Uploaded by lulgjurajmaria23

epdf.pub sense-and-nonsense-about-crime-drugs-and-communities

advertisement
Sense and Nonsense
about Crime, Drugs,
and Communities
EIGHTH EDITION
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Sense and Nonsense
about Crime, Drugs,
and Communities
EIGHTH EDITION
Samuel Walker
University of Nebraska–Omaha
Australia • Brazil • Mexico • Singapore • United Kingdom • United States
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
This is an electronic version of the print textbook. Due to electronic rights restrictions, some third party content
may be suppressed. Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall
learning experience. The publisher reserves the right to remove content from this title at any time if subsequent
rights restrictions require it. For valuable information on pricing, previous editions, changes to
current editions, and alternate formats, please visit www.cengage.com/highered to search by
ISBN#, author, title, or keyword for materials in your areas of interest.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Sense and Nonsense about Crime,
Drugs, and Communities,
Eighth Edition
Samuel Walker
Product Director: Marta
Lee-Perriard
Product Manager: Carolyn
Henderson Meier
Product Assistant: Catherine Ryan
Media Developer: Ting Jian Yap
© 2015, 2011 Cengage Learning
WCN: 02-200-203
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. No part of this work covered by the
copyright herein may be reproduced, transmitted, stored, or used
in any form or by any means graphic, electronic, or mechanical,
including but not limited to photocopying, recording, scanning,
digitizing, taping, Web distribution, information networks, or
information storage and retrieval systems, except as permitted
under Section 107 or 108 of the 1976 United States Copyright Act,
without the prior written permission of the publisher.
Marketing Manager: Kara
Kindstrom
For product information and
technology assistance, contact us at Cengage Learning
Customer & Sales Support, 1-800-354-9706.
For permission to use material from this text or product,
submit all requests online at www.cengage.com/permissions.
Further permissions questions can be e-mailed to
permissionrequest@cengage.com.
Art and Cover Direction,
Production Management, and
Composition: Integra
Manufacturing Planner: Judy
Inouye
Text and Image Research:
PreMediaGlobal
Illustrator: Frank Irwin
Cover Image: Jim Colao/Luxtone
Media
Library of Congress Control Number: 2014934270
ISBN-13: 978-1-285-45902-8
ISBN-10: 1-285-45902-4
Cengage Learning
200 First Stamford Place, 4th Floor
Stamford, CT 06902
USA
Cengage Learning is a leading provider of customized learning
solutions with office locations around the globe, including
Singapore, the United Kingdom, Australia, Mexico, Brazil, and Japan.
Locate your local office at www.cengage.com/global.
Cengage Learning products are represented in Canada by
Nelson Education, Ltd.
To learn more about Cengage Learning Solutions, visit
www.cengage.com.
Purchase any of our products at your local college store or at our
preferred online store www.cengagebrain.com.
Printed in the United States
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 18 17 16 15 14
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Brief Contents
PROPOSITIONS
FOREWORD
PREFACE
PART
PART
PART
PART
PART
I
II
III
IV
V
VI
x x iii
THINKING CLEARLY ABOUT CRIME
1
1
Crime and Policy: A Complex Problem
2
Models of Criminal Justice
3
The Going Rate
4
The Prediction Problem
2
38
58
81
“GET TOUGH”: THE CONSERVATIVE ATTACK ON CRIME
5
Unleash the Cops!
6
Deter the Criminals
7
Lock ’Em Up
8
Close the Loopholes
133
161
196
9
Protect Crime Victims
226
10
Control Gun Crimes
252
REFORM: THE LIBERAL PRESCRIPTION
11
Treat ’Em!
12
Gain Compliance with the Law
225
281
282
THE DRUG PROBLEM
315
335
Sense and Nonsense about Drugs and Crime
336
PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER: CRIME AND COMMUNITY
14
99
100
THE MIDDLE GROUND: GUNS AND VICTIMS
13
PART
x viii
x xi
Crime and Community: Putting It All Together
369
370
v
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Contents
PROPOSITIONS
FOREWORD
PREFACE
PART
I
xviii
xxi
xxiii
THINKING CLEARLY ABOUT CRIME
1
1
Crime and Policy: A Complex Problem
Crime Trends: Conflicting, Confusing
The Great American Crime Drop 3
Is the Crime Drop Genuine?
2
2
5
Explaining the Crime Drop 5
The Purpose of This Book 6
Problem-Oriented Crime Policy 7
Contextual versus Policy Factors 10
The New Standard: Evidence-Based Crime Policy
12
Understanding Crime and Justice in the United States
Crime Problems in the United States 15
Waging War on Crime 16
The Racial Dimensions of the War on Crime
14
18
Waging “War” Is the Wrong Way to Deal with Crime
A “Social Ledger” of Crime Policy 21
Crime Policy: A Plague of Nonsense
20
22
The Ground Rules 23
What Do We Mean by Crime Prevention?
24
vii
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
viii
CONTENTS
The Question of Reasonable Goals
Guilty: Liberals and Conservatives
Crime Control Theology 26
Conservative Theology
24
26
27
Liberal Theology 29
A Word about Rules 30
Ideological Confusion: Switching Sides
Conclusion 32
Notes
2
31
32
Models of Criminal Justice
38
The Crime Commission’s Model 41
The Criminal Justice Wedding Cake 43
“Celebrated Cases”: The Top Layer 44
Serious Felonies: The Second and Third Layers
47
An Example of the Complexity of the System: “Back-End
Sentencing” in California 48
The Impact of Prior Record 49
The Impact of the Victim–Offender Relationship
Prior Relationship: A Policy Dilemma 51
49
Hard or Soft on Crime? Unraveling the Paradox
52
The Lower Depths: The Fourth Layer
Conclusion 54
Notes
3
53
54
The Going Rate
58
Evaluating the System 58
The Criminal Justice Funnel
59
A Closer Look Inside the Funnel 62
Weeding out the Weak Cases: Rejections and Dismissals
Sentencing: The Going Rate Gets Tougher
63
66
How Do We Compare? An International Perspective on the Going
Rate 67
The Courtroom Work Group 69
An Administrative System of Justice
The Limits of Reform
69
71
The Dynamics of Reform 73
Justice Thermodynamics 73
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
ix
CONTENTS
Wrongful Convictions: How Common Are Mistakes?
Conclusion
Notes 78
4
75
77
The Prediction Problem 81
The Risk Assessment Tradition 82
Searching for the Career Criminal
Wolfgang’s Birth Cohort 83
Other Cohort Studies
83
85
Career Criminals: Defining Our Terms and Concepts
From Research to Policy 87
Application Problems 88
Confronting the Prediction Problem
86
89
Looking for Violent Delinquents: The Wenk Study
The Texas Death Row Inmate Study 91
The Federal Sentencing Guidelines
89
91
The Rand Selective Incapacitation Study 92
How Much Crime Do They Commit? 94
Conclusion
Notes 96
PART
II
96
“GET TOUGH”: THE CONSERVATIVE ATTACK ON CRIME
5
Unleash the Cops!
99
100
More Cops on the Street 101
Some Basics about Police Patrol and Crime
101
The Deterrent Effect of Patrol: Lessons of the Kansas City
Experiment 103
Understanding Police Patrol and Deterrence 104
The All-Seeing Eye: CCTV 105
Police “Crackdowns” on Crime 106
Crackdowns 106
A Different Kind of Crackdown? The NYPD Stop-and-Frisk
Controversy 107
Faster Response Time 109
Smart Policing: Promising Futures
110
Problem-Oriented Policing 111
Compstat: Data-Driven Policing 113
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
x
CONTENTS
Focused Deterrence, or “Pulling Levers”: The Most Effective
Response? 115
Operation Ceasefire: The Boston Gun Project 115
Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce Violence
116
A Few Words of Caution about Police Innovations 117
Predictive Policing: Science or Just the Latest Fad? 117
Drones: The Police Patrol of the Future? 118
More Detectives and Better Detective Work 119
Myths and Realities of Detective Work 119
The Science of Crime Detection: Fingerprints and Other Popular
Myths 121
Eliminate the “Technicalities” 122
Repeal the Exclusionary Rule? 122
Abolish the Miranda Warning
Conclusion 127
Notes
6
125
127
Deter the Criminals
Deterrence Theory
133
133
Assumptions Underlying Deterrence 134
From Theory to Practice: Deterrence in the Real Word of
Criminal Justice 136
Communicating the Message 136
Understanding the “Costs” of Crime
138
The Perceived vs. the Real Risk of Punishment 139
Choosing Crime: The Rational Criminal? 140
Scare the *%!#@ out of Them! 141
A Famous but Failed Program 141
Deterrence and the Death Penalty
Sorting out the Issues 142
142
Executions and Crime: The Debate Continues
Deterring the Drunk Driver 144
The “Killer Drunk” and Other Myths
143
145
Deterrence and Drunk Driving 147
Drunk Drivers in Court 149
A Multipronged Strategy for Dealing with Traffic Fatalities
Ignition Interlock Systems: Focused Incapacitation? 154
Specialized DUI Courts
151
155
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xi
CONTENTS
Conclusion
Notes
7
156
157
Lock ’Em Up
161
Getting Criminals off the Street 161
Jail Not Bail: Preventive Detention 162
Crime on Bail: Myths and Reality 165
The Prediction Problem Revisited 166
A Comment on Preventive Detention and Mass Incarceration
168
Speedy Trial: A Better Way 168
Incapacitation as a Crime Policy 169
Selective Incapacitation: The Rand Formula 169
Gross Incapacitation: Zedlewski’s New Math 172
Incapacitation: A Sober Estimate 173
Selective Incapacitation Reborn 175
Mandatory Sentencing
176
“The Nation’s Toughest Drug Law” 177
The Real Impact of the Rockefeller Drug Law
179
The Special Case of the Federal Mandatory Minimums
The Growth of Life without Parole 181
Mandatory Sentencing and Crime
180
182
Three Strikes—We Are All Out 183
Implementation and Impact of Three-Strikes Laws
184
Summary: Striking Out 185
Just Keep Them Away from Us: Sex Registration and Notification
Laws 186
Enforcement Problems
Summary 190
188
Conclusion 190
Notes 191
8
Close the Loopholes 196
Prosecute the Career Criminal 196
Does a Special Prosecutorial Unit Make a
Difference? 197
The San Diego Major Violator Unit
197
Abolish the Insanity Defense 199
An Insanity Defense Loophole? 200
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xii
CONTENTS
Sorting out the Issues
200
The Reality of the Insanity Defense
Aftermath of Acquittal 202
Danger to the Community
200
203
Abolish the Insanity Defense? 203
Abolish or Reform Bargaining? 207
Day-in, Day-out Plea Bargaining 208
Abolishing Plea Bargaining: Alaska Tries
209
Reforming Plea Bargaining in King County, Washington
Plea Bargaining and Crime 213
Evading Harsh Mandatory Sentences: Two Case Studies
211
214
The Case of Sex Offender Notification Laws 214
The Supreme Court Rules on Plea Bargains: New Day or Business
as Usual? 215
Restrict Appeals 217
Limiting Appeals
218
The Reality of Postconviction Appeals
Two Limits on Appeals 219
218
Conclusion 220
Notes 221
PART
III
THE MIDDLE GROUND: GUNS AND VICTIMS
9
Protect Crime Victims
225
226
Victims in the Criminal Justice System 226
The Crime Victims’ Rights Movement 226
The Historical Background 227
The Goals of This Chapter 228
Victims’ Rights Today: Laws and Programs
228
Constitutional and Statutory Guarantees of Victims’ Rights
Victims’ Services 229
Evaluating the Impact of Crime Victims’ Laws and Programs
Victims’ Rights and Crime 230
Serving Special Populations of Crime Victims
Women 232
People with Disabilities
228
230
231
235
Juvenile Runaways and Thrown-aways
236
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xiii
CONTENTS
People Who Are Elderly
236
Native Americans 238
Victims’ Programs and Services
Victim Notification
238
238
Victim/Witness Assistance Programs 240
Protecting Victims from Harm 241
Expanding the Victim’s Voice 241
Post-Conviction Services 243
Victim Compensation Programs 243
Ensuring Professionalism in Victim Services
244
Evaluating the Impact of Victim Programs and Services
245
“Getting Tough” on Crime: Does It Help Crime Victims?
Conclusion 247
Notes 247
10
Control Gun Crimes 252
The Problem with Guns—and Gun Policy
Gun Violence in Perspective
Sorting out the Issues 255
246
252
253
Policy Options 255
Which Firearms Are We Talking About? 256
The Political Context: Public Attitudes about Guns and Gun
Violence 256
Gun Ownership and Gun-Related Violence
Gun Ownership 257
Gun-Related Laws 258
The Supreme Court and Gun Ownership
Gun-Related Laws and Regulations
257
258
259
The Policy Options 259
Ban Handguns 259
Ban Assault Weapons 262
Summary on Banning Firearms
263
Regulate the Sale and Possession of Handguns
Regulate Gun Dealers 263
Background Checks: The Brady Law 264
263
The Gun Show Exception: A Loophole? 266
State-by-State Variations in Laws and Enforcement 266
Summary on Regulating the Sale of Firearms 267
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xiv
CONTENTS
Keeping Guns Away from Special Locations: Airports and
Schools 268
Airports 268
Schools
268
More Guns? Less Crime? 269
The “Stand-Your-Ground” Law Controversy
271
Get Tough on Guns and Gun-Related Offenses 272
Tough Sentencing in Detroit: An Early Experiment 272
Promising Approaches to Reducing Gun Violence
The Kansas City Gun Experiment 273
The Boston Gun Project: A National Model
273
274
Conclusion 276
Notes 276
PART
IV
REFORM: THE LIBERAL PRESCRIPTION
11
Treat ’Em!
281
282
Rehabilitation or Correcting Criminals 282
The Philosophy of Rehabilitation 282
Old and New Programs 283
New Developments in the Field 283
The “Nothing Works” Controversy 283
The Prediction Problem Revisited 285
Traditional Rehabilitation Programs 285
Probation 286
The Effectiveness of Probation
Parole 288
286
Does Parole Work? 289
Does More Make It Better? 291
Perverting Parole: Crisis in California
Diversion
292
293
The Original Model: The Manhattan Court Employment
Project 294
The Net-Widening Problem 295
Do Diversion Programs Rehabilitate? 296
The New Intermediate Punishments 297
The Rise and Fall of Boot Camps 298
What Is a Boot Camp?
298
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xv
CONTENTS
Home Confinement and Electronic Monitoring
300
Lessons of the Intermediate Punishment Movement
Confused Goals 302
301
A Conservative Alternative: Faith-Based Treatment
303
Sorting out the Issues 303
Are Faith-Based Programs Effective?
304
Drug Courts: A New Approach 305
What Are Drug Courts? 306
Are Drug Courts Effective? 306
The Dangers of Over-Expansion 307
New Directions: Evidence-Based Policy in Probation and
Parole 308
Conclusion 310
Notes
12
310
Gain Compliance with the Law
315
The Basis of an Orderly Society 315
Compliance with the Law 315
Legitimacy and Compliance 316
Sources of Legitimacy 316
Justice versus Punishment
317
The Evidence on Procedural Justice in the Criminal Justice
System 318
The Evidence from Policing 318
The Evidence from Drug Courts 320
The Evidence from Criminal Courts
321
The Evidence from Victims’ Services Programs 321
Does Procedural Justice Work? A Meta-Analysis 322
Building Legitimacy 322
Reducing Police Misconduct and Building Fair and Respectful
Policing 323
Procedural Justice in the Courts 327
Prisons and Imprisonment 327
The Criminal Law and Legitimacy: Decriminalization
Conclusion 330
Notes
328
331
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xvi
PART
CONTENTS
V
THE DRUG PROBLEM
13
335
Sense and Nonsense about Drugs and Crime
336
Drugs and Drug-Related Crime 336
Myths and Realities about Drug Use and Drug-Related
Crime 337
The Drug Hysteria Problem 337
The Extent of Illegal Drug Use
337
The Drug–Crime Connection 339
The Drug Policy Choices 342
The War on Drugs: Policy and Consequences
Drug Supply–Reduction Efforts 344
Street-Level Police Drug Enforcement Efforts
Interdiction and Eradication 345
Tougher Sentencing
342
344
346
Limits of the Criminal Law: The Lessons of History
The Lessons of History 348
When Social Control Does Work 349
Demand Reduction: Drug Abuse Education
“Just Say No” 350
DARE: Success or Failure?
353
354
The Promise of Drug Courts
Legalize Drugs? 358
Varieties of Legalization
350
352
But Some Education Programs Do Work
Drug Treatment 354
Varieties of Treatment
347
357
359
The Impact of Legalization 359
A Specific Legalization Proposal 360
Conclusion 362
Notes 362
PART
VI
PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER: CRIME
AND COMMUNITY 369
14
Crime and Community: Putting It All Together
The New Community Focus on Crime Control 370
The New Operating Principles
370
371
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xvii
CONTENTS
The Theoretical Background
373
The Empirical Basis 374
The Evidence of Effective Crime Policies
The Evidence from Policing
375
375
The Evidence from Community Courts
Offender Reentry Programs 380
376
The Challenge of Returning Offenders
Reentry and Legitimacy 384
380
The Way Forward? The Justice Reinvestment Initiative
The Alternative of Restorative Justice 388
Conclusion
Notes
Index
386
390
391
395
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Propositions
1. Most current crime control proposals are nonsense.
2. Waging “war” is the wrong way to fight crime.
3. Both liberals and conservatives are guilty of peddling nonsense
about crime.
4. Most crime control ideas are based on false assumptions about
how the criminal justice system works.
5. It is not possible to precisely predict future criminal behavior in
a way that will significantly reduce crime.
6. Simply putting more cops on the street will not reduce crime.
7. Faster response time will not produce more arrests or lower the
crime rate.
8. Carefully planned and focused problem-oriented policing strategies
can be successful in reducing crime and disorder.
9. More detectives, or other changes in detective work, will not
raise clearance rates or lower the crime rate.
10. The Supreme Court rulings in Mapp and Miranda are not
significant barriers to effective crime control by the police.
11. Deterrence-oriented crime policies are not likely to reduce
serious crime.
12. The death penalty does not deter homicides.
13. Enforcement crackdowns do not deter drunk driving over the
long term.
14. A multipronged strategy, including using noncriminal justice
programs, have proven effective in reducing traffic-related fatalities.
15. Preventive detention will not reduce serious crime.
14
20
26
39
94
105
110
116
122
127
141
144
151
156
168
xviii
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROPOSITIONS
16. Incapacitation, whether selective or gross, is not a realistic strategy
for reducing serious crime.
17. Mandatory sentencing, in all of its forms, is not an effective means of
reducing serious crime.
18. Sex offender registration, notification, and residency restriction
laws are not effective in preventing repeat sex crimes and in certain
respects inhibit effective control and treatment of offenders.
19. Special prosecution units do not produce either higher conviction
rates or lower crime rates.
20. Abolishing or limiting the insanity defense will have no impact
on serious crime.
21. Abolishing or even significantly reforming plea bargaining will not
reduce serious crime.
22. Limiting habeas corpus appeals of criminal convictions will have no
effect on serious crime.
23. Most victims’ rights laws and programs are worthy ideas that were
long overdue. Only a few, however, provide the kind of direct
services that are likely to reduce crime.
24. Attempts to ban the possession of handguns, or certain kinds of
guns, are not a viable option for reducing crime.
25. Laws that seek to keep guns out of the hands of criminals and
the mentally ill have at best some limited effect but are easily evaded
by the black market in guns.
26. Laws designed to allow more people to carry guns and laws that
allow them to use their guns in a greater range of circumstances are
more likely to increase rather than reduce homicides.
27. Carefully designed and focused programs directed toward a small
group of known offenders have been found to be effective in reducing
gun violence.
28. Probation and parole have their proper places in the criminal justice
system, but there is no evidence of any programs likely to make them
more effective in reducing crime.
29. Traditional diversion programs do not reduce serious crime.
30. Home confinement and electronic monitoring do not reduce crime.
31. There is little persuasive evidence that faith-based treatment
programs are any more or any less effective in reducing crime than
are secular treatment programs.
32. Carefully designed and well-managed drug courts are a promising
treatment program that have demonstrated their effectiveness in
reducing crime.
xix
175
186
190
199
206
217
220
247
263
267
272
276
293
297
301
305
308
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xx
PROPOSITIONS
33. The evidence-based corrections movement is an important
development, but at this point, the jury is still out on whether it
will help reduce crime.
34. Enhancing legitimacy is an important, and indeed necessary, strategy
for reducing crime.
35. Drug courts are a promising approach to reducing both drug use
and crime among criminal offenders.
36. The impact of legalizing drugs on serious crime is not known
at this time.
310
330
358
361
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Foreword
S
hortly after its initial publication, Samuel Walker’s Sense and Nonsense
about Crime was recognized as an important new book, a substantive contribution to the literature on crime and justice. Over the years, he has
reworked its themes and developed its arguments in five more editions
(updating the title to reflect an expanded discussion of drugs and drug policy
in the third edition), and the field’s appreciation of this book has only
increased. Today, it is a major text in the study of crime and justice; some
call it a nascent classic work in its field. It is a respected argument about our
knowledge base for crime and justice, and it is one of those rare books that
are deeply respected by scholars and policymakers alike.
It is, therefore, with extraordinary pleasure that I welcome the eighth edition to the Wadsworth Contemporary Issues in Crime and Justice Series. The
series is devoted to giving detailed and effective exposure to important or emerging issues and problems that ordinarily receive insufficient attention in traditional
textbooks. The series also publishes books meant to provoke thought and change
perspectives by challenging readers to become more sophisticated consumers of
crime and justice knowledge. If you are looking for a book that will make you
an informed student of crime and justice policy and practice, you could not do
better than the one you are now holding.
Why is this book so important? There are two reasons. First, so much of
what is commonly believed about crime—and so much of what shapes public
policy on crime—is nonsense. Second, Walker’s book was the first (and is
still the most effective) book written to point that out. The book provides
a masterful critique of the U.S. penchant for short-sighted, metaphorical
strategies to prevent crime (boot camps are a good example) or feel-good
rhetoric about crime priorities (end poverty, end crime) that have, over the
years, not gotten us far in our pursuit of a safer society. Today, we are
enjoying a welcome, sustained national drop in crime rates. But this drop
still leaves us with higher rates of crime than we want, and (perhaps more
xxi
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xxii
FOREWORD
to the point) the source of the drop is more of a mystery to us than a lesson
in crime prevention policy.
The contribution of this book—what makes this book special—is its willingness to show evenhandedly how favorite strategies of diverse political agendas
have as their foundation some degree of “nonsense.” If there is a lesson that
this book brings to us repeatedly, it is that cherished images of crime and justice
are flawed, inaccurate, and doomed to fail for particular reasons of the more or
less well-known facts that we so often want to ignore to sustain our favorite
ideologies. This book challenges us where we need to be challenged: in our willingness to ignore reality to nurture our frequently inadvisable pet ideas about
crime and crime fighting.
You want your police to be tough, to chase dangerous criminals, to make
life-saving arrests? Well, Professor Walker points out that you have to contend
with the fact that police spend little of their time acting in this way, and even
when they do, not much in the way of crime control seems to result. You want
your judges to lock’em up and throw away the key? Walker shows all the ways
that this belief is expensive and ineffective, even counterproductive. You think
we need to save money through closer surveillance of the people convicted of
crime? Make our lives safer by treating juveniles as though they were adults? End
drug abuse through an all-out war on drugs? Here again, the book sheds cool
light on hot emotions, showing how such strategies can backfire.
This book is not, however, just about nonsense in crime and justice. Perhaps
nonsense gets the majority of the attention because so much of what we do is
based on faulty thinking. But Walker is willing to tell us what makes “sense” as
well. Big proposals lack much support, and politically popular proposals may be
downright silly. But there are smaller, less ambitious ways in which we can contribute to a safer society, and we can do so without suspending our constitutional
rights or giving up our public freedoms. One way we have learned to be smarter
about crime is through the philosophy of evidence-based practice. This approach
asks hard questions about criminal policy, seeking to base crime strategies on
established studies that show those policies will work. Professor Walker applies
the evidence-based criterion to his review of crime and justice policy: what
emerges is a powerfully dispassionate analysis that gives us a carefully crafted challenge to start “making sense” in the way in which we talk about crime and
develop policies to cope with it.
If you are getting ready to read this book, chances are you are contemplating
a career in the field of criminal justice. At the very least, you have an informed
citizen’s interest in the problems of crime and justice. In either case, you have
come to the right place to become more knowledgeable in your pursuits. After
you read this book, you will join a large number of its alumni, dedicated to
crime policies that make sense. I commend you.
Todd R. Clear
Series Editor
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Preface
T
he eighth edition marks the thirtieth anniversary of Sense and Nonsense
about Crime. Much has changed over those thirty years in U.S. society
and in criminal justice. It has been an exciting challenge to keep pace
with those changes and make sure that this edition is relevant to current
developments.
When the first edition appeared, crack was just beginning to appear on the
streets of the United States. One result was an epidemic of gun violence among
young men. Some criminologists predicted that youth homicides would continue to soar. They didn’t. Instead, serious crime, including homicide, began a
completely surprising decline that is unprecedented in the United States. In
New York City and other cities, violent crime has dropped to levels not seen
since the early 1960s. Keeping track of these changes, and attempting to explain
them, has been an important but necessary task. When the first edition of this
book appeared, policymakers and criminologists were in the midst of a fierce
debate over “career criminals.” The questions of the day were how to identify
that small group of offenders and what would be the impact of different policies
that targeted them. You don’t hear much about career criminals today, however.
Policies that were hot new ideas twenty-five years ago did not work out, criminological research undermined most of the underlying assumptions, and the policy debate has moved on.
The eighth edition of Sense and Nonsense continues the expanded title Crime,
Drugs, and Communities, which is the second change in the subtitle since the first
edition. These changes reflect my efforts to keep the book relevant to the changing world of crime and criminal justice. The focus on communities began with
the sixth edition and is now incorporated into the expanded title, Crime, Drugs,
and Communities. As various chapters explain, some of the most important innovations in crime policy have a community focus: problem-oriented policing,
community policing, community prosecution, focused deterrence programs,
xxiii
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xxiv
PREFACE
and now a new emphasis on community reinvestment as a strategy for better
dealing with offenders released from prison.
The new edition continues the “nonsense” theme of the first edition. We
continue to have crime policies that are not supported by empirical evidence
and which, in many cases, only make matters worse. Chapter 7, for example,
covers sex offender registration and notification laws, which often include restrictions on where sex offenders can live. As you will learn, these requirements
cover many offenders who are not going to be dangerous predators. As a result,
law enforcement and corrections officers carry huge caseloads and struggle to
focus on the few offenders who really do pose a possible risk to the community.
Other new policies that seem to have little empirical support continue to appear.
This is the latest in “predictive policing.” Our discussion is highly critical of it.
Time will tell whether it proves to have some value or whether it is simply one
more item in the long list of nonsense policies.
At the same time, this edition puts a greater emphasis on the “sense” theme.
There is growing evidence that some programs actually do work, because they are
solidly rooted in the best criminological research. People often ask if academic
research ever makes a practical contribution to crime policy. The answer is that
yes, some of it does. As you will learn, there is an emerging consensus that some
—but not all—problem-oriented policing programs, drug courts, and community
prosecution programs can be effective. Most interesting, as you will learn in Chapter 6, is that focused deterrence programs have been found to be effective because
they differ significantly from traditional deterrence-oriented programs.
The emergence of crime policies that have been found to be effective
through rigorous evaluation is an extremely exciting development. If nothing
else, it demonstrates the maturity of the field of criminology, and the new standards for effectiveness that have developed. Future editions of this book will
assess whether this promise is fulfilled in practice.
New elements in the Eighth edition include the following:
Chapter 1 includes up-to-date information about gun violence, including
mass shootings and the gun violence crisis in Chicago; a new Sidebar on
“fads” in crime policy, citing issues that were current in older editions of the
book but have since faded away; an expanded discussion of evidence-based
crime policy; a provocative new sidebar on the argument that lead in the
environment explains long-term crime trends.
Chapter 2 contains discussions of both the Sandy Hook School shooting and
the George Zimmerman trial to illustrate the celebrated case syndrome; the
most recent data on school safety to illustrate the gap between public perceptions of violent crime and the empirical reality.
Chapter 3 has been substantially revised to provide a better discussion of
long-term imprisonment trends, with a discussion of “mass incarceration,” as
well as the new developments that indicate a change in the public mood.
Chapter 4 replaces the outdated emphasis on career criminals with a more
relevant focus on the prediction problem in criminal justice.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PREFACE
xxv
Chapter 5 has been reorganized to put all of the various “smart policing”
efforts in a broader perspective; additional information of focused deterrence
programs; new material on the Boston Marathon bombing in the discussion
of closed-circuit television (CCTV) systems as a deterrent to crime; brandnew discussions of both “predictive policing” and the potential role of
drones as a form of police patrol; a critical discussion of the recent “reinvestment” proposal to shift public funding from imprisonment to innovative
police programs.
Chapter 6 has an important discussion the recent National Academy of
Sciences report on deterrence and the death penalty and its implications for
the entire theory of deterrence. This chapter also has an important new
section of special DUI courts that are modeled after drug courts, which have
proven to be effective.
Chapter 7 has been completely revised to provide a more coherent discussion
of trends in sentencing over the past few decades and the evidence of a new
turn in state sentencing laws against the overuse of incarceration.
Chapter 8 has a new critical discussion of the two 2012 Supreme Court
decisions on plea bargaining, which some people believe will have a radical
effect on the practice, whereas others disagree.
Chapter 9 has been completely rewritten and reorganized, with a new
emphasis on “special populations” of crime victims: women, the elderly, and
juvenile runaways and thrown-aways.
Chapter 10 has been updated with discussions of the important recent mass
shooting cases and the George Zimmerman trial. There is a new sidebar on
“Stand-Your-Ground” laws and the evidence on their impact. There is also
a new discussion of guns and the mentally ill.
Chapter 11 has a greatly expanded examination of drug courts and a discussion of why they are often more effective than other treatment programs.
Chapter 12 has been completely reorganized and rewritten to focus on procedural justice and the prospects for securing greater compliance with the law.
Chapter 13 includes new material on the impact of the Mexican drug cartels
on crime and violence in the United States.
Chapter 14 continues and expands the discussion begun in the seventh edition that draws on the promising new developments discussed in the book
that have demonstrated effectiveness, including focused deterrence, drug
courts, and procedural justice.
Ancillaries
eBank Instructor’s Resource Manual with Test Bank. The manual includes
learning objectives, key terms, a detailed chapter outline, discussion topics, and a
test bank. Each chapter’s test bank contains questions in multiple-choice, true–
false, fill-in-the-blank, and essay formats, with a full answer key. The test bank is
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xxvi
PREFACE
coded to the learning objectives that appear in the main text, and includes the
page numbers in the main text where the answers can be found. Finally, each
question in the test bank has been carefully reviewed by experienced criminal
justice instructors for quality, accuracy, and content coverage. The manual is
available for download on the password-protected web site and can also be
obtained by e-mailing your local Cengage Learning representative.
Dedication
I would like to dedicate this book to Mary Ann Lamanna, who has been a wonderful companion over thirty years. But despite the demands of her own publishing deadlines over the years, she knows that there is always time for a movie.
About the Author
Samuel Walker is Professor Emeitus of Criminal Justice at the University of
Nebraska–Omaha, where he taught for thirty-one years. He is the author of
fourteen books on policing, criminal justice history and policy, and civil liberties.
His most recent books include Presidents and Civil Liberties from Wilson to Obama
(2012) and The New World of Police Accountability, 2nd. ed. (Sage, 2014). He continues to write and consult on issues of police accountability, focusing primarily
on citizen oversight of the police and police early intervention systems.
Samuel Walker
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PART
I
Thinking Clearly about Crime
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
1
Crime and Policy:
A Complex Problem
CRIME TRENDS: CONFLICTING, CONFUSING
Crime trends in the United States are conflicting, confusing, and seemingly contradictory. Murders in Chicago soared to 513 in 2012, which was up from 448
in 2010, and the dramatic increase in violent gun deaths made national news.
But in New York City, murders (and all crime) fell to a level not seen since
the 1960s. Violent crime was up in Baltimore but down in Washington, DC
just sixty miles away.1
Other contradictions are easy to find. Mass shooting incidents such as the
2012 Sandy Hook School massacre in which twenty-six people died seem to
be on upsurge. Earlier in the 2012 movie multiplex shooting in Aurora, Colorado, James Holmes shot and killed twelve people and wounded fifty-eight
others. His weapons included a shotgun, a semi-automatic rifle, and a Glock
22 handgun. In 2011, Congresswoman Gabby Giffords was seriously wounded,
six people died, and eleven others were wounded in a shooting in Tucson,
Arizona. These horrific shooting incidents, however, occurred in the context
of a long-term decline in violent crime, including homicides. One part of
that decline was a dramatic reduction in domestic violence. Between 1994
and 2010 the rate of intimate partner violence fell from 9.8 to 3.6 per 1,000,
which is a decline of 63.6 percent.2
The decline in domestic violence is only one part of a broader decline in
both violent and property crimes that began in 1993. According to Uniform
Crime Reports (UCR), the robbery rate fell from a peak of 272.7 per 100,000
in 1991 to 112.9 in 2012. The burglary rate also fell by half from its peak in
1974 to 2010. It is true that the National Crime Victimization Survey (NCVS),
an alternative measure of crime, reported a 15.4 percent increase in violent crime
in 2012 compared to 2011, and this is cause for concern that should be
2
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
3
Rate per 1,000 persons age 12 or older
100
80
60
Total violent crime
Not reported
to police
40
20
Reported to police
0
'93 '94 '95 '96 '97 '98 '99 '00 '01 '02 '03 '04 '05 '06* '07 '08 '09 '10 '11 '12
F I G U R E 1.1 Violent victimization reported and not reported to police, 1993–2012.
*See original report for cautions about using 2006 data.
SOURCE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2012 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2013).
monitored closely, but the important story is the broader 18.7 percent decline in
violent crime between 2003 and 2012, a trend that reflects the all-important
Great American Crime Drop.3
The contradictions in crime trends have an important racial dimension. In
the Chicago homicides, young African American men are both the primary
offenders and the victims. But by contrast, in virtually all of the mass shooting
cases, the perpetrators were young white males, and all but a few of the victims
were white. At the same time, however, for domestic violence homicides,
African Americans enjoyed the same significant decline in vicitimzations as
white Americans, and enjoyed an even greater reduction in that violence than
whites. As we begin our search for sensible and effective crime policies in this
book we must continually be aware of the often surprising contradictions regarding crime and victimization in the United States.4
THE GREAT AMERICAN CRIME DROP
The dramatic decline in crime since the early 1990s is a historic event, the longest and largest since we began keeping national statistics on crime. We call this
event The Great American Crime Drop. With the exception of some cities, and
certain parts of many cities, Americans are much safer today than they were
twenty years ago. In New York City, murders fell from an astonishing 2,260 in
199 to only 416 in 2012. The number of murders was the lowest since the
1960s. On the west coast, there were only 38 murders in 2011 in San Diego,
compared with 167 in 1991.5
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
4
CHAPTER
1
The crime drop seems like a miracle to many Americans. For the first time
in a generation, there is good news about crime and violence. When crime rates
began to soar around 1963, crime ripped the social fabric of the United States
and became a major issue in U.S. politics. In addition to the harm inflicted by
particular crimes—murder, robbery, and rape—crime devastates our communities, instilling fear and causing people to move out of their neighborhoods. In the
political realm, moreover, the issue of “crime” became intertwined with race,
aggravating the racial polarization of U.S. society.6
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
5
Is the Crime Drop Genuine?
Some skeptics question whether the crime drop is genuine, suggesting that it
might be a fluke, a temporary blip, or statistical manipulation. These doubts are
no longer valid. All of the evidence indicates that the crime drop is indeed real.
First, the NCVS is regarded as a reliable measure of criminal activity. No criminologist has ever suggested that the data are manipulated or methodologically
flawed. Second, the NCVS trends have continued for twenty years and cannot
be dismissed as a temporary phenomenon. Third, even though the FBI’s UCR
uses a different methodology, and does not measure all crimes committed, it too
has reported significant declines in crime over the past five to twenty years.7
Explaining the Crime Drop
How do we explain the Great American Crime Drop? What are the causes?
Criminologists and policy analysts have hotly debated these questions. The advocates of particular policies all argue that it was their favored approach: increased
incarceration, community policing, a decline in the use of crack cocaine, a stronger economy, and so on. Franklin Zimring offered a fresh perspective on this
debate with the simple idea of comparing crime trends in the United Sates to
other countries. What he found puts the Great American Crime Drop in a useful
perspective.
Zimring found that in the decade of the 1990s, several countries experienced
declines in crime. The most important example is Canada, where crime went
down in six of the seven UCR categories. Canada is a particularly useful comparison for us because it is contiguous to the United States, shares a common
language (with the partial exception of French-speaking Quebec) and culture,
and the two countries have close economic relations. If crime trends in the two
countries are so similar, the changes in the United States cannot be readily
explained by unique U.S. factors such as police strategies or imprisonment
trends. Let’s take a closer look at this issue.8
The United States and Canada began the decade of the 1990s with different
levels of crime, especially violent crime. The murder and robbery rates in the
United States were far higher than in Canada. That is a basic fact about crime
in the United States: it has high levels of violent crime compared with other
industrialized countries. Nonetheless, it is the similarity in the declines in the
two countries that commands our attention.
The most important issue involves imprisonment. The prison population in
the United States soared in the 1990s, increasing 57 percent, while it dropped 6
percent in Canada.9 Although this hardly settles the debate, it calls into question
the role of incarceration on the Great American Crime Drop. How could
Canada get roughly the same results by moving in the opposite direction on
imprisonment? A similar problem arises with regard to the number of police.
The Community Oriented Policing Services (COPS) program provided federal
funds to increase the number of police officers in the United States by something
like sixty to seventy-five thousand. Some analysts estimate that this represented a
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
6
CHAPTER
1
14 percent increase in the police-to-population ratio. In Canada, meanwhile, the
ratio fell by an estimated 10 percent. These data make it difficult to argue that
increasing the number of police officers contributed to the Great American
Crime Drop. A similar problem exists with regard to economic factors. While
the Canadian economy improved, just as it did in the United States, unemployment was consistently higher than in the United States throughout the period.
Yet, crime went down just as it did in the United States despite an indicator that
suggests it should not.10
In the end, how then do we explain the “extraordinary parallels” in crime
trends in the two countries? The “central puzzle,” Zimring argues, lies in the fact
that Canada experienced a greater decline “than could be explained by any visible causes.” He concludes that it might involve broad changes in behavior that
are beyond the reach of social science to explain. In short, there are no “easy
explanations.”
The absence of easy explanations is extremely important and is a theme that
runs through this book. Criminal behavior is extremely complex, and so is the
administration of justice that has at least some effect on crime. The basic lesson is
that we should always be on guard against simple answers; and also be careful
about jumping to conclusions based on short-term data, and be wary of anyone
claiming that their favorite crime policy is responsible for some recent good
news.
In a collection of articles in The Crime Drop in America, Al Blumstein and Joel
Wallman reach a conclusion roughly similar to Zimring’s, arguing that “no single
factor can be invoked as the cause of the crime decline in the 1990s.”11
It is too early for us to throw up our hands and say we can’t explain anything. We should not give up just because there are no easy, immediate answers.
One of the major goals of this book, after all, is to clear away the nonsense about
crime policy. Consequently, we have to look more closely at the various explanations that have been offered for the crime drop. We will find some plausible
reasons to explain at least part of the crime drop in some of these arguments.
There is fairly persuasive evidence, for example, that the dramatic decline in
the use of crack had a major impact on crime trends. We will look at this
in detail in Chapter 13. At the same time, there is some promising evidence
regarding the impact of recent innovations in policing—particularly focused
deterrence—although we should not exaggerate their impact on national crime
rates.
THE PURPOSE OF THIS BOOK
This book is a search for effective crime policies. It attempts to answer one basic
question: what works? What criminal justice policies are effective in reducing serious crime? We will review some of the major crime control proposals and evaluate their effectiveness in light of what we know about crime and justice.
Previous editions of this book, written when crime rates were high, sought to
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
BOX
1.1
7
DID CRIME FALL BECAUSE OF LEGALIZED ABORTION?
Some economists made the controversial argument that the legalization of abortion by the 1973 Roe
v. Wade decision played a major role in the crime drop. Abortion, they argued, resulted in a cohort
of 1.5 million “unborn offenders,” which would have entered its high crime years (fifteen to
twenty-four years) in the early 1990s, and its absence accounted for part of the crime drop that
began in 1993. Additionally, they argued, abortions were disproportionately high among women
whose children would be most at risk for criminal behavior (poor, single mothers, etc.).12
Many criminologists stayed away from this controversial idea, but Franklin Zimring examined
it closely and found that the evidence does not support it. He found that despite 1.5 million annual
abortions, the annual number of live births actually increased slowly but steadily after Roe v. Wade.
In short, there was no reduction of the number of youths in their high crime years in the early
1990s. Additionally, the percentage of births to single mothers increased significantly in the period.
Finally, there is the matter of timing. The number of abortions began to increase beginning in
1974. The first wave of unborn offenders would have been fifteen in 1989 and crime did not begin
to fall until 1993. Thus, the expected crime drop because of abortion did not begin when the
economists argued it should have.13
There is an important lesson in the argument that “abortion caused the crime drop.” We
should always be skeptical of provocative, single-explanations theories for any change in crime patterns. If nothing else, this book is designed to foster a healthy skepticism and critical thinking about
crime and crime policy.
determine what might work. Now, in the face of the great crime drop, we have
to turn the question around: What has worked? Did certain crime policies contribute to the reduction in crime? If so, which ones? Why exactly were they
effective? And can the lessons from one success story be transferred to other programs in other parts of the criminal justice system?
Our examination will also tell us a lot about what does not work. In fact, we
will spend more time on unsuccessful policies (the nonsense) than successful
ones. We begin in this section by discussing some threshold issues that will help
clarify our thinking. First we discuss a problem-oriented approach to crime policy and the importance of thinking about particular crimes rather than crime as
an undifferentiated phenomenon. Second, we discuss the distinction between
contextual factors that affect crime and criminal justice policies. This book
focuses on policies, but we should not forget the importance of the broader
social context. Third, we discuss evidence-based crime policy, which has become
the new standard for evaluating the effectiveness of crime policies.
Problem-Oriented Crime Policy
We can begin to make sense of crime in the United States by taking a problemoriented crime policy (POCP) approach. More than thirty years ago Professor
Herman Goldstein developed the idea of problem-oriented policing (POP),
and POP eventually became a widely used approach in policing.14 POP holds
that the police should quit thinking about crime as a single undifferentiated phenomenon and instead break it down into specific components: commercial robberies, household burglaries, graffiti, open-air drug dealing, nuisance disorders,
and so on. Each one is different, with different degrees of seriousness, different
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
8
CHAPTER
BOX
1.2
1
OR WAS IT BECAUSE OF LEAD?
An investigative reporter in 2013 advanced the startling argument that the crime drop was the result
of lead, and not increased imprisonment, the economy, changes in drug-use patterns, or other
commonly cited causal factors. Lead?, you might ask. What does lead have to do with crime?
Actually, lead may have a lot to do with criminal behavior. It is well-established in the medical literature that exposure to lead in children contributes to lower IQ levels, hyperactivity and
other behavioral problems, and learning disabilities. All of these effects can contribute to problems
in school, juvenile delinquency, and then more serious adult crime. A low IQ and hyperactivity
easily lead to suspensions and then expulsion from school, and that can send a young person on the
path to delinquency and crime.
Concerns about the environment and public health led to a national effort to reduce the levels
of lead in the environment. The biggest sources of lead have been leaded gas and lead-based paint.
Both of which have been substantially reduced since the 1970s. The use of leaded gas soared from
the 1940s through the 1970s, when environmental regulations began reducing it. Advocates of the
lead-crime theory allow for a lag of about twenty-three years, and this they believe explains both
the great increase in crime in the 1960s and the great crime drop in the 1990s.
The impact of lead is also not spread evenly. Lead from automobile tailpipes settles into the
ground where it can still affect people. Older parts of cities still have this legacy, whereas newer
suburbs never had a lot of automobile traffic. Older neighborhoods, of course, are where the poor
live, and thus lead contributes to other social factors associated with criminal behavior. Compounding this is the fact that older homes still have many houses with lead-based paint, despite
efforts to eliminate it. Newer houses were built after lead-based paint was prohibited.
Is this a plausible argument? Can we attribute fluctuations in the crime rate to the two main
sources of lead in the environment? Maybe, maybe not. The overlap between lead and poor, high
crime neighborhoods has merit. And when we consider who lives in poor neighborhoods, the
connection takes on social class and racial dimensions. But our crime rates have fluctuated in a more
complex way that the lead-crime advocates admit. Crime leveled off in the 1970s, but homicides
among youths soared in the late 1980s before plunging in the early 1990s. The argument that the
drug crack best explains the 1980s homicide surge and decline is still persuasive. And the lead-crime
argument does not explain the sudden rise in gun homicides in Chicago in 2011 and 2012, to cite
one example, and the persistent high levels of gun violence in some cities compared with the
declines in other cities.
In short, as with other single-cause theories, the lead-crime argument is a little too simplistic.
SOURCE: Kevin Drum, “America’s Real Criminal Element: Lead,” Mother Jones (January 3, 2013). See also, Gerald
Markowitz and David Rosner, Lead Wars (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2013).
causes, and different impacts on individuals and neighborhoods. And each one
requires a different response. The Center for Problem-Oriented Policing has
published guides on street robbery, drive by shootings, graffiti, and a wide
range of other crime and disorder categories.15
Goldstein’s concept of POP also called on the police to put less emphasis on
responding to symptoms—mainly 911 calls—and to search for the underlying
causes that the police can address. To find effective responses, Goldstein advised,
the police should use the model of Scanning, Analysis, Response, and Assessment
(SARA): study the problem (Scan), Analyze data, develop an appropriate
Response, and the conduct an Assessment of the impact.16
We can apply Goldstein’s concept of POP to the entire criminal justice system with POCP. Applying it to the gun violence issues we have already
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
BOX
1.3
9
THE FAD SYNDROME IN CRIME POLICY
Criminal justice policy debates have a long history of fads: exciting ideas that appear suddenly,
attract a lot of attention, and in some cases have a major impact on policy, and then suddenly fade
away and are forgotten. We call it the Fad Syndrome, and you can track it by looking through the
first seven editions of this book. (I did, and believe me it is a depressing experience.) Here is a short
list of some of the major fads (dare we call them “major offenders”?).
Selective Incapacitation.
The first edition of this book gave special attention to the idea of selective incapacitation.
Research had found that a small group of offenders are responsible for a large percentage of all
serious crimes. Those findings led to the idea that if we could just identify those offenders and
give them long prison sentences, we would achieve substantial reductions in serious crime. It
didn’t work out, and no one talks about selective incapacitation. Instead, the United States
embarked on a decades-long policy of gross incapacitation—locking up massive numbers of
people. This edition keeps the discussion of selective incapacitation (Chapters 4 and 7) because
it illuminates a number of issues that are very relevant to current crime policy debates.
Repealing the Exclusionary Rule and the Miranda Warning.
The first editions of this book examined the conservative calls for repealing the exclusionary
rule and the Miranda warning. Conservatives were convinced that these and other alleged
“loopholes” allowed many criminals to go free and were one of the main reasons why the
criminal justice system was so weak in controlling crime. You don’t hear much about ending
either the exclusionary rule or Miranda today (although both have been weakened by the
Supreme Court) because the evidence never supported the argument that they limited police
effectiveness. We have continued to cover the debate over these two policies, however,
because the analysis helps us to understand police crime-fighting efforts.
Boot Camps.
Boot camps were suddenly all the rage in the 1980s and were adopted by many states. Boot
camps are short-term facilities for felony offenders designed to “correct” their behavior
through a rigorous military-style regimen of physical exercise along with other correctional
programs. The purely military aspects caught the public eye, although the more successful
programs did not emphasize that. And then, as soon as they appeared, they vanished from
policy debates. The research simply did not find any evidence that they were any more effective in reducing recidivism than ordinary sentences.
“Three Strikes and You’re Out.”
“Three strikes and you’re out” sentencing law exploded on the national scene in the mid1990s. President Bill Clinton gave the idea a strong endorsement, and many states jumped on
the band wagon and passed three-strikes laws. With only some variation, the laws provided
for a mandatory and long prison sentence for a third felony conviction. Virtually all criminologists denounced the idea, pointing out that it completely ignored the severity of the crimes
involved. A felony conviction for theft of a lawn mower (one early case involved theft of a
pizza) counted the same as an armed robbery or sexual assault. Nor did they take into account
relevant factors regarding the offender. The long sentences only added to the already growing
prison population. California passed the most publicized law, and Los Angeles County made
the heaviest use of it. Prosecutors in other jurisdictions generally found ways to evade the law.
You don’t hear much about three-strike laws today, except in reference to an embarrassing
policy from the past.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
10
CHAPTER
1
discussed, our scan quickly tells us that street-level and often gang-related shootings are different from mass shooting incidents at shopping malls or schools.
They have different patterns of perpetrators, generally different patterns of victims, and different weapons used. A more detailed scan could be done for
domestic violence homicides and robbery-related homicides. In later chapters of
this book, we will continue the process with a scan, analysis, and response to
each of these problems.
Contextual versus Policy Factors
In their paper for the Urban Institute, “Reflections on the Crime Decline Lessons for the Future?” Jeremy Travis and Michelle Waul make an important distinction between contextual and policy factors that affect crime.17 The
distinction is crucial. It may be that certain contextual factors—poverty, demographic changes—have a major impact on crime, and we should not ignore
them. In this book, however, we are concerned with crime policies, and we
want to keep our eye focused on that subject.
Contextual factors include demographic changes, the rise and fall of the crack
cocaine epidemic, and changes in labor markets. The increase in the proportion
of crime-prone young people in the population in the 1960s (the famous Baby
Boom–era) explained about half of the great crime increase in the 1960s, but the
influence of demography has been far more complicated in the last thirty years.
A demographic analysis failed to predict the great increase in violent crime in the
mid-1980s, as well as the sharp decline after 1993. The changing popularity of
crack provides a much better explanation. The rise in violent crime coincided
with the arrival of crack, and the crime drop has coincided with its waning popularity. Travis and Waul suggest that a younger generation saw the devastating
effects of crack and decided that the drug was just not cool. With respect to
changing labor markets, the Urban Institute paper cites data showing that the
real wages (actual wages adjusted for inflation) of low-skilled workers declined
by almost 25 percent from the early 1980s to 1993, when it bottomed out
(from 9.00 per hour to 6.74).
The criminal justice policies that the Urban Institute paper considers most relevant include innovations in policing (Chapters 5 and 14), the increase in incarceration and consequent incapacitation of offenders (Chapter 7), and several gun
control policies (which we will examine in detail in Chapter 10). After considering
all these, the Urban Institute paper concludes that no single factor can explain the
great crime drop. Instead, it is probably the interplay of different factors, including
both contextual factors and criminal justice policies, that best explains it. If this is
true, one of the challenges in this book is for us to identify which of those factors
contributed to the crime drop, and the relative importance of each one.
Looking ahead, one of the arguments in this book is that no single policy is
likely to be the main factor in reducing crime. A sensible approach is that effective crime reduction is likely to be the result of several different policies working
together. Consequently, our analysis shifts the focus from specific policies or
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
11
components of the justice system (for example, police, sentencing) to the communities where the impact of different policies are felt.
THE ECONOMIC CRISIS AS A CONTEXTUAL FACTOR The
economic recession that began in 2008 is an important new contextual factor
that has created a serious resource crisis in U.S. criminal justice. Common sense
tells us that to be effective, a crime policy has to have sufficient resources. That is
true regardless of what your goals are. If you believe that police patrol deters
crime, you have to have enough officers and patrol cars to effectively accomplish
that goal. If you believe that drug treatment programs reduce crime, you have to
have enough treatment programs, with enough staff and beds (for residential
programs) to get the job done.
Police department budgets have been severely hit by the recession. Many
police departments are short-handed because they have been forced to lay off
officers or been unable to hire new officers to replace retirees. Budget cuts also
affect the quality of policing. A Police Executive Research Forum (PERF) report
found that training was often one of the first programs to be reduced. Budget
constraints also make it difficult or impossible for departments to undertake
innovative policing strategies.18
The resource crisis has affected other parts of the criminal justice system.
Public defenders’ offices have increased caseloads, which prevent them from providing adequate legal representation for their clients. A study in Kentucky found
that prosecutors have a budget that exceeds 130 million for handling cases
involving the indigent, while public defenders have only 56 million for the
same cases. In Harris County, Texas (Houston), the prosecutor’s office has thirty
investigators, but there are none for defense attorneys who were being paid by
contract.19 As a result, public defenders don’t have time to work with their clients, seek out potential witnesses, or examine the evidence carefully. They do
not have the time to negotiate plea bargains as well as they might.
The lack of resources has aggravated an already serious shortage of drug
treatment programs. An Urban Institute study found that among 1.5 million
offenders at risk for drug abuse or dependency, only about 55,000 actually
receive treatment. That is only 3.8 percent of the need. The cost of providing
that treatment was estimated at 1 billion—a huge cost, to be sure. But studies
have estimated that drug courts and related treatments save 2.21 for every 1.00
invested. The savings are estimated on the basis of the dollar cost of the number
of crimes a nontreated offender would commit (including cost to victims, cost of
arrest, cost of detention and adjudication, and cost of the sentence). Thus, the 1
billion investment would save 2.21 billion, for a net savings to society of about
1.2 billion annually.20
Prisons across the country are overcrowded; some of them dangerously so.
The crisis in California is simply the worst in any state by far. In 2009 California
prisons held 167,000 prisoners and were at almost double their official capacity.
A federal judge finally ordered the state to reduce its number of prisoners by
41,000. Under the state’s Public Safety Realignment law, 15,000 prisoners have
been transferred to county jails. This change, however, did not reduce the
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
12
CHAPTER
1
number of people incarcerated, only relocated them, transferring the resource
problem to the local jails. An expert panel on adult offender rehabilitation
found that 50 percent of those leaving prison had not participated in any work
or rehabilitation program and never had a work assignment for their entire prison
term.21
The resource crisis in California extends to parole officers who had case
loads averaging seventy parolees per officer. This is up from forty-five per officer
in the 1970s; the American Probation and Parole Association recommends fifty
per officer. As a result, many parolees receive absolutely no meaningful supervision whatsoever. About 80 percent of the parolees have two 15-minute, faceto-face meetings per month with their parole officers. In the system’s least
restrictive supervision category, parolees “report” by mailing a post card to their
parole officer.22
A basic lesson is apparent here: The justice system needs adequate resourses
to handle its routine workload effectively. When it is overloaded, serious problems arise. The system does not “collapse” like a building, however. It keeps
on going, but only through adjustments that are often undesirable and counterproductive with respect to effective crime control.
The New Standard: Evidence-Based Crime Policy
A new standard has emerged for evaluating the effectiveness of crime policies. It
is a far higher and demanding scientific standard than has been used in the past.
Evidence-based policymaking is extensively used in healthcare policy and has
become one of the most important developments in criminology. Take a look
at the Duke University Medical Center’s Introduction to Evidence-Based Practice to get an idea of how extensive the movement is in the field of medicine.23
Evidence-based policy making requires that policies to be based on a solid foundation of evidence based on research that meets the highest scientific standards.
Evidence-based policy making has taken root in criminal justice. George
Mason University houses both a Center for Evidence-Based Crime Policy
(CEBCP) and an Evidence-Based Policing Research Program.24 In addition to
policing, the CEBCP maintains research related to boot camps, court-mandated
interventions for persons convicted of domestic violence, the effectiveness of
incarceration-based drug treatment programs, and others issues.25 The Center for
Evidence-Based Corrections at the University of California–Irvine, meanwhile,
has a program of research and technical assistance, with much of it focused on
the California corrections system.26 A Justice Department report, “Implementing
Evidence-Based Policy and Practice in Community Corrections,” lists eight
“Principles for Effective Intervention.”27 We will examine them in Chapter 11.
A study of the application of evidence-based probation (EBP) in Oklahoma,
meanwhile, found that the application of EBP practices were the crucial factor
in making reduced probation case loads effective in reducing recidivism.28
Evidence-based crime policy has added a refreshing, demanding, and long
overdue element of scientific rigor to policy debates. The former director of
the Office of Justice Programs, Deborah Daniels, declared: “In the past, criminal
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
13
justice practitioners operated on instinct and assumption, not science. They tried
new approaches, if they did so at all, because they sounded as though they
should be effective. But it did not occur to the practitioners to examine the
research before they instituted a particular practice, or to measure its effectiveness
as they deployed it.”29 Along the same lines, gang expert Malcolm W. Klein
made the somber observation that almost all crime control programs are
described as “promising” for the simple reason that “so little has been tested
properly.”30 The new era of evidence-based crime policy requires testing and
evidence of success. Later in this chapter, we call the traditional approach crime
control theology because it rests of faith rather than facts.
Even worse than the lack of evidence, many policies have been continued—
at great expense—despite the fact that good research has found them to be ineffective. Daniels cited the example of the Drug Abuse Resistance Education
(DARE) program, the highly popular school-based drug prevention initiative.
It has operated in as many as 75 percent of all school districts in some years at a
cost of about 200 million a year. The General Accountability Office (GAO)
reviewed evaluations of DARE, and in 2003 reported that there were “no statistically significant differences in illicit drug use between students who received
D.A.R.E. lessons in the fifth or sixth grade, referred to as intervention groups,
and students who did not—the control groups.”31
Even worse than being ineffective, some popular crime policies have actually
caused harm. Can this be possible? Can programs designed to help people actually leave them worse off? Sadly, the answer is yes. The noted criminologist Joan
McCord found an example in the famous Cambridge–Somerville (Massachusetts)
Youth Study from the 1930s to 1945 (with follow-up reports on the original
subjects through the early 1980s). The study matched boys younger than age
ten, who received treatment, with control group boys, who did not receive
treatment. The treatment consisted of professional counseling, referral to specialists for particular problems, tutoring, and activities such as summer camps.
McCord found that among the 103 pairs of youths who had different outcomes,
those in the treatment group were actually more likely to have been convicted of
a UCR Index crime, to have died at a younger age, or to have been diagnosed as
alcoholic, schizophrenic, or manic depressive than those boys not receiving treatment. Even worse, the adverse effects were greater among those boys who
received longer and more intensive treatment.32
Scared Straight is an idea that keeps reappearing in different forms. The original program was designed to frighten kids out of criminal behavior by exposing
them to the terrible conditions in prison. The Scared Straight idea was popularized by a 1979 television documentary and was eventually adopted in thirtyeight states. An evaluation of the San Quentin (California) Squires program,
however, found that after twelve months, 81 percent of the treatment group
had been arrested, compared with only 67 percent of the control group. (We
take a closer look at Scared Straight in Chapter 6).33
The disturbing news is that well-intentioned treatment can sometimes harm.
Evidence-based policy making is designed to guard against this possibility by
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
14
CHAPTER
1
requiring a review of program evaluations (and accepting only those evaluations
that meet scientific standards).
Evidence-based crime policy sets a high standard of experimental or quasiexperimental research design in which subjects are randomly assigned to treatment
and control groups. There is also a requirement of replication. Findings of effectiveness must be confirmed by similar studies using a similar research design. The
lack of replication has been a serious problem in criminal justice. Many policies
have been based on only one study. The 1974 Kansas City Preventive Patrol
Experiment (see Chapter 5) was enormously influential in thinking about policing,
but it was never completely replicated.34 Similarly, the Minneapolis Domestic Violence Experiment had a huge influence on the growth of mandatory arrest policies
for domestic violence. It was replicated, but when the replications found mixed
support for mandatory arrest, they were largely ignored.35 Finally, the findings of
replications need to be subject to systematic reviews of studies, or what are called
meta-analyses. To determine whether or not a policy is effective, policy analysts
should systematically review all of the available studies. It is no longer sufficient
that a policy be based on one study that finds it effective.
UNDERSTANDING CRIME AND JUSTICE
IN THE UNITED STATES
The first obstacle to developing sensible and effective crime policies is that most
people do not understand the nature of our many crime problems and also how
the criminal justice system works. Their understanding is based on preconceptions, myths, stereotypes, and media stories that distort reality. In a review of
public opinion surveys, the Sentencing Project found that the public “consistently misjudges” trends in crime; in the 1990s people continued to believe
that crime was rising, even though it was actually falling dramatically. The Sentencing Project also found that people consistently believe that the criminal justice system is far more lenient than it really is.36
This book argues that people simply don’t understand the nature of criminal
activity, how the police operate, what happens to defendants in court, who goes
to prison and for how long, and so on. A good example of serious public misunderstanding involves recidivism of convicted rapists. It is widely believed that
rapists reoffend at a high rate. Table 1.1, however, clearly indicates that rapists
have the lowest rearrest rates among people convicted of different serious crimes.
As a result of the level of public misunderstanding, which politicians generally perpetuate rather than try to correct, we have crime policies with no relation
to reality. This leads us to our first Proposition:
1
PROPOSITION
Most current crime control proposals are nonsense.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
15
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
T A B L E 1.1
Sorting fact from fiction: Sex offender rearrest rates
MYTH : Violent sex offenders have high recidivism rates
DATA: R eleased F elony D efendants R earrested Prior to Case Disposition, 2004
Felony Misdemeanor
Criminal Charge
Murder
R ape
Percent Rearrested
Rearrest
Rearrest
39
29
10
6
3
2
R obbery
21
12
9
Burglary
25
18
7
Drug Trafficking
21
14
7
EVIDENCE: Sex offenders (rape, at least) have the lowest reoffending rates.
POLICY IMPLICATIONS: Laws designed to control sex offenders through closer surveillance
(for example, sex offender registration laws; community notification) on the assumption that they
have high reoffending rates are based on erroneous assumptions.
SOURCE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2004 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2008).
Crime Problems in the United States
We can begin to unravel the complexities of the crime problems in the United
States by applying our POCP approach to the question: who are the victims of
crime? A quick scan reveals that your risk of being a crime victim depends a lot
on who you are, especially your race or ethnicity, age, gender, and your income.
The victimization rate for violent crime in 2012 was 25.2 per 1,000 for white
Americans, 24.5 for Hispanics, and 34.2 for African Americans. The burglary rate
for the poorest American housholds (annual income of less than 7,500) has always
been more than twice the rate for the wealthiest (income of 75,000 or more).37
Data on homicides provide especially dramatic evidence of the racial disparity in
victimization. Although the murder victimization rate for African Americans has
declined, as it has for whites, it is still about seven times higher than for whites
and even higher for men between the ages of eighteen and twenty-four.38
In short, many analysts believe that the United States has two crime problems: one that affects most white, middle-class Americans and another that
affects people of color, the poor, and young people of color in particular.
Poor neighborhoods have been overwhelmed by crime and drugs. For their
residents, whom some analysts call the underclass, the quality of daily life worsened significantly in the 1980s.39 In some neighborhoods, the drug trade
completely takes over the streets, with open drug use and selling. And despite
the crime drop, many of these neighborhoods are still filled with unacceptable
levels of violent crime, disorder, and community breakdown.
A different scan examines the crime problem in the United States according
to the most serious types of crime. Criminologists Franklin Zimring and Gordon
Hawkins argue that the problem is primarily one of violent crime, particularly
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
16
CHAPTER
1
lethal crime.40 The New England Coalition to Prevent Gun Violence dramatized the extraordinary level of gun-related lethal violence in the United States
compared with Great Britain. In 2008, there were a grand total of 42 gun-related
deaths in Great Britain. The population of the United States is about five times
that of Britain (61 million), so when we multiply their gun deaths by five, we get
210. Compare this with 30,364 gun-related deaths in the United States (for
2005), which includes homicides, suicides, and accidental deaths.
Great Britain: 210
populations)
5
210 (Estimated deaths, assuming equal
United States: 30,364 (Actual deaths)
England, meanwhile, does have a crime problem, but it is different than our
problem. The Institute for the Study of Civil Society compared crime rates in
the European Union (EU) with countries both inside and outside the EU and
found that the murder rate in England and Wales was 1.1 per 100,000 compared
with 5 per 100,000 in the United States (at the time the report was done). The
two countries were virtually tied with regard to rape, and England and Wales
actually had a slightly higher rate for robbery than the United States (137 per
100,000 and 133, respectively). For both assault and burglary, however, England
and Wales had significantly higher crime rates than the United States (927 per
100,000 and 262 for assault, respectively; 986 and 715 per 100,000 for burglary,
respectively). To be sure, the data are not necessarily comparable with respect to
crime definitions and reporting rates, but every other study has reached similar
conclusions. In short, other countries have crime problems, but the United States
is unique with respect to lethal violence.41
WAGING WAR ON CRIME
For a half a century we have been waging “war on crime.” President Lyndon Johnson, a liberal Democrat, first declared war on crime in 1965. Then President
Richard Nixon, a conservative Republican, announced his own war in 1969, and
followed with a famous war on drugs announcement in 1971. Presidents Ronald
Reagan and Bill Clinton both initiated policies that were designed to be tough on
crime.42 Politicians and policymakers at the state level have followed their lead, in
particular initiating sentencing and imprisonment policies designed to lock up
criminals they regard as dangerous and to keep them in prison for long terms.
State-level policies, of course, are the most important because state and local officials
are responsible for dealing with most of the crime in the United States. Of the
1.5 million prisoners in 2011, for example, 87 percent were in state prisons.43
The consequences of the wars on crime and drugs have been enormous.
The number of prisoners has soared from 196,429 in 1970 to 1,504,150 in
2011. Add in the 735.601 people held in local jails in 2011, and we have more
than 2.2 million people behind bars. The United States has been on an imprisonment orgy. Figure 1.2 dramatically reveals how the last forty years represent a
radical break with the past. The incarceration rate rose from 96 per 100,000 in
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
17
1,800,000
1,600,000
1,400,000
1,200,000
1,000,000
800,000
600,000
400,000
200,000
0
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
F I G U R E 1.2 Sentenced prisoners in state and federal prisons, 1960–2010.
SOURCE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, Historical Statistics on Prisoners in State and Federal Institutions, Yearend
1925–1986 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1988). Bureau of justice Statistics, Prisoners in 2012—Advance
Counts (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2013).
1970 to 731 in 2010, including both state and federal prisoners. This compares
with incarceration rates of 107 per 100,000 in Canada, 126 in Australia, and 62
in Japan.44 No other country locks up so many people.
Prisons and jails are only part of the story. The number of people on probation
grew from 1,079,258 adults in 1976 to 3,971,319 in 2011, and the number of adults
on parole soared from 156,194 to 853,852 by 2011. The result was almost 7 million
people “under correctional supervision” by 2011.45 Finally, we need to include the
32,000 immigrants being detained on an average day in 2011 by Homeland Security
in 204 facilities around the country, with the total for the year being 429,000.
We should add quickly that there are some signs of a reversal of the imprisonment boom. The Sentencing Project reports that the national prison population declined by 1.5 percent in 2011 (a pretty small decrease, but at least not an
increase), involving 28,582 prisoners. This reduction was largely the result of
revisions of sentencing policy among the states. In 2012, at least twenty-four
states adopted forty-one different reforms that affected sentencing. We will
examine this entire issue in detail in Chapter 7.46
Several forces have contributed to the imprisonment boom. The most
important has been public attitudes about crime and drugs, and a popular belief
that the justice system has been and still is soft on crime. Beginning in the mid1970s, every state and the federal government revised its law on sentencing, adding stronger mandatory imprisonment laws; longer sentences; “truth in sentencing” laws that require prisoners to serve, for example, 85 percent of the original
sentence; and limitations on “good time” provisions that allow early release of
prisoners. An increase in drug arrests, together with tougher sentences for drug
crimes, has also contributed to the imprisonment boom. A special problem exists
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
18
CHAPTER
1
4,500,000
3,917,319
4,000,000
3,500,000
3,000,000
2,500,000
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,504,150
1,000,000
853,852
735,601
500,000
0
Prisons
Jails
Probation
Parole
F I G U R E 1.3 Total correctional population of the United States, 2011.
SOURCE: Bureau of Justive Stastistics, Prisoners in 2011 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2012). Bureau of
Justice Statistics, Probation and Parole in the United States, 2011 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2012).
in California where more people enter prison every year because of parole revocation rather than a sentence from a court.
In Chapter 7, we will examine sentencing laws and look at the evidence on
whether imprisonment deters crime and whether longer sentences effectively
reduce crime through incapacitation. Most experts argue that they do not, and
add that they have had a destructive effect on U.S. society, particularly on the
African American community, as many people argue?
The Racial Dimensions of the War on Crime
Michelle Alexander’s best-selling book The New Jim Crow argues that the policy
of mass incarceration has been a consciously racist policy to subjugate African
Americans. “The drug war,” she argues, “has been waged almost exclusively in
ghetto communities, resulting in what I believe is a racial under class.” Arrest and
incarceration has been compounded by indifference to the impact of a policy of
mass incarceration because of race. “It was because of race that we didn’t care
much what happened to those people and imagined the worst possible things
about them.” She chose the title the New Jim Crow to make the point that incarceration has been a deliberate policy to roll back the gains of the civil rights
movement and impose a new racial caste system on the United States.47
Alexander’s provocative argument gained much attention outside the world
of criminology. Her book became a national best seller, and she gave many talks
around the country. The book altered the national debate over imprisonment in
two important respects. First, her use of the term mass incarceration changes how
we think about the enormous prison population in the United States. It is no
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
19
longer a matter of, say, prison overcrowding, but a deliberate social policy. Second, she has placed race at the center of the debate.
Not everyone has accepted her argument. The most serious criticism is that
she confuses the results of the war on crime with the intent of the great change in
U.S. imprisonment policy. Many people have studied, criticized, and challenged
race discrimination in the U.S. criminal justice system. Many have been arguing
for decades that the drug war in particular has a discriminatory impact. And many
have attacked the imprisonment boom, for its racial aspect and its other destructive
effects. But not all are certain that establishing a racial caste system was the original
and deliberate intent of the war on crime and mass incarceration.
Years ago Jerome Miller once characterized the war on crime as a case of
“search and destroy” directed at young African American men. One report estimated that on any given day, 42 percent of the young African American men
(ages eighteen to thirty-five) in Washington, DC, are under the control of the
justice system: either in prison or jail or on probation or parole. The figure for
Baltimore was 56 percent. About 75 percent of the African American men in
Washington, DC, were likely to be arrested before they reached age thirtyfive.48 In short, a huge number of African American men are acquiring arrest
records as a result of the war on drugs. Some analysts have argued that by the
1990s, there were more African American men in prison than in college, but
others reply that the pattern changed in 2002 and there are now slightly more
African American men in college than in prison.49 Whatever the exact figures,
the important point is that they are even close.
The debate over Alexander’s thesis continues, but there is no question that
she has put race at the center of the discussions of U.S. crime policy.
The data on racial disparities in the criminal justice system are impossible to
ignore, particularly with regard to drugs. African Americans represent 13 percent of
the U.S. population, but 35 percent of all people arrested for drug offenses, 55 percent
of those convicted for drug crimes, and 74 percent of those sentenced to prison.50
Many critics have pointed out that the racial patterns in arrests, convictions,
and sentencing, however, are not consistent with the evidence on drug usage.
The 2011 National Survey of Drug Use and Health (the best data on the subject)
found some differences in reported illicit drug use by race and ethnicity but not
as great as the differences in arrest. In 2011, 8.7 percent of whites reported using
an illicit drug in the past month compared with 10 percent of African Americans,
8.4 for Hispanics, and 13.4 for American Indians. Illicit drug use is higher among
African Americans, but not to the extent that arrests, convictions, and prison
sentences would suggest.51
It is useful to put the data on drug usage in perspective by looking at alcohol
consumption. The National Survey of Drug Use and Health found that in 2011,
23.9 percent of whites reported “binge” drinking compared with 19.4 percent for
African Americans. The racial gap was even greater among twelve- to twenty-year
olds, where abuse among whites was twice that of African Americans, at 18.6 percent compared with 9.4 among African Americans. To the extent that binge
drinking leads to drunk driving, it becomes a serious public safety issue. In short,
substance abuse varies by race and ethnicity, depending on the illegal substance.52
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
20
CHAPTER
1
Waging “War” Is the Wrong Way to Deal with Crime
War is the wrong metaphor for crime policies. First, it raises unrealistic expectations, promising a victory and an end to the war. In fact, we will never
completely eliminate crime. At best, we will succeed in reducing it, hopefully
to the point where it does not destroy entire communities. For the same reason,
many medical experts do not like the idea of declaring war on cancer or other
diseases. Whether the problem is crime or cancer, a realistic and sensible goal is
to get it down to some manageable level.53
The war metaphor is also wrong because it suggests that we are fighting a
foreign enemy. This leads people to demonize criminals as people apart from
the rest of us. To a great extent, this tendency to demonize has encouraged racial
and ethnic stereotypes and aggravated the racial polarization of U.S. society.
Additionally, the us-versus-them attitude encourages police officers to regard
suspects as people who do not have the same rights as other U.S. citizens. Community policing, which emphasizes close working relations between police and
citizens, is a far more appropriate approach for a democratic society. Finally, as
we have already seen, the current war on crime has had a terrible effect on U.S.
society, particularly on racial and ethnic minority communities. These facts lead
us to the following proposition:
2
PROPOSITION
Waging “war” is the wrong way to fight crime.
The truth is, we do not face a foreign enemy. We are up against ourselves. We
need to deal with our own social institutions, our own values, our own habits,
and our own crime control policies. Criminologists Steven F. Messner and
Richard Rosenfeld argue that “the sources of crime” in this country lie “in the
very same values and behaviors that are conventionally viewed as part of the
American success story.” The values of material success and individual advancement work for many people, but for others the opportunity to achieve the
“American Dream” is blocked. They argue that to deal effectively and responsibly with the crime problem we cannot demonize criminals as “others,” but
instead need to reexamine how well our institutions serve all people.54
The U.S. response to the crime problem resembles the way many people
deal with being overweight—by “diet binging.” Just as people go on crash
diets, lose weight, put it all back on, and then take up another diet fad a year
later, so we tend to “binge” on crime control fads. In the 1980s it was selective
incapacitation; in the 1990s boot camps and three-strike laws; today it is offender
reentry programs (see Chapter 14). And so it goes. Typically, everyone forgets
yesterday’s fad without examining whether it really worked. The solution to a
weight loss problem does not lie in a miracle cure; instead, it involves difficult
long-term changes in one’s own behavior: eating less, eating less fattening food,
and exercising more. By the same token, we will reduce crime when we make
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
21
basic changes in all of our social policies that affect families, employment, and
neighborhoods. There is no quick, easy, “miracle” cure for crime.
A “Social Ledger” of Crime Policy
Criminologist Robert J. Sampson recently made a creative proposal for an
“imprisonment ledger” regarding the impact of imprisonment. His proposal
arose in response to an article arising from Wakefield and Wilderman’s Fragile
Families Study on the impact of imprisonment on the children of prisoners,
which found that children of incarcerated fathers suffered significant behavioral
and mental health problems. He proposed developing a “social ledger for incarceration,” taking into account all of its social impacts. He pointed out that in
policy debates over imprisonment criminologists traditionally focused “almost
exclusively” on deterrence and incapacitation.55
Sampson’s worthwhile proposal can and should be extended to all criminal
justice policies, so that we have a comprehensive social ledger of crime policies.
Police operations have many consequences. Increasing police patrol or
implementing aggressive strategies such as “hot spots,” large numbers of stops
and frisks (as in New York City), or a “broken windows” attack on less serious
disorder incidents should be evaluated in terms of more than the impact on
crime and disorder. A social ledger should include the impact on people who
are stopped and frisked illegally or are subjected to other forms of police misconduct. An increase in traffic stops in an African American neighborhood easily
leads to charges of racial profiling. A comprehensive social ledger needs to be
properly balanced, taking into account for example the measureable crime
reduction effects of a visible police presence. In Chapters 5 and 6, we discuss
the effectiveness of focused deterrence programs that are narrowly directed
against known offenders and have proven to be effective.
In the courts, denying pretrial release in an effort to prevent defendants from
committing new crimes has the effects of denying defendants the right to bail,
punishing poor people who cannot obtain their release, harming the families of
those who are held, increasing the costs to the county for holding them, and
increasing the probability of conviction. Over the decades, criminologists have
examined all of these consequences. No one, however, has put together a full
social ledger that accounts for all of the social costs.
Todd Clear’s book, Imprisoning Communities, develops a community perspective on imprisonment. He notes that judges sentence individuals to prison,
but imprisonment as a policy has enormous adverse effects on communities.56
His book arose out of the growing interest in communities among criminologists, but it fits comfortably into a social ledger framework. He argues that our
policy of mass incarceration has had a devastating impact on communities, and
African American communities in particular. It breaks up families, weakens the
critical social control function of parents, removes positive role models, and
damages the economic health of communities, which are already distressed
(by removing potential breadwinners). We might add that to the extent that a
weakened social structure leads to an increase in crime it causes middle-class
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
22
CHAPTER
1
and working-class families to move out, thereby further removing positive role
models and lowering the economic status of the neighborhood.57
A comprehensive social ledger on imprisonment would take into account the
combined effect of adverse impacts on the collective efficacy of neighborhoods: the
capacity of ordinary people to work together to solve neighborhood problems.
Criminologists increasingly emphasize the importance of informal controls over
crime (for that matter, all behavior): intimate partnerships, families, friendship networks, neighborhood ties, and so on. From this perspective, imprisonment of
some offenders may prevent some crimes, but mass imprisonment undermines
the capacity of communities to prevent crime through their own efforts.
One of the most profound consequences of the war on crime is the loss of the
right to vote. Virtually every state strips a convicted felon of the right to vote. The
impact on the African American community is enormous, considering that an estimated 10 percent of the adult African American population is under correctional
supervision at any given moment. The Sentencing Project estimates that in 2010 about
5.8 million Americans could not vote because of a felony conviction, up dramatically
from 1.2 million in 1976. One in every 13 African Americans is disenfranchised, more
than four times the rate for other Americans. Disenfranchisement has enormous political ramifications. In Florida, which has been a “battleground” state in the last four presidential elections, the African American disenfranchisement rate is 23 percent.58
We will take a closer look at disenfranchisement and other restrictions
imposed on ex-offenders in Chapter 14. The disparate impact of the war on
crime has been profound on attitudes toward the justice system, and the result
is a deep distrust of the justice system among African Americans.
A comprehensive social ledger also needs to account for the enormous cost of
the war on crime and the resulting shift of tax dollars from education, public health,
and the economic infrastructure of roads and bridges. In California, for example,
state expenditures for corrections were only half the amount spent on higher education in the early 1980s; by 1994, they were equal. Prison budgets had risen dramatically, whereas the state colleges and universities had suffered drastic cuts.
CRIME POLICY: A PLAGUE OF NONSENSE
Americans have trouble thinking clearly about crime. Crime rates have fallen dramatically since the early 1990s, but public fear of crime still remains high. We still
get a lot of crime control proposals that are disconnected from the reality of crime
and justice. One reason is that even with the Great American Crime Drop we still
have far more violent crime than any other industrialized country.59
Fear of crime pervades our daily lives like a plague, affecting the way we think,
the way we act, the way we respond to one another. Almost half (47 percent) of
Americans in 2011 reported that they worried about their home being burglarized
when they were not there.60 (And this is despite the fact that the NCVS reports a
steady decline in the household burglary rate.) Crime has a corrosive effect on interpersonal relations, making us wary of small acts of friendliness toward strangers. It
also distorts the political process, with politicians offering quick-fix solutions that
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
23
have no realistic hope of reducing crime. Fear and frustration about crime produce
irrational thinking. Almost every year some new proposal promises to make a dramatic reduction in crime. Most of these proposals, we argue, are nonsense.
Even some of the most informed experts on criminal justice are overwhelmed
by the problem. Several years ago, when Jerome Miller first submitted the manuscript of his book Search and Destroy, his editor called it “too pessimistic”; it had no
optimistic recommendations on what to do about crime. Miller admitted that his
editor was right; he did not “have many suggestions—and those I do have, aren’t
likely to be taken.”61 Many other criminologists and public figures have also been
unable to formulate sensible, realistic proposals for reducing crime.
This book, however, is more optimistic than Miller—cautiously optimistic, but
optimistic, nonetheless. Research on crime and justice has paid some dividends.
Today, we know a lot about what does not work, and we have small number of policies that show promise of helping to reduce crime. We discuss them later in this book.
We need to make an important distinction regarding the goals of different
reform proposals. Many sensible proposals involve reducing the harm done by the
criminal justice system. They follow the ancient medical precept, “First, do no
harm.”62 As we have argued, many of our crime policies, especially the war on
crime, do serious harm and fail to effectively reduce crime.
The Ground Rules
Let’s begin our search for sensible and effective crime policies by establishing the
ground rules. First, we will focus on crime control. We are concerned with policies that will reduce the level of serious crime. We will consider questions of
justice and fairness as constraints on crime policy, but as important as they are,
those issues are not our primary focus in this book.
Second, there are limits to what we can do. A democratic society respects
the rule of law and standards of justice and fairness, unlike totalitarian societies,
in which government power is unlimited. We cannot round up and hold all
alleged suspects who the police say “look like” the perpetrator of a crime. Nor
do we immediately shoot offenders who have been convicted after a short trial.
We also respect what the Supreme Court called the “evolving standards of
decency that mark the progress of a maturing society.”63 We no longer stone
people to death or cut off the hands of burglars.
Third, we will focus primarily but not exclusively on the crimes of robbery and
burglary. This limited focus helps impose some discipline on our thinking. Too many
people evade the hard questions about crime by changing the subject. Liberals often
find it difficult to talk about robbery and burglary, changing the subject to victimless
crimes, marijuana arrests, or justice issues. Conservatives, meanwhile, focus on celebrated cases (particularly extremely vicious crimes) that have little to do with the routine felonies of robbery and burglary. We will discuss celebrated cases and how they
distort our understanding of how the justice system works in Chapter 2.
As we go forward we will consider some other crimes to illustrate important
points about how the justice system works. An entire section is devoted to drunk
driving because this subject provides useful insights into such issues as
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
24
CHAPTER
1
police crackdowns and deterrence that are relevant to crime policy in general.
Chapter 13 covers drugs because it is impossible to talk about serious crime and
crime policy today without addressing drugs, drug gangs, and drug-related crime.
Fourth, this book concentrates on crimes committed by adults. Juvenile
crime and delinquency are serious problems that warrant attention, but the
world of juvenile justice is a special realm, with its own unique problems, that
deserves a separate critical inquiry.
What Do We Mean by Crime Prevention?
As a 1997 University of Maryland report on Preventing Crime argues, many people are confused about the term crime prevention. The report points out that “the
national debate over crime often treats ‘prevention’ and ‘punishment’ as mutually
exclusive concepts, polar opposites on a continuum of ‘soft’ versus ‘tough’
responses to crime.”64 As we explain shortly, this dichotomy generally defines
conservatives as the advocates of “tough” (that is, punishment-oriented) policies
and liberals as the advocates of “soft” (that is, prevention-oriented) policies.
Gun violence expert David Kennedy argues that “the false divide between
prevention and law enforcement is not only mistaken but catastrophically
misguided.”65 Regardless of their label, all crime policies are designed to prevent
crime. Kennedy explains that “Working with a kid’s mother to help her run a
stable home is prevention.” But by the current misguided logic, a police officer
telling the same kid “he’ll go to prison if he shoots somebody” is somehow not
prevention. But in reality, both approaches keep violent crimes from happening,
no matter what label you put on each one. Particular policies are simply different
means to that end. An allegedly soft-treatment program such as outpatient drug
abuse counseling is intended to prevent crime no less than is an allegedly toughsentencing policy such as a three-strikes sentencing law. Regardless of the label,
our concern is on policies that reduce crime.
The Question of Reasonable Goals
Our search for sensible and effective crime policies raises a difficult question of
criteria. What do we mean by effective? Let us say we find a policy that would
reduce crime by 5 percent without doing any serious harm. Is that a goal worth
pursuing? A 5 percent reduction is not much, given the size of our crime problem.
We would still be swamped by murder, robbery, rape, and drug abuse. But we
should not dismiss that policy too quickly. If we combine that one program with
others each reducing crime by 5 percent, the combined effect becomes significant.
Criminologist Gary Kleck makes a persuasive case for modest goals. We should
not expect quick and dramatic changes because unreasonable expectations lead to disappointment and frustration. Kleck advises thinking in terms of modest goals that can
be achieved.66 In the long run, a sensible approach to crime will probably include a
series of different policies, each one focusing on a different aspect of the larger problem
and each one producing a modest reduction in crime. The best example, which we
will discuss in Chapter 6, involves traffic fatalities. The rate of traffic fatalities has gone
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
25
down steadily since the 1920s. This is not the result of any single policy (for example,
a tough sentencing law for drunk drivers) but a combination of improvements in
roads, automobile design, seat belts, and other changes.
LEARNING FROM PUBLIC HEALTH We gain an extremely valuable
perspective on how to control crime from recent achievements in the area of
public health. Many social indicators have moved in a positive direction over
the past thirty years, and in some cases even longer.67 Table 1.2 indicates steady
decreases in teenage pregnancy and infant mortality. These trends reflect important changes in peoples’ behavior that parallel crime trends. People are not doing
things they used to do, or they are taking precautions (getting prenatal health
care, for example) that they previously did not. Smoking by adults, moreover,
has fallen by more than half since the mid-1960s: from 43 percent of all adults
in 1966 to 19 percent in 2010. Another often forgotten success story is the
remarkable 75 percent reduction in childhood deaths from accidental poisonings
following the 1970 Poison Prevention Packaging Act. Additionally, as we will
discuss in detail in Chapter 6, the motor vehicle fatality rate, measured in terms
of per 100,000 miles driven, has steadily fallen without interruption since the 1920s.
Crime does not occur in a vacuum, and all of the positive trends in these other
areas of life suggest some broad changes in the behavior of Americans.
A 2013 article in the prestigious Journal of the American Medical Association
(JAMA) argues that we can learn much from the successes in other areas when
we try to deal with gun violence. We did not reduce smoking by trying to outlaw cigarettes. We tried that with the prohibition of alcohol in the 1920s.
Instead, the authors of the JAMA article point out that we have used an array
of indirect measures that include raising the price of tobacco products through
taxation, media and educational campaigns, and a more pervasive change in cultural and social norms that disfavor and subtly stigmatize smoking (banning
smoking from buildings, airplanes, and other locations). (Personal note: this
author can remember going to rock concerts in the late 1970s and coming
home with clothes reeking of tobacco odor.) True, we have not ended smoking
completely, but we have made enormous progress in reducing a serious health
risk. As we will discuss in Chapter 6, auto fatalities fell because of a set of
T A B L E 1.2
Positive trends in two U.S. social indicators: Teenage births and infant
mortality, 1970–2003
Teenage births
Births to women, ages 15–19 per 1,000
Infant mortality
Deaths per 1,000 live births
1970
68.3
1970
20.0
1980
53.0
1980
12.6
1990
59.9
1990
9.2
2000
47.7
2000
6.9
2010
34.2
2010
7.0
SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2012 (Washington, DC: Bureau of the
Census, 2011).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
26
CHAPTER
1
improvements in diving safety (better roads, better signs, safer cars, seat belts,
etc.). Accidental childhood poisonings were reduced through adoption of the
childproof pill bottle (yes, we adults often struggle with it, but its contribution
to safety is well worth it). Public education about safe storage and the development of poison hot lines have also contributed to the decline in deaths.68
The basic point of the JAMA article is that the successes in public health have
been achieved through carefully designed multipronged approaches. No single policy
did the trick, but several approaches reinforced each other to achieve a significant
result. The lesson for crime control is that we should avoid single policies that
make grand promises of success. And we should avoid the extreme rhetoric that
accompanies this approach (“war on crime,” “lock ’em up,” “get criminals off the
streets,” and so on). And as many chapters in this book will argue, our knowledge
base in criminal justice has expanded so much so that we can identify potential
points of intervention where we can make small but important differences.
The state of the economy, as reflected in the unemployment rate, is a cause
for concern because it has direct implications on criminal behavior. The healthy
U.S. economy in the 1990s supported all the positive social trends, but the recession that began in 2008, and the resulting increase in unemployment, is a serious
matter. Moreover, the unemployment rate for African Americans is twice that of
whites. In September 2012, the rate for people age sixteen and older was 7 percent for whites, 9.9 for Hispanics, and 13.4 for African Americans.69 This is a
worrisome factor with respect to risk for criminal activity.
GUILTY: LIBERALS AND CONSERVATIVES
Nonsense about crime is politically nonpartisan. Both liberals and conservatives
have been guilty of making extravagant promises about crime reduction. In
1967, the President’s Crime Commission, representing a liberal perspective,
promised “a significant reduction in crime” if its recommendations were “vigorously pursued.” Ten years later, the conservative James Q. Wilson offered a program that he claimed would reduce serious crime by 30 percent.70 Neither of
these promises was realistic. Over the years other criminologists and public officials representing all political persuasions have made equally ridiculous promises.
Consequently, our third proposition is as follows:
3
PROPOSITION
Both liberals and conservatives are guilty of peddling nonsense about crime.
CRIME CONTROL THEOLOGY
Liberals and conservatives base their policies on different assumptions about
crime, the administration of justice, and human nature. Let’s examine each side’s
assumptions.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
27
The heart of the problem is that for both sides faith usually triumphs over
facts, and fundamental assumptions are almost like religious beliefs that ignore
empirical evidence. We call this phenomenon Crime Control Theology.71 Most
conservatives, for example, believe that the death penalty deters crime. This
view persists despite considerable research finding no conclusive evidence of a
deterrent effect, as we will see in Chapter 6. Most liberals, meanwhile, believe
that “treatment” can effectively correct the behavior of offenders and put them
on the path to law-abiding lives despite the evidence on the limited effectiveness
of most treatment programs.
Many people, whether conservative or liberal, are at times selective applying their principles. In Point Blank, Gary Kleck points out how people switch
sides on deterrence. Conservatives believe that the death penalty deters crime
but then argue that the exclusionary rule does not deter police misconduct.
Liberals switch sides in the opposite direction, arguing that the death penalty
does not deter crime but that the exclusionary rule does work.72 We make a
serious effort in this book to maintain consistency with respect to our ideas and
arguments.
Conservative Theology
Crime control theologies represent idealized worlds that express people’s highest
hopes and deepest fears. Conservative crime control theology envisions a world
of discipline and self-control in which people exercise self-restraint and subordinate immediate gratification to their long-term interests. It is a world of limits
and clear rules about human behavior.
© 2015 Cengage Learning
BOX
1.4
THE LIBERAL / CONSERVATIVE DICHOTOMY ON CRIME POLICY
Policy
Conservative
Liberal
Police community
More cops on the street
Improve police relations.
Death Penalty
The death penalty
deters crime.
No evidence that the death
penalty deters crime.
Bail
Deny bail to “dangerous”
offenders.
No evidence of high rates
of offending by defendants
released on bail.
Plea bargaining
Plea bargaining allows
dangerous criminals to
beat the system.
Plea bargaining does not result
in the release of dangerous
offenders.
Imprisonment sentences
Long and mandatory prison
sentences prevent crime.
Long and mandatory only for
the most dangerous offenders.
Gun violence
More guns in law-abiding
hands prevents crime.
Gun control will prevent crime.
Drug-related crime
More imprisonment
More treatment for drug users.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
28
CHAPTER
1
Conservative crime control theology emphasizes personal responsibility and
argues that criminals lack self-control and succumb to their passions. They kill
because they cannot control their anger. They steal because they want something
now and are unable to defer gratification. Poverty or other social conditions are
no excuse for crime, in the conservative view. People remain poor because they
lack the self-discipline to get an education, find a job, and steadily try to improve
themselves. Conservatives are fond of pointing to the many individuals who
were born in poverty but worked hard and became rich and successful.
Free will, rational choice, and moral responsibility reign supreme in conservative crime control theology. People are responsible for their own fate; they
choose to commit crime. James Q. Wilson and Richard J. Herrnstein argue: “At
any given moment, a person can choose between committing a crime and not
committing it.”73
In rational choice theory, people weigh the relative risks and rewards of
committing crime. If the risk of punishment is low or the punishments are relatively light, the theory holds, more people will commit crime. If the chance of
being caught and punished is high and the punishments are relatively severe,
fewer people will choose to commit crime. The certainty and severity of punishment are important elements in conservative thinking on crime.74 We will look
critically at deterrence theory in Chapter 6.
Punishment also has a moral dimension in conservative thinking. Because
criminals choose to offend, they deserve punishment; they are morally responsible for their actions. Rules are the basis of a civil society, and rule breaking
should be punished. This is called retribution, or desert. James Q. Wilson summed
it up in a frequently quoted statement: “Wicked people exist. Nothing avails
except to set them apart from innocent people.”75
Conservatives are deeply ambivalent about the role of government in controlling crime. William J. Bennett, John J. Dilulio, Jr., and John P. Walters argue that
the “root cause” of crime is “moral poverty” (as opposed to material poverty). Too
many children grow up not learning right from wrong. Moral health, they argue,
is nurtured primarily by strong, two-parent families, religious training, and social
institutions that reinforce the right values. “Can government supply manner and
morals?” they ask. “Of course it cannot,” they answer. People are socialized into
law-abiding behavior primarily by private institutions, beginning with the family.
But, these conservatives argue that, government does have an important role to
play in providing effective examples of holding people responsible for their behavior. Thus, the swift, certain punishment of criminals helps breed moral health.
Moral poverty is fostered by the failure of the criminal justice system to punish
criminals. Thus, although government cannot do everything to build an orderly
society, it can do some things that contribute to that goal.76
Underlying conservative crime control theology is an idealized image of the
patriarchal family. Punishment resembles parental discipline. Minor misbehavior is
greeted with a gentle warning, a second misstep earns a sterner reprimand, and
serious wrongdoing receives a severe punishment. The point is to teach the
wisdom of correct behavior by handing out progressively harsher sanctions and
threatening even more unpleasant punishment if the behavior continues.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
29
The problem for conservative crime theology, however, is that the real
world of crime and justice does not work like this idealized family. It is filled
with some incorrigible children, some of whom are so deeply alienated from
society that they do not respect the overall structure of authority. Punishment,
in fact, may only distance them further, undermining the legitimacy of the system, as we will discuss in Chapter 12. Some observers believe, for example, that
arrest and imprisonment are such common experiences in some poor racial and
ethnic minority neighborhoods that they have lost whatever deterrent threat
they might have once had.77
Conservatives explain the failure of punishment to work by focusing on
problems in the criminal justice system. Punishment, they say, is not certain or
severe enough. Too many loopholes allow criminals to beat the system: the
exclusionary rule, the Miranda warning, the insanity defense, plea bargaining,
and so on. The idea that many criminals “beat the system” and “get off easy” is
an article of faith in conservative crime control theology. Close these loopholes,
ensure certainty of punishment, and we can reduce crime. Longer prison terms
and the death penalty, meanwhile, will increase the deterrent effect and reduce
crime. We will take a close look at this idea in several of the chapters
ahead. John Braithwaite’s provocative book Crime, Shame, and Reintegration offers
a useful perspective on this problem. Braithwaite describes the process of “reintegrative shaming” as being much like the way a family handles someone who
breaks the rules. But his theory also clearly indicates that informal sanctions work
when close social bonds link the sanctioner and the sanctioned, and where no
great differences in values exist in the community—that is, when the relationship
more closely resembles a family.78
This is the heart of the problem for conservative crime control theology. The
family analogy breaks down in the real world because we have a heterogeneous
and fragmented society, characterized by great differences in wealth, race, ethnicity, religion, culture, and lifestyles. Our society is anything but a tightly knit community with a common set of values. Braithwaite’s theory, in fact, is a good
explanation of why informal, family-style sanctions do not work in our society.
His description of the conditions under which a system of reintegrative shaming
can work is actually an accurate description of a seventeenth-century New England village, where that approach to crime control was used effectively.79
The limits of reintegrative shaming lend further support to the importance
of a community orientation and the interdependency of institutions and policies emphasized by the University of Maryland Preventing Crime report. Effective reintegration requires a reasonably healthy community. Achieving a
healthy community, in turn, probably requires a series of crime prevention
programs directed toward a number of different institutions: families, schools,
the local labor market, and so on.
Liberal Theology
Liberal crime control theology emphasizes the social context of crime. Criminal
behavior is largely the result of social influences such as the family, the peer
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
30
CHAPTER
1
group, the neighborhood, economic opportunities, and discrimination. Much
criminological theory, such as Shaw and McKay’s social disorganization theory,
reflects this view.80
Liberal crime policy seeks to alter social influences that are associated with
crime. Rehabilitation programs, for example, are designed to provide a structured set of interventions—job counseling, substance abuse treatment—designed
to encourage law-abiding behavior. Liberals favor community-based alternatives
to imprisonment because they represent a normal social environment compared
with the abnormal environment of prison.
Liberals are as guilty of wishful thinking as are conservatives. A fundamental
article of faith in liberal crime control theology is the optimistic belief that people’s
behavior can be reshaped through some kind of formal treatment program. The
history of prison and correctional reform is the story of a continuing search for
the Holy Grail of rehabilitation: a program that will truly reform offenders. The
people who invented the prison in the nineteenth century thought that that
imprisonment would do the job.81 When it had obviously failed, reformers
invented parole and the indeterminate sentence, believing that placing a prisoner’s
release date in his hands would encourage him to display evidence of remorse and
rehabilitation. When these measures did not solve the problem of crime, reformers
came up with new variations (group counseling, intensive supervision, and so
forth). None of these programs has demonstrated consistent effectiveness.
If conservatives refuse to face the facts about the failure of punishment, liberals refuse to look at the sad history of the failure of rehabilitation. Faith continues to survive in the face of repeated failure. It is also an article of faith among
liberals that the United States is the most punitive country in the world. We do,
in fact, lock up more people than any other country. Our current incarceration
rate of 743 per 100,000 leads the world. If conservatives believe that most of our
problems are the result of loopholes that let too many people off easy, liberals are
often guilty of blaming everything on overly harsh punishments.
Liberals are ambivalent on the question of individual responsibility.
Although they emphasize the importance of social conditions in causing crime
and reject the conservative preoccupation with individual responsibility, they
cannot completely ignore the role of individual choice. Rehabilitation programs,
in fact, are designed to influence individuals to make different (and better)
choices. In the realm of the public policy debate, however, liberals tend to
downplay the element of individual responsibility.
A Word about Rules
One way to distinguish between conservatives and liberals with respect to crime
policy is their attitude toward rules. Both sides believe in rules and that rules
should by applied in a consistent fashion. This is what people mean when they
refer to the “rule of law.”
Conservatives and liberals mainly disagree over which set of rules to emphasize. In criminal justice, we have two basic sets: criminal law and criminal procedure. The substantive criminal law is a set of rules governing everyone’s behavior.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
31
It defines certain behavior as criminal and specifies the penalty for breaking the
rules. Criminal procedure, on the other hand, is a set of rules governing criminal
justice officials. It tells them what they may not do (for example, conduct unreasonable searches and seizures) and what they must do (for example, bring the
suspect before a magistrate without unnecessary delay).82
Conservatives emphasize the rules of the criminal law. Harming a person or
taking someone else’s property violates the basic standards of a decent society.
Anyone who violates these rules should be punished. Liberals tend to emphasize
the rules of criminal procedure. A free society is one that strictly limits the
potentially awesome power of government officials. This is a bit of an oversimplification, but it serves to highlight the different emphases of each side when it
comes to crime and crime policy.
One way to understand the difference between liberal and conservative
attitudes toward rules is to recognize what each side sees as its worst nightmare. For conservatives, unchecked criminality leads to anarchy and the
death of freedom. For liberals, unchecked government power leads to tyranny and the death of freedom. The difference is really a question of what
represents the greatest threat to freedom. Both sides are ambivalent about
rule breaking. Conservatives tend to be willing to excuse violations of the
rules of procedure to control crime. They will overlook the unreasonable
search if it helps convict a criminal. Liberals, on the other hand, are more
concerned about official rule breaking. They are willing to see a criminal suspect
go free if a police officer or some other official has made a serious mistake.
These differences are not absolute, of course. They are really matters of emphasis. Conservatives do not endorse gross abuses by the police, and liberals do not
endorse crime.
The classic statement of the difference between conservatives and liberals on
this issue is Herbert Packer’s essay on the “two models of the criminal process.”83
Conservatives embrace the crime control model, which puts a high priority on the
effective control of crime. To this end, they are willing to grant officials considerable
leeway, not restricting them with a lot of rules. Liberals prefer the due process model,
in which the highest priorities are fair treatment and the presumption of innocence.
Formal rules (due process guarantees) are designed to achieve these goals.
Ideological Confusion: Switching Sides
The conservative/liberal dichotomy is a useful way to think about crime policy.
It helps identify the basic assumptions that underlie different policies. In the last
few years, however, this dichotomy is not quite as sharp as it was a few years ago.
Strange things have been happening. Some conservatives have adopted traditional liberal policies, and many liberals have embraced traditional conservative
ideas. Understanding the crime debate today requires sorting our way through
this ideological confusion.
One major change involves the issue of legalizing drugs. Decriminalization has
traditionally been a proposal by liberals. They have argued that we should not
criminalize behavior that does not harm others. Moreover, criminalizing a lot of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
32
CHAPTER
1
behavior often tends to make things worse, by overloading the criminal justice
system, encouraging corruption, and failing to respond effectively to what are
really social and medical problems. Surprisingly, many prominent conservatives
endorse legalizing drugs. The most prominent is the writer and television talk
show host William F. Buckley. We will examine the arguments in favor of drug
legalization in Chapter 13. For the moment, it is important to note that some
conservatives have switched sides and adopted a traditional liberal position.
Also, the conservative administration of George W. Bush has strongly supported offender reentry programs (see Chapter 14), which involve the traditional
liberal idea of reintegrating offenders into society.
Meanwhile, many liberals have adopted some conservative crime control
proposals. The best example is former President Bill Clinton. The 1994 Violent
Crime Control Act, which he supported, calls for more police and longer
prison sentences. In the 1996 presidential election campaign, political observers
said that Clinton had moved to the right and embraced the traditional Republican position on crime, supporting three-strikes laws and two federal laws
limiting the rights of criminal offenders. In short, the ideological lineup on
crime control policies has become muddled. Nonetheless, it is still possible to
identify a set of crime policies that, because of their underlying assumptions,
can be classified as conservative and another set that can be classified as liberal.
These categories will help us analyze the different policies we will consider in
this book.
CONCLUSION
Crime is a serious problem in the United States. Despite the Great American
Crime Drop, we still have a serious problem of violent crime that is far higher
than in other industrialized countries. Unfortunately, we do not have many good
ideas about how to solve the crime problem. In this initial chapter, we have tried
to sketch out some of the complexity of the U.S. crime problem. We have also
indicated briefly why so many crime control policies are worthless. In the
chapters that follow, we will develop these themes in more detail. The next
two chapters take a closer look at how the criminal justice system actually
works. Then we will turn our attention to specific crime control proposals. As
we already indicated, our basic goal is to find some crime control policies that
make sense and that are supported by persuasive evidence.
NOTES
1 Crime data for New York City, Chicago, and San Diego are available on the
websites of their police departments.
2 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Intimate Partner Violence, 1993–2010 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2012).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
33
3 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2012 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2013). Federal Bureau of Investigation, Crime in the United
States, 2012 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2013).
4 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2011. Bureau of Justice Statistics,
Intimate Partner Violence, 1993–2010.
5 Crime data for New York City, Chicago, and San Diego are available on the
websites of their police departments. http://www .nyc.gov/html/nypd/html/home/
home.shtml. http://www.cityofchicago.org/city/en/depts/cpd.html. http://www
.sandiego.gov/police/ Accessed February 9, 2014.
6 Samuel Walker, Cassia Spohn, and Miriam DeLone, The Color of Justice: Race,
Ethnicity and Crime in America, 5th ed. (Belmont, CA: Cengage, 2012).
7 Long-term UCR crime data are available at Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of
Criminal Justice Statistics, online edition, Table 3.106. 201.
8 Franklin E. Zimring, The Great American Crime Decline (New York: Oxford
University Press, 2007). See especially Chapter 5, “Which Twin Has the Toni?
Some Statistical Lessons from Canada,” pp. 107–134.
9 Ibid.
10 Ibid., 120–121.
11 Alfred Blumstein and Joel Wallman, eds., The Crime Drop in America (New York:
Cambridge University Press, 2000), 11.
12 Steven D. Levitt, “Understanding Why Crime Fell in the 1990s: Four Factors That
Explain the Decline and Six That Do Not,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18
(Winter 2004): 163–190.
13 Zimring, The Great American Crime Decline, 85–103.
14 Herman Goldstein, “Improving Policing: A Problem-Oriented Approach, Crime and
Delinquency, 25 (April 1979): 236–258. See the materials at the website of the
Center on Problem-Oriented Policing: www.popcenter.org. Accessed February 9,
2014.
15 The Center on Problem-Oriented Policing website is www.popcenter.org. Accessed
February 9, 2014.
16 The SARA model is explained at http://www.popcenter.org/about/?p=sara.
Accessed February 9, 2014.
17 Jeremy Travis and Michelle Waul, Reflections on the Crime Decline Lessons for the Future?
(Washington, DC: Urban Institute, 2002). Available on the Urban Institute website.
18 Police Executive Research Forum, Is the Economic Downturn Fundamentally Changing
How We Police? (Washington, DC: Police Executive Research Forum, 2010).
19 The Constitution Project, Justice Denied America’s Continuing Neglect of Our
Constitutional Right to Counsel (Washington, DC: The Constitution Project, 2009).
20 Avinash Singh Bhati, John K. Roman, and Aaron Chalfin, To Treat or Not to Treat
Evidence on the Prospects for Expanding Treatment to Drug-Involved Offenders
(Washington, DC: The Urban Institute, 2008). Accessed February 9, 2014. http://
www.urban.org/url.cfm ?ID=411645.
21 Ryken Gratter, Joan Petersilia, and Jeffrey Lin, Parole Violations and Revocations in
California (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2008).
22 Ibid.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
34
CHAPTER
1
23 The evidence-based medicine website is http://www.hsl.unc.edu/services/tutorials/
ebm/. Accessed February 9, 2014.
24 The most important early statement regarding policing was Lawrence W. Sherman,
Evidence-Based Policing (Washington, DC: The Police Foundation, 1998).
25 See the Center for Evidence-Based Crime Policy at http://cebcp.org/. Accessed
February 9, 2014.
26 For the evidence-based corrections website, go to http://ucicorrectionis.seweb.uci.
edu/. See, for example, Jennifer Eno Louden and Jennifer L. Skeem, “Paroles with
Mental Disorder: Toward Evidence-Based Practice,” Center for Evidence-Based
Corrections, The Bulletin 7 (April 2011).
27 Meghan Guevara, Crime and Justice Institute, and Enver Solomon, Implementing
Evidence-Based Policy and Practice in Community Corrections, 2nd ed. (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2009).
28 Sarah Kuck Jalbert and William Rhodes, “Reduced Caseloads Improve Probation
Outcomes,” Journal of Crime and Justice 35 (No. 2, 2012): 221–238.
29 Remarks of the Honorable Deborah J Daniels, Assistant Attorney General of Justice
Programs, at the National Forum on Evidence-Based Crime and Substance Abuse Policy,
Washington, DC, June 14, 2004.
30 Malcolm W. Klein, “Comprehensive Gang and Violence Reduction Programs:
Reinventing the Square Wheel,” Criminology and Public Policy 10 (4):1037–1038.
31 General Accounting Office, Letter to Senator Richard Durbin, January 15, 2003,
“Subject: Youth Illicit Drug Use Prevention: DARE Long Term Evaluations and
Federal Efforts to Identify Effective Programs.” Accessed February 9, 2014. www
.gao.gov/new.items/do3172r.pdf.
32 Joan McCord, “Cures That Harm: Unanticipated Outcomes of Crime Prevention
Programs,” in David Weisburd, Anthony Petrosino, and Cynthia Lum, eds.,
“Assessing Systematic Evidence in Crime and Justice: Methodological Concerns and
Empirical Outcomes,” Special Issue, The Annals 587 (May 2003): 16–30.
33 James O. Finckenauer, Scared Straight and the Panacea Phenomenon (Englewood Cliffs,
NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1982).
34 George L. Kelling, Tony Pate, Duane Diekman, and Charles E. Brown., The Kansas
City Preventive Patrol Experiment: Executive Summary (Washington, DC: The Police
Foundation, 1974).
35 Lawrence W. Sherman, Janelle D. Schmidt, and Dennis P. Rogan, Policing Domestic
Violence: Experiments and Dilemmas (New York: The Free Press, 1992). Christopher
D. Maxwell, Joel H. Garner, and Jeffrey A. Fagan, The Effects of Arrest on Intimate
Partner Violence: New Evidence from the Spouse Assault Replication Program (Washington,
DC: Justice Department, 2001). NCJ 188199.
36 The Sentencing Project, Crime, Punishment and Public Opinion: A Summary of Recent
Studies and Their Implications for Sentencing Policy (Washington, DC: The Sentencing
Project, n.d.). Available on the Sentencing Project website. www.sentencingproject
.org. Accessed February 9, 2014.
37 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2011 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2012), Table 7. Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table
3.21. 2010.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
35
38 Bureau of Criminal Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table
3.106.2010. Bureau of Justice Statistics, Homicide Trends in the United States, 1980–
2008 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, November 2011).
39 William Julius Wilson, The Truly Disadvantaged: The Inner City, The Underclass, and
Public Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1987).
40 Franklin E. Zimring and Gordon Hawkins, Crime Is Not the Problem: Lethal Violence
in America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1997).
41 Nick Cowen, Comparison of Crime in OECD Countries (London: CIVITAS Institute
for the Study of Civil Society, 2010), updated April 2012). http://www.civitas.org
.uk/crime/crime_stats_oecdjan2012.pdf. Accessed February 9, 2014. Additional
sources: New England Coalition to Prevent Gun Violence Great Britain vs. United
States in Gun Deaths, http://necpgv. blogspot.com/. Accessed February 9, 2014. Jan
van Dijk, John van Kesteren, and Paul Smit, Criminal Victimization in International
Perspective: Key Findings from the 2004–2005 ICVS and EU ICS (New York: United
Nations, Office on Drugs and Crime, 2008).
42 Samuel Walker, Popular Justice: A History of American Criminal Justice, 2nd ed. (New
York: Oxford University Press, 1998).
43 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, online edition,
Table 6.13.2010.
44 The Sentencing Project, Trends in U.S. Corrections (Washington, DC: The
Sentencing Project, 2012).
45 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Correctional Populations in the United States, 2011
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2012).
46 Nicole D. Porter, The State of Sentencing 2012: Developments in Policy and Practice
(Washington, DC: The Sentencing Project, January 2013).
47 Michelle Alexander, The New Jim Crow: Mass Incarceration in the Age of Colorblindness
(New York: The New Press, 2010).
48 Jerome G. Miller, Search and Destroy: African American Males in the Criminal Justice
System (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1996). National Center on
Institutions and Alternatives, Hobbling a Generation: African American Males in the
District of Columbia’s Criminal Justice System (Alexandria, VA: NCIA, 1992).
49 Bryan J. Cook, By the Numbers: More Black Men in Prison Than in College? Think
Again, American Council on Education (Fall 2012).
50 Federal Bureau of Investigation, Crime in the United States, 2011. Bureau of Justice
Statistics, Prisoners in 2011. Sentencing Project, Trends in U.S. Corrections.
51 Substance Abuse and Mental Health Services Administration, Results From the 2011
National Survey on Drug Use and Health: Summary of National Findings (Washington,
DC: Department of Health and Human Services, 2012).
52 Ibid.
53 The best early critique of the harmful effect of declaring war on crime is the classic
essay, Egon Bittner, “The Police and the ‘War on Crime,’” in Egon Bittner, Aspects
of Police Work (Boston: Northeastern University Press, 1990), 89–232.
54 Steven F. Messner and Richard Rosenfeld, Crime and the American Dream, 5th ed.
(Belmont, CA: Wadsworth, 2012).
55 Robert J. Sampson, “The Incarceration Ledger: Toward a New Era in Assessing
Societal Consequences, Criminology and Public Policy, 10 (July 2011): 819–828. Sara
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
36
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
CHAPTER
1
Wakefield and Christopher Wilderman, “Mass Imprisonment and Racial Disparities
in Childhood Behavioral Problems, Criminology and Public Policy, (10 July 2011):
793–817.
Todd R. Clear, Imprisoning Communities: How Mass Incarceration Makes Disadvantaged
Neighborhoods Worse (New York: Oxford University Press, 2007).
Ibid. See especially Chapter 7 on “The Impact of Incarceration on Community
Safety,” pp. 149–174.
Christopher Uggen, Sarah Shannon, and Jeff Manza, State Level Estimates of Felon
Disenfranchisement in the United States, 2010 (Washington, DC: The Sentencing
Project, 2012).
See the reports from the International Crime Victimization Survey [ICVS]. www
.unodc.org. Accessed February 9, 2014.
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table 2.39. 2011.
Miller, Search and Destroy: African American Males in the Criminal Justice System.
Contrary to popular impression, the admonition to “First, do no harm” does not
appear in that exact form in the Hippocratic Oath. It has been inferred from other
parts of what is known as the Hippocratic Corpus, a larger body of writings.
Trop v. Dulles, 356 U.S.86 (1958).
Lawrence W. Sherman, Denise Gottfredson, Doris MacKenzie, John Eck, Peter
Reuter, and Shawn Bushway, Preventing Crime: What Works, What Doesn’t, What’s
Promising (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1997).
David M. Kennedy, Don’t Shoot: One Man, A Street Fellowship, and the End of
Violence in Inner-City America (New York: Bloomsbury, 2011), 219.
Gary Kleck, Point Blank Guns and Violence in America (New York: Aldine de
Gruyter, 1991), 432–433.
The best summary of social trends is Marc Minngoff and Marque-Luisa Miringoff,
The Social Health of the Nation How America Is Really Doing (New York: Oxford
University Press, 1999). Check the most recent Statistical Abstract of the United States
(annual) for the most recent data.
Dariush Mozaffarian, David Hemenway, and David S. Ludwig, “Curbing Gun
Violence: Lessons from Public Health Success,” Journal of the American Medical
Association 309 (February 13, 2013): 551–552.
Bureau of Labor Statistics, Unemployment Rate Demographics, September 2012 (October
10, 2012). http://www.bls.gov/opub/ted/2012/ted_20121010_data.htm. Accessed
February 9, 2014.
President’s Commission on Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice, The
Challenge of Crime in a Free Society (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office,
1967), vi. James Q. Wilson, Thinking about Crime.
George C. Thomas and David Edelman, “An Evaluation of Conservative Crime
Control Theology,” Notre Dame Law Review 63 (1988): 123–160.
Kleck, Point Blank.
James Q. Wilson and Richard J. Herrnstein, Crime and Human Nature: The Definitive
Study of the Causes of Crime (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1985), 44.
But see the article Wilson coauthored with Allan Abrahamse, “Does Crime Pay?”
Justice Quarterly 9 (September 1992): 359–377.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CRIME AND POLICY: A COMPLEX PROBLEM
37
75 Wilson, Thinking about Crime, 209.
76 William J. Bennett, John J. DiIulio, and John P Walters., Body Count: Moral Poverty–And
How to Win America’s War against Crime and Drugs (New York: Simon and Schuster,
1996), 205.
77 See the discussion of this point in Daniel S. Nagin, “Criminal Deterrence Research
at the Outset of the Twenty-First Century,” in Michael Tonry, ed., Crime and
Justice: A Review of Research, vol. 23 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998),
4–5.
78 John Braithwaite, Crime, Shame, and Reintegration (New York: Cambridge University
Press, 1989). John Braithwaite, “Restorative Justice: Assessing Optimistic and
Pessimistic Accounts,” in Michael Tonry, ed., Crime and Justice: A Review of Research,
vol. 25 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1999), 1–127.
79 Walker, Popular Justice: A History of American Criminal Justice, 2nd ed., 33–34.
80 Clifford R. Shaw and Henry D. McKay, Juvenile Delinquency in Urban Areas
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1942). Lawrence M. Friedman, Crime and
Punishment in American History (New York: Basic Books, 1993).
81 David J. Rothman, The Discovery of the Asylum (Boston: Little, Brown, 1971).
82 On the subject of rules and discretion, see Samuel Walker, Taming the System The
Control of Discretion in American Criminal Justice, 1950–1990 (New York: Oxford
University Press, 1993).
83 Herbert L. Packer, “Two Models of the Criminal Process,” in The Limits of the
Criminal Sanction (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1968), chap. 8.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
2
Models of Criminal Justice
T
he U.S. criminal justice system is extremely complex. People not familiar
with police discretion, how plea bargaining works, the law of sentencing,
and why the sentence pronounced by the judge does not usually reflect how
much time the offender will actually serve are often confused and frustrated.
This complexity helps explain why faith so often triumphs over fact, as we
explained in Chapter 1. Many people simply choose to believe what they want
to believe, regardless of the facts.
The United States actually has more than fifty separate criminal justice
systems (fifty state systems, the federal system, American Indian justice systems,
the military justice system), which include 18,769 separate state and local law
enforcement agencies. (And there is even dispute about that figure and what
constitutes a “law enforcement” agency.)1 Our state court systems are all structured differently.2 The criminal laws of the states vary, and punishments for the
same crimes differ. In the 2012 elections, two states legalized private possession
of marijuana, creating new enforcement complexities because of the conflict
between state and federal drug laws. Physician-assisted suicide is a crime in
most states, but not in Oregon, Washington, and Vermont. Same-sex marriage
was almost unheard of just a few years ago (and unthinkable when the first
edition of this book was published in 1985), but by early 2014 it was legal in
seventeen states and the District of Columbia.
The day-to-day administration of justice is even more complex than the
formal machinery of the justice system. To the casual observer, things often
seem chaotic. Many important decisions are made in informal, “low-visibility”
settings—the arrest (or non-arrest) on the street or the plea bargain negotiated
in the court hallway. The good news is that after five decades of increasingly
sophisticated research, we now have a reasonably good picture of police discretion and plea bargaining. But we continue to learn. The racial profiling controversy that erupted about fifteen years ago exposed the fact that there had been
no study of traffic enforcement since 1969.3 We now have a much better picture
of the factors that go into an officer’s decision to stop a car: the driving behavior;
the context such as the neighborhood; the race, ethnicity, or gender of the
38
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
39
driver; the department’s policy on traffic enforcement; and the attitudes of the
officer.4 The controversy over Florida’s “stand-your-ground” law in the controversial shooting of Trayvon Martin by George Zimmerman in 2012 introduced
a new issue in the national debate over gun violence.
4
PROPOSITION
Most crime control ideas are based on false assumptions about how the criminal
justice system works.
Two attitudes dominate thinking about the administration of criminal
justice: the Old Idealism and the New Cynicism. Neither helps explain how
the system works. As an alternative, we offer the Sober Realism perspective.
The Old Idealism is the classic civics-book picture of justice. In this scenario,
diligent and hardworking officials enforce the law as it is written in the statutes; a
person who commits a crime is duly arrested and prosecuted for that offense;
if convicted, he or she receives the prescribed punishment. It is an adversarial
system of justice that determines the truth of guilt or innocence through a public
contest between prosecution and defense, overseen by an impartial judge.
Although inspiring, this version of the criminal process does not describe the
reality of our justice system.
The New Cynicism is a mirror image of the Old Idealism. It portrays a
chaotic criminal justice system in which there is no law, order, or justice. Police
discretion is completely out of control: Officers arrest whomever they want, use
force without provocation, and so on. Prosecutors plea bargain wildly, letting
guilty people get off whereas innocent people are railroaded into prison. Defense
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
40
CHAPTER
2
attorneys and prosecutors are friends and cut deals to suit each other’s needs.5
Sentencing, according to the New Cynicism, is totally arbitrary: There is no
rhyme or reason why some people go to prison and others get probation. Parole
boards grant or deny release without any rational or scientific basis for their
decisions.6
The New Cynicism comes in two versions. Conservative cynics see irrational
decision making undermining effective crime control. Criminals are not punished
for their crimes: They are not arrested, they get their charges dropped, or they
obtain early parole release. Crafty defense lawyers manipulate the rules of criminal
procedure to beat the system. Liberal cynics, on the other hand, believe that the
apparent chaos of the system hides systematic discrimination. The poor are punished whereas “respectable” offenders get off easy; African Americans and Hispanic
Americans are the victims of systematic discrimination in arrests, plea bargains, and
sentencing. In The New Jim Crow, Michelle Alexander argues that the criminal justice system not only has a racist result but it driven by a racist purpose.7
In place of the tired and worn-out Old Idealism and New Cynicism we offer
Sober Realism as a far more useful perspective. Sober Realism is rooted in an
evidence-based view of how the criminal justice system actually works. (See
Chapter 1 for our discussion of evidence-based crime policy making.) This does
not mean we throw values under the bus and just say “anything goes.” We retain
our values, whether they be pro-death penalty or anti-death penalty, pro-gun control or anti-gun control. On these and other cases, however, Sober Realism holds
that to develop effective crime control policies we have to first understand the
situation we face. A gun control advocate, for example, has to face the fact that we
have an estimated 270 million firearms in private hands, 114 million of them hand
guns. A pro-death penalty person has to face the fact that factually innocent people
are sometimes convicted and sentenced to death. The Innocence Project has
exonerated 310 convicted offenders through DNA evidence since 1989; eighteen
were on death row at the time they were exonerated, and another sixteen had
been convicted of capital crimes but not sentenced to death.8 Sober Realism rejects
old myths about the criminal justice system and emotionally driven ideas that arise
from sensational “celebrated cases” (which we will explain shortly).
Undeniably, much decision making is irrational. Many offenders do escape
punishment. Except for murder, the risk of arrest is low for most crimes. Two
experts on drugs estimated the risk of arrest for drug dealers who average 1,000
deals per year (which would be almost 3 a day) at 1 in 4,500 transactions. We
can assume that the risk of arrest is even lower for less-active dealers, on the
theory that they are simply exposed to arrest less often.9 And as we will see in
Chapter 6 with regard to drunk driving, one of the top experts on the subject
estimated the risk of even being stopped for a breath test at 1 in 1 million miles
driven.10 (Check your odometer to calculate your personal risk.) There is racial
discrimination in the system. Research on the death penalty has found that the
African American who murders a white person has a greater probability of being
sentenced to death than the white person who murders an African American.
A higher probability, however, does not mean an absolute certainty—and that
is a part of the complexity of the system.11
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
41
We argue that our alternative perspective, Sober Realism, provides a better
interpretation of how the justice system handles routine cases on a day-to-day basis.
The purpose of this book is the help unravel the underlying patterns of the administration of justice. This chapter argues that most of the time, the system operates in
a fairly consistent and predictable manner. This does not mean it operates in a
good or just manner, just a predictable one. Much criminal justice research supports this view. Donald Black and others, for example, have found predictable patterns in police arrest discretion.12 Studies of plea bargaining have found that about
80 percent of the outcomes were predictable if the seriousness of the offense and
the defendant’s prior record were known in advance. We will discuss this interpretation of plea bargaining in detail in Chapter 8.13
Despite a high degree of predictability, the justice system is filled with paradoxes and inconsistencies. There is much truth in the comment made almost
forty years ago by Frank Zimring and colleagues that “the problem is not that
our system is too lenient, or too severe; sadly, it is both.”14 About a quarter of
a century ago, Norval Morris and Michael Tonry argued that we simultaneously
send too many people to prison and give others meaningless forms of probation
with little supervision: “We are both too lenient and too severe.”15 This paradox
is a key to understanding how our criminal justice system really works. Two
different outcomes occur at the same time in the same part of the justice system.
It is hard for many people to accept this, but it does happen, and we believe the
evidence supports this view.
Routine policing offers a concrete example of the contradictions in the
administration of justice. In the same city, in the same precinct, on the same
night, within the space of an hour, a pair of police officers both overenforce and
underenforce the law: They may be overly aggressive toward a young African American man hanging out on a street corner, and then within an hour not make an
arrest in a domestic violence incident a few blocks away, giving the male assailant a
break while denying the female victim the protection of the law.16 The apparent
contradiction is explained by the fact that the two different situations we just
described are different contexts with different dynamics. And we need to point
out that both situations involve forms of discrimination: against the young guy
on the street in the first and against the female victim of domestic violence in
the second. In this example, then, there is a hidden pattern of discrimination
underlying the surface contradiction. Sentencing offers additional examples. Some
people with multiple drunk driving convictions manage to avoid mandatory prison
terms, whereas someone arrested for possession of a small amount of drugs is sentenced to twenty-five years in prison. In terms of the relative harm to society of
the two offenses, this inconsistency makes no sense, but it does happen.
THE CRIME COMMISSION’S MODEL
To help understand how the justice system works, social scientists have constructed models of the system. The first and most famous model (Figure 2.1)
was developed more than forty-five years ago by the President’s Crime
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
42
Crime and
Law
Offenses
known to
police
CHAPTER
2
Police
Prosecution
Unsolved
or not
arrested
Released
without
prosecution
Released
without
prosecution
Defense
Charges
dropped or
dismissed
Charges
dropped or
dismissed
Information
Criminal
victimization
Investigation
Self-reported
criminal
activity
Arrest
Booking
Initial
appearance
Preliminary
hearing
Bail or
detention
Grand jury
Refusal to indict
Felonies
Statutory
provisions
Information
Attitudes
concerning
crime and
justice
Misdemeanors
Release or
station adjustment
Police
juvenile unit
Released
Intake hearing
Juvenile offenses
Nonpolice referrals
Nonjudicary
disposition
F I G U R E 2.1 The Crime Commission’s model of the criminal justice system.
SOURCE: President’s Commission on Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice, Task Force Report: Science and
Technology (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1967) pp. 58–59.
Commission (officially the President’s Commission on Law Enforcement and
Administration of Justice).17 At the time it first appeared, the Crime Commission’s model was an enormously important conceptual breakthrough. It
allowed people to see for the first time the criminal justice system as a whole,
and understand it as a “system.” Today, we take this conceptual framework for
granted, but in 1967 it was something new and illuminating. Previously,
criminal justice experts thought in terms of separate justice agencies that had
little relationship to each other.18 The systems approach helped researchers
and policy makers understand the complex interactions of the different parts
of the justice system.
The Crime Commission’s model accomplished exactly what models are
designed to do: provide a conceptual framework, or paradigm, that helps identify
general patterns, define problems, and focus research and policy planning.
The systems model focuses attention on the flow of cases among agencies,
the interrelationships among agencies (or “components” of the system), and the
pervasiveness of discretionary decision making throughout the system.19
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
Courts
43
Corrections
Charge dismissed
Acquitted
Arraignment
Trial
Pardon
and
clemency
Probation
Revocation
Sentencing
Penitentiary
Out of system
Guilty pleas
Parole
Appeal
Reduction of charge
Charge
dismissed
Habeas
corpus
Acquitted
Arraignment
Trial
Revocation
Capital
punishment
Probation
Sentencing
Guilty pleas
Revocation
Out of system
Jail
Fine
Nonpayment
Released
Petition to court
Adjudicatory hearing
Probation
Revocation
Juvenile institution
Out of system
Parole
Revocation
The discovery of the pervasiveness of discretion prompted researchers to study
the social, organizational, and situational factors that influence each of those
decisions. Today we have a better understanding of police arrest decisions and
plea bargains. We now understand, for example, that plea bargains are not the
result of “bad” people, but the result of sociological factors such as managing
the case workload. The systems approach also emphasizes the dynamic relationship
among components of the system and how decisions at one point (say, the prosecutor) affect decisions “upstream” (the police) and “downstream” (the judge).
Although the Crime Commission’s model was a great innovation and still
dominates thinking about the administration of justice, it has certain limitations.
Based on the substantial body of research evidence since then, we offer an alternative model.
THE CRIMINAL JUSTICE WEDDING CAKE
The major shortcoming of the Crime Commission’s model is that it portrays
a single justice system that handles all cases alike. Our alternative model is a
four-layer wedding cake that focuses our attention on important variations
in how cases are handled according to their seriousness (Figure 2.2). The
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
44
CHAPTER
2
F I G U R E 2.2 The criminal justice wedding cake.
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
wedding cake model was first developed by Lawrence Friedman and Robert
V. Percival in The Roots of Justice, a history of criminal justice in Alameda
County, California, between 1870 and 1910. Additional support, based on
contemporary evidence, is found in Michael and Don Gottfredson’s Decision
Making in Criminal Justice.20
The wedding cake model emphasizes two points. First, there are significant
differences between types of cases, based primarily on the seriousness of the
offense, the offender’s prior record, and the relationship between the victim
and the offender. Keep these three factors in mind, because they will reappear
throughout this book. Second, there are fairly consistent patterns of disposition
within each category.
“Celebrated Cases”: The Top Layer
At the top of the wedding cake is a small layer of “celebrated cases.” Every year
the news is dominated by a celebrated case involving either a famous person or a
particularly gruesome crime. The Sandy Hook School shooting on December
14, 2012, in which Adam Lanza shot and killed twenty schoolchildren, six
school teachers and staff members, his mother, and finally himself, provoked
national horror and outrage. It reenergized the debate over guns and gun violence in the United States. Seven months later, the trial of George Zimmerman
for shooting and killing Trayvon Martin gripped the nation, raising again old questions about race and justice in the United States (See our discussion is in Chapter 10).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
45
These were classic celebrated cases, generating enormous public interest, but they
were not typical of the routine operations of the criminal justice system.
Celebrated cases are different from routine cases in several respects. First,
many usually involve the full criminal process, including that rare event, the criminal trial, as was true of the Zimmerman/Martin case. (Twenty years ago, the
televised 1995 trial of O. J. Simpson for murdering his wife gripped the nation
to an even greater degree.) In a trial, we get to see fundamental issues contested
in public view: the sanity of the defendant; the admissibility of the evidence; the
credibility of the witnesses; the competence of the prosecutor and defense attorney, and the fairness of the judge. Trials are dramatic events, filled with tense
cross-examination and suspense about the outcome. They are rare events, however. The Bureau of Justice Statistics estimates that only 5 percent of all criminal
cases ever go to trial; the other 95 percent are settled by plea bargaining. And
those figures only involve cases presented to prosecutors. Many thousands more
arrests each year are dropped by the police without even going to the
prosecutor.21
School shootings are horrific events, but as the evidence in Box 2.1 indicates,
schools are relatively safe spaces in the United States and have been getting safer in
recent years.
Second, celebrated cases receive an enormous amount of publicity, usually
because of the nature of the crime itself (the shooting of twenty school children
in the Sandy Hook case, for example; in the O. J. Simpson case, it was the
explosive mixture of a celebrity, race, and sex). A few cases become celebrated
because they result in landmark Supreme Court rulings. The famous Miranda
case is an excellent example because of the importance of the decision (requiring
police to advise suspects of their rights) and its lasting impact on police
procedures.
© Cengage Learning
BOX
2.1
FACT VERSUS FICTION: HOW DANGEROUS ARE OUR SCHOOLS?
The Case of School Violence
The spate of school shootings has understandably raised public fears about the safety of children
(and teachers) in school. The Sandy Hook school shooting in 2012 was an unspeakable tragedy
and parents naturally fear for their children’s lives. Yet, the 2011 Indicators of School Crime and Safety
shows no increase in violent deaths in schools, and in fact a significant decline in total victimizations. Homicides of youth ages five to eighteen at school is down from the early 1990s to
2007–2010. Because of the low numbers, which are subject to significant variations, it is best to use
three-year rolling averages. From an average of 30.3 homicides between 1992 and 1994–1995, they
fell to an average of 18.3 in the 2007–2010 period.22 The rates of total victimizations against
students between 1992 and 2010 is especially revealing The rate is one-third of what it was eighteen
years before. Most important, at-school victimizations parallel the away-from-school trend. Reports
from the NCVS over the years have documented this long-term downward trend throughout U.S.
society.23
We can draw two conclusions from this. First, schools today are much safer than they were
when today’s recent high school graduate entered first grade. Second, schools are not isolated from
the communities they serve. Some are more dangerous than the average school and some are safer.
The public panic over the safety of their children at school is misplaced.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
46
CHAPTER
2
Third, as we have already mentioned, the publicity surrounding celebrated
cases distorts public perceptions about criminal justice. People mistakenly assume
that they are typical of all cases. The Zimmerman/Martin trial was televised
and featured on cable television station almost every night. But day-in, dayout, few of the 95 percent of all cases that are settled through plea bargains
receive much publicity at all.
The celebrated 1995 O. J. Simpson murder trial provides an excellent example
of how systematic data can dispel myths. Simpson’s acquittal led many people to
conclude that spouse murderers “beat the system” all the time. Even worse, it led
many whites to believe that African American jurors will not convict an African
American defendant. Both of these perceptions are grossly wrong. In response to
the Simpson trial outcome, the Bureau of Justice Statistics (BJS) analyzed its data
on spouse murders from the seventy-five largest counties in the country for 1988.
This included a total of 540 cases.24 As Figure 2.3 indicates, few accused spouse
murderers escaped conviction and punishment. In fact, only 2 percent of the husbands were acquitted. Wives were more likely to win acquittal (14 percent) because
there were more likely to be mitigating circumstances, such as killing in selfdefense. The system was tough on spouse murder defendants at every stage. Only
13 percent were not prosecuted. And of those who were convicted, 71 percent
were sentenced to prison (81 percent of the husbands and 57 percent of the
wives). This is an excellent example of how good, systematic data can debunk popular myths and provide an accurate picture of how the system really works.
Unfortunately, the BJS data set does not report the racial composition of
juries. Because the data come from the seventy-five largest urban counties in
the country, however, it is a safe assumption that racial minorities were well
represented. Thus, there is probably no truth to the idea that minority jurors
refuse to convict minority defendants. These data, in fact, indicate no real difference in the conviction rates between whites (81 percent) and African Americans
(79 percent).
11% not prosecuted
Of 318 husbands
46% pleaded guilty
41% convicted at trial
Probation 5%
Sentenced to
Prison 81%
(Average prison term:
16.5 years)
© Cengage Learning
2% acquitted at trial
16% not prosecuted
Of 222 wives
39% pleaded guilty
31% convicted at trial
Jail 1%
Probation 12%
Sentenced to
14% acquitted at trial
Jail 1%
Prison 57%
(Average prison term:
6 years)
F I G U R E 2.3 Dispositions of spouse murder defendants.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
47
The great value of the BJS data set is that it reflects the routine, day-in, dayout administration of justice. It gives us a far more accurate picture of how the
system operates than celebrated cases such as the O. J. Simpson trial. To understand how routine robberies and burglaries are handled, we need to turn our
attention to the second and third layers of the wedding cake. The lesson is
clear: beware of celebrated cases. Sure, they are great fodder for gossip, but
they do not reflect how the system works for most cases.
Serious Felonies: The Second and Third Layers
Serious felonies fall into two wedding cake layers, and the distinction between
more and less serious felonies is crucial for the analysis that follows. The more
serious felonies such as rape and robbery generally fall in is the second layer,
whereas less serious felonies such as burglary and larceny are generally in the
third. Felonious assaults are divided among the two layers, and misdemeanor
assaults are in the fourth layer.
A large body of research supports the view that criminal justice officials
consistently use several factors to define the seriousness of an offense: (1) the
nature of the crime, (2) whether a weapon was used, (3) whether the victim
was injured, (4) the suspect’s prior record, and (5) the relationship between the
victim and the offender.25
Once a criminal case begins, it is processed by member of the courtroom
work group (more about that in a moment). Processing involves classifying it
according to seriousness, or how much the work group thinks it is “worth,”
through an informal process. Traditionally, there was no actual check list, but
this is not completely true anymore. Some prosecutors’ offices have formal
guidelines that embody considerations of seriousness.26 Essentially, officials ask
themselves, “How much is this case worth?” or “How bad is this offender?” “Is
he or she a danger to the community?” The everyday language of police and
prosecutors reveals a lot about how cases are handled. They refer to “heavy”
cases and “real” crimes as opposed to the “garbage” or “bullshit” cases. A study
of California probation officers found that they used the same definitions of
“heavy duty” and “lightweight” cases that judges and prosecutors used.27
These judgments about seriousness are shared by all the members of the
courtroom work group, which we will explain in more detail in Chapter 3. The
courtroom work group plays a central role in determining how the system
works. The work group consists of criminal justice officials who work together
day in and day out. For the sake of efficiency, they develop shared understandings about how to handle routine cases. This process has two important consequences. First, it means that individual discretion is controlled informally, through
shared understandings and expectations rather than through formal rules. Second,
it produces a high degree of consistency within each layer of the wedding cake.
The shared definition of seriousness facilitates rapid disposition of a high volume
of cases. Prosecutors and defense attorneys do not spend a lot of time arguing
over particular cases; they know that an armed robbery where the victim was
injured is a serious case. As we will see in Chapter 8, the whole idea of plea
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
48
CHAPTER
2
“bargaining” is misleading. The criminal court is not like a Middle Eastern
bazaar, where people haggle over the price of each item. Malcolm Feeley argues
that it resembles a modern supermarket, with set prices and high volume.28 The
“fixed prices” reflect the shared assumptions about how much cases are worth.
Criminologist Robert Bohm characterizes the process as “McJustice,” with the
efficient handling of a large volume of business at set prices as a part of the
broader “McDonaldization” of society.29
Ulmer’s study of sentencing in three Pennsylvania counties also found,
however, that the degree of shared understandings can vary. One county court
system had a high degree of stability among prosecutors, defense attorneys, and
judges, and as a result had collegial relations and shared understandings. A large
urban county, on the other hand, had a high degree of turnover in the district
attorney’s office, which resulted in conflict between prosecutors and defense
attorneys and a low level of collegiality and understanding between defense
attorneys and judges.30 In short, although most court systems operate under
shared understandings, there are important variations depending on the composition and culture of the local courtroom work group. We will discuss the work
group in more detail in Chapter 3.
Robbery illustrates how officials distribute cases between the second and
third layers. All robberies are not the same. Because robbery is generally considered a serious crime, most cases end up in the second layer, especially if a
weapon is used. About one-third of all robberies, however, are between
acquaintances. These are often private disputes: a disagreement over borrowed
money or tools where the “offender” takes back his or her property by force.31
These robbery cases tend to end up in the third layer because they are not considered as serious as robberies by strangers. If, however, the offender has a long
prior record of arrests and convictions, the case might remain in the second layer.
An Example of the Complexity of the System: “Back-End
Sentencing” in California
Despite the general pattern of consistency and predictability, exceptions do
occur, and such exceptions add to the complexity of the criminal justice system.
One example is the pattern of back-end sentencing in California. Two-thirds of
all the people entering prisons in California are parole violators rather than newly
sentenced offenders. Officials call it back-end sentencing, because parole officials
are doing what we think judges should do: send people to prison. For the simple
reason that it represents two-thirds of the people entering prison, it is a major
part of the state criminal justice systems. Among other things, it contributes to
the serious prison overcrowding in the state that has resulted in federal court
orders to reduce the prison population.
The process is a result of some unique aspects of California sentencing and
parole laws. Under California’s Determinate Sentencing Law, all but a few prisoners are automatically released on parole. The parole laws, meanwhile, require
parole officers to report parolees for a wide range of parole violations. About
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
49
66 percent are sent back to prison within three years (about 60 percent for parole
violations rather than for a new crime). Some parolees commit new offenses.
Rather than prosecute them, however, local authorities simply revoke their
parole. Parole revocations require a lower standard of proof (preponderance of
the evidence) rather than proof beyond a reasonable doubt, and thus are considered a “sure thing.”32
The Impact of Prior Record
The BJS report on Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2006 provides
powerful evidence on the impact of prior record in the disposition of cases. As
Table 2.1 indicates, the percentage of defendants convicted of a felony sentenced
to prison dropped from 54 percent for those with two or more prior felony
convictions to only 29 percent for those with no prior convictions (felony or
misdemeanor). A similar pattern exists for persons convicted of a property
offense.
The Impact of the Victim–Offender Relationship
The relationship between the victim and the offender is also an important factor
in criminal justice decision making. A Vera Institute study of felony arrests in
New York City provides powerful data on its impact. Figure 2.4 indicates
that 88 percent of the stranger robberies resulted in conviction. Moreover, prosecutors were not lenient in plea bargaining: 77 percent of those convictions
(68 percent of the original arrests) were on felony charges. Nearly threequarters (74 percent) of those convicted were incarcerated, and half of them did
time of a year or more. This is hardly the picture of a system “soft” on crime.33
The prior-relationship robberies are a completely different story. Only about
a third (37 percent) of the suspects were convicted, and only 13 percent of them
(5 percent of the number originally arrested) were convicted on felony charges.
Slightly more than half (56 percent) of those convicted were incarcerated, but
none did a year or more.
The powerful effect of prior relationships is also evident in rape cases. About
half of the sexual assaults in the Vera Institute study were committed by men
who knew the victim. Sixty percent of these cases were dismissed; another
T A B L E 2.1
Percentage of defendants sentenced to prison by prior record
Prior Record
Percentage Sentenced to Prison
More than one prior felony conviction
54
Only one prior felony conviction
45
Prior misdemeanor one or more prior conviction
26
No prior convictions
29
SOURCE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2006 (Washington, DC Justice
Department, 2010), Table 15.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
50
CHAPTER
2
20 percent ended in a guilty plea with only minor punishment. All of the
stranger-rape cases, however, went to trial. Three-quarters of these resulted in
conviction and imprisonment, and two-thirds of the prison terms exceeded
twenty-five years.
The third layer of the criminal justice wedding cake is a different story.
The less serious cases are regularly dismissed; defendants are often allowed to
plead guilty to lesser offenses; and, if convicted, defendants are placed on
probation. Outcomes are less predictable in the third layer because there is
less consensus about the seriousness and the appropriate response than in the
second layer.
Prior-Relationship Robbery Arrests
100
Stranger Robbery Arrests
100% (34 cases)
100% (19 cases)
Convictions
on felony
charges
88%
90
80
65%
70
60
50
37%
40
30
20
10
0
Arrests
0%
5%
Convictions Sentences
on any
to jail or
charges
prison
Sentences
to felony
time over
one year
Prior-Relationship Burglary Arrests
100
32%
68%
21%
100% (17 cases)
Arrests
Convictions Sentences
on any
to jail or
charges
prison
Sentences
to felony
time over
one year
Stranger Burglary Arrests
100% (27 cases)
89%
90
Convictions
on felony
charges
80
70
53%
60
48%
50
40
30
20
6%
10
0
Arrests
Convictions Sentences
on any
to jail or
charges
prison
0%
Sentences
to felony
time over
one year
Arrests
7%
Convictions Sentences
on any
to jail or
charges
prison
0%
Sentences
to felony
time over
one year
F I G U R E 2.4 Outcomes of stranger and nonstranger robberies and burglaries,
New York City.
SOURCE: Vera Institute, Felony Arrests, rev. ed. (New York: Longman, 1981), pp. 68, 86. Reprinted with permission.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
51
In their classic study of the jury, Harry Kalven and Hans Zeisel explain this
lack of consensus for less serious questions in terms of a “liberation” hypothesis.
Under certain circumstances, they argue, jurors are “liberated” from normal
constraints in assessing the importance of criminal cases.34 Applying this hypothesis to the wedding cake, we can say that in the third layer, the lack of consensus
about the seriousness of the crime or the offender’s prior record liberates prosecutors and judges from the conventional shared understandings of seriousness.
This allows them to base their decision on other factors. In some instances, the
defendant’s race or other personal attribute becomes a factor.
Spohn and Cederblom explored the liberation hypothesis in a study of 4,655
violent felony cases in Detroit from 1976 to 1978.35 They found that African
Americans were more likely to be incarcerated than whites. But this was true
only in the less serious crimes: in assaults rather than more serious felonies, in
acquaintance crimes, and in cases in which there were no prior violent felony
convictions or no gun was involved. The outcomes in the more serious crimes
(that is, the second-layer cases) were more consistent, with whites and African
Americans treated equally harshly. In the less serious (for example, third-layer)
cases, there was less consensus about how much these cases were worth, and
this allowed extralegal factors such as race to come into play.
Finally, with regard to the impact of the seriousness of cases on criminal
justice officials, we should note that crime victims make the same distinctions
about seriousness in decisions they make. The NCVS consistently finds that
victims report the more serious crimes at a higher rate than less serious ones.
Between 2006 and 2010, victims reported 59 percent of all robberies, but only
44 percent of simple assaults and 33 percent of all thefts.36 The pattern seems
clear: the less serious the personal harm or the value of the property stolen, the
less seriously crime victims take the event, and as a result are less likely to report
it as a crime. In short, decisions of criminal justice officials on the question of
seriousness reflect the values of Americans generally.
Prior Relationship: A Policy Dilemma
The role of the prior relationship between victim and offender presents a major
policy dilemma. At issue is whether it is legitimate to use this role as a factor in
decision making.
In the area of domestic violence, research has found that police traditionally
have taken into account the nature of the relationship. The more intimate the
relationship, the less likely the police are to make an arrest.37 Thus, they are less
likely to arrest the abusive husband than the abusive boyfriend or lover. In
response to protests from women’s groups, many police departments have
adopted mandatory arrest or arrest-preferred policies that either require an arrest
in a felonious domestic assault or advise officers that arrest is the preferred disposition. The intent is to ensure equal enforcement of the law and to eliminate
discrimination based on marital status.38
Along the same lines, Susan Estrich argues that all sexual assaults should be
prosecuted with equal vigor. Rapes between acquaintances should not be treated
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
52
CHAPTER
2
less seriously than rapes perpetrated by a stranger. Estrich describes her conversation with a local prosecutor who explained that he used the prior-relationship
criterion in all criminal cases, not just rape. He was accurately describing how
officials generally handle criminal cases.39
What would happen if we did eliminate prior relationship as a decision
making factor in all criminal cases? At the arrest stage, it would produce more
domestic violence arrests. The arrest rate trends for aggravated assault (which
includes felony domestic violence arrests) indicate an interesting pattern. Between
1980 and 1995, the national arrest rate for aggravated assault doubled. During the
same time period, the arrest rate for robbery (the closest personal crime of
violence) fluctuated from year to year but with an overall stable rate. These data
suggest that the police did begin making more domestic violence arrests in those
years, undoubtedly in response to increased public concern about domestic
violence and new police department arrest policies. The influence of prior
relationship was not completely eliminated, of course, but it would appear that it
was significantly modified in response to a changing social and legal context.40
This outcome presents us with a policy dilemma. Eliminating prior relationship
as a decision-making factor would produce greater equality in the administration
of justice—a desirable outcome. At the same time, however, it would increase the
overall puntiveness of the justice system. Is that a desirable result?
A general lesson can be learned here. Significant changes in criminal justice
policy often involve major trade-offs. The gains on one side of the equation
need to be considered in light of the consequences on the other side.
Hard or Soft on Crime? Unraveling the Paradox
Is the criminal justice system hard or soft on crime? Our wedding cake illuminates
the paradox noted by Zimring, Morris, and Tonry: The system is simultaneously
harsh and lenient. A great deal depends on the seriousness of the case. The system
is hard on second-layer cases, such as robberies committed by people with long prior
records. But it is relatively soft on assaults by offenders with no prior records. It is
hard on stranger rapes, which fall in the second layer of the Wedding Cake, but
more lenient on acquaintance assaults, which fall in the third layer.
Additional support for the distinction between the second and third layers of
the wedding cake is found in some career-criminal prosecution programs. We
will look at these in detail in Chapter 8. These programs are designed to concentrate prosecutorial resources on a special class of cases involving career criminals
to make sure they are convicted and sentenced to prison. The San Diego Major
Violator Unit succeeded in convicting 91.5 percent of the career criminals it
handled. But 89.5 percent of the career criminals were being convicted before
the program began. Under the program, 100 percent of the convicted career
criminals were incarcerated, but the rate had been 95.3 percent beforehand. In
short, criminals deemed “serious” by commonsense criteria were already being
taken seriously. As Diana Gordon, former director of the National Council on
Crime and Delinquency, put it, “Being tough doesn’t work because being
lenient is not the source of the problem.”41
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
53
The idea that our criminal justice system is tough on serious crime comes as
a surprise to many people. A Sentencing Project report found that most people
believe that the system is much softer than it actually is.42 There are two reasons
for this misperception. First, they are influenced by celebrated cases that are not
typical of general patterns in the justice system. Second, because official data
usually aggregate sentences into general categories, they obscure the important
distinctions between serious and less serious crimes. Aggregate data give the
appearance of softness because relatively few cases end up in the second layer.
Violent crimes represent only 10 percent of all felonies reported to the police.
Larceny, the least serious felony, accounts for 54 percent of the total. The
wedding cake model allows us to focus on how the system responds to the
most serious crimes, those in the second layer.
We need to add here that over the last several decades the criminal justice
system has gotten much tougher on serious crime, a fact that accounts for the
soaring prison population. We will discuss this in detail in Chapters 3 and 7.
The important point here is that, given that change, the distinction between
the second and third layers of the Wedding Cake remains consistent, as do the
patterns of predictability within each of the two layers.
The Lower Depths: The Fourth Layer
The fourth layer of the wedding cake is a world unto itself. The lower criminal
courts handle all of the misdemeanors in most jurisdictions. The volume of cases
is staggering, far outnumbering felonies. The eight Part I Index crimes accounted
for only 17 percent of the 9.5 million arrests in 2011. About half of the Part II
Index crime arrests involved “public order” offenses: disorderly conduct, breach
of the peace, drunkenness, and so on. In fact, the largest single arrest category
every year is “All other offenses (except traffic),” with a total of 2.7 million in
2011.43 Under the criterion of seriousness, these cases are not considered to be
worth much at all. Few of the defendants are regarded as real threats to public
safety.
Because of the huge volume of cases and their relative lack of seriousness,
relatively little concern is shown for the formalities of the felony process. In an
excellent study of the lower courts of New Haven, Connecticut, Malcolm
Feeley concludes that these institutions remain virtually untouched by the dueprocess revolution.44 To enter these courts is to step back in time eighty years.
None of the defendants in the 1,640 cases he examined insisted on a jury trial.
Half never had an attorney. Even for those that did, the lawyer’s contribution
was minimal. Even more shocking, by our standards of due process, defendants
were arraigned en masse, in assembly-line fashion. Sentences were extremely light.
Half of the defendants received a fine of fifty dollars or less, and only 4.9 percent
were sentenced to jail.
Feeley concludes that the “process is the punishment”: Simply being
brought into the lower courts is the real punishment, quite apart from the eventual outcome of the case. Insisting on your “rights” only increases the
“punishment.” A private attorney, for example, would charge 200 dollars to
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
54
CHAPTER
2
handle a case (about 800 dollars at today’s rates). This is four times the fine
were you simply to cop a plea at the earliest possible moment. Moreover,
because most defendants in the lower courts are hourly wage earners rather
than salaried professionals, the lost wages involved in fighting a case would
generally exceed the potential fine. (Each case in Feeley’s study averaged three
court appearances. Fighting the case would only increase the number and length
of court dates.)
The closer we look, however, the more complicated the picture becomes.
A study of the Philadelphia lower courts offers a different view and illustrates the
hazards of generalizing about criminal justice. Stephen J. Schulhofer found that
in Philadelphia’s two lower courts—Municipal Court and the Court of
Common Pleas—about half (48 percent) of all cases went to trial, virtually all
defendants had legal counsel, and the punishments meted out to the guilty
were relatively significant. Nearly a quarter (22 percent) of the convicted offenders received a jail sentence, and 17.4 percent received fines (which ranged as
high as several hundred dollars). Schulhofer argues that Feeley overstated the
“process” costs of contesting a case in the lower courts. The price of the likely
penalty, at least in Philadelphia, makes the case worth fighting. The main reason
appears to be that penalties are significantly stiffer in Philadelphia than in New
Haven.45
We do not need to resolve the differences between Feeley and Schulhofer’s
findings here. The basic points are that (1) the lower courts are different from the
upper courts and (2) there are significant differences between courts in different
jurisdictions.
CONCLUSION
Our wedding cake model of the criminal justice system is designed to help us
make sense of the administration of justice in action. As we go along, the most
important thing to keep in mind is that we should not be distracted by celebrated cases. They make great stories for the tabloids, but they interfere with
our understanding of routine operations in criminal justice. In particular, we
want to be skeptical of any policies that are based on celebrated cases. And
because we are primarily concerned with the control of serious crime—robbery
and burglary in particular—we need to keep our eyes focused on the second
layer of the wedding cake.
NOTES
1 Wesley G. Skogan and Kathleen Frydl, Fairness and Effectiveness in Policing: The
Evidence (Washington, DC: National Academies Press, 2004).
2 Bureau of Justice Statistics, State Court Organization, 2004 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2006).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
55
3 John A. Gardiner, Traffic and the Police: Variations in Law-Enforcement Policy
(Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 1969).
4 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Contact Between the Police and the Public, 2008
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2011).
5 This interpretation is vividly captured in “The Practice of Law as a Confidence
Game,” in Abraham Blumberg, Criminal Justice, 2nd ed., (New York: New
Viewpoints, 1979), 242–243.
6 For a reasonable review of the evidence, see Samuel Walker, Cassia Spohn, and
Miriam DeLone, The Color of Justice Race, Ethnicity, and Crime in America, 5th ed.
(Belmont, CA: Cengage, 2012).
7 Michelle Alexander, The New Jim Crow: Mass Incarceration in the Age of Colorblindness
(New York: The New Press, 2010).
8 See the Innocence Project’s website for the most recent data: www
.innocenceproject.org. Accessed February 9, 2014.
9 David Boyum and Peter Reuter, An Analytic Assessment of US Drug Policy
(Washington, DC: AEI Press, 2005).
10 H. Laurence Ross, Confronting Drunk Driving: Social Policy for Saving Lives (New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1992).
11 Walker, Spohn, and DeLone, The Color of Justice.
12 Black, The Manners and Customs of the Police
13 Peter F. Nardulli, James Eisenstein, and Roy B. Flemming, The Tenor of Justice
Criminal Courts and the Guilty Plea Process (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1988).
14 Franklin Zimring, Sheila O’Malley, and Joel Eigen, “Punishing Homicide in
Philadelphia: Perspectives on the Death Penalty,” University of Chicago Law Review
43 (Winter 1976): 252.
15 Norval Morris and Michael H. Tonry, Between Prison and Probation Intermediate
Punishments in a Rational Sentencing System (New York: Oxford University Press,
1990), 3.
16 Walker, Spohn, and DeLone, The Color of Justice, chap. 4.
17 President’s Commission on Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice, Task
Force Report Science and Technology (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office,
1967), 58–59.
18 Samuel Walker, Popular Justice: A History of American Criminal Justice, 2nd ed. (New
York: Oxford University Press, 1998), 202–206.
19 On the origins of the systems perspective, see Samuel Walker, “Origins of the
Contemporary Criminal Justice Paradigm: The American Bar Foundation Survey,
1953–1969,” Justice Quarterly 9 (March 1992): 201–229.
20 Lawrence M. Friedman and Robert V. Percival, The Roots of Justice Crime and
Punishment in Alameda County, California, 1870–1910 (Chapel Hill: University of
North Carolina Press, 1981). Michael R. Gottfredson and Don M. Gottfredson,
Decision Making in Criminal Justice Toward the Rational Exercise of Discretion, 2nd ed.
(New York: Plenum, 1988).
21 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2006
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2010).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
56
CHAPTER
2
22 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Indicators of School Crime and Safety: 2011 (Washington,
DC: Department of Justice, 2012), Figure 1.1, Figure 2.1.
23 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2010 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2011).
24 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Spouse Murder Defendants in Large Urban Counties
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1995).
25 Jeffrey T. Ulmer, Social Worlds of Sentencing: Court Communities Under Sentencing
Guidelines (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1997), 60–62.
26 William F. McDonald, Plea Bargaining Critical Issues and Common Practices
(Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1985).
27 The informal language is reported in several studies: Lynn Mather, “Some
Determinants of the Method of Case Disposition: Decision Making by Public
Defenders in Los Angeles,” Law and Society Review 8 (Winter 1974): 187–216. David
Sudnow, “Normal Crimes: Sociological Features of the Penal Code in a Public
Defender Office,” Social Problems 12 (Winter 1965): 255–276. John Rosecrance,
“Maintaining the Myth of Individualized Justice: Probation Presentence Reports,”
Justice Quarterly 5 (June 1988): 235–256. See also our discussion of this issue with
respect to plea bargaining in chapter 8.
28 Malcolm M. Feeley, “Perspectives on Plea Bargaining,” Law and Society Review 13
(Winter 1979): 199.
29 Robert M. Bohm, “McJustice: On the McDonaldization of Criminal Justice” Justice
Quarterly 23 (March 2006): 127–146.
30 Ulmer, Social Worlds of Sentencing: Court Communities Under Sentencing Guidelines.
31 Donald Black, Toward a General Theory of Social Control, vol. 2 (Orlando, FL:
Academic Press, 1984), 1–28.
32 Ryken Grattet, Joan Petersiha, and Jeffrey Lin, Parole Violations and Revocations in
California (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2008).
33 Vera Institute, Felony Arrests, rev. ed. (New York: Longman, 1981).
34 Harry Kalven, Jr., and Hans Zeisel, The American Jury (Boston: Little, Brown, 1966),
164–166.
35 Cassia Spohn and Jerry Cederblom, “Race and Disparities in Sentencing: A Test of
the Liberation Hypothesis,” Justice Quarterly 8 (September 1991): 306.
36 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Victimizations Not Reported to the Police, 2006–2010
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2012).
37 Black, The Manners and Customs of the Police.
38 Lawrence W. Sherman, Janell D. Schmidt and Dennis P. Rogan, et al., Policing
Domestic Violence (New York: The Free Press, 1992).
39 Susan Estrich, Real Rape (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1987).
40 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Arrest in the United States, 1980–2009 (Washington, DC,
Department of Justice, 2011).
41 U.S. Department of Justice, An Exemplary Project Major Violator Unit—San Diego,
California (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1980). Diana R. Gordon,
Toward Realistic Reform A Commentary on Proposals for Change in New York City’s
Criminal Justice System (Hackensack, NJ: National Council on Crime and
Delinquency, 1981), 16.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
MODELS OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
57
42 The Sentencing Project, Crime, Punishment, and Public Opinion: A Summary of Recent
Studies and Their Implications for Sentencing Policy (Washington, DC: The Sentencing
Project, nd).
43 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, online edition.
Table 4.7.2011.
44 Malcolm M. Feeley, The Process Is the Punishment (New York: Russell Sage
Foundation, 1979).
45 Stephen J. Schulhofer, “No Job Too Small: Justice Without Bargaining in the
Lower Criminal Courts,” American Bar Foundation Research Journal (Summer 1985):
519–598.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
3
The Going Rate
EVALUATING THE SYSTEM
We now turn our attention to the question of how the criminal justice system
works on a day-to-day basis. How effectively does it control crime? How
successful is it in catching, prosecuting, and punishing dangerous criminals? Is
the system fair? Is there a pattern of discrimination against people of color?
Much controversy surrounds these questions. For years, the Sentencing
Project has argued that we lock up far too many people.1 Michelle Alexander
in The New Jim Crow indicts the criminal justice system for intentional and
systematic race discrimination.2 Yet, for four decades, the majority of Americans
and state legislatures have been convinced that we need to put more people in
prison and for longer terms.3
Evaluating the performance of our criminal justice system is a difficult task.
As we have already learned, on some questions we do not even have good data.
The national controversy over “driving while black” exposed the embarrassing
fact that we didn’t have any systematic data on traffic enforcement, on who
gets stopped, and what happens to them. Even where reasonably good data are
available, experts disagree over what they mean. There is much debate over
whether the traffic stop data we now have indicate racial and ethnic discrimination or disparities that can be explained by other factors.4
This chapter identifies some general features of the criminal process. As we
argued in Chapter 2, a high level of consistency and predictability exists in the
justice system. There is also a going rate for crime in each jurisdiction, although
there are variations among local jurisdictions. The going rate is defined as the
standard and predictable punishment for a particular crime. What is the expected
outcome, for example, of a criminal case involving a first offense robbery
where the defendant has two prior felony theft convictions with sentences of
probation?
The overall going rate has changed significantly over the last thirty to forty
years, however. The criminal justice system has become harsher in punishing convicted offenders than ever before. This fact is dramatically evident in Figure 1.2 in
58
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
59
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
Chapter 1 on the explosion in the prison population.5 That is a dramatic change
by any measure. Within that pattern of toughness, we will argue in this chapter,
familiar themes of consistency still prevail.
THE CRIMINAL JUSTICE FUNNEL
A good starting point is the President’s Crime Commission analysis of the flow
of cases through the system (Figure 3.1). Although the data are from the 1960s,
they illustrate important basic patterns that have not fundamentally changed.
The Crime Commission found that despite 6 million reported and unreported
crimes, only 63,000 offenders were sentenced to prison. This led to the conclusion that only 1 percent of all criminals go to prison. Many people have
cited this figures as evidence that the criminal justice system fails to punish
offenders. We argue that the 1 percent estimate seriously distorts how the
system really works.
In a sharp critique, Charles Silberman argued that the Crime Commission’s
analysis was “grossly misleading.”6 Reanalyzing the same data (Figure 3.2), he
pointed out that about 260,000 (35.7 percent) of the original 727,000 arrests
involved juveniles whose cases were transferred to juvenile court. What happens
to them is, of course, extremely important but not our concern here. In this
book we are focusing on adults.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
60
CHAPTER
3
2,780,000 Index crimes reported
727,000
arrested
177,000 formal
felony complaints
160,000 sentenced
63,000 to prison
F I G U R E 3.1 The funneling effect of the criminal justice system.
SOURCE: President’s Commission on Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice, Task Force Report: Science and
Technology (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1967), p. 61.
Subtracting the juveniles leaves 467,000 adult arrests. Silberman argued that
this is the proper baseline for assessing the performance of the adult criminal justice system. About 27 percent of these arrests (128,000) were dismissed, leaving
339,000 prosecuted adults. This results in a prosecution rate of 73 percent, which
is hardly a sign of softness on crime. Then, about half (48 percent) of these
defendants pled guilty to a misdemeanor. These cases were not “lost,” as many
some estimates suggest. The defendants were convicted of a crime and suffered
all the collateral consequences of having a criminal record. In Chapter 2, we
cited Malcolm Feeley’s analysis of all this as the “process” costs of the lower
courts.
Subtracting the misdemeanor convictions leaves 177,000 adult felony complaints. Of these, 90 percent were convicted: 130,000 by a guilty plea and
30,000 by trial. A 90 percent conviction rate is impressive. When we combine
the 160,000 felony convictions with the 162,000 misdemeanor convictions, we
have a total of 332,000 adults convicted. This represents 69 percent of all the
adults arrested and 95 percent of those prosecuted. This is a picture of a fairly
tough criminal justice system.
Have things changed since the 1960s? The BJS report Felony Defendants in
Large Urban Counties, 2006 indicates that 68 percent of all felony arrests presented
to prosecutors resulted in a conviction (up from 64 percent in 2000); 56 percent
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
61
727,000
arrested
260,000
juveniles
467,000
adults arrested
339,000
adults prosecuted
162,000
plead guilty to
misdemeanors
128,000
dismissed
177,000
adult felony complaints
130,000
plead guilty
17,000
not guilty
30,000
guilty at trial
Total “in”
or punished:
322,000 adults
Total “out”:
145,000 adults
260,000 juveniles
F I G U R E 3.2 Silberman’s recalculation of the Crime Commission’s funnel.
SOURCE: Charles Silberman, Criminal Violence, Criminal Justice (New York: Random House, 1978), pp. 257–261.
were convicted of a felony and 11 percent were convicted of a misdemeanor.
These patterns are not radically different from the 1960s.7
When we apply our wedding cake model to the BJS data, we find important patterns. Conviction rates vary by the type of crime. In 2009 (the most
recent data available), 70 percent of all murder defendants were convicted, as
were 68 percent of rape defendants and 66 percent of robbery defendants.
These figures represent total conviction rates. Among the robbery defendants,
59 percent were convicted of a felony and 7 percent of a misdemeanor. For
rape defendants, 57 percent were convicted of a felony and 11 percent were
convicted of a misdemeanor. The lowest conviction rate was for assault defendants (56 percent overall; 39 percent for a felony). What happens to felony
defendants who are convicted? According to the BJS report, 73 percent were
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
62
CHAPTER
T A B L E 3.1
3
Sentences for convicted offenders, 2009
Conviction
Incarcerated
Offense
Prison
Murder
98
R ape
84
R obbery
Assault
Not Incarcerated
Jail
Probation
Other
2
0
0
5
11
0
71
18
11
1
47
34
18
1
Burglary
53
26
20
1
Larceny/theft
40
32
27
0
Drug Trafficking
45
35
19
1
SOURCE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2009 (Washington, DC: Department
of Justice, 2013).
incarcerated; 36 percent went to prison; and 37 percent went to jail.8 The major
change since the 1960s has been a dramatic increase in the incarceration rate (the
percentage of offenders sentenced to prison or jail) and the length of prison
sentences.
The incarceration rate needs some further discussion. People who argue that
the criminal justice system is systematically “soft” on crime cite the fact that
36 percent of all convicted felons are sentenced to prison. They overlook the
fact that 35 percent are sentenced to jail. This issue requires a judgment call
based on our values. Time in jail is not a pleasant experience. Jails have fewer
programs than prisons. And the offender still has a criminal conviction with
all the collateral consequences.9 From our perspective, then, the 73 percent
incarceration figure is the proper standard.
A CLOSER LOOK INSIDE THE FUNNEL
The picture gets even more complicated when we step back and take a
broader view of the entire criminal process. The BJS data represent cases that
are presented to prosecutors (the Methodology section defines them as “felony
filed with the court”).10 This omits a lot of people who have been arrested.
The police routinely decide not to file charges against some people they have
arrested. In some cases a supervising sergeant refuses to sign off on the arrest
charge. The evidence may simply be too weak; the witnesses may be unreliable; or there may be no witnesses at all. Joan Petersilia found that about
11 percent of all arrests in California were dropped by the police.11 Prosecutors, meanwhile, reject many cases, usually because of witness or evidence or
witness problems.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
63
The official arrest data reported by the FBI, it turns out, are less precise than
they appear. The key word is official arrests, which means officially recorded arrests.
An arrest is only an official arrest if the police complete an arrest report. A Police
Foundation report found that police departments do not complete official arrest
reports in a standard fashion.12 If you are taken into custody by the police and
held, you are arrested, in both a legal and psychological sense, but not necessarily
in an official sense. Some police departments officially record all such arrests, but
many do not. Some officially record arrests only when a suspect is taken to a
police facility. Some officially record them only if the suspect is questioned.
The net result is that arrest data across police departments are not comparable.
(This fact is not acknowledged by criminologists who do cross-sectional studies
of arrest activity.) The BJS felony defendants data do not take into account
everyone who is arrested, and the “true” number of persons arrested by the
police in any given year is not known but certainly larger than official data
indicate.
Weeding out the Weak Cases: Rejections and Dismissals
After a case reaches the prosecutor’s desk, it can then be rejected by the prosecutor
or dismissed by a judge. Table 3.2 presents BJS data on the reasons for rejections
and dismissals in New York and San Diego. (These data are a little old, but the
general patterns still holds today.) The most notable point is that the major
reason for rejections by prosecutors is insufficient evidence or lack of any evidence: 61 percent in New York and 51 percent in San Diego. Witness problems
are the second most important reason: 18 percent of the rejections in New York
and 19 percent in San Diego. For most crimes against persons (robbery, rape,
assault), the testimony of the victim or a witness is the primary evidence. In
short, evidence and witness problems account for about 70 to 80 percent of all
rejections. These data are relevant to the too-soft or too-harsh debate. Cases
with weak evidence are not going to result in a conviction. They are rejected
or dismissed not because prosecutors and judges are soft on crime, but because
these officials are realistic: why waste everyone’s time on a losing case? The
reason for the “loss” of these cases lies in the nature of the cases themselves,
not in the attitudes of criminal justice officials.
A closer look reveals that the even the term dismissal is misleading. Many of
these cases are not really lost, as some critics of the system argue. In San Diego,
for example, almost half of the dismissals involved an action that kept the defendant in the criminal justice system: 11 percent were diverted, 27 percent were
referred for other prosecution, and 10 percent were covered by another case
(for a combined total of 48 percent). This is not the sign of soft-hearted judges
or a “weak” system.
The data on rejections and dismissals have important policy implications and
how we view the justice system. Most important, they clearly indicate that dueprocess problems—illegal searches or coerced confessions—are not a major
reason why cases are not prosecuted. (We will discuss this issue and the controversy
over Supreme Court decisions on searches and interrogations in Chapter 5.)
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
0
0
0
0
R ape
R obbery
Aggravated assault
Burglary
0%
0
0
0
0
0
Percentage of declinations
Murder and manslaughter
R ape
R obbery
Aggravated assault
Burglary
Most serious charge
Diversion
0
Murder and manslaughter
San Diego, California 1988
0%
0
0
0
0
0
0%
Other
prosecution
0
3
8
0
0
3%
Other
prosecution
59
39
49
30
50
51%
Evidence
79
33
63
30
75
61%
Evidence
0
0
0
0
0
2%
Due process
15
46
36
60
3
19%
Witness
8
2
1
0
0
13%
Due process
Arrests declined because of:
21
40
22
40
25
18%
Witness
Arrests declined because of:
8
9
6
8
30
11%
Interest of
justice
0
13
3
30
0
10%
Interest of
justice
5
1
0
1
0
3%
Covered by
other case
0
0
0
0
0
0%
Covered by
other case
(continued)
5
3
7
2
17
4%
Other
0
11
4
0
0
6%
Other
CHAPTER
Percentage of declinations
Most serious charge
Diversion
Why felony arrests are declined for prosecution
Manhattan, New York 1988
T A B L E 3.2
64
3
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
1
0
Aggravated assault
Burglary
0
0
0
2
2
Murder and manslaughter
R ape
R obbery
Aggravated assault
Burglary
25
26
17
4
20
27%
Other
prosecution
0
0
0
0
1
0%
Other
prosecution
12
21
27
22
20
14%
Evidence
15
10
18
13
17
19%
Evidence
0
0
0
0
0
0%
Due process
10
17
27
22
0
6%
Witness
0
0
1
0
0
0%
Due process
Cases dismissed because of:
11
26
21
33
15
14%
Witness
SOURCE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, The Prosecution of Felony Arrests, 1988 (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1992).
11%
Percentage of declinations
Most serious charge
Diversion
0
R obbery
San Diego, California 1988
0
11
Murder and manslaughter
R ape
0%
Diversion
Percentage of declinations
Most serious charge
Cases dismissed because of:
Why felony arrests are declined for prosecution (continued)
Manhattan, New York 1988
T A B L E 3.2
6
5
4
31
30
7%
Interest of
justice
13
13
4
4
2
10%
Interest of
justice
13
5
3
4
0
10%
Covered by
other case
6
3
4
3
14
6%
Covered by
other case
32
23
22
18
30
25%
Other
54
48
53
47
39
51%
Other
THE GOING RATE
65
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
66
CHAPTER
3
They accounted for only 15 percent of the rejections and none of the dismissals in San Diego. Equally important, due-process problems arose primarily in drug and weapons cases. They accounted for only 1 percent of the
rejections of robbery cases and 8 percent of the burglary rejections. In short,
thousands of criminals are not “beating the system” in the early stages of prosecution because of legal “technicalities” or loopholes. (We will look more
closely at plea bargaining and some other alleged loopholes in the system in
Chapter 8.)
The most important point in this discussion is that a high degree of screening
occurs as cases flow through the system, from arrest to a final decision to prosecute. The weak cases are screened out, leaving only the strong cases where the
evidence of guilt of fairly strong. Bowen’s research on plea bargaining in King
County (Seattle), Washington, found that the main concern of the prosecutorial
charging unit was whether prosecutors felt they could get a conviction.13 This
more than anything else explains the fact that 95 percent of all convictions are
the result of guilty pleas: all the cases at this point are ones where there is strong
evidence of guilt; the weak cases have been disposed of. (We will come back to
this in Chapter 8 when we discuss whether plea bargaining is a “loophole” that
allows criminals to “beat” the system.) Once the weak cases are out, the system
becomes tough, and as we already mentioned, it has gotten much tougher over
the course of forty years.
SENTENCING: THE GOING RATE GETS TOUGHER
It is fair to say that the single most dramatic change in criminal justice has been a
revolution in sentencing, which has produced the enormous growth of the
prison population. “Sentencing,” however, is a complex and multidimensional
phenomenon, including a number of procedures, some of them largely hidden.
The best example is probably California where more people enter prison as a
result of parole revocation than by judicial sentencing.
Sentencing by judges involves two basic decisions: first, whether to sentence
the convicted offender to probation or to prison; second, if prison, the length of
the prison term. Both decisions have been greatly affected by changes in state
and federal laws of sentencing over the last forty years. The most important are
mandatory minimum sentencing laws that both mandate a prison sentence for
conviction of certain offenses and require a minimum term of imprisonment
for those and other crimes. Other changes, meanwhile, affect the amount of
time served by prisoners. Many states have revised their “good-time” laws to
deny eligibility for conviction on certain offenses. This has the effect of delaying
parole eligibility and extending prison terms. Additionally, many states have
adopted “truth-in-sentencing” laws that require a prisoner to serve 85 percent
of his or her official sentence. A 1994 federal law required states to adopt the
85 percent rule to qualify for federal funds for prisons. By 2008 thirty-five states
and the District of Columbia had adopted the 85 percent rule.14
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
67
The 2009 BJS data on sentences for felony convictions indicate a criminal
justice system that is extremely harsh. Half of all convicted murderers received
a sentence of life, and another 70 percent received maximum sentences of ten
years. Among convicted robbers, 20 percent received maximum sentences of
ten years and 20 percent received sentences of six to ten years (for a combined
total of 40 percent of all robbers). About half (49 percent) of all convicted
robbers received sentences of up to two years, and another 24 percent received
sentences of between two and four years. All of these sentences are longer than
those reported in earlier BJS reports.15
In the real world of criminal justice, the judge’s sentence is one thing, but
actual time served is something different. A 2012 report on Time Served by the
Pew Center on the States detailed the procedures by which states have increased
the length of prison terms just between 1990 and 2009. The average time served
for prisoners released in 2009 was 36 percent longer than in 1990. The increase
was fairly consistent across types of crime. Drug offenders in 2009 had served an
average of 2.2 years, compared with 1.6 years in 1990 (an increase of 36 percent).
Offenders sentenced for violent crimes served an average of 5 years in 2009
compared with 3.7 in 1990 (a 37 percent increase).16
A number of specific changes in each state contributed to the increasing time
served. In Florida, for example, a 1995 truth-in-sentencing law required prisoners to serve 85 percent of their sentence, thereby delaying parole eligibility dates.
Interestingly, the state legislature voted unanimously for the law, which applied to
all prisoners, regardless of the seriousness of their conviction offense. Other laws
increased the severity of punishments. For any crime involving the use of a gun,
the sentence range became ten to twenty years to life imprisonment. If anyone
was wounded or killed, there was a mandatory twenty-five years to life sentence.
Revisions to the state criminal code in 1997, meanwhile, increased the sentences
for many crimes, added some mandatory imprisonment provisions, and gave
judges greater discretion in sentencing. The effect of these changes was to give
prosecutors greater leverage in plea bargaining, which allowed them to get pleas
involving prison terms that avoided the harsh potential sentences but were still
longer that the previous going rate.17 California, meanwhile, also adopted an
85 percent truth-in-sentencing law and enacted its famous “three strikes and
you’re out” law in 1994. Other states adopted these and other provisions that
helped to increase the overall time served by offenders sentenced to prison.
How Do We Compare? An International Perspective
on the Going Rate
It is useful to put the U.S. criminal justice system in perspective. How does the
going rate for crime in the United States compare with its counterpart in other
countries? A standard liberal criticism is that our criminal justice system is far
more punitive than that of any other country. Conservatives, meanwhile, argue
that we are too lenient and fail to punish criminals. James Lynch’s careful analysis
of comparative data suggests that both liberals and conservatives are clinging to
their favorite myths on this question.18
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
68
CHAPTER
3
On one hand, we do lock up (in both prisons and jails) a huge number of
people: 2.2 million in 2012. We already have the highest incarceration rate in
the world (716 per 100,000 in 2011, including both the prison and jail populations). And as our previous discussion indicates, we are fairly tough on those
offenders whom we manage to arrest. From this perspective, it is hard to say
that we are soft on crime.
At the same time, however, our high incarceration rate is mainly the result
of our high rates of violent crime. Before the Great American Crime Drop.,
the U.S. murder rate was four times higher than Canada’s and ten times higher
than England’s and West Germany’s. Our robbery rate was five times higher
than those of England and West Germany. These differences have narrowed
in recent years because of the Great American Crime Drop (see Chapter 1),
but our rates of violent crimes are still much higher than those of other industrialized societies. Violent crimes are more likely to result in prison sentences,
and armed robbery more likely to result in a prison sentence than unarmed
robbery. Lynch points out that a far higher proportion of robberies in the
United States are armed than in other countries. In other words, our
high incarceration rate is partly as a result of our high rates of those crimes
that typically send an offender to prison.19
The relevant question becomes: Is the going rate for particular crimes significantly higher in the United States than it is in other countries? Lynch estimated
the chances of going to prison for a person arrested for murder, robbery,
burglary, and larceny or theft in the United States, England, Canada, and West
Germany. He found that a robber’s chance of going to prison was 36 percent in
the United States, 41 percent in Canada, and 39 percent in the United Kingdom.
The odds were lower only in West Germany. Additionally, the odds of going to
prison were fairly similar for murder, burglary, and larceny in the three Englishspeaking countries. In terms of the tendency to send persons convicted of major
felonies to prison, then, the United States is not that much more punitive than
other countries 20
In terms of time served, Lynch found that the United States was significantly
more punitive, especially for property crimes. He found that the average number
of months served in prison for murder in the United States (50.5) was slightly
higher than in England and Wales (43) but lower than in Canada (57). Average
time served for robbery was somewhat higher in the United States and substantially higher for both burglary and theft. Burglars in the United States, for example, served an average of 16.06 months, compared with 5.23 in Canada and
6.72 in England and Wales. The gap was even greater for theft. Convicted
thieves in the United States served an average of 12 months, compared with
only 2 in Canada and 4.65 in England and Wales. And remember, the going
rate has gotten much harsher since his study.
Lynch’s comparative research highlights the fact that that then and now the
going rate in the United States is far more punitive primarily with regard to time
served. His study did not, however, include drug offenses, where the United
States is particularly punitive in terms of both incarceration and length of
sentences.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
69
THE COURTROOM WORK GROUP
The going rate is established and maintained by the people who work in the
criminal justice system. The phrase the system implies some impersonal entity,
but in fact it is a process involving people who make a series of discretionary decisions day in and day out.21 Prosecutors, defense attorneys, judges, and to some
extent police officers make up the courtroom work group, or what some refer to as
the local legal culture. To understand how the system works, we need to examine
how they go about their jobs: the decisions they make, the factors that influence
them, and how they adjust to changes in the law or the workload.
In perhaps the best study of this phenomenon, Nardulli, Eisenstein, and
Flemming characterized local courthouses as communities. “After spending an
enormous number of hours in various county courts,” they observed, “we
became convinced that the concept of a courthouse community can be an
immensely useful tool in trying to understand them.”22 In this context, community means that a group of people work together and have a mutual interest in
getting the job done as efficiently as possible.
The bureaucratic setting of the courtroom work group exerts a major influence on the decisions of individual officials. All criminal justice officials exercise
enormous discretion, but there are important differences in the settings in which
they work. Police officers generally work alone or in pairs, often with no witnesses. For this reason, police work has been characterized as a “low-visibility”
activity. To be sure, if an officer makes an arrest, it will be reviewed by others: a
supervisor will sign off on it and prosecutors and defense attorneys will review it.
But if the officer does not make an arrest, the decision is not reviewed by anyone.
Prosecutors, defense attorneys, and judges, on the other hand, work in the highly
visible setting of the courthouse. Their actions also leave a paper trail that enhances
accountability. The news media and the public are potential witnesses to decisions
that occur in open court. Finally, other members of the work group constrain the
decisions of individual members. A truly outrageous decision by a prosecutor is
likely to be challenged by a defense attorney or judge. Bail amounts and plea
agreements are, in fact, negotiated among work group members. As a result, the
actions of courtroom officials are constrained by other officials.
Working together every day, members of the courtroom work group reach
a general consensus about how different kinds of cases should be handled. As we
will see in Chapter 8, this involves a shared understanding about how much cases
are “worth.” There are “heavy” cases (that is, serious violent crimes) and “garbage”
cases (relatively minor theft). Shared understandings of these value judgments helps
to move cases along quickly.
An Administrative System of Justice
Conflict between prosecution and defense is the exception rather than the rule in
the U.S. criminal justice system. In theory we have an adversarial system of justice. The bedrock principle of the Anglo-American system of justice is that a
person is innocent until proven guilty and that the state has to prove guilt
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
70
CHAPTER
3
beyond a reasonable doubt. Additionally, the defendant has a right to challenge
the prosecutor’s case, with the assistance of counsel, in a public trial overseen by
a neutral judge. This is different from the inquisitorial system of justice, where
there is a presumption of guilt and the rights of defendants are not protected
the way they are in the U.S. system.
The reality of criminal justice, however, is that we have an administrative
system of justice. Few cases are settled through a public trial, about 5 percent
in the most recent data. In an administrative system of justice there is no public
clash between prosecution and defense. That occurs only in the few celebrated
cases, for example the 2013 trial of George Zimmerman for shooting Trayvon
Martin in Florida. In our administrative system of justice, decisions are quietly
negotiated among members of the courtroom work group, with a high degree of
consensus and cooperation. A study of nine courts by the National Center for State
Courts found that work group members in each court shared a “norm of proportionality,” that is, of how much different cases are worth. Experts on plea bargaining
describe the process as a “supermarket,” with set prices and a high volume of
business.23 Criminologist Robert Bohm has labeled it “McJustice,” arguing that
the system of high volume predictable outcomes resembles the way McDonalds
sells hamburgers. (His argument is an application of George Ritzer’s broader
argument that all of society reflects a similar “McDonaldization.”)24
Frederic Suffet’s study of bail setting offers an excellent illustration of the consensus and cooperation that prevail in the courtroom work group. (His work is
several decades old now, but more recent studies have only confirmed his analysis
of the basic dynamics of the bail-setting process.) Only 3 percent of the cases he
examined involved any conflict over the bail decision; some disagreement arose in
another 9 percent.25 Over the years, the members of this work group had developed a shared understanding about how much bail to set for different kinds of
cases—in other words, how much each case was worth. In her study of plea bargaining, Alissa Pollitz Worden found a high degree of judicial agreement with
prosecutorial sentence recommendations. She speculated that going rates “may be
so predictable that a prosecutor need not make a formal recommendation in order
to ensure that a sentence bargain will be honored by the court.”26 Deirdre M.
Bowen’s research on King County (Seattle), Washington, found that the principal
concern of the prosecutor’s office screening unit was whether or not there was
sufficient evidence to secure a conviction. There was also a high degree of consensus about how much particular cases were worth, to the point where participants
classified about 70 percent of cases as “no-brainers,” with no disagreement. Amplifying other studies, she found that another 30 percent did involve some disagreements and involved more genuine negotiation.27
Another example of the courtroom work group in operation at a different
decision point is John Rosecrance’s study of presentence investigation (PSI)
reports by probation officers. In theory, the PSI is an independent evaluation of
a convicted offender’s social history, taking into account criminal record,
employment history, family status, and so on. Yet Rosecrance found that probation officers (POs) classified offenders quickly on the basis of their offense and
prior record. Even more important, they based their recommendations on what
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
71
they thought judges and prosecutors wanted. The California POs he studied
were in regular contact with prosecutors and discussed their cases with them.
They rarely challenged plea agreements, which often included an understanding
about the sentence. As one PO put it, “It’s stupid to try and bust a deal… . Who
needs the hassle? … Everyone, including the defendant, has already agreed.”28
Nardulli, Eisenstein, and Flemming add the important point that courtroom
work groups vary from jurisdiction to jurisdiction. Each courtroom community
has its own “distinctive character.” Typically, one person plays “a dominant
role… by virtue of personality, professional skills (or reputation), political
power, longevity, or some other attribute.”29 Ulmer’s study of three Pennsylvania courts found important differences related to the stability of the membership
in local work groups. In the wealthy suburban court system (“Rich County”),
there was a high degree of membership stability and a culture of understanding
and collegiality. In the large urban court (“Metro County”), on the other hand,
there was considerable turnover in the prosecutor’s office, which resulted in
conflict between prosecutors and defense attorneys and close relations between
the defense attorneys and judges. The Metro County example illustrates the
extent to which other members of a courtroom work group adjust to some
kind of disruption arising from one member of the group.30
Research on case processing dispels the popular belief that heavy case loads
are the driving factor in plea bargains and the major cause of delays. A National
Center for State Courts study found that efficient case processing was not necessarily related to caseloads and staff resources. The more efficient court had a
strong a sense of mutual respect among work group members. Prosecutors and
defense attorneys regarded each other as competent and well prepared. Even
disagreements over evidence-related issues involved mutual respect for the
other side’s professionalism. In the slower courts, work group members did not
respect each other’s competence, and the resulting questions and misunderstandings
slowed down the processing of cases.31
The Limits of Reform
The courtroom work group has enormous power to limit, frustrate, or even
block reforms in the justice system. A state legislature might pass a new law, or
the Supreme Court might issue a landmark ruling, but that does not guarantee
that the process will really change. Our capacity to make significant changes in
how the system works—in the interest of more effective crime control, for
example—is extremely important. Remember, we are searching for policies
that will help reduce crime. Assuming we find some policies that do work, we
have to be able to implement them and change how the system works. A few
examples illustrate the power of the courtroom work group to frustrate reforms.
The Supreme Court ruled in 1967 that defendants in juvenile court have a
constitutional right to an attorney (In re Gault). Barry Feld, however, found
that only half (47.7 percent) of the kids in Minnesota juvenile courts in 1984
actually had legal counsel. State officials simply did not comply with the law.32
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
72
CHAPTER
3
The Supreme Court ruled in 1963 (Gideon v. Wainiwight) that adult felony
defendants have a constitutional right to an attorney. A recent report by
the Constitution Project, however, found that because of the resource crisis
in criminal justice (see Chapter 1), many public defenders offices are overwhelmed with cases and cannot provide meaningful representation for their
clients. Some public defenders have even threatened to or actually have
refused to accept more cases.33
Congress passed a “speedy trial” law in 1974, and several states enacted
similar laws. Malcolm Feeley, however, found that these laws had almost no
effect on the flow of cases. All members of the courtroom work group—
judges, prosecutors, and defense attorneys—had their own reasons for
delaying cases. The laws permit exceptions to the requirement, and officials
take advantage of them. As one judge explained, “Our court has figured out
ways to deal with the [speedy trial] act that don’t cause us to change our
practices at all.”34
Many states passed “three-strikes” laws in the 1990s, but with the exception
of California, prosecutors in most states were simply not using the law.
Wisconsin had used it only once in a year and a half, whereas five other
states had not used it at all. Even in California, use of the law varies
tremendously by jurisdiction. Out of 8,381 inmates serving a third-strike
sentence in California in 2008, 3,140 (or 37 percent) were sentenced in
Los Angeles County. San Diego County had sentenced 659, and San
Francisco County only 39.35
In Chapter 8, we will see how South Carolina courtroom work groups
adapted to reduce the number of juveniles charged with sex offenses who
would suffer the registration and notification requirements of a harsh
sex offender law.
Passing a law, in short, does not guarantee that it will be used or used in a
consistent manner in the same state. This is not the whole story, however.
Although courtroom work groups have the capacity to evade or reduce the
impact of harsh sentencing laws, they do not have the power to nullify the effect
completely. The Sentencing Project, for example, argues that three-strikes laws
have been used enough in several states to account for a part of the prison
population growth. They estimated at one point that about 20 percent of all
California prisoners were serving three-strike terms.36 The Pew Center for the
States argues that the prison population explosion has been as a result in part of
such things as three-strikes laws, mandatory minimum prison sentences, and
truth-in-sentencing laws that require prisoners to serve 85 percent of their
nominal sentence. In short, some changes in the law do work and have a significant effect on the going rate. Courtroom work groups can mitigate the impact of
some laws to a certain extent laws but cannot nullify them completely.37
We should not be completely cynical about the prospects for change. Some
reforms have been implemented and their effects are readily apparent. A few
examples illustrate this point.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
73
The Minnesota sentencing guidelines enacted in 1980 had the explicit goal
of limiting the use of imprisonment. To a great extent this strategy has
worked, and Minnesota has maintained the lowest incarceration rate of any
state (with the possible exception of South Dakota).38
The federal sentencing guidelines imposed harsher sentences and limited the
discretion of judges. Although some judges have found ways to get around
the guidelines’ strict requirements, there has been a significant increase in
imprisonment for federal crimes.
And as we mentioned previously, the Pew Center for the States found that
changes in sentencing laws designed to keep offenders in prison longer have
in fact accomplished that.39
The lesson of the previous discussion is that while there are some enduring
patterns of consistency in the processing of cases, the U.S. criminal justice system
also has many complexities and contradictions. Our Sober Realism perspective
requires keeping an eye on both of these factors and not lapsing into
oversimplifications.
The Dynamics of Reform
In short, some reforms are successfully implemented and some are not. What
makes the difference? A great deal depends on the nature of the reform itself.
Some experts believe that modest reforms, which require only slight changes in
how the courtroom work group operates, are more likely to succeed than
sweeping changes. Raymond T. Nimmer argues that “the probability of system
change is inversely related to the degree of change sought by a reform.”
Eisenstein, Flemming, and Nardulli agree, concluding that “the more radical a
proposed change the less likely is its adoption.”40 The three-strikes laws, for
example, represent radical disruptions of established going rates, and probably
for that reason have been ignored in most jurisdictions.
In the conclusion of their study of courts and their communities, Eisenstein,
Flemming, and Nardulli offer some other sobering conclusions about the possibilities for reform. On one hand, changes mandated from outside the courtroom
work groups face serious obstacles. They agree with Feeley that work groups
have enormous ability to resist change. At the same time, however, change initiated from within, by the work group itself, also faces major obstacles. Efforts by
judges to speed up trials may be blocked by prosecution and defense attorneys.41
In short, some reforms do work. In our search for effective crime policies, we
should not be cynical and assume that nothing works, or be naive in thinking that
everything works. Our Sober Realism perspective involves calculating the impact of
a proposed reform on the courtroom work group and other actors in the system.
Justice Thermodynamics
The systems perspective on the administration of justice helps us see how
changes in one part of the system affect decisions in other parts. Malcolm Feeley
suggests that a major change may set off a “chain reaction throughout the entire
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
74
CHAPTER
3
system,” forcing other officials to adapt and in some cases creating new and
unanticipated problems.42 We explain this chain reaction effect in terms of
“criminal justice thermodynamics.” You may remember from a physics class
that the law of thermodynamics says that every action has an equal and opposite
reaction. The justice system works in much the same way: actions produce
reactions. Our law of criminal justice thermodynamics states:
A major increase in the severity of the penalty will result in less frequent
application of that penalty.
Our law has an important corollary:
The less often a severe penalty is applied, the more arbitrary will be the
occasions when it is applied.
The death penalty is an excellent example of the law of criminal justice
thermodynamics. Because it is the ultimate penalty, it exerts enormous pressure
on the courtroom work group. Many devices are used to evade its application
(plea bargaining to a second-degree murder charge, demanding a jury trial, using
the insanity defense, appealing on every potential issue, requesting pardon or
commutation, and so forth). Thus, the action of the prosecutor in filing firstdegree murder charges (making the case eligible for the death penalty) causes a
reaction by the defense.
Because the death penalty is rarely used, its application is arbitrary. In the
landmark case of Furman v. Georgia (1972), the Supreme Court characterized
the application of the death penalty as being so rare that it is “freakish” and
akin to being “struck by lightning.”43
Three-strikes laws are another excellent example. These laws provide severe
sentences for people convicted of a third felony (part of the California law also
applies to people with certain kinds of second felonies)—typically, life or a long
mandatory prison term. Every study, however, has found that prosecutors rarely
if ever use the law. And even in California, where it is used most often, it is
primarily used by prosecutors only in certain counties.44
A study of correctional practices in New York illustrates how an increase in
severity can produce adaptations that, in many respects, undermine the original
intent of getting tougher with criminals. New York adopted a series of mandatory sentencing laws in 1973 and 1978, followed by several early release
programs in 1987 and 1989. The result was an odd mix of indeterminate and
mandatory sentencing policies. The prison population began to increase, but
because of financial constraints, the state did not build all of the planned new
prisons.45
The three new early release programs—shock incarceration, “earned eligibility” for parole, and Comprehensive Alcohol and Substance Abuse Treatment
(CASAT)—gave correctional officials enormous discretion over offenders’
eligibility for early release. They began using these programs to reduce prison
populations. Under earned eligibility, inmates gained a “presumption of release”
for merely participating in a treatment, educational, or work program. Thus,
they received a reward for what in the past had been considered minimal good
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
75
conduct. The net effect was to release them early and to undercut the intent of
mandatory minimum sentencing laws. Meanwhile, many offenders released
under work release programs were allowed to live at home and report in twice
a week. More than one-third of the participants in this “day-reporting” program
had been convicted of violent crimes. Here, also, correctional officials gained a
vast amount of hidden discretion and used it to undercut the supposedly tough
sentencing laws.
WRONGFUL CONVICTIONS: HOW COMMON ARE MISTAKES?
There is the notorious case of the Texas lawyer representing a defendant facing a
possible death sentence who fell asleep at trial. (The defendant was sentenced to
death, but won a new trial on appeal.)46 Do things like this happen often? How
many miscarriages of justice do occur? Are innocent people convicted and
sentenced to prison? Are some even sentenced to die? We conclude our discussion of how the system works by examining fundamental questions about
fairness.
The short answer is that of course mistakes occur, either because of negligence, incompetence, or bias. It is unreasonable to expect perfection in any large
complex operation, including the criminal justice system. The news brings us
stories of factually innocent people being released from prison after serving
many years. Celebrated cases, we have argued, distort our perceptions of how
the criminal justice system operates on a routine basis. The question is, how
frequently do serious mistakes occur? How often are factually innocent people
convicted, and how often are they sentenced to long prison terms or even the
death penalty?
The administration of justice is a human process, involving day-in, day-out
decisions by members of the courtroom work group, and it is inevitable that
some mistakes will occur. We want to know, how often? Unfortunately, we
only learn about the mistakes that are uncovered. We cannot know about
mistakes that remain hidden, leaving an innocent person to serve many years in
prison, or even to die there.
In 1992 Barry Scheck and Peter Neufeld established the Innocence Project
at Cardozo Law School in New York City to provide legal assistance to convicted offenders on DNA issues. By 2012, 302 convicted offenders had been
exonerated and released as a result of DNA testing that either confirmed their
innocence or identified the real offender. They had served an average of 13.6
years in prison before their release. Eighteen had been sentenced to death and
served time on death row; another 16 had been charged with capital crimes,
but were not sentenced to death. Larry Mayes, for example, served 18 1/2
years in prison in Indiana after being wrongfully convicted of rape and robbery
and sentenced to 80 years in prison. Local Innocence Projects have been established in forty-eight states and the District of Columbia, with some states having
several local chapters.47
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
76
CHAPTER
3
How can an innocent person be convicted of murder and sentenced to
death or life in prison? The Innocence Project analyzed its cases and found that
72 percent involved, at least in part, an erroneous eyewitness identification.
Improper or invalid forensic evidence were a factor in 50 percent of the cases.
(The percentages add up to more than 100 because many cases involve two or
more factors.) False confessions were a factor in 25 percent, and 18 percent
involved false or incorrect information from informants. Wrongful convictions
involve a strong racial disparity, with 62 percent of the Innocent Projects
302 cases involving African Americans.
Errors such as these raise disturbing questions about the courtroom work
group. If the police or prosecutor engaged in misconduct, why didn’t the
defense attorney or judge notice and blow the whistle? If a defense attorney
was grossly incompetent, why didn’t the judge intervene? The answer to
these questions goes to the nature of the courtroom work group. The basic
norms of the group emphasize cooperation and not challenging other members
of the group. Although this facilitates efficient handling of cases in the vast
majority, the cases handled by the Innocence Project indicate that it can also
cover up willful misconduct or incompetence—and send an innocent person to
death row.
Most of the Innocence Project cases were celebrated cases to begin with:
usually gruesome murders or rape and robbery crimes. Exoneration through
DNA evidence automatically moved all of them into the celebrated case category. The question for us is, how often do mistakes happen in routine cases?
How often do they occur in run-of-the-mill burglary and robbery cases? What
is the overall error rate? Are there just a few celebrated cases, or do miscarriages
of justice happen all the time?
C. Ronald Huff and his colleagues developed an ingenious method for
estimating the number of wrongful convictions. They surveyed 229 Ohio criminal justice officials (judges, prosecutors, public defenders, police), along with
attorneys general from all states, and asked for their estimate of the frequency
of wrongful convictions. After eliminating the extremely high and low estimates,
they concluded that errors occur in slightly less than 1 percent of all felony
cases.48
What are we to make of this estimate? From one perspective, an error rate
of less than 1 percent is good. We should all be so successful in whatever we do.
It compares favorably with the false-positive and false-negative rates we will
encounter with the prediction problem in Chapter 4. But Huff and his associates
projected this error rate to the national level and estimated 5,729 wrongful convictions in 1981 (one-half of 1 percent of the total of 1,145,780 convictions
across the country). Almost 6,000 innocent people convicted of a felony every
year is a shocking fact to contemplate.
A recent study of wrongful convictions reached an even higher estimate of
mistakes. Because the state of Virginia had preserved the forensic evidence for
cases since the 1970s, the Urban Institute study was able to study cases from
1973 to 1987. Focusing only on sexual assault and homicide cases, they found
634 cases eligible for reanalysis (out of 3,000 cases with some retained evidence),
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
77
which had resulted in the conviction of 715 individuals. The evidence was then
sent to a private laboratory for analysis. Taking a conservative approach, the
study came up with two estimates. The high estimate was that wrongful convictions occurred in 7.8 percent of convictions (56 out of 715), whereas the lower
estimate was 5.3 percent (38 out of 715).49
The estimates in the Urban Institute study shocked many observers. Even
the low estimate was more than five times higher than the 1 percent from the
previous studies. An important note of caution is in order, however. These
estimates were for the crimes of sexual assault and murder only, whereas Huff’s
estimate was for all felony cases. The Urban Institute estimates, therefore, cannot
be generalized for all cases. Robbery and burglary cases rarely leave DNA
evidence. Nonetheless, if wrongful convictions occur in even 5 percent of all
sexual assault and murder cases, the kind of cases most likely to result in long
prison terms, the justice system has some serious problems.
As for the death penalty, Hugo Bedau and Michael Radelet estimated
that for every 20 persons executed in this country since 1900, at least 1
innocent person was convicted of a capital crime. They found a total of
343 persons mistakenly convicted of capital crimes; 25 were actually executed, whereas many of the others served prison terms of up to twenty-five
years.50
In short, serious mistakes do occur in the criminal justice system. Some
innocent people are in fact convicted and sent to prison—in some cases for
long prison terms. We need to be ever-vigilant to guard against such mistakes
and develop appropriate policies that will help prevent them.
CONCLUSION
A going rate for crime exists in the United States. If you are convicted of a
certain crime, given its seriousness and your prior record, it is possible to predict
the outcome of your case with a high degree of accuracy. The going rate can
vary among jurisdictions but is fairly stable within each one. It is established
and maintained by the members of the courtroom work group, who work
together daily. Finally, the going rate has become much harsher over the last four
decades.
The concept of the going rate is extremely important for our search for sensible and effective crime policies for two reasons. First, many proposed policies
are based on mistaken assumptions about how the system works. They do not
take into account the fact that the administration of justice is stable, consistent,
and predictable and that it is relatively tough on those offenders who are caught
and prosecuted. Second, many proposed reforms would have trouble being
implemented. The going rate is determined by the courtroom work group,
which has tremendous power to adapt and either ignore or evade the intent of
a new law or policy. Simply passing a new law does not necessarily mean that
the intended changes will occur.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
78
CHAPTER
3
NOTES
1 See the Sentencing Project website: www.sentencingproject.org. Accessed February
10, 2014. See also Marc Mauer [Sentencing Project Director], Race to Incarcerate
(New York: The Free Press, 2013).
2 Michelle Alexander, The New Jim Crow: Mass Incarceration in the Age of Colorblindness
(New York: the New Press, 2010).
3 Pew Center for the States, Time Served: The High Cost, Low Return of Longer Prison
Sentences (Washington, DC: Pew Charitable Trusts, 2012).
4 Samuel Walker, Cassia Spohn, and Miriam DeLone, The Color of Justice: Race,
Ethnicity, and Crime in America, 5th ed. (Belmont, CA: Wadsworth, 2012). Michael
Tonry and Matthew Melewski, “The Malign Effects of Drug and Crime Control
Policies on Black Americans,” in Michael Tonry, ed., Crime and Justice: A Review of
Research (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2008), 1–44.
5 Marc Mauer, Race to Incarcerate (New York: The Free Press, 2013).
6 Charles Silberman, Criminal Violence, Criminal Justice (New York: Random House,
1978), 258.
7 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in State Courts, 2009 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2013).
8 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2009.
9 See the discussion of the barriers faced by prisoners reentering society in Joan
Petersilia, When Prisoners Come Home: Parole and Prisoner Reentry (New York: Oxford
University Press, 2003).
10 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Sentences in Large Urban Counties, 2009, 15.
11 Joan Petersilia, Racial Disparities in the Criminal Justice System (Santa Monica,
CA: Rand, 1983), 21.
12 Lawrence W. Sherman and Barry Glick, The Quality of Police Arrest Statistics
(Washington: The Police Foundation, 1984).
13 Deirdre M. Bowen, “Calling Your Bluff: How Prosecutors and Defense Attorneys
Adapt Plea Bargaining Strategies to Increased Formalization,” Justice Quarterly 26
(March 2009): 2–29.
14 Pew Center on the States, Time Served. Bureau of Justice Statistics, Truth in
Sentencing in State Prisons (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1999).
15 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2009,
Appendix.
16 Pew Center on the States, Time Served.
17 Ibid.
18 James Lynch, “Crime in International Perspective,” in James Q. Wilson and Joan
Petersilia, eds., Crime (San Francisco: ICS Press, 1995), 11–38.
19 Lynch, “Crime in International Perspective.”
20 Ibid. A more recent and more thorough analysis is Bureau of Justice Statistics, CrossNational Studies in Crime and Justice (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2004).
NCJ 200988.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE GOING RATE
79
21 Samuel Walker, Taming the System: The Control of Discretion in Criminal Justice, 1950–
1990 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993). Michael R. Gottfredson and
Don M. Gottfredson, Decision Making in Criminal Justice, 2nd ed. (New York:
Plenum, 1988).
22 Peter F. Nardulli, Roy B. Flemming, and James Eisenstein, The Tenor of Justice
(Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1988).
23 Brian J. Ostrom and Roger A. Hanson, Efficiency, Timeliness, and Quality: A New
Perspective from Nine State Criminal Trial Courts (Williamsburg, VA: National Center
for State Courts, 1999). Available on the National Center for State Courts website.
Malcolm Feeley, “Perspectives on Plea Bargaining,” Law and Society Review 13
(Winter 1979): 199.
24 Robert M. Bohm, “McJustice’: On the McDonaldization of Criminal Justice,”
Justice Quarterly 23 (March 2006):127–146. George Ritzer, The McDonaldization of
Society, 6th ed., (Thousand Oaks: Pine Forge Press, 2011).
25 Frederic Suffet, “Bail-Setting: A Study in Courtroom Interaction,” Crime and
Delinquency 12 (1966): 318–331.
26 Alissa Pollitz Worden, “The Judge’s Role in Plea Bargaining: An Analysis of Judges’
Agreement with Prosecutors’ Sentencing Recommendations,” Justice Quarterly 12
(June 1995): 273.
27 Deirdre M. Bowen, “Calling Your Bluff: How Prosecutors and Defense Attorneys
Adapt to Plea Bargaining Strategies to Increased Formalization,” Justice Quarterly 26
(March 2009), 2–29.
28 John Rosecrance, “Maintaining the Myth of Individualized Justice: Probation
Presentence Reports,” Justice Quarterly 5 (June 1988): 235–256.
29 Nardulli et al., Tenor of Justice, 41.
30 Jeffrey T. Ulmer, Social Worlds of Sentencing, Court Communities Under Sentencing
Guidelines (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1997) especially Table 8.1.
31 Ibid.
32 Barry C. Feld, Justice for Children: The Right to Counsel and the Juvenile Courts (Boston:
Northeastern University Press, 1993), 55.
33 National Right to Counsel Committee, Justice Denied America’s Continuing Neglect of
Our Constitutional Right to Counsel (Washington, DC: The Constitution Project,
2009).
34 Malcolm Feeley, Court Reform on Trial (New York: Basic Books, 1983), 173.
35 Ashley Nellis and Ryan S. King, No Exit: The Expanding Use of Life Sentences in
America (Washington, DC: The Sentencing Project, 2009).
36 Ibid.
37 Pew Center for the States, Time Served.
38 Terance D. Miethe and Charles A. Moore, Sentencing Guidelines: Their Effect in
Minnesota (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1989). Bureau of Justice
Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics Online. Available on the SUNY
Albany website, http://www.albany.edu/sourcebook/. Information about the
Minnesota sentencing guidelines is available on the Minnesota Sentencing
Guidelines Commission website, http://mn.gov/sentencing-guidelines/.
39 Pew Center for the States, Time Served.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
80
CHAPTER
3
40 Raymond T. Nimmer, The Nature of System Change (Chicago: American Bar
Foundation, 1978), 181. Eisenstein et al., Contours of Justice, 294.
41 Eisenstein, et al., 291–305.
42 Malcolm Feeley, Court Reform on Trial, 184.
43 Furman v. Georgia, 408 U.S. 238 (1972). Raymond Paternoster, Capital Punishment in
America (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1991).
44 Nellis and King, No Exit.
45 Pamala L. Griset, “The Politics and Economics of Increased Correctional Discretion
over Time Served: A New York Case Study,” Justice Quarterly 12 (June 1995):
307–323.
46 “Inmate Whose Lawyer Slept Gets New Trial,” The New York Times, June 4, 2002.
47 The Innocence Project, www.innocenceproject.org. Accessed February 10, 2014.
48 C. Ronald Huff, Arye Rattner, and Edward Sagann, “Guilty Until Proven
Innocent: Wrongful Convictions and Public Policy,” Crime and Delinquency 32
(October 1986): 518–544. C. Ronald Huff, Arye Rattner, and Edward Sagarin,
Convicted but Innocent (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1996).
49 John Roman, Kelly Walsh, Pamela Lachman, and Jennifer Yahner, Post-Conviction
DNA Testing and Wrongful Conviction (Washington, DC: Urban Institute, 2012).
50 Hugo Adam Bedau and Michael L. Radelet, “Miscarriages of Justice in Potentially
Capital Cases,” Stanford Law Review 40 (November 1987): 21–179.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
4
The Prediction Problem
T
he Crime Commission model of the criminal justice system illuminates the
flow of cases through the system, the various “exit” points where cases leave
the system, and the fact that each point in the system involves discretionary
decisions. In this chapter we explore the fact that many of those discretionary
decisions involve predictions about the person involved: as a citizen on the street,
a suspect, a defendant, as a convicted offender, as a prisoner, and so on. The
questions we will examine are, how good are those predictions? What kind of
evidence are they based on? Is there any way we can improve the quality of the
predictions—for example, by making more accurate decisions about which convicted offenders are safe to place on probation and which should go to prison?
As a report by the Pew Center on the States puts it, “Every day, criminal
justice officials make decisions that have enormous implications for public safety
and spending.”1 A short and incomplete list of discretionary decisions includes
the following:
A police officer stops a juvenile on the street at night, and finding him in
possession of a bottle of bourbon takes the bottle, empties it, and tells the
kid to go home immediately. The officer’s decision represented a prediction
about the kid and his future behavior: that he is not dangerous, is unlikely to
commit any serious crimes, and therefore does not need to be arrested as a
“minor in possession.”
A convicted robber comes before the judge. He has a long criminal record:
several arrests as a juvenile (but with no incarcerations), two burglaries
(probation for both offenses), and a prior robbery for which he received a
short prison sentence. The judge sentences him to a five- to seven-year term
in prison. The sentence is a prediction: that given his prior record this person
is likely to commit more burglaries or robberies in the near future.
A young woman is convicted of possession of stolen property. The property
actually belonged to her boyfriend, who was convicted and sentenced to
prison for a series of household burglaries. The judge sentences her to
81
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
82
CHAPTER
4
probation, deciding that given the facts of the case she is unlikely to commit
a serious felony and does not need to go to prison.
A parole officer discovers technical violations by a parolee: two curfew
violations and some beer in his apartment. The officer could write up
charges of formal violations but decides not to. His thinking is that the
violations are relatively minor, the parolee has an otherwise decent record
on parole, and has expressed remorse for the crime that sent him to prison
(an unarmed robbery). The parole officer decides to give him a break,
believing that he is unlikely to commit another robbery or other serious crime
in the immediate future.
These cases are fairly typical of decisions that are routinely made day in and
day out in the criminal justice system. All are discretionary decisions, and the two
cases in which the person got the benefit of the doubt are unlikely to be discovered by any supervisor or other official. In this chapter we will look at such decisions as predictions—predictions about a person’s future behavior. The central
question is whether these predictions have any validity. Are they based on solid
evidence (for example, about the offenders probability of reoffending), or just a
hunch on the part of the decision maker? And what informs those hunches?
Experience? If so, what kind of experience? A special case that sticks in the
decision-maker’s mind (the equivalent of our “celebrated case”), or a thoughtful
consideration of many cases? And to what extent are hunches based on stereotypes about social class, race or ethnicity, or gender—stereotypes that involve
unconscious judgments about “good” and “deserving” people as opposed to
“bad” people. Unconscious assumptions about race are prevalent in U.S. society,
and there is now a science of unconscious racism. Experiments using police shoot
or don’t shoot computer simulations found that many subjects are more likely to
shoot the unarmed African American than the white “suspect.”2
THE RISK ASSESSMENT TRADITION
What we demand is reliable predictions that are grounded in scientific evidence.
Remember, our goal in this book is to identify ways to reduce crime. Better
predictions about future criminal behavior would allow judges, for example, to
predict which convicted offenders are likely to go on to become career criminals
and which are likely to desist from criminal activity.
In fact, there has been a long history of attempts to develop evidence-based
tools to help criminal justice officials make better predictions. It is known as risk
assessment and has been concentrated in the area of corrections. A 2011 report
on Risk/Needs Assessment 101 by the Pew Center on the States discusses how
effective risk/needs assessment tools can improve the decisions made by courts
(in bail decisions, sentencing, revocations decisions, and the conditions of
supervision), probation and parole agencies (in determining levels of supervision,
specialized treatment needs, and revocation decisions), prisons and jails (in inmate
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
83
classification systems, inmate programming), and parole boards (release decisions
and conditions of supervision).3
The Pew report summarizes the seven risk/needs factors that research has
identified. They fall into two categories: dynamic factors, which are changeable,
and static factors, which are unchangeable. The seven factors include: antisocial
personality patterns; pro-criminial attitudes; social supports for crime (that is,
peers who are engaged in crime); substance abuse; poor family or marital relationships; school and/or work failure; and lack of pro-social recreational activities.
Does the application of these factors in fact enhance decision making? And
do the resulting decisions help to reduce crime? In this chapter we will look at
the evidence on our ability to predict future criminal behavior. In fact, we will
examine some notable risk assessment instruments to see how they perform. But
remember the standard we set in Chapter 1. We are not looking for or expecting
perfection. That is an unreasonable dream. In this book we are looking for policies that make some meaningful improvements over current practice. That is a
modest, sober realistic goal.
We begin with a review of the subject of career criminals. This was a hot
criminal justice issue in the 1980s, and the research it stimulated provides some
good evidence for our discussion. To understand the interest in career criminals
we need to begin with the project that initially inspired policy makers, Marvin
Wolfgang’s birth cohort study.
SEARCHING FOR THE CAREER CRIMINAL
The career criminal was a major focus of crime control policy for many years. It
is not quite the hot topic it was in the 1980s and is another example of the Fad
Syndrome in criminal justice policy, in which a new idea arises, generates a lot of
excitement and policy development, and then fades as research slowly undermines the assumptions.
Nonetheless, the subject of the career criminal is relevant for our purposes.
Several important crime control policies that we will examine in this book—
preventive detention, major-offender prosecution programs, and selective
incapacitation—are aimed at repeat offenders or career criminals. All of these
programs assume that if we can identify and effectively respond to these
offenders—through incapacitation, treatment, or another method—we could
make significant reductions in crime. The search on career criminals that
flourished in the 1980s taught us a lot—a lot about what we know and don’t
know and about what we can and cannot do in terms of predicting future
criminal behavior. These lessons will serve us well in assessing the merits of a
number of crime control policies that we will consider in the chapters ahead.
WOLFGANG’S BIRTH COHORT
People have always talked about “hard-core” criminals, “repeaters,” “chronic
recidivists,” or “career criminals,” but typically they did not define precisely
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
84
CHAPTER
4
who they were talking about. In fact they were often relying on myths and
stereotypes about criminals. That changed with a landmark study conducted by
Marvin Wolfgang, Robert Figlio, and Thorsten Sellin titled Delinquency in a Birth
Cohort. Often referred to as the Wolfgang Cohort Study, it is one of the most
important pieces of criminal justice research in the last fifty years, has had a
profound influence on thinking about crime policy.4 Wolfgang’s birth cohort
included all the males born in Philadelphia in 1945 and traced their careers
through their eighteenth birthday in 1963. Using official records, including
police and school records, the study reconstructed the criminal careers of a
sample of 9,945 juveniles. The principal finding, which caught everyone’s attention, was that a small percentage of delinquents were responsible for a majority
of all crimes and for about two-thirds of all violent crimes.
As Table 4.1 indicates, 35 percent of the cohort had at least one officially
recorded contact with the police. Of that group, 46 percent had no more contacts.
Wolfgang labeled them “one-time offenders.” He divided the remaining 1,862
juveniles into two groups. The 1,235 with two, three, or four contacts were
labeled the “non-chronic recidivists.” The remaining 627 with five or more
contacts were the “chronic delinquents.” They represented 6 percent of the
original cohort and 18 percent of the 3,475 delinquents. These 627 are the socalled career criminals.
Several comments about Wolfgang’s data are in order. Most important, he
measured delinquency in terms of officially recorded police contacts. Recall our
discussion in Chapter 3 about the problems with official police arrest data, and
how it certainly undercounts the number of people who in fact had some
contact with the police.5 Obviously, many delinquents are never caught, and
the actual prevalence of criminal behavior among the juveniles he studied was
undoubtedly higher than 35 percent. Some may have had contact with the
police, but the officer chose not to record it. Some of those with a recorded
police contact, meanwhile, may have been picked up by mistake and should
not be considered “offenders” at all. Also, many of the “one-time delinquents”
committed other illegal acts but were never caught. And, finally, some
“nonchronic delinquents” committed more than four crimes.
T A B L E 4.1
Wolfgang’s birth cohort
Number
Percentage of
original sample
Total criminal
offenses
Percentage of
total offenses
Original sample
9,945
Delinquents
3,475
34.9
10,214
One officially recorded
contact with police
1,613
16.2
1,613
15.8
Two to four contacts
1,235
12.4
3,296
32.3
627
6.3
5,305
51.9
F ive or more contacts
SOURCE: Marvin Wolfgang, Robert M. Figlio, and Thorsten Sellin, Delinquency in a Birth Cohort (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1972).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
85
Despite these limitations, however, the cohort study highlighted some
important patterns in delinquency. First, it gave us the first clear picture of
the prevalence of delinquency: that is, the percentage of any group of males
who commit crime. Second, it gave us a good picture of the percentage we can
consider career criminals. Finally, it documented the fact that most delinquents
stop committing illegal acts at some point, and most of them stop relatively
early. We do not know what makes them stop. Some “mature out.” Others
may have be deterred by their contact with the police. Or perhaps their parents
gave them a real tongue-lashing. Still others may be helped by the treatment
program included in their juvenile court disposition, or someone may have
gotten them involved in a local church or community group program that
helped them. All we know for sure is that most juveniles who had a recorded
contact with the police eventually stop their misbehavior or criminal activity.
Wolfgang’s most important finding, and the one that excited policy makers,
was the small group of 627 chronic recidivists that was responsible for more than
half (52 percent) of all the crimes committed by the entire cohort and 63 percent
of all the Index crimes (71 percent of the murders, 73 percent of the rapes,
and 82 percent of all the robberies). The one-time offenders committed only
16 percent of the total; the nonchronic recidivists, the remaining 32 percent.
The policy implications of these data are obvious: If we could successfully
identify and effectively respond to that 6 percent, we could achieve a major
reduction in serious crime. And the point is relevant for both liberal and conservative crime policies. If you are a liberal who believes in rehabilitation, identifying and successfully treating that 6 percent would achieve a huge reduction in
crime. If you are conservative, you will argue that we can get a tremendous
crime reduction by successfully incapacitating in prison that same 6 percent.
OTHER COHORT STUDIES
Wolfgang’s original findings have been confirmed by other cohort studies. He
and his associates conducted a follow-up study of males and females born in Philadelphia in 1958. This was a larger cohort (28,338 subjects) and more representative in terms of race and sex. Following the cohort’s criminal careers between
1968 and 1974 (ages ten to eighteen), they found a similar pattern in criminal
behavior: 33 percent had at least one recorded contact with the police, and the
chronic recidivists represented 7.5 percent of the total cohort (compared with 6.3
percent in the original study).6
The 1958 cohort did commit more crimes. Remember, this study covered
the late 1960s, when the crime rate soared. The murder rate was three times
higher and the robbery rate five times higher than for the 1945 cohort. Thus,
about the same percentage of cohort members became delinquent, but those
who did committed more crimes and far more serious ones.
Some people might question whether Philadelphia is representative of the
rest of the country. Lyle Shannon studied three cohorts in Racine, Wisconsin,
tracing the careers of 6,127 persons born in 1942, 1949, and 1955. Unlike Wolfgang,
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
86
CHAPTER
4
he followed his subjects into adulthood. Members of the 1942 cohort were thirtythree years old when the study ended. Shannon found that most of his subjects had
at least one contact with the police: 68 percent of the 1942 group, 69 percent of the
1949 cohort, and 59 percent of the 1955 cohort (but the members of this last cohort
were only twenty-two years old when the data collection ended, so it missed part of
their high-crime years). These figures may seem frightening until we learn that most
of the arrests were for relatively minor crimes. Part I Index crimes represented only
12.7 percent of all the arrests for the 1942 cohort and 15.9 and 24.6 percent for the
1949 and 1955 cohorts, respectively. These data confirm what criminologists have
long known: that most males in this country break the law at some point in their
lives, but that most of the lawbreaking involves minor crimes such as vandalism.7
The career criminal patterns in Racine closely resembled those in Philadelphia. Shannon found that 9.5 percent of the 1942 cohort had 51 percent of the
police contacts, 8 percent of the 1949 group had 50.8 percent of the contacts,
and 5.8 percent of the 1955 group had 50.8 percent of that group’s police
contacts. Looking at felony arrests only, he found that people with four or
more contacts represented 0.6 percent of the 1942 cohort but accounted for
27.1 percent of the felony arrests. For the 1949 group, 1.7 percent of the cohort
had four or more contacts and were responsible for 44.1 percent of the felony
contacts; for the 1955 group, 3.5 percent of the cohort had four or more and
accounted for 63.8 percent of the felony contacts.
The fact that the Racine findings parallel those from Philadelphia is significant. Racine is a relatively small Midwestern community, with a population of
only 71,000 in 1950 and 95,000 in 1970. Racial minorities constituted only 11
percent of the population in 1970. Philadelphia in 1970 was the third largest city
in the country, with a minority population of 33.6 percent. The Racine study
suggests that Wolfgang’s most important finding holds true for other communities with different demographic characteristics. Additional support comes from
David Farrington’s study of young men in London. Farrington found that 6
percent of his sample accounted for 49 percent of all the criminal convictions
in the cohort.8 In short, there appears to be a near-universal pattern in which a
small group of offenders account for a high proportion of all the crimes committed by their cohort.
CAREER CRIMINALS: DEFINING OUR TERMS AND CONCEPTS
Before going any further, it is important to clarify some of the terminology used in
career criminal research.9 First, we can distinguish criminal careers from career criminals.
Every offender has a criminal career. Some have short ones; others have long ones.
Everyone who goes to school has an academic career. If you drop this and every
other course tomorrow and never return to school, you have had an academic
career—a short one. The kid who commits one act of minor vandalism has a criminal career—a short one. The career criminal, on the other hand, is the person with a
long history of criminal activity.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
87
Another basic concept is the prevalence of criminality. We define this in terms
of participation in crime, which distinguishes between those who commit at least
one crime and those who do not commit any. In the Wolfgang study 35 percent
of the original cohort had a contact with the police, and so the prevalence of
delinquency was 35 percent.
To identify the real career criminals, we need to know the frequency of
offending —that is, the rate at which active criminals commit crimes. As we
will learn later, this issue has extremely important implications for crime policy. If the frequency is about five felonies a year, imprisoning offenders will
have a certain crime reduction effect through incapacitation. But if the frequency is 144 felonies per year, the crime reduction effect will be much
greater. Obtaining an accurate estimate of the frequency, then, is extremely
important for assessing the impact of incapacitation. We will discuss this more
in Chapter 7. Determining the seriousness of offending is also important,
because we want to identify those who commit the more serious crimes.
The beginning of a criminal career is referred to as the onset. Do career criminals begin earlier than one-time offenders? If they do, we might be able to
spot them that way. Persistence refers to continuing criminal activity and desistance to stopping. The amount of time between onset and desistance is the
career length.
FROM RESEARCH TO POLICY
Wolfgang’s original birth cohort study generated an enormous amount of
excitement, stimulating further research and influencing the development of
crime policies. The study was published at a politically opportune moment.
By 1972, crime rates had been rising dramatically for a decade. The public
was disillusioned with the liberal rehabilitation-oriented policies of the 1960s
and was ready for programs that promised to “get tough” with hard-core
criminals.10 Wolfgang’s data suggested that it might be possible to identify
that small group.
This book examines some of the specific policies inspired by the career criminal
research. They include police programs that target suspected career criminals for
intensive surveillance (Chapter 5), pretrial detention of allegedly “dangerous”
offenders (Chapter 7), career criminal prosecution programs (Chapter 8), and
selective incapacitation for repeat offenders (Chapter 7). Many of the treatmentoriented crime control policies proposed by liberals are also designed to deal with
particular classes of offenders. Intensive probation programs (Chapter 11) are
designed for high-risk offenders, whereas boot camps are designed for special categories of offenders.
The data in Table 4.1 make it look simple: Spot the chronic recidivists and
either treat or punish them accordingly. The problem, however, is that nothing
is simple in the real world of criminal justice. Ideas that sound good in theory
do not necessarily work out in practice. Let us look at some of the problems
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
88
CHAPTER
4
that arise when we try to translate Wolfgang’s birth cohort research into crime
control policy.
APPLICATION PROBLEMS
As is so often the case with path-breaking research, Delinquency in a Birth
Cohort raised many questions that needed to be answered. It was a major
breakthrough to learn that we needed to focus on 6 percent of a cohort,
but that was only the beginning. Criminologists have devoted an enormous
amount of time and energy to answering some basic questions. First, exactly
who are the career criminals? Second, when do they begin their criminal
careers, and can we identify them early in their careers before they commit
most of their crimes? Third, how much crime does each one commit? (As we
will see shortly, this question is particularly important.) Fourth, what kinds of
crime do they commit? Fifth, how long do they remain active criminals?
Sixth, when do they stop? Seventh, why do they stop? Is it the result of
some criminal justice policy or do they simply mature out? All of these issues
are related to the bottom line question: Are there criminal justice programs
or interventions that cause them to stop earlier than they otherwise would?
The basic challenge confronting any policy directed toward career criminals
is to identify and control these offenders and only them. It is a waste of time and
money (and also unfair), for example, to imprison one-time offenders who do
not commit more crimes. Traditionally, criminal justice officials believed that
they could identify the repeat offenders or the truly dangerous criminals. Judges
denied bail to defendants they “knew” were dangerous. Judges granted some
convicted offenders probation because they “knew” they were not going to
commit more crimes. Most of these decisions were based on hunch, guesswork,
or just plain bias. At best, they relied on the seriousness of the immediate offense
and the offender’s prior record.
This issue is illustrated by the famous story about how one Supreme Court
justice defined pornography. In the Supreme Court decision in Jacobellis v. Ohio
(1964), Justice Potter Stewart famously admitted that he could not define “hardcore pornography” but said, “I know it when I see it.”11 Similarly, many criminal
justice officials believe that they know a career criminal when they see one. But
when you are talking about decisions that affect peoples’ lives and liberty—as in
sending them to prisons—Justice Stewart’s I-know-it-when-I-see-it standard is not
acceptable. The law demands that such important decisions have a solid empirical
basis and that the outcomes are fair and equitable.
In the real world of criminal justice, career criminal programs run into two
serious problems. The first is correctly identifying the career criminal and not
mistakenly identifying low-rate offenders. We call this the prediction problem. The
second is accurately estimating how much crime these career criminals actually do
(the frequency of offending)—and thus how much crime we will prevent by either
imprisoning or treating them. Let us look at both of these problems in detail.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
89
CONFRONTING THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
Identifying someone as a career criminal is essentially a prediction. We are predicting that they will commit many crimes in the future. In this discussion, we
are looking at the problem from the standpoint of the decision maker: the judge
or the parole board. This is different from the perspective of the social scientist.
The researcher may find strong correlations: for example, between prior drug
involvement plus low income and reoffending. Correlations tell us a lot about
general patterns of behavior. A judge, however, is not interested in general
patterns. He or she has to make a decision about the convicted offender standing
in front of the bench to be sentenced.
We can use three basic methods for predicting criminal behavior. The first is
an actuarial approach that relies on patterns of behavior among individuals with
similar characteristics. Insurance companies use this method. The data indicate
that young drivers have more accidents than middle-age drivers and that young
men have much worse records than young women. Thus, insurance companies
charge higher insurance rates for young people.
A second approach uses the prior history of the individual. Someone has committed many crimes in the past, and so we predict that this behavior will continue in the future. Or, in education we say that you flunked the first test in this
course and, therefore, we predict that you will flunk the next one. As we learned
in Chapter 3, criminal justice officials typically use prior criminal record to assess
offenders. Sentencing guidelines build prior record into the matrix, assigning
more points for each offense.
A third approach is clinical evaluation. Here, predictions about future
behavior are based on the assessments of trained experts. A psychologist or
social worker, for example, might conduct a personal interview, review the
individual’s social history (family, employment record, and so forth), and possibly administer a psychological test. Presentence investigations by probation
officers are an example of clinical evaluations based on an offender’s social
history.
Looking for Violent Delinquents: The Wenk Study
The question is, can these techniques be used, alone or in combination, to
successfully predict future criminal behavior? A good test was conducted on behalf
of the National Council on Crime and Delinquency by Ernst A. Wenk, James
O. Robison, and Gerald W. Smith. The results were not reassuring. Wenk and
his colleagues began with a sample of 4,146 youths committed to the California
Youth Authority (CYA). Of this group, 104 subsequently became “violent
recidivists.” Wenk and his colleagues sought to develop a prediction instrument
that would have identified these 104 individuals if it had been used in advance.
Their instrument involved a combination of prior record and clinical assessment,
using each juvenile’s prior criminal record and history of violence and substance
abuse, among other factors. Clinical assessments were based on psychological tests
and interviews.12
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
90
CHAPTER
T A B L E 4.2
4
Number of youths predicted to be violent and nonviolent who proved to
be violent and nonviolent, California, 1972
Predicted violent
Predicted nonviolent
Actual violent
True positives: Violent persons
correctly identified as and
incarcerated
52
F alse-negatives: Violent persons
incorrectly identified as nonviolent
and not incarcerated
52
Actual Nonviolent
F alse-positives: N onviolent persons
incorrectly identified as violent and
needlessly incarcerated
404
True negatives: Nonviolent
persons correctly identified
as nonviolent
3,638
SOURCE: Ernst A. Wenk, James O. Robison, and Gerald W. Smith, “Can Violence Be Predicted?” Crime and Delinquency
18 (October 1972): 393–402.
Table 4.2 indicates the results. As is obvious, the method successfully identified only half (52) of the 104 who subsequently committed a violent act. Members of this group, referred to as the true positives, were correctly and positively
identified as likely to commit a violent act. The other 52 slipped through the
net, however. We call them the false-negatives. They were falsely (or incorrectly)
predicted not to be violent. From this perspective, the prediction instrument was
only 50 percent accurate; it missed half of those who actually became violent.
But as we shall see, determining the correct success rate of the instrument is
complex.
Consider this problem. As Table 4.2 indicates, 404 people were incorrectly
predicted as likely to become violent. These are referred to as the false-positives,
incorrectly identified as potentially violent. What the false-positive problem
means is that the Wenk method incorrectly identified about eight people for
everyone who was successfully identified as likely to become violent. Translated
into real-world terms, it would mean imprisoning eight nonrecidivists for every
violent recidivist correctly identified. Obviously, the imprisonment costs and
unnecessary deprivation of liberty would be enormous. (And as we will see in
Chapter 7, this is what we have been doing as a society for the past forty
years.)
So what is the real success rate of the Wenk study prediction instrument? If
we focus narrowly on identifying and locking up violent offenders, the instrument is only 50 percent successful: it correctly identify 52 of the 104 violent
offenders, but it misses the other 52 as well, which is not so good when we are
talking about violent crime. Taking a broader view, however, we can count the
3,638 true negatives as successes. Adding them to the 52 true positives, we find
that the instrument is successful 88 percent of the time (3,690 out of 4,146).
The Wenk study reveals the difficulty in predicting human behavior. Even
with the extensive data available, the study’s method produced large numbers of
both false-positives and false-negatives. Even though many people think that
they “know” career criminals “when they see one,” in fact it is difficult to
predict future behavior accurately.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
91
We can illustrate the prediction problem by applying it to Wolfgang’s birth
cohort. If juvenile court officials had prospectively used the same prediction
instrument to identify the 627 chronic recidivists, they would have missed half
of them (313) and then needlessly locked up 2,500 juveniles who would have
been incorrectly labeled chronic recidivists (using the 1 in 8 ratio in the Wenk
study). The same problem bedevils all prediction schemes, and as we shall
see, that it affects both conservative-oriented incapacitation policies and liberaloriented rehabilitation programs.
The Texas Death Row Inmate Study
Another test of predicting dangerousness was conducted by the Texas Defender
Service, the agency that represents death row inmates. It reviewed 155 cases in
which prosecutors in recommending the death penalty had used experts to
predict a defendant’s future dangerousness. It then examined the prison disciplinary records of these inmates with respect to violent behavior. The predictions of
dangerousness were wrong in 95 percent of the cases. Only 8 of the 155 predicted
dangerous inmates had records of “seriously assaultive behavior.” In fact, 20 percent
of the inmates (n = 31) had no disciplinary violations of any sort. The remaining
75 percent had some record of disciplinary actions, but none involved serious
assaults. Sixty-seven of the 155 inmates had been executed and had spent an average
of twelve years on death row. Forty were on death row at the time of the study and
had been incarcerated an average of eight years. Forty-eight inmates had their
sentences reduced and had served an average of nearly twenty years.13
The Federal Sentencing Guidelines
The 1987 law creating the federal sentencing guidelines also established the U.S.
Sentencing Commission with a staff and a mandate to evaluate the implementation and impact of the guidelines. Because one of the goals of the guidelines is to
reduce crime through incapacitation, the commission attempted to evaluate
whether they were accurately predicting future criminal behavior. In a 2004
report, the commission found that the guidelines system of criminal history
scores was positively correlated with recidivism rates. As offender criminal history
scores increased, so did recidivism rates. Only 13.6 percent of the offenders with
the lowest scores (Criminal History Category [CHC] I) recidivated in the first
two years, compared with 55.2 percent of those with the highest scores (CHC
VI). The Sentencing Commission concluded that the guidelines were accurately
predicting future criminal behavior.14
The problem with the Sentencing Commission study is that its prediction
system relies on broad categories, and like all such systems it is generally correct
a lot of the time: people with longer criminal histories are more likely to commit
more crime in the future than people with less serious criminal histories. But it
does not move beyond that to a more precise prediction of the behavior of individual offenders that is more accurate and as a consequence more effective in
reducing crime.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
92
CHAPTER
4
In the end, the evidence clearly indicates that the prediction problem is a
recurring issue in criminal justice. We will encounter it again in Chapter 7
with regard to bail setting and incarceration and in Chapter 11 with respect to
probation and parole decision making.
The Rand Selective Incapacitation Study
Another exercise in prediction was conducted by the Rand Corporation in its
report Selective Incapacitation.15 The Rand Inmate Survey (RIS) involved selfreport interviews in California, Texas, and Michigan in which prison inmates
were asked how many crimes they had committed between arrests. Although
far from perfect, this self-report method yields a reasonably good estimate of
the undetected crime committed by these offenders.
Then, the Rand researchers correlated the self-reported criminal activity
with the social histories of the 2,190 inmates. They identified thirteen characteristics that were correlated with high rates of criminal activity. With one
notable exception, (which we will discuss), extralegal factors such as race,
ethnicity, or gender were not used. An offender’s race is not a legally appropriate factor, for example. Rand then used these data to develop a seven-point
prediction scale (Table 4.3). Offenders with four or more points were then predicted to be high-rate offenders; those with two to three points were predicted
to be medium rate, and those with only one or no points were low-rate
offenders.
In the next stage, Rand retrospectively correlated the prediction scores with
inmates’ actual reported criminal activity. The results appear in Table 4.4. The
prediction device was correct only 51 percent of the time. This represents the
combination (reading diagonally from top left to bottom right) of the predicted
low-risk offenders who proved to be low risks (14 percent), the predicted
medium risks who proved to be medium risks (22 percent), and the predicted
high risks who actually proved to be high risks (15 percent). A 51 percent
accuracy rate is not good. You could do as well flipping a coin, and dispense
with all the elaborate statistical analysis.
T A B L E 4.3
Seven-point scale of factors affecting prediction of offense rates
1.
Prior conviction for the instant offense type
2.
Incarcerated more than 50 percent of preceding two years
3.
Conviction before age sixteen
4.
Served time in a state juvenile facility
5.
Drug use in preceding two years
6.
Drug use as a juvenile
7.
Employed less than 50 percent of the preceding two years
SOURCE: Peter W. Greenwood, Selective Incapacitation (Santa Monica, CA: Rand, 1982), p. 50.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
93
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
T A B L E 4.4
Predicted versus self-reported offense ratio for robbery and burglary
Self-reported offense rates (%)
Score on prediction scale
Low
Medium
High
Total
Low
(0–1)
14
10
3
27
Medium
(2–3)
12
22
10
44
High
(4–7)
4
10
15
29
30
42
28
100
Total
SOURCE: Peter W. Greenwood, Selective Incapacitation (Santa Monica, CA: Rand, 1982). p. 59.
At the same time, the prediction device was grossly wrong in 7 percent of the
cases: the 4 percent who were predicted to be high risks but who turned out to
be low risks (false-positives) and the 3 percent who were predicted to be low
risks but proved to be high risks (false-negatives). The prediction device was moderately wrong in the remaining 42 percent of the cases. In the end, then, the
Rand attempt to develop a scientific prediction method failed to develop a
system that was better than existing practices.
Several years later, Rand researchers made another attempt at predicting
career criminals. They used two samples. One group included 2,700 men who
had been committed to the CYA as juveniles between 1966 and 1971. The
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
94
CHAPTER
4
second group included 200 RIS inmates who had been incarcerated for either
burglary or robbery and had been released at least two years before the new
study. Rand used its original seven-point prediction scale for the RIS group
and a modified five-point scale for the CYA group.16
The results of this study are expressed in the subtitle of the Rand report:
Why the High-Rate Offenders Are Hard to Predict. The authors concluded that
“high rate offenders cannot be accurately identified, either prospectively or retrospectively,
on the basis of their arrest rates alone,” [emphasis added]17 and they conceded that
the previous Rand conclusions about the ability to identify high-rate offenders
and reduce crime by selectively incapacitating them were “overly optimistic.”18
We agree with the Rand’s conclusion. Although they limited their conclusions to using “arrest rates alone,” we feel that the evidence we have reviewed
here supports skepticism about predictive tools that use a broader range of
factors. This is not to say that all risk assessments are worthless. Clearly some
offenders, say at the point of sentencing, are far more likely to become repeat
offenders than others, based on their prior record alone. And some prisoners
are more likely to recidivate than others, based on their prior criminal records
and their conduct while in prison. But as we mentioned at the beginning of
this chapter and in Chapter 1, the purpose of this book is to find policies that
will make marginal but meaningful improvements over what we are currently
doing. Based on the evidence, we offer the following proposition:
5
PROPOSITION
It is not possible to precisely predict future criminal behavior in a way that will
significantly reduce crime.
HOW MUCH CRIME DO THEY COMMIT?
A critically important problem in translating career criminal research into crime
policy involves estimating how many crimes the average high-rate offender commits. The estimate has important practical ramifications. How many crimes will
we prevent if we lock up an armed robber for five years? How much safer will
we be compared with the robber’s completing a three-year sentence? Criminologists have devoted considerable energy to developing estimates of the annual
offending rate for career criminals.
The RIS attempted to estimate annual offending rates through interviews
with inmates in three states. It was one of the most influential studies, and its
findings have been widely used. The self-report method was a major advance
because official records (for example, arrest reports) do not provide a complete
picture of a criminal’s criminal behavior. Many crimes are not reported, and
obviously, most crimes do not result in an arrest.
The RIS estimated high rates of criminal activity, but with some important
variations. California robbers averaged 53 robberies per year, compared with
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
95
77 for Michigan robbers but only 9 a year for those in Texas. The RIS also
found that criminals did not specialize in one type of crime. California robbers
also averaged 90 burglaries, 163 thefts or frauds, and 646 drug offenses each year.
Texas robbers, meanwhile, averaged 24 burglaries and 98 thefts each year.19
The variations in annual offending rates among the three states are striking.
Why were the rates so much higher for Michigan and California compared with
Texas? The best explanation is that Texas judges sent more robbers to prison,
regardless of their actual criminal histories. As a result, the Texas sample included
a higher proportion of low-rate offenders than the Michigan and California
samples did, thereby dragging down the group’s average. California judges were
being more selective, incarcerating only the worst robbers, with the result that
the inmates in that state had much higher annual crime rates.
The difference in the annual offending rates may seem like a minor technical
point, but it has tremendous practical consequences. We need a precise estimate
of the annual offending rate to calculate the amount of crime reduction we will
get. The annual offending rate is expressed as lambda. If the lambda is large, then
we can expect a substantial reduction in crime for every career criminal who is
imprisoned or rehabilitated. But if the lambda is low (that is, if the average career
criminal commits relatively few crimes each year), then the payoff will be much
lower.
Estimates of lambda by respected scholars vary enormously. Alfred Blumstein
and Jacqueline Cohen estimated that adult arrestees committed an annual average
of 3.4 robberies and 5.7 burglaries in Washington and 4.7 robberies and 5.3
burglaries in Detroit. The National Youth Survey estimated that active offenders
committed an average of 8.4 robberies and 7.1 burglaries per year.20 At the other
end of the scale, Edwin W. Zedlewski, in Making Confinement Decisions, used an
estimate of 187 felonies per year.21 The practical implications of these different
estimates are obvious. If we accept Zedlewski’s figure, we could expect a great
reduction in crime. But if we accept Blumstein and Cohen’s figure, we will get a
much smaller payoff for locking up each offender. When we discuss incapacitation as sentencing policy in Chapter 7, we will take a critical look at Zedlewski’s
use of his 187 figure.
A major part of the problem here is the concept of average offending rates.
The RIS data clearly indicate that there is no such thing as an “average” career
criminal. The median annual robbery rate for the RIS inmates was five per year.
The top 10 percent, however, averaged eighty-seven robberies per year. It is
important to remember that the RIS inmates were a pretty select group: They
got caught and were sent to prison because judges regarded them as dangerous
offenders. The top 10 percent of the RIS sample, then, were the worst of the
worst.
From a practical standpoint, to get some real payoff in terms of crime
reduction, it is necessary to identify this small group from among all the other
“serious” offenders. Say, for example, that you wanted to send most robbers
(five robberies per year) to five-year prison terms and give the really high-rate
robbers (eighty-seven robberies per year) fifteen years. You would have to
make precise predictions.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
96
CHAPTER
4
We will examine this subject again in Chapter 7 when we discuss incapacitation as a crime control strategy. It is worth pointing out, however, that despite
all the initial excitement about the possibilities of applying career criminal
research through selective incapacitation, we have in practice abandoned that
goal and adopted a policy of gross incapacitation. The prison population has
soared because we are locking up lots of people without making fine
distinctions.
CONCLUSION
The prediction problem is an excellent example of the difficulties of translating
research into policy. Wolfgang’s original finding about the fact that a small group
of offenders is responsible for a huge percentage of all crime was an important
and exciting event. But because of the prediction problem, policy makers have
been unable to develop meaningful policies based on it.
Research on the prediction problem indicates that it is difficult, if not
impossible, to precisely identify in advance the small group of high-rate offenders. This difficulty is compounded by the fact that estimates differ on how
much crime these high-rate offenders actually do. If the averages are in fact
low, we will not get that much payoff in terms of crime reduction.
The problems we have identified here have a direct impact on many of the
crime control policies we will examine in the chapters ahead. As we mentioned
previously, the administration of justice consists of a series of discretionary decision points. Many of those decisions involve predictions about who is and who is
not dangerous.
NOTES
1 Pew Center on the States, Risk/Needs Assessment 101: Science Reveals New Tools to
Manage Offenders (Washington, DC: Pew Center on the States, September 2011).
2 Addressing unconscious bias in policing is the mission of the Fair and Impartial
Policing project directed by Professor Lorie Fridell of the University of South
Florida. The website explains provides links to the scientific research on unconscious
bias: www.fairandimpartialpolicing.com.
3 Pew Center on the States, Risk/Needs Assessment 101.
4 Marvin Wolfgang, Robert M. Figlio, and Thorsten Sellin, Delinquency in a Birth
Cohort (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1972).
5 Lawrence W. Sherman and Barry Glick, The Quality of Police Arrest Statistics
(Washington, DC: The Police Foundation, 1984).
6 Paul E. Tracy, Marvin E. Wolfgang, and Robert M. Figlio, Delinquency in Two Birth
Cohorts (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1985).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM
97
7 Lyle W. Shannon, Judith L. McKim, James P. Curry, and Lawrence J. Haffner,
Criminal Career Continuity Its Social Context (New York: Human Sciences Press,
1988).
8 The findings of all the longitudinal studies are reviewed in David P. Farrington,
Lloyd E. Ohlin, and James Q. Wilson, Understanding and Controlling “Crime”: Toward
a New Research Strategy (New York: Springer, 1986), see especially pp. 50–52.
9 Alfred Blumstein, Jacqueline Cohen, Jeffrey Roth, and Christy A. Visher, eds.,
Criminal Careers and “Career Criminals” (Washington, DC: National Academy Press,
1986).
10 Samuel Walker, Popular Justice A History of American Criminal Justice, 2nd ed. (New
York: Oxford University Press, 1998).
11 Jacobellis v. Ohio, 378 U.S. 184, 197 (1964).
12 Ernest A. Wenk, James O. Robison, and Gerald W. Smith, “Can Violence Be
Predicted?” Crime and Delinquency 18 (October 1972): 339–402.
13 Texas Defender Service, Deadly Speculation Misleading Texas Capital Juries with False
Predictions of Future Dangerousness (Austin: Texas Defender Service, 2004). Available
on the Texas Defender Service website.
14 U.S. Sentencing Commission, Measuring Recidivism The Criminal History Computation
of the Federal Sentencing Guidelines (Washington, DC: Author, 2004).
15 Peter W. Greenwood and Allan Abrahamse, Selective Incapacitation (Santa Monica,
CA: Rand, 1982).
16 Peter W. Greenwood and Susan Turner, Selective Incapacitation “Revisited”: Why the
High-Rate Offenders Are Hard to Predict (Santa Monica, CA: Rand, 1987).
17 Ibid., p. x.
18 Ibid., p. 49.
19 The data are in Greenwood and Abrahamse, Selective Incapacitation. The original
report is Joan Petersilia, Peter W. Greenwood, and Marvin Lavin, Criminal Careers of
Habitual Felons (Santa Monica, CA: Rand, 1977).
20 Alfred Blumstein and Jacqueline Cohen, “Estimating Individual Crime Rates from
Arrest Records,” Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology 70 (1979): 561–585.
Blumstein et al., Criminal Careers and “Career Criminals”
21 Edwin W. Zedlewski, Making Confinement Decisions (Washington, DC: Government
Printing Office, 1987).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PART
II
“Get Tough”: The
Conservative Attack
on Crime
C
onservatives argue that we can reduce serious crime if we just “get tough” with
criminals. Their crime control agenda, which has not changed in forty years,
includes the following items. First, we can reduce crime if we would just unleash
the cops and give them more power and resources. We will look at several strategies
for unleashing the cops in Chapter 5. Second, we can deter crime through swifter,
more certain, and more severe punishments. We will take a close look at the theory
of deterrence and some deterrence-oriented programs in Chapter 6. Third, we
should lock up more criminals and send them to prison for longer prison terms.
This represents a strategy of incapacitation. We will look at several incapacitation
programs in Chapter 7. Fourth, conservatives believe that too many criminals “get
off” through loopholes in the criminal justice system. We will examine four proposals designed to close loopholes in Chapter 8. Conservatives and some policy analysts believe that the recent reduction in crime is a result of these policies.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
5
Unleash the Cops!
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
T
he police are the front line of the criminal justice system. They are the most
visible part of the criminal justice system, and arrests are the entry point for
criminal cases. The public is highly conscious of the police, partly because of the
visible presence of patrol officers throughout our communities and also because
they are staple items in televisions shows and the movies. For all these reasons,
people have high expectations of the police in terms of public safety, expecting
the police to prevent crime. The police, meanwhile, have always encouraged
these expectations, publicizing their frontline role with respect to crime.
100
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
101
The traditional conservative belief has long been that we can reduce crime if
we just “unleash” the cops. Give them more officers and expand their powers of
searches and interrogations they argue, and the police will reduce crime. Many
Americans agree; when asked about the best way to reduce crime, one-third
consistently say they want more police.1 As we shall see in this chapter, however,
policing is complex. Commonsense assumptions about reducing crime by
putting more cops on the street do not work out in practice. In this chapter,
we will explain why that is so. We will also examine other common proposals
regarding the police and crime: hiring more detectives and eliminating restrictions on police powers of search and seizure and interrogations. But if criminological research has demolished many longstanding assumptions about the
police and crime, it has also provided the basis for important innovations in
policing that hold considerable promise for effective crime reduction. Although
traditional thinking about increasing police effectiveness almost always boiled
down to “more” (more patrol, etc.), the innovations we will examine come
down to the word smarter: using of the best research, focusing on particular
crimes, places, and suspects, and so on.
MORE COPS ON THE STREET
Robert Peel invented modern policing in 1829, and his assumptions and strategies still guide police operations today. His basic idea was simple. It made more
sense to prevent crime than to respond after it had occurred, and the way to
prevent crime was through a continuous police presence throughout the
community. Potential offenders would see police officers, calculate the risk of
committing a crime, and conclude that the risk of arrest outweighed the potential gains of crime. Peel’s ideas live on today. Routine police patrol is still the
basic police strategy for fighting crime.2
Police patrol is designed to deter crime. But does it? More to the point, does
more patrol deter crime more effectively than current levels of patrol? Or are
there particular strategies for how patrol officers are deployed that are more
effective than others?
Some Basics about Police Patrol and Crime
We need to begin by reviewing some basic points about police patrol and
crime. The standard measure of the level of police protection is the policepopulation ratio: the number of sworn officers per 1,000 people. Nationally,
there were 2.2 sworn officers per 1,000 people in the United States in 2011.
In the largest cities (250,000 or more people), however, the figure is 2.7 per
1,000, compared with only 1.8 in medium-sized cities (100,000 to 249,000
population). There are some significant regional variations, however. Big cities
in the northeast have 4.1 officers per 1,000 compared with only 1.9 in the
west.3
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER
T A B L E 5.1
5
Deployment of patrol officers in two hypothetical cities
Population
Sworn officers
Percentage of officers assigned to patrol
Officers assigned to patrol
Percentage of patrol officers assigned to 4 p.m.–12 a.m. shift
Patrol officers, 4 p.m.–12 a.m. shift
One-officer patrols
City X
City Y
500,000
500,000
900
600
50
70
450
420
33
50
148
210
20
190
Two-officer patrols
64
10
Total patrols, 4 p.m.–12 a.m.
84
200
© Cengage Learning
102
In practice, the police-population ratio is meaningless as a measure of police
effectiveness. It only tells us how many police officers are on the payroll, and
nothing about how those officers are used. If a department puts a low percentage
of its officers on the street, or if it uses inefficient two-officer patrols, it will not
have as much police strength as departments with more efficient personnel
practices. Table 5.1 illustrates the point by comparing two hypothetical police
departments, one that is efficiently operated and one that is not. Both are in cities
with populations of 500,000. One has 900 sworn officers, the other 600. The
department with 900 officers, however, assigns a lower percentage to patrol.
Many officers are probably assigned to desk jobs. The department also does not
assign its patrol officers according to a rational workload formula, leaving the
busy evening shift understaffed. Finally, it employs two-officer patrol units,
which are much less efficient than one-officer units. The net result is that the
city with the higher police-population ratio actually has fewer patrol units on
the street during the high-crime evening shift. The citizens are paying more for
police protection but getting less. Simply adding more officers to a poorly managed department, in short, will be largely wasted.
Even more important than the number of officers on patrol is the question
of what officers actually do while on patrol. If officers engage in little active
police work—not initiating contacts with citizens or intensively patrolling highcrime areas, for example—the public gets little in the way of actual crime fighting. In short, simply adding more cops to a department where the officers don’t
do much active policing is another waste.
Are there lower crime rates in cities with more cops? In the most systematic
review of the evidence, Eck and Maguire reviewed twenty-seven studies of the
relationship between the number of police officers and the crime rate. They
found mixed results. Only 20 percent of the studies found that more police was
correlated with lower crime rates, whereas 30 percent found just the reverse: more
police was correlated with more crime. (Keep in mind, the findings involved correlations and not causations.) By the standards of evidence-based crime policy, this
is not persuasive evidence that increasing the number of police reduces crime.4
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
103
THE DETERRENT EFFECT OF PATROL: LESSONS OF THE
KANSAS CITY EXPERIMENT
For nearly 150 years, Robert Peel’s idea that a visible police presence deters crime
was accepted on faith, without any scientific evidence to support it. The Kansas
City Preventive Patrol Experiment (1972–1973), arguably the most important
research projects in police history, finally tested the deterrent effect of policing.5
Virtually all of the important innovations in policing over the past forty years
derive, directly or indirectly, from the Kansas City Patrol Experiment.
The Kansas City experiment sought to test whether varying the level of
police patrol had any impact on crime. It divided the South Patrol District into
three groups. Proactive beats received two or three times the normal level of
patrol. Reactive beats received no routine patrol. Police cars entered those areas
only in response to a citizen’s call for service; officers handled the call and then
left the beat area. Control beats kept the normal level of patrol. A victimization
survey (which was still a new research tool at that time), allowed the researchers
to examine the effect of different levels of patrol on criminal activity, citizen
perceptions of the level of police protection and fear of crime, and any changes
in citizen behavior that might affect criminal activity. It is possible, for example,
that people who notice the absence of the police would take more protective
measures (not going out at night or going out alone). By reducing people’s risk
of victimization, such actions would probably lower the crime rate, but it would
be the result of fewer police on patrol rather than more. The experiment ran for
an entire year, and the findings were explosive, generating national news stories.
The experiment found that the level of patrol had no effect on either crime
or citizen perceptions of police protection or fear of crime. Crime did not
increase in the reactive beats where there was less patrol and did not fall in the
proactive beats where there was more patrol. Moreover, people did not seem to
notice the differences in the level of patrol. Fear of crime did not go up in the
reactive beats and did not go down in the proactive beats.
It is important to emphasize that the experiment did not prove that patrol has
no effect on crime. At no time were there beats with no police presence whatsoever. Patrol cars entered reactive beats to handle 911 calls, and officers in other
units (for example, juvenile, criminal investigation) entered those beat to handle
their own assignments. Law-abiding citizens and potential criminals alike saw
marked police cars in the reactive beats and legitimately regarded them as part
of the “normal” police presence.
The Kansas City findings were partly confirmed by the subsequent Newark
(New Jersey) Foot Patrol Experiment (1978–1979), which found that different
levels of foot patrol had no effect on the crime rate. Interestingly, however, it
also found that additional foot patrol officers reduced citizen fear of crime and
improved attitudes toward the police department. This finding proved to be
one of the keys to the development of community policing and problemoriented policing, by suggesting that there are things the police can do to reduce
fear of crime.6
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
104
CHAPTER
5
Understanding Police Patrol and Deterrence
Why did more patrol officers not reduce crime in either Kansas City or Newark?
Part of the answer lies in the theory of deterrence, which assumes that visible
police patrol communicates a threat of arrest and causes people to choose not to
commit crime. In the real world of policing, however, the theory does not work.
The Kansas City experiment illuminated what has been called residual deterrence.
Assuming there is any deterrent effect of police patrol, it will be there if people
believe the police are around, even if in fact they are not. Think about how we
live our daily lives. When we see a patrol car we assume they are in all beats all
through the community, even though they actually may not be everywhere at all
times. We don’t really know how many patrol cars are patrolling our neighborhood at any given moment; what matters is that we believe they are. As a practical
matter, moreover, we pass through several police beats as we go about our lives:
from home to job, school, the store, a bar, and so on. When we see a patrol car in
one beat, that impression stays with us as we move through other beats. If we see a
police car on Tuesday, the perception carries over to Wednesday and beyond. The
residual deterrent effect stays with us.7 One lesson of the Kansas City experiment is
that a little police patrol goes a long way, thanks to residual deterrence.
Another practical factor that affects the potential deterrent effect of police
patrol is the fact that patrol is spread thin in every police department. A patrol
car actually passes each point in its assigned beat rarely in any day, and may not
pass some sites for weeks or months. Doubling the number of patrol cars (that is,
increasing the “dosage” in the experiment) does not represent a difference that
people are likely to perceive. It is sort of like taking four aspirins instead of two
for a serious health problem.
Another problem with deterrence theory is that offenders do not perceive
police patrol as a meaningful threat. They simply don’t think that they will be
caught. One study estimated that drug dealers who average 1,000 transactions a
year face an imprisonment risk of 1 in 4,500 per transaction. (1,000 a year is
three a day, so the risk is far lower form small-time drug dealers).8 The national
clearance rate for Index Crimes has always been about 20 percent. The FBI
clearance rate data, moreover, are based on reported crimes. When we factor in
unreported crimes, the actual clearance rates are much lower. Teenagers and
many criminals, moreover, have a sense of invincibility. Much crime is impulsive, with offenders not rationally calculating. Experienced criminals, on the
other hand, are fatalistic and assume that sooner or later they will be caught.
The Rand Inmate Survey, for example, found that most prison inmates thought
there was a good chance they would be arrested, convicted, or even injured as a
result of doing crime. Nonetheless, almost all had committed repeat offenses.
Clearly, the fear of adverse consequences did not deter them.9
Finally, many crimes are inherently not suppressible by patrol. The majority
of murders and assaults, and about half of all rapes, occur between people who
know each other. Because they usually occur indoors and in the heat of passion,
the level of police patrol out on the street has no effect on them. Robbery, burglary, and auto theft, on the other hand, occur outside, and are at least theoretically suppressible through patrol.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
105
In short, the evidence from the Kansas City and Newark experiments
persuasively indicate that simply adding more patrol officers does not increase
the deterrent effect of patrol. This leads us to the following proposition:
6
PROPOSITION
Simply putting more cops on the street will not reduce crime.
THE ALL-SEEING EYE: CCTV
In one of the most sensational crime cases in recent years, the two perpetrators of
the terrorist bombing at the 2013 Boston Marathon were quickly identified,
tracked down, and arrested (one was killed in the process). They were identified
by surveillance camera images from the marathon finish line. The incident gave a
powerful boost to the idea that surveillance video cameras in public places can
effectively control crime. Does the evidence support this view? Do they help to
reduce routine felonies? Or was the Boston terrorism episode just a classic
“celebrated case” that is not relevant to day-to-day crime?
Police patrol, we have just argued, is actually spread thinly around the
community. Technology, however, has created the possibility of continuous
surveillance in the form of closed circuit television cameras (CCTV). Many people are excited about this development, believing that knowledge about the
cameras will deter crime more effectively than traditional police patrol and that
the video recordings will help identify offenders and lead to more arrests. Let’s
look at the evidence.
CCTVs have been widely used in particular locations: banks, conveniences
store, apartment buildings entrances, warehouses, and so on. In some cases they
do provide useful images of robbers that are helpful in making an arrest. The
question is whether they are effective out in public places. CCTVs are used far
more extensively in England than the United States. Between 1998 and 2001
alone, the British government spent the equivalent of US 250 million on
CCTVs. In the United States, New York City has developed an extensive
CCTV network. The New York Civil Liberties Union, concerned about privacy issues, estimated that the number of cameras in the Greenwich Village/
SOHO area increased from 142 in 1998 to 2,227 in 2005. This is a huge number
of cameras for such a relatively small part of the city.10 A 2008 California survey
found that eighteen cities in the state had “significant” CCTV systems, including
Los Angeles, Sacramento, and Fresno.11
The effectiveness of CCTVs has been evaluated by some of the world’s top
criminologists, and the evidence is mixed. Welsh and Farrington reviewed fortyfour studies of the impact of CCTVs on violent and property crimes. CCTVs
were deployed in different ways in these studies in four types of settings: city
center areas, public housing buildings, public transportation centers, and car
parking locations. Overall, CCTVs had a “modest but significant desirable effect
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
106
CHAPTER
5
on crime,” but they were most effective with regard to surveillance of parked
cars. Ten of twenty-two evaluations of CCTVs in city centers reported positive
results, five had “undesirable” effects, one had mixed results, and six had no
measurable effects. The evaluations found some overall reduction in property
crime, but no reduction in violent crimes. Another five evaluations involved
automobile parking areas, and all included additional changes in the target sites
such as improved lighting. Four of those five evaluations reported reductions in
crime, and one reported an increase in crime.12
One significant limitation of CCTVs is that they are deployed in public areas
and have no impact on crimes that occur in private spaces. (As we mentioned
previously, this is also true of police patrol.) This is particularly true of many
murders, which occur between people who know each other, and domestic
violence assaults and murders, and a certain number of aggravated assaults
between acquaintances who are not in an intimate relationship.
In the end, CCTVs appear to be most effective in reducing property crime
in parking areas, particularly when coupled with other improvements such as
better lighting. This makes sense. Parking areas are fixed locations (much like
convenience stores) that are likely targets. There is mixed evidence regarding
crime in general public areas, and no evidence of a positive impact on violent
crime. This too makes sense. Assaults and robberies on the street do not occur
at fixed locations, but are randomly distributed throughout neighborhoods without any consistent pattern. Considering the enormous cost of deploying CCTVs
in every neighborhood, the evidence raises questions about the cost effectiveness
of CCTVs as a crime-fighting strategy for the community as a whole.
POLICE “CRACKDOWNS” ON CRIME
A traditional alternative to routine patrol involves police crackdowns, which are
brief intensive enforcement efforts. The following section examines how
enforcement efforts have evolved dramatically in recent decades from oldfashioned “crackdowns” to more sophisticated, data-driven efforts such as
problem-oriented policing, “hot spots” policing, and focused deterrence. These
new efforts build on the best research in criminology and represent what is often
called “smart policing.” Let’s begin by looking at old-fashioned crackdowns to
see why they were not effective.
Crackdowns
Police crackdowns are a classic example of the get-tough approach to crimefighting. A crackdown is defined as a short burst of intensive law enforcement,
involving many arrests, directed toward a particular area or problem such as
drugs or gangs.13 One well-known antidrug crackdown was Operation Pressure
Point (OPP) in New York City. In the early 1980s, OPP targeted an open-air
drug market on the city’s Lower East Side that had been described as a “drug
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
107
buyer’s paradise.” An additional 240 officers flooded the area, dispersing crowds,
stopping and questioning suspected drug buyers and sellers, writing traffic tickets,
and making a high volume of arrests (more than 2,000 in the first month alone).
The police also ended its Desk Appearance Ticket (DAT) policy, which allowed
persons charged with misdemeanors to be released immediately, and the U.S.
attorney’s office agreed to process many of the drug arrests in federal court,
where the defendants would face harsher sentences.14
There are a many questions about the process and impact of OPP. First, the
evaluation did not control for the possible displacement of drug trafficking into
other neighborhoods. (One of the great advances in police research was the
recognition and measurement of both the possible displacement of crime or possible diffusion of positive effects of a crime fighting program.) Drug dealers,
meanwhile, adapted to the crackdown with more sophisticated techniques, such
as using lookouts and “steerers” to protect dealers from the police. The cost
effectiveness of the large number of arrests in terms of both police officer time
and court processing time was not evaluated. Nor was there an evaluation of the
outcomes of the many arrests. In one highly publicized crackdown in Los
Angeles, for example, virtually all of the arrests were dismissed.15
Finally, the evaluation mentioned but did not examine the police misconduct that the program encouraged. Officers disrupted drug dealing, for example,
by harassing potential buyers and scaring them off. Another problem is the
replacement effect. A drug crackdown may well remove drug dealers from an
area, but they may also be replaced by other individuals who see an opportunity
to make money. As one police officer put it, for every person arrested “there is
always a replacement.”
In truth, crackdowns have typically been more publicity stunts than carefully
planned efforts to reduce crime. They are really directed at the media and the
general public, to create the impression that the police department is doing
something about crime. In the era of evidence-based crime policy, however,
doing “something” is no longer sufficient, and traditional crackdowns are definitely
not smart policing.
A Different Kind of Crackdown? The NYPD
Stop-and-Frisk Controversy
A more focused form of a crackdown is the New York City Police Department
(NYPD) program of stops and frisks of people officers believe to be criminal
suspects. The number of stops escalated to more than 600,000 in 2011 and was
the subject of a fourteen-year controversy and several law suits challenging the
legality of the practice.
Stopping and questioning people has always been a basic part of police
work. Traditionally stops have been referred to as “field interrogations.” The
law of stops and frisks was defined by the U.S. Supreme Court in the 1968
Terry v. Ohio decision16 as a temporary detention of a person about whom the
officer has reasonable suspicion that he or she is committing or may be about to
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
108
CHAPTER
5
commit a crime. A stop is not an arrest, and reasonable suspicion is a lower
evidentiary standard than probable cause. The court held that a police officer
can frisk the detained person, defined as a pat-down but not a full search (such
as searching a person’s pockets), to determine whether the person has a weapon.
The purpose of the frisk is to ensure the officer’s safety.17
Stops and frisks raise a number of important issues, including whether they
are done in a constitutional manner and their impact on police-community
relations and the legitimacy of the police, Our concern here is whether they
effectively reduce crime. With respect to crime, stops and frisks have two potential effects. First, police officers may in fact identify criminal offenders and arrest
them. Second, a policy of widespread stops and frisks may deter criminal activity,
the carrying of weapons, or both, by sending a message of intense police surveillance in an area. Let’s see how it has worked in practice in New York City.
In 2011 the number of people stopped by New York City police officers
reached a peak of 685,725, a 600 percent increase over 97,296 in 2002. Of
those people stopped, 381,704, or 57 percent, were frisked.18 New York City
officials claimed that the stops and frisks were directly responsible for the great
decline in crime. There is no question about the dramatic crime reduction in the
city. Murders in New York City declined from 2,605 in 1990 to 952 in 2000
and 774 in 2011. Robberies fell from 112,380 in 1990 to only 28,396 in 2011.
This is an extraordinary success story, and we need to consider the possible causes
carefully.19
The outcomes of the stops and frisks in New York raise serious questions
about their direct impact on crime. Year after year, only about 10 to 12 percent
of the people stopped were either arrested or issued a summons, even though the
officer in each case claimed to have reasonable suspicion that a crime had
occurred or was about to occur (and had to fill out the required UF 220 report
to that effect). Yet, it appears that they were wrong about 90 percent of the
time. In the 381,704 frisks in 2011, meanwhile, officers seized a total of only
780 guns, for a “success” rate of 1.9 percent for all frisks and 1.1 percent for all
stops. In short, the evidence does not support the idea of a direct effect (arrests,
summons, guns seized) on criminals and criminal behavior.20
Other evidence questions the city’s argument that its stop-and-frisk
program was responsible for the great reduction in crime. The country has a
whole experienced the Great American Crime Drop beginning in the early
1990s. Although it is true that New York City enjoyed a greater reduction in
crime than other cities, the decline began before the NYPD escalated its stopand-frisk program. San Diego, moreover, enjoyed a steady reduction in crime
without an aggressive stop-and-frisk program. Additionally, the NYPD undertook several innovations since the mid-1990s, including “zero-tolerance”
policing and COMPSTAT (see the discussion later). In this context, it is
difficult if not impossible to isolate the impact of any one of these programs,
including the stop-and-frisk program. Bernard Harcourt concluded that
Boston, San Francisco, San Diego, Los Angeles, Houston, Dallas, and San
Antonio had all experienced significant crime reductions without aggressive
use of stops and frisks.21
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
109
Unfortunately, there has been relatively little research on the impact of stops
and frisks on crime (several important studies of New York City were completed
just as this book was going to press; see the endnote at the end of this paragraph).
A study of field interrogations in San Diego in the 1970s found some reduction
in suppressible crimes (burglary, petty theft, disturbances, and public disorder
offenses) in areas with field interrogations compared with those with none.
Field interrogations, however, did not yield more arrests.22 The one study of
the New York City program found it to be extremely inefficient with regard
to the number of arrests and weapons seized (the “outputs” in the study) given
the number of stops and frisks (the “inputs”).23 There are no recent studies from
other cities that would, for example, compare crime trends in precincts that
receive intensive stops and frisks with a matched group that receive normal
policing. In the era of evidence-based police policy making, an aggressive stopand-frisk policy does not pass the test. In short, there is simply no evidence to
confirm or refute the NYPD’s claims that it is directly responsible for the
reduction in crime. (A set of studies appeared too late to be included in this
book, but they are now the best studies yet of the impact of stops and frisks on
crime in New York City, and well worth looking at.)24
Finally, it is necessary to discuss stops and frisks in terms of the “social
ledger” we discussed in Chapter 1. Each and every crime policy needs to be
evaluated in terms of its full range on consequences. The New York City policy
of aggressive stops and frisks had an extremely negative impact on its principal
targets, young African American and Latino males. A Vera Institute study of
young people between the ages of 18 to 25, which included in-depth interviews
with a subset of subject, found that 44 percent had been stopped repeatedly by
the police, and 29 percent reported that they were never informed of the reason
for the stop. Seventy-one percent had been frisked at least once and 44 percent
reported that they had been threatened by a police officer.25 These extremely
negative impacts have major implications for crime reductions. As we will discuss
in detail in Chapter 12, there is growing evidence of the importance of
legitimacy in criminal justice. People who believe the police and other criminal
justice agencies are legitimate are more likely to cooperate with officials, which
increases the effectiveness of the system, and also to obey the law. To the extent
that the New York City policy of stops and frisks undermined legitimacy it also
undermined the crime control effectiveness of the police.
FASTER RESPONSE TIME
The belief that faster response times to reported crimes will result in more arrests
and reduce the crime rate is another part of the popular folklore of policing.
People expect a fast response to their 911 calls, in part because the police have
advertised their policy of quick response. But does it actually reduce crime?
The evidence overwhelmingly indicates that faster response times do
not produce more arrests and have no effect on the crime rate. The police are
actually called to few crimes in progress. Only about 30 percent of all patrol
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
110
CHAPTER
5
dispatches involve any criminal activity, and some studies put the figure as low as
17 percent. Moreover, about 75 percent of these crime-related calls involve
“cold” crimes. Typically, it is a burglary that occurred many hours previously,
and the offender is long gone. In these cases it makes no difference whether
the police get there in three minutes or three hours.26
The remaining crime-related calls are termed involvement crimes, meaning
that a confrontation exists between the victim and a suspect. They represent
only 25 percent of crime-related calls, and only 7.5 percent of all patrol
dispatches. Response time rarely makes a difference in these crimes, either. In
many cases, the victim and offender are acquaintances, as in domestic violence
incidents. The victim can identify the suspect no matter when the police arrive.
Equally important, crime victims usually do not call the police immediately.
Traumatized and confused, they often try to compose themselves, decide
whether to even call the police, and often call a friend or family member first.
This delay in calling the police renders irrelevant the police travel time in terms
of catching the offender. At best, faster police response potentially makes a
difference in a small number of crime calls: about 3 percent, according to a
study by the Police Executive Research Forum. Commercial robberies are the
best example. If someone calls the police while the crime is in progress, a quick
response time might improve the chances of catching the offender at the scene.
We have to emphasize might, because there has been no research indicating that
the faster response time does make a difference. And in any event these kinds of
crime are rare events.27
The National Academy of Sciences report concluded that improving police
response time will not reduce crime.28 We agree.
7
PROPOSITION
Faster response time will not produce more arrests or lower the crime rate.
SMART POLICING: PROMISING FUTURES
If the evidence does not support the traditional strategies of adding more police
patrol or increasing response times, a number of newer strategies show some
promise of effectiveness in fighting crime. Often referred to collectively as
“smart policing,” they include problem-oriented policing (POP), “hot spots”
policing, zero-tolerance policing (sometimes called “broken windows” policing),
COMPSTAT, and focused deterrence. The Bureau of Justice Assistance has
funded the Smart Policing Initiative (SPI), which is assisting more than thirty
local law enforcement agencies with innovative projects.29
Several features are common to all of these strategies in varying degrees. All
build on the best criminological research, involve careful planning, are datadriven, and are focused on particular crimes, places, or suspects. Many programs
combine two or more of these elements.30 A POP project, for example, might
be directed toward hot spots and have a focused deterrence orientation. The
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
111
pattern of creative innovation in U.S. policing that David Bayley noted twenty
years ago continues, and if anything, has increased its pace.31 The major significance of the new smart policing initiatives is that they demolish the myth that
the police cannot really do anything to affect the crime rate. This myth was an
understandable by unfortunate consequence of the Kansas City Patrol Experiment which we discussed earlier, and which concluded that adding more patrol
does not reduce crime. Yet, as we pointed out, the experiment studied only the
amount of patrol and did not examine what police officers actually do. Frank
Zimring argues that today’s good news is that “police and police strategy can
make a difference in big city crime.” Let’s look at some the most important
innovative programs.32
Problem-Oriented Policing
POP, first proposed by Herman Goldstein in 1979, has become quite widespread in U.S. policing. POP holds that instead of trying to attack “crime” in
a global and unfocused way, the police should identify particular problems (for
example, open-air drug dealing or residential burglaries, and so on), examine
the underlying causes, and develop strategies specifically designed to address
them.33
POP developed the Scanning, Analysis, Response, and Assessment (SARA)
model. Scanning involves surveying the community and identifying particular
crime or disorder problems that need to be addressed. Analysis involves studying a particular problem and identifying the underlying factors that contribute
to the problem: abandoned houses that facilitate drug dealing, for example.
Response involves developing a program directed toward the problem and the
underlying causal factors: developing a working partnership with property
owners and city officials to either board up or demolish the abandoned
homes. Assessment involves an evaluation of the effectiveness of the response.
Other important elements of POP include developing partnerships with both
private resources and public agencies, and using noncriminal justice approaches.
GETTING SMART IN OAKLAND An ambitious POP program involved
the Specialized Multi-Agency Response Team (SMART) program directed
toward drug hot spots in Oakland, California. The police were part of a multiagency task force (a good example of partnerships), and their role included
increased enforcement activity: more patrol, field interrogations, arrests, and so
on. SMART also mobilized officials from the housing, fire, and public works
departments to enforce local building codes and clean up the physical appearance
of the neighborhoods (an example of noncriminal justice approaches). A training
program for landlords was designed to help them screen prospective tenants and
evict existing tenants for rules violations. The evaluation of SMART found that
it reduced the level of drug activity in the target areas and did not displace crime
to nearby areas. Additionally, it had a “diffusion” effect of improving the quality
of life in areas surrounding the target beats.34
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
112
CHAPTER
5
HOT SPOTS IN LOWELL AND JERSEY CITY Hot spots policing is a
strategy that developed out of Lawrence W. Sherman’s path-breaking 1989
analysis of 911 calls in Minneapolis, which found the then-astonishing fact that
5 percent of the addresses in the city accounted for 64 percent of all 911 calls. A
few places, which he labeled hot spots, consumed a disproportionate amount of
police time and effort.35 Similar patterns are believed to be common in all urban
areas. Hot spots policing is based on the assumption that if the police direct
focused, intensive efforts at the areas with high concentrations of crime and
calls for service they can reduce crime and disorder. Hot spots policing contains
several of the elements of smart policing; it is research-based, data-driven, and
focused on particular geographic areas, and often particular crimes such as drugs.
A hot spots experiment in Lowell, Massachusetts, used the SARA model to
identify thirty-four separate hot spots of crime and disorder that represented only
2.7 percent of the area of the entire city, but about 30 percent of all violent
crime calls to the police. The thirty-four areas were then distributed into seventeen matched pairs. Police captains were assigned responsibility for developing
appropriate responses in their areas. In addition to traditional police enforcement
efforts, such as increased patrol, dispersing loiterers, and public nuisance arrests,
the responses also included non-law enforcement tactics such as cleaning up
vacant lots and improving street lighting.
Data collected for the experiment included traditional calls for service, and
both photographs of the physical appearance and observations of social activities
(for example, the number of people engaging in disorderly activity) in each area.
The weekly average of misdemeanor arrests in the treatment areas increased
about 18 percent. Calls for service regarding violent crime went down significantly (42 percent for robbery and nondomestic assault incidents), and observed
social disorder was reduced in fourteen of the seventeen treatment areas. In the
areas surrounding the treatment and control areas, moreover, crime increased
only slightly and not to a statistically significant degree. In short, there was no
displacement of crime.36
A hot spots experiment in Jersey City, New Jersey, was directed at illegal
drug markets and prostitution. The antiprostitution effort on Cornelison Avenue
included three elements that represented both traditional policing with innovative noncriminal justice efforts: increased enforcement in the form of arrests of
prostitutes; cleaning up trouble spots by fencing off a wooded lot and closing
one street to limit access for “johns” cruising for prostitutes; and finally working
with community groups to help prostitutes deal with personal problems such as
drugs. An evaluation found that the POP efforts not only reduced crime in the
experimental areas but also in neighboring areas. In short, crime was not
displaced by intensive police efforts, and the crime reduction was diffused to
surrounding areas that did not receive the innovative treatment.37
The evidence from these innovative programs is promising. They indicate
that smart policing can make a difference in reducing crime and disorder. The
main barrier to this innovative approach to police crime fighting is implementation. There have been many community policing and POP experiments over the
past thirty years.38 Unfortunately, many were poorly designed or poorly
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
113
implemented. A department did not use the SARA model, or did not use it
properly; the police responses were not always appropriate for the underlying
problem; or the effort was not maintained throughout the experiment. Innovative smart policing, in short, can make a difference, but it is a major challenge to
design and carry out a successful program.
COMPSTAT: DATA-DRIVEN POLICING
The most widely publicized innovation in police crime-fighting in recent years is
COMPSTAT (for COMPuterSTATistics). Within just a few years after it burst
on the national scene, about one-third of all police departments claimed they
had adopted it. A major reason for its rapid spread was New York City where
Police Commissioner William J. Bratton aggressively publicized the adoption of
COMPSTAT and a resulting decline in crime. The core element of COMPSTAT
is a computerized database that provides timely data on crime and disorder, which
enables the police to respond quickly to changing patterns of crime and disorder. In
the best programs, the turnaround time for data is twenty-four hours or less. The
data are analyzed at regular command level meetings (weekly in the Minneapolis
CODEFOR program; every two weeks in Fort Worth) where commanders are
held responsible for developing appropriate responses to the problems in their
areas. The NYPD program received a lot of attention over the fact that commanders
were grilled at the weekly COMPSTAT meetings, and then-Police Commissioner
Bratton advertised them as great “theater.”39
Police departments have chosen a variety of strategies about how to use
the COMPSTAT data. New York City was already doing zero-tolerance
(also called “broken windows”) policing when COMPSTAT was adopted.
Fort Worth used a variety of strategies, including a combination of hot
spots and zero-tolerance policing: Zero Tolerance Units were assigned to
each to the department’s four patrol division. In addition, neighborhood
police officers, a part of an existing community policing program, focused on
public nuisances and disorderly conduct (zero-tolerance, or broken-windows
policing).40
There is no question that crime fell significantly in New York City during
the COMPSTAT years. The number of murders fell from 2,605 in 1990, before
COMPSTAT was adopted) to 774 in 2011. The robbery rate, meanwhile, fell
from 624.7 per 100,000 in 1990 to 145.9 in 2011.41 The question, of course, is
to what extent COMPSTAT was responsible for this result or at least some part
of it. As we have already indicated, COMPSTAT in New York City coincided
with other major developments, including the Great American Crime Drop; the
decline in the use of the drug crack, which was responsible for many homicides;42 zero tolerance policing; and a 35 percent increase in the size of the
NYPD itself (to 40,000 officers).43
Perhaps even more important, some observers argued that the NYPD had
become “bureaucratically dysfunctional” by the 1980s. Former Police Commissioner
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
114
CHAPTER
5
Bratton has said that the department basically “gave up” on serious efforts to fight
crime by the 1960s.44 His leadership, which included both zero-tolerance policing
and COMPSTAT were major efforts to reinvigorate the department.45 The
department always claimed that its aggressive stop-and-frisk program directly
contributes to the continued decline in crime. Some observers have commented
that any good leadership for the NYPD would have made a huge difference, and it
would have been reflected in lower crime rates. As we argued previously with
regard to stops and frisks, with all of these changes occurring simultaneously,
how do we specify the specific contribution of any one of them? And so it
would wise to be skeptical about the claims made for COMPSTAT in New
York.46
An evaluation of COMPSTAT in Fort Worth, Texas, is particularly valuable
because it takes us out of the special context of New York City, with all of its
unique factors. Fort Worth’s application of COMPSTAT closely resembled New
York. Crime strategy meetings were held every two weeks where crime data for
the previous twenty-eight days were presented, and division commanders
identified the major problems and their strategies for dealing with them. The
department’s crime data system provided a twenty-four-hour turn around,
which permitted a timely response to any changes in neighborhoods. Crime
mapping technology also permitted the identification of crime hot spots. Special
Zero Tolerance Units were created to address hot spots. Finally, the Neighborhood Police Officer program embraced broken windows policing directed
toward minor nuisance offenses. Fort Worth did not, however, copy the “punitive” accountability tactic that New York highlighted, where commanders were
grilled by higher level police officials and deliberately embarrassed if crime had
not gone down in their areas.47
An evaluation of the Fort Worth experience concluded that COMPSTAT
“played a significant role in reducing property crimes and total index crime
rates.” It did not, however, “significantly reduce violent crime rates.”48 But
even here, it is not clear what was the critical innovation. Was it COMPSTAT
itself, or the innovations the department used to implement it?
Disturbing questions about COMPSTAT were also raised by a study of
data manipulation under COMPSTAT. Eterno and Silverman mailed questionnaires to retired commanders (captains and higher) from the NYPD. The
491 completed questionnaires were divided among officers who retired before
1995 (33.9 percent), the year COMPSTAT became operational, and those
who retired after 1995 (66.1 percent). The post-1995 respondents reported
“higher levels of managerial pressure” to get the crime rate down, increase
arrests and summons, and reduce citizen complaints. Significantly, there was
less pressure regarding integrity related to crime data. Promotions, moreover,
were perceived to be more likely to be based on crime statistics. Interviews
with a select group of retirees, moreover, found many who had observed
unethical changes in crime reports. Commanders would make special efforts
to verify the value of reported stolen property; lowering the value to make
the reported offense a misdemeanor rather than a felony would have the effect
of reducing the official crime rate.49
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
115
FOCUSED DETERRENCE, OR “PULLING LEVERS”:
THE MOST EFFECTIVE RESPONSE?
Arguably, the most important police innovation in recent years has been focused
deterrence. Particularly important, it has passed the rigorous test of EvidenceBased Crime Policy. A meta-analysis of eleven focused deterrence evaluations
found “strong” evidence of effectiveness.50
Operation Ceasefire: The Boston Gun Project
The original program, which inspired many variations, was the Boston Gun
Project in the 1990s. The project was a response to a serious upsurge in gun
violence in the city in the late 1980s, particularly among young African American
males. Community leaders brought together all of the relevant stakeholders to
develop Operation Ceasefire, a multiphased strategy to reduce gun violence, that
began in 1995. A collaborative partnership was developed among the Boston
Police Department, other law enforcement agencies, state and county probation and parole agencies, other public and private social service agencies, and
finally community groups. Analysis of the gun violence problem determined
that much of it was associated with particular gangs, and Operation Ceasefire
focused on the leaders of those gangs. This focus on a small group of individuals departed from traditional police crackdowns, which as we have already
discussed were indiscriminate in whom they arrested.51
Operation Ceasefire involved intensive law enforcement by both the Boston
Police Department and federal authorities, together with enforcement of the
terms of probation and parole by correctional officials, focused on gang leaders.
The strategy of “pulling levers” involved using all potential violations by the
targeted gang leaders, from the most serious, such as gun crimes, to the least serious, such as motor vehicle law violations. The levers included arresting people
with outstanding warrants, seizing the unregistered vehicles, and vigorously
enforcing probation and parole conditions. Probation or parole status is a particularly useful lever because many gang members have prior convictions and are
out on probation or parole. Operation Night Light involved evening visits to
probationer and parolee’s residences by teams of police and correctional officers
to check for possible violations such as alcohol, drugs, or weapons possession.
A major part of the pulling levers strategy were “forums” with gang members, which have been called call-in or notification meetings in other cities. Gang
members were brought in voluntarily, at the request of social service street
workers, or compelled to attend as a condition of their probation or parole status. At the meetings they were given a strong message that if gun violence
occurred, the authorities would use every possible lever against them. These
face-to-face meetings gave the special focus to the idea of focused deterrence.
(In Chapter 6 on deterrence, we will discuss in more detail the limitations of
most deterrence-oriented programs, which are generally unfocused in terms of
their intended audience.)
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
116
CHAPTER
5
Did the Boston Gun Project work? An evaluation found a 63 percent reduction in monthly youth homicides and smaller reductions in youth gun assaults
and calls to the police regarding gunshots. You might properly point out that
at the time, the entire country was experiencing the Great American Crime
Drop, but the evaluation, found a greater reduction in crime in Boston than in
other cities across the country.
Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce Violence
Because of its innovative approach and reported success, the Boston Gun Project
became the most highly publicized police antigun violence program in the
country. An important replication involved the Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce
Violence (CIRV). Two factors distinguish this effort. First, aware that Boston
and some other projects had faded after their initial successes, the planning
included creating an organizational structure designed ensure its continuity.
Second, the evaluation included both twenty-four- and forty-eight-month postintervention periods, the longest of any focused deterrence effort.52
Launched in 2007, CIRV incorporated the basic components of the Boston
Gun Project. Police enforcement efforts sought to increase both the certainty
and severity of the consequences of law-breaking. Twenty-eight “call-in” meetings reached 568 identified violent gang members, and another four meetings in
prisons involved 168 offenders due for release. Finally, 163 home or street visits
reached identified high-risk individuals in the community. As in Boston, the various meetings delivered a clear message that the police would respond to any
homicide involving a violent gang member with a concerted enforcement effort
(pulling levers) directed at all members of the group. In the end, 223 offenders
were arrested on various charges, and another 17 were indicted on federal
charges. The second component of the program involved delivering “tailored”
social services to individuals who wanted to leave the life of gang violence.
The third component involved efforts to change “community norms” regarding
violence through community outreach programs.
The results were impressive: a 41.1 percent reduction in gang memberinvolved (GMI) homicides after 42 months. Non-gang member-involved homicides, by comparison, increased 38.3 percent over the same time period. The fact
that the reduction among the targeted group continued for forty-two months
makes the findings especially persuasive. Interestingly, however, there was no
evidence of a direct impact of the social services component of the call-in meetings
on homicides or violent firearms incidents.
Together with the positive evaluations of other focused deterrence
programs, the success of CIRV indicates that it is the most promising police
program for reducing serious crime. This leads us to the following proposition:
8
PROPOSITION
Carefully planned and focused problem-oriented policing strategies can be
successful in reducing crime and disorder.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
117
A Few Words of Caution about Police Innovations
The various smart policing innovations are an exciting development in U.S.
policing, representing significant advances over traditional policing. A few
words of caution are in order, however. The first is the problem of institutionalizing these reforms in police departments. There is a long history of important
police reforms related to both crime and accountability just fading away with
time.53 The celebrated Boston Gun Project fell into disarray after a few years
because of a variety of problems. David Kennedy, one of the key figures in the
project, reported, that it suffered from changes in personnel, conflicts among key
stakeholders, and other problems.54 Sustaining such a highly complex, multidimensional effort, requires continuing administrative attention, and that is true of
all the recent smart policing innovations. CIRV responded to this challenge by
creating at the outset an organizational structure designed to institutionalize the
project and try to endure its continuity—and the results to date seem to justify
the wisdom of that approach.55
Bringing about a major innovation is policing is a major challenge. The old
cliché about “turning around a battleship” is often used to describe it. So, before
we celebrate the successes of focused deterrence too quickly, we need to be
conscious of the difficulties in implementing complex innovations and make
sure that we know how to make them endure over the long haul.
PREDICTIVE POLICING: SCIENCE OR JUST THE LATEST FAD?
There has been considerable buzz in the police world in the last few years about
something called “predictive policing.” Its advocates tout it as a great scientific
leap into a future where the police, using sophisticated data analysis, will be
able to predict when and where crimes will be committed, and as a result be
able to prevent them. Does this idea have any merit, or is it just the latest fad?
Some advocates of predictive policing argue that it is modeled after private
industry, where manufacturers and retailers use sophisticated data analyses to
predict the markets for their products. The development of data-driven policing
in the form of COMPSTAT and early intervention systems has created new possibilities for applying these techniques to policing. But can we actually predict
criminal activity so that police departments can respond proactively?56
The advocates of predictive policing cite some initial success stories. Richmond, Virginia, for example, had a problem with people celebrating New Year’s
Eve by firing guns into the air. Detroit and some other cities have had the same
problem. The analysis of data by the police department, it claimed, allowed it to
“anticipate the time, location and nature of future incidents.” By strategically
placing police officers on the basis of this data, the Richmond Police Department
reduced gunfire by 47 percent and increased gun seizures by 246 percent.57
One hardly needs to be a criminologist to ask, with regard to the Richmond
example, isn’t this really a matter of plain common sense? In fact, you don’t
really have to do any “data analysis” to be aware of the recurring New Year’s
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
118
CHAPTER
5
Eve gunfire. Tom Casady, the respected former police chief in Lincoln, Nebraska,
pointed this out, commenting that “This is pretty basic stuff, and we have been
doing this for years.” No other more credible examples have been offered by the
advocates of predictive policing.
In the era of evidence-based policy making, predictive policing lacks even the
most elementary evidence. It appears as commonsense policing wrapped in a fancy
package and surrounded with the aura of “science” and data-driven policing.
DRONES: THE POLICE PATROL OF THE FUTURE?
“The drones are coming to a neighborhood near you,” declared a New York
Times editorial on Christmas Day 2012.58 Will drones be the new form of police
patrol? Will they help reduce crime? Or will they be a massive invasion of
privacy, as opponents of their use in policing claim?
Several points are indisputable: drones are already here; the technology of
drones is advancing at warp speed; they have already been used in some law
enforcement situations; and there will be increasing pressure to increase their
application. They have the lure of the first patrol car in the early twentieth
century: they are incredibly efficient in their ability to cover a wide range of
territory at a relatively low cost (relative to a police officer in a patrol car, that
is). Some additional facts are relevant here. Congress authorized the development
of domestic use of drones in 2012 and the Department of Homeland Security
has developed plans for “public safety” drones, with as many as 30,000 drones
deployed by 2020. The Federal Aviation Agency has designated six sites to test
their safety. The FBI admitted in 2013 that it had received FAA clearance to use
domestic drones on at least four occasions between 2010 and 2013. In short,
drones are here.59
Domestic public safety drones raise many questions. Our concern in this
book is with crime reduction. Would the systematic use of drones by a local
police department be an effective crime reduction strategy? Would “drone
patrol” be a more effective deterrent to crime than traditional police patrol?
Would the knowledge that a drone equipped with surveillance cameras (and
presumably with zoom lens capability for close ups) might suddenly appear and
be able to follow you deter potential robbers and burglars? Would it deter drunk
driving because of its surveillance and recording capabilities? We don’t yet know.
There are good reasons for skepticism about the crime reduction potential of
domestic drones. It is likely that they would have little impact on interpersonal
crimes of violence. As we know, these crimes typically impulsive crime that
occur indoors, between people who know each other. The supposed “efficiency” of drones will be offset by their inherent inefficiencies. In fact, we have
been through this before in police history. The efficiency of the patrol car in
terms of geographic coverage was offset by the inefficiencies of the lost contact
between the police and the public. No one really noticed until the riots of the
1960s, when many argued that the police in African American neighborhoods
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
119
appeared as “occupying armies,” as some put it, with little contact with neighborhood residents. The community policing movement, in fact, sought to overcome
the loss of legitimacy of the police with strategies to establish productive working
relationships with neighborhoods. It is now generally accepted that the trust and
cooperation that results from closer police-citizen relationships has a direct payoff
in terms of crime fighting. It has been well-established that police crime-fighting
efforts depend on the cooperation of people, to report crimes and neighborhood
problems, to provide information about suspects, and to serve as witnesses. Drones
will produce none of that, and in that respect may undermine crime control.
In the end, we don’t know whether drones are the future of police patrol.
Local communities, worried about privacy issues, may forbid their police departments from using them. Or they may limit them to certain special events, such as
disasters. And as we have argued, even if widely used the readily apparent
efficiencies may be offset by important but less evident inefficiencies.
MORE DETECTIVES AND BETTER DETECTIVE WORK
Criminal investigation dominates the popular image of policing. Detectives are
the major subjects of television shows and movies about the police, to a far
greater degree than patrol work. Popular folklore holds that we could reduce
crime if we would just improve detective work: add more detectives, improve
training for detectives, and so on. Let’s look at the evidence on this subject.
Myths and Realities of Detective Work
Detective work is surrounded by myths perpetuated by the media and the police
themselves. Movies and television cop shows portray criminal investigation in
three different forms. One presents it as fast-paced, exciting, and dangerous
work with shootings, car chases, and confrontations with dangerous criminals.
In the classic 1950s television show Dragnet, Sgt. Joe Friday (Jack Webb) always
caught the offender through patient, dogged leg work. Today, the highly popular television show CSI emphasizes the forensic aspects of detective work. From
Dragnet to CSI, however, the media image of detectives is pure mythology.
The reality of criminal investigation is different from the popular image.
Most detective work is boring, unglamorous, and highly unproductive. Instead
of kicking in doors, ducking bullets, wrestling with dangerous sociopaths, or
solving scientific puzzles, detectives spend most of their time writing reports.
The overall clearance rate (the percentage of crimes solved by arrest) for Part I
Index crimes has always been around 20 percent; in 2011 it was 64.8 percent for
homicide, 41.2 percent for rape, 28.7 percent for robbery, and only 12.7 percent
for burglary and 11.9 percent for larceny.60
When the police do solve a crime, it is generally because the victim or a
witness knows the offender or can provide the first police officer on the scene
with a good lead about the perpetrator.61 In many acquaintance crimes (for example,
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
120
CHAPTER
5
assaults and rapes) the offender is still there when the police arrive, so that no real
“detective” work is required. This explains why between 60 and 80 percent of all
arrests are made by patrol officers instead of detectives.62
The importance of having a good lead at the beginning was documented
more than forty years ago in a pioneering study by the President’s Crime Commission. It analyzed 1,905 cases handled by the Los Angeles Police. As Figure 5.1
indicates, the LAPD cleared 86 percent of the 349 cases in which a suspect was
immediately identified by the victim or witness. But they cleared only 12 percent
of the remaining 1,556 cases in which no suspect was immediately identified.63
The key to solving crimes and making arrests, in short, is information about a
specific suspect. When the police begin with little or no information to work with,
the chances of clearing the crime are low. In other words, the odds of solving a
crime depend primarily on the characteristics of the crime rather than the number
of detectives or the amount of hours they devote to a case. Increasing the number of
detectives is not going to help if there is not a good lead to work with. Detectives
always complain about being overworked, and it is true that they are swamped with
cases. But lack of information rather than lack of time is the real problem.64
It is indeed true that detectives sometimes solve some crimes through
exhaustive detective work. We hear about them because they are rare events—
the celebrated cases we discussed in Chapter 2. The Rand study of criminal
investigation found that the typical case gets an average of about four hours’
work, and most of that involves paperwork.65
Named suspects
Unnamed suspects
Uncleared
Cases = 48
Rate = 14%
Uncleared
Cases = 1375
Rate = 88%
Cleared
Cases = 301
Rate = 86%
Cleared
Cases = 281
Rate = 12%
Total cases = 1905
Total clearance rate = 25%
F I G U R E 5.1 Clearance of crimes with named and unnamed suspects, Los Angeles Police
Department, 1966.
SOURCE: President’s Commission on Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice, Task Force Report: Science and
Technology (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1967), p. 8.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
121
Better training for detectives is not likely to increase the clearance rate. Even
the smartest and best-trained detective is not likely to solve a “cold” crime for
which there are no leads. The Rand study of criminal investigation found that
the quality of training made little difference in clearance rates between
departments.66 Training is not completely irrelevant, of course. An incompetent
detective can easily lose a case by bungling the interrogation or mishandling the
evidence. Skill does make a difference and training can improve skills. But this
assumes that there is a suspect or some evidence to begin with.
The Science of Crime Detection: Fingerprints
and Other Popular Myths
A major part of the mythology of detective work involves fingerprints and other
forms of scientific crime detection. Beginning in the 1930s, the FBI elevated fingerprints to near-mythical status as a method for solving of crimes. The Bureau
now has more than 200 million fingerprint cards on file, representing more than
70 million individuals. The mystique of fingerprints projected an image of the
FBI as an incredibly efficient agency—efficient because it was backed by the
massive weight of “science.”67
In reality, fingerprints are rarely the critical factor in solving crimes. It is
extremely difficult to get usable prints from a crime scene. The New York
City police obtain usable prints in only about 10 percent of all burglaries. And
in only 3 percent of those cases do the prints help with the arrest. In Long Beach,
California, a suspect was identified through fingerprints in only 1.5 percent of all
cases.68 The TV show CSI is great entertainment, but it seriously distorts the
reality of police work. Fingerprints, blood samples, and hair specimens are not
what solve most crimes. Information about a suspect does.
The problem with fingerprints, however, goes far deeper than the practical
matters of obtaining a print and matching it to a suspect. Law professor David
Harris argues that, contrary to popular belief and the arguments of the FBI and
other agencies, the fingerprint identification system does not really meet the
standards of science. The identification system goes by the acronym ACE-V
(for analyze, compare, evaluate, verify). The examiner determines that a print
has enough detail to be useful, notes the points of agreement between various
prints, and then determines whether there is a “match” between the new print
and a print on file. Verification involves a different examiner repeating the
process. The problem, Harris points out, is that there is no official standard in
the United States for the number of corresponding points between the new
print and a print on file to qualify for a match. Other countries, by comparison,
have a minimum number. Italy and France require sixteen matching characteristics, for example; in Brazil and Argentina the standard is thirty. In short, the
critical matching phase of fingerprint identification in the United States is highly
subjective. This is not science.69
Harris places fingerprints in the broader context of obtaining evidence
against a suspect. He argues that polygraphs, line-ups, and in-custody interrogations
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
122
CHAPTER
5
are fraught with problems of reliability. And in fact, the Innocence Project has
helped exonerate 310 wrongly convicted people since 1989 through DNA
evidence. (DNA does appear to be a scientific technology that is reliable.) People
were convicted, and in some cases given the death penalty, through erroneous
eyewitness identifications, false confessions that were obtained through police
manipulation, and other problems.70
The basic point is that we should not be mystified by the alleged “science”
of fingerprints and should expect the highest standards for all forms of police
evidence collection. Harris makes sixteen recommendations for needed change.
The National Academy of Sciences has also called for major reforms in its 2009
report Strengthening Forensic Science in the United States.71
In the end, we have to face an unpleasant truth. Arrest is the weakest point
in the criminal justice system, as we explained in Chapter 2. The other parts of
the system are actually quite productive. Only about 20 percent of reported
Index crimes are cleared by arrest, but about 50 percent of all arrests are
prosecuted and about 90 percent of prosecuted cases result in a conviction.
Unfortunately, there does not appear to be any way to increase the clearance
rate significantly. The ability of the police to solve crimes is determined primarily
by the nature of individual crimes, and in particular whether there is a good lead
about a suspect. The evidence leads to our next proposition:
9
PROPOSITION
More detectives, or other changes in detective work, will not raise clearance
rates or lower the crime rate.
ELIMINATE THE “TECHNICALITIES”
Conservatives firmly believe that the courts have “handcuffed” the police with
procedural rules that limit their power to investigate and solve crimes. According to this view, these technicalities of criminal procedure allow streetwise
criminals to “beat the system” and avoid punishment. At issue are the Supreme
Court decisions affirming the constitutional rights of criminal suspects and
limiting police powers. The two most famous decisions, Mapp (1961) and
Miranda (1966), coincided with the great increase in crime between the early
1960s and early 1970s, and many people blamed the court for that development.72 Have court decisions limiting police powers been responsible for
letting criminals “go free” and as a result causing high crime rates? Let’s take
a look at the evidence.
Repeal the Exclusionary Rule?
The Supreme Court established the exclusionary rule in the 1961 Mapp v. Ohio
decision. The court held that “all evidence obtained by searches and seizures in
violation of the Constitution is, by that same authority, inadmissible in a state
court.”73 Prosecutors cannot use evidence obtained in violation of the Fourth
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
123
Amendment’s guarantee of “the right of the people to be secure in their persons,
houses, papers, and effects, against unreasonable searches and seizures.” Evidence
obtained illegally is “excluded,” or inadmissible in court.74
Mapp produced a storm of controversy that continues today. Critics argue
that the exclusionary rule has limited the ability of the police to gather evidence
necessary to convict criminals. Actually, the exclusionary rule was nothing new
in 1961. The Supreme Court had applied it to federal proceedings in 1914
(Weeks v. United States) and by 1961 it was already in effect in more than half
of the states, mainly through decisions by state supreme courts. Mapp simply
applied the exclusionary rule to all the states through the Due Process Clause
of the Fourteenth Amendment. The exclusionary rule has always evoked far
more outrage than the equally famous Miranda warning. Miranda excludes
confessions that have been obtained improperly. Even many law-and-order
advocates concede that a coerced confession is wrong. But the Mapp exclusionary rule applies to physical evidence that speaks for itself, no matter how it was
obtained.
The conservative argument regarding the exclusionary rule is that many
criminal cases are “lost” because of it. With the crucial evidence excluded, the
defendant (always called a criminal by critics of the rule) goes free and is able to
pursue his or her criminal activity. Studies of the impact of the exclusionary rule
have found that it has virtually no impact on the crime-fighting capacity of the
police. James J. Fyfe concluded that the impact is “minuscule” and “infinitesimal,”75 with few cases lost because of excluded evidence.
When we consider the realities of police work, we can understand why the
exclusionary rule has such a limited impact on police crime-fighting. As we
pointed out previously, the police solve crimes when they immediately obtain
a good lead about a suspect, from either the victim or a witness. Physical
evidence, independent of some other kind of identification of the suspect, is
rarely the primary factor in arresting and convicting an offender. True, it is
often important secondary, supporting evidence, but not the primary factor.
The limited impact of the exclusionary rule is mainly confined to drug possession, weapons possession, and gambling cases. It is easy to see why. The most
important element of a drug possession case is whether the defendant actually
had the drugs and how the police obtained the evidence. Robbery cases, on
the other hand, are more likely to depend on eyewitness identification of the
suspect. Physical evidence is rarely the crucial factor.
Once in court, few defendants try to use the exclusionary rule, and even
fewer succeed. Procedurally, the defense attorney asks the court to exclude or
suppress the evidence. Judges have the discretion to grant or deny the motion.
Peter F. Nardulli found that motions to suppress physical evidence were made in
fewer than 5 percent of all cases and were successful in only 0.69 percent of the
total. A General Accounting Office study of the federal courts found that
motions to suppress evidence were filed in only 11 percent of all cases and that
between 80 and 90 percent of those were denied. Finally, a study of search
warrants by the National Center for State Courts showed that only 5 percent
of all motions to suppress were successful.76
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
124
CHAPTER
5
Defense lawyers file motions to suppress evidence because they have a
professional obligation to represent their clients’ interests. Not filing such
motions might raise questions about their competence. Most of the time,
however, they are just going through the motions, if you will pardon the expression. They are not the “crafty” lawyers of popular folklore. Most felony cases are
handled by public defenders who are conscientious but extremely overworked.
They have little time to devote to any one case, and in some jurisdictions they
meet their clients only moments before entering the courtroom.
Even when a motion to exclude evidence succeeds, the defendant will not
necessarily go free. He or she can still be convicted on other evidence. If an
appeals court overturns a conviction under the exclusionary rule, the prosecutor
can refile charges on the basis of the remaining evidence. A study of search
warrant cases found that twelve of the seventeen defendants (70 percent) who
succeeded in having evidence suppressed were subsequently convicted on other
charges.77
Judges vary greatly in their willingness to invoke the exclusionary rule.
Sheldon Krantz and his colleagues found in their study of Boston that one
judge granted 45.4 percent of the motions to suppress, whereas another granted
only 22.2 percent. Three judges denied all motions presented to them. Motions
to suppress were successful in only 2 percent of all the gambling and drug cases
that Krantz and colleagues studied.78
A controversial 1982 study by the National Institute of Justice produced a
much higher estimate of the rule’s impact. It claimed that in 520,993 felony
arrests in California between 1976 and 1979 prosecutors rejected cases for various
reasons. Illegally obtained evidence accounted for 4,130 of those rejections. The
Justice Department then claimed that the 4,130 represented 4.8 percent of the
86,033 rejections.79 In a pair of stinging critiques, Thomas Y. Davies and James
J. Fyfe each argued that it was more accurate to consider the 4,130 rejections as
a percentage of the original 520,993 cases, which yields a rejection rate of only
0.8 percent (a figure that is close to other studies).80
In short, the exclusionary rule does not let “thousands” of dangerous
criminals loose on the streets, and it has almost no effect on violent crime.
True, some defendants succeed in having their cases dismissed because of the
exclusionary rule. And some (perhaps even most) are factually guilty of the
crimes they were charged with. But these are rare events, the classic celebrated
cases we discussed in Chapter 2.
In passing, we should take note of the positive aspects of the exclusionary
rule. Far from impairing police work, it has helped to improve the professionalism of the police. Myron Orfield’s study of narcotics officers in Chicago found
that the exclusionary rule provoked a number of significant reforms. The
Chicago police and the Illinois state attorney’s office developed a closer working
relationship, the state attorney scrutinized applications for warrants more closely,
and the police department improved its own training and supervision of officers.
The result was better police work. Interviews with Chicago narcotics detectives
found that they supported the rule and were concerned that weakening it would
open the door to police abuse. Officers said that the experience of having
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
125
evidence excluded in court was a valuable learning experience—the best onthe-job training they ever got.81 Many thoughtful law enforcement executives
now accept and even welcome the rule. Former FBI Director William Sessions
said that “protections that are afforded by the exclusionary rule are extremely
important to fair play and the proper carrying out of the law enforcement
responsibility.”82
Abolish the Miranda Warning
The Miranda warning is the second major so-called technicality that conservatives
believe handcuffs the police. The 1966 Miranda v. Arizona decision held that to
ensure a suspect’s Fifth Amendment protection against self-incrimination, the
police must advise a criminal suspect of certain rights: Before any questioning,
the person must be warned that he or she has a right to remain silent, that any
statement he or she does make may be used against him or her, and that he or
she has a right to the presence of an attorney, either retained or appointed.83
Conservatives have been angry about Miranda ever since. In the original
decision, Justice Byron White spoke for them in his dissenting opinion when
he wrote that it “return[s] a killer, a rapist or other criminal to the streets and
to the environment which produced him, to repeat his crime whenever it pleases
him.” Other opponents have repeated this criticism for more than forty years.84
Almost a half century later, the Miranda warning is the most widely known
and probably most misunderstood element of police procedure. Hollywood and
television writers love it. The warning adds a special dramatic complication to
the plot. In one movie, a narcotics detective wrestles the suspect to the ground
with one arm while reading from the Miranda warning card he holds in the other
hand. Get it? The police have one hand tied behind their backs. A 1991 public
opinion poll on the 200th anniversary of the Bill of Rights found that although
only 10 percent knew why it was originally adopted, 80 percent knew about
their right to remain silent if arrested.85 A recent book observed that “School
children are more likely to recognize the Miranda warnings than the Gettysburg
Address.”86
Does the Miranda warning really handcuff the police? First, let’s clear up a
few myths about the decision. The Miranda warning does not have to be given at
the moment of arrest but only before questioning. If a suspect blurts out a
confession (“Why did I do it?”), the confession is admissible. Also, a suspect
can waive his or her rights by agreeing to talk and agreeing to do so without a
lawyer. In fact, many suspects do waive their rights.
Paul G. Cassell, a strong critic of Miranda, and Bret S. Hayman properly raise
the question of how we should measure the impact (or the “cost”) of Miranda.
They make a persuasive argument that we should not look at the number of
convictions overturned because of a Miranda violation, but the number of
confessions the police do not get. Surveying all of the studies done to date,
they estimate that the rate of confessions has declined by 16 percent because of
Miranda. But that is not the whole story, because some offenders are convicted
even without a confession. The authors estimate that confessions are needed in
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
126
CHAPTER
5
about 24 percent of all cases. Thus, in their calculation the net effect is that
Miranda results in a “loss” of convictions in 3.8 percent of all cases (16 percent
of 24 percent = 3.8 percent). Despite Cassell and Hayman’s own claims,
however, this is not a significant impact.87
Stephen J. Schulhofer argues that Cassell and Hayman’s analysis suffers from
a number of methodological flaws. One of the more serious is their failure to
take into account the fact that confession rates were dropping in the years before
Miranda, for reasons unrelated to the decision. Factoring in a continuation of this
trend and adding in the effect of other methodological problems, Schulhofer
estimates that the loss resulting from Miranda is not 3.8 percent but less than 1
percent (0.78). “For all practical purposes,” he concludes, “Miranda’s empirically
detectable net damage to law enforcement is zero.”88
The best study of Miranda in operation is Richard Leo’s “Inside the Interrogation Room,” in which he directly observed a total of 182 police interrogations
in three police departments. He found that 78 of the suspects waived their Miranda
rights and cooperated with the police. As a result, two-thirds (64 percent) made a
full confession, a partial confession, or some incriminating statement. What tactics
did the police use to get them to cooperate? In more than 80 percent of the cases,
the police either confronted them with evidence of their guilt or appealed to their
self-interest (for example, it will help you if you talk), or both.89
In short, the Miranda warning was no great barrier to the police obtaining
confessions. In the vast majority of the cases, the police got suspects to waive
their rights and confess or make an incriminating statement, and they did so
through lawful means. It should be noted, however, that in 30 percent of the
cases, the police lied by confronting the suspects with false information about
their guilt, as in falsely telling them that their partner had confessed. This evidence supports keeping the Miranda warning.
Why do so many suspects waive their rights and confess? Why do only
about 20 percent of suspects take advantage of their right to remain silent? The
first point is that the police do not arrest many suspects. They clear only about
29 percent of all robberies and 13 percent of all burglaries. Thus, they usually
have some evidence against the few suspects they do arrest. This leaves a small
group of cases in which there is reasonably good evidence. And as Leo discovered, detectives confront 85 percent of all suspects with evidence of their guilt.
The suspects in these remaining cases have powerful incentives to cooperate and
confess. They know that they committed the crime, and they realize that the
police have some fairly good evidence against them. A lot of them feel guilty
about it. Leo found that detectives appealed to suspects’ consciences in 23 percent
of all cases. Some suspects who confess hope to get a better deal in a plea bargaining. The detectives in Leo’s study appealed to the suspects’ self-interest in
88 percent of the cases.90
The image of the tough, streetwise criminal who is skilled at manipulating
the rules is another myth. Some suspects do invoke their Miranda rights, but the
majority cooperate with the police. Felony suspects are typically young, poorly
educated, and in many instances functionally illiterate. Most failed to learn how
to manipulate the public school bureaucracy to their advantage, and they are not
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
127
much more successful in the criminal justice system. The typical robber or burglar is so disorganized and impulsive that he does not even plan his crimes well.
The Rand Inmate Survey found that 40 percent of the juvenile robbers and 25
percent of the adults had not even intended to rob anyone when they left home.
As one kid put it, “It was just a sudden thing. I didn’t really mean to do it. I
didn’t plan nothing; it just happened.” Among the adult career criminals,
only 40 percent bothered to visit the sites of their crimes in advance, and as
few as 22 percent made an effort to check on police patrol in the area.91 In
custody, young offenders may strike a tough pose, but it is usually nothing
more than that—a pose, an act. A skilled professional detective can get most
suspects to talk.
10
PROPOSITION
The Supreme Court rulings in Mapp and Miranda are not significant barriers
to effective crime control by the police.
CONCLUSION
The police are the front line of the criminal justice system. Patrol is the primary
strategy for preventing crime, and arrest is the “gate-keeping” point for all
criminal cases. Many people believe that we could reduce crime significantly
if we would just unleash the cops: give them more resources and more powers.
We have found that these ideas are not likely to reduce crime.
The good news is that promising programs that involve carefully planned,
focused, evidence-based strategies, such as hot spots and problem-oriented
policing programs, have proven successful in several experiments. The significance of these programs goes far beyond policing. As we will find in the chapters
ahead, similarly focused, problem-oriented programs—such as drug courts and
community prosecution—have also shown promising results. These successes
provide the foundation for a potentially comprehensive approach to crime and
disorder.
NOTES
1 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table 2.28.2010.
2 On the history of the U.S. police and the influence of Robert Peel, see Samuel
Walker, Popular Justice: A History of American Criminal Justice, 2nd ed. (New York:
Oxford University Press, 1998).
3 Federal Bureau of Investigation, “Police Employee Data,” Crime in the United States
2011 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice 2012).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
128
CHAPTER
5
4 John Eck and Edward Maguire, “Have Changes in Policing Reduced Violent
Crime? An Assessment of the Evidence,” in Alfred Blumstein and Joel Wallman,
eds., The Crime Drop in America (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000),
210–214, especially Table 7.1.
5 George L. Kelling, Tony Pate, Duane Diekman, and Charles E. Brown, The Kansas
City Preventive Patrol Experiment: A Summary Report (Washington, DC: The Police
Foundation, 1974).
6 The Police Foundation, The Newark Foot Patrol Experiment (Washington, DC: The
Police Foundation, 1981).
7 Ibid.
8 David Boyum and Peter Reuter, An Analytic Assessment of US Drug Policy
(Washington, DC: AEI Press, 2005).
9 James Q. Wilson and Alan Abrahamse, “Does Crime Pay?” Justice Quarterly 9
(September 1992): 372–373.
10 New York Civil Liberties Union, “Who’s Watching” Video Camera Surveillance in
New York City and the Need for Public Oversight (New York: NYCLU, 2006).
11 Aundreia Camerono, Elke Kolodinski, Heather May, and Nicholas Williams,
Measuring the Effects of Video Surveillance on Crime in Lost Angeles (Los Angeles: School
of Policy, Planning, and Development, 2008).
12 Brandon C. Welsh and David P. Farrington, “Effects of Closed-Circuit Television
on Crime,” Annals 587 (May 2003): 110–135. Brandon C. Welsh and David P.
Farrington, Effects of Closed Circuit Television Surveillance on Crime, The Campbell
Collaboration, Campbell Systematic Reviews 2008:17 (last updated December 2,
2008).
13 Lawrence W. Sherman, “Police Crackdowns,” in Michael Tonry and Norval
Morris, eds., Crime and Justice: An Annual Preview of Research, vol. 12 (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1990), pp. 1–48.
14 Lynn Zimmer, “Proactive Policing against Street-Level Drug Trafficking,” American
Journal of Police 9 (no. 1, 1990): 43–74.
15 Jerome H. Skolnick and James J. Fyfe, Above the Law: Police and the Excessive Use of
Force (New York: Free Press, 1993), 206–207.
16 Terry v. Ohio, 392 U.S. 1 (1968).
17 Nancy La Vigne, Pamela Lachman, Andrea Matthews, and S. Rebecca Neusteter,
eds., Key Issues in the Police Use of Pedestrian Stops and Searches: Discussion Papers from
an Urban Institute Roundtable (Washington, DC: Urban Institute, 2012).
18 New York City Police Department, 2011 Reasonable Suspicion Stops: Precinct Based
Comparison by Stop and Frisk Description (New York: New York City Police
Department, 2012). New York Civil Liberties Union, Stop and Frisk 2011: NYCLU
Briefing (New York: New York Civil Liberties Union, 2012).
19 The NYPD has historical crime data from 2000 on its website. For data from 1960
to 2011: http://disastercenter.com/crime/nycrime.htm. Accessed February 13, 2014.
20 Joseph Ferrandino, “The Efficiency of Frisks in the NYPD, 2004–2010,” Criminal
Justice Review 38 (2): 149–168.
21 Jack R. Greene, “Police Field Stops: What Do We Know, and What Does It
Mean?” in La Vigne, et al., eds., Key Issues in the Police Use of Pedestrian Stops and
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
129
Searches, p. 17. Bernard Harcourt, Illusion of Order: The False Promise of Broken
Windows Policing (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2001), 90–120.
John E. Boydston, San Diego Field Interrogations: Final Report (Washington, DC: The
Police Foundation, 1975). Greene, “Police Field Stops: What Do We Know, and
What Does it Mean?” in La Vigne, et al., eds., Key Issues in the Police Use of Pedestrian
Stops and Searches, 12–23.
Ferrandino, “The Efficiency of Frisks in the NYPD, 2004–2010.”
Recently published studies on the crime decline in New York City are available at:
www.cuny.edu/crimedecline. Accessed February 13, 2014.
Jennifer Fratello, Andres F. Rengifo, and Jennifer Trone,, Coming of Age with Stop
and Frisk: Experiences, Self-Perceptions, and Public Safety Implications (New York: Vera
Institute of Justice, 2013).
William Spelman and Dale K. Brown, Calling the Police Citizen Reporting of Serious
Crime (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1984).
Ibid.
Wesley G. Skogan and Kathleen Frydl, eds., Fairness and Effectiveness in Policing: The
Evidence (Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 2004), 226–227.
See the Smart Policing Initiative website: http://www.smartpolicinginitiative.com/.
Accessed February 13, 2014.
For a broader discussion of these new elements in policing, see Samuel Walker, The
New World of Police Accountability, 2nd ed. (Newbury Park: Sage, 2014).
David Bayley, Police for the Future(New York: Oxford University Press, 1994), 101.
Franklin E. Zimring, The City That Became Safe: New York’s Lessons for Urban Crime
and its Control (New York: Oxford University Press, 2012).
Herman Goldstein, Problem-Oriented Policing (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1990).
Michael S. Scott, Problem-Oriented Policing: Reflections on the First Twenty Years
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2000).
Lorraine Green, “Cleaning Up Drug Hot Spots in Oakland, California: The
Displacement and Diffusion Effects,” Justice Quarterly 12 (December 1995): 737–754.
Lawrence W. Sherman, Patrick R. Gartin, and Michael E. Buerger, “Hot Spots of
Predatory Crime: Routine Activities and the Criminology of Place,” Criminology 27
(1989): 27–55.
Anthony A. Braga and Brenda J. Bond, “Policing Crime and Disorder Hot Spots: A
Randomized Control Trial,” Criminology 46:3 (2008): 576–607.
David Weisburd, Laura A. Wycoff, Justin Ready, John Eck, Joshua C. Hinckle, and
Frank Gajewski, “Does Crime Just Move Around the Corner? A Controlled Study
of Spatial Displacement and Diffusion of Crime Control Benefits,” Criminology 44:3
(2006): 549–591.
Scott, Problem-Oriented Policing Reflections on the First Twenty Years.
William J. Bratton and Peter Knoblauch, Turnaround: How America’s Top Cop
Reversed the Crime Epidemic (New York: Random House, 1998). Minneapolis Police
Department: http://www.ci.minneapolis.mn.us/police/. Hyunseok Jang, Larry T.
Hoover, and Hee-Jong Joo, “An Evaluation of Compstat’s Effect on Crime: The
Fort Worth Experience,” Police Quarterly 13 (4): 387–412.
Jang, Hoover, and Joo, “An Evaluation of Compstat’s Effect on Crime: The Fort
Worth Experience,” Accessed February 13, 2014. See N. 39.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
130
CHAPTER
5
41 Franklin E. Zimring, The Great American Crime Decline (New York: Oxford
University Press, 2007), 149–150.
42 Zimring, The Great American Crime Decline.
43 K. Jack Riley, Crack, Powder Cocaine, and Heroin Drug Purchase and Use Patterns in Six
US Cities. NCJ 167265 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1997); For an
examination of the declining appeal of crack cocaine, see R. Terry Furst, Bruce D.
Johnson, Eloise Dunlap, and Richard Curtis, “The Stigmatized Image of the ‘Crack
Head’: A Sociocultural Exploration of a Barrrier to Cocaine Smoking among a
Cohort of Youth in New York City,” Deviant Behavior, 20 (1999): 153–181.
44 Jang, Hoover and Joo, “An Evaluation of Compstat’s Effect on Crime,” 405.
45 George L. Kelling and Catherine M. Coles, Fixing Broken Windows: Restoring Order
and Reducing Crime in Our Communities (New York: Martin Kessler Books, 1996).
46 The best discussion of the changes in the New York City Police Department and
their impact on crime is Zimring, The City That Became Safe: New York City’s Lessons
for Urban Crime and its Control.
47 Hyunseok Jang, Larry T. Hoover, and Hee-Jong Joo. “An Evaluation of Compstat’s
Effect on Crime: the Fort Worth Experience,” Police Quarterly 13 (no. 4, 2010):
387–412.
48 Ibid., 405.
49 John A. Eterno and Eli B. Silverman, “The NYPD’s Compstat: Compare Statistics
or Compose Statistics?,” International Journal of Police Science and Management 12
(No. 3, 2010): 426–449.
50 Anthony A. Braga and David L. Weisburd, “The Effects of Focused Deterrence
Strategies on Crime: A Systematic Review and Meta-Analysis of the Empirical
Evidence,” Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency (2011): 1–36.
51 David M. Kennedy, Anthony A. Braga, and Anne M. Piehl, Reducing Gun Violence
The Boston Gun Project’s Operation Ceasefire (Washington, DC: Department of Justice,
2001). NCJ 188741.
52 Robin S. Engel, Marie Skubak Tillyer, and Nicholas Corsaro, “Reducing Gang
Violence Using Focused Deterrence: Evaluating the Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce
Violence (CIRV),” Justice Quarterly 30 (3): 403–439.
53 Samuel Walker, “Institutionalizing Police Accountability Reforms: The Problem of
Making Police Reforms Endure,” St. Louis University Public Law Review XXXII (No. 1,
2012): 57–92.
54 David M. Kennedy, Don’t Shoot: One Man, a Street Fellowship, and the End of Violence
in Inner-City America (New York: Bloomsbury, 2011).
55 Kennedy, Don’t Shoot: One Man, a Street Fellowship, and the End of Violence in InnerCity America, 147. Engel, et al., “Reducing Gang Violence Using Focused
Deterrence: Evaluating the Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce Violence (CIRV).”
56 On data-driven policing, see Walker, The New World of Police Accountability.
57 Beth Pearsall, “Predictive Policing: The Future of Law Enforcement?” NIJ Journal,
No. 266 (June 2010), 16–19.
58 “The Dawning of Domestic Drones,” The New York Times, December 25, 2012.
59 Peter Singer, Wired for War Military Robots and the Laws of War (New York: Penguin,
200).
60 Federal Bureau of Investigation, Crime in the United States 2011.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
UNLEASH THE COPS!
131
61 Wesley Skogan and George Antunes, “Information, Apprehension, and Deterrence:
Exploring the Limits of Police Productivity,” Journal of Criminal Justice 1 (Fall 1979): 217–
241.
62 Albert J. Reiss, The Police and the Public (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press,
1971), 104.
63 President’s Commission on Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice, Task
Force Report: Science and Technology (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office,
1967), 8.
64 John E. Eck, Solving Crimes: “The Investigation of Burglary and Robbery” (Washington,
DC: Police Executive Research Forum, 1983).
65 Peter Greenwood, The Criminal Investigation Process (Santa Monica, CA: Rand,
1975).
66 Greenwood, Criminal Investigation Process.
67 David A. Harris, Failed Evidence: Why Law Enforcement Resists Science (New York:
NYU Press, 2012).
68 Joan Petersilia, “Processing Latent Fingerprints—What Are the Payoffs?” Journal of
Police Science and Administration 6 (June 1978): 157–167.
69 Harris, Failed Evidence, 24–30.
70 The Innocence Project website is www.innocenceproject.org. Accessed February
13, 2014.
71 Harris, Failed Evidence, 130–155. National Academy of Sciences, Strengthening
Forensic Science in the United States (Washington, DC: National Academies Press,
2009).
72 Walker, Popular Justice A History of American Criminal Justice, 2nd ed., 180–193.
73 Mapp v. Ohio, 367 U.S. 643 (1961).
74 Ibid.
75 James J. Fyfe, “The NIJ Study of the Exclusionary Rule,” Criminal Law Bulletin 19
(May–June 1983): 253–260.
76 Peter F. Nardulli, “The Societal Costs of the Exclusionary Rule: An Empirical
Assessment,” American Bar Foundation Research Journal 1983 (Summer 1983): 585–
690; Comptroller General of the United States, Impact of the Exclusionary Rule on
Federal Criminal Prosecutions, Report #GGD-79-45 (April 19, 1979); National
Center for State Courts, The Search Warrant Process (Williamsburg, VA: National
Center for State Courts, 1986).
77 National Center for State Courts, Search Warrant Process.
78 Sheldon Krantz, Bernard Gilman, Charles G. Benda, Carol Rogoff Hallstrom, and
Gail J. Nadworny, Police Policymaking (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1979),
189–192.
79 National Institute of Justice, The Effects of the Exclusionary Rule A Study in California
(Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1982).
80 Fyfe, “The NIJ Study of the Exclusionary Rule”; Thomas Y. Davies, “A Hard Look
at What We Know (and Still Need to Learn) about the ‘Costs’ of the Exclusionary
Rule: The NIJ Study and Other Studies of ‘Lost’ Arrests,” American Bar Foundation
Research Journal 3 (Summer 1983): 611–690.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
132
CHAPTER
5
81 Myron W. Orfield, Jr., “The Exclusionary Rule and Deterrence: An Empirical
Study of Chicago Narcotics Officers,” University of Chicago Law Review 54 (Summer
1987): 1016–1055.
82 Sessions quoted in New York Times, 5 November 1987.
83 Miranda v. Arizona, 384 U.S. 436 (1966).
84 An invaluable collection of articles on the subject is Richard Leo and George C.
Thomas, III, eds., The Miranda Debate Law, Justice, and Policing (Boston: Northeastern
University Press, 1998).
85 “Poll Finds Only 33% Can Identify Bill of Rights,” New York Times, 15 December
1991.
86 Paul G. Cassell and Bret S. Hayman, “Police Interrogation in the 1990s: An
Empirical Study of the Effects of Miranda,” UCLA Law Review 43 (February 1996):
860. Paul G. Cassell, “Miranda’s Social Costs: An Empirical Reassessment,”
Northwestern University Law Review 90 (Winter 1996): 387–499.
87 Leo and Thomas, eds., Miranda Debate, xv.
88 Stephen J. Schulhofer, “Miranda’s Practical Effect: Substantial Benefits and
Vanishingly Small Social Costs,” in Leo and Thomas, eds., Miranda Debate, 205.
89 Richard A. Leo, “Inside the Interrogation Room,” Journal of Criminal Law and
Criminology 86 (1996): 266–303. For a full discussion of interrogations and other
“scientific” investigation techniques, see Richard A. Leo, Police Interrogation and
American Justice (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2008).
90 Leo, Police Interrogation and American Justice.
91 Joan Petersilia, Peter W. Greenwood, and Martin Lavin, The Criminal Careers of
Habitual Felons (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1978).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
6
Deter the Criminals
C
ops on the streets deter crime. More cops, therefore, must deter crime more
effectively. Right? Not really. The threat of long prison sentences also deters
criminals. Right? Maybe, or maybe not. The threat of a prison sentence for
drunk driving deters people from driving while drunk. Right? Possibly, but
probably not. We have already discussed the theory of deterrence in Chapter 5
with regard to police patrol. Now let’s take a broader view of the subject.
Deterrence is an article of faith among conservatives: Punishment deters
crime; swifter, more certain, and more severe punishments will reduce crime
more effectively than current policies. We are going to violate our own ground
rules a little in this chapter and discuss some issues that fall outside our primary
focus on robbery and burglary, including the death penalty and drunk driving.
We do this because both cases offer important some evidence about deterrence.
The issue of drunk driving, moreover, is a good example of how addressing a
social problem with noncriminal justice responses can be effective. We will also
take another look at the promising new evidence on focused deterrence, which
we discussed in Chapter 5. This will help clarify why the focused element of
these programs is more effective than traditional deterrence ones.
DETERRENCE THEORY
The theory of deterrence has a simple, intuitive appeal. People want to avoid
unpleasant experiences, so if we make the punishment for crime more unpleasant, fewer people will commit crime. The basic theory is simple, however,
applying it in practice is complicated. The underlying assumptions do not necessarily work in the real world of criminal justice.1
To get started, we need to distinguish between the general deterrent effect of
the criminal law, on one hand, and the more limited deterrent intent of particular
policies or programs on the other. The criminal law certainly has some general
deterrent effect on our behavior, but it is only one part of a broader structure of
133
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
134
CHAPTER
6
social control. The law defines the boundaries of acceptable behavior and the consequences of breaking the law. Most of us do not commit serious crimes; we are not
murderers, robbers, or burglars. This is a result of our socialization: the influence of
our parents, religious upbringing, education, peer group, close friends, the positive
opportunities available to us, and so on. The justice system’s threat of punishment
reinforces our behavior because the criminal law expresses our values: it is wrong to
kill, and wrong to take something that does not belong to us. For most of us, however, obedience to the law has become an unconscious habit. After all, how many
of us ever sit around thinking about how much time in prison we might get for
committing a robbery or a burglary? We don’t because we don’t even think about
stealing something from our neighbors, or worse. The important point here is that
the criminal law can be effective in reinforcing established behavior; it is not clear
that it can be effective as the primary or the sole influence on peoples’ behavior.
The crime problem is that some people are not well socialized; they lack selfcontrol, are impulsive, and are lured by the immediate gratification of the money
from a robbery. The habit of obeying the law is not as deeply ingrained for them
as it is with most of us. Deterrence theory enters the picture at this point as a strategy
for influencing the behavior of the less-well socialized. Think back to Wolfgang’s
birth cohort. We want to influence that 35 percent of the cohort that had one contact with the police. Common sense suggests that those who have one contact will
be relatively easy to influence, by one means or another. Those with two to four
contacts will be harder to influence, and those with five more (the so-called “career
criminals”) will be hard to change, if we can change them at all.
The specific goal of all crime control policies is, as we have emphasized, to
improve on what we are currently doing. And so we expect that of deterrenceoriented policies. Daniel Nagin explains that the real issue of deterrence is “whether
a specific policy, grafted onto the existing structure, will materially add to the preventive effect.”2 Are there policies that will reduce serious crime from its current
level? Are there some policies that are more effective in that regard than others? As
we will see, there is a lack of clear and convincing evidence about policies that, from
a deterrence perspective, produce real, long-term reductions in crime. To understand why we should be skeptical about the added deterrent effect of any criminal
justice policy, let’s examine the assumptions underlying deterrence.
Assumptions Underlying Deterrence
The theory of deterrence involves a number of basic assumptions. As we noted
in Chapter 5, deterrence theory operates in the realm of social psychology. It
assumes the existence of an information loop involving peoples’ knowledge, perception, and response to the potential punishment for a crime, and in particular a
change in the level of punishment. First, potential offenders have to be aware of
the threat. They have to know, for example, that a new law imposes a mandatory jail or prison term for a first-offense conviction for drunk driving or that a
new law requires a mandatory ten-year prison term for a conviction of drug possession. If someone does not know about a new harsh sentencing requirement
there will be no added deterrent effect.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
135
Second, potential offenders have to perceive the consequences of lawbreaking as
unpleasant and something to be avoided. They have to believe that arrest, prosecution,
conviction, imprisonment, and having a criminal record would be bad for them. If
arrests and imprisonment are common events in some communities (which is in fact
the case among low-income African American males), the stigma is far weaker, if it
exists at all, than for other groups in society and the added deterrent effect is lost.
Third, they have to believe there is a real risk of arrest, conviction, and punishment. If they believe that the risk of arrest and punishment is low, they will
not be deterred. As Scott Decker and his colleagues point out, “Deterrence is
essentially a psychological process that involves the balancing of personally held
beliefs about possible punishment and anticipated gain.”3 Criminologists who
believe in deterrence emphasize the need to increase the certainty and severity
of punishment to drive home the message of both the risk and the unpleasantness
of doing crime. This is one of the reasons why advocates of the death penalty,
for example, object to the endless appeals for people on death row. Because it
extends the time between the crime and the punishment, they argue, it weakens
the connection between the crime and the punishment.
Fourth, and perhaps most important, deterrence theory assumes that people
are rational actors who weigh the relative costs and benefits of their actions and
make conscious decisions about the best course. Many economists who do
research on criminal justice embrace deterrence theory because it involves their
favorite economic theory, rational choice, which holds that changing the costs or
benefits can influence human behavior. Thus, if we raise the cost of crime by
making punishment more certain or more severe, we will influence people to
recalculate the new balance between possible gains versus possible pain, and as
a result choose not to commit crime. As we shall see shortly, a major problem
with deterrence, of course, is that some people do not act rationally.
Finally, we have to consider the element of legitimacy, which has gained
increased importance in criminal justice. Legitimacy holds that people are more
likely to obey the law if they respect and trust the criminal justice system, particularly the police. Under the principles of procedural justice, people are more likely to
believe the criminal justice system is legitimate if they feel they are treated fairly, are
respected, have situations explained to them (such as, why a police officer stopped
them), and have an opportunity to express their own interpretation of a situation. If
as a result of bad experiences with the police and/or the courts people do not
believe the criminal justice system is legitimate, they are not likely to respect any
deterrent messages the law sends out.
Deterrence operates in two ways, depending on the target audience. Specific
deterrence is directed at the individual offender or potential offender. The threat of
punishment is to encourage that person to make a rational decision to obey the law
rather than break it. General deterrence is directed at the society as a whole. Punishing
a few criminals is designed to communicate a message to the larger audience.4
With respect to the objectives we set out in Chapter 1 of this book, there is an
important distinction between absolute and marginal deterrence. No one really
believes in absolute deterrence: that a particular punishment threat will completely
deter crime or a particular crime. Instead, we think in terms of marginal deterrence:
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
136
CHAPTER
6
a relative improvement over what we are currently achieving.5 As we explained in
Chapter 1, we should think in terms of adding relatively small reductions in crime
from different crime policies to achieve an aggregate large reduction in crime.
Deterrence theory was out of favor among criminologists for decades, but
then enjoyed a tremendous revival in the 1980s. The revival was not confined
to criminal justice policy, and rational choice theory became a popular topic in
many of the social sciences in the 1980s, particularly economics.6 It was especially influential in economic theory and many aspects of social policy. Conservative welfare reform policies, for example, rest on the assumption that
traditional welfare programs provided too few incentives for finding employment. Cutting welfare benefits and putting a cap on the number of years of eligibility, conservatives argue, encourages people to find employment and get off
welfare.7 Rational choice theory continues to be a vigorous part of criminological theory today (although it does have its critics).8 Daniel Nagin in 2007 argued
for “Moving Choice to Center Stage in Criminological Research and Theory.”9
As we explained in Chapter 1, people are not always consistent in their attitude
toward deterrence. Although deterrence theory is generally favored by conservatives,
liberals accept it on certain issues. Some liberals, for example, believe that the exclusionary rule (Mapp v. Ohio) deters illegal searches and seizures by police officers and
that citizen review of complaints against the police will deter police misconduct. Conservatives, meanwhile, reject the idea that gun control laws will deter gun violence.10
FROM THEORY TO PRACTICE: DETERRENCE IN THE REAL
WORD OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE
There are several reasons why deterrence-oriented policies do not necessarily
work in practice.11 The National Academy of Sciences established a distinguished panel to review the evidence on deterrence and the death penalty, and
the panel’s 2012 report was devastating, concluding that the research evidence is
inconclusive about “whether capital punishment decreases, increases, or has no
effect on homicide rates.”12 It also faulted most of the research for some significant methodological failings (which we will discuss shortly). The research on the
death penalty is particularly important because that issue has been the subject of
the most intensive research regarding a possible deterrent effect. Additionally, the
flaws that the National Academy panel found in the research are also applicable
to the question of deterrence and other crimes. We will now walk through the
assumptions underlying deterrence theory.
Communicating the Message
As we noted previously, deterrence theory requires that the target audience be
aware of the punishment, or, to be more precise, the increase in the certainty or
severity of the punishment or both. If the would-be robber doesn’t know about
a new law with a mandatory twenty-five-year prison sentence, there is no
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
137
possibility that he will be deterred by the change. This is true even if none of the
other problems with deterrence theory, which we will discuss shortly, are
operative.
It is reasonable to assume that most of the people actively engaged in crime
have some idea of what the penalties are for armed robbery, drug dealing, illegal
weapons possession, and so on. After all, if they are active criminals they
undoubtedly know people who have been arrested, convicted, and sentenced
to prison. In fact, it is likely that many of them have been to prison themselves.
It is naïve to assume that they don’t know. Today’s active criminal, moreover,
must know how harsh the “going rate” is, even if he or she is not aware of how
much harsher it is than was the case thirty years ago. (See our discussion of this
change in Chapter 7.) But if they do know what the punishment is, then why do
they continue to commit crime? We will explore this question shortly when we
discuss how active criminals make choices about their behavior.
The question of communicating the message leads us to reconsider the focused
deterrence programs we discussed in Chapter 5. They are especially important
because they have been found to be the most promising innovation in policing.
You will recall that the key component in the focused deterrence programs are
the “call-in” or “notification” meetings where known active gang members or
active criminals are called in and given an in-person warning that in the event of a
gang-related homicide the police will use all lawful methods to arrest them, be it
major or minor charges. Delivering this threat is referred to as “pulling levers” in
focused deterrence programs. The pulling levers strategy was successful in the Boston Gun Project (until it ran into organizational problems, however) and the Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce Violence (CIRV) project.13 Those successes were
related to two key program elements that distinguish them from traditional
deterrence-oriented crime policies. First, the message was delivered in person to a
selected target audience. There is no question that the audience heard the message.
By contrast, it is never clear that the message of traditional deterrence-oriented programs, such a new and harsher sentencing law, really reaches the intended audience.
The second key element contributing to the success of the “pulling levers”
strategy is that the law enforcement agencies did in fact follow up on the threat
with tough enforcement activity directed at the audience that received the message. The evaluation of the CIRV program cited the number of targeted offenders who were subsequently arrested.14 This reinforced the message of the
certainty of punishment. And it is important to point out that the arrests were
sharply focused and did not involve indiscriminate “sweeps” that caught up large
number of other people who were not in the target group.
The successful focused deterrence programs, in short, suggest that delivering
the threat to a selected audience and then following up on the threat can have a
deterrent effect. This is promising news. But there is other evidence that is cause
for concern. Shortly we will consider a set of programs that go by the name of
“scared straight,” where the threat of unpleasant consequences of misconduct is
delivered in person and which have not been found to be successful. In short,
there are some unresolved questions about how to effectively deliver an inperson threat of punishment.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
138
CHAPTER
6
Understanding the “Costs” of Crime
Deterrence theory further assumes that potential criminals understand the “cost”
of crime and will seek to avoid it. The cost of crime involves several elements:
the actual pain of arrest, prosecution, and punishment; the collateral consequences of a criminal record, including lost job opportunities, denial of eligibility
for public housing, and many other collateral penalties15; and finally the social
stigma of a criminal record.
The costs of crime (typically defined in terms of whether there is a mandatory prison sentence and the length of the prison term) are a central element for
criminologists who subscribe to deterrence theory because they assume that raising the costs will cause current or potential offenders to choose not to do crime.
Deterrence theory holds that the greater the added cost, the more powerful the
deterrent effect. This point illustrates why rational choice theory is so popular
among economists. Their world involves calculating such effects as the more
sales that will result from lowering a product’s price, or whether the increased
sales will be offset by the lower sale price, and so on. The world of rational
choice-oriented economists is one where human behavior can be manipulated
by altering the costs; it is simply a matter of calculating the probable results of
any change. Applied to criminal justice, this assumption about human behavior
leads to calculations about how much crime will be reduced by imposing, for
example, mandatory imprisonment for a third drunk driving offense or a mandatory ten-year prison sentence rather than a five-year term for robbery.
There are a number of problems with this approach to crime policy.
The National Academy of Sciences report, Deterrence and the Death Penalty,
faulted the existing body of research for failing to take into account the larger
“regime” of punishments for homicide, meaning all the possible outcomes and
punishments.16 Assuming a potential murderer is rationally considering to kill
someone, the decision is influenced by other possible punishments: life in prison,
life without parole, a twenty-year prison term, and so on. The National Academy’s point is well taken, and in fact it has implications that extend far beyond
the death penalty. It applies with equal force to all crimes: robbery, drunk
driving, and all crimes.
The “regime” of alternatives also includes more than just the alternative
punishments. It includes positive alternatives as well. The person contemplating
a robbery might also contemplate applying for a job he or she heard about, or
exploring financial aid possibilities that would allow him or her to pursue a GED
or a vocational education program. This may sound a little fanciful, but the fact is
deterrence theory operates this way. Remember that deterrence theory assumes that
we can influence the possibility of people committing crime by manipulating the
“pain” of doing crime relative to the anticipated “gain” (e.g., the money obtained
through a burglary or robbery).
Some criminologists have faulted rational choice theory in criminal justice
for emphasizing the “pain” side of the ledger and ignoring increasing the incentives to law-abiding behavior.17 The admittedly simplistic scenario described
(robbery or GED) highlights the social justice side of crime policy that liberal
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
139
policy makers have always favored and conservatives have ignored. The mainstream of liberal thinking about crime reduction has always emphasized creating
job opportunities, educational opportunities, expanded treatment programs for
substance abuse, and so on. Criminologist Elliott Currie, in his address on
accepting the August Vollmer Award, and in a tone of near-despair, noted that
for forty years we have disinvested in the things that are likely to induce lowincome males not to choose crime, calling the net result “among the greatest
social catastrophes ever to strike an advanced industrial nation.”18 Although conservatives have tended to dismiss such thinking as not directly relevant to crime
control policy, our reading of deterrence theory suggests that it should be
central.
Turning to another problem with the pain calculus of deterrence theory: if
arrest and imprisonment are common experiences for a particular social group,
the stigma begins to lose its negative effect and the deterrent effect weakens.
Criminologist Robert Tillman estimated that in California 66 percent of young
African American males were likely to be arrested before they reached age of
thirty. For white males, the estimate was 34 percent.19 Many critics of the war
on drugs and our imprisonment policies believe that the high prevalence of arrest
among African American males has made arrest a “normal” life experience in the
neighborhood. One result is that this weakens the deterrent effect of the threat
of arrest and punishment. (And Tillman’s study was published in the 1980s, well
before arrests and imprisonment reached their current peaks.) And in fact, the
career criminals we discussed in Chapter 4 are not deterred by their frequent
arrests and convictions.
The Perceived vs. the Real Risk of Punishment
The next set of problems with deterrence theory involves how offenders perceive the risk of arrest and punishment. On this issue, there is some complex
evidence. It is necessary here to distinguish between the real risks of arrest and
punishment, as indicated by official data and other assessments, and the perceived
risks on the part of current or potential offenders.
As we have already discussed in this book, the real risk of arrest and punishment is fairly low. (Our point in Chapters 2 and 3 was that given an arrest with
strong evidence and a defendant with a prior record the probability of conviction
and incarceration is fairly high.) Take the case of robbery. The NCVS indicates
that victims report about 61 percent of all robberies, and the police cleared of
29 percent of the reported robberies in 2011. After rejections by the police and
prosecutors and dismissals by judges, a fairly small percentage of the original robbery incidents are left. The risks for other offenses have been estimated to be
even lower. In an assessment of drug enforcement policies, David Boyum and
Peter Reuter estimated that for drug dealers doing 1,000 sales a year, the risk
of arrest is roughly 1 in every 4,500 sales. One thousand drug sales is an average
of three a day, every day of the year, which means that such a person will have a
high exposure to arrest. Smaller-time drug dealers would have substantially lower
exposure and lower risk of arrest.20
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
140
CHAPTER
6
The risk of arrest and punishment is high mainly for murder. Virtually all
murders are discovered and reported to the police. The police cleared 65 percent
of all murders in 2011. In a study of spousal murders (see the discussion in
Chapter 1), the Justice Department found that 87 percent of all husbands tried
for murdering their wives were convicted, and 81 percent of them were
sentenced to prison.21
Objectively, the real risk of doing one crime (other than murder) is low.
Doing many crimes increases the risk. The subjective assessment of risk is another
matter altogether, and we now turn our attention to that issue.
Choosing Crime: The Rational Criminal?
How current or potential offenders weigh the pains of punishment and other
alternatives and make a rational choice is an extremely complex matter. The
National Academy of Sciences criticized death penalty research for not investigating this central issue. One question, of course, is whether most criminals are
rational actors at all, as deterrence theory assumes.
The Rand report on selective incapacitation contains some interesting evidence on the thinking of active offenders. The Rand Inmate Survey (RIS),
which forms the empirical base for the report’s estimates about incapacitation,
found that offenders were extremely fatalistic about being arrested and punished;
they assumed they would eventually be arrested and punished. This did not seem
to deter them from criminal activity, however. Prisoners in three states (California,
Michigan, and Texas) were asked to estimate the probable results of doing crime.
More than 80 percent believed that they had an “even chance” of being arrested,
imprisoned, injured, or killed, and more than 60 percent believed that they had a
“high chance” of arrest and imprisonment or that it was “certain.” Significantly,
they were only half as likely to expect a high chance or certainty of enjoying the
benefits of crime, such as “high living,” having “expensive things,” or “being
[their] own man.”22
Analyzing these responses, James Q. Wilson and Allan Abrahamse asked the
obvious question: If their estimate of bad consequences was so high and their
estimate of good consequences was so low, why do they commit crime? The
answer, as James Q. Wilson and Allan Abrahamse concluded, was that the RIS
offenders did not act rationally, as deterrence theory requires.23
Inquiring further, Wilson and Abrahamse also found that the prisoners consistently overestimated the financial rewards of crime. They acted impulsively,
overestimating the immediate, short-term gains of crime and underestimating
unpleasant consequences, such as imprisonment, which lay in the future.24 At
the same time, they also may have felt that they had no meaningful alternatives
in terms of legitimate work—in other words, they perceived no positive rewards
for a law-abiding lifestyle. In short, the RIS evidence provides little support for
traditional deterrence theory. Even if the message of more severe punishment for
doing robbery or drug dealing is communicated to potential offenders, the
incentives for law-abiding behavior are so weak in their minds that the shortterm gains of crime loom more attractive.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
141
The evidence on deterrence theory and the realities of the criminal justice
system leads us to our next proposition:
11
PROPOSITION
Deterrence-oriented crime policies are not likely to reduce serious crime.
SCARE THE *%!#@ OUT OF THEM!
A Famous but Failed Program
A popular deterrence-based program for potential offenders is Scared Straight,
which originally involved exposing juveniles to the experience of going to prison
as a way of scaring them out of criminal behavior. Scared Straight gained
national prominence as the title and subject of a 1978 television documentary
that was loosely based on an actual program in a penitentiary in Rahway, New
Jersey. (There is also a more recent version available on DVD, following up on
the story thirty-five years later.) The program was begun by inmates serving life
sentences. Burly, tough-looking prisoners talked tough and yelled at adolescents
about how terrible life is in prison. On the surface it seemed like a great idea.
Who better to give kids a realistic idea of where crime leads than a group of
lifers?25
Scared Straight is a simple deterrence-based program: Give juveniles direct
and frightening evidence about the unpleasant consequences of criminal behavior. Many other programs are based on the same theory. Some drug awareness
programs, for example, try to convince people that drug use will cause permanent damage. One of the most famous, of course, was the old “thisis-your-brain-on-drugs” advertisement (we will discuss this in Chapter 13).
Many antismoking advertisements warn about the hazards of smoking. The original Marlboro Man, who was featured in advertisements for that cigarette, eventually died of lung cancer, and before his death did some antismoking ads. Antidrunk driving programs try to scare kids by showing them pictures of cars that
have been totaled in drunk driving accidents.
The evidence on Scared Straight, however, is not good. One review examined all the evaluations of programs based on the Scared Straight principle that
met evidence-based standards (independent evaluation, randomized or quasirandomized assignment to treatment and control groups, etc.). They found
nine studies over twenty-five years that involved a total of more than one thousand participants.26 None of the programs effectively reduced crime, and some
even had adverse outcomes. A Michigan program in the 1960s resulted in a
43 percent recidivism rate for those who were subjected to the “scare” component compared with only 17 percent for the control group. Several studies had
results that were statistically insignificant, but with more negative than positive
results. Finckenauer’s evaluation of the highly publicized New Jersey Scared
Straight program found recidivism rates of 41 percent for those in the program
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
142
CHAPTER
6
and only 11 percent for the controls. Only one of the nine evaluations found
positive results, but they were not statistically significant.
Despite these depressing findings, Scared Straight programs continue to be
popular. This represents another triumph of faith over facts. Because it has a
commonsense appeal, people don’t want to consider the evidence. In fact,
when the negative results of the Squires program in California were released,
officials ended the evaluation and kept the program.
Why did some of these programs have criminogenic effects and produce higher
rates among the treatment group compared with the control group? What is it about
these programs that are harmful? Some people argue that fear-based campaigns only
heighten the allure of the product and lead to higher usage. In some cases, the claims
are so exaggerated that they become jokes among the intended audience. The thisis-your-brain-on-drugs ads, for example, were often laughed at.
What is the difference between the Scared Straight programs with prison
inmates trying to terrify juveniles and the call-in meetings in focused deterrence
programs that we have concluded are successful? Both deliver the message inperson to a select audience. The difference is probably that in the focused deterrence programs the threat of enforcement was followed by actual enforcement.
In Cincinnati, for example, there were 240 arrests of people in the targeted
group. With the prison-based Scared Straight programs there were no consequences for subsequent criminal acts. It is even easier to explain the failure of
fear-based advertising campaigns such as the this is your brain on drugs. In
those programs the message was delivered to a general public audience, rather
than a carefully selected one, and there were no immediate consequences.
In the end, we conclude that fear-based deterrence programs do not reduce
crime.
DETERRENCE AND THE DEATH PENALTY
The death penalty has always been at the center of discussions of deterrence. The
idea that it deters crime is one of the two main justifications for the death penalty,
with retribution—that it is a just punishment for the most heinous crime—being the
other. The subject of deterrence and the death penalty has been one of the most
intensively studied issues in criminal justice, with the research focusing on homicides, the only crime for which the death penalty is a possible sentence. And in a
2012 review of the literature, the National Academy of Sciences concluded that
there is no evidence that the death penalty decreases, increases, or has any effect
whatsoever on homicides.27 Let’s take a closer look at this controversial issue.
Sorting out the Issues
The merits of the death penalty can be discussed in terms of three separate
issues.28 First there is the moral question of whether it is a just form of punishment. Some people firmly believe that the death penalty is a morally justifiable
form of punishment for murder, whereas others believe that it is morally wrong.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
143
This debate involves basic conceptions of morality and justice and is not subject
to empirical proof one way or the other. The second issue involves the legal
question of whether the death penalty is constitutional. Constitutional challenges
began in the 1960s and eventually led to the 1972 Furman v. Georgia decision, in
which the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that the death penalty had been applied in
an unconstitutionally arbitrary and capricious fashion.29 It rejected the argument
that capital punishment was inherently cruel and unusual. Four years later, in
Gregg v. Georgia, the Court upheld the constitutionality of the death penalty
where there were guidelines to control its application.30
The third issue is the one we will discuss here: Does the death penalty deter
crime? We do not cover the first two issues not because they are unimportant—
they are in fact extremely important—but because as we explained in Chapter 1,
our focus in this book in on crime policy.
Executions and Crime: The Debate Continues
The deterrent effect of capital punishment has been hotly debated and intensively researched for several decades. The research has been marked by steadily
more sophisticated research methodologies. One of the earliest studies by
the noted criminologist, Thorsten Sellin, compared neighboring states, two
with and one without the death penalty. He found that Ohio and Indiana,
two death penalty states, did not have lower crime rates than Michigan,
which did not have the death penalty. Murder rates in all three states changed
in roughly the same direction during the period studies, decreasing from
the 1930s to the early 1960s and then rising sharply. This suggests that broad
social factors common to all states, rather than executions, were the primary
causal factors in homicide rates.31 Sellin’s methodology was simplistic by
today’s standards, failing to control for the relevant variables that affect murder
rates, and would not be acceptable by today’s standards for death penalty
research.
Isaac Ehrlich raised the debate to a new level in 1975 with a methodologically sophisticated study of executions and crime trends between 1930 and 1969.
He concluded that the death penalty had a powerful deterrent effect, with each
execution preventing seven or eight murders.32 An economist, he embraced the
rational choice theory of human behavior, popular in that discipline, explaining
that the “propensity” to commit crimes “is influenced by the prospective gains
and losses associated with their commission.”33 Critics, however, found serious
flaws in Ehrlich’s analysis. As is the case with studies using many variables and
large data sets, his approach is highly sensitive to problems with the reliability
of the data and the time frame studied. In their respective analyses, Brian Forst,
Peter Passell, and William Bowers and Glenn Pierce all argue that when the
years from 1962 to 1969 are excluded (when crime rates rose dramatically,
coinciding with a de facto moratorium on executions that began in mid-1967),
Ehrlich’s deterrent effect vanishes.34 His formula does not explain the trends
between the 1930s and the early 1960s, when executions declined while the
crime rate either declined or remained stable.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
144
CHAPTER
6
Ehrlich’s use of FBI Uniform Crime Reports (UCR) data is also problematic.
We have good reason to believe that because of the lack of professionalism in most
police departments, these data seriously undercount the amount of crime. In New
York City alone, for example, at least two well-documented episodes (in 1955 and
1965) occurred in which administrative changes in the police department produced huge increases in officially reported crime. In Chicago, meanwhile, reporters in 1983 caught the Chicago police unfounding a substantial number of crimes.
In other words, the apparent risk of apprehension was higher in the pre-1960 years
because police record keeping probably kept the number of reported crimes artificially low.35 Consequently, the real risk of apprehension had not declined as much
between 1930 and 1969 as Ehrlich asserted.
The 2012 report by the National Academy of Science delivered a devastating report on the subject of deterrence and the death penalty. After reviewing all
of the studies conducted over the previous thirty years (the date of the previous
National Academy of Sciences report), it concluded that there is no persuasive
evidence about “whether capital punishment decreases, increases, or has not
effect on homicide rates.”36
In fact, the National Academy expressed “disappointment” in the body of three
decades of research, finding a number of serious conceptual and empirical flaws in
virtually all of the studies. We have already discussed the major problems, but it is
appropriate to summarize them again here. First, studies of the death penalty failed
to place it in the context of the full “regime” of sanctions, which include life in
prison, life in prison without parole, or a fixed prison term of, say twenty years.
We don’t know how these alternative sentences affect the decisions of potential
murderers. Second, the National Academy pointed out that studies have not examined how potential murderers “respond to the objective risk of execution.” In fact,
we know little if anything about the process of risk assessment by potential murderers. The National Academy report pointed out that only 15 percent of those
persons given a sentence of death since 1976 (when executions resumed) were in
fact executed. Do potential murderers know this? What exactly is their perception
of the risk of doing murder in a death penalty state? And as with all crimes, are the
offenders acting as rational people, as deterrence theory assumes?
In the end, we agree with the National Academy of Sciences about the lack
of evidence regarding the impact of the death penalty, and offer the following
proposition:
12
PROPOSITION
The death penalty does not deter homicides.
DETERRING THE DRUNK DRIVER
In the 1980s, a crusade against drunk driving arose and swept the country. Spurred
by a wave of public outrage, virtually every state enacted new laws and policies,
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
145
most of which were designed to deter drunk driving through tougher punishment.37 Leading the national crusade was an organization called Mothers Against
Drunk Driving (MADD), founded by Candi Lightner, whose thirteen-year-old
daughter, Cari, was killed in a crash involving Clarence Busch, who had two previous drunk driving convictions and was out on bail on a third drunk driving charge.
Lightner’s death confirmed the belief of many people that repeat drunk drivers beat
the system, and it is a classic example of a celebrated case.
The “Killer Drunk” and Other Myths
A report on the “hardcore drunk driver” opens by telling readers to “Look no
further than the headlines across this country.”38 Like so many aspects of criminal
justice, the subject of drunk driving is dominated by myths and celebrated cases
that inhibit the development of sound and effective policies. The news media
prominently cover the worst drunk driving cases, typically where there is a
death, even multiple deaths, or serious injuries. Such events are the classic celebrated cases, and they distort the reality of drinking and driving and inhibit the
development of sensible policies to combat the problem.
It is widely believed, for example, that drunk drivers are responsible for half
of all traffic fatalities. One Justice Department report repeated the widely publicized claim that drunk driving kills fifty thousand people every two years—“almost
as many American lives as were lost in the entire ten years of the Vietnam
war.”39 This grossly exaggerated estimate originated in a 1968 report by the
U.S. Department of Transportation (DOT) and has been widely repeated
ever since. It just isn’t true, however.
In 2011, 9,878 people died in alcohol-impaired accidents, representing 31 percent of all traffic fatalities.40 Take careful note of the phrase “alcohol-impaired.”
Alcohol was not necessarily the cause of each of those accidents, but only that the
driver was impaired by alcohol. And the data do not indicate the degree of
impairment. There is an important distinction between drivers who have been
drinking and those whose driving is impaired by drinking.41 In fact, the number of
alcohol-related fatalities has been falling in recent years, from 13,472 in 2002 to
9,878 in 2011, a 27 percent decline.42 This is a significant achievement, and we
should be on guard against alarmist claims about a drunk driving “epidemic” the
next time there is a tragic death because of a drunk driver. And we will take a
good look at the important point in those data: what are the reasons why alcoholrelated fatalities have declined so significantly?
Another popular myth is that many “killer drunks,” people with a serious
drinking problem and many arrests, frequently beat the system.43 The myth of the
killer drunk affects our thinking about alcohol and driving in several ways. First, it
places the blame on a small number of dangerous people. Second, it emphasizes the
killing of innocent people. Third, it puts much of the blame on the criminal justice
system for not punishing these offenders and keeping them off the road. Fourth, it
makes criminal punishment the primary focus of efforts to reduce traffic fatalities.
H. Laurence Ross, one of the top experts on the subject, argues that each of
these myths distorts the reality of alcohol-related fatalities.44 First, the problem of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
146
CHAPTER
6
drinking and driving is not confined to a few dangerous people. Driving after
drinking is fairly common. The 2012 National Survey on Drug Use and Health
estimates that in the years 2006–2009, 30.7 million people older than sixteen
reported driving while under the influence of alcohol per year, or 13.2 percent
of all people in that age group. Another 10.1 million people, meanwhile, reported
driving while under the influence of an illicit drug. And because about 20 to 30
percent of the population does not drink at all, the percentage of drinkers who
drive after drinking is higher than 13.2 percent. The good news is that the prevalence of driving while under the influence has declined, from 14.6 percent of the
population 16 and older in 2002–2005 to 13.2 percent in 2006–2009.45
There is, of course, a small number of people who are chronic drunk drivers,
and we should not minimize that problem. The Century Council (an anti-drunk
driving advocacy group sponsored by the leading distillers) defines the “hardcore
drunk driver” as someone who drives with a blood-alcohol count (BAC) level of
0.15, does so repeatedly, has more than one arrest, and is “highly resistant” to
changing his or her behavior. Interviews with 365 clients in special drunk driving
courts yielded some illuminating and alarming findings. Keep in mind, that this is
not a representative sample of drivers or even persons arrested for drunk driving.
The group averaged three arrests and 2.6 convictions for drunk driving. In the
thirty days before their last arrest, 80 percent reported driving drunk at least a
few times a month, and 11 percent said they did so almost every day.
The responses by members of this group provide an interesting perspective on
deterrence theory: 73 percent reported that it is likely that the police will stop a
drinking driver at some point, 95 percent think that if stopped they will be arrested,
and 97 percent of those think that they will be convicted. In short, they are
extremely fatalistic about being stopped, arrested, and convicted—and in fact overestimate the real probabilities—but do not change their ways. Clearly, these people
are aware of the threat of criminal sanctions, understand the consequences to be
unpleasant, and assess the risk to be high. Nonetheless, all of this has no deterrent
effect on them. Interestingly, most felt some remorse for their actions, and 81 percent
said that a more severe sanction after their first arrest would have caused them to
change their behavior. We should be highly skeptical of such statements because
the immediate context of the interviews—DUI (Driving Under the Influence)
Court and a recent arrest—undoubtedly enhanced their feelings or remorse.
Their actual behavior, moreover, suggests that any such remorse was a temporary feeling46
The evidence of this one study suggests that the hardcore drunk drivers are
not deterred by their experience of arrest and punishment. Increasing the punishment seems unlikely to have any effect on their behavior. We should not
ignore hardcore or repeat drunk drivers, however. They are indeed a problem,
but they distort our perception of the broader drunk driving problem and how
we might control it.
Another part of the myth of the killer drunk is that innocent drivers or
bystanders are the typical victims of alcohol-related crashes. The evidence does
not support this belief. Two-thirds (66 percent) of all the people killed in 2011
were the drivers themselves, and another 16 percent were passengers in those
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
147
cars, 11 percent were driving another car, and only 7 percent pedestrians. In
some of these cases, they were themselves impaired by alcohol. Thus, only 18
percent can be considered innocent by-standers.47
Third, the argument that the criminal justice system is “soft” on drunk drivers is one part of a general view of the criminal justice system that we have
already discussed in Chapters 2 and 3. We will take a close look at the alleged
loopholes in the criminal justice system in Chapter 8. Later in this chapter we
will look specifically at the handling of drunk driving cases.
In fact, most of the drivers killed in alcohol-related crashes do not have a
history of drunk driving. The hardcore drunk drivers are a small part of the
drinking and driving population, which as we mentioned previously, the best
national survey estimates to be 30.7 million people a year, plus the 10 million
who reported driving while under the influence of drugs. The problem, of
course is that we cannot spot them in advance on the basis of their driving
records. Once again, we are up against the prediction problem we discussed in
Chapter 4.
Finally, and perhaps most important in terms of reducing drinking and driving, both H. Laurence Ross and James B. Jacobs argue that we are not going to
reduce alcohol-related traffic fatalities with a single policy and certainly not with
a single criminal justice policy. They argue that many different kinds of policies
can contribute to reducing alcohol-related traffic fatalities.48 In Chapter 1 we
discussed the progress that has been made in reducing smoking and accidental
childhood poisonings, and that these achievements have been the result of multipronged efforts.49 As we will argue shortly, the same is true with the drunk
driving problem. But first let’s take a close look at the idea of deterrence and
drunk driving.
Deterrence and Drunk Driving
Deterrence-oriented efforts to reduce drunk driving involve both short-term
enforcement “crackdowns” (see our discussion in Chapter 5) and long-term
changes in sentencing policy.50 In theory, there are some reasons for thinking
that tougher punishment is more likely to work with drunk driving than, for
example, with robbery or burglary. People who drink and drive are more representative of the general population and are likely to have a stake in society, and
therefore are more likely to feel threatened by the stigma of a serious alcoholrelated accident, an arrest, and the impact of such events on their jobs and families. Drunk driving, moreover, occurs in plain view over an extended period of
time where it is observable to the police. This leads some people to think that
the risk of arrest is higher than, for example, robbery or burglary. The evidence,
however, suggests that these assumptions do not work in practice and that deterring the drunk driver is extremely difficult.
One of the most famous drunk driving crackdowns involved the 1967 Road
Safety Act in England. The law empowered the police to require a breath test of
any driver and specified that refusal to submit to the test was punishable as an actual
failure. It attempted to increase the certainty of apprehension, without changing the
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
148
CHAPTER
6
severity of punishment.51 The new law did have an immediate impact. Weekend traffic fatalities and serious injuries dropped to one-third of their previous
levels. Some observers saw this as evidence of a deterrent effect. But the effect
gradually wore off. Within three years, fatalities had returned to their previous
level. This “decay” of the deterrent effect appears to be a general phenomenon
in enforcement crackdowns. A 1984 Justice Department evaluation of four
anti-drunk driving campaigns found similar results and concluded that the deterrent effects of an enforcement effort, even when it exists, “appear to diminish
over time.”52
The British crackdown also illustrated a phenomenon known as the
announcement effect. The publicity surrounding a crackdown caused people to
alter their behavior: they decided not to have another drink, or they asked someone else to drive them home; a bartender refused to serve a drink, or friends told
someone that he or she had had enough to drink. In short, people did know
about the crackdown, did perceive the threat of increased punishment, and
made rational decisions to alter their behavior. In some instances, these changes
occurred before the law actually went into effect, as people’s awareness of the
potential penalty rises.
The announcement effect may also influence the behavior of police officers,
causing them to become more active in stopping drunk drivers in the early
months of a new law. The Justice Department evaluation of four anti-drunk
driving campaigns found that arrests went up in three of them but not in the
one where there was “relatively little publicity” about the mandatory imprisonment law.53 As the publicity surrounding an enforcement effort diminishes,
however, the effect wears off. Drinkers become less conscious of the risks and
gradually revert to their normal drinking and driving behavior. Police officers
return to their normal levels of enforcement activity. The announcement effect
strikes at the heart of deterrence theory. The theory assumes that the message is
communicated to its intended audience. But if that message wears off with time,
then so does the deterrent effect.
One of the problems with drunk driving crackdowns is that the risk of arrest
is in fact extremely low. In his evaluation of the British experiments, H. Laurence Ross estimated that the probability of being asked to submit to a breath test
was 1 per million vehicle miles driven. (Consider this figure in terms of the mileage on your odometer.) The risk was higher for drinking drivers because their
behavior attracted the attention of the police, but it was still “low by any reasonable criterion.” The U.S. DOT estimated that someone would have to drive
drunk between two hundred and two thousand times to be apprehended—and
even then would face only a 50 percent chance of being punished.54
Most people, moreover, believe that the risk is low. A 2009 study of
licensed drivers in Maryland found that 72 percent did not feel that it was likely
they would be stopped by the police if they drove after having too much to
drink; 28 percent felt that it was likely. Previous studies reached nearly identical
estimates.55 These findings are especially important for deterrence theory
because, as we explained, to be deterred people have to perceive a risk of something unpleasant. Hardcore drunk drivers are a special case and not representative
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
149
of the general population. They believe the risks of arrest and punishment are
high, but that does not affect their behavior. For most people, the belief in a
low risk of arrest for drunk driving is a realistic assessment.
Looking at drunk driving enforcement from the perspective of the police
officer also helps explain why the risk is low. Both regular patrol officers and
traffic unit officers are theoretically on the lookout for drunk drivers. Regular
patrol officers, however, have many responsibilities—law enforcement, order
maintenance, and service—and are concerned primarily with answering calls for
service. Moreover, as we learned in Chapter 5 they are spread thin and are
responsible for patrolling streets that are not prime “hunting grounds” for
drunk drivers. Traffic unit officers, meanwhile, represent no more than about
10 percent of the sworn officers in a department. They also have other responsibilities, such as watching for speeders. An arrest, moreover, takes a traffic officer
out of service for as long as an hour or two. In short, the number of police officers actively hunting for drunk driving is fairly low.
Traffic enforcement is affected by both incentives and disincentives. The primary incentive is that traffic arrests result in court time. Depending on the
department, that may be a lucrative source of overtime pay. The disincentives
include several factors. Traffic stops are unpleasant and occasionally dangerous
experiences for police officers. Citizens resent them, are sometimes belligerent,
and on occasion the incident escalates into a serious confrontation. Traffic situations are also the fourth most hazardous situation for police officers in terms of
officers killed on duty (and these situations include accidents resulting from pursuits).56 In the absence of any strong incentives, such as ticket quotas, most cops
prefer to avoid traffic stops except in the most serious cases. When officers do
make arrests, the law of diminishing returns comes into play. Processing an arrest
may take up to two hours (or more, depending on local procedures). Thus,
each arrest removes the police officer from the street and lowers the level of
enforcement on the streets. Although there may be some gain in specific deterrence related to the person arrested, there is an offsetting loss in general
deterrence.
If the hunters are few, the hunted are many and well hidden among lawabiding drivers. Experts estimate that even during the peak drunk driving hours
(Friday and Saturday nights), only about 3 to 4 percent of all drivers are legally
drunk.57 Perhaps another 5 percent have some detectable level of alcohol in their
blood. But some drivers who are legally drunk may not be impaired, and their
driving may not attract the attention of the police. The drive home from a neighborhood bar may be short, leaving a small window of opportunity for detection.
Drunk Drivers in Court
Another factor undermining the deterrent effect of a crackdown is the fate of
drunk driving cases in court. James B. Jacobs estimates that about 90 percent of
all arrested drunk drivers are convicted through guilty pleas.58 In this respect, the
prosecution of drunk driving offenses is similar to the handling of other criminal cases.
Those data, however, reflect only convictions. The main purpose of crackdowns is to
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
150
CHAPTER
6
deter drunk driving by increasing the severity of punishment, usually through a
mandatory jail or prison sentence.
Mandatory sentencing provisions can be evaded through dismissal, plea bargaining, or blatant disregard for the law. H. Laurence Ross and James P. Foley
examined the implementation of new mandatory sentencing laws enacted in
New Mexico and Indiana in the 1980s. The New Mexico law required a jail
term of not less than forty-eight hours for offenders with a prior drunk driving
conviction and prohibited suspended sentences. Ross and Foley found that in
238 cases, the mandated sentence was imposed and served in only 106, or 45 percent of the total. In another 60 cases (25 percent), the mandatory sentences were
imposed but there was no documented proof that the offenders served them. In
10 percent of the cases, the judge suspended the sentence, and in another 20 percent
the offender served no jail sentence. The Indiana law mandated five days in jail, with
at least forty-eight consecutive hours, or a minimum of eighty hours of community
service for offenders with a prior drunk driving conviction. Yet 30 percent of the
convicted offenders did not serve the mandated sentence. Of 753 cases, 64 percent
served the forty-eight consecutive hours, and another 6 percent did the required
eighty hours of community service.59
Ross and Foley offer several possible explanations for this evasion of mandatory sentences. In some cases, the judges may have been ignorant of the
offender’s prior record. We might ask whether this was a result of inefficiencies
in court records or whether judges consciously chose not to find out as a deliberate strategy for evading the mandatory sentencing provision. It is possible that
some jurisdictions do not have data systems that accurately record all prior convictions. Or it is possible that prosecutors do not file evidence of prior convictions (This is one of the methods prosecutors use to evade three-strikes laws, as
we will see in Chapter 7). In others, judges may have chosen to interpret the
law as covering only certain kinds of prior convictions (for example, felonies
and not misdemeanors). Judges may have simply ignored the law in some
cases. For some sentenced offenders, the term forty-eight hours may not have
been interpreted literally. Correctional officials may have counted a few hours
a day as representing the entire day; if the offender spent a few hours in jail
spanning midnight, he or she might have been credited with having served
both days. Similar evasions of mandatory sentencing have been found in studies
of other crackdowns.
Evasion of the law by justice officials is not universal by any means. The
Justice Department’s evaluation of enforcement efforts in Seattle found that the
incarceration rate for convicted drunk drivers went from 9 to 97 percent as a
result of new mandatory confinement procedure was adopted. The law was not
that tough, however; it mandated only a minimum of one day in jail for convicted drivers with a blood alcohol count of 0.10 or greater. In Memphis, where
a new law mandated forty-eight-hour incarceration for first-time offenders
and forty-five days for second offenses, incarceration went from 29 to almost
100 percent.60 A 1982 California law increased the statewide jail incarceration
rate for second-time offenders from 83 percent in 1980 to 97.5 percent in
1984. In Sacramento County, the percentage of first-time drunk drivers sent to
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
151
jail went from 10 percent to more than 50 percent. These data make it clear that
second-offense drunk drivers were not getting off easy before passage of the new
law. The most significant effect of the California law was on first-time offenders;
the percentage going to jail increased from about 10 percent to more than
50 percent.61 In short, patterns of prosecution vary, according to the standards
of local court room work groups, and we need to be sensitive to that.
As the Ross and Foley study suggests, a certain amount of evasion of mandatory sentencing persists in some jurisdictions that undermines both the certainty
and the severity of punishment. This compounds the low perceived and actual
risk of arrest. In the end, most experts believe that enforcement crackdowns are
not likely to deter drunk driving. After reviewing all the evidence, Ross concludes
that “deterrence-based policies are questionable in the long run. No such policies
have been scientifically demonstrated to work over time.”62 Jacobs agrees but adds
that deterrence-based laws play a symbolic role in expressing society’s moral condemnation of drunk driving.63 Our conclusion can be stated as follows:
13
PROPOSITION
Enforcement crackdowns do not deter drunk driving over the long term.
A MULTIPRONGED STRATEGY FOR DEALING
WITH TRAFFIC FATALITIES
Actually, there is considerable good news about traffic fatality trends. As Table 6.1
indicates, the motor vehicle death rate per 100,000 vehicle miles dropped from
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
152
CHAPTER
T A B L E 6.1
6
Motor vehicle deaths per 100,000 vehicle miles
Year
Death rate
1927
16.33
1937
14.68
1947
8.82
1957
5.98
1967
5.50
1977
3.35
1987
2.51
1997
1.71
2003
1.75
2008
1.27
2011
1.10
SOURCE: National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Traffic Safety Facts, 2011 Data
(Washington, DC: Department of Transportation, 2013), Table 1. U.S. Department of
Transportation Facts 2003 (Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Transportation, 2004).
16.33 in 1927 to 3.35 in 1977 to 1.10 in 2011 (this includes all fatalities and not
just alcohol-related).64 The long-term decline since 1927 is enormous, and the 37
percent reduction between 2003 and 2011 alone is remarkable. The number of
people killed in traffic accidents, moreover, declined by 27 percent from 2002
(13,472) to 2011 (9,878).65
Interestingly, the number of motorcycle-related deaths increased from 4,462
in 2009 to 4,741 in 2011. This was during a period when automobile fatalities
were declining. The main for the increase was the tremendous growth is sales
and the number of motorcycles on the road. Moreover, the fatality rate
increased, both in terms of per 100,000 registered vehicles and also per 100 million vehicle miles traveled. The increase in the fatality rate for motorcycle accidents suggests that many of the new motorcycle owners were inexperienced in
operating a bike.66 A 2005 study, moreover, found that the use of helmets
among both motorcycle drivers and riders declined from 71 percent in 2000 to
58 percent in 2002 (but it rebounded to 66 percent by 2011). The study estimated that helmets reduce fatalities by 37 percent. (The methodology involved
comparing fatality rate in two passenger accidents where one was wearing a helmet and the other not wearing one.) It concluded that 1,798 lives would be
saved nationally if helmet use was 100 percent.67
How do we explain the steady drop in motor vehicle deaths over the
course of many decades? The evidence suggests that it was not as a result of
enforcement crackdowns. Instead, it was a process of several changes working
together over the long term. Tougher enforcement by the criminal justice
system may have contributed to this decline, but both Ross and Jacobs argue
that at best it was only one factor. Other social policies also played important
roles.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
153
First, cars have become safer. Steering wheels, for example, are less likely to
impale a driver than they were in the 1950s. Dashboards and door handles have
been redesigned over the years to reduce potential harm in accidents.
Second, new safety features, including seat belts, airbags, and child restraints
have saved many lives. Seat belts are required on all new cars, and their use is
mandatory in every state except New Hampshire. The National Highway Traffic
Safety Administration (NHTSA) estimates that seat belts saved 11,949 lives in
2011, and a total of 292,471 since 1975. That is a lot of lives. Child restraints,
meanwhile, saved 263 lives in 2011, and 9,874 since 1975. Finally, airbags saved
2,204 lives in 2011, and 34,757 since 1975. Motorcycle helmets saved 1,829 lives
in 2008 (the most recent data available). Table 6.2 presents the estimated lifesaving totals for all safety devices and laws.68
Third, federal law has forced states to raise the legal age for drinking to
twenty-one (by withholding federal highway funds if they do not). Although
this law has not necessarily curbed teenage drinking, it may have helped reduce
drunk driving by teenagers; DOT estimates that the higher age limit saved 714
lives in 2008.69
Fourth, the policy of administrative license revocation (ALR) has resulted in
speedier loss of driver’s licenses. In this procedure, a police officer can revoke a
license on the spot if the driver fails a breath test. Forty-one states have ALR
laws. It is important to point out that this is a civil law rather than a criminal
law approach. It rests on the theory that a driver’s license is essentially a privilege
that can be withdrawn without resort to the full criminal process. Ross argues
that it is both swift and certain, resulting in the immediate incapacitation of the
offender (in the sense that the person cannot drive legally, although obviously
some people drive without a license). He cites studies indicating that this
approach has been effective in reducing alcohol-related accidents and fatalities.70
Fifth, socialization may have contributed to some of the long-term reduction in traffic fatalities. The national anti-drunk driving crusade, with all of the
attendant publicity, may have helped change attitudes and behavior about drinking and driving. According to the National Household Survey, the best longitudinal data available, the percentage of people reporting that they drove after
drinking fell from 25 percent in 1983 to 16 percent in 1995 and 11.1 percent
in 2011. This is a steady and significant decline. The percentage indicating that
they “never” drove after drinking rose correspondingly.71
Sixth, the National Safety Council’s policy of Graduated Driver Licensing
(GDL) allows limited driving privileges to teenagers and then gradually expands
T A B L E 6.2
Lives saved in 2011 by restraints and minimum drinking age laws
Child
restraints
Seat belts
Frontal air
bags
Motorcycle
helmets
Minimum drinking
age laws
11,949
2,204
1,829 (2008)
714 (2008)
263
SOURCE: National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, 2011 Data, Occupant Protection (Washington, DC NHTSA,
2013). National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Traffic Safety Facts, Lives Saved in 2008 by Restrain Use and
Minimum Drinking Age Laws (Washington, DC: NHTSA, 2009).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
154
CHAPTER
6
them. (For additional information, go to the National Safety Council website.) It
is well known that teenagers, and young men in particular, engage in the riskiest
driving behavior. Reducing their driving, or introducing them to driving gradually, is likely to reduce traffic accidents and fatalities. Although almost all states
always had provisions for temporary licenses, the idea of a comprehensive system
emerged only in the 1980s, first in New Zealand and then in Canada. It finally
began to spread in the United States in the 1990s. Evaluations have found reductions in the number of crashes ranging from a high of 60 percent to a low of
4 percent among teenage drivers.72
Ignition Interlock Systems: Focused Incapacitation?
The seventh change contributing to the decline traffic fatalities, and alcoholrelated accidents and fatalities in particular, is the “interlock” ignition system.
The interlock is an in-car breathalyzer test that prevents the vehicle from starting
if the driver records a BAC that is too high. To prevent evasion by having
another person take the initial test to start the car, interlock devices can be set
for a series of “running” tests once the vehicle is operating to ensure that the
same person is driving the car. Interlocks are used as part of the punishment for
a drunk driving conviction, and their use has been growing. In 2009 an estimated 180,000 systems were in use, and one report indicated that by mid-2013
there were 300,000.73
Interlock systems are actually a form of selective incapacitation rather than
deterrence. (We will discuss incapacitation in detail in Chapter 7.) Deterrence, as
we explained, is a strategy for changing the choices about behavior that people
make. With an interlock, however, the subject has no choice: the car won’t start.
Indeed, it thwarts the choice that the would-be driver has made (to drive after drinking). Interlocks are selective in that they target a small and specific group of people.
Granted, there are undoubtedly ways of evading interlock devices, such as
borrowing someone else’s car that has no interlock system. Even then, however,
many if not most family members and friends are likely to think about their
potential liability and be reluctant loan their care to someone with a drunk driving record and current criminal sentence. (Dysfunctional family members and
friends who would loan the car, of course, are always a problem in this regard.)
The problem with tough sentencing laws, as we discussed, is that the deterrent
message is diffuse, spread over the entire population. And as experience has
taught us, tough sentences leave a lot of room for prosecutorial and judicial discretion regarding “mandated” sentences.
Evaluations of interlock systems have consistently found them to be effective
in reducing recidivism during the time they are operational. This is hardly surprising
because the device is designed to keep the person from driving that car. With
respect to the postinterlock period, one evaluation found that drunk driving
recidivism returned to the level of the control group. One other study, however,
found a carryover effect, with reduced recidivism continuing into the following
two- and four-year periods. The authors suggested a learning theory explanation
for this continued benefit.74 In this regard, the Century Council recommends
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
155
that alcohol education and treatment are included in any interlock sentence. The
problem with repeat offenders, and hardcore drunk drivers in particular, is that
they are resistant to deterrence messages and need to undergo significant behavioral change. How to achieve that is a major challenge that goes beyond the
scope of our discussion here.
The point of the previous discussion is that we have in fact dealt effectively
with a serious social problem, motor vehicle deaths, over the long term. The
data in Table 6.1 are powerfully impressive. We have done it primarily with
strategies that do not involve criminal law enforcement, and certainly not
enforcement crackdowns, and we did not rely on any single strategy. This follows our discussion in Chapter 1 of dealing with social problems through multipronged strategies and not relying exclusively on the criminal justice system.
Criminal sanctions may one part of a multipronged approach, but should not
be the only or even the most important strategy. We will return to it again
when we discuss drugs and drug-related crime in Chapter 13. There are important implications here for dealing with robbery and burglary, the original focus of
this book, and other crimes.
Specialized DUI Courts
Another important new development regarding drunk driving involves specialized drunk driving courts (which we will call DUI courts). They are modeled
after drug courts, which we discuss in Chapter 13, and are designed to provide
treatment as part of a criminal sentence for repeat drunk driving offenders. They
have been evaluated and the results are promising.
A NHTSA study evaluated DUI courts in three Georgia counties that had
served a total of 1,053 clients by the time of the study. Eligibility in each of the
three DUI courts involved two DUI convictions in the last three to five years, and
some additional criteria for each court. Consistent with national data on drinking
and driving, the clients were mainly male (83 percent), white (61 percent), and
employed (60 percent). DUI court participants’ performance was compared with
one group of matched offenders who were in court before the DUI courts were
created and another matched group of offenders in counties without DUI courts.75
The treatment component of DUI Courts is designed to affect behavioral
change. It is increasingly recognized that repeat drunk driving offenders, who
the Century Council call hardcore drunk drivers, have serious behavioral problems that are at the root of their lifestyles and drinking habits. These behavioral
problems inhibit the deterrent effect of tough criminal sanctions because the
hardcore drunk drivers do not make rational choices about risks and benefits.
Nor do they learn from the unpleasant experience of their early arrests and convictions. The DUI courts in the study included intensive supervision of offenders
by both judges and probation officers. Active involvement of judges is also one
of the special features of drug courts. Alternative sanctions and treatments
included a fine, license revocation, ignition interlock, alcohol treatment services,
random alcohol and drug testing, community service, and the threat of a jail sentence (probation revocation) for noncompliance with the terms of the program.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
156
CHAPTER
6
The evaluation found that during the four years studied, DUI court clients had
an overall recidivism rate of 15 percent, compared with a 24 percent for the
matched contemporary group and 35 percent for the matched group of pre-DUI
court offenders. The number of prior DUI convictions was a powerful predictor
of recidivism, with each prior increasing the likelihood of recidivism by 28 percent.
This suggests that the hardcore drunk drivers are more deeply committed to their
drinking behavior are simply less amenable to treatment by the DUI courts.
The success of the DUI courts highlight several themes that arise in several
chapters of this book. We discuss DUI courts in this chapter on deterrence, but
the evidence does indicate that relying solely on the threat of criminal sanctions
has at best only limited effect in addressing what we regard as a problem in criminality (drunk driving). The evidence suggests that traffic fatalities have been
reduced over the decades by a multipronged approach that includes many different approaches. In Chapter 1, we cited the successes in the public health area in
this regard.76 The DUI courts rely on many of the same principles used in the
police innovations we discussed in Chapter 5: focusing on a select group of serious offenders, developing partnerships with social service agencies, and using
interventions other than pure criminal sanctions. In Chapter 13, we will see
how drug courts have been successful with the same approach.
14
PROPOSITION
A multipronged strategy, including using noncriminal justice programs, have
proven effective in reducing traffic-related fatalities.
CONCLUSION
The commonsense notion that people will avoid unpleasant things and that we
can influence their decisions by increasing the unpleasantness does not necessarily
work in the real world of criminal justice. Let us be careful about exactly what we
are saying. As in so many other areas, it is not true that “nothing works.” The
criminal law does have some deterrent effect. Most of us, after all, do not become
career criminals. The threat of punishment, however, probably plays a relatively
minor role in influencing the behavior of law-abiding people. The threat works,
but it just is not the major factor. In terms of controlling behavior, the broader
processes of socialization are the primary factors. As criminologist Leslie Wilkins
once put it, there are “those of us who have never needed a deterrent.”77
In this chapter we have seen that the authoritative National Academy of
Sciences found no persuasive evidence of a deterrent effect of the death penalty,
in terms of reducing homicides, increasing homicides, or having no impact whatsoever. The most devastating aspect of the report was its criticism that the
research on the subject was deeply flawed. And we should remember that the
death penalty has been the most intensively studied subject with respect to deterrence. We simply do not know how potential offenders perceive the risk of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
157
punishment and process that perception in deciding whether or not to commit
crime. What we have learned about drunk driving is particularly relevant for
deterrence and other crime policies. In fact, we have made substantial progress
in reducing traffic fatalities and saving lives. We have not achieved that through
crackdowns designed to deter drunk driving. We have achieved it through a
multipronged approach that includes a variety of strategies, only some of which
involve criminal prosecution. As we mentioned in Chapter 1, the same approach
has been successfully applied to other social problems. There is an important
lesson here for the entire criminal justice system.
NOTES
1 The best treatment of the subject is still Franklin E. Zimring and Gordon J.
Hawkins, Deterrence: The Legal Threat in Crime Control (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1973).
2 Ibid.
3 Scott Decker, Richard Wright, and Robert Logie, “Perceptual Deterrence among
Active Residential Burglars: A Research Note,” Criminology 31 (February 1993):
135.
4 Zimring and Hawkins, Deterrence, 92–248.
5 Ibid., pp. 13–14.
6 Ronald L. Akers, “Rational Choice, Deterrence, and Social Learning Theory in
Criminology: The Path Not Taken,” Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology 81 (Fall
1990): 653–676.
7 See, for example, the extremely influential conservative argument in Charles
Murray, Losing Ground American Social Policy, 1950–1980 (New York: Basic Books,
1984).
8 Alex R. Piquero and Stephen G. Tibbetts, eds., Rational Choice and Criminal
Behavior: Recent Research and Future Challenges, 2nd ed. (New York: Routledge,
2012).
9 Daniel S. Nagin, “Moving Choice to Center Stage in Criminological Research and
Theory: The American Society of Criminology 2006 Sutherland Address,”
Criminology 45 (no. 2, 2007): 259–272.
10 Dallin Oaks, “Studying the Exclusionary Rule in Search and Seizure,” University of
Chicago Law Review 37 (Summer 1970): 665–757.
11 Daniel S. Nagin, “Criminal Deterrence Research at the Outset of the Twenty-First
Century,” in Michael Tonry, ed., Crime and Justice: A Review of Research, (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1998), 23:4–6.
12 Daniel S. Nagin and John V. Pepper, eds., Deterrence and the Death Penalty
(Washington, DC: National Academies Press, 2012), 2.
13 Robin S. Engel, Marie Skubak Tillyer, and Nicholas Corsaro, “Reducing Gang
Violence Using Focused Deterrence: Evaluating the Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce
Violence (CIRV)”, Justice Quarterly 30 (No. 3, 2013):403–439.
14 Ibid.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
158
CHAPTER
6
15 The full range of post-prison release disabilities are catalogued in Joan Petersilia,
When Prisoners Come Home: Parole and Prisoner Reentry (New York: Oxford
University Press, 2003).
16 Nagin and Pepper, Deterrence and the Death Penalty, 4–5.
17 Francis T. Cullen, Travis Pratt, C. L. Micelli, and M. M. Moon, “Dangerous
Liaison: Rational Choice Theory as the Basis for Correctional Intervention,” in Alex
Picquero and Stephen Tibbetts, eds., Rational Choice and Criminal Behavior: Recent
Research and Future Challenges (New York: Routledge, 2002), 279–296.
18 Elliott Currie, “On Being Right, But Unhappy,” Criminology and Public Policy 9 (no. 1,
2010): 8.
19 Robert Tillman, “The Size of the Criminal Population: The Prevalence and
Incidence of Adult Arrest,” Criminology 25 (August 1987): 561–597.
20 David Boyum and Peter Reuter, An Analytic Assessment of US Drug Policy
(Washington, DC: AEI Press, 2005).
21 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Spouse Murder Defendants in Large Urban Counties
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1995).
22 James Q. Wilson and Allan Abrahamse, “Does Crime Pay?” Justice Quarterly 9
(September 1992): 373.
23 Wilson and Abrahamse, “Does Crime Pay?”
24 Ibid., 372–373.
25 James O. Finckenauer, Scared Straight and the Panacea Phenomenon (Englewood Cliffs,
NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1982).
26 Anthony Petrosino, Carolyn Turpin-Petrosino, and John Buehler, “Scared Straight
and Other Juvenile Awareness Programs for Preventing Juvenile Delinquency: A
Systematic Review of the Randomized Experimental Evidence,” The Annals of the
American Academy of Political and Social Science 589 (September 2003): 41–62.
27 Nagin and Pepper, Deterrence and the Death Penalty, 2.
28 Raymond Paternoster, Capital Punishment in America (Lexington, MA: Lexington
Books, 1991), part IV, “Arguments for and against the Death Penalty,” 185–270.
29 Furman v. Georgia, 408 U.S. 238 (1972).
30 Gregg v. Georgia, 428 U.S. 153 (1976).
31 Thorsten Sellin, The Penalty of Death (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1980).
32 Isaac Ehrhch, “The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: A Question of Life and
Death,” American Economic Review 65 (1975): 397–417.
33 Ibid.
34 Brian Forst, “Capital Punishment and Deterrence: Conflicting Evidence,” Journal of
Criminal Law and Criminology 74 (Fall 1983): 927–942. Peter Passell, “The Deterrent
Effect of the Death Penalty: A Statistical Test,” Stanford Law Review 28 (November
1975): 61–80. William J. Bowers and Glenn Pierce, “The Illusion of Deterrence
in Isaac Ehrlich’s Research on Capital Punishment,” Yale Law Review 85 (1975):
187–208.
35 Robert Hood and Richard Sparks, Key Issues in Criminology (New York: McGrawHill, 1980), 40–41. Zimring and Hawkins, Deterrence, 334. Philip Wattley, “City Hit
on Crime Data,” Chicago Tribune, 28 April 1983: 1–2.
36 Nagin and Pepper, Deterrence and the Death Penalty.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
DETER THE CRIMINALS
159
37 The two best studies of the subject are H. Laurence Ross, Confronting Drunk Driving:
Social Policy for Saving Lives (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1992), and
James B. Jacobs, Drunk Driving: An American Dilemma (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1989).
38 The Century Council, Stopping Hardcore Drunk Driving: Offender’s Perspectives on
Deterrence (Washington, DC: The Century Council, nd.)
39 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Jailing Drunk Drivers: Impact on the Criminal Justice SystemStatistical Tables (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1984).
40 National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Traffic Safety Facts, 2011 Data:
Alcohol-Impaired Driving (Washington, DC: National Highway Traffic Safety
Administration, 2012).
41 Jacobs, Drunk Driving, 27–28; Ross, Confronting Drunk Driving.
42 National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Traffic Safety Facts 2011 Data:
Alcohol-Impaired Driving.
43 Ross, Confronting Drunk Driving, 21–22, 168–170.
44 Ross, Confronting Drunk Driving.
45 National Survey on Drug Use and Health, State Estimates of Drunk and Drugged
Driving (May 31, 2012).
46 The Century Council, Stopping Hardcore Drunk Driving: Offender’s Perspectives on
Deterrence (Washington, DC: The Century Council, nd).
47 National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Traffic Safety Facts, 2011: AlcoholImpaired Driving.
48 Jacobs, Drunk Driving, Ross, Confronting Drunk Driving.
49 Dariush Mozaffarian, David Hemenway, David S. Ludwig, “Curbing Gun Violence:
Lessons from Public Health Success,” Journal of the American Medical Association 309
(February 13, 2013): 551–552.
50 Lawrence W. Sherman, “Police Crackdowns: Initial and Residual Deterrence,” in
Michael W. Tonry and Norval Morns, eds., Crime and Justice: An Annual Review of
Research (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990), V. 12: 1–48.
51 H. Laurence Ross, Deterring the Drinking Driver: Legal Policy and Social Control, rev.
ed. (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1984), 24–34.
52 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Jailing Drunk Drivers, 2.
53 Ibid.
54 Ross, Deterring the Drinking Driver, 33, 105.
55 Donald E. Green, “Past Behavior as a Measure of Actual Future Behavior: An
Unresolved Issue in Perceptual Deterrence Research,” Journal of Criminal Law and
Criminology 80 (1989): 781–804.
56 Federal Bureau of Investigation, Law Enforcement Officers Killed and Assaulted, 2003.
Report issued annually.
57 Jacobs, Drunk Driving, 47.
58 Jacobs, Drunk Driving, 98–100.
59 H. Laurence Ross and James P. Foley, “Judicial Disobedience of the Mandate to
Imprison Drunk Drivers,” Law and Society Review 21:2 (1987): 315–323.
60 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Jailing Drunk Drivers, 2.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
160
CHAPTER
6
61 Rodney Kingsworth and Michael Jungsten, “Driving under the Influence: The
Impact of Legislative Reform on Court Sentencing Practices in Drunk Driving
Cases,” Crime and Delinquency 34 (January 1988): 3–28.
62 Ross, Deterring the Drinking Driver, 111.
63 Jacobs, Drunk Driving, 126.
64 National Safety Council, Injury Facts (Washington, DC: National Safety Council,
2003). National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Traffic Safety Facts 2008 Data
Overview, Table 2.
65 National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Traffic Safety Facts, 2011 Data:
Alcohol-Impaired Driving, Figure 1.
66 Ibid., Table 3. National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Occupant Protection:
2011 Data (Washington, DC: National Highway Traffic Safety Administration,
2013). Traffic Safety Facts: 2008 Data, Motorcycles (Washington, DC: National
Highway Trafffic Safety Administration, 2009).
67 William V. Deutermann, Calculating Lives Saved by Motorcycle Helmets Traffic Safety
Fact: Research Note (Washington, DC: National Highway Traffic Safety
Administration 2005).
68 National Highway Traffic Safety Administration, Traffic Safety Facts Lives Saved in
2008 by Restraint Use and Minimum Drinking Age Laws (Washington, DC: NHTSA,
2009), Table 1.
69 Ibid.
70 U. S. Department of Transportation, Reducing Highway Crashes Through Administrative
License Revocation (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1986); Ross,
Confronting Drunk Driving, 63–67.
71 National Survey on Drug Use and Health, State Estimates of Drunk and Drugged
Driving.
72 Herb M. Simpson, “The Evolution and Effectiveness of Graduated Licensing,”
Journal of Safety Research 34 (2003): 25–34.
73 The Century Council, Ignition Interlocks: What You Should Know (Washington,
DC: The Century Council, nd). Insurance Institute for Highway Safety, Alcohol
Ignition Interlocks and the Prevention of Alcohol Impaired Driving. Presentation, NHTSA
Meeting, August 22, 2007, Washington, DC.
74 Richard Roth, Robert Voas, and Paul Marques, “Mandating Interlocks for Fully
Revoked Offenders: The New Mexico Experience,” Traffic Injury Prevention 8
(2007): 20–25. William J. Rauch, et al, “Effects of Administrative Ignition Interlock
License Restrictions on Drivers with Multiple Alcohol Offenses,” Journal of
Experimental Criminology 7 (2011): 127–148.
75 James C. Fell, Scott Tippetts, and Elizabeth Langston, An Evaluation of the Three
Georgia DUI Courts (Washington, DC: National Highway Traffic Safety
Administration, 2011).
76 Dariush Mozaffarian, David Hemenway, David S. Ludwig, “Curbing Gun Violence:
Lessons from Public Health Success,” Journal of the American Medical Association 309
(February 13, 2013): 551–552.
77 Quoted in Zimring and Hawkins, Deterrence, 97.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
7
Lock ’Em Up
GETTING CRIMINALS OFF THE STREET
“Lock ’em up” is not just a conservative crime policy. For the last forty years it
has been the U.S. crime policy. The first edition of this book in 1985 labeled it a
conservative policy, as distinct from the liberal’s preferred policy to seeking to
rehabilitate rather than punish criminal offenders. Even then, however, the
ground was shifting rapidly, and liberals were already on the way toward
embracing crime policies designed to lock up offenders: preventive detention
rather than bail; the philosophy of incapacitation to keep serious offenders in
prison and off the streets; and mandatory sentences to curb the discretion of
judges and ensure that convicted offenders would be sentenced to prison and
for long prison terms.1 We will look at each of these policies in this chapter.
The national consensus about locking up criminals resulted in a new and
astonishing era in U.S. criminal justice history, as Figure 1.2 in Chapter 1 indicates.
The impacts range far beyond crime and the criminal justice system, moreover,
affecting communities, families, race relations, prison conditions, and the budgets
of governments at the federal, state, and local levels. Taking 1972 as our starting
point, the number of people locked up in prison rose from 174,379 in 1972 (the
year before the surge began) to 1,598,780 in 2011. In addition there were 735,601
people in jail in 2011 (mid-year), 3.9 million on parole and 853,000 on probation,
parole, for a total of 6.9 million people “under correctional supervision.”2 At the
time it began forty years ago, no one had any idea that the enthusiasm for locking
people up would lead to this.
Criminologist have deplored the lock ’em up movement from the beginning. In the early years many predicted that it would not reduce crime, and
later, with evidence available, produced studies indicating that longer sentences
or incarcerating more people did not lead to lower crime rates. The titles of
some of their books express their sense of alarm: Jerome Miller’s Search and Destroy
(1996) argued that the war on drugs in particular targeted African American men3;
Todd Clear’s Imprisoning Communities argued that the huge imprisonment rate
161
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
162
CHAPTER
7
in the United States destroyed the communities from which most offenders come
from4; Michelle Alexander’s best-selling book The New Jim Crow went even
further, seeing a deliberate social policy to reverse the gains of the civil rights
movement and reestablish a racial caste system in the United States.5 These
books and numerous studies, however, had no impact whatsoever on popular
opinion or the decisions of elected officials.
We need to add a note here that there are straws in the wind of a change in
both public attitudes and public policy. Beginning in 2010, the growth in the
U.S. prison population leveled off. Across the country, many states revised their
policies to lower sentences or allow for the earlier release of prisoners.6 It is still
too early to tell whether a genuine reversal of public policy will occur. After all,
the change at the moment involves only an end to the growth in the prison
population, not a significant reduction. We will need to monitor events closely
in the years ahead.
Given the strong consensus of opinion on both the ineffectuality of mass
incarceration and its destructive collateral damage, criminologist Richard
Rosenfeld is surely correct in stating that “Mass incarceration is the criminological issue of our time.”7 In this chapter we will examine the major policy landmarks that have been responsible for so many people being locked up:
preventive detention as a bail policy, incapacitation as a sentencing policy,
and mandatory sentencing, including particularly the New York Rockefeller
Drug Law and California’s three-strikes law. We will conclude with an examination of sex offender registration and notification laws. Although they do not
involve locking people up, they reflect the same impulse of trying to keep
criminals at a distance from mainstream society.
JAIL NOT BAIL: PREVENTIVE DETENTION
The first opportunity to lock up a suspected criminal comes with the judge’s
decision to grant or deny bail. Conservatives believe that people released on
bail commit a large number of crimes. Thirty years ago, President Ronald
Reagan’s Task Force on Victims of Crime declared in 1982, “A substantial
proportion of the crimes committed in this country are committed by defendants
who have been released on bail or on their own recognizance.”8 Preventive
detention, a policy that allows judges to deny bail to high-risk criminal
defendants, is designed to prevent crime through incapacitation. It originated as
a conservative policy on bail, with most liberals denouncing it as both unconstitutional and ineffective in preventing serious crime. Over the past thirty years,
however, preventive detention has gone from a controversial innovation to
standard U.S. policy in every jurisdiction. Let’s see how this happened and
how it affected crime rates.
Bail is guaranteed by the Eighth Amendment to the U.S. Constitution, and
it was originally designed to ensure the defendant’s appearance at trial. What
most people do not realize, however, is that the Eighth Amendment does not
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
163
guarantee an absolute right to release on bail, but only that “excessive bail” may
not be imposed. Traditionally, it meant that all criminal defendants were eligible
for release on bail, with the exception of persons accused of capital crimes, or
those crimes punishable by the death penalty.9 In practice, a system of money
bail developed, which led to injustice for the poor defendants who could not
raise bail. Critics labeled U.S. jails the “new poorhouses.” Wealthy organized
crime figures easily raised large bail amounts, whereas poor people stayed in jail.10
Law professor Caleb Foote’s pioneering studies of bail in the 1950s found
that defendants not released on bail were more likely to be convicted and
imprisoned, thereby compounding the injustice of forcing them to remain in
jail before their court date.11 In addition, the money bail system contributed to
jail overcrowding, imposing unnecessary costs on counties. The civil rights
movement focused attention on the plight of the poor in jail, and the result
was a bail reform movement and led to the historic 1966 federal Bail Reform
Act. The law created a presumption of release and spurred the development of
release on recognizance and 10 percent bail plans, which allowed poor or
working poor people to obtain their release. Each of the fifty states followed
the federal example with their own bail reform laws. The impact of these laws
was dramatic. The percentage of people in jail who were being held for trial
dropped from 52 percent in 1967 to 33 percent in 1971 and then to 28.2 percent
in 2002.12 The change represented a significant victory for social justice.
Bail reform, however, coincided with the great crime increase in the mid- to
late-1960s. Between 1963 and 1973, the robbery rate tripled, and the burglary
rate went up two-and-a-half times. Conservatives saw a causal relationship
between the two developments (just as they did with the Supreme Court
decisions on the police, as we saw in Chapter 5), and blamed the new bail system
for the growing crime problem.13 Their response was to propose the policy of
preventive detention, which would allow judges to deny bail to defendants they
regarded as a danger to the community.
The initial demand for preventive detention focused on Washington, DC,
because of rising crime rates in the city and the fact that Congress, which governed the city, could act on the issue. In 1970, Congress passed a preventive
detention law for the District of Columbia, and the law offered the first test of
how preventive detention might work. It allowed a judge to hold without bail
for sixty days a defendant charged with a crime of violence or a dangerous crime.
Several procedures were designed to protect defendants’ rights. A formal hearing
was required to determine that substantial probability of guilt existed and that no
other release procedure could guarantee public safety. The defendant must have
been convicted of a crime in the preceding ten years; been a narcotics addict; or
been on pretrial release, probation, or parole. Finally, if the trial was not held
within sixty days, the defendant had a right to release on bail.14
Something funny happened in Washington, however. The law was hardly
ever used. (As we will see later in this chapter, the same thing happened in
most jurisdictions with three-strikes laws.) Judges detained few defendants without bail. A study by Georgetown University and the Vera Institute found that in
the first six months, prosecutors filed detention motions against only twenty of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
164
CHAPTER
7
six thousand felony defendants (or less than one-third of 1 percent!). These
motions resulted in nine formal hearings and eight actual detentions. Another
two defendants were detained through judicial initiative. Thus, only ten defendants were detained in six months.15 Moreover, five of the ten detentions were
reversed on appeal or reconsideration. Another was dismissed when the grand
jury refused to indict the suspect. Thus, a grand total of four people were fully
detained during the entire ten-month period.
What happened? The answer reveals how the courtroom work group can
adapt to a law it does not like. Federal prosecutors in the District of Columbia
had full discretion to use or not use the law, and they had some good reasons not
to. They could easily detain a defendant simply by setting a high bail that he or
she could not meet. Because most robbers are poor, unemployed, or marginally
employed, setting a higher bail amount than a defendant can afford is easy to do.
This is the courtroom work group’s traditional method of covertly undermining
the nominal right to bail. In effect, it says, “Sure you have a right to bail—how
much can’t you afford?” And remember from our discussion of the courtroom
work group in Chapter 3 that disagreements rarely erupt over bail.16 In short,
the DC preventive was effectively nullified.
The political mood of the country quickly changed, however, and beginning in the mid-1970s public attitudes about locking up allegedly dangerous
offenders affected courtroom work groups across the country, including
Washington, DC. By the 1980s, every state had enacted some form of preventive detention law. Congress finally embraced it for federal cases with the 1984
Bail Reform Act, which allows federal judges to detain a defendant without bail
if “no condition or combination of conditions … will reasonably assure … the
safety of any other person and the community.” Federal judges used it extensively, reflecting the “get tough” mood of the country. The number of defendants detained by federal judges increased from 2,733 in the first six months of
1987 (before the Supreme Court upheld the law in United States v. Salerno) to
4,470 in the last six months of 1988.17
The war on drugs—and the shift in public attitudes that drove it—
accounted for much of this increase: More people were arrested for drug
offenses, and prosecutors requested detention for drug defendants far more
often than for defendants of other crimes. Between 70 and 75 percent of the
prosecutors’ requests for detention were granted.18 The percentage of all federal
defendants detained before trial increased from 24 to 34 percent by 1996. In
truth, the major change was a shift in the method of detention. Before the 1984
law, virtually all of the detained defendants remained in jail because they could
not raise bail. After the law went into effect, about one third of those detained
could not raise bail; the other two-thirds were held because of the law.19 In
short, the 1984 law gave judges legal authority to do openly what they had
previously done covertly by simply setting a high bail amount.
At the state level, meanwhile, a steadily rising percentage of defendants
remained in jail before trial. By 2009, 38 percent of defendants in large urban counties remained in jail before trial, an increase over the 33 percent in 1971. These
individuals form part of the 2.2 million people who are counted as part of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
165
LOCK ’EM UP
the national incarcerated population. We might note that the seriousness of the
current offense and prior record, which we discussed in Chapters 2 and 3, has a
significant influence on bail decisions. Among robbery defendants, 56 percent
were held before trial, compared with 32 percent for larceny. Meanwhile, only 25
percent of those with no prior convictions were held, compared with 42 percent of
those with two to four prior convictions, and 53 percent of those with between five
and nine.20
We need to pause here to reflect on the significance of the dramatic shift in
bail policy from the 1960s to the present. The 1970 Washington, DC preventive
detention law was effectively nullified by the courtroom work group, but in later
years courtroom work groups across the country chose to implement similar
laws. The relevant point is that although courtroom work groups have enormous
power to shape the day-to-day administration of justice, they are not completely
autonomous and insulated from outside influences. On important issues of great
public concern—the war on crime and drugs, for example—they respond to and
reflect the dominant attitudes in society.
Crime on Bail: Myths and Reality
For our purposes, the question is whether preventive detention prevents
crime. We can examine the question by looking at the data on how much crime
defendants commit while released on bail. Let’s take a look at the data.
A defendant released on bail can “fail” in one of two ways: either by
committing a crime or by failing to appear (FTA) at a scheduled court hearing.
Let’s first look at crime on bail in Table 7.1. In 2006 (the most recent national
data available), 33 percent of felony defendants in large urban counties committed some misconduct. More than half (18 percent) failed to appear at court, and
another 18 percent were rearrested for a crime. (The figures add up to more than
33 percent because some defendants committed two violations.) Only 11 percent
were rearrested for a felony, however, and this figure indicates that the claim that
people out on bail are responsible for much of our crime problem is not based in
reality. The felony rearrest rates in 2006 varied according to their current arrest
T A B L E 7.1
Pretrial misconduct by released felony defendants, 2009
All F elony D efendants
Murder
Not rearrested (%)
Felony arrest (%)
Misdemeanor arrest (%)
84
8
7
100
0
0
R ape
86
3
8
R obbery
76
11
11
Burglary
78
12
7
Drug trafficking
82
10
8
SOUR CE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in L arge Urban Counties, 2009 (Washington, DC: Department of
Justice), Table 19.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
166
CHAPTER
7
charge. Persons charged with a violent crime were less likely to be arrested
(9 percent) than either property crimes (11 percent) or drug offenses (13 percent)
Given the public fear of sexual predators being set free, it is interesting to note that
rape defendants on bail had the lowest felony rearrest rate (4 percent) among all
crimes with the exception of murder (0 percent).21
With respect to FTA, moreover, most are not intentional. Defendants forget
their court date or are confused about the process (remember, felony defendants
are not known for their self-discipline). Most FTAs, in fact, are located and
eventually appear in court. The ones we should be concerned about are the
defendants who flee and become fugitives from justice.22
In short, the evidence does not support the conclusion that hordes of offenders out on bail are a major part of the crime problem in the United States. The
idea that offenders are is largely a result of the occasional celebrated case in
which someone released on bail does commit a horrific crime. Keeping more
pretrial defendants in jail will not reduce serious crime.
The Prediction Problem Revisited
Although it is true, then, that the felony rearrest rate for persons on bail is fairly
low, it is also true that some people on bail do commit felonies. It would be
good if we could prevent those crimes by keeping the defendants in jail before
trial. This brings us back to the prediction problem we discussed in Chapter 4.
Lowering the rate of crime on bail requires that judges make better predictions
about which defendants are most likely to commit another crime. The point of
preventive detention is to detain them and only them. Overpredicting dangerousness will result in many people needlessly being detained in jail. But as we
learned in Chapter 4, despite decades of research criminologists have yet to
come up with good methods of predicting criminal behavior. The data in
Table 7.1 reinforce the point that we have limited capacity to predict who is
likely to commit crime. Persons charged with a violent crime, who the public
really worries about, are less likely to commit another felony than persons
charged with property or drug crimes, and rape defendants have the lowest
felony rearrest rate.
Many people believe that testing arrestees for drug use would be a reliable
method of predicting whether a defendant is likely to commit a crime on bail.
The assumption is that the combination of an arrest and illegal drug use indicates a lifestyle that includes crime. A National Institute of Justice study of pretrial misconduct in six cities, however, found that “except for heroin use,
pretrial drug testing did not appear to help predict rearrests.” In fact, even
those defendants who tested positive for more than one drug were not more
likely to be rearrested than other defendants. Heroin use did predict rearrest
and was a particularly strong predictor in three of the six cities. Cocaine use
was a predictor of only FTAs. In the end, the best predictor of rearrest was
the number of prior arrests.23 In short, testing for drug involvement does not
help judges improve their decisions related to pretrial misconduct. And in fact,
according to the ADAM II program which tests arrestees for drugs, the
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
167
majority of arrestees in most cities test positive for use of at least one drug: 86
percent of arrested males in Chicago and 62 percent of arrested males in Atlanta
in 2012.24
A NATURAL EXPERIMENT A 1984 Supreme Court case on preventive
detention for juveniles produced a natural experiment in predicting dangerousness. A natural experiment occurs when a change in policy or practice creates
comparable experimental and treatment groups. A New York law had authorized preventive detention of juveniles who posed a “serious risk” of committing
another crime if released. In 1981, however, a federal judge declared the law
unconstitutional and enjoined its operation. New York appealed, and in 1984
(Schall v. Martin) the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that preventive detention for
juveniles was unconstitutional.25
The district court decision had a quirk, however; the judge enjoined the
commissioner of corrections from detaining allegedly dangerous juveniles, but
judges were not similarly enjoined. Thus, judges continued to order some
juveniles detained. These kids were turned over to the commissioner of corrections, who was forced to release them. This arrangement produced a natural
experiment that allowed an examination of how accurate the judges were in
predicting the dangerousness of a small group of juvenile defendants who were
ordered detained but promptly released.26
Jeffrey Fagan and Martin Guggenheim identified sixty-nine at-risk juveniles
who were ordered detained by judges but then released. They were compared
with a control group of sixty-four with similar backgrounds but who were not
ordered detained. After ninety days, 40 percent of the at-risk group had been
rearrested, compared with only 15.6 percent of the control group. In short, the
judges were reasonably accurate in identifying juveniles who posed a higher risk
than comparable offenders. This was achieved, however, at the cost of a high
rate of false-positives: 60 percent of the at-risk group were not rearrested.
Moreover, only 19 percent were rearrested for a violent crime, meaning that
the judges were not successful in predicting violent behavior.
Fagan and Guggenheim argue, as others have, that the goal of policy
reform is not to achieve perfection but to improve on current practice, to
make some marginal improvement in predictive accuracy. If you used an actuarial method for making preventive detention decisions based on objective
criteria and applied it to all the juveniles in their study, you would detain
members of the control group. Remember that they were comparable to an
at-risk group in terms of their background characteristics (about 90 percent of
both groups had some prior criminal record, for example). Yet only 15.6 percent
of the control group were arrested within ninety days (think of them as falsenegatives). Applying the same objective prediction formula to the control group
would result in detaining the 84.4 percent of the control group who were not
rearrested. This outcome translates into five false-positives for every true positive.
(Recall from Chapter 4 that the Wenk study produced eight false-positives for
every true positive.)
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
168
CHAPTER
7
Fagan and Guggenheim concluded that “the accuracy of prediction of
dangerousness during the pretrial period remains questionable.” And because of
the costs and limited marginal gains likely to be achieved, “preventive detention
appears to be unjustified.”27 As we will see shortly, the Rand Corporation
reached a similar conclusion regarding the prediction of high-rate criminal
offenders.
A Comment on Preventive Detention and Mass Incarceration
Preventive detention has contributed to mass incarceration. In mid-2012,
735,565 people were in jail in the United States on an average day. About
411,000, or 56 percent, of them had not yet been convicted of any crime.
In 1971, by comparison, only 33 percent of defendants were held before trial.
If the bail practices of that year had been in effect in 2012, there would
have been about 171,000 fewer people in jail, or about 8 percent of the total
incarcerated population.28
The evidence on crime committed by people released on bail leads us to the
following proposition:
15
PROPOSITION
Preventive detention will not reduce serious crime.
Speedy Trial: A Better Way
If we want to prevent both crime on bail and failure to appeal, speedy trial is a
much better approach. Among the 2006 defendants who were rearrested
before trial (or what we should really call the case disposition because as we
have noted many times already, only 5 percent of felony cases actually go to
a real courtroom trial), 7 percent were rearrested in the first week, 26 percent
within a month, and 49 percent after three months.29 Disposing of all cases
within five to six weeks would prevent about half of the crime committed by
persons out on bail (this assumes that most will be convicted and sentenced to
some confinement). Speedy disposition would also reduce the FTA rate and
preserve two constitutional rights: the right to bail and the right to a speedy
trial.
Actually, we have tried to require speedy trials. Congress and many states
have enacted speedy-trial laws. Yet, as Malcolm Feeley found in his research
on court reform, these laws were routinely evaded by the courtroom work
group.30 This is not a matter of prosecutors and defense attorneys being lazy or
irresponsible. Attorneys on both sides have good reasons for delaying trial. They
need time to prepare their case, to interview witnesses, and examine the evidence, and so on. Thus, we face another dilemma: how to achieve a desired
reform in the face of resistance by the courtroom work group. One possibility
might be to expedite trials for only those offenders who are high risks. This
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
169
policy would preserve their constitutional rights to both bail and a speedy trial as
well as protecting the public.
INCAPACITATION AS A CRIME POLICY
The theory underlying the U.S. lock ’em up policy is incapacitation, which
holds that crime can be reduced by imprisoning serious offenders. The logic is
simple: if a repeat offender is in prison, he or she won’t be able to commit more
crimes. It follows that if we keep them in prison twice as long (a ten-year
sentence rather than a five-year one), we will prevent twice as many crimes. As
a sentencing philosophy, incapacitation seeks only to detain; it does not try to
rehabilitate offenders, nor does it seek to deter them.31
There is an important distinction between two kinds of incapacitation.
Selective incapacitation is designed to lock up only the few high-rate offenders,
or career criminals. Like preventive detention, it builds on Wolfgang’s career
criminal research, which we discussed in Chapter 4. Gross incapacitation, on the
other hand, involves locking up large numbers of offenders regardless of their
criminal histories. That, in fact, is exactly what we have been doing for the last
forty years.
Selective Incapacitation: The Rand Formula
Selective incapacitation was one of the hot ideas in criminal justice in the 1970s
and 1980s. James Q. Wilson endorsed it in his influential 1975 book, Thinking
about Crime, claiming that serious crime could be reduced by one-third if each
person convicted of a serious crime received a mandatory three-year prison
sentence. He cited a study claiming that selective incapacitation could reduce
crime by an amazing 80 percent.32
These extravagant claims generated much excitement, and some criminologists set out to develop sophisticated selective incapacitation formulas. The lure
of selective incapacitation was that it would be scientifically precise. We would
imprison only the most serious repeat offenders, and thereby not increase the
prison population, with its attendant costs, while reducing crime. In fact, some
argued that we could actually lower the prison population and save money by no
longer imprisoning offenders who were a low risk of reoffending. As we now
know, it did not work out that way. Politics trumped criminology, and we
embarked on a decades-long policy of gross incapacitation, which many now
call mass incarceration.
Despite the failure of selective incapacitation to become national policy, it is
worth examining the idea in detail because the experience contains valuable
lessons about how sentencing policies work in practice, and the limits of even
the most sophisticated criminological ideas. The best statement of the idea was
a 1982 report, Selective Incapacitation, by Peter Greenwood and associates at the
Rand Corporation.33 It estimated that a fine-tuned sentencing policy could
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
170
CHAPTER
7
reduce robbery by 15 percent while also reducing prison populations by 5 percent.
We already discussed this report in Chapter 4, but let’s take another look at it in
terms of sentencing policy.
The Rand sentencing proposal was based on the Rand Inmate Survey (RIS),
which involved interviews with 2,190 prison and jail inmates in California,
Texas, and Michigan. The interviews were used to develop estimates of the average annual offending rates for offenders,34 which in turn used to estimate how
much crime would be reduced by locking up particular types of offenders. The
estimated annual offending rates were the crucial linchpin of selective incapacitation, and they proved to be the subject of considerable controversy among
criminologists, and ultimately the idea’s fatal flaw. Using the wrong estimate,
after all, will have a huge impact. If we estimate that the average career criminal
commits more than a hundred crimes a year, incapacitation will achieve a
substantial crime reduction. But if the average offending rate is only about five
crimes a year, the payoff will be relatively small.35
Rand developed a prediction instrument by correlating inmates’ background
characteristics with their self-reported criminal behavior. The result is a sevenpoint scale of factors associated with high rates of criminal behavior (see Table 4.3,
Chapter 4). Offenders were then classified as low risk (one point), medium risk
(two to three points), and high risk (four to seven points).
Rand then correlated inmates’ predicted offense category with their actual
self-reported level of criminal activity (see Table 4.4). The prediction scale was
correct 51 percent of the time. The 51 percent figure is calculated by adding the
predicted low rate and actual low rate (14 percent), the predicted medium risk
and actual medium risk (22 percent), and the predicted high risk and actual high
risk (15 percent). Thus, the prediction device was grossly wrong 7 percent of the
time (the 4 percent who were predicted high but actually low, and the 3 percent
predicted low but actually high). In the remaining 42 percent of the cases, the
prediction scale was only moderately accurate.36
In assessing the Rand estimates, it is important to remember that our goal is
to improve on current practice. When the Rand experts correlated their predictions with inmates’ actual sentences, they found that the judges imposed a
“correct” sentence (that is, a long sentence for a predicted high-rate offender)
42 percent of the time. In short, Rand’s proposed sentencing formula would be
only a slight improvement over what judges are currently doing, and what you
would get from flipping a coin.37
Why such a small improvement? The Rand formula has several problems.
Most important is our old friend the prediction problem. As other studies have
found, prior criminal records and other indicators such as drug use are relatively
weak predictors of future behavior. We consistently get significant numbers of
false-positives (people erroneously predicted to be serious repeat offenders) and
false-negatives (repeat offenders who were not identified by the formula).
In fact, in the face of widespread criticism, Rand reexamined its proposal
five years later and admitted that its previous estimates were “overly
optimistic.” And in a major concession that undermined the entire selective incapacitation enterprise, it conceded that “there are no reliable methods for either
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
171
measuring or predicting future offense rates.” In short, there is no reliable way to
achieve significant crime reduction by using predictions of offenders’ future
criminal behavior.38
A major problem with the Rand approach is that the estimated offending
rates are averages that, like all averages, are inflated by the extremely high rates
for the worst offenders. The Rand report itself admitted that “most offenders
reported fairly low rates of crime.” The median robbery rate was only five per
year, but the worst 10 percent averaged eighty-seven per year!39 Incapacitating a
member of the 90th percentile would in fact produce a significant crime reduction, but there would be only limited payoff for locking up any of the other
offenders with low annual offending rates.
The most shocking aspect of the Rand prediction scale is the use of employment history as a criterion for sentencing (see Table 4.3 in Chapter 4). An offender
acquires one point for having been unemployed for more than half of the two
preceding years. In their formula it carries the same weight as a prior conviction
for the same offense. Under the formula, an additional point might reclassify the
offender from a low risk to a medium risk, and thus it would mean the difference
between jail and prison. When you take out any one of the seven factors in the
prediction scale, the entire scheme begins to collapse. With only six factors, the
success rate will fall below the 51 percent that Rand estimates. You would then
be doing no better than judges currently do, using a combination of presentence
investigations and pure hunch.
It is outrageous that imprisonment might be contingent on unemployment.
The Rand formula would take us back more than two hundred years to the days
of imprisonment for debt. Even if such a policy were to become practice
somewhere, it would immediately be challenged in court. The fact is that
unemployment is highly correlated with criminal activity, but that correlation is
not something we should translate into crime policy. An alternative response to
the problem would be not to punish people for being unemployed but to
provide greater employment opportunities.
Finally, as our sentencing history over the past four decades clearly indicates,
the Rand selective incapacitation proposal faced a major political obstacle. The
idea of not imprisoning low-risk and medium-risk offenders is exactly what
corrections experts advocated in the 1960s. The 1967 President’s Crime
Commission argued that we locked up too many people, for prison terms that
were unnecessarily long, and recommended greater use of probation. In 1980 the
American Bar Association’s Standards for Criminal Justice stated that “in many
instances prison sentences which are now authorized, and sometimes required,
are significantly higher than are needed in a vast majority of cases.”40
But because of the get-tough-on-crime attitude that swept the nation, these
recommendations were ignored in favor of a policy of gross incapacitation, or
what has now been labeled mass incarceration.
If selective incapacitation seems too good to be true, that is because it is. The
evidence indicates that because of the prediction problem and the political obstacles related to adopting the lower sentences, we have to conclude that selective
incapacitation is not a realistic crime policy.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
172
CHAPTER
7
Gross Incapacitation: Zedlewski’s New Math
One advocate of selective incapacitation used the Rand data to produce a truly
astonishing estimate of the dollar savings that could be achieved. Edwin J. Zedlewski’s report Making Confinement Decisions. reached the startling conclusion that
imprisonment actually saves money. Challenging the liberal conventional wisdom
about the high cost of imprisonment, he calculated that for every dollar we
spend imprisoning a criminal, we save seventeen dollars in total social costs.
Although he focused on the dollar costs of crime, his formula has important
implications for crime reduction.41
How did Zedlewski reach such an amazing conclusion? Let us take a close
look at his figures. First, he estimated that in 1983 crime cost U.S society a total
of about 100 billion. This included 33.8 billion for criminal justice system
expenditures, 35 billion in victim losses (medical care, lost wages, property
damage, etc.), 26.1 billion for private security expenses, and so forth. The
NCVS, meanwhile, estimated that 42.5 million crimes were committed in
1983. Thus, Zedlewski calculated that each felony costs society 2,300 ( 100 billion
total crime costs divided by 42.5 million crimes).
Using the Rand RIS data, Zedlewski then estimated that each criminal
commits an average of 187 crimes a year. Locking up each offender for one
year, therefore, “saves” society 430,000 per year ( 2,300 multiplied by 187
equals 430,000). After you subtract the cost of imprisonment ( 25,000 per
year at that time), you get a net social “savings” of 405,000 a year for each
offender imprisoned (or about seventeen times the 25,000 cost of
incarceration).
If this seems too good to be true, it is. Franklin Zimring and Gordon Hawkins demolished the key assumptions underlying Zedlewski’s computations.42
The most serious problem is the estimate of 187 crimes a year. They point out
that Zedlewski did not mention the great disagreement among career-criminal
specialists over annual offending rates. Many put the figure at about eighteen
crimes a year, and some use an even lower estimate. If the average is only
eighteen, then locking up one criminal saves only 43,000 a year, according to
Zedlewski’s formula.
It was professionally dishonest of Zedlewski not to mention the debate over
annual offending rates and to use one of the highest possible estimates. As we
mentioned in Chapter 1, faith often triumphs over facts in discussions of crime
policy. Here we have a case of someone deliberately misrepresenting the facts to
make a point.
Zedlewski also did not take into account the problem of diminishing
returns. Assuming that judges systematically take into account prior record, as
we lock up more people we quickly skim off the really high rate offenders and
begin incarcerating more of the less serious offenders. Because they average far
fewer crimes per year (perhaps as few as five, according to the RIS), we get progressively lower returns in crime reduction and dollar savings for each offender
sentenced to prison.
The estimate of the dollar savings is also flawed. A reduction in crime does
not produce a direct reduction in criminal justice system costs. If the crime rate
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
173
goes down by 25 percent, no city is going to cut police department budgets by
25 percent. Because about 90 percent of all department budgets involve personnel costs, this would really mean laying off one-quarter of all the officers. In fact,
police departments have not reduced their size as a result of the Great American
Crime Drop that began in the early 1990s. Police officers do a lot more than
fight crime. About 70 to 80 percent of patrol work involves order maintenance
and service activities.43 These are important tasks that people want the police to
perform. The same is true for other criminal justice system costs. If crime drops
by 25 percent, the cost of running the criminal courts will not automatically
decline by the same percentage.
Finally, Zimring and Hawkins demonstrated that Zedlweski’s own formula
leads to utterly absurd estimates of crime reduction. They point out that between
1977 and 1987 the prison population increased by 230,000. If each criminal did
an average of 187 crimes a year, that should have “prevented” 43 million crimes
(230,000 multiplied by 187 equals 43 million). Yet this figure is a little more
than the number of crimes the NCVS reported as occurring in 1987. In short,
Zedlewski’s formula predicted the complete elimination of all crime by 1986,
which you might have noticed did not occur.
Of course that did not happen. First, criminals do not average 187 crimes
a year, as Zedlewski estimated (a small percentage of them do, but most
average only a few crimes). And second, he did not consider the replacement
factor: As some drug dealers are arrested, others take their place. You can do
your own update of Zimring and Hawkins’s critique with more recent data.
Compute the increase in the prison population from the mid-1980s to the
present, and using the estimated annual rate of 187 crimes per offender,
estimate the amount of expected crime reduction. In fact, as Frank Zimring
points out in his sober discussion of the Great American Crime Decline in the
1990s, when you look at imprisonment rates and crime rates for the entire
period beginning with the early 1970s, you find that crime rates fluctuated
like a roller coaster (up in the late 1980s, down in the 1990s), with no clear
correlation between the two.44
Incapacitation: A Sober Estimate
Having demolished Zedlewski’s fantastic estimates, Zimring and Hawkins undertook their own study of incapacitation, examining incarceration and crime trends
in California in the 1980s. Using a variety of sophisticated models, they
concluded that the incarceration of each offender in California prevented 3.5
crimes per year. We should note that this is one-fiftieth of the 187 figure used
by Zedlewski and is even lower than the estimates of other experts on career
criminals. The huge increase in the state prison population during the period
they studied reduced the crime rate by 15 percent by their estimate.45
As Zimring and Hawkins pursued their analysis, however, some problems
surfaced. For burglary, juvenile arrests declined significantly, but adult arrests
increased. This is “exactly the opposite” of what the incapacitation model
would predict because most of those incarcerated were adults. A similar pattern
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
174
CHAPTER
7
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
appeared with larceny and rape, but not robbery. Consequently, Zimring and
Hawkins concluded that it was not absolutely clear that incapacitation was the
“primary cause” of the drop in crime.46
Zimring and Hawkins also did a cross-state comparison of changes in incarceration rates and crime rates in seventeen states during the 1980s. California
stood at one extreme, with the greatest increase in imprisonment and the greatest
reduction in crime. Yet Georgia had a high increase in imprisonment and one of
the highest rises in crime. Minnesota, meanwhile, had almost no increase in
incarceration and virtually no change in the crime rate. In short, Zimring and
Hawkins could detect “no clear patterned relationship” across states between
incarceration rates and crime rates.47
Serious crime declined in the 1990s, but we should be skeptical of claims
that incapacitation was the sole or even the primary cause. Remember that we
have been on an imprisonment binge for forty years. Imagine going to a doctor,
getting a prescription, taking the medicine (two pills a day), but not getting any
better. You go back to the doctor, who increases the dosage (four pills a day).
But you still do not get any better. The doctor then raises the dosage again (six a
day). You repeat this process for twenty years. Finally, in about the nineteenth
year, you begin to get better. Was it the medicine? Probably not. You cannot
claim success for a prescription (pills/prisons) that failed for nineteen years and
then suddenly appeared to work in the twentieth year. In his more recent
book on The Great American Crime Decline, Zimring points out that the greatest
proportional increase in imprisonment occurred in the five years after 1982, but
that was a period of increasing crime. And recall that unlike deterrence, where it
may take some time for the message to take effect, incapacitation operates
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
175
immediately: the robber is in jail and then prison beginning with his arrest.
Finally, as we discussed in Chapter 1, Zimring points out that Canada enjoyed
a reduction in crime almost identical to the United States and the imprisonment
rate actually declined by 6 percent. Clearly, incapacitation was not a factor in
Canada’s success.48
In the end, there is no convincing evidence that incapacitation is an effective
policy for reducing crime. The idea of selective incapacitation failed for two
reasons. First, there was never any political support for imprisoning only a select
number of offenders, and second the idea of being able to identify only dangerous and repeat offenders proved to be a delusion. Although it is true that crime
rates began to drop in the early 1990s, the drive toward mass incarceration was
already almost twenty years old at that point and had had no evident impact.
Consequently, the evidence leads us to the following proposition:
16
PROPOSITION
Incapacitation, whether selective or gross, is not a realistic strategy for
reducing serious crime.
Selective Incapacitation Reborn
Many crime proposals never die; they just reappear some years later with a new
name, some new evidence, and the same old extravagant claims. So it is with
selective incapacitation. The Journal of Criminology and Public Policy in 2011 published a lengthy symposium on a proposal to both reduce the prison population
and reduce crime. We discussed this in Chapter 5, with regard to the police and
crime, but it deserves to be examined briefly in this chapter.
Steven N. Durlauf and Daniel S. Nagin present a proposal that involves
reducing the prison population and taking the dollar savings to invest in innovative police programs that have shown effectiveness in reducing crime.49 There
are several problems with their proposal, however. First, the innovative police
programs they cite have proven to be effective, but it is not clear that large
numbers of police departments are capable of undertaking such sophisticated
programs. Second, as we mentioned in Chapter 5, there is a long history of
police innovations fading away after the initial enthusiasm for them wears off.
With respect to the prison population side of their proposal, the evidence of
the last forty years indicates no political support for significantly putting fewer
people in prison. To be sure, there are signs of change, but the national prison
population has essentially leveled off, without any significant reduction.50 Second, Durlauf and Nagin skip lightly over the problems in designing a selective
imprisonment policy, which we have discussed. They argue that imprisonment
should be “reserved for repeat offenders who also commit serious crimes involving violence or large property losses.” (Notably, their bibliography does not
include Selective Incapacitation.) Our argument is that the tools for a scientifically
valid predictive formula do not exist, and considering the failure of criminologists
to develop such tools over many decades, are unlikely to be developed now.51
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
176
CHAPTER
7
The Durlauf and Nagin proposal is a bold and challenging one. No doubt it
will be examined more closely and debated in the immediate future. We need to
keep an eye on it. For the moment, however, it looks too much like the old
selective incapacitation idea, without addressing the political and the policy
problems that afflicted it.
MANDATORY SENTENCING
October 7, 2009, was a historic day in New York State because revisions to the
state’s Rockefeller Drug Law took effect. The 1973 Rockefeller Drug Law
became the model for harsh sentencing laws across the country over the next
forty years, putting a special emphasis on mandatory prison sentences as a
method of achieving incapacitation. A 1996 Justice Department report on
sentencing policies found that all fifty states had some form of mandatory
sentencing by 1994. The various laws designed to implement mandatory
sentencing are many. Most states have mandatory provision related to specific
offenses. Forty-one states have it for repeat offenders, thirty-one for certain
drunk driving offenses, thirty-two for certain drug offenses, and forty-two for
some weapons offenses.52 In many cases, mandatory imprisonment and a mandatory minimum prison sentence are combined in the same statute. Since 1971,
forty-three states enacted life-without-parole statues, resulting in a significant
increase in prisoners serving life sentences.53 Twenty-eight adopted truthin-sentencing laws that require prisoners to serve 85 percent of their sentences,
and another three have a 100 percent requirement.54 Meanwhile, by 1996,
about twenty-two states had adopted three-strikes laws, the crudest and most
extreme form of mandatory sentencing, which we will examine in detail
shortly.55 Finally, many states passed laws limiting the application of goodtime provisions to prison sentences, thereby delaying the possible early release
of many prisoners.56
Two factors have driven the popularity of mandatory sentencing laws.
The first is the punitive attitude that swept the U.S. public beginning in
the 1970s and the consequent support for greater use of imprisonment. The
second is the celebrated case syndrome we discussed in Chapter 2, which
regularly provides the public with an example of a criminal who commits
another horrific crime. The sudden popularity of three-strikes laws in the
early 1990s was driven in large part by the highly publicized case of Polly
Klaas in California. Twelve-year-old Polly was brutally murdered by Richard
Allen Davis, who was out on parole and had been twice convicted of
kidnapping. The understandable reaction of many Americans was to ask,
why wasn’t he in prison? If he had been, Polly would be alive today. Similar
cases occur regularly, all across the country. But as we argued in Chapter 2,
they are highly publicized precisely because they are so unusual, and for that
reason are not a sound basis for developing sound and effective crime
policies.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
177
Because it had such a profound influence on U.S. sentencing policy, and
mandatory sentencing for drug offenses in particular, the New York Rockefeller
Drug Law deserves a close look.
“THE NATION’S TOUGHEST DRUG LAW”
The 1973 New York Rockefeller Drug Law was immediately labeled the
“nation’s toughest drug law” because of its harsh provisions.57 The law contained
three major provisions designed to incapacitate drug offenders and deter future
drug use: mandatory and long prison terms for heroin dealers, restrictions on plea
bargaining for heroin dealers, and mandatory prison terms for certain categories
of repeat offenders.
The law established three categories of heroin dealers. Class A-I offenders
(major dealers, defined as people who either sold one ounce of heroin or
possessed two ounces) would serve minimum prison terms of fifteen or twentyfive years and a maximum of life imprisonment. Class A-II (middle-level dealers,
defined as those who sold one-eighth of an ounce of heroin or possessed one to
two ounces) would serve prison terms of at least six to eight and one-third years
and a maximum of life. Class A-III offenders (minor street dealers, defined as
anyone who sold less than one-eighth of an ounce of heroin or possessed up to
one ounce) would serve a minimum prison term of at least one to eight and
one-third years and a maximum term of life. In short, anyone caught selling heroin would definitely go to prison and would face the possibility of life
imprisonment.
The prescribed prison terms were considered extremely harsh at the time,
but they are not unusual today. The major change is that state laws and the federal sentencing guidelines have extended harsh mandatory minimum sentences to
other drugs, the use of firearms, sex offenses, and repeat offenses for other crimes.
The law attempted to prevent evasion of the law through plea bargaining.
(We will examine that issue in Chapter 8.) Anyone arrested for either an class
A-I or A-II offense could plead guilty to a class A-III charge, but people originally charged with a class A-III offense could not plead to anything lower. The
result was a floor that meant at least some prison time and a potential life term.
The law also included a habitual-criminal provision, imposing mandatory prison
terms on anyone with a prior felony conviction. To cope with the anticipated
increase in the criminal courts’ workload as a result of the law, New York added
forty-nine new judges, thirty-one of them in New York City.
In practice, the law provided yet another example of the power of the
courtroom work group to undermine the intent of a new law that sought to
change established practices. (Although as we shall argue shortly, that was a
short-term effect that eventually changed.) An early evaluation of the law concluded that “the threat embodied in the words of the law proved to have teeth
for relatively few offenders.”58 As the law went into effect, an enormous amount
of slippage occurred between arrest and conviction. Between 1972 and 1976, the
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
178
CHAPTER
7
percentage of drug arrests leading to indictment declined from 39 to 25 percent.
Meanwhile, the percentage of indictments resulting in a conviction fell from
86 to 80 percent. Thus, the overall percentage of arrests leading to conviction
fell from 33.5 to 20 percent. For those who were convicted, however, the rate of
incarceration went up from 33 to 55 percent, but this still meant that about half
the defendants were evading the supposedly “mandatory” sentencing provisions.
In this respect, little changed. The percentage of people arrested for sale of
heroin who went to prison was 11 percent in 1972–1973, and it was 11 percent
in 1976. The big change involved the longer prison terms. The percentage of
those who were convicted receiving a sentence of three years or longer rose
from 3 percent of all those convicted to 22 percent. This was the most important
effect of the law, and we will look at it more closely in a moment.
The slippage that occurred in the application of the Rockefeller Drug Law is
consistent with the long history of mandatory sentencing laws. A 1997 National
Institute of Justice review of mandatory sentencing found that “arrest rates,
indictments, plea bargains, and convictions decline after mandatory sentencing
laws go into effect,” and “early dismissals, early diversions, trial rates and sentencing delays increase.” These developments help many defendants evade mandatory sentences, whereas others are caught by them. The net result, according to
the NIJ report is that “The net probability that offenders will be imprisoned is
unaffected.”59 Although this was the traditional courtroom work group response
to mandatory sentencing laws, we will argue shortly that the data on the soaring
U.S. prison population clearly indicates that over time and across the country
mandatory sentencing provisions did work as intended and sent hundreds of
thousands of people to prison.
Finally, and most important from our perspective, the Rockefeller Drug
Laws had no significant effect on crime or drug use. An evaluation found that
heroin use in New York City was as widespread in 1976 as it had been in
1973. Serious property crime, the kind generally associated with heroin users,
increased 15 percent between 1973 and 1975, but neighboring states had similar
increases. Even more important, when cocaine and crack cocaine in particular
replaced heroin as the most serious drug, the law did not prevent an epidemic
from occurring in the late 1980s. New York City was particularly hard hit by the
crack epidemic.60
Over the years, the Rockefeller Drug Law led to a dramatic increase in the
number of people sent to prison on drug charges. Critics, however, charge that
in another example of the bait-and-switch syndrome, it mainly hit minor targets
rather than major ones. Many if not most prison sentences were disproportionate
to the harm of the crime involved. Although supposedly directed toward drug
“kingpins,” most of those people imprisoned under the law were convicted of
low-level, nonviolent crimes, and many had no prior criminal records. The law
eventually resulted in serious prison overcrowding, with all the associated costs.
In 2009, the twelve thousand offenders then in prison under the law represented
21 percent of all state prisoners, at a cost of an estimated 525 million a year
(at 45,000 per year per inmate in New York). Two-thirds had never been
imprisoned before, and 80 percent had never been convicted of a violent felony.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
179
African Americans and Latinos represent 90 percent of those in prison under the
law. And as we will argue in Chapter 14, this disproportionate impact has a devastating effect on families and communities.61
The 2009 reforms (which we should remember came thirty-six years after
the law went into effect) reduced the penalties in several different ways. They
eliminated mandatory sentencing for first-time Classes B, C, D, and E drugrelated felonies, and eliminated mandatory sentences for second-time classes
C, D, and E drug-related felonies. In both cases, judges can sentence convicted
offenders to probation, treatment alternatives, or prison. Prison is still mandatory for second-time Class B drug felonies if the defendant was convicted of or
had pending a violent felony in the past ten years. Additionally, the reforms
expanded drug treatment and alternatives to incarceration, with an appropriation of almost 71 million. Finally, it allowed resentencing for about 1,500
currently imprisoned offenders in certain categories. The new law did keep
mandatory prison sentences for the most serious offenses: Classes A-I and A-II
felonies.62
The 2009 reforms of the Rockefeller Drug Law had an immediate and dramatic impact. The New York Division of Criminal Justice Services reported that
commitments to state prisons for drug offenses dropped 33 percent, from 5,190
in 2008 to 3,513 in 2011. And the largest declines occurred for African American
and Hispanic offenders, dramatizing the racial dimensions of the war on drugs.63
The revision of the Rockefeller Drug Law in 2009 was a harbinger of an apparent shift in the national mood regarding imprisonment, as other states began to
revise their laws. We will take a look at that development shortly.
THE REAL IMPACT OF THE ROCKEFELLER DRUG LAW
The real impact of the Rockefeller Drug Law was not its short-term impact on
prosecution, imprisonment, crime, and drug usage in New York State, but its
role as a model for harsh sentencing laws across the country over the next four
decades. Every state enacted mandatory sentencing laws resulting harsher penalties for drug offenses and other serious, leading to our soaring prison population,
and what critics have labeled a national policy of mass incarceration. Driving this
process was a national mood insisting on more punitive sentencing that
overwhelmed the traditional capacity of the courtroom work group to evade
mandatory sentencing laws.
It is difficult to track all of the changes affecting sentencing and time served
by prisoners in all fifty states and the federal system over the past forty years.
Figure 7.1 lists the major categories, and it is important to understand how many
interacted with and reinforced each other. States’ mandatory minimum prison
sentence laws, for example, were often reinforced by a truth-in-sentencing law
that required prisoners to serve 85 percent of their sentence.
Convenient perspectives on the various laws contributing to longer prison
terms is offered by the Sentencing Project’s reports on recent sentencing reform
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
180
CHAPTER
7
efforts and the Pew Center for the States report on Time Served. These reports
are important indicators of the change in the public mood about sentencing, and
the resulting changes in state laws, but they also provide extremely valuable
perspective on how we got where we are today in terms of mass incarceration.
The Sentencing Project report The State of Sentencing 2012 identified a total
of forty-one changes in policies in twenty-four states in the year 2012 alone. In
2011, twenty-nine states revised fifty-five sentencing policies.
Seven states relaxed their mandatory minimum sentencing laws (and four did
so in 2011); one state (Connecticut) abolished the death penalty; two states created
or expanded procedures for modifying sentences after conviction; seven states
expanded the application of good time or limited the use of probation or parole
revocations to send offenders to prison; and three states modified their juvenile
life-without-parole laws (we will discuss life without parole in a separate section). 64
Regarding mandatory minimum sentences, the most notable changes
occurred when California voters in November 2012 modified the state’s threestrikes law, limiting its use only to cases where the third felony is a serious or
violent crime. Kansas, meanwhile, modified its penalties for drug possession,
eliminating presumptive prison sentences and allowing lesser sentences or drug
treatment. Five states (Georgia, Hawaii, Missouri, Oklahoma, and Pennsylvania)
adopted new laws under the Justice Reinvestment framework that prioritize
alternatives to incarceration for persons convicted of certain nonviolent crimes
and also expanding early release procedures. (The Justice Reinvestment concept
is an important development we will discuss in Chapter 14.)65 With respect to
probation and parole, Colorado created a new category of “achievement earned
time” that advances parole eligibility; Louisiana restored parole eligibility for certain life sentences; an Oklahoma referendum authorized parole eligibility for
nonviolent offenses (with 59 percent voting for it); and Pennsylvania expanded
the sentencing options for parolees guilty of technical parole violations.66
In short, there has been a change in the public mood and the beginnings of a
shift in public policy. Across the country, states are beginning to modify the laws
that have built up over the past forty years and which are responsible for today’s
enormous prison population. Most important, with regard to the purpose of this
book, an increasing number of people and elected officials are accepting what
most criminologists have been saying all along: that simply locking people up
does not reduce crime. The results so far are modest in terms of the total prison
population, and we will have to see if they represent the beginnings of a real
change in U.S. policy toward locking people up.
The Special Case of the Federal Mandatory Minimums
The mandatory minimum sentences prescribed by the federal sentencing guidelines, particularly for drug offenses, are a special case and have been subjected to
widespread criticisms. The severity of the federal sentencing guidelines is a direct
result of the stated purpose of the guidelines. The 1984 Comprehensive Crime
Control Act directed the development of guidelines that would further the basic
purposes of punishment: “deterring crime, incapacitating the offender, providing
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
181
just punishment, and rehabilitating the offender.”67 In practice, the first three
goals, deterrence, incapacitation, and punishment dominated the eventual
sentencing guidelines. The federal guidelines contrast sharply with the stated
purpose of the Minnesota sentencing guidelines, which were developed
explicitly to limit the use of imprisonment: “Because state and local correctional
facility capacity is finite, confinement should be imposed only for offenders who
are convicted of more serious offenses or who have longer criminal histories. To
ensure such usage of finite resources, sanctions used in sentencing convicted
felons should be the least restrictive necessary to achieve the purposes of the
sentence.” And the guidelines have achieved this purpose. For several decades,
Minnesota has had the lowest or next to lowest incarceration rate among all
the states.68
The harshest federal mandatory minimums involve drug offenses. The
guidelines mandate a five-year prison sentence for a first offense conviction
manufacture, distribution, or possession with intent to distribute twenty-eight grams
of crack or one hundred marijuana plants. A second offense carries a mandatory
ten-year sentence. They key phrase is the “possession with intent to distribute,”
because the intent aspect is far more flexible in interpretation that an act of
distribution. A first offense conviction for brandishing (but not firing) a firearm
during a crime of violence or drug trafficking carries a mandatory seven-year
sentence added to the sentence for the underlying crime (for example, the
robbery or drug sale).
In 2011, in response to a directive from Congress, the U.S. Sentencing
Commission delivered a report on the impact of mandatory minimum sentences.
(It was only the second such report in twenty years.) The report was highly
critical of mandatory minimum sentences. The principal findings included that
people serving a mandatory sentence represented 40 percent of all federal prisoners; the number of offenses carrying a mandatory minimum sentence had
doubled, from 98 in 1991 to 195 in 2010; three-quarters (77.4 percent) of the
convictions with a mandatory sentence involved drug trafficking; mandatory
minimum sentences were applied inconsistently, with some prosecutors’ offices
not applying them where they thought cases were “too harsh for low-level
drug offenders;” a majority of federal judges thought mandatory sentences were
“too high.” The report recommended reducing both the scope and the severity
of existing mandatory minimum sentence requirements.69
One particularly troubling part of the Sentencing Commission report are the
findings on disparities in applying the mandatory minimums. The purpose of all
sentencing guideline systems at both the federal and state levels, after all, is to ensure
consistency in sentencing. The fact that federal prosecutors find ways to evade mandatory requirements and reintroduce disparities is extremely troubling. We will
discuss this issue in more detail in Chapter 8 when we cover plea bargaining.
The Growth of Life without Parole
Another form of mandatory sentencing has been the growth of life sentences,
many of which are specifically designated life without parole (LWOP). By
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
182
CHAPTER
7
2012, one in nine U.S. prisoners was serving a life term (up from one in
eleven in 2008, a dramatic increase in such a short time). This involves a
total of 159,520 prisoners (up from just 34,000 in 1984), 49,081 of whom
have no possibility of parole. Five states account for more than half (58 percent)
of all the LWOP prisoners: Florida, Pennsylvania, Louisiana, California, and
Michigan. Additionally, about 2,500 juveniles are serving LWOP sentences
(out of a total of more than 6,000 serving life terms). Two Supreme Court
decisions, however, have greatly altered the status of juvenile LWOP
sentences.
In 2010, in Graham v. Florida, the Court ruled that, because of the scientific
evidence on adolescent brain development, with the exception of murder, a
person who was a juvenile at the time the crime was committed could not be
given the harshest sentence available. Two years later, in Miller v. Alabama, the
court, again citing scientific evidence regarding adolescents, ruled that a LWOP
sentence for a juvenile that did not take into account age and other relevant
factors violated the Eight Amendment prohibition of cruel and unusual
punishment. The latter decision may affect as many as 2,000 sentenced juveniles,
but whether the decision is retroactive and will result in the release of already
sentenced juveniles is still being litigated.70
The harshness of LWOP laws caused courtroom work groups to adapt, illustrating the laws of criminal justice thermodynamics we discussed in Chapter 3.
Although there were 3,140 prisoners serving three-strikes’ life sentences from
Los Angeles in 2008, there were only 39 from San Francisco where prosecutors
simply refused to use the law often.
Sentences of LWOP have been criticized on many grounds. Although they
are often used as an alternative to the death penalty, they do not receive the
same close scrutiny that death sentences receive and have only recently received
critical scrutiny. LWOP sentences also achieve virtually no crime reduction. It is
well-established in criminology that criminal activity goes down sharply with age
and reaches low levels after the age of thirty. Elderly prisoners are simply not
likely to commit any crimes. Of twenty-one people older the age of fifty
released in Ohio in 2000, none was rearrested in the next three years. In Pennsylvania, there was a recidivism rate of 1.4 percent in the ten to twenty-two
months after release in this same age group. Elderly inmates also impose additional costs on prison systems, particularly with regard to health care. California
estimated that it costs the state 98,000 to 138,000 a year for elderly prisoners,
which includes the construction of needed hospital beds for seriously ill
inmates.71 In short, LWOP is a sentencing absurdity: in addition to unjustly
imposing harsh sentences on thousands of people, it raises the prison population,
imposes huge costs on prison systems, and achieves no crime reduction.
Mandatory Sentencing and Crime
For the purposes of this book, the basic question is whether mandatory sentences
effectively reduce crime. On this issue, the evidence we have already cited with
regard to incapacitation is directly relevant because mandatory sentences are
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
183
essentially the device used to achieve incapacitation. As early as 1982, a Justice
Department report concluded that “it is difficult, perhaps fundamentally impossible, to substantiate the popular claim that mandatory sentencing is an effective
tool for reducing crime.”72 Years later, we had much more experience with
mandatory sentencing. A 1996 report on structured sentencing in a variety of
states found no correlation between incarceration rates and crime rates.73 Finally,
Zimring and Hawkins’s multistate comparison of incapacitation, which we cited
previously, also did not find any clear correlation between incarceration rates and
crime rates.74
After reviewing all of the evidence on mandatory sentencing, Michael
Tonry, one of the leading experts on sentencing, declared, “Mandatory penalties
do not work.”75 In his view, they are widely circumvented, tend to shift discretion from justices to prosecutors, and often result in punishments that are
“unduly harsh.” We agree.
THREE STRIKES—WE ARE ALL OUT
The most radical approach to mandatory sentencing involved the so-called
“three strikes and you’re out” laws. The idea of three strikes emerged suddenly
in the early 1990s, and is a classic example of how a new idea suddenly appears,
captures the public imagination as a “quick fix” for crime, and is seized on by
politicians and then translated into law. You do not hear much about threestrikes laws today, but they are on the books in several states and continue to
affect sentencing.
State three-strikes laws vary, but the basic concept is a mandatory life prison
sentence for anyone convicted of a third felony. The state of Washington passed
the first law, the Persistent Offender Accountability Act, in November 1993.
The idea really caught fire after the brutal murder of Polly Klaas in California
by Richard Allen Davis, a man with a long criminal record who had been
paroled only three months previously. California passed its three-strikes law in
March 1994.76
The Washington law mandated LWOP for conviction of a “most serious
offense” if the person had two prior convictions of “most serious offenses,”
which includes a wide range of felonies. The California law (which has since
been revised substantially) had separate two-strikes and three-strikes provisions.
The second-strike provision doubled the sentence for a person convicted of a
felony who has a prior felony conviction to a designated “strikeable” offense.
The third-strike provision mandated life imprisonment, with no parole eligibility
before twenty-five years, to someone convicted of a felony who has two prior
convictions for designated strikeable offenses. The 1994 Georgia law mandated
LWOP for a second conviction to a “serious violent felony.”77
Three-strikes laws were almost universally condemned by criminologists and
experts on sentencing. Franklin Zimring called it “the voodoo economics of
California crime.” Jerome Skolnick denounced it as representing the values of
“the dark ages.” John J. Dilulio, a conservative defender of the idea, countered
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
184
CHAPTER
7
by arguing that “society has a right not only to protect itself from convicted
criminals but to express its moral outrage at their acts by, among other things,
keeping them behind bars.”78
One of the major criticisms has been that three-strikes laws are crude instruments and do not focus on repeat offenders who have committed a series of
major crimes. They are, in fact, the polar opposite of the scientific precision
that selective incapacitation sought to achieve. The first California case, in fact,
involved Jerry Williams, who stole a slice of pepperoni pizza. The first woman
prosecuted under the law was arrested for a 20 cocaine purchase that occurred
fourteen years after her second strike. One of the first people sentenced to life in
prison in the state of Washington had stolen 151 from a sandwich shop; his two
previous strikes involved robberies totaling 460. In short, these laws violate the
basic principle of reserving imprisonment and long prison sentences for the few
offenders with the most serious criminal records in terms of the number and
seriousness of their offenses.
Actually, states have had repeat offender law for a long time. The first such
law in the United States was passed in 1797. A famous 1926 New York law
mandated life in prison for conviction to a third felony. A national survey of
repeat offender laws by William F. McDonald in the mid-1980s found that
these older laws were “rarely used” and widely regarded as a “dead letter.”79
Clearly, courtroom work groups simply ignored them. Forty-one states had
some kind of repeat offender or habitual offender law on the books in February
1994, before the three-strikes movement took off.80 Three-strikes laws raise the
same questions we have already considered in this book. First, will a law in fact
be implemented or simply evaded by the courtroom work group? Second,
assuming it is implemented, what impact will it have on the criminal justice
system? Third, will it reduce serious crime?
Implementation and Impact of Three-Strikes Laws
With the exception of California, and to a certain extent Georgia, states have not
used their three-strikes laws. An early study found that Wisconsin used its law
only once in the first year and a half, whereas Tennessee, New Mexico, and
Colorado did not use theirs at all.81 Evasion is easy: local prosecutors simply do
not file the charges necessary for the three-strikes provisions to take effect. In
some instances, the law becomes a plea bargaining tool. Many cases can be
filed either as felonies or misdemeanors (say, misdeanor assault versus felonious
assault). The law gives the prosecutor a powerful weapon to get a guilty plea to
a misdemeanor; in Sacramento, California, there were charge reductions in
67 percent of all the eligible cases. Even in California, application of the law
varied tremendously. Two-thirds of all cases under the law originated in Los
Angeles County. Officials in San Francisco, meanwhile, publicly stated that
they would not use it in certain kinds of cases, including drug cases.82
Did the law reduce serious crime as its supporters promised? Did it cause
huge backlogs in criminal courts as its opponents warned? What was the fiscal
impact on the state? In 2004, to mark the tenth anniversary of the California
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
185
law, the Justice Policy Institute (JPI) undertook an evaluation of the law’s
impact.83 First, the law did send a lot of people to prison for long terms.
By 2004 more than 42,000 strikers were serving terms in California prisons,
representing between 20 and 25 percent of all prisoners. Second, the immediate
impact of the law was not as great as initially expected. The California Department of Corrections had projected an additional 80,000 prisoners by 1999.
The reason only half as many were actually sentenced is simple: only a few
prosecutors in California used the law heavily. Los Angeles prosecutors used it
a lot, but San Francisco prosecutors hardly at all.
Third, consistent with the bait-and-switch problem we have previously discussed, the law weighed most heavily on the less serious offenders. The number
of third strikers grew from 254 in 1994 to 7,234 in September 2003, but the
number of second strikers soared from 4,154 in 1994 to 35,211 in September
2003. The JPI concluded that “[t]he Three Strikes law has a disproportionate effect
on people convicted of non-violent offenses.” Almost two-thirds (64.5 percent) of
second and third strikers were in prison for a nonviolent offense.84
The law also compounded the racial disparities in the California justice
system. The JPI found that the African American incarceration rate for third
strikes (143 per 100,000 African American residents) was twelve times higher
than the third-strike incarceration rate for whites (12 per 100,000 white
residents). Latinos were only moderately affected by the law.
Most important from our standpoint, the three-strikes law did not produce a
reduction in crime. In Punishment and Democracy: Three Strikes and You’re Out in
California, Franklin Zimring and his colleagues argue that even if fully applied, the
law would havehad only a modest impact on crime. They estimate that even if
all the arrestees who were eligible under the law “were to disappear from the
earth without a trace” (and thus commit no more crimes), the result would be
only a 10.6 percent reduction in felonies.85
The failure of the law to reduce crime was also confirmed by cross-state
comparisons. States without three-strikes laws experienced a greater average
drop in violent crime in the 1990s than states with such laws. In 2000, California
voters passed Proposition 36, the Substance Abuse and Crime Prevention Act,
which required that drug possession offenders be eligible for drug treatment
instead of prison. This included offenders who were three strikes—eligible and
had been out of prison for five years. And finally, in November 2012 the votes
substantially weakened the three-strikes law altogether.
Summary: Striking Out
Three-strikes laws represent all the worst aspects of the “get-tough” approach to
crime. First, they are a classic example of overreaction to celebrated cases.
Second, they represent a crude, meat-ax policy that sweeps up many nondangerous criminals. Third, they are not consistently implemented and thus increase the
arbitrariness of the administration of justice. Fourth, they upset the normal going
rate and impose new costs on local criminal justice systems, including more trials,
delays, and greater dollar costs. Finally, no clear evidence indicates that they
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
186
CHAPTER
7
reduce serious crime (and some good evidence shows that they incarcerate a lot
of people who will not commit any crimes at all).
Rereading today William F. McDonald’s 1986 report on the old repeat
offender laws is a sobering and depressing experience. In effect, McDonald
predicted all of the problems associated with three-strikes laws. Surveying all of
the states with such laws, he found: “Only a small fraction of eligible habitual
offenders have been or are currently being sentenced as such.” McDonald
interviewed members of the courtroom work group and found a general perception that “prior criminality is already being taken proper account of under the
normal sentencing structure.”86 In short, as we argued in Chapter 3, the prevailing
going rate did allow serious offenders to avoid significant punishment. For the
most part, the old repeat offender laws were used as plea-bargaining tools. Not
surprisingly, prosecutors gave the laws generally favorable ratings, whereas defense
attorneys and judges were highly critical.
McDonald’s report also anticipated the conceptual confusion that surrounds three-strikes laws. The old repeat offender laws failed to distinguish
among seriousness, repetitiveness, intensity, and dangerousness. Seriousness
refers to gravity of the particular crimes, including both the immediate crime
for which an offender is being prosecuted and past crimes. Repetitiveness refers to a
defendant’s prior record or criminal career. Intensity refers to the rate at which a
defendant has committed crimes in the past, as in the annual offending rate.
Dangerousness, meanwhile, represents a predictive assessment of the amount of
harm an offender might do to the community. McDonald found that practitioners
believed that the old laws often sentenced offenders who were “not truly dangerous predators but comparatively petty offenders.”87 As we have seen, three-strikes
laws are blunt instruments that often result in the incarceration of persons
convicted of relatively less serious offenses but whose records happen to fit a
mechanical formula.
17
PROPOSITION
Mandatory sentencing, in all of its forms, is not an effective means of
reducing serious crime.
JUST KEEP THEM AWAY FROM US: SEX REGISTRATION AND
NOTIFICATION LAWS
The national panic over sex offenses, especially sexual abuse or rape of children,
has led to a set of restrictive policies directed at sex offenders, including sex
offender registration and notification requirements, and restrictions on where
they may live. Restrictions on sex offenders are not, strictly speaking, a lock
’em up crime policy. But in important respects the policy is a first cousin. Instead
of keeping offenders in prison, it seeks to keep them away from our neighborhoods and our children.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
187
The celebrated case syndrome has had an enormous impact on the issue of
sex offenders. For obvious reasons, child abduction and sexual assault cases
generate enormous publicity. Yet, they are very rare; estimates consistently find
fewer than 200 child abductions by nonfamily members every year.88
The current national panic over sex offenders began with yet another
celebrated case, the 1994 rape and murder of seven-year-old Megan Kanka in
New Jersey. As a result, many laws are referred to as Megan’s Law. A 1996 federal law requires sex offenders who are released to the community to register
with state officials. The law allows state and local officials some discretion in
establishing procedures for notifying community residents about where
convicted sex offenders are living. The 2006 federal Adam Walsh Act expanded
the categories of offenders required to register for their entire lives. Also, for
the first time, juveniles as young as fourteen were required to register for fifteen
years.89
Advocates of registration and community notification believe that sex offenders pose a high risk of reoffending, that registration will assist law enforcement
in surveilling or arresting them, that the knowledge of this surveillance will deter
them from reoffending, and that notification will help residents take protective
measures they feel are appropriate.
The New Jersey registration and notification law illustrates how many laws
operate. It has three tiers based on an assessment of the offender’s risk of reoffending. Tier-one offenders, in the lowest risk category, are only required to
notify local law enforcement officials and their victim after release from prison.
Tier-two offenders are also required to notify organizations such as schools,
daycare centers, and summer camps. Tier-three offenders, in the highest risk
category, are subject to public notification through posters, pamphlets, and the
Internet.90
The New Jersey law and its counterparts in other states bring up our old
friend the prediction problem. How accurate are the New Jersey risk classifications? Are they evidence based? These questions, in turn, force us to take a look
at the facts on sex offenders and their reoffending rates. As we have already seen
in our discussion of bail, rapists have the lowest reoffending rate of all major
felony categories.
The Center for Sex Offender Management (CSOM), summarizing the
available data, estimates that sex offenders reoffend at a rate of between 10 and
24 percent.91 In one study, the rearrest rate for parolees who had been convicted
of rape over three years was 46 percent within the next three years after parole.
Although this was higher than in other studies, it was still lower than the rearrest
rate for all felons paroled (67 percent); it was far lower than the rearrest rate for
robbers (70 percent) and burglars (74 percent).92 In short, the danger of sex
offenders reoffending has been exaggerated.
The data on reoffending rates focuses our attention on the relevant question:
What is the real danger regarding sex offenders? How can we effectively protect
society? In fact, reported sex offenses have been declining for years. Adult rape
and sexual assault went down 37 percent between 2002 and 2011 as part of the
Great American Crime Drop.93 In New Jersey, the decline in reported sex
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
188
CHAPTER
7
offenses began in 1985. The social and political panic over predatory sex offenders,
therefore, is excessive.
The data on who offends, moreover, suggest that registration and notification laws do not protect us from the real potential offenders. Among sexual
assault victims under age eighteen, 90 percent knew their abusers; 34 percent
of the offenders were family members, and 59 percent were acquaintances. In
short, the image of the stranger predator lurking in the park to snatch a child
does not accurately represent most sex offenders. Nor are most sex offenders
repeaters: 87 percent of persons arrested for sex crimes had no previous criminal
conviction. Politicians repeatedly cite recidivism rates of 40, 74, or even 90 percent
(A public opinion survey found that the public believes it is about 75 percent). Yet
the data do not support such claims. A Justice Department study of fifteen states
found that among 9,691 male offenders, only 5.3 percent had been arrested for a
sex crime (and 3.5 percent had been convicted) after three years.94
Enforcement Problems
There are a number of problems with current sex offender and registration laws,
and they include the following issues.
OVERBREADTH The laws cover many people who are not really dangerous offenders and are certainly not likely to kidnap and rape or kill a child. The
laws cover people who have been convicted of urinating in public (exposure is
classified as a sex crime); people who have engaged in consensual sex, for
example between an adult male and a teenage female; adults who buy and
sell sex with each other; and even children who expose themselves as childish
pranks (the old game of playing “Doctor”). There is also overbreadth in the
length of time people are required to register. Seventeen states now make
people register for life.
Because of overbreadth, local law enforcement officials have difficulty even
keeping track of all the registered sex offenders they are responsible for. In Iowa,
for example, the County Attorney’s Association reported that local prosecutors
had lost track of half of all registered offenders. Offenders move and don’t report
where they are going; they lie about their status in their new location. One
county reported that before the law took effect, they knew where 90 percent
of the offenders were; afterward, they knew the residence of only about 50 to
55 percent. The laws make enforcement difficult because they drive offenders
underground. The requirements often separate them from their families if for
example, family members live too close to a school.
A previous evaluation of the Wisconsin community notification law found
that it imposed more work on probation and parole officials, especially when
intensive supervision was part of the requirement, and that community notification meetings left as many people attending those meetings feeling worried about
being victimized as were reassured. Offenders almost unanimously reported that
notification hindered their readjustment to society, making it difficult to find
housing and jobs, generating threats or harassment, and creating a general
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
189
atmosphere of social ostracism. (When we examine offender reentry programs in
Chapter 14, we will examine the many obstacles facing offenders who return to
the community.) The Wisconsin study did not, however, attempt to evaluate the
law’s effect on recidivism.95
RESIDENCY RESTRICTIONS The Human Rights Watch report, No
Easy Answers, concludes that the residency requirements in sex offender laws
“may be the harshest as well as the most arbitrary” of all the new restrictions
on criminal offenders. About twenty states have laws that put restrictions on
where sex offenders can live. Typically they forbid an offender from living less
than 1,000 or 2,500 feet from schools, daycare centers, and public parks and
swimming pools. Some homeless shelters refuse to accept sex offenders. In
some cases, there is almost no place an offender can live. In Orange City,
Florida, only 5 percent of the city is outside a zone where sex offenders cannot
live. Nearly half the sex offenders in Florida reported they could not live with
their own family members. Meanwhile, hundreds of cities have similar local
ordinances. And in Miami, Florida, a group of offenders were living under a
bridge because they could not find housing anywhere. One offender in Iowa
could not live with and care for his sick grandmother because she lived near a
child care center. Another Iowa registrant listed his address as “behind the Target
[store] on Euclid [street].”96
INTERFERING WITH EFFECTIVE TREATMENT Registration,
notification, and residency restriction laws interfere with effective treatment for
sex offenders. Family members are the people who are likely to be supportive of
and help them rehabilitate themselves (reminding them to attend their counseling sessions, keeping an eye on them, and so on). In many cases, the added
financial stress of maintaining two residences disrupts offenders’ lives and those
of family members. Numerous laws, meanwhile, prevent them from finding
employment. It is difficult to get and keep a job when you are living out behind
a Target store or under a bridge. Some employers are required to check sex
offender registries. Many employers refuse to hire offenders even though the
law does not prohibit them from doing so. States do, however, have laws barring
employment at schools and child care centers. Parolees unable to meet the
employment conditions of their release, of course, are more likely to recidivate
(as is the case with all ex-offenders, regardless of their crime).
FAILURE TO PROTECT SOCIETY Perhaps most seriously, the laws do
not really protect society. A Minnesota study found that offenders were more
likely to recidivate if they traveled to a different city. The two offenders who
did commit new sex crimes committed them miles from where they were living.
A 2007 Minnesota study found that most repeat offenders found their victims
through social networks and not as strangers on the street or in a park.
An evaluation of the New Jersey Sex Offender Registration and Notification
Law found only “limited effects” on crime. It had “no demonstrable effect on
the number of victims involved in sexual offenses.” Sex crimes began declining
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
190
CHAPTER
7
in the state since 1985, a decade before the law was passed, and that downward
trend continued. As is the case nationally, half of all sex offenses involve incest
or child molestation, and in half of all cases the victim knows the offender. In
2006, counties across New Jersey spent an estimated 3.9 million implementing
the law.97
Summary
After looking at all the evidence, what do we know? The best answer is reflected
in the title of the Human Rights Watch report: there are No Easy Answers. Sex
crimes are indeed a serious problem, with terrible, traumatic effects on their
victims, particularly when they are children. A certain number of sex offenders
do repeat. We should not minimize these unpleasant facts. The problem is that
our current policies have swung too far in the direction of crime control,
exaggerating the problem and imposing restrictions that are not only irrelevant
for many offenders but are also ineffective for the real problem cases and often
counterproductive. Human Rights Watch found that the United States is the
only country in the world with such an array of restrictions on sex offenders.
Other countries debated similar laws but rejected them. As is the case with
overincarceration of offenders, the United States is “alone in the world.”
18
PROPOSITION
Sex offender registration, notification, and residency restriction laws are
not effective in preventing repeat sex crimes and in certain respects inhibit
effective control and treatment of offenders.
CONCLUSION
From a commonsense standpoint, lock ’em up strategies appear to be a simple
and effective way to reduce crime: Get repeat offenders off the street and they
won’t be able to prey on society. Unfortunately, it is not that simple in the real
world of the criminal justice system. First, we cannot precisely identify the
small group of high-rate offenders. Second, gross incapacitation policies create
all sorts of problems in the justice system. Third, because of these problems, the
courtroom work group often finds ways to evade extremely punitive laws.
Fourth, no conclusive evidence indicates that locking up a lot of people
actually produces the promised reductions in crime. Finally, even when some
crime reduction does occur, it is not clear that it is worth the enormous dollar
cost to society.
Where does that leave us? As we have already suggested, the best response is
captured by the title of the Human Rights Watch Report: there are No Easy
Answers. Dangerous criminals do exist, and they deserve to be punished. The
problem is that it is difficult to spot them early in their criminal careers. The
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
191
prediction problem gets in the way of many easy-sounding solutions. Unfortunately, we have ignored the prediction problem and embarked on a course of
gross incapacitation. As we have argued, this not only does not effectively reduce
crime, but it also imposes many other high costs on society. In Chapter 14, we
will try to bring together some of the promising policies that have emerged and
suggest some sensible answers to our difficult crime problem.
NOTES
1 See the critical discussion of President Bill Clinton’s crime policies in the 1990s in
Michael Tonry, “Less Imprisonment is No Doubt a Good Thing: More Policing
Probably is Not,” Criminology and Public Policy 10 (no 1, 2011), 137–152.
2 Nicole D. Porter, The State of Sentencing 2011 (Washington DC: The Sentencing
Project, 2012). Bureau of Justice Statistics, Historical Statistics on Prisoners in State and
Federal Institutions, Yearend 1925–1986 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice,
1988), Table 1.
3 Jerome G. Miller, Search and Destroy: African American Males in the Criminal Justice
System (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
4 Todd R. Clear, Imprisoning Communities: How Mass Incarceration Makes Disadvantaged
Communities Worse (New York: Oxford University Press, 2007).
5 Michelle Alexander, The New Jim Crow: Mass Incarceration in the Age of Colorblindness
(New York: The New Press, 2010).
6 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Prisoners in 2011 (Washington, DC: Department of
Justice, 2012).
7 Richard Rosenfeld, “From Mass Incarceration to Targeted Policing: Introduction to
the Special Issue,” Criminology and Public Policy 10 (No. 1, 2011), 3.
8 President’s Task Force on Victims of Crime, Final Report (Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office, 1982), 22.
9 Caleb Foote, “The Coming Constitutional Crisis in Bail,” University of Pennsylvania
Law Review 113 (May 1965): 959–999 and ibid., (June 1965): 1125–1185.
10 On the background of the bail issue, see Wayne Thomas, Bail Reform in America
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1976).
11 Caleb Foote, “Compelling Appearance in Court: Administration of Bail in
Philadelphia,” University of Pennsylvania haw Review 102 (1954): 1031–1079.
12 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Profile of Jail Inmates, 2002 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2004). Thomas, Bail Reform in America.
13 Samuel Walker, Popular Justice: A History of American Criminal Justice, 2nd ed. (New
York: Oxford University Press, 1998).
14 Preventive Detention in the District of Columbia: The First Ten Months (Washington,
DC: Georgetown Institute of Criminal Law and Procedure, 1972); Thomas, Bail
Reform in America, 231–232.
15 Thomas, Bail Reform in America, 231-232.
16 Frederic Suffet, “Bail Setting: A Study of Courtroom Interaction,” Crime and
Delinquency 12 (1966): 318–331.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
192
CHAPTER
7
17 United States v. Salerno, 481 U.S. 739 (1987).
18 General Accounting Office, Criminal Bail: “How Bail Reform Is Working in Selected
District Courts” (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1987). Bureau of Justice
Statistics, Pretrial Release and Detention: The Bail Reform Act of 1984 (Washington,
DC: Department of Justice, 1988).
19 Thomas E. Scott, “Pretrial Detention under the Bail Reform Act of 1984: An
Empirical Analysis,” American Criminal Law Review 27 (No. 1, 1989): 1–51. Bureau
of Justice Statistics, Federal Pretrial Release and Detention, 1996 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 1999).
20 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2009
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2013), Tables 12, 13.
21 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2009. Bureau
of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2004, Statistical Tables
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2008).
22 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2006, Table 18.
23 William Rhodes, Raymond Hyatt, and Paul Scherman, Predicting Pretrial Misconduct
with Drug Tests of Arrestees: Evidence from Six Sites (Washington, DC: Department of
Justice, 1996).
24 Office of National Drug Control Policy, Adam II 2012 Annual Report (Washington,
DC: Department of Justice, 2013).
25 Schall v. Martin, 467 U.S. 253 (1984).
26 Jeffrey Fagan and Martin Guggenheim, “Preventive Detention and the Judicial
Prediction of Dangerousness for Juveniles: A Natural Experiment,” Journal of
Criminal Law and Criminology 86(2) (1996): 415–448.
27 Ibid., 445, 448.
28 Bureau of Criminal Justice Statistics, Jail Inmates at Midyear 2012—Statistical Tables
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2013).
29 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2006, Table 10.
30 Malcolm Feeley, Court Reform on Trial (New York: Basic Books, 1983).
31 Franklin E. Zimring and Gordon Hawkins, Incapacitation: Penal Confinement and the
Restraint of Crime (New York: Oxford University Press, 1995).
32 James Q. Wilson, Thinking about Crime (New York: Basic Books, 1975), 200–202.
33 Peter Greenwood, Selective Incapacitation (Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corporation,
1982).
34 Jan M. Chaiken and Marcia R. Chaiken, Varieties of Criminal Behavior Summary and
Polity Implications (Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corporation, 1982).
35 Alfred Blumstein, Jacqueline Cohen, Jeffrey Roth, and Christy Visher, eds., Criminal
Careers and “Career Criminals” (Washington, DC: National Academy of Sciences,
1988).
36 Ibid., 59.
37 Ibid., 60.
38 Peter W. Greenwood and Susan Turner, Selective Incapacitation Revisited: Why the
High-Rate Offenders Are Hard to Predict (Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corporation,
1987).
39 Ibid., Table 4.3.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
193
40 American Bar Association, Standards for Criminal Justice, “Sentencing Alternatives and
Procedures,” Standard 18-2.1 (Boston: Little, Brown, 1980), 18–25. A good
discussion of recent developments is Nicole Porter, The State of Sentencing, 2011:
Developments in Policy and Practice (Washington, DC: The Sentencing Project, 2012).
41 Edwin W. Zedlewski, Making Confinement Decisions (Washington, DC: Department
of Justice, 1987).
42 Franklin E. Zimring and Gordon E. Hawkins, “The New Mathematics of
Imprisonment,” Crime and Delinquency 34 (October 1988): 425–436. See also
Zimring and Hawkins, Incapacitation.
43 Enc J. Scott, Calls for Service (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1981).
44 Franklin E. Zimring, The Great American Crime Decline (New York: Oxford
University Press, 2007), 46–56.
45 Zimring and Hawkins, Incapacitation.
46 Ibid., 126.
47 Ibid., 106–107.
48 Zimring, The Great American Crime Decline, 51, 120–121.
49 Steven N. Durlauf and Daniel S. Nagin, “Imprisonment and Crime: Can Both Be
Reduced?” Criminology and Public Policy 10 (No. 1, 2011): 13–54.
50 Recent developments are reported in Porter, The State of Sentencing 2011.
51 Durlauf and Nagin, “Imprisonment and Crime: Can Both be Reduced?,” 38.
52 Bureau of Justice Assistance, National Assessment of Structured Sentencing (Washington,
DC: Department of Justice, 1996), 24–25.
53 The Sentencing Project, Life Goes On: The Historic Rise in Life Sentences in America
(Washington, DC: The Sentencing Project, 2013).
54 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Truth in Sentencing in State Prisons (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 1999).
55 Campaign for an Effective Crime Policy, The Impact of “Three Strikes and You’re Out”
Laws: What Have We Learned (Washington, DC: Campaign for an Effective Crime
Policy, 1996).
56 A good introduction to the various laws affecting prison terms is the review of
recent efforts by states to modify or repeal them in Porter, The State of Sentencing,
2011.
57 U.S. Department of Justice, The Nation’s Toughest Drug Law Evaluating the New York
Experience (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1978).
58 Ibid., 18.
59 Dale Parent, Terence Dunworth, Douglas McDonald, and William Rhodes,
Mandatory Sentencing (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1997).
60 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Drugs, Crime, and the Justice System (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 1992), 30.
61 Drug Policy Alliance, New York’s Rockefeller Drug Laws: Explaining the Reforms of
2009 (New York: Drug Policy Alliance, 2009). www.drugpolicy.org. Partnership
for Responsible Drug Information, Rockefeller Drug Law Information Sheet (New
York: Partnership for Responsible Drug Information, 2009). www.prdi.org.
62 Ibid.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
194
CHAPTER
7
63 New York Division of Criminal Justice Services, 2009 Drug Law Changes, June 2012
Update (Albany: Division of Criminal Justice Services, 2012).
64 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table 6.13.2011.
65 Council of State Governments, Lessons from the States: Reducing Recidivism and
Curbing Corrections Costs Through Justice Reinvestment (Washington, DC: Council of
State Governments, 2013).
66 Porter, The State of Sentencing, 2011.
67 U.S. Sentencing Commission, 1987 Federal Sentencing Guidelines Manual, Chapter
One: Introduction and General Application Principles.
68 Minnesota Sentencing Commission, Minnesota Sentencing Guidelines and Commentary
(August 1, 2012). State incarceration rates: Bureau of Justice Statistics, Prisoners in
2012—Advance Counts (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2012).
69 U.S. Sentencing Commission, Report to Congress: Mandatory Minimum Penalties in the
Federal Criminal Justice System (Washington, DC: U.S. Sentencing Commission,
2011). See the review of the report in The Sentencing Project, Federal Mandatory
Minimum Sentencing: An Overview of the 2011 Report by the U.S. Sentencing Commission
(Washington, DC: The Sentencing Project, 2011).
70 The Sentencing Project, Life Goes On, p. 11. Ashley Nellis, “Tinkering with Life: A
Look at the Inappropriateness of Life without Parole as an Alternative to the Death
Penalty,” University of Miami Law Review 67 (2013): 439–458. Ashley Nellis and
Ryan S. King, No Exit: The Expanding Use of Life Sentences in America (Washington,
DC: The Sentencing Project, 2009). Graham v. Florida, 560 U.S. ___ (2010). Miller
v. Alabama, 567 U.S. ___ (2012).
71 Nellis and King, No Exit.
72 U.S. Department of Justice, Mandatory Sentencing: The Experience of Two States
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1982).
73 Bureau of Justice Assistance, National Assessment of Structured Sentencing, 117.
74 Zimring and Hawkins, Incapacitation.
75 Michael Tonry, “Mandatory Penalties,” in Michael Tonry, ed., Crime and Justice: A
Review of Research, 16 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1992), 243.
76 Franklin E. Zimring, Gordon Hawkins, and Sam Kamin, Punishment and Democracy:
Three Strikes and You’re Out in California (New York: Oxford University Press, 2001).
77 Michael G. Turner, Jody Sundt, Brandon K. Applegate, and Francis T. Cullen,
“‘Three Strikes and You’re Out’ Legislation: A National Assessment,” Federal
Probation 59 (September 1995): 16–35.
78 Jerome H. Skolnick, “Wild Pitch,” American Prospect 17 (Spring 1994): 31–37.
Shichor and Sechrest, Three Strikes and You’re Out. John J. Dilulio, Jr., “Instant
Replay,” American Prospect 18 (Summer 1994): 12–18.
79 William F. McDonald, Repeat Offender Laws in the United States: The Form, Use, and
Perceived Value (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1986), 5.
80 Bureau of Justice Assistance, National Assessment of Structured Sentencing, pp. 24–25.
Turner et al., “‘Three Strikes and You’re Out’ Legislation.”
81 Zimring, Hawkins et al. Punishment and Democracy: Three Strikes and You’re Out in
California.
82 Ibid.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
LOCK ’EM UP
195
83 Scott Ehlers, Vincent Schiraldi, and Jason Ziedenberg, Still Striking Out: Ten Years of
California’s Three Strikes (Washington, DC: Justice Policy Institute, 2004). Available
on the Justice Policy Institute website. http://www.justicepolicy.org/index.html.
Accessed February 14, 2014.
84 Ibid.
85 Zimring, Hawkins et al. Punishment and Democracy: Three Strikes and You’re Out in
California.
86 McDonald, Repeat Offender Laws in the United States, Abstract, np.
87 Ibid., 7, 9.
88 An estimate of 115 per year is at National Center for Missing and Exploited
Children, Key Facts, available at www.missingkids.com/keyfacts. Accessed February
14, 2014.
89 Human Rights Watch, No Easy Answers: Sex Offender Laws in the United States
(New York: Human Rights Watch, 2007). Peter Finn, Sex Offender Community
Notification (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1997).
90 Kristen M. Zgoba, and Karen Bachar, Sex Offender Registration and Notification:
Limited Effects in New Jersey (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, April 2009).
91 Center for Sex Offender Management, Fact Sheet: What You Need to Know About Sex
Offenders (Washington, DC: Center for Sex Offender Management, 2008).
92 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Recidivism of Prisoners Released in 1994 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2002).
93 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2011 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2012), Table 2.
94 Human Rights Watch, No Easy Answers.
95 Richard G. Zevitz and Mary Ann Farkas, Sex Offender Community Notification:
Assessing the Impact in Wisconsin (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2001).
96 Human Rights Watch, No Easy Answers.
97 Zgoba, and Bachar, Sex Offender Registration and Notification Limited Effects in New Jersey.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
8
Close the Loopholes
D
o dangerous criminals “beat the system” and escape punishment because of
loopholes in the system? Do their lawyers get their cases dismissed? Are they
allowed to plead guilty to lesser offenses, so that they either don’t go to prison or
only for short terms? Do they have their convictions overturned on appeal, so
that they go free? Conservatives believe that loopholes allow many dangerous
criminals to avoid conviction and punishment and are a major part of our
crime problem. Let’s take a close look at these beliefs and some of the proposals
to close alleged loopholes in the criminal justice system.
PROSECUTE THE CAREER CRIMINAL
Many conservatives believe that dangerous criminals repeatedly avoid prosecution, punishment, and conviction, and as a result are able to commit many repeat
offenses. To close this alleged loophole, some prosecutor’s offices have created
major-offender or career criminal programs. The basic idea is to focus special attention
on this category of offenders and to make sure they are prosecuted, convicted,
and sentenced to an appropriately long prison term. Some programs focus on the
career criminals we discussed in Chapter 4, offenders with long criminal records.
Others focus on people charged with particularly serious crimes, such as sexual
assaults or crimes where guns are used. Do these programs work? Do they close a
loophole in the system? Does this loophole even exist? If it does, how big is it?
And can it be closed?
Special prosecutor’s units address the distinction between “horizontal” and
“vertical” approaches to prosecution. Most large urban prosecutors’ offices use a
horizontal approach. One group of prosecutors handles the initial filing of
charges and arraignment. Another group takes the case to trial and negotiates
plea bargains. In some offices, a separate group of trial specialists handles the
few trials that occur. In the vertical approach, one prosecutor (or more, in a
complex case) handles the case from initial charge through to its end.
196
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
197
Advocates of vertical prosecution believe it has many benefits. Each prosecutor
becomes intimately involved in the cases he or she is responsible for. Important
factors are not lost as a case is passed from one attorney to another. Some advocates
believe that prosecutors are more likely to become more personally committed to
each case and with the victims, and consequently are less likely to plea bargain
down to a much lesser charge. Vertical prosecution programs involving particular
crimes such as sexual assaults are believed to keep prosecutors focused on the seriousness of those crimes. An additional expected benefit is that crime victims gain
greater comfort from dealing with only one attorney throughout the case. The
prosecutors, meanwhile, get to know the victims, and this is believed to increase
their commitment to a case. With regard to sex crimes or gun crimes, moreover, specialization helps prosecutors develop expertise in handling the special
characteristics of those kinds of cases. Continuity can also help eliminate disparities
in dispositions. Presumably, you don’t have different prosecutors negotiating
different kinds of plea bargains.
Does a Special Prosecutorial Unit Make a Difference?
Does having a special prosecutorial unit make a difference? Cassie Spohn and
Dawn Beichner compared the prosecutors’ offices in Kansas City, Missouri,
which had a special prosecutorial unit for sex crimes, with Miami, Florida,
which did not have one. In Kansas City, special unit prosecutors handled cases
from the initial charging decision through to the final disposition. In Miami, one
set of attorneys handled the initial charging decision, and the case was then
passed to a separate group who handled the case to its end. Most notably, charges
were filed in nearly identical percentage of all cases received by the two offices
(both around 58 percent). Interviews, moreover, found that prosecutors in both
offices reported that the same factors influenced decisions. Both charged or
dismissed on whether there was proof beyond a reasonable doubt of the defendant’s guilt. That is, both asked, can we win this case? A statistical analysis of
factors associated with charging decisions also found “nearly identical” patterns
between the two offices. Of particular interest is the fact that neither prosecutor’s
office allowed a differential racial mix (for example, black defendant, white
victim) to affect its charging decisions.1
The main implications of the findings are that a special unit for sexual assault
cases did not close a loophole that allowed offenders to slip through with no
charge or significantly lower charges for the simple reason that there was no
loophole. Strength of the evidence and the likelihood of conviction shaped
decisions in both offices.
The San Diego Major Violator Unit
An evaluation of the San Diego Major Violator Unit addressed the question of
whether a special prosecutors unit resulted in a higher rate of convictions and
more severe punishment. The unit targeted robbery and robbery-related homicide cases in which the defendant was charged with three or more separate
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
198
CHAPTER
8
robbery-related offenses or had been convicted of one or more serious offenses
in the preceding ten years.2 Taking a vertical approach, the individual prosecutor
was assigned a major-violator case and followed it through to final disposition.
Like many other special prosecutor programs, the Major Violator Unit
included restrictions on plea bargaining.3 Prosecutors could not charge bargain,
that is, accept a plea to a lesser offense; they could only accept a guilty plea to the
top felony count. Charge bargaining, as we will see when we discuss plea
bargaining later in this chapter, is what critics of plea bargaining believe to be
the main way in which offenders avoid prison, or a long mandatory prison
term, by pleading to a lesser felony or even a misdemeanor.
Despite these special procedures, however, the Major Violator Unit had
only a modest impact on the prosecution of career criminals. True, it won
conviction in an impressive 91.5 percent of its cases, but San Diego prosecutors
normally convicted 89.5 percent of all defendants with similar charges and prior
records. The unit did, however, increase the percentage of convicted offenders
sent to prison, from 77.1 percent to 92.5 percent. But this change was less significant than it might appear. More than 90 percent comparable offenders (the
current crime and their criminal history) were already being incarcerated. The
difference is that some had gone to jail (and thus for short terms), rather than
prison.4 In short, as we indicated in Chapters 2 and 3, the system was already
tough on career criminals and there was no loophole to close.
The San Diego data illustrate another often misunderstood aspect of
sentencing in the United States. The category of incarceration includes both
sentences to prison and split sentences, in which the offender does some time in
jail followed by release on probation. Split sentences are actually fairly common.
In 2009, 73 percent of all convicted felony defendants in large urban counties
were sentenced to some form of incarceration, and they were almost equally
split between prison (36 percent) and jail (37 percent) terms.5 As we discussed
in Chapter 1, the distinction between prison and jail sentences can have an
enormous impact on public perception of how the system works. If you ask
what percentage of convicted offenders went to prison (36 percent), the system
looks somewhat weak. But when you include everyone who is incarcerated,
meaning prison and jail (73 percent), it looks a lot tougher. True, going to jail
is not as serious as going to prison, but it is still an unpleasant experience, and
these offenders are not beating the system.
The Major Violator Unit did double the average length of incarceration. In
this respect, it significantly increased the severity of punishment. But it is important to recall that the length of prison terms had begun rising all across the country in that time period, particularly for serious crimes and for defendants with
long criminal histories. It is likely that much, although not necessarily all, of the
increase in prison terms in San Diego probably would have occurred even without the Major Violator Unit.
Did the San Diego Major Violator Unit have any impact on the crime rate?
The evaluation did not address this question. Common sense, however, suggests
that it could not have had any significant effect because the changes in the
percentage of offenders convicted and the percentage incarcerated were so
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
199
small. True, there was an increase in the length of prison terms, but as we
learned in Chapter 7, there is little persuasive evidence that longer prison
terms reduces crime.
These data on the prosecution of so-called career criminals confirm the
points made in Chapters 2 and 3. First, the criminal justice system is generally
tough on repeat offenders who have committed another serious crime. Second,
these patterns of prosecution and sentencing reflect the going rate agreed upon
informally by the local courtroom work group. In short, local prosecutors and
judges, without the benefit of a special program, are generally tough on major
offenders. Many people are surprised to find that the system is consistently tough
on career criminals. In 2002, 67 percent of Americans felt that the criminal
courts in their area were not harsh enough in dealing with criminals.6 We can
explain this misperception in terms of our criminal justice wedding cake
(Chapter 2). Public perception is heavily influenced by a few celebrated cases in
the top layer: the armed robber who got probation; the rapist who pled guilty to
misdemeanor assault. Do such things happen? Of course, they do. But they are
the exceptions rather than the rule, and the major lesson of this book is that we
should not develop policies on the basis of exceptional cases. The evidence leads
to the following proposition:
19
PROPOSITION
Special prosecution units do not produce either higher conviction rates or
lower crime rates.
ABOLISH THE INSANITY DEFENSE
John W. Hinckley never succeeded at much in life, but for a brief moment he
was singlehandedly responsible for some significant changes in the U.S. criminal
justice. Hinckley’s acquittal in a verdict or not guilty by reason of insanity for the
attempted assassination of President Ronald Reagan in 1981 sparked a national
outcry over the insanity defense. In the succeeding years almost every state and
the federal government changed its law on the insanity defense.7 Twelve states
adopted a new “guilty but mentally ill” (GBMI) standard and five abolished the
insanity defense altogether.8
Hinckley’s acquittal touched one of the raw nerves of public opinion: the
sight of a guilty person “beating the rap” and “getting off” because of a
“technicality.” There was no question that Hinckley shot and wounded the
president; the videotape was broadcast on television around the world. People
were outraged over the Hinckley verdict of not guilty by reason of insanity
(NGRI), which appeared to let him off. The fact is, however, that he was institutionalized—in a hospital, from which he was not free to leave, rather than a
prison. He remains there today, although in 1999 he was granted the right to
leave the hospital to have supervised visits with his parents, and later gained longer unsupervised visits. By 2013 he had won the right to be on release for up to
ten days at a time, and Secret Service records (remember, he shot a president of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
200
CHAPTER
8
the United States) indicated that he spent his time going to shopping malls,
eating at Wendy’s, and shopping at Walmart and Target, without any adverse
incidents. In short, he behaved like millions of people in this country. Hinckley’s
notoriety has probably kept him in the hospital with limited release procedures
far longer than if he had shot an ordinary person (and especially not a president
of the United States), pled guilty, and gone to prison.
An Insanity Defense Loophole?
For many people, the insanity defense is the classic loophole. It conjures up
terrifying images of criminally insane persons roaming the streets in search of
more victims. Insanity defense proceedings also anger many people. The parade
of psychiatrists and expert witnesses on both sides of the case creates the impression that you can always find an expert somewhere to say what you want said.
Like the famous O. J. Simpson trial in 1995, the Hinckley case supports the
impression that the wealthy can buy lawyers and experts who will win them
acquittal on the criminal charges. (Hinckley’s father was a corporate executive.)
In one public opinion survey, 87 percent of the respondents felt that the insanity
defense was a loophole; about 40 percent called it the “rich person’s defense.”9
The conservative response was to try to close the loophole. Changes in the
law following the Hinckley case fall into six categories: (1) abolishing the insanity
defense altogether; (2) changing the test of insanity; (3) shifting the burden of
proof to the defendant (instead of the state having to prove criminal intent, the
defendant has to prove mental illness); (4) creating a new “guilty but mentally ill”
verdict; (5) revising trial procedure for raising an insanity plea; and (6) changing
procedures for committing a person found not guilty by reason of insanity.10
Sorting out the Issues
To make sense of changes in the law on the insanity defense we need to sort out
four separate issues. The first concerns the extent of the use of the defense. How
many criminal defendants try to use the insanity defense and how many successfully
win verdicts of NGRI (not guilty by reason of insanity)? A second issue involves
the fate of those who do win acquittal. Do they return to the streets? How soon? Do
they endanger the public? The third issue is predicting dangerousness. If some offenders are dangerous, how can we identify them? How can we tell when it is safe to
release them? The fourth issue is the effect of abolishing the insanity defense. Would
it reduce crime? What would be the impact on the criminal justice system?
The Reality of the Insanity Defense
Despite all the attention it receives, the insanity defense is rarely used successfully. Few defendants even try to use it, and not many of them succeed. Studies
have consistently found that the insanity defense is raised in less than 1 percent of
all criminal indictments, and only between 15 and 25 percent of those efforts are
successful.11 Henry J. Steadman and his colleagues, for example, found that in
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
201
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
four states (California, Georgia, Montana, and New York), the insanity defense
was raised in slightly less than 1 percent (0.90 percent) of all felony indictments,
and only about 23 percent of those succeeded in getting an NGRI verdict.12
The American Psychiatric Association Insanity Defense Work Group concluded,
“[w]hile philosophically important for the criminal law, the insanity defense is empirically unimportant (involving a fraction of 1 percent of all felony cases).”13
A study of insanity defense in New York County (one of the five jurisdictions in New York City) examined a sample of 172 defendants indicted
for a felony who claimed a psychiatric defense between 1988 and 1997.
Only seventeen cases, or 10 percent went before a jury where the insanity
defense was argued, and only four cases resulted in an acquittal. That represents only 2 percent of those defendants who raised a claim of insanity, and
24 percent of the few cases that went to trial. In short, few offenders raise it,
fewer still get to court with it, and most of those do not win with it.14
The extent of public misunderstanding about the frequency of the insanity
defense is extraordinary. An Illinois poll found that people believed that nearly
40 percent of all criminal defendants used the insanity defense. These data indicate the extraordinary power of celebrated cases on public opinion. The public
misunderstanding explains the fact that nearly half of the respondents wanted the
insanity defense abolished.15 Insanity defense cases are completely unrepresentative of the full range of felony cases and tell us nothing about how most serious
crimes are routinely handled.
Given how infrequently the insanity defense is successfully used, we can
safely conclude that no real loophole exists with respect to the insanity defense,
and reducing the already limited success rate in its usage would have absolutely
no measurable impact on the crime rate.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
202
CHAPTER
8
When the insanity defense is successfully used, it is usually the result of a plea
bargain or a stipulated finding. That is, the prosecutor, defense attorney, medical
experts, and judge all agree that the defendant is indeed mentally ill. This is
another example of the courtroom work group in operation: settling cases
through mutual agreement. A study of 60,432 felony indictments in Baltimore,
Maryland, in 1991 found that the insanity defense was raised in only 190 cases; it
was eventually dropped in 182 cases, and the remaining eight defendants were
stipulated mentally ill by both prosecution and defense.16 This is not a picture of
hordes of dangerous criminals beating the system and then going out a preying
on the public.
Another popular myth about the insanity defense is that the people who use
it are violent and dangerous. Not all of the defendants committed to mental
health institutions by way of an insanity verdict have committed a violent
offense, however. Of the five hundred men in the Bridgewater State Hospital,
more than one hundred were charged with vagrancy.17 These one hundred
people are not dangerous sociopaths. They are pathetic individuals who have
serious mental health problems and cannot cope with their lives. Most sank
through the various safety nets and ended up on skid row, where they finally
were arrested.18
Aftermath of Acquittal
What happens to defendants who are committed to mental institutions after winning NGRI verdicts is a matter of much controversy. Liberals generally contend
that they are likely to spend more time in a mental hospital than if they had been
found guilty of the crime and sent to prison. Conservatives argue that they get
out too soon.
In the past, there was some truth to the liberal argument. Many allegedly
mentally ill people were hospitalized for years, even decades, without any treatment or any evidence that they were really dangerous. Supreme Court decisions
and new state laws, however, have led to greater protection of the rights of the
confined, especially the right to treatment.19 One of the most important is a
mental patient’s right to periodic review of his or her condition to determine
whether continued confinement is justified. The landmark case of Baxstrom v.
Herold (1966) forced the release of persons held for long periods of time in the
New York State Hospital for the Criminally Insane and necessitated the development of new procedures for continued confinement.20
Despite changes in the law and practice over the years, people hospitalized
after being found NGRI still spend more time confined in hospitals than comparable offenders spend in prison after being found guilty of the crime. Henry
Steadman and his associates found that in New York, 88 percent of all NGRIs
were hospitalized; of the 12 percent immediately released, a disproportionate
share were women. Those who were charged with murder but found NGRI
spent an average of 6.4 years in the hospital; those acquitted of other violent
crimes were hospitalized for an average of 5.2 years; and for nonviolent crimes,
hospital stays averaged 2.8 years. For all the crimes except murder, these terms of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
203
confinement were longer than for offenders found guilty of similar crimes in
those years.21 As a result of the growth of mandatory minimum sentencing in
the United States, prison terms today are much longer than they were when
these studies were conducted and are now likely to be even longer than the
terms of confinement for the mentally ill.
In a previous study, Steadman studied a group of defendants found incompetent to stand trial to see whether they “beat the rap.” A defendant who is too
mentally ill to comprehend the nature of a criminal trial is committed to an
institution until he or she is able to understand the proceedings, at which
point the criminal process resumes. Steadman found that those defendants
deemed “non-dangerous” spent less than two years in mental institutions,
whereas the “dangerous” were confined an average of two years and two
months. If they were subsequently convicted at trial, they faced the possibility
of additional prison time. Do you beat the rap by taking the mental health
route? Steadman argues not: “Mental hospitals are simply an alternative
place to do time.”22 In short, the system is not turning hordes of dangerous
psychotics loose on society.
Danger to the Community
How dangerous are the criminally insane? We have had some natural experiments
on this question as a result of court decisions that forced the release of criminal
defendants. A 1971 decision forced the clinical reassessment of 586 inmates of
Pennsylvania’s Fairview State Hospital for the Criminally Insane. More than twothirds were eventually released. Over the next four years, 27 percent were
rearrested, but only 11 percent for a violent crime. Including some others who
were rehospitahzed for a violent act, a total of 14.5 percent of those released
proved to be dangerous.23 A recent review of the literature concluded that the
recidivism rate for persons acquitted by reason of insanity was “no greater than
that of felons.”24
Once again we encounter our old friend the prediction problem from
Chapter 4. A decision to release or confine a person alleged to be criminally
insane involves a prediction about his or her future behavior. Does he or she
pose a danger to the community? The success rate in predicting the dangerousness of the criminally insane is no better than in other areas of criminal justice.
Because only 14.5 percent of the Fairview inmates committed another violent
act, you could argue that the experts were wrong about the other 85.5 percent.
This translates into six false-positives (people unnecessarily locked up) for each
true positive.
Abolish the Insanity Defense?
For many people, “abolishing” the insanity defense is a slogan, much like abolishing plea bargaining. As we have seen, changing the law on the insanity
defense can be done in six different ways. Each of these changes involves complex legal and practical problems.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
204
CHAPTER
8
Abolishing or modifying the insanity defense raises fundamental issues about
the criminal law. Our justice system rests on the principle that the accused is
innocent until proven guilty and that the prosecution must prove guilt beyond
a reasonable doubt. To prove guilt, the prosecution must establish three things:
The accused committed the act (actus reus), the accused had criminal intent (mens
rea), and a connection exists between the two (that is, the accused did it and
intended to do it).25
The key issue with the insanity defense is the mens rea requirement. The
criminal law has long recognized different degrees of intent. The law distinguishes between a planned murder (first degree) and one committed in the heat
of passion (second degree). It further recognizes that some homicides occur
without any criminal intent (manslaughter). Differences in the degree of intent
are reflected in the severity of the punishment. First-degree murder carries a
potential death sentence in many states.
The law has historically recognized that some people lack criminal intent
because they do not understand what they are doing. We readily accept the idea
that the five-year-old who picks up the loaded handgun and accidentally kills his
brother does not have criminal intent. He simply does not understand the nature
and consequences of firing the gun. Another example is the truly deranged person
who kills because he or she hears voices from another planet. Like the child, this
person does not appreciate the criminal nature of his or her act.26
Unfortunately, not all cases are as simple as these examples. The legal system
has struggled for 170 years to develop a formula for resolving questions about the
accused’s mental state. The principle of insanity first entered English law in 1843
with the famous M’Naughton case, which established the “right-wrong test”:
Did the accused understand the difference between right and wrong? Because
this test is somewhat crude, legal scholars have attempted to develop alternatives,
such as the “irresistible impulse” test. Laypersons are often mystified by the
arcane distinctions among those alternatives, none of which resolves the basic
problem created by the intersection of medical diagnoses, with their inevitable
shades of gray, and the legal system, with its requirement of an absolute verdict
of guilt or innocence.27
Attempts to abolish the insanity defense run up against the mens rea requirement. Suppose a state adopted a law that said “mental condition shall not be a
defense to any charge of criminal conduct.” This might be interpreted as abolishing the mens rea requirement altogether. The prosecution would not have to
prove anything about the accused’s mental state, only that he or she did the
crime. Among other things, it would wipe out the distinction between firstdegree murder, second-degree murder, and manslaughter. It is doubtful that
even the most ardent opponents of the insanity defense seriously want to take
this approach, which would probably be found unconstitutional. Wisconsin
(1909) and Mississippi (1928) abolished the insanity defense early in the previous
century. In both cases, the new laws were declared unconstitutional under the
due process clauses of their state constitutions.28
A more limited restriction on the use of the insanity defense would be that
an affirmative plea of not guilty by reason of insanity could not be raised. The
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
205
crucial distinction here is between affirmative and ordinary defenses. An ordinary
defense is simply an attempt to show that the prosecution has failed to connect the
accused with the crime. An affirmative defense is that, yes, the accused did kill the
victim and intended to, but he or she does not have criminal responsibility for
the act (because of self-defense, duress, or insanity).
What would happen if we abolished insanity as an affirmative defense? As one
review of the literature pointed out, we have little empirical evidence on this question because so few states (five) have actually abolished the insanity defense and also
because there are so few cases. Put yourself in the shoes of a defense attorney, and
the answer is obvious. You would directly attack the prosecution’s case on the basic
mens rea requirement and argue that your client lacked the necessary criminal
intent. You would not win every time, of course, but you might win some of the
time, with the net result that your client would be fully acquitted. The people who
oppose the insanity defense would find this outcome even more outrageous than
our current situation. Even if you did not win, you would force the prosecution
to address your client’s mental state. In short, the basic issues underlying the insanity
defense would reappear in a different form. There is no getting around it; the mens
rea requirement is a bedrock principle of our legal system.
The GBMI alternative has three serious flaws. First, it strikes indirectly at the
mens rea requirement, introducing the slippery notion that the accused had partial, but not complete, criminal intent. Second, it creates a lesser and included
offense that judges and juries may choose simply as a compromise verdict.
They may decide that the accused probably did something wrong and deserves
some punishment, but they are unwilling to bring in a verdict of guilty on the
top charge. The GBMI option would allow them to split the difference and
choose the lesser verdict. Finally, the GBMI verdict does not guarantee
treatment for the person who has been declared mentally ill.
Prisons and jails are ill-equipped to treat mentally ill inmates. Some estimates
have found that 16 percent of all state and federal prisoners suffer from a mental
illness, which would be about 240,000 people in 2012. Thirty-six percent of
state prison inmates reported having been involved in a fight since their admission, compared with 24 percent of other inmates. The figure was even higher
among jail inmates. More seriously, almost a quarter of state prison inmates had
been admitted to an overnight mental hospital or treatment program since they
entered prison. Half had received a prescribed medication, and slightly less than
half 44 percent) had received counseling or therapy (although the report did not
indicate the length or quality of those programs).29
For the GBMI offenders, we can imagine the sequence of events. The convicted offender is sentenced to prison, where his or her behavior becomes a
problem. He or she is then transferred to the state mental hospital for treatment.
After his or her behavior stabilizes, he or she is transferred back to prison, where,
because of the brutal conditions, his or her behavior again deteriorates. The cycle
then repeats itself. This is not to suggest that our mental hospitals are models of
effective treatment and humane custody. They are not, and much of the “treatment” is meaningless. But sending an allegedly mentally ill person to prison is an
even worse solution.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
206
CHAPTER
8
The GBMI option has already proved to be a bogus reform. A 1981 Illinois law
added GBMI as an additional verdict, retaining the traditional insanity defense. In
Cook County (Chicago), NGRI verdicts actually increased from 34 to 103 between
1981 and 1984. At the same time, GBMI verdicts went from 16 in 1982, the first
year the option was available, to 87 in 1984. This represents a variation on the baitand-switch problem that we have previously discussed, whereby a new law is
advertised as affecting one category of crime but actually affects other less serious
ones. GBMI verdicts appear to have involved people who would otherwise have
been found guilty, not defendants who would have been found NGRI.30
The Illinois GBMI law also failed to provide medical treatment for GBMI
defendants. An evaluation found that “not a single GBMI offender has been
transferred from the Department of Corrections to the Department of Mental
Health” for treatment. The law only “complicated rather than resolved [the]
fundamental issues surrounding the insanity defense.”31 A study of the GBMI
verdict in another state reached similar conclusions: There was no reduction in
the number of insanity pleas, jurors were more likely to be confused about the
legal issues, many offenders receiving a GBMI verdict were placed on probation,
and offenders had no assurance that they would receive any medical treatment.32
The real function of the GBMI option is symbolic to appease public opinion
by providing a verdict with the word “guilty” in it. The public has little concern
for the details of what actually happens to a mentally ill criminal defendant.
Basically, it wants a symbolic statement of guilty. In practice, as Richard Moran
points out, the GBMI verdict has as much meaning as “guilty but brown eyes.”33
In sum, the various proposals to abolish or modify the insanity defense fail
on two counts. Not only do they fail to reduce crime because the insanity
defense is so rare, but they create new problems for the criminal justice system.
The evidence is overwhelming that the insanity defense is not a loophole that
allows thousands of dangerous offenders to beat the system. This leads us to
our next proposition:
20
PROPOSITION
Abolishing or limiting the insanity defense will have no impact on serious
crime.
Richard Moran offers the best verdict on the issue of the insanity defense:
“The insanity defense has been misinterpreted and abused”—not by criminal
defendants but “by politicians and journalists who mistakenly attack it as a
major loophole in the law.”34 A review of attempts to revise or abolish the
insanity defense over the past twenty years concluded that all of these changes
have had “little effect,” in large part because “there is no real evidence that it is
broken.”35
But it isn’t just the politicians. It’s also the public, with a lot of help from the
news media. The entire insanity defense episode in the 1980s illustrates the powerfully distorting effect of a national-level celebrated case on the criminal justice
system. The Hinckley verdict touched off public outrage, media commentary,
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
207
demands for law reform, and a fair amount of criminal justice research. And
then, after a few years, the entire issue just vanished. Today, the public seems
not the least bit interested in the issue. At the same time, criminal justice scholars
have almost completely lost interest in the subject, and there is precious little
published research on the subject since the early 1990s.
ABOLISH OR REFORM BARGAINING?
Did the Supreme Court lob a hand grenade into the criminal justice system
with two rulings of plea bargaining in 2012? The decisions held that convicted offenders have a right to challenge their convictions because of ineffective assistance of counsel, in violation of the Sixth Amendment guarantee
of “Assistance of Counsel for his defence.” Some commentators called the
decisions “landmark” because of the potential impact on the routine processing
of cases, in which 95 percent of all cases are settled through plea bargains.
We have an answer to the question of the impact of these two decisions, and
it is based on what we know about the reality of plea bargaining. Let’s take a
good critical look at this key part of the criminal justice system.
Everyone seems to dislike plea bargaining (everyone except the participants,
that is). Conservatives believe that it is a major loophole through which criminals
beat the system and avoid punishment. Liberals, meanwhile, believe that it is the
source of grave injustices: a hidden and unregulated process by which prosecutors offering better deals to some types of defendants than others; with defense
attorneys making private deals with prosecutors rather than fighting for their
clients; and with defendants being coerced into waiving their right to a trial.36
We should be concerned about plea bargaining. After all, it is how most
criminal cases are resolved. In 2006 (the most recent data available), 95 percent
of all convictions in large urban courts were obtained through a guilty plea.37
Additionally, our justice system is different from European countries. A comparative study of plea bargaining in the United States, Germany, France, and Italy
concluded that “[p]rosecutors’ overly broad and essentially unchecked discretion
remains perhaps the most distinctive feature of the American criminal justice
system.”38 Uncontrolled discretion is usually an invitation to trouble.
In many respects, the process of plea bargaining makes a mockery of justice.
Defendants routinely plea to a crime that is not the one they were originally
charged with (although it may be a lesser and included offense). Some critics
argue that plea bargaining encourages overcharging, where the prosecutor files
additional charges to be used as negotiating chips in the bargaining process.
Overcharging does not typically involve completely false charges, but instead
adding charges that the prosecutor has no expectation of winning, or possibly
lesser and related charges that are simply chips the prosecutor can trade away.
In court the judge goes through the charade of asking the defendant whether
any promises have been made in return for the guilty plea, and the defendant
answers no. But of course, a deal has been made.39
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
208
CHAPTER
8
Efforts to address the problems associated with plea bargaining fall into two
categories. Some people want to abolish it altogether. Others want to keep it but
reform it through rules and regulations. In 2003 a columnist for the conservative
Cato Institute, Timothy Lynch, argued “The Case against Plea Bargaining.”
Citing the evidence of a “trial penalty” for defendants who refuse to plea bargain
and insist on a trial, he argued that plea bargaining is unconstitutional because the
government (in this instance, prosecutors) penalize criminal defendants who
exercise their constitutional right to a trial. He concluded that plea bargaining
should be abolished completely.40 We will discuss the trial penalty phenomenon
shortly in our discussion of King County, Washington, but for the moment we can
define it as additional punishments for defendants who choose trial over a plea.
Other commentators argue for regulating plea bargaining to preserve its
benefits while curbing actual or potential abuses. This approach is consistent with
the general view that it is impossible to abolish any form of discretion in the
criminal justice system—police discretion, for example—and that attempting to
do so would only produce undesirable adaptations.41 Regulating plea bargain
essentially involves developing rules to guide its use. Alarmists have always warned
that the criminal process would “collapse” without plea bargaining to efficiently
process all the cases. We will examine attempts to regulate plea bargaining later.
Day-in, Day-out Plea Bargaining
Let’s begin with a brief description of what plea bargaining is. Basically, it is a
negotiated plea of guilty by the defendant, typically in return for some concession on the part of the prosecutor. Plea bargains fall into two basic categories:
charge bargaining and sentence bargaining. In charge bargaining, the defendant
agrees to plead guilty to a lesser charge. The effect usually means that the defendant avoids a prison term, often by avoiding a mandatory sentencing provision,
receives a shorter prison term, or in the case of a plea to a misdemeanor, avoids a
felony conviction with all of the collateral consequences of that. A plea to a
misdemeanor might, however, include a jail term of less than a year. Sentence
bargaining, meanwhile, involves a guilty plea in return for an agreement by the
prosecutor to recommend a particular sentence to the judge. The recommendation cannot bind the judge’s decision, but in the courtroom work group such
recommendations are typically accepted.
Plea bargaining has endured over many decades because it offers something
for everyone. The prosecutor is guaranteed a guilty verdict; the defense attorney
can claim to have gotten a better deal than appeared possible at the outset; and the
defendant gets a sentence less severe than could have been the case. Particularly
important, both sides get the certainty of an agreement, and both sides avoid the
time, expense, and uncertainty of a trial. All sides, including the judge, get the
benefit of efficiently processing a large number of criminal cases. One of the key
elements of the process that makes it work efficiently is the early rejection of cases
by prosecutors. This removes cases in which there is some genuine uncertainty
about the facts, leaving a core of cases in which guilt is almost certain (these are
called “no-brainers” in the King County, Washington, example we discuss).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
209
With these considerations in mind, now let’s take a look at Alaska’s famous
attempt to abolish plea bargaining.
Abolishing Plea Bargaining: Alaska Tries
For a few years in the 1970s, there were loud calls to abolish plea bargaining.
Public outrage reached its peak in 1973, when Vice President Spiro Agnew, in
perhaps the most famous plea bargain in American history, avoided going to
prison on extortion charges by pleading no contest to a lesser charge of tax evasion. In 1973, the National Advisory Commission on Criminal Justice Standards
and Goals recommended that plea bargaining be abolished within five years.42 It
didn’t happen. When we take a closer look at plea bargaining, including Alaska’s
ban, we will begin to understand why.
The most celebrated attempt to abolish plea bargaining occurred in Alaska,
when Attorney General Avrum Gross abolished plea bargaining in the entire
state.43 On July 3, 1975, he issued a memorandum that read, in part:
I wish to have the following policy implemented with respect to all
adult criminal offenses in which charges have been filed on or after
August 15, 1975:
1) District Attorneys and Assistant District Attorneys will refrain from
engaging in plea negotiations with defendants designed to arrive at an
agreement for entry of a plea of guilty in return for a particular sentence…
(4)While there continues to be nothing wrong with reducing a charge,
reductions should not occur simply to obtain a plea of guilty. (5) Like any
general rule, there are going to be some exceptions to this policy [which
must be approved by the attorney general’s office].
The new policy attacked plea bargaining in three ways: forbidding sentence
bargaining and charge bargaining and establishing procedures for supervising plea
negotiations. Gross’s action was possible in part because of the special structure of
Alaska’s criminal justice system. Local prosecutors are appointed by and work
under the supervision of the state attorney general. In other states, local prosecutors are elected and enjoy almost complete political and administrative
independence.
What happened when Alaska banned plea bargaining? Contrary to the standard warnings of alarmists, the criminal courts did not collapse. The traditional
defense of plea bargaining is that it is necessary to handle the heavy load of cases
and that the courts will grind to a halt if it is abolished. The Alaska courts,
however, continued to function pretty much as they had before. Additionally,
there was little change in the rate of guilty pleas. Trials increased, from 6.7 to
only 9.6 percent of all cases.44
Other dire predictions also did not come true in Alaska. Many experts argue
that discretion cannot be eliminated and that attempts to abolish it only serve to
move it to other parts of the justice system. Restricting a prosecutor’s discretion
to accept guilty pleas, according to this argument, would shift discretion
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
210
CHAPTER
8
“upstream” to police officers or “downstream” to judges.45 As we will see
shortly, the Alaska ban did shift discretion upstream to prosecutors at the initial
screening stage.
Overall, the ban did not disrupt the processing of criminal cases or cause any
major problems. The rate of dismissals, for example, remained consistently high:
about 52 percent before and after the ban. Dismissals in drug possession and
morals cases increased, but this seemed to be a function of the low priority prosecutors gave these cases rather than anything related to the ban on plea
bargaining.46
There were some unexpected positive effects on case processing. One
surprising result was that cases actually moved through the courts faster than
before. The expectation had been that there would be more delays because of
more trials and a greater backlog of cases. In Anchorage, the mean disposition
time for felony cases was cut in half, dropping from 192.1 months to
89.5 months. Case processing time also dropped in Fairbanks and Juneau. We
can explain this unexpected outcome. Restrictions on plea bargaining eliminate
certain alternatives and uncertainties about which one to choose. With less to
negotiate, the prosecutor and defense attorney reach agreements more quickly.
Or to put it another way, the courtroom work group has a smaller menu to
choose from.47 If anything, this experience illustrates the capacity the courtroom
work group to adapt to any major change in the formal rules of the justice
system.
Another positive result, which was highlighted in a follow-up study of the
ban, was that the ban forced the police to improve the quality of their investigations. Prosecutors’ initial screening decisions became the key point under the ban
and “set the tone for all subsequent actions” in a case. In short, the ban did shift
discretion upstream to an early prosecutor’s decision. As a result, the police had
to present stronger evidence for the screening decision. In a reevaluation of the
ban, a veteran police officer admitted that before 1975 police work had been
“very sloppy,” and initial weaknesses in a case were resolved through charge bargaining. The ban on charge bargaining forced police officers to “become good
investigators.”48
For our purposes, the most significant result was that the ban on plea
bargaining had no impact on cases involving defendants charged with serious
crimes or those with substantial criminal records. An evaluation concluded that
“the conviction and sentencing of persons charged with serious crimes of violence such as murder, rape, robbery, and felonious assault appeared completely
unaffected by the change in policy.” In short, dangerous offenders had not
been beating the system beforehand through plea bargaining (any more than
they had in San Diego), and the ban did not change that.
The ban did, however, have an unexpected effect on less serious cases, and
resulted in more severe sentences. This is another variation of the bait-and-switch
problem. Our wedding cake model helps explain this process. Policies directed
toward second-layer cases actually have their greatest impact on third-layer cases.
As Zimring and Hawkins argue, bait and switch occurs when a new policy promises to deal with serious crime but ends up affecting mainly less serious ones.49
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
211
Under normal circumstances, third-layer cases—low-level assaults or burglaries
where little of value is stolen—are often settled with pleas to even lesser offenses
and sentences of probation. A get-tough policy, such as a ban on plea bargaining,
however, closes off this avenue of mitigation and produces both convictions on
more serious charges and harsher sentences than would normally be the case.
Third-layer cases are moved into the second layer, where they are treated more
harshly. The problem, of course, is that these third-layer cases were not the
original target of the policy change, and there is no impact on serious crime.
From the standpoint of our inquiry, the important question is whether the
Alaska ban on plea bargaining affected the crime rate. The evaluation did not
examine this issue. Nonetheless, the mere fact that the ban had no real effect
on the disposition of cases involving serious crimes suggests that it probably had
no impact on the crime rate.
DID THE BAN SURVIVE? Over the long haul, did the Alaska ban on plea
bargaining survive? Or did it wither away and die at the hands of the court room
work group? A 1991 follow-up evaluation by the Alaska Judicial Council found
a mixed and complex situation. Officially, the ban remained in force, although it
had been modified in certain respects by subsequent attorneys general and was
affected by a law creating presumptive sentencing. To a great extent, however,
the ban had “decayed” and that charge bargaining, although officially banned,
had become “fairly common.” Dismissals and charge reductions had increased
after ten years. Nonetheless, some important positive results survived. Screening
decisions remained the critical point in the process and resulted in higher
standards for sending a case forward. The resulting pressure for improved police
investigations also continued.50
In the end, then, the 1975 ban of plea bargaining demonstrated how the
courtroom work group adapts to a major change. On the one hand, some positive results survived. But on the other hand, traditional practices (notably charge
bargaining) resurfaced. Regardless, however, there is no evidence that a major
loophole that allowed many dangerous criminals to beat the system ever existed,
and the ban had no impact on crime.
Reforming Plea Bargaining in King County, Washington
Today few people seriously believe that we can abolish plea bargaining, and only
a few commentators even discuss the idea seriously (but see our previous discussion of Timothy Lynch). Similarly, no one seriously proposes abolishing police
discretion, or completely eliminating all judicial discretion in sentencing (as some
people proposed in the 1970s, with something called “flat-time” sentencing.)
Discretion is inevitable, and most experts acknowledge that it can serve some
good purposes. The realistic approach to the problems associated with discretion
is to regulate it with formal policies and procedures.51
The dominant approach to addressing the problems with plea bargaining
involves some form of regulating the process to curb actual or potential abuses.
Deirdre M. Bowen examined the reforms in King County, Washington (Seattle),
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
212
CHAPTER
8
which included a structured process for handling cases, with some clear rules on
plea negotiations and higher levels of supervision for attorneys. The King
County reforms resemble those in other jurisdictions, and for that reason it serves
as an example with broad national relevance. The new process uses a horizontal
approach to prosecution, with separate prosecutorial units handling the different
stages of prosecution. Criminal cases are initially handled by the Charging Unit,
which screens cases in terms of seriousness, the strength of the evidence, and the
defendant’s prior record. The primary consideration in setting the charge is
whether the case can be won. Cases are then passed to the Early Plea Unit
(EPU) which tries to negotiate a guilty plea. Cases that are not settled through
a guilty plea are then handled by the Trial Unit. The main rules for plea negotiations are that plea negotiations are not available to any case that bypasses the
EPU, that no plea negotiations should occur at trial, and that plea offers must be
in writing. These changes were designed to eliminate the traditional informality
of plea negotiations and, through the EPU (which, in practice, consists of a
single prosecutor), centralize negotiations and presumably make them more
consistent.52
The net result was a high level of consistency in case processing. Seventy percent of cases were settled by the EPU. The courtroom work group, consistent
with our discussion in Chapter 3, operated with a high degree of collegiality,
cooperation, and an understanding of the rules of the game. “Overwhelmingly,”
Bowen found in her interviews, members of the work group “took the view that
they should work together to settle on the appropriate charge and punishment.”
Significantly, the facts of a case were rarely in dispute, and the work group called
most of them “no brainers.” In part, this was the result of a conservative charging
policy, in which charges were filed only on charges the attorneys felt they could
win at trial. Overcharging, adding additional charges to be traded away in plea
negotiations and that many plea bargaining critics see as one of the systems’
worst abuses, was explicitly discouraged. Bowen’s findings provide more recent
confirmation of most of the important points about how the courtroom work
group operates, which we discussed in Chapter 3, but which were based on
much earlier research.
In practice, the work group adapted to and worked around the formal rules
of governing the handling of criminal cases. Even though they were not supposed to, trial attorneys were willing to negotiate pleas in some cases, often
because of their workloads. Defense attorneys admitted they monitored the
calendars of trial prosecutors for this reason. There were some opportunities for
negotiating pleas with the supervising prosecutor (rather than the EPU), and this
was mainly because of what Bowen terms “history”: “a long-standing personal
relationship” among members of the courtroom work group. In other words,
personal relationships that had developed over time trumped the formal rules of
the prosecutor’s office. Such relationships, and their impact on everyday work,
are characteristic of courtroom work groups.
The implementation of a more formal process, with some clear rules, did not
in the end make any significant changes in the handling of cases. There may have
been greater efficiency because the rules were clear to everyone, and there was
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
213
greater openness and less chance of misunderstanding because of the rules of the
game. Higher levels of supervision, moreover, enhanced consistency among
cases. It is likely that, as is the case with rule on police discretion and sentencing
guidelines, formal rules eliminated the exceptional cases that really did depart
from the norm and discredited the system.53
Particularly important, Bowen’s study documented the existence of the trial
penalty for not pleading guilty. Defendants faced the possibility of additional
criminal charges, sentencing enhancements, or an undesirable sentencing recommendation. These penalties can involve significant consequences in terms of
longer prison terms. The interesting point is that these threats exist at all in a
system where reforms were designed to eliminate such informal procedures.
The survival of the trial penalty is powerful testimony of the power of the courtroom work group to adapt to change.54
Bowen’s qualitative study of the King Country process provides a richer and
more nuanced view of plea bargaining that previous studies. Although it found
that about 70 percent of all the cases were no-brainers, around which there was
almost complete agreement among the courtroom work group participants,
there was some disagreement and conflict in the other 30 percent. Other studies
have tended to overstate the degree of consensus, or at least have left that
impression. Bowen cites the defense attorneys’ frustration and even anger at
times at how they were treated by prosecutors in certain parts of the process.
Nonetheless, when faced with frustrating obstacles defense attorneys were able
to find opportunities to create advantages for their cases.
Plea Bargaining and Crime
The case of King County, Washington, illustrates an important point that is
directly relevant to the purpose of this book. Plea bargaining has proven to be
a phantom loophole. Despite the criticisms, it is not a device by which large
numbers of serious offenders are beating the system. Our discussions of the
criminal justice wedding cake (Chapter 2) and the role of the courtroom work
group (Chapter 3) help explain why plea bargaining survives. As Malcolm Feeley
suggests, we should think of the criminal courts as supermarkets, handling a high
volume of business with fixed prices.55 Criminologist Robert Bohm, in an essay
on the “McDonaldization of Criminal Justice,” labels the process “McJustice” an
“efficient, calculable, predictable” process, doing business much like a fast food
restaurant.56 Once the work group reaches a consensus about the proper “going
rate” for different kinds of cases, not much actual bargaining is necessary. A
National Center for State Courts report characterizes this consensus as a shared
“norm of proportionality” about the seriousness and worth of different cases.57
All of the studies of plea bargaining have found a high degree of regularity
and predictability in the disposition of cases. One of the most systematic studies
concluded that you can predict the outcome of most cases, if you know the seriousness of the top charge and the defendant’s prior record.58 Most important, in
King County, Washington, and the two prosecutors’ officers we discussed at the
beginning of this chapter, the key consideration for prosecutors is whether they
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
214
CHAPTER
8
can win the case. Those cases they feel they can’t win, they reject. The important point here is that the offenders in those cases would not be convicted no
matter what system exists. Even in some hypothetical system where plea bargaining was abolished and every case went to trial, those defendants would not be
convicted. A lot of those defendants probably did the crime, but there is not
sufficient evidence to convict them. But we can’t blame plea bargaining for the
fact that they go free.
Courtroom work groups have accommodated themselves to sentencing
guideline laws. Many observers have feared that by restricting the discretion of
judges, these laws would radically shift power to prosecutors and result in more
charge bargaining or more trials. Studies of the impact of sentencing guideline
jurisdictions, however, have found that most courtroom work groups conduct
their business pretty much as before, with relatively little change.59 This is
but another example of both the enduring strength of routine plea bargaining
practices and the power of the courtroom work group to accommodate major
change.
EVADING HARSH MANDATORY SENTENCES:
TWO CASE STUDIES
The Case of Sex Offender Notification Laws
One of the traditional criticisms of plea bargaining, and particularly charge
bargaining, is that it allows defendants to evade mandatory prison sentences or
other harsh punishments. This view is part of the conservative argument that
plea bargaining is one of the major “soft” spots in the criminal process. Sentencing guidelines have been developed for the federal criminal justice system
and among several states for the specific purpose of ensuring consistency in
sentencing. There is evidence from two sources indicating that in certain circumstances prosecutors and the courtroom work group have been able to circumvent
mandatory sentencing requirements.
The first involves a particularly harsh South Carolina sex offender registration and notification law enacted in 1995. Juveniles convicted of sex offenses
were required to register their home address, school, and other personal information with the county sheriff twice a year. The authorities were required to notify
their schools, victims, and nearby child-related business or organizations of their
sex offender registration status. The law was amended in 1999 to include lifetime
online registration.
A study analyzed the disposition of 3,176 juvenile sex offense cases, 20,424
assault cases, and 2,212 robbery cases in the state between 1990 and 2004. For
sex offense cases, there was an increase in plea bargains to non–sex offense charges,
which allowed defendants to avoid the registration and notification requirements.
There was also an increase in plea bargains to lower sex offense charges. Interestingly, the likelihood of a plea bargain fell as the age of defendants age increased,
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
215
indicating a special interest in protecting younger defendants from harsh registration and notification requirement. Overall, there was a “large and statistically
significant” increase in plea bargains for juvenile sex offenses. By comparison,
there was only a “trivial” increase in plea bargains in assault cases. Finally, there
was no increase in plea bargains for robbery offense cases.60
This evidence suggests that plea bargaining was a convenient means by
which the courtroom work group could evade the harsh punishment of sex
offender registration and notification, and after 1999 the penalty of lifetime
registration. It seems clear that members of the work group shared a consensus
of opinion that most, but not all juveniles initially charged with sex offenses
should not suffer severe punishments. The fact that plea bargains were greater
among the younger juveniles clearly suggests a shared greater compassion
among members of the work group for people they feel may not be as fully
responsible for their criminal conduct.
The second example involves the mandatory minimum sentencing requirements in the federal sentencing guidelines. In 2011, in response to a directive
from Congress, the U.S. Sentencing Commission issued a report on the impact
of mandatory minimum sentences. We have already discussed the impact in
Chapter 7. Here we focus on the report’s findings about evasion of the mandatory requirements.61
The Commission studied thirteen federal districts, conducting interviews
with prosecutors and defense attorneys. Charge bargaining was the exception
rather than the rule, although there were some variations across districts. One
particularly important finding involved Section 851 notices of intent to file
mandatory sentencing enhancements (that is, enhancements to the sentences for
the underlying offense). Prosecutors did not automatically file them in nine of
the thirteen districts, reserving for later the discretion to file or not. Defense
attorneys saw this maneuver as a strategy for coercing a guilty plea, as prosecutors
could always threaten (subtly or not so subtly) to file the enhancement charge.
Section 851 notices were filed in every case in two districts, and in one district
they were always filed, but often withdrawn as part of plea negotiations. Finally,
in one district they were rarely filed on one district, and reserved as a “hammer
for the worst offenders.” In short, federal courtroom work groups responded in
various ways to the mandatory sentencing provision, with some clearly undermining the intent of the sentencing guidelines.
The Supreme Court Rules on Plea Bargains: New Day
or Business as Usual?
At the beginning of our discussion of plea bargaining, we mentioned the two
2012 Supreme Court decisions that some commentators believe will throw a
monkey wrench into the traditional plea bargaining process. Each of the
decisions held that convicted offenders had a right to challenge their convictions
on grounds of ineffective assistance of counsel in violation of the Sixth Amendment. Alarmists envisioned thousands of convicted offenders bringing appeals of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
216
CHAPTER
8
their plea bargains, jamming already crowded court dockets, further undermining
the certainty of punishment, and in an unknown number of cases setting free
convicted offenders. Will such a disaster befall the criminal courts? Let’s take a
look at the two cases.
In Missouri v. Frye, Frye was arrested for his fourth driving with a revoked
license offense, which meant he faced a felony charge and possible four-year
prison term. The prosecutor offered to accept a plea to a misdemeanor and a
ninety-day jail term. Frye’s defense attorney never communicated the offer to
Frye, and it expired. While waiting for his preliminary hearing, Frye was arrested
again for the same offense. With no plea offer available, he pled guilty to a
felony and received a three-year prison sentence. He appealed his conviction,
claiming ineffective assistance of counsel because his lawyer did not tell him
about the original plea offer in the earlier case. The Supreme Court agreed and
remanded his case to the lower courts for reconsideration. In Lafler v. Cooper,
Lafler faced a murder charge, but his attorney advised him to reject a plea offer
that involved a possible four- to seven-year sentence, arguing that given the facts
of the case, he would never be convicted of first-degree murder. At trial,
however, he was convicted of first-degree murder and received a sentence of
fifteen to thirty years in prison. He appealed, claiming ineffective assistance of
counsel under the Sixth Amendment, and the Supreme Court agreed.62
Some commentators argued that these were landmark decisions that would
drastically alter the entire process of plea bargaining. Previously, relatively little
attention had been given to the quality of plea negotiations by defense attorneys,
including such issues as the actual communication between attorneys and their
clients and the judgments made by attorneys about the best course of action.
Will the courts be flooded with appeals claiming ineffective assistance of counsel
in plea bargains? If so, what will the impact on plea negotiations themselves be?
Law professor Cynthia Alkon argues that little will change, and we agree.
Her experience as a prosecutor confirmed what we know about plea bargaining:
most defendants do not contest their guilt; the factually weak cases have already
been screened out, as we pointed out in Chapters 2 and 3. As we have already
mentioned several times, the reason 95 percent of criminal convictions are settled
by plea bargains is because for the screening process leaves only those cases where
guilt is not in doubt. All that is left is bargaining over the exact charge and the
punishment. In fact, defense lawyers around the country told Professor Alkon
that “nothing has changed,” and it’s “business as usual” in the court houses.63
Alkon makes the persuasive argument that the two Supreme Court decisions
will have little impact because few defense attorneys would make the mistakes
that were at issue in the two cases: failing to present an offer to the defendant
in the first case and making such a bad prediction about a trial in a high stakes
first-degree murder case as happened in the second. We should quickly add that
defense lawyers do make mistakes. Some are even incompetent, grossly so on
occasion. There was, after all, the infamous case of the Texas defense attorney
who fell asleep at trial in a death penalty case.64 But such degrees of incompetence are the classic celebrated cases—that’s why these two cases went to the
Supreme Court. Day in and day out, however, it is business as usual in the
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
217
criminal courts, there is a high degree of consensus about what a case is worth,
and the mistakes that do occur do not have the enormous significance of those
made in the two Supreme Court cases. To bring this issue back to the purpose of
this book, the two cases will not result in thousands of convicted offenders being
freed and thereby able to return to the streets and lives of serious crime.
In the end, the evidence is overwhelming: Plea bargaining is not a loophole
that lets many dangerous offenders beat the system. Therefore, we can safely
posit our next proposition:
21
PROPOSITION
Abolishing or even significantly reforming plea bargaining will not reduce
serious crime.
RESTRICT APPEALS
Conservatives believe that postconviction appeals undermine the criminal justice
system in several ways. First, some offenders win and thereby escape punishment
altogether. Second, appeals delay final resolution of a case and undermine the
deterrent effect of the criminal law. Deterrence theorists, as we discussed in
Chapter 6, believe that punishment must be swift and certain for the deterrent
effect to work. Third, appeals transform the criminal process into a “sporting
contest,” a game rather than a search for truth. Liberals, on the other hand, see
the absence of finality as a virtue. Protection of individual rights requires recognition of the possibility of error in the criminal justice system, and the existence
of a procedure for correcting mistakes.65
Years ago, Judge Macklin Fleming argued that granting numerous postconviction appeals represented a quixotic search for “perfect justice.”66 He listed
twenty-six possible challenges available in California on search-and-seizure
grounds alone, including but not limited to moving for dismissal of all charges
at the preliminary examination; appealing a denial of that motion to the state
supreme court; moving to have the case transferred to federal court on grounds
that federal civil rights had been violated; objecting to admission of the evidence
at trial; if convicted, appealing for postconviction relief in the state supreme
court; and if that failed, appealing the conviction in federal court.
Nor is this all. Fleming points out that “in almost every one of the foregoing
steps the losing defendant can petition for a rehearing or reconsideration by the
court that ruled against him.”67 Thus, innumerable potential challenges to a
criminal charge can be made just on Fourth Amendment search-and-seizure
issues. If these fail, many postconviction appeals are possible—for example, on
grounds of inadequate assistance of counsel in violation of the Sixth Amendment.
For the imaginative and determined offender, the possibilities are seemingly
endless. As we shall see, however, the key word here is seemingly. In the real
world of criminal justice, Judge Fleming’s nightmare scenario occurs only rarely,
and even then, typically only in death penalty cases.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
218
CHAPTER
8
Limiting Appeals
Conservatives believe that limiting appeals will close a loophole that undermines
the criminal justice system. The 1981 Attorney General’s Task Force on Violent
Crime recommended a three-year statute of limitations on habeas corpus
petitions and a prohibition on federal courts’ holding evidentiary hearings “on
facts which were fully expounded and found in the state court proceeding.”68
Habeas corpus is one of the cornerstones of Anglo American law. The
British Parliament formalized it with the Habeas Corpus Act of 1679, and
Americans wrote it into the U.S. Constitution. Article III, Section 9, of the
Constitution reads, “The privilege of the writ of habeas corpus shall not be
suspended, unless when in case of rebellion or invasion the public safety may
require it.” The writ of habeas corpus is a device to challenge the detention of
a person taken into custody. A person under arrest or in prison may demand an
evidentiary hearing before a judge to examine the legality of the detention. The
writ of habeas corpus is purely procedural: It guarantees only a right to a hearing
and says nothing about the substance of the issues in the case.
The Supreme Court greatly expanded the ability of an offender convicted in
a state court to obtain a rehearing in federal court in the 1963 decision Fay v.
Noia.69 One of the underlying issues here is the role of the Supreme Court in a
federal system. Conservatives have long argued that the court, particularly under
Chief Justice Earl Warren, intruded into matters that should be left to the states
and to legislatures. Liberals, on the other hand, saw the court as the principal
guardian of individual rights.
The Reality of Postconviction Appeals
In actual practice, postconviction appeals play a minor role in the administration
of criminal justice. A national study of 10,000 habeas corpus petitions filed in
federal district courts by offenders challenging their convictions found that only
1 percent succeeded. Federal judges dismissed 63 percent (usually for failing to
exhaust state remedies) and ruled against the offender on the merits of the case in
35 percent. The typical habeas corpus petition was filed by someone convicted
of a violent offense (23 percent had been convicted of murder) and sentenced to
a long prison term. The most frequent claim raised was ineffective assistance of
counsel.70
How many convicted offenders “abuse” the right to appeal? The study
found a rate of fourteen habeas corpus petitions for every 1,000 prisoners—or
only 1.4 percent of all imprisoned offenders. This figure confirms what we
have already learned: that most convictions are obtained through plea bargains
in which the facts of the case are not seriously contested. The study also found
that the impact of habeas corpus petitions on the workload of the courts has
been greatly exaggerated. These appeals represented only 4 percent of the civil
case filings in U.S. District Courts.71
In short, Macklin Fleming’s nightmare vision of convicted offenders endlessly filing appeals on all of the theoretically possible issues is pure fantasy. Appeal
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
219
of felony convictions through habeas corpus petitions is much like the insanity
defense: a procedure that raises a lot of fascinating legal issues but is rarely used in
practice and rarely successful even when tried. There are two important exceptions to this rule. People on death row do exhaust every possible appeal, and
appeals may drag on for fifteen years or longer. The fact, however, is that mistakes do occur with the death penalty. In early 2000, the governor of Illinois
ordered a halt to all executions in the state because thirteen people sentenced
to die had their convictions overturned—as many as had actually been executed
since the death penalty was restored in that state. The possibility that innocent
people might be wrongfully executed dramatizes the importance of keeping
open all possible avenues of appeal.
A second exception involves the “writ writers,” prisoners who file innumerable appeals in federal court challenging their conviction or prison conditions. These individuals represent a tiny proportion of all inmates. The few
who succeed in winning their release make a negligible contribution to the
crime rate, even in the worst circumstances.
Two Limits on Appeals
In 1996, Congress passed two laws limiting the right of convicted offenders to
file appeals: the Antiterrorism and Effective Death Penalty Act and the Prison
Litigation Reform Act. The laws were important indicators of the state of public
opinion on crime and justice in the mid-1990s. Although this book has always
presented limiting appeals as a conservative crime control policy, the two laws
had substantial support among liberal Democrats in Congress and were strongly
supported by President Bill Clinton, a liberal Democrat.
Both laws attacked what its supporters believed were serious problems with
postconviction appeals. The Antiterrorism and Effective Death Penalty Act reflected
the belief that endless appeals undermine the deterrent effect of the death penalty in
two different ways. First, the argument is that it extends the time between the crime
and the punishment, thereby nullifying both swift and certain justice. Second, it
overturns a number of convictions, thereby absolutely nullifying certain justice.
The facts of capital punishment confirm the impact of appeals on death sentences.
In 2011, 137 inmates were removed from death row, and only forty-three (31 percent) were executed. Those inmates had been in prison an average of 198 months
(or more than sixteen years) between before being executed. Slightly more than half
as many (twenty-four) died in prison of other causes. (And many of the
deaths occurred because they had been in prison so long because of their protracted
appeals.) Fifty-one (37 percent) had their death sentences overturned on appeal
(8 had the conviction itself overturned, and forty-three had the death sentence overturned). Finally, nineteen (14 percent) had their sentences commuted.72
The facts of the impact of appeals on death sentences are clear. The 1996
law limited appeals by essentially barring second or third habeas corpus appeals
once a first appeal had been decided, along with several restrictions. Opponents
of the law denounced it as an attack on the historic right of habeas corpus, not
only denying that right to an extremely vulnerable population but also in cases of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
220
CHAPTER
8
literal life and death. What effect did the law have? The answer is difficult to
determine because just a few years after the law was passed, the country began
turning away from capital punishment. After a peak of 315 in 1996, the number
of death sentences declined to 140 in 2005 and only 80 in 2011. Executions,
meanwhile, fell from a peak of 98 in 1999, to 60 in 2005 and 43 in 2011.73
There is no reason to think that the restrictions on appeals caused the number of death sentences to decline. More important from our standpoint, there
is also no reason to think that the limitations on appeals had any impact on
homicides. In Chapter 6 we discussed the conclusion of the National Academy
of Sciences that after decades of research there is no evidence that capital punishment decreases, increases, or has any effect on homicide rates.74
The other law restricting appeals, the Prison Litigation Reform Act, does not
concern us here. It severely limited the right of prisoners to file appeals over prison
conditions, and in this respect has no implications for deterring criminal conduct.
In the end, the available facts about the use of appeals do not support the
conservative argument that multiple appeals contribute to crime. Conservatives
argue that appeals delay “finality” and thereby undermine the deterrent effect
of the criminal process. Several things are wrong with this argument. First,
appeals are filed in so few cases that they cannot have any broad impact on criminal justice. Second, as we have also learned, many factors undermine the deterrent effect (low probability of arrest, a relatively high probability of the charges
being rejected or dismissed, whether the threat of punishment even works for
certain categories of offenders, and so forth). Appeals are at best a minor factor.
Like the insanity defense, successful postconviction appeals are rare events.
On occasion, a convicted offender is released through a successful appeal. But
these are the few celebrated cases that do not represent the general pattern in
the criminal justice system. Therefore, our next proposition is:
22
PROPOSITION
Limiting habeas corpus appeals of criminal convictions will have no effect on
serious crime.
CONCLUSION
One of the traditional conservative beliefs about the criminal justice system has been
that many criminals beat the system through loopholes that allow them to return to
the streets and prey on innocent citizens. Our review of the evidence, however,
indicates that the insanity defense, plea bargaining, and postconviction appeals are
not loopholes. To be sure, mistakes do occur, and dangerous people do commit
major crimes after having once been in the system. But these are the classic celebrated cases. The evidence is that prosecutors take major offenders seriously, and
always have, and that the insanity defense, plea bargaining, and postconviction
appeals are not major loopholes. To reduce crime, we need to look elsewhere.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
221
NOTES
1 Dawn Beichner and Cassia Spohn, “Prosecutorial Charging Decisions in Sexual
Assault Cases: Examining the Impact of a Specialized Prosecution Unit,” Criminal
Justice Policy Review 16 (December 2005): 461–498.
2 U.S. Department of Justice, An Exemplary Project Major Violator Unit—San Diego,
California (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1980).
3 Some examples are described in William F. McDonald, Plea Bargaining: Critical Issues
and Current Practices (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1985).
4 McDonald, Plea Bargaining.
5 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2009
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2013), Table 24.
6 National Opinion Research Center, General Social Surveys, 1972–2002, cited in
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, online edition,
Table 2.47.
7 Jack Hinckley, Breaking Points (Grand Rapids, MI: Chosen Books, 1985).
8 Randy Borum and Solomon M. Fulero, “Empirical Research on the Insanity
Defense and Attempted Reforms: Evidence toward Informed Policy,” Law and
Human Behavior, 23, no. 1 (1999): 117–135.
9 Reported in Rita J. Simon and David E. Aaronson, The Insanity Defense: A Critical
Assessment of Law and Policy in the Post-Hinckley Era (New York: Praeger, 1988), 166.
10 Simon and Aaronson, Insanity Defense, Table 3.2, 40.
11 Borum and Fulero, “Empirical Research on the Insanity Defense,” 120.
12 Ibid., 27–28.
13 American Psychiatric Association, American Journal of Psychiatry 140 (1983):
681–688.
14 Stuart M. Krischner and Gary J. Galperin, “Psychiatric Defenses in New York
County: Pleas and Results,” Journal of the American Academy of Psychiatry and the Law
29 (No. 2, 2001): 194–201.
15 Valerie Hans, “An Analysis of Public Attitudes toward the Insanity Defense,”
Criminology 24 (May 1986): 393–414.
16 Jeffrey S. Janofsky, Mitchell H. Dunn, and Erik J. Ruskes, “Insanity Defense Pleas in
Baltimore County: An Analysis of Outcome,” American Journal of Psychiatry, 153,
no. 11 (1996): 1464–1468.
17 Newsweek, 24 May 1982.
18 For a good study of this subject, see Egon Bittner, “Police on Skid Row: A Study in
Peacekeeping,” American Sociological Review 32 (October 1967): 694–715.
19 Rights of the Mentally Disabled: Statements and Standards, rev. ed. (Arlington: American
Psychiatric Publishing, 2002).
20 Baxstrom v. Herold, 383 U.S. 107 (1966).
21 Henry J. Steadman et al., Before and After Hinckley (New York: Guilford, 1993),
58–61, 97–99.
22 Henry J. Steadman, Beating a Rap? Defendants Found Incompetent to Stand Trial
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979), 104.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
222
CHAPTER
8
23 Terence P. Thornberry and Joseph E. Jacoby, The Criminally Insane: A Community
Follow-up of Mentally III Offenders (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979). For
another study with similar results, see Henry J. Steadman and James J. Cacozza,
Careers of the Criminally Insane (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1974).
24 Borum and Fulero, “Empirical Research on the Insanity Defense,” 121.
25 Norval Morns, Madness and the Criminal Law (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1982).
26 Ibid.
27 Ibid.
28 Grant H. Morns, The Insanity Defense: A Blueprint for Legislative Change (Lexington,
MA: Lexington Books, 1974).
29 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Mental Health Treatment of Inmates and Probationers
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1999).
30 John Klofus and Ralph Weisheit, “Guilty but Mentally Ill: Reform of the Insanity
Defense in Illinois,” Justice Quarterly 4 (March 1987): 39–50.
31 Ibid.
32 Kurt M. Bumby, “Reviewing the Guilty but Mentally Ill Alternative: A Case of the
Blind ‘Pleading’ the Blind,” Journal of Psychiatry and the Law 21.2 (1993): 191–220.
33 Moran, “Insanity Defense,” 81.
34 Ibid., 77–78.
35 Borum and Fulero, “Empirical Research on the Insanity Defense,” 133.
36 The traditional criticism of plea bargaining is Abraham Blumberg, Criminal Justice
Issues and Ironies, 2nd ed. (New York: New Viewpoints, 1979). The best recent
study is McDonald, Plea Bargaining.
37 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2006
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2010), Table 11, and the discussion at 10.
38 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2004. Yue Ma,
“Prosecutorial Discretion and Plea Bargaining in the United States, France,
Germany, and Italy: A Comparative Perspective,” International Criminal Justice Review
12 (2002): 22–52.
39 On the “copout” ceremony, see Jonathan D. Casper, American Criminal Justice: The
Defendant’s Perspective (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1972), 81–86.
40 Timothy Lynch, “The Case Against Plea Bargaining,” Regulation (Washington, DC:
The Cato Institute, 2003).
41 Samuel Walker, Taming the System: The Control of Discretion in Criminal Justice,
1950–1990 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).
42 National Advisory Commission on Criminal Justice Standards and Goals, Courts
(Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1973), 46.
43 Michael L. Rubinstein, Stevens H. Clarke, and Teresa J. White, Alaska Bans Plea
Bargaining (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1980).
44 Rubinstein et al., Alaska Bans Plea Bargaining.
45 Norval Morns and Gordon Hawkins, Letter to the President on Crime Control
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1977), 61.
46 Rubinstein et al., Alaska Bans Plea Bargaining.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CLOSE THE LOOPHOLES
223
47 This point is argued in Walker, Taming the System, 95–96.
48 Teresa White Carns and John Kruse, Alaska’s Plea Bargaining Ban Re-Evaluated
(Anchorage: Alaska Judicial Council), 16.
49 Franklin E. Zimring and Gordon Hawkins, Crime Is Not the Problem, Lethal Violence
in America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1997), 19.
50 Carns and Kruse, Alaska’s Plea Bargaining Ban re-Evaluated.
51 Walker, Taming the System.
52 Diedre M. Bowen, “Calling Your Bluff: How Prosecutors and Defense Attorneys
Adapt Plea Bargaining Strategies to Increased Formalization,” Justice Quarterly 26
(March 2009): 2–29.
53 This point is argued in Walker, Taming the System.
54 Bowen, “Calling Your Bluff,” 6, 9, 23, 26.
55 Malcolm W. Feeley, “Perspectives on Plea Bargaining,” Law and Society Review 13
(Winter 1979): 199.
56 Robert M. Bohm, “‘McJustice:’ On the McDonaldization of Criminal Justice,”
Justice Quarterly 23 (March 2006): 127–146.
57 Brian J. Ostrom and Roger A. Hanson, Efficiency, Timeliness, and Quality: A New
Perspective from Nine State Criminal Courts (Williamsburg, VA: National Center for
State Courts, 1999). Available on the National Center for State Courts website.
http://www.ncsc.org/. Accessed February 15, 2014.
58 Peter F. Nardulli, James Eisenstein, and Roy B. Flemming, The Tenor of Justice:
Criminal Courts and the Guilty Plea Process (Urbana: University of Illinois, 1988).
59 Bureau of Justice Assistance, National Assessment of Structured Sentencing (Washington,
DC: Government Printing Office, 1996), 98–100. Jeffrey T. Ulmer, Social Worlds of
Sentencing (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1997).
60 Elizabeth J. Letourneau, Kevin S. Armstrong, Dipankar Bandyopadhyay, and
Debajyoti Sinha, “Sex Offender Registration and Notification Policy Increases Plea
Bargains,” Sexual Abuse: A Journal of Research and Treatment 25 (no 2, 2012):
189–207.
61 U.S. Sentencing Commission, Report to the Congress: Mandatory Minimum Sentences in
the Federal Criminal Justice System (Washington, DC: U.S. Sentencing Commission,
2011).
62 Missouri v. Frye, 566 U.S. ___ (2012). Lafler v. Cooper, 566 U.S. ____ (2102).
63 Cynthia Alkon, Plea Bargaining, “Just as It Ever Was,” The Mayhew-Hite Report on
Dispute Resolution and the Courts 10, No. 4 (May 2012).
64 “Inmate Whose Lawyer Slept Gets New Trial,” The New York Times, June 4, 2002.
65 Herbert Packer, “Two Models of the Criminal Process,” in Packer, The Limits of the
Criminal Sanction (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1968), 149–173.
66 Macklin Fleming, The Price of Perfect Justice (New York: Basic Books, 1974).
67 Ibid.
68 U.S. Department of Justice, Attorney General’s Task Force on Violent Crime
(Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1981), 58.
69 Fay v. Noia, 372 U.S. 391 (1963).
70 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Federal Habeas Corpus Review Challenging State Court
Criminal Convictions (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1995). See also Victor
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
224
71
72
73
74
CHAPTER
8
E. Flango, Habeas Corpus in State and Federal Courts (Williamsburg, VA: National
Center for State Courts, 1994).
Data on appeals can be found at the website of the Administrative Office of the
United States Court: http://www.uscourts.gov/Home.aspx. Accessed February 15,
2014.
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Capital Punishment, 2011—Statistical Tables (Washington,
DC: Department of Justice, 2013), Tables 9, 10.
Ibid. Current data are available at the Data Death Penalty Information Center
website: www.deathpenaltyinfo.org. Accessed February 15, 2014.
National Academy of Sciences, Deterrence and the Death Penalty (2012).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PART
III
The Middle Ground: Guns
and Victims
T
here are two things liberals and conservatives agree on. First, crime victims
have certain rights that should be protected, and they are entitled to
programs and services that will address the needs that result from their victimization. With only a few exceptions, liberals and conservatives agree with most of
what the victims’ rights movement has been doing on behalf of victims. Second
liberals and conservatives agree that guns violence is a major part of the crime
problem. They disagree strongly, however, on the exact nature of the problem
and what should be done about it. Liberals focus on guns and want to limit their
availability. Conservatives focus on criminals who use guns and want to get
tough with them. Some conservatives even want to increase the number of
guns people carry. The policies each side recommends reflect their fundamentally
different assumptions about crime and criminals.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
9
Protect Crime Victims
VICTIMS IN THE CRIMINAL JUSTICE SYSTEM
The Crime Victims’ Rights Movement
From the beginning of the modern criminal justice system, the crime victim was
the forgotten person. Unless required to testify in court (and we know how few
cases actually go to trial), victims typically received little if any follow-up from
the police or prosecutors. They had no input into plea bargains, which they
often did not even know about or have a voice in, and no right to express
their views to the judge about the sentence. In 1982, the chair of the President’s
Task Force on Victims of Crime declared: “The neglect of crime victims is a
national disgrace.”1
All of that began to change in the 1970s. A victims’ rights movement arose
with powerful political support, advocating new policies that would give
victims certain formal legal rights and to provide services and financial compensation for them. The change over the last forty years has been dramatic. Every
state has passed a variety of victims’ rights laws. Some even added victims’
rights amendments to their constitutions. In Oregon, to take just one example,
there were twenty crime victims services providers in 2006 that received funds
through the state’s Crime Victims’ Services Division and that almost certainly
did not include numerous programs maintained by religious and civic groups
that did not receive any state funds.2 The U.S. Justice Department established
the Office for Victims of Crime (OVC) in 1983 to provide a broad range of
services and information, and many states have similar units in their attorneys
general offices. The OVC estimates that there are 27,000 victims’ rights laws
across the country. Congress passed a Victims of Crime Act in 1984, the
Violence Against Women Act in 1994, and then passed a federal Crime
Victims Act in 2004, which include a right to protection, notification about
legal proceedings, right to attend and to speak at those proceedings, a right to
restitution, and other rights.3
226
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
227
In short, the status of the victim in the U.S. criminal justice system has
been completely transformed. As it developed over the years, the victims’
rights movement itself has changed in important ways since the 1982 President’s Task Force on the Rights of Crime Victims. That report reflected the
conservative political perspective of President Ronald Reagan’s administration
and included many favorite conservative crime control proposals, such as
modifying the exclusionary rule (see our discussion in Chapter 5), that were
not directly related to crime victims. The victims’ rights movement has instead
given increased emphasis to the needs of specific populations of victims,
including women, the elderly, the disabled, juvenile runaways and thrownaways, racial and ethnic minorities, and people who are lesbian, gay, transgendered, or bisexual.
The 2013 report by the U.S. Office for Crime Victims, Vision 21: Transforming Victims Services, reflects the growth and maturation of the crime victims’
movement. Chapter 1 of the report calls for “Forging a Future Informed by
Research,” noting the “dearth of data and research in the field.” Chapter 3,
meanwhile, ambitiously calls for efforts to reach “all victims.”4 Finally, it calls
for a process of systematic strategic planning to guide the future growth and
quality of victims’ services and programs.
The Historical Background
In modern Anglo-American law, the crime victim has had no formal role in the
criminal process. The prosecutor represents the public interest, including that of
the victim. This is why, in some states, cases are formally titled “The People
versus.” As an American Civil Liberties Union (ACLU) handbook on The Rights
of Crime Victims explains, “The victim is not a formal party to a criminal
proceeding.”5 It was not always this way. Until the mid-nineteenth century,
crime victims represented themselves, bringing their own cases before magistrates
and judges. The office of the modern prosecutor gradually emerged in the nineteenth century (as did modern policing) and assumed the role of representing the
public in general and crime victims in particular.6
A professional criminal justice system, where disinterested public officials
handle criminal cases, arose for several reasons. First, it establishes the idea that
a crime is an offense against society as a whole and not just an individual.
Second, it removes the element of vengeance from the handling of a case. A
public official will be free of anger and personal animosity toward the offender.
Third, professionals bring training and experience to the job, which increases the
likelihood that justice will be done.
The victims’ rights movement challenged the exclusion of the victim from
direct participation in the criminal justice system. Its leaders argued that police
and prosecutors did not inform victims about important events related to their
cases, such as bail hearings or even trials; victims had no say in plea bargain agreements, sentencing, or parole decisions. An early survey in Alameda County,
California (Oakland), for example, found that only about 12 percent of victims
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
228
CHAPTER
9
had ever been notified that an arrest had been made in their case.7 The alienation
and anger of crime victims over being excluded fueled much of the early victims’
rights movement.
Although conservatives dominated the victims’ rights movement at the
beginning, groups advocating for specific victim populations were also important,
and some had different political perspectives. The women’s rights movement was
particularly important in this regard, and it helped to secure new laws and policies to protect the victims of domestic violence and rape, such as mandatory
arrest laws for domestic violence, shelters for victims, and counseling programs
for offenders. Mothers Against Drunk Driving (MADD), as we discussed in
Chapter 6, led a national anti-drunk driving crusade to protect the victims of
drunk driving.
The Goals of This Chapter
This chapter examines the goals, achievements, and limitations of the victims’
rights movement. What reforms have been proposed? Which ones have been
adopted? Do victims’ rights laws work? If so, which ones, and why? Were
they good ideas in the first place? And we will also look at some reforms
that really have benefitted crime victims. Finally, and most important for
the purposes of this book, do crime victims’ laws and programs help to
reduce crime?
VICTIMS’ RIGHTS TODAY: LAWS AND PROGRAMS
The victims’ rights movement has been successful in achieving significant
legislative victories. By the early 1990s, every state had passed some kind of
victims’ rights law, more than thirty had amended their constitutions to protect and advance the rights of crime victims, and there an estimated 27,000
victims’ rights law altogether. Box 9.1 presents the victims’ rights amendment
to the Arizona state constitution, which includes some, but not all, of the
new laws and procedures that now exist. In the following section, we will
take a quick look at the major categories of new laws and procedures on
victims’ rights.
Constitutional and Statutory Guarantees of Victims’ Rights
One major goal of the victims’ rights movement has been to guarantee rights
either through a constitutional amendment or a statute. See, for example, the
victims’ rights amendment to the Arizona state constitution in Box 9.1 It
includes provisions that are common to almost all victims’ rights laws and constitutional amendments, including particularly a right to notification about court
proceedings, a right to be heard at those proceedings. Placing victims’ rights in
a constitution gives them a more solid legal foundation than simply passing a
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
BOX
9.1
229
STATE OF ARIZONA CONSTITUTION, ARTICLE 2, SECTION 2.1
A) To preserve and protect victims’ rights to justice and due process, a victim of crime has a right:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
To be treated with fairness, respect, and dignity, and to be free from intimidation, harassment,
or abuse throughout the criminal justice process.
To be informed, upon request, when the accused or convicted person is released from
custody or has escaped.
To be present at and, upon request, to be informed of all criminal proceedings where the
defendant has the right to be present.
To be heard at any proceeding involving a post arrest release decision, a negotiated plea, and
sentencing.
To refuse an interview, deposition, or other discovery request by the defendant, the
defendant’s attorney, or other person acting on behalf of the defendant.
To confer with the prosecution, after the crime against the victim has been charged, before
trial or before any disposition of the case and to be informed of the disposition.
To read presentence reports relating to the crime against the victim when they are available
to the defendant.
To receive prompt restitution from the person or persons convicted of the criminal conduct
that caused the victim’s loss or injury.
To be heard at any proceeding when any post conviction release from confinement is being
considered.
To a speedy trial or disposition and prompt and final conclusion of the case after the conviction
and sentence.
To have all rules governing criminal procedure and the admissibility of evidence in all criminal
proceedings protect victims’ rights and to have these rules be subject to amendment or repeal
by the legislature to ensure the protection of these rights.
To be informed of victims’ constitutional rights.
new law, which potentially could be found to be unconstitutional or simply
repealed. There have been several attempts to add victims’ rights to the U.S.
Constitution, but none has been successful.
Victims’ Services
Every state and many local governments have created agencies and programs
that provide direct services to crime victims. At the same time, many private
non-profit agencies also provide services, such as shelters for domestic violence
victims. The Minneapolis Police Department, for example, distributes a handout listing the range of service agencies in the community, ten of which maintain twenty-four-hour hotlines in cases of emergencies.8 Two of the most
common services around the country are hotlines and shelters for the victims
of domestic violence. The 2012 national census of shelters and services for
women surveyed 1,643 agencies, a figure that indicates how well-established
such programs have become across the country.9 Every state maintains a program
for financial compensation of crime victims. Victim and witness assistance
programs, designed to help crime victims deal with being a witness in a criminal
trial, are also extremely popular.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
230
CHAPTER
9
EVALUATING THE IMPACT OF CRIME VICTIMS’
LAWS AND PROGRAMS
The impact of crime victims’ laws and programs can be evaluated from three
different perspectives.
Impact on Crime Victims. The first criterion for assessing the impact of any
crime victims’ law or program is its direct or indirect impact on crime
victims. Does a particular law or program achieve its stated objectives?
Does it help victims in any tangible way? What is the evidence
regarding the impact?
Impact on the Criminal Justice System. A second criterion involves the impact
of a law or program on the criminal justice system. Does it affect the
system in any way? Does it improve the operations of the criminal
justice system in any measureable way, or does it create new problems?
Does it, for example, create inefficiencies that impede the functioning
of the system? If so, what is the evidence on this issue? Or, as we will
discuss later, does it improve the justice system by enhancing confidence,
trust, and legitimacy?
Crime Reduction. The third criterion involves crime reduction. Because this is
the central focus of this book, we need to discuss it in a separate section,
which follows.
Victims’ Rights and Crime
The focus of this book is on developing effective policies to reduce crime. It is
fair, then, to ask what victims’ rights services and programs have to do with that.
It is a good question. As we shall see, some victims’ services have a direct impact
on crime and victimization. Others, however, may only have an indirect effect at
best. Finally, some programs are unlikely to have any direct or indirect effect on
crime. Victim compensation programs, which provide monetary compensation
for victims’ losses, for example, are not likely to reduce crime.
Programs designed to provide advice on how to avoid being a victim of
crime are obviously likely to have a direct effect. The Arizona Department of
Public Safety, for example, has information on its website on how to “Reduce
Your Risk” of sexual assault. A Philadelphia program for elderly crime victims
provides funds to help install better locks and other safety devices that are likely
to prevent future victimization.10 Shelters and other services for runaway or
thrown-away juveniles may help reduce their chance of being victimized while
alone and out on the street, including sexual victimization.11
In addition to these direct crime reduction effects, some crime victims’
programs may also have an indirect effect. Most important in this regard are the
victims’ voice laws. To the extent that giving victims an active role in the justice
system helps them feel respected, it is also likely to increase their trust and
confidence in the system. This, in turn, is likely to enhance the legitimacy of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
231
the criminal justice system. We have already discussed the importance of legitimacy in several chapters of this book, see for example, Chapter 6, p. 135, and
will discuss it in much greater detail in Chapter 12. Experts on legitimacy argued
that if people have a greater sense of legitimacy, they are more likely to cooperate with the justice system in practical and important ways. They are more likely
to report crimes and neighborhood problems to the police; they are more likely
to give the police information of offenders and to serve as witnesses in crime. All
of these actions may increase arrests, prosecutions, and convictions—in short, to
help reduce crime.
SERVING SPECIAL POPULATIONS OF CRIME VICTIMS
The major change in the development of victims’ rights movement over the
years has been the growing attention to special populations of victims. In the
beginning of the movement, there was a strong tendency to talk about “victims”
as a vast undifferentiated group. Women, particularly with regard to domestic
violence, were the first distinct group to receive attention as crime victims, but
today the list of groups has expanded significantly. The Vision 21 report by the
Office for Victims of Crime reports that “[s]eismic attitudinal shifts in American
culture have made populations of previously underserved victims more visible,
such as minors who are victims of domestic sex trafficking; victims with disabilities; lesbian, gay, bisexual, transgender, and queer or questioning (LGBTQ) victims; and older victims of sexual abuse.”12
The shift to an emphasis on special populations allows policy makers and
service providers to focus on the special circumstances and needs of each
group. It hardly needs to be said that runaway juveniles, American Indians,
and elderly people in nursing homes are different people in different circumstances, with different problems and needs. The crimes they suffer are different
and preventing those crimes requires different approaches. Box 9.2 lists the
major special populations that have become the focus on the victims’ rights
movement.
BOX
9.2
© 2015 Cengage Learning
Previously Underserved Populations of Crime Victims
Women
Juvenile runaways and thrown-aways
People with disabilities
People who are elderly
Native Americans
Sex-trafficking victims
Lesbian, bisexual, gay, and transgendered (LBGT) communities
Child sex abuse victims
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
232
CHAPTER
9
Women
The 2012 National Census of Domestic Violence Shelters and Services
provides a valuable perspective on the achievements of the crime victims’
movement. On September 12, 2012, it surveyed 1,643 local programs across
the country. That day, these programs served a total of 64,324 people. Of
that group, 35,323 used shelters or emergency housing, and 29,001 received
nonresidential services. Eighty percent of the clients received some form of
children’s support or advocacy; 53 percent received some assistance related to
court proceedings, including accompaniment to court or advocacy; and 20,821
hotline calls were received. In addition, there were 10, 471 requests for services
that went unmet; 65 percent of those involved requests for housing.13
The sheer number of such agencies across the country is powerful testimony
to how deeply entrenched are victims’ services just related to women and
domestic violence. The high volume of services provided every day, moreover,
testifies to the need for such services.
Public concern about domestic violence coincided with the birth of the
victims’ rights movement in the 1970s. Before then, domestic violence had not
been recognized as a major social problem. The attention of women’s advocates
and policy makers focused on police response to domestic violence incidents.
The police had traditionally taken a no-arrest approach, treating domestic assaults
not as a crime. Women’s advocates challenged this practice in a number of
jurisdictions, arguing that a no-arrest policy denied women equal protection of
the law. The settlement of one case in Oakland, California, required the
Oakland Police Department to develop a new policy requiring an arrest where
there was probable cause of a felonious assault.14
The idea of mandatory arrest in domestic violence incidents gained considerable support across the country, and the result was an intense national debate
over the best policy for the police. Although some advocates argued for a mandatory arrest policy, others supported an arrest preferred policy that left police
officers with some discretion over whether or not to make an arrest, based on
the circumstances of the situation.15
Advocates of mandatory arrest in domestic violence incidents believed that it
would reduce reoffending by arrested assailants. An experiment in Minneapolis
by the Police Foundation appeared to confirm this belief. Subsequent studies,
however, found mixed results, with no clear pattern that arrest rather than no
arrest prevented further assaults. At present, there is no convincing evidence on
the crime reduction effects of arrest.16
As the debate over mandatory arrest continued, police departments across
the country adopted formal policies on the handling of domestic violence
incidents. This was a dramatic change from the past when departments had no
formal policies of any sort. Today, written policies on domestic violence are
nearly universal in policing. (Written policies on a range of critical incidents,
including use of force and vehicle pursuits, has become the standard law enforcement approach to controlling police discretion and reducing misconduct.)17
The most common policy today mandates arrest where there is clear evidence
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
233
of a felonious assault but grants police officers discretion in the handling of less
serious incidents. A 2008 report found that twenty-two states and the District of
Columbia had mandatory arrest laws; another six had arrest-preferred laws, and
eleven had laws guiding officer arrest discretion.18
In addition to new police arrest policies, prosecutors developed written
policies, and in some instances special units, to handle domestic incidents. The
Seattle City Attorney, for example, maintains a special Domestic Violence Unit
to handle misdemeanor domestic assault cases.19 States also passed new sentencing provisions for domestic violence. Some states passed laws covering all aspects
of domestic violence, from police response to prosecution and sentencing. At the
same time, services for the victims of domestic violence by private nonprivate
agencies proliferated, including hotlines for crisis situations, shelters for victims
and their families, and counseling programs for both victims and abusers.
PROTECTION ORDERS Protection orders (also often called restraining
orders) forbidding an offender from having any contact with the victim are
commonly used in domestic conflict situations and are designed to both prevent
repeat assaults and provide assurance and security to victims. Before the victims’
rights movement, there were some significant legal problems with the enforcement of protection orders. Generally, the violation of a protection order is a
misdemeanor, and a police officer cannot make an arrest unless it occurs in his
or her presence. This requires the victim to obtain a warrant for the violator’s
arrest before an arrest can be made. In cases where the victim feels threatened
but the violator is not present, the requirements limit the ability to make an
immediate arrest.20
Because of frustration with the limits on police arrest powers related to
protection orders, many states have revised their law to permit an arrest without
observing the violation. Washington state law now provides that “[a] peace
officer shall arrest without a warrant and take into custody a person whom the
peace officer has probable cause to believe has violated [a protection] order …”21
The victim who has obtained an order must establish that a valid order exists,
and people are advised to keep a copy with them at all times.
A quick web search of local prosecutors’ offices around the country reveals
that many, if not most, have detailed information pages on protection orders,
which indicates the now-established commitment to this process as a service to
crime victims.
A study of protection orders in one state, involving women who had obtained
protection orders, found them to be generally effective, although there were some
implementation problems. The study interviewed 213 women, equally divided
among urban and rural areas at three-week, three-month, and six-month intervals.
Half of the women reported that the protection order was violated in some way
(either by property damage, threats, or physical violence). Other studies have
found violation rates ranging from 23 to 70 percent, for an average of 40 percent.
Nonetheless, the subjects as a whole experienced significantly lower incidents of
violence. Among the urban women, “violence severity” scores dropped from an
average of 16.9 in the six months before the order to only 3 in the six months
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
234
CHAPTER
9
after the order went into effect. The women also reported lower rates of distress,
loss of sleep, and fear of future harm. The one problematic finding was that success
rates were lower in rural areas, and that arrests and prosecutions for domestic
violence were also lower in those areas. Other studies have found arrest rates for
protection order violations at 20 and 34 percent, but with significantly higher rates
in jurisdictions where the police had a mandatory arrest policy.22
The study concluded that protective orders were effective and that “they are
relatively low cost, especially when compared with the social and personal costs
of partner violence.” If similar effects occur nationally, we can say that protection
orders are one form of victim assistance that are effective.
© 2015 Cengage Learning
BOX
9.3
WOMEN AND THE NEW ORLEANS POLICE DEPARTMENT:
A CASE STUDY
Effectively addressing domestic violence is extremely complex, requiring coordination of different
agencies, each of which needs to have adequate commitment and resources. A 2011 investigation of
the New Orleans Police Department by the U.S. Justice Department found serious problems with the
handling of domestic violence incidents and ordered major reforms. Although the department had a
special Domestic Violence Unit, its policies were vague and inadequate on all the key procedures:
how 911 operators should take calls, the procedures for preliminary investigations of crime scenes,
identifying and documenting injuries to victims, and procedures for follow-up investigations. The
Domestic Violence Unit was understaffed, with only three detectives for the 6,200 domestic violence
calls the department received in the first half of 2010. An examination of domestic violence incident
reports did not indicate that follow-up interviews of witnesses were conducted.23
The Justice Department investigation led to a consent decree requiring a number of reforms,
including “clear and detailed guidelines” for handling domestic violence incidents putting a priority on
victim safety, discouraging the arrest of both the alleged victim and the offender, and requiring arrest for
violating a protection order. Additionally, the police department was directed to develop a working
relationship with the New Orleans Family Justice Center, assign “sufficient staff” to the Domestic Violence Unit, and develop a program for additional training for all officers related to their specific duties.24
The Justice Department also investigated the New Orleans police department’s handling of
sexual assault cases, and its findings closely paralleled those related to domestic violence. The
department misclassified many rape and attempted rape cases, with the result that they were never
investigated. Cases that were investigated were marked by inadequate documentation of incidents,
including frequent failures to locate and interview witnesses. More seriously, the department’s
handling of rape cases were deeply influenced by “stereotypical assumptions and judgments about
sex crimes and victims of sex crimes.” The department had outdated policies on sexual assaults, and
supervision of detectives was inadequate. The resulting consent decree mandated a set of reforms
designed to overcome these deficiencies.
The New Orleans case dramatizes the many challenges facing any effort to address the
victimization of any group, not just women. Those challenges involve public agencies making a
serious commitment, providing adequate staffing and resources, maintaining policies that meet
current best practices from around the country, properly training and supervising front-line
workers, maintaining effective relations with other criminal justice agencies, and finally developing
productive working relationships with private social service agencies.
These lessons apply with equal force to other special populations, including the elderly,
persons with disabilities, juvenile runaways and thrown-aways, and others. The U.S. Justice
Department, for example, investigated the Portland, Oregon, police department and found a
number of serious problems related to the response to people with mental illnesses, including
excessive use of force, inadequate training for officers, and a failure to establish good working
relationships with mental health agencies.25
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
235
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
In the end, the question for us is whether the many changes related to
domestic violence over the past forty years have had any impact on crime. The
National Crime Victimization Survey has persuasive evidence of a dramatic
decline in intimate partner violence (another widely used term for domestic
violence) from 1994 to 2010, falling 64 percent in that period. The data alone,
however, do not permit any conclusions as to the cause of this development.
The decline is part of the Great American Crime Drop, which we discussed in
Chapter One. The best guess is that the various programs designed to change the
response of the police and other agencies to domestic violence, along with the
development of services for the victims of this particular crime, all contributed in
some way and that the cumulative effect was undoubtedly significant.26
People with Disabilities
There are an estimated 59 million people with disabilities in the United States.
This includes people with emotional, mental, and physical disabilities. Many
offensive stereotypes affect people with disabilities, for example, by labeling
them as defective and as less than fully human. People with disabilities are
particularly vulnerable to criminal victimization because they may not be able
to understand fully what is happening to them, unable to resist, or unable to
seek help. And in some cases, the offender is a person of trust, a family member,
caretaker, or staff person at a nursing home or other institution.
According to the National Crime Victimization Survey, people with disabilities
experience violent crime at a higher rate rather than people without disabilities and are less likely to call the police to report their victimization.27 In
2010, the violent victimization rate for disabled persons was almost twice
that for people without disabilities (28 per 1,000 versus 15 per 1,000). One
disturbing pattern is that people with disabilities are victimized less often by
strangers than people without disabilities: 33 versus 41 per 1,000, meaning that
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
236
CHAPTER
9
they are more likely to be victimized by someone they know, including family
members or caretakers. And for the same reason, offenses against people with
disabilities are less often reported to the police: 41 versus 53 percent for people
without a disability.28
The Civil Rights Division of the U.S. Department of Justice is empowered
to investigate violations of the civil rights of persons with mental illnesses or
disabilities who reside in state institutions. An investigation of the New Hampshire mental health system in 2011 concluded that the system was “broken.” In
fact, the state agreed with most of the findings. The Justice Department report
found pervasive incidents of “day-to-day harm associated with improperly and/
or under-treated mental health conditions,” and many “serious incidents that
prompt involvement with law enforcement, the correctional system, and the
court system.” In particular, there was a lack of “safe, affordable, and stable community housing, including supported housing, for persons with mental illness.”
The reference to “safe” community housing clearly indicates that many people
with mental illnesses became the victims of crime.29
Juvenile Runaways and Thrown-aways
Juveniles who are out on the street, alone and away from their homes, are found
in all communities in the United States. Runaways leave home for many reasons,
including physical abuse or fear of abuse, a lack of respect and emotional support,
or because of their own rebellious and delinquent behavior. Some leave home
because they are lesbian or gay and their parents refuse to accept that fact. The
term thrown-away juveniles describes “those who are denied housing by their
families or prevented from returning home by a parent or other household
adult.” Both runaways and thrown-aways are symptomatic of family breakdown,
including divorce and separation, which often create serious financial problems,
physical, sexual or emotional abuse, conflict between the parents or step-parents,
or alcohol or drug abuse, which the juvenile may then take up.30
Runaways and thrown-aways are particularly vulnerable to crime. With no
shelters, they are easy targets for robbery, physical abuse, or sexual exploitation.
The most immediate need is physical shelter for the night and meals. Helping
them find permanent shelter and the services that will help them address past
victimization, particularly sexual abuse, alcohol or drug abuse, or emotional
problems arising from their situation, represents a major challenge for social
services. The police are typically, the first responders to the symptoms of such
problems, but a genuinely effective response requires a comprehensive response
by public and private agencies.31
People Who Are Elderly
With respect to crime victimization, we need to look at elderly people with a
dual lens. On the one hand, they have the lowest violent crime victimization
rate among all age groups. People sixty-five years old and older experience violent crime at a rate of 3.5 per 1,000, which is dramatically lower than even the
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
237
rate for fifty- to fifty-four-year-olds, 13.5 per 1,000. The rate is highest, 43.7 per
1,000 for twenty- to twenty-four-year-olds. The reasons for these differences are
easy to explain. Elderly people are much less likely to be out on the street at
night than younger people both because of their lifestyle and fear of crime.32
At the same time, however, the elderly are particularly vulnerable to certain
crimes. The Los Angeles County District Attorney’s Office has an Elder Abuse
web page that lists ten crimes against the elderly, including identify theft,
telemarketing and home repair scams, healthcare fraud, and real estate fraud.33
Victimization of elderly people often involves emotional and psychological
abuse and forms of neglect that may not always rise to the level of crime.
A special category of elderly crime victims involves abuse of people in residential
long-term care facilities.
CASE STUDY: CRIME REDUCTION SERVICES FOR THE
ELDERLY IN PHILADELPHIA The Elderly Victims Emergency Security
Fund (EVESF) in Philadelphia is a good example of a direct service to a special
population that has some direct effect on the likelihood of victimization. EVESF
assists Philadelphia residents who are age sixty and older, on a limited income,
and have been the victims of crime or abuse. Security funds assist them securing
their home environment by replacing or repairing locks, boarding or repairing
windows and doors, installing locks on windows, or even installing window
security bars in extreme circumstances, and helping with other emergency
measures if needed.34
An evaluation of the program found that most clients received assistance
with repairing or replacing their door lock (85.4 percent), 13.1 percent received
assistance with replacing a door, and 24.1 percent received assistance with
measures to secure their windows. Interviews with older adults receiving the
services and professionals working with them agree that the EVESF services
were provided efficiently and were of high quality. Among the older adults
who had previously received assistance with lock repairs/replacements 63 percent
were not the victim of a crime in the year prior to the survey, and 70 percent
believed that the EVESF services they received helped prevent having something
stolen from them or their home.
ELDER ABUSE IN LONG-TERM CARE FACILITIES A particularly
serious aspect of the victimization of elderly persons is abuse in long-term
care facilities. The evidence indicates that the problem is pervasive. More than
3 million people are in some form of long-term care facility, including both
nursing homes and board and care homes. Shockingly, a 2000 study of nursing
home residents reported that 44 percent of residents said they had been abused,
and 95 percent said they had been neglected or seen another resident neglected.
In a more recent study 50 percent of nursing home staff admitted to mistreating
a patient either physically or mentally. Of all reported complaints of mistreatment
in a 2010 report on nursing homes, 29 percent involved physical abuse and 7
percent involved sexual abuse.35
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
238
CHAPTER
9
Existing preventive measures appear to be not working as planned. Federal standards for nursing homes exist, but a 2001 report to Congress found
that one in three nursing homes were cited for violations of standards and
had the potential to allow harm or had actually led to harm in the previous
two years.36
Native Americans
Native Americans experience violent crime at twice the rate of the rest of the
U.S. population. The aggravated assault rate is twenty-five per 1,000, compared
with thirteen among African Americans and eight among whites. The murder
rate among Native Americans, however, is the same as for the general
population.37
The Vision 21 report pointed out that there are “complex jurisdictional
issues, along with the cultural diversity of tribes,” that pose significant challenges
to both lowering crime rates and providing victim services.38 A basic problem is
the simple fact of geography. Reservations typically cover vast rural areas. Alaska
Native villages are often remote and even inaccessible in winter. Many tribes
operate their own tribal law enforcement agencies, and many are inadequately
staffed and suffer from poor training. As a result, basic victim assistance and law
enforcement are often inadequate or completely unavailable.39
A 2013 Bureau of Indian Affairs report on Making Indian Communities Safer
listed the challenges ahead, many of which involved simply bringing tribal
criminal justice systems up to contemporary professional standards. Those challenges include: revising out-of-date tribal criminal codes, developing adequate
detention facilities to serve remote locations, improving recruitment services
for tribal justice officials, adopting contemporary police technology such as
computer-aided dispatch, and developing collaborative relationships with
various stakeholders.40
VICTIMS’ PROGRAMS AND SERVICES
The victims’ rights movement has resulted in the development of a wide variety
of programs and services for crime victims. Table 9.1 presents the results of a
1994 survey indicating the prevalence of programs just in prosecutors’ offices.41
The following section examines in detail some of the more important programs
and the issues surrounding them.
Victim Notification
One of the most important original goals of the victims’ rights movement
was to keep victims informed about the status of the criminal case in which
they were victimized. Victim notification procedures are designed to overcome the traditional neglect of victims and their resulting alienation from
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
239
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
T A B L E 9.1
Victim services that jurisdictions require prosecutors’ offices to
provide, 1994
Percentage of offices
Full-time office (population served)
Type of service
All
offices
500,000
or more
Less than
500,000
Part-time
office
Notification/alert
Notify victim
82
87
85
73
Notify witness
55
67
59
42
Orientation/education
Victim restitution assistance
60
62
62
55
Victim compensation procedures
58
73
65
41
Victim impact statement assistance
55
78
60
40
Orientation to court procedures
41
57
48
24
Public education
15
20
17
9
Escort
Escort victim
23
39
28
9
Escort witness
17
31
19
9
Property return
38
46
39
35
R eferral
32
46
37
18
Personal advocacy
17
26
22
5
Counseling/assistance
Counseling
10
21
12
5
Crisis intervention
10
19
14
0
Number of offices
2,282
119
1,480
683
SOUR CE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, Prosecutors in State Courts, 1994 (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1996), p. 9.
the criminal justice system. In principle, notification requirements cover all
the critical points in the criminal justice system: bail setting, preliminary hearings, plea bargaining, trial, sentencing, postconviction appeals, and parole
hearings. Notification procedures are closely related to victim voice laws
and procedures, by which victims are guaranteed a right to speak at any of
key points in the system. But notification is separate to the extent that the
victim may not want to speak but only to be kept informed of the status of
the case.
Victim notification is a sound and humane idea that was long overdue.
There is absolutely no reason that the police should not keep victims informed
and many reasons that they should. Mainly it would help build positive police–
community relations. By 1997, about one-third of all city police departments
and county sheriffs’ departments had some kind of victim assistance program.42
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
240
CHAPTER
9
Meanwhile, almost all state prosecutors (93 percent) reported in 1990 that
they informed victims of the outcome of cases, compared with only 35 percent
in 1974.43
There are some potential problems with victim notification, however. Most
important, the notification requirements impose a significant administrative burden on police departments, prosecutors, and correctional agencies. It requires
additional staff to monitor criminal cases, maintain a current contact information
for all victims, and then notify them in a timely fashion. These demands are all
the more challenging in today’s environment of budget stress on state and local
agencies.
Another problem is that some victims may not want to be contacted. The
Houston, Texas, police department incorporated victim recontact program as
one component in a larger “fear reduction” experiment. Police officers contacted
crime victims to express sympathy and ask whether they needed any further
assistance or information. An evaluation, however, found that the program
achieved none of its goals. Victims who were contacted did not express any less
fear of crime or greater confidence in the police, compared with victims who
were not contacted. Victims with poor English skills were actually more fearful
than those who were not recontacted. They did not understand why the police
were contacting them and became more fearful as a result. The Houston data
suggest that many victims may prefer just to be left alone, which of course is
their right.44
Victim/Witness Assistance Programs
Victim/witness assistance programs vary widely. Many provide emergency services in the form of shelter, security repair, financial assistance, and onthe-scene comfort. Most provide follow-up counseling. Nearly all have some
form of advocacy and support services, such as intervening with the victim’s
employer or landlord. Many help with insurance claims or efforts to obtain restitution. Nearly all provide court-related services concerned with the victim’s role
as witness for the prosecution, such as orienting victims or witnesses to court
procedures, notifying them of court dates, providing transportation to court,
escorting them at the court, and providing child care.
How well do these programs work? A survey of sixty-two victim service
programs in North Carolina found that the state’s 1986 Fair Treatment for
Victims and Witnesses Act was meeting the needs of victims “only
minimally.”45 Almost all of the programs were providing referral to social,
restitution, and compensation services; notification about court cases; and
allowances for victim impact statements. Nonetheless, 59 percent of crime
victims surveyed in the state expressed dissatisfaction with the criminal justice
system. Particularly significant was the fact that about one-third were not even
aware of their right to make a victim impact statement. This suggests that a
major provision of the law was not being fully implemented. An evaluation
concluded that the programs provided primarily witness assistance rather than
victim assistance.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
241
Protecting Victims from Harm
Another important service for crime victims is to protect them from harm. Many
victims are fearful of the person who victimized them and worry about further
violence at a court proceeding or later. For some, even seeing the offender adds
to the original trauma of the crime. This issue applies to all of the special populations of crime victims we have discussed.
The Minnesota crime victims law guarantees victims a right to a secure waiting area during court proceedings, a right to request that their home address not
be disclosed in court, a right to request police withhold a victim’s identity from
the public (although this provision raises important fair trial considerations), and a
right to make a confidential request that the offender be tested for HIV. The
Minneapolis Police Department, meanwhile, has a Personal Safety Referral List,
which lists eighteen separate agencies or services for crime victims, three
of which are related to children, and ten with twenty-four-hour hotlines for
emergency situations.46
To the extent that provisions do protect victims from another offense, they
are likely to reduce crime. Emergency services, such as those listed by the Minneapolis police department, particularly if they can provide temporary housing,
can prevent further victimization of people who find themselves homeless and
out on the street.
Expanding the Victim’s Voice
One of the major goals of the victims’ rights movement has been to expand the
role of victims in the criminal justice process, giving them a greater voice in bail
decisions, plea bargains, sentencing, and parole release decisions. Item 4 of the
victims’ rights section of the Arizona constitution provides a right “[t]o be
heard at any proceeding involving a post arrest release decision, a negotiated
plea, and sentencing.” Adopted by California voters in 1982, Proposition 8 provided that “the victim of any crime, or the next of kin of the victim … has the
right to attend all sentencing proceedings … [and] to reasonably express his or
her views concerning the crime, the person responsible, and the need for
restitution.”47 The U.S. Office for Victims of Crime publishes a bulletin on
The Crime Victim’s Right to be Present, with current information on laws and procedures. A second bulletin covers victim input into plea agreements.48
The idea of expanding victims’ voices has several goals. One is to give
crime victims a feeling of participating in the justice system and to end their
feelings of isolation and alienation. Giving victims a voice is consistent with
the goals of procedural justice, which we will discuss in Chapter 12. Tom
Tyler and other experts on this subject argue that people are more likely to
have positive feelings about a process if they feel they have an opportunity to
participate in it, to express their views (having a “voice”), and thereby have
some control over the outcome. Greater satisfaction with the criminal process,
Tyler argues, is likely to lead to greater trust in the justice system and lower
levels of law breaking.49
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
242
CHAPTER
9
Another goal is to ensure that offenders are properly punished and not
allowed to get off too easily. The assumption is that the victim will object to a
too-lenient plea bargain or sentence.
VICTIMS’ VOICE LAWS: THE RETURN OF VENGEANCE?
Opponents of victims’ voice laws fear that it brings vengeance (as opposed to
justice) into the criminal process. One of the functions of a professional criminal
justice bureaucracy is to ensure fair and impartial treatment of all accused persons.
A professional is someone who is not emotionally involved in a case and
acts impersonally on the basis of the facts and circumstances. A lawyer, for example, has a professional obligation to prosecute or defend a criminal defendant
regardless of his or her personal feelings about the person or what he is accused of
doing.
The Supreme Court has shared some of these fears about the danger of
vengeance and emotionalism distorting the criminal process. In Booth v. Maryland
(1987) and South Carolina v. Gathers (1989), the Court reversed death sentences
because of statements read to the jury about the victim. In Gathers, for example,
the prosecutor read from religious material that had been in the possession of a
murder victim and also mentioned that he was a registered voter.50 The Court
ruled that this information was not related to the circumstances of the crime.
Two years later, however, in Payne v. Tennessee (1991), the Court ruled that
the victim impact statements in that case were not unconstitutional.51
THE IMPACT OF VICTIMS’ VOICE LAWS There is mixed evidence
about the impact of victims’ voice laws. On the one hand, many victims do not
take advantage of the opportunities to participate in the process. Also, those who
do are not always seeking severe punishment. Nonetheless, some evidence exists of
harsher punishment for offenders in cases in which victims do in fact participate.
A national study found that among those victims who were notified about
hearings (and many were not, as we have seen), more than 90 percent chose to
make an impact statement at sentencing. Participation was much lower for other
stages in the criminal process, however. Less than 40 percent of those who were
notified made a statement at bail hearings, and less than 20 percent chose to
attend parole hearings.52
Does victim participation make a difference in the outcome? A study of 500
Ohio felony cases between June 1985 and January 1989 found several notable
effects. First, victim impact statements (VISs) were submitted in about half (55
percent) of all cases. Under the program, VIS staff solicited information from
victims at the time of grand jury hearings. Only 18 percent of victims appeared
at trial or sentencing, and only 6 percent exercised their right to speak. Victim
participation was heavily influenced by the seriousness of the crime. Not surprisingly, VISs were filed in 73 percent of “aggravated or special felony” cases,
including 81 percent of sexual offenses but only 49 percent of property crime
cases, and only 13 percent of those that were handled as misdemeanors. Somewhat surprisingly, 61 percent of male victims filed a VIS, compared with only 28
percent of females.53
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
243
Of those who did submit a VIS, 60 percent requested that the offender be
incarcerated. Convicted offenders were somewhat more likely to be incarcerated
if a VIS was filed or if the victim appeared in court or requested incarceration
(but, surprisingly, not if the victim only spoke in court). Also, filing a VIS
statement, appearing in court, and requesting incarceration were associated with
longer prison terms. The overall impact of the VIS law was somewhat limited,
however. Case outcomes were affected primarily by offense severity and
offenders’ prior record.54
A previous study of sexual assault cases in Ohio found that 60 percent of the
victims made statements at sentencing. This study concluded that the statements had
little effect on sentencing. A high level of agreement was noted between the sentence
the victim recommended and the sentence the judge considered appropriate.55
In Pennsylvania, however, a study found that victim impact statements had a
significant effect on the chances of an offender being paroled. The Pennsylvania
Board of Probation and Parole denied parole in 43 percent of one hundred cases
in which there was some victim input but in only 7 percent of a comparable set
of one hundred cases in which there was no input.56 These findings lend support
to concerns about the possible undesirable effects of victim impact statements.
Whether a victim makes a statement may be a matter of chance, and it means
that one offender will serve longer than another who committed the same crime
because of an arbitrary factor unrelated to the crimes they committed.
In any event, apart from the satisfaction that VISs may give to the victims
themselves, no evidence indicates that they have any effect on serious crime.
Some offenders may serve slightly longer prison terms, but as we have already
seen, there is no evidence that they are any less likely to eventually recidivate.
Post-Conviction Services
With many crimes, the impact on the victim does not end with the conviction
and sentencing of the offender. As the Oregon Department of Justice explains,
“[in] most criminal cases, the guilty verdict is only the beginning. Many cases
continue on through layers of appeals or are revisited at parole and psychiatric
review hearings.”57 Subsequent legal proceedings include direct appeals,
federal habeas corpus petitions, parole and post-prison supervision hearings, and
psychiatric security review board hearings.
Victim Compensation Programs
The most popular victims’ rights program involves financial compensation.
California passed the first crime victims’ compensation law in 1965, and today
they exist in every state. The 1984 Victims of Crime Act provides federal
financial support for state and local programs. Federal funds are derived from
fines, assessments, and forfeitures (mainly bond forfeitures from failure to appear
in court) from federal offenders. Each state receives a base amount of $500,000,
whereas public and private victims’ services programs compete for additional
funds.58
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
244
CHAPTER
9
There is also a National Association of Crime Victim Compensation Boards
to provide professional leadership to what is now an established part of the criminal justice system. As of 2013, compensation programs around the country grant
almost $500 million a year to more than 200,000 crime victims. Most of the
money comes from offenders, through fines or fees imposed on convicted offenders. Federal funds provide about 35 percent of the money awarded to victims;
most of that money also comes from fines and assessments against offenders.59
In the state of Washington, the covered expenses include medical and dental
costs, wage replacement, prescription drug coverage, mental health treatment,
and death benefits that include grief counseling and funeral expenses. The
victims’ compensation fund does not cover the costs of identity theft, personal
property crimes, and crime scene cleanup, or injuries sustained as a result of the
victims own actions (such as provoking, inciting, or participating in the event
that led to the injuries). The Washington state program makes grants of about
$14 million a year (minus administrative costs).60
Evaluations of victim compensation programs have not been overly favorable, however. Many requests are denied, leaving victims frustrated and
unhappy. The New York State Crime Victims Board denied as many as 60
percent of all requests in the late 1980s. The most common reason for denying
claims is the failure to provide sufficient documentation of the injury or loss.61
Even more disturbing, according to William Doerner’s study of Florida crime
victims, is that those who did receive compensation did not have more favorable attitudes toward the criminal justice system than did victims whose claims
were denied.62
Despite the problems that do exist, victim compensation is a worthy idea
that was long overdue. The heavy toll that crime takes on people gives the
government good reason to maintain some kind of insurance or compensation
program. To the extent that compensation improves victims’ attitudes toward
the justice system, it benefits the system. There is no reason to believe, however,
that victim compensation programs reduce crime.
ENSURING PROFESSIONALISM IN VICTIM SERVICES
The maturation of the victims’ rights movement, as the Vision 21 report indicates, includes ensuring that programs and services meet the highest professional
standards. Immigration is changing the face of the United States, bringing people
from many different countries and cultural traditions. In addition, traditional
populations such as Native American also introduce cultural issues. One issue
involves simply being able to communicate with special victim populations and
also to understand and be sensitive to different cultural traditions. The Crime
Victims’ Services Division in Oregon, for example, publishes a Victims’ Rights
Guide in five languages other than English: Spanish, Russian, Chinese, Korean,
and Vietnamese. There is also a version written for juveniles, in English, Spanish,
and Russian.63
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
245
The Oregon Crime Victims’ Services Division has adopted a set of Cultural
Competency Standards. The standards apply to all personnel associated with
state-funded programs, including board members, directors, and administrators;
all employees, volunteers, and human resource employees; and finally aspects of
physical facilities and the agency’s environment. The standards call for all
employees and volunteers to “[m]aintain up-to-date knowledge of the beliefs
and conventions of the diverse cultural groups in the community served.” Agencies also need to engage in a “self-assessment for continuous improvement in
culturally responsive interactions.” One example calls for an annual budget that
reflects the “costs of providing services to the full range of community
members,” including the cost of non-English speakers and translators. Employee
promotions should include as one criterion a candidate’s “participation in cultural
competency training, planning and participation in community events, membership
on related committees or organizations.”64
As an aside, we should point out that these standards are relevant for all
criminal justice agencies—police, court personnel, corrections agencies—to
ensure that their personnel have adequate cultural competence for the diverse
populations they serve.
The Oregon Crime Victims’ Services Division tested its cultural competence
standards and found that the “greatest success” resulted from establishing both
formal and informal partnerships with community groups and that the informal
conversations were particularly valuable in developing relationships and
understanding.
Evaluating the Impact of Victim Programs and Services
Despite the fact that the victims’ rights movement is now forty years old, the
Vision 21 report rather shockingly pointed out that there is “surprisingly little
research examining how victims’ rights provisions are implemented, whether
victims actually receive the rights and services to which they are entitled under
law, and whether being provided with these rights and services actually increases
victims’ well-being, cooperation, and satisfaction with the criminal justice system
and improves criminal justice system outcomes.”65 The report urged a commitment to evidence-based crime policy making, in which existing and new
programs are subjected to rigorous evaluations using the highest standards of
scientific research. As we discussed in Chapter 1, evidence-based policy making
has emerged as the standard in criminal justice.
In 2006, Oregon began to require all crime victims service providers receiving
funds through the state undergo an evaluation using three Common Outcome
Measures. All grant recipients were required to survey their clients on the following questions. (1) “The services provided by this program helped me make
informed choices about my situation”; (2) “After working with this agency, I
have some new ideas about how to stay safe,” and “After working with this
agency, I know more about resources that may be available, including how to
access them”; (3) “As a result of the information I received from this agency, I
better understand my rights as a victim of crime,” and “The information given
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
246
CHAPTER
9
to me by this agency helped me better understand the criminal justice system
process as it relates to my case.”66
The results from agency surveys were overwhelmingly positive. In virtually
all cases, only 1 percent of the client respondents disagreed. In one, for example,
in response to the question that the program “Helped me make informed
choices about my situation,” among 9,875 respondents 65 percent strongly
agreed, 29 percent agreed, and only 1 percent disagreed. Responses from clients
of the Portland Women’s Crisis Line were particularly interesting. Eighty-seven
percent reported that they “feel safer,” as a result of the crisis line, and 94 percent
reporting knowing more about available resources. Most of the negative
responses involved the outcome of their case, as opposed to the quality of the
Crisis Line’s services. In particular, the greatest source of discontent was among
“victims who were unhappy with the plea bargains that the DA’s (District Attorneys) offered and the defendants accepted.”
“GETTING TOUGH” ON CRIME: DOES IT HELP CRIME VICTIMS?
In the early years of the crime victims’ movement, many proposals were essentially
conservative “get-tough-on-crime” recommendations. This reflected the significant role of political conservatives in the early victims’ rights movement. The President’s Task Force on Victims of Crime, sponsored by President Reagan, for
example, recommended legislation “to abolish the exclusionary rule,” “to abolish
parole,” to permit hearsay evidence at preliminary hearings, and to authorize preventive detention.67 These were all major items in the conservative crime control
agenda, and we have already discussed two of them in this book.
The relevant question is, does getting tough on criminals help crime victims,
either directly or indirectly? The short answer is, no, they do not. In Chapter 5,
we found that repealing the exclusionary rule will not reduce crime. There is no
evidence that the rule allows thousands of criminals to “beat the system,” go free,
and prey again on innocent people. In Chapter 7, we found that limiting the
right to bail through preventive detention is also not likely to reduce violent
crime. Only 8 percent of felony defendants released on bail in 2009 were
arrested for another felony while on bail, and no one has developed a reliable
formula for predicting which defendants they are from among all felony
defendants. Moreover, as we pointed out, sex offenders, who are the subject of
particular fear among both crime victims and the general public, have the lowest
reoffending rate. If these policies do not reduce crime, then they do nothing to
help crime victims. In Chapter 11, we will examine whether abolishing parole
would have any effect on crime.
The President’s Task Force recommendation that hearsay evidence should
be admissible at preliminary hearings is particularly dangerous and requires special
comment. The proposal is based in part on the belief that it will protect the
victim from the trauma of testifying in person at trial (and having to face the
accused). Relaxing the established rules of evidence to permit hearsay testimony
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
247
at any stage in the criminal justice process sets a dangerous precedent, however.
Allowing it only at preliminary hearings, moreover, is silly and misleading. It will
be of little help in convicting the offender if it is inadmissible at trial.68
CONCLUSION
The victims’ rights movement is one of the more significant developments in
recent criminal justice history. Forty years ago, there was little concern about
crime victims and few programs to assist them. Today, laws and programs designed
to help crime victim are an established part of the criminal justice system in every
jurisdiction. The question, of course, is whether they reduce crime.
Some of the crime victim laws and programs are good ideas, providing
valuable assistance to people who have been harmed by crime. Some others,
however, are bad ideas that promise to help crime victims and reduce crime
but in fact do neither. Some may reduce crime, but there is no persuasive
evidence that they do.
Providing crime victims with notification about court proceedings is a good
idea that may help to build trust and confidence in the criminal justice system.
The most promising outcome has involved crime prevention advice and
assistance to the elderly that will help them become the victims of crime. Advice
on how to avoid financial fraud and assistance on securing their places of residence are likely to reduce crime. Providing emergency shelter and counseling
services to runaway or thrown-away teenagers on the street are also likely to be
effective. Shelters and other forms of emergency housing for the victims of
domestic violence. To date, however, we do not have any solid evidence that
they achieve this objective.
23
PROPOSITION
Most victims’ rights laws and programs are worthy ideas that were long
overdue. Only a few, however, provide the kind of direct services that are
likely to reduce crime.
NOTES
1 President’s Task Force on Victims of Crime, Final Report (Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office, 1982), vii.
2 Oregon Crime Victim Services Division, Report on Common Outcome Measures Use by
CVSD Grantees to Collect Client Feedback, July 2010–June 2011 (Eugene: Oregon
Department of Justice, 2011).
3 Office for Victims of Crime, Putting Victims First: 2009 OVC Report to the Nation
(Washington, DC: Office of Victims of Crime, 2009). Available on the website of
the Office for Victims of Crime at www.ojp.usdoj.gov/ovc/.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
248
CHAPTER
9
4 Office for Victims of Crime, Vision 21: Transforming Victim Services (Washington,
DC: Office for Victims of Crime, 2013).
5 James H. Stark and Howard Goldstein, The Rights of Crime Victims (New York:
Bantam, 1985), 19.
6 Allen Steinberg, The Transformation of Criminal justice Philadelphia, 1800–1880
(Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1989).
7 R. Lynch, “Improving Treatment of Victims: Some Guides for Action,” in William
McDonald, ed., Criminal Justice and the Victim (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1976),
165–176.
8 Minneapolis Police Department, Assistance for Victims of Domestic Abuse. Accessed
January 13, 2014, at http://www.ci.minneapolis.mn.us/www/groups/public/
@mpd/documents/webcontent/convert_261411.pdf.
9 National Network to End Domestic Violence (NNEDV), Domestic Violence Counts
2012: A 24-Hour Census of Domestic Violence Shelters and Services (Washington, DC:
NNEDV, 2013).
10 Philadelphia Health Management Corporation, An Evaluation of the Elderly Victim’s
Emergency Security Fund (Philadelphia: Center for Advocacy for the Rights and
Interests of the Elderly, 2001).
11 National Center for Victims of Crime, Outreach to Underserved Teen Victims of Crime:
Chart a Course for Expanding Victim Services to Youth (Washington, DC: National
Center for Victims of Crime, 2012).
12 Office for Victims of Crime, Vision 21: Transforming Victim Services, 1.
13 National Network to End Domestic Violence (NNEDV), Domestic Violence Counts
2012: A 24-Hour Census of Domestic Violence Shelters and Services.
14 Nancy Loving, Responding to Spouse Abuse and Wife Beating: A Guide for Police
(Washington, DC: Police Executive Research Forum, 1980).
15 Lawrence W. Sherman, Janell D. Schmidt, and Dennis P. Rogan, Policing Domestic
Violence: Experiments and Dilemmas (New York: Free Press, 1992).
16 Ibid.
17 Samuel Walker and Carol A. Archbold, The New World of Police Accountability, 2nd
ed. (Newbury Park: Sage, 2014).
18 David Hirschel, Domestic Violence Arrest Cases: What Research Shows about Arrest and
Dual Arrest Rates (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2008). Bureau of Justice
Statistics, Local Police Departments 2000 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice,
2004), Table 58. NCJ 196002.
19 The website is: http://www.seattle.gov/law/domestic_violence/.
20 T. K. Logan, Lisa Shannon, and Robert Walker, “Protective Orders: Questions and
Conundrums,” Trauma, Violence and Abuse 7 (July 2006): 175–205.
21 Washington statute. Washington Courts, “Domestic Violation Protection Order
Process” available at https://www.courts.wa.gov/dv/?fa=dv_order.ordviol. Accessed
February 116, 2014.
22 T. K. Logan and Robert Walker, “Civil Protective Orders Effective in Stopping or
Reducing Partner Violence,” Carsey Institute Policy Brief No. 18 (Durham, NH:
Carsey Institute, 2011).
23 U.S. Department of Justice, Civil Rights Division, Investigation of the New Orleans
Police Department (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, March 16, 2011).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
249
Available at the Civil Rights Division Special Litigation Section website: http://
www.justice.gov/crt/about/spl/police.php. Accessed February 16, 2014.
United States v. City of New Orleans, Consent Decree Regarding the New Orleans
Police Department (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, January 11, 2013).
Available at the Civil Rights Division Special Litigation Section website: http://
www.justice.gov/crt/about/spl/police.php. Accessed February 16, 2014.
U.S. Department of Justice, Civil Rights Division, Letter to Mayor Sam Adams,
Portland, Oregon, Investigation of the Portland Police Bureau, (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, September 12, 2012). Available at the Civil Rights Division
Special Litigation Section website: http://www.justice.gov/crt/about/spl/police.
php.
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Intimate Partner Violence, 1993–2010 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2012).
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Crime Against People with Disabilities, 2008–2010
(Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2011).
National Center for Victims of Crime, Disabilities and Victimization (Washington,
DC: National Center for Victims of Crime, 2013). Bureau of Justice Statistics, Crime
Against Persons with Disabilities, 2008–2010.
U.S. Department of Justice, Civil Rights Division, Letter to Hon. Michael A.
Delaney, Attorney General, State of New Hampshire, United States’ Investigation of
the New Hampshire Mental Health System Pursuant to the Americans with Disabilities Act
(April 7, 2011). Available at: http://www.justice.gov/crt/about/spl/documents/
New_Hampshire_MH_findlet_04-07-11.pdf. Accessed February 16, 2014.
National Center for Victims of Crime, Outreach to Underserved Teen Victims of Crime:
Chart a Course for Expanding Victim Services to Youth (Washington, DC: National
Center for Victims of Crime, 2012), 13.
Ibid.
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2012 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2013), Table 7.
The Los Angeles District Attorney’s web page is available at: http://da.lacounty
.gov/seniors/crimes.htm. See also the U.S. Justice Department’s web page on
Financial Crimes Against the Elderly: http://www.cops.usdoj.gov/Default.asp?
Item=2560.
Philadelphia Health Management Corporation, An Evaluation of the Elderly Victim’s
Emergency Security Fund.
National Center on Elder Abuse, Research Brief: Abuse of Residents of Long Term Care
Facilities (Washington, DC: National Center on Elder Abuse, n.d.). Bureau of Justice
Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2008 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice,
2009), Table 4. Catherine Hawes, Testimony, U.S. Senate, Elder Abuse in
Residential Long-Term Care Facilities, June 18, 2002. Available on the National
Center on Elder Abuse website (under Reports and Studies), www.ncea.aoa.gov.
U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Government Reform, Abuse of
Residents Is a Major Problem in U.S. Nursing Homes (Washington, DC: July 30, 2001).
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Criminal Victimization, 2012, Table 7. Bureau of Justice
Statistics, American Indians and Crime (Washington, DC: Department of Justice,
2004).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
250
CHAPTER
9
38 Office for Victims of Crime, Vision 21: Transforming Victim Services, 12–13.
39 Bureau of Indian Affairs, Crime Reduction Best Practices Handbook 2012, Making Indian
Communities Safer (Washington, DC: Bureau of Indian Affairs, 2013).
40 Ibid.
41 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Prosecutors in State Courts, 1994 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 1996), 9.
42 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Law Enforcement Management and Administrative Statistics,
1991, xix.
43 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Prosecutors in State Courts, 2001 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2002).
44 Lee P. Brown and Mary Ann Wycoff, “Policing Houston: Reducing Fear and
Improving Service,” Crime and Delinquency 33 (January 1986): 71–89.
45 Robert A. Jerin, Laura J. Moriarty, and Melissa Gibson, et al., “Victim Service or
Self Service: An Analysis of Prosecution Based Victim-Witness Assistance Programs
and Providers,” Criminal Justice Policy Review 7 (no. 2, 1995): 152.
46 Minneapolis Police Department, Accessed January 13, 2014, at http://www.ci
.minneapolis.mn.us/police/report/police_crime-reporting_victim-assistance.
47 Edwin Villmoare and Virginia V. Neto, Victim Appearances at Sentencing under
California’s Victims’ Bill of Rights (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office,
1987); Candace McCoy, Politics and Plea Bargaining Victims’ Rights in California
(Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1993).
48 President’s Task Force on Victims of Crime, Final Report, 114.
49 Tom R. Tyler, Why People Obey the Law (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1990).
50 South Carolina v. Gathers, 490 U.S. 805 (1989); Booth v. Maryland, 482 U.S. 496
(1987).
51 Payne v. Tennessee, 501 U.S. 808 (1991).
52 Dean G. Kilpatrick, David Beatty and Susan Smith Howley, The Rights of Crime
Victim—Does Legal Protection Make a Difference? (Washington, DC: Department of
Justice, 1998), 6.
53 Edna Erez and Pamela Tontodonato, “The Effect of Victim Participation in
Sentencing on Sentence Outcome,” Criminology 28(3) (1990): 451–474.
54 Ibid.
55 Anthony Walsh, “Placebo Justice: Victim Recommendations and Offender
Sentences in Sexual Assault Cases,” Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology 11
(Winter 1986): 1126–1141.
56 William H. Parsonage, Frances Bernat, and Jacquehn Helfgott, “Victim Impact
Testimony and Pennsylvania’s Parole Decision Making Process: A Pilot Study,”
Criminal Justice Policy Review 6(3) (1994): 187–206.
57 Oregon Department of Justice, at: http://www.doj.state.or.us/victims/pages/
advocacy.aspx. Accessed February 16, 2014.
58 Office for Victims of Crime, Putting Victims First 2009 OVC Report to the Nation.
59 National Association of Crime Victim Boards, available at: http://www.nacvcb.org/.
Accessed February 16, 2014.
60 Washington Crime Victims Claims Board http://www.lni.wa.gov/ClaimsIns/
CrimeVictims/About/BudgetHistory/Default.asp. Accessed February 16, 2014.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PROTECT CRIME VICTIMS
251
61 Andrew Karmen, Crime Victims: An Introduction to Victimology, 2nd ed. (Pacific
Grove, CA: Brooks/Cole, 1990), 321.
62 William Doerner, “The Impact of Crime Compensation on Victim Attitudes
toward the Criminal Justice System,” Victimology 5(2) (1980): 61–77.
63 Barbara Glick, Cultural Competency Standards for Programs Serving Victims of Domestic
Violence and Sexual Assault and Other Crimes in Oregon, Rev. ed. (Eugene: Oregon
Department of State Police, 2006).
64 Ibid.
65 Office for Victims of Crime, Vision 21: Transforming Victim Services, 14–15.
66 Oregon Crime Victims’ Services Division, Report on Common Outcome Measures Use
by CVSD Grantees to Collect Client Feedback, July 2010–June 2011 (Eugene: Oregon
Department of Justice, 2011).
67 President’s Task Force on Victims of Crime, Final Report, 17–18.
68 Cassia Spohn and Julie Horney, Rape Law Reform: A Grass Roots Revolution and Its
Impact (New York: Plenum 1992).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
10
Control Gun Crimes
THE PROBLEM WITH GUNS—AND GUN POLICY
The debate over guns and gun violence changed dramatically in the winter of
2012–2013. On December 14, 2012, Adam Lanza shot and killed twenty-six
people at the Sandy Hook Elementary School shooting in Newtown, Connecticut; twenty of those killed were children. That tragedy followed the July 20, 2012,
mass shooting in Aurora, Colorado, where James Holmes shot and killed twelve
people and wounded fifty-eight others at a multiplex movie theater. These horrific
events shocked the nation and reenergized the debate over gun violence and gun
control.
Or did it? President Barack Obama made a strong pledge to do something
about gun violence in his January 2013 Inaugural Address and introduced a gun
control bill in Congress. The bill died in a Senate vote on April 17, 2013, and
the issue of gun control disappeared from national political discussion almost as
quickly as it had appeared.
The sudden swings in national attention about guns and gun violence reflects
the deeply divided attitudes of the U.S. people on the subject. Polls consistently
show support for greater controls over guns, but specific legislative proposals have
won support only in a few states and have gotten nowhere in Congress.
Firearms, especially handguns, are the most serious part of the crime problem
in the United States, and a deeply divisive issue among Americans. Firearms are
used in about 70 percent of all homicides each year. In addition to the loss of
lives and suffering for families and friends, the medical costs are estimated to be
$2.3 billion a year, of which taxpayers pay $1.1 billion. Firearms are also used in
41 percent of all robberies, according to the FBI. In addition, in 2010 there were
19,392 firearms suicides, more than the 6,115 handgun homicides that year.
Guns take a special toll among African Americans. The homicide rate for African
Americans is almost eight times that of white Americans (14.6 per 1,000
compared with 1.9). And homicide has been the leading cause of death among
African American men between the ages of fifteen and twenty-four.1
252
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
253
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
Gun Violence in Perspective
There is bad news and good news about guns and gun-related crime in the
United States. First, the bad news. As Table 10.1 indicates, the United States
stands alone in terms of the number of people killed each year by handguns.
Mass shootings at schools and public places generates a pervasive fear for safety
throughout U.S. society, and as we have already mentioned, gun deaths take a
special toll on the African American society.
Despite the grim statistics about gun violence, there is actually some good news
when we step back and take the long view. The plain fact, obscured by the headlines on mass shootings, is that gun violence is down significantly. The 6,371
handgun-related homicides in 2012 represented a 53 percent decline from 13,510
T A B L E 10.1
An international perspective: People murdered
by guns, 2006
18
Austria
27
Australia
59
England and Wales
60
Spain
190
Canada
194
Germany
10,177
United States
SOUR CE: Brady Campaign Against Gun Violence, www.bradycampaign.org.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
254
CHAPTER
10
Firearm Homicides, 1993−2011
Rate per 100,000 persons
Number
20,000
8
6
15,000
Rate
10,000
4
5,000
2
0
'93 '94 '95 '96 '97 '98 '99 '00 '01 '02 '03 '04 '05 '06 '07 '08 '09 '10 '11
0
F I G U R E 10.1 Trends in firearm-related crime, 1993–2011.
SOURCE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, National Crime Victimization Survey.
in 1994. This was part of the Great American Crime Drop, and it is an important
and positive development. Homicides, moreover, are down among all racial and
ethnic groups: down 51 percent among African Americans between 1993 and
2011, compared with a 48 percent decline for whites and a 54 percent decline for
Hispanics. Murder rates also fell among Native Americans and Asian/Pacific Islanders.2 One important part of this change was the decline in intimate partner violence
that occurred among white, African American, and Hispanic Americans alike.3
In short, we have less crime overall, less violent crime, and fewer crimes committed with a firearm, compared with ten or twenty years ago. The data suggest
that if we want to understand gun violence and how to reduce it, we need to
understand the factors related to the changes in the larger U.S. crime problem.
Actually, there are two gun violence problems in the United States. Mass
shootings, such as the Sandy Hook Elementary School shooting, receive
enormous publicity but are fairly rare events. One survey found a total seven
mass shooting incidents in 2012, in which sixty-six people were shot and killed
(not including suicides by the perpetrators); in 2011 there were three incidents,
with nineteen dead. (We should note that there are several such surveys by the
news media, with no consensus on what should be counted as a “mass”
shooting.)4 Another survey found sixty-two mass shooting incidents since 1982,
which is an average of only about two per years.5
In short, mass shootings represent a tiny percentage of all firearms-related homicides in the country. We should think of them as celebrated cases that get a lot of
attention, arouse people to fear and anger, but do not represent the typical pattern of
gun violence. The vast majority of gun-related homicides occur on the streets in poor,
high crime, and predominantly African American and Latino neighborhoods. That is
where the majority of the 11,101 gun homicides in 2011 occurred, and any realistic
strategy to reduce gun violence has to address the circumstances of those shootings.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
255
Gun violence in Chicago received an enormous amount of national attention
between 2010 and 2013, and it is a situation worth exploring because it reveals
some of the complexities related to gun violence. To begin, Chicago experienced
the same decline in crime as did the rest of the country since the early 1990s. Murders fell from 943 in 1992, to 667 in 2001, and then to 437 in 2010. The situation
suddenly worsened in the next two years, and Chicago had 513 murders in 2012,
an increase of 17 percent in just two years. The dramatic reversal after a long-term
decline caught everyone by surprise and was cause for widespread alarm. (New
York City, by comparison continued its steady twenty-year decline in crime.) In
Chicago, the year 2013 opened on a particularly tragic note when fifteen-year-old
Hadiya Pendleton, who had performed at President Barack Obama’s inaugural was
shot to death. Several deadly weekends with multiple shootings, created the
impression that gun violence would surge even higher than 2012. But by the end
of the year, 2013 murders were in fact down compared with 2012.6
We need to reflect carefully on the Chicago case, and put it in its proper perspective. First, it dramatizes the central place of low-income African American and Latino
communities as the center of our gun violence problem. In 2011, 75.3 percent of
the murder victims in Chicago were African American, 18.9 percent were
Latino, and only 4.6 percent were white. Similar patterns are found in other big
cities.7 Second, even after rising in 2012, murders in Chicago were down significantly from twenty years previously. Third, other cities, notably New York and
San Diego, enjoyed long-term declines in murder, reaching record lows by 2012.8
SORTING OUT THE ISSUES
Because the debate over guns is so emotional, with passionate feelings on both
sides, and a lot of misunderstanding and incorrect information, it is important to
begin by clarifying the various issues involved.
Policy Options
The policy options regarding guns and gun violence can be conveniently divided
into two broad categories: supply reduction and demand reduction. As we will
discover in Chapter 13, the same categories reappear regarding drug policy.9
Supply reduction sees guns as the problem and seeks to reduce their availability: by banning guns, or at least some kinds of guns, or restricting who can own
them. Demand reduction focuses on gun offenders and seeks to reduce their
“demand” (i.e., their desire to own and use) for guns through tough punishment, for example, mandatory prison terms, long prison terms, and so on. This
combines deterrence and incapacitation strategies that we discussed in Chapters 6
and 7. The supply reduction and demand reduction positions do share some
common ground. Everyone wants to prohibit people with criminal records or
mental health problems from legally purchasing and owning guns. Some policies,
however, do not fit conveniently into either category. Pro-gun advocates
support “right-to-carry” laws that allow citizens to carry concealed weapons in
public. This is really a deterrence-oriented self-protection approach to crime.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
256
CHAPTER
10
Which Firearms Are We Talking About?
Much of the public debate over guns and gun violence is confused and unproductive because people are not clear about which firearms they are talking about
and often confuse the terms weapons, firearms, and handguns. The basic categories
are the following:
Weapons. The category of weapons includes all instruments capable of
injuring or killing people, including firearms, knives, hands and fists, poisons,
and so on.
Firearms. Firearms includes handguns, rifles, shotguns, automatic weapons,
and so on. In short, everything that fires a bullet or projectile of some sort.
Rifles and Shotguns. Rifles and shotguns are long-barreled firearms that are fired
from the shoulder and require two hands to use. Rifles have a rifled barrel.
Handguns. This includes only handguns, regardless of size or firepower,
including automatic pistols with large capacity magazines. It excludes “long
guns” such as rifles and shotguns.
Saturday Night Specials. Saturday night specials are one kind of handgun:
small, easily concealed, and cheap. We do not hear as much about this
category as we did years ago. At that time, some gun control advocates, in
an attempted compromise, proposed banning only Saturday night specials,
believing they were disproportionately involved in crime.
Assault Weapons. Assault weapons are rifles or pistols with high capacity
magazines that are capable of rapid-fire action.
The distinctions among weapons are extremely important because virtually
everyone agrees that handguns are the problem with respect to crime (and
suicide, for that matter). They represent 96 percent of all the firearms used in
robberies. True, rifles and shotguns are used, including in some of the horrific
mass murder incidents, but as we have already pointed out, such events are
rare. Shotguns, for example, accounted for only 303 homicides in 2012, and
rifles accounted for 322. As we have stated, handguns are the problem with
regard to crime, and that will be our focus.10
THE POLITICAL CONTEXT: PUBLIC ATTITUDES ABOUT GUNS
AND GUN VIOLENCE
Americans are deeply and passionately divided on the “hot button” issue of guns.
When asked in a 2013 survey which was more important, 50 percent said
“control gun ownership,” whereas 46 percent said “protect [the] right of Americans to own guns.” Interestingly, only 4 percent did not have an opinion.11 Part of
the reason for Americans’ deep interest is that firearms ownership is fairly widespread, and therefore proposals to restrict gun ownership directly affect a large
number of people.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
257
It is often reported that a majority of Americans favor gun control. This
statement is only partly true and is also misleading. The term gun control encompasses a number of different policy alternatives. For some people, it means
restrictions on the purchase of guns by people with criminal records or who are
mentally ill. For others, it means tougher penalties for criminals who use guns.
Thus, two people can answer yes the question of whether they support “stricter”
gun control but mean completely different policies.
Support for a ban on the manufacture, sale, or possession of assault rifles
(the term is ambiguous because of the variations among automatic weapons)
has also been falling, from 68 percent in 1995 to 44 percent in 2012 (when
51 percent opposed a ban). In 2012, only 24 percent of Americans favored
banning possession of handguns and support has been steadily falling, from
43 percent in 1991. The overwhelming majority (80 percent) favored requiring a
police permit for purchasing a gun (in a 2002 survey), and about the same
percentage supported a five-day waiting period for a gun purchase. Similar majorities supported mandatory gun safety training and designing guns so they cannot be
fired by children. Finally, large majorities favor tough criminal penalties: 78 percent
support doubling prison terms for crimes committed with a gun.12
GUN OWNERSHIP AND GUN-RELATED VIOLENCE
Gun Ownership
There are literally hundreds of millions of firearms in private hand in the United
States. Some Americans deplore this fact and see it as the heart of the problem.
Others celebrate widespread gun ownership. Like it or hate it, the prevalence of
guns in U.S. society is a fact of life that any intelligent discussion of guns and gun
violence must take into account.
The international Small Arms Survey estimates that there are 270 million
firearms in circulation in the United States, or about 90 for every 100 people.
Other recent estimates have placed the figure at more than 300 million by
2013.13 Using the high estimate, this includes about 114 million handguns,
110 million rifles, and 86 million shotguns. Additionally, more than 5 million
“small arms” were manufactured in the United States in 2010, almost twice the
3 million manufactured in 1986. (“Small arms” are defined basically as weapons that
can be carried and fired by a single person.) These new weapons undoubtedly more
than replace those that break or are lost or stolen.14 Finally, another 1.7 million
handguns are imported into the United States, according to the Bureau of Alcohol,
Tobacco, and Firearms (BATF). It is important to keep the 114 million handguns in
mind throughout our discussion. They are out there, and they are not going to
disappear. Many are bought and sold on the black market every year. Any effective
gun control policy has to take them into account.
There is some controversy over the percentage of households in the United
States with a firearm. The General Social Survey, conducted regularly by the
National Opinion Research Center (NORC) found that 32 percent of all
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
258
CHAPTER
10
households had a firearm in 2010, which represented a significant decline
from the 50 percent reported in 1973. The Gallup Poll, however, found that
43 percent of households had a firearm in 2012. The Gallup poll findings have
fluctuated over the years, with no clear trend, and have never fallen below
36 percent. The reasons for the variations in the two studies are a matter of
dispute.15
Men are more likely to own guns than are women (50 versus 41 percent in
2011), and whites are more likely than are African Americans, a significant
margin (51 versus 33 percent). The most important variable in ownership is
region. People in the southeastern United States are the most likely to own a
handgun, in large part because the region is predominantly rural and has a strong
tradition of hunting. Handgun ownership is lowest in the urbanized Northeast.16
Data from the NORC’s General Social Survey indicate that gun ownership is
highly correlated with people “who are members of social groups where gun
ownership is the norm.”17
Whether the percentage of households is stable or falling, given the significant
increase in the number of firearms in private hand it is clear that people who own
guns generally have more guns.
GUN-RELATED LAWS
The Supreme Court and Gun Ownership
The U.S. Supreme Court transformed the issue of gun control in 2008 with a
landmark decision ruling that a District of Columbia gun control law unconstitutional. The Heller v. District of Columbia decision affirmed for the first time that
the Second Amendment to the Constitution guaranteed the right of individuals
to own guns: “In sum, we hold that the District’s ban on handgun possession in
the home violates the Second Amendment, as does its prohibition against
rendering any lawful firearm in the home operable for the purpose of immediate
self-defense.”18
What exactly does the Heller decision mean? Are all gun control laws
unconstitutional? Does absolutely everyone have a constitutional right to own
a gun, including ex-felons and people with a history of mental health
problems? The Second Amendment protects the right to “keep and bear
arms.” What, exactly, does arms include? Machine guns? A military howitzer
is an arm. Can people own them, too?
In some respects, the Heller decision was a lot less radical than many people
think is. Justice Antonin Scalia’s majority opinion clearly stated that the Second
Amendment right was “not unlimited.” It does not include “any weapon,” or
prohibitions against ex-felons and mentally ill people owning guns, or restrictions
on carrying concealed weapons in public, or in “sensitive” public places such as
schools and government facilities, or other restrictions on the sale of firearms.
The dominant theme of Scalia’s opinion was the right to own guns for selfdefense. The Supreme Court reinforced Heller in 2010 in McDonald v. Chicago,
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
259
when it declared a handgun ban in Chicago unconstitutional under the Second
Amendment.19
In short, many existing gun regulations laws are undoubtedly still constitutional after Heller, and the full impact of the decision on a wide range of gun
polices—and ultimately on gun violence—is still uncertain.
Gun-Related Laws and Regulations
It is a myth that the United States has no laws designed to control gun-related
crime. In fact, we have numerous federal, state, and local laws on guns. One
group of laws seeks to limit the supply of guns, by banning them altogether, or
outlawing their manufacture or importation, or banning certain kinds of weapons, or restricting who can purchase and own guns. Another group of laws is
directed toward the criminal use of guns, by restricting purchase and ownership,
or imposing harsh punishment for the illegal ownership or use of guns. The best
source on this issue is BATF’s annual compilation of State Laws and Published
Ordinances (available on its website).20 Our question, as it is in every chapter of
this book, is whether particular laws are effective in reducing crime.
We will now examine the different policy options related to guns and gunrelated violence.
THE POLICY OPTIONS
Ban Handguns
The most extreme gun control proposal is to ban handguns. The idea of
“banning” handguns actually consists of several different policies: outlawing
possession, outlawing bullets, prohibiting the manufacture and sale of handguns,
and banning only Saturday night specials or assault weapons. As we have already
learned, the Supreme Court has declared unconstitutional laws that absolutely
ban the possession of guns. Nonetheless, it is useful to consider this option
because it illuminates both the assumptions underlying it and its likelihood of success if it were a viable option.
BAN POSSESSION OF HANDGUNS A few cities in the United States
actually banned the possession of handguns. Their experience gives us some
idea of what this approach can and cannot accomplish. The District of Columbia
banned the purchase, sale, transfer, and possession of all handguns in 1975. It
exempted handguns and long guns previously registered under a 1968 gun registration law. In 2008, as we mentioned previously, the Supreme Court in Heller v.
District of Columbia held the law an unconstitutional violation of the Second
Amendment.
It is useful to discuss the effectiveness of the DC law while it was in effect.
The nation’s capital represents a tough test of banning handguns because it is a
major city with a lot of violent crime and a lot of guns on the streets. The U.S.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
260
CHAPTER
10
Conference of Mayors, a leading gun control advocate, claimed that the law was
responsible for a “significant reduction in both firearm and handgun crime.”
Other analysts, however, believe that the mayors’ report was flawed and inconclusive. Edward Jones found in 1981 that comparable cities experienced even
greater reductions in gun-related crime during the same period, without the
benefit of gun control. Jones conceded that the law may have made some
contribution to reducing handgun crime, but it was impossible to argue that it
was the only or even the most important cause.21
Murder trends in Washington over the last forty years cast doubt on the
effectiveness of the 1975 law. Murders declined significantly in the late 1970s
and early 1980s, reaching a low of 147 in 1985. Then they skyrocketed to 482
by 1991, mainly as a result of the crack cocaine epidemic. Clearly, young men in
Washington who wanted to obtain a handgun had little trouble getting one.
Murders then began to fall, as a part of the Great American Crime Drop, reaching 186 in 2008, and then falling to only 92 in 2012. The fluctuations over the
years reflected national patterns in violent crime. After an exhaustive review of
all studies of the DC handgun ban, the National Academy of Sciences found “no
conclusive evidence” regarding the impact of the law. One troubling fact for gun
control advocates is that homicides fell by half between the 2008 Heller decision
and 2012.22
THE LIMITS OF BANNING HANDGUNS The Washington, DC,
experience illustrates the limits of attempting to outlaw possession of handguns.
The main problem is the 114 million handguns that already exist. No one has
offered a realistic plan for how they might be removed from circulation. As law
professor John Kaplan once pointed out, crusaders who seek to outlaw a product
(alcohol, drugs, guns) always focus on the alleged dangers of the item and spend
“little time and energy” estimating the costs of enforcement and the likelihood
of effectiveness.23
A sizable black market in handguns and other weapons already exists.
Surveys consistently indicate that criminals often obtain their guns through the
illegal firearms market. More than half of arrestees in one study (55 percent)
reported that guns were easy to obtain: More than one-third (37 percent) said
that they could obtain one in less than a week, and 20 percent said that they
could get one in a day or less. Thirteen percent said that they had stolen a gun
at some point in their life.24 Interviews with state prison inmates found that
40 percent obtained their gun from an illegal source, 37.4 percent got it from a
family member or friend, and only 7.3 obtained it from a retail store—a fact that
casts doubt on the effectiveness of laws regulating the sale of guns by licensed
dealers in keeping them out of the hands of criminals.25
A complete federal ban on handgun possession would undoubtedly foster the
growth of the black market. We have a lot of unhappy experience with this phenomenon. The prohibition of alcohol between 1920 and 1933 stimulated a huge
black market in the manufacture, sale, and consumption of alcohol. One collateral
consequence was the growth of organized crime to control the business. The
criminalization of drugs, meanwhile, has created drug markets, including drug
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
261
cartels to control that market. We will discuss the consequences of attempting to
outlaw certain products and services—alcohol, guns, gambling, drugs—in more
detail in Chapter 13. In any event, given the Supreme Court decision in Heller,
banning handguns or all firearms is not a viable option today.
BAN THE MANUFACTURE AND IMPORTATION OF HANDGUNS
Another way to reduce the availability of handguns in the United States is to
outlaw their manufacture and importation. This supply reduction approach is
designed to dry up the supply of handguns over the long run. As a practical matter, it is not a realistic idea. Banning any product would require a finding by
Congress that the item in question is a public health risk with no socially
redeeming value. Many products are dangerous but not banned. Cars and knives,
for example, are involved in the deaths and injuries of many people, but no one
suggests outlawing them. A ban on manufacturing handguns in the United
States, moreover, would only stimulate an international black market similar to
the one that dominates the drug trade. Also, it has been estimated that the
current supply of 114 million handguns is enough to last for the next hundred
years.26
GUN AMNESTY OR BUY BACK PROGRAMS Another supply reduction strategy involves gun amnesty or buy-back programs, where law enforcement agencies accept guns without questions from people who want to get rid
of guns they do not want. St. Louis conducted two buy-back programs, bringing
in 7,500 guns in 1991 and another 1,200 in 1994. Richard Rosenfeld evaluated
the program and found “little evidence” of any impact on gun assaults or
homicides in the city. An evaluation of a buy-back program in Seattle also failed
to find any reduction in crime.27
Trying to put a more optimistic interpretation on his findings, Rosenfeld
argues that buy-back programs are more likely to be effective in achieving
other goals such as strengthening community bonds and building support for
community leadership and that they should be evaluated on those terms.
Gun amnesty or buy-back programs have serious limitations for obvious
reasons. The available supply of handguns is so huge that it is unrealistic to
significantly reduce the number in any community. Firearms are turned in by
people who are the least likely to commit a gun crime, particularly the elderly.
Many people simply want to dispose of an unwanted weapon. In some cases, a
husband who owned guns dies and his widow does not want the guns in the
house. In St. Louis, for example, 62 percent of those turning in a gun retained
another weapon in the home. In short, there is no evidence that amnesty or
buy-back programs are likely to reduce significantly either the number of guns
in the community or crime.
BAN SATURDAY NIGHT SPECIALS A compromise strategy for
banning handguns advocated by some liberals is to outlaw only the so-called
Saturday night specials.28 The BATF defines the “Special” as a gun of 0.32 caliber
or less, with a barrel less than three inches in length and priced at fifty dollars or
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
262
CHAPTER
10
less. In 1996, Los Angeles became the fourteenth city in the United States (along
with the state of Maryland) to outlaw the sale of Specials, specifically prohibiting
twenty-three different weapons.29 Advocates of outlawing the specials believe that
these weapons are favored by criminals because of their price and their ability to be
easily concealed.
Outlawing only Saturday night specials probably will not accomplish what
its advocates expect. The role of the Specials in crime has been greatly exaggerated. Gary Kleck found that far from being the “preferred” weapon of criminals,
they represent only between 10 and 27 percent of all handguns used in crime.
Banning only the Specials would likely produce a substitution effect, in which
criminals simply move up to a larger weapon. Kleck further argues that Specials
are the primary self-defense weapon for low-income people. Banning them
would deprive poor people, who are victimized by violent crimes more than
middle-class people, of one of their principal means of self-protection.30
The proposal to ban only the Saturday night specials is essentially a political
copout. It allows people to appear to be doing something about the gun problem without directly threatening most gun owners. The same can be said about
the proposal to ban cop-killer bullets, which some people proposed in the past:
It focuses on a small part of the problem, one that has high symbolic power,
while avoiding the hard questions associated with the real problem.
Ban Assault Weapons
Although the issue of Saturday night specials has largely faded away, assault
weapons has become one of the most hotly contested issues. Several mass shootings have involved assault weapons, and the rise of gang-related violence in the
1980s aroused public concern about so-called assault weapons. There was much
publicity about gangs being heavily armed with Uzis, AK-47s, and similar
weapons.
The term assault weapon generally refers to “semiautomatic firearms with a
large magazine of ammunition that [are] designed and configured for rapid fire
and combat use.”31 They can be pistols or rifles. The BATF estimated in 1993
that about 1 percent of all guns then in private hands were assault weapons.
Many people want to ban them because they are not legitimate hunting weapons
and have no purpose other than killing people. In 2012, 44 percent of Americans
supported a ban on assault rifles, down significantly from 68 percent in 1995.32
The 1994 Violent Crime Control Act outlawed the manufacture and sale of
nineteen specific types of assault weapons for a period of ten years. The ban
expired in 2004, as was specified in the original law, and has not been
renewed.
Evaluations of the assault weapons ban found that, at best, the ban had only
a limited impact on gun crimes. One study estimated that assault weapons were
used in only 2 to 8 percent of gun crimes before the ban, whereas large capacity
magazines, which were also banned, were used in between 14 to 26 percent of
gun crimes. The Brady Center, a leading gun control group, estimated that the
ban produced a 66 percent drop in the use of assault weapons, reducing the
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
263
usage rate to 1.1 percent. A study by Koper and Roth, however, concluded that
the law may have contributed to the decline in gun violence, but that estimating
the actual effect is extremely difficult because of a variety of methodological
problems with this particular kind of crime. Also, the law went into effect just
as the Great American Crime Drop was occurring.33
The Violence Prevention Center pointed out that the gun industry undermined the law by producing weapons with only minor changes that technically
made them legal firearms. This is a classic example of the phenomenon of adaptation, which appears in other criminal justice issues.
As with Saturday night specials, the importance of assault weapons has been
greatly exaggerated. Kleck points out that the ordinary handgun remains the gun
of choice among robbers. Virtually all of the police officers feloniously killed are
killed with handguns. In short, although extremely deadly, assault weapons are
not the real problem in gun-related crimes. The 1994 ban expired in 2004, and
bills to reinstate it have been introduced several times in Congress, but they have
not been acted on.
Summary on Banning Firearms
All of the policies designed to eliminate the possession of handguns or certain
types of guns run up against the same basic problems: Millions of these weapons
already are in circulation (primarily those 114 million handguns), there is no
practical plan for eliminating them, a black market already exists, and any kind
of ban would only foster the growth of the black market. This leads us to the
following proposition:
24
PROPOSITION
Attempts to ban the possession of handguns, or certain kinds of guns, are not
a viable option for reducing crime.
REGULATE THE SALE AND POSSESSION OF HANDGUNS
The basic U.S. strategy for controlling handguns, embodied in numerous laws, is
to regulate their sale, purchase, and ownership to keep them out of the hands of
certain categories of people: convicted offenders, people with a history of mental
illness, and juveniles. This is essentially a “bad person” strategy. No one seriously
opposes this approach. The problem, and it is a big one, is how to effectively
ensure that members of these groups do not obtain weapons.
Regulate Gun Dealers
A major strategy for keeping guns out of the hands of certain groups has been to
regulate gun dealers. Federal law requires all commercial gun dealers, including
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
264
CHAPTER
10
pawn shops, to obtain a federal firearms license (FFL) to sell guns. In 2012 there
were 125,481 federally licensed gun dealers, down by more than half since 1992
when there were about 284,000.34 In the past, many licenses were held by individuals who were not commercial gun dealers, and one BATF survey found that
46 percent had sold no guns in the previous year. There are two basic problems
with the licensing of gun dealers. First, a series of reports have found that many
FFLs fail to comply fully with the federal regulations. Second, investigations have
found that a small number of “problem” dealers were responsible for a high
percentage of guns used in crime. The BATF, for example, traced half of all
seized guns back to less than 1 percent (0.4 percent) of all the licensed dealers.35
Beginning in 1993 a new set of laws and policies tightened up the regulation
of FFLs, including higher license fees; a requirement that dealers submit photographs and fingerprints of gun buyers; and that they report gun thefts within
forty-eight hours. As a result, the number of FFLs dropped significantly. An
evaluation by Christopher Koper found that the new regulations did eliminate
a large number of problem FFLs, but it is not clear that this had a direct impact
on gun-related crime. The changes occurred during the Great American Crime
Drop and may have contributed in some marginal way to that decline.36
In a later section, we will discuss the variations among state regulation of
gun sales and gun dealers and the impact on interstate trafficking of handguns.
Background Checks: The Brady Law
The 1994 Brady Handgun Violence Prevention Act (popularly known as the
“Brady Act”) requires background checks and a one-week waiting period for
all handgun purchases. The law forced thirty-two states to adopt new procedures
for background checks to comply with the Brady requirements. The other
eighteen states already had similar laws or even more stringent requirements.
The Brady Act specifically prohibits convicted felons, people with mental disabilities, and known drug addicts from owning guns. In 1996 the Lautenberg
Amendment prohibited persons with domestic violence convictions, including
even misdemeanors, from owning guns. This law had serious potential implications for police officers and military personnel for whom carrying a gun is part of
the job.
Did the Brady Act prevent crime by keeping guns out of the wrong hands?
Under the law, 2.2 percent of all gun purchase applicants were rejected, representing a total of 66,000 would-be gun buyers in 2001, and a total of 1.6 million
purchases between 1999 and 2009. More than half (56 percent) were rejected
because of a felony conviction, and another 14.7 percent were rejected because
of a domestic violence record (10.9 percent involved a misdemeanor conviction,
and 3.8 percent involved a restraining order).37 Cook and Ludwig compared
violent crime trends in the thirty-two states that had to change their laws
to comply with the Brady Act (making them the “treatment” group because
something changed) with those in the eighteen states unaffected by the law
(the “control” group because nothing changed). They found no significant
differences in crime trends between the two groups of states.38
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
265
The major weakness with regulating gun dealers as a way of keeping guns
out of the hands of the wrong people is the black market including both legal
private gun transactions and illegal gun sales or thefts. Illegal sales of guns, of
course, affect all current or proposed gun policies. Mark H. Moore estimated
several years ago that between 500,000 and 750,000 gun transactions take
place between private individuals every year.39 Most of these do not involve
active or potential criminals. They are sales or gifts between friends, family
members, gun collectors, and hunters. But a certain number do involve illegal
sales among active criminals. A 2004 survey of state prison inmates asked
where they obtained their firearm. The largest source, accounting for 40 percent of the total, involved illegal means, including theft, from someone off the
street, or a fence. Another 37.4 percent got their firearm though a family
member or friend. Only 7.3 percent bought it from a retail gun dealer. And
finally, less than 1 percent obtained it at a gun show.40
The Brady Law also stumbles over some serious problems with official
criminal history data. Offenders whose records do not show up in the files will
not be rejected. Some other people are incorrectly listed as having a criminal
record (through mistaken identity, data that were entered inaccurately, mistakes
that were not expunged, and so forth). There is also the problem of the “straw
purchaser,” a person who can legally purchase a firearm and resell it someone
who is ineligible to buy one. In one Pennsylvania case, for example, one straw
purchaser bought twenty-six guns in nine months, reselling them for money and
drugs. He bought fifteen of those guns at one store. This highlights a related
problem: some gun dealers are known to be “easy,” not carefully checking on
whether purchasers are eligible.41
THE PROBLEM OF GUNS AND THE MENTALLY ILL After the
2012 Sandy Hook School shooting there were loud calls for more effective
laws to keep guns out of the hands of people with mental health problems.
Lanza, the perpetrator in that case, clearly had some serious mental health issues.
The idea makes a lot of sense; we do not want guns in the hands of people who
are likely to have a mental health episode and begin killing people. In practice,
however, the idea runs head long into several serious problems.
Federal law prohibits the sale of any firearm or ammunition to any person
who “has been adjudicated as a metal defective or has been committed to any
mental institution.” The problem, however, is that only a small number of people are ever formally adjudicated or committed to an institution. In fact, there
are millions of people in the United States with mental health issues. The 2006
National Survey of Drug Use and Health (the latest available) estimated that 30.4
million people eighteen and older had experienced at least one Major Depressive
Episode (MDE) in the past year, representing 13.9 percent of all adults. Another
3.2 million juveniles between ages twelve and seventeen, representing 12.8 percent
of that population, experienced an MDE. The combined total is almost 35 million
people. And remember, these involve self-reported major depressive episodes,
which presumably excludes people who are temporarily depressed over a
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
266
CHAPTER
10
routine life incident, such as a relationship break-up, school problems, or job
problems.42
How do we begin to prevent gun violence among these 35 million people? It
is obvious that the vast majority do not resort to criminal gun violence. Remember, one survey estimated only three mass shooting incidents in 2011 and seven in
2012. This brings us up against an even more complex aspect of the old prediction
problem. How would be identify those who are depressed or having other mental
health issues and who are likely to turn to a gun? What criteria would we use?
Some would argue that medical professionals should make those diagnoses and
report people they treat who they think likely to commit a violent act, with or
without a gun. Such a requirement, however, might only deter many people
with genuine mental health problems from seeking professional help. And do we
really want a national data file on people who are severely depressed? Who would
have access to such a file? How would it be used?
There are already serious gaps in the data currently reported to the National
Instant Background Check System (NICS) regarding mental health issues. It has
been estimated that the NICS lists only 20 percent of the people who have in
fact been involuntarily committed to a hospital for mental health problems, or
402,000 people out of an estimated 2.7 million. Additionally, in this report eighteen states had not reported any mental health data at all to the NCIS. The most
glaring and tragic example of this failure is the case of Cho Seung-Hui, the
Virginia Tech University student who in 2007 shot and killed thirty-two
students and faculty on campus (before killing himself). A Virginia court had
declared him a danger to himself, making him ineligible to own a gun, but the
state did not forward his name to the NCIS.43
The Gun Show Exception: A Loophole?
In the debates over gun violence following the Sandy Hook Elementary School
shooting, there was much discussion over closing the gun show “loophole.”
Thirty-two states do not require background checks at gun shows, and only
nine states require them for all gun show purchases. Where there is no requirement, sellers can sell a gun, and as many guns as they want, to people who are
barred from buying the same gun from a licensed dealer. In fact, however, the
loophole is not as great as many people believe. Most sellers at gun shows are
licensed dealers, with an FFL, and are required to comply with all federal and
state laws, including the background checks. Additionally, one estimate is that
gun shows account for 4 to 9 percent of all gun sales. And the 2004 survey
of state prison inmates found that less than 1 percent reported obtaining their
firearm at a gun show. In short, gun show sales do not represent a significant
“loophole” in gun sale regulations.44
State-by-State Variations in Laws and Enforcement
The U.S. federal system with fifty states and a federal government, creates a
number of problems for the effective enforcement of gun regulation laws.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
267
Although the Washington, DC, ban on guns was still in effect, supporters noted
that DC was surrounded by states with weak gun laws, which made it easy to
import guns from them into DC. The result, they complained, undermined the
impact of the city’s attempt to keep guns out of Washington, DC.
Weak gun laws in many states affect efforts to keep guns out of the wrong
hands. A report by the group Mayors Against Illegal Guns used BATF trace data
to identify the origin of guns seized in crimes. It found that just ten states
accounted for half (49 percent) of guns that had crossed state lines before being
recovered in a crime. These ten states “exported” guns at rate seven times higher
than the ten states with the lowest export rates.45
The study then correlated the “export” of guns that with strong and
weak state gun laws. “Strong” state gun laws were defined in terms of several
specific laws restricting or regulating gun sales. Nine states have state criminal
penalties (that parallel federal law) for “straw” purchases (buying a gun for
someone who is ineligible). Twenty-three states have criminal penalties for
providing false information on a gun purchase application. Twenty-five states
have criminal penalties for gun dealers who fail to conduct background
checks. Sixteen states require background checks at gun shows. Twentythree states have laws allowing state inspection of gun dealers that supplement
federal inspection. The study found that states with weak gun laws consistently had gun “export” rates that were higher than the national average.
States with penalties for straw purchases, for example, exported guns at a
rate of 9.5 guns per 100,000 population, compared with 15.6 per 100,000
for states without such laws. States that require background checks at gun
shows had an export rate of 7.5 per 100,000, compared with 19.8 per
100,000 for states that do not require gun show background checks.46 In
short, stricter state gun laws have significantly reduced the interstate travel
of guns that are eventually recovered in crimes.
Summary on Regulating the Sale of Firearms
Despite their many limitations, regulations designed to deny ownership to certain
categories of “bad” people undoubtedly succeed to a certain extent. Many of the
people who fail the background check probably stop at that point. But others
who are determined to get a gun continue their quest. With an estimated 114
million handguns in existence, there is an active, thriving black market in guns,
and criminals themselves say that they have or would have no trouble quickly
obtaining a weapon. The greatest problem is that people with criminal records,
who know they will fail the background check, go directly to the black
market.47
25
PROPOSITION
Laws that seek to keep guns out of the hands of criminals and the mentally
ill have at best some limited effect but are easily evaded by the black market
in guns.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
268
CHAPTER
10
KEEPING GUNS AWAY FROM SPECIAL LOCATIONS:
AIRPORTS AND SCHOOLS
A special part of the gun violence problem involves keeping guns away from
particularly sensitive locations, such as airports and schools. Airports are particularly important because of the danger of plane hijacking. Keeping guns out of
schools, of course, is intended to ensure a safe environment for children.
Airports
A federal law prohibits the carrying of a weapon onto an airplane, and all
passengers are electronically screened at the gate. The electronic screening at
airports makes enforcement fairly effective. In 2012, the Transportation Security
Administration (TSA) seized 1,527 firearms at airports. This was almost twice the
number (833) seized in 2008, but only a small fraction of the millions of prohibited items seized. Some people, it seems, just do not get it regarding airport security regulations. On Thanksgiving weekend in 2002, for example, despite all the
publicity about the new post-September 11 security procedures, airport
personnel seized 15,982 pocket knives, ninety-eight box cutters, six guns, and
a brick.48
Many of the people detained in these seizures apparently forgot that they
had a gun with them. This testifies to the prevalence of guns in U.S. society,
the casualness with which people carry them around, and the limited deterrent
effect of a well-known law. Nonetheless, the law has been effective in curbing
airplane hijacking. The number of hijackings decreased from forty in 1969 to
only one attempted hijacking each in both 1990 and 1991, and none in either
of the next two years. The September 11 terrorist hijackings, of course, did not
involve guns, but there was a failure to detect the box cutters used by the
terrorists.49
Schools
Guns in schools are another special case. Because of a series of sensational
crimes, notably the 2012 Sandy Hook Elementary School massacre in Connecticut, there has been great national concern about guns and violence in public
schools. Several strategies have been adopted to keep guns out of schools. The
1994 Gun-Free Schools Act requires schools receiving federal education funds
to have a policy mandating the expulsion of students who bring firearms to
school. Some schools have instituted metal detectors similar to those used at
airports.
The evidence, however, indicates that mass shootings in schools are another
example of the celebrated case phenomenon we discussed in Chapter 2. In fact,
schools are fairly safe and have been getting safer in recent years. There was an
average of thirty or more shooting incidents in the 1990s, but in academic year
2009–2010 there were only seventeen, (which was the same as for the previous
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
269
year). School homicides, moreover represented only 1.1 percent of all homicides
of kids between the ages of five and eighteen. Finally, the decline is school
homicides parallels a general decline in school crime.50 In short, although school
safety is always a matter of concern, the data clearly indicate that gun-related
homicides are not a great problem and that schools are actually getting safer.
There are two explanations for the decline in gun incidents in schools. One
is the Great American Crime Drop across society. The other is the development
of a range of new school security measures. Between 1999 and 2006 the
percentage of schools with one or more selected security measures more than
doubled, from 19 to 43 percent. The five most widely used measures are
controlled access to schools during school hours (in place in 85 percent of all
schools), controlled access to the entire school grounds (41 percent), required
IDs for all faculty and staff (48 percent), security cameras (43 percent), and
random dog sniffs to detect drugs (23 percent).51 The lesson seems to be that a
range of reasonable and well-designed measures can make a significant difference
in school safety. This parallels the lesson we discussed on traffic fatalities in
Chapter 6. The fatality rate has gone down steadily since the 1920s not because
of a single “get tough” measure, but because of a variety of changes, all of which
make incremental contributions to the overall effect.
MORE GUNS? LESS CRIME?
Gun rights advocates argue that there would be less crime if more people carried
guns on a routine basis. The assumption is that they would be able to scare off
potential robbers, rapists, or burglars and even shoot to kill them if necessary.
Some argue that more guns at mass shooting incidents would at least reduce
the number of people who are killed in such incidents.
There is some dispute over how frequently crime victims or people who
believe they are threatened use a gun to protect themselves. Bureau of Justice
Statistics estimates that between 1987 and 1992, 62,200 victims of violent
crime annually used guns to defend themselves. This represents 1 percent of
violent crimes during that period. Gary Kleck, however, estimated that handguns
are used 2.1 million times a year for self-protection. Gun rights advocates
have widely circulated this estimate, but other scholars have questioned the
methodology that produced it.52
The National Crime Victimization Survey (NCVS) found that slightly less than
1 percent of crime victims threatened the offender with a firearm.53 Also using the
NCVS data, from 1979 to 1985, Gary Kleck and Miriam DeLone found that
robbery victims used a gun to resist the offender in 1.2 percent of all robberies
(including both completed and attempted robberies). Few of these incidents involved
a shootout between victim and offender. They concluded that when victims did use
guns, they were frequently successful in preventing a completed robbery.54
About forty states have adopted “shall issue” laws, which require officials to
issue permits to citizens who meet certain eligibility criteria allowing them to
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
270
CHAPTER
10
carry concealed handguns. These laws have replaced discretionary “may issue”
laws, which give officials broad authority to deny permits.55
In a highly controversial study, John R. Lott, Jr., and David B. Mustard
estimated that if states without shall issue laws adopted them, it would prevent
about 1,570 murders, 4,177 rapes, and more than 60,000 aggravated assaults
every year. Lott followed up with a book, More Guns, Less Crime, elaborating
his argument that allowing people to carry concealed weapons would deter violent crime.56
Because of its direct implications for public policy, and the deep divide in
public opinion over guns in U.S. society, Lott’s work spurred further research.
By 2005 there were an estimated fifteen studies reanalyzing the original Lott and
Mustard data. In addition, there have been studies using different data sets and
methodologies. The result of this intensive research effort is inconclusive. About
half (eight) of the reanalyses of Lott and Mustard generally confirmed their
findings, whereas five found no effect on violent crime rates, and three found
increases in violent crime. Other studies have also found conflicting results. The
National Academy of Sciences undertook its own study and devoted an entire
chapter of its report on guns to the right-to-carry issue. It concluded that studies
are highly sensitive to both the model employed and to the control variables that
are employed. This is an inherent problem in all longitudinal studies that use
many variables from different jurisdictions. Several studies have found that, for
some unknown reason, Florida has a powerful effect on studies that compare it
with other states. In some instances, including or excluding Florida reverses the
findings. In the end, the National Academy concluded that it was not possible to
determine a causal link between right-to-carry laws and the crime rate.57
With respect to the more guns/less crime argument and mass shooting incidents, there are no scientific studies, for the obvious reasons. They are extremely
rare events and it would be difficult to identify retrospectively all the variables in
each incident. Common sense, however, suggests that the availability of more
guns at a mass shooting incident in a public area (say, a shopping mall or theater)
would likely result in more deaths. Think about the shooting of Congresswoman
Gabby Giffords at a shopping mall in Tucson, Arizona, in 2011 where six people
died and thirteen were wounded. As soon as one or more other people fired a
weapon to stop the original assailant, the others with guns would not know who
was the original perpetrator. People in this second group would inevitably think
members of the first group of responders were the perpetrators and begin shooting at them. The resulting escalation would be utter chaos, with far more people
shot and killed or wounded.
Another compelling perspective on whether more guns reduces crime, as
right-to-carry advocates argue, comes from our highest crime, highest gun violence neighborhoods. It is clear that much of the gun violence in these areas is
the result of the prevalence of guns. These weapons only encourage others to
carry guns. The result is a self-perpetuating gun culture. People carry guns to
protect themselves and others feel compelled to do the same. As James D.
Wright explains, these individuals “live in a very hostile and violent environment, and many of them have come to believe, no doubt correctly, that their
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
271
ability to survive in that environment depends critically on being adequately
armed.” They are “highly motivated gun owners who are not easily persuaded
that they should not have one.”58 Unfortunately, many guns carried for selfdefense are eventually used as offensive weapons, in response to real or imagined
slights or other situations that are not life-threatening.
The “Stand-Your-Ground” Law Controversy
On the night of February 26, 2012, George Zimmerman, a neighborhood watch
volunteer, confronted Trayvon Martin, a young African American whom he
suspected of criminal activity. In the ensuing struggle Zimmerman shot and
killed Martin. The case received enormous national publicity, with allegations
of racial profiling by Zimmerman. On July 13, 2013, a jury acquitted Zimmerman of second degree murder charges.
One aspect of the case was Zimmerman’s claim that his actions were justified
in part by the Florida stand-your-ground law. Because there is much misunderstanding about stand your ground laws, we present the full text of the Florida
law in Box 10.1.
As with other hotly contested issues, the stand-your-ground laws have
prompted research. A 2012 study of the impact of stand-your-ground laws on
homicides and firearm injuries found that they are associated with increases in
homicides among white males and also hospital emergency department visits for
firearm-related injuries. The authors estimated that there are between twentyeight and thirty-three additional white males killed each month as a result of
stand-your-ground laws. Interestingly, there was no increase in homicides
among African Americans. Additionally, based on the FBI’s Supplemental
Homicide Reports, the increase in the killing of white males was not associated
with the shooting of assailants, suggesting that the incidents were not selfdefense situations in the face of serious threats to life.59
It is not hard to imagine the dynamics that lead to more homicides as a
result of stand-your-ground laws. No one seriously disputes the basic right of
self-defense. If you are attacked, you have the right to defend yourself. The
problem with stand-your-ground laws is that people will misinterpret them in
© 2015 Cengage Learning
BOX
10.1
THE FLORIDA STAND-YOUR-GROUND LAW
776.012 Use of force in defense of person.—A person is justified in using force, except deadly
force, against another when and to the extent that the person reasonably believes that such conduct is
necessary to defend himself or herself or another against the other’s imminent use of unlawful force.
However, a person is justified in the use of deadly force and does not have a duty to retreat if:
1.
2.
He or she reasonably believes that such force is necessary to prevent imminent death or
great bodily harm to himself or herself or another or to prevent the imminent commission
of a forcible felony; or
Under those circumstances permitted pursuant to s. 776.013.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
272
CHAPTER
10
a far more permissive way and shoot where the law does not actually permit it.
Read the Florida law carefully. It permits the use of deadly force only where
there is a threat of “imminent death or great bodily harm.” This does not justify shooting in response to just any belligerent challenge or abusive words
from someone. Standard police department policies across the country, for
example, limit the use of deadly force to “defense-of-life” situations. Police
officers, moreover, receive extensive training, including regular in-service
training over their deadly force policies.60 Recruitment policies screen out candidates who have self-control problems or evident mental health issues. Many
ordinary people, carrying a gun under the law, and who have self-control issues
and do not fully understand the law, are likely to shoot in instances not justified by the law.
26
PROPOSITION
Laws designed to allow more people to carry guns and laws that allow them
to use their guns in a greater range of circumstances are more likely to
increase rather than reduce homicides.
GET TOUGH ON GUNS AND GUN-RELATED OFFENSES
The primary conservative policy on crime is to get tough on offenders, and
gun-related crime is no exception. This approach translates into mandatory
prison terms for people convicted of gun-related crimes and also longer prison
terms. Such laws are widespread. In 1994, forty-one states had mandatory
minimum sentencing laws for illegal weapons possession.61 Florida law
imposes a mandatory minimum sentence of twenty years in prison for use of
a weapon in the commission of violent or drug-related crimes and prohibits
the granting of certain types of good-time credit during the mandatory minimum period.
As we have already argued in previous chapters, the criminal justice system is
not soft on serious crimes, and gun-related crimes fall in that category. In 2009,
80 percent of all persons convicted of a weapons offense in large urban courts
were incarcerated, and two-thirds of those went to prison rather than jail—the
same figure as for robbery. For those sentenced to prison, the average sentence
was thirty-eight months (or just over three years). These data again confirm the
point we have emphasized throughout this book, that the criminal justice system
is fairly harsh on serious crimes.62
Tough Sentencing in Detroit: An Early Experiment
In 1977, Michigan passed a law mandating two years in prison for any gunrelated crime. The law precluded either probation or parole and was advertised
as “One with a gun gets you two.” At the same time, the Wayne County
(Detroit) prosecutor announced a new policy prohibiting plea bargaining of
gun charges under the new law.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
273
An evaluation by Colin Loftin and David McDowall focused on two questions: Did the law increase the certainty and severity of punishment? Did it lower
the crime rate? The key issue in regard to the severity of sentences concerned the
effective minimum prison terms; that is, how much time could a convicted
offender reasonably expect to serve before becoming eligible for release, when
reductions for both good time and parole were taken into account? They
found “no statistically significant change in the expected minimum sentence” for
gun-related murders and armed robberies, but a significant increase in the
expected minimum sentences for gun-related assaults.63
Two factors—the going rate and the trickle-up phenomenon—explain what
happened. The expected minimum sentences for murder and robbery did not
increase because the going rate for these crimes was already high. Armed robbers
in Detroit had been serving prison terms averaging six years before the new law,
and few convicted robbers ever got probation. The system was not soft on crime
beforehand, and the supposed get tough law did not change things.
Sentences for assaults increased because the going rate for those offenses had
been rather low. Probation and suspended sentences were common, and incarcerated offenders got an average of six months. Much of this seeming leniency
stemmed from the ambiguity of the crime of assault. The nature of the act is
often difficult to specify with precision; it may also be difficult to determine
who initiated the altercation. Moreover, as we argued in Chapters 2 and 3,
criminal justice officials routinely treat assaults between people who know each
other as essentially private disputes and frequently dismiss the charges or settle the
case with a plea to a lesser offense. The new law raised the severity of sentences
by eliminating this opportunity for mitigating punishment.
Loftin and McDowall also found that “the gun law did not significantly alter
the number or type of violent offenses committed in Detroit.” Murder, robbery,
and assault did decline, but the decrease in the rate had begun five months before
the law went into effect—long enough in advance to rule out the possibility of
the announcement effect that has appeared with other laws toughening criminal
penalties.64
PROMISING APPROACHES TO REDUCING GUN VIOLENCE
The good news is that there are some programs that have proven to be effective.
We have examined them already in previous chapters, but it is important to discuss them again because of their relevance to gun-related violence.
The Kansas City Gun Experiment
The Kansas City Gun Experiment (1992–1993) was an early effort that involved
intensive enforcement of existing laws on the illegal carrying of handguns.
Funded by the federal Weed and Seed program, it represented a combination
of two innovations in policing: problem-oriented policing, in which the police
focus on a specific problem, and hot spots, in which patrols focus on a particular
area (see our discussion in Chapter 5).65
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
274
CHAPTER
10
The experiment was conducted in a particularly high crime precinct in
Kansas City, Missouri, where the 1991 murder rate was 177 per 100,000, or
about twenty times higher than the national average at the time. Two two-officer
patrol cars, working overtime, patrolled for six hours every night, concentrating
exclusively on detecting and seizing illegally possessed guns. The officers would
stop cars on legitimate legal grounds (e.g., a traffic violation) but focus on weapons seizures. Almost half (45 percent) of all the guns eventually seized were
found through a search incident to arrest, another 21 percent were found in
plain view, and 34 percent were found in frisks as authorized by the Supreme
Court in Terry v. Ohio (1968).66
Over the course of twenty-nine weeks, the gun unit officers seized a total of
twenty-nine guns. Meanwhile, regular patrol officers in the target beat seized
another forty-seven guns, for a combined total of seventy-six. The number of
gun crimes in the target beat declined by 49 percent, but only by 4 percent in
a control beat. The experiment controlled for a possible displacement effect and
found that gun crimes went up in some of the neighboring beats and down in
others. The reduction in gun crimes could have occurred as a direct result of
removing guns from the area, through deterrence, or through the incapacitation
of potential offenders who were arrested and imprisoned.
The Kansas City Gun Experiment suggested that a clearly focused program
to remove guns from the streets can reduce gun-related crime. A number of
questions about the program remain, however. It was extremely expensive
when measured in terms of the cost per gun seized or crime prevented. (The
costs are almost entirely related to police officer salaries for the time involved in
the project.) It is not clear that a police department could afford to run such a
program as a part of normal operations. Nonetheless, the idea of a clearly focused
effort on gun violence inspired other more comprehensive approaches.
The Boston Gun Project: A National Model
The Boston Gun Project, which we have already discussed in Chapters 5 and 6,
is possibly the single-most celebrated and influential criminal justice project of
the last twenty years. It serves as a model of problem-oriented policing by focusing on a specific crime problem, making extensive use of partnerships, and
combining traditional enforcement efforts with innovative nontraditional methods. It involved academic experts in the project’s planning and development,
drew on the research literature about what works and what does not, used
sophisticated data analysis, and allowed itself to be evaluated by top criminologists. It is the model for the Lowell, Massachusetts, gun initiative and the
Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce Violence (CIRV), which we have previously
discussed.67
In response to an upsurge in gun violence in the late 1980s, a coalition of
community leaders, criminal justice officials, and academics developed Operation
Ceasefire. The program focused on particular gangs and their leaders who were
at the heart of the gun violence. The basic strategy involved what has become
known as “pulling levers”: factors that give law enforcement and correctional
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
275
officials leverage over people involved in gun violence. The levers included a
broad range of enforcement tactics focused on key individuals: arrests for outstanding warrants; seizing unregistered vehicles; vigorously enforcing probation
and parole conditions (e.g., prohibitions on using drugs and alcohol or possessing
guns). Operation Night Light involved evening visits to the residences of people
on probation or parole by teams of police and correctional officers to enforce
conditions of these individuals’ release (no weapons, no drugs or alcohol, compliance with curfews, etc.) Local, state, and federal officials also maintained a
coordinated effort to track illegal guns and prosecute traffickers on federal
charges. Finally, call-in meetings were held with identified gang members to
send a clear message of tough enforcement: if there were gun violence in
their neighborhoods, authorities would pull every available “lever” until it
ceased. There would be no “deal”; gang members would not get any favor
for refraining from violence; they would be expected to be law abiding. In
short, the effort was carefully planned, multiphased, coordinated, and focused
on key suspects.68
An evaluation found a 63 percent reduction in monthly youth homicides
and smaller reductions in youth gun assaults and calls to the police regarding
gunshots. You might properly question these findings on the grounds that the
entire country was experiencing a great reduction in violent crime during those
years. The evaluation, however, found a greater reduction in Boston than across
the country and in other New England cities.
Variations of the Boston Gun Project have been implemented in several
other cities, and they are now referred to as a focused deterrence approach to
gang and gun violence problems. A particularly successful program was the
CIRV, which we have discussed in Chapter 5. The results in Cincinnati were
impressive. After forty-two months there was a 41.1 percent reduction in homicide involving gang members. The fact that the reduction among the targeted
groups continued after forty-two months makes the findings especially
persuasive.69
The most important point in terms of the discussion in this chapter is how
the Boston Gun Project and similar programs differ from the other policies we
have discussed. Attempting to ban guns or restricting the purchase of guns by
people with criminal records ignores the plain fact that guns are readily available
on the black market. Tough prosecution and sentencing has been U.S. crime
policy for forty years, and there is no reason to believe that getting tougher
will reduce gun violence any further. The virtues of the Boston Gun Project
are that it is narrowly focused, with a specific target audience, and that it is
proactive, operating before further gun violence occurs.
Focused deterrence programs are the only gun-related policies that have
solid research evidence supporting their effectiveness, and it addresses the heart
of the gun violence problem by focusing on low-income, high-crime, and high
gun violence neighborhoods.70 It is effective primarily because it focuses on
known gun offenders, the people who actually use guns (primarily handguns)
for criminal purposes. It is useful in this regard to review quickly the limits of
the other gun policies we have covered.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
276
CHAPTER
10
Making focused deterrence and other closely related programs work is
not easy, however. The programs that have been found to be effective are
extremely complex, require careful planning, and implementation, particularly with regard to identifying the known gun offenders, collaboration
among many different agencies, and close administration to make sure that
all the different parts work and work together. The danger is that already
some people have become overenthusiastic and are recommending a hasty
expansion.71
27
PROPOSITION
Carefully designed and focused programs directed toward a small group
of known offenders have been found to be effective in reducing gun
violence.
CONCLUSION
Gun-related violence is a serious problem in U.S. society. Many different
solutions have been proposed. Most have been found to be ineffective.
Banning guns is an empty gesture (and now unconstitutional), given the
number of handguns already in circulation. Trying to keep guns out of the
hands of bad people also appears to be futile. Nor does it appear that threats
of severe punishment will deter or incapacitate offenders in a way that will
significantly reduce crime. There is persuasive evidence, however, from
Boston, Cincinnati, Project Safe Neighborhoods, and other examples, that
carefully designed, research-based, coordinated problem-oriented approaches
can help reduce gun violence.
NOTES
1 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Firearm Violence, 1993–2011 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2013), p. 5, Figures 5 and 6; Appendix, 21, Table 8.
2 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Firearm Violence, 1993–2011, 3, Table 3.
3 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Intimate Partner Violence, 1993–2010 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2012).
4 Aviva Shen, “A Timeline of Mass Shootings in the US Since Colubine,”
Thinkprogress, December 14, 2012. Available at: http://thinkprogress.org/justice/
2012/12/14/1337221/a-timeline-of-mass-shootings-in-the-us-since-columbine/
5 Emily Badger, “6 Timelines That Explain America’s Persistent Gun Culture,” The
Atlantic Cities, December 17, 2012. Available at: http://www.theatlanticcities.com/
politics/2012/12/6-timelines-explain-americas-persistent-gun-culture/4181/.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
277
6 Chicago Police Department, Compstat, Week 40. Available at https://portal
.chicagopolice.org/portal/page/portal/ClearPath/News/Crime%20Statistics
Accessed February 16, 2004.
7 Chicago Police Department, 2011 Murder Analysis (Chicago: Chicago Police
Department), 37–39.
8 New York City, crime data 2000–2012, available at the New York City Police
Department website: http://www.nyc.gov/html/nypd/html/home/home.shtml,
accessed February 16, 2004. San Diego crime data, 1950–2012. Accessed January 14,
2014, at http://www.sandiego.gov/police/pdf/2013/UCRActuals1950to2012.pdf.
9 Mark H. Moore, “Controlling Criminogenic Commodities: Drugs, Guns, and
Alcohol,” in James Q. Wilson, ed., Crime and Public Policy (San Francisco: ICS Press,
1983), 125–144.
10 Federal Bureau of Investigation, Crime in the United States 2012 (Washington, DC:
Department of Justice, 2013), Expanded Homicide Data, Table 8.
11 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table 2.0018.2013.
http://www.albany.edu/sourcebook/. Accessed February 16, 2004.
12 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table 2.0004.2012.
http://www.albany.edu/sourcebook/. Accessed February 16, 2004.
13 Small Arms Survey, Estimating Civilian Owned Firearms (Geneva, Switzerland: Small
Arms Survey, 2011). Also see, www.smallarmssurvey.org. Accessed February 16,
2004.
14 National Academy of Sciences, Firearms and Violence: A Critical Review
(Washington, DC: National Academies Press, 2005), “Defensive Gun Use,”
103–108.
15 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table 2.59.2012.
http://www.albany.edu/sourcebook/. Accessed February 16, 2004.
16 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, Table 2.60.2011.
http://www.albany.edu/sourcebook/. Accessed February 16, 2004.
17 Edward L. Glaeser and Spencer Glendon, “Who Owns Guns? Criminals, Victims,
and the Culture of Violence,” American Economic Review 88 (May 1998): 458–462.
Gary Kleck, “Crime, Culture Conflict and the Sources of Support for Gun Control,
American Behavioral Scientist 39 (February 1996): 387–404.
18 District of Columbia v. Heller, 554 U.S. 570 (2008).
19 McDonald v. Chicago, 561 U. S. 3025 (2010).
20 Bureau of Alcohol, Firearms and Tobacco, State Laws and Published Ordinances
(annual), www.atf.gov/. Accessed January 14, 2014.
21 Edward D. Jones, “The District of Columbia’s ‘Firearms Control Regulations Act of
1975’: The Toughest Handgun Control Law in the United States—Or Is It?” The
Annals 455 (May 1981): 138–149.
22 Washington, DC, Metropolitan Police Department, Annual Report 2012
(Washington, DC: Metropolitan Police Department, 2013). National Academy of
Sciences, Firearms and Violence: A Critical Review, 97–98.
23 John Kaplan, “The Wisdom of Gun Prohibition,” The Annals 455 (May 1981):
11–23.
24 Scott H. Decker, Susan Pennell, and Ami Caldwell, Illegal Firearms: Access and Use by
Arrestees (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1997).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
278
CHAPTER
10
25 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Firearm Violence, 1993–2011, 13, Table 14.
26 James D. Wright, Peter H. Rossi, and Kathleen Daly, Under the Gun: “Weapons,
Crime, and Violence in America” (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1983), 320.
27 The St. Louis and Seattle evaluations, along with other articles, are in Martha
Plotkin, ed., Under Fire Gun Buy-Backs, Exchanges, and Amnesty Programs
(Washington, DC: Police Executive Research Forum, 1996).
28 Robert Sherrill, The Saturday Night Special (New York: Charterhouse, 1973).
29 “Los Angeles Bans the Sale of Inexpensive, Small Guns,” New York Times, 8
September 1996.
30 Gary Kleck, Point Blank: Guns and Violence in America, (New York: Aldine de
Gruyter, 1991), 85–86.
31 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Guns Used in Crime (Washington, DC: Department of
Justice, 2000) 6.
32 Gallup Poll data cited in Bureau of Justice Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice
Statistics, Table 20004.2012.
33 Jeffrey A. Roth and Christopher S. Koper, Impacts of the 1994 Assault Weapons Ban:
1994–96 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1999). Christopher S. Koper,
An Updated Assessment of the Federal Assault Weapons Ban Impacts on Gun Markets and
Gun Violence, 1994–2003. Research Report to the National Institute of Justice
(Philadelphia: Jerry Lee Center of Criminology, University of Pennsylvania, 2004).
34 U.S. Department of Justice, Office of the Inspector General, Review of ATF’s Federal
Firearms Licensee Inspection Program (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, April 2013).
35 Data cited in National Academy of Sciences, Firearms and Violence: “A Critical
Review”, “Regulating Gun Dealers,” 89–90.
36 Christopher Koper, “Federal Legislation and Gun Markets: How Much Have
Recent Reforms of the Federal Firearms Licensing System Reduced Criminal Gun
Suppliers?” Criminology and Public Policy 1 (2002): 151–178. And see also the
comments by Deborah S. Azrael and James B. Jacobs.
37 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Background Checks for Firearms Transfers, 2009—Statistical
Tables (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2010).
38 Philip J. Cook and Jens Ludwig, Gun Violence: The Real Costs (New York: Oxford
University Press, 2000).
39 Mark H. Moore, “Keeping Handguns from Criminal Offenders,” Annals 455 (May
1981): 92–109.
40 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Firearm Violence, 1993–2011, 13, Table 14.
41 Mayors Against Illegal Guns, Inside Straw Purchasing How Criminals Get Guns Illegally
(Washington, DC: Mayors Against Illegal Guns, 2008), 7.
42 Department of Health and Human Services, Substance Abuse and Mental Health
Services Administration, Results from the 2011 National Survey on Drug Use and Health:
National Findings (Washington, DC: Department of Health and Human Services,
2012).
43 Mayors Against Illegal Guns, Fatal Gaps: How Missing Records in the Federal
Background Check System Put Guns in the Hands of Killers (Washington, DC: Mayors
Against Illegal Guns, 2011).
44 Garen Wintemute, Inside Gun Shows: What Goes on When Everybody Thinks Nobody’s
Watching (Sacramento, CA: Violence Prevention Research Program, UC Davis
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CONTROL GUN CRIMES
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
279
School of Medicine, 2009). Bureau of Justice Statistics, Firearm Violence, 1993–2011,
13, Table 14.
The ten states are Mississippi, West Virginia, Kentucky, Alaska, Alabama, South
Carolina, Virginia, Indiana, Nevada, and Georgia. Mayors Against Illegal Guns, Trace
the Guns: The Link Between Gun Laws and Interstate Gun Trafficking (Washington, DC:
Mayors Against Illegal Guns, 2010).
Mayors Against Illegal Guns, Trace the Guns. See the previous report, Mayors Against
Illegal Guns, The Movement of Illegal Guns in America the Link Between Gun Laws and
Interstate Gun Trafficking (Washington, DC: Mayors Against Illegal Guns, 2008). See
also, www.mayorsagainstillegalguns.org. Accessed February 16, 2004.
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Guns Used in Crime.
“More Than 800 Guns Seized at U.S. Airport Checkpoints Last Year,” February 24,
2009. http://www.ticklethewire.com/2009/02/24/more-than-800-guns-seized-atus-airport-checkpoints-last-year/. The Transportation Security Administration posts
incomplete data on its website, www.tsa.gov/. Accessed February 16, 2004.
“Airports’ Thanksgiving Seizures: 15,982 Knives and a Brick,” USA Today, 3
December 2002.
Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States,1995. Available at: http://
www.census.gov/compendia/statab/. Accessed February 16, 2004.
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Firearm Violence, 1993–2011, 9, Table 8. National Center
for Education Statistics and Bureau of Justice Statistics, Indicators of School Crime and
Safety 2012 (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2013).
National Center for Education Statistics and Bureau of Justice Statistics, Indicators of
School Crime and Safety, 2012, Indicator 20, Figure 20.1.
See the discussion in National Academy of Science, Firearms and Violence. Gary
Kleck and Miriam A. DeLone, “Victim Resistance and Offender Weapon Effects in
Robbery,” Journal of Quantitative Criminology 9 (1993): 55–81.
Bureau of Justice Statistics, Firearm Violence, 1993–2011, 12, Table 11.
Gary Kleck and Miriam A. DeLone, “Victim Resistance and Offender Weapon
Effects in Robbery,” Journal of Quantitative Criminology 9 (1993): 55–81.
Pro-right-to-carry information is available from the National Rifle Association.
www.nra.org. Accessed February 16, 2004. Opposition maternal is available from
the Brady Campaign, www.bradycampaign.org. Accessed February 16, 2004.
John R. Lott, More Guns, Less Crime: Understanding Crime and Gun-Control Laws
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998).
Tomislav V. Kovandzic, Thomas B. Marvell, and Lynn M. Vieratitis, “The Impact
of ‘Shall-Issue’ Concealed Handgun Laws on Violence Crime Rates,” Homicide
Studies 9 (November 2005): 292–323. National Academy of Sciences, Firearms and
Violence.
James D. Wright, “Ten Essential Observations on Guns in America,” Society 32
(March/April 1995): 66.
Chandler B. McClellan and Erdal Tekin, Stand Your Ground Laws, Homicides, and
Injuries, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 18187
(Revised, October 2012). Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w18187.
Accessed February 16, 2004.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
280
CHAPTER
10
60 Samuel Walker and Charles M. Katz, The Police in America: An Introduction, 8th ed.
(New York: McGraw-Hill, 2013).
61 Bureau of Justice Statistics, National Assessment of Structured Sentencing (Washington,
DC: Department of Justice, 1996), 24–25.
62 Bureau of Justice Statistics, Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2009—
Statistical Table (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 2008), Talbes 24, 25. ]
63 Colin Loftin and David McDowall, “‘ One with a Gun Gets You Two’: Mandatory
Sentencing and Firearms Violence in Detroit,” The Annals 455 (May 1981):
150–167.
64 Ibid.
65 Lawrence W. Sherman, James W. Shaw, and Dennis P. Rogan, The Kansas City
Gun Experiment (Washington, DC: Department of Justice, 1995).
66 Terry v. Ohio, 392 U.S. 1 (1968).
67 For a good overview of developments in this area, see David M. Kennedy, Don’t
Shoot: One Man, a Street Fellowship, and the End of Violence in Inner-City America (New
York: Bloomsbury, 2011).
68 David M. Kennedy, Anthony A. Braga, and Anne M Piehl, Reducing Gun Violence
The Boston Gun Project’s Operation Ceasefire (Washington, DC: Department of Justice,
2001). Kennedy, Don’t Shoot.
69 Robin S. Engel, Marie Skubak Tillyer, and Nicholas Corsaro, “Reducing Gang
Violence Using Focused Deterrence: Evaluating the Cincinnati Initiative to Reduce
Violence (CIRV),” Justice Quarterly 30 (No. 3, 2013): 403–439.
70 Anthony A. Braga and David L. Weisburd, “The Effects of Focused Deterrence
Strategies on Crime: A Systematic Review and Meta-Analysis of the Empirical
Evidence,” Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 49 (August 2012): 323–358.
71 Steven N. Durlauf and Daniel S. Nagin, “Imprisonment and crime: Can both be
reduced?” Criminology and Public Policy 10 (February 2011):13–54.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
PART
IV
Reform: The Liberal
Prescription
L
iberals traditionally took a different approach to crime policy than did
conservatives. As we indicated in Chapter 1, liberals are much more optimistic
about our capacity to reduce crime by changing either people or society. In the
two chapters that follow, we will take a close look at the two most important
components of liberal crime policy. Chapter 11 examines both the concept of
rehabilitation and specific programs designed to change criminal offenders into
law-abiding citizens. Chapter 12 looks at potential reforms by increasing public
confidence in the criminal justice system, and as a consequence, increasing
commitment to lawful behavior.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
11
Treat ’Em!
REHABILITATION OR CORRECTING CRIMINALS
The concept of rehabilitation, or correcting criminal offenders, is the cornerstone of traditional liberal crime control policy. Although the rhetoric has
changed over the years, the basic idea remains the same: reduce crime by
rehabilitating, correcting, or treating criminals to help them reestablish lives
and be reintegrated into their communities as law-abiding citizens. The
terminology used by state agencies reflects the continued commitment to
this approach. We have departments of corrections rather than departments of
punishment. Why do we use this terminology? The terms corrections and
rehabilitation carry the aura of healing and helping people and in that regard
represent an inspiring ideal. That idea, moreover, places corrections officials
on the same professional status as medical doctors and social workers, with a
capacity to diagnose and treat.1
The Philosophy of Rehabilitation
What exactly is rehabilitation? The National Academy of Sciences defines it
as “any planned intervention that reduces an offender’s further criminal
activity.”2 The key words here are planned and intervention. As Wolfgang’s
career criminal research suggests (see our discussion in Chapter 4), most
lawbreakers stop sooner or later. It is well established that criminal activity
is highest between the ages of fourteen and twenty-four, peaks in the late
teens for both burglary and robbery, and then declines sharply. The truth
is, aging is the best crime reduction policy we know about.3 The goal of
rehabilitation is to make offenders stop sooner rather than later. Planned
interventions include education, job training, counseling, substance abuse
treatment, and other programs. As we explained in Chapter 1, rehabilitation
is a crime prevention strategy; it simply takes a different approach than
punishment-oriented strategies.
282
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
283
“Unfortunately, corrections is a field in which quackery is pervasive.”
What Criminologist F rancis T. Cullen and his colleagues call quackery, we call nonsense.
What they say about corrections is also true of almost every aspect of the criminal justice
system.
F I G U R E 11.1 Faith, Fads, and Quackery.
SOURCE: Francis T. Cullen, Kristie R. Blevins, Jennifer S. Trager, and Paul Gendreau, “The Rise and Fall of Boot Camps: A
Case Study in Common Sense Corrections,” Journal of Offender Rehabilitation 40 (NJos. 3–4, 2005): 55.
Old and New Programs
A variety of different programs have existed to rehabilitate offenders and reintegrate them into the community. Probation and parole have been the most
important programs for more than one hundred years. During this time, a variety
of different approaches have been attempted to enhance their effectiveness,
including intensive supervision, boot camps, curfews, mandatory drug testing,
and other restrictions. As we will see, the entire subject of rehabilitation has
been afflicted with fads—new ideas that generate a lot of excitement and new
programs, only to fade away when the evidence begins coming in that they do
not really work or make much difference. Criminologist Francis Cullen and his
colleagues put it bluntly (Figure 11.1): “Unfortunately, corrections is a field in
which quackery is pervasive.”4 They call it quackery, we call it nonsense, but it
is the same thing: ideas based on faith rather than facts.
New Developments in the Field
A number of important new developments have overtaken the field of corrections
in recent years. As part of the larger movement toward evidence-based policy
making, which we discussed in Chapter 1, there are now a set of evidence-based
best practices for probation and parole. A second development involves community reinvestment. This involves laws and policies that reduce a state’s prison
population and the reinvestment of part of the money saved in community
programs and services designed to treat offenders and hopefully reduce crime.
Finally, drug courts have established themselves as an effective way to both
sentence and treat persons charged with drug-related offenses.
We will examine all of these developments, but first we will describe and
discuss traditional approaches to correctional treatment, to understand their
purpose, practices, and limitations. This will serve to put the new developments
in their proper context.
THE “NOTHING WORKS” CONTROVERSY
About forty years ago, criminologist Robert Martinson threw down the gauntlet
over rehabilitation, framing the terms of a debate that continues today. In a 1974
article (and later a book), he concluded that “with few and isolated exceptions,
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
284
CHAPTER
11
the rehabilitative efforts that have been reported so far have had no appreciable
effect on rehabilitation.”5
The Martinson report is several decades old, but the debate continues to
rage: Do rehabilitation programs work? Or are they ineffective? The question
has direct relevance, for example, to drug courts. Do they work? What is the
evidence? Or do most programs, as critics charge, allow many offenders to
avoid the punishment of going to prison, undermine the deterrent effect of punishment, and allow these offenders to go free and prey on society?
At the time, Martinson’s conclusions were a bombshell, although as often
happens the report was widely misinterpreted. The title of his original article
was “What Works?” Many people, however, interpreted it to mean that “nothing works.” He did not actually say that. In fact, he found positive outcomes in
48 percent of the program evaluations he reviewed. Almost half is a long way
from nothing. And a few years later, he unequivocally stated that “some treatment
programs do have an appreciable effect on recidivism,” adding, “the critical fact
seems to be the conditions under which the program is delivered.”6 The National
Academy of Sciences’ Panel on Research on Rehabilitative Techniques reviewed
his work and concluded that he was “essentially correct.”7 It supported Martinson’s view that there was little evidence “to allay the current pessimism about
the effectiveness of institutional rehabilitation programs as they now exist.”
The challenge of designing effective treatment programs is exceedingly high.
A quarter of a century after Martinson, Doris Layton MacKenzie, in a thorough
review of what works in corrections could, at best, conclude that “some treatment
programs work with at least some offenders in some situations.”8 We should note
that she qualified her conclusion with three uses of the word some. Keep her comment in mind as we proceed in this chapter, because it becomes relevant again.
Martinson’s comment about how programs deliver their treatment is crucial for
our discussion in this chapter. It is not helpful to talk in terms of treatment, or
rehabilitation. There are programs that vary in many different ways. The crucial
questions are, what do they seek to do, how do they attempt to achieve their
goals, do they have the resources necessary to achieve those goals, and so on.
The Martinson report is a classic example of how social science research is
often misinterpreted and misused in the political arena. In the 1970s when the
report was published, many people wanted to believe that nothing works
because they were disillusioned with the philosophy of rehabilitation. They
were angry over what was then ten years of soaring crime rates. Conservatives
blamed rehabilitation programs for being soft on crime, whereas liberals attacked
the same programs for violating standards of due process (for example, denying
some prisoners parole because they are not “ready” for release, without any
verifiable standards to distinguish them from those who are deemed “ready”).
The disillusionment with rehabilitation was part of a more general conservative
mood that arose in the mid-1970s and continues today.9
The story of Martinson’s report is fascinating in itself. His team reviewed all
evaluations of correctional programs published in English between 1945 and
1967. In important respects, his report was a precursor to the current evidencebased policy movement. They were able to find only 231 that met rigorous
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
285
scientific standards. Most evaluations they rejected because they used unreliable
measures, failed to specify the “treatment,” did not use proper control groups, or
drew questionable conclusions from the data.10 Martinson exposed a scandalous
case of professional irresponsibility: the correctional community’s failure to
develop a systematic process of evaluation. Programs routinely claimed “success”
without any legitimate basis for doing so. The academic community shared
much of the responsibility because formal evaluations were done either by
researchers under contract or by in-house professionals with academic training.
Because his findings were so threatening, the state of New York did not release
the report and even denied Martinson permission to publish it. He sued and
eventually forced the report’s release.
The Prediction Problem Revisited
Criminologist Daniel Glaser replied to the Martinson report by arguing that
“certain sentencing and correctional policies, which differ according to the
criminalization of the offender, are more likely than their alternatives to reduce
recidivism rates.”11 His defense of rehabilitation highlights the central problem
facing all treatment-oriented programs: the need for a good match between
offender and treatment program. As MacKenzie argued, it is certainly true that
some programs are effective for some offenders. Achieving the proper match,
however, brings us back to our old friend the prediction problem, which we discussed in Chapter 4 and have referred to several times in other chapters.
Sentencing a convicted offender to a community-based drug treatment program
represents a prediction that he or she (1) is not a serious danger to the community
and therefore does not need to go to prison and (2) will respond positively to the
drug treatment program. Drawing on the work of John Hagan, Glaser argues that
some individuals are more deeply “embedded in crime” than others.12 Those who
are less deeply embedded are more “amenable” to community-based treatment.
So far, so good.
The crucial question is whether judges and correctional officials can correctly
identify the more “amenable” offenders and sentence them to the right treatment program. Can we accurately pick, for example, those offenders who are
likely to respond to a drug court program? We have already criticized conservative programs because of their inability to accurately predict which offenders are
the really high-risk ones who should be sentenced to long prison terms, as we
have previously argued in Chapters 4 and 7. Choosing which offenders to place
on probation is simply the other side of the same sentencing coin. The criticisms
we made of conservative punishment-oriented programs apply with equal force
to liberal rehabilitation-oriented programs.
TRADITIONAL REHABILITATION PROGRAMS
Let us now examine the traditional rehabilitation-oriented programs—probation,
parole, and diversion—to see what evidence there is regarding their effectiveness.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
286
CHAPTER
11
This discussion will provide the context for our discussion of recent innovations, such as evidence-based corrections, that seek to improve on their
effectiveness.
Probation
Probation is the most widely used correctional program in the criminal justice
system. In 2011, 3.9 million adults were on probation in the United States,
almost four times the 1.1 million in 1980. Twenty-five percent of all
convicted felons were sentenced to probation in 2009, and another 37 percent
were sentenced to “split sentences that included a jail term followed by
probation.”13
Probation embodies the traditional philosophy of rehabilitation by keeping
convicted offenders in the community rather than sending them to prison.
Probation treatment generally consists of supervision by a probation officer and
some restrictions on a probationer’s behavior: reporting regularly to a probation
officer, not leaving the area without permission, taking drug or alcohol counseling, furnishing employment verification or evidence of seeking a job, not possessing a weapon, and so on. Traditionally, probation was designed to help
rehabilitate offenders by having probation officers help them find a job and
deal with other personal problems.
Probation serves a number of different purposes. In many cases, it is the
appropriate sentence for someone convicted of a less serious offense or for a
first-time offender. In this respect it serves the goal of proportionality in sentencing, of making the punishment proportional to the harm done by the offense.
Probation is also far cheaper than imprisonment. The Pew Center for the States
estimated in 2009 that regular probation costs 1,248 a year, compared with
28,835 for prison. Costs vary by the type of program and region. Intensive
probation, for example, costs as much as 4,000 nationally, but in California it
costs 43,000 a year for one inmate.14 In important respects, we use probation as
a matter of necessity. We simply could not afford to imprison all convicted felons
even if we wanted to.
The Effectiveness of Probation
Does probation work? Is it effective in rehabilitating offenders and reducing
crime? Actually, there are two separate questions related to effectiveness. First,
is probation more effective than incarceration? Second, are some kinds of probation
programs more effective than others? There is much debate over the effectiveness of
probation. Evaluations have found failure rates that range from 12 to 65 percent.15
Where does the truth lie?
The Rand study of felons on probation in California is arguably the best data
available. The findings are depressing. After forty months on probation, 65 percent
of the probationers had been rearrested, and 51 percent had been reconvicted of a
new offense (see Figure 11.2). Moreover, one-third of those reconvicted (18 percent
of the original sample) were reconvicted of a serious violent crime. Nor did they wait
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
287
65%
53%
51%
34%
22%
Arrested
Charged
Convicted
Incarcerated, Incarcerated,
jail or prison
prison
F I G U R E 11.2 Probation outcomes after three years, California.
SOURCE: Joan Petersilia, Granting Felons Probation (Santa Monica: Rand Corporation, 1985).
long to fail. Probationers reconvicted of a violent crime took an average of only eight
months to recidivate, whereas those reconvicted of property offenses took an average
of only five months.
In short, most felons placed on probation fail; they do not become lawabiding citizens. Why? Many experts argue that traditional probation programs
do not provide any kind of meaningful supervision or treatment. The level of
supervision has always been minimal, involving a meeting with a probation officer (PO) perhaps once a month. The PO fills out the required reports, and that is
that. Joan Petersilia found that offenders on regular probation in Los Angeles
County met with their POs only once a month. Another report indicated that
because some PO caseloads exceeded a thousand probationers per PO. In Los
Angeles POs spent an average of one hour and forty-seven minutes per year
with each offender.16 The level of supervision has gotten even worse in
recent years because of the increase in caseloads. As we noted previously, the
number of people on probation nearly quadrupled between 1980 and 2011,
but the number of probation officers did not quadruple.17
A third issue involves the quality of the content of treatment services. Even
assuming that a probationer is officially enrolled in a drug treatment or anger
management program, it is not clear that this particular program is well run or
that any kind of service—in and of itself—can overcome the problems that led
the probationer to commit crime in the first place.
In the long run, most probationers eventually rehabilitate themselves, through
maturation, finding a job, getting married, and so on. John Hagan, as we already
mentioned, argues that whether a person becomes law abiding or continues in a
life of criminal activity depends on the extent to which he or she is “socially embedded” in either legitimate or criminal opportunities. Some individuals have more
contacts—with family members or friends in the neighborhood—that lead to jobs.
These contacts, moreover, tend to multiply: One job results in additional contacts that lead to other and often better job opportunities. Individuals who are
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
288
CHAPTER
11
embedded in these kinds of networks are far more likely to establish law-abiding
lives than those who are not—regardless of the kind of probation or parole services they receive. Generally, white youths are more embedded in positive networks than African American or Hispanic youths. Whites are simply more likely
to have a family member, friend, or acquaintance who can refer them to a job
opening than is the case with young men of color, who are more likely to live in
economically devastated neighborhoods.18
Research on offender prison re-entry programs provides a valuable glimpse
into the lives of criminal offenders after their release. Although the research is
specifically related to parole, it applies just as well to probation. Interviews with
400 recently released offenders who returned to Chicago found that they suffered from major problems that made readjustment to a normal life difficult: 30
percent had “significant” health problems, but 81 percent had no healthcare
insurance; about half (48 percent) had no close friends, and among those with
friends, 40 percent had a friend who had also been in prison. Convicted felons
face restrictions on employment, housing, welfare, and voting. In short, they are
embedded in social experiences that impose many hurdles but offer few
supports.19
Parole
Parole is the second-most prevalent rehabilitation program. Traditionally,
most offenders sent to prison were released early under some form of supervision, but the percentage has declined in recent years. Parole is seen as a
rehabilitation program because, like probation, it seeks to reintegrate the
offender into the community. In 2011, 853,852 adults were on parole in
the United States, more than three times the number in 1980.20 The use of
discretionary release parole has declined as a result of the growth of sentencing guidelines. Between 1978 and 2012, the percentage of all prison releases
that were “unconditional” (meaning no parole supervision) doubled from
about 17 percent to 33 percent.21
When it was first developed, experts believed that parole would facilitate
rehabilitation by placing a prisoner’s future in his own hands. They believed
that the possibility of gaining an earlier release would encourage inmates to
learn good behavior that would continue after release. Despite these promises,
parole has always been the unloved child of the criminal justice system. Ever
since it became widespread in the United States in the 1920s, it has been criticized from all directions. Conservatives argue that it allows dangerous offenders
to get out of prison early, whereas liberals argued (before the development of
sentencing guidelines) that parole release decisions are made without any scientific foundation and are thus arbitrary and often discriminatory.22 Despite persistent criticisms, however, parole survives because it serves a number of purposes
unrelated to rehabilitation: It offers prisoners an incentive to behave in prison,
gives prison officials some power to control them, and serves as a safety valve
for prison overcrowding.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
289
TREAT ’EM!
Does Parole Work?
A 2009 report by the Urban Institute put the question directly: “Does Parole
Work?” After reviewing the evidence, it concluded that “[o]verall, parole supervision has little effect on the recidivism rates of released prisoners.”23 That is to
say, it found no evidence that some forms of parole supervision were more effective than other recidivism that other forms. It is important to note exactly what the
Urban Institute report said and did not say. It did not criticize the institution of
parole, the practice of releasing prisoners early, but only that no one has yet
designed a form of parole supervision that is more effective than others.
The effectiveness of parole has traditionally been measured in terms of the
recidivism rate.24 As with probation, an offender can fail either by being arrested
for a new crime or through a technical violation of parole conditions. In terms of
a new crime, it depends on whether we measure failure in terms of being
rearrested, reconvicted, or reincarcerated (see Table 11.1).
The data on parole outcomes are as discouraging as for probation. The most
recent and most thorough study of parole outcomes found that within three
years, 67.5 percent were rearrested for either a felony or a serious misdemeanor.
About 47 percent were convicted of a new offense, and 25 percent were
returned to prison for a conviction of a new offense.25 These figures lend a
great deal of support to the widespread belief that neither prison nor parole is
successful in rehabilitating offenders. The policy question for us is whether parole
can be made to work more effectively.
The Urban Institute review of the evidence did find some variation in rearrest rates, depending on the type of release and the characteristics of the released
prisoners. Those with fewer prior arrests who were obtained discretionary release
were somewhat less likely to be arrested than those who were released unconditionally. The same pattern held for those who had been incarcerated for a public
T A B L E 11.1
Parole-outcome recidivism rates of prisoners released in 1994 from
prisons in fifteen states
Cumulative Percent of Released Prisoners Who Were—
Returned to prison with
a new sentencea,c (%)
Rearresteda,b (%)
Reconvicted (%)
6 months
29.9
10.6
5.0
1 year
44.1
21.5
10.4
2 years
59.2
36.4
18.8
3 years
67.5
46.9
25.4
Time after release
a
With a new sentence, including to state or federal prisons but not to local jails.
Because of missing data, prisoners released in Ohio and Virginia were excluded from the calculation of those returned to prison
with a new prison sentence.
c
Because of missing data, prisoners released in Ohio were excluded from the calculation of percent reconvicted.
b
SOUR CE: Bureau of Justice Statistics, R ecidivism of Prisoners R eleased in 1994 (Washington, DC Department of Justice, 2002).
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
290
CHAPTER
11
order offense. Women who obtained discretionary release were also less likely to
reoffend than those released unconditionally. Unfortunately, however, supervision had no evident effect on persons who had been convicted of a violent
offense or a drug offense. In the end, the report had to conclude that the overall
impact of supervision was minimal or nonexistent for the largest groups of people released from prison: males who had been convicted of violent, drug, or
property crimes. Part of the reason, the report added, is that “Parole supervision
is, in fact, quite minimal in most cases.”26
Petersilia amplifies point about the generally minimal nature of parole supervision. In California, 85 percent of parolees are on regular supervision, with each
parole officer carrying an average caseload of sixty-six parolees and conducting
an average of 1.7 contacts per parolee per month. The remaining parolees are
on intensive supervision with and parole officer caseloads of twenty-five per
officer and an average of 5.6 contacts per month.27
Second, there are serious questions about the availability and content of
treatment services. A California study estimated that 10,000 parolees were homeless but only 200 shelter beds were available to them. Similarly, only four mental
health clinics were available for an estimated 18,000 parolees with psychiatric
problems. And there were only 750 beds in treatment programs for 85,000 parolees
with alcohol or drug problems.28 Even if there were more of these services
available, there is no strong evidence that we successfully match offenders to
the specific treatment they need.
Research on offender reentry confirms the inadequacy of treatment services.
The Urban Institute interviewed 400 released offenders who returned to
Chicago. Although 87 percent had participated in prerelease programs related
to such practical matters as finding a job, obtaining a photo ID, and finding a
place to live, once they were home only 25 percent received an actual referral
to a job, only 15 percent received a referral to a substance abuse treatment
program, and only 22 percent contacted a community program based on a referral from the prerelease program. In short, the released offenders has significant
needs but received little in the way of services to address those needs.29
THE PREDICTION PROBLEM AGAIN Parole is where criminal justice
officials first encountered the prediction problem, beginning in the 1920s. For
about ninety years, parole officials and criminologists have tried to develop
formulas for predicting success on parole and to ensure that parole is granted
only to those offenders who are rehabilitated and ready for release into the community. The sad fact, however, is that criminologists have been searching for
better parole release criteria since the 1920s. It is not clear that they are any
closer to a successful formula today than they were then.30
Repeatedly, research has confirmed the basic point made by Martinson and
MacKenzie: that some programs work for some offenders. The problem, of
course, is in matching offenders to the right programs. Petersilia reports that
California uses risk prediction instruments, but there is no evidence that they are
any more effective in predicting success than the tools used in previous decades.31
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
291
Does More Make It Better?
INTENSIVE SUPERVISION FOR PROBATION AND PAROLE
Intensive probation supervision or intensive parole supervision (IPS) was one of
the new intermediate punishments designed to improve both probation and
parole that flourished in the 1990s. It is frequently combined with other intermediate sanctions (boot camps, home confinement, and electronic monitoring)
and applied to high-risk offenders.
The idea of intensive supervision was nothing new. California developed a
pioneering Special Intensive Parole Unit (SIPU) program in the mid-1950s and
maintained it for ten years. Martinson reviewed the SIPU evaluations and found
that three of the four phases produced no meaningful improvement in parolees’
behavior. The phase involving smaller caseloads did yield some positive results,
however. Martinson concluded that this was a deterrent rather than a rehabilitative effect. Parolees behaved themselves a little better when they knew that they
faced a real prospect of being sent back to prison.32
The federal probation system, meanwhile, developed the San Francisco
Project in the 1960s. Two IPS groups had caseloads of only twenty probationers,
whereas two other groups had caseloads of forty, and another group had
caseloads of several hundred clients. All other offenders were assigned to groups
with normal levels of supervision, meaning that probation officers had between
70 and 130 clients.33 An evaluation found no significant difference in the recidivism rates of offenders in the various groups. IPS did not consistently reduce the
failure rate.
The original IPS programs rested on the flawed assumption that increasing
the intensity of supervision simply by lowering case loads and increasing the
frequency of contact would enhance effectiveness.34 Mere contact with a probation or parole officer, however, may have little impact on an offender’s behavior,
and increasing the number of those contacts, it follows, will not necessarily make
a difference. The new IPS programs of the 1990s attempted to overcome some
of this problem by incorporating other intermediate sanctions such as home
confinement, mandatory drug and alcohol tests, and electronic monitoring.35
One important result is that intensive supervision has become primarily enforcement oriented rather than treatment oriented, with the primary goal being control
of the offender.
Are the new IPS programs effective? That is, are they more effective than
traditional probation? Petersilia found the results in three California probation
programs “particularly discouraging.” After one year, about 35 percent of the
IPS probationers had been rearrested, another 40 percent committed technical
violations of probation conditions, and only 25 percent had no violations of
any sort. Admittedly, the offenders assigned to these IPS programs were labeled
high risk, but a 75 percent failure rate after only one year is a poor showing.
Perhaps even more significant, their rearrest rates were no different from those
of other probationers. This outcome suggests that the intense supervision did not
stop them from committing crime. More intensive supervision did result in
much higher rates of technical violations. This result is hardly surprising because
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
292
CHAPTER
11
more frequent contacts and drug tests increases the chance of catching technical
violations.36
Why are IPS programs no more successful than regular probation in reducing
recidivism? The answer may be that no form of probation or parole supervision—
intensive or minimal—has any real impact on the lives of people who are embedded in environments with few positive opportunities, weak or nonexistent family
supports, and many dysfunctional peer influences such as friends involved in drugs
and crime. The “treatment” of intense supervision may not be able to overcome
the real problems that offenders have.
Disillusionment with parole reached such a point in the 1970s that several
jurisdictions simply abolished discretionary parole release (although some kept
postrelease supervision). The 1977 California Determinate Sentencing Law abolished discretionary parole release. Once a prisoner has served the sentence
imposed by the judge (with good time deducted) he or she is released and serves
a one-year period of parole supervision. The federal sentencing guidelines that
took effect in 1987 also abolished discretionary parole release, replacing it with
automatic release followed by supervised parole. Sixteen states have now abolished discretionary parole release. As a result, the percentage of all prisoners
released through discretionary parole has declined to slightly more than 30 percent
in recent years, a sharp decline over the previous twenty years, whereas about half
now leave prison through mandatory release, meaning that they have completed
their prison sentence.37
Abolishing parole may or may not be a good idea, but the evidence indicates
that it is not an effective crime reduction policy. A 2001 Bureau of Justice Statistics report found that in 1999, 54 percent of the prisoners released through discretionary parole were not rearrested, compared with 33 percent who left prison
through mandatory release.
Perverting Parole: Crisis in California
Parole has been completely perverted in California, to the point where it
undermines the original purpose of parole and also contributes directly to
the prison overcrowding crisis in the state. Every year, more people—six
out of ten—enter prison because their parole was revoked than because of a
sentence by a judge. That involved 78,721 parolees in 2006. To put this in
context, New York had the second-highest total of revocations to prison
with 11,548. The California prisons were so overcrowded a federal judge
found the prison system to be unconstitutional under the Eighth Amendment
and ordered a cap on prison populations. The Supreme Court upheld the
decision in 2011. The state responded with a Public Safety Realignment program requiring that offenders not convicted of a violent or sexual offense, or
not considered “serious” offenders under state law would be sentenced to
county jails.38
Underlying the California crisis was the 1978 sentencing reform law which
ended discretionary parole release and substituted a mandatory release when prisoners completed their sentence. Release is followed by a period of one year of
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
293
supervised parole. The unanticipated effect was to transfer the discretion
previously exercised by the parole board to parole officers, who increasingly
used parole revocation as a form of control of offenders. Violations of parole
conditions or a new crime increasingly resulted in revocation that sent the
offender back to prison. The process made a mockery of the traditional idea of
parole supervision as a means of reintegrating offenders into the community.
And because parole caseloads were so high, officers had almost no time for
many of their clients. Some categories of parolees could even report to their
parolees by mail. We can properly ask, what was the point of even pretending
there was any supervision? Additionally, many of the revocations were for
extremely short periods of time: one month, in some cases. The revolving
door of revoked parolees entering and then quickly leaving prison only overburdened and disrupted prison administration, which was already suffering
from severe overcrowding. Could anyone reasonably expect this process to be
successful in rehabilitating offenders, or even to send them any kind of positive
message?
28
PROPOSITION
Probation and parole have their proper places in the criminal justice system,
but there is no evidence of any programs likely to make them more effective
in reducing crime.
DIVERSION
Diversion was one of the exciting reforms of the 1960s. The President’s Crime
Commission gave it a strong endorsement in 1967, and in the 1970s an estimated
1,200 diversion programs were established.39 A diversion program is a planned
intervention with a treatment component and the goal of getting offenders out
of the criminal justice system as early as possible.
Actually, diversion was nothing new in the 1960s. Historically, many offenders were diverted from the criminal justice system at an early stage. Police officers routinely chose not to arrest someone even though there was probable
cause, and prosecutors dismissed cases when prosecution would not serve the
“interests of justice.” We call these practices the old diversion. The new diversion
programs were different because they were formal programs, with official goals, a
professional staff, and treatment services.40 (As we will see, today’s drug courts
are essentially another form of diversion, although with important differences
that we will discuss.)
Diversion programs are designed to rehabilitate offenders, and thereby
reduce crime, in two ways. First, they keep people accused of relatively minor
offenses out of jails and prisons. This reflects labeling theory in criminology,
which holds that formal processing in the criminal justice system, and imprisonment in particular, only accentuates a person’s tendency toward criminal behavior.
The President’s Crime Commission argued: “Institutions tend to isolate offenders
from society, both physically and psychologically, cutting them off from schools,
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
294
CHAPTER
11
jobs, families, and other supportive influences and increasing the probability that
the label criminal will be indelibly impressed upon them.”41 The Wolfgang cohort
data we examined in Chapter 4, moreover, suggest that most juveniles “mature
out” in relation to criminal behavior. Diversion programs assume that the best
approach is to intervene in people’s lives as little as possible.
Second, diversion programs are designed to provide treatment services that
address the offender’s real problems: drug or alcohol treatment, employment
counseling, anger management, and so forth. Advocates of diversion believe
that arrest, prosecution, and punishment aggravate rather than treat those problems
(while at the same time overloading the criminal justice system).
Finally, diversion programs are intended to reduce the costs of the criminal
justice system by avoiding the expenses of full criminal prosecution and
imprisonment.
In short, diversion promised the best of all possible worlds—an approach that
was more effective, more humane, and cheaper. An old adage says that if something seems too good to be true, it probably is. Let us take a look at diversion in
practice.
The Original Model: The Manhattan Court Employment Project
The earliest and most influential diversion program was the Manhattan Court
Employment Project. Sponsored by the Vera Institute, the project provided
employment services to arrested persons. The basic assumption was that because
unemployment is a major cause of crime, facilitating employment will reduce
subsequent criminal activity. Even though the Court Employment Project
occurred many years ago, its story highlights a number of enduring problems
that affect more recent programs.
Each day staff members of the Court Employment Project reviewed the
arrest docket and identified defendants who met the program’s criteria: resident
of New York City; between the ages of sixteen and forty-five; unemployed or
earning less than 125 a week; and charged with a felony other than homicide,
rape, kidnapping, or arson. In addition, the defendant must have not had prior
jail or prison experience of one year or longer. With the prosecutor’s consent,
the case was suspended for ninety days while the defendant received counseling,
assistance in obtaining any short-term public assistance for which he or she might
have been eligible, and referral to a job opening with one of the 400 cooperating
employers. Charges were dropped completely if the defendant “succeeded” by
keeping a job. If the person “failed” to secure employment, the case was
prosecuted.
An early evaluation declared the Manhattan Court Employment Project a
huge success. In its first three years, the project accepted 1,300 clients, about
half of whom (48.2 percent) succeeded. About 70 percent of these 626 people
had been unemployed at the time of arrest. Fourteen months later, about 80 percent
of those who could be located were still employed. Only 15.8 percent of these
successful clients committed another crime in the twelve months following their
release from the program. This recidivism rate was half of that for both offenders
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
295
who failed in the program and a control group. The program cost only 731 per
client, or 1,518 per success.42
A subsequent evaluation, however, reached different conclusions. It
found that the project did not reduce recidivism and had no discernible effect
on the employment record or the behavior of its clients. Moreover, it did
not reduce pretrial detention time or lower the number of convictions. A
major problem was that about half of the clients served by the program
would not have been prosecuted at all if there had been no court employment project.43 They would have been completely diverted from the justice
system. The fact that the program kept them in the system and under some
form of control, was a classic example of “net widening.” Because this
phenomenon affects so many well-intentioned reforms, we need to discuss
it in detail.
The Net-Widening Problem
Net widening is the process by which more people are brought under some form
of social control through the criminal justice system. The unwritten law of net
widening is that less punitive alternatives tend to be applied to people who
would otherwise not be under any social control at all; that is, they would be
truly diverted and not arrested, prosecuted, or incarcerated.
Evaluations of early diversion programs found that they led to substantial net
widening. More than half of the juveniles referred to fifteen diversion projects in
California would not have been committed to any kind of program under
traditional practice. Thomas G. Blomberg found that juvenile diversion programs
produced a 32 percent increase in the total number of juveniles under some form
of control. Other evaluations have found varying degrees of net widening.44 And
as we shall see, net widening has plagued many of the new intermediate punishments such as boot camps.
A study of reforms in the San Francisco juvenile justice system in the mid1990s, which included new prevention and intervention systems and cost
20 million, found a significant increase in the detention of juvenile arrestees,
even though juvenile arrests declined by about half. And in fact, the average
length of detentions increased despite the original goal of diverting juveniles
from the system.45
The dynamics of net widening are easy to understand. Officials continue to
use severe sanctions (for example, prison) for offenders they regard as dangerous
and use new and less punitive programs for less serious offenders whose cases
they might have dismissed altogether. Thus, instead of dismissing cases and keeping less serious offenders completely out of the system, they “divert” them into a
treatment program. As a result, more people are under control of the criminal
justice system. The problem, of course, is that most of those low-risk offenders
probably would have succeeded without the benefit of the program. The treatment, whatever it is, added no additional crime reduction.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
296
CHAPTER
11
The net-widening phenomenon suggests that the old diversion actually did a
better job of achieving the basic goal of keeping people out of the system. When
a police officer does not make an arrest, that person is truly diverted; when
a prosecutor dismisses all charges, that defendant is genuinely diverted. New
diversion programs, however, keep people under some form of control, thereby
maintaining or even increasing the total costs to the system.46
Do Diversion Programs Rehabilitate?
The most relevant question for us is whether diversion programs effectively
rehabilitate offenders and thereby reduce crime. More precisely, the question is:
Do diversion programs provide a treatment or intervention that reduces future
criminal behavior more effectively than normal prosecution or even dismissal?
A number of evaluations found that they do not. The Justice Department touted
the Des Moines (Iowa) Adult Diversion Project as an “exemplary project” that
other communities should adopt. An evaluation, however, found that it had
“little impact in reducing recidivism among diverted, compared to nondiverted offenders.” In another program, diverted offenders had lower recidivism
rates than did juveniles sent to juvenile court but, alas, had higher recidivism
rates than did kids released outright without the benefit of any treatment.47
The failure of diversion programs is the result of a number of problems; ones
that we should keep in mind when we look at drug courts, reentry programs, or
other recent innovations. First, many do not actually deliver the treatment services
they claim to deliver. Some intensive probation supervision programs, for example,
promised a high rate of contact between probationers and probation officers but
did not achieve that goal.48 Second, even when treatments are delivered, there are
questions about the content of those treatment services. Do drug and alcohol treatment programs effectively reduce substance abuse? How many of the successful
clients would have done so on their own without the benefit of the treatment?
Additionally, if net widening occurs, the promised cost savings will not
necessarily be achieved because there are now more rather than fewer people
under the control of the criminal justice system.
Finally, diversion programs introduce serious due-process considerations.
A person who agrees to enter a treatment program in the expectation of having
criminal charges dropped is, in effect, admitting guilt. Rather than contest the
charge, the person is saying, “Yes, I have done something wrong, and you
have a right to force me to undergo treatment.” By offering a seemingly more
attractive alternative to prosecution and possible incarceration, the program
coerces this tacit admission of guilt in a subtle but powerful way. In addition,
the selection of the program’s clients may be unfair.49
In the end, diversion offers a false promise. It fails to achieve its own goals,
may in fact contradict them, and does not offer a realistic solution to the problem
of serious crime. Diversion is not really used for persons charged with robbery or
burglary. Nor is there persuasive evidence that it rehabilitates lesser offenders in a
way that keeps them from becoming serious offenders.
An evidence-based crime policy approach leads us to the following proposition:
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
297
29
PROPOSITION
Traditional diversion programs do not reduce serious crime.
THE NEW INTERMEDIATE PUNISHMENTS
In their influential 1990 book Between Prison and Probation, Norval Morris and
Michael Tonry leveled a major criticism at criminal sentencing in the United
States. They argued that at sentencing, a judge faced a stark choice between
two extremes: probation or prison. In many cases, however, prison is too
harsh a punishment, whereas probation is too lenient. Their argument
exposed the problem that probation involves neither meaningful treatment
nor effective control of offenders in the community. Consequently, they
called for the development of a range of intermediate punishments that
would be less extreme than prison but with more content than traditional
probation.50
Correctional officials and politicians across the country responded to Morris
and Tonry by developing a set of new programs called intermediate punishments,
which included boot camps, shock incarceration, intensive probation/parole
supervision, home confinement, and electronic monitoring. These programs
often overlap, and sentences typically include two or more different programs.
Boot camps are often defined as a form of shock incarceration and frequently
include a period of intensive parole supervision following release. Intensive probation/parole supervision might include home confinement, which may be
enforced through electronic monitoring.51 All of these programs may include
frequent random drug tests. In examining a particular intermediate punishment,
therefore, it is important to look beyond the label and determine exactly what
program elements it contains.
Ted Palmer and some others regard the new intermediate punishments as a
revival of rehabilitation. Is this true? Palmer’s own choice of words raises some
doubts. He refers to correctional intervention instead of rehabilitation. The difference is more than a matter of semantics. As we shall see, the new intermediate
punishments emphasize surveillance and control of offenders, often with little
emphasis on traditional treatment components. Petersilia argues, as have other
critics, that parole has become largely devoted to the surveillance and control
of parolees and that services designed to help them adjust to society have
decreased and in many instances vanished altogether. What kind of services or
control exists, for example, for the California parolees who report to the parole
officers by mail?52
We now have many years of experience with the new intermediate punishments. What is the evidence for their effectiveness? We will start with a discussion
of boot camps, a classic example of a new idea that generated a lot of excitement,
and then quickly faded away.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
298
CHAPTER
11
Illustration by Frank Irwin, © Wadsworth, Cengage Learning.
The Rise and Fall of Boot Camps
Does anyone remember boot camps? Most students reading this book will not.
Most faculty will remember them, but even some of the younger faculty may
not. Boot camps burst on the scene in the mid-1980s as an exciting innovation,
generating publicity as an effective alternative to prison sentences. By 2000, there
were ninety-five boot camps in the country, enrolling 12,751 prisoners.53
Gradually, however, the excitement faded. Susan Turner in 2010 recalled the
“great fanfare” that greeted their arrival and the loss of their “luster” when the
evaluations arrived indicating their failure to reduce recidivism among their
clients.54 The evidence was that they were no more effective than other
sanctions. The title of the article by criminologist Francis Cullen and his colleagues
in a special 2005 issue of the Journal of Offender Rehabilitation said it all: “The Rise
and Fall of Boot Camps.”55
Boot camps are a classic example of the fad syndrome in criminal justice: an
exciting new idea today is gone tomorrow. If you do a web search for “boot
camps,” you find mostly commercial camps for special interests: boot camps for
fitness, for teens, for computer skills—just about something for everyone, except
for criminals.
What Is a Boot Camp?
A boot camp usually involves (1) a short period of incarceration (typically three
to six months); (2) in a facility separate from a regular prison; (3) for young firsttime offenders (many exclude offenders convicted of violent crimes); (4) with a
program of rigorous physical, educational, and substance-abuse-prevention
programs; and followed by (5) a period of intensive supervision in the community.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
299
Many of the first boot camps emphasized their purely military aspects, which
caught the public’s attention and were the basis of their popularity: “military drill
and ceremony, hard labor, physical training, and strict rules and discipline.”56 As
time passed, correctional officials gave more emphasis to the treatment elements,
such as drug counseling. As is the case with other intermediate punishments,
boot camps have multiple and conflicting goals. They are simultaneously
intended to rehabilitate, punish, control, and reduce prison overcrowding.
The basic idea underlying boot camps is nothing new. Judges have routinely
given split sentences: short periods of incarceration followed by probation. The
first boot camps were different primarily by virtue of the military rhetoric that
surrounded them and the intensive probation supervision that usually followed
release.
Boot camp programs vary considerably in terms of how participants are
selected, the content of the boot camp program, and the nature of the postrelease supervision. In some states, judges sentence offenders directly to boot camp
(these are sometimes referred to as front-end intermediate punishments). In others,
correctional officials select participants from among prison inmates (referred to as
back-end programs). In some states, boot camp participation is voluntary, meaning
that an offender must choose it. In others, it is mandatory for those sentenced to
it. Offenders in some states can voluntarily drop out of the boot camp and return
to prison.57
In terms of content, Mackenzie and her colleagues found that one of the
greatest differences among the boot camps in the eight states they evaluated
was “the amount of time in the daily schedule that is devoted to work, drill,
and physical training versus such treatment-type activities as counseling, drug
treatment, or academic education.”58 Some early boot camps were almost
entirely military-style programs, whereas others put much more emphasis on
traditional rehabilitation efforts.
Do boot camps work? Are they more effective than other forms of correctional
treatment in reducing recidivism? The good news is that boot camps have been
subject to rigorous evaluations. The bad news is that they do not produce lower
recidivism rates and thereby reduce crime. In an assessment of ten years of experience with boot camps, a Department of Justice report found that they generally
produced “positive short-term changes in attitudes and behaviors” among their
participants but that “with few exceptions, these positive changes did not lead to
reduced recidivism.” The graduates of some boot camps did have lower recidivism
rates, but they participated in camps with more treatment services, more intensive
sessions, and more intensive postrelease supervision. In short, there is today no
consistent evidence that boot camps are more effective in reducing recidivism than
are other types of correctional programs.59
A number of problems affect boot camp programs. The Department of
Justice report concluded that “the length of stay in boot camps—usually from
90 to 120 days—was too brief to realistically affect recidivism.” In short, as
with many other correctional programs, there was not much “treatment.” The
report also found that there was “little or no postrelease programming to prepare
graduates to lead productive lives.”60 One-third to half of offenders failed to
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
300
CHAPTER
11
complete the program. There also appeared to be significant net widening
because judges or correctional officials placed low-risk offenders in boot camp
programs. As a result, overall system costs often increased rather than decreased.
One problem that has affected all new intermediate punishment programs is
that intensified surveillance (for example, more contacts with parole officers, frequent drug tests) identifies more technical violations of the conditions of release.
This increases the failure rate and results in sending more offenders back to
prison, a development that eliminates the potential cost savings.
Some critics argue that the emphasis on military drill is fundamentally
misguided. Yelling at inmates, treating them with disrespect, and forcing them
to undergo painful physical exercises may be counterproductive, teaching
inmates that disrespect and verbal abuse are the keys to success in life. Such
programs also value the most aggressive definition of masculinity. Finally, the
legendary rigors of Marine boot camp at least offer a reward at the end: entry
into the proud fellowship of the Corps. If prison boot camps offer nothing of
comparable positive value at the end but only a return to the same neighborhood with the same bleak prospects (what Hagan refers to as a life socially
embedded in crime), they are not likely to have a long-term positive impact on
the people who pass through them.61
HOME CONFINEMENT AND ELECTRONIC MONITORING
Home confinement (HC) and electronic monitoring (EM) are designed to keep
the offender under fairly strict surveillance and control. HC is essentially a
curfew. In some cases, it is enforced through EM; in others, it is not. Both HC
and EM have the same mixture of goals as does IPS. They are designed to simultaneously reduce prison overcrowding and both control and rehabilitate the
offender.
EM emerged in 1983 when Judge Jack Love of Albuquerque adopted the
Gosslink system for a convicted offender. The idea quickly caught on. By
1996, there were 13,868 probationers and 8,491 parolees in EM programs.62
An early report found EM to be far cheaper than imprisonment: it cost as little
as 1,350 per year, versus 20,000 for prison at that time. Basically two different
EM technologies are available. Passive monitoring radio frequency systems place a
transmitter on the offender (a tamper-proof bracelet or anklet) and a dialer on
the telephone. If the probationer leaves the premises, the signal is interrupted,
and the dialer automatically calls the probation office. Active monitoring
programmed contact systems involve periodic, usually random telephone calls to
the probationer’s home. The calling may be done automatically by machine or
by the PO’s personal phone call.
Initially, the largest group of offenders in EM programs were traffic violation
offenders. By 1989, property offenders and drug offenders had become the two
largest categories. Sentences generally ran from 60 to 120 days. A Justice Department survey found that most failures occurred within the first two months.
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
TREAT ’EM!
301
About 4 percent of the total sample committed a new offense, and half of those
occurred in the first 60 days. About 22 percent of the sample committed a
technical violation of the terms of their confinement.63
Many people initially opposed EM because it conjured up images of George
Orwell’s famous novel 1984, with Big Brother continuously monitoring everyone’s private behavior. That analogy was not really accurate because EM programs
involve convicted offenders and any sentence would involve some loss of freedom.
In actual practice, EM does not always deliver on its promises. Although advertised
as a technological “fix” for the crime problem, EM systems often have serious
technical and administrative problems. The signal can be disrupted by certain
kinds of housing construction, and random calls in the middle of the night disrupt
the probationer’s sleep (not such a good idea if we want that person to hold a
steady job) and require that a staff person be on duty to respond to a violation.
A 2008 report by the International Association of Chiefs of Police (IACP) warned
that the practical demands of operating an EM system (for example, monitoring
the equipment, teaching offenders how it works, monitoring and responding to
alerts) increases the workload for law enforcement officers. Also, the IACP
warned, an EM system can create a false sense of security that overlooks the possibility of offenders tampering with the equipment or simple mechanical failures.64
Finally, the overall cost savings also represent only a small fraction of criminal justice systems costs. The 12,000 offenders in EM programs in 1992 (probation and
parole combined) represented a minuscule fraction of the 4.8 million under correctional supervision that year.65
The intensive surveillance that EM (and IPS) provides creates a special
problem for the criminal justice system. It does succeed in detecting violations
of probation or parole conditions, and many of the offenders are returned to
prison. As the report Performance Measures for the Criminal Justice System pointed
out, there is serious disagreement over whether a high rate of technical violations
indicates success or failure. If the purpose of EM is to control offenders and
detect misbehavior, then EM is a success. But if the purpose is to control costs
and reintegrate the offender into the community, then it is a failure.66
Most important for our purposes, evaluations indicate that IPS, HC, and EM
are no more effective in reducing crime than conventional prison or probation
programs. Offenders in these programs have the same rearrest rate as those on
conventional probation or parole.
This leads us to conclude:
30
PROPOSITION
Home confinement and electronic monitoring do not reduce crime.
Lessons of the Intermediate Punishment Movement
Reviewing the first ten to fifteen years of the intermediate punishment movement,
Petersilia reached some sobering conclusions. Most of the programs were “more
symbolic … than substantive.”67 Most seriously, there was no evidence that intermediate
Copyright 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the
eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional
content at any time if subsequent rights 
Download