Accepted Manuscript A general equilibrium analysis of FDI growth in Chinese services sectors María C. Latorre, Hidemichi Yonezawa, Jing Zhou PII: DOI: Reference: S1043-951X(17)30121-9 doi: 10.1016/j.chieco.2017.09.002 CHIECO 1103 To appear in: China Economic Review Received date: Revised date: Accepted date: 9 September 2016 27 July 2017 1 September 2017 Please cite this article as: María C. Latorre, Hidemichi Yonezawa, Jing Zhou , A general equilibrium analysis of FDI growth in Chinese services sectors, China Economic Review (2017), doi: 10.1016/j.chieco.2017.09.002 This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain. ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT A general equilibrium analysis of FDI growth in Chinese services sectors María C. Latorre (Universidad Complutense de Madrid) Hidemichi Yonezawa (ETH Zurich) PT Jing Zhou (Xiangtan University) Abstract AC CE PT E D MA NU SC RI This paper analyzes one of the features of the Chinese economic transition, namely, the impact of foreign direct investment (FDI) accruing to advanced services sectors. To that aim we use an innovative computable general equilibrium (CGE) model that includes, in a multi-regional setting, foreign multinationals operating in monopolistic competition. The model is based on data that split the world economy in 2016 into 11 regions (China - US - EU27 - Great Britain other advanced economies - India - Japan - South East Asia - Latin America - Middle East - Sub Saharan Africa) and 21 sectors. We provide quantitative evidence on several characteristics of the 21 sectors in China, EU27 and the US, as well as other data on the role of China in the global stage, including its evolution since 2004. Several scenarios focusing on the increase of FDI inflows in services, because of the reduction of its FDI barriers, are simulated deriving short and long run results. We find that the impact of more foreign multinationals in services is positive for China but smaller than the one that had been obtained in other previous studies on FDI in manufactures. This is due to the still limited role of services in the Chinese economy and to a crowding out effect that domestic firms experience after the entry of foreign multinationals. On the whole the impact is, however, slightly positive for China, because manufactures benefit from the entry of foreign services multinationals. The rest of regions are unaffected or benefit very slightly, due to the fact that services production is less export oriented and more devoted to private consumption than in the case of manufactures. However, their manufacturing sectors are slightly harmed by the stronger Chinese competition. Many of them manage to more than offset this latter trend through higher exports or FDI in services directed to China. JEL codes: C68, F14, F15, F17, F21 Keywords: Multinationals, CGE, monopolistic competition, fragmentation, vertical integration, consumption-oriented growth. Corresponding author: María C. Latorre. Facultad de Estudios Estadísticos, Universidad Complutense de Madrid, Avda. Puerta de Hierro s/n, Ciudad Universitaria, 28040-Madrid. Tel. (34) 91 394 3990 Fax: (34) 91 394 4024 Email: mmunozla@ucm.es 1 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT A general equilibrium analysis of FDI growth in Chinese services sectors Abstract CE PT E D MA NU SC RI PT This paper analyzes one of the features of the Chinese economic transition, namely, the impact of foreign direct investment (FDI) accruing to advanced services sectors. To that aim we use an innovative computable general equilibrium (CGE) model that includes, in a multi-regional setting, foreign multinationals operating in monopolistic competition. The model is based on data that split the world economy in 2016 into 11 regions (China - US - EU27 - Great Britain other advanced economies - India - Japan - South East Asia - Latin America - Middle East - Sub Saharan Africa) and 21 sectors. We provide quantitative evidence on several characteristics of the 21 sectors in China, EU27 and the US, as well as other data on the role of China in the global stage, including its evolution since 2004. Several scenarios focusing on the increase of FDI inflows in services, because of the reduction of its FDI barriers, are simulated deriving short and long run results. We find that the impact of more foreign multinationals in services is positive for China but smaller than the one that had been obtained in other previous studies on FDI in manufactures. This is due to the still limited role of services in the Chinese economy and to a crowding out effect that domestic firms experience after the entry of foreign multinationals. On the whole the impact is, however, slightly positive for China, because manufactures benefit from the entry of foreign services multinationals. The rest of regions are unaffected or benefit very slightly, due to the fact that services production is less export oriented and more devoted to private consumption than in the case of manufactures. However, their manufacturing sectors are slightly harmed by the stronger Chinese competition. Many of them manage to more than offset this latter trend through higher exports or FDI in services directed to China. AC JEL codes: C68, F14, F15, F17, F21 Keywords: Multinationals, CGE, monopolistic competition, fragmentation, vertical integration, consumption-oriented growth. 2 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 1. Introduction NU SC RI PT Despite the recent lower rates of economic growth in China, FDI inflows have not ceased to increase and are becoming more oriented to services. The latest World Investment Report (2016, p. 45) asserts: “In China, inflows [in 2015] rose by 6 per cent to $136 billion and continued to shift towards services, which accounted for a new record of 61 per cent of FDI. Inflows to the sector expanded by 17 per cent, while FDI into manufacturing stagnated”. Furthermore, according to the OECD (2017), the 2015 edition of the “Catalogue for the Guidance of Foreign Investment Industries”, which governs FDI, is aimed at liberalizing some services sectors. The OECD (2017) also highlights that the China’s 13th Five-Year-Plan (20162020) aims at raising the share of services in GDP1. In addition, due to the US withdrawal from the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), China will probably strengthen its position as a destination of FDI in services. Against this background, in this paper, we analyze the impact of the increase of FDI in Chinese services sectors. We cover the effects for China but also for other regions of the world. To that aim, we use a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of the world economy split in 11 regions (China - US - EU27 - Great Britain - other advanced economies India - Japan - South East Asia - Latin America - Middle East – Sub Saharan Africa) and 21 sectors for the year 2016. AC CE PT E D MA A general equilibrium analysis has several advantages. It is based on a robust theoretical framework and uses a broad set of real micro and macroeconomic data. Thus, the results cover several micro and macroeconomic variables, including, sectoral production, exports, imports and prices, together with GDP, wages, capital remuneration, welfare, aggregate exports, aggregate imports and the Consumer Price Index, respectively. The model includes the interactions between goods and factor markets, as well as the supply and demand side of the economy in a unified framework. It seems intuitive that there must be some relationships across all these different variables and possible perspectives in the economy in order to properly estimate the impact of FDI. However, the literatures analyzing them tend to be disconnected. In the international business literature, the analysis focuses often within the multinational. This idea underlies the comments of Meyer (2004: 260-1): “international business research has been largely looking into the multinational, rather than ‘looking out’ from multinationals to the societies in which they are operating” and that “One of the challenges is to tie the partial views discussed in different literatures together to allow 1 China is opening up its services sectors step by step. After successful pilot-run in a few cities, liberalization will be carried out across different regions. Some sectors like retail and wholesale, education, construction, computer services and logistics have already a relatively low barrier for foreign investment. Banking, insurance, healthcare, air and maritime transport, telecoms and broadcasting are under way of liberalization. Due to the significance of real estate to Chinese economy, the authority is cautious about its liberalization. China hopes to restructure its economy and regards as valuable the role of services in economic growth. It has made great efforts in services negotiations in Doha, GATS and WTO, as well as in Trade in Services Agreement (TISA). 3 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT comprehensive assessments” (Meyer, 2004: 261). CGE models belong more to the economic literature (Shoven and Whalley, 1984; Latorre et al., 2009). NU SC RI PT Our model incorporates the real data on different types of costs and production destination across the sectors and regions we consider. This microeconomic detail contrasts with the approach of a few more stylized multi-country general equilibrium models which explicitly consider FDI (such as, Arkolakis et al., 2015; Arita et al. 2014; Burstein and Monge-Naranjo, 2009; McGrattan and Prescott, 2009; Ramondo, 2013; Ramondo and Rogríguez-Clare, 2013). These latter studies do not offer any impact across sectors in the economy, since their analyses have relied in most cases on aggregates of manufacturing sectors, which we disaggregate, while we also cover services and indeed, the entire economy. Our model further incorporates an innovative feature, which is the introduction of three characteristics that to the best of our knowledge are not available in any previous CGE model: multiregional framework, monopolistic imperfect competition and foreign multinationals. Very few CGE models have considered the presence of FDI flows and foreign multinationals. Tarr (2012) and Latorre (2009) review the few available ones. Furthermore, even less CGE models have looked at the impact of FDI going to services. AC CE PT E D MA Zhou and Latorre (2014a; 2014b; 2015) have focused on the impact of FDI in Chinese manufacturing sectors. In those papers, we find that FDI inflows generally raise GDP, wages, national income and welfare considerably in China. However, the magnitude of the impact depends on the particular sector to which FDI accrues. In particular, the results depend on whether it is an export or private consumption oriented sector and on whether it relies more heavily on imported or on domestic intermediates. FDI in manufacturing usually raises exports, which tends to crowd out other foreign competitors but raise the demand for imported intermediates coming from other Asian suppliers. Regions with a GDP structure and export specialization similar to the one of China are crowded out by tougher Chinese competition after the arrival of FDI. By contrast, regions that exhibit a structure of production and exports, which complements the one of China in the global value chain, get better off after FDI inflows in China. Other studies have also found a close relationship between FDI inflows and the Chinese impressive growth rates achieved in the last decades (e.g., Kim et al., 2003, Whalley and Xin, 2010). Furthermore, FDI seems to play an important role in Chinese foreign trade (e.g., Dean et al., 2009). Koopman et al. (2014) have shown that only around 40-50% of the value added embodied in Chinese exports is created in China, the rest being imported from Japan, Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong and the US. In the case of some electronics devices the share of foreign content in exports even rises to 80%. However, as we have already noted, the focus of all these previous analyses has been primarily on the impact of FDI in manufacturing. Interestingly, the impact of FDI in services may be different than the one in manufacturing due to several reasons. First, because services’ production is less devoted to the external market than that of goods, their effects work differently. As we shall see below, one important characteristic of services sectors is that they are more oriented to domestic activities than to exports. This contrasts, sharply, with manufacturing sectors, whose products cross borders more easily than services. This trend will reinforce the change in the former Chinese exportoriented FDI and growth strategy. It seems that FDI in services will contribute to the shift from the Chinese export-led growth to a consumption-led growth pattern. 4 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT PT Second, Konan and Maskus (2006) and Konan and Kim (2004) derive for developing economies, that the relative poor condition of domestic services with respect to services in developed countries, results in high costs and unproductive input services. Since many of these services, such as, finance, communications and business services provide key intermediates for all sectors of the economy, better foreign intermediates would contribute to overall productivity. Latorre and Yonezawa (2017) and Latorre et al., (2015) also obtain this result in the context of developed economies in their analysis of the potential impact of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP). In this case, foreign intermediates provided by the affiliates of multinationals provide a wider variety of inputs that raise exports in manufacturing and contribute to overall GDP and welfare growth. NU SC RI Third, services liberalization brings about gains to the economy that are more evenly distributed across sectors and factors owners than in the case of goods. Indeed, goods’ liberalization through tariff reductions results in the specialization of an economy in a few sectors in which abundant factors benefit disproportionately (Konan and Maskus, 2006; Konan and Kim, 2004). Latorre et al. (2009) and Latorre (2013; 2012) have also found these concentration effects after the entry of FDI in manufacturing sectors in contrast with FDI accruing to services sectors. Such redistribution impacts are absent or milder after services liberalization because their contribution in the form of better intermediates for all sectors tends to raise production and factors’ income in a more balanced way. AC CE PT E D MA Fourth, barriers to foreign services are different than the ones experienced by FDI in goods or trade in goods. Many cross border services’ transactions do not involve tangible products so that customs and port clearance procedures are generally less relevant for services. Konan and Van Assche (2007) delve into this important aspect. They derive that the success of services liberalization is related to issues of market structure and domestic regulation. One key resulting issue is the quality of the technology of the foreign firms, in particular, whether they are more efficient than the incumbent firms. Unless the former is more efficient than the latter, there will not be beneficial productivity effects due to the use of better intermediates across sectors. Another important issue is to promote through pro-competitive regulatory reforms, that the new entrants will not collude but compete with incumbents. This should ensure that prices of intermediates and final goods will go down since there is more competition. In our present analysis, we simulate the increase of FDI inflows going to services after the reductions of the (mostly regulatory) barriers they face in China. This matches the current policy orientation of the government regarding the attraction of FDI in services. It is also consistent with the rising importance of FDI in services versus that of manufacturing. The particular services we analyze are water transport, air transport, communications, finance, insurance and business services. The existent barriers in those sectors are rather high, when we compare them with the ones faced by multinationals in other large regions such as the EU27 or the US. We estimate such impact in the short and long run on China and also derive their effects for the rest of regions considered in our CGE model. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we put the Chinese economy in the world context and discuss several of its important characteristics relying on detailed sectoral 5 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT data. Section 3 explains the model, data and simulations. Section 4 presents the outcomes for China of several scenarios of increases of FDI inflows. Within the results section we also perform a sensitivity analysis. A final section of summary and conclusions closes the paper. 2. China in the world economy SC RI PT In this section we offer an overview of several characteristics of the Chinese economy. We begin with the data on the GDP and exports’ composition in the years 2004 and 20162. Table 1 offers the weight of each sector in total GDP and exports in China and in the world economy as a whole. In addition, the last column of each year presents the weight of China in the world economy. The rows display the 21 sectors of the model, together with some summarizing figures of “All manufactures” (which includes other primary and construction) and “All services”. Appendix one offers sectors’ definitions and their conversions across several classifications. D MA NU The weight of Chinese GDP in the world economy has risen from 5.0% in 2004 to 13.3% in 2016. As shown at the bottom of the last columns for each year, the weight is higher in manufacturing sectors turning from 7.0 to 17.7 from 2004 till 2016, than in services where the figures are of 3.3. and 9.6, respectively. In 2016, China still exhibits a very low share of services sectors in its GDP (of 45.7%), not just compared with advanced economies but also with respect to the world average (which is of 63.3%). This indicates there is a natural process ahead of turning more and more into a services economy while development unfolds. The other side of the coin is that the weight of manufactures in the Chinese economy (41.9%) is still very high compared to world standards (31.4%)3. 2 AC CE PT E Chinese overall exports have risen from 8.8% in 2004 of total world exports to 12.8% in 2016. Chinese trade is dominated by manufacturing goods, which constitute 93.9% of its total trade in 2016. In general, world trade is mostly of manufactures (81.5% in 2016) and has not changed much in the latest years, since it was 81% in 2004. However, we can see that this pattern is considerably more marked in China4. The share of Chinese manufacturing trade in the world for all manufactures rises from 10.1% in 2004 to 14.8% in 2016. For some sectors, such as textiles (43.6%), electronics (35.6%), other manufactures (31.2%) the Chinese shares in world trade are impressive, well beyond the importance of those sectors within the Chinese We cover the longest period available in the latest release of the GTAP9A Database from May 2016. Note that the GTAP database uses variables measured in nominal prices from the World Bank “Word Development Indicators”, it would be an immense effort to deflate so many variables across sectors for the world economy. In that sense, it is underestimating the actual shift to services that China has already experienced according to other sources in which services already account for 50.5% of GDP in 2015, while manufacturing including construction, mining and utilities accounts for 40.5% (KPMG, 2016; OECD, 2017). There is a trade-off between accuracy in the data and being able to put the Chinese economy in a world context. Issues like re-exports are dealt carefully by the GTAP team, which use United Nations COMTRADE for their calculations. 3 4 In some regions, such as Great Britain (32.6%), India (28.1) and EU27 (22.0%) trade in services is above the world average. This will be important for our results later on. 6 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT export structure. Indeed, they account for 15.9%, 22.8% and 6.5% in total Chinese exports, respectively. SC RI PT Table 2 further looks at the sectoral detail by analyzing the destination of imports accruing to China, the EU27 and the US and the destination of production in those regions. In other words, the table presents the percentage of imports and production that go to private consumption or are intermediates for further processing in each sector5. We can see that in the three regions most of the trade is of intermediates. This resembles the intense process of fragmentation present in the world economy (Koopman et al, 2014). However, this trend is even more pronounced in China, whose shares of intermediate imports are much larger than in the US and EU27. The Asiatic giant also stands out due to the very low share of imports that are related to private consumption. China has exhibited very high rates of savings for years, which goes hand in hand with lower rates of private and public consumption6. It is important to note that imports from services sectors tend to be more oriented to private consumption in the three regions than imports from manufacturing. PT E D MA NU Table 2 also presents the destination of production across sectors. Although most of the production is devoted to intermediates for further processing, in China this tendency is more accentuated. Again, as happened with imports, the production devoted to private consumption is in China, in general, much smaller than in the US and EU. The EU27 stands out as a very active exporter, who exhibits enormous shares of exports. China has reduced its export intensity in 2016, compared to the data from 2004. This contrasts with the trend in the EU27 which has increased it for the same period. In all regions the share of production devoted to exports is much more reduced in services’ sectors than in manufacturing. This trend is even more pronounced in China. Further, as happened with imports, services sectors production tends to be more oriented to private consumption than the one from manufactures. CE All in all, Table 2 shows that China has its own peculiarities. In 2016 its production and imports are very oriented to intermediates’ production and to exports. China is indeed the “factory of the world”. On the other hand, we see that the nature of services’ sectors differs considerably from manufacturing sectors. Services are more oriented to private consumption and less oriented to exports. AC Figure 1 shows data related to the level of protection from the operations of foreign multinationals in advanced services sectors in China, the EU27 and the US. In particular, the numbers are the costs (in percentage of total costs) of undertaking all procedures necessary to operate in the host economies7. As can be seen, Chinese protection is really high compared to 5 The shares related to investment and public consumption are omitted in Table 2 to facilitate the analysis of the main patterns. In the case of production the share devoted to exports is also included. 6 We have deeply analyzed the consequences of these patterns for the impact of FDI in several manufacturing sectors in Zhou and Latorre (2014a; 2014b; 2015). 7 Technically these costs are called “Ad valorem equivalents (AVEs)”, which quantify existing restrictions to the operations of foreign multinationals providing an estimation of their corresponding percentage cost equivalence. These restrictions may take the form of red tape, accumulation of procedures, payments, time to complete formalities. . . etc. The larger the AVEs the more costly it is for firms to 7 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT the other two regions. We know the government is trying to open up these and other advanced manufacturing sectors for private investment (OECD, 2017; KPMG, 2016). As a consequence, these barriers should go down, thus, bringing about important costs reductions for foreign multinationals. This is exactly the approach that we model in order to estimate the impact of FDI in services8. NU SC RI PT The more sizeable the reductions in barriers are, the stronger the cost savings for potential entrant firms9. This is the way in which FDI is endogenized in our model. Note that these barriers, on the one hand, hinder competition and provide rents for incumbent firms. On the other hand, they also may cause inefficiencies (bureaucracy, red tape…etc.) which imply a waste of resources10. In addition, the larger the reductions in costs the stronger the pressure for lower prices of intermediates provided by foreign firms. In other words, if foreign entrants experience larger costs savings, due to the liberalization of barriers, more of them will accrue to services sectors thus increasing competition and lowering prices of the goods they provide. To analyze the channel by which other sectors benefit from the provision of foreign intermediates, we need to look at what is the weight in total costs per sector of the use of intermediates coming from advanced services sectors. These are the data shown in Table 3. AC CE PT E D MA Table 3 presents the cost of intermediates coming from advanced services sectors per unit of production. Advanced services sectors are the ones that have foreign multinationals, namely, water transport, air transport, communication, finance, insurance and business services. For example, the value of 2.3% in Chinese agriculture means that from the total costs of production in agriculture only 2.3% are related to payments to providers of intermediates coming from advanced services sectors. We again put Chinese data in perspective with respect to the EU27 and to the US. Intermediates coming from business services sectors play a smaller role in China than in the EU27 and in the US. Only a few exceptions appear in water and air transport, which are two very small sectors. operate in a particular sector. Jafari and Tarr (2015) explain the different sources consulted to econometrically derive the AVEs. The data are publicly available. 8 Unfortunately, there are no estimations of these barriers to FDI in manufacturing sectors, so other approaches are necessary to model its impact in these sectors. For example, Latorre and Hosoe (2016) model FDI in manufacturing in China using detailed microeconomic information in a dynamic context. 9 We will later see that we assume reductions in barriers to FDI of 25% and 50%. These costs’ reductions are modelled as iceberg trade costs reductions. In the algebraic description of the model (Appendix 3) the iceberg costs are for simplicity, included in the price PY of equation (10). 10 We assume that 60% of the costs of the barriers are efficiency losses, while 40% create rents. Due to the lack of other data, we rely on the study of Francois et al. (2013) for this assumption. Their estimations are for the same sectors and are based on business surveys, consultations with regulators and sector experts as well as on literature reviews, but their sources come mainly from the US and the EU. Konan and Maskus (2016) show that eliminating barriers that create inefficiencies brings about more sizeable GDP and welfare increases than the same percentage elimination of barriers that create rents. In the latter case incumbent firms in the host economy gain some rent from the barriers, while in the former case nobody gains from the barriers. 8 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 3. The model, data and simulations The main data we use is the latest available GTAP database version 9 (Narayanan et al., 2016). This is a database for the world economy which offers information for 140 regions (most of which are the countries) and 57 sectors. Using GEMPACK or GAMS software the data can be aggregated to different regions and sectoral configurations. The GTAP 9 covers the years 2004, 2007 and 2011. We have taken the data from 2004 and 2011, but have updated the latest one using GDP growth rates from 2012 till 2015 using the IMF world economic outlook (IMF, 2016). Thus our final year is 201611. NU SC RI PT The data on barriers to foreign multinationals come from the publicly available database created at the World Bank (Jafari and Tarr, 2015). We model two different conservative cuts of 50% and 25%. In the literature of FDI in services summarized in Tarr (2012) usually 50% cuts have been simulated, while Konan and Van Assche (2007), Konan and Maskus (2006) , as well as Konan and Kim (2004) eliminate the full barriers, which, additionally, tend to be larger than the ones we find for China. The share in sales of foreign multinationals in advanced services sectors across the different regions are from the US International Trade Commission Database (Fukui and Lakatos, 2012)12. MA As noted before, we use a CGE model which has several innovative features. In particular, the simultaneous consideration of three characteristics: monopolistic competition, a multiregional framework and foreign multinationals in advanced services sectors had not previously been achieved to the best of our knowledge13. 11 CE PT E D Our model extends the multiregional framework of Balistreri et al. (2015) by including the imperfect competition setting in the sectors with foreign multinationals and a long run steady state simulation which goes beyond its short run impact. Balistreri et al. (2015) had, in turn, extended the small open economy framework of Balistreri and Tarr (2011), and of other single country models, such as Rutherford and Tarr (2008) and Latorre (2016). As already noted, only a few CGE models include the operations of multinationals. For a long time, this has only be possible in a single country framework (e.g., Konan and Van Assche, 2007; Konan and Maskus, AC This procedure does not update the entire production structure for the single countries and economic regions we analyze, since in a multiregional setting we need a harmonized dataset. However, it takes into account important changes in the size of the regions during the period 2011-2015, according to IMF data. This seems of relevance given the differences across regions. China and India exhibit the largest growth with a 33% and 29.6%, respectively, in that period. They are followed by Southeast Asia and SubSaharan Africa with 19%. The smallest increase is the one experienced in EU27 (without the UK) with a 2.3% increase in GDP for the entire period. In addition, Chinese Input-Output tables are only available every five years. The latest one was for the year 2012 and was used to construct the GTAP9 database, thus, the next one is expected to reflect the 2017 data. 12 These data probably underestimate the current shares in sales of foreign multinationals, coming from different areas of the globe, operating in China. However, we have not found any other source to proxy their actual sales. 13 We use this model for the analysis of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) with a different regional configuration, benchmark year and set of simulations in Latorre and Yonezawa (2017), which is still an unpublished paper. Recently, Olekseyuk (2016) has also introduced FDI in a framework of imperfectly competition, but FDI is modelled only in the region in which the analysis focuses, namely, Ukraine, while it is absent in the rest of regions in the model. Most notably, Oleseyuk’s model includes heterogeneous firms in manufacturing in her multiregional framework. 9 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 2006; Konan and Kim, 2004; Latorre et al., 2009; Latorre 2012; Latorre 2013). However, when a multiregional framework is used, we can fully incorporate the foreign economies and keep track of the impact on foreign countries, as well as the impact on China14. Also, the effects of FDI creation and diversion among different host countries can be traced, much in the same way as trade diversion or creation cannot be captured in a single country model but only in a multi-regional setting (e.g., Ortiz and Latorre, 2017). MA NU SC RI PT The model has three types of sectors: 1) Manufacturing sectors with economies of scale and monopolistic competition (chemicals, electronics, automobiles, textiles and other manufacturing); 2) Advanced services sectors with foreign multinationals, which also have economies of scale and monopolistic competition (water transport, air transport, communication, finance, insurance and business services); 3) Perfect competition, which consist of the rest of manufacturing and services sectors, that have not been included in the previous groups, as well as agriculture. We follow the literature, especially Francois et al. (2013), in defining which sectors should be modelled under perfect or imperfect competition. However, the issue is not exempt from difficulties. In a latter paper analyzing the same issues as Francois et al. 2013, Egger et al. (2015, pp. 551-2) derive a taxonomy based on trade elasticities in which large (small) negative values imply a more (less) competitive sector. While their data suggest that Motor vehicles, Other machinery and Energy production exhibit monopolistic competition and economies of scale, elasticities’ values for the rest of sectors look more similar, which makes their classification complicated15. PT E D In the perfect competition sectors firms produce with constant returns to scale. Products differ according to their country of origin. In other words, an Armington (1969) specification is used so that each region in the model produces a specific variety, which is an imperfect substitute for varieties coming from other regions. This Armington assumption grasps the empirical evidence that countries trade different varieties of the same good or service. 14 AC CE The imperfect competition sectors are modelled as Dixit-Stiglitz monopolistic competition, following Krugman (1980) and Helpman and Krugman (1985). This implies that a growing number of varieties of a product (either through more domestic firms, exports or a higher number of foreign affiliates) leads to potential increases in both consumers’ welfare and producers’ productivity. The latter effect arises because with more firms and higher competition the intermediates they produce become cheaper, which helps to save costs in production for the firms using them. There is empirical evidence of FDI in services leading to To the extent that the change in the foreign economies does affect Chinese economy (through the change in trade of these foreign countries and China), even if we were only interested in China, incorporating a multi-regional framework is of relevance. 15 Furthermore, our sectors’ conversion from GTAP is not exactly the same as in Egger et al. (2015) and Francois et al. (2013). In addition, other problems arise. For example, real estate and health services fit well in an oligopoly structure, since only few giant companies dominate the supply, while the barriers to foreign capital are still high. Our simulation tries to evaluate the impact of lower barriers in business sectors, which comprises real estate and the housing market. But business sectors, as reflected in Appendix 1 also comprises other sectors, such as, legal and accounting activities, engineering activities, advertising and market research, etc., which tend to be better proxied by monopolistic competition. In fact, following business services liberalization, the supply would be larger and households would benefit from lower prices due to the entry of more competitors. Although, it is also true that in the case of real estate there is a very strict limit in their expansion arising from the supply of land. 10 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT higher productivity in other sectors of the economy using panel data and controlling for the endogeneity of FDI (e.g., Fernandes and Paunov, 2012; Arnold et al., 2008). These results have been well established more generally in the literature (e.g., Broda and Weinstein, 2006 and Goldberg et al., 2009). RI PT In each region there is a representative consumer whose income stems from all factors’ remunerations. She fully spends her income in private consumption, which is the component of final expenditure that adjusts in the model. Public spending remains constant in real terms to avoid the distortions that its variation would bring about. So does investment, except in the long run formulation in which the capital stock adjusts in order to maintain the initial rate of return of capital. The intuition behind this is that in the long run firms can adjust their capital stocks across sectors in the economy. Technically, for this steady state formulation we follow the approach of Balistreri et al. (2016). MA NU SC The model includes a rich description of different types of costs with their corresponding taxes across sectors, as well as abundant information on trade patters with different tariffs by sector. Our model differentiates the impact of FDI flows according to the services’ sector to which they accrue, which is in accordance with the fact that the effects of multinationals vary across sectors (e.g., Smarzinska, 2004). We also include the impact of profit repatriation that is assumed to be 50% in all the results we analyze. This issue is of importance according to previous evidence (Konan and Van Aschee, 2007; Latorre et al., 2009; Gómez-Plana and Latorre, 2014). D Appendix 3 presents the algebraic description of the model. PT E 4. Results 4. 1 Impact on the Chinese economy AC CE Table 4 displays in its rows the impact on the main macroeconomic variables, namely, welfare (measured as Hicksian equivalence of consumption), GDP, wages, capital remuneration, aggregate exports, aggregate imports and the Consumer Price Index (CPI). The results are available for the short run (2-3 years, approximately), as well as for the long run impact (more than 4 years after the shock). The columns present cuts by 50% and 25% in the costs related to the barriers faced by the foreign firms in advanced services sectors. The figures should be interpreted as annual percentage changes in the years coming after the barriers have been reduced. The entry of foreign multinationals in advanced services sectors would increase Chinese welfare by nearly one third of a percentage point (0.31%) annually in the short run, if barriers are reduced by 50%. There would be a mild increase in wages and capital remuneration. The GDP would also go up slightly. Aggregate imports and exports would rise somewhat more heavily. The CPI would go down benefitting consumers. To understand these results we can think that the entry of foreign multinationals brings more economic activity, thus, raising 11 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT wages and in some cases, as here, also the capital remuneration16. This, in turn, increases GDP and private consumption, to which our measure of welfare is related. The increases in production related to the presence of the foreign multinationals have an impact on foreign trade. Multinationals tend to rely more on imported intermediates for their production than national firms do17. SC RI PT In the long run, the capital stock expands such that the capital return stays the same. The capital stock expansion contributes to the positive effect on the economy although it comes with the increase in investment spending18. This setting of the long run results in a small increase relative to the short run. The only exception would be welfare, whose percentage increase is smaller than in the short run. Even though capital remuneration and wages would increase more heavily in the long run, the resulting larger national income would be allocated to a smaller extent to private consumption (a trend that would be welfare enhancing) than to investment. This implies smaller welfare gains compared to the ones exhibited by the rest of macroeconomic aggregates, when moving from the short run to the long run. CE PT E D MA NU All in all, the entry of more foreign multinationals would bring a positive, but rather limited, impact on the Chinese economy. To put these results in perspective we can compare them with the ones obtained for developing countries such as Tunisia and Egypt in the analyses of Konan and Kim (2004), Konan and Maskus (2006) and Konan and Van Assche (2007). These authors derive much larger positive impacts than the ones we obtain for China. This can be explained by the already alluded to fact that their barriers are larger than ours and they assume they would be fully eliminated. They, however, assume different climates of competition (either oligopolistic or perfect competition), which makes the comparison more complicated. We can also contrasts our results with the ones derived for the US and the EU28 in Latorre and Yonezawa (2017) in the same climate of imperfect competition. This is interesting given the fact that, as noted above, the barriers to FDI are considerably lower in the EU28 and US than in China. A 0.36% (0.25%) and 0.43% (0.37%) welfare (GDP) increase are obtained in the long run for a 25% reduction of the FDI barriers for the EU28 and the US, respectively. 16 AC We believe two important forces make the impact of FDI in China smaller in the comparison versus the EU 28 and the US. First, the weight of services in the Chinese economy is much more reduced than in the TTIP partners, as we saw above in the data. Furthermore, we also saw, that the role of services sectors as suppliers of intermediates for downstream sectors was In other studies of the impact of FDI in China, such as Zhou and Latorre (2015) and Zhou and Latorre (2014a, 2014b), we have obtained that FDI would reduce capital remuneration. In contrast with the models used in those papers, this one has imperfect competition and economies of scale. 17 This is confirmed by the study of Latorre and Hosoe (2016), who explicitly analyze the differences in costs of Japanese multinationals versus domestic firms across manufacturing sectors in China using very detailed data. It is also confirmed in Latorre (2013, 2014), who also looks at costs differences using a rich dataset to analyze multinationals in the Czech Republic. 18 Following the capital accumulation equation with steady state condition, we can derive that the percentage change in capital stock equals the percentage change in investment spending. See Balistreri et al. (2016) for more details. 12 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT also more limited in China than in the EU27 and in the US. This necessarily limits several positive mechanisms usually assigned to the availability of a larger number of providers (i.e., foreign multinationals) specialized in the production of advanced services. Second, FDI in China brings about a crowding out effect that will reduce production in services sectors. Let us turn to its analysis by looking in more detail to the sectoral outcomes. PT E D MA NU SC RI PT Table 5 presents the evolution of output, exports, imports and prices in a structure analogous to the one of the aggregate outcomes. We now display the detail for all sectors. The mild reduction in output of services sectors (“all services”) reflects the presence of a crowding out effect in the advanced services (i.e., the ones with FDI) after the entry of multinationals. Because multinationals benefit in many of them from very sizeable savings in costs, they become very competitive and drive out of business some Chinese firms19. In communications, in which the initial barriers are much lower than in the rest, this crowding out effect is not present. The lower the reduction in the FDI barriers, the smaller this crowding effect and, accordingly, the reduction of output in services sectors. However, this trend in services releases labor that goes to manufacturing sectors. Because the intermediates coming from services have become cheaper, manufacturing sectors are now more competitive (their prices also go down) and can produce more, thereby increasing the demand for labor. Indeed, not only services exports increase but also the ones from manufacturing sectors. By contrast, manufacturing sectors now reduce the imports they need. Because their products are comparatively cheaper they source more domestically, whereas more multinationals coming to services sectors carry with them more imports. The reduction of prices that foreign multinationals carry with them is more sizeable the larger the reduction in the barriers. This is crucial for the competitiveness of manufacturing sectors, which constitute the bulk of Chinese exports. That is why the larger the cut in the barriers to FDI, the better for overall macroeconomic outcomes. Overall exports of the Chinese economy are stronger the more sizeable the cut in barriers and so is its total output, as can be seen, in the last row of the table. AC CE In the long run the outcomes in China for all sectors tend to be slightly better than in the short run. The fall (increase) of output experienced in services (manufacturing) sectors is smaller (larger) than in the short run. However, the differences are small since the crowding out effect is still present and most manufacturing sectors behave very similarly. 4.2 Impact on the rest of regions Recall that our model has split the world economy into 10 more regions apart from China20. In Table 6 we present the same aggregate outcomes we have analyzed before but now for all the regions. To keep the analysis (and number of tables) manageable we focus on the short and long run impact of the 50% reductions in costs related to FDI barriers. These are the ones that 19 The percentage reductions in the number of domestic firms are limited, however. Their most sizeable reduction appears in Air transport for the 50% cuts in costs. In this scenario, the number of domestic firms would go down by around -4.5% both in the long and short run, but for smaller cuts they fall by less than -2.0%. For the rest of sectors, the reductions are always below -2.0% and generally below 1.0%. 20 Appendix two has the country composition of each of the regions. 13 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT are more likely to affect the rest of regions, since they bring about the heaviest impact on China. We keep the results that have already been presented for the Chinese economy (in Table 4) to facilitate the comparison. PT E D MA NU SC RI PT It is interesting that we find no evidence of negative effects for the rest of regions when more multinationals from the services sectors come to China. This contrasts heavily with our previous results derived from the impact of FDI going to Chinese manufacturing sectors (Zhou and Latorre, 2014a, 2014b, 2015). What could explain these differences between FDI accruing to manufacturing and the ones accruing to services? On the one hand, services’ sector themselves are less oriented to exports, as we saw, in our data above. Accordingly the mechanism of transmission of the shock occurring in China to other economies is much weaker than in manufacturing sectors. On the other hand, the increases we have derived in exports from manufacturing sectors are rather modest, compared to the situation in which multinationals were going to manufacturing sectors directly. For example, in Zhou and Latorre (2014a, 2014b, 2015) we model multinationals going to the same sector of Electronics modelled here, but the benchmark is 2007 in that case. Electronics is by far the sector that is more globalized across manufacturing sectors with important international networks of production. After the entry of FDI its exports go up by around 30%, while in the results we obtain here they increase less than 1%. In Zhou and Latorre (2014b, 2015) we further analyze the impact of FDI going to the same Machinery sector we have modelled now. For this sector, exports went up by 19.6%, due to the also important international networks present in it. Following these important increases in exports, we had derived that the rest of regions (which were no more than six in those analyses) were crowded out from world markets due to the fierce Chinese competition. Some of the regions did indeed reduce their GDP and wages in accordance with other analysis undertaken from an econometric perspective focusing on manufacturing sectors (e.g., Pierce and Schott, 2016 and Autor et al., 2013). AC CE In Latorre and Yonezawa (2017) we find that after the TTIP other areas could be slightly crowded out, with the notable exception of China. However, the bulk of the analysis includes not only the impact of barriers to FDI but also to trade. Note that the TTIP regions together account for a larger share of trade and GDP than China alone does. However, when we confine the analysis to the impact of FDI in services sectors after the TTIP (i.e., excluding barriers to trade), we do not obtain any remarkable evidence of negative impacts for outsides of the TTIP. If we look at the sectoral details of all of the regions we find the following. As reflected in Table 7 most manufacturing sectors tend to reduce production very slightly after the entry of multinationals in Chinese services. By contrast, they increase also only marginally, their production in services sectors. This contrasts with the evolution in China, that as can be seen is just the contrary. Services sectors are reducing production moderately due to the crowding out effect, while manufacturing mildly increase it. These trends imply that China is substituting imports with domestic production in manufacturing and increasing imports, related to the services’ affiliates in services sectors. The consequence of this is that the rest of regions are reducing their manufacturing exports to China and increasing their services ones. These are indeed the patterns reflected in the exports what we also see in Table 7. Comparing output and exports, we can see that the evolution of output reflects that of exports. 14 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT These results imply that we find a mild crowding out effect of manufacturing production in the rest of regions after the entry of FDI in services in China. The Asiatic giant weighs much in manufacturing trade and even small increases in its exports convey and effect for other areas of the world. On the other hand, the increase of FDI in services will carry with it exports from other regions to China in these sectors. Since China is more an exception in being still so specialized in manufacturing, the positive trend in services in the rest of regions compensates the reduction in exports in manufacturing21. PT E 4.3 Sensitivity analysis D MA NU SC RI PT That is why at the macroeconomic level regions look to a great extent unaffected. However, looking at the outcome of GDP (back in Table 8), Great Britain stands out with an impact that in the short run is closed to the one in China. This has to do with the important specialization in advanced services in this economy (reflected in Tables 1 and 2). As Table 8 shows, it derives important increases in its capital remuneration which are related to the fact that its multinationals will increase heavily their revenue in China. India benefits from an important increase in aggregate exports. The EU27 is a mixture of the pattern of Great Britain and India since it benefits from the side of more FDI in services coupled with more exports in those sectors. The US by contrast does not gain much, despite its important specialization in services exports. This is because the US is a rather closed economy and its production in services (as appears in Table 4) is not much export oriented. Other advanced economies, which has important Chinese partners such as Korea and Hong Kong, does not have such as specialization in services exports as the one of Great Britain, India, the EU27 or the US. However, it benefits more from its proximity to China insofar as its trade ties are strongest with China across all the regions we consider. AC CE In this section, we examine the effects of different specifications for parameter values, mainly the elasticities in the model. Following Harrison et al. (1993), we vary each of the parameters one by one, while we keep the rest of parameters at the initial values. We again display the results for the short-run version of a 50% cut in costs in the model, since we have found the same pattern in the long-run version. We also focus on the welfare impact because the trends were the same for GDP as well. The results are in Table 8, and the first row shows the result in our central setting (“reference”), which is the one we have analyzed so far. We see that the results in the central setting are quite robust with respect to all the parameters except two. The most influencing one is the supply elasticity with respect to the price of output of firms in the sectors with scale economies (namely, service sectors and manufacturing). When this elasticity is high, the production of the sectors will not be so quickly constrained by the increased cost of the specific capital required for the firm expansion. Since the elasticities in service sectors are higher than manufacturing sectors, the change in these elasticities are strongly related to the FDI reform (although in this paper we consider only the 21 Although Table 7 displays only the short term results, we have also analyzed the long run ones. The latter exhibit the same patterns as the former, with only a slightly more beneficial impact for exports and production across all regions. This is consistent with the macroeconomic results in Table 6. 15 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT FDI reform, we could think of the reduction of other types of trade costs, such as non-tariff barriers faced by trade), and the benefit of the FDI reform is increased significantly. In contrast, when we choose the low value of this supply elasticity, the welfare impact is not changed much. This is because the central value of this elasticity (calculated based on the empirical studies) does constrain the responsiveness already and further restriction does not affect much. SC RI PT The other influencing assumption is the share of profit repatriation. In our central setting, it is assumed that 50% of the profit of FDI firms is taken back to the source country. It could be surprising that the increase in this share to 75% improves the welfare in China because FDI firms in China now take more profit back to their countries. However, the reasoning is that because of the higher share of profit repatriation, there is larger incentive to expand FDI, which leads to the larger expansion of FDI and the positive impact on the welfare in China. Such a positive impact outweighs the negative impact of higher profit repatriation. NU 5. Summary and conclusions AC CE PT E D MA China is transitioning from an economy led by investment and exports, to one driven by consumption and innovations, with a growing share of services. China is the “factory of the world” due to its dominance in manufacturing, specifically in the lower and middle stage of production chain. Our data show that China is in 2016 still remarkably specialized in manufacturing production. The share of services in GDP is not only very far from the one in advanced economies but also compared to the world average. This highlights that there is a lot of scope for “a shift to services”, which is a natural process as economies develop. The data also point to the fact that services sectors are of very different nature compared to manufactures. The former are more oriented to the provision of private consumption than the latter. Also, in comparison with manufacturing, they are less export oriented. This implies that more productive capital in the form of FDI would enhance the push exerted by other forces to a more consumption oriented economy, with less importance of exports and investment ratios. For 2016 our data show that Chinese imports and production are still very oriented to the provision of intermediates for further processing. In a comparison with the US and the EU27 for that year, the share of imports and production that is devoted to private consumption is remarkably low in China. In China, advanced services sectors (water transport, air transport, communication, finance, insurance and business services) are remarkably more protected from foreign competition than other regions such as the US and the EU27. The Chinese government seems committed to lower those barriers (OECD, 2017; KPMG, 2016) and FDI has been increasing heavily in services, more than in manufacturing, in the last years according to UNCTAD (2016). In our analysis we find that because the initial barriers are so high, foreign multinationals would benefit from sizeable cost savings. This would deeply increase their competitiveness, which would crowd out a small percentage of national firms operating in those advanced services sectors. Production would go down, indeed, in advanced services sectors with the only exception of communication in which the initial barriers are the smallest and far from the 16 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT existing ones in the rest of sectors. The services sectors that do not have multinationals, such as personal services and other services would, however, increase their production. Despite the process of crowding out, the entry of foreign multinationals in services brings about a reduction in their prices which is beneficial for manufacturing sectors. This is because services provide intermediates to manufacturing sectors which will therefore increase their export competitiveness. Due to the still very high share of manufactures in Chinese GDP, this positive trend more than compensates the reduction in the services sector to which multinationals accrue, resulting in an overall positive impact for the Chinese economy. NU SC RI PT We examine different levels of reductions in the costs related to the barriers that foreign multinationals encounter (50% and 25%) deriving the impact for the short and long run. Despite the fact that more crowding out takes place in services sectors, the larger the cuts in the barriers are, the more positive the overall impact is. This is because the reduction in prices of intermediates and final goods is also more sizeable with relatively large (i.e., with greater percentage) cuts. In the long run, a process of domestic capital accumulation simultaneously occurs to the entry of foreign multinationals. As a consequence, the entire process is slightly more positive in this setting. All in all, a small positive increase in wages, capital remuneration and GDP at the aggregate level takes place. Welfare and foreign trade also increase, while the CPI goes down, benefitting consumers. PT E D MA Regarding the impact for the other regions of the world, we obtain, that they remain nearly unaffected or benefit very slightly. No region loses. This contrasts sharply with other previous analysis focusing on FDI going to manufacturing sectors, in which other areas would be displaced in their exports due to the fierce Chinese competition (e.g., Zhou and Latorre, 2014a, 2014b, 2015), resulting in wages reductions. Other papers using different methodologies have also derived a negative impact from FDI going to manufacturing in China (e.g., Pierce and Schott, 2016). CE Due to the lower export orientation of services sector compared to manufactures and to their still limited role in the Chinese economy the impact of FDI in services is considerably dampened for China itself and for the rest of areas in the world, compared to FDI in manufacturing. AC The results have been derived using an innovative CGE model, which simultaneously includes three features relevant for this analysis. These features are, first, the presence of foreign multinationals, which very few CGEs consider. Second, the inclusion of monopolistic competition in the sectors with foreign multinationals and FDI, previously modelled in other CGEs. However, we have not seen any other model combing the two previous characteristics with the third one, namely, the multi-regional setting. To conclude, in our view, several policy recommendations emerge from this analysis. First, there is a possible crowding out effect for domestic firms in services sectors after the entry of foreign multinationals. But the provision of high quality and cheap intermediates that multinationals facilitate benefits overall production and GDP in China. China would move up the value chain by shifting out-of-dated services firms, thus reinvigorating services sectors and improving manufacturing competitiveness and efficiency. In this respect, the impact of FDI in 17 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT services contrasts with the one in manufactures. The latter sectors do not play such an important role for the provision of intermediates across most sectors in the economy. In any case, the authorities have the chance to implement more pro-competitive or protectionist regulation in order to shape these outcomes on resulting competition after the entry of multinationals. PT Second, multinationals in services (and also in manufactures) benefit consumers’ welfare expanding the variety and quality of choices to which households have access. The rising living standards of Chinese households urges this higher quality and wider choices of services, which services’ liberalization can enhance. NU SC RI Third, the larger the cuts in existing barriers to the operations of foreign multinationals are, the more intense the attraction of FDI and increase in the number of firms and varieties are. In the light of previous studies, we have been conservative in the percentage cost reductions of barriers that we assume. Had we assume larger ones, the positive impact would have been more sizeable. Note also, that in the case of services, these barriers tend to be more related to domestic regulation than in the case of goods, due to the general intangible nature of the former. Thus again, FDI in services contrasts with that of manufactures. In the case of FDI in goods, many effects are more directly related to foreign trade protection or openness. Liberalization regulation in services will be more oriented to beyond border reforms. D MA Fourth, the data we have used assume that the use of intermediates coming from advanced services sectors across manufacturing sectors is rather limited (compared to their use in the EU and the US). This matches the fact that the role of services is still underdeveloped in the Chinese economy. We believe these data probably underestimate the real figures. Thus, the positive impact from FDI in services could be considerably larger. CE PT E Fifth, our analysis includes the effects of profit repatriation. But our sensitivity analysis derives that allowing the repatriation of a larger share of the rents of foreign multinationals incentivizes FDI inflows more than in the case of lower shares, resulting in more positive outcomes for China. This contrasts with other previous studies suggesting that more profit repatriation could be harmful for host economies. AC With the rise in labor cost and higher stands in environment, some industries are divesting from China to South Asia. Thus, the Chinese economy experiences big challenges and should upgrade its economic structure. We have seen this is possible through the provision of more varieties of services’ intermediates and goods for consumption that foreign affiliates could provide. This would further improve its manufacturing competitiveness and would also be good for sustainable economic development which is in danger due to extensive reliance mode on manufacturing in overall Chinese production. China will probably be the factory of the world for a long time but FDI in services will promote high-quality manufactures. Acknowledgements XXXXXXXX gratefully acknowledges that this research has been conducted thanks to the financial support of Real Colegio Complutense at Harvard University and as a Research Fellow 18 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT of both the Center for International Development (CID) at the Harvard Kennedy School and of Real Colegio Complutense. She also gratefully acknowledges the financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness (Projects: ECO2016-78422-R and ECO201341317-R). XXXXXXX is grateful for the financial support from the Educational Commission of Hunan Province of China (No. 16B267) and from Chinese Social Funds (No. 12CJL047). They want to thank Edward Balistreri, David Tarr and Antonio G. Gómez-Plana for their very helpful comments and suggestions. RI PT References SC Arita, S. and Tanaka, K. (2014) “Heterogeneous multinational firms and productivity gains from falling FDI barriers”, Review of World Economics, vol. 150, pp. 83–113. NU Arkolakis, C, Ramondo, N., Rodríguez-Clare, A. and Yeaple, S. (2015) “Innovation and Production in the Global Economy”, NBER Working Paper Series 18972. MA Armington, P. (1969): “A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production”, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, XVI, pp. 159-78. D Arnold, J., Mattoo, A. and Gaia, N. (2008): “Services Inputs and Firm Productivity in SubSaharan Africa: Evidence from Firm Level Data”, Journal of African Economies, vol. 17, pp. 578599. PT E Balistreri, E. J., Tarr D. G., and Yonezawa, H. (2015) “Deep Integration in Eastern and Southern Africa: What are the Stakes?”, Journal of African Economies, vol. 4, pp. 677-706. Balistreri, E. J. and Tarr, D. G. (2011) `Services liberalization in preferential trade arrangements: the case of kenya.' World Bank Policy and Research Working Paper No. 5552, January AC CE Balistreri, E. J., Maliszewska, M., Osorio-Rodarteand, I., Tarr D. G., and Yonezawa, H. (2016) “Poverty and shared prosperity implications of deep integration in Eastern and Southern Africa", Policy Research Working Paper: 7660, The World Bank, Development Economics, Development Prospects Group. Broda, C. and Weinstein, D. (2006) “Globalization and the Gains from Variety”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vo. 121, pp. 541-85. Burstein, A. and Monge-Naranjo, A. (2009) “Foreign know-how, firm control, and the income of developing countries”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 124, pp. 149-195. Dean, J. M., Lovely, M. E., & Mora, J. (2009) “Decomposing China–Japan–U.S. Trade: Vertical Specialization, Ownership, and Organizational Form”, Journal of Asian Economics, vol. 20, pp 596-610. Egger, P., J. Francois, M. Manchin, and D. Nelson (2015). Non-tariff Barriers, Integration, and the Transatlantic Economy. Economic Policy, vol. 30, no.83, pp. 541-548. 19 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Fernandes, A. M. and Paunov, C. (2012): “Foreign direct investment in services and manufacturing productivity: evidence for Chile”, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 97, pp. 305-321. Francois, J., Manchin M., Norberg H., Pindyuk O. and Tomberger P. (2013). Reducing Transatlantic Barriers to Trade and Investment, An Economic Assessment, Study for the European Commission, CEPR Report. PT Fukui, T. and Lakatos, C. (2012): “A Global Database of Foreign Affiliate Sales”, GTAP Research Memoranda 4009, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University. RI Goldberg, P., Khandelwal, A, Pavcnik, N. and Topalova, P. (2009) “Trade Liberalization and New Imported Inputs”, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, vol. 99, pp. 494-500. SC Gómez-Plana, A. G. and Latorre, M.C. (2014) “When multinationals leave: A CGE analysis of divestments”, Economics-The Open Access Open-Assessment E-Journal, vol. 8, pp. 1-41, available at: http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2014-6 NU Harrison, G. W., Jones, R.E., Kimbell, L. J. & Wigle, R. M. (1993) “How Robust Is Applied General Equilibrium Analysis”, Journal of Policy Modeling, vol. 15, pp. 99-115. MA Helpman, E. and Krugman, P. (1985): Market Structure and Foreign Trade, Cambridge MA: MIT Press. D IMF (2016) “World Economic Outlook (WEO): Too Slow for Too Long”, April 2016. PT E Jafari, Y. and Tarr, D.G. (2015): “Estimates of Ad Valorem Equivalents of Barriers Against Foreign Suppliers of Services in Eleven Services Sectors and 103 Countries”, The World Economy. CE Kim, W. S., Lyn, E. and Zychowicz, E. (2003) “Is the Source of FDI Important to Emerging Market Economies? Evidence from Japanese and U.S. FDI”, Multinational Finance Journal, vol. 7, pp. 107-130. AC Koopman R., Wang, Z. and Wei, S.-J. (2014) “Tracing Value-Added and Double Counting in Gross Exports”, American Economic Review, vol. 104, pp. 459-94. KPMG (2016) “China outlook 2016”, Available at: https://www.kpmg.com/CN/en/IssuesAndInsights/ ArticlesPublications/Documents/chinaoutlook-2016.pdf Konan D. E. and Van Assche, A. (2007) “Regulation, Market Structure, and Services Trade Liberalization,” Economic Modelling, vol. 24, November, pp. 895-923. Konan D. E. and Maskus, K. E. (2006) “Quantifying the Impact of Services Liberalization in a Developing Country,” World Bank Policy Research Paper No. 3193, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 81, pp. 142-162 20 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Konan D. E. and Kim, K. E. (2004) “Beyond Border Barriers, Services Liberalization in Tunisia and Egypt,” World Economy, vol. 27, pp. 1429-1447. Krugman, P. (1980): “Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade”, American Economic Review, vol. 70, pp. 950-59. Latorre, M.C. (2009): “The economic analysis of multinationals and foreign direct investment: A review”, Hacienda Pública Española/Revista de Economía Pública, vol. 191, pp. 97-126. PT Latorre, M. C. (2012): “Industry restructuring in transition after the arrival of multinationals: A general equilibrium analysis with firm-type costs’ differences”, Post-communist economies, vol. 24, p. 441-463. RI Latorre, M. C. (2013): “On the differential behaviour of national and multinational firms: A within and across sectors approach”, The World Economy, vol. 36, pp. 1245-1372. NU SC Latorre, M. C. (2016): “A CGE analysis of the impact of foreign direct investment and tariff reform on female and male workers”, World Development, vol. 77, pp. 346-366. Available online: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0305750X150 01928. MA Latorre, M. C. and Hosoe, N. (2016) “The role of Japanese FDI in China”, Journal of Policy Modeling, vol. 38, pp. 226-241. PT E D Latorre, M. C. and Yonezawa, H. (2017) “Stopped TTIP? Its potential impact on the world and the role of neglected FDI”, MPRA Paper No. 77162, March, available at:https://www.ethz.ch/content/dam/ethz/special-interest/mtec/cer-eth/economics-energyeconomicsdam/documents/people/hyonezaw/MPRA_paper_62297_Latorre_Yonezawa_2017.pdf. Latorre, M. C., Bajo-Rubio, O. and Gómez-Plana, A. G. (2009): “The effects of multinationals on host economies: A CGE approach”, Economic Modelling, vol. 26, pp. 851-864. CE Latorre, M. C., Yonezawa, H. and Zhou, J. (2015) El impacto del TTIP en la economía Española, Instituto de Estudios Económicos, Madrid. AC Meyer, K. E. (2004) “Perspectives on Multinational Enterprises in Emerging Economies”, Journal of International Business Studies, vol. 34, pp. 259-277. McGrattan, E. & Prescott, E., 2009. Openness, technology capital, and development. Journal of Economic Theory, 144 (6): 2454–2476. Narayanan, G., B., Aguiar, A. and McDougall, R. (Eds.) (2016): “Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 9A Data Base”, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. OECD (2017) “Services Trade Restrictiveness Index Country Notes: China”, available at: http://www.oecd.org/tad/services-trade/STRI_CHN.pdf Olekseyuk, Z. (2016) “Modeling of FDI in business services: additional effects in case of Ukraine’s European integration”, The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development vol. 25, pp. 1010-1043. 21 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Ortiz Valverde, G. and Latorre, M.C. (2017) “No Trans-pacific partnership? Good or bad for Mexico?”, Journal of International Trade Law and Policy, vol. 16, No. 2, pp. 116-123, 2017. Rutherford, T. F. and Tarr, D. G. (2008): “Poverty effects of Russia’s WTO accession: Modeling “real” households with endogenous productivity effects”, Journal of International Economics, vol. 75, pp. 131–150. Ramondo, N. (2014) “A quantitative approach to multinational production”, Journal of International Economics, vol. 93, pp. 108-122 PT Ramondo, N. and Rodríguez-Clare, A. (2013) “Trade, multinational production, and the gains from openness”, Journal of Political Econonomy, vol. 121, pp. 273–322. SC RI Shoven, J. B. and Whalley, J. (1984) “Applied general-equilibrium models of taxation and international trade: An introduction and survey”, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 22, pp. 1007-1051. NU Smarzynska, B. (2004) “Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages”, American Economic Review, vol. 94, pp. 605-627. D MA Tarr, D. G. (2012): “Putting Services and Foreign Direct Investment with Endogenous Productivity Effects in Computable General Equilibrium Models” in Dixon, P. And Jorgenson, D. (Eds.) Handbook of Computable General equilibrium modeling, Elsevier, North-holland, available at: http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/IW3P/ IB/ 2012/03/26/000158349_20120326084225/Rendered/PDF/WPS6012.pdf PT E UNCTAD (several years) World Investment Report, United Nations, New York and Geneva. CE Zhou, J. and Latorre, M. C. (2015) “FDI in China and global production networks: Assessing the role of and impact on big world players (East Asia, Japan, EU28 and U.S.)", MPRA Paper 62297, University Library of Munich, Germany. AC Zhou, J. and Latorre, M. C. (2014a) “How does FDI influence the triangular trade pattern among China, East Asia and the U.S.? A CGE analysis of the sector of Electronics in China”, Economic Modelling, vol. 44, Supplement, pp. S77–S88. Zhou, J. and Latorre, M. C. (2014b) “The impact of FDI on the production networks between China and East Asia and the role of the U.S. and ROW as final markets”, Global Economic Review: Perspectives on East Asian Economies and Industries, vol. 43, pp. 285-314. 22 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 1. GDP and export structure in China and the world in 2004 and 2016 4. 2 6. 2 1. 2 0. 3 1. 9 4. 5 0. 5 4. 8 2. 3 29 .3 39 1.2 13.5 2.0 3.7 3.0 7.4 2.5 9.3 1.3 5.8 0.6 5.9 1.3 10.4 3.3 7.5 1.5 6.5 17.Finance 18.Insuranc e 19.Business services 20.Personal services 21.Other services All 14.1 4.9 0.4 13.5 0.5 2.9 2.3 4.2 5.2 4.4 1.3 11. 1 1.8 3.1 43. 6 28. 3.7 2.2 3.4 7.0 9.8 2.9 13.0 1.3 28.7 1.8 12.3 3.3 18.8 2.7 1.2 3. 7 7. 8 0. 4 0. 2 1. 9 6. 0 0. 4 5. 7 2. 4 28 .7 41 24.4 18.6 0.6 14.1 1.2 27.5 3.2 20.2 1.7 29.0 6.5 15.8 0.4 13.2 0.4 7.0 2.3 10.9 5.2 15.4 1.2 4.8 9.9 7.7 2.8 41. 1 31. 11.0 9.3 17.7 23 PT 3.9 5.0 SC 2.6 30.5 Ch in a 1. 2 1. 1 2. 5 18 .3 3. 5 8. 1 6. 6 1. 9 1. 6 26 .7 14 .7 NU 6.9 AC 7.Metals 8.Motor vehicles 9.Other transport 10.Electroni cs 11.Other machinery 12.Other manufactur es 13.Construc tion 14.Water Transport 15.Air Transport 16.Commun ications 3.0 5.4 MA 6.Chemicals 19.8 2016 W orl %CHN/ d World D 4.Textiles 5.Wood and paper 3.9 Ch in a 12 .3 3. 7 2. 8 2. 8 1. 7 4. 7 5. 1 1. 7 0. 6 2. 5 4. 9 PT E 3.Food 2004 W orl %CHN/ d World CE 1.Agricultur e 2.Other primary Ch in a 15 .3 4. 0 2. 0 3. 2 1. 5 4. 4 4. 6 1. 4 0. 7 2. 7 4. 9 Export structure 2004 2016 W Ch W orl %CHN in orl %CHN d /world a d /world 1. 2.3 4.8 0 2.6 4.7 0. 13. 9.0 1.1 3 6 0.3 2. 3.8 5.7 0 4.0 6.5 15 5.6 28.7 .9 4.7 43.6 3. 3.2 9.7 8 2.4 20.5 13. 10 15. 4 5.4 .8 5 9.0 7. 6.3 9.4 5 7.6 12.8 2. 7.6 2.3 1 5.8 4.7 2. 2.7 5.4 3 2.5 11.4 12. 22 3 19.3 .8 8.2 35.6 13. 19 13. 9 9.3 .4 9 18.0 RI GDP structure 6. 8 0. 2 0. 2 0. 4 0. 2 0. 1 0. 1 0. 8 0. 5 4. 4 92 2.9 20.8 0.5 4.5 0.7 2.0 1.8 1.8 0.4 3.3 0.8 1.3 0.7 1.7 4.6 1.6 1.2 3.6 6.5 81. 6.0 10.1 6. 5 0. 3 0. 1 0. 3 0. 1 0. 1 0. 1 1. 2 0. 4 2. 8 93 2.7 31.2 0.6 7.1 0.6 1.3 1.6 2.4 0.4 4.3 1.1 1.4 0.7 2.4 4.8 3.3 1.0 4.8 5.8 81. 6.3 14.8 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT manufactur es .9 7 44 .8 5. 0 67. 4 10 0 .9 4 45 .7 13 .3 63. 3 10 0 .1 0 .9 16. 5. 7 3.5 2 10 12 %World 5.0 13.3 0.0 8.8 .8 W CH orl %CHN CH N d /world N Source: Authors’ estimations based on Narayanan et al. (2016) and IMF (2016). 3.3 9.6 6. 6 8. 8 AC CE PT E D MA NU SC RI PT All services 24 5 15. 9 10 0.0 W orl d 4.2 12.8 %CHN /world ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 2. Imports by demand type and demand use of production in China, EU27 and US (2016, in percentage). 4.Textiles 5.Wood and paper 7.Metals 8.Motor vehicles AC 9.Other transport CE PT E 6.Chemica ls 10.Electro nics 11.Other machinery 12.Other manufact ures 13.Constr uction 14.Water PT RI SC NU 3.Food Denand use of production Private consumptio Intermedia n tes Exports E E C E U C U U C U U H U S H 2 S H 2 S N 27 A N 7 A N 7 A 2 1 6 6 6 2 2 4. 14 4. 9. 1. 3. 1. 3. 2. 7 .8 8 9 3 2 2 2 0 9 6 9 3 0. 1. 0. 8. 8. 2. 1. 0. 7. 7 2 0 3 0 6 0 7 3 4 5 5 2 3 2 1. 45 4. 5. 9. 7. 3. 4. 8. 9 .7 7 0 8 0 1 3 2 1 4 6 2 4 2 3 3. 35 6. 1. 7. 4. 5. 6. 7. 6 .9 5 1 3 6 3 4 1 1 8 6 7 1 2 4. 12 5. 3. 0. 0. 1. 6. 6. 5 .8 8 2 1 1 6 6 1 1 8 4 5 4 2 6. 9. 8. 5. 4. 9. 8. 5. 1. 2 3 8 4 4 2 4 4 9 9 5 8 3 1 0. 1. 1. 1. 7. 2. 6. 8. 4. 3 8 5 3 6 1 4 2 6 2 4 1 2 5 1 9. 15 8. 6. 9. 3. 5. 8. 9. 9 .5 9 2 2 9 4 9 1 1 2 3 3 1 4 3 6. 5. 1. 8. 5. 2. 9. 8. 3. 8 8 8 0 4 0 3 7 8 4 2 5 4 5 1 3. 8. 6. 9. 8. 3. 2. 4. 7. 3 2 6 1 6 6 0 0 1 4 2 3 1 5 2 2. 4. 8. 9. 8. 5. 8. 3. 6. 5 7 6 0 5 6 3 7 8 1 8 5 6 1 2 1 2. 22 8. 3. 1. 3. 2. 3. 3. 1 .9 9 2 6 3 7 6 3 2 2 0. 2. 0. 5. 5. 7. 0. 2. 0. 0 3 0 9 5 6 3 4 4 4. 3. 1 8 7 7 1. 2 3. MA 2.Other primary D 1.Agricult ure Impors by demand type Private consumptio Intermediat n es E C E U C U H U S H 2 U N 27 A N 7 SA 3 9 6 3. 33 8. 5. 5. 61 5 .4 6 7 7 .4 9 9 10 0. 2. 0. 9. 8. 0. 1 0 0 9 0 0 3 5 6 4 5. 56 4. 4. 3. 45 1 .7 2 9 3 .8 1 7 8 3 4. 62 2. 5. 7. 27 6 .8 4 3 1 .1 2 9 8 5. 14 2. 3. 3. 67 2 .6 7 9 8 .8 2 9 8 5. 16 7. 4. 1. 72 4 .4 0 6 0 .5 9 9 0. 1. 3. 8. 6. 94 2 7 3 7 1 .8 1 3 5 4 0. 37 8. 1. 6. 26 0 .9 6 0 0 .8 1 3 4 8. 10 2. 6. 9. 52 2 .5 2 8 4 .7 2 8 5 5. 16 0. 6. 6. 54 0 .7 3 4 9 .0 1 6 6 2. 9. 4. 2. 1. 44 8 5 7 4 2 .6 6 8 5 4. 40 8. 9. 7. 30 5 .0 0 7 9 .0 2 0. 1. 0. 6. 0. 9. 0 6 4 2 5 3 7. 13 1. 8 8 98 25 1.Agricult ure 2.Other primary 3.Food 4.Textiles 5.Wood and paper 6.Chemica ls 7.Metals 8.Motor vehicles 9.Other transport 10.Electro nics 11.Other machinery 12.Other manufact ures 13.Constr uction 14.Water 5 15.Air Transport 6. 8 3 2. 4 1 1. 3 4 7. 5 33 .0 2. 0 1 9. 8 2 4. 5 4 4. 8 1. 6 4 3. 2 2 1. 8 16 .7 16.Comm unications 17.Financ e 18.Insuran ce 19.Busines s services 20.Person al services 29 .5 18 .2 47 .1 51 .7 3. 7 5 8. 9 3 0. 2 3. 8 9 1. 5 6 7. 6 8 7. 0 5 2. 5 6 7. 8 4 9. 5 6 5. 2 6. 6 6 7. 0 7 0. 5 8 1. 8 5 2. 8 7 2. 5 3 5. 6 4 4. 9 .4 1 2 4. 5 98 .0 5. 8 3 3. 9 1 1. 8 4 7. 3 13 .4 4. 9 4 7. 9 4 0. 9 5 7. 2 1. 6 4 3. 6 2 3. 2 3. 2 80 .2 68 .0 55 .2 94 .3 41 .1 28 .8 20 .2 49 .8 48 .3 5. 7 7 4. 2 5 2. 2 9. 9 8 4. 2 6 4. 9 8 6. 2 4 9. 9 6 4. 7 4 7. 0 4 7. 7 0 Transport 8. 6 2. 9 4 8. 4 1 2. 8 15.Air Transport 1. 1 8. 4 2. 4 16.Comm unications 0. 3 17.Financ e 3. 7 18.Insuran ce 2. 3 8. 5 1 8. 3 1 0. 5 3. 3 PT .2 3. 2 3 8. 2 6 2. 8 7 1. 3 3 1. 9 7 4. 0 3 1. 0 2 5. 0 5. 0 19.Busines s services 2. 0 9. 4 2. 6 20.Person al services SC 3 NU Transport RI ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 8. 0 7 9. 2 4 7. 5 5 3. 4 3 9. 1 8 4. 7 2 2. 9 2 1. 5 0 2. 8 AC CE PT E D MA 21.Other 43 69 37 1. 4. 1. services .9 .0 .0 3 4 3 All manufact ures All services %World Source: Authors’ estimations based on Narayanan et al. (2016) and IMF (2016). 26 21.Other services ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 3. Percentages in total costs of intermediates coming from advanced services sectors (in percentage in 2016) Intermediates from advanced services CHN EU27 USA 2.3 7.1 13.7 11.2 11.5 7.6 2.9 11.4 8.8 4.1 10.1 8.4 3.8 11.9 6.3 4.0 9.4 6.0 4.3 9.3 6.3 5.0 10.2 5.6 4.4 12.6 6.9 6.9 16.8 11.3 5.1 11.5 7.1 AC CE PT E D MA NU SC RI PT 1.Agriculture 2.Other primary 3.Food 4.Textiles 5.Wood and paper 6.Chemicals 7.Metals 8.Motor vehicles 9.Other transport 10.Electronics 11.Other machinery 12.Other manufactures 4.5 10.7 8.1 13.Construction 5.1 11.2 11.3 14.Water Transport 22.4 19.3 28.1 15.Air Transport 19.1 13.9 13.9 16.Communications 24.0 36.2 33.5 17.Finance 24.5 48.0 28.7 18.Insurance 43.0 60.8 45.4 19.Business services 19.3 30.7 19.0 20.Personal services 6.7 14.2 19.7 21.Other services 10.6 13.3 13.3 Source: Authors’ estimations based on Narayanan et al. (2016) and IMF (2016). 27 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 4. Short term and long term impact of reductions in FDI barriers on main aggregate variables in China (% change with respect to the initial data) 0.19 1.12 0.85 -0.28 0.09 0.50 0.39 -0.13 RI 0.03 0.47 0.36 -0.12 AC CE PT E D MA NU SC Welfare GDP Wages Capital remuneration 0.06 Exports 1.06 Imports 0.79 CPI -0.26 Source: Authors’ estimations. Long run 50% 25% 0.24 0.11 0.19 0.09 0.17 0.08 PT Short run 50% 25% 0.31 0.14 0.09 0.04 0.09 0.04 28 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 5. Short term and long term impact of 50% reductions in FDI barriers on output, exports, imports and prices in China (% change with respect to the initial data) Output Short run Long run 50% 25% 50% 25% Exports Short run Long run 50% 25% 50% 25% Imports T P Short run 50% 25% Long run 50% 25% 0.17 1.Agriculture 0.37 0.17 0.39 0.18 0.82 0.37 0.83 0.37 0.14 0.06 2.Other primary 1.07 0.48 1.28 0.56 2.76 1.21 3.22 1.41 -0.13 -0.05 3.Food 0.34 0.15 0.33 0.15 1.04 0.46 1.10 0.49 0.02 4.Textiles 0.47 0.21 0.50 0.22 0.56 0.25 0.58 0.26 5.Wood and paper I R 0.08 -0.06 0.01 SC -0.02 0.00 0.12 0.06 0.15 0.07 0.37 0.17 0.48 0.21 1.15 0.51 1.23 0.55 -0.17 -0.07 -0.09 -0.04 6.Chemicals 0.55 0.25 0.64 0.28 0.98 0.44 1.02 0.45 -0.20 -0.08 -0.13 -0.05 7.Metals 0.54 0.24 0.73 0.32 1.37 0.61 1.56 0.69 -0.06 -0.02 0.05 0.02 8.Motor vehicles 0.39 0.17 0.54 0.24 1.23 0.55 1.23 0.55 -0.64 -0.28 -0.45 -0.20 9.Other transport 0.50 0.23 0.68 0.30 1.79 0.79 1.92 0.85 -0.55 -0.24 -0.42 -0.18 10.Electronics 0.72 0.32 0.78 0.35 0.76 0.34 0.77 0.35 0.09 0.04 0.19 0.09 11.Other machinery 12.Other manufactures 13.Construction 0.66 0.29 0.85 0.38 1.59 0.70 1.74 0.77 -0.25 -0.11 -0.13 -0.05 0.41 0.18 0.60 0.27 1.20 0.53 1.19 0.53 0.06 0.03 0.31 0.14 0.90 0.40 0.95 0.43 -0.67 -0.14 -0.30 -0.06 -0.42 0.10 -0.19 0.05 D E U N A M PT E C C A 29 -0.14 Prices Short run Long run 50% 25% 50% 25% 0.14 0.06 0.13 0.06 0.27 0.12 0.32 0.14 0.18 0.08 0.20 0.09 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.20 0.09 0.22 0.10 0.07 0.03 0.06 0.03 0.21 0.09 0.24 0.11 0.15 0.07 0.12 0.05 0.22 0.10 0.24 0.10 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.23 0.10 0.25 0.11 0.12 0.05 0.09 0.04 - ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 14.Water Transport 15.Air Transport 16.Communications 0.19 0.08 0.15 0.06 0.95 0.43 1.01 0.45 4.40 1.89 4.36 1.87 1.04 0.64 1.10 0.66 13.73 32.90 14.69 32.94 14.71 0.97 0.43 1.09 0.48 1.33 0.70 1.27 1.22 0.54 1.30 0.57 10.71 1.68 0.82 1.70 0.84 6.50 C S U T P I R 0.67 0.32 0.74 0.35 28.18 12.92 28.26 12.96 20.Personal services 0.26 0.12 0.28 0.13 1.06 0.47 1.09 0.49 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.01 21.Other services 0.20 0.09 0.23 0.11 1.12 0.50 1.20 0.54 -0.12 -0.05 -0.11 -0.05 All manufactures 0.48 0.21 0.61 0.27 1.07 0.48 1.13 0.50 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.00 1.02 0.47 1.09 0.50 -0.16 -0.07 -0.09 -0.04 8.71 3.99 8.74 4.00 0.79 0.36 0.85 0.39 All services 0.02 0.01 0.18 0.40 30.41 19.Business services 18.Insurance 0.05 0.04 0.56 0.92 13.71 0.02 0.09 0.56 1.01 17.Finance 0.01 0.04 0.18 0.44 30.36 D E M N A T P E C C Total 0.32 0.14 0.42 0.19 1.06 0.47 1.13 0.50 Source: Authors’ estimations. A 30 0.21 0.31 0.70 0.31 0.42 0.57 0.37 0.25 0.27 0.16 0.40 0.25 0.67 5.19 10.73 5.20 3.08 6.49 3.08 0.09 0.14 0.32 0.14 0.19 0.27 0.16 0.11 0.12 0.07 0.18 0.11 0.22 0.34 0.71 0.35 0.46 0.58 0.38 0.26 0.29 0.17 0.42 0.26 0.10 0.15 0.33 0.16 0.20 0.27 0.17 0.11 0.13 0.07 0.19 0.12 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 6. Short term and long term impact of reductions in FDI barriers on main aggregate variables across regions (% change with respect to the initial data) Welfare GDP Wages Capital remuneration Exports Imports CPI Short run Long run Short run Long run Short run Long run Short run Long run Short run Long run Short run Long run Short run Long run CHN EU27 GBR USA IND JPN LAC MEN OAC SEA SSA 0.31 0.08 0.10 0.02 0.06 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.02 0.24 0.10 0.12 0.02 0.07 0.03 0.05 0.08 0.08 0.03 0.09 0.04 0.08 0.01 0.04 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.01 0.19 0.07 0.09 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.06 0.02 0.09 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.07 0.00 C S U I R T P 0.07 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.17 0.05 0.05 0.01 0.08 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.06 0.07 0.16 0.03 M 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.01 0.19 0.10 0.19 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.03 0.06 0.08 0.02 1.06 0.19 0.07 0.13 0.48 0.03 0.05 0.10 0.14 0.07 0.10 C C T P E D E N A 0.06 1.12 0.21 0.09 0.14 0.50 0.04 0.06 0.10 0.15 0.09 0.11 0.79 0.10 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.85 0.12 0.08 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.06 0.07 0.03 0.05 0.04 -0.26 0.02 0.04 num 0.08 -0.02 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 -0.28 0.01 0.04 num 0.08 -0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.00 A 31 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Source: Authors’ estimations. Note: LAC stands for Latin America, OAC for other advanced countries, SEA for Southeast Asia, SSA for Sub-Saharan Africa and MEN for Middle-East and North of Africa. Appendix 2 has the country composition of each of the regions. T P I R C S U N A D E M T P E C C A 32 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 7. Short term impact of 50% reductions in FDI barriers on output and exports across regions (% change with respect to the initial data) Ouptut CHN 1.Agriculture 2.Other primary 3.Food 0.37 1.07 0.34 EU27 0.04 -0.10 0.05 GBR 0.02 -0.31 0.05 USA 0.03 0.02 0.02 IND 0.02 JPN Exports -0.55 0.02 LAC 0.00 0.10 0.02 0.02 -0.07 4.Textiles 0.47 -0.03 -0.07 -0.02 -0.11 -0.02 5.Wood and paper 0.37 -0.01 -0.06 -0.02 -0.08 6.Chemicals 0.55 -0.02 -0.08 0.00 7.Metals 0.54 -0.15 -0.30 8.Motor vehicles 9.Other 0.39 0.50 -0.05 -0.11 -0.10 -0.26 0.03 MEN 0.04 -0.06 0.05 D E OAC 0.01 -0.13 SEA M -0.09 0.04 -0.03 -0.03 -0.05 -0.03 -0.02 PT -0.03 -0.02 -0.07 -0.07 -0.15 -0.01 -0.03 -0.02 -0.07 -0.06 -0.08 -0.28 -0.06 -0.15 -0.11 -0.20 -0.14 -0.01 -0.04 -0.10 -0.23 0.00 0.02 -0.03 -0.09 -0.02 -0.06 -0.05 -0.13 -0.02 -0.06 E C C A 33 C H N 0. 03 0. 02 0. 82 0. 03 0. 03 0. 02 0. 01 0. 13 0. 01 - 1. 04 EU 27 2. 76 0. 56 1. 15 0. 98 1. 37 1. 23 1. GB R 0. 11 0. 53 0. 12 0. 16 0. 32 0. 13 0. 40 0. 20 - T P I R 0. 00 0. 20 C S U 0.04 N A 0.03 SS A 0. 01 0. 09 0. 17 0. 09 0. 29 0. 20 - US A 0. 04 0. 06 0. 06 0. 04 0. 07 0. 01 0. 15 0. 03 - IN D 0. 37 1. 03 0. 37 0. 39 0. 55 0. 19 0. 61 0. 29 - JP N LA C M EN 0. 14 0. 01 0. 09 0. 00 0. 10 0. 02 0. 08 0. 21 0. 07 0. 24 0. 04 - 0. 00 0. 02 0. 14 0. 09 0. 21 0. 07 0. 14 0. 09 0. 09 0. 03 0. 09 0. 01 0. 0. 03 - O AC 0. 02 0. 15 0. 03 0. 07 0. 26 0. 12 0. 22 0. 09 - SE A 0. 02 0. 13 0. 01 SS A 0. 08 0. 03 0. 00 0. 17 0. 12 0. 20 0. 05 0. 06 0. 01 0. 15 0. 02 - 0. 04 0. 0. 10 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT transport 10.Electronic s 11.Other machinery 12.Other manufacture s 13.Constructi on 14.Water Transport 15.Air Transport 16.Communi cations 0.72 -0.25 -0.24 -0.30 0.18 0.41 0.59 0.43 0. 00 0. 08 0. 34 PT 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.06 0. 03 0. 97 0. 11 0. 44 0. 26 0. 54 0. 24 0. 16 0. 03 0. 16 0. 07 1. 22 1. 68 0. 67 1. 06 0. 21 1. 07 1. 96 0. 01 0. 10 0. 18 0. 95 0. 11 -0.34 -0.08 -0.15 -0.15 -0.16 -0.12 0.66 -0.21 -0.34 -0.12 -0.28 -0.13 -0.21 -0.13 -0.32 -0.24 0.41 -0.07 -0.11 -0.11 -0.16 -0.06 -0.06 -0.03 -0.10 -0.08 0.06 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.19 -0.01 -0.06 0.03 -0.11 0.01 0.04 0.15 -4.40 0.52 0.03 0.14 0.54 0.25 0.02 0.06 0.05 0.02 0.01 E C 0.01 D E 79 0. 90 0. 95 1. 04 0. 25 0. 26 0. 39 0. 18 0. 09 0. 14 1. 66 0.00 0.04 0.13 17.Finance -0.09 0.07 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.06 0.05 0.05 18.Insurance 19.Business services -0.56 0.15 0.05 0.04 0.26 0.04 0.09 0.16 0.15 0.09 -1.01 0.14 0.14 0.06 0.83 0.02 0.09 0.22 0.16 0.17 0. 02 0. 05 0. 08 0.26 0.06 0.07 0.02 -0.13 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.06 0. 02 20.Personal services C A 34 0. 76 1. 59 1. 20 0. 11 0. 34 0. 24 0. 03 0. 61 0. 33 0. 70 0. 40 0. 32 0. 05 3. 48 0. 08 0. 05 2. 72 2. 18 0. 26 T P I R C S U N A M 0. 13 0. 13 0. 10 0. 07 0. 02 3. 32 1. 33 0. 41 0. 49 0. 65 1. 20 0. 09 02 0. 19 0. 20 0. 24 0. 04 0. 07 1. 78 2. 10 0. 19 0. 14 0. 40 0. 15 0. 07 1. 06 3. 26 0. 07 0. 11 0. 25 0. 09 0. 02 1. 22 1. 65 01 0. 04 0. 43 1. 77 0. 15 0. 15 0. 32 0. 14 0. 02 0. 28 1. 47 0. 26 0. 12 0. 10 0. 21 0. 10 0. 15 0. 12 1. 86 1. 11 0. 41 1. 95 1. 36 1. 05 1. 12 1. 75 0. 35 0. 53 1. 14 0. 47 1. 36 1. 99 0. 09 0. 02 0. 00 0. 34 1. 33 1. 74 0. 05 0. 03 0. 03 0. 06 0. 16 0. 06 0. 13 0. 15 0. 05 0. 00 0. 81 1. 60 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT 21.Other services All manufacture s 0.20 0.04 0.05 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.48 -0.06 -0.11 -0.04 -0.13 -0.03 -0.04 -0.04 -0.10 -0.05 All services -0.06 0.07 0.06 0.02 0.09 0.01 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.06 Total 0.32 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.03 -0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 IND JPN Short Short run run LAC Short run MEN Short run OAC SEA Short Short run run CHN EU27 GBR USA Short Short Short Short run run run run Source: Authors’ estimations. Note: See note on Table 6. D E T P E C C A 35 0. 16 0. 30 0. 41 0. 07 0. 05 0. 10 0. 55 0. 13 0. 38 0. 40 1. 54 0. 48 T P I R C S U N A M 0. 1. 00 12 0. 1. 03 07 0. 1. 02 02 0. 1. 00 06 SS A Short run 0. 07 0. 21 0. 84 0. 19 0. 04 0. 08 0. 62 0. 03 0. 02 0. 12 0. 60 0. 05 0. 03 0. 10 0. 82 0. 10 0. 13 0. 19 0. 87 0. 14 0. 00 0. 11 0. 54 0. 07 0. 01 0. 04 0. 67 0. 10 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Table 8. Sensitivity analysis: Short run impact on welfare of 50 % cuts in FDI barriers Reference 25% Profit repatriation 75% Profit repatriation σ (D, M) (high) σ (D, M) (low) σ (M, M) (high) σ (M, M) (low) σ (qi, qj) (goods, high) σ (qi, qj) (goods, low) θm (i) (high) θm (i) (low) σ (A1,…,An) (alternative) ε (fi) (high) ε (fi) (low) σ (qi, qj) (services, high) σ (qi, qj) (services, low) σ (va, bs) (high) σ (va, bs) (low) σ (L,K) (high) σ (L,K) (low) θr (i) (high) CHN 0.31 EU27 0.08 GBR 0.10 USA 0.02 IND 0.06 JPN 0.02 LAC 0.04 MEN 0.06 OAC 0.08 0.21 0.07 0.11 0.02 0.06 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.08 0.07 0.02 0.79 0.31 0.30 0.32 0.29 0.27 0.40 0.32 0.30 0.10 0.08 0.07 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.10 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.11 0.11 0.10 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.08 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.30 0.24 1.47 0.08 0.05 0.14 0.11 0.09 0.10 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.02 0.05 0.06 0.04 0.09 0.08 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.06 0.08 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.08 T P E 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.11 0.02 0.06 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.07 0.02 0.07 0.10 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.11 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.13 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.10 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.08 0.08 0.09 0.07 0.08 0.08 0.12 0.07 0.08 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.09 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.04 C C 0.36 0.28 0.45 0.17 0.31 0.31 0.41 A D E N A M 36 T P I R C S U SEA 0.07 SSA 0.02 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT θr (i) (low) 0.22 Source: Authors’ estimations. σ (D, M) σ (M, M) θm (i) σ (A1,…,An) σ (qi, qj) (goods) σ (qi, qj) (services) ε (fi) σ (va, bs) σ (L,K) θr (i) 0.05 0.08 0.01 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.01 Armington elasticity of substitution between imports and domestic goods in CRTS sectors Armington elasticity of substitution between imports from different regions in CRTS sectors Share of value added in multinational firms in sector i due to specialized primary factor imports in the benchmark Elasticity of substitution in intermediate production between composite Armington aggregate goods Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive goods sectors Elasticity of substitution between firm varieties in imperfectly competitive services sectors Elasticity of supply with respect to price of output in national firms and multinationals in services Elasticity of substitution between value-added and business services Elasticity of substitution between primary factors of production in value added Spillover of FDI barrier cut on exporters T P I R C S U N A D E M T P E C C A 37 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT Figure 1. Costs related to FDI barriers (% of total costs) 00 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 T P 14.Water Transport I R C S U 15.Air Transport N A 16.Communications D E 17.Finance T P E C C 18.Insurance 19.Business services M A Source: Jafari and Tarr (2014). 38 CHN EUR USA ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT CE PT E D MA NU SC RI We offer an overview of the changing role of China in the world from 2004 to 2016 We analyze the impact of FDI inflows accruing to services sectors in China We use an innovative computable general equilibrium (CGE) model The impact of FDI in services contrasts sharply with the one of FDI in manufactures The effects are slightly positive for China and the rest of regions AC PT Highlights 39