Mao Tse-tung and the Theory of the Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 Stuart R. Schram In the history of the Chinese communist movement, the re-emergence of the term "permanent" or "uninterrupted" revolution is clearly associated with the Great Leap Forward of 1958. It is then that the concept was first put forward once more after an eclipse of 30 years, and though it has since been employed from time to time, the most important articles on the subject were published in 1958 and 1959. The Cultural Revolution, has, however, altered our perception of this as of so many other important matters, both by making available new information and by placing the events of the previous decade, in a new perspective. Ten years ago, when I undertook to translate some of the articles on this subject which had appeared in the Chinese press, and to offer an interpretation of their significance,1 we were dealing with writings signed by relatively unknown ideologists who claimed to be speaking in the name of Mao Tse-tung. These writers did indeed quote a few tantalizing sentences by the Chairman himself, but it was impossible to put such citations in context and properly to understand their significance, since they came, as we now know, from inner-Party documents then entirely inaccessible. Now we are in a position to study Mao's own formulation of the theory, in the light of many other materials regarding the ideological and policy debates which took place within the Chinese Communist Party at the time of the Great Leap. The time therefore seems ripe for a reconsideration of the subject. In my earlier monograph referred to above, I considered the theory in three different contexts: as it derived from persistent traits in Mao's own thought and approach to politics; as compared to the views of other Marxist thinkers - Marx, Lenin, Trotsky, Stalin; and as a reflexion of conditions in China at the time. In this article, I should like to follow a pattern basically similar, but different in emphasis. On the relation between Mao's theory and the Marxist tradition, and especially on the similarities and differences between Mao and Trotsky, I shall say relatively little, for I would not have a great deal to add to what I wrote a decade ago. I will refer once more to the differences between Mao and Stalin, for these are fundamental to an understanding of Mao's origin1. S. Schram, La "revolution permanente" en Chine. (Paris: Mouton, 1963). (Despite the publication date, the book was in fact written in 1960-61, and printed in 1962.) 222 The China Quarterly ality. My main concern, however, will be neither with the history of Marxist doctrine, nor with the contrast between the Soviet and Chinese conceptions of revolution, but with the circumstances in which the theory emerged in China in 1958. The information which has become available about past ideological differences between Mao and his comrades is worthy of interest in itself, but it can also guide us in taking a new look at the reality which called forth such radically different responses. It is this dimension of the problem which was most inadequately treated in my earlier monograph. It should be possible today to grasp somewhat better this central question of the relation between theory and practice. It is perhaps appropriate to say a word, at the very beginning, about the tedious but inescapable question of how "pu-tuan ko-ming" should be translated. During the period of the Great Leap, the term was, of course, rendered into western languages, in official translations published in Peking, as "uninterrupted" or "continuous" revolution.2 Although this is the most accurate translation in terms of the literal meaning of the Chinese expression, I preferred in the early 1960s, and still prefer today, the translation "permanent revolution." The essential reason for this lies in the fact that pu-tuan ko-ming is the term which has been used for more than three decades, and is still used today, to translate into Chinese Trotsky's "theory of the permanent revolution." It was clear from the beginning that those who chose this terminology could not be unaware that they were courting a comparison with Trotsky. The situation has become even clearer since we have been able to read Mao Tsetung's speech of 28 January 1958, to the Supreme State Conference, in which he says: " Wo chu-chang pu-tuan ko-ming lun. Ni-men pu yao i-wei shih T'o-lo-ssu-chi ti pu-tuan ko-ming lun " (" I advocate the theory of the permanent revolution. You must not think that this is Trotsky's theory of the permanent revolution ").8 Quite obviously, if Mao were not deliberately using the same term as Trotsky, and thus inviting confusion, there would be no need for him to warn his listeners against confusion. Moreover, the Chinese used in 1958, and still use today, pu-tuan ko-ming to translate Marx's expressions "die Revolution in Permanenz" or "die Permanenzerklarung der Revolution."* Much more could be said on this question, but the foregoing remarks 2. Since 1969, the Chinese have suddenly started translating pu-tuan ko-ming as " continued revolution," instead of " uninterrupted " or " continuous " revolution, thus deliberately obscuring the difference between this term and the concept of "continuing the revolution under the dictatorship of the proletariat" (wucli' an-chieh-chi chuan-cheng hsia chi-hsu ko-ming), which became current during the later stages of the Cultural Revolution. I shall return to this point and its possible significance at the end of the present article. 3. In Mao chu-hsi tui Feng, Huang, Chang, Chou fan-tang chi'tuan ti p'i-p'an (n.p., n.d.), p. 3; translated (badly) in Chinese Law and Government, Vol. I, No. 4, pp. 13-14. 4. For the latest example, see the article by Chao Yang, originally published in Jen-min jih-pao (People's Daily) (Peking) on 5 July 1969, and translated in Peking Review, No. 5 (1970), p. 4. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 should suffice to explain my position. In any case, these semantic controversies about translation into a western language are obviously of slight importance compared to the problem of what the Chinese term meant to Mao - and to those who disagreed with him - and how it related to their own experience at the time of the Great Leap. Turning now to matters of substance, I should like to begin by situating the theory in the context of Mao's mentality and the development of his thought. If we are to approach this problem correctly, it is necessary, I think, to take as our starting-point a judgment which at first glance may appear paradoxical: as a philosopher in the strict sense, Mao is not original, nor even competent; and yet he has a profoundly philosophical turn of mind. Let us consider in turn the two aspects of this contradiction. As for Mao's grasp of Marxist philosophy as such, the most striking evidence is provided by the lectures on dialectical materialism which he delivered in the spring and summer of 1937 at the Anti-Japanese MilitaryPolitical University in Yenan. Until quite recently, these were known only from a fragment published in 1940, the authorship of which had been questioned by some. The complete text, revised "here and there by Mao in 1959, has now become available in the Red Guard compilation Mao chu-hsi wen-hsiian (Selected Writings by Chairman Mao). An examination of this shows that well over half of the whole text, and from 80 to 90 per cent, of those passages dealing with the principles of Marxist dialectics, rather than with their application in China, are copied more or less verbatim from translations of Soviet writings.5 5. Although Mao would apparently prefer to forget this production today, there is not the slightest doubt as to its authenticity. As I have pointed out elsewhere, articles by Chang Ju-hsin in Chieh-fang jih-pao (Liberation Daily) (18 and 19 February 1942) specifically referred to it as Chairman Mao's most important contribution to dialectics, and the very passage which he quoted (which I translated in part in a review in The China Quarterly, No. 29 (January-March 1967), p. 159), appears verbatim in the recently-available Red Guard text. The sources employed for Chapter II of "Dialectical Materialism" are the same as those identified earlier by K. A. Wittfogel in his study of Chapter I ("Some Remarks on Mao's handling of Concepts and Problems of Dialectics," Studies in Soviet Thought, Vol. m , No. 4 (December 1963), pp. 251-277). The extent of the plagiarism is, however, even greater than in Chapter 1.1 propose to publish subsequently in The China Quarterly an analysis of this text, with detailed indications regarding the borrowings from the Soviet writings translated by Ai Ssu-ch'i and others, and also of the changes made by Mao in revising, in 1959, the contemporary text of the lectures as published in K'ang-chan ta-hsiieh in 193S. (See The Political Thought of Mao Tse-tung (New York and London: Praeger. Revised edition, 1969), pp. 84-89 and 185-190. In view of the subsequent appearance of a complete English translation, in Joint Publications Research Service (JPRS) (Washington), No. 50792, I shall probably not go ahead in the immediate future with the plan announced there for publishing my own English version of paragraphs 1 to 6 of Chapter II.) The variants between the 1938 and 1959 versions are indicated in the Chinese text as reprinted recently in the edition of Mao's writings edited by a group of young Japanese scholars under the leadership of Takeuchi Minoru. (Collected Writings of Mao Tse-tung, Vol. 6 (Tokyo: Hokubosha, 1970), pp. 265-305.) (See the review of this issue, pp. 366-69.) By way of illustration of the extent of plagiarism involved in this text, paragraph 4 of Chapter II, as 223 224 The China Quarterly It is quite evident to anyone who reads through this text with an open mind why Mao preferred for the most part to copy rather than to express the same ideas in his own words. He was only an apprentice in the study of Marxist philosophy, and was afraid that if he reformulated the more abstruse theoretical points, he might distort them and betray his ignorance. But this point is not really of great importance, except to those who regard philosophy as the be-all and end-all of human endeavour. For though Mao's contribution to the "science of dialectics" is small, his contribution to the "dialectics of revolution" is very great indeed, and it is that which interests us here. His applications of dialectics to the problems of man and the universe, and above all to the problems of political struggle, are as picturesque and colourful as his formal exposition of "dialectical materialism" is awkward and wooden. More important, they translate a conception of man, society and the universe in ceaseless and unending flux which has no real parallel in Soviet thought, and which lies at the heart both of the Great Leap Forward of 1958, and of the Cultural Revolution. This mentality receives particularly compact and striking expression in one of the fragments on dialectics, dated "early 1959 or thereabouts," which appear in Mao chu-hsi wen-hsilan: Sons are transformed into fathers, and fathers are transformed into sons,' women are transformed into men, and men are transformed into women. Such transformation cannot take place directly, but after marriage sons and daughters are born; is this not transformation? The oppressors and the oppressed are transformed into one another; such are the relations between the bourgeoisie and the landlords on the one hand, and the workers and peasants on the other . . . The finite is transformed into the infinite, the infinite is transformed into the finite. The dialectics of the ancient world were transformed into the metaphysics of the middle ages, and the metaphysics of the middle ages was transformed into the dialectics of the modern period. The universe is also in the process of transformation; it is not immutable. Capitalism leads to socialism, socialism leads to communism, and communism too will be transformed, it will also have a beginning and an end, it will certainly be divided into stages, or there will be still another name, it cannot be established once and for all, having only quantitative changes and no qualitative changes, that would go against dialectics. There is nothing in the world that does not appear, develop and decay. Monkeys were transformed into man, man appeared and the whole human race will cease to exist in the end, it may be transformed into something else, and at that time the globe itself will have ceased to be. The whole earth will be destroyed, and the sun will also originally written, is made up as follows (using the symbols TK for Hsin chehsiieh ta-kang (Tu-shu sheng-huo ch'u-pan-she, 1936), and HC for Che-hsueh hsuan-chi (San-lien shu-tien, 1950)): TK, p. 191, lines 1-4 and 11-12, p. 192, lines 8-12, p. 193, lines 8-13, p. 194, lines 1-3; HC p. 161, lines 11-14, p. 163, lines 4-13; TK p. 194, line 12, followed by lines 4-11, p. 195, lines 11-13, p. 196, line 1, p. 197, lines 5-6, 7-9, 11-14, p. 198, lines 1-4, 5-13, p. 200, lines 3-4, p. 201, lines 2-3, 5-9. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 cool off, the temperature of the sun is already much lower man it was in ancient times . . .6 The basic point in this quotation, for the purposes of the present discussion is, of course, Mao's view of communist society as something which does not necessarily represent the ultimate destiny of humanity. I could not, however, resist including the first few sentences, which illustrate the fact that it is not only China's Khrushchev who clothes his exposition of dialectics in metaphors taken from biology rather than from physics and mathematics.7 There is a striking parallel between this passage and one written by Mao in 1918, when he was a student at the Normal School in Changsha. which is clearly inspired not by Marxism, but by the heterodox currents in traditional Chinese thought: I say: the concept is reality, the finite is the infinite, the temporal is the intemporal, imagination is thought, I am the universe, life is death, death is life, the present is the past and the future, the past and the future are the present, the small is the great, the yin is the yang, the high is the low, the impure is the pure, the thick is the thin, the substance is the words, that which is multiple is one, that which is changing is eternal.8 It would, of course, be absurd to suggest that there is today only Taoism and no Marxism in Mao's conceptual framework, though it appears that, at the time of the Great Leap, some professional philosophers thought just that. The Concise Philosophical Dictionary, Mao complained, contradicted him by saying that the concept of the transformation of life into death and death into life was "metaphysical," and the concept of the transformation of war into peace and peace into war was "erroneous."9 But another fragment of 1959, even as it illustrates, in curious language, the traditional notion that male and female merge into one another, adds a vital element absent from tradition, which Mao has drawn both from Marxism and from his own experience, namely the importance of struggle as the source of truth and progress: Errors must also be committed, it is impossible not to commit them, the commission of errors is a necessary condition for the taking shape of a correct 6. Mao chu-hsi wen-hsiian, pp. 29-30; also translated in JPRS, No. 50792, p. 32. 7. See The Political Thought of Mao Tse-tung, p. 94. 8. Quoted by Mao's biographer Li Jui. See The Political Thought of Mao Tse-tung, p. 26. 9. Mao chu-hsi wen-hsiian, p. 29, translated in JPRS, No. 50792, p. 31. The point of these criticisms was presumably sot Mao's idea that opposites are transformed into one another as such — since, as indicated by a quotation in paragraph 5 of "On Contradiction," Lenin, too, had spoken in these terms — but the nature of the examples chosen, which evoked all too clearly the old yin-yang dialectics. (Because of the very large numbers of editions, both English and Chinese, of "On Contradiction" now about, I have identified citations to this work, here and elsewhere, by the paragraph in which they appear rather than by the page number, with the thought that this would make it easier for the reader to locate them.) 225 226 The China Quarterly line. The correct line is defined with reference to the erroneous line, the two constitute a unity of opposites, the correct line takes shape in a struggle with the erroneous line. . . . That there should be only what is correct, and not what is erroneous, is without example in history. This is the negation of the law of the unity of opposites, it is metaphysical. If there were only men and no women, if women were to be negated, what would happen then? (Fo-ting nii-jen tsen-mo pan)10 The quest for the antecedents of the dialectical bent of Mao's thought is a fascinating - though perhaps insoluble - problem in intellectual history, but it is of less concern to us here than how Mao applied this approach to the problems of Chinese society during the period of the Great Leap. As a basis for the discussion of this question I should like to quote here in full the two main passages in which Mao, in January 1958, put forward the theory of the permanent revolution. Both of these are now available in translation,11 but there is always room for disagreement regarding the nuances of ideological texts such as these. Let me therefore present here my own versions, first of the brief paragraph from Mao's speech of 28 January to the Supreme State Conference, and then of the more elaborate formulation in paragraphs 21 and 22 of the Sixty j .Articles on Work Methods. I. Extract from Mao's speech of 28 January 1958 to the Supreme State Conference: I advocate the theory of the permanent revolution. You mustn't think that this is Trotsky's theory of the permanent revolution. In making revolution, one must strike while the iron is hot, one revolution following another; the revolution must advance without interruption. The Hunanese have a saying: "There is no pattern for straw sandals; they take shape as you weave them." Trotsky advocated that the socialist revolution should be launched even before the democratic revolution was completed. We do not proceed like that. For example, liberation in 1949 was followed by land reform, and as soon as land reform was completed, we set up mutual aid teams, followed by lower-stage co-operatives, and then by higher-stage co-operatives. Within seven years, co-operativization was carried out, and the productive relations were changed. Following this, we carried out rectification, and then, striking while the iron is hot, we proceeded, after rectification, to launch the technical revolution . . .12 II. From the Sixty Articles on Work Methods: 21. Permanent revolution. Our revolutions follow each other, one after another. Beginning with the seizure of power on a nation-wide scale in 1949, there followed first the anti-feudal land reform; as soon as land reform was 10. Mao chu-hsi wen-hsuan, p. 30, translated in JPRS, No. 50792, p. 33. 11. The speech of 28 January in Chinese Law and Government, Vol. I, No. 4, pp. 10-14; the Sixty Articles in Current Background {CB\ (Hong Kong: U.S. Consulate General), No. 892, pp. 1-14, and in Jerome Ch'en: Mao Papers (London: Oxford University Press, 1970), pp. 57-75. 12. Mao chu-hsi tui Feng . . . , p. 3. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 completed, agricultural co-operativization was begun. There also followed the socialist transformation of private industry, commerce and handicrafts. The three great socialist transformations, that is to say, the socialist revolution in the ownership of the means of production, were basically completed in 1956. Following this, we carried out last year the socialist revolution on the political and ideological fronts. This revolution can be basically concluded before July 1st of this year. But the problem is still not resolved, and for a fairly long period to come, the method of airing of views and rectification must be used every year to solve the problems in this field. We must now have a technical revolution, in order to catch up with and overtake England in fifteen years or a bit longer. Because China is economically backward, and its material foundation is weak, we have hitherto been in a passive position. Mentally, we feel that we are still fettered; in this respect, we have not yet achieved liberation. We must summon up our energies, and in another five years, we may be in a somewhat more active position. After ten years, we will be in a still more active position. After fifteen years, when we have more grain and more iron and steel, we will be in a position to exercise yet greater initiative. Our revolution is like fighting a war. After winning one battle, we must immediately put forward new tasks. In this way, we can maintain the revolutionary enthusiasm of the cadres and the masses, and diminish their self-satisfaction, since they have no time to be satisfied with themselves even if they wanted to; new tasks keep pressing in, and everyone devotes his mind to the question of how to fulfil the new tasks. In calling for a technical revolution, we aim to make everyone study technology and science. The rightists say we are petty intellectuals, incapable of leading the big intellectuals. There are also those who say that the old cadres should be "bought off," paid a bit of money and asked to retire, because the old cadres do not understand science and technology, and only know how to fight and to carry out land reform. We must definitely summon up all our energies, we must definitely study and carry through this great technical revolution bestowed on us by history. This question must be discussed in cadres' meetings, and we must hold a general meeting of cadres to discuss what other skills we possess. In the past, we were capable of fighting and of carrying out land reform. Now it is not enough to possess these skills alone. We must learn new skills, we must really understand professional work (yeh-wu), we must really understand science and technology. Otherwise, we will be incapable of exercising good leadership. In " On People's Democratic Dictatorship," which I wrote in 1949, I had this to say: " The serious task of economic construction lies before us. We shall soon put aside some of the things we know well, and be compelled to do things we don't know well. This means difficulties." "We must overcome difficulties, we must learn what we do not know." A period of eight years has elapsed. During these eight years, one revolution has followed another, and with everyone's mind concentrated on these problems, a great many people were unable to find time to study science and technology. Beginning mis year, we must, even as we carry forward and complete the socialist revolution on the political and ideological fronts, shift the emphasis in the Party's work to the technical revolution. This question must receive the attention of the whole Party. Party committees at all levels may carry out a preliminary exchange of views within the Party in advance, and explain things clearly to the cadres, but for the time being no propaganda should appear in the press. After July 1st, 227 228 The China Quarterly we will play up the matter, because by that time the rectification campaign at the grassroots level will be drawing to a close, and the main attention of the Party can be shifted to the technical revolution. Once attention is shifted to the technical side, there is also the possibility of neglecting politics. We must therefore pay attention to integrating technology with politics. 22. The relation between redness and expertness, between politics and professional activities (yeh-wu), is that of the unity of two opposites. We must definitely criticize and repudiate the tendency to pay no attention to politics. On the one hand, we must oppose empty-headed politicians; on the other hand, we must oppose pragmatists who lose their sense of direction. There is not the slightest doubt about the unity of politics and economics, the unity of politics and technology. This is the case year after year, and will be the case for ever. This is precisely what is meant by " both red and expert." The term "politics" will continue to exist in the future, but its content will change. Those who pay no attention to ideology and politics, and are busy with their work all day long, will become economists or technicians who have lost their sense of direction, and this is very dangerous. Ideological work and political work are the guarantee that economic and technical work will be carried through, they serve the economic basis. Ideology and politics are 'the supreme commander; they are the soul. Whenever we are even slightly lax in our ideological and political work, our economic and technical work will certainly take a false direction. At present, there is on the one hand the grave class struggle between the socialist world and the imperialist world. On the other hand, as regards conditions within our country, classes have not yet been finally wiped out, and there is still class struggle. These two points must be taken fully into account. In the past, the basic content of politics consisted in struggle against the class enemy. But after the people come to have their own political power, the relationship between this political power and the people is basically a relationship among the people, and the method employed is not forcible repression, but persuasion. This is a new political relationship. It is only in dealing with the law breakers among the people who disrupt the normal social order that this political power adopts temporarily, and in varying degrees, methods of forcible repression, as a supplement to persuasion. During the period of transition from capitalism to socialism, there are still hidden among the people some anti-socialist hostile elements, such as the bourgeois rightists. In dealing with such elements, we also adopt basically the method of solving the problems by letting the masses air their views. It is only toward serious counter-revolutionary elements and saboteurs that we adopt the method of repression. After the transition period has come to an end, and classes have been completely abolished, then, as far as conditions within the country are concerned, politics will consist entirely of relationships among the people. At that time, ideological and political struggle among man and man, as well as revolution, will definitely still continue to exist, and moreover cannot fail to exist. The law of the unity of opposites, the law of quantitative and qualitative change, the law of affirmation and negation, exist forever and universally. But the nature of struggle and revolution is different from what it was in the past It is not a class struggle, but a struggle between the advanced and the backward among the people, a struggle between advanced and backward science and technology. The Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 transition from socialism to communism is a struggle, a revolution. Even when we have reached the era of communism, there will definitely still be many, many stages of development, and the relationship between one stage and another will necessarily be a relation leading from quantitative change to qualitative change. Every mutation or leap is a revolution, and they must all go through struggle. The " theory of no clashes " is metaphysical. Politicians must understand something of specialized work (yeh-wu). It is difficult to understand too much, but it won't do to understand too little either; they must definitely understand something of i t Those who do not understand reality are pseudo-red; they are empty-headed politicians. We must integrate politics with technology. In agriculture we must run experimental plots; in industry, we must grasp advanced models, try out new techniques, and experiment with the manufacture of new products. All this involves using the method of " comparison." Under similar conditions, the advanced and the backward are compared, thus inciting the backward to catch up with the advanced. The advanced and the backward are the two extremities of a contradiction, and "comparison" is the unity of opposites. There is disequilibrium between one enterprise and another, and, within an enterprise, between one workshop and another, one work group and another, one individual and another. Disequilibrium is a universal objective law. Things forever proceed from disequilibrium to equilibrium, and from equilibrium to disequilibrium, in endless cycles. It will be forever like this, but each cycle reaches a higher level. Disequilibrium is constant and absolute; equilibrium is temporary and relative. The changes in economic equilibrium and disequilibrium in our country at the present time involve many partial qualitative changes in the midst of an overall process of quantitative change. A certain number of years hence, when China has been transformed from an agricultural country to an industrial country, there will be a leap, and after that the process of quantitative change will continue. Criticism and comparison should be extended not merely to economics, production, and technique; we should also compare in the field of politics, that is, in the art of leadership, to see who can lead a bit better.13 These texts, and especially the second one, raise so many important ideological and policy issues that it is difficult to know where to begin in analysing them. It may be convenient to start with the problem of permanent revolution and the relation between the successive stages of the revolution, which occupied a prominent place in the controversies in Russia regarding Trotsky's theory. This aspect is not really central to an understanding of Mao's ideas at the time of the Great Leap, but precisely for that reason it will be helpful to get it out of the way first. The official position on this problem was laid down in the resolution of the Wuhan Plenum on the communes in December 1958, in which it was stated: 13. The above passage includes the full text of paragraphs 21 and 22 of the Sixty Articles on Work Methods, as given in an untitled collection of Mao's writings and speeches distributed by Richard Sorich of Columbia University. Mao's preface is dated 31 January 1958; the document was apparently distributed by the Central Committee on 19 February. 229 230 The China Quarterly On the question of transition from socialism to communism, we must not mark time at the socialist stage, nor should we drop into the Utopian dream of skipping the socialist stage and jumping over to the communist stage. We are advocates of the Marxist-Leninist theory of permanent revolution; we hold that no "Great Wall" exists or can be allowed to exist between the democratic revolution and the socialist revolution and between socialism and communism. We are at the same time advocates of the Marxist-Leninist theory of the development of revolution by stages; we hold that different stages of development reflect qualitative changes and that these stages, different in quality, should not be confused.14 This was entirely in accord with what Mao had said in 1937 about the relation between the democratic and the socialist revolutions: In the case of a two-part essay, the second part can be written only after the first part has been completed. Resolute leadership of the democratic revolution is the condition for achieving the victory of socialism. . . . We advocate the theory of the transition of the revolution, of the transition from a democratic revolution to a socialist orientation. The democratic revolution will undergo several stages of development, all under the slogan of a democratic republic, not that of a soviet regime. . . . We advocate the theory of the transition of the revolution, not the Trotskyite theory of permanent revolution nor semi-Trotskyite "Li Li-sanism." We stand for going through all the necessary stages of a democratic republic in order to arrive at socialism.15 As I wrote in my 1963 monograph on the subject, this warning against the temptation of leaping from one stage to another was above all a verbal precaution to ward off the accusations that Mao was imitating Trotsky, who had explicitly called for "telescoping" the stages of the revolution.16 For, although in the course of the Chinese revolution, both before and after 1949, Mao has shown a strong sense of the need to distinguish "stages" - that is, a realization that everything was not possible at a given time - he has also been reluctant to draw the boundaries between these stages too rigidly, lest they serve as a pretext for inaction and for lack of vigour in pressing the revolution. This aspect of Mao's thinking comes through clearly in a brief passage on the permanent revolution in his speech of March 1958 at the Chengtu conference, which marked the real beginning of the implementation of the Great Leap Forward policies, when he said: In the democratic revolution of the past, the revolution was constantly divided into two stages, the former serving as a preparation for the latter. We are partisans of the theory of the permanent revolution, and yet so many comrades give no thought to the time for carrying out the socialist revolution, or to how land reform should be carried out. They close their eyes to the sprouts of socialism (she-hui-chu-i meng-ya), although the sprouts 14. H. Can-fere d'Encausse and S. Schram, Marxism and Asia (London: Allen Lane, The Penguin Press, 1969), p. 302. 15. The Political Thought of Mao Tse-tung, pp. 226-227. 16. La "revolution permanente" en Chine, pp. xviii, xxvii. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 of socialism appeared long ago. For example, in Juichin, and in the amtiJapanese base areas, sprouts of socialism appeared in the form of mutual-aid teams.17 The use of the term meng-ya, or sprouts, the same which figured in the celebrated controversy of a decade ago about " sprouts of capitalism " under the (presumably feudal) society of the Ming, clearly implies that, even during the phase of the democratic revolution, socialist elements were maturing within the womb of the old society. Similarly, even though the exaggerated claims about building communism overnight were abandoned in December 1958, it was still postulated that "communist elements" existed in the China of the communes, and that they must be actively cultivated, so that a number of partial qualitative changes would have taken place in Chinese society and the final great qualitative change from socialism to communism would be merely a matter of form. There is still a distinction here between Mao's theory and Trotsky's "telescoping" and "leaping over" stages, but it is a very fine one. The problem of the relation between stages in the revolutionary process is manifestly linked to that of the nature of the qualitative changes occurring in socialist and communist society. But before dealing with this, it is time to consider Mao's view of the state of Chinese society in 1958, and of the way in which the revolution should be carried forward. The reference, in the passage just quoted, to "so many comrades" who did not understand the need to cultivate the "sprouts of socialism" during the democratic phase of the revolution evokes the differences within the Chinese Communist Party in the 1950s regarding the pace of agricultural collectivization. Clearly there were still disagreements at the time of the Great Leap regarding the speed of economic and social change, but the originality of Mao's position was characterized rather by the pattern and spirit he wished to impart to the whole process. The essence of his approach is summed up in homely form in the Hunanese folk-saying quoted in his speech of 28 January, and in more philosophical terms in the concept of "disequilibrium" expounded in the Sixty Articles. "There is no pattern for straw sandals; they take shape as you work on them." In other words, the course of the revolution cannot be laid down in advance in all its details. The broad goals economic development, socialism, communism - are of course known, but their meaning, and the path for reaching them, must be continually reassessed in the light of events. This view, which might be called Mao's "uncertainty principle," finds its theoretical justification in his insistence on the importance of "disequilibrium." One cannot fail to note the parallel between Mao's statement in point 22 of the Sixty Articles: "Disequilibrium is constant and absolute; equilibrium is temporary and relative," and what he has written else17. Mao chu-hsi wen-hsuan, p. 80. (The translation in JPRS, No. 49826, p. 48, unfortunately omits entirely the clause referring to the permanent revolution.) 231 232 The China Quarterly where about the universality and absoluteness of contradictions. Indeed, " On Contradiction " actually contains, in paragraph 4, a sentence referring to the fundamental character of disequilibrium. But, once more, the real key to understanding the meaning of this concept in 1958 is to be found not in textual comparisons, but in a consideration of Mao's economic policies at that time. As already suggested, it was not simply the very rapid pace of economic development set at the time of the Great Leap Forward which ultimately led to Mao's rupture with Liu Shao-ch'i and other Party leaders. In his public statements at least, Liu not only accepted the need for such an acceleration, but justified it most eloquently. Thus, in his speech of May 1958 to the Second Session of the Eighth Party Congress, he declared: Some say that speeding up construction makes people feel "too tense," and so it's better to slow down the tempo. But are things not going to get tense if the speed of construction is slowed down? Surely one should be able to see that a frightfully tense situation would exist precisely if more than six hundred million people had to live in poverty and cultural back-, wardness for a prolonged period. . . .18 The crux of the matter was rather the economic philosophy underlying the Great Leap, according to which the organizations at various levels responsible for taking decisions regarding industrial and/or agricultural production were incited to advance as rapidly as possible, without worrying unduly about the compatibility between all these different activities. To be sure, Mao had dealt at some length, in his speech of April 1956 on the Ten Great Relations, with the balance between the various sectors of the economy. The following year, discussing China's planned economy in his speech "On the Correct Handling of Contradictions among the People," he described balance as " nothing but a temporary, relative unity of opposites," continually upset by changes in the situation, but treated disequilibrium as the result of a "mistake" to be overcome.19 But, by 1958, his ideas had clearly undergone a change, for the paragraph in the Sixty Articles on Work Methods dealing specifically with the relation between national and local planning implies in reality the negation of balance as an effective principle governing economic development. The relevant passage, in paragraph 9 of the Sixty Articles, is vital to an understanding of what Mao meant when he spoke, in more abstract language, of the universality of disequilibrium, and therefore ought to be quoted here: There are three sets of production plans. The Center has two sets. One is the plan that must be fulfilled and is made public; the other is the plan that is expected to be fulfilled and is not made public. The local administration also has two sets. The first set of the local administration is the second 18. Marxism and Asia, p. 298. 19. Selected Readings from the Works of Chairman Mao Tse-tung (Peking, 1967), p. 361. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 set of the Center, and this is the one which must be fulfilled by the local administration. The second set is expected to be fulfilled by the local administration. Appraisal and comparison should be made with the Center's second set as the criterion.20 It is clear that, in this pyramid of plans, the lower one goes, the higher the targets. Thus the centre's second plan, which is not made public, sets higher targets than are publicly announced, and these higher targets are binding on the local authorities, who for their part are expected to set privately and to strive for even more ambitious objectives. When, in the atmosphere of euphoria which swept across China in the summer of 1958, local authorities at various levels and the leaders of the newly established communes began to vie with one another in setting increasingly inflated targets, the third set of plans referred to by Mao became in fact the only meaningful set as far as the greater part of China's productive activity was concerned. And since appraisal and comparison were to be made with the centre's second set - long since left behind by events - as the criterion, one can only conclude that there remained no effective basis for the co-ordination of production. But was this anything to worry about? Mao had clearly suggested in the Sixty Articles that it was not. Just as Hegel (and Mao himself) had described contradictions as the motor of all change, the passage quoted above implies that disequilibrium is a spur driving economic progress forward. "Disequilibrium," Mao wrote, "is a universal objective law. Things forever proceed from disequilibrium to equilibrium, and from equilibrium to disequilibrium, in endless cycles. It will be forever like this, but each cycle reaches a higher level." Not surprisingly, Mao's enthusiasm for disequilibrium was not shared by the planners. This was made abundantly clear, in terms both of theory and of practical policy, by the organ of the State Planning Commission, Chi-hua ching-chi {Planned Economy). Although Mao's draft of the " Sixty Articles on Work Methods " containing the passage already quoted, was dated 31 January 1958, the views expressed in the first four issues of this journal for 1958 were by no means fully in accord with Mao's. In the first issue, dated 9 January 1958, Li Fu-ch'un himself, after criticizing those conservatives who did not want to apply Chairman Mao's General Line for building socialism "more, faster, better, and more economically," turned his attention to the errors of the "adventurists." Such people, he said, rather than concentrating China's scarce resources on critical points, demanded that every sector and every productive unit forge ahead as rapidly as possible. The result of these uncoordinated efforts would be entirely counter-productive. Plans drawn up under the guidance of such thinking might be "well-intentioned," but they would lead inevitably to the negation of critical points, and of 20. Untitled collection (see footnote 13), p. 30; translated in CB, No. 892, p. 3. 233 234 The China Quarterly "comprehensive balances" among the components of the national economy." By the time issue No. 3 appeared on 9 March, the editors had manifestly read Mao's directive and felt themselves obliged to take account of it, but they did so in a spirit significantly different from his. "Equilibrium is temporary and relative," quoted the lead editorial, but it went on to say that in drawing up plans, this temporary and relative equilibrium was most important. Should disequilibrium emerge, strenuous efforts should be made to overcome it.22 Another editorial in the same issue, on the importance of the mass line in planning work, declared that when " difficulties and disequilibrium appeared in the course of implementing the plan, the masses should be consulted and mobilized in order to overcome such negative phenomena."28 In the April issue, those who regarded equilibrium as something absolute and unchanging were criticized, but the alternative offered was "living," "positive" or "active" equilibrium, rather than disequilibrium. A view according to which " the more disequilibrium the better, the sharper the contradictions the better " was described as "obviously untenable." "Active equilibrium," the editorial stated, "consists in letting the advanced carry along the backward, letting the backward catch up with the advanced. It is upwardlooking equilibrium, not downward-looking equilibrium."2* In other words, the essential principle remained equilibrium just the same. When issue No. 5 of Planned Economy appeared on 9 May, four days after Liu Shao-ch'i had proclaimed the slogan of " permanent revolution " at the Second Session of the Eighth Party Congress, it contained a resounding editorial on "putting politics in command" of planning work, in which the positive function of disequilibrium was finally recognized. The sentence already mentioned from "On Contradiction" stating that "disequilibrium is basic" was cited as the authority for this view. While the technique of drawing up balances should, of course, be used, it was wrong, the article stated, to reduce production of one commodity just because it was running ahead of others entering into the same process.25 This seemed clear enough - but the very next issue revealed how little enthusiasm the editors, and behind them the State Planning Commission, had for Mao's approach. It contained a symposium entitled: "What is the Basic Method of Planning Work," in which none of the four contributors appeared to agree with Mao. Three of the articles argued that the method of balances and the mass line should be taken as equally fundamental, and constituted in fact an inseparable unity. As one of them pointed out, there was nothing mysterious about drawing up plans and 21. Chi-hua ching-chi, No. 1 (1958), p. 3. The problem of translation is complicated by the fact that p'ing-heng can refer either to balance or equilibrium as a general concept, or to balances as a planning technique. Given the focus of this article, I have chosen the first alternative whenever the context did not preclude this. 22. Ibid., No. 3 (1958), p. 4. 23. Ibid., p. 6. 24. Ibid., No. 4 (1958), p. 2. 25. Ibid., No. 5 (1958), pp. 1-2. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 balances, and the masses were already doing it; the Party's slogan "Let the whole people manage industry" meant precisely "Let the whole people do planning." The remaining author came down firmly in favour of the idea that the method of balances was and must remain the basic method of planning work, though it might have been misapplied in the past by those divorced from the masses and obsessed with equilibrium for its own sake. The basic task was to "organise equilibrium on the foundation of the mass line." Only one of the contributors even mentioned such a thing as disequilibrium, and he dealt with the topic by quoting the relevant passage from Mao's speech of 27 February 1957, drawing from it the conclusion: " We can see that Chairman Mao, like Lenin, regards balance as the mark of the superiority of a planned economy."26 At the end of 1958, Planned Economy ceased publication. Times had, of course, changed, but an article in the very first issue of the new journal combining planning and statistics showed how little the planners had altered their views. The human consciousness, the author said, has a tendency to lean to one side (i pien too, as recommended by Mao in 1949 in "On People's Democratic Dictatorship"). In the past, there were a lot of people who stressed comparisons and equilibrium, and made absolutes of them, imagining that the whole national economy should advance in good order like the ranks of an army. When, in 1958, the iron and steel industry had forged ahead in the course of the Great Leap, this "old theory of equilibrium" had been subjected to quite justified criticism. But others had now fallen into the opposite error, imagining that comparison and balances were no longer necessary. In this other mistaken view: It is all right if there is disequilibrium in the development of the national economy; wherever the Commander-in-chief goes, the others will follow. If there is disequilibrium, well, let there be disequilibrium. These people hold that in planning work, there is no need to calculate material balances, or to pay attention to what is possible in the light of material and technical conditions, otherwise it is "negative equilibrium," or "the theory of conditions." " It would be going too far to assume that the "commander-in-chief" referred to in this passage was today's "great supreme commander and great helmsman"; the reference is presumably to the local Party secretaries who were making bold claims for their area or commune. But the view ridiculed here sounds strangely like that of Chairman Mao. The purpose of interpolating the above passage on the theoretical discussions of 1958-59 is not to give a complete and balanced account of the views of Chinese economists, since that would require a much more detailed analysis of the ideas expounded in many journals, including, in particular, Ching-chi yen-chiu (Economic Research), which took a 26. Ibid. No. 6 (1958), pp. 13-18. 27. Chi-hua yii tung-chi (Planning and Statistics), No. 1 (1959), p. 7. 235 236 The China Quarterly somewhat different line.28 It is rather to suggest, on the basis of actual materials rather than of imagination, some of the policy debates which lay behind Mao's theories at the time of the Great Leap. Mao himself admitted, in his speech of 23 July 1959 at Lushan, that the methods he had been promoting, if carried to an extreme (as in fact they were), amounted to the negation of planning. Although he put the blame, rather disingenuously, on the State Planning Commission, which had ceased, from the summer of 1958, to draw up comprehensive balances for the national economy, he did recognize that he had not adequately grasped the complexities of the problem: They rejected comprehensive balances, they completely failed to calculate the amounts of coal, iron and transport required. Coal and iron cannot walk by themselves, they must be transported in wagons. This point I had not foreseen.29 This does not mean, of course, that Mao repudiated, in 1959 or at any time thereafter, the basic convictions underlying the Great Leap Forward, which might be summed up, in grossly oversimplified form, as follows: (1) Rapid economic development was indispensable if China were to maintain her position in the world, especially at a time when it was already clear that less support and assistance would be forthcoming from the Soviet Union. (2) This development, as Mao had begun to spell out in his collectivization speech of 31 July 1955, would have to be labour intensive rather than capital intensive, and would thus call for many small-scale local undertakings, which could hardly be centrally planned and controlled, and would therefore require a large measure of initiative at the grass roots. (3) Many cadres, both political and technical, had not adequately grasped the urgency of more rapid development or the need to break new paths to achieve it. We have already suggested that the pace of development was not in itself a decisive issue, at least between Mao and Liu Shao-ch'i. More controversial was the problem of keeping cadres constantly on their toes and urging them to go all out. " The ideology of the permanent revolution," wrote one of the authors whose articles on the subject I translated a decade ago, "is an ideology which constantly stimulates the enthusiasm of the cadres and the masses."80 As we have already seen, this was directly inspired by Mao's own statement, in the Sixty Articles of January 28. For the views on equilibrium and "proportioned development" of another very senior and influential Chinese economist, see Kenneth Walker, "Ideology and Economic Discussion in China: Mao Yin-ch'u on Development Strategy and his Critics," Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. XI, No. 2, Part I (January 1963), pp. 113-133. 29. Mao chu-hsi tui Feng . . . . p . 10. 30. Kao Yang-chih, article in Cheng-chih hsiieh-hsi (Political Study), No. 18 (1959), in La " revolution permanente " en Chine, pp. 57-58. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 1958, that permanent revolution is a way to " maintain the revolutionary enthusiasm of the cadres and the masses." There were, quite clearly, a certain number of what might be called genuine rightists in the Chinese Communist Party at that time, but the dividing line between Mao and Liu Shao-ch'i (as between Mao and Stalin, who had certainly not hesitated to force the pace of economic and social change in the Soviet Union) was not so much the question of tempo as the question of order versus disorder, of leadership versus spontaneity. To be sure, Mao is no worshipper of spontaneity and uncontrolled mass initiative. Informed that the Shanghai people's commune had proposed the abolition of " chiefs " (chang), Mao declared in February 1967: " This is extreme anarchy; it is most reactionary.... In reality, there will always have to be chiefs." ai And it is an open question to what extent the actions of the supreme chief in China over the past four years have promoted genuine mass spontaneity and initiative. But, as Mao himself said in 1956, summing up his philosophical credo in a single sentence: "Everywhere in the world there are contradictions; if there were no contradictions, there would be no world."* 2 If we endeavour to grasp what may have been the relation between the partisans of the Great Leap Forward and the real conservatives within the Chinese Communist Party, it is instructive to take once more as a starting-point a text from Chairman Mao, who said in his Chengtu speech of March 1958: In 1956, something got blown away - the general line of "more, faster, better, and more economical," the promoters of progress, the Forty Articles [on agricultural development]. There were three kinds of people, and three different reactions: one was regret, another was indifference, and the third was rejoicing that something had got blown away, the feeling that a rock had dropped to the ground, and from now on the empire would be at peace. Of the groups of people having these attitudes, the two extremes were small, while that in the middle was large. Regarding very many issues in 1956, there were these three attitudes. When it was a question of fighting Japan, fighting Chiang Kai-shek, or land reform we were relatively united, but on the question of forming co-operatives, there had to be three attitudes. Is this assessment correct?88 It has, of course, been pointed out by many people in the past (in particular by Franz Schurmann), that the radical impulse imparted to Chinese economic policies by Mao during the second half of 1955 and the early months of 1956, was largely dissipated for a year and a hah*, from the spring of 1956 to the autumn of 1957. Here we have confirmation of this fact from the most authoritative possible source. These remarks of Mao's clearly fall within the compass of our present discussion, for the "to-k'uai-hao-sheng'" General Line was explicitly 31. Talk with Chang Ch'un-ch'iao and Yao Wen-yuan, in Mao chu-hsi wenhsiian, p. 62; translation in JPRS, No. 49826, p. 44. 32. " On the Ten Great Relations." Untitled collection (see footnote 13), p. 19. 33. Mao chu-hsi wen-hsiian, p. 33; JPRS, No. 49826, p. 51. 237 238 The China Quarterly linked to the theory of the permanent revolution by virtually all those who wrote on it at the time of the Great Leap Forward, and regarded as the most succinct expression in concrete policy terms of the same radical impulse.84 Indeed, one of the most detailed and interesting articles on the subject went so far as to identify the two, declaring: "The great leap forward in the productive forces of our country has resulted precisely from the revolution consciously carried out by the people of our country in their social relations, as in the rectification movement and the formation of people's communes. It has been urged forward by the line of the permanent revolution put forward by Comrade Mao Tse-tung: 'Summon up all our energies, advance with all our strength, to build socialism more, faster, better and more economically.'"85 Other articles published in late 1959 and early 1960 describe the "permanent revolution" as a process of permanent or uninterrupted struggle with right opportunist thinking. Mao's statement at Chengtu in March 1958 made it plain, however, - as he has repeatedly done in other texts throughout his career - that the hot and the cold are always a minority, and the lukewarm form the great mass of humanity. The problem was therefore not only to combat the genuine rightists, but to stir the great mass in the middle out of their complacency. It will be recalled that, in the Sixty Articles on Work Methods, Mao specifically stressed this aspect of "permanent revolution," declaring: "Our revolution is like fighting a war. After winning one battle, we must immediately put forward new tasks. In this way, we can maintain the revolutionary enthusiasm of the cadres and the masses, and diminish their self-satisfaction, since they have no time to be satisfied with themselves even if they wanted to; new tasks keep pressing in, and everyone devotes his mind to the question of how to fulfil the new tasks." This passage was taken over in virtually the same words, though with the order slightly rearranged, in one of the articles I translated a decade ago. There the author proceeds to sum up this idea, and perhaps the main concrete implication of the theory, in the following sentence: "Therefore, in this sense, the ideology of the permanent revolution is also an ideology which continuously stimulates the enthusiasm of the cadres and the masses." *• But if the main policy implication of the theory of the permanent revolution is to urge on the cadres to mobilize the masses, there remains the intriguing philosophical problem of the nature of the qualitative changes occurring in socialist and communist society. Here Mao's originality lies partly in the simple affirmation that there will be revolutions even when the stage of communism has been reached. It will be recalled that the passage on the permanent revolution in the Sixty Articles on 34. Cf. Sun Ting-kuo, article in La " revolution permanente " en Chine, pp. 4-5; Kuan Feng, ibid. p. 18. 35. Wu Chiang, article in Che-hsueh yen-chiu, No. 8 (1958), p. 25; translated in op. cit. p. 23. 36. Kao Yang-chih, article in Cheng-chih hsueh-hsi, No. 18 (1959), p. 19; translated in La "revolution permanente" en Chine, pp. 57-58. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 Work Methods began: "Our revolutions follow each other, one after another." This sentence was quoted in a number of articles which I translated earlier. In two of these, the citation continues in quotation marks as follows: " I n the past it was like this, and in the future it will also be like this, it will be like this eternally. Even when communist society has been reached, it will be no exception; it is simply that, at that time, the nature and form of the revolutions will be different from those in class society, that's all." 37 This passage does not occur in the January 1958 draft of the Sixty Articles. It is reported that the Sixty Articles were re-issued in the spring of 1956 in revised form, as a regular inner-Party document, and these sentences may have been added at that time. In any case, there is little doubt that they stem from Mao. Even more interesting is Mao's conception of the nature of these "revolutions" under communism, and the way in which they take place. The essential point here, in terms of the philosophical concepts involved, is that the type of qualitative changes under communism which Mao has baptized "revolutions" will take the form of a rupture in the continuity of development, or of a leap from one quality or stage to another. The notion that there are sudden changes (ch'ung-t'u) and leaps (fei-yao) in the development of things appears twice at least in Mao's 1937 lectures on dialectical materialism, and both times it is taken straight from one of the two sources he is copying.18 There are, however, two fundamental differences. First, the Mao of 1937 (like his sources) saw the universe as involved in ceaseless flux, but as nevertheless unending and indestructible. For example, he wrote in his discussion of movement: [Dialectical materialism] holds that the appearance of a new form, a new quality, or a new category of things, arises from a rupture in the continuity and passage through a leap resulting from a clash (ch'ung-t'u) and a rupture (p'o chit), but at the same time the continuity and reciprocal links between things can definitely not be absolutely demolished. Finally, dialectical materialism holds that the world is inexhausible (unlimited), and this is true, not only of the world as a whole, but also of parts of the world. Does not the electron, just like the atom, manifest a complex yet inexhaustible world? We now know that the electron manifests no such thing. Indeed, the Mao of 1937, following his Soviet sources which still talked about the "ether" as something real, was much farther removed from the perspectives of modern physics than the Mao of 1959, with his vistas of a time when " the globe itself will have ceased to be." 8 9 This point, though intriguing, is obviously less central for our purposes than the nature of 37. Wu Chiang, article in Che-hsueh yen-chiu, No. 8, 1958; translated in La "revolution permanente" en Chine, p. 20. 38. See paragraphs 4 and 6 of Chapter II, compared to HC, p. 163, and TK, pp. 222-223. The quotation below is from para. 6. Cf. Collected Writings of Mao Tse-tung, Vol. 6, p. 288. 39. Mao did not modify the passage quoted above in revising his lectures in 1959, but then the revision of this text was very superficial. 239 240 The China Quarterly the political clashes and leaps which will take place under communism. Here the situation is, in a word, that Mao has moved forward from his Soviet sources of the thirties to a more radical vision of social change in the future, whereas, by the time Mao read these translations in 1936 and 1937, Stalin had already begun to move backward towards a less dialectical view of social change under communism. In 1927, at the height of the struggle with the Opposition, Stalin had given an eloquent description of the contradictions within the Soviet Union, even using the metaphor of "waves" which has since become dear to Mao: In our country there are classes, there are contradictions within the country, there is a past, a present and a future, in our country there are contradictions between them, and we cannot advance placidly through the waves of life. Our advance passes through struggle, through the development of contradictions . . . , through the discovery and liquidation of these contradictions The struggle between the old and the new, between that which is dying and that which is being born, such is the foundation of our development40 But, as early as his report of 1936 on the new constitution, Stalin declared that the frontier between workers and peasants was fading away, and that the contradictions between them were in the process of disappearing. And in the article on dialectical and historical materialism which he contributed to the History of the CPSU published in 1938, he stated categorically: " A n example of the complete correspondence between the relations of production and the character of the productive forces is the socialist economy of the U.S.S.R., where collective ownership of the means of production corresponds fully to the collective character of the process of production." 41 To be sure, in the last years of his life, Stalin refuted those Soviet ideologists who had drawn excessively sweeping conclusions from these words, to the effect that there were absolutely no contradictions at all, even minor ones, between the productive forces and the relations of production in the Soviet Union; he had been talking, he said, about the situation as a whole. But at the same time, he put forward the singularly un-dialectical view that contradictions' in socialist society were resolved not by revolutions, but by gradual change, without qualitative leaps. Even such a profound transformation as agricultural collectivization in the Soviet Union, he said, had taken the form of a gradual transition, "without ruptures," because it constituted a "revolution from above." 42 Whatever may have been his errors and sins later on, Lu Ting-i was clearly speaking directly for Mao when he challenged these views in April 1960, in the context of the great campaign against "modern revi40. Stalin, Sochineniya, 13 vols. (Moscow, 1946-51), Vol. X, pp. 330-331. 41. Istoriya Vsesoyuznoy Kommunisticheskoy Partii (Bol'shevikov) (Moscow, 1950), p. 118. 42. Stalin, Marksizm i Voprosy Yazykoznaniya (Moscow, 1953), pp. 28-29; see also his Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR (Moscow, 1952). Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 sionism" which had just been launched. In his speech on that occasion he criticized "certain theories" according to which "it suffices to consolidate the socialist system, and there is no need to develop it; and even if it must still be developed, even if we must still advance toward communism, it is quite unnecessary to pass through a struggle or a qualitative leap." In this way, he continued, " the process of permanent revolution of human society would continue to a certain point and then stop. On a philosophical level this corresponds to a metaphysical viewpoint and not to the viewpoint of dialectical materialism."4* We can now observe that Lu's very language was borrowed from Mao, who had written in the Sixty Articles: "Every mutation or leap is a revolution, and they must all go through struggle. The ' theory of no clashes' is metaphysical." This statement by Mao is clearly a direct attack on the views of Stalin himself. It is therefore not surprising that, in his Chengtu speech of March 1958, Mao should have declared: Superstition restrains our mind and does not allow us to consider problems freely. When one studies Marxism, it is very dangerous if one does not do it in an audacious style. Stalin also advocated audacity, but afterwards he deteriorated somewhat. Nevertheless, the Leninist foundation of his wri'tings on linguistics and economics [obviously " Questions of Linguistics " of 1950 and "Economic Problems of Socialism in the U.S.S.R." of 1952] was relatively correct, or fundamentally (chi-pen) correct.*4 If Stalin in his later writings was only "relatively correct" in Mao's eyes, this was probably in large part because he did not share Mao's open-ended, dialectical vision of the future of socialist and communist society, and believed instead that everything could be kept tidily under control by a "revolution from above." 45 This discussion of the theoretical differences between Mao and Stalin has brought us to the point where we can endeavour to sum up the essential policy differences dividing Mao not only from the Soviet leader and his successors, but also from a large group - probably the majority - within the Chinese Communist Party, as caught and refracted in the theory of the "permanent revolution." The argument about "revolution from above" versus the mass line contains within it, by implication, all the 43. Jen-min jih-pao, 23 April 1960. See also Wu Chiang's similar remarks as translated in La "revolution permanente" en Chine, p. 21. 44. Mao chu-hsi wen-hsuan, p. 79. The translation in JPRS, No. 49826, p. 47 is not quite accurate, and thus obscures some of these points. 45. Another interesting illustration of what Mao thought of Stalin as a philosopher is to be found in the original 1937 version of "On Practice," which constitutes para. 11 of Chapter II of the lectures on dialectical materialism. Here Mao said (according to the recent Red Guard text), after stressing the importance of dialectics as a guide to revolutionary action: "This complete doctrine of dialectical materialism was created by Marx and Engels, Lenin developed mis doctrine, and on reaching the present period of the victory of the socialist revolution in the Soviet Union and of the world revolution, this doctrine has again moved to a new stage, its content has become even richer. . . ." (Mao chu-hsi wenhsiian, p. 26). Not a word about Stalin in all this. 241 242 The China Quarterly other issues we have been talking about previously. For it means, in effect, no large-scale struggle among the members of society, since initiative is firmly in the hands of the leading Party cadres. It also means no ruptures or brusque leaps in the process of economic development, since the course of development is set by the planners at the centre and not by innovation from below. Finally, it means a stress on expertise rather than redness. As can be seen from the corresponding passage in the Sixty Articles, for Mao there was no "red and expert dichotomy"; it was indispensable that everyone should be both. For the Soviets and for many of his comrades, on the other hand, a choice was in fact necessary, and there was no doubt in their minds as to which should receive priority. Thus, I have looked (all too cursorily) at the theory of the permanent revolution, both as the expression of Mao Tse-tung's dialectical vision of the universe, and as a symbol of his uncompromising will to drive the revolution forward, despite the opposition of the conservatives and the inertia of the waverers, at a time when the rhythm of socialist transformation was constantly a subject of debate. It would be a fascinating exercise to trace this concept year by year through the ensuing decade, but the result would be to expand this article into a book. I shall therefore leap directly to the present, with only one passing glance at the intervening decade. The term "permanent revolution," though less in vogue than at the time of the Great Leap, has, as everyone knows, cropped up from time to time in Chinese ideological writings ever since 1958. It is perhaps of interest to note that an instruction of Lo Jung-huan to the People's Liberation Army (PLA) Political Academy on 12 September 1958, reproduced in February 1961 in the Bulletin of Activities,™ after stressing that the study of Chairman Mao's works was the primary thing, and the classical writings of Marx, Engels, Lenin and Stalin should be read "selectively," declared that the three main texts for learning Mao's philosophy were "On Practice," "On Contradiction" and the "Sixty Articles on Work Methods " - of which the only genuinely philosophical part is the two points quoted above regarding the permanent revolution and the dialectics of socialist and communist society. In other words, the " permanent revolution " was certainly still very much on the order of the day in 1961, as far as the PLA was concerned, at a time when Lin Piao was already deeply involved in turning the army into a "great school" of Mao Tse-tung's thought. This is most intriguing in the light of a paradox which I shall now simply point out, without seriously urging any explanation of it. This is that, while a reference to "permanent" or "uninterrupted" revolution has been written into the new Party Constitution, Lin Piao did not use the term even once in his very long report to the Ninth Party Congress, where the Constitution was adopted. Moreover, the term was wantonly 46. Kung-tso t'ung-hsun, No. 8, pp. 12, 14. Mao Tse-tung and Theory of Permanent Revolution, 1958-69 mistranslated into English as "continued revolution." 47 It is obviously possible to disagree as to whether pu-tuan ko-ming should be translated as "permanent," "uninterrupted," or "continuous" revolution, but to translate it "continued revolution" makes no sense at all. Why this should be done I cannot understand, unless it be to veil the difference between this term and the one used repeatedly by Lin Piao in his report, "continuing the revolution under the dictatorship of the proletariat." This is not a very convincing hypothesis, but I cannot think of any other. The brief passage in the constitution is a summary of most of the basic ideas going under the name of permanent revolution, as they were expounded by Mao Tse-tung in 1958: Socialist society is a relatively long historical stage. Classes, class contradictions, and class struggle will exist from beginning to end of this historical stage as will the struggle between the two roads of socialism and capitalism, the danger of a capitalist restoration, and the threat of subversion and aggression from imperialism and modern revisionism. These contradictions can only be resolved by relying on the theory and practice of Marxist permanent revolution. The great proletarian cultural revolution in our country is precisely a great political revolution under conditions of socialism, in which the proletariat opposes the bourgeoisie and all exploiting classes.48 Two months after the close of the Ninth Party Congress, in July 1969, Jen-min jih-pao published an article by Chao Yang ("morning sun" perhaps a pseudonym?) of " a certain unit under the PLA General Logistics Department," entitled "Conscientiously Study Chairman Mao's Theory of Continuing Revolution under the Dictatorship of the Proletariat." The expression in the title is Lin Piao's, but the term pu-tuan ko-ming occurs constantly throughout the article. For some reason, this article was translated into English only half a year later, on 30 January 1970; once again, the term is persistently rendered as "continued revolution" - except in referring to Marx, when it becomes "permanent," or to Lenin when it becomes (consistently with Lenin's own vocabulary) " uninterrupted." 49 Apart from references to events of the past few years, and an occasional quotation from recent statements by Mao, this article does not differ greatly from those published during the period of the Great Leap - for example, from that of Ju Ch'ien, published in Jen-min jih-pao almost exactly a decade earlier, on 27 June 1959. Perhaps the only significant thing about it is that it ends with the classic quotation from the resolution of December 1958 - which, as we have seen, was directed superficially at least against leftist excesses. This passage is followed by only two sentences of conclusion: " That is to say, we are partisans of a permanent revolution by stages, and also of continuing the revolu47. See the English version of the constitution in Peking Review, No. 18 (1969), p. 36. 48. My translation. Political Thought of Mao Tse-tung, pp. 327-328. 49. Peking Review, No. 5 (1970), pp. 4-7. 243 244 The China Quarterly tion by stages. (Wo-men shih yu chieh-tuan-ti pu-tuan-ko-ming-Iun-che, yeh shih yu chieh-tuan-ti chi-hsu-ko-ming-lun-che.) Once we grasp this theory, we shall be able to overcome and prevent both 'left' and right opportunist errors, and carry forward the revolutionary cause of the proletariat both actively and steadily." Instead of offering a lengthy conclusion about the significance of the theory of the permanent revolution yesterday and today, I propose to end with a piece of rather tentative speculation. Consider the strict parallelism of the balanced elements in the two sentences just quoted (which, incidentally, disappears completely from the Peking Review translation, since "permanent" and "continued" revolution are regarded as the same thing, and the first sentence is therefore telescoped to read "We are advocates of continued revolution by stages"). Could it be that "permanent" revolution is regarded as a potentially "leftist" thing, as well as a mentality which characterizes the activists, while "continued" revolution (i.e., chi-hsii ko-ming) is a potentially rightist thing, a thing which characterizes the steady, reliable elements, the backbone of the Party bureaucracy? Were this interpretation correct, it would follow that there exist in China today two tendencies, which might be called the party of activism and the party of order or moderation, and that Lin Piao is on the side of order. Perhaps the spirit of "permanent revolution," though the term is written into the Party Constitution, is not really very much alive in China today. WORLD POLITICS A Quarterly Journal of International Relations Offering articles based on research on the frontiers of scholarship—-in history, geography, economics, international relations, military affairs, foreign policy, sociology, and political theory. Articles of prime importance and interest appearing in No. 4 VoL XXIII July 1971 Development under Two Systems: Comparative Productivity Growth since 1950 Abram Bergson The Social Costs of Modernization: David E. Powell Ecological Problems in the U.S.S.R. The Arms Race Phenomenon Colin S. Gray Strategic Interdependence and the Politics of Michael J. Brenner Inertia: Paradoxes of European Defense Cooperation The Macedonian Syndrome: An Historical Model of Myron Weiner International Relations and Political Development Review Articles Political Science in the U.S.S.R.: " To Be Rolf H. W. Theen Or Not To Be " William Welch and Soviet Foreign Policy Studies and Jan F. Triska Foreign Policy Models One Year $7.50 . Two Years 11130 . Single Copies $2.50 Published under the editorial spoo orshipoftbe CENTER OF INTERNATIONAL STUDIES Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey 08540