Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance 29 (2021) 100451 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbef Does investor attention matter for market anomalies?✩ ∗ Hung T. Nguyen a , , Mia Hang Pham b a b School of Economics and Finance, Massey University, New Zealand Massey Business School, Massey University, New Zealand article info Article history: Received 16 May 2020 Accepted 17 December 2020 Available online 29 December 2020 JEL classification: D91 G11 G12 G41 a b s t r a c t This paper examines the relation between investor attention and stock market anomalies in the US stock market. We find anomalies are stronger following high rather than low attention periods. Returns on the long–short strategy based on a composite mispricing score during high attention months are 2.25 times higher than those during low attention periods. The results are consistent with the notion that high levels of attention can exacerbate investor overreaction to irrelevant information. Mispricing is then corrected, leading to increased anomaly returns following high attention periods. © 2020 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Investor attention Market anomalies Mispricing 1. Introduction Attention is a limited cognitive resource (Kahneman, 1973), and it serves as a major factor in determining security selection and investment decisions (Peng and Xiong, 2006; Barber and Odean, 2008). While there has been a sharp focus on the impact of attention on market reactions to accounting information, corporate behavior and outcomes, managerial incentives, market liquidity, and investment performance,1 less is known about the impact of attention on the efficiency of financial markets. This paper examines whether, and to what extent, investor attention influences financial market anomalies. Prior literature provides mixed predictions regarding the impact of investor attention on stock market anomalies. On the one hand, classical asset pricing models imply that the attention– anomaly relation would be irrelevant, as investors are assumed to be fully rational and the attention effect, if any, would be eliminated by rational decisions attempting to exploit mispricinginduced arbitrage opportunities (e.g., Sharpe, 1964). On the other ✩ Acknowledgments: We appreciate helpful comments from Philip Gray and Cameron Truong. Harvey Nguyen acknowledges financial supports from the Accounting and Finance Association of Australia and New Zealand (AFAANZ) Research Grant and Massey University Strategic Research Excellent Fund. All errors are our own. ∗ Correspondence to: School of Economics and Finance, Massey University, North Shore, Auckland 0632, New Zealand. E-mail addresses: h.nguyen3@massey.ac.nz (H.T. Nguyen), m.h.pham@massey.ac.nz (M.H. Pham). 1 See Barber and Odean (2013) and Gabaix (2019) for a review of the literature. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100451 2214-6350/© 2020 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. hand, a growing strand of behavioral finance literature suggests that traditional rational frameworks should incorporate psychologically-related factors to improve our understanding of asset pricing (e.g., Hirshleifer, 2001; Barberis and Thaler, 2003; Branch, 2014). Given human beings have bounded rationality and limited cognitive resources to process information (Barber and Odean, 2008), it is possible that investor attention matters for the efficiency of financial markets. The relation between investor attention and market anomalies is intuitive for two reasons. First, given a limited amount of attention to devote to investment decisions, attention-constrained investors may miss important information, leading to delayed information processing and underreaction to relevant information (Peng and Xiong, 2006; Hirshleifer et al., 2009). Second, high levels of attention can exacerbate investor overreaction to irrelevant information or their private information, thus generating more pronounced anomaly returns (Hou et al., 2009; Barber and Odean, 2013). The United States is a natural setting for our study given a large body of documented anomalies in economic and finance literature (e.g., McLean and Pontiff, 2016; Hou et al., 2020). We study a set of 11 prominent anomalies in the US stock market and a composite mispricing measure constructed based on these anomalies. We find that long–short returns of anomalies are stronger following high rather than low attention periods. Specifically, nine of the anomalies produce positive and significant long–short returns following high attention periods, whereas, only two of the anomalies generate significant long–short returns following low attention months. Furthermore, long–short returns H.T. Nguyen and M.H. Pham Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance 29 (2021) 100451 Table 1 Investor attention and anomaly returns. Anomaly Mispricing score Net stock issues Composite equity issues Accruals Net operating assets Asset growth Investment-to-assets Distress O-score Momentum Gross profitability premium Return on assets Whole sample High attention periods Low attention periods Long (1) Short (2) Long–Short (3) Long (4) Short (5) Long–Short (6) Long (7) Short (8) Long–Short (9) 0.651 (2.16) 1.152 (5.66) 1.200 (5.89) 1.042 (3.50) 1.220 (4.53) 1.172 (4.54) 1.171 (4.92) 1.121 (4.84) 1.015 (4.02) 1.348 (4.39) 1.238 (5.63) 1.159 (4.94) −0.240 (−0.61) 0.891*** (4.00) 0.553*** (3.57) 0.478*** (2.62) 0.284* (1.90) 0.704*** (4.60) 0.416** (2.27) 0.431*** (2.78) 0.674** (2.09) 0.190 (1.07) 0.992*** (2.92) 0.282 (1.45) 0.609*** (2.71) 0.473 −0.836 0.784 0.203 1.400 0.620 0.905 0.578 1.363 0.708 1.037 0.736 1.087 0.740 0.998 0.776 1.468 0.527 0.974 0.505 1.333 0.750 1.010 0.761 1.312 0.747 1.031 0.733 1.414 0.431 0.829 0.462 1.248 0.825 0.783 0.825 1.730 0.139 0.968 0.573 1.414 1.191 1.063 0.723 1.390 0.499 1.309*** (4.24) 0.780*** (3.34) 0.655** (2.10) 0.348 (1.58) 0.941*** (3.82) 0.584* (1.95) 0.565** (2.41) 0.983** (2.33) 0.424* (1.74) 1.591*** (3.49) 0.223 (0.84) 0.891*** (2.64) 0.929 0.601 0.581** (2.05) 0.327* (1.83) 0.301 (1.60) 0.222 (1.22) 0.469*** (2.85) 0.249 (1.24) 0.298 (1.55) 0.366 (0.81) −0.042 (−0.17) 0.395 (0.88) 0.341 (1.40) 0.328 (1.01) 0.599 (2.09) 0.722 (2.51) 0.758 (2.75) 0.516 (1.83) 0.756 (2.54) 0.740 (2.57) 0.447 (0.99) 0.825 (2.57) 0.356 (0.91) 0.956 (3.07) 0.550 (1.53) The table reports the value-weighted excess returns for 11 anomalies and mispricing score based on the combination of all anomalies following high and low attention months. Decile portfolios are formed every month for the January 1980 to December 2016 period by sorting stocks based on each of the anomaly variables over the past one month. Portfolio 1 (10) is the portfolio of stocks associated with the highest (lowest) average returns over the past month, as reported in the literature. Long, short, long–short returns are reported in percentage. High (low) attention periods are defined based on the sample median of the aggregate investor attention index from Chen et al. (2019). The sample period is from January 1980 to December 2016. Newey and West (1987) adjusted t-statistics are in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. of the composite mispricing score are more pronounced following high rather than low attention periods. The results are consistent with the conjecture that too much attention allocated to irrelevant information triggers investor overreaction to information. Once the mispricing is corrected, more anomaly returns are realized following high attention periods. Our paper adds two contributions to the literature. First, this study extends to a growing literature that shows the impacts of investor attention on various cognitive-demanding activities such as stock picking or investment decisions. We find that levels of investor attention are associated with the degree of mispricing. Second, our paper contributes to a recent strand of studies documenting drivers of capital market anomalies (e.g., Stambaugh et al., 2012; McLean and Pontiff, 2016). The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes our data and sample. Section 3 discusses the main findings. Section 4 provides further analyses. Section 5 concludes the paper. individual attentional proxies commonly employed in the literature.3 Our sample covers the period from January 1980 (when attention measure becomes available) to December 2016. 3. Main findings 3.1. Univariate portfolio analysis We provide a detailed description of each anomaly in Appendix. For each of the 11 anomalies and the composite mispricing score, all stocks are sorted into decile portfolios every month, where decile 10 (decile 1) is assigned to stocks associated with the lowest (highest) average return, as discussed in the literature. We examine the return differences between the top and bottom deciles of each anomaly and report the results in Columns (1) to (3) in Table 1. We study anomaly returns following high and low investor attention periods. A high (low) investor attention month is one in which the value of the aggregate investor attention is above (below) the median value for the sample periods. Columns (4) to (9) in Table 1 report long, short, and long–short value-weighted returns for each anomaly and a composite mispricing score following high and low attention periods. The results presented in Table 1 suggest that long–short returns of anomalies are stronger following high rather than low attention periods. Specifically, nine of the 11 anomalies produce positive and statistically significant long–short returns following high attention periods, whereas, only two of the 11 anomalies 2. Data and methodology We study a comprehensive set of 11 market anomalies as in Stambaugh et al. (2012, 2014, 2015). For each of the anomalies, we obtain value-weighted portfolio returns for the top and bottom deciles of the anomaly’s sorting variable returns from Stambaugh and Yuan (2017).2 The composite mispricing measure of a stock is constructed by combining its rankings on the 11 anomalies’ variables. We source market excess returns and risk factor returns are from Kenneth French’s data library. We obtain an aggregate investor attention measure from Chen et al. (2019) who construct the market-wide attention measure based on 12 3 The twelve attention measures include abnormal trading volume, extreme returns, analyst coverage, past returns, advertising expenses, fund inflow, media coverage, Google search volume, nearness to the Dow 52-week high and historical high, and EDGAR search (Chen et al., 2019). We thank Goufu Zhou for making the data publicly available on his website: http://apps.olin.wustl. edu/faculty/zhou/. 2 We thank Robert Stambaugh for making the data available at http://finance. wharton.upenn.edu/~stambaug/. 2 H.T. Nguyen and M.H. Pham Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance 29 (2021) 100451 Table 2 Regression analysis. Anomaly Intercept Mispricing score Net stock issues Composite equity issues Accruals Net operating assets Asset growth Investment-to-assets Distress O-score Momentum Gross profitability premium Return on assets R2 (%) ATTENTION coeff. t-stat coeff. t-stat 0.892*** 0.553*** 0.478*** 0.284* 0.705*** 0.416** 0.431*** 0.674 0.190 0.992*** 0.281 0.609*** (4.15) (3.73) (2.75) (1.90) (4.84) (2.32) (2.79) (0.67) (1.10) (2.97) (1.46) (2.89) 0.576** 0.404** 0.490** 0.025 0.404** 0.314 0.305** 0.720** 0.354** 0.521 0.192 0.605*** (2.47) (2.27) (1.99) (0.17) (2.32) (1.31) (2.11) (2.08) (1.96) (1.58) (1.10) (2.61) 1.53 1.81 1.87 0.01 1.65 0.64 0.82 1.00 0.80 0.37 0.03 1.86 The table reports the estimates of the following model specification: ERetP10−P1, t +1 = α + ATTENTIONt + Et +1 , where ERetP10−P1, t +1 is the long–short value-weighted excess return of each anomaly and the composite mispricing score based on 11 anomalies, and ATTENTIONt is lagged monthly investor attention from Chen et al. (2019). Newey and West (1987) adjusted t-statistics are in parentheses. The sample covers the period from 1980 to 2016. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Table 3 Control for alternative explanations. (1) (2) (3) (4) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Constant −0.272 (−0.02) ATTENTION 0.556** (2.27) 0.248 (0.09) 0.947 (3.08) 0.586** (2.46) 1.392 (0.07) 0.575** (2.39) 0.640 (0.67) 0.560** (2.30) 0.831 (4.31) 0.547** (2.29) 0.810 (3.52) 0.544** (2.31) 0.899 (4.13) 0.582** (2.49) 0.793 (3.05) 0.777** (2.32) 1.893 (2.17) 0.541** (2.29) 0.509 (0.22) 0.573** (2.56) 222.402 (0.55) 0.888*** (2.61) −16.486 (−0.38) 51.742 (0.51) −31.150 (−0.30) 0.158 (0.97) 0.590 (0.40) 21.521 (0.72) 0.744 (0.46) −0.261 (−0.63) −41.942 (−1.27) 4.120 (0.68) 2.10 GDP per capita Inflation −21.425 (−0.27) Employment −0.098 (−0.02) Industrial production 0.003 (0.25) Business cycle 0.331 (0.32) Hourly compensation 26.124 (1.03) T-bill 0.289 (0.92) Market sentiment 0.171 (0.46) Market volatility −21.518 (−1.07) Macroeconomic uncertainty R2 (%) 1.18 1.33 1.31 1.19 1.24 1.45 1.41 3.04 1.64 0.575 (0.16) 1.33 The table reports the estimates of the monthly regression of the value-weighted returns for a composite mispricing score based on the combination of all anomalies on lagged attention index after controlling for various market-wide variables. The model specification is as follows: ERetP10−P1, t +1 = α + ATTENTIONt + Macrot + Et +1 , where ERetP10−P1, t +1 is the long–short value-weighted excess return of the composite mispricing score based on 11 anomalies, ATTENTIONt is lagged monthly attention index from Chen et al. (2019), and Macrot refers to macroeconomic variables. Investor Sentiment is principal components of three sentiment indices including Baker and Wurgler (2006)’s sentiment index, University of Michigan’s consumer sentiment index, and the Chicago Board Options Exchange’s VIX index. We source macroeconomic variables from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and the US Bureau of Economic Analysis. GDP per capita is the natural logarithm of GDP per capita; Inflation is personal consumption expenditures; Employment is the growth rate of employment level; Industrial Production is industrial production index; Business Cycle is from NBER; Hourly Compensation is nonfarm business sector: real compensation per hour; T-bill is the yield on the 3-month Treasury bill; Market volatility is measured using an EGARCH (1,1) model; Macroeconomic Uncertainty is the economic uncertainty index of Jurado et al. (2015). Newey and West (1987) adjusted t-statistics are in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. generate significant long–short returns following low attention months. Furthermore, long–short returns of the composite mispricing score constructed based on all anomalies during high attention months are 2.25 times higher than those during low attention periods (1.309% versus 0.581%). lagged 1-month attention and report results for these tests in Table 2.4 The results in Table 2 suggest that long–short value-weighted returns of seven of the 11 anomalies are statistically and positively related to previous month investor attention. More importantly, the coefficient on the attention measure is positive and statistically significant (coefficient of 0.576 and t-stat of 2.47) when the aggregate mispricing score is used as a dependent variable. The attention–mispricing effect is economically significant, with one standard deviation increase in investor attention being 3.2. Regression analysis We further examine the relation between investor attention and the long–short returns of anomalies and mispricing scores using a regression framework. We regress long–short valueweighted returns of each anomaly and the mispricing score on 4 Attention index is scaled to have zero mean and unit standard deviation. 3 H.T. Nguyen and M.H. Pham Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance 29 (2021) 100451 Table 4 Sensitivity analysis. Intercept R2 (%) ATTENTION coeff. t-stat coeff. t-stat 0.492*** (2.80) 2.11 (1.96) 4.97 (2.24) 1.18 Panel A: Equal-weighted portfolio returns 1.378*** (8.60) Panel B: Alphas with respect to the Fama and French (1993)’s three-factor model 1.383*** (5.70) 0.410** Panel C: Subsample analysis, excluding financial turmoil (2007–2008) 0.800*** (3.67) 0.514** The table reports results for sensitivity analysis for the monthly regression of the value-weighted returns for a composite mispricing score based on the combination of all anomalies on lagged investor attention index as in Table 2. In Panel A, we use long–short equal-weighted returns of mispricing scores as the dependent variable. In Panel B, we use alphas with respect to the Fama and French (1993)’s three-factor model instead of excess returns as the dependent variable. In Panel C, we rerun Table 2’s regression after excluding the financial turmoil (2007–2008). Newey and West (1987) adjusted t-statistics are in parentheses. The sample covers the period from 1980 to 2016. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Table A.1 List of market anomalies in Stambaugh and Yuan (2017). No. Anomaly Description 0 Composite mispricing score The composite mispricing measure of a stock is constructed by combining its rankings on the 11 anomalies’ variables computed at the end of each month. The mispricing measure ranges between 0 and 100 with higher (lower) value indicates more overpriced (underpriced). 1 Net stock issues Loughran and Ritter (1995) find a negative relation between net stock issues and subsequent stock returns. 2 Composite equity issues Daniel and Titman (2006) show stock returns are negatively related to composite equity issues. 3 Accruals Sloan (1996) shows that firms with high accruals earn lower average returns compared to firms with low accruals. 4 Net operating assets Hirshleifer et al. (2004) find net operating assets are negatively associated with long-run stock returns. 5 Asset growth Cooper et al. (2008) find companies that grow their total assets more earn lower subsequent returns. 6 Investment to assets Titman et al. (2004) show that higher past investment predicts lower future returns. 7 Distress Campbell et al. (2008) show that firms with high failure probability have lower rather than higher subsequent returns. 8 O-score Ohlson (1980) finds firms with high bankruptcy risk earn lower than average returns. 9 Momentum Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) find that high (low) past recent returns forecast high (low) future returns. 10 Gross profitability premium Novy-Marx (2013) finds gross profitability positively predicts returns. 11 Return on assets Fama and French (2006) find that more profitable firms have higher expected returns than less profitable firms. associated with $0.0057 of additional long–short monthly profit on a strategy with $1 in each leg of the spread. stock returns (Baker and Wurgler, 2006; Bali et al., 2017). Our results reported in Table 3 are consistent with previous findings. Furthermore, we consider a set of sensitivity analysis and find our results, reported in Table 4, hold when we (i) consider equal-weighted returns, (ii) use alphas with respect to Fama and French’s (1993) three-factor model, or (iii) exclude the period of financial turmoil in 2007–2008. 4. Alternative explanations and sensitivity analysis We control for a wide set of macroeconomic variables that can influence both investor attention and mispricing in the stock market to ensure that they are not the drivers of our attention– anomaly results. We focus on the aggregate mispricing measure as the mispricing score diversifies away noise related to individual anomalies and hence is a robust measure of mispricing (Stambaugh et al., 2015). Specifically, we control for market sentiment, market volatility, and other macroeconomic variables, including GDP per capita, inflation, employment, business cycle, industrial production, compensation, and macroeconomic uncertainty, as these variables can be priced in the cross-section of 5. Conclusion This paper finds that anomalies are generally stronger following high rather than low attention periods. long–short returns of a composite mispricing score constructed based on all anomalies during high attention months are more pronounced than during low attention periods. Our study highlights the roles of investor attention, an important cognitive resource, in understanding the efficiency of capital markets. 4 H.T. Nguyen and M.H. Pham Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance 29 (2021) 100451 Data availability Hirshleifer, D., Hou, K., Teoh, S.H., Zhang, Y., 2004. Do investors overvalue firms with bloated balance sheets?. J. Account. Econ. 38, 297–331. Hirshleifer, D., Lim, S.S., Teoh, S.H., 2009. Driven to distraction: Extraneous events and underreaction to earnings news. J. Financ. 64 (5), 2289–2325. Hou, K., Xiong, W., Peng, L., 2009. A tale of two anomalies: The implications of investor attention for price and earnings momentum. Working Paper. Ohio State University. Hou, K., Xue, C., Zhang, L., 2020. Replicating anomalies. Rev. Financ. Stud. 33 (5), 2019–2133. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhy131. Jegadeesh, N., Titman, S., 1993. Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency. J. Financ. 48 (1), 65–91. Jurado, K., Ludvigson, S.C., Ng, S., 2015. Measuring uncertainty. Am. Econ. Rev 105 (3), 1177–1216. Kahneman, D., 1973. Attention and Effort. vol. 1063. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Loughran, T., Ritter, J.R., 1995. The new issues puzzle. J. Financ. 50 (1), 23–51. McLean, R.D., Pontiff, J., 2016. Does academic research destroy stock return predictability?. J. Financ. 71 (1), 5–32. Newey, Whitney. K., West, Kenneth. D., 1987. A simple, positive semidefinite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55, 703–708. Novy-Marx, R., 2013. The other side of value: The gross profitability premium. J. Financ. Econ. 108 (1), 1–28. Ohlson, J.A., 1980. Financial ratios and the probabilistic prediction of bankruptcy. J. Account. Res. 10, 9–131. Peng, L., Xiong, W., 2006. Investor attention,overconfidence and category learning. J. Financ. Econ. 80 (3), 563–602. Sharpe, W.F., 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J. Finance 19 (3), 425–442. Sloan, R.G., 1996. Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flows about future earnings?. Account. Rev. 289–315. Stambaugh, R.F., Yu, J., Yuan, Y., 2012. The short of it: Investor sentiment and anomalies. J. Financ. Econ. 104 (2), 288–302. Stambaugh, R.F., Yu, J., Yuan, Y., 2014. The long of it: Odds that investor sentiment spuriously predicts anomaly returns. J. Financ. Econ. 114 (3), 613–619. Stambaugh, R.F., Yu, J., Yuan, Y., 2015. Arbitrage asymmetry and the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle. J. Financ. 70 (5), 1903–1948. Stambaugh, R.F., Yuan, Y., 2017. Mispricing factors. Rev. Financ. Stud. 30 (4), 1270–1315. Titman, S., Wei, K.J., Xie, F., 2004. Capital investments and stock returns. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 39 (4), 677–700. Data are available from the data sources identified in the paper. Appendix See Table A.1. References Baker, M., Wurgler, J., 2006. Investor sentiment and the cross-section of stock returns. J. Financ. 61 (4), 1645–1680. Bali, T.G., Brown, S.J., Tang, Y., 2017. Is economic uncertainty priced in the cross-section of stock returns?. J. Financ. Econ. 126 (3), 471–489. Barber, B.M., Odean, T., 2008. All that glitters: The effect of attention and news on the buying behavior of individual and institutional investors. Rev. Financ. Stud. 21 (2), 785–818. Barber, B.M., Odean, T., 2013. The behavior of individual investors. In: In Handbook of the Economics of Finance, 2, Elsevier, pp. 1533–1570. Barberis, N., Thaler, R., 2003. A survey of behavioral finance. In: Handbook of the Economics of Finance, 1, pp. 1053–1128. Branch, B., 2014. Institutional economics and behavioral finance. J. Behav. Exp. Financ. 1, 13–16. Campbell, J.Y., Hilscher, J., Szilagyi, J., 2008. In search of distress risk. J. Financ. 63 (6), 2899–2939. Chen, J., Tang, G., Yao, J., Zhou, G., 2019. Investor Attention and Stock Returns. Working paper. Washington University in St. Louis. Cooper, M.J., Gulen, H., Schill, M.J., 2008. Asset growth and the cross-section of stock returns. J. Financ. 63 (4), 1609–1651. Daniel, K., Titman, S., 2006. Market reactions to tangible and intangible information. J. Financ. 61 (4), 1605–1643. Fama, E.F., French, K.R., 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. J. Financ. Econ. 33, 3–56. Fama, E.F., French, K.R., 2006. Profitability investment and average returns. J. Financ. Econ. 82 (3), 491–518. Gabaix, X., 2019. Behavioral inattention. In: Handbook of Behavioral Economics: Applications and Foundations 2. pp. 261–343. Hirshleifer, D., 2001. Investor psychology and asset pricing. J. Finance 56 (4), 1533–1597. 5