B 15.6 60 289 96 0 M 14.0 48 96 80 0 F 6.0 0 0 0 0 A n in v e s to r w is h e s to a c h ie v e a n e x p e c te d re tu rn o f 1 2 p e r c e n t a n d is c o n s id e rin g th re e w a y s this m a y b e done: a) in v e s t in A a n d B b) in v e s t in B a n d F c) in v e s t in M a n d F. 207 B usiness finance F or e a c h o f th e se o p tio n s , c a lc u la te th e p o r tfo lio w e ig h ts r e q u ire d a n d th e p o r tfo lio s ta n d a rd d e v ia tio n . S h o w th a t assets A a n d B a re p r ic e d a c c o r d in g to th e c a p ita l a sse t p r ic in g m o d e l a n d , in th e lig h t o f th is result, c o m m e n t o n y o u r fin d in g s . 11 Portfolio performance appraisal [LO 11 ] In 2 0 1 4 th e re tu rn o n th e F o rt K n o x Fund w a s 1 0 p e r ce n t, w h ile th e re tu rn o n th e m a rk e t p o r tfo lio w a s 1 2 p e r c e n t a n d th e risk-fre e re tu rn w a s 3 p e r ce n t. C o m p a ra tiv e sta tistics a r e s h o w n in th e ta b le b e lo w . S ta tis tic F o rt K n o x fu n d S & P /A S X 2 0 0 sh a re p r ic e in d e x Standard deviation of return 15% 30% Beta 0.75 1.00 C a lc u la te a n d c o m m e n t o n th e p e rfo rm a n c e o f th e fu n d u s in g th e fo llo w in g th re e a p p ro a c h e s : a) th e s im p le b e n c h m a rk in d e x b) th e S h a rp e ra tio c) th e T re y n o r ra tio . REFERENCES Bodie, Z., Kane, A. & Marcus, A.J., /nvesfmenfs, 1 1th edn, M cG raw-H ill, N e w York, 20 1 3 . ------ , ------- 7 'The equity premium,/ Journal o f Finance, April 2 0 0 2 , pp. 6 3 7 -5 9 . Brailsford, T. & Faff, R., 'A derivation o f the CAPM for pedagogical use', Accounting a n d Finance, M a y 1993, pp. 5 3 -6 0 . Heaton, J. & Lucas, P ortfolio choice and asset prices: the importance of entrepreneurial risk', Journal of Finance, June 2 0 0 0 , pp. 1 1 6 3 -9 8 . -------, ------- & Oliver, B.; Research Design Issues in the Estimation of Beta, M cG raw -H ill, Sydney, 1997. Ibbotson, R.G. & Goetzmann, W . N ., 'History and the equity risk premium', A pril 2 0 0 5 , Yale ICF W orking Paper No. 0 5 -0 4 . Available at h ttp ://s s rn .c o m /a b s tra c t-7 0 2 3 4 1 . ------ , Gaunt, C. & O 'Brien, M ., 'Size and book-tomarket factors in Australia7, Australian Journal of Management, August 2 0 1 2 , pp. 2 6 1 -8 1 . ------ , Handley, J. & M aheswaran, K., The historical equity risk premium in Australia: post-GFC and 128 years of data7, Accounting and Finance, M arch 2 0 1 2 , pp. 2 3 7 -4 7 . Carhart, M . M w 'O n persistence in mutual fund performance', Journal of Finance, March 1997, pp. 5 7 -8 2 . Claus, J. & Thomas, J., 'Equity premia as low as three per cent? Evidence from analysts' earnings forecasts for domestic and international stock markets7, Journal of Finance, O ctober 2 0 0 1 , pp. 1 6 2 9 -6 6 . Coleman, L, M aheswaran, K. & Pinder, S., 'Narratives in managers, corporate finance decisions', Accounting and Finance, September 2 0 1 0 ; pp. 6 0 5 -3 3 . Dimson, E., Marsh, P.R., Staunton, M . & G arthwaite, A., Credit Suisse G lobal Investment Returns Yearbook, Credit Suisse A G Research Institute, Zurich, 20 1 3 . Fama, E.F., 'Risk, return and equilibrium : some clarifying comments', J o u rn o /o f F/nonce, M arch 1968, pp. 2 9 -4 0 . -------, Foundations of Finance, Basic Books, N ew York, 1976. ------ & French, K.R., 'The cross-section of expected stock returns', Journal of Finance, June 1 9 9 2 ; pp. 4 2 7 -6 5 . ------ , ------- , 'Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds', Journal of Financial Economics, February 1993, pp. 3 -5 6 . ------ , ------- , 'M ultifactor explanations o f asset pricing anomalies', Journal of Finance, March 1996, pp. 5 5 -8 4 . 208 Jegadeesh, N . & Titman, S., 'Returns to buying winners and selling losers: implications for market efficiency7, Journal of Finance, 1993, pp. 6 5 -9 1 . Jensen, M ., The performance of mutual funds in the period 1 9 4 5 -1 9 6 4 ', Jo u rn o /o f F/nonce, M a y 1 9 6 8 ; pp. 3 8 9 -4 1 6 . ------ , 'Risk, the pricing of capital assets, and the evaluation of investment portfolios', Journal of Business, April 1969, pp. 1 6 7 -2 4 7 . -------, 'C apital markets: theory and evidence7, Bell Journal of Economics a n d M anagem ent Science, Autumn 1972, pp. 3 5 7 -9 8 . Jorion, Value at Risk: The N e w Benchmark for Controlling Market Risk, 3rd edn, M cG raw -H ill, Chicago, 2 0 0 6 . -------& Goetzmann, W .N ., ’G lobal stock markets in the twentieth century,/ Journal of Finance, June 1999, pp. 9 5 3 -8 0 . Levy, H. & Sarnat, M ., Capitol Investment a n d Financial Decisions, 4th edn; Prentice-Hall, N ew Jersey, 1990, pp. 3 1 9 -2 2 . Lintner, J., ;The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets', Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1965, pp. 1 3 -3 7 . M arkow itz, H .M ., 'Portfolio selection', Journal of Finance, M arch 19 52 , pp. 7 7 -9 1 . -------, Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments, John W ile y & Sons, N ew York, 1959. C hapter seven Risk Sharpe, W.F., 'C apital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk', Journal of Finance, September 1964, pp. 4 2 5 -4 2 . Mossin, Jw 'Security pricing and investment criteria in competitive markets’,Amencan Econom/’c /?eWew, December 1969, pp. 7 4 9 -5 6 . -------, 'Mutual fund performance', Journal of Business, January 1966, pp. 1 1 9 -3 8 PricewaterhouseCoopers, Investigation into Foreign Exchange Losses at the National Australia Bank, Melbourne, 2004. Statman, M ., 'H ow many stocks make a diversified portfolio?', Joumcr/ o f F/ncmaa/ anc/ Gt/cmf/faf/Ve September 1987, pp. 3 5 3 -6 3 . Ritter, J.R., The biggest mistakes we teach7, Journal of Financial Research, Summer 2 0 0 2 , pp. 1 5 9 -6 8 . Treynor, J.L, 'H ow to rate management investment funds', January 1966, Harvard Business Review, pp. 6 3 -7 5 . Roll, R., 'A critique of the asset pricing theory's tests; Part 1: On the past and potential testability of the theory', Journal of Financial Economics, March 19 77 , pp. 1 2 6 -7 6 . Zhang, L., The value premium', Journal of Finance, February 2 0 0 5 , pp. 6 7 -1 0 3 . CHAPTER SEVEM REVIEW Mehra, R. (& Prescott, E.C., 'The equity premium: a puzzle', Journal of Monetary Economics, M arch 1985, pp. 1 4 5 -6 1 . a n d return 209 CHAPTER CONTENTS ED I n t r o d u c t io n 21 1 EB F in a n c ia l in t e r m e d ia r ie s 220 EQ F in a n c ia l a g e n c y in s titu tio n s 215 ESI In v e s tin g in s titu tio n s 224 LEARNING OBJECTIVES A f t e r s tu d y in g th is c h a p t e r y o u s h o u ld b e a b le to : 1 u n d e r s ta n d th e f u n c tio n s o f a c a p it a l m a r k e t 2 d is tin g u is h b e t w e e n f in a n c ia l a g e n c y in s titu tio n s , f in a n c ia l in t e r m e d ia r ie s a n d in v e s tin g in s titu tio n s 3 4 5 id e n t if y a n d e x p la in th e r o le o f f in a n c ia l a g e n c y in s titu tio n s o u t lin e th e r o le o f s e c u r it is a tio n 6 id e n t if y a n d e x p la in th e r o le o f in v e s tin g in s titu tio n s . id e n t if y a n d e x p la in th e r o le o f f in a n c ia l in t e r m e d ia r ie s Z C hapter eight T he capital market ■ jjJ ~ l^ tr o d u c tio n In Chapters 5 and 6 we discussed the methods used to select a company s assets. The company also has to decide how to finance those assets. Where w ill the money come from? Is the money needed fo r a long time, or only a short time? Depending on the answers to these and related questions, the company w ill enter in to different arrangements and different types o f financial assets w ill be created. Financial a sse ts are legally enforceable claims to future cash flows. Bank deposits, trade creditors, debt securities and shares are different types o f financial assets. The markets in which financial assets are bought and sold are commonly referred to as financial markets and include the equity (share) market, the bond m arket and the foreign exchange m arket. The financial markets in which companies raise long-term funds are referred to collectively as the capital m arket. In this chapter we discuss the benefits o f having a capital m arket and the m ajor features o f the Australian capital m arket, paying p articular attention to the characteristics o f the im p o rta n t in stitu tio n s th a t participate in the market. Over a given period an economic e n tity such as an individual, a company or an unincorporated business w ill be either a ‘deficit u n it’ or a ‘surplus u n it’. A deficit u n it is one whose expenditure exceeds its income for a particular period, whereas a surplus u n it is one whose income exceeds its expenditure fo r a particular period. The financing process involves a flow o f funds from the surplus units to the deficit units. I f a company wishes to grow, b ut does n o t generate sufficient funds interna lly to finance an increase in its assets— th a t is, the company is a deficit u n it— it w ill need to finance the difference by drawing on the funds held by surplus u nits.1 Surplus units may be households, businesses, governments or the overseas sector. The flow o f funds from surplus units to deficit units may be direct or indirect. A direct flow o f funds may result solely from negotiation between the parties, or a financial in s titu tio n may be involved as an adviser or underw riter.2 For example, when a company issues (that is, creates and sells) debt securities, an investm ent bank may advise on and/or underw rite the issue.3 However, the funds w ill flow directly from the purchasers o f the debt securities to the issuing company. D irect funding is more commonly used where the borrower has a recognised credit rating and wishes to raise relatively large amounts. Alternatively, the flow o f funds may be indirect— th a t is, i t occurs through financial interm e­ diaries, such as banks and finance companies. In this case the deficit u n it obtains funds from a financial interm ediary th a t has borrowed the funds from surplus units. Interm ediated funding is more commonly used where the credit risk o f the deficit u n it (the borrower) needs to be assessed, and where the amounts fo r both borrowers and lenders are relatively small. Financial intermediaries have an im portant role in facilitating the flow o f funds from surplus units to deficit units. The number o f financial assets th a t are created in the overall financing process is an im p o rta n t difference between direct and indirect financing. I f a company raises funds directly by, fo r example, issuing a bond to an investor (lender), only one financial asset has been created. The bond is a financial asset held by the investor and it is a lia b ility o f the company. In contrast, i f the investor deposits funds in a bank, which then makes a loan to a company, two financial assets are created. The bank deposit is an asset owned by the investor and the bank loan is an asset owned by the bank. Corresponding to these tw o assets are two liabilities. The deposit is a lia b ility o f the bank and the bank loan is a lia b ility o f the borrower. FINANCIAL ASSETS assets such as shares, bonds and bank deposits, as distinct from real assets CAPITAL MARKET market in which long­ term funds are raised and long-term debt and equity securities are traded FINANCIAL INTERMEDIARY institution that acts as a principal in accepting funds from depositors or investors and lending them to borrowers m The capital m arket enables the suppliers o f funds (the surplus units) and the users o f funds (the deficit units) to negotiate the conditions on which the funds w ill be transferred. Equity or share markets involve 1 2 3 Internally generated funds are discussed in Section 9.8. Underwriting is discussed further in Section 8.2.2. The activities of investment banks are discussed in Section 8.2.2. These institutions were generally referred to as merchant banks until the early 1990s when the US term investment bank' was widely adopted in Australia. In this chapter we use the latter term, except in cases where the historical context makes the earlier term appropriate. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Understand the functions of a capital market B usiness finance ownership and usually a permanent transfer o f funds, w ith returns to shareholders contingent on the future p ro fita b ility o f the company raising the funds. Debt markets usually involve a transfer o f funds fo r a fin ite period, w ith predetermined promised returns to lenders. In the finance literature, equity and debt markets together form the capital m arket.4 PRIMARY MARKET market for new issues of securities where the sale proceeds go to the issuer of the securities SECONDARY MARKET market where previously issued securities are traded EXCHANGE-TRADED MARKET market in which trading takes place by competitive bidding on an organised exchange OVER-THE-COUNTER MARKET there is no organised exchange and the market consists of financial institutions that are willing to trade with a counterparty Financial markets may be classified in several ways. For example, the d istinction between debt markets and equity markets is based on the type o f financial asset th a t is traded in the market. Similarly, markets fo r financial assets may be either prim ary m arkets, where financial assets are firs t sold by th e ir originators, or secondary m arkets, where pre-existing financial assets are traded. Prim ary markets are im p o rta n t because it is in these markets th a t a deficit u n it— fo r example, a company— raises new funds to finance its investments. For example, a company may make a new share issue or a new bond issue to finance the development o f a new m ine or the acquisition o f another business. A transaction in the secondary m arket does n ot raise any new funds fo r the issuer o f the securities th a t are traded. A ll th a t happens is a change o f ownership; the seller o f the security transfers, fo r a price, ownership o f the security to the buyer. However, secondary markets are im p o rta n t because they provide a way in which securities can be exchanged fo r cash— th a t is, they provide liquidity. The existence o f a secondary m arket enables companies to raise long-term funds, even though individual suppliers o f funds may be w illin g to provide funds only fo r much shorter terms. For example, a company may issue a 7-year bond to an investor who wishes to invest fo r only 3 years. The investor is w illin g to buy the bond because she knows that, after 3 years have passed, she w ill be able to sell the bond in the secondary m arket. In this way, the existence o f an active secondary m arket facilitates capital raising in the p rim ary market. W ith o u t an active secondary m arket, many investors would n o t participate in prim ary markets because they require the fle xib ility to redeploy th e ir funds. The secondary m arket provides this flexibility. A nother im p o rta n t d istin ction between different financial markets is based on the organisational structure o f the markets. Indirect financing takes place through financial intermediaries, which raise funds by issuing financial claims against themselves and use those funds to purchase financial assets, most o f which cannot be traded in a secondary m arket. For example, a loan provided by a bank is often retained as an asset o f th a t bank u n til it has been repaid. In contrast, the financial assets created through direct financing are usually marketable securities. These securities may be traded through an organised exchange or they may be traded in an over-the-counter market. In an exchange-traded m arket, securities are traded through an organised exchange such as a stock exchange, where brokers carry out d ie nts, instructions to buy or sell nom inated securities. In an over-the-counter m arket there is no organised exchange and the m arket consists o f financial in s titu tio n s (dealers) who trade w ith clients and w ith each other. The Australian capital m arket includes financial intermediaries and markets o f both these types. Exchange-traded securities include shares, options on shares and futures contracts. Debt securities, swaps and currency options are usually traded in over-the-counter markets. Some features o f the financial system remain essentially constant over tim e while other features are subject to change, which may be gradual or, in some cases, very rapid. For example, banks have had a very im p o rta n t role in Australia since the firs t bank was established in 1817. However, the relative importance o f banks has varied over tim e — many new banks have entered the market, a few banks have failed and several have been acquired by other banks. The factors th a t can trigger significant changes in the financial system include changes in regulation and technology, changes in the demand fo r different form s o f funding and the effects o f financial crises. The evolution and expansion o f the Australian financial markets in the last three decades were largely an outcome o f the deregulation o f those markets in the 1980s. W hile the Australian financial markets have been largely deregulated, this deregulation has n o t extended to the removal o f controls th a t serve a prudential purpose. The p rim ary regulator o f Australia’s banks, insurance companies, superannuation 4 In practice, participants in the financial markets usually refer to the direct short-term debt market—that is, where loans are for 12 months or less—as the m on ey m ark e t. The term c a p ita l m a r k e t is used to describe the direct long-term debt market. C hapter eight T he funds, credit unions and b uilding societies is the Australian Prudential Regulation A u th o rity (APRA, www.apra.gov.au). In 1998, APRA took over prudential supervision functions from Australia’s central ban k — the Reserve Bank o f Australia (RBA, www.rba.gov.au). Arguably, the m ost im p o rta n t role fu lfille d by banking regulatory authorities is ensuring that depositors* funds are adequately protected. One way o f protecting the interests o f depositors is to require banks to m aintain an adequate level o f ‘capital’ ( fo r example, shareholders’ funds): the more capital a bank has, the more it relies on its shareholders fo r funding and hence the less it relies on its depositors. Therefore, the depositors are safer than they otherwise would be. I f a bank is judged by the regulator to be carrying too much risk, it can be required to increase its capital, thus sh ifting more o f the cost o f risk­ bearing from the banks depositors to the banks shareholders. In 1988, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision established a set o f recommendations known as the 1988 Capital Accord (or sim ply the Basel Accord). The Basel Committee was established by the Bank fo r International Settlements (BIS, w w w .bis.org), which its e lf can be thought o f as a bank fo r central banks. To illustrate one simple consequence o f the Basel Accord, a banks loan to a company would be judged to be twice as risky as a loan secured by a firs t mortgage over fam ily-held real estate. Hence, twice as much capital m ust be m aintained by the bank to protect the depositors. Gup (2004) notes that during the period from 1980 to 1996, 133 o f the 181 member countries o f the International M onetary Fund experienced serious banking sector problems, including those countries that adopted the 1988 accord. Some o f the deficiencies o f the first set o f recommendations have been addressed in a second accord, commonly referred to as Basel II, which provides a more comprehensive method by which banks account for risk.5 The Basel II framework has applied in Australia from 1 January 2008. The adequacy o f m any aspects o f bank regulation was called in to question by the global financial crisis th a t began in m id-2007 when problems th a t o riginated in credit m arkets in the US became widespread th ro ug h ou t the developed nations. This crisis saw tu rm o il in m any financial m arkets during 2008 and 2009 and the failure or near-failure o f many financial in s titu tio n s in the US, the UK and Europe. I t also involved unprecedented actions by central banks, financial regulators and governments to restore confidence and s ta b ility in the financial system and to lim it the effects o f the crisis on economic activity. In several stages beginning in December 2009 the Basel Com m ittee has proposed fu rth e r refinem ents, inclu ding more detailed regulations aimed at increasing the q u a n tity and q ua lity o f bank capital and strengthening bank liq u id ity . Together, these proposals have been referred to as Basel III. In September 2012, APRA announced th a t the capital reform s w ould be im plem ented on 1 January 2013 (APRA, 2012b). In May 2013 APRA stated th a t i t w ould introduce changes to liq u id ity regulation based on Basel III in three stages on 1 January 2014, 1 January 2015 and 1 January 2018 (APRA, 2013b). When the structure o f the financial system is viewed in terms o f the in s titu tio n s th a t operate w ith in it, four main developments can be identified over the post-deregulation period— th a t is, from 1985 to 2005 (RBA March 2006). These developments are: • • • • a significant increase in the importance o f banks a decrease in the relative importance o f b uilding societies, credit unions, finance companies and money m arket corporations a significant increase in the share o f assets held through managed funds, particularly superannuation funds rapid growth in securitisation. These developments, which typically occurred gradually, were followed by some much more rapid changes associated w ith the global financial crisis. In Australia, the effects o f the financial crisis were less severe than in the US, the U K and Europe b u t the effect on equity prices was comparable to the changes experienced in other countries: from its peak in November 2007, the Australian stock m arket fell by more than 50 per cent to a low in March 2009. O ther effects included a fu rth e r strengthening o f the dom inant position held by banks and a significant reversal o f the previous grow th in securitisation. These, and other developments, are discussed in Sections 8.2 to 8.4. 5 See Gup (2004) for a detailed discussion of the background to the introduction of Basel II and a critical analysis of its recommendations • capital market CENTRAL BANK a bank that controls the issue of currency, acts as banker to the government and the banking system and sets the interest rate for overnight cash B usiness finance Business funding LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Distinguish between financial agency institutions, financial intermediaries and investing institutions FINANCIAL AGENCY INSTITUTION arranges or facilitates the direct transfer of funds from lenders to borrowers INVESTING INSTITUTION accepts funds from the public and invests them in assets; includes superannuation funds, life insurance companies and unit trusts AUTHORISED DEPOSIT­ TAKING INSTITUTION a corporation that is authorised under the Banking Act 1959 to accept deposits from the public Sections 8.2 to 8.4 outline the m ajor financial in s titu tio n s in the Australian capital m arket involved in providing funds to companies. In stitu tio n s such as b uilding societies and credit unions, whose main function is consumer lending, are n o t discussed. The financial in s titu tio n s we discuss can be divided into three broad categories: financial agency institutio ns, financial intermediaries and investing institutions. A financial agency in stitu tio n arranges or facilitates the direct transfer o f funds from lenders to borrowers; typically, the funds are transferred from investors to companies. Companies usually obtain the assistance o f a stockbroker or investm ent bank when they wish to raise capital externally. For example, a broker or an investm ent bank may place a company s newly issued shares w ith in stitu tio n a l clients. Stockbroking firm s and investm ent banks fu nctio n as agency in stitu tio n s and w ill receive a fee or commission fo r arranging a transaction. Financial agency in s titu tio n s are discussed in Section 8.2. A financial intermediary, such as a bank, provides funds as a principal— th a t is, a company that borrows from a bank has an obligation to repay the bank, b u t it has no obligation to the banks depositors. Similarly, a bank acts as a principal in its relationship w ith depositors who have claims against the bank; depositors do n ot have claims against those who have borrowed from the bank. In contrast to agents, whose earnings consist m ostly o f fees and commissions, financial intermediaries obtain a significant part o f th e ir income from the in te re s t m argin,, which is the difference between the interest rates they charge for loans and the rates they pay to depositors. M ost financial interm ediaries also charge various fees. Companies w ith large funding requirements and high credit ratings are well placed to access debt funds directly. Such companies can therefore raise m ost or all o f th e ir funding requirements w ith o u t the services o f an interm ediary. However, m ost companies would fin d it either impossible or very expensive to access debt funds directly, so these companies typically borrow from financial intermediaries. The funds provided are sourced m ainly from depositors, so financial intermediaries have to provide services th a t depositors find attractive. Financial intermediaries are discussed in Section 8.3. Investing in stitu tio n s are sim ilar to financial intermediaries in th a t they accept funds from the public and invest the funds in assets. However, there are im p o rta n t differences between them. Essentially, financial intermediaries, such as banks, accept deposits and make loans. The m ajor roles o f investing in s titu tio n s — which include superannuation funds, life insurance companies and u n it tru sts— are to provide insurance and funds management. Funds placed w ith these in s titu tio n s are generally n ot in the form o f deposits and, while some o f these in s titu tio n s do make loans, they also invest in shares, debt securities, infrastructure assets and real estate, giving them a w ider spread o f assets than financial intermediaries. Another difference is th a t the returns provided by investing in s titu tio n s usually depend directly on the performance o f the assets held by them, whereas intermediaries have ‘fixed’ commitments to depositors th a t m ust be m et even i f an unexpectedly high pro po rtio n o f borrowers fa il to repay th eir loans. Investing in stitu tio n s are discussed in Section 8.4. W hile Sections 8.2 to 8.4 discuss financial agency institutio ns, financial intermediaries and investing in stitu tio n s, tw o qualifications should be noted. First, there are some entities th a t do n ot fit neatly in to any one o f these three categories. In particular, despite the fact th a t securitisation vehicles do not conform to our d e fin itio n o f ‘financial interm ediary’,we discuss securitisation in Section 8.3 because it is a process widely used by financial intermediaries. Second, some o f the differences between these three types o f in stitu tio n s have become less d istin ct in recent years. Many investing in s titu tio n s now offer products, such as housing loans, th a t were previously provided almost exclusively by intermediaries. In addition, there has been a considerable grow th in financial conglomerates th a t provide a wide range of financial services. For example, many banks have funds management, stockbroking and life insurance subsidiaries, while some life insurance companies have banking subsidiaries. These developments are likely to continue. However, there are s till fundam ental differences between financial interm ediation, the life insurance business and funds management. For example, the assets and liabilities o f a bank and the risks involved in banking are quite different from those o f a life insurance company. Therefore, while customers see a b lu rrin g o f previous distinctions, the differences between, say, banking and insurance continue to be im p o rta n t to those involved in managing and regulating financial institutio ns. A nother d ifficu lty arises from the terms used to refer to some institutio ns. In particular, the term inve stm en t bank* is used despite the fact th a t these in s titu tio n s may n ot be au th orised deposit-taking in stitu tio n s (ADIs) and are therefore n o t p erm itted to use the word ‘bank’ in th e ir title . On the other C hapter eight T he capital market hand, many investm ent banks in Australia are the local wholesale m arket operations o f foreign banks. In summary, activities described as ‘investm ent banking’ may be carried out by a bank or by a non-bank. The to ta l assets o f the main types o f financial in s titu tio n s are shown in Table 8.1, which shows that banks are by far the largest group o f in stitu tio n s in the Australian market, followed by life insurance companies and superannuation funds. The grow th o f banks, life insurance companies and superannuation funds, other managed funds and p articularly securitisation vehicles was relatively high in the period from 1990 to 2007, while the assets o f other ADIs and registered financial corporations grew more slowly. Table 8.1 also shows th a t fo r some institutio ns, such as life insurance companies and superannuation funds, the rate o f asset grow th has slowed since 2007, while fo r registered financial corporations, other managed funds and securitisation vehicles, the value o f assets has fallen since 2007. Generally, these differences between pre- and post-2007 conditions reflect the effects o f the global financial crisis. TABLE 8.1 Assets of Australian financial institutions, $ billi on r Life in s u ra n c e 3 0 Ju n e | A u th o ris e d R e g iste re d c o m p a n ie s a n d O th e r d e p o s it-ta k in g fin a n c ia l s u p e ra n n u a tio n m anaged in s titu tio n s c o rp o ra tio n s fu n d s fu n d s ___ B a n ks (o th e r O th e r th a n RBA) A D Is . G e n e ra l in s u ra n c e S e c u ritis a tio n c o m p a n ie s v e h ic le s Total 1990 325.8 31.4 109.0 158.9 43.3 21.7 5.7 695.9 1995 437.9 27.4 95.6 241.1 57.7 38.9 9.8 908.3 2000 731.0 34.2 134.6 455.1 151.7 61.4 65.0 1633.0 2005 1363.5 49.2 166.7 662.9 243.0 105.1 184.5 2774.8 2006 1581.1 53.6 176.3 787.1 300.6 113.8 216.5 3228.9 2007 1876.9 59.3 222.8 1024.9 378.3 143.7 274.0 3980.0 2008 2324.1 64.6 251.4 997.0 352.7 137.2 239.2 4366.2 2009 2590.2 67.5 215.6 936.5 313.8 134.2 192.7 4450.5 2010 2613.2 73.0 168.6 1050.6 312.6 133.4 146.1 4497.6 2011 2733.2 82.2 171.2 1172.1 287.8 152.9 136.1 4735.6 2012 2964.9 68.7 154.0 1233.7 272.5 163.4 126.8 4984.0 2013 3103.0 66.8 155.5 1421.0 278.0 175.2 127.5 5327.0 Note: The figures for life insurance companies, superannuation funds and other managed funds have been consolidated by the Australian Bureau of Statistics. They should not be compared with the figures in Tables 8.5, 8.6 and 8.7, which are unconsolidated. Source: Table B1, Reserve Bank of Australia website, www.rba.gov.au. 8.2 Financial agency institutions Financial agency in stitu tio n s are those th a t facilitate direct funding b u t do n o t themselves provide the funds. These in stitu tio n s operate in the p rim ary markets to b ring together surplus units and deficit units, and assist w ith the design o f appropriate contracts. They also operate in the secondary markets. The m ain financial agency in stitu tio n s in Australia are stockbrokers and investm ent banks. LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Identify and explain the role of financial agency institutions 8.2.1 I Brokers and the stock exchange The trad ition al function o f the stock exchange (and o f stockbrokers) is to provide facilities fo r the trading o f shares, bonds and other securities such as convertible notes, options and preference shares. As a result, a stock exchange perform s three functions. First, i t mobilises savings. Because there are large numbers of investors, issues o f securities can be fo r large sums. The presence o f a stock exchange allows companies to issue debt or equity securities in relatively small units, and each surplus u n it can then invest its desired amount. Second, it allocates resources. A stock exchange facilitates the allocation o f resources (savings) among a large num ber o f competing investm ent opportunities. Third, it allows investments to be realised through the sale o f securities— th a t is, i t provides investors w ith liquidity, and therefore the o pp ortu nity to adjust th e ir portfolios. As explained earlier, the existence o f a liq u id secondary m arket encourages investm ent in the p rim ary market. Development of the Australian Stock Exchange In 1987 the Australian Stock Exchange Ltd (ASX, www.asx.com.au) commenced business as a national stock exchange form ed by amalgamating the six independent exchanges th a t previously operated in the state capital cities. U n til 1998, the ASX was a company lim ite d by guarantee. However, follow ing dem utualisation in 1998, i t became a company lim ite d by shares. In 2006 the ASX merged w ith the SFE Corporation, the owner o f the Sydney Futures Exchange, resulting in an exchange group th a t operated as the Australian Securities Exchange (ASX) u n til 1 August 2010 when it adopted the name ASX Group. The ASX is a large and sophisticated m arket. A t the end o f 2012, more than 2000 companies had equities listed on the exchange, w ith a to ta l m arket capitalisation o f $1335 billion. In th a t year, the average daily value o f share trading was about $4 b illio n and more than $41 b illio n o f new equity capital was raised during the year. By market capitalisation o f its listed entities, the ASX ranks te n th in the world; by the value o f share trading, i t ranks tw e lfth .6 Other equity markets in Australia There are two smaller stock exchanges in Australia: the Asia Pacific Stock Exchange and the National Stock Exchange o f Australia. • • The Asia Pacific Stock Exchange (www.apx.com .au), usually referred to as the APX, was started in 1997 and targets grow th-oriented companies based in Australia or elsewhere in the Asia-Pacific region, including China. I t is owned by AIMS Financial Group. The N ational Stock Exchange o f Australia (www.nsxa.com .au), usually referred to as the NSX, is located in Newcastle and in 2013 had over 100 securities listed. I t is owned by its shareholders and is its e lf listed on the ASX. It generally attracts smaller companies than the ASX because its listing requirements are less demanding. For example, to lis t on the ASX a company m ust have at least 300 shareholders and a m arket capitalisation o f at least $10 m illion , whereas the NSX requires only 50 shareholders and a m arket capitalisation o f at least $500 000. Australia also has other equity markets designed to meet the needs o f small and medium-sized enterprises. These include the Australian Small Scale Offerings Board (www.assob.com.au) and the CAPstart Private Equity M arket (w w w.capstart.com .au), which facilitate capital raising by small unlisted companies. Automation of trading Since 1990, all shares have been traded electronically through systems th a t enable stockbrokers to trade from term inals in th e ir offices; clients can place orders w ith online brokers using the internet. Visitors to the stock exchanges can now view share prices and other inform ation, such as local and overseas m arket indices, on video screens in the visitors* gallery. The ju n io r exchanges also use electronic trading and the prices o f listed securities can be obtained from th e ir websites. Table 8.2 provides some ASX m arket statistics fo r the period 1990 to 2012. 6 Ranks refer to the 53 members of the World Federation of Exchanges (www.world-exchanges.org). C hapter eight T he capital market TABLE 8.2 ASX market statistics as at December, 1990-2012 Year V a lu e o f A ll O r d in a r ie s s h a re , M a r k e t c a p ita lis a tio n d o m e s tic p r ic e in d e x e q u itie s ($ m illio n ) N u m b e r o f c o m p a n ie s w ith e q u itie s liste d 1990 1280 139572 1136 1995 2203 329647 1178 2000 3155 670918 1406 2005 4709 1109596 1807 2006 5644 1390315 1908 2007 6421 1478651 2077 2008 3659 969046 2086 2009 4883 1403117 2043 2010 4847 1419001 2072 2011 4111 1168712 2079 2012 4665 1335 837 2056 Source: Compiled from Australian Stock Exchange Ltd, Fact Book 2001, 2001 and www.asx.com.au/research/market— info/index.htm. The role of the stockbroker Traditionally, stockbrokers have played a leading role in the new-issues market. In the year to 31 December 2012, ASX-listed entities raised $41.2 b illio n in new equity capital compared w ith the 2010 and 2011 totals o f $56.5 b illio n and $47.8 b illio n respectively. The 2012 to ta l comprised $7.2 b illio n raised in in itia l public offerings by newly listed entities and $34.0 b illio n raised by entities th a t were already listed (see w w w .asx.co m .au /a bo ut/m a rke t-sta tistics.htm ). A company may m aintain a continuing relationship w ith a stockbroking firm th a t advises it on the m ost appropriate means o f raising funds and the terms o f a new issue o f securities. The same broker or an associated company may underw rite the issue, which means th a t the broker or associated company agrees to subscribe to any p o rtio n o f the issue th a t is not subscribed to by other investors during a given period. In addition, a broker may undertake to sell the issue, mainly to the brokers clients and in s titu tio n a l investors. The larger stockbroking firm s also frequently advise companies th a t are considering a merger or acquisition, and may assist w ith negotiations if the merger or acquisition proceeds. Many stockbroking firm s have extended th e ir services beyond those trad ition ally offered. O ther services offered by brokers include advice on financial planning and superannuation, research and trading of derivative securities (such as options), access to stock markets outside Australia and investments in commercial bills and other money m arket assets.7 Although a stockbroking firm may provide these services directly, they are usually provided through associated investm ent banks. 8 .2 .2 1 Investment banks The role of investment banks The term investm ent bank* has no official defin itio n in Australia. Rather, investm ent banks are identified by the range o f financial services th a t they provide. Their m ain activities involve wholesale banking and trading in the financial markets. The range o f activities is broad and includes financial interm ediation (borrowing and lending), trading in securities, foreign exchange and derivatives, investm ent management, 7 Derivatives are discussed in Chapters 17 and 18 and commercial bills in Chapter 10. Jw w ^J provision o f corporate advisory services, u nd erw riting and stockbroking. Thus, unlike most banks and other authorised deposit-taking in s titu tio n s (ADIs), investm ent banks have little involvem ent in retail banking. Accordingly, they usually have m inim al dealings w ith individuals except perhaps as managers o f funds such as cash management trusts or as advisers to a small number o f very wealthy individuals. There is no <typical, investm ent bank because many o f them specialise in particular products and services. However, as a group, investm ent banks focus on wholesale m arket operations, where they deal w ith corporations, other financial institutio ns, governments and supranational bodies. Their main functions can be outlined in four categories: The wholesale banking operation provides a service to companies th a t wish to deposit tem porarily idle cash balances, or to borrow funds fo r a short to m edium period, b The investment management function involves managing the p ortfolios o f in s titu tio n a l investors and an investm ent banks own u n it trusts. Part o f this fu nctio n is to direct funds to the new issues o f Australian companies. c The corporate financial advisory function involves providing advice to companies about raising additional capital, or a merger or takeover, and the provision o f und erw riting facilities and m arketing services fo r new issues. The u n d erw rite rs skills, contacts and knowledge o f the capital m arket are expected to result in a higher price than i f the issuer attempted to m arket the securities itself. In addition, the m arketing risk is assumed by the underw riter. I f the issue is priced appropriately, the supply o f securities w ill match the demand. I f the issue is over-priced, the u nderw riter w ill be le ft holding the unsold securities, d Making a market in foreign exchange and derivative securities involves being w illin g to quote b oth a price to buy and a price to sell in these m arkets— th a t is, this fu nctio n requires the investm ent bank to be w illin g to deal on both sides o f the m arket at all times. a Regulation of investment banks The regulatory provisions th a t apply to an investm ent bank w ill depend, at least in p art, on its structure and the range o f services th a t it provides. An investm ent bank operating in Australia w ill be structured either as an AD I or as a money m arket corporation. Those th a t are ADIs w ill be subject to the provisions o f the Banking Act 1959 and to prudential supervision by APRA (w w w .a p ra .g o v .a u ). Investm ent banks th a t are structured as money m arket corporations are n o t subject to prudential supervision, b ut are required to register w ith, and provide statistical data to, APRA in accordance w ith the Financial Sector (Collection of Data) Act 2001. Their name may n ot include the word ^ank*, but guidelines issued by APRA in January 2006 allow registered money m arket corporations to use expressions such as 'merchant bank* in relation to th e ir business. Because they are corporations, they are also regulated by the Australian Securities and Investments Commission (ASIC, w w w .a s ic .g o v .a u ) and are subject to the same conduct and disclosure regulations as other corporations. As a provider o f financial advice or as a dealer in financial markets, an investm ent bank m ust have an Australian Financial Services Licence issued by ASIC. In addition, m ost o f those th a t trade in the financial markets are members o f the Australian Financial M arkets Association (AFMA, w w w .a fm a . c o m .a u ). AFM A is an ind ustry association th a t represents the in s titu tio n s th a t operate in Australia’s over-the-counter financial markets. It imposes a degree o f self-regulation through measures such as its code o f conduct, codification o f m arket conventions and standardisation o f documentation. Developments in Australian investment banking A fte r the deregulation o f the banks in the 1980s, lending became a much less im p o rta n t activity o f money m arket corporations, while other investm ent banking activities have grown considerably. Therefore, the value o f th e ir assets and the associated m arket shares shown in Table 8.3 (see Section 8.3) are n o t good measures o f the sectors importance. O ther measures, such as the value o f equity capital raised and fees earned, are better indicators o f the importance o f investm ent banking. As noted above, investm ent banks th a t engage in securities trading and u n d erw riting w ill usually be members o f AFM A. In 2013, AFM A had more than 130 members and there are many investm ent banks th a t are n ot members o f AFMA. These non-members do n o t trade in the financial markets and focus instead on activities such as advisory services, investm ent and funds management. Investm ent banking can involve inherent conflicts o f interest th a t m ust be managed i f they cannot be avoided. These conflicts are m ost likely to arise in cases where the firm has a wide range o f activities C hapter eight T he including stockbroking, securities trading and u nderw riting. In such cases, investors and regulators may be concerned th a t the broking analysts* recommendations on which shares to buy or sell may be influenced by th e ir colleagues who are seeking to attract or retain business in u nd erw riting or corporate advisory activities. Further, i f share trading undertaken by one section o f an investm ent bank is m otivated by confidential inform a tion gathered by another section o f the bank, then the bank may be subject to a charge o f insider trading. The standard approach to managing such conflicts o f interest is to employ internal barriers— know n as inform a tion barriers or, more frequently, Chinese walls_ to lim it the flow o f confidential client inform a tion between departments. Concerns about the effectiveness o f Chinese walls were widely publicised in the US in 2001. One outcome was that M errill Lynch agreed to pay a fine o f US$100 m illion because o f allegations th a t its broking analysts issued overly optim istic reports on the shares o f companies that were clients o f its investment banking operation. In Australia, ASIC took civil action against Citigroup in 2006 in the only recorded Australian case to consider Chinese walls as a defence against insider trading (Overland and Li, 2012). Citigroup was successful in defending the charges but the outcome o f the case highlights the importance o f m aintaining adequate Chinese wall arrangements. In particular, the policies and procedures underpinning such arrangements should be documented extensively, and understood and applied by employees. Some investment banks avoid any exposure to inherent conflicts o f interest by restricting the scope o f th e ir activities. Firms that take this approach focus on advisory services and do n ot engage in securities trading or underwriting. Investment banks and the global financial crisis The global financial crisis saw m ajor investm ent banks in the US experience severe stress. Bear Stearns suffered a severe liq u id ity shortage in March 2008 and failure was avoided only when J. P. Morgan Chase agreed to purchase Bear Stearns in a takeover facilitated by government authorities. By the end o f August 2008, the losses th a t had been recognised by financial in stitu tio n s w ritin g down the values o f assets had accumulated to a global to ta l o f around US$500 billion. Pressure on the equity prices o f financial institutions made it more d iffic u lt fo r banks to replenish th e ir depleted capital bases or to raise loan funds from markets where lenders were unw illing to accept anything other than the lowest credit risks. W ith th e ir higher leverage and exposures to impaired assets, investm ent banks experienced the greatest pressure. O f the m ajor US investm ent banks, Lehman Brothers, w ith assets o f about $639 billion, faced the m ost severe problems and when it was unable to raise urgently needed funding the company filed for bankruptcy protection in September 2008— the largest ‘bank’ failure in US history. The failure o f Lehman Brothers and the planned takeover o f M e rrill Lynch by the Bank o f America would leave just two big investm ent banks: Goldman Sachs Group Inc. and Morgan Stanley. A week after Lehman Brothers failed, the US central bank, the Federal Reserve, announced that, at a 9 pm meeting, its Board o f Governors had approved applications delivered earlier th a t day by b oth firm s to become bank holding companies— th a t is, firm s th a t own or control banks. The im plications o f this change o f status included regulation by the Federal Reserve instead o f the Securities and Exchange Commission, lower financial leverage, greater reliance on deposits from retail customers rather than borrow ing by issuing bonds and probably less risk taking. A report by Bloomberg began: The Wall Street that shaped the financial world for two decades ended last night, when Goldman Sachs Inc. and Morgan Stanley concluded there is no future in remaining investment banks now that investors have determined the model is broken.8 W hile the effects in Australia were less severe than in the US, the global financial crisis had significant effects on investm ent banks in Australia. The Sydney-based investm ent bank Babcock & Brown (B&B), which listed on the ASX in 2004 and had at its peak 28 offices worldwide and a m arket capitalisation in excess o f $9 billion , became a victim o f the crisis when it failed in 2009. B&B had a leading role as an adviser on structured finance including leases and securitisation, invested in real estate and infrastructure as a principal and managed several satellite* funds th a t i t established. B&B relied heavily on short-term debt to finance its holdings o f m ostly illiq u id assets, such as real estate and shareholdings in unlisted related businesses. W ith financial markets disrupted and concerns about the high debt levels o f B&B and its satellite funds, the company was unable to refinance its debt and was placed in voluntary adm inistration in March 2009 and then in to liqu id atio n in August 2009. The Australian subsidiaries o f US and European 8 See Harper and Torres (2008). capital market B usiness finance investm ent banks such as M e rrill Lynch and UBS reduced th e ir workforces to offset lower revenues. As financial markets stabilised in 2009 and 2010, these and other investm ent banks were able to earn substantial fees by arranging and u nd erw riting share issues fo r companies whose managers recognised the need to reduce th e ir financial leverage. 8.3 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 4 Identify and explain the role of financial intermediaries Financial interm ediaries Financial intermediaries borrow funds on th e ir own behalf and then lend the funds to another party. The types o f financial intermediaries in the Australian capital m arket include banks, money m arket corporations, finance companies, building societies and credit unions. Recent statistics on the assets o f the financial interm ediaries th a t are im p o rta n t as lenders to businesses are shown in Table 8.3. TABLE 8.3 Total assets of selected financial intermediaries ($ billion) and market shares (percentage of total) r 3 0 June M o n e y m a rk e t $ b illio n F in a n c e c o m p a n ie s c o rp o ra tio n s B a n ks % $ b illio n % $ b illio n , Total % $ b illio n 1990 325.8 74.9 53.6 12.3 55.4 12.7 434.8 1995 437.9 82.1 51.2 9.6 44.4 8.3 533.5 2000 731.0 84.5 63.7 7.4 70.9 8.2 865.6 2005 1363.5 89.1 80.1 5.2 86.5 5.7 1530.1 2006 1581.1 90.0 79.0 4.5 97.3 5.5 1757.4 2007 1876.9 89.4 106.7 5.1 116.1 5.5 2099.7 2008 2324.1 90.3 121.9 4.7 129.5 5.0 2575.6 2009 2590.2 92.3 94.5 3.4 121.1 4.3 2805.8 2010 2613.2 93.9 64.8 2.3 103.9 3.7 2781.8 2011 2733.2 94.1 66.7 2.3 104.5 3.6 2904.5 2012 2964.9 95.1 49.1 1.6 104.9 3.4 3118.8 2013 3103.0 95.2 43.6 1.3 111.8 3.4 3258.5 Source: Table B1, Reserve Bank of Australia website, www.rba.gov.au. 8.3.1 | Banks The to ta l assets o f financial in stitu tio n s in Australia are shown in Table 8.1. As can be seen from the table, banks are the largest group o f financial in stitu tio n s in Australia. As at June 2013, th e ir assets accounted directly fo r more than 58 per cent o f the assets held by all financial in stitu tio n s. However, this understates the overall importance o f banks because many o f them also have interests in other financial institutio ns, such as investm ent banks, finance companies, insurance companies, fund managers and stockbrokers. Accordingly, banks— p articularly the larger ones— provide a wide range o f products and financial services including funds management, insurance, und erw riting , security dealing and stockbroking. In many cases, these activities are carried out through subsidiaries and affiliated businesses. A m ajor part o f banking business is borrow ing from depositors and other investors and lending to a wide range o f borrowers, including governments, businesses and consumers. Therefore, banks need to offer services th a t attract both borrowers and depositors. The m ain attraction to borrowers is obvious: access to debt capital. Banks are large lenders to the business sector, and in the 12-m onth period ended C hapter eight T he capital market June 2013 accounted fo r more than 90 per cent o f commercial lending by interm ediaries.9 But banks offer more than mere access to debt capital— they offer a wide range o f loans w ith different characteristics. For example, there are short-term loans and long-term loans, secured loans and unsecured loans, fixedinterest rate loans and variable-interest rate loans, and domestic-currency loans and foreign-currency loans. The most distinctive fo rm o f bank lending is the overdraft facility, which involves an arrangement whereby borrowers may draw funds, at th e ir discretion, up to a specified lim it. How do banks attract depositors? A n obvious answer is: by paying interest. But why would someone deposit money in a bank, which then lends the money to a borrower, when the banks deposit interest rate is almost certainly less than the interest rate charged to the borrower? In other words, why n o t lend directly, instead o f going through the bank? The answer is that, in addition to paying interest, banks provide valuable services to th e ir depositors, including: • • • • • Credit assessment. Banks typically have much greater expertise than depositors in assessing the quality o f loan applicants, thus reducing default risk. Credit enhancement. Partly by applying th e ir credit assessment skills, banks are able to offer low -risk investments to depositors, even i f some o f the loans made by the bank are high risk. Diversification. Banks reduce risk by lending to a much w ider variety o f borrowers than an individual depositor could.10 Maturity transformation. Depositors often wish to lend fo r short periods (such as a few m onths or a few years) whereas borrowers often wish to borrow fo r term s o f many years; banks make this transform ation possible. Transaction services. Banks assist depositors to receive and pay funds by (for example) cheques and electronic transfers.11 In addition to m aking loans and meeting the needs o f depositors, banks also provide many other services. These services include assisting clients to borrow from sources o ther than the bank by providing guarantees, letters o f credit and b ill acceptances. O ther services assist clients in risk management and involve market-related activities such as entering in to forw ard rate agreements, transacting in various foreign-currency contracts and dealing in derivatives. As at 11 October 2013, 69 banks were authorised to operate in Australia. O f these, 21 were predominantly Australian owned, eight were subsidiaries o f foreign banks and 40 were branches o f foreign banks. A foreign bank subsidiary is incorporated in Australia and m ust hold capital w ith in Australia, whereas a foreign bank branch is essentially just a p art o f the parent bank th a t is authorised to conduct banking business w ith in Australia. As discussed below, foreign bank branches are subject to some restrictions th a t do n o t apply to subsidiaries o f foreign banks. Some foreign banks have both a branch and a subsidiary in Australia. As from 1 July 1998, the responsibility fo r bank supervision was transferred from the RBA to APRA. The RBA retains responsibility fo r m onetary policy and the maintenance o f financial stability, including th a t o f the payments system— which is the cash, cheque and electronic means by which payments are effected. As a result, the current regulatory structure requires close cooperation between the RBA and APRA. An a uth ority from APRA is required before a bank is perm itted to operate in Australia. APRA also imposes a number o f other controls over banks, including m inim um capital requirements and asset requirements. Banks are also required to provide APRA w ith extensive data on th e ir activities and management systems. W hile subsidiaries o f foreign banks are subject to the same requirements as locally owned banks, branches o f foreign banks are n ot subject to m inim um capital requirements in Australia. However, such branches are effectively confined to operating in the wholesale m arket because they are n ot perm itted to accept in itia l deposits o f less than $250000 from Australian residents and non-corporate institutio ns. Therefore, a foreign bank th a t wishes to operate in the retail m arket m ust establish a subsidiary in Australia. Before the global financial crisis, the Australian government did n o t explicitly guarantee deposits in Australian banks. As p art o f its response to the crisis, the government introduced an explicit guarantee 9 This percentage is derived from the Australian Bureau of Statistics publication L e n d in g F in an ce, A u str a lia , cat. no. 5671.0, Table 3. 10 See Chapter 7 for a discussion of how diversification of a portfolio can reduce risk. 11 Banks are the major participants in the payments system in the settlement of cheques, which is conducted through exchange settlement accounts at the RBA. DEFAULT RISK the chance that a borrower will fail to meet obligations to pay interest and principal as promised B usiness finance Finance in ACTION GOVERNMENT GUARANTEE EXTENDED O N BANK DEPOSITS P r io r to th e g lo b a l f in a n c ia l c ris is , b a n k d e p o s its in A u s t r a lia w e r e n o t g u a r a n t e e d , a lth o u g h d e p o s it in s u r a n c e s c h e m e s w e r e c o m m o n in o t h e r c o u n tr ie s . F a c e d w ith a c ris is o f c o n fid e n c e in la te S e p t e m b e r / e a r ly O c t o b e r 2 0 0 8 , m a n y g o v e r n m e n ts in c r e a s e d th e lim it o n th e a m o u n t o f d e p o s its g u a r a n t e e d u n d e r th e s e s c h e m e s w h ile o th e rs w e n t fu r t h e r b y p r o v id in g a g u a r a n t e e o v e r a ll d e p o s its , t y p ic a lly f o r a s e t p e r io d o f a r o u n d 2 y e a r s . S o m e g o v e r n m e n ts a ls o m o v e d to p r o v id e a g u a r a n t e e o n w h o le s a le b o r r o w in g b y d e p o s it - ta k in g in s titu tio n s . W h il e m o s t A u s t r a lia n in s titu tio n s r e m a in e d s o u n d a n d p r o f it a b le , th e A u s t r a lia n g o v e r n m e n t to o k s im ila r m e a s u re s so t h a t A u s t r a lia n b a n k s a n d o fh e r d e p o s it - ta k in g in s titu tio n s w o u ld n o t b e d is a d v a n t a g e d in te r n a tio n a lly . A n a r t ic le in T /ie A g e o u t lin e d th e g o v e r n m e n t's in itia tiv e s . T h e G o v e r n m e n t w i l l g u a r a n t e e t h e $ 6 0 0 —$ 7 0 0 b i l l i o n d e p o s it s in A u s t r a lia n f i n a n c i a l in s t it u t io n s in a m o v e t o s h o r e u p lo c a l c o n f id e n c e a n d p r o t e c t t h e n a t i o n ’ s in t e r n a t i o n a l c o m p e t it iv e n e s s . D e c la r i n g t h a t t h e c o u n t r y is in 't h e e c o n o m ic e q u i v a le n t o f a r o l lin g n a t io n a l s e c u r it y c r is is 7, [ P r im e M in is t e r ] K e v in R u d d h a s a ls o a n n o u n c e d t h a t a l l b o r r o w i n g b y A u s t r a lia n b a n k s a n d o t h e r d e p o s it - t a k in g in s t it u t io n s f r o m o v e r s e a s w i l l b e g u a r a n t e e d . T h e d e p o s it a n d le n d in g g u a r a n t e e s a r e u n p r e c e d e n t e d in A u s t r a lia n b a n k i n g h is t o r y a n d a r e a n im m e d ia t e r e s p o n s e t o t h e d r a m a t i c m o v e s b y o t h e r c o u n t r ie s t o p r o p u p t h e ir f a i l i n g f i n a n c i a l s y s te m s . . . . A u s t r a lia n b a n k s w e lc o m e d t h e G o v e r n m e n t 's m o v e s . A u s t r a lia n B a n k e r s A s s o c i a t io n c h i e f e x e c u t iv e D a v id B e ll s a id A u s t r a lia n b a n k s w e r e w e ll c a p it a l is e d b u t w e r e s till a f f e c t e d b y t h e s e iz u r e o f i n t e r n a t i o n a l f i n a n c i a l m a r k e ts . 'T h is le v e ls t h e p l a y i n g f ie l d a n d a l lo w s A u s t r a lia n b a n k s t o c o m p e t e e q u a l l y a n d f a i r l y 7, h e s a id . Source: 'Rudd's $700 billion bank guarantee,/ Michelle Grattan and Vanessa O'Shaughnessy, The Age, 13 October 2008. |w w w j on deposits in banks and other AD Is.12 (See Finance in Action.) Some o f these guarantees were temporary b u t the government continued to guarantee deposits o f up to $250 000 per person per ADI. The Australian banking sector is dominated by fo ur m ajor banks, the AN Z Banking Group (www. anz.com.au), the Commonwealth Bank o f Australia (w w w.com m bank.com .au), the N ational Australia Bank (w w w .national.com .au) and Westpac Banking Corporation (www.westpac.com .au). These banks accounted fo r 79 per cent o f the to ta l assets o f the Australian banking sector as at October 2013 (APRA 2013c). Each has a nationwide branch netw ork and provides a fu ll range o f banking services for individuals as well as business customers b oth locally and overseas. O ther Australian-owned banks are smaller and many are referred to as Regional banks’ because they originally had a regional base in one state. M any o f these smaller banks, including the Bendigo and Adelaide Bank, Suncorp Bank and the Bank o f Queensland, have since expanded to compete w ith the m ajor banks by achieving broader coverage of the Australian market. Historically, foreign-owned banks played only a m in o r role in the Australian financial system. However, in recent years they have attracted increased a tte ntio n through measures such as attractive interest rates paid on internet-based savings accounts. Foreign banks have also begun to compete more aggressively in lending in Australia and at the end o f 2008 they held around 16 per cent o f overall Australian bank assets. However, by the end o f October 2013, th e ir share o f bank assets had declined to 11.5 per cent (APRA 2013c). Following the collapse o f the m ajor US firm Lehman Brothers in September 2008 and the failure or near-failure o f many other financial institutio ns, there was a widespread loss o f confidence in the solvency o f financial in stitu tio n s and the sta bility o f the global financial system. Governments in several countries, including Australia, moved to restore confidence through measures th a t were in some cases unprecedented. As m entioned above, in Australia one o f the m ajor changes was the announcement o f an explicit government guarantee o f bank deposits. 12 For discussion of the guarantee measures, see Schwartz (2010). C hapter eight T he capital market 8 .3 .2 1 Money market corporations The activities o f money m arket corporations (MMCs) were discussed in Section 8.2.2. Table 8.3 shows that the assets o f these in stitu tio n s have declined from around 10 per cent o f the to ta l assets o f banks, MMCs and finance companies in the mid-1990s to around 5 per cent from 2004 to 2008; they then fell fu rth e r to only 1.3 per cent in 2013. As discussed in Section 8.2.2, the long-term decline reflects the ongoing effects o f the deregulation o f the Australian financial system, whereby restrictions th a t applied to banks were removed, allowing them to strengthen th e ir com petitive position at the expense o f non-bank financial intermediaries. The more rapid decline over the 2008 to 2013 period coincides w ith the global financial crisis and its afterm ath. Since MMCs are n o t authorised deposit-taking in s titu tio n s (ADIs) th eir borrowings were not covered by the government guarantee announced in October 2008. 8 .3 .3 | Finance companies Initially, finance companies were p rim a rily concerned w ith lending to individuals by providing instalm ent credit for retail sales. In 1954 this accounted fo r 85 per cent o f finance company lending b ut by June 2010, lending to individuals accounted fo r only 27 per cent o f the to ta l assets o f finance companies.13 Finance companies grew rapidly during the period in which the Australian financial markets were highly regulated. They offered a wide range o f financial services fo r companies, including instalm ent credit, lease financing, inventory financing, discounting o f accounts receivable, mortgages and other commercial loans. Their success was due largely to the regulatory constraints on th e ir natural competitors, the banks. In fact, each o f the m ajor banks acquired a finance company subsidiary in order to gain access to markets denied them by bank regulations. The deregulation o f the banking sector in the 1980s removed much o f the competitive advantage h itherto enjoyed by finance companies. As can be seen from Table 8.3, the assets o f finance companies have grown at a much lower average rate than the assets o f banks over the period from 1995 to 2013 and declined in dollar terms from 2008 to 2013. Many finance companies have become specialised in stitu tio n s focusing on specific areas such as m otor vehicle finance or the financing o f machinery and equipment. 8 .3 .4 | Securitisation14 S e c u ritis a tio n is the process o f converting illiq u id assets such as bank loans in to tradable securities. In a typical case, an originator o f financial assets— such as a bank th a t has provided a significant number o f housing loans— sells a p o rtfo lio o f these loans to a specially created company or trust. This entity, generally referred to as a securitisation vehicle or special purpose vehicle (SPV), finances its purchase o f the loans by issuing tradable securities to investors using the underlying assets (the housing loans) as collateral. I f these securities are long term they are generally referred to as asset-backed bonds, or i f the loans involved are all mortgage loans over residential property, the securities may be referred to as residential mortgage-backed securities (RMBS). I f the securities are short term — th a t is, th e ir term to m aturity is less than a year— they may be referred to as asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP). The end result is th a t securitisation allows a financial in s titu tio n to fund its lending indirectly through the capital market instead o f by the trad ition al m ethod o f gathering deposits or borrow ing directly in its own name. A traditional interm ediary assesses loan applications and provides funds to approved loan applicants. One advantage claimed fo r securitisation is th a t it enables the credit assessment fu nctio n to be separated from the funding function. That is, the lending in s titu tio n continues to assess loan applicants but, through securitisation, the funds are provided by investors. One view is th a t this process enables in stitu tio n s to specialise in either credit assessment or funding, depending on where th e ir expertise lies. A nother view is that this separation may incur agency costs: the credit assessor may n o t bear the fu ll costs o f making poor assessments. The securitisation m arket in Australia has been dominated by securitisation o f residential mortgages but the range o f assets that can be securitised also includes commercial mortgages, leases, trade receivables 13 See Reserve Bank of Australia, Table B10, www.rba.gov.au. 14 Facts related to the Australian securitisation market mentioned in this section are mostly drawn from Reserve Bank of Australia (2004) pp. 48-56 and Debelle (2009). LEARNING OBJECTIVE 5 Outline the role of securitisation SECURITISATION the process of making assets marketable by aggregating incomeproducing assets in a pool and issuing new securities backed by the pool B usiness finance a n d m o to r v e h icle lo an s. A s s h o w n in Table 8.1, th e assets o f A u s tra lia n s e c u ritis a tio n ve h icle s g re w fro m a ro u n d $ 1 0 b illio n in J u n e 1 9 9 5 to a p e a k o f $ 2 7 4 b illio n in J u n e 2 0 0 7 b u t th e n fe ll to $ 1 2 8 b illio n in Ju n e 2 0 1 3 . D u rin g th e p e rio d o f ra p id g ro w th t h a t co m m e n ce d in th e 19 90 s, th e share o f re s id e n tia l [ wwn^] m o rtg a g e lo a n s fu n d e d th ro u g h s e c u ritis a tio n in cre a se d fr o m less th a n 10 p e r c e n t in th e la te 1990s to a lm o s t 25 p e r c e n t in J u n e 2 0 0 7 (see D e b e lle 2 0 0 9 , p. 4 3 ). C u rre n t in fo r m a tio n a b o u t s e c u ritis a tio n is p ro v id e d b y th e A u s tra lia n S e c u ritis a tio n F o ru m (ASF, w w w .securitisation.com .au). The assets o f A u s tra lia n s e c u ritis a tio n ve h icle s are s h o w n in Table 8.4. TABLE 8.4 Assets of securitisation vehicles, $ million O th e r 3 0 Ju n e I M o r tg a g e s lo a n s a n d Asse 卜 backed O th e r A ll o th e r p la c e m e n ts bonds se cu ritie s assets Total assets 1990 4794 845 5734 1995 5358 1456 928 1229 894 9845 2000 41306 7905 8072 2515 5 216 65014 2005 146984 11293 12286 3972 9970 184505 2006 176288 11162 13738 2946 12327 216461 2007 215201 17319 18907 3025 19525 273977 2008 179669 19106 20997 2753 16715 239240 2009 142885 15346 15858 525 18104 192718 2010 115 794 11922 9229 0 8835 146073 2011 110666 13353 6983 255 4813 136070 2012 106495 13747 1556 0 5 024 12 6 8 2 2 2013 106156 14175 1374 0 5554 127259 Source: Table B19, Reserve Bank of Australia website, www.rba.gov.au. The ra p id g ro w th in s e c u ritis a tio n u p to 2 0 0 7 can be a ttr ib u te d to tw o m a in fa c to rs . F irs t, th e d e m a n d f o r h o u s in g fin a n c e in A u s tra lia re m a in e d s tro n g . Second, th e c o m p o s itio n o f le n d e rs in th e m o rtg a g e m a rk e t changed, w it h m o rtg a g e o rig in a to rs t h a t s e c u ritis e a lm o s t a ll o f t h e ir lo a n s g a in in g a g ro w in g share a fte r e n te rin g th e m a rk e t in th e 19 90 s (D e b e lle 2 0 0 9 , p p . 4 3 - 4 ) . The fa ll in th e assets o f s e c u ritis a tio n vehicles a fte r 2 0 0 7 is a n o th e r o u tc o m e o f th e g lo b a l fin a n c ia l c ris is . A t tim e s d u r in g th is crisis, m a rk e ts f o r asset-backed s e c u ritie s w e re e ffe c tiv e ly fro z e n , w ith m a n y sellers b u t n o b u ye rs, so th e re was li t t le i f a n y tra d in g in s e c o n d a ry m a rk e ts . Issuance o f n e w s e c u ritie s d e c lin e d m a rk e d ly a n d in som e cases ceased a lto g e th e r. W it h re p a y m e n ts o n th e u n d e rly in g lo a n s b e in g a p p lie d to a m o rtis e th e p r in c ip a l o f e x is tin g s e c u ritie s a n d m in im a l issuance o f n e w s e c u ritie s , th e assets o f s e c u ritis a tio n veh icle s in e v ita b ly fe ll. 8.4 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 6 Identify and explain the role of investing institutions Investing institutions The m a in in v e s tin g in s titu t io n s in A u s tra lia are life in s u ra n c e com p an ies, s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s , p u b lic u n it tr u s ts a n d ge n e ra l in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s. A s n o te d e a rlie r, m a n y o f the se in s titu t io n s are o w n e d b y b a n ks o r are m e m b e rs o f fin a n c ia l c o n g lo m e ra te s . There is also s ig n ific a n t o v e rla p b e tw e e n th e categories. In p a rtic u la r, m a n a g e m e n t o f s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s is a m a jo r a c tiv ity o f life in s u ra n c e com p an ies, so m o s t o f th e assets h e ld b y the se co m p a n ie s are w it h in s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s . C hapter eight T he 8.4.1 | Insurance companies and superannuation funds As s h o w n in Table 8.1, th e t o ta l assets o f ge ne ral in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s are a ro u n d $ 1 7 5 b illio n , w h ic h is a b o u t 3 p e r ce n t o f th e assets o f a ll A u s tra lia n fin a n c ia l in s titu tio n s . In A u s tra lia , m o s t o f th e g e ne ral in su ra n ce b u sin ess in vo lve s p r o v id in g in s u ra n c e c o ve r f o r assets such as m o to r veh icle s a n d b u ild in g s w h ere a n y losses are g e n e ra lly in c u rre d w it h in 12 m o n th s o f re c e iv in g th e p re m iu m . In s u ra n c e com p an ies u s u a lly m a tc h th e d u ra tio n o f t h e ir assets w ith th e d u ra tio n o f t h e ir lia b ilitie s . T h e re fo re , w h ile g e ne ral in su ra n ce com panies do m a k e som e lo n g -te rm in v e s tm e n ts , th e m a jo r ity o f t h e ir assets are s h o rt te rm . This fa c to r, to g e th e r w it h t h e ir re la tiv e ly s m a ll size, m ea ns t h a t ge n e ra l in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s are n o t a m a jo r source o f c o m p a n y fin a n ce . Hence, in th is s e c tio n w e fo cu s o n life in s u ra n c e com p an ies a n d s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s , w h ic h m ake lo n g e r te r m in v e s tm e n ts . In s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s a n d m o s t s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s are re g u la te d b y A P R A , th e o n ly e x c e p tio n b e in g se lf-m a n a g e d s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s (SMSFs) w h ic h are re g u la te d b y th e A u s tra lia n T a x a tio n O ffice . L ife in su ra n ce co m p a n ie s a n d s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s are m a jo r sources o f co m p a n y fin a n ce . These in s titu tio n s raise la rg e a m o u n ts as p re m iu m s a n d c o n trib u tio n s , w h ic h are la rg e ly lo n g -te rm c o m m itm e n ts and, a cco rd in g ly, such in s titu t io n s te n d to a cq u ire lo n g -te rm assets such as shares issu e d b y p u b lic com p an ies, an d b o n d s a n d o th e r fo rm s o f d e b t issu e d b y g o v e rn m e n ts a n d com p an ies. A u s tra lia s s u p e ra n n u a tio n in d u s tr y has g ro w n ra p id ly since th e e a rly 19 90 s in resp on se to th e C o m m o n w e a lth G o v e rn m e n t s s u p e ra n n u a tio n g u a ra n te e charge p o lic y , w h ic h a im s to p ro m o te u n iv e rs a l s u p e ra n n u a tio n coverage. The g ro w th o f assets w it h in th e s u p e ra n n u a tio n s yste m is e xp e cte d to c o n tin u e , a lth o u g h th e ra te o f g ro w th w ill be in flu e n c e d b y changes in g o v e rn m e n t p o lic y a n d flu c tu a tio n s in in v e s tm e n t re tu rn s . Table 8.5 show s th e re c e n t g r o w th in b o th th e assets h e ld b y s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s a n d th e to t a l n u m b e r o f fu n d s . TABLE 8.5 Assets and number of funds—superannuation funds N u m b e r o f s u p e ra n n u a tio n e n titie s c la s s ifie d b y ty p e P o o le d s u p e r­ P u b li 7 _ A s s e ts ~ 3 0 Jun e ; ($ b illio n ) j C o r p o ra te In d u s try se cto r R e ta il S m a ll a n n u a tio n trusts Total ____ : _____________ ____: ___ : ______ j 2000 484.2 3389 155 81 293 212538 164 216620 2005 751.4 962 90 43 228 296813 130 298266 2006 904.2 555 80 45 192 315924 123 316919 2007 1172.8 287 72 40 176 356309 101 356985 2008 1131.0 226 70 40 169 381413 90 382008 2009 1067.4 190 67 40 166 404131 82 404676 2010 1198.5 168 65 39 154 418928 79 419433 2011 1350.9 143 61 39 143 446597 77 447060 2012 1400.5 122 56 39 135 481538 67 481957 Source: Australian Prudential Regulation Authority, www.apra.gov.au, Annual Superannuation Bulletin, June 2006, June 2010 and June 2013a. The la rge increase in to t a l s u p e ra n n u a tio n assets o v e r th e 7 years to J u n e 2 0 0 7 re fle c ts th e c o m b in e d effects o f p o s itiv e n e t c o n tr ib u tio n flo w s — t h a t is, c o n trib u tio n s exceeded b e n e fits p a id — a n d s tro n g in v e s tm e n t re tu rn s o n som e asset classes, p a r tic u la r ly A u s tra lia n e q u itie s , a fte r 2 0 0 2 . In th e years im m e d ia te ly a fte r 2 0 0 7 , n e t c o n trib u tio n s re m a in e d p o s itiv e b u t fa lls in th e value s o f m a n y fin a n c ia l assets, p a rtic u la rly e q u itie s , m e a n t t h a t t o ta l s u p e ra n n u a tio n assets d e c lin e d in 2 0 0 8 a n d 20 09 . Since 20 09 , th e assets h e ld b y s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s have re su m e d t h e ir lo n g -te rm tre n d , g ro w in g b y 31 p e r ce n t in th e 2 0 0 9 to 2 0 1 2 p e rio d . capital market The s ig n ific a n t increase in th e n u m b e r o f fu n d s o v e r th e p e rio d covered b y Table 8 .5 is due e n tire ly to g r o w th in th e n u m b e r o f s m a ll fu n d s , m o s t o f w h ic h are SMSFs. The n u m b e r o f s m a ll fu n d s is d is p ro p o rtio n a te ly h ig h re la tiv e to th e v a lu e o f t h e ir assets. To illu s tra te , a t 30 J u n e 2 0 1 2 s m a ll fu n d s a cco u n te d f o r 9 9 .9 p e r c e n t o f th e to t a l n u m b e r o f fu n d s b u t o n ly 31 .5 p e r c e n t o f th e to t a l assets h e ld b y s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s (A P R A 2 0 1 3 c, Tables 1 a n d 9). W h ile th e n u m b e r o f s m a ll fu n d s has g ro w n stro n g ly, Table 8.5 shows th a t th e n u m b e r o f fu n d s in o th e r categories, p a rtic u la rly c o rp o ra te fu n d s , has d e clin e d d ra m a tic a lly in rece nt years. In la rge p a rt, th is decline refle cts th e effects o f lic e n s in g re q u ire m e n ts th a t w ere phased in d u rin g a tra n s itio n a l p e rio d th a t ended on 30 J u n e 2 0 06 . The tru ste e s o f m a n y sta n d -a lo n e c o rp o ra te fu n d s chose n o t to seek a licence a n d th e m em bers an d assets o f these fu n d s w ere tra n s fe rre d to o th e r fu n d s , p a rtic u la rly in d u s try fu n d s and re ta il fun ds. The v a lu e o f assets h e ld b y s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s o u ts id e life in su ra n ce co m p a n ie s is s h o w n in Table 8.6. I t show s t h a t s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s are la rge , a n d g ro w in g , in v e s to rs in th e shares o f A u s tra lia n co m p a n ie s a n d in u n its in tru s ts . These assets ty p ic a lly a cco u n te d f o r a b o u t 45 p e r c e n t o f t o ta l fu n d assets in th e la s t fe w years, co m p a re d w it h less th a n 3 0 p e r c e n t in 1 9 9 0 . These fig u re s , in c o n ju n c tio n w it h tho se in Table 8.1, s h o w t h a t s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s are p o te n tia lly th e la rg e s t in s titu t io n a l source o f e q u ity c a p ita l f o r A u s tra lia n co m p a n ie s. O verseas assets m ad e u p 19 p e r c e n t o f to t a l assets in 2 0 1 3 com p are d w ith 1 1 .4 p e r c e n t in 19 90 . S im ila rly , cash a n d d e p o s its m ade u p 1 6 .4 p e r c e n t o f t o t a l assets in 20 1 3 , co m p a re d w it h o n ly 1 0 .7 p e r c e n t in 19 90 . In c o n tra s t, th e d e b t-ty p e in v e s tm e n ts — lo a n s, p la ce m e n ts a n d s h o r t- te rm s e c u ritie s — decreased fr o m a lm o s t 15 p e r c e n t o f t o ta l assets in 1 9 9 0 to 6 .7 p e r c e n t in 2 0 1 3 , w h ile in v e s tm e n ts in lo n g -te rm g o v e rn m e n t s e c u ritie s d e c lin e d fr o m 10 .1 p e r ce n t o f assets in 1 9 9 0 to o n ly 1.7 p e r c e n t in 2 0 1 3 . W h ile d e b t-ty p e in v e s tm e n ts have d e c lin e d as a pe rce n ta g e o f fu n d assets, th e a b s o lu te size o f t h e ir asset p o o l is such t h a t s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s re m a in a s ig n ific a n t source o f d e b t fin a n c e , e ith e r d ire c tly o r in d ire c tly , f o r businesses. F o r exa m ple, th e in v e s tm e n t o f $7 9 b illio n in s h o r t- te rm s e c u ritie s a t J u n e 2 0 1 3 w o u ld in c lu d e b ills o f exchange issu e d b y c o rp o ra te b o rro w e rs . A lso , th e cash a n d d e p o s its o f $ 2 2 7 b illio n h e ld in 2 0 1 3 w o u ld c o n s is t m o s tly o f d e p o s its in b a n ks, w h ic h co u ld use the se d e p o sits to fu n d lo a n s, in c lu d in g lo a n s to com p an ies. M a n a g e m e n t o f s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s is a v e ry im p o r ta n t a c tiv ity o f life in s u ra n c e com p an ies: as a t J u n e 2 0 1 2 , assets h e ld in s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s a cco u n te d f o r o ve r 90 p e r c e n t o f th e assets o f these c o m p a n ie s, c o m p a re d to a b o u t 65 p e r c e n t in 1 9 9 2 . D e s p ite th is h ig h p r o p o r tio n , th e re has been TABLE 8.6 Assets held by superannuation funds outside life nsurancec:ompanies, $ million 3 0 June L o n g -te rm E q u itie s C ash a n d i Loans a n d S h o rt-te rm g o v e rn m e n t a n d u n its in Land a n d O th e r A ssets d e p o s its 1 p la c e m e n ts se cu ritie s se c u ritie s trusts b u ild in g s assets o v e rs e a s Total assets 1990 8629 4234 7703 8191 23 770 12668 6399 9226 80820 1995 11143 5375 8794 20632 56 715 11006 8 513 21094 143272 2000 23469 16138 19376 19877 144266 17294 21239 68065 329724 2005 57443 5 292 25134 21579 281691 32157 29159 114419 566874 2006 70102 5 756 27261 28032 352674 36602 33 499 147312 701236 2007 114270 7220 36197 29755 476461 48408 49917 184930 947 157 2008 1 1 5 561 7981 40124 27253 453015 56986 52829 179601 933 351 2009 137118 9035 46467 22819 401814 61589 53281 148678 880803 2010 13 8 2 2 0 10272 55 206 25885 463862 66687 61191 171437 992 760 2011 16 8 9 5 0 11148 50200 21254 542262 76685 64796 187637 1122934 2012 208998 11963 60872 20661 525960 86089 66136 201064 1181742 2013 227003 13 232 78924 22857 621688 96450 60984 262926 1384066 Source: Table B15, Reserve Bank of Australia website, wvsrw.rba.gov.au. C hapter eight T he capital market TABLE 8.7 Assets held by life insurance companies—statutory funds, $ million L o n g -te rm 3 0 Ju n e ( C a sh a n d Loan s a n d S h o rt-te rm d e p o s its p la c e m e n ts se cu ritie s E q u itie s g o v e rn m e n t a n d u n its in ; L a n d a n d se cu ritie s trusts b u ild in g s , O th e r A ssets | assets o ve rse a s Total assets 1990 2 680 10 701 5 347 14 265 24 415 13 397 6 217 8 401 85 422 1995 4 912 5 817 9 927 23 779 38 076 9 486 9 321 17 214 118 532 2000 7 015 8 819 14 040 24 093 78 477 7 474 17 608 32 953 190 478 2005 4 429 2 577 12 757 13 441 156 021 n.a. n.a. 15 828 231 444 2006 4 777 4 396 11261 9 784 172 418 3105 21903 14 299 241 943 2007 5146 3 945 10 772 9 296 200 656 3 367 21 738 12 070 266 990 2008 4 643 3 975 8 771 9 405 173 943 2 710 20 814 11839 236 099 2009 7 816 3 594 10 349 7 091 149 238 1722 21 027 10 057 210 895 2010 7 261 2 337 9 821 7 066 165 534 1719 18 846 10 896 223 481 2011 8 464 2 284 6136 7 324 178 697 1829 18 765 11196 234 695 2012 11348 2 696 6 521 8 614 167 968 1871 21148 14 979 235 146 2013 12 034 1953 5 847 9 667 189 896 1520 19 303 14 986 255 206 Source: Table B1 4, Reserve Bank of Australia website, www.rba.gov.au. a s ig n ific a n t d e clin e in th e share o f t o ta l s u p e ra n n u a tio n assets h e ld b y life in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s. T h e ir share o f th e t o ta l s u p e ra n n u a tio n p o o l p eaked a t 4 4 p e r c e n t in 1 9 9 2 b u t d e c lin e d to less th a n 15 p e r ce n t b y J u n e 2 0 1 2 (APR A, 2 0 1 2 a ). The assets o f life in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s are s h o w n in Table 8.7. W h ile th e d a ta in Table 8 .7 w ill la rg e ly re fle c t th e assets h e ld in s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s m a n a g e d b y life in su ra n ce com p an ies, th e re are som e n o tic e a b le d iffe re n ce s b e tw e e n th e d is tr ib u tio n s o f assets in Tables 8.6 an d 8.7. C o m p a re d w it h th e s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s o u ts id e life in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s, based on th e 2 0 1 3 fig u re s, th e life in s u ra n c e com p an ies have in v e s te d a h ig h e r p r o p o r tio n o f t h e ir assets in d o m e s tic e q u itie s a n d tr u s ts (7 4 .4 p e r c e n t versu s 4 4 .9 p e r c e n t), a lo w e r p r o p o r tio n in cash an d d e po sits (4 .7 p e r c e n t versu s 1 6 .4 p e r c e n t) a n d a lo w e r p r o p o r tio n in overseas assets (5 .9 p e r c e n t versus 19.0 p e r ce n t). Table 8 .7 sho w s t h a t life in s u ra n c e c o m p a n ie s are n o t la rg e le n d e rs to th e c o rp o ra te sector. H is to ric a lly , m o s t o f t h e ir in v e s tm e n t in d e b t to o k th e fo r m o f g o v e rn m e n t d e b t se c u ritie s . H o w eve r, h o ld in g s o f ‘o th e r assets’,w h ic h in c lu d e s d e b t s e c u ritie s issu ed b y n o n -g o v e rn m e n t b o rro w e rs , have te n d e d to increase as t h e ir h o ld in g s o f lo n g -te rm g o v e rn m e n t s e c u ritie s have de clin e d . In c o n tra s t, lik e s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s o u ts id e life in s u ra n c e com p an ies, th e y are s ig n ific a n t s u p p lie rs o f e q u ity , w ith shares a n d u n its in tru s ts g e n e ra lly c o n s titu tin g b e tw e e n 70 a n d 75 p e r c e n t o f t h e ir to t a l assets a t th e end o f J u n e each ye a r fro m 2 0 0 6 to 2 0 1 3 . W h e n assessing th e asset d is tr ib u tio n s s h o w n in Tables 8 .6 a n d 8.7, tw o q u a lific a tio n s s h o u ld be n o te d . F irs t, th e in v e s tm e n t b y s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s a n d life in s u ra n c e com p an ies in p r o p e r ty is c o n s id e ra b ly g re a te r th a n suggested b y th e fig u re s s h o w n f o r 4la n d a n d b u ild in g s 1. M a n y o f the se in s titu t io n s in v e s t in p ro p e rty b y p u rc h a s in g u n its in re a l esta te in v e s tm e n t tru s ts (R E IT s)15 m a in ly because th e y p re fe r th e liq u id ity t h a t these tru s ts p ro v id e , p a r tic u la r ly i f th e t r u s t is lis te d o n a s to c k exchange. These in v e s tm e n ts are in c lu d e d in th e fig u re s f o r ‘E q u itie s a n d u n its in tr u s t s ’. Second, th e ‘s to c k ,fig u re s s h o w n in these ta b le s do n o t n e ce ssa rily p ro v id e an accu rate in d ic a tio n o f th e w a y in w h ic h new m o n e y flo w in g in to s u p e ra n n u a tio n is in ve ste d . F o r exa m ple, as n o te d above, th e ta b le s s h o w t h a t e q u itie s a n d u n its 15 Real estate investment trusts (REITs) were traditionally referred to as property trusts, which could be listed or unlisted. The term REIT was adopted in Australia in 2008. Where such trusts are listed on the ASX, they are referred to as A-REITs. in tru s ts m a ke u p a la rg e a n d ty p ic a lly g ro w in g p r o p o r tio n o f th e assets o f s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s and life in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s. In th e case o f s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s o u ts id e life in s u ra n c e com p an ies, th is asset class in cre a se d fr o m less th a n 30 p e r c e n t o f to t a l assets in 1 9 9 0 to ju s t o v e r 5 0 p e r c e n t o f to ta l assets in 2 0 0 7 a n d has since s ta b ilis e d a t a b o u t 4 5 p e r ce n t. Thus, i t m ig h t seem t h a t th e p r o p o r tio n o f s u p e ra n n u a tio n c o n trib u tio n s d ire c te d in to d o m e s tic e q u itie s pe ake d a ro u n d 2 0 0 6 -0 7 a n d th e n declin ed . H o w eve r, th e values o f th e v a rio u s assets h e ld a t a n y tim e w ill re fle c t p a s t re tu rn s as w e ll as th e p a tte r n o f n e w in v e s tm e n t. The r e tu rn s o n A u s tra lia n shares w e re u n u s u a lly h ig h fr o m 2 0 0 2 to 2 0 0 7 b u t n e g a tiv e in 2 0 0 8 a n d 20 0 9 . S pe cifica lly, th e S & P /A S X A ll O rd in a rie s share p ric e in d e x , w h ic h w as 3 1 6 3 .2 a t th e e n d o f J u n e 2 0 0 2 , a lm o s t d o u b le d to reach 6 3 1 0 .6 a t th e e n d o f J u n e 2 0 0 7 a n d th e n fe ll to 3 9 4 7 .8 a t th e e n d o f J u n e 2 0 0 9 . T h e re fo re , o v e r th e 2 0 0 2 to 2 0 0 9 p e rio d , a ty p ic a l fu n d c o u ld e x h ib it an in crea se in th e value o f e q u itie s as a pe rce n ta g e o f it s to t a l assets u p to 2 0 0 7 , fo llo w e d b y a d e clin e , even i f th e p r o p o r tio n o f n e w c o n trib u tio n s in v e s te d in each asset class re m a in e d c o n s ta n t o v e r tim e . The reverse can also occur: fr o m J u n e 2 0 0 9 to J u n e 2 0 1 3 , th e S & P /A S X A ll O rd in a rie s share p ric e in d e x rose b y 21 p e r c e n t b u t o ve r th e sam e p e rio d th e share o f t o t a l assets h e ld as e q u itie s a n d u n its in tru s ts fe ll m a rg in a lly fr o m 4 5 .6 to 4 4 .9 p e r c e n t. U n it tr u s ts are a c o m m o n f o r m o f c o lle c tiv e in v e s tm e n t in w h ic h th e fu n d s o f in v e s to rs are p o o le d a n d in v e s te d b y a p ro fe s s io n a l m a n a g e m e n t co m p a n y in a w id e ran ge o f in v e s tm e n ts , u s u a lly o f a specific asset ty p e . F o r e xa m p le , th e re are R EITs, A u s tra lia n e q u ity tr u s ts a n d in te r n a tio n a l e q u ity tru s ts . These a n d a v a r ie ty o f o th e r p o o le d in v e s tm e n ts are cla ssifie d as ‘m a n a g e d in v e s tm e n t sche m es’. The re g u la to ry re g im e f o r the se in v e s tm e n ts is set o u t in th e Managed Investments Act 1998. I t spe cifie s t h a t m an ag ed in v e s tm e n t schem es are to be o p e ra te d b y a sin g le R esponsible e n tity *, w h ic h m u s t be an A u s tra lia n p u b lic c o m p a n y h o ld in g an a p p ro p ria te A u s tra lia n F in a n c ia l Services Licence. M o s t o f th e se re sp o n sib le e n titie s are su b s id ia rie s o f b a n ks, in v e s tm e n t b a n k s o r in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s. In v e s to rs place t h e ir m o n e y in p o o le d in v e s tm e n ts to o b ta in a spre ad o f r is k a n d to o b ta in re tu rn s fr o m assets t h a t are to o exp en sive f o r in d iv id u a ls to p u rcha se d ire c tly . F o r som e in v e s to rs , tr u s ts m a y also be a ttra c tiv e f o r ta x reasons. In ge n e ra l, a t r u s t is n o t ta xe d p ro v id e d t h a t i t d is trib u te s a ll o f its in c o m e to in v e s to rs . Each in v e s to r is th e n ta x e d o n th e in c o m e th e y re ce ive d fr o m th e t r u s t . 16 T h ere fore, t r u s t in c o m e is a lm o s t in v a ria b ly d is tr ib u te d in f u ll w hereas a co m p a n y can r e ta in a ll o r p a r t o f its p r o f it to fin a n c e exp a n sio n . M a n y tr u s ts are o p e n -e n d fu n d s , w h ic h m ea ns t h a t n e w u n its m a y be cre a te d c o n tin u a lly as in v e s to rs c o n trib u te a d d itio n a l cash. These tru s ts are u n lis te d a n d in v e s to rs p u rch a se a n d re d e e m u n its a t values, c a lc u la te d d a ily b y th e fu n d m an ag er, based o n th e v a lu e o f th e assets h e ld b y th e t r u s t . The t r u s t m a y b u y a d d itio n a l assets a t a n y tim e a n d m a y ne ed to se ll assets a t tim e s in o rd e r to m e e t re d e m p tio n req ue sts fr o m e x is tin g in v e s to rs . In J u n e 2 0 1 3 , p u b lic u n it tr u s t s 17 in A u s tra lia h a d t o ta l assets o f $ 2 3 8 b illio n a n d a f u r t h e r $2 5 b illio n w as h e ld b y cash m a n a g e m e n t tr u s ts (R eserve B a n k o f A u s tra lia , Table B l, www. rba.gov.au). A w id e ran ge o f lis te d m a n a g e d in v e s tm e n ts (L M Is ) is also ava ila ble. A t th e e n d o f J u n e 2 0 1 3 , 2 0 4 m an ag ed in v e s tm e n ts w e re lis te d o n th e A S X a n d th e m a rk e t c a p ita lis a tio n o f the se e n titie s to ta lle d $ 1 63 b illio n . Based o n m a rk e t c a p ita lis a tio n a t t h a t tim e , th e la rg e s t c a te g o ry o f L M Is is re a l esta te in v e s tm e n t tru s ts ($ 9 5 b illio n ) , fo llo w e d b y in fr a s tr u c tu r e fu n d s ($ 4 0 b illio n ) a n d lis te d in v e s tm e n t com p an ies a n d tru s ts ($ 2 0 b illio n ) (A u s tra lia n S e cu ritie s E xchange, w w w .asx.com .au/products/m anaged-funds/ m arket-update.htm .) REITs a llo w in v e s to rs to acq uire an in te re s t in a p ro fe s s io n a lly m a n a g e d p o r tf o lio o f re a l estate. Some R EITs in v e s t o n ly in a p a r tic u la r ty p e o f re a l esta te such as in d u s tr ia l (w a reho use s a n d fa c to rie s ), offices, h o te ls o r re ta il (s h o p p in g ce n tre s, m a lls a n d cin e m a s). O th e rs are m o re d iv e rs ifie d a n d in v e s t in tw o o r m o re o f th e se ty p e s o f re a l estate. There are also in te r n a tio n a l R EITs, w h ic h are lis te d o n th e A S X b u t in v e s t in sp e cific o ffs h o re m a rk e ts such as th e US, E u ro p e o r Japan. 16 In many cases, the distributions from REITs are partly tax deferred, which means that investors do not pay tax on the taxdeferred component of the distribution until their holding in the trust is sold. 17 Public unit trusts are investment funds, excluding property and trading trusts, that are open to the Australian public. C hapter eight T he capital market A R E IT lis te d o n th e A S X w i ll have one o f tw o s tru c tu re s : • a s ta n d -a lo n e t r u s t t h a t p ro v id e s in v e s to rs w it h e xp o su re o n ly to an u n d e rly in g p o r tf o lio o f real estate assets; o r • a g ro u p c o n s is tin g o f a co m p a n y a n d one o r m o re re la te d tru s ts . P a rtly because o f it s ta x a tio n tre a tm e n t, a s ta n d -a lo n e t r u s t is s u ita b le f o r h o ld in g a n d m a n a g in g a p o r tfo lio o f assets t h a t p ro d u ce passive r e n ta l in c o m e f o r d is tr ib u tio n to in v e s to rs . P ro p e rty d e v e lo p m e n t a n d /o r m a n a g e m e n t are u s u a lly b e tte r u n d e rta k e n b y a c o rp o ra te s tru c tu re r a th e r th a n a tr u s t. In a g ro u p s tru c tu re , in c o m e -p ro d u c in g p ro p e rtie s w ill be h e ld b y th e tru s t(s ) w h ile an a sso cia te d c o m p a n y w i ll c a rry o u t p ro p e rty d e v e lo p m e n t a n d /o r m a n a g e m e n t. The g ro u p w ill issue s t a p le d s e c u r it ie s c o m p ris in g a STAPLED SECURITIES share in th e c o m p a n y p lu s a u n it in each o f th e tru s ts . The te r m s ta p le d ' re fe rs to th e re q u ire m e n t t h a t two or more legally separate instruments, typically an ordinary share plus units in one or more related trusts, which cannot be traded separately th e tw o se c u ritie s m u s t be tra d e d to g e th e r as i f th e y w e re a s in g le s e cu rity. In fra s tru c tu re fu n d s in v e s t in assets in v o lv e d in th e s u p p ly o f e s s e n tia l goods a n d services such as p o r t fa c ilitie s , ra ilw a ys, t o ll roa ds, a irp o rts , c o m m u n ic a tio n fa c ilitie s , p o w e r lin e s a n d o il/g a s p ip e lin e s . Some in fra s tru c tu re fu n d s in v o lv e a c o m p a n y /tru s t g ro u p th a t issues s ta p le d se c u ritie s . L ike REITs, in fra s tru c tu re fu n d s g e n e ra lly receive a stab le in c o m e s tre a m a n d p a y re g u la r d is tr ib u tio n s to in v e s to rs . In v e s to rs can also choose t o in v e s t b y b u y in g shares in a lis te d in v e s tm e n t co m p a n y (L IC ). T yp ica lly, an LIC w ill in v e s t in a d iv e rs ifie d p o r tf o lio o f in v e s tm e n ts , o fte n c o n s is tin g o f th e shares o f a w id e range o f o th e r com p an ies t h a t are also lis te d o n th e ASX. In v e s to rs th e re fo re achieve a d iv e rs ifie d p o r tf o lio w ith o u t th e need to p e rs o n a lly select, b u y a n d m anage a la rg e n u m b e r o f in v e s tm e n ts . Som e LICs specialise in p a rtic u la r typ e s o f assets such as in te r n a tio n a l shares, s m a ll co m p a n ie s o r g o ld co m p a n ie s, o r th e y m a y focus on p a r tic u la r g e o g ra p h ic a l re g io n s such as E u ro p e o r A sia . In c o n tra s t to u n lis te d m an ag ed in v e s tm e n ts , LICs are e s s e n tia lly clo sed -end , m e a n in g t h a t th e co m p a n y does n o t c o n tin u a lly issue n e w shares o r cancel shares as s h a re h o ld e rs jo in a n d leave th e com pany. R a th e r, th e co m p a n y s shares are tra d e d o n th e A S X in th e sam e w a y as o th e r lis te d shares, a n d th e size a n d t im in g o f a n y share issues o r repurchases w ill be d e te rm in e d b y th e c o m p a n y s m anagers. The m a rk e t p ric e o f th e shares is d e te rm in e d b y m a rk e t forces. The share p ric e w ill o fte n be s im ila r to th e m a rk e t va lu e o f th e L IC s assets b u t can be a t a p re m iu m or, m o re o fte n , a t a d is c o u n t to th e n e t asset value. The fa c t t h a t som e m a n a g e d in v e s tm e n ts are s tru c tu re d as a t r u s t w h ile o th e rs use a c o m p a n y s tru c tu re creates im p o r t a n t ta x a tio n d iffe re n ce s. F o r exa m ple, i f a t r u s t m akes a p r o fit, th e e n tire p r o fit w ill be passed o n to in v e s to rs as a d is tr ib u tio n a n d each in v e s to r w ill be ta x e d a t t h e ir in d iv id u a l rate. I f a lis te d in v e s tm e n t co m p a n y m ake s th e sam e p r o fit, i t w ill p a y ta x a t th e co m p a n y ta x ra te o n t h a t p r o fit. The a fte r-ta x p r o f it can th e n be d is tr ib u te d to sh a re h o ld e rs as a fra n k e d d iv id e n d .18 The A u s tra lia n c a p ita l m a rk e t is p a r t o f th e g lo b a l c a p ita l m a rk e t a n d f o r m a n y years th e re has b e en a sizeable flo w o f fu n d s fro m overseas f o r in v e s tm e n t in A u s tra lia n com p an ies. These flo w s have c o m p ris e d b o th e q u ity a n d d e b t, in c lu d in g e q u ity fu n d in g o f n e w v e n tu re s a n d f o r p o r tf o lio in v e s tm e n t. Some A u s tra lia n com p an ies, p a r tic u la r ly v e ry la rge ones, b o rro w d ire c tly fr o m overseas, a n d b a n ks a n d o th e r in te rm e d ia rie s have been v e ry a ctive in o b ta in in g fu n d s f r o m overseas. Because A u s tra lia n b a n ks ty p ic a lly have h ig h c re d it ra tin g s , th e y are b e tte r p lace d to b o rro w overseas th a n m a n y com p an ies. The fu n d s b o rro w e d b y th e in te r m e d ia ry are th e n le n t to c u sto m e rs. W h ile sizeable fu n d s have flo w e d fr o m overseas f o r in v e s tm e n t in A u s tra lia n co m p a n ie s, A u s tra lia has also been a s ig n ific a n t source o f fu n d s f o r in v e s tm e n t in fo re ig n com p an ies. F o r exa m p le , as s h o w n in Table 8.6, A u s tra lia n s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s have la rg e in v e s tm e n ts in overseas assets a n d the se in v e s tm e n ts have a t tim e s exceeded 20 p e r c e n t o f th e fun ds* assets. The in flo w to , a n d o u tflo w o f c a p ita l fro m , A u s tra lia is c o n s is te n t w it h in v e s to rs re c o g n is in g th e advantages o f d iv e rs ific a tio n , in c lu d in g th e o p p o r tu n ity to in v e s t in in d u s trie s t h a t m a y n o t be p re s e n t in t h e ir d o m e s tic eco no m ies. 18 Franked dividends are discussed in detail in Section 11.4.1. SUMMARY • A t a n y g iv e n tim e , s o m e e n titie s w ill h a v e su rp lu s b y c o m p a n ie s to ra is e e q u ity a n d lo n g -te rm d e b t is fu n d s (the 's u rp lu s u n its '), w h ile o th e rs w ill b e s e e k in g c o n s id e re d in m o re d e ta il in C h a p te rs 9 a n d 1 0 . fu n d s (the 'd e f ic it u n its '). A m a jo r ro le o f th e c a p it a l m a rk e t is to tra n s fe r fu n d s fro m th e s u rp lu s u n its to • • S e v e ra l ty p e s of f in a n c ia l in s titu tio n s fo rm an im p o r ta n t p a r t o f th e c a p it a l m a rk e t. T h e se in c lu d e th e d e fic it un its. in s titu tio n s th a t o p e r a te a s a g e n ts (such a s b ro k e rs ), The A u s tra lia n c a p ita l m a rk e t is la rg e , a c tiv e a n d w e ll f in a n c ia l in te r m e d ia r ie s (such as b a n k s ) a n d in v e s to rs re g u la te d a n d o ffe rs a w id e ra n g e o f o p tio n s fo r surp lu s (such a s in s u ra n c e c o m p a n ie s a n d s u p e ra n n u a tio n un its a n d d e fic it units. The use o f th e c a p ita l m a rk e t fu n d s ). KEY TERMS a u th o ris e d d e p o s i 卜 ta k in g in s titu tio n c a p ita l m a rk e t c e n tra l b a n k d e fa u lt ris k 214 211 in v e s tin g in s titu tio n 213 p r im a r y m a rk e t e x c h a n g e -tra d e d m a rk e t 212 fin a n c ia l a g e n c y in s titu tio n 214 211 212 212 s e c o n d a ry m a rk e t s e c u ritis a tio n 211 214 o v e r-th e -c o u n te r m a rk e t 22 1 fin a n c ia l assets fin a n c ia l in te r m e d ia r y 212 223 s ta p le d s e cu ritie s 229 QUESTIONS 1 [L O 1 D is tin g u is h b e tw e e n d ir e c t f in a n c e a n d in te r m e d ia te d fin a n c e . D iscu ss w h y s o m e b o r r o w e r s m ig h t p re fe r d ir e c t fin a n c e , w h ile o th e rs m ig h t p r e fe r in te r m e d ia te d fin a n c e . 2 [LO 1] W h y is th e e x is te n c e o f a s e c o n d a r y m a rk e t e x p e c te d to in c re a s e th e d e m a n d f o r s e c u ritie s is s u e d in th e c o r r e s p o n d in g p r im a r y m a rk e t? 3 4 [ L O l ] W h a t a r e th e m a in d iffe re n c e s b e tw e e n a n e x c h a n g e -tr a d e d m a rk e t a n d a n o v e r-th e -c o u n te r m a rk e t? [L O 2 ] D is tin g u is h b e tw e e n f in a n c ia l a g e n c y in s titu tio n s , f in a n c ia l in te r m e d ia r ie s a n d in v e s tin g in s titu tio n s . W h y is th e re s u ch a r a n g e o f in s titu tio n s in th e c a p it a l m a rk e t? 5 6 [L O 3 ] D iscu ss th e re la tiv e im p o r ta n c e o f th e f o llo w in g in s titu tio n s a s p r o v id e r s o f c o m p a n y fin a n c e : a) s to c k b ro k e rs b) in v e s tm e n t b a n k s c) banks d) fin a n c e c o m p a n ie s e) s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s . [L O 3 ] O u tlin e th e s e rv ic e s p r o v id e d b y fin a n c ia l in s titu tio n s , su ch a s s to c k b ro k e rs a n d in v e s tm e n t b a n k s , to c o m p a n ie s w is h in g to ra is e fu n d s d ir e c t fro m th e c a p it a l m a rk e t. 7 [L O 3 ] W h a t d is tin c tio n s c a n b e m a d e b e tw e e n th e a c tiv itie s o f la r g e A u s tr a lia n b a n k s a n d in v e s tm e n t banks? 8 [L O 3 ] In v e s tm e n t b a n k s c a n fa c e in h e re n t c o n flic ts o f in te re s t. E x p la in h o w th e se c o n flic ts o f in te re s t u s u a lly a ris e . H o w c a n th e y b e m a n a g e d ? 9 [L O 3 ] D u rin g th e g lo b a l f in a n c ia l c ris is , a t le a s t o n e A u s tr a lia n - b a s e d in v e s tm e n t b a n k c o lla p s e d , w h ile o th e rs , in c lu d in g th e s u b s id ia r ie s o f US a n d E u ro p e a n firm s , c o n tin u e d to o p e r a te b u t o n a s o m e w h a t s m a lle r s c a le . O u tlin e th e m a in d iffe re n c e s th a t c o n trib u te d to th e se v e r y d iffe r e n t o u tc o m e s . 10 [L O 4 ] W h a t s e rv ic e s d o b a n k s o ffe r to d e p o s ito rs ? 11 [ L 0 4 ] W h a t s e rv ic e s d o b a n k s o ffe r to c o r p o r a te c lie n ts ? C hapter eight T he [LO 4 】W h a t a re th e m a in r e g u la to r y d iffe re n c e s b e tw e e n a fo r e ig n b a n k s u b s id ia r y o p e r a tin g in A u s tr a lia a n d a fo r e ig n b a n k b r a n c h o p e r a tin g in A u s tr a lia ? W h a t a r e th e m a in im p lic a tio n s o f th e se d iffe re n c e s ? 13 [LO 5 】The m a jo r b a n k s in A u s tr a lia s e c u ritis e o n ly a s m a ll p r o p o r tio n o f th e ir m o r tg a g e lo a n s , r e g io n a l b a n k s m a k e g r e a te r use o f th is te c h n iq u e a n d s p e c ia lis t m o r tg a g e o r ig in a t o r s s e c u ritis e m o s t o f th e ir lo a n s . E x p la in w h y th e se d iffe re n c e s e x is t. 14 [LO 6 ] E x p la in p o s s ib le re a s o n s f o r th e r a p id in c re a s e in th e n u m b e r o f s u p e r a n n u a tio n fu n d s in e x is te n c e as w e ll a s th e to ta l assets h e ld b y th o s e fu n d s . 15 [LO 6 ] Institutional investors have a lw ays been m a jo r suppliers o f co m p a n y finance. D iscu ss th is s ta te m e n t a n d e x p la in h o w th is f lo w o f fu n d s o c c u rs . REFERENCES Australian Bureau of Statistics, Lending Finance, Australia, cat. no. 5 6 7 1 .0 , Table 3. Australian Prudential Regulation Authority, Annual Superannuation Bulletin, wvy^v.apra.gov.au, Commonwealth of Australia, ACT, June 2 0 0 6 , June 2 0 0 9 and June 2 0 1 3 a . September 2 0 0 8 . Available at w w w .blo om b erg.co m /a pps/ news?pid=2107 00 01 & sid=axaX5i4871 UO, 22 September 20 08 . -------; li f e insurance industry overview 7, A PRA Insight, Issue 3, 20 12 a, pp. 1 8 -3 9 , w w w .apra.gov.au. Investing in Australian Real Estate: A Guide for Global Investors, King & W ood Mallesons, 2 0 1 3 . Available at www.mallesons.com/Documents/Real_Estate_Real_ 0pportunities% 20_0ct% 201 1_hyperlinks.pdf. -------; Regulation Impact Statement: Implementing Basel III Capital Reforms in Australia, September 2 0 1 2 b , w w w .a p ra . gov.au. O verland , 丄 & Li, K., 'Room for improvement: Insider trading and Chinese w alls', Australian Business Law Review, 2 0 1 2 , pp. 2 2 3 -4 0 . -------, Discussion Paper: Implementing Basel III Liquidity Reforms in Australia, M a y 2 0 1 3 b , w w w .apra.gov.au. Reserve Bank of Australia, 'Asset securitisation in Australia', Financial Stability Review, September 2 0 0 4 , pp. 4 8 -5 6 . -------, Monthly Banking Statistics, O ctober 2 0 1 3c. Schwartz, C., 'The Australian Government Guarantee Schemed Reserve Bank of Australia, Bulletin, M arch 2 0 1 0 , pp. 1 9 -2 6 . Carew, E.; Fast M o n e y 4, Allen & Unwin, Sydney, 1998. Debelle, G ., 'W hither securitisation?/, Reserve Bank of Australia, Bulletin, December 2 0 0 9 , pp. 4 3 -5 3 . Gup, B.E., The N e w Basel Capital Accord, Texere, N ew York, 20 04 . C H A P T E R EIGHT R E V I E W 12 capital market Viney, C. & Phillips, P., Financial Institutions, Instruments and Markets, 7th edn, M cG raw-H ill, Sydney, 20 12 . Harper C. & Torres C., 'G oldm an, M organ Stanley bring down curtain on an era' (Update 5), Bloomberg, 22 231 CHAPTER CONTENTS I n t r o d u c t io n T h e c h a r a c t e r is tic s o f o r d in a r y s h a re s ^ 0 P riv a te e q u it y I^ Q I n f o r m a tio n d is c lo s u r e m F lo a tin g a p u b lic c o m p a n y g g■ g m S u b s e q u e n t is s u e s o f o r d in a r y s h a re s 252 E m p lo y e e s h a r e p la n s 265 In te r n a l fu n d s 266 M a n a g in g a c o m p a n y ’s e q u it y s tru c tu r e 268 LEARNING OBJECTIVES m A f te r s tu d y in g th is c h a p t e r y o u s h o u ld b e a b le to : 1 o u t lin e th e c h a r a c t e r is tic s o f o r d in a r y s h a re s 2 e x p la in th e a d v a n t a g e s a n d d is a d v a n t a g e s o f e q u it y a s a s o u r c e o f f in a n c e 3 o u t lin e th e m a in s o u rc e s o f p r iv a t e e q u it y in th e A u s t r a lia n m a r k e t 4 id e n t it y th e in f o r m a t io n t h a t m u s t b e d is c lo s e d w h e n is s u in g s e c u r itie s 5 o u t lin e th e p ro c e s s o f f lo a t in g a p u b lic c o m p a n y 6 d is c u s s a lte r n a tiv e e x p la n a t io n s f o r th e u n d e r p r ic in g o f in it ia l p u b lic o f f e r in g s 7 o u t lin e e v id e n c e o n th e lo n g - te r m p e r f o r m a n c e o f c o m p a n ie s t h a t a r e f lo a t e d 8 e x p la in h o w c o m p a n ie s r a is e c a p it a l t h r o u g h r ig h ts is s u e s , p la c e m e n ts , s h a r e p u r c h a s e p la n s a n d s h a r e o p t io n s 9 o u t lin e th e d if f e r e n t ty p e s o f e m p lo y e e s h a r e p la n s 10 o u t lin e th e a d v a n t a g e s o f in te r n a l f u n d s a s a s o u r c e o f f in a n c e 11 o u t lin e th e e ffe c ts o f b o n u s is s u e s , s h a r e s p lits a n d s h a r e c o n s o lid a t io n s . C hapter n in e S ources of f in a n c e : equity In th is c h a p te r a n d in C h a p te r 10, w e discuss m e th o d s b y w h ic h a c o m p a n y m a y fin a n c e its assets. In th is c h a p te r we discuss e q u ity , C h a p te r 10 covers d e b t, a n d le a s in g is co n sid e re d in C h a p te r 15. In th is cha pter, several w ays o f ra is in g e q u ity are co n sid e re d . The m a jo r ity o f e q u ity in A u s tra lia is raised b y p u b lic co m p a n ie s a n d u n it tru s ts w it h shares, u n its a n d stapled secu rities lis te d o n a s to c k exchange. I m p o r ta n t sources o f e q u ity f o r lis te d co m p a n ie s in c lu d e in it ia l p u b lic o ffe rin g s (IP O s) o f primary raising, V ig hts* issues, share pu rcha se o f w h ic h is a secondary raising o f c a p ita l. O th e r, shares, w h ic h is an e xa m ple o f a p la n s, p la ce m e n ts a n d re in v e s tm e n t o f d iv id e n d s , each less s ig n ific a n t sources o f e q u ity in c lu d e share issues to em ployees, calls o n c o n tr ib u tin g shares a n d exercise o f c o m p a n y-issu e d o p tio n s . In a d d itio n , th e use o f in te r n a l fu n d s as a source o f fin a n c e is discussed. E q u ity ra ise d b y is s u in g o rd in a ry shares is an im p o r t a n t source o f fin a n c e f o r A u s tra lia n co m p a n ie s. The im p o rta n c e o f e q u ity is illu s tra te d b y th e fa c t t h a t a t th e en d o f D e ce m b e r 2 0 1 3 , th e va lu e o f shares a n d o th e r e q u itie s lis te d on th e A u s tra lia n S e cu ritie s E xchange (ASX) was $ 1 5 2 7 b illio n . 1 As s h o w n in Table 9.1 , e q u ity c a p ita l o f a p p ro x im a te ly $ 3 1 5 b illio n was ra ise d th ro u g h th e issue o f shares a n d o th e r s e c u ritie s b y lis te d e n titie s ove r th e 5 -ye a r p e rio d e n d in g 30 J u n e 20 13 . TABLE 9.1 Listings and equity raisings by ASX-listed entities, financial year ended 30 June ($ billion) 2010 2011 2012 2013 1.9 11.4 35.6 10.2 9.9 Rights issues 28.5 23.2 7.4 8.1 4.0 Placements and share 42.0 28.6 10.1 12.8 19.2 15.0 10.2 7.8 9.3 6.9 2.1 2.4 2.1 2.4 2.3 0.5 0.7 0.2 0.1 0.1 90.0 76.5 63.2 42.9 42.4 【Type o f c a p ita l ra is in g 2009 Primary raisings IPOs Secondary raisings purchase plans R einvestm ent o f dividends Company-issued o p tio n s and employee share schemes O thers Total capital Source: Australian Financial Markets Association, 2 0 1 3 Australian Financial Markets Report, February 2014, p. 55. A m u ch s m a lle r b u t s t ill im p o r t a n t m a rk e t is th e p riv a te e q u ity m a rk e t, w h e re fin a n c e is ra ise d b y is s u in g s e c u ritie s t h a t are n o t p u b lic ly tra d e d . P riv a te e q u ity in c lu d e s v e n tu re c a p ita l, w h ic h re fe rs to th e fin a n c in g o f n e w v e n tu re s o r s ta rt-u p * com p an ies. B efo re d is c u s s in g th e ways in w h ic h co m p a n ie s raise e q u ity, we o u tlin e th e fe a tu re s o f th e m a in ty p e o f e q u ity s e c u ritie s th e y issu e— t h a t is, o rd in a ry shares. P reference shares, w h ic h are le g a lly e q u ity b u t also have som e o f th e c h a ra c te ris tic s o f d e b t, are discussed in C h a p te r 10. 1 Australian Securities Exchange Limited, www.asx.com.au/about/historical-market-statistics.htm#End_of_month_values. The figure quoted does not include the value of overseas-based equities listed on the ASX. There are also many private and unlisted companies, most of which are much smaller than listed companies. STAPLED SECURITIES two or more legally separate instruments, typically an ordinary share plus units in one or more related trusts, which cannot be traded separately B usiness finance 9.2 The characteristics of o rd in a ry shares E q u ity is th e m o s t fu n d a m e n ta l f o r m o f c o rp o ra te fin a n c e because e v e ry co m p a n y m u s t raise som e e q u ity LEARNING OBJECTIVE 1 Outline the characteristics of ordinary shares ORDINARY SHARES securities that represent an ownership interest in a company and provide the owner with voting rights. Holders of ordinary shares have a residual interest in the net assets of the issuing company and are therefore exposed to greater risk than other classes of investors RESIDUAL CLAIM b y is s u in g ordinary sh ares. A n o rd in a ry share gives th e h o ld e r o w n e rs h ip o f a p r o p o r tio n o f th e e q u ity o f th e com p an y. I f a co m p a n y has 10 0 0 0 0 issu ed shares a n d an in v e s to r h o ld s 1 0 0 0 shares, th e in v e s to r has an o w n e rs h ip in te re s t in 1 p e r c e n t o f th e n e t assets o f th e com pany. T h is does n o t m ea n t h a t th e in v e s to r can exercise o w n e rs h ip rig h ts w it h re sp e ct to sp e cific assets o f th e com p an y. H o w eve r, w h e n d iv id e n d s are p a id , o r i f th e co m p a n y is ta k e n o v e r b y a n o th e r com pany, o r is p lace d in t o liq u id a tio n , th e in v e s to r has th e r ig h t to receive 1 p e r c e n t o f th e p a y m e n ts m ad e to o rd in a ry s h a re h o ld e rs. P e rio d ica lly, a co m p a n y s d ire c to rs m a y decide to p a y d iv id e n d s to s h a re h o ld e rs an d, as discussed in S e c tio n 4 .3 , th e va lu e o f an o rd in a ry share can be v ie w e d as th e p re s e n t va lu e o f exp ected f u tu r e d iv id e n d s . The in te re s t h e ld b y s h a re h o ld e rs is a residual claim in th e sense t h a t s h a re h o ld e rs w ill receive d iv id e n d s o n ly a fte r a co m p a n y has m e t its o b lig a tio n s to a ll o th e r c la im a n ts such as su p p lie rs , em ployees, le n d e rs a n d g o v e rn m e n ts . S im ila rly , i f a c o m p a n y is placed in to liq u id a tio n , o rd in a ry s h a re h o ld e rs have a re s id u a l c la im o n th e proceeds fr o m th e sale o f th e co m p a n y s assets. Because s h a re h o ld e rs are p a id la s t, th e y face g re a te r r is k th a n o th e r in v e s to rs in a com pany. To com p en sate f o r th is ris k , in v e s to rs in o rd in a ry shares exp ect a ra te o f r e tu r n t h a t is g re a te r th a n th e y c o u ld o b ta in b y le n d in g to th e com pany. 9.2.1 | Fully paid and partly paid shares W h e n n e w shares are cre a te d a n d issu ed th e y w ill have a s ta te d issue p rice . T his p ric e m a y be payable in claim to profit or assets that remain after the entitlements of all other interested parties have been met has been p a id , shares are re fe rre d to as p a r tly p a id shares o r c o n trib u tin g shares. O nce th e t o ta l issue CALL p ric e has been p a id th e shares are f u lly p a id a n d th e h o ld e r c a n n o t be re q u ire d to c o n trib u te a n y m o re notice given by a company that the holders of partly paid shares must make an additional contribution of equity LIMITED LIABILITY legal concept that protects shareholders whose liability to meet a company’s debts is limited to any amount unpaid on the shares they hold f u ll a t th e tim e th e shares are issu e d o r p a r t o f th e issue p ric e m a y be payable in it ia lly w it h th e balance to be p a id in s u b se q u e n t in s ta lm e n ts , g e n e ra lly k n o v rn as calls. The a m o u n t a n d t im in g o f each call m a y be sp e cifie d in it ia lly o r th e c o m p a n y s d ire c to rs m a y d e te rm in e th e m la te r. W h e re o n ly p a r t o f th e issue p rice fu n d s to th e com pany, a lth o u g h th e y m a y be g iv e n th e o p p o r tu n it y to do so. A v e ry s im ila r s e c u rity th a t has b e e n issu e d to in v e s to rs is ca lle d an in s ta lm e n t re c e ip t. C o n tr ib u tin g shares a n d in s ta lm e n t re ce ip ts are discussed in d e ta il in S e ctio n 9.6 .3 . 9 .2 .2 ! Limited liability W h ile s h a re h o ld e rs face g re a te r r is k th a n le n d e rs, t h e ir r is k is lim it e d in t h a t th e y e n jo y lim ited liability. This m ea ns t h a t a s h a re h o ld e r is n o t p e rs o n a lly lia b le f o r th e co m p a n y s de bts. In th e case o f a co m p a n y lim ite d b y shares, th e lia b ilit y o f sh a re h o ld e rs is lim it e d to a n y a m o u n t u n p a id o n th e shares h e ld .2 F or exa m ple, i f an in v e s to r purchases shares w it h an issue p ric e o f $ 2 .5 0 p e r share, t h a t are p a r tly p a id to $1 .7 5 , th e in v e s to rs lia b ilit y f o r fu tu r e p a y m e n ts is lim it e d to 75 cen ts p e r share. C o n se q u e n tly, i f th e c o m p a n y is placed in to liq u id a tio n a n d has in s u ffic ie n t cash to p a y its c re d ito rs , h o ld e rs o f its p a r tly p a id shares can be re q u ire d to c o n trib u te u p to 75 cen ts p e r share to w a rd s th e p a y m e n t o f c re d ito rs . H o ld e rs o f f u lly p a id shares w o u ld n o t be re q u ire d to m ake a n y c o n tr ib u tio n to w a rd s th e p a y m e n t o f c re d ito rs , so th e m a x im u m a m o u n t th e y can lose is th e a m o u n t a lre a d y p a id to p u rch a se th e shares. 9 .2 .3 | No liability companies The m a jo r ity o f com p an ies lis te d o n th e A S X are lim it e d lia b ilit y com p an ies, b u t th e re are also m a n y m in in g co m p a n ie s th a t are re g is te re d as n o lia b ilit y co m p a n ie s. Such com p an ies m u s t in c lu d e th e w o rd s *No L ia b ility * o r th e a b b re v ia tio n lNV a t th e e n d o f th e co m p a n y s na m e. These c o m p a n ie s ty p ic a lly have p a r tly p a id shares on issue a n d can raise c a p ita l in stages b y c a llin g u p p a r t o f th e u n p a id c a p ita l. N o lia b ilit y co m p a n ie s have tw o m a in fe a tu re s t h a t d is tin g u is h th e m fr o m o th e r ty p e s o f com p an ies. O ne is t h a t th e y are re s tric te d to o p e ra tin g o n ly in th e m in in g in d u s try . The second fe a tu re is t h a t i f th e c o m p a n y fa ils , sh a re h o ld e rs have n o lia b ilit y f o r th e co m p a n y s de bts. A c c o rd in g ly , h o ld e rs o f p a r tly *5 6 1 2 The advantages and disadvantages of limited liability are discussed in Lipton, Herzberg & Welsh (2010, p. 24). See also section 516 of the C o rp o ratio n s A c t 2 0 0 1 . C hapter n in e S ources of fin a n c e : equity p a id shares issued b y a n o lia b ilit y c o m p a n y are n o t o b lig e d to p a y calls m ad e b y th e com pany. H o w eve r, sha reh old ers w h o fa il to pay a ca ll f o r f e it t h e ir shares. N o lia b ilit y co m p a n ie s are ty p ic a lly in v o lv e d in m in e ra l o r o il e x p lo ra tio n . T h e re fo re , th is second fe a tu re a llo w s sh a re h o ld e rs to re v ie w t h e ir in v e s tm e n t in a ris k y v e n tu re w h e n a d d itio n a l fu n d s are b e in g ra ise d a n d gives th e m th e o p p o r tu n ity to a b a n d o n th e in v e s tm e n t i f th e y be lie ve t h a t its p ro sp e cts are u n a ttra c tiv e .3 9.2.4|T he rights of shareholders S hareholders in a lis te d co m p a n y have m a n y rig h ts , such as th e r ig h t to receive an a n n u a l re p o rt, to be n o tifie d o f m e e tin g s a n d to a tte n d th o se m e e tin g s . In p ra ctice , m o s t o f these rig h ts are o f l i t t le im p o rta n c e and, generally, th e re are ju s t th re e rig h ts t h a t are im p o r t a n t to sh a re h o ld e rs in lis te d com p an ies: a S ha reh old ers are e n title d to a p ro p o r tio n a l share o f a n y d iv id e n d t h a t is de cla red b y d ire c to rs , b As p a rt ow n e rs o f th e com p an y, o rd in a ry s h a re h o ld e rs e x e rt a degree o f c o n tro l o v e r its m a n a g e m e n t th ro u g h th e v o tin g rig h ts a tta c h e d to t h e ir shares. These rig h ts in c lu d e th e r ig h t to e le ct m e m b e rs o f th e B o a rd o f D ire c to rs . The B oa rd, w h ic h is u s u a lly e lected a t th e A n n u a l G en eral M e e tin g , has u ltim a te c o n tro l o ve r th e o p e ra tio n s o f th e com p an y. U su ally, sh a re h o ld e rs have one v o te f o r each share h e ld .4 The r ig h t o f s h a re h o ld e rs to e le ct th e B o a rd o f D ire c to rs gives th e m som e c o n tro l o ve r th e co m p a n y s o p e ra tio n s . H o w eve r, in p ra c tic e , t h e ir a b ility to exercise c o n tro l is lim it e d because th e B oa rd o f D ire c to rs is g e n e ra lly able to m u s te r s u ffic ie n t vo te s, in c lu d in g p ro x ie s , to e n sure th a t its m e m b e rs are re -e le cte d a t th e A n n u a l G e n e ra l M e e tin g .5 C S ha reh old ers have th e r ig h t to sell t h e ir shares. This r ig h t can be exercised re a d ily in th e case o f lis te d shares because th e shares can be s o ld th ro u g h th e s to c k exchange. 9 .2 .5 1 Advantages and disadvantages of equity as a source of finance E q u ity raised b y is s u in g o rd in a ry shares has im p o r ta n t advantages as a source o f fin a n ce : • A c o m p a n y is n o t required to pay d iv id e n d s to o rd in a ry sh a re h o ld e rs: p a y m e n t o f d iv id e n d s is a t th e d is c re tio n o f d ire c to rs . T h ere fore, i f a c o m p a n y s u ffe rs a d e clin e in p r o fita b ilit y o r is s h o rt o f cash, i t can o m it th e p a y m e n t o f d iv id e n d s w ith o u t a n y s e rio u s le g a l consequences. In c o n tra s t, fa ilu re to pay in te re s t o n d e b t, o r delays in p a y in g in te re s t, w ill a lm o s t c e rta in ly have se rio u s legal consequences a n d can u ltim a te ly le a d to a c o m p a n y b e in g p laced in to liq u id a tio n . • O rd in a ry shares do n o t have a n y m a t u r ity date, w h ic h m ea ns t h a t th e is s u in g c o m p a n y has no o b lig a tio n to red ee m th e m .6 A g a in , in c o n tra s t, d e b t must be re p a id (o r *redeem ed,) w h e n i t m a tu re s. • The h ig h e r th e p r o p o r tio n o f e q u ity in a co m p a n y s c a p ita l s tru c tu re , th e lo w e r is th e r is k th a t le n d e rs w ill s u ffe r losses as a re s u lt o f th e b o rro w e r e x p e rie n c in g fin a n c ia l d iffic u lty . T h ere fore, ra is in g e q u ity b y is s u in g o rd in a ry shares lo w e rs th e in te re s t ra te t h a t a c o m p a n y w ill have to pay o n de bt. W h ile e q u ity has im p o r t a n t advantages, i t also has som e disad vanta ges. • I f a co m p a n y issues m o re o r d in a r y shares to raise n e w c a p ita l, e x is tin g sh a re h o ld e rs w i ll have to e ith e r o u tla y a d d itio n a l cash o r s u ffe r som e d ilu t io n o f t h e ir o w n e rs h ip a n d c o n tro l o f th e com pany. 3 4 5 6 Arguably, another feature of no liability (NL) companies is also important. Historically, NL companies had greater flexibility than other companies to raise capital by issuing shares at a discount to their par value. When the C o rp o ratio n s A c t was amended to abolish the par value concept from 1 July 1998, this advantage no longer existed. Subsequently, some NL companies have converted to limited liability status and the number of new NL companies listing on the ASX has declined. As at February 2014, only 68 of the 2140 companies listed on the ASX were NL companies (see www.asx.com.au/asx/ research/ASXListedCompanies.csv). The voting rights of a company s shareholders must be specified in its constitution. For companies listed on the ASX, the form of the voting rights is specified in Chapter 6 of the Exchange’s Listing Rules. As many shareholders do not attend the Annual General Meeting, the right to vote by proxy is provided. Voting by proxy involves a shareholder assigning to another person the right to vote on resolutions at the Annual General Meeting. While ordinary shares have no maturity date and can, in principle, exist in perpetuity, companies are permitted to repurchase their ovm shares, which leads to cancellation of those shares. Share buybacks are discussed in Chapter 11. m LEARNING OBJECTIVE 2 Explain the advantages and disadvantages of equity as a source of finance B usiness finance B o rro w in g , o n th e o th e r h a n d , a llo w s fu n d s to be ra ise d w ith o u t such d ilu tio n . S m a ll sh a re h o ld e rs m a y n o t be co n ce rn e d i f t h e ir in te re s t in a co m p a n y is d ilu te d , p ro v id e d th e n e w sh a re h o ld e rs pay a f a ir p ric e f o r th e shares th e y o b ta in , b u t in v e s to rs w h o o w n a s ig n ific a n t p r o p o r tio n o f a com p an y's shares m a y be u n w illin g to have t h e ir in te re s t d ilu te d . • The tra n s a c tio n costs o f ra is in g fu n d s b y is s u in g shares are u s u a lly h ig h e r th a n th e costs o f b o rro w in g a s im ila r a m o u n t. O n e rea son is th a t, as discussed in S e ctio n 9.4, a share issue b y a p u b lic co m p a n y o fte n re q u ire s a p ro s p e c tu s . Because o f th e v o lu m e o f in fo r m a tio n t h a t is u s u a lly p ro v id e d , a p ro s p e c tu s f o r a share issue ty p ic a lly ru n s to m o re th a n 1 0 0 pages a n d is c o s tly to p re pa re. A lso , share issues are o fte n u n d e r w r itte n : th is o fte n in v o lv e s a fee b e in g p a id to th e u n d e r w r ite r w h o gu a ra n te e s to pu rcha se a n y shares n o t ta k e n u p b y in v e s to rs . In o u t lin in g th e advan ta ge s a n d disad vanta ges o f e q u ity , ta x a tio n has n o t been m e n tio n e d because, u n d e r th e A u s tra lia n ta x syste m , th e o v e ra ll ta x b u rd e n s o n d e b t a n d e q u ity are o fte n th e sam e fo r A u s tra lia n re s id e n t in v e s to rs . A s discussed in S e ctio n 1 2 .5 .2 ,th e s yste m is e ith e r n e u tra l o r biase d to w a rd s e q u ity d e p e n d in g o n th e in v e s to rs m a rg in a l ta x rate. F o r overseas in v e s to rs in A u s tra lia n co m p a n ie s th e ta x b u rd e n o n e q u ity m a y be h ig h e r th a n th e ta x b u rd e n o n d e b t. T h e re fo re , in A u s tra lia , a n y ta x a tio n ad va n ta g e o r d isa d va n ta g e th a t m a y arise in a p a r tic u la r case de pe nd s o n th e circu m sta nce s o f th e s h a re h o ld e r co n ce rn e d a n d is n o t an in h e re n t fe a tu re o f e q u ity as a source o f fin a n ce . 9.3 Private equity M o s t o f th is c h a p te r covers e q u ity c a p ita l ra is in g b y com p an ies w h o se shares are lis te d a n d tra d e d p u b lic ly LEARNING OBJECTIVE 3 Outline the main sources of private equity in the Australian market o n a s to c k exchange. There is also a m u c h s m a lle r b u t s t ill v e ry im p o r ta n t p riv a te e q u ity m a rk e t. The te rm p riv a te e q u ity * is o fte n used to de scrib e tw o d is tin c t typ e s o f in v e s tm e n t. The f ir s t ty p e is also k n o w n as V e n tu re capital* a n d re fe rs to fu n d in g f o r s m a lle r a n d r is k ie r co m p a n ie s w it h p o te n tia l f o r s tro n g g ro w th . F o r the se co m p a n ie s, p riv a te e q u ity can be m o re a ttra c tiv e th a n a s to c k exchange lis tin g . F o r exa m ple, th e a m o u n t o f c a p ita l re q u ire d m a y be to o s m a ll to ju s t if y th e cost o f a share m a rk e t flo a t. A ls o , th e fu tu r e o f th e v e n tu re — w h ic h a t th e e a rlie s t stage m a y be n o m o re th a n an id e a — m a y be to o u n c e rta in to a ttra c t fu n d s f r o m a la rge n u m b e r o f in v e s to rs . The second ty p e is th e a c q u is itio n o f a lis te d p u b lic co m p a n y b y a g ro u p o f in v e s to rs w h o p riv a tis e * th e co m p a n y so t h a t i t is d e lis te d fr o m th e s to c k exchange. Such a c q u is itio n s u s u a lly in v o lv e a h ig h p r o p o r tio n o f d e b t fin a n c e a n d are c o m m o n ly k n o w n as leveraged b u y o u ts (LB O s), w h ic h are discussed in S e ctio n 1 9 .7 .3 . The re m a in d e r o f th is s e c tio n focuses o n p riv a te e q u ity fu n d in g f o r v e n tu re s o th e r th a n LBO s. 9.3.1 | W hat is private equity? P riv a te e q u ity re fe rs to e q u ity s e c u ritie s t h a t are n o t p u b lic ly tra d e d . P riv a te e q u ity can be ra ised fr o m v a rio u s sources in c lu d in g fa m ily m e m b e rs, frie n d s a n d ‘bu sin ess angels’,b u t th e m o re fo r m a l p riv a te e q u ity m a rk e t in v o lv e s fu n d s b e in g c h a n n e lle d to businesses b y p riv a te e q u ity fu n d m an ag ers. P riva te e q u ity fu n d in g can be d iv id e d in to fo u r ca te g o rie s:7 a start-up fin a n c in g f o r a b u sin ess less th a n 3 0 m o n th s o ld w h e re fu n d s are re q u ire d to de ve lo p th e c o m p a n y ’s p ro d u c ts b expansion fin a n c in g w h e re a d d itio n a l fu n d s are re q u ire d to m a n u fa c tu re a n d sell p ro d u c ts c o m m e rc ia lly c d turnaround fin a n c in g f o r a c o m p a n y in fin a n c ia l d iff ic u lt y management buyout (M B O ) fin a n c in g w h e re a b u sin ess is p u rch a se d b y its m a n a g e m e n t te a m w ith th e assistance o f a p riv a te e q u ity fu n d . Because p riv a te e q u ity is n o t p u b lic ly tra d e d , th e m a rk e t is illiq u id a n d in v e s to rs m u s t be p re p a re d to c o m m it fu n d s f o r th e lo n g te rm , w ith p e rio d s o f 5 to 10 years b e in g ty p ic a l. 7 This four-category breakdown is provided by Connolly and Tan (2002). C hapter NINE $ 〇URCES 〇F FINANCE: EQUITY E n tre p re n e u rs a n d in v e s to rs in n e w v e n tu re s se e kin g s ta rt-u p fin a n c in g face th re e im p o r t a n t in fo r m a tio n p ro b le m s .8 a Information gaps: in fo r m a t io n a b o u t th e va lu e o f th e v e n tu re is lik e ly to be in c o m p le te a n d v e ry u n c e rta in . b Information asymmetry: im p o r t a n t in fo r m a tio n is u s u a lly d is tr ib u te d u n e v e n ly b e tw e e n th e p a rtie s , w h ic h is th e p ro b le m k n o w n as in form ation asym m etry. In p a rtic u la r, th e e n tre p re n e u r w ill a lm o s t c e rta in ly have m o re accurate in fo r m a tio n th a n o u ts id e in v e s to rs a b o u t th e te c h n ic a l o r s c ie n tific m e r it o f an id e a a n d o f th e te c h n o lo g y re q u ire d to e x p lo it th e idea. O n th e o th e r ha n d , o u ts id e in v e s to rs m a y have m o re re a lis tic in fo r m a tio n a b o u t th e e co n o m ic v a lu e o f th e idea. H o w eve r, p o te n tia l in v e s to rs in a n e w v e n tu re are n o t co n ce rn e d o n ly w ith th e va lu e o f th e u n d e rly in g idea o r in v e n tio n . T hey also ne ed to assess th e s k ills a n d c o m m itm e n t o f th e e n tre p re n e u r. Som e e n tre p re n e u rs have an accurate a p p re c ia tio n o f t h e ir o w n s k ills , a b ility an d c o m m itm e n t, w h ile o th e rs te n d to be less re a lis tic . C Information leakage: th e re is th e r is k t h a t o th e rs m a y a p p ro p ria te th e e n tre p re n e u r s idea. To con vin ce p ro s p e c tiv e in v e s to rs t h a t a p ro p o s a l is va lu a b le , th e e n tre p re n e u r w ill have to p ro v id e th e m w it h som e in fo r m a tio n a b o u t th e idea. U n fo rtu n a te ly , d is c lo s in g th is in fo r m a tio n m a y a llo w som eone else to e x p lo it th e o p p o rtu n ity . INFORMATION ASYMMETRY situation where all relevant information is not known by all interested parties. Typically, this involves company 'insiders' (managers) having more information about the company’s prospects than 'outsiders' (shareholders and lenders) The m a rk e t f o r n e w v e n tu re fin a n ce has som e u n iq u e fe a tu re s t h a t have d e velope d to m in im is e th e effects o f these in fo r m a tio n p ro b le m s . The m a in such fe a tu re is t h a t fin a n c e f o r n e w v e n tu re s is n o rm a lly p ro v id e d in stages ra th e r th a n as a sin g le lu m p sum . A lso , th e p ro v is io n o f fin a n c e a t each stage is g e n e ra lly lin k e d to th e a ch ie ve m e n t o f m ile s to n e s , such as c o m p le tio n o f a p ro to ty p e o r successful o p e ra tio n o f a p ilo t p la n t. A c h ie v e m e n t o f the se m ile s to n e s o r o th e r p e rfo rm a n c e b e n c h m a rk s h e lp s to reduce in fo r m a tio n a s y m m e try in tw o ways. F irs t, i t p ro v id e s in v e s to rs w ith ta n g ib le evidence a b o u t th e v ia b ilit y o f th e p ro je ct. Second, i t also p ro v id e s th e m w it h in fo r m a tio n a b o u t th e s k ill a n d a b ility o f th e e n tre p re n e u r. P ro v id in g th e fin a n ce in stages is c le a rly sen sib le fr o m th e v ie w p o in t o f in v e s to rs . I f a p ro je c t is d e s tin e d to fa il due to te c h n ic a l d iffic u ltie s , la c k o f c o n s u m e r d e m a n d o r h ig h m a n u fa c tu rin g costs, i t is b e tte r to discove r these p ro b le m s b e fo re a ll th e fu n d s needed to c o m p le te th e p ro je c t have b e en c o m m itte d to it . Staged fin a n c in g is also in th e in te re s t o f th e e n tre p re n e u r. F o r an e n tre p re n e u r w ith n o tra c k re c o rd o f successful v e n tu re s , i t w ill be d iff ic u lt to co n vin ce o th e rs t h a t fu n d s in v e s te d in a n e w v e n tu re w ill be used p ro fita b ly . F o r th e e n tre p re n e u r, ra is in g m o n e y fr o m o u ts id e in v e s to rs in th e e a rly stages o f a v e n tu re is ge n e ra lly expensive. In th is c o n te x t, expensive* m eans t h a t th e e n tre p re n e u r w ill have to g ive u p a la rge fra c tio n o f o w n e rs h ip to raise a r e la tiv e ly s m a ll a m o u n t o f c a p ita l. A c h ie v e m e n t o f each m ile s to n e reduces u n c e rta in ty an d increases th e va lu e o f a p ro je c t. R a isin g fin a n c e in stages, a fte r m ile s to n e s have been achieved, th e re fo re h e lp s th e e n tre p re n e u r to r e ta in g re a te r o w n e rs h ip th a n w o u ld o th e rw is e be th e case. F in a lly, c o n s id e r th e p o s s ib ility t h a t release o f in fo r m a tio n to p ro s p e c tiv e in v e s to rs m a y le a d to a p p ro p ria tio n o f th e e n tre p re n e u r s idea. The e n tre p re n e u r m a y seek p ro te c tio n b y a s k in g p ro s p e c tiv e in v e s to rs to sig n c o n fid e n tia lity a g re e m e n ts w h e n th e y are g iv e n a co p y o f th e b u sin ess p la n . H o w eve r, m a n y in v e s to rs re fu se to sig n such a g re e m e n ts because a le a k o f in fo r m a tio n fr o m a n y source can re s u lt in c o s tly le ga l d isp u te s. I t is m o re im p o r t a n t to th e e n tre p re n e u r t h a t a p o te n tia l in v e s to r is h o n e s t a n d can be tru s te d n o t to m isu se c o n fid e n tia l in fo r m a tio n . T h e re fo re , p riv a te e q u ity f u n d m an ag ers w ill t r y to e sta b lish an d p ro te c t a re p u ta tio n f o r h o n e s ty a n d in te g rity . There are m a n y p o te n tia l sources o f fin a n c e f o r a n e w v e n tu re . These sources in c lu d e th e e n tre p re n e u r s p e rso n a l resources, p riv a te e q u ity fu n d s a n d fu n d s ra ise d b y an in itial public offering o f shares associated w ith lis tin g o n a s to c k exchange. The s u ita b ility o f th e se a n d o th e r sources o f fin a n c e depends o n th e v e n tu re s stage o f d e v e lo p m e n t. E v e ry v e n tu re is d iffe re n t a n d i t is im p o s s ib le to id e n tify a *life cycle’ o f d e v e lo p m e n t stages t h a t a p p lie s to a ll n e w v e n tu re s . There are, h o w e ve r, som e id e n tifia b le stages th a t w ill a p p ly in m a n y cases. M a n y v e n tu re s w ill b e g in w it h a research a n d d e v e lo p m e n t phase 8 Our discussion of these information problems is based on Smith and Smith (2000, pp. 27-8). IN ITIAL PUBLIC OFFERING a company's first offering of shares to the public B usiness finance w h ic h , i f successful, w ill be fo llo w e d b y a s ta rt-u p phase w h e re th e e q u ip m e n t a n d p e rs o n n e l needed fo r p ro d u c tio n are assem bled. I f th e p ro d u c t is accepted b y cu sto m e rs, th e v e n tu re m a y g ro w , p e rha ps v e ry ra p id ly a t fir s t, a fte r w h ic h th e re w ill o fte n be p e rio d s o f s lo w e r g ro w th , m a t u r ity a n d p e rh a p s decline. There m a y be n o cle ar d e m a rc a tio n p o in t b e tw e e n the se stages b u t in m a n y cases th e tr a n s itio n w ill c o rre s p o n d to id e n tifia b le m ile s to n e s . In t u r n , th e re is o fte n a re la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n the se m ile s to n e s and th e a v a ila b ility o f d iffe re n t sources o f fina nce . A t th e research an d d e v e lo p m e n t stage th e e n tre p re n e u r w i ll u s u a lly re ly in it ia lly o n p e rso n a l resources— t h a t is, savings, m o n e y t h a t can be b o rro w e d b y m o rtg a g in g th e fa m ily h o m e a n d p e rha ps lin e s o f c re d it lin k e d to c re d it cards. U nless th e e n tre p re n e u r is v e ry w e a lth y , these resources m a y be e x h a u ste d b e fo re th e v e n tu re is f u lly d e velope d a n d i t w ill u s u a lly be necessary to o b ta in fin a n c e fro m o u ts id e rs such as fa m ily m e m b e rs, frie n d s , in d iv id u a ls k n o w n as ‘b u sin ess an ge ls’ a n d p riv a te e q u ity fu n d s . O u ts id e fin a n c e ra ise d in th e e a rly stages o f a v e n tu re s d e v e lo p m e n t is n o r m a lly in th e fo r m o f e q u ity — t h a t is, th e e n tre p re n e u r tra n s fe rs a share o f o w n e rs h ip to th e n e w in v e s to rs a n d th e re tu rn s to the se in v e s to rs w ill d e p e n d d ire c tly o n th e success o r o th e rw is e o f th e v e n tu re . 9 .3 .4 1 Finance from business angels B usiness angels are w e a lth y in d iv id u a ls p re p a re d to in v e s t in p ro je c ts t h a t are a t a n e a rly stage o f d e v e lo p m e n t.9 The a m o u n ts in v o lv e d ty p ic a lly range fr o m te n s o f th o u s a n d s to h u n d re d s o f th o u s a n d s o f d o lla rs p e r in v e s tm e n t. These in v e s to rs w ill o fte n p ro v id e th e fu n d s ne eded to de ve lo p a v e n tu re to th e stage w h e re i t is p o ssib le to seek o u ts id e fin a n c e fr o m p riv a te e q u ity fu n d s , b a n ks a n d o th e r fin a n c ia l in s titu tio n s . B usiness angels are g e n e ra lly p re p a re d to in v e s t in a v e n tu re f o r 5 to 10 years. M a n y o f th e m have b u sin ess o r te c h n ic a l s k ills a n d a im to add v a lu e to a n e w v e n tu re b y p ro v id in g ad vice a n d e x p e rtis e as w e ll as fin a n ce . T ra d itio n a lly th e m a rk e t has o p e ra te d in fo r m a lly o n th e basis o f c o n ta c ts a n d re fe rra ls. H o w eve r, th e m a rk e t has re c e n tly been fo rm a lis e d b y th e d e v e lo p m e n t o f b u sin ess in tr o d u c tio n services t h a t seek to m a tc h in v e s to rs w it h e n te rp ris e s t h a t need c a p ita l. Som e o f the se services s im p ly p ro v id e in fo r m a tio n , w h ile o th e rs m a in ta in databases o f b o th in v e s to rs a n d c o m p a n ie s a n d a im to a c tiv e ly m a tc h the se p a rtie s . Services o p e ra tin g in A u s tra lia in c lu d e Business A n g e ls P ty L td (w w w .businessangels.com . au) a n d th e A u s tra lia n S m a ll Scale O ffe rin g s B o a rd (w ww.assob.com .au). Som e b u sin ess angels w ill in v e s t in p e rh a p s one p ro je c t p e r y e a r w h ile o th e rs w ill in v e s t in several. M o s t r e s tr ic t t h e ir in v e s tm e n ts to in d u s trie s w h e re th e y u n d e rs ta n d th e te c h n o lo g y a n d to p ro je c ts lo c a te d in t h e ir o w n g e o g ra p h ic a l area. A ty p ic a l e xa m p le is <J o h n ,, a 6 3 -y e a r-o ld c h a rte re d a c c o u n ta n t w h o has m a d e 12 in v e s tm e n ts in 8 years as a f u ll- tim e e q u ity in v e s to r.10 H e p o in ts o u t t h a t th e e x p e rtis e t h a t b u sin ess angels can p ro v id e is u s u a lly m o re im p o r t a n t th a n th e m o n e y th e y in v e s t. F in d in g m o n e y is easy i f a bu sin ess is good. A n g e l in v e s to rs lo o k f o r a b u sin ess w it h a w eakness t h a t th e y can h e lp to o ve rco m e so t h a t i t becom es a g o o d business. J o h n lo o k s f o r o p p o rtu n itie s in in d u s trie s w it h h ig h g ro w th p o te n tia l. Because he does n o t w a n t h is m o n e y tie d u p f o r m o re th a n 5 years, he lo o k s f o r a co m p a n y th a t can b e n e fit v e ry q u ic k ly fr o m re o rg a n is a tio n o r a d d itio n a l e x p e rtis e . Such co m p a n ie s are u s u a lly s m a ll a n d have a g o o d idea, b u t la ck e x p e rtis e in m a n a g e m e n t, m a rk e tin g , m a n u fa c tu rin g o r d is tr ib u tio n . J o h n w i ll in v e s t u p to $ 2 0 0 0 0 0 , re q u ire s a seat o n th e B o a rd a n d w ill sp e n d u p to h a lf a d a y each w eek w o rk in g o n th e com p an y. F in a lly , he lo o k s f o r c o m p a n ie s t h a t can p ro v id e h ig h re tu rn s o n h is in v e s tm e n t b y d e v e lo p m e n t to a stage w h e re th e c o m p a n y can be s o ld to o r m erg e w it h a la rg e r com pany, a ttra c t th e in v o lv e m e n t o f a p riv a te e q u ity fu n d o r lis t o n a s to c k exchange. 9 .3 .5 1 Finance from private equity funds The A u s tra lia n B u re a u o f S ta tis tic s (ABS) e s tim a te s t h a t $ 1 9 .8 b illio n was c o m m itte d to th e p riv a te e q u ity m a rk e t a t 30 J u n e 2 0 1 3 , o f w h ic h $ 1 3 .8 b illio n was d ra w n d o w n , le a v in g $6 b illio n u n c a lle d .11 A c c o rd in g to th e ABS, a t J u n e 2 0 1 3 a t o ta l o f 2 3 1 p riv a te e q u ity fu n d s o p e ra te d in A u s tra lia b y 1 2 2 v e n tu re c a p ita l 9 For a detailed discussion of this market in Australia, see Abernethy and Heidtman (1999). 10 This example is cited by Abernethy and Heidtman (1999, pp. 137-40). The remainder of this section relies heavily on that source. 11 Australian Bureau of Statistics (2014). C hapter n in e S ources of fin a n c e : equity m anagers h a d in v e s te d in 7 2 0 com p an ies. V e n tu re c a p ita l m an ag ers have tw o m a in roles: ra is in g m o n e y fro m in v e s to rs a n d s e le c tin g s u ita b le co m p a n ie s in w h ic h to in v e s t th e c a p ita l. In A u s tra lia , in v e s to rs in c lu d e s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s , w h ic h are th e la rg e s t source o f fu n d s , w e a lth y in d iv id u a ls a n d ba nks. W h ile these in v e s to rs have la rg e sum s ava ila ble, p riv a te e q u ity fu n d in g is n o t easy to o b ta in . A c c o rd in g to th e ABS, th e 1 2 2 m anagers re v ie w e d 6 6 0 4 p o te n tia l n e w in v e s tm e n ts in th e fin a n c ia l yea r e n d in g Ju n e 20 13 , f u r t h e r an alysis was c o n d u c te d o n 8 5 0 o f th o se a n d o n ly 76 w e re succe ssful in a ttra c tin g in v e s tm e n t. D u rin g th a t p e rio d the se v e n tu re c a p ita l m an ag ers m ad e n e w a n d fo llo w - o n in v e s tm e n ts to ta llin g $ 1 1 2 4 m illio n . V e n tu re c a p ita l fu n d m a n a g e rs g e n e ra lly in v e s t a m o u n ts in th e o rd e r o f $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 to $2 0 m illio n f o r p e rio d s o f 3 to 7 years. T hey lo o k f o r a bu sin ess w ith g o o d p ro sp e cts f o r g ro w th , m a n a g e d b y p e o p le w h o are capable, h o n e s t a n d c o m m itte d to th e success o f th e bu sin ess. P riv a te e q u ity in v e s tm e n ts ty p ic a lly have a h ig h e r le ve l o f r is k th a n m o s t o th e r in v e s tm e n ts . T h ere fore, fu n d m an ag ers seek a re la tiv e ly h ig h ra te o f r e tu r n t h a t w ill v a ry w it h th e p e rce ive d ris k . F o r e xa m p le , p ro v is io n o f seed a n d s ta rt-u p c a p ita l in vo lve s a h ig h le v e l o f r is k a n d in v e s to rs m a y seek a ra te o f r e tu r n o f a t le a st 30 to 4 0 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m o ve r th e life o f th e in v e s tm e n t. A t a la te r stage w h e n p r o d u c tio n has co m m e n ce d a n d p ro d u c t is b e in g sold, p ro v is io n o f c a p ita l f o r e x p a n s io n in v o lv e s lo w e r r is k so t h a t th e m in im u m ra te o f r e tu r n s o u g h t m a y be 20 to 30 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m . To o b ta in p riv a te e q u ity i t is e s s e n tia l to have a w e ll-d o c u m e n te d a n d b e lie v a b le b u sin ess p la n . The p la n s h o u ld p ro v id e in fo r m a t io n on: • th e s tru c tu re , a c tiv itie s a n d fin a n c ia l h is to r y o f th e bu sin ess • analysis o f th e in v e s tm e n t o p p o r tu n ity • th e a m o u n t o f c a p ita l s o u g h t • h o w th e c a p ita l w ill be used • fin a n c ia l p ro je c tio n s • th e q u a lific a tio n s a n d e xp e rie n ce o f th e m a n a g e m e n t team . As w e ll as b e c o m in g p a r t o w n e rs o f th e businesses th e y in v e s t in , fu n d m an ag ers ty p ic a lly re q u ire a seat on th e c o m p a n y s B o a rd o f D ire c to rs . This does n o t m e a n t h a t th e y seek d a y -to -d a y c o n tro l. R a th er, p riv a te e q u ity fu n d s g e n e ra lly ta k e a s ig n ific a n t m in o r it y share in th e c o m p a n y a n d a im to p ro v id e v a lu a b le advice o n b o th te c h n ic a l a n d m a n a g e m e n t issues. A n e n tre p re n e u r m a y be able to o b ta in c a p ita l fr o m a v a rie ty o f sources, b u t a fu n d m a n a g e r can also p ro v id e m a n a g e m e n t in p u t based o n th e e xp erience o f h e lp in g o th e r com p an ies ove rco m e th e p ro b le m s ty p ic a lly e n c o u n te re d b y new , fa s t-g ro w in g businesses. The in v e s tm e n t veh icle s d iffe r c o n s id e ra b ly in size, th e ty p e o f in d u s trie s th e y in v e s t in an d th e typ e s o f m a n a g e m e n t s u p p o rt th e y can p ro v id e . T h e re fo re , i t is im p o r t a n t t h a t an e n tre p re n e u r se e kin g p riv a te e q u ity s h o u ld be aw are o f the se d iffe re n ce s a n d a p p ro a ch th e fin a n c ie rs t h a t are b e s t e q u ip p e d to p ro v id e th e c a p ita l a n d s u p p o rt t h a t th e b u sin e ss is lik e ly to need. M o s t fu n d m an ag ers a im t o achieve th e m a jo r ity o f t h e ir r e tu r n in th e f o r m o f c a p ita l g a in ra th e r th a n d iv id e n d s . A c c o rd in g ly , th e y u s u a lly p la n to d ispo se o f th e in v e s tm e n t, ty p ic a lly w it h in a p e rio d o f 3 to 7 years. D isp o sa l m a y ta k e place in one o f th re e ways: a an in it ia l p u b lic o ffe rin g a sso cia te d w it h s to c k exchange lis tin g b sale C voluntary liquidation. W h e re a sale occurs th e b u y e r m a y be a la rg e r co m p a n y (a ‘tra d e sale’) ,th e m a jo r ity o w n e r, th e m a n a g e m e n t o r a n o th e r o u ts id e in v e s to r. W h ile d isp o sa l o f th e in v e s tm e n t can re s u lt in s p e c ta c u la r gains, th e le ve l o f r is k is h ig h a n d i t is to be e xp ected t h a t a s ig n ific a n t p r o p o r tio n o f th e d isp o sa ls th a t occur w ill in v o lv e a loss. In som e cases th e p ro je c t w ill fa il a n d th e in v e s tm e n t w i ll be liq u id a te d . P riva te e q u ity in v e s tm e n t in A u s tra lia has g ro w n ra p id ly since th e e a rly 1 9 9 0 s. F actors t h a t have c o n trib u te d to th is g ro w th in c lu d e : • g ro w th in th e v o lu m e o f fu n d s flo w in g in to s u p e ra n n u a tio n , to g e th e r w it h in cre a se d re c o g n itio n b y • g o v e rn m e n t p ro g ra m s to en cou rage in v e s tm e n t in n e w v e n tu re s , such as th e In n o v a tio n In v e s tm e n t fu n d m anagers o f th e ro le o f p riv a te e q u ity in v e s tm e n ts as p a r t o f a d iv e rs ifie d p o r tf o lio F u n d p ro g ra m a n d th e E a rly Stage V e n tu re C a p ita l L im ite d P a rtn e rs h ip s p ro g ra m (see w w w . ausindustry.gov.au). • re g u la to ry changes t h a t a llo w b a n ks to m a ke e q u ity in v e s tm e n ts . |www j 9.4 Information disclosure C h a p te r 6 D o f th e LEARNING OBJECTIVE 4 Identify the information Corporations Act co n ta in s p ro v is io n s designed to ensure th a t in v e s to rs in p u b lic com panies are p ro te c te d b y disclosu re o f in fo rm a tio n . There are p a rtic u la r disclosure re q u ire m e n ts th a t a p p ly to o ffe rs o f secu ritie s so th a t in v e s to rs s h o u ld be able to m ake an in fo rm e d de cisio n on w h e th e r to that must be disclosed purchase th e securities. These re q u ire m e n ts are g e n e ra lly sa tisfie d b y p ro v id in g p o te n tia l in ve sto rs w ith a when issuing securities disclosure docum ent c o n ta in in g in fo rm a tio n a b o u t th e issu er a nd d e tails o f th e secu ritie s o ffe re d fo r sale. H ow ever, th e re are v a rio u s e x e m p tio n s th a t m ean a disclosu re d o c u m e n t is n o t needed f o r som e o ffe rs o f secu ritie s. DISCLOSURE DOCUMENT prospectus, profile statement o r offer In cases w h e re d is c lo s u re is needed, th e d isclo su re re q u ire m e n ts v a ry d e p e n d in g o n w h e th e r th e s e c u ritie s are a lre a d y lis te d o n th e s to c k exchange. W e n o w discuss th e d isclo su re re q u ire m e n ts f o r o ffe rs o f s e c u ritie s t h a t do n o t fa ll in to a n y o f th e e x e m p t categories. information statement that must be supplied 9.4.1 | Offers of unlisted securities to potential investors to provide information about an offer of O ffe rs o f u n lis te d s e c u ritie s in c lu d e in it ia l p u b lic o ffe rin g s o f o r d in a r y shares a n d issues b y lis te d securities co m p a n ie s o f a n e w class o f se c u ritie s . In the se cases, th e s e c u ritie s do n o t have an o b se rva b le m a rk e t p ric e a n d in th e case o f an in it ia l p u b lic o ffe rin g th e re m a y be lit t le , i f any, p u b lic ly a va ila b le in fo r m a tio n a b o u t th e com p an y. T h ere fore, th e disclo su re re q u ire m e n ts t h a t a p p ly to o ffe rs o f u n lis te d se c u ritie s are m o re s tr in g e n t th a n th o se f o r lis te d se cu ritie s. The g e n e ra l ru le is t h a t an o ffe r o f s e c u ritie s to in v e s to rs c a n n o t p ro cee d u n t il a d isclo su re d o c u m e n t has b e e n lo d g e d w it h th e A u s tra lia n S e cu ritie s a n d In v e s tm e n ts C o m m is s io n (A S IC ). D isclo su re d o c u m e n ts m a y be g iv e n to p o te n tia l in v e s to rs as so o n as th e y have b e en lo d g e d w it h A S IC . F o r u n lis te d s e c u ritie s , a w a itin g p e rio d o f a t le a st 7 days is im p o s e d b e fo re a p p lic a tio n s b y in v e s to rs can be accepted. The w a itin g p e rio d a llo w s th e d isclo su re d o c u m e n t to be e x a m in e d b y A S IC a n d o th e r in te re s te d p a rtie s . I f th e d o c u m e n t is fo u n d to be d e fic ie n t, th e issue o f s e c u ritie s can be delayed u n t il an acceptable s u p p le m e n ta ry o r re p la c e m e n t d o c u m e n t is p ro v id e d . The in fo r m a t io n t h a t m u s t be in c lu d e d va rie s w it h th e ty p e o f d is c lo s u re d o c u m e n t. The typ e s m o s t c o m m o n ly used are: • a p ro s p e c tu s • a s h o r t- fo rm p ro sp e ctu s • an o ffe r in fo r m a t io n s ta te m e n t.12 Prospectuses PROSPECTUS a docum ent that, A p ro sp ectu s is th e m o s t c o m p re h e n sive d o c u m e n t a n d g e n e ra lly c o n ta in s in fo r m a t io n o f fo u r m a in types: a m o ng other things, provides details of a the co m p a n y and fu n d s w ill be used, a n y u p p e r o r lo w e r lim it s o n th e a m o u n t t h a t each in d iv id u a l can in v e s t a n d any the terms of the issue of securities, w hich must be pro vided to in fo r m a t io n a b o u t th e s e c u rity issue— h o w m u c h c a p ita l is s o u g h t, th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e , h o w th e m in im u m s u b s c rip tio n le ve l th a t m u s t be ach ie ved b n o n -fin a n c ia l in fo r m a t io n a b o u t th e issu e r— a d e ta ile d d e s c rip tio n o f it s b u sin ess a n d re p o rts fro m d ire c to rs o r e x p e rts in th e in d u s tr y potential investors by a co m p a n y seeking to C a d e ta ile d d is c u s s io n o f th e ris k s associated w ith th e bu sin ess issue shares or other d fin a n c ia l in fo r m a tio n a b o u t th e is s u e r— th e m o s t re c e n t a u d ite d fin a n c ia l s ta te m e n ts an d, in m a n y securities cases, fin a n c ia l fo re ca sts in c lu d in g fo re ca sts o f p r o fits a n d d iv id e n d s . The t e x t o f a ll p ro sp e ctu se s issu ed in A u s tra lia since 2 0 0 1 is a va ila ble a t w w w .s e a rc h .a s ic .g o v .a u / o f f e r li s t / o f f e r l is t 一 is s u e r 一 n a m e .h tm l. A p ro s p e c tu s is th e m o s t exp e n sive o f th e d o c u m e n ts to p re p a re , p r i n t a n d d is trib u te . The fa c to rs th a t c o n trib u te to these costs in c lu d e th e size o f th e d o c u m e n t a n d th e fees payable to e x p e rts w h ose re p o rts 12 These disclosure documents apply in the case of security issues by companies. If funds are being raised for a managed investment, such as a property trust, a different type of disclosure document known as a product disclosure statement (PDS) is required. C hapter n in e S ources are in clu d e d . M o re o v e r, d e ficie n cie s in a d isclo su re d o c u m e n t can lead to p e op le w h o w ere in v o lv e d in its p re p a ra tio n o r in th e is s u in g o f s e c u ritie s b e in g lia b le f o r c r im in a l p ro s e c u tio n . T hey m a y also be re q u ire d to com pensate in v e s to rs f o r losses su ffe re d as a re s u lt o f a m is s ta te m e n t in , o r an o m is s io n fro m , th e d o cu m e n t. H o w eve r, th e Corporations Act p ro v id e s a *due d ilig e n c e , defence in re la tio n to a p ro s p e c tu s and o th e r d isclo su re d o cu m e n ts. T his is a defence a g a in s t a c la im o f m is s ta te m e n t o r o m is s io n i f th e p e rso n m ade a ll reasonable e n q u irie s a n d b e lie ve d o n rea son able g ro u n d s t h a t th e s ta te m e n t w as n o t m is le a d in g o r de ceptive, o r th a t th e re w as n o o m is s io n . The p re p a ra tio n o f a p ro s p e c tu s can in v o lv e e x te n s iv e an d c o s tly in v e s tig a tio n s to e n su re t h a t th e in fo r m a tio n p ro v id e d is as accurate as p o ssib le a n d t h a t th e due d ilig e n ce defence w ill be a va ila b le i f a n y d e fic ie n c y is fo u n d . The p ro sp e ctu s d is tr ib u te d to p o te n tia l in v e s to rs can be in a s h o r t f o r m 1, w h ic h m ea ns t h a t i t re fe rs to m a te ria l in d o c u m e n ts lo d g e d w ith A SIC in s te a d o f p ro v id in g t h a t m a te ria l in th e p ro sp e ctu s. A s h o rt fo rm pro sp e ctu s m u s t in fo r m in v e s to rs t h a t th e y are e n title d to a fre e cop y o f th e a d d itio n a l m a te ria l o n request. O ffer information statements A n o ffe r in fo r m a tio n s ta te m e n t (O IS ) m a y be used in s te a d o f a p ro s p e c tu s i f th e a m o u n t o f m o n e y to be raised is re la tiv e ly sm a ll. S p e cifica lly, an O IS m a y be used o n ly i f th e a m o u n t o f m o n e y to be ra ise d b y th e issuer, w h e n adde d to a ll a m o u n ts p re v io u s ly raised, is less th a n $ 1 0 m illio n . A n O IS is m u c h less c o s tly to p re p a re th a n a p ro s p e c tu s because th e in fo r m a tio n to be disclose d is m in im a l a n d e x te n s iv e *due d ilig e n c e ’ e n q u irie s are n o t needed. 9 .4 .2 1 Offers of listed securities The d isclosu re re q u ire m e n ts are less o n e ro u s f o r o ffe rs o f s e c u ritie s t h a t are a lre a d y lis te d o n a s to c k exchange. A n exa m ple is a rig h ts issue w h e re n e w shares are o ffe re d to e x is tin g sh a re h o ld e rs. As discussed in S e ctio n 9.6 .1 , a p ro s p e c tu s is n o lo n g e r re q u ire d f o r a rig h ts issue, b u t th e re m a y be cases w h ere such issues are a cco m p a n ie d b y a p ro sp e ctu s. A lis te d e n t it y is s u b je c t to c o n tin u o u s d isclo su re re q u ire m e n ts u n d e r s to c k exchange lis tin g ru le s backed b y th e Corporations Act. A n y m a te ria l p ric e - se n sitive in fo r m a tio n has to be d isclo se d to th e s to c k exchange o n a c o n tin u o u s basis. T h e re fo re , m u c h o f th e in fo r m a tio n t h a t w o u ld n o rm a lly have to be in c lu d e d in a p ro s p e c tu s is a lre a d y p u b lic ly ava ila ble, so, i f a rig h ts issue is m ad e u n d e r a p ro sp e ctu s, i t does n o t n e ed to be as d e ta ile d as a p ro s p e c tu s f o r an issue o f u n lis te d se c u ritie s . 9 .4 .3 1 Offers that do not need disclosure There are v a rio u s e x e m p tio n s t h a t m e a n a d isclo su re d o c u m e n t is n o t ne eded f o r som e o ffe rs o f se c u ritie s .13 The m a in e x e m p tio n s are o u tlin e d in Table 9.2. TABLE 9.2 Main types of offer that do not need disclosure D e s c rip tio n O ff e r ty p e Small-scale offerin gs Personal offers th a t re s u lt in issues to no m ore th a n 20 in vestors in a ro llin g 1 2 -m o n th p e rio d , w ith a m a x im u m o f $2 m illio n raised. Rights issues A p ro -ra ta o ffe r made o f a d d itio n a l shares to e x is tin g shareholders. The term s o f the o ffe r to each shareholder m u s t be id e n tic a l and the new shares m u s t be o f the same class as those already held. S ophisticated investors: The a m o u n t payable fo r securities m u s t be a t least: • Large offers $ 5 0 0 0 0 0 , OR continued 13 The circumstances where a disclosure document is not required are set out in section 708 of the C o rp o ratio n s A ct. of f in a n c e : equity B usiness finance Table 9 .2 continued O f f e r ty p e D e s c rip tio n • O ffers to w e a lth y in vestors th e in v e s to r had a gross incom e over each o f the previous tw o fin a n c ia l years o f a t least $250 000 o r n e t assets o f a t least $2.5 m illio n , OR • O ffers to experienced in vestors th e o ffe r is made th ro u g h a licensed securities dealer w h o is satisfied th a t the in v e s to r has s u ffic ie n t previous experience in in v e s tin g in securities to assess m a tte rs such as th e m e rits o f th e o ffe r and th e risks involved. Executive officers and O ffers to d irectors and o th e r persons in vo lve d in th e m anagem ent o f the associates issu ing e n tity and ce rta in o f th e ir relatives and associated e n titie s . E x is tin g s e c u rity holders O ffers o f fu lly pa id o rd in a ry shares u n d e r a d iv id e n d re in v e s tm e n t plan, bonus share pla n o r share purchase plan. O ffers o f debentures to e x is tin g debenture holders. 9.5 Floating a public com pany W h e n a c o m p a n y f ir s t in v ite s th e p u b lic to su b scrib e f o r shares i t is u s u a l to re fe r to t h is as L E A R N IN G OBJECTIVE 5 Outline the process floating th e com pany. A n a lte rn a tiv e te r m is t h a t th e c o m p a n y m akes an in it ia l p u b lic o ffe rin g (IP O ). A co m p a n y m a k in g it s f ir s t issue o f o rd in a ry shares to th e p u b lic w ill u s u a lly a p p ly f o r s to c k exchange lis tin g , w h ic h of floating a public m ea ns t h a t sh a re h o ld e rs in th e c o m p a n y can se ll t h e ir shares o n th e s to c k exchange.14 To o b ta in lis tin g , co m p a n y th e d ire c to rs o f th e c o m p a n y m u s t e n sure t h a t it s p ro p o s e d s tru c tu re c o m p lie s w it h th e re q u ire m e n ts o f th e exchange. F o r exa m ple, th e A S X has e xte n sive lis tin g ru le s t h a t are based o n seve ral p rin c ip le s d e sig n e d to p ro te c t th e in te re s ts o f lis te d e n titie s , in v e s to rs a n d th e r e p u ta tio n o f th e m a rk e t. L is te d e n titie s m u s t s a tis fy m in im u m s ta n d a rd s o f q u a lity a n d size, a n d c o m p ly w it h s trin g e n t re q u ire m e n ts o n d isclo su re o f in fo r m a tio n . F o r exa m ple, to achieve lis tin g o n th e ASX, a c o m p a n y m u s t u s u a lly have a t le a s t 3 0 0 sh a re h o ld e rs, each s u b s c rib in g f o r shares w it h a v a lu e o f a t le a s t $ 2 0 0 0 . E n titie s to be lis te d m u s t also s a tis fy e ith e r a p r o f it te s t o r an assets te s t. The p r o f it te s t re q u ire s th e co m p a n y to have g e n e ra te d a m in im u m aggregate p r o f it o f $1 m illio n o v e r th e p re v io u s th re e years a n d a t le ast $ 4 0 0 0 0 0 in th e p re v io u s 12 m o n th s . The re q u ire m e n ts o f th e assets te s t in c lu d e n e t ta n g ib le assets o f a t le a st $3 m illio n (a fte r d e d u c tin g th e costs o f fu n d ra is in g ) o r a m a rk e t c a p ita lis a tio n o f a t le a s t $10 m illio n . 15 The A S X sets the se c o n d itio n s in an e f f o r t to ensure t h a t th e re w ill be an a ctive m a rk e t in th e co m p a n y s shares a fte r th e y are lis te d . C o m pa nie s t h a t are u n a b le to s a tis fy th e re q u ire m e n ts f o r lis tin g o n th e ASX WWW m a y o p t f o r lis tin g o n one o f th e m a rk e ts t h a t have d e ve lo p e d to m e e t th e needs o f s m a lle r com panies. These in c lu d e th e A s ia Pacific S to ck Exchange (w w w .a p x .c o m .a u ) a n d th e N a tio n a l S to ck Exchange o f A u s tra lia (w w w .n s x a .c o m .a u ), b o th o f w h ic h a im to p ro v id e a m a rk e t in th e shares o f s m a ll a n d m e d iu m ­ sized e n titie s w it h as fe w as 50 s e c u rity h o ld e rs. 9.5.1 I Public versus private ownership A co m p a n y u n d e rta k in g a flo a t m a y be e ith e r a n e w c o m p a n y o r an e x is tin g p riv a te com pany. In th e la tte r case, th e co m p a n y is said to be g o in g p u b lic 1. There are tw o m a in reasons w h y a p riv a te c o m p a n y m a y go p u b lic . F irs t, lis te d p u b lic com p an ies u s u a lly have b e tte r access to th e c a p ita l m a rk e t th a n p riv a te com p an ies. A s discussed in S e c tio n 9.3, p riv a te e q u ity in v e s to rs are v e ry se le ctive a n d th e te rm s t h a t th e y re q u ire m a y n o t be a ttra c tiv e to th e o w n e rs o f a com p an y. G re a te r access to th e c a p ita l m a rk e t is m o s t v a lu a b le to h ig h -g ro w th co m p a n ie s t h a t re q u ire fu n d s to im p le m e n t a ttra c tiv e n e w p ro je c ts . Second, a 14 While stock exchange listing normally follows a public issue, a company can list without raising any capital at the time of listing provided it complies with the ASX Listing Rules. This approach is referred to as a compliance listing*. An alternative way to become a listed public company is by a 'back-door listing*. This involves an unlisted company taking over a company that is listed on the stock exchange. 15 These and other listing requirements apply to all companies. There are additional requirements that differ depending on whether the company s main activities involve investment, mining exploration or scientific research. They are set out in Chapter 1 of the ASX Listing Rules. C hapter n in e S ources p u b lic flo a t a llo w s th e o w n e rs o f a c o m p a n y to cash in o n th e success o f th e bu sin ess th e y have developed. The cash th e y receive b y s e llin g p a r t o f t h e ir in te re s t in th e co m p a n y can be used to d iv e rs ify t h e ir in v e s tm e n t p o rtfo lio . G o in g p u b lic also has several costs t h a t m u s t be co n sid e re d . The m o s t s ig n ific a n t is u s u a lly th e loss o f c o n tro l associated w it h s h a rin g o w n e rs h ip o f th e co m p a n y w it h m a n y o th e r in v e s to rs . The o rig in a l owners* v o tin g p o w e r w ill be red uce d a t th e tim e o f a flo a t a n d t h e ir p ro p o r tio n a l o w n e rs h ip m a y d e clin e ove r tim e as th e y sell som e o f t h e ir shares o r as th e co m p a n y raises c a p ita l b y is s u in g m o re shares to n e w in ve sto rs. A p u b lic lis tin g also in v o lv e s d ire c t costs such as s to c k exchange lis tin g fees a n d s h a re h o ld e r s e rv ic in g costs. In a d d itio n , lis te d c o m p a n ie s in c u r costs associated w it h g re a te r in fo r m a tio n d isclo su re . These costs in c lu d e p ro d u c in g th e re q u ire d in fo r m a tio n a n d th e tim e s p e n t b y m a n a g e m e n t o n in v e s to r re la tio n s . In p a rtic u la r, m anagers m a y n e e d to discuss th e c o m p a n y s p la n s a n d p ro sp e cts w it h a n a lysts e m p lo y e d b y b ro ke rs a n d in s titu t io n s because th e re c o m m e n d a tio n s p ro d u c e d b y a n a lysts can in flu e n c e a co m p a n y s share p ric e a n d its a b ility to raise c a p ita l b y is s u in g m o re shares. F in a lly , th e in fo r m a tio n t h a t a lis te d com p an y is re q u ire d to disclose m a y in c lu d e d e ta ils t h a t are v a lu a b le to c o m p e tito rs . 9 .5 .2 | Initial public offering of ordinary shares As s h o w n in Table 9.3, th e n u m b e r o f IPO s a n d t h e ir v a lu e can v a ry c o n s id e ra b ly fr o m yea r to year. W h e n a c o m p a n y is to go p u b lic ,, its p ro m o te rs u s u a lly seek th e assistance o f a fin a n c ia l in s t it u t io n w ith e xp e rtise in a rra n g in g share issues. T y p ic a lly , th is has b e en th e fu n c tio n o f th e la rg e r s to c k b ro k e rs an d in v e s tm e n t b a n ks. B o th typ e s o f in s t it u t io n can advise o n th e p ric e o f th e issue, u n d e rw rite th e issue a n d h a n d le th e sale o f th e shares. TABLE 9.3 New listings on the ASX Year en d e d June 3 0 2009 N u m be r o f new lis tin g s 45 In itia l cap ital raised 1.9 2010 93 11.5 2011 160 29.4 2012 99 10.2 2013 82 9.9 ($ b illio n ) Source: ASX Limited, 2 0 1 3 Annual Report. 9 .5 .3 | Pricing a new issue D e cid in g o n th e p ric e o f a n e w issue is a d iff ic u lt ta sk. The is s u e r faces p o te n tia l p ro b le m s i f th e o ffe r p ric e is set to o h ig h o r to o lo w . I f th e p ric e is set to o h ig h , fe w in v e s to rs w ill w a n t to sub scrib e a n d th e issue m a y fa il unless i t is u n d e rw ritte n , in w h ic h case th e u n d e r w r ite r w ill have to m e e t th e s h o rtfa ll. In t u r n , th is o u tco m e w ill have a n e g a tive e ffe c t o n th e m a rk e t p ric e o f th e shares a fte r th e y are lis te d . I f th e p ric e is set to o lo w , th e o w n e rs w ill s u ffe r an o p p o r tu n it y loss because th e y w o u ld have received a h ig h e r p a y m e n t i f th e n e w issue h a d been m ad e a t a h ig h e r p rice . The a va ila b le evide nce suggests th a t, o n average, n e w issues in it ia lly tra d e a t a p ric e above th e issue p rice . In t h is sense th e y are u n d e rp ric e d ,. The u n d e rp ric in g o f in it ia l p u b lic o ffe rin g s is discussed in S e c tio n 9.5 .6 . The ta s k o f s e ttin g th e issue p ric e is p a r tic u la r ly d iff ic u lt w h e n th e co m p a n y has ju s t b e e n fo rm e d , as th e re is n o re co rd o f fin a n c ia l p e rfo rm a n c e . W h e re th e co m p a n y has p re v io u s ly o p e ra te d as a p riv a te com pany, th e ta s k is n o t as d iff ic u lt because p a s t p r o fits m a y be a g u id e to f u tu r e p ro fits . The m o s t c o m m o n a p pro ach to p r ic in g used b y advisers is to use h is to ric a l p r o fits as th e basis f o r e s tim a tin g fu tu re e a rn in g s p e r share. The a d vise r w ill also e x a m in e th e p ric e -e a rn in g s (P /E ) ra tio (th e m a rk e t price o f a share, d iv id e d b y th e e a rn in g s p e r share) o f e x is tin g co m p a n ie s in th e sam e o r s im ila r in d u s trie s . Forecasts o f fu tu re e a rn in g s p e r share a n d th e in fo r m a tio n o n p ric e -e a rn in g s ra tio s w ill th e n be used b y th e a d vise r to suggest a p o ssib le range o f issue p rice s f o r th e co m p a n y s shares. F o r exa m ple, i f a c o m p a n y is expected to e a rn 30 cen ts p e r share a n d th e p ric e -e a rn in g s ra tio s o f s im ila r co m p a n ie s are b e tw e e n 9 and 14, th is suggests an issue p ric e o f b e tw e e n $ 2 .7 0 a n d $ 4 .2 0 p e r share. I f in s titu t io n s are e n th u s ia s tic a b o u t th e p ro p o se d issue, th e issue p ric e m a y be set close to $ 4 .2 0 . In c o n tra s t, i f th e re is li t t le in te re s t of fin a n c e : equity A B usiness finance in th e issue, th e issue p ric e m a y be set clo se r to th e lo w e r e n d o f th e range. As is e v id e n t fr o m th e above d e s c rip tio n , use o f th is a p p ro a ch to set th e issue p ric e in v o lv e s co n sid e ra b le ju d g m e n t. In th e case o f a fix e d -p ric e o ffe r, th e p ric e m u s t be se t b e fo re th e p ro s p e c tu s is p r in te d a n d th e o ffe r is u s u a lly o p e n f o r a t le a s t 2 to 3 w eeks. C o n se q u e n tly, th e success o f th e o ffe r is s u b je c t to general m o v e m e n ts in share p rice s d u rin g a p e rio d o f seve ral w eeks. F o r exa m ple, i f th e g e n e ra l le v e l o f share prices increases s ig n ific a n tly d u rin g t h a t p e rio d , i t is lik e ly t h a t th e fix e d p ric e w ill be to o low . H o w eve r, i f share p rice s decrease s ig n ific a n tly d u r in g t h a t p e rio d , in v e s to rs m a y re g a rd th e fix e d p ric e as b e in g to o h ig h , a n d th e issue w ill close u n d e rs u b s c rib e d . A n a lte rn a tiv e a p p ro a ch w h e n p r ic in g a n e w issue is to use book-building— a process t h a t in v o lv e s c o m p e titiv e b id d in g b y m a rk e t p a rtic ip a n ts , p a r tic u la r ly in s titu t io n a l in v e s to rs . T his a p p ro a ch uses e ith e r open pricing o r constrained open pricing. In b o th cases, p o te n tia l in v e s to rs place b id s f o r th e shares w h e re th e y in d ic a te th e q u a n titie s th e y w is h to p u rcha se a t v a rio u s prices. The fin a l p ric e is d e te rm in e d a t th e e n d o f th e b id d in g process. In th e case o f o p e n p ric in g , shares are u s u a lly a llo c a te d o n ly to b id d e rs w h o o ffe re d p rice s e q u a l to o r h ig h e r th a n th e fin a l p rice . O p e n p r ic in g has b e en used in som e A u s tra lia n flo a ts , b u t c o n s tra in e d o p e n p r ic in g is m o re c o m m o n . In c o n s tra in e d o p e n p ric in g , b o th u p p e r an d lo w e r lim it s are placed o n th e p ric e a n d a ll b id s b e tw e e n th o s e lim it s are co n sid e re d . The p ro s p e c tu s w ill set o u t th e c r ite r ia to be used in a llo c a tin g shares to b id d e rs . U su a lly, th e p ric e ran ge can be re v is e d d u rin g th e b id d in g process i f d e m a n d f o r th e shares is fo u n d to be s u b s ta n tia lly g re a te r o r less th a n expected. O nce th e fin a l p ric e has been d e te rm in e d , a ll successful b id d e rs p a y th e sam e p ric e b u t th o se w h o m ade h ig h e r b id s have a h ig h e r p r o b a b ility o f re c e iv in g an a llo c a tio n o f shares. O ffe rs to in s titu t io n s u n d e r a b o o k -b u ild in g process are o fte n a cco m p a n ie d b y an o ffe r to th e general p u b lic (a 'r e ta il o ffe r*), w h e re a m a x im u m p ric e is sp e cifie d in advance a n d r e ta il in v e s to rs m a y also be o ffe re d a p ric e d is c o u n t. F o r exa m ple, in th e flo a t o f Q R N a tio n a l L td in N o v e m b e r 2 0 1 0 , th e re was an in s titu t io n a l b o o k -b u ild w it h an in d ic a tiv e p ric e ran ge o f $ 2 .5 0 to $3 a n d a re ta il o ffe r, w h ic h was su b je ct to a m a x im u m p ric e o f $ 2 .8 0 p e r share. Successful a p p lic a n ts in th e re ta il o ffe r p a id th e lo w e r o f th e fin a l p ric e p a id b y in s titu t io n s less a d is c o u n t o f 10 cen ts p e r share a n d th e m a x im u m r e ta il p ric e o f $2 .80. B o o k -b u ild in g was f ir s t used in A u s tra lia b y th e N e w S o u th W ales G o v e rn m e n t w h e n i t so ld th e G o v e rn m e n t In s u ra n c e O ffic e (G IO ) in 19 92 . Since th e G IO issue, i t has b e en use d in m a n y la rg e issues, in c lu d in g th e W o o lw o rth s , Q an ta s, T e ls tra a n d N in e E n te rta in m e n t flo a ts , a n d in som e s m a lle r flo a ts such as th o s e o f K a th m a n d u H o ld in g s ($ 3 4 0 m illio n in N o v e m b e r 2 0 0 9 ) a n d th e c re d it-c h e c k in g co m p a n y Veda G ro u p ($ 3 4 1 m illio n in D e cem b er 2 0 1 3 ). The m a in a d va n ta g e o f b o o k -b u ild in g is t h a t i t a llo w s th e is s u e r a n d its ad vise rs to o b ta in fee dba ck fr o m in fo rm e d in s titu t io n a l in v e s to rs o n t h e ir assessm ent o f th e va lu e o f th e shares. The in fo r m a tio n g a th e re d fr o m th e se in v e s to rs can be used in s e ttin g th e issue p rice . W h ile th is a p p ro a ch is e xp ected to re s u lt in a lo w e r le v e l o f u n d e rp ric in g , c o n d u c tin g a b o o k -b u ild is a c o s tly process, so i t is u s u a lly w o r th w h ile o n ly f o r la rg e r flo a ts . H ence, th e m a jo r ity o f flo a ts in A u s tra lia s t ill in v o lv e fix e d -p ric e o ffe rs. W it h a fix e d -p ric e o ffe r, once th e te rm s h a ve b e e n se t, th e a d v is e r u s u a lly e n su re s t h a t th e p ro p o s e d o ffe r s a tis fie s a ll re le v a n t le g a l re q u ire m e n ts a n d a s sists in p r e p a rin g th e o ffe r d o c u m e n t (u s u a lly a p ro s p e c tu s ), e n su re s t h a t s to c k exch an ge lis t in g re q u ire m e n ts are m e t, lo d g e s th e p ro s p e c tu s w it h A S IC a n d m a rk e ts th e shares to in s t it u t io n a l a n d p r iv a te in v e s to rs . The co sts o f p re p a rin g th e p ro s p e c tu s in c lu d e le g a l fees, fees f o r th e p re p a ra tio n o f a n in v e s tig a tin g a c c o u n ta n t's r e p o r t a n d th e co st o f p r in t in g . The t o t a l costs o f th e a d v is o ry se rv ic e s , in c lu d in g th e c o sts o f p re p a rin g a p ro s p e c tu s a n d o b ta in in g s to c k exch a n g e lis tin g , can v a r y w id e ly a n d u s u a lly re p re s e n t b e tw e e n 2 a n d 5 p e r c e n t o f th e a m o u n t ra is e d . A s discu sse d in S e c tio n 9 .5 .6 , th e costs can be less th a n 2 p e r c e n t o f th e a m o u n t ra is e d f o r la rg e r flo a ts . C o n ve rse ly, f o r v e r y s m a ll flo a ts t h a t ra is e $ 1 0 m illio n o r less, th e co sts are u s u a lly m u c h h ig h e r th a n 5 p e r c e n t. I f th e p ro m o te rs agree w i t h th e a d v is e rs re c o m m e n d a tio n s o n th e te rm s o f th e flo a t, th e sam e a d v is e r w i ll u s u a lly be a p p o in te d to u n d e r w r ite a n d h a n d le th e sale o f th e shares. A s p re v io u s ly in d ic a te d , w ith a fix e d -p ric e o ffe r th e is s u e r is s u b je c t to th e vag aries o f th e m a rk e t fr o m th e tim e w h e n th e p ric e is set u n t il th e issue closes. In m a n y cases th e issu e r w ill pass th is r is k o n to an u n d e rw rite r, w h ic h is ty p ic a lly an in v e s tm e n t b a n k o r a m a jo r s to c k b ro k e r. I f th e b o o k -b u ild in g process is used, o n e o r m o re in v e s tm e n t b a n ks o r b ro k e rs w ill be n e ed ed to receive a n d c o lla te th e in s titu t io n a l bids, advise th e p ro m o te rs o n th e issue p ric e a n d m an ag e th e issue. In th is case, th e in s titu t io n s in v o lv e d are C hapter n in e S ources of fin a n c e : equity ty p ic a lly re fe rre d to as 'lea d m anagers* o f th e issu e .16 N a tu ra lly , w h e n an u n d e r w r ite r acts as b o th a lead m anager as w e ll as f u lf illin g th e m o re t r a d itio n a l u n d e r w r itin g ro le , separate fees are o fte n charged. F o r exam ple, w h e n T en N e tw o rk H o ld in g s ra ise d $ 1 6 1 m illio n v ia th e in s titu t io n a l tra n c h e o f its e n title m e n t o ffe r in Ju n e 20 1 2 , i t p a id its ad vise rs, C itig ro u p , 1.8 5 p e r c e n t o f th e gross pro cee ds as an u n d e r w r itin g fee and a n o th e r 0.5 p e r ce n t as an o ffe r m a n a g e m e n t a n d a rra n g e m e n t fe e ,. I f th e issue is u n d e rw ritte n , th e o b lig a tio n s o f th e co m p a n y a n d th e u n d e rw rite r are c o n ta in e d in an u n d e rw ritin g ag ree m ent. The u n d e r w r ite r co n tra c ts to purchase a ll shares f o r w h ic h a p p lic a tio n s have n o t been received b y th e c lo sin g date o f th e issue. In re tu rn , th e u n d e rw rite r charges a fee, u s u a lly based o n a fix e d percentage o f th e a m o u n t to be raised b y th e issue. The fee is n e g o tia te d an d w ill re fle c t th e u n d e rw rite r s p e rce p tio n o f th e d iffic u lty o f s e llin g th e issue a n d th is in t u r n w ill be d e te rm in e d b y fa c to rs such as th e com pany s sta tu re in th e m a rk e t, th e p ric e o f th e issue an d general m a rk e t c o n d itio n s . The u n d e rw ritin g agreem ent n o rm a lly in clu d e s escape clauses th a t sp e cify th e circum stances in w h ic h th e u n d e rw rite r w ill be released fro m its o b lig a tio n s .17 In som e cases, th e ro le o f th e in s titu tio n s th a t m anage a flo a t m a y in clu d e price s ta b ilis a tio n once th e shares are lis te d . Price s ta b ilis a tio n , also k n o w n as a greenshoe o p tio n (a fte r th e com p an y th a t f ir s t used it ) , re q u ire s a special d is p e n s a tio n fro m ASIC. A d is p e n s a tio n o f th is ty p e was o b ta in e d b y th e in v e s tm e n t b a n ks th a t m anaged th e N o ve m b e r 2 0 1 0 flo a t o f ra il o p e ra to r Q R N a tio n a l, w h ic h was p re v io u s ly w h o lly o w n e d b y th e Q ue enslan d S tate G o v e rn m e n t (see F inance in A c tio n ). PRICE STABILISATION IN FLOAT OF RAIL OPERATOR____________ T h e Q R N a t io n a l m e d ia re le a s e a n d A S X a n n o u n c e m e n t a b o u t th e p r ic in g a n d a llo c a t io n o f s h a re s in its f lo a t c o n t a in e d th e f o llo w in g s ta te m e n t: 'F o llo w in g th e tr a n s f e r o f Q R N a t i o n a l S h a re s b y th e S ta te to s u c c e s s fu l a p p lic a n t s , th e S ta te w ill in it ia lly r e ta in 8 2 1 4 3 6 7 3 5 Q R N a t i o n a l S h a re s . T h is a m o u n t m a y in c r e a s e b y u p to 1 4 6 4 0 0 0 0 0 Q R N a t io n a l S h a r e s d e p e n d in g o n w h e t h e r th e J o in t L e a d M a n a g e r s e x e r c is e a n o p t io n to p u r c h a s e u p t o 6 p e r c e n t o f Q R N a t i o n a l S h a re s o n is s u e to c o v e r a n y o v e ra llo c a t io n s m a d e a s p a r t o f th e O ff e r , a s d e s c r ib e d in s e c tio n 2 . 4 . 3 o f th e O f f e r D o c u m e n t / T h e m e a n in g o f th is s ta te m e n t w a s e x p la in e d a n d d is c u s s e d in a r tic le s b y f in a n c ia l jo u r n a lis ts . E x c e rp ts fr o m o n e s u ch a r t ic le a p p e a r b e lo w . R e a d th e Q R N a t io n a l m e d ia r e le a s e a b o u t t o d a y ’ s f lo a t c a r e f u lly a n d y o u r e a lis e th o s e c a n n y in v e s tm e n t b a n k e r s s o ld 6 6 p e r c e n t o f th e s h a re s in th e c o m p a n y . W h y s e ttle o n 6 6 p e r c e n t? T h e a n s w e r ta k e s us to th e d a r k a r t o f th e f lo a t 's jo in t le a d m a n a g e r s e n t e r in g th e m a r k e t a n d b u y in g s h a re s to s u p p o r t Q R 7s p r ic e . T h e p r ic e s u p p o r t t o o l k n o w n a s 'th e g r e e n s h o e ' is ( v e r y o p a q u e ly ) d is c lo s e d in th e p r o s p e c tu s . .. T h e t a n g le d t e c h n ic a lit ie s o f th e g r e e n s h o e s p e c if y it is a n o v e r - a llo c a tio n o p t io n . T h e te c h n ic a lit ie s m e a n th e o v e r - a llo c a te d s to c k c a n b e b o u g h t b a c k o n th e m a r k e t b y th e in v e s tm e n t b a n k s , p r o v id in g th e p r ic e s u p p o r t. G u e s s w h a t ? T h e o v e r - a llo c a t io n o p t io n — a n d th e r e f o r e th e p r ic e s u p p o r t — o n ly k ic k s in a f t e r th e Q u e e n s la n d g o v e r n m e n t s e lls 6 0 p e r c e n t o f th e s to c k . A n d th e o v e r - a llo c a tio n o p t io n is lim it e d to 6 p e r c e n t o f th e to ta l s to c k o n is s u e . N o w 6 0 p e r c e n t p lu s 6 p e r c e n t e x p la in s w h y th e o f f e r s o ld a m a g ic 6 6 p e r c e n t o f th e c o m p a n y . N o t 6 1 p e r c e n t. N o t 6 4 p e r c e n t. R ig h t o n th e k n o c k e r o f 6 6 p e r c e n t. A s in a n y f lo a t , it is h a r d to s e e w h e r e t o d a y 's p r ic e la n d s . continued 16 It is possible for a share issue to be underwritten and priced using book-building. As discussed in Section 9.6.2, this approach is often used for share placements where issuers desire certainty of funding and, given the short time involved, the underwriting risk is low and its cost may be acceptable. In the case of IPOs, vendors are generally prepared to accept the risk that the market clearing price1established in a book-build may be less than they expected. In such cases, the indicative price range may be lowered or the proposed share issue may be withdrawn. 17 The escape clauses in an underwriting agreement relate to factors that would seriously affect demand for shares in general, such as the outbreak of war, a significant reduction in a benchmark market index such as the S&P/ASX 200, as well as company-specific events that could reduce the value of the shares. F in a n c e in ACTION N e w s <W n 墨. B usiness finance continued B e c e r t a in o f th is : if th e s h a r e p r ic e f a lls b e lo w th e o f f e r p r ic e , th e r e is p r ic e s u p p o r t a v a ila b l e in th e fo r m o f f iv e in v e s tm e n t b a n k s w it h a b o u t 9 p e r c e n t o f th e to ta l t r a d e d s h a re s a v a ila b l e to b u y . If th e s h a r e p r ic e is h o v e r in g a b o v e a n d b e lo w th e o f f e r p r ic e , r e a d th e Q u e e n s la n d g o v e r n m e n t 's v ic t o r io u s m e d ia r e le a s e s w it h a d e g r e e o f s c e p tic is m . T h e s h a r e p r ic e is m o r e th a n lik e ly b e in g g a m e d . Source: 'Greenshoe on cue may be used to keep QR National 0^001', Stuart Washington, Sydney Morning Herald, 22 November 2010. The la rg e r s to c k b ro k e rs are m a jo r u n d e rw rite rs , p r im a r ily because th e y have an e s ta b lis h e d c lie n te le p re p a re d to su b scrib e f o r th e issues th e y u n d e rw rite . A n u n d e r w r ite r w ill fre q u e n tly a tte m p t to li m it its e xp osu re to th e r is k o f u n d e rs u b s c rip tio n b y in v it in g o th e r in s titu t io n s to a ct as s u b u n d e rw rite rs . These in s titu t io n s m a y in c lu d e life a n d g e n e ra l in s u ra n c e co m p a n ie s, b a n k s a n d s u p e ra n n u a tio n fu n d s . The ro le o f th e s u b u n d e rw rite r is to ta k e u p a p r o p o r tio n o f a n y u n d e rs u b s c rip tio n in r e tu r n f o r a fee, p a id b y th e u n d e rw rite r, w h ic h is based o n a fix e d p r o p o r tio n o f th e issue p ric e .18 I f a s to c k b ro k e r is th e u n d e r w r ite r o r le a d m a n a g e r o f an issue o f shares i t w ill u s u a lly a ct as a s e llin g ag en t f o r th e issue. By p r o m o tin g an issue, a s to c k b ro k e r p ro te c ts its in te re s ts as u n d e r w r ite r a n d also earns b ro k e ra g e fees. D e p e n d in g o n th e size o f th e issue, one o r m o re o th e r b ro k in g fir m s m a y also be a p p o in te d as m a n a g e rs o r co-m a na gers to assist in p u b lic is in g th e issue a n d d is tr ib u tin g th e shares to a w id e range o f c lie n ts . The fees p a id to the se firm s w ill u s u a lly be s tru c tu re d so t h a t b ro k e rs w h o can d is tr ib u te shares to c lie n ts have an in c e n tiv e to co m p e te a g a in s t in s titu t io n a l b id s in a b o o k -b u ild . To th is end, th e fees f o r b ro k e rs m a y be d iv id e d in to a ‘f ir m a llo c a tio n fe e ’ a n d a ‘h a n d lin g fee’. The separate h a n d lin g fee encourages b ro k e rs to place b id s f o r a d d itio n a l shares above t h e ir f ir m a llo c a tio n in th e e x p e c ta tio n th a t th e a d d itio n a l shares can be so ld to t h e ir c lie n ts . G re a te r c o m p e titio n b e tw e e n in s t it u t io n a l in v e s to rs and b ro k e rs ’ c lie n ts (re ta il in v e s to rs ) is, o f course, d e sira b le f o r th e is s u e r a n d th e lead m an ag er. W h e re a fix e d -p ric e issue is n o t u n d e r w r itte n , a b ro k e r w ill s t ill be engaged to a ssist in d is tr ib u tin g th e shares. B roke rag e fees are n e g o tia b le a n d d e p e n d o n fa c to rs such as th e size o f th e issue, th e s ta tu s o f th e is s u in g co m p a n y a n d th e p e rio d f o r w h ic h th e issue is to re m a in open. B roke rag e fees are u s u a lly set b e tw e e n 1 a n d 2 p e r c e n t o f th e issue p rice . I t was n o te d in S e c tio n 9 .2 .5 t h a t ra is in g c a p ita l b y is s u in g shares can in v o lv e s ig n ific a n t costs. In th e case o f c o m p a n y flo a ts th e costs fa ll in to th re e m a in categories: a Stock exchange listing fees and the costs ofpreparing and distributing a prospectus. These costs in c lu d e le ga l fees, fees f o r th e p re p a ra tio n o f an in v e s tig a tin g a c c o u n ta n ts r e p o rt, fees f o r e x p e rt re p o rts a n d p r in t in g costs. b Fees paid to underwriters or lead managers and commissions paid to brokers for selling the shares. The t o ta l o f these fees a n d costs can v a ry c o n s id e ra b ly b u t f o r m o s t flo a ts th e costs w o u ld fa ll in th e ran ge fro m 1 to 5 p e r c e n t o f th e fu n d s raised. C Underpricing. The t h ir d c a te g o ry o f costs re la te s to th e fa c t t h a t th e issue p ric e o f shares s o ld in an IP O is u s u a lly less th a n th e m a rk e t v a lu e o f th e shares once th e y are lis te d . The costs t h a t fa ll in to th e f ir s t tw o cate gories m a y be c o m b in e d to fo r m a t o t a l cost o f lis tin g . U n d e rp ric in g o f IPO s can be s ig n ific a n t a n d is discussed a fte r we discuss th e costs o f lis tin g . The fa c to rs t h a t in flu e n c e th e costs o f lis tin g f o r a flo a t in c lu d e its size, th e ris k in e s s o f th e co m p a n y a n d th e c o m p le x ity o f th e u n d e rly in g bu sin ess. The t o ta l costs w ill g e n e ra lly increase w it h th e size o f th e 18 The subunderwriting fee is usually only slightly less than the underwriting fee. For example, if the underwriting fee was 3 per cent of the issue price, the subunderwriting fee would usually be about 2.5 per cent of the issue price. C hapter n in e S ources of f in a n c e : equity flo a t, b u t because o f th e fix e d n a tu re o f som e c o m p o n e n ts o f th e costs, th e y w ill be la rg e r in p e rcen ta ge te rm s w h e n th e a m o u n t o f fu n d s s o u g h t is sm a ll. F o r exa m ple, w h e n th e a m o u n t s o u g h t is less th a n $ 1 0 m illio n , th e costs can be m o re th a n 15 p e r c e n t o f th e a m o u n t s o u g h t. F o r flo a ts t h a t raise m o re th a n $ 1 0 0 m illio n , th e costs are u s u a lly fr o m 2 to 5 p e r c e n t o f th e a m o u n t s o u g h t a n d can be even lo w e r f o r la rg e r flo a ts . H o w eve r, v e ry la rg e flo a ts m a y be h a rd e r to sell a n d re q u ire a g re a te r m a rk e tin g e ffo r t. F o r exam ple, i f a flo a t is so la rge t h a t i t is necessary to a ttr a c t m a n y in te r n a tio n a l in v e s to rs , th e average cost m a y be h ig h e r th a n f o r a s m a lle r flo a t t h a t is s o ld o n ly in th e A u s tra lia n m a rk e t. I f a co m p a n y has aboveaverage business ris k , i t w i ll g e n e ra lly be m o re d iff ic u lt to d e te rm in e an a p p ro p ria te p ric e f o r th e shares a n d m o re d iffic u lt to se ll th e shares to in v e s to rs . T h ere fore, a m in in g e x p lo ra tio n co m p a n y w ill be m o re c o s tly to flo a t th a n an e s ta b lis h e d in d u s tr ia l co m p a n y w it h sta b le cash flo w s. F in a lly , i f a co m p a n y s o p e ra tio n s are c o m p le x o r d iff ic u lt to u n d e rs ta n d , i t w ill be m o re c o s tly to c a rry o u t ‘due d ilig e n c e ’ in v e s tig a tio n s o f th e com pany, a n d to engage in research a n d m a rk e tin g . F o r exa m ple, a d d itio n a l in d e p e n d e n t experts* re p o rts m a y be re q u ire d a n d a d d itio n a l costs m a y be in c u rre d in p r o m o tin g th e flo a t. W h e re a flo a t is u n d e r w r itte n , th e u n d e r w r itin g fee g e n e ra lly ranges fr o m 1 to 5 p e r c e n t o f th e fu n d s so u g h t. H is to ric a lly , th e m a jo r ity o f A u s tra lia n flo a ts have be en u n d e r w r itte n , b u t in re c e n t years th e p o p u la rity o f u n d e r w r itin g has d e c lin e d as m o re flo a ts have be en p ric e d a n d so ld u s in g th e b o o k ­ b u ild in g process. W h e re b o o k -b u ild in g is used, in v e s tm e n t b a n ks a n d b ro k e rs are s t ill in v o lv e d in th e IPO. H ow ever, in s te a d o f b e in g p a id to g u a ra n te e t h a t a c e rta in su m w ill be raised, th e y are p a id to p ro v id e a range o f services, in c lu d in g p re p a ra tio n o f research re p o rts o n th e com pany, a rra n g in g s e m in a rs an d a n a lyst b rie fin g s , a n d m a n a g in g th e b o o k -b u ild in g process. T h ere fore, b o o k -b u ild in g in v o lv e s s ig n ific a n t costs a n d w ill n o t ne ce ssa rily be che ap er th a n h a v in g a flo a t u n d e r w r itte n . In s u m m a ry , th e costs o f lis tin g are g e n e ra lly lo w e s t f o r la rge , lo w - r is k flo a ts w h e re th e u n d e rly in g b u sin ess is e a sily u n d e rs to o d b y in v e s to rs . F o r exa m ple, in th e 2 0 1 0 flo a t o f Q R N a tio n a l, w h ic h ra ise d $ 4 .0 5 b illio n , issue costs as d e ta ile d in se ctio n 1 0 .1 3 .4 o f th e c o m p a n y s O ffe r D o c u m e n t a m o u n te d to $ 7 5 .5 m illio n , w h ic h is less th a n 1.9 p e r ce n t o f th e fu n d s raised. U n d e rp ric in g o f a n IP O re p re s e n ts a re a l co st to th e o rig in a l sh a re h o ld e rs, w h o are e ffe c tiv e ly s e llin g assets to th e n e w sh a re h o ld e rs f o r less th a n t h e ir f a ir value. T his d iffe re n c e in v a lu e is o fte n re fe rre d to as m o n e y le ft o n th e ta b le 1. M o re pre cise ly, m o n e y le f t o n th e ta b le is u s u a lly d e fin e d as th e r e tu r n o n th e f ir s t day o f tra d in g , an d is ty p ic a lly m e a su re d b y th e n u m b e r o f shares sold, m u ltip lie d b y th e d iffe re n c e b e tw e e n th e firs t-d a y c lo s in g m a rk e t p ric e a n d th e issue p rice . I t has b e e n w e ll d o c u m e n te d t h a t in IPO s th e a m o u n t o f m o n e y le f t o n th e ta b le is ty p ic a lly large. F o r exa m ple, R itte r a n d W e lch fo u n d t h a t th e average firs t-d a y r e tu r n f o r 6 2 4 9 IP O s in th e US b e tw e e n 1 9 8 0 a n d 2 0 0 1 was 1 8 .8 p e r c e n t.19 R itte r a n d W elch also fo u n d t h a t th e average firs t-d a y r e tu r n v a rie d c o n s id e ra b ly o v e r tim e . In th e 19 80 s, th e average firs t-d a y r e tu r n was 7 .4 p e r c e n t a n d i t in crea sed to a lm o s t 1 1 .2 p e r c e n t d u r in g 1 9 9 0 -9 4 a n d 1 8 .1 p e r cent d u rin g 1 9 9 5 -9 8 b e fo re ju m p in g to 65 p e r c e n t d u rin g th e in t e r n e t b u b b le , p e rio d in 1 9 9 9 -2 0 0 0 and th e n re v e rtin g to 14 p e r c e n t in 2 0 0 1 .20 In A u s tra lia , a s tu d y b y Lee, T a y lo r a n d W a lte r (1 9 9 6 ) o f 2 6 6 in d u s tr ia l IP O s b e tw e e n 1 9 7 6 a n d 1 9 8 9 fo u n d an average firs t-d a y a b n o rm a l r e tu r n o f 11 .9 p e r ce n t. D im o v s k i a n d B ro o ks (2 0 0 3 ) s tu d ie d 3 5 8 in d u s tria l a n d resource IP O s in A u s tra lia fr o m 1 9 9 4 to 1 9 9 9 a n d fo u n d t h a t th e average firs t-d a y r e tu r n was 25 .6 p e r c e n t, w h ile th e m e d ia n firs t-d a y r e tu r n was 9.3 p e r ce n t. The IP O s th e y s tu d ie d ra ise d a to ta l o f $ 2 4 ,4 3 9 b illio n in c a p ita l, th e t o ta l a m o u n t o f m o n e y le f t o n th e ta b le was $ 5 ,6 7 8 b illio n a n d t o t a l issue costs w ere $ 5 9 2 m illio n . Da S ilva Rosa, V e la y u th e n a n d W a lte r (2 0 0 3 ) re p o rte d m e d ia n u n d e rp ric in g o f 12 p e r c e n t f o r t h e ir sam p le o f 3 3 3 A u s tra lia n in d u s tr ia l IP O s f r o m 1 9 9 1 to 19 9 9 . G on g a n d S h e kh a r (2 0 0 1 ) s tu d ie d a ll 11 g o v e rn m e n t-s e c to r IPO s in A u s tra lia b e tw e e n 1 9 8 9 a n d 19 99 . T hey fo u n d an average firs t-d a y a b n o rm a l r e tu r n f o r r e ta il in v e s to rs o f a p p ro x im a te ly 11 p e r c e n t a n d c o n c lu d e d t h a t th e re is n o evidence th a t th e u n d e rp ric in g o f the se IPO s d iffe rs fr o m t h a t o f A u s tra lia n p riv a te -s e c to r IPO s o r o f g o v e rn m e n t-s e c to r IP O s in o th e r O EC D c o u n trie s . The u n d e rp ric in g p h e n o m e n o n is n o t re s tric te d to th e US a n d A u s tra lia . P ro fe s s o r Jay R itte r fr o m th e U n iv e rs ity o f F lo rid a is one o f th e w o r ld s fo re m o s t e xp e rts in th e area o f IP O u n d e rp ric in g a n d has c o lle c te d th e e m p iric a l re s u lts fr o m m a n y stu d ie s u n d e rta k e n in d iffe re n t c o u n trie s a ro u n d th e w o rld (see h t t p : / / b e a r . w a r r in g t o n . u f l. e d u / r it t e r / ip o d a t a . h tm ) . F igu re 9.1 d e m o n s tra te s th e in it ia l re tu rn s en jo yed, o n average, b y IP O su b scrib e rs in te r n a tio n a lly an d illu s tra te s ju s t h o w p e rv a s iv e IP O u n d e rp ric in g has been. 19 Ritter and Welch (2002). The equally-weighted average first-day return measured from the offer price to the first closing price listed by CRSP is 18.8 per cent. 20 For an analysis of possible reasons for this variation, see Loughran and Ritter (2004). |wwwj B usiness finance Source: Loughran, T., Ritter, J. and Rydqvist, K., Initial public offerings: International insights: 2014 update', 17 January 2014, http://bear.warrington.ufl.edu/ritter/lnt2014.pdif. Reasons for underpricing M a n y p o s s ib le e x p la n a tio n s f o r th e u n d e rp ric in g o f IPO s have b e en p ro p o s e d . O n e e x p la n a tio n is based o n in fo r m a t io n a s y m m e try in t h a t som e in v e s to rs are m o re in fo rm e d th a n th e issu er, p e rh a p s a b o u t LEARNING OBJECTIVE 6 Discuss alternative explanations for the underpricing of initial public offerings th e g e n e ra l d e m a n d f o r shares in th e m a rk e t. I t is also based o n th e c o n ce p t t h a t som e in v e s to rs are w e ll in fo rm e d a b o u t th e value o f th e shares b e in g o ffe re d w h ile o th e rs are u n in fo r m e d a n d th e re fo re have d iff ic u lt y e s tim a tin g th e fu tu r e m a rk e t p ric e o f th e shares. T his a p p ro a ch pro po ses t h a t a degree o f u n d e rp ric in g is necessary to a ttr a c t the se in v e s to rs . U n in fo rm e d in v e s to rs m a y a p p ly f o r a n y IP O b u t in fo r m e d in v e s to rs w ill o n ly s u b scrib e w h e n an issue is u n d e rp ric e d . T h e re fo re , w h e n an issue is o v e rp ric e d , a ll th e shares w ill be a llo c a te d to u n in fo rm e d in v e s to rs . C onversely, w h e n an issue is u n d e rp ric e d , in fo r m e d in v e s to rs w ill c ro w d out* th e u n in fo rm e d , w h o w i ll be a llo c a te d o n ly a fra c tio n o f th e shares. T his e x p la n a tio n m a y be illu s tra te d w it h a s im p le exa m ple. C o n s id e r tw o IPO s, one o f w h ic h records a firs t-d a y r e t u r n o f + 2 0 p e r ce n t, w h ile th e o th e r re co rd s a firs t-d a y r e t u r n o f - 1 0 p e r ce n t. Hence, th e average firs t-d a y r e tu r n is 5 p e r ce n t. Because th is r e tu r n is p o s itiv e , th e re appears to be u n d e rp ric in g . N o w c o n s id e r th e r e tu r n e a rn e d b y an u n in fo rm e d in v e s to r w h o a p p lie s f o r $ 1 0 0 0 0 w o r th o f shares in each o f th e se IP O s a n d is a llo c a te d $ 5 0 0 0 w o r th o f shares in th e f ir s t IP O a n d th e f u ll $ 1 0 0 0 0 w o r th o f shares in th e second. The u n in fo rm e d in v e s to r s r e t u r n is 0 p e r c e n t. T h e re fo re , fr o m th e v ie w p o in t o f th e u n in fo r m e d in v e s to r, th e IPO s are o n average f a ir ly p ric e d . In s u m m a ry , w h ile IPO s in v o lv e la rg e average in it ia l r e tu rn s , th is does n o t n e ce ssa rily m e a n t h a t e v e ry in v e s to r can e xp e ct to e a rn a b n o rm a l r e tu rn s b y s u b s c rib in g f o r co m p a n y flo a ts . W IN N E R ^ CURSE problem that arises in bidding because the bidder who ’wins’ is likely to be the one who most overestimates the value of the assets offered for sale U n in fo rm e d in v e s to rs , th e re fo re , face a w inn er^ curse. I f th e y g e t a ll o f th e shares th e y d e m an d, i t is because th e in fo r m e d in v e s to rs d id n o t w a n t th e m . Faced w it h th is s itu a tio n , u n in fo r m e d in v e s to rs w ill o n ly s u b scrib e to IPO s i f th e y are s u ffic ie n tly u n d e rp ric e d , o n average, to c o m p e n sa te f o r th e bias in th e a llo c a tio n o f shares ( fo r m o re d e ta ils , see R o ck 1 9 8 6 ). In research re la te d to th e ‘w in n e r ’s curse’ e x p la n a tio n i t is c o m m o n to assum e t h a t la rg e r in v e s to rs are b e tte r in fo rm e d th a n s m a ll in v e s to rs . Lee, T a y lo r a n d W a lte r (1 9 9 9 ) e xa m in e th is issue b y s tu d y in g IPO s o n th e S to ck E xchange o f S in ga pore w h e re d e ta ile d d a ta o n a p p lic a tio n s f o r a n d a llo c a tio n s o f shares are ro u tin e ly p ro v id e d . T h e ir re s u lts are c o n s is te n t w it h R o c k s (1 9 8 6 ) m o d e l: la rg e r in v e s to rs are m o re in fo rm e d in t h a t th e y a p p ly f o r re la tiv e ly m o re shares in issues t h a t are u n d e rp ric e d . Thus, s m a ll in v e s to rs are c ro w d e d o u t o f th e m o s t u n d e rp ric e d issues a n d receive la rg e r p r o p o r tio n s o f th e less a ttra c tiv e issues. A seco nd e x p la n a tio n f o r th e u n d e rp ric in g o f IP O s is t h a t p o te n tia l in v e s to rs w i ll a tte m p t to ju dg e th e in te re s t o f o th e r in v e s to rs a n d w ill o n ly s u b scrib e f o r IP O s t h a t th e y b e lie ve w i ll be p o p u la r. I f an in v e s to r perceives t h a t a flo a t is n o t p o p u la r w it h o th e r in v e s to rs , th e n he o r she m a y decide n o t to sub scrib e. I f th e is s u e r sets a p ric e t h a t is p e rce ive d as o n ly a l i t t le to o h ig h , th e re is a s ig n ific a n t p r o b a b ility t h a t th e issue w ill be a fa ilu re , w it h in v e s to rs d e c id in g n o t to s u b scrib e because o th e rs have also de cid e d n o t to sub scrib e. T h ere fore, issu ers m a y have an in c e n tiv e to u n d e rp ric e an issue in o rd e r to in d u c e som e p o te n tia l in v e s to rs to buy. The a c tio n o f the se in v e s to rs m a y th e n se t o f f a cascade in C hapter n in e S ources w h ic h o th e r in v e s to rs are w illin g to sub scrib e. R itte r a n d W e lch (2 0 0 2 ) n o te t h a t th is e x p la n a tio n is s u p p o rte d b y evidence t h a t IP O s te n d to be e ith e r u n d e rs u b s c rib e d o r h e a v ily o v e rsu b scrib e d , w it h fe w b e in g m o d e ra te ly o v e rsu b scrib e d . U s in g b o o k -b u ild in g to p ric e an IPO, w h ic h in c re a s in g ly has becom e s ta n d a rd p ra ctice , a llo w s issuers to o b ta in in fo r m a tio n fro m in fo rm e d in v e s to rs . A f te r an in d ic a tiv e p ric e ran ge has been set, th e issu e r a n d th e lead m a n a g e r u s u a lly go o n a ‘ro a d s h o w ’ to p ro m o te th e co m p a n y to p ro s p e c tiv e in v e s to rs . The lead m a n a g e r can th e n gauge d e m a n d f o r th e shares as exp re ssio n s o f in te re s t are rece ive d fr o m p o te n tia l in ve sto rs. I f d e m a n d is h ig h , th e o ffe r p ric e w ill be set a t th e to p o f th e in d ic a tiv e p ric e range o r i t m a y be set above th a t le ve l i f d e m a n d is p a r tic u la r ly s tro n g . H o w e ve r, p o te n tia l in v e s to rs w ill be u n w illin g to reveal t h e ir tru e in te re s t in th e IP O i f th e y k n o w t h a t s h o w in g s tro n g in te re s t is lik e ly to re s u lt in a h ig h e r o ffe r p ric e — un le ss th e y are o ffe re d s o m e th in g in re tu rn . U n d e rp ric in g th e n becom es p a r t o f th e in d u c e m e n t needed to g e t p o te n tia l in v e s to rs to t r u t h f u lly re ve a l t h a t th e y are w illin g to pu rcha se th e shares a t a h ig h price. A n a ly s is o f d a ta o n IPO s p ric e d u s in g b o o k -b u ild in g in th e US is c o n s is te n t w ith th is a rg u m e n t. F o r e xa m p le , R itte r a n d W e lch fo u n d t h a t o v e r th e 1 9 8 0 to 2 0 0 1 p e rio d , f o r IP O s th a t were p ric e d w it h in th e in d ic a tiv e p ric e range, average u n d e rp ric in g was 12 p e r ce n t. H o w e ve r, w h e n th e o ffe r p ric e was above th e in d ic a tiv e p ric e range, average u n d e rp ric in g was 53 p e r ce n t. The a d d itio n a l u n d e rp ric in g is re g ard ed as c o m p e n s a tio n to in d u c e in v e s to rs to reve al t h e ir h ig h in d iv id u a l d e m a n d f o r th e shares— b u t as R itte r a n d W e lch n o te , average u n d e rp ric in g o f 53 p e r c e n t seems to be excessive c o m p e n s a tio n f o r re v e a lin g in fo r m a tio n . Several stu d ie s have fo u n d t h a t g re a te r u n d e rp ric in g is a sso cia te d w it h h ig h e r tra d in g v o lu m e once th e shares becom e lis te d . A c c o rd in g ly , a t h ir d e x p la n a tio n f o r u n d e rp ric in g is t h a t i t p ro v id e s b e n e fits th ro u g h g re a te r liq u id ity . F o r exa m ple, a b ro k e r w h o u n d e rw rite s an IP O can e a rn h ig h e r b ro ke ra g e fees fo r h a n d lin g tra d e s in th e p o s t-lis tin g m a rk e t i f th e issue is u n d e rp ric e d . L iq u id ity can also b e n e fit issuers, p a rtic u la rly i f th e y have re ta in e d a h ig h p r o p o r tio n o f th e c o m p a n y s shares. P ham , K a le v an d Steen (2 0 0 3 ) argue t h a t g re a te r u n d e rp ric in g encourages s m a ll in v e s to rs to su b scrib e f o r an IPO, w h ic h re su lts in a b ro a d e r an d m o re d iffu s e o w n e rs h ip base. U s in g a sam ple o f A u s tra lia n IPO s th e y s h o w t h a t these fa c to rs are s ig n ific a n tly a n d p o s itiv e ly a sso cia te d w it h th e liq u id it y o f th e shares once th e y are lis te d . C onversely, th e y argue t h a t lo w e r u n d e rp ric in g w ill g ive ris e to a m o re c o n c e n tra te d o w n e rs h ip s tru c tu re , w h ic h m a y be p re fe rre d i f la rge sh a re h o ld e rs o b ta in b e n e fits fr o m c o n tro l o r can p ro v id e va lua ble m o n ito r in g o f th e c o m p a n y s m a n a g e m e n t. A f o u r t h e x p la n a tio n is t h a t u n d e rp ric in g o f IPO s is in th e in te re s ts o f th e is s u in g com p an y. O ne aspect o f th is e x p la n a tio n is t h a t u n d e rp ric e d IP O s *leave a g o o d taste* w it h in v e s to rs , ra is in g th e p ric e a t w h ic h sub se q u e n t share issues b y th e c o m p a n y can be s o ld .21 A re la te d a rg u m e n t is t h a t u n d e rp ric in g re fle cts, a t le ast in p a rt, th e co st to th e is s u in g co m p a n y o f p u rc h a s in g research coverage b y a n a lysts. C liff a n d D e nis (2 0 0 4 ) n o te t h a t in a d d itio n to p re -IP O a c tiv itie s re la te d to th e p r ic in g a n d m a rk e tin g o f a share issue, in v e s tm e n t b a n k s p ro v id e a ran ge o f p o s t-is s u e services such as m a rk e t-m a k in g a n d a n a ly s t research coverage. T hey also n o te t h a t is s u in g co m p a n ie s a p p e a r to place a v a lu e o n s e c u rin g research coverage fr o m a n a lysts, p a r tic u la r ly th o s e w it h s tro n g re p u ta tio n s . A c c o rd in g ly , issu ers p la n n in g an IPO m a y seek o u t u n d e rw rite rs w h o th e y e xp e ct w ill p ro v id e research coverage b y a h ig h ly ra te d a n a ly s t a n d issuers w ill be p re p a re d to p a y f o r t h a t a n a ly s t coverage— p e rh a p s d ire c tly b y w a y o f h ig h e r u n d e r w r itin g fees. H o w eve r, C lif f a n d D e n is fo u n d t h a t u n d e r w r itin g fees are la rg e ly u n ifo r m a n d p ro p o se in s te a d t h a t gre a te r u n d e rp ric in g serves to in d ir e c tly com p e n sa te u n d e rw rite rs f o r p ro v id in g a n a ly s t coverage. F o r exam ple, u n d e rw rite rs can b e n e fit fr o m u n d e rp ric in g b y a llo c a tin g shares to fa v o u re d c lie n ts w h o are expected to p ro v id e th e u n d e r w r ite r w it h in v e s tm e n t b a n k in g o r b ro k in g b u sin e ss in th e fu tu re . A f if t h e x p la n a tio n is t h a t issu e rs u n d e rp ric e IP O s to reduce th e r is k o f b e in g sued b y in v e s to rs . W h ile th e p o te n tia l le ga l lia b ilit y o f issu e rs m a y be a fa c to r in som e IPO s, p a r tic u la r ly in th e US, o th e r c o u n trie s , w h ere litig a t io n is m u c h less c o m m o n , e xp erience s im ila r levels o f u n d e rp ric in g . T h e re fo re , i t seems u n lik e ly th a t le ga l lia b ilit y is th e m a in fa c to r t h a t d e te rm in e s th e u n d e rp ric in g o f IPO s. F in a lly , L o u g h ra n a n d R itte r (2 0 0 2 ) n o te t h a t issuers ra re ly ap p e a r to be u p s e t a b o u t le a v in g s u b s ta n tia l a m o u n ts o f m o n e y o n th e ta b le in IPO s. T hey p ro p o se a b e h a v io u ra l e x p la n a tio n f o r th is p u z z lin g p h e n o m e n o n . T h e ir e x p la n a tio n can be illu s tra te d u s in g a h y p o th e tic a l e xa m p le . Suppose th a t M arcus T h o m p s o n o w n s a la rg e successful b u sin ess an d, a fte r d is c u s s io n w ith an in v e s tm e n t b a n k , he plan s to sell 60 p e r c e n t o f th e co m p a n y in an IPO , w h ic h w ill be p ric e d u s in g a b o o k -b u ild . The in d ic a tiv e *1 4 9 21 For an analysis of this explanation, see Welch (1989). The explanations for underpricing of IPOs outlined above are only some of the possible explanations that have been proposed. Further explanations are discussed by Ibbotson, Sindelar and Ritter (1994) and Brau and Fawcett (2006). of f in a n c e : equity B usiness finance p ric e ran ge f o r th e b o o k -b u ild is set a t $ 4 .5 0 to $5 p e r share, b u t, a fte r a successful ro a d s h o w , w h e re th e in v e s tm e n t b a n k reco rds s tro n g in te re s t fr o m in s titu tio n s , i t advises M a rcu s t h a t th e issue p ric e s h o u ld be in cre a se d to $6 p e r share. G iv e n th e g o o d ne w s t h a t h is c o m p a n y is w o r th a t le a st 2 0 p e r c e n t m o re th a n he p re v io u s ly th o u g h t, M a rcu s accepts th e advice a n d does n o t b a rg a in f o r a h ig h e r issue price. W h e n th e shares are lis te d o n th e ASX, th e firs t-d a y c lo s in g m a rk e t p ric e is $1 0. M a rc u s has le f t a large a m o u n t o f m o n e y o n th e ta b le b u t he has also d isco ve re d t h a t th e in te re s t he re ta in e d — 4 0 p e r c e n t o f th e shares— is w o r th tw ic e as m u c h as he expected. G ive n th e p le a s a n t s u rp ris e a b o u t h is n e w -fo u n d w e a lth , M a rcu s m a y fe e l happy, d e sp ite th e o p p o r tu n it y loss o n th e shares t h a t he so ld to o th e r in v e s to rs . I f th e la rge in it ia l re tu rn s o n IPO s re fle c t ra tio n a l b e h a v io u r b y issuers a n d in v e s to rs , th e n these re tu rn s s h o u ld be re la te d to fa c to rs such as th e a m o u n t o f in fo r m a tio n a va ila ble to in v e s to rs a n d th e b e n e fits t h a t issu ers m a y d e riv e f r o m u n d e rp ric in g . E m p iric a l evide nce s u p p o rts th is e x p e c ta tio n . F or exa m ple, Lee, T a y lo r a n d W a lte r (1 9 9 6 ) fo u n d a s tro n g in v e rs e re la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n th e le n g th o f th e de la y b e tw e e n p ro sp e ctu s re g is tra tio n a n d exchange lis tin g a n d th e le v e l o f u n d e rp ric in g . In o th e r w o rd s, IPO s w it h s h o rte r delays in lis tin g are s ig n ific a n tly m o re u n d e rp ric e d . T his fin d in g is c o n s is te n t w it h th e ^w in n e rs curse* e x p la n a tio n in w h ic h in fo rm e d in v e s to rs w ill q u ic k ly s u b scrib e f o r u n d e rp ric e d issues th e re b y e n s u rin g t h a t th e issue w ill be fille d in a s h o rt p e rio d . H o w , Iz a n a n d M o n ro e (1 9 9 5 ) also fo u n d a s tro n g re la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n de la y in lis tin g a n d th e le ve l o f u n d e rp ric in g . F u rth e r, th e y fo u n d th a t u n d e rp ric in g is re la te d to m easures o f b o th th e q u a lity a n d q u a n tity o f in fo r m a t io n a va ila b le a b o u t th e com pany. S pe cifica lly, u n d e rp ric in g was lo w e r w h e n th e u n d e r w r ite r h a d a g o o d re p u ta tio n a n d i t was also lo w e r f o r co m p a n ie s w it h m o re in fo r m a t io n a va ila b le .22 C am p, C o m e r a n d H o w (2 0 0 6 ) s tu d ie d 4 9 N e w Z e a la n d IPO s t h a t lis te d b e tw e e n 1 9 8 9 a n d 2 0 0 2 . They fo u n d t h a t u n d e rp ric in g was s ig n ific a n tly lo w e r f o r issues t h a t used b o o k -b u ild in g ra th e r th a n a fix e d p ric e o ffe r. T his re s u lt is c o n s is te n t w it h th e a rg u m e n t t h a t b o o k -b u ild in g p ro v id e s issuers w ith feedback fr o m in fo rm e d in v e s to rs , w h ic h a llo w s m o re accurate p r ic in g o f th e IPO. T hey also fo u n d t h a t g re a te r u n d e rp ric in g is associated w it h h ig h e r tra d in g v o lu m e in th e p o s t-lis tin g m a rk e t, su g g e s tin g a tra d e -o ff b e tw e e n th e cost (u n d e rp ric in g ) o f g o in g p u b lic a n d th e b e n e fit (g re a te r liq u id ity ) o f d o in g so. C am p e t al. also fo u n d t h a t u n d e rp ric in g is p o s itiv e ly re la te d to th e p r o p o r tio n o f shares re ta in e d b y th e p re -IP O sh a re h o ld e rs. C o n s is te n t w it h L o u g h ra n a n d R itt e r s e x p la n a tio n , issu ers w h o re ta in m o re shares in th e c o m p a n y a p pe ar to be less co n ce rn e d a b o u t u n d e rp ric in g because a n y loss o f w e a lth o n th e shares sold in th e IP O w i ll be o ffs e t b y a g a in o n th e shares th e y re ta in . U n d e rp ric in g o f IPO s is a p e rs is te n t p h e n o m e n o n t h a t is y e t to be f u lly e x p la in e d . In e v a lu a tin g th e p ro p o s e d e x p la n a tio n s o u tlin e d p re v io u s ly , th e q u e s tio n s h o u ld n o t be: ‘W h ic h m o d e l is co rre c t? ’ R a th er, w e s h o u ld ask q u e s tio n s such as: ‘W h ic h m o d e l is m o re u s e fu l in th is case?’ A lso , w e s h o u ld re m e m b e r t h a t th e reasons f o r u n d e rp ric in g can change o v e r tim e . F o r exa m ple, th e re is evidence t h a t u n d e rp ric in g is g e n e ra lly lo w e r f o r com p an ies t h a t engage h ig h e r-q u a lity u n d e rw rite rs a n d h ig h e r-q u a lity a u d ito rs . These p a rtie s have been v ie w e d as p ro v id in g a c e rtific a tio n role; in v e s to rs are c o n fid e n t t h a t a h ig h q u a lity u n d e r w r ite r w ill n o t o v e rp ric e an IP O because d o in g so w o u ld h a rm its r e p u ta tio n w it h in v e s to rs . H o w e ve r, th e u s u a l re la tio n s h ip b e tw e e n u n d e rp ric in g a n d u n d e r w r ite r q u a lity re ve rse d d u rin g th e 1 9 9 9 -2 0 0 0 in t e r n e t b u b b le \ A s discussed p re v io u s ly , one e x p la n a tio n f o r th is re v e rs a l is t h a t th e o b je c tiv e s o f issu ers cha ng ed in t h a t th e y becam e less co n ce rn e d a b o u t u n d e rp ric in g a n d w e re p re p a re d to p a y f o r research coverage b y le a d in g an alysts. The c o n s is te n t fin d in g t h a t IPO s are o n average u n d e rp ric e d does n o t ne ce ssa rily m e a n t h a t issue prices are ‘to o lo w ’ 一 i t is also p o ssib le t h a t firs t-d a y m a rk e t p rice s are 'to o h ig h ,. T his p o s s ib ility is c o n s is te n t LEARNING OBJECTIVE 7 Outline evidence on the long-term performance of companies that are floated w it h evide nce t h a t th e p o s itiv e firs t-d a y re tu rn s o n IP O s are o fte n reve rsed o v e r tim e — t h a t is, several stu d ie s have fo u n d t h a t th e shares o f n e w ly lis te d co m p a n ie s te n d to u n d e rp e rfo rm d u r in g th e f ir s t fe w years a fte r lis tin g . U n fo rtu n a te ly , i t is v e ry d iff ic u lt to a c c u ra te ly assess th e lo n g -ru n p e rfo rm a n c e o f c o m p a n ie s t h a t go p u b lic . O n e rea son is t h a t th e m a rk e t m o d e l, w h ic h was in tro d u c e d in S e ctio n 7.6.3, c a n n o t be used to e s tim a te th e be tas o f th e s e c u ritie s because p re -lis tin g r e tu r n d a ta does n o t e x is t f o r IPO s. T h ere fore, researchers have used a v a r ie ty o f o th e r approaches to assess w h e th e r p o s t-lis tin g re tu rn s are a b n o rm a l. O ne a p p ro a ch is to com p are p o s t-lis tin g r e tu rn s o n IP O co m p a n ie s to one o r m o re 22 The underwriting fee as a percentage of the issue proceeds was used as a measure of the underwriters reputation and the size of the company was used as a measure of the quantity of information. C hapter n in e S ources of fin a n c e : equity m a rk e t in d ice s, w ith o u t a n y a d ju s tm e n t f o r ris k . A n o th e r a p p ro a ch is to co m p a re th e re tu rn s o n th e IPO com panies w ith a c o n tro l sam ple o f o th e r lis te d co m p a n ie s m a tc h e d o n th e basis o f one o r m o re ch a ra cte ristics such as size (m a rk e t c a p ita lis a tio n ) a n d in d u s try . R itte r (1 9 9 1 ) s tu d ie d co m p a n ie s t h a t w e n t p u b lic in th e US in th e p e rio d 1 9 7 5 to 1 9 8 4 .23 H e fo u n d t h a t an in v e s to r w h o p u rc h a s e d shares in IP O co m p a n ie s a t th e c lo s in g p ric e o n th e f ir s t d a y o f p u b lic tra d in g an d th e n h e ld th e shares f o r 3 years w o u ld have e a rn e d an average t o ta l r e tu r n o f 3 4 .4 7 p e r cen t. F o r a c o n tro l sam ple o f n o n -IP O com p an ies m a tc h e d b y size a n d in d u s try , th e average t o ta l r e tu r n o ve r th e same p e rio d was 6 1 .8 6 p e r cen t. The u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e b y IP O co m p a n ie s v a rie d s ig n ific a n tly fr o m yea r to yea r a n d across in d u s trie s b u t i t was c o n c e n tra te d a m o n g re la tiv e ly y o u n g , g ro w th com p an ies, p a rtic u la rly th o s e t h a t w e n t p u b lic in years w h e n th e re was a h ig h v o lu m e o f IPO s. L o u g h ra n a n d R itte r (1 9 9 5 ) fo u n d t h a t th e p o o r lo n g -te rm p e rfo rm a n c e o f IP O s c o n tin u e d b e y o n d 3 years a n d was sha red b y com p an ies m a k in g su b s e q u e n t e q u ity issues— k n o w n as s e a s o n e d e q u i t y SEASONED EQUITY o f f e r in g s (SEOs) in th e US. U s in g la rge sam ples o f co m p a n ie s t h a t issu ed e q u ity in th e p e rio d 1 9 7 0 to OFFERING 19 9 0 , th e y re p o rte d average a n n u a l re tu rn s o v e r th e 5 years a fte r th e is s u in g o f o n ly 5 p e r c e n t f o r IPO s a n d 7 p e r c e n t f o r com p an ies m a k in g SEOs. In c o n tra s t, in v e s tin g in n o n -is s u in g com p an ies o f th e same size an d h o ld in g th e in v e s tm e n t f o r th e sam e p e rio d w o u ld have p ro d u c e d an average a n n u a l re tu r n o f 12 p e r ce n t f o r IPO s a n d 15 p e r c e n t f o r SEOs. L o u g h ra n a n d R itte r p ro p o se t h a t t h e ir evide nce is c o n s is te n t w ith a m a rk e t w h e re shares are p e rio d ic a lly o v e rv a lu e d a n d t h a t com p an ies ta ke ad van ta ge o f these E n d o w s o f o p p o r tu n it y 1 b y is s u in g e q u ity a t th o s e tim e s . T h a t idea, a n d th e re la te d p ro p o s itio n th a t in v e s to rs w ill re s p o n d b y c u ttin g share p rice s w h e n an issue is a n n o u n ce d , are n o t new . F o r e xa m ple, S m ith (1 9 8 6 ) re p o rte d t h a t w h e n a US co m p a n y a n n o u n ce s an SEO, its share p ric e fa lls b y a b o u t 3 p e r cen t o n average. L o u g h ra n a n d R itte r p o in t o u t t h a t i f in v e s to rs are to receive th e sam e lo n g -te rm re tu rn s on issuers as o n n o n -is s u e rs o f th e sam e size, th e fa ll in p ric e w h e n an issue is a n n o u n c e d s h o u ld be m u c h larger. T h e ir n u m b e rs *im p ly t h a t i f th e m a rk e t re a cte d f u lly to th e in fo r m a tio n im p lie d b y a n e q u ity issue a n n o u n c e m e n t, th e average a n n o u n c e m e n t e ffe c t w o u ld be - 3 3 p e r c e n t, n o t - 3 p e r cent* (L o u g h ra n an d R itte r 19 9 5 , p. 4 8 ). L o u g h ra n a n d R itte r r e fe r to th e u n e x p la in e d lo w lo n g -te rm re tu rn s fo llo w in g e q u ity issues as ‘th e n e w issues p u z z le ’. The sig n ifica n ce o f th e n e w issues p u z z le is c o n tro v e rs ia l. B rav a n d G o m p e rs (1 9 9 7 ) s h o w t h a t lo w p o s t-lis tin g re tu rn s te n d to be c o n c e n tra te d a m o n g s m a ll com p an ies, w h ic h m ea ns t h a t m ea sure d u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e is m u c h s m a lle r w h e n re tu rn s are v a lu e w e ig h te d ra th e r th a n e q u a lly w e ig h te d . They also fin d t h a t u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e is a c h a ra c te ris tic o f s m a ll com p an ies w it h lo w b o o k -to -m a rk e t ra tio s regardless o f w h e th e r th e y are n e w ly lis te d o r n o t. I n o th e r w o rd s , B ra v a n d G o m p e rs f in d t h a t c om p an ies th a t go p u b lic do n o t e x h ib it lo n g -te rm u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e w h e n r e tu rn s are m e a su re d re la tiv e to c o n tro l com panies m a tc h e d o n b o th size a n d b o o k -to -m a rk e t ra tio . Eckbo, M a s u lis a n d N o r li (2 0 0 0 ) arg ue t h a t th e *new issues puzzle* id e n tifie d b y L o u g h ra n a n d R itte r can be reso lve d w ith o u t re s o rtin g to e x p la n a tio n s based o n m a rk e t u n d e rre a c tio n to th e in fo r m a tio n in a n n o u n c e m e n ts o f s e c u rity issues. E ckbo e t al. analyse re tu rn s fo llo w in g a la rg e sam p le o f seasoned issues o f b o th e q u ity a n d d e b t fr o m 1 9 6 4 to 1 9 9 5 . T hey argue t h a t th e m a tc h e d -firm te c h n iq u e does n o t p ro v id e a p ro p e r c o n tro l f o r r is k f o r tw o reasons. F irs t, an e q u ity issue lo w e rs th e fin a n c ia l leverage o f th e is s u in g c o m p a n y so issu ers also lo w e r t h e ir ris k , a n d th e re fo re t h e ir e xp e cte d r e tu rn , re la tiv e to th e m a tch e d firm s . Second, th e y f in d t h a t share t u r n o v e r increases s ig n ific a n tly a fte r SEOs, b u t tu r n o v e r does n o t change f o r th e m a tc h e d firm s . In o th e r w o rd s , liq u id it y increases a fte r SEOs so th e shares o f is s u in g com panies c o u ld re q u ire lo w e r liq u id it y p re m iu m s a fte r an issue. In sum , th e y con clu de t h a t evidence o f lo n g -ru n u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e p ro d u c e d b y th e m a tc h e d -firm te c h n iq u e is an a r tifa c t o f th e te c h n iq u e its e lf* (Eckbo, M a s u lis & N o r li 2 0 0 0 , p. 2 5 3 ). G om pe rs a n d L e rn e r (2 0 0 3 ) p o in t o u t t h a t m o s t stu d ie s th a t re p o rt u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e b y IP O s have e xa m in e d d a ta fr o m th e tim e p e rio d a fte r fo r m a tio n o f th e N asdaq syste m w h e re m o s t US IPO s are tra d e d . The N asdaq is th e la rg e s t e le c tro n ic e q u ity s e c u ritie s tra d in g m a rk e t in th e US. W h e n e sta b lish e d in th e e a rly 19 70 s b y th e N a tio n a l A s s o c ia tio n o f S e cu ritie s D ealers, i t was th e w o r ld s f ir s t e le c tro n ic sto c k m a rk e t. To te s t w h e th e r th e re is a ‘N a sda q e ffe c t’,G o m p e rs a n d L e rn e r c o n d u c te d an o u t-o f-s a m p le in v e s tig a tio n u s in g d a ta o n 3 6 6 1 IPO s fr o m 1 9 3 5 to 1 9 7 2 — a p e rio d p r io r to th e c re a tio n o f N asdaq. They fo u n d t h a t th e re la tiv e p e rfo rm a n c e o f a n IP O sam p le depends c r itic a lly o n th e m e th o d used to assess p e rfo rm a n c e . O ne m e th o d re ve aled som e u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e , b u t th is m e a su re d u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e 23 Updated evidence on the long-term performance of US IPOs from 1970 to 2013 is available at http://bear.w arrington.ufl. edu/ritter/ipodata.htm. offer to sell equity securities of a class that is already traded B usiness finance d isa p p e a re d w h e n th e sam e sam p le was s tu d ie d u s in g o th e r m e th o d s , in c lu d in g re g re ssio n s based o n th e C A P M (see S e c tio n 7 .6 .2 ) a n d th e Fam a a n d F re n c h th re e -fa c to r m o d e l (see S e ctio n 7 .7 ). G om pe rs and L e rn e r co n clu d e t h a t th e evide nce f o r u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e b y IP O s is w eak. M ix e d evide nce o n th e lo n g -te rm p e rfo rm a n c e o f c o m p a n ie s t h a t go p u b lic is n o t c o n fin e d to th e US. F o r A u s tra lia n IPO s, lo n g -te rm u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e , re la tiv e to th e m a rk e t in d e x , has b e en re p o rte d by Lee, T a y lo r a n d W a lte r (1 9 9 6 ) o v e r 3 years, a n d D im o v s k i a n d B ro o ks (2 0 0 3 ) o v e r 1 year, a fte r lis tin g . F o r t h e ir sam p le o f 2 6 6 IPO s, Lee e t al. re p o rte d a m a rk e t-a d ju s te d r e t u r n o f - 5 1 p e r c e n t o v e r 3 years. D im o v s k i a n d B ro o ks re p o rte d a n average m a rk e t-a d ju s te d r e tu r n o f - 4 . 0 p e r ce n t o v e r 1 ye a r f o r a sam p le o f 2 5 1 IP O s fr o m 1 9 9 4 to 19 9 8 . H o w e ve r, th e re s u lts w e re n o t u n if o r m ly n e g a tiv e w h e n th e sam p le w as d iv id e d in to su b g ro u p s. F o r exa m ple, th e average m a rk e t-a d ju s te d r e tu r n f o r 7 8 n o lia b ilit y co m p a n ie s w as - 3 0 p e r c e n t a fte r 1 ye a r b u t f o r th e 1 7 3 lim it e d lia b ilit y co m p a n ie s th e c o rre s p o n d in g average r e t u r n w as +7.7 p e r ce n t. The m e d ia n m a rk e t-a d ju s te d r e t u r n a fte r 1 y e a r w as n e g a tiv e f o r th e sam p le as a w h o le a n d f o r e ve ry su b g ro u p . In c o n tra s t, da S ilva Rosa, V e la y u th e n a n d W a lte r (2 0 0 3 ) used several b e n c h m a rk s a n d co n clu d e d t h a t th e sam p le th e y s tu d ie d d id n o t u n d e rp e rfo rm in th e 2 years fo llo w in g lis tin g . In s u m m a ry , th e evidence o n lo n g -ru n p e rfo rm a n c e fo llo w in g IP O s re m a in s c o n tro v e rs ia l. M a n y stu d ie s have re p o rte d u n d e rp e rfo rm a n c e b y IP O co m p a n ie s o v e r p e rio d s o f 1 to 5 years a fte r lis tin g . There is evide nce t h a t co m p a n ie s t h a t issue e q u ity , w h e th e r th r o u g h an IP O o r a seasoned o ffe rin g , te n d to be p o o r lo n g -te rm in v e s tm e n ts . H o w e ve r, several a u th o rs have q u e s tio n e d w h e th e r th e *new issues puzzle* is re a l a n d p ro v id e evide nce t h a t suggests t h a t i t m a y be n o m o re th a n a n illu s io n . 9.6 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 8 Explain how companies raise capital through rights issues, placements, share purchase plans and share options Subsequent issues of o rd in a ry shares A f te r a c o m p a n y has been flo a te d , a d d itio n a l e x te rn a l fin a n c e w i ll u s u a lly be re q u ire d a t som e tim e to fin a n c e e x p a n s io n . M a n a g e m e n t has th e choice o f is s u in g m o re shares a n d /o r b o rro w in g . I f i t is de cid e d to issue m o re shares, th e re are several choices ava ila ble. I f th e fu n d s are to be ra is e d f r o m e x is tin g sh a re h o ld e rs, th e c o m p a n y can m ake a p ro -ra ta share issue (e n title m e n t o ffe r) o r set u p a share p u rch a se p la n (SPP). A p ro -ra ta sha re issue m a y in t u r n be e ith e r a tr a d itio n a l r ig h ts issue o r a n a ccelerated e n title m e n t o ffe r an d in e ith e r case th e o ffe r m a y be re n o u n ce a b le o r n o n -re n o u n c e a b le . I f m a n a g e m e n t decides to raise fu n d s fr o m selected in v e s to rs , w h o m a y o r m a y n o t be e x is tin g s h a re h o ld e rs in th e co m p a n y, i t m u s t choose a p la c e m e n t. Share issues o f the se typ e s m a y be c a rrie d o u t in d iv id u a lly o r in c o m b in a tio n . F o r exa m ple, a co m p a n y m a y raise c a p ita l th ro u g h a p la c e m e n t a n d an SPP t h a t are a n n o u n c e d s im u lta n e o u s ly . The re g u la to ry re g im e t h a t g o ve rn s c a p ita l ra is in g s b y lis te d co m p a n ie s is o u tlin e d in Table 9.4. TABLE 9.4 The Australian capital-raising regime for listed companies R e g u la to ry re q u ire m e n ts M a in c h a ra c te ris tic s T yp e o f c a p ita l ra is in g Renounceable P a rtic ip a tio n is based on each The tim e ta b le fo r e n title m e n t offers is e n title m e n t o ffe r shareholder s e x is tin g in te re s t in the specified in th e ASX L is tin g Rules. The company. A prospectus m ay be needed. disclosure req uire m en ts are set o u t in Shareholders are able to sell th e ir rig h t th e Corporations Act. to p a rtic ip a te in th e e n title m e n t offer. N on-renounceable P a rtic ip a tio n is based o n each The tim e ta b le fo r e n title m e n t offers e n title m e n t o ffe r shareh old er’s e x is tin g in te re s t in the is specified in th e ASX L is tin g Rules. company. A prospectus m ay be needed. The L is tin g Rules lim it th e size o f the Shareholders are n o t able to sell th e ir rig h t to p a rtic ip a te in th e offer. A n y o ffe r to a m a x im u m o f one new share fo r each e x is tin g share. The disclosure rig h ts n o t take n up m ay be placed a t the re q u ire m e n ts are set o u t in the d iscre tio n o f th e com pany s Board o f Corporations Act. D irectors. C hapter n in e S ources of fin a n c e : equity Table 9 .4 continued — T ype o f c a p ita l ra is in g R e g u la to ry re q u ire m e n ts M a in c h a ra c te ris tic s Placement P a rtic ip a tio n b y in vestors is at the ASX L is tin g Rules re s tric t placem ents d is c re tio n o f th e com pany’s Board o f to no m ore th a n 15 p e r cent o f issued D ire cto rs and m anagem ent. O pen cap ital over a 1 2 -m o n th p e rio d w ith o u t to ‘s o p h istica te d ’ o r ‘p ro fe ssio nal’ appro val by shareholders. U n de r certain investors. A prospectus is n o t required. circum stances, th is lim it increases to 25 p e r cent o f issued cap ital fo r sm aller firm s w ith m a rk e t cap ita lisa tio n s o f less th a n $300 m illio n . The Corporations Act p e rm its placem ents w ith o u t a disclosure d o cu m e n t p ro vid e d a cleansing notice* is issued. The SPP m echanism is stip u la te d in the Share purchase plan P a rtic ip a tio n is open to e x is tin g (SPP) shareholders. There is no re q u ire m e n t L is tin g Rules. The disclosure regim e has fo r a prospectus p ro v id e d a cleansing been p ro vid e d by ASIC in a series o f n o tice is issued, offers are lim ite d R e gu latory Guides and Class Orders. to $15 000 p e r shareholder over a 1 2 -m o n th p e rio d , and th e shares are fu lly p a id a nd issued a t a d isco u n t to th e m a rk e t price d u rin g the 30 days o f tra d in g p rio r to e ith e r th e o ffe r date o r th e issue date. 9 .6 .1 1 Rights issues A rig h ts issue— also k n o w n as an e n title m e n t o ffe r— is a n issue o f n e w shares to e x is tin g sh a re h o ld e rs. U n d e r th e te rm s o f a rig h ts issue, sh a re h o ld e rs receive th e r ig h t to s u b scrib e f o r a d d itio n a l shares in a fix e d ra tio to th e n u m b e r o f shares a lre a d y h e ld . P ro v id e d each s h a re h o ld e r accepts th e o ffe r, th e re is no d ilu tio n o f a n y s h a re h o ld e rs pe rce n ta g e o w n e rs h ip in th e com pany. To illu s tra te th e e le m e n ts o f a r ig h ts issue: assum e t h a t an in v e s to r h o ld s 1 0 0 0 shares, w h ic h re p re s e n t 1 p e r ce n t o f a c o m p a n y s issu e d c a p ita l o f 1 0 0 0 0 0 shares. I f th e c o m p a n y m akes a rig h ts issue th a t e n title s each s h a re h o ld e r to p u rch a se one a d d itio n a l share f o r e v e ry fo u r shares h e ld , th e s h a re h o ld e r is SUBSCRIPTION PRICE e n title d to b u y an e x tra 2 5 0 shares, th u s in c re a s in g th e s h a re h o ld in g to 1 2 5 0 . In to ta l, th e c o m p a n y w ill the price that must be paid to obtain a new share issue 25 0 0 0 n e w shares. T h e re fo re , th e p e rcen ta ge o w n e rs h ip o f th e s h a re h o ld e r in th e c o m p a n y re m a in s un cha ng ed a t 1 p e r ce n t because 1 2 5 0 /1 2 5 0 0 0 = 1 p e r ce n t. W ith a rig h ts issue, s h a re h o ld e rs b u y a d d itio n a l shares. The com p an y, th e re fo re , has to se t a subscription price. U su a lly, th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e is less th a n th e c u rre n t m a rk e t p ric e o f th e shares, because o th e rw is e n o -o n e w o u ld w a n t to s u b scrib e f o r th e n e w shares. G ive n t h a t th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e is b e lo w th e c u rre n t m a rk e t p ric e , th e r ig h t to b u y a n e w share has a value . I f th e rig h ts are re n o u n ce a b le , a s h a re h o ld e r is able to se ll th e rig h ts to a n o th e r in v e s to r i f th e y w is h to . A fo rm u la k n o w n as th e theoretical rights price can be used to e s tim a te th e v a lu e o f a r ig h t. To de ve lo p th is fo rm u la suppose t h a t a c o m p a n y m akes a 1 - fo r - N re n o u n ce a b le rig h ts issue a t a s u b s c rip tio n p ric e of S d o lla rs p e r sha re— t h a t is, each s h a re h o ld e r o b ta in s th e r ig h t to pu rcha se o n e n e w share f o r e v e ry shares th a t th e y c u rre n tly h o ld an d w ill p a y S d o lla rs N f o r each n e w share. A ll re n o u n ce a b le rig h ts issues ex-rights date. I f an in v e s to r pu rcha ses shares in th e c o m p a n y b e fo re th e pu rcha se is said to be cum righ ts a n d th e in v e s to r w ill receive rig h ts to purcha se n e w sp e cify a date, called th e e x -rig h ts date, th e shares. The rig h ts th e m s e lv e s m a y be tra d e d s e p a ra te ly f r o m th e shares o n o r a fte r th e e x -rig h ts date. I f an in v e s to r purchases shares o n o r a fte r th e e x -rig h ts da te th e p u rcha se is sa id to be in v e s to r will not receive a n y rig h ts . ex-rights a n d th e EX-RIGHTS DATE date on which a share begins trading ex-rights. After fhis date a share does not have attached to it the right to purchase any additional share(s) on the subscription date CUM RIGHTS when shares are traded cum rights the buyer is entitled to participate in the forthcoming rights issue A ssu m e t h a t a n in v e s to r purchases is NM w h e re M is N shares ju s t b e fo re th e e x -rig h ts date. The co st o f th is purchase th e m a rk e t p ric e o f a share cu m rig h ts . T his in v e s to r is e n title d to th e r ig h t to purchase one n e w share. E x a c tly th e sam e in v e s tm e n t can be a ch ie ved b y e n te rin g th e m a rk e t ju s t a fte r th e shares b e g in tra d in g e x -rig h ts a n d p u rc h a s in g T his w ill c o st NX + R} w h e re X is N shares e x -rig h ts a n d also p u rc h a s in g th e r ig h t to one n e w share. th e m a rk e t p ric e o f a share e x -rig h ts a n d R is th e m a rk e t p ric e o f th e r ig h t to p u rcha se one n e w share. In th e absence o f a n y n e w in fo r m a tio n t h a t causes p ric e s to change, b o th in v e s tm e n t stra te g ie s s h o u ld co st th e same. T h a t is: 9.1 N M =N X +R I f th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e is pa yab le im m e d ia te ly , th e n th e r ig h t to one n e w share can be im m e d ia te ly c o n v e rte d to a n e w share b y p a y m e n t o f th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e . T h e re fo re , w h e n th e shares b e g in tra d in g R and X. To p re v e n t a rb itra g e , e x -rig h ts , an in v e s to r c o u ld o b ta in a share e ith e r b y b u y in g th e r ig h t to one n e w share a t a cost o f th e n p a y in g th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e o f S, o r b y b u y in g a share d ir e c tly a t a p ric e o f b o th in v e s tm e n t s tra te g ie s m u s t co st th e same. T h a t is: _______ R+ S= X THEORETICAL RIGHTS S u b s titu tin g E q u a tio n 9.2 in to E q u a tio n 9.1, a n d re a rra n g in g , gives: PRICE N+ 1 S u b s titu tin g E q u a tio n 9.3 in to E q u a tio n 9.2, a n d re a rra n g in g , gives: NM+S X THEORETICAL EX-RIGHTS SHARE PRICE the expected price of one share when shares begin to be traded ex-rights N(M -S) R. the expected price of one right calculated on the basis of the cum-rights share price The p ric e s t h a t r e s u lt fr o m u s in g E q u a tio n s 9.3 a n d 9 .4 are o fte n re fe rre d to as th e price a n d th e theoretical ex-righ ts sh are price, theoretical righ ts resp ective ly. W h a t is th e e ffe c t o f a rig h ts issue o n th e va lu e o f an in v e s tm e n t in shares? To a n s w e r th is q u e s tio n , c o n s id e r E xam p le 9.1. E x a m p l e 9 .1 A th o l o w n s 1 0 0 0 s h a re s in R a ven E n te rp ris e s Ltd (REL), w h o s e c u rre n t s h a re p r ic e (cu m rig h ts ) is $ 2 p e r s h a re . REL m a k e s a l- f o r - 4 rig h ts issu e w ith a s u b s c rip tio n p r ic e o f $ 1 . 4 0 p e r s h a re . A th o l w is h e s to c a lc u la te : a) th e v a lu e , R, o f th e r ig h t to b u y 1 n e w s h a re b) th e e x -rig h ts s h a re p r ic e , X c) th e v a lu e o f h is in v e s tm e n t c u m rig h ts a n d e x -rig h ts . In th is c a s e , N = 4 , M = $ 2 . 0 0 a n d S = $ 1 . 4 0 . SOLUTION a) U s in g E q u a tio n 9 . 3 , th e v a lu e o f th e r ig h t to b u y 1 n e w s h a re is: R _ N IM - S ) N+ 1 4($2.00-$1.40) 471 — = 4 8 cents b) U s in g E q u a tio n 9 . 4 , th e e x -rig h ts s h a re p r ic e is: v NM + S A = ----------------- N+ 1 4($2.00)-$1.40 — = $ 4^1 1.88 C hapter n in e S ources c) of f in a n c e : equity C u m rig h ts , th e in v e s tm e n t is w o r th : ( 1000)($2) =$2000 E x -rig h ts , th e in v e s tm e n t is w o r th : (1 0 0 0 )($ 1 .8 8 ) + (2 5 0 )($ 0 .4 8 ) =$2000 A c c o r d in g to th is a n a ly s is th e to ta l v a lu e o f th e in v e s tm e n t is u n a ffe c te d . B e fo re th e issu e A th o l o w n e d 1 0 0 0 s h a re s w o r th $ 2 e a c h — a to ta l o f $ 2 0 0 0 . A fte r th e issu e h e o w n s 1 0 0 0 s h a re s w o r th $ 1 . 8 8 e a c h ( $ 1 8 8 0 ) p lu s 2 5 0 rig h ts w o r th 4 8 c e n ts e a c h ( $ 1 2 0 ) , w h ic h in to ta l is a ls o w o r th $ 2 0 0 0 . C le a rly , th e v a lu e o f th e rig h ts ju st o ffs e ts th e d e c lin e in th e v a lu e o f th e s h a re s . If A th o l d e c id e s to sell his rig h ts he c a n e x p e c t to r e c e iv e $ 1 2 0 , w h ic h s h o u ld b e r e g a r d e d a s a p a r tia l re tu rn o f c a p it a l as d is tin c t fro m a p r o fit o r re tu rn on c a p it a l. F in a lly , s u p p o s e th a t in s te a d o f a l- f o r - 4 rig h ts issu e w ith a s u b s c rip tio n p r ic e o f $ 1 . 4 0 p e r s h a re , REL m a k e s a l- f o r - 2 issu e w ith a s u b s c rip tio n p r ic e o f 7 0 ce n ts p e r s h a re . C le a rly , b o th issues w o u ld ra is e e x a c tly th e s a m e fu n d s f o r REL a n d r e w o r k in g th e a b o v e c a lc u la tio n s w o u ld s h o w th a t th e e x -rig h ts v a lu e o f A t h o l’s in v e s tm e n t w o u ld a g a in b e $ 2 0 0 0 . This a n alysis relates to th e v a lu e o f a n in v e s tm e n t m ad e a t th e tim e o f th e e x -rig h ts da te a n d i t suggests th re e im p o r t a n t c o n c lu s io n s . F irs t, sha reh old ers* w e a lth is n o t a ffe c te d b y th e m e re fa c t o f a share b e g in n in g to tra d e o n an e x -rig h ts basis. In t u r n , th is suggests th e second c o n c lu s io n th a t, o f its e lf, a rig h ts issue has n o v a lu e to sh a re h o ld e rs. T his c o n c lu s io n s h o u ld n o t be a s u rp ris e . I f a rig h ts issue increased (decreased) sha reh old ers* w e a lth w e w o u ld e xp e ct rig h ts issues to o c c u r m u c h m o re (less) fre q u e n tly th a n th e y do. T h ird , i t suggests t h a t in th e case o f a rig h ts issue th e le v e l o f th e s u b s c rip tio n price has n o e ffe c t o n sha reh old ers* w e a lth . I f a ll s h a re h o ld e rs su b scrib e f o r a rig h ts issue, th e n w h e th e r a co m p a n y raises, say, $2 m illio n b y is s u in g 1 m illio n shares a t $2 each, o r 2 m illio n shares a t $1 each, s h o u ld n o t m a tte r to its sh a re h o ld e rs. H o w eve r, th e above a n a lysis ig n o re s som e fa c to rs t h a t can be im p o r ta n t. F irs t, th e announcement o f a rig h ts issue m a y a ffe c t sha reh old ers* w e a lth because th e a n n o u n c e m e n t can have in fo r m a tio n c o n te n t. F o r exam ple, US a n d A u s tra lia n evide nce suggests th a t, o n average, th e m a rk e t in te rp re ts th e a n n o u n c e m e n t o f e q u ity c a p ita l issues, in c lu d in g rig h ts issues, as 'bad* n e w s .24 S m ith (1 9 8 6 ) p ro v id e d an e x p la n a tio n o f th e n e g a tive a n n o u n c e m e n t e ffe c t: m an ag ers w ill t r y to issue e q u ity w h e n th e y be lie ve i t is o ve rva lu e d . In v e s to rs are aw are o f m anagers* in fo r m a tio n ad van ta ge a n d w ill re s p o n d b y re d u c in g t h e ir e s tim a te o f th e co m p a n y s va lu e w h e n an issue is a n n o u n ce d . The im p lic a tio n s f o r fin a n c in g d e cisio n s are discussed in S ectio n 12 .9.4. Second, th e te rm s o f a rig h ts issue such as th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e m a y a ffe c t th e m a rk e t re a c tio n to an issue w h e n i t is a n n o u n ce d . I f th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e is se t o n ly s lig h tly b e lo w th e m a rk e t p ric e o f th e shares, a m in o r fa ll in th e co m p a n y s share p ric e c o u ld cause th e issue to fa il— n o ra tio n a l s h a re h o ld e r w ill sub scrib e f o r th e rig h ts issue i f th e shares can be p u rch a se d m o re ch e a p ly o n th e s to c k m a rk e t. C learly, th is ris k can be red uce d b y s e ttin g a lo w e r s u b s c rip tio n p rice , b u t d o in g so m a y w a rn in v e s to rs t h a t m a n a g e m e n t is fe a rfu l o f a p o ssib le fa ll in th e co m p a n y s share p rice . Hence, s e ttin g a lo w e r s u b s c rip tio n p rice m a y re s u lt in a la rg e r fa ll in share p ric e w h e n th e issue is a n n o u n ce d . T h ird , th e a n a lysis assum es t h a t th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e is payable o n th e e x -rig h ts da te, w h ere as, in fact, i t is u s u a lly n o t pa yab le u n t il several w eeks la te r. T his gives ris e to th e f u r t h e r p o in t t h a t th e h o ld e r o f a r ig h t is p e r m itte d to p u rch a se shares a t th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e , b u t is n o t o b lig e d to do so. I f th e share p rice o n th e s u b s c rip tio n d a te is less th a n th e s u b s c rip tio n p ric e , th e h o ld e r o f th e r ig h t does n o t have to purchase th e shares. T his ty p e o f a g re e m e n t is k n o w n as an o p t io n , b u t th e th e o re tic a l m o d e l ig n o re s th e o p tio n -lik e fe a tu re s o f a r ig h t a n d is th e re fo re lik e ly to u n d e rs ta te th e v a lu e o f a r ig h t. 24 There is evidence that the market response to the announcement of equity issues differs between countries but is consistently negative on average. Thus, in the US, Smith reports an average decline of about 3 per cent for rights issues by industrial companies (see Smith 1986), while in the UK, Marsh found a much smaller decline for such issues (see Marsh 1979). In Australia, a study of 636 rights issues by Balachandran, Faff and Theobald (2008) found an average fall in share price of 1.74 per cent when the issues were announced. OPTION the right but not the obligation to buy or sell underlying assets at a fixed price for a specified period B usiness finance The option component o f a rig h ts value is usually small in dollar terms b u t can be a significant p ro po rtio n o f the value o f a rig ht, particularly i f the share price is close to the subscription price. For example, the subscription price fo r the rights issue by Colonial Group in 1998 was $4.50, payable no later than 13 July, and the rights were traded on the ASX from 4 June to 2 July. On 11 June, the closing price o f Colonial shares was $4.53 while the rights closed at 14.5 cents. I f holders o f the rights were obliged to pay the subscription price and had to pay it immediately, the rights would have been w orth only $4.53 - $4.50 = 3 cents. In this case, the option component o f the rig hts’ value was 11.5 cents. Disclosure and regulation of rights issues Historically, a company m aking a rights issue was required to supply shareholders w ith a disclosure document, usually a prospectus. The cost o f preparing a disclosure document was an im p o rta n t factor that influenced issuers to prefer placements rather than rights issues. The requirements fo r rights issues have been aligned w ith those fo r placements by changes to the Corporations Act contained in the Corporations Legislation Amendment (Simpler Regulatory System) Act 2007. From 2007, issuers can proceed w ith a rights issue w ith o u t a prospectus provided they: • • lodge w ith the ASX a notice known as a ‘rights issue cleansing notice ’ ;and send to shareholders a short document th a t describes the reasons fo r the rights issue and sets out the term s and tim in g o f the issue. In addition to stating th a t the issuer complies w ith certain provisions o f the Corporations Act, a rights issue cleansing notice m ust deal w ith two issues. First, it m ust contain any excluded* in fo rm a tio n — that is, in fo rm a tio n that: • • has previously been w ithheld from investors based on one o f the exceptions to disclosure contained in the listing rules25 investors would reasonably require and expect to be included in a disclosure document fo r the purpose o f assessing the financial position, performance and prospects o f the issuer. Second, the notice m ust provide inform a tion about any effects th a t the issue could have on the control o f the listed entity. I f a company has disclosed all price-sensitive info rm a tio n related to its operations and makes a rights issue fo r a general purpose such as raising w orking capital or repaying debt, a rights issue cleansing notice would be the obvious choice. In other cases a prospectus may be preferred. For example, suppose th a t a company makes a rights issue to raise funds fo r a new project th a t has been under development fo r some tim e b u t whose existence has n o t been disclosed to the shareholders. In th a t case, a rights issue cleansing notice should contain extensive details o f the new project. However, it may instead be preferable to issue a prospectus containing the same inform ation. One factor favouring the use o f a prospectus is th a t a cleansing notice is n o t defined as a disclosure document. Therefore, i f a cleansing notice is found to contain errors or omissions, the ‘due diligence’ defence outlined in Section 9.4.1 is n o t available. As discussed in Section 9.4.2, the prospectus fo r a rights issue can be much less detailed than the prospectus fo r an issue o f unlisted securities. Provided the company s shares have been listed fo r at least 12 m onths p rio r to the issue, the prospectus does n o t have to contain extensive inform a tion on the assets, liabilities, performance and prospects o f the issuing company. Rather, the prospectus can focus on details o f the new securities and on the expected effects o f the new issue on the company. The significance of rights issues The frequency o f rights issues fluctuates over tim e but they continue to be an im p o rta n t way o f raising equity fo r Australian companies. In the 2012-13 financial year, ASX-listed companies raised $4 b illio n through rights issues. In comparison, in the 2008-09 financial year, $28.5 b illio n was raised through rights issues. Details o f selected rights issues by listed companies are shown in Table 9.5. 25 R u le 3 .1 o f th e A u st r a lia n S e c u r it ie s E x c h a n g e L is t in g R u le s r e q u ir e s im m e d ia t e d is c lo s u r e o f m a t e r ia l in fo r m a t io n b y lis t e d e n t it ie s b u t R u le 3 .1 A p r o v id e s s o m e e x c e p tio n s t o th e c o n tin u o u s d is c lo s u r e r e q u ir e m e n t s . C hapter n in e S ources TABLE 9.5 Details of selected rights issues by listed companies Am ount Issue ra is e d ( $ m ): p r ic e ($ ) P re-issue s h a re p r ic e ($ ) 1U n d e r w r itin g fe e (%) Com pany D a te a n n o u n c e d Wesfarmers Ltd 22/01/2009 3:7 3700 13.50 15.78 2.1 TEN Network Holdings 15/06/2012 3:8 200 0.51 0.64 2.35 Billabong 21/06/2012 International Ltd 6:7 221 1.02 1.83 2.9 Bionomics Ltd 1:8 0.36 0.41 3.0 S o u rc e : 5/03/2013 Issue r a tio 16.4 Announ cem ents to the A S X a n d c o m p a n y prospectuses. Designing a successful rights issue A rights issue that failed to raise all or most o f the planned funds could be very costly fo r the issuing company. The costs o f planning the issue and preparing a prospectus or other documentation have to be paid regardless o f the outcome, and failure is likely to harm a company s reputation because it may be thought th a t existing shareholders lack confidence in the company s prospects and/or the performance o f its managers. Therefore, managers w ill employ various measures to maximise the probability th a t a rights issue w ill be successful. An obvious measure o f this type is to have the issue underw ritten. Another approach m ight be to make the issue renounceable and to set the subscription price substantially below the current m arket price o f the shares so there is a high probability th a t shareholders w ill either exercise their entitlem ent, or sell th e ir rights to others who w ill subscribe fo r the shares. In this case, i t m ig ht seem that there should be no need fo r the company to have the issue underw ritten, b u t in fact the m ajority o f rights issues in Australia are underw ritten. There appear to be fo ur m ain reasons fo r this practice. First, while the subscription price may be well below the share price at the tim e an issue is announced, a substantial unexpected fall in share price is always possible and could spell failure fo r a non-underw ritten issue. Second, as discussed above, setting a low subscription price may result in a larger fall in the share price when a rights issue is announced. Therefore, managers may tr y to m inim ise the adverse effect on shareholders’ wealth by setting a higher subscription price and having the issue underw ritten. Third, there w ill always be some shareholders who, fo r one reason or another, either do n o t receive n otification o f an issue, or do n ot respond in tim e to subscribe fo r the new shares. Finally, because o f the high costs o f complying w ith securities laws in countries such as the US, Australian companies usually specify that a rights issue w ill be made only to shareholders whose registered address is in Australia or New Zealand. ASX Listing Rule 7.7 requires th a t where foreign shareholders are n o t eligible to participate in a renounceable rights issue, they m ust s till be advised o f the issue and th a t the value, i f any, o f th e ir entitlements should be paid to them. Therefore, one role o f the und erw rite r is to sell any new shares that represent the entitlem ents o f ineligible foreign shareholders. Orica Lim ited is an Australian-based manufacturer o f chemicals and explosives w ith operations in about 50 countries and its shareholders include both Australian and overseas investors. In November 2005, Orica announced a fu lly underw ritten l-fo r-8 renounceable rights issue at $15 per share, substantially less than the m arket price o f $20.55. The issue was made to all ordinary shareholders w ith a registered address in Australia or New Zealand and to in s titu tio n a l ordinary shareholders in Hong Kong, Singapore and the UK. On 19 December 2005, Orica announced a shortfall, including the entitlem ents o f ineligible foreign shareholders, o f 2.4 m illion shares, or approximately 7 per cent o f the total. In this case, the sh ortfa ll shares were sold to in s titu tio n a l investors w ith the issue price determ ined by an overnight book-build conducted by the underwriters. The issue price fo r these shares was $20.30, which m eant th a t Orica received $15 per share and the balance o f $5.30 per share was paid to the non-subscribing shareholders and ineligible foreign shareholders. In summary, u nd erw riting is one way o f ensuring that the issuing company w ill receive all the planned funds regardless o f the level o f subscriptions by shareholders and may be less costly than attem pting to increase shareholder take-up by lowering the subscription price. The closer the subscription price on the rights issue is set to the m arket price o f shares, the greater is the need to have the issue underw ritten, of f in a n c e : equity B usiness finance SHORTFALL FACILITY a m echanism under w hich a co m p a n y m ay issue shortfall shares to eligible shareholders or other investors SHORTFALL SHARES new shares not subscribed for b y eligible shareholders a c c o rd in g to their entitlements under a rights issue . and the higher the u nd erw riting fee. The u nd erw riting fee is usually between 1 and 3 per cent o f the subscription price. W hile u nd erw riting ensures th a t all the planned funds w ill be raised, there are other measures that can be used to increase the likelihood th a t a rights issue w ill be successful. The m ain such measures are issuing the rights w ith bonus share options as a sweetener* and providing a sh o rtfall facility. As discussed in Section 9.6.5, bonus share options are issued ‘free’ in a fixed pro po rtio n to the new shares taken up by existing shareholders. Balachandran, Faff and Theobald (2008) studied rights issues announced by Australian companies from 1995 to 2005 and found th a t almost one-third o f the issues in th e ir final sample provided bonus share options. A nother measure to increase the take-up o f new shares by existing shareholders is the inclusion o f a shortfall facility. In its simplest form , a shortfall fa cility allows existing shareholders to apply fo r extra shares in addition to th e ir pro-rata entitlem ent. In this case, any shares n o t subscribed fo r by some shareholders (s h o rtfa ll shares*) w ill be issued to those who applied fo r additional shares. A shortfall fa cility can also allow the company to issue sh o rtfall sh ares to other investors, including underw riters, and the company may have the rig h t to accept oversubscriptions. For example, in February 2007 Argo Investments made a rights issue th a t was n o t u nd erw ritte n and was expected to raise $441 m illion , b ut shareholders taking up th e ir entitlem ents were invite d to apply for additional shares and the company reserved the rig h t to accept oversubscriptions. The end result was that the issue raised approximately $446 m illion. As shown in Table 9.4, there is no upper lim it on the size o f a renounceable rights issue so an issue o f this type can be used to raise a large amount, provided investors are prepared to subscribe fo r the new shares. Further, provided shareholders take up th e ir entitlem ent, a rights issue w ill have no effect on the control o f the company as there is no change in shareholders1relative vo ting strengths. For these reasons a rights issue may appeal to a company s board as a means o f raising finance. W hile many companies m aking rights issues specify th a t the issue is renounceable, sometimes a rights issue w ill be non-renounceable. I f a company makes a non-renounceable issue, shareholders cannot sell th e ir entitlem ent to take up new shares. The only choices available to them are to exercise th eir entitlem ent, either fu lly or partly, or to p e rm it it to lapse.26 I f investors take the la tte r choices the issue w ill be undersubscribed. For this reason non-renounceable issues are frequently underw ritten. As noted earlier, the m arket often interprets the announcement o f equity capital issues, including rights issues, as ‘bad’ news. Balachandran, Faff and Theobald (2008) found an average abnormal return o f -1 .7 4 per cent over a 3-day announcement period fo r a sample o f 636 rights issues by Australian companies from 1995 to 2005. I f the term s o f an issue such as whether the issue is renounceable or und erw ritte n also convey info rm a tio n to investors, then the price response to issue announcements may differ between rights issues w ith different terms. Balachandran, Faff and Theobald found th a t there is no difference between the average m arket reaction to renounceable and non-renounceable issues b ut the reaction to rights issue announcements is related to the u nd erw riting status o f the issue. Alm ost 60 per cent o f the issues in th e ir sample were fu lly und erw ritte n and the average abnormal retu rn associated w ith announcement o f these issues was -1.0 4 per cent, b ut fo r non-underw ritten issues the average abnormal retu rn was -2.23 per cent. As discussed in Section 9.5.6, underw riters are seen as certifying the value or quality* o f the securities being offered. When deciding whether to have an issue underw ritten, issuers w ill consider the benefits th a t u nd e rw ritin g provides relative to the cost o f the u nd erw rite rs fee. The fee w ill be related to the risk o f undersubscription and w ill reflect any costs th a t the underw riter incurs in assessing th a t risk. This is likely to include the costs o f investigating the current financial position and the prospects o f the issuer. Thus, a decision to fu lly underw rite an issue w ill typically be associated w ith low risk and/or low investigation costs and is associated w ith a smaller negative m arket reaction. Where the risk and/ or investigation costs are higher, issuers may choose to accept the risk o f undersubscription rather than pay an underw riting fee. N ot surprisingly, w ith o u t an u n d erw rite rs certification, the m arket reaction is more negative. That is n ot to suggest th a t certification by a reputable underw riter guarantees the success o f a capital raising. To illustrate this point, consider the announcement o f a proposed $225 m illio n 6:7 entitlem ent offer by Billabong International Ltd in June 2012. The issue was jo in tly u nd erw ritte n by Goldman Sachs and Deutsche Bank, and was priced at a significant 44 per cent discount to the pre-announcement share 26 I g n o r in g tr a n s a c t io n c o s t s , th e c h o ic e s a v a ila b le to s h a r e h o ld e r s a r e n o t r e d u c e d b y a r ig h t s is s u e b e in g n o n - r e n o u n c e a b le r a t h e r t h a n re n o u n c e a b le . I f a n is s u e is n o n - r e n o u n c e a b le , s h a r e h o ld e r s c a n t a k e u p th e r ig h t s a n d th e n r e a lis e t h e ir v a lu e b y s e llin g t h e s h a r e s o b ta in e d . C hapter n in e S ources price. The m arket responded very negatively to the announcement, w ith Billabong shares closing down 48 per cent when the m arket reopened. A lthough the share price subsequently recovered slightly, to be above the proposed subscription price, approximately 49 per cent o f retail investors s till chose n ot to participate in the issue, leaving the underw riters to purchase the rem aining 33.2 m illio n shares. In an amazing example o f managerial o ptim ism the CEO o f Billabong, Launa Inman, issued a statement on the company s behalf stating that <rThe company is pleased by the support shown by our retail shareholders fo r the Entitlem ent Offer. The Retail E ntitlem ent O ffer completes an im p o rta n t capital raising fo r Billabong, allowing the Company to focus on the next phase o f its strategy’.27 As at February 2014, Billabong shares were trading at about a 30 per cent discount to the subscription price o f the retail offer. Traditional and accelerated rights issues One disadvantage o f a trad ition al renounceable rights issue is th a t it is a relatively slow way o f raising funds. W hile the ASX has revised its timetables to shorten the offer period, a trad ition al renounceable rights issue cannot be completed in fewer than 23 business days. A non-renounceable issue is potentially quicker since no rights trading period is required, b u t i t is s till slower than a share placement. The traditional rights issue structure has been adapted to allow companies to raise funds more quickly. The ASX commonly grants waivers o f its listin g rules to allow companies to make non-traditional or Accelerated* rights issues. These issues involve tw o stages: an in itia l accelerated offer o f shares to institutio ns and a second offer to retail shareholders.28 The structures used fo r these issues include: • • • Accelerated Non-Renounceable E ntitlem ent O ffer (or 'JumboO structure. A non-renounceable pro­ rata offer is made to in s titu tio n a l shareholders over a period o f 1 or 2 business days. The issue price may be determined by an in s titu tio n a l book-build or i t may be fixed p rio r to the announcement of the issue. In the second stage, a non-renounceable pro-rata offer is made to retail shareholders at the same price as the first-stage pro-rata offer. Accelerated Renounceable E ntitlem ent O ffer (AREO), which differs fro m the Uumbo* structure in two ways: the offer is renounceable and the procedure involves two book-builds. In the firs t stage, eligible in stitu tio n a l shareholders may subscribe fo r th e ir pro-rata e ntitlem ent to new shares at a fixed offer price. Any shares n o t taken up by in s titu tio n a l shareholders are then offered to other in stitu tio n a l investors through a book-build— so there is no trading o f rights on the exchange and any entitlem ents th a t are renounced are sold off-m arket1. The second stage is a pro-rata entitlem ent offer to retail shareholders at the same fixed offer price as the in s titu tio n a l entitlem ent offer. Retail shareholders w ill be provided w ith details o f the offer in a prospectus or offer booklet and w ill usually have about 2 weeks to decide whether to take up th e ir entitlem ents. Finally, a second bookbuild is undertaken where any shares not taken up by retail shareholders are offered to in s titu tio n a l investors. I f the prices established in either o f the book-builds exceed the fixed offer price, the excess is paid to the shareholders who did n ot take up th e ir entitlem ents. Simultaneous Accelerated Renounceable E ntitlem ent O ffer (SAREO), which is essentially the same as the AREO structure except th a t any renounced entitlem ents are sold through a single bookbuild. This book-build is open only to in s titu tio n a l investors and is carried out after b oth o f the entitlem ent offers have been completed, so it ensures th a t each group o f investors receives the same price for any entitlem ents they renounce. While accelerated rights issues can differ in significant details, all such issues have one im p orta nt feature: the proceeds o f the in s titu tio n a l component w ill be received very soon after the issue is launched. For a company w ith large in s titu tio n a l shareholdings, the proceeds o f the in s titu tio n a l offer w ill make up the m ajority o f the issue proceeds, so the outcome is, to a large extent, sim ilar to m aking a placement. Because the tim e period involved is short, the risk o f a significant sh ortfa ll is lower than fo r a trad ition al rights issue, so the cost o f u n d e rw ritin g should also be lower. Im portantly, the accelerated structures allow funds to be raised quickly w hile retail shareholders can s till participate in the capital raising. Also, renounceable rights issues are regarded as the m ost equitable because shareholders who choose not to participate can realise some value by selling th e ir rights. However, the accelerated structures do 27 A S X A n n o u n c e m e n t, 'B illa b o n g c o m p le t e s $ 2 2 5 m illio n c a p it a l r a isin g *, 2 0 J u l y 2 0 1 2 . 28 A m e n d m e n ts to th e C o rp o ratio n s A c t in 2 0 0 7 in t r o d u c e d a n e w d e fin itio n o f l i g h t s 1 is s u e , w h ich r e q u ir e s t h a t th e t e r m s o f su c h a n is s u e m u s t b e th e s a m e f o r a ll s h a r e h o ld e r s . S in c e a c c e le r a te d is s u e s in v o lv e d iffe r e n t t e r m s fo r in s t it u t io n a l a n d r e ta il s h a r e h o ld e r s th e y d o n o t c o n fo r m t o t h is d e f in it io n a n d a r e m o r e c o r r e c tly d e s c r ib e d a s e n t it le m e n t o ff e r s . F o r e a s e o f e x p o s it io n w e u s e th e t e r m r ig h t s is s u e to e n c o m p a s s b o t h t r a d it io n a l r ig h t s is s u e s a n d a c c e le r a te d is s u e s . of f in a n c e : equity not necessarily ensure th a t all shareholders are treated fairly. First, the tim e allowed fo r completion of the in s titu tio n a l component can disadvantage shareholders who do n o t have sufficient funds available to take up th e ir fu ll entitlem ents at short notice. Second, the AREO structure w ith tw o separate bookbuilds means th a t any prem ium d istributed to shareholders who renounce th e ir entitlem ents can differ depending on whether the shareholder is an in s titu tio n a l or retail investor. The SAREO structure addresses the la tte r concern b u t may n o t provide a perfect solution because it means th a t in stitu tio n a l shareholders who sell1th e ir rights have to w ait fo r some weeks to find out w hat price they w ill receive. F in a n c e in ACTION UNDERWRITER BUYS SHARES TO PROVIDE IMMEDIATE FUNDING_____________________________________________________ New sC ^^ In s o m e c a s e s it is im p o r t a n t f o r th e is s u e r t o re c e iv e a ll o f th e fu n d s b y a c e r t a in d a t e a n d th is c a n b e a c h ie v e d b y e x te n d in g th e r o le o f th e u n d e r w r it e r to in c lu d e th e p r o v is io n o f s h o rt-te rm f u n d in g . F o r e x a m p le , o n 9 M a r c h 2 0 0 7 , S u n c o r p - M e t w a y Ltd a n n o u n c e d a 2 - f o r - 1 5 e n title m e n t = 1 o f f e r to ra is e a p p r o x im a t e ly $ 1 . 1 7 b illio n f r o m s h a r e h o ld e r s . T h e p u r p o s e o f th e is s u e w a s to p a r t ia lly fu n d th e c a s h c o m p o n e n t o f th e c o n s id e r a t io n p a y a b le b y S u n c o r p - M e t w a y in c o n n e c tio n w ith its th e n p r o p o s e d m e r g e r w ith P r o m in a Ltd. T h e S u n c o r p - M e t w a y issu e w a s d iv id e d in to in s titu tio n a l a n d r e ta il o ffe r s , e a c h f o llo w e d b y a n in s titu tio n a l b o o k - b u ild . T h e m e r g e r in v o lv e d a S c h e m e o f A r r a n g e m e n t t h a t w a s s u b je c t to c o u r t a p p r o v a l a t a h e a r in g s c h e d u le d to ta k e p la c e o n 1 2 M a r c h 2 0 0 7 . O n c e th e c o u r t a p p r o v e d th e s c h e m e , S u n c o r p - M e t w a y h a d a n o b lig a t io n to m a k e p a y m e n ts to P r o m in a s h a r e h o ld e r s , so it n e e d e d a c c e s s to th e issu e p r o c e e d s s h o r tly a ft e r th e c o u r t h e a r in g . T h is w a s a c h ie v e d b y n e g o tia t in g a n u n d e r w r it in g a g r e e m e n t w h e r e b y th e u n d e r w r it e r , C it ig r o u p G lo b a l M a r k e ts A u s t r a lia , s u b s c r ib e d f o r a ll o f th e n e w s h a re s t h a t w e r e o f f e r e d f o r s a le . T h e n e w s h a re s w e r e th e n t r a n s fe r r e d b y C it ig r o u p to s h a r e h o ld e r s w h o c h o s e t o t a k e u p t h e ir e n title m e n ts a n d to in v e s to rs w h o a c q u ir e d s h a re s t h r o u g h th e t w o b o o k - b u ild s . T h e c a p it a l r a is in g w a s c o m p le te d w ith th e s e c o n d b o o k - b u ild o n 1 3 A p r i l 2 0 0 7 b u t S u n c o r p M e t w a y h a d re c e iv e d th e fu ll p r o c e e d s f r o m C it ig r o u p o n 1 2 M a r c h . O f c o u r s e , th e u n d e r w r it in g a g r e e m e n t r e q u ir e d S u n c o r p - M e t w a y to p a y a d a ily f u n d in g fe e r e p r e s e n tin g in te re s t o n th e fu n d s t h a t it e ffe c tiv e ly b o r r o w e d fr o m th e u n d e r w r ite r . 9 .6 .2 1 Placements (private issues) PLACEMENT an issue of securities direct to chosen investors rather than the ge neral public A placem ent o f ordinary shares is a new issue o f shares made to a lim ite d number o f investors. These issues are typically made to larger in s titu tio n s such as life insurance companies and investm ent funds. Such organisations are m ajor holders o f Australian shares and have become the prim e targets for placements because they have large sums to invest. Hence, a significant am ount o f capital can be raised quickly by making a placement to a small num ber o f in s titu tio n s o r to a single in s titu tio n . Details o f some recent placements are shown in Table 9.6. TABLE 9.6 Details of selected placements 2013-14 Am ount C om pany D a te a n n o u n c e d i ra is e d ($ m ) Issue p r ic e as % o f P ric in g a n d p re -a n n o u n c e m e n t m a rk e t p ric e issue m e th o d The Reject Shop A pril 2013 30 96.9 Underwritten ERM Power November 2013 75 93.4 Underwritten Insurance Australia Group December 2013 1200 96.2 Underwritten Alumina February 2014 452 103.0 S o u rce : C o m p ile d from c o m p a n y announcem ents. Issue to a single investor C hapter n in e S ources In some cases the shares are purchased by another company rather than by financial institutio ns, often as part o f the form ation o f a strategic alliance between tw o companies whose businesses are related. For example, in December 2006, Queensland Gas Company (QGC) entered in to an agreement w ith AGL Energy under which AGL Energy purchased a 27.5 per cent ownership interest in QGC fo r $327 m illion. The two companies also entered in to a 20-year gas supply agreement and AGL Energy was entitled to appoint three directors on the QGC board. A company m aking a placement w ill usually n o t be required to issue a disclosure document. Placements usually involve offers o f securities to sophisticated and in s titu tio n a l investors. As discussed in Section 9.4.3, these offers o f securities do n o t require a disclosure document. Many placements are underw ritten, p articularly where the issue is large and /or the new shares are distributed to many investors. Where an issue is n o t underw ritten, the company m aking the issue generally uses the services o f a broker or investm ent bank to assist in placing the shares w ith investors. The broker is n ot obliged to dispose o f all the shares: the brokers task is best described as undertaking the placement o f the shares on a ‘best-efforts’ basis. U nd erw ritin g fees fo r share placements are influenced by several factors, including the absolute size o f the placement, the size, liq u id ity and perceived m arket risk o f the issuing company and the reason fo r raising the equity. For example, a placement to fund a profitable acquisition w ill involve lower m arket risk, and lower fees, than one th a t is needed to recapitalise a company whose financial leverage has become excessive. The fees fo r arranging and/or u nd erw riting a placement are usually n o t disclosed. Macquarie Capital Advisers Lim ited has indicated th a t fo r placements by ASX-listed companies, u nd e rw ritin g fees can range from around 1 per cent to 5 per cent o f the gross offer proceeds. It has become common fo r larger placements to in s titu tio n s to be priced using the book-building process and in some cases the managers o f the book-build may also underw rite the issue. For example, in November 2006, O rigin Energy raised $400 m illio n by a placement th a t was priced using a book-build and also underw ritten by the two investm ent banks th a t conducted the book-build. U nderw ritin g may be preferred when a company has entered in to a com m itm ent th a t creates a specific need fo r additional funds. In the case o f the O rigin Energy placement, the proceeds were used to p a rtly fund the acquisition o f a gas retailing business th a t O rigin had agreed to purchase from the Queensland Government. There has been considerable opposition from shareholders to companies m aking placements o f shares. Some shareholders may oppose placements because they reduce the percentage o f ownership and voting power o f existing shareholders. Also, some shareholders may believe th a t they are being deprived o f a possible p ro fit from the sale o f the rights. However, we have already shown th a t the retu rn that shareholders receive from the sale o f rights represents, in effect, a retu rn o f a p o rtio n o f th e ir investm ent in the company. More im p orta ntly, i f the placement is made to new shareholders at a price below the current m arket price, there is a reduction in the value o f the existing shareholders’ investment. The ASX has placed a general lim it o f 15 per cent on the am ount o f capital th a t a company can issue privately in any 1 year w ith o u t the p rio r approval o f its shareholders.29 However, it is n o t d ifficu lt to exceed this lim it w ith o u t viola ting the ASX rules. A fte r m aking a placement th a t falls w ith in the 15 per cent lim it, a company w ill often have the placement ratified by shareholders. Ratification o f a placement ‘refreshes’ the company’s capacity to raise capital because it means th a t the placement w ill n o t be included when assessing the company s a b ility to make a future placement. In other words, a company may make two or more placements in a 12-m onth period, provided each placement increases its issued capital by less than 15 per cent and each placement is ratified by shareholders before the next placement occurs. Also, the ASX has allowed larger placements in cases where i t is confident th a t a company s issued capital is about to be increased by another share issue. In such cases, the ASX is w illin g to apply the 15 per cent lim it to the expanded capital base rather than to the existing issued capital. For example, a company that is comm itted to m aking a fu lly und erw ritte n 1 -fo r-l e ntitlem ent offer could obtain a waiver o f the '15 per cent rule, th a t allows i t to make a placement o f 30 per cent o f its issued capital p rio r to the entitlem ent offer (ISS Governance Services, 2010, p. 13). 29 S e e R u le s 7 .1 a n d 7 .2 o f th e A u s t r a lia n S e c u r it ie s E x c h a n g e L is t in g R u le s, w h ich p r o v id e t h a t , in g e n e r a l, o n ly 1 5 p e r c e n t o f a c o m p a n y s is s u e d s h a r e c a p it a l m a y b e is s u e d t o n o n - s h a r e h o ld e r s w ith o u t th e p r io r a p p r o v a l o f s h a r e h o ld e r s a t a g e n e r a l m e e tin g . T h ere a re e x c e p tio n s to t h is r u le t h a t r e la te sp e c ific a lly t o s m a ll a n d m id - siz e c o m p a n ie s w ith m a r k e t c a p it a lis a t io n s le s s t h a n $ 3 0 0 m illio n . of fin a n c e : equity B usiness finance CONTRIBUTING SHARES shares on w hich only part of the issue price has been paid. A lso known as p a 厂 f/y pa/c/ shares INSTALMENT RECEIPT marketable security for w hich on ly part of the issue price has been paid. The balance is p a y a b le in a final instalment on As discussed in Section 9.2, con tributing sh ares, also known as p a rtly paid shares, are shares on which only p a rt o f the issue price has been paid. The issuing company can call up the unpaid part o f the issue price in one or more instalments (known as calls*) and, in the case o f a lim ite d lia b ility company, the holder has a legal obligation to pay these calls. C ontributing shares are quite common in Australia and can be used to provide a company w ith a reliable source o f funds. The unpaid am ount is referred to as Reserve capital1and the shares can be created by a rights issue where the issue price is to be contributed in stages at specified times. Many co ntribu ting shares are issued by m ining and oil exploration companies, which make calls when additional funds are required. C ontributing shares can be im p o rta n t in raising capital b ut the amounts involved are typically small in comparison to other sources o f equity.30 Typically, in stalm en t receipts are issued when existing fu lly paid shares are offered to the public, w ith the sale price to be paid in two instalments. A ll three sales by the Australian Government o f shares in Telstra Ltd involved instalm ent receipts. For example, in the case o f the th ird Telstra share offer in November 2006, retail investors paid a firs t instalm ent o f $2 w ith a second instalm ent o f $1.60 payable by 29 May 2008. Partly paid shares and instalm ent receipts are very sim ilar b ut there are some im p orta nt differences between them. These differences include: or before a specified date • • • fo r instalm ent receipts, the amount and tim in g o f all instalm ents are specified at the tim e o f the original sale rather than being at the discretion o f directors instalm ents are payable to the vendor o f the shares rather than to the issuing company holders o f instalm ent receipts are usually e ntitled to the same dividends as holders o f fu lly paid shares, whereas holders o f p artly paid shares usually receive a p artial dividend based on the p roportion o f the issue price th a t has been paid. Companies listed on the ASX are p erm itted to raise lim ite d amounts o f funds from existing shareholders through share purchase plans (SPPs). These issues do n o t require a prospectus provided they comply w ith ASIC Regulatory Guide 125, which requires th a t SPPs are accompanied by a cleansing notice. ASIC recognises th a t the costs o f preparing and d istrib u tin g a prospectus could be very high relative to the benefits when the risk to investors is lim ite d because the am ount th a t can be invested is restricted. Accordingly, the am ount th a t a listed company can raise in this way is restricted to $15 000 per annum from each shareholder. Share purchase plans may be attractive to shareholders because the subscription price m ust be less than the m arket price p rio r to the announcement o f the issue and there is no brokerage. As discussed in Section 9.6.6’ share purchase plans are sometimes used in conjunction w ith an in s titu tio n a l placement, giving all existing shareholders the o p p o rtu n ity to purchase additional shares at the price paid by the in stitu tio n s th a t took up the placement. An o ption to purchase the shares o f a company gives the holder o f that option the rig h t to take up shares in the company by a specified date on predeterm ined term s.31 For example, a company may issue, at no cost, 10000 options th a t may be exercised by the payment o f $1 per option during the next 5 years. Consequently, option holders can purchase a m axim um o f 10 000 shares fo r $1 each at any tim e during the next 5 years, regardless o f th e ir m arket price at the tim e. The option holder therefore has the o pp ortu nity to benefit from an increase in the m arket price o f the company s shares. I f the company s share price 30 C o n t r ib u t in g s h a r e s c a n a ls o b e is s u e d t o d ir e c t o r s a n d o t h e r s a s p a r t o f a c o m p e n s a t io n p a c k a g e . T h is u s e o f c o n tr ib u t in g 31 A n im p o r t a n t d iffe re n c e b e tw e e n th e o p t io n s d is c u s s e d h e r e a n d th e e x c h a n g e - t r a d e d o p t io n s d is c u s s e d in C h a p t e r 1 8 is th a t s h a r e s is a n a ly s e d b y B ro w n a n d H a th a w a y ( 1 9 9 1 ). t h is s e c t io n d is c u s s e s o p t io n s is s u e d b y th e c o m p a n ie s t h e m s e lv e s . In c o n t r a s t , a n e x c h a n g e - t r a d e d o p t io n is c r e a te d b y a c o n tr a c t b e tw e e n tw o in v e s t o r s a n d d o e s n o t in v o lv e th e c o m p a n y w h o se s h a r e s u n d e r lie t h e o p t io n . T h a t is , u p o n e x e r c ise o f a c o m p a n y - is s u e d o p t io n , th e c o m p a n y c r e a t e s a n d i s s u e s n e w s h a r e s , w h e r e a s w h e n a n e x c h a n g e - t r a d e d o p t io n is e x e r c ise d , o n ly e x is t in g s h a r e s c h a n g e o w n e r s h ip a n d n o n e w s h a r e s a r e c r e a te d . C hapter n in e S ources increases to $1.20, then option holders can purchase 10000 shares fo r $10000, which is $2000 below their current m arket value. There are three m ajor provisions included in an option agreement: • • • the exercise price o f the option the period during which the options may be exercised the rights o f option holders in the event o f new issues o f shares by the company. In general, it is usual fo r the exercise price o f an option to be set near the share price at the tim e the option is issued. The term o f an option may extend fo r several years and, other things being equal, a long-term option is more valuable than a short-term option. In the case o f company-issued options, the option holder is often prevented from exercising the option fo r a certain period after it has been granted. I f a company makes an issue o f shares during the o ptio ns life, it is possible fo r the value o f the option to be reduced to almost zero. For example, i f a company splits each o f its shares in to two, other things being equal, the price per share w ill be halved. In tu rn , this w ill result in a corresponding reduction in the benefit that the option holder w ill receive from any subsequent increase in the share price. As a result, option agreements usually provide holders w ith the rig h t to participate in share issues by the company during the life o f the option. Options may be issued as follows: To employees. The objective when m aking o ption issues is to reward employees in a way th a t is likely to encourage them to w ork towards im proving the company s profitability. Such issues are typically made w ith an exercise price equal to the current share price, which does n ot expose the employee to any immediate tax obligation. I f the company becomes more profitable, it is likely to command a higher share price, which, in tu rn , w ill increase the value o f the option, b As a sweetener to an equity issue. Many exploration and m in ing companies issue both ordinary shares and options to subscribe fo r additional shares. For example, an investor purchasing 1000 shares in a new issue may also receive 1000 options, each o f which entitles the investor to buy one additional share at a fixed price before a specified date. Frequently these options are listed separately on the stock exchange. Therefore, an investor obtains the o p p o rtu n ity to make an additional gain from an increase in the company s share price. A company th a t issues shares accompanied by options hopes to encourage investors to participate in the issue, thereby reducing the possibility o f undersubscription. c As a sweetener to a private debt issue. On occasions, a company seeking debt finance w ill offer share options to the lender. The company benefits either by obtaining debt finance th a t i t would not otherwise have received o r by obtaining the funds on better term s— fo r example, at a lower interest rate. However, neither p arty to an agreement o f this type w ill make the options conditional on the granting o f the loan because this may jeopardise the tax d eductibility o f interest on the debt. a In the cases outlined above, i t is evident th a t options are n ot issued p rim a rily as a means o f raising finance, although they are often issued as p art o f a finance package. Nevertheless, significant sums can be raised when company-issued options are exercised. 9.6.6 | Choosing between equity-raising methods The previous sections have outlined several external methods to raise equity funds, including rights issues, placements, share purchase plans, calls on p a rtly paid shares and the exercise o f company-issued options. M ost o f these methods involve long-term arrangements and i f a significant ‘one-off’ equity raising is needed, it w ill involve a rights issue a nd/or a placement o f shares. W hat factors influence the choice between these methods? Chan and Brown (2004) studied this question using Australian data from July 1996 to March 2001, a period in which the ASX increased the annual ceiling fo r placements w ith o u t shareholder agreement* from 10 per cent to 15 per cent o f ordinary share capital. They found th a t the ceiling imposed by the lis tin g rules has a strong effect on company behaviour, w ith a significant tendency fo r the issue size to be chosen so th a t i t falls just under the prescribed ceiling. As expected, placements w ith o u t shareholder agreement* became more common after the ceiling was increased to 15 per cent and it was rare fo r companies to make rights issues where of f in a n c e : equity B usiness finance the am ount o f funds raised was less than the ceiling fo r placements. Where the am ount o f funds sought exceeded the prescribed ceiling, it was more common fo r companies to make a placement w ith shareholder agreement than to make a rights issue. In summary, th e ir m ain conclusion was th a t companies generally prefer placements to rights issues. A part from the influence o f any ceiling imposed by stock exchange lis tin g rules, the m ain advantages o f placements are speed (funds can be raised in a few days rather than weeks), certainty (a placement may be u nd erw ritte n and, given th a t the risk o f a shortfall exists fo r only a short period, i t should n ot be d ifficu lt to obtain the support o f an underw riter), lower transaction costs and the shares may be placed w ith investors considered to be frien dly* to the existing management. Rights issues have the advantage that shareholders can preserve th e ir ownership proportions and voting power. Thus, rights issues are seen as being more equitable to existing shareholders. A rights issue may require a prospectus and is slower than a placement, but, as noted in Section 9.6.1, fo r companies w ith m ostly in s titu tio n a l shareholders, the m a jo rity o f the funds raised by a rights issue can be received quickly i f one o f the accelerated offer structures is used. C om bination issues As noted above, where the am ount o f funds sought is below the ceiling fo r a placement w ith o u t shareholder agreement,, companies almost invariably opt fo r a placement rather than a rights issue. Where the am ount o f funds sought is above the ceiling, a rights issue may be chosen b ut the choice involved is n ot sim ply lig h ts issue versus placement w ith shareholder agreement'. Rather, the company may make a placement in combination w ith another m ethod o f equity raising, such as a share purchase plan or a nonrenounceable rights issue. Where these com bination issues are used, the placement component is almost invariably just under the 15 per cent ceiling so th a t shareholder agreement is n ot required. Another feature o f combination issues is th a t the placement is often priced using an in s titu tio n a l book-build. The issue price established by the book-build is then used to determine the price o f the shares fo r the second component o f the issue. Since retail shareholders have the o pp o rtu n ity to participate in the capital raising at the same price as institutio ns, this approach addresses the concern th a t a placement alone discriminates against those shareholders who are n o t invited to participate. Com bination issues involving a placement and an SPP in close p ro xim ity have become common. W hile the placement/SPP combination may be appealing as a way o f accommodating small shareholders, it has been criticised as being far less equitable to small shareholders than a rights issue. The critics make two main points. First, the lim it o f $15 000 per shareholder fo r share purchase plans means th a t the b ulk o f new shares is issued to institutio ns. Second, i f the SPP price is set at a large discount to the m arket price, demand w ill be high and retail investors can end up w ith much less than th e ir $15 000 entitlement*. This problem arose w ith the issues by O rigin Energy, which started w ith a $400 m illion placement to in stitu tio n s in November 2006. The issue price was $7.10 per share, which represented a discount o f about 2.5 per cent to the m arket price at the tim e. A t the same tim e, O rigin announced th a t it would raise additional funds on sim ilar term s through an SPP early in 2007. The details announced in January 2007 included a target o f $75 m illio n fo r the SPP. By the closing date fo r applications, the m arket price o f O rigin shares had increased to about $9. N ot surprisingly, many shareholders applied to purchase shares, w ith the result th a t allocations were scaled back to a m axim um o f 200 shares per shareholder. A nother type o f com bination involves three offers o f shares: a placement, an in s titu tio n a l entitlem ent offer and a retail entitlem ent offer. For example, Alesco Corporation used this approach to raise a total o f $193 m illio n in July and August 2007. The closing price o f Alesco shares on 23 July was $13.96, after which the company announced the acquisition o f another business and details o f an associated capital raising, including an in s titu tio n a l placement w ith the issue price to be determ ined by a book-build w ith an indicative price range o f $12.10 to $12.80 per share. The capital raising also included an in stitu tio n a l e ntitle m e nt offer and a non-renounceable und erw ritte n l-fo r-9 rights issue (retail entitlem ent offer). It was announced th a t the issue price fo r both o f these offers would be set equal to the price set fo r the in s titu tio n a l placement. On 26 July, the company announced th a t the issue price had been set at the top o f the book-build price range at $12.80 per share and th a t the in s titu tio n a l offers were *strongly oversubscribed’. On 23 August, Alesco announced th a t its retail e ntitlem ent offer had raised approximately $61 m illio n in addition to the am ount o f approximately $132 m illio n raised from in s titu tio n s in late July. The company stated th a t the retail offer had been ^strongly supported by existing shareholders w ith over C hapter n in e S ources of fin a n c e : equity 60 per cent o f the rights being taken up by eligible shareholders1. The approach used by Alesco has been used by several other companies, including Asciano Group, which raised $2.35 b illio n in June 2009, and Graincorp, which raised about $600 m illio n in October 2009. W hile it is n ot very common, i t is also possible to combine an issue to existing shareholders w ith a public offer o f shares. This approach may be favoured i f the company wishes to attract a wider spread o f shareholders, or i f the am ount o f funds sought is large relative to the size o f the company. For example, in October 2007, Essential Petroleum Resources Ltd (EPR) (see Finance in Action), a small explorer w ith a market capitalisation o f less than $20 m illion , made a l-fo r-2 non-renounceable rights issue and a public offer to raise a total o f $10 m illio n .32 ESSENTIAL PETROLEUM MAKES RIGHTS ISSUE A N D PUBLIC OFFER E s s e n tia l P e tro le u m h a s n 't e x a c t ly s e t th e w o r ld o n f ir e s in c e its F e b r u a r y 2 0 0 1 Finance in ACTION lis tin g . F r id a y ’s c lo s in g p r ic e o f 5 . 5 c e n ts a s h a r e te lls a s m u c h . B u t p a t ie n c e w it h th e O t w a y B a s in o il a n d g a s e x p lo r e r , lik e t h a t s h o w n b y th e g r o u p ’ s b ig g e s t s h a r e h o ld e r , f o r m e r JB W e r e re s o u rc e s g u r u P e te r W o o d f o r d , m ig h t ju s t d e liv e r s o m e b ig r e w a r d s in 2 0 0 8 . M a n a g in g d ir e c t o r J o h n R e m fry h a s w o r k e d th e g r o u p in to a p o s it io n w h e r e it w i ll b e a s to c k t o w a t c h n e x t y e a r a s it sets a b o u t d r illin g n e a r-te rm d e v e lo p m e n t o p p o r t u n it ie s in th e o n s h o r e O t w a y w h ile a ls o c h a s in g u p th e b ig - t im e p o t e n t ia l o f its o f f s h o r e p e r m its , f la n k in g w h a t E s s e n tia l r e c k o n s c o u ld b e th e n e x t m a jo r h y d r o c a r b o n p r o v in c e — th e D is c o v e r y B a y ' H i g h 7 o f f s h o r e fr o m P o r tla n d in w e s te r n V ic t o r ia . A n o t h e r g e o lo g ic a l f e a tu r e , th e P e c te n 'H i g h 7 o f f s h o r e fr o m P o rt C a m p b e ll h a s a l r e a d y b e e n p r o v e n a s a h y d r o c a r b o n f a ir w a y . E s s e n tia l re c k o n s t h a t b a c k a t th e b i g g e r D is c o v e r y B a y H ig h , th e p o t e n t ia l in its p e r m its is f o r m o r e th a n 5 t r illio n c u b ic f e e t o f r e c o v e r a b le g a s a n d m o re th a n 2 b illio n b a r r e ls o f r e c o v e r a b le o il. T h a t ’s b ig t a lk f r o m a c o m p a n y o f E s s e n tia T s s iz e , b u t w e l l s o o n k n o w i f it 7s h o t a i r o r n o t. T h a t's b e c a u s e E s s e n tia l is p u llin g in $ 1 0 m illio n fr o m a $ 6 m illio n r ig h ts is s u e ( u n d e r w r it t e n b y B e ll P o tte r a n d C o m s e c ) a n d $ 4 m illio n fr o m a p u b lic o f f e r a t 4 c e n ts a s h a r e . A t th e is s u e p r ic e , th e g r o u p 's m a r k e t c a p it a lis a t io n w i ll b e a ll o f $ 2 2 m illio n . S o u rc e : 2 9 'After a few quiet years, Essential m a y prove it h a s all the ingredie nts,/ B a rry Fitzgerald, The A g e , O c to b e r 2 0 0 7 . Table 9.1 shows th a t listed companies have raised significant funds through employee share plans, although the prim ary purpose o f such plans is to m otivate senior managers and other employees by giving them an ownership interest in th e ir employer. There are several types o f employee share plans that have been used in Australia, including:3 33 2 • • 32 Fully paid share plans. Employees are able to purchase new or existing shares, usually at a discount from m arket value. The purchases are usually funded by loans from the company th a t are interestfree or at a low interest rate and dividends on the shares may be used to repay the loans. Sometimes there is a provision to w rite o ff the loans i f the company fails. Partly paid share plans. The shares issued to employees are in itia lly p a rtly paid and converted to fu lly paid shares by a series o f calls. In this case employees can be liable fo r calls i f the company fails before the shares are fu lly paid. In th e y e a r t o 3 0 J u n e 2 0 0 8 , E P R r e c o r d e d a n e t lo s s o f $ 1 0 .9 m illio n a n d in th e fo llo w in g y e a r a fu r t h e r lo s s o f a lm o s t $ 2 4 .8 m illio n . In F e b r u a r y 2 0 1 0 , it s s h a r e h o ld e r s a p p r o v e d a c a p it a l r e s t r u c t u r e w h e r e b y d e b t o b lig a t io n s o f $ 2 3 m illio n w ere c o n v e r te d in t o e q u it y o r fo r g iv e n . F o llo w in g th e r e s t r u c t u r e , 5 1 .9 p e r c e n t o f th e c o m p a n y s v o t in g s h a r e s w e re h e ld b y B e a c h E n e r g y L t d , a n e w b o a r d w a s a p p o in t e d a n d t h e c o m p a n y ’s n a m e c h a n g e d t o S o m e r t o n E n e r g y L td . 33 C h a r a c te r istic s o f th e v a r io u s t y p e s o f e m p lo y e e s h a r e p la n s a re d is c u s s e d in d e t a il b y S tr a d w ic k ( 1 9 9 6 ) . LEARNING OBJECTIVE 9 O utline the different types of em ployee share plans B usiness finance • • • Option plans. Under these plans employees in itia lly purchase (or are granted) an option to buy shares at some future tim e at a specified price. O ption plans involve a small in itia l outlay w ith potential for large capital gains i f the company is successful. Employee share trusts. Employees have an interest in a tru s t th a t holds shares in the employer company. The tru s t is norm ally funded by the employer. Employees who hold units in the tru s t can dispose o f the u nits only to other members o f the trust. Replicator plans. Replicator plans do n ot involve shares in the employer company. Instead, payments are made to employees based on the achievement o f certain performance criteria. For example, such a plan may involve phantom shares* w ith a price th a t is linked to the p ro fita b ility o f the company or to the performance o f a division. The popularity o f the various plans varies among different types o f employers. For example, in Australia the m a jo rity o f employee share plans are option plans and this type o f plan is p articularly popular as a way o f rewarding the senior executives o f large listed companies. Recent changes in the taxation treatm ent of employee share plans may encourage more widespread use o f plans o f other types fo r general staff. The use o f a tru s t structure can be attractive fo r private companies where there are restrictions on ownership o f shares in the company itself. Replicator plans are popular w ith unlisted companies, where i t is d ifficult to establish a m arket price fo r the shares, and can also be useful fo r relatively new businesses, where issuing shares would dilute the ownership and control o f the founders. Over the years the Commonwealth Government has sought to encourage employee share ownership by providing tax concessions in cases where shares or rights to shares are given to employees or issued to them at a discount. The tax status o f employee share plans has been subject to frequent change and some degree o f uncertainty. The provisions th a t apply to employee shares mean that, in general, any benefit to an employee under an employee share plan is taxable in the year in which the share or rig h t is acquired. Consequently, the difference between the m arket value o f a share and the consideration paid to acquire i t is assessable in the year o f acquisition. However, where the employee share scheme meets the conditions fo r classification as a ‘tax-deferred’ scheme, tax may be deferred to a later date. The m ain conditions fo r ‘tax-deferred’ status would generally be satisfied i f the shares have been purchased via a salary-sacrifice scheme or alternatively where the employee faces a *real risk o f forfeiture* o f the shares due to em ploym ent circumstances such as failing to meet performance hurdles or serving a m inim um term o f em ploym ent.34 Under the ASX Listing Rules a company m ust have a proposed employee share plan approved by shareholders and employees may even have to be provided w ith a prospectus i f the prim ary m otivation fo r the plan is fundraising as opposed to providing employees w ith the o pp o rtu n ity to participate in ownership o f the company. Given the complexity o f the taxation provisions and other regulatory requirements, the financial manager o f a company th a t introduces an employee share plan is likely to need specialised advice. 9.8 LEARNING OBJECTIVE 10 O u tline the a d va ntage s of internal funds a s a source of finance Internal funds So far we have discussed external sources o f equity finance. However, a company th a t is operating profitably w ill also generate funds internally. The relative importance o f interna l and external sources o f funds may be assessed using different measures o f in te rn a l funds*. One approach is to define internal equity finance as retained profits plus depreciation charges, where retained p ro fit is equal to accounting p ro fit after company tax, less dividends paid to shareholders. A problem w ith this approach is th a t a company cannot spend its accounting p ro fit— suppliers and employees m ust be paid w ith cash. In other words, the prim ary source o f interna l funding is cash p ro fit, which can differ significantly from accounting profit, which is prepared on an accrual basis. Cash p ro fit is reported by companies in th e ir cash flow statements. The cash flow statement is a funds statement th a t shows the sources and uses o f funds, where funds are defined as cash. A 2009 Reserve Bank o f Australia (RBA) analysis o f corporate sources and uses o f funds relied on data from these statements.35 The approach adopted by the RBA divides sources o f funds into two basic categories: interna l funding and external funding. Internal funding is equal to cash p ro fit— that 34 F o r fu r t h e r in fo r m a t io n o n th e t a x t r e a t m e n t o f e m p lo y e e s h a r e s c h e m e s s e e w w w .a t o .g o v .a u / G e n e r a l/ E m p lo y e e - s h a r e sc h e m e s/. 35 S e e R B A ( 2 0 0 9 ). C hapter n in e S ources is, cash received from customers and non-interest-bearing investments (e.g. dividends) less payments to suppliers, wages and salaries paid to employees and tax payments. Thus, cash p ro fit is measured before payment o f interest expense and any other financing charges and is n o t affected by depreciation. External funding comprises tw o sources: net debt and net equity, where net debt is equal to funds borrowed from intermediated (e.g. bank loans) and non-interm ediated (e.g. issuing corporate bonds) sources. Finally, net equity is equal to funds raised by issuing new shares, less cash paid o ut to repurchase shares. Funds may be used in three ways: investm ent in assets, payment o f dividends and payment o f interest. The use o f internal funds as a source o f finance has im p o rta n t advantages. Using interna l funds does not affect the control o f the company as it does n o t involve the company in issuing any additional shares. Therefore, using internal funds does n o t com m it the company to increased dividend payments in the future, w ith the result that no additional strain is placed on the company s cash resources. A fu rth e r advantage is that, unlike a new issue o f shares, internal funding involves no issue costs such as brokerage, fees paid to underw riters and other advisers or costs incurred in preparing a prospectus. Internal funds are a convenient source o f finance th a t does n ot involve any explicit costs such as transaction costs, but they are n ot a free source o f finance fo r a company. Internal funds generated by a company are invested by the company on its shareholders’ behalf. I t follows th a t internal funds have an o pportunity cost— th a t is, the funds could have been invested elsewhere by shareholders. Therefore, when a company uses internal funds, shareholders w ill n ot benefit unless the company is able to invest the funds profitably. This analysis is discussed in more detail in Chapter 14. The relative importance o f interna l funds in providing a company s to ta l financial requirements is related to the nature o f a company s business and can also vary considerably over tim e. Between 2003 and 2012, around 86 per cent o f funding fo r resource companies has been sourced internally, whereas only about 68 per cent o f funding fo r non-resource based companies comes from internal sources. Furthermore, both o f these percentages rose dramatically during the global financial crisis beginning in 2007 when external finance was increasingly hard to obtain. (Reserve Bank o f Australia, March 2013, p. 53). A dividend reinvestment plan (DRP) allows shareholders the choice o f using th e ir dividends to purchase additional shares instead o f receiving cash.36 The firs t DRPs were introduced by Australian companies in the early 1980s. W ith in 10 years, m ost o f Australia’s largest companies were offering such plans and reinvestment o f dividends has become a significant source o f equity fo r listed companies, particularly larger companies. The main reason fo r the popularity o f DRPs is related to the intro du ction o f the dividend im putation tax system, which caused investors to demand high dividend payouts. A dividend reinvestment plan allows a company to meet the demand fo r a high dividend payout w ith o u t straining its cash resources. Technically, investors who participate in a DRP receive the dividends and therefore obtain the tax benefits o f im putation, and then reinvest the cash in additional shares. This means that, for tax purposes, dividends can be considered as being paid* to investors w ith o u t any cash payment by the company. Provided the shares issued under a DRP are fu lly paid, there is no need fo r a prospectus and shares issued under a DRP are exempt from the *15 per cent in 12 m onths1capital raising lim it contained in the Listing Rules. DRPs are inflexible in th a t the tim in g o f any capital raising is tied to the tim in g o f dividend payments and may n o t provide a reliable source o f funds because participation by shareholders is voluntary. The la tte r problem can be overcome, at a cost, by having a company s DRP underw ritten. The main advantage o f DRPs centres on transaction costs: fo r many companies, the costs o f operating a DRP are lower than the costs involved in m aking rights issues and share placements to replace cash paid out as dividends. D uring the 2012-13 financial year, A ustralian-listed companies used DRPs to raise $6.9 b illion (Australian Financial Markets Association, 2013, p. 55). 36 A S X s t a t is t ic s in c lu d e d iv id e n d r e i n v e s t m e n t a s p a r t o f e q u it y r a is e d e x te rn a lly . H o w e v e r, w e d is c u s s D R P s in th e c o n te x t o f in t e r n a l fu n d s b e c a u s e d iv id e n d r e in v e s t m e n t la r g e ly in v o lv e s fu n d s t h a t c o m p a n ie s w o u ld h a v e r e ta in e d , b u t fo r th e h ig h e r d iv id e n d p a y o u t s n e e d e d t o t r a n s f e r f r a n k in g c r e d it s t o s h a r e h o ld e r s . In o t h e r w o r d s, e q u it y 'ra ise d * th r o u g h d iv id e n d r e in v e st m e n t is, in e ffe c t, in t e r n a l fu n d s t h a t h a v e b e e n <r e la b e lle d , a s e x t e r n a lly p r o v id e d . D iv id e n d r e in v e s t m e n t p la n s a re d is c u s s e d in m o re d e t a il in C h a p t e r 1 1 . of fin a n c e : equity 9.9 M a n a g in g a com pany’s equity structure In this chapter we have discussed the various sources o f equity individually. In practice, the financial manager w ill usually have a long-term plan fo r the management o f a company s capital structure, including its equity structure. The m ost im p o rta n t aspect o f such a plan involves the tim in g and amounts o f future capital raisings based on forecasts o f the company s cash flows, capital expenditures and loan repayments. As part o f this process, companies, equity structures are sometimes rearranged through procedures th a t change the number o f shares on issue w ith o u t either raising capital or returning capital to shareholders. These procedures— which include bonus issues, share splits and consolidations— are now considered. 9.9.1 | Bonus issues and share splits L E A R N IN G O B JEC TIVE 11 Outline the effects of bonus issues, share splits a n d share consolidation s A bonus issue is a ‘free’ issue o f shares made to existing shareholders in p ro p o rtio n to th e ir current investm ent. Bonus issues used to be common in Australia and were used as a way o f increasing the dividends paid to shareholders. A bonus issue is equivalent to a rights issue w ith a zero subscription price. In accounting terms, a company could make a bonus issue by using the balances o f reserves, such as a share premium reserve, and /or retained earnings— th a t is, p art o f a reserve is converted to issued capital b u t the to ta l o f shareholders’ funds remains unchanged. Regulatory changes, including the intro du ction o f the dividend im p utatio n tax system and the abolition o f par value fo r shares, removed any tax advantage associated w ith bonus issues. Accordingly, companies th a t have the capacity to pay higher dividends usually increase the rate o f dividend per existing share rather than making a bonus issue and m aintaining the same dividend rate. W hile bonus issues have virtu a lly disappeared from the Australian market, companies can achieve a sim ilar result by sp littin g th e ir shares. For example, a share s p lit th a t doubles the num ber o f a company s issued shares has the same effect fo r shareholders as a 1 -fo r-l bonus issue. Australian companies that have made share splits since 2002 include Toll Holdings, W H K Group, CSL Lim ited, Incitec Pivot and Fortescue Metals Group. A bonus issue or share sp lit involves no cash flow — apart from the adm inistration costs involved— and should n o t have any effect on shareholders’ wealth. Therefore, i f a company makes, say, a 1 -fo r-l bonus issue, the num ber o f shares on issue w ill double and the m arket price o f each share should decrease by half, leaving unchanged the to ta l m arket value o f the shares held by each investor. The Australian evidence is consistent w ith this expectation— th a t is, bonus issues do n o t affect shareholders1wealth.37 A lthough a bonus issue— by its e lf— would n o t be expected to have an im pact upon shareholder wealth, the in fo rm a tio n contained w ith in the announcement o f a bonus issue may result in a significant change in wealth. Bonus issues and share splits are typically made by companies th a t have been perform ing well and th a t have recently experienced significant increases in share price. Investors are aware that, follow ing a bonus o r split, companies usually do n o t reduce dividends per share to the extent necessary to m aintain the same to ta l dividend payout. For example, after a 1 -fo r-l bonus issue, a company currently paying a dividend o f 10 cents per share would need to pay a dividend o f only 5 cents per share to m aintain its dividend payout. However, companies w ill often n ot reduce th e ir dividend per share to th a t extent. For example, the company may end up paying a dividend of, say, 7.5 cents per share after the bonus issue has been made. I f the behaviour o f m ost companies after a bonus issue follows this pattern, the m arket w ill be confident th a t a company m aking a bonus issue w ill probably increase its to ta l dividend payout (Ball, Brown & Finn 1977). This, in tu rn , indicates the confidence o f management in the company s future. Consequently, the share price may increase in response to this new inform ation. Therefore, bonus issues may result in an increase in shareholder wealth— n o t sim ply because o f the new shares issued— but instead because the announcement o f the issue provides an o pp o rtu n ity fo r management to signal to the m arket positive info rm a tio n th a t was n o t already incorporated into the company s share price. 37 S e e S lo a n ( 1 9 8 7 ) . T h is e v id e n c e c o n t r a s t s w ith th e U S e v id e n c e , w h ich h a s fo u n d p o s it iv e a b n o r m a l r e t u r n s o n th e e x -b o n u s d a y fo r U S s t o c k d iv id e n d s a n d s h a r e s p lit s ; s e e L a k o n is h o k a n d V e r m a e le n ( 1 9 8 6 ) a n d G r in b la t t , M a s u lis a n d T it m a n ( 1 9 8 4 ). C hapter n in e S ources The dividend-based explanation fo r the m arket reaction to bonus and sp lit announcements, which was firs t proposed by Fama et al. (1969), does n o t appear to explain fu lly the m arket reaction to such announcements. Asquith, Healy and Palepu (1989) studied share splits by companies th a t did n o t pay cash dividends. They found th a t these companies had large earnings increases before the split, b u t no unusual changes in earnings or in itia tio n o f dividends after the split. An im p o rta n t conclusion o f th eir study was th a t the announcement o f a sp lit leads investors to expect th a t past earnings increases are permanent. A share split may be made by a company w ith a *thin, market fo r its shares. Management may believe that reducing the m arket price per share w ill increase the demand fo r the company s shares. In September 2008, fe rtiliser and explosives m anufacturer Incitec Pivot, which had a share price around $140, made a 2 0 -fo r-l share split. The stated purpose was to benefit shareholders by m aking the company s shares more affordable to retail investors. W hile there is evidence th a t both announcement and execution o f share splits are associated w ith significant positive returns, empirical evidence that splits lead to improved liq u id ity and m arketability is mixed. On the one hand, there is evidence th a t both the number o f shareholders and the num ber o f share transactions increase after splits, b ut little evidence th a t the dollar value o f trading increases. On the other hand, there is evidence th a t splits increase bid-ask spreads and return volatility, both o f which suggest a decrease in liq u id ity .38 A share consolidation— also know n as a reverse sp lit— decreases the number o f shares on issue and increases the price per share. For example, i f a company w ith 100 m illio n issued shares makes a l-fo r-1 0 consolidation, i t w ill end up w ith 10 m illio n issued shares. A fte r the consolidation, the m arket price per share should increase by a factor o f 10. Consolidations are unusual in Australia b ut have become more common follow ing the global financial crisis. For example, in September 2010, gold m iner St Barbara Ltd announced th a t it planned a share consolidation o f six existing shares fo r one new share. Directors noted th a t the company s share price o f around 40 cents meant th a t some international in s titu tio n s that were potential investors in the company were precluded from investing in companies w ith share prices less than US$1. Sim ilar reasons usually given fo r consolidations include raising the share price into a popular trading range, overcoming perceptions th a t a company is n o t respectable because o f its low share price, and reducing shareholder servicing costs. O ther companies th a t have recently consolidated th e ir securities include Australand, Boart Longyear and GPT Group. I f these suggested reasons are correct and consolidations provide benefits fo r shareholders, the market response to these events should be positive. This does n o t appear to be the case: several US studies report th a t consolidations are associated w ith negative share returns. For example, Desai and Jain (1997) report an average abnormal retu rn o f -4.5 9 per cent in the m onth th a t consolidations are announced. They also found th a t negative returns in the announcement period were followed by a d rift th a t averaged 10.76 per cent in 1 year and 33.90 per cent in 3 years. One interpretation is th a t consolidations convey a signal th a t management lacks confidence th a t there w ill be future share price increases resulting from improvements in earnings. There is evidence th a t consolidations are followed by higher trading volume and a decrease in bid-ask spread. This finding suggests th a t consolidations enhance the liq u id ity o f a stock, which should be beneficial fo r investors. Taken together, the evidence suggests th a t consolidations *may be better characterised as a device th a t management, given its assessment o f future earnings, can use to improve the liq u id ity o f the stock’ ( Han 1995, p. 169). 38 S tu d ie s t h a t r e p o r t e v id e n c e o n t h e e ffe c t s o f s h a r e s p l i t s o n liq u id ity in c lu d e Ik e n b e r ry , R a n k in e a n d S tic e ( 1 9 9 6 ) a n d M u sc a r e lla a n d V e ts u y p e n s ( 1 9 9 6 ) . 〇 f fin a n c e : equity B usiness finance SUMMARY • • In th is c h a p te r w e c o n s id e r e d th e w a y s in w h ic h r a t io to th e n u m b e r o f s h a re s a lr e a d y h e ld . A • t r a d itio n a l Those who in v e s t in new v e n tu re s w h e re an issu e is s lo w in v o lv e s o f a n in v e n tio n o r id e a in c lu d e w e a lt h y in d iv id u a ls ra is e la r g e a m o u n ts o f fu n d s . R ig h ts issues m a y a n d p r iv a te e q u ity fu n d s . b e r e n o u n c e a b le o r n o n -re n o u n c e a b le a n d c a n W h e re c a p it a l a is ra is e d in v e s to rs by is s u in g m u st g e n e r a lly d is c lo s u re d o c u m e n t. b e m a d e w ith o u t a p ro s p e c tu s . T h e fu n d s c a n b e s e c u ritie s , re c e iv e d s o o n e r th a n u s u a l b y a d o p tin g o n e o f b e s u p p lie d T h is th e a c c e le r a te d o ffe r s tru ctu re s. d o c u m e n t, often a p ro s p e c tu s , sets o u t in fo r m a tio n to e n a b le in v e s to rs to assess th e risks in v o lv e d and • • A p la c e m e n t is a n issu e o f s h a re s to b r o k e r s 7 c lie n ts th e a n d /o r in s titu tio n a l in v e s to rs s u ch as life in s u r a n c e c o m p a n ie s a n d in v e s tm e n t fu n d s . v a lu e o f th e s e c u ritie s . O r d in a r y s h a re h o ld e rs fa c e h ig h e r ris k th a n o th e r Issue c o sts a r e in v e s to rs, rig h ts issu e s, b u t f o r a lis te d c o m p a n y a lim it b u t a re p ro te c te d to so m e e x te n t b y lim ite d lia b ility . A s p a rt-o w n e rs o f th e c o m p a n y , of c a p it a l th a t it c a n ra is e b y p la c e m e n ts in a n y v irtu e o f th e ir r ig h t to e le c t m e m b e rs o f th e B o a rd o f y e a r w ith o u t th e p r io r a p p r o v a l o f s h a r e h o ld e r s . D ire c to rs . S h a re h o ld e rs in a liste d p u b lic c o m p a n y W h e re m a y sell th e ir sh a re s o n a s to ck e x c h a n g e . th e E q u ity has im p o r ta n t a d v a n ta g e s as a s o u rc e 15 lo w e r f o r p la c e m e n ts th a n fo r o r d in a r y s h a re h o ld e rs e x e rt a d e g r e e o f c o n tro l b y p e r c e n t is th e 15 A lte r n a tiv e ly , o r to re d e e m (re p a y ) o r d in a r y s h a re s. R a isin g n e w w ith e q u ity c a p ita l lo w e rs fin a n c ia l ris k a n d issu e. lo w e rs th e • a cent c e ilin g , th e am ount of sought exceeds c o m p a n ie s o fte n p la c e m e n t c a n p u rc h a s e p la n be c o m b in e d a n d /o r a rig h ts E q u ity c a n a ls o b e ra is e d b y is s u in g c o n trib u tin g o p tio n s e m p lo y e e s . (IPO ) o f o r d in a r y a s h a re s h a re s , it b o rro w s . on s h a re s E m p lo y e e s h a re and sh a re s to p la n s c a n q u a lif y fo r ta x c o n c e s s io n s . s h a re s is re fe r r e d to as f lo a t in g a c o m p a n y a n d is u s u a lly a c c o m p a n ie d b y th e lis tin g o f th e s h a re s o n on a m o u n t o f fu n d s per fin a n c e . C o m p a n ie s a r e n o t re q u ire d to p a y d iv id e n d s M a k in g a n in it ia l p u b lic o ffe r in g p la c e d m a k e a p la c e m e n t w ith s h a r e h o ld e r a p p r o v a l. of in te re s t ra te th a t th e c o m p a n y w ill h a v e to p a y w h e n • A m a jo r s o u rc e o f e q u ity fin a n c e is in te rn a l in th e a s to c k e x c h a n g e . D e te r m in in g th e issu e p r ic e f o r a n se n se th a t it re su lts fro m th e p o s itiv e n e t c a s h flo w s IP O c a n b e d iff ic u lt a n d in la r g e flo a ts it h a s b e c o m e th a t c o m m o n to use c o m p e titiv e b id d in g g e n e r a te d b y in s titu tio n s to set th e p ric e . D e ta ils o f th e issu e a n d th e is s u in g a s u c ce ssfu l fu n d s com pany have g e n e ra te s . s e v e ra l In te rn a lly a d v a n ta g e s over e q u ity fu n d s ra is e d e x te rn a lly . In c o n ju n c tio n w ith c o m p a n y m u st b e p r o v id e d in a p ro s p e c tu s . F lo a tin g h ig h e r d iv id e n d p a y m e n ts u n d e r th e im p u ta tio n ta x a th e syste m , m a n y A u s tr a lia n c o m p a n ie s h a v e in tro d u c e d la rg e s t c o s t is a s s o c ia te d w ith th e u n d e r p r ic in g o f d iv id e n d re in v e s tm e n t p la n s th a t a llo w in v e s to rs to com pany in v o lv e s s ig n if ic a n t co sts. O fte n , th e s h a re s — th e issu e p r ic e f o r a n IP O is u s u a lly less use th a n th e m a rk e t p r ic e w h e n t r a d in g c o m m e n c e s . s h a re s . T h is a llo w s d iv id e n d s to b e p a id a n d f r a n k in g A fte r a c o m p a n y h a s b e e n flo a te d , a d d itio n a l e q u ity c re d its to b e d is tr ib u te d to in v e s to rs w h ile re ta in in g can c a s h w ith in th e c o m p a n y . be ra is e d in s e v e ra l w ays, in c lu d in g rig h ts th e ir cash d iv id e n d s to p u rc h a s e issu es, p la c e m e n ts a n d s h a re p u rc h a s e p la n s . KEY TERMS c a ll 234 c o n trib u tin g sh a re s c u m rig h ts 262 e x -rig h ts d a te 240 253 in fo rm a tio n a s y m m e try in itia l p u b lic o ffe r in g in s ta lm e n t re c e ip t lim ite d lia b ilit y o p tio n 237 237 262 234 260 p ro s p e c tu s 240 234 se a s o n e d e q u ity o ffe r in g s h o rtfa ll f a c ility 258 s h o rtfa ll sh a re s 258 s ta p le d se c u ritie s 234 25 1 233 s u b s c rip tio n p ric e 253 th e o re tic a l e x -rig h ts s h a re p ric e th e o re tic a l rig h ts p ric e 255 o r d in a r y sh a re s p la c e m e n t re s id u a l c la im 253 d is c lo s u re d o c u m e n t 270 and h ig h e r co sts th a n a p la c e m e n t b u t c a n b e u se d to w ith • rig h ts e n tre p re n e u r n e e d s f in a n c e fo r th e d e v e lo p m e n t p o te n tia l • rig h ts issu e (e n title m e n t o ffe r) is a n o ffe r to s h a re s . E v e ry c o m p a n y m u st issu e o r d in a r y s h a re s. • • A e x is tin g s h a re h o ld e rs o f n e w s h a re s in a fix e d a c o m p a n y m a y ra is e e q u ity b y is s u in g o r d in a r y w in n e r ’s cu rs e 248 254 254 a d d itio n a l C hapter n in e S ources of f in a n c e : equity 1 [L0 1] The interest held by ordinary shareholders is a residual claim. E x p la in th e m e a n in g a n d s ig n ific a n c e o f th is s ta te m e n t. 2 3 [L O 1] W h a t a re th e m o s t im p o r t a n t rig h ts o f s h a re h o ld e rs in a c o m p a n y ? [ L O l ] W h a t a r e th e m a in s im ila ritie s b e tw e e n c o n tr ib u tin g s h a re s a n d in s ta lm e n t re c e ip ts ? H o w d o th e y d iffe r? 4 5 [LO 2 ] W h a t a r e th e m a in a d v a n ta g e s o f r a is in g e q u ity ra th e r th a n b o r r o w in g ? [LO 2: D is tin g u is h b e tw e e n lim ite d lia b ilit y a n d n o lia b ilit y c o m p a n ie s . W h y a r e n o lia b ilit y c o m p a n ie s c o n fin e d to e x p lo r a t io n a n d m in in g c o m p a n ie s ? 6 [LO 3 ] D e fin e p r iv a te e q u ity . W h a t a r e th e m a in fe a tu re s th a t d is tin g u is h p r iv a te e q u ity fro m o th e r fo rm s o f e q u ity fin a n c e ? 7 [LO 31 P riv a te e q u ity fu n d in g fo r n e w v e n tu re s is t y p ic a lly p r o v id e d in s ta g e s . W h a t a r e th e m a in re a s o n s fo r th is a p p r o a c h ? 8 [LO 4 ] W h a t ty p e o f in fo r m a tio n is g e n e r a lly r e q u ire d in th e o f fe r d o c u m e n ts is s u e d p r io r to c a p it a l r a is in g ? W h y d o y o u th in k r e g u la to rs m ig h t h a v e a v o id e d p r o v id in g a s im p le 'c h e c k lis t7 o f ite m s f o r in c lu s io n a n d C H A P T E R Isfl^E R E V I E W QUESTIONS in s te a d ta k e n a b r o a d e r a p p r o a c h to r e g u la tio n ? 9 [L O 5 ] Listed p u b lic c o m p a n ie s h a v e th e a d v a n ta g e o f g r e a te r a c c e s s to th e c a p it a l m a rk e t th a n p r iv a te o r u n lis te d c o m p a n ie s . H o w e v e r, th is a d v a n ta g e a ls o in v o lv e s s ig n ific a n t costs. W h a t a r e th e m a in co sts? 10 [L O 5 ] A com pany is floated by m aking a public issue of ordinary shores. O u t lin e th e p ro c e d u re s in v o lv e d 11 [L O 5 ] 12 [L O 5 ] O u tlin e th e m a in a d v a n ta g e s o f u s in g b o o k - b u ild in g fo r a n in it ia l p u b lic o ffe r in g o f s h a re s ra th e r th a n 13 [ L 0 5 ] W h a t a r e th e a d v a n ta g e s a n d d is a d v a n ta g e s o f h a v in g a s h a re issu e u n d e r w r itte n ? 14 [L O 5 ] W h y a r e u n d e r w r it in g fe e s h ig h e r f o r c o m p a n y flo a ts th a n f o r rig h ts issues? 15 [L O 6 in f lo a tin g a c o m p a n y . A company usually seeks the assistance o f a financial institution before undertaking any large capital raising. E x p la in w h y th is is so . D e s c rib e fu lly th e re le v a n t s e rv ic e s th a t a f in a n c ia l in s titu tio n p ro v id e s . m a k in g a fix e d - p r ic e o ffe r. W h a t a r e th e d is a d v a n ta g e s o f b o o k - b u ild in g ? In itia l p u b lic o ffe r in g s o f s h a re s a re t y p ic a lly u n d e r p r ic e d b u t v e n d o rs a r e r a r e ly u p s e t a b o u t le a v in g la r g e a m o u n ts o f m o n e y o n th e ta b le . H o w is 'm o n e y le ft o n th e t a b le 7 u s u a lly m e a s u re d ? H o w c a n th e p u z z lin g a ttitu d e o f v e n d o rs b e e x p la in e d ? 16 [ L 0 6 ] In d is c u s s in g th e ir re s e a rc h o n IP O s, C a m p e t a l. ( 2 0 0 6 ) c o n c lu d e th a t 'th e c h o ic e s issu ers m a k e a t th e o ffe r in g re fle c t th e tr a d e - o ff b e tw e e n th e co sts a n d b e n e fits o f th e IP O 7. F o r issu e rs, th e m a in c o s t o f a n IP O is re p re s e n te d b y u n d e r p r ic in g . W h a t a r e th e m a in b e n e fits ? 17 [L O 7 ] O u tlin e th e 'n e w issues p u z z le 7. W h y is th e e v id e n c e f o r its e x is te n c e c o n tro v e rs ia l? 18 [L O 8 ] A lth o u g h m o st c o m p a n ie s p e r m it rig h ts to b e tr a d e d o n th e s to c k e x c h a n g e , a n u m b e r o f c o m p a n ie s h a v e m a d e n o n -re n o u n c e a b le rig h ts issu es. W h y w o u ld c o m p a n ie s w is h to m a k e th e ir rig h ts issues n o n -re n o u n c e a b le ? 19 [ L 0 8 ] T h e re h a s b e e n re s is ta n c e to c o m p a n ie s r a is in g fu n d s b y a p r iv a te p la c e m e n t o f s h a re s . D e s c rib e th e 20 [ L 0 8 ] M W B Ltd is a p r o fita b le c o m p a n y w h o s e o r d in a r y s h a re s a r e lis te d o n th e A S X . T h e c o m p a n y ha s a d v a n ta g e s a n d d is a d v a n ta g e s to e x is tin g s h a re h o ld e rs o f a p r iv a te p la c e m e n t. p a id r e g u la r d iv id e n d s to s h a re h o ld e rs a n d h a s g e n e r a lly fin a n c e d its g r o w th b y r e ta in in g a b o u t 5 0 p e r c e n t o f p ro fits . Its c u rre n t 5 - y e a r p la n in c lu d e s in v e s tm e n t in f ix e d a sse ts o n a s c a le th a t w ill re q u ire th e r a is in g o f e x te rn a l e q u ity fin a n c e d u r in g th e p la n n in g p e r io d . A d v is e th e d ir e c to r s o n th e m a in fa c to rs th a t th e y s h o u ld c o n s id e r in d e c id in g h o w to ra is e e q u ity . T he d ir e c to r s a r e c o n s id e r in g : 21 a) a rig h ts issue b) a se rie s o f s h a re p la c e m e n ts c) e s ta b lis h in g a d iv id e n d re in v e s tm e n t p la n . Combining a shore purchase plan with a placement to institutions should satisfy shareholders who argue that as far as possible, companies should raise equity through rights issues. D o y o u a g r e e w ith th is [L O 8 ] s ta te m e n t? E x p la in y o u r a n s w e r. 271 B usiness finance 22 [ L 0 8 ] N o w that rights issues con be made without a prospectus, they w ill become much more popular and placements may become rare. D o y o u a g r e e w ith th is s ta te m e n t? E x p la in y o u r a n s w e r. 23 [L O 8 ] O u tlin e th e m a in fe a tu re s o f a n a c c e le r a te d r e n o u n c e a b le e n title m e n t o ffe r. W h a t a r e th e m a in d iffe re n c e s b e tw e e n su ch a n o ffe r a n d a t r a d itio n a l r e n o u n c e a b le rig h ts issue? 24 [L O 8 ] A lis te d c o m p a n y m a y m a k e a p u b lic o f fe r o f s h a re s , p o s s ib ly in c o n ju n c tio n w ith a rig h ts issue. Id e n tify fa c to rs th a t m a y f a v o u r th e use o f a fu rth e r p u b lic o ff e r o f s h a re s ra th e r th a n a p la c e m e n t o r a rig h ts issue a lo n e . 25 [L O 8 ] Options are often used as on incentive to various groups or individuals. D e s c rib e h o w o p tio n s c a n b e u se d to th e a d v a n ta g e o f a c o m p a n y a n d its s h a re h o ld e rs . 26 [ L 0 9 ] W h a t is th e in c e n tiv e fo r a c o m p a n y to p r o v id e c o m p e n s a tio n f o r m a n a g e rs in th e fo rm o f sh a re s ra th e r th a n s a la r y ? W h a t is th e a d v a n ta g e o f s h a re c o m p e n s a tio n o v e r a n d a b o v e c o m p e n s a tio n u s in g s h a re o p tio n s ? 27 [L O 1 0 ] W h a t a r e in te rn a l fu n d s ? W h a t a r e th e ir a d v a n ta g e s a s a s o u rc e o f e q u ity ? 28 [L O 1 0 ] O u t lin e th e im p a c t o f th e g lo b a l f in a n c ia l c ris is o n A u s tr a lia n c o m p a n ie s in te rm s o f th e ir m ix o f in te rn a l ve rsu s e x te rn a l fu n d in g o v e r th e 2 -y e a r p e r io d fro m m id - 2 0 0 7 . 29 [L O ll] W h a t is a s h a re s p lit? W h y m ig h t th e d ir e c to r s o f a c o m p a n y w is h to s p lit its s h a re s ? 30 [L O ll] W h a t is a s h a re c o n s o lid a tio n ? E v a lu a te th e re a s o n s th a t m a y b e g iv e n to ju s tify a s h a re c o n s o lid a tio n . 31 [L O 1 1 ] E x p la in b r ie f ly w h y th e s h a re p r ic e o f a c o m p a n y m a y in c re a s e w h e n th e c o m p a n y a n n o u n c e s a b o n u s issu e o r s h a re s p lit. PROBLEMS 1 E co n o m ic fa c to rs a n d f in a n c in g p o lic y [L O 2 】 C h o o s e a c o m p a n y a n d tra c e th e m a jo r c h a n g e s in its c a p ita l stru ctu re d u rin g th e p a s t 1 0 y e a rs . O u tlin e th e e c o n o m ic fa c to rs th a t y o u c o n s id e r h a v e c o n trib u te d to th e m a jo r c h a n g e s in its fin a n c in g p o lic y d u r in g this p e rio d . 2 P u b lic s h a re issu e [L O 5 ] K a tz Pty Ltd is a w e ll-e s ta b lis h e d c o m p a n y w h o s e d ire c to rs h a v e d e c id e d to c o n v e rt to p u b lic c o m p a n y status, m a k e a p u b lic s h a re issue a n d list o n th e s to ck e x c h a n g e . T he c o m p a n y n e e d s to ra is e $ 7 9 2 0 0 0 0 to e x p a n d its o p e ra tio n s . Its p ro s p e c tu s fo re c a s ts a d iv id e n d o f 2 0 cen ts p e r sh a re in its firs t y e a r a s a p u b lic c o m p a n y a n d d iv id e n d s a r e e x p e c te d to g r o w a t 6 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m in d e fin ite ly . S h a re h o ld e rs re q u ire a re tu rn o f 1 4 p e r c e n t p e r a n n u m a n d th e c o s t o f lis tin g a m o u n ts to 1 2 p e r c e n t o f th e g ro s s p ro c e e d s fro m th e issue. H o w m a n y s h a re s m ust K a tz issue? 3 R ig h ts issu e [L O 8 ] C o m p a n y A h a s 4 m illio n sh a re s o n issue a n d w is h e s to ra is e $ 4 m illio n b y a l- f o r - 4 rig h ts issue. 4 a) W h a t is th e th e o re tic a l v a lu e o f 1 r ig h t if th e m a rk e t p r ic e o f 1 s h a re (cum rig h ts) is $ 5 ? b) W h a t is th e th e o re tic a l s h a re p r ic e (ex-rights)? c) D o e s a n in v e s to r g a in th ro u g h a rig h ts issue? R ig h ts issu e [L O 8 ] C r o s lin g Ltd sh a re s a re tr a d in g a t $ 1 2 e a c h . Its d ire c to rs h a v e a n n o u n c e d a l- fo r - 6 rig h ts issue w ith a s u b s c rip tio n p r ic e o f $ 1 0 . 6 0 p e r sh a re . W h a t is: 5 a) th e th e o re tic a l v a lu e o f a r ig h t to o n e n e w s h a re b) th e th e o re tic a l e x -rig h ts s h a re p ric e ? R ig h ts issu e [L O 8 ] M a x w e ll Ltd is a liste d b io te c h n o lo g y c o m p a n y . O n 5 M a y 2 0 1 4 it a n n o u n c e d a l- fo r - 3 re n o u n c e a b le rig h ts issue a t a s u b s c rip tio n p r ic e o f $ 6 . 2 0 p e r sh a re w ith a n e x -rig h ts d a te o f 2 5 M a y . T he c o m p a n y a ls o a n n o u n c e d th a t fu n d s ra is e d b y th e issue w o u ld b e use d to e s ta b lis h p r o d u c tio n fa c ilitie s fo r its n e w a n tim a la r ia d ru g th a t re c e n tly p a s s e d its fin a l c lin ic a l tria ls . T he s h a re p r ic e ro s e fro m $ 6 . 9 0 to $ 7 . 0 5 a fte r th o se a n n o u n c e m e n ts . T he c lo s in g p ric e o f M a x w e ll sh a re s o n 2 4 M a y w a s $ 7 p e r sh a re . 272 C hapter n in e S ources W h a t is a r e n o u n c e a b le rig h ts issue? b) W h a t is th e m o st lik e ly e x p la n a tio n fo r th e s h a re p ric e ris e o n 5 M a y a fte r th e c o m p a n y 's a n n o u n c e m e n ts ? c) W h a t d o y o u e x p e c t th e p r ic e o f th e sh a re s to b e o n 2 5 M a y ? S h o w a ll c a lc u la tio n s . d) W h a t is th e th e o re tic a l v a lu e o f a rig h t? S h o w a ll c a lc u la tio n s . e) E x p la in w h y th e sh a re p ric e c h a n g e fro m 2 4 M a y to 2 5 M a y d o e s n o t re fle c t a n y c h a n g e in s h a re h o ld e rs 7 w e a lth . 6 Alternative w ays of raising equity [LO 8 】 G e o rg e B a n ks In te rn a tio n a l (G B I) Ltd h a s 1 0 0 m illio n fu lly p a id o r d in a r y sh a re s o n issue a n d its sh a re s a r e liste d o n th e A S X . A b o u t 6 0 p e r c e n t o f th e sh a re s a r e h e ld b y A u s tra lia n fin a n c ia l in s titu tio n s a n d th e c lo s in g p ric e o f th e s h a re s o n 1 5 O c to b e r 2 0 1 4 w a s $ 4 . The c o m p a n y h a s a fu lly d r a w n $ 5 0 0 m illio n b a n k lo a n fa c ility , w h ic h is d u e to b e r o lle d o v e r o r r e p a id o n 3 0 N o v e m b e r 2 0 1 4 . G B I Ltd is c lo s e to b re a c h in g a n im p o rta n t c o v e n a n t a n d its d ire c to rs h a v e re s o lv e d to ra is e e q u ity to r e p a y th e lo a n o n o r b e fo re th e d u e d a te . The c o m p a n y 's la s t sh a re issue o c c u rre d in 2 0 1 1. a) A s s u m in g a n issue p r ic e o f $ 3 . 8 0 p e r s h a re , w h a t is th e m a x im u m a m o u n t th a t G B I Ltd c a n ra is e b y m a k in g a s h a re p la c e m e n t w ith o u t s h a re h o ld e r a p p r o v a l? b) A d v is e th e d ire c to rs o n th e fe a s ib ility o f ra is in g th e re q u ire d fu n d s b y a tr a d itio n a l re n o u n c e a b le o r n o n -re n o u n c e a b le rig h ts issue. c) C H A P T E R NINE R E V I E W a) of f in a n c e : equity A fte r r e c e iv in g y o u r a d v ic e , th e d ire c to rs a re c o n s id e rin g th e c o m b in a tio n o f a n in s titu tio n a l p la c e m e n t fo llo w e d im m e d ia te ly b y a n a c c e le ra te d e n title m e n t o ffe r. i) D o e s th e m a x im u m a m o u n t th a t c a n b e ra is e d b y th e p la c e m e n t re m a in th e s a m e a s in (a)? W h y , o r w h y not? ii) R e v ie w y o u r a n s w e r to (b). H o w w ill y o u r a d v ic e c h a n g e , g iv e n th a t a n a c c e le ra te d o ffe r s tru c tu re is to b e used? d) A s s u m e th a t th e c o m p a n y p ro c e e d s w ith a n a c c e le ra te d e n title m e n t o ffe r. F rom th e v ie w p o in t o f G B I's s h a re h o ld e rs , w h a t is th e m a in e ffe c t o f m a k in g th e o ffe r re n o u n c e a b le ra th e r th a n n o n -re n o u n c e a b le ? W ill a re n o u n c e a b le o ffe r n e c e s s a rily e n s u re th a t a ll s h a re h o ld e rs a re tre a te d e q u a lly ? W h y , o r w h y not? Lj REFERENCES Abernethy, M.