Uploaded by bookdownload

Sample Essay

advertisement
Fighting terrorism:
Why formal institutions are more
effective than informal institutions
Zeng Fan Yi
U1840312K
30 November 2018
Abstract
With the rise of transnational terrorism, finding ways to combat terrorism is becoming
ever more relevant today. In this paper, I will argue that formal institutions are more
effective than informal institutions in preventing the spread of terrorism. Formal
institutions, unlike informal institutions, are capable of shaping unfavorable external
conditions against terrorists, restricting opportunities for terrorist attacks. This can be
done using the tools formal institutions have at their disposal, such as surveillance,
intelligence, and screening. By making it more likely for terrorists to be caught, formal
institutions can also increase the risks of terrorist activities, deterring individuals from
engaging in terrorism. Furthermore, formal institutions are able to directly address
structural deficits which provide motivation for terrorism, improving material standards
of living so that individuals neither need nor want to turn to terrorism. The appeal of
terrorism is reduced even more as the value of leading a non-terrorist life increases with
economic progress. It would therefore be more pragmatic and effective to focus
existing resources on using formal institutions to address terrorism.
Suicide bombings, mass shootings, and gruesome videos of beheadings—these are just
some of the many methods terrorists use to spread fear and gain worldwide
attention. Terrorism is the deliberate creation and exploitation of fear through violence,
or the threat of violence, in the pursuit of political changes or goals (Hoffman, 2017).
While not a new phenomenon, terrorism is becoming more challenging to tackle due to
its increasingly transnational nature in the recent years (Bohemen, 2016). It is therefore
of urgent necessity to understand how best to curb terrorism.
Finding the root causes of terrorism is a challenging endeavor, and there is still an
ongoing debate on whether terrorism stems from inherent conflicts between cultures
(Huntington, 2011), economic constraints (Schneider, Brück & Meierrieks, 2009), or
other reasons (Meierrieks & Krieger, 2010). While examining the causes of terrorism
is important for a comprehensive understanding of terrorism, time is of essence and it
is impractical to wait for a consensus on the main causes before we attempt to begin
solving the problem. It would therefore be more pragmatic for solutions—at least in the
short term—to focus on addressing the contributing factors to terrorism which have
been pinpointed, such as structural deficiencies and the spread of extremist ideologies
(Newman, 2006).
Institutions are humanly-devised constraints that structure political, economic, and
social interactions (North, 1991). Formal institutions are openly codified, in the sense
that they are established and communicated through channels that are widely
accepted as official. Informal institutions are socially-shared rules that exist and are
enforced outside formal channels of communication (Helmke & Levitsky, 2004). A
combination of both formal and informal institutions is needed to address the different
factors contributing to terrorism, minimizing both the motivation and opportunity for
terrorism. However, it is crucial to determine whether using formal or informal
institutions would be more effective in tackling terrorism, as resources can then be
focused on formulating the most effective counter-terrorism strategy. In this paper, I
will argue that formal institutions are more effective than informal institutions in
preventing the spread of terrorism.
Strip a terrorist of his weapons, and he is a normal man
Formal institutions have more capacity to manipulate external conditions than informal
institutions. Parliaments have the legislative power to draft policies prohibiting the
private ownership of resources which are deemed dangerous, such as firearms,
explosives and the like. Since the state claims a monopoly on the legitimate use of
violence within a given territory (Weber, 1972), formal institutions also have the power
and authority to execute and enforce such policies. Strict gun control by the state in
countries such as Japan and Singapore, for one, has successfully led to low rates of gun
ownership (Gun Policy, 2018), demonstrating the power of formal institutions in
restricting access to specialized, higher-risk resources. By making it highly difficult for
terrorists to obtain weapons, formal institutions can minimize the opportunities for
terrorists to execute attacks.
However, it must be acknowledged that such restrictions would not be able to
completely prevent terrorists from obtaining or creating weapons. Terrorists have found
ways to make bombs out of widely-available materials, the effects of which have been
seen in the 2015 Paris attacks (Dodd, 2018). Furthermore, with increasingly
unconventional methods of attacks being used by terrorists recently, the definition of
‘weapon’ itself is broadening. Trucks have been used to drive into crowds, such as in
the 2016 Nice truck attack (Al Jazeera, 2018). Given that more objects found in
everyday life are being used as weapons, restricting access to such items is not only
difficult but unfeasible.
As such, the increasing difficulty faced by formal institutions in controlling
terrorism through restricting resources does not mean that formal institutions have been
rendered ineffective. Rather, it highlights the need to focus more on the other tools
formal institutions have at their disposal, such as intelligence-gathering, which has been
shown to be effective in intercepting potential terrorist attacks (The Spectator, 2018).
Surveillance mechanisms such as CCTV networks are also able to monitor and track
suspicious movement, while screening procedures at strategic locations like airports
can reveal the presence of possible weapons. By focusing more on developing these
tools and making external circumstances more difficult for terrorists to navigate, formal
institutions can minimize opportunities for terrorism.
Deterrence: Be a terrorist if you want, but face the repercussions
Using formal institutions to indirectly influence motivations is more feasible than using
informal institutions to directly influence motivations. While both formal and informal
institutions can shape and change motivations, formal institutions do it indirectly via
shaping the external environment in which individuals live. By increasing the chances
of being caught through the methods mentioned earlier, formal institutions are able
to create a deterrence effect by making the option of becoming a terrorist seem less
desirable, appealing to the rationality of individuals. Although it cannot be assumed
that all individuals are rational actors, even individuals who are motivated by irrational
motivation—as long as they still possess some semblance of rationality—would still
have to weigh the perceived benefits of their irrational actions against the material costs.
In fact, those who are overwhelmingly irrational are noted to be outliers, implying that
a significant proportion of terrorists are still subject to rational considerations even if
they possess irrational motivations (Caplan, 2006). Therefore, formal institutions,
through increasing the perceived risks of terrorism, can deter individuals from terrorism
by appealing to the common rational desire in most to maximize utility.
In comparison, while informal institutions are able to influence motivations directly,
they are of arguably little help in the short term. Indeed, building social capital can
increase trust among individuals (Glaeser, Laibson, Scheinkman & Soutter, 1999),
contributing to a socially-cohesive community which is more psychologically resistant
to extremist ideology. Unfortunately, social capital takes a long time to build, and
solutions focused on building social capital cannot be immediately effective.
Furthermore, although informal institutions can be used to shape positive morals and
virtues, such a method would not be sufficiently comprehensive to curb terrorism.
Undeniably, informal institutions have the power to influence our world views
significantly, prescribing a set of beliefs and ethical standards which we live by. Similar
to how certain interpretations of religious texts can be used to promote religious
extremism (Dandachli, 2017), informal institutions can also be used to encourage a
peaceful way of living. However, the thoughts and interpretations of individuals
ultimately cannot be controlled: To the extent that religious leaders can step out to
denounce extremist interpretations of religious texts, terrorist groups can also reach out
to spread and support such interpretations. Therefore, attempting to curb terrorism by
using informal institutions to spread a peaceful world view to everyone—while ideal—
would hardly be feasible.
Informal institutions are doubtlessly important in influencing motivations.
However, we have more control over our use of formal institutions as compared to
informal institutions in achieving the desired outcome. Focusing on formal institutions
to influence motivations via shaping external conditions would therefore be the more
pragmatic choice.
Rectifying structural deficiencies: increasing terrorism’s opportunity cost
Formal institutions, unlike informal institutions, have the capacity to directly close
structural gaps, such as in addressing economic constraints which have been identified
to contribute to terrorism (Newman, 2006). States are able to implement policies
directed at alleviating poverty and reducing inequity, improving material standards of
living. This reduces the perceived need of individuals to turn to terrorism. Such a
method also increases terrorism’s opportunity cost, which is defined economically as
the cost of the next best alternative foregone (Henderson, 2018). Increasing material
standards of living raises the value of leading a non-terrorist life: With more to lose,
there is less incentive for individuals to resort to terrorism, given that most individuals
are still guided (albeit to different extents) by their rationality (Caplan, 2006).
Informal institutions, on the other hand, are unable to change material conditions. While
some may argue that informal institutions can change an individual’s outlook such that
individuals do not resort to terrorism—whether these individuals end up attempting to
improve their material conditions through other means or accepting their present
economic reality—the impact of informal institutions is limited especially in
circumstances where material conditions are poor to the extent that even basic survival
becomes a challenge. In such cases, informal institutions would not be able to influence
one’s outlook as the foremost priority of individuals would be to ensure their survival
through whatever means possible, including terrorism. The most effective solution to
grievances arising from poor material standards of living would thus be to change the
economic reality itself, which can only be achieved by formal institutions. Formal
institutions, therefore, are more helpful in addressing material factors contributing to
terrorism.
Counter-terrorism: Focusing on formal institutions
Formal institutions have the power to manipulate external conditions such that they are
disadvantageous for terrorists, restricting opportunities for terrorism. Formal
institutions are also able to appeal to the rationality of individuals, deterring the
latter from resorting to terrorism by heightening the risk of facing consequences,
and increasing the opportunity cost of terrorism by raising material standards of living.
Meanwhile, informal institutions—although necessary—operate with higher levels of
uncertainty in terms of achieving the desired outcome, as compared to formal
institutions,
which are
able
to provide
more
feasible
and
comprehensive
plans. Therefore, formal institutions are more effective than informal institutions in
preventing the spread of terrorism.
This is true at least in the present climate of terrorism as well as in the foreseeable future.
However, changes in the form, scope, and range of terrorism over time means that the
relative importance of formal and informal institutions are also subject to change. The
effectiveness of informal institutions, for one, may rise given a longer time frame, and
focusing on using informal institutions may become more feasible when terrorism is no
longer as urgent a threat. Hence, while the use of formal institutions should be focused
on and maximized in present counter-terrorism strategies, periodic re-examination and
re-evaluation of the effectiveness of using formal versus informal institutions to tackle
terrorism are needed to ensure that the most appropriate counter-terrorism strategy is
designed for each context.
References
Al Jazeera. (2018, July 10). Truck Attack in Nice. Retrieved November 24, 2018,
from https://www.aljazeera.com/programmes/aljazeeraworld/2018/07/truck-attacknice-180710132318265.html
Bohemen, G. (2016, December 12). UN Security Council: Open Debate:
Threats to International Peace and Security caused by Terrorist Acts. Retrieved
November 24, 2018, from https://www.mfat.govt.nz/en/media-and-resources/ministrystatements-and-speeches/un-security-council-open-debate-threats-to-internationalpeace-and-security-caused-by-terrorist-acts-3/
Caplan, B. (2006). Terrorism: The relevance of the rational choice
model. Public Choice, 128(1-2), 91-107. doi:10.1007/s11127-006-9046-8
Dodd, H. (2018, March 17). Why is it so easy to buy bomb ingredients?
Retrieved November 24, 2018, from https://www.bbc.com/news/uk-42690177
Dandachli, R. (2017, January 05). Fighting ideology with ideology: Islamism
and
the
challenge
of
ISIS.
Retrieved
November
25,
2018,
from
https://www.brookings.edu/opinions/fighting-ideology-with-ideology-islamism-andthe-challenge-of-isis/
Hoffman, B. (2017). Inside terrorism. New York: Columbia University Press.
Huntington, S. P. (2011). The clash of civilizations and the remaking of world
order. New York: Simon & Schuster.
Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal Institutions and Comparative
Politics: A Research Agenda. International Handbook on Informal Governance, 2(4),
725-740. doi:10.4337/9781781001219.00011
Henderson, D. (2018). Opportunity Cost. Retrieved November 25, 2018, from
https://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/OpportunityCost.html
Glaeser, E., Laibson, D., Scheinkman, J., & Soutter, C. (1999). What is Social
Capital? The Determinants of Trust and Trustworthiness. NBER Working Paper Series.
doi:10.3386/w7216
Gun Policy (2018). Gun Law and Policy: Firearms and armed violence, country
by country. Retrieved November 24, 2018, from https://www.gunpolicy.org/
Meierrieks, D., & Krieger, T. (2010). What Causes Terrorism? SSRN Electronic
Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1148682
Newman, E. (2006). Exploring the “Root Causes” of Terrorism. Studies in
Conflict & Terrorism, 29(8), 749-772. doi:10.1080/10576100600704069
North, D. C. (1991). Institutions. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1),
97-112.
Schneider, F. G., Brück, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2009). The Economics of
Terrorism and Counter-Terrorism: A Survey. 14-31. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1679750
The Spectator. (2018, August 15). Terrorism isn't 'losing'. It has already lost.
Retrieved November 29, 2018, from https://www.spectator.co.uk/2018/08/terrorismisnt-losing-it-has-already-lost/
Weber, M. (1972). Politics as a vocation. Philadelphia: Fortress Press.
Download