Unit 2.1: Demand theory What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • Law of demand Income and substitution effects (HL only) Law of diminishing marginal utility (HL only) Demand curve Relationship between individual consumer demand and market demand Non-price determinants of demand Movements along the demand curve and shifts of the demand curve The importance of markets The market is a central feature of the study of microeconomics. A market for a good or service exists where buyers and sellers interact and the price and quantity of the product traded is established. Markets can be narrowly defined (the market for the touch screen iPad in Australia) or broadly defined (the world market for oil). The world market for oil is worth $86 trillion Neoclassical economic theory is the behaviour of markets based on demand and supply. The theory is focused on four basic theoretical market structures that are used to analyse how markets behave. The four structures are: • Perfect competition • Monopolistic competition • Oligopoly • Monopoly *Detailed theory on these market structures is set out in chapters 2.11(2) - 2.11(4). © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Defining demand Demand is the willingness and ability of consumers to pay a sum of money for a good or service at a given price and at a given point in time. Demand theory comes from the ‘human wants’ part of the central economic problem. Individuals want to buy goods and services because of the satisfaction they gain from consuming them. For example, the demand for social media sites like Facebook and Instagram is partly based on the human desire to interact with different groups and individuals. The law of demand – how price affects quantity demanded *In the analysis of demand and supply in Unit 2.1 and Unit 2.2 both the demand and supply curves are used in the diagrams to illustrate how different variables affect demand and supply in markets. In the coverage of demand in this chapter, an upward sloping supply curve is used to represent the output of firms in different markets. This is covered in detail in Unit 2.2. Changes in demand and supply in markets will affect price and output in markets and this is covered in detail in Unit 2.3 on competitive market equilibrium. The law of demand states that as the price of a good or service rises, the quantity demanded falls and as the price of a good falls, the quantity demanded rises (ceteris paribus). As such, there is a negative relationship between price and quantity demanded. The demand curve The demand curve or demand schedule shows the negative relationship between the price and quantity demanded of a good or service. This is shown in diagram 2.1 where the quantity demanded of the iPad increases from 20m units to 30m units as the price of them falls from $400 to $300. In this case, the price has fallen because the supply of the iPad has increased because of improvements in technology. Real income effect (HL) The real income effect can be used to explain the law of demand because a change in the price of a good affects the income households have available to buy the good. As the price of a good falls, the quantity demanded increases partly because of the real income effect. At a lower price, consumers can afford more of the product than at higher prices. In this case, the fall in the price of the iPad from $400 to $300 makes them more affordable to consumers, so the quantity demanded rises. The opposite occurs if the price of the iPad rises and consumers have effectively less real income to buy the good. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Substitution effect (HL) The substitution effect is based on the price of a good or service relative to alternative products consumers can buy to satisfy the same or similar human want. As the price of a good falls, the quantity demanded rises partly because the good offers greater satisfaction to the consumer per unit of money spent compared to its substitutes. For example, if the price of the iPad falls, it offers more satisfaction per unit of money spent compared to its substitutes. This means consumers substitute towards the iPad away from PCs. The opposite occurs if the price of a good rises and it offers less satisfaction per unit of money spent compared to its substitutes. The law of diminishing marginal utility Utility Utility theory is based on looking at demand in terms of the satisfaction an individual receives from consuming a good or service. The more satisfaction an individual receives from consuming a good the greater their demand for that good. A person’s satisfaction can be measured in terms of the number of utils they gain from consuming a good or service. A util is a unit of satisfaction. Total utility is the total satisfaction an individual derives from consuming successive units of a good. Marginal utility Marginal utility is the satisfaction an individual receives from the last unit of the good they consume and is measured in utils. In demand theory, you can relate the marginal utility someone gets from consuming a good to the price they are prepared to pay for the good. The higher the marginal utility a person gets from consuming a good, the higher the price they are prepared to pay for the good. The law of diminishing marginal utility states that for each extra unit of a good consumed by an individual, the marginal utility they receive from consuming the good falls. This is shown in the table where a person is consuming increasing units of chocolate biscuits. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 For each extra biscuit, the individual consumes the marginal utility falls. Consider the utility data in the table. When you are hungry the first biscuit will give you lots of satisfaction (15 utils) but as you consume increasing numbers of biscuits the marginal utility of each extra biscuit falls because you get less and less satisfaction from consuming each biscuit. Eventually, you will reach a point of consumption where you get no satisfaction at all from the good, which is the case with the fifth biscuit (0 utils). Relationship between total utility and marginal utility The relationship between total utility and marginal utility and units consumed is shown in diagram 2.2. If you relate the marginal utility from consuming each biscuit to the price the individual is prepared to pay for the biscuit in the table, you can see the price the individual is willing to pay falls as consumption increases because the marginal utility falls. Marginal utility and the law of demand The law of diminishing marginal utility can be used to explain the law of demand. If individuals get less marginal utility from the higher quantities they consume, they will be willing to pay a lower price. As quantity increases, price decreases. If an individual receives more marginal utility from less quantity consumed then they will be willing to pay a higher price. As quantity decreases, price increases. This is shown in the table where the amount the individual is prepared to pay for the chocolate biscuits goes down as their marginal utility diminishes. For example, the individual in the table is prepared to pay 0.75c for the first biscuit they consume because they receive 15 utils (marginal utility) of satisfaction from its consumption, but are only willing to pay 0.20c for the fourth biscuit because they get 3 utils (marginal utility) of satisfaction from its consumption. Relationship between an individual consumer’s demand and market demand The market demand curve for a good or service is derived by summing the demand curves of all the individuals in the market. In the market for music streaming, for example, the quantity demanded of each consumer at a given price is added together to get the market demand at that price. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Price of related goods and demand Substitutes A substitute for a good is an alternative product that can be used to satisfy a similar want in place of a good. A substitute for the iPad, for example, would be laptops. The more precisely a good is defined the easier it is to find substitutes for it. One brand of laptop computer, such as Sony, has many close substitutes from firms such as Panasonic, LG and Lenovo. There are also substitutes for Sony laptops such as personal computers and smartphones, but these are not as close as the branded alternatives. There is a positive relationship between the price of a substitute for a good and the demand for the good itself. If the price of laptops, a substitute for the iPad falls, then the demand for the iPad will fall as consumers substitute away from the iPad to the relatively lower-priced laptop. Changes in the price of a substitute for a good cause a change in demand for the good and the demand curve shifts. This means the quantity demanded for a good changes at each price. In our IPad example, a fall in the price of laptops causes the demand for the iPad to shift to the left. The fall in demand for the iPad is shown in diagram 2.3. As demand falls, the price of the iPad and the quantity traded both fall. Complements A complement is a good that can be consumed together with another good. The complements for the iPad include goods such as broadband connection, iPad stylus, cases, screen protectors, and apps. For example, if you buy an iPad you may also want to get a broadband connection in your house to access the internet on your tablet or buy some apps to access different web-based services. The complements of the personal computer. There is a negative relationship between the price of a complement for a good and the demand for the good itself. If the price of a complementary good for the iPad, such as broadband connection falls, then the demand for the iPad increases. This is shown in diagram 2.4. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Income and demand There are four basic relationships between the demand for a good and consumer income. Normal goods Normal goods demonstrate a positive relationship between income and demand. As income rises the demand for normal goods rises, and as income falls, demand falls. This is shown by shifts in the demand curve for a good. Most goods are normal goods. If household incomes rise they will spend more money on food, transport, housing, furniture etc. For example, a rise in income would lead to a rise in demand for the iPad, as shown in diagram 2.4 with a rise in price and quantity sold. Necessity goods Necessity goods are a type of normal good. They are goods that consumers need to sustain their normal lives. They include basic staple foods like bread and rice, housing, electricity and clothing. As household incomes rise, demand for necessity goods will increase, but at a less than proportionate rate than the increase in income. For example, if a person gets a 5 per cent pay rise may well use more electricity, but we might expect their consumption of electricity to rise by only 2 per cent. Luxury goods Luxury goods are another type of normal good. Economists sometimes refer to luxury goods when there is a strong positive correlation between income and demand. As household incomes increase, the demand for luxury goods increases by a greater than proportionate amount relative to the rise in income. This normally applies to goods and services consumers do not need to buy to sustain their lives, such as holidays, branded clothing, restaurant meals and tickets to the cinema. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Inferior goods Inferior goods show a negative relationship between income and demand. As household incomes rise, the demand for an inferior goods falls and as incomes fall, demand for an inferior goods rises. This relationship often applies to lowerpriced goods such as tinned fruit and vegetables, processed meats and manmade fibre clothing. Diagram 2.5 shows a rise in demand for tinned fruit as incomes fall in a recession. Other factors that change demand Population and demographics Population changes can have a significant impact on the demand for a good because it affects the number of consumers in the market. Population growth at a national or local level will cause a rise in demand for many goods and services, but it is often most noticeable in the demand for goods such as transport, housing, education and healthcare. At a global level, a rise in the world’s population leads to a rise in demand for goods such as food and water. In terms of population structure, there is an ageing population in many developed countries which has led to a rise in demand for healthcarerelated goods and services. Consumer taste Consumer tastes change over time due to social and cultural changes. The rise in demand for vegetarian and vegan food is partly due to social change, as more people give up eating meat for animal welfare, and environmental and health reasons. Firms can influence consumer taste through advertising and promotion. The huge sums spent by the sports businesses Nike and Adidas have a major impact on the demand for the products they sell. Price expectations The demand for a good or service in the present can be affected by consumers’ expectations of what the price for that product might be in the future. If, for example, a government plans to increase indirect taxes on new cars, consumers may decide to buy their car now rather than wait until the tax increases the price of the car in the future. This could increase the demand for new cars in the present. Expectations are particularly important in asset markets like shares and houses. Expectations of a future rise in house prices can increase the demand for houses in the present and this makes the © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 price of houses rise now and into the future. For example, if a person expects the price of houses to rise by 10 per cent next year, then they buy a house now and own an asset that may be worth 10 per cent more in a year’s time. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Unit 2.2: Supply theory What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • Law of supply Assumptions underlying the law of supply Supply curve Relationship between an individual producer’s supply and market supply Movements along and shifts of the supply curve Non-price determinants of supply Defining supply Supply is the willingness and ability of producers to offer a given quantity of a good for sale at a point in time and at a given price. Supply refers to the resource element of the central economic problem of scarcity. The factors of production (land, labour, capital, and enterprise) are used to produce goods and services on the supply side of a market. For example, supply in the sportswear market is made up of the workers who work for businesses like Nike and Adidas, the capital used to manufacture their sportswear products, the raw materials used in production, and the entrepreneurs who organise and manage the companies in the sportswear market. The law of supply – how price affects quantity supplied The law of supply states that an increase in price leads to an increase in the quantity supplied of a good or service, and a decrease in price leads to a fall in quantity supplied. There is a positive relationship between price and quantity supplied. The supply curve The positive relationship between price and quantity supplied is illustrated by the supply curve. Diagram 2.6 shows that a rise in the price of soft drinks from 60c to 80c leads to a rise in quantity supplied from 2 million to 3 million units. As the price changes, there is a movement along the supply curve. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Profits and supply The law of supply can be explained by how a rise in price can lead to an increase in producer profits. The increase in profit from a higher price gives producers a greater incentive to increase supply. The higher price also means a higher unit cost of production can be covered by the price. For example, if the unit cost of producing an extra unit of a soft drink increases as a firm produces more, the higher price can cover this extra cost and make the increase in production profitable. *The law of supply can be explained using the law of diminishing returns and how this affects a firm's costs of production. This explanation is covered in detail in Unit 2.11(1). Non-price determinants of supply Cost of factors of production Changes in the costs of the factors of production used to produce a good or service will affect supply and cause the supply curve to shift. If, for example, the cost of coffee beans used by coffee shops increases, then the supply of coffee from coffee shops will fall and the supply curve will shift to the left. This is shown in diagram 2.7 where the supply curve for coffee sold in coffee shops shifts from S1 to S2 and the price of coffee and the quantity of coffee traded falls. A decrease in the cost of factors of production would lead to an increase in supply, and the supply curve would shift to the right. For example, a reduction in the minimum wage would reduce the cost of labour for businesses like coffee shops and would increase supply. Competitive supply Many firms produce a range of goods, and a change in the price of one good a firms sells may affect the quantity supplied of other products they sell. An agricultural producer of soft fruit, for example, might sell strawberries and raspberries. If the price of strawberries rises, the farm may allocate more land to strawberries, which means less land is allocated to raspberries. As a result of this, the supply of raspberries will fall, and the supply curve for raspberries will shift to the left. If the price of strawberries falls the producers might reduce their supply of strawberries and allocate more land to raspberries which increases the supply of raspberries. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Joint supply When a production process yields two or more goods at the same time this is called joint supply. This means increasing the supply of one good directly leads to an increase in the supply of a good it is in joint supply with. Joint supply often occurs in the agricultural industry with examples such as beef and leather, wheat and straw, and mutton and wool. Another example of joint supply occurs in the production of oil. The refinery process for oil also produces the chemical bases for plastics. This means an increase in the supply of oil will lead to an increase in the supply of plastic. Technology As technology in the production process advances the production capacity of firms increases. As a result, businesses supply more to the market. This has been the case with manufactured goods like computers, mobile phones, televisions and cars. You can also see the impact of advances in technology on supply in service industries such as online music, games and film streaming services. Diagram 2.8 shows an increase in the supply of mobile phones as a result of improvements in technology in the mobile phone market. As the supply of mobile phones increases it leads to a fall in their price and a rise in the quantity traded. Supply-side shocks A country or region may experience supply-side shocks which lead to a decrease in supply. This is particularly true in agricultural markets where the weather can impact on growing conditions. Cold conditions in coffee-growing areas can dramatically reduce the output of coffee producers and the supply of coffee. The Tsunami in Japan in 2011 led to a significant fall in the production of cars as many manufacturers were forced to reduce output for a period of time. The destruction caused by a Tsunami that hit Japan in 2011 © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Price expectations Producer supply decisions can be affected by their expectations of what may happen to the price of a good or service in the future. If, for example, a construction company believes that the price of a building will be worth 20 percent more in two years, they may wait for two years before they put the building onto the market which reduces supply. If producers expect prices to fall, they may increase supply in the present. For example, housebuilders might increase the supply of housing in the present if they expect house prices to fall next year. Number of producers in the market As more firms enter a market, the supply in the market increases and as firms leave a market, the supply falls. The growth of online shopping has led to a rise in the number of delivery businesses. As more delivery firms enter the market, the supply of this service increases. Taxes When indirect taxes are levied on goods and services supply decreases as a tax adds to a firm's costs of production. For example, taxes on cigarettes, alcohol, and petrol cause the supply curve of these goods to shift upwards leading to an increase in price and a decrease in market output. *The impact of taxation on supply is covered in more detail in Unit 2.7(1). Subsidies A subsidy on a good or service leads to an increase in supply as the cost of production decreases. For example, subsidies on agricultural goods and renewable energy cause the supply curve to shift downwards leading to a decrease in price and an increase in market output. *The impact of subsidies on supply is covered in more detail in Unit 2.7(1). The impact of tax and subsidies on supply are covered in Unit 2.7(1) © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Unit 2.3: Competitive market equilibrium What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • Resource allocation through the price mechanism Signalling function of price Incentive function of price How price rations goods and services in a market Consumer Surplus Producer surplus Social/community surplus maximisation What is market equilibrium? Equilibrium in markets occurs where demand equals supply and the marketclearing price and output are established. The equilibrium price is known as the market-clearing price because at that moment in time all the consumers who are willing and able to buy the product at the equilibrium price can purchase it and all the producers who are willing and able to sell the product at the equilibrium price can sell it. Disequilibrium If the price of a good is not at the equilibrium level there is natural market pressure to push it to the equilibrium price. Diagram 2.9 illustrates the market for a music festival. The equilibrium price is $100 and the equilibrium quantity is 10,000 tickets. If the price is above the equilibrium at $150 there will be excess supply and there will be natural pressure for the price to fall to the equilibrium. At a price of $40 which is below the equilibrium, there is excess demand and the price rises to the equilibrium. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 The rationing function of price The central economic problem of scarcity means there is always a limited supply of goods and services to be shared out amongst consumers. Price has a rationing function in this situation because it distributes goods so there are no shortages or surpluses. All the consumers in the market who are willing and able to buy a good at the market price can buy it and all the firms in the market who are willing and able to sell their goods at the market price can sell it. The example of festival tickets in diagram 2.9 illustrates the rationing function of price. Changes in equilibrium The equilibrium price and quantity in a market will change if there is a change in either demand or supply. Change in demand A change in a non-price demand factor that shifts the demand curve will lead to a change in the market equilibrium price and quantity. The rise in the popularity of music streaming services because of taste and fashion has increased the demand for music streaming services. This leads to an increase in the equilibrium price from $10 to $15 and an increase in the quantity of music streaming from 2 million to 3 million units. This is shown in diagram 2.10. Change in supply In the same way as a change in non-price factors changes demand, a change in a non-price supply factor will shift the supply curve and lead to a change in the equilibrium price and quantity. An improvement in technology in the television market has led to an increase in the supply of televisions in diagram 2.11. This results in a fall in the price from $400 to $300 and an increase in the quantity of televisions traded from 5 million to 6 million units. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Functions of the price mechanism The allocation of resources Resource allocation is the distribution of the factors of production to different markets in the economy. In free markets, the price mechanism guides resources to different markets through what Adam Smith called ‘the invisible hand’. In this theory, price is seen to have two functions in allocating resources, the signalling and incentive functions of price. The signalling function of price When a price changes in a market, it sends information (a signal) to producers and consumers that market conditions are changing, and the price change provides them with information to make decisions on how they might act in response to the price change. Diagram 2.12 shows the market for olive oil. If there is an increase in demand for olive oil, there will be excess demand at the existing market price of $4 per litre. For the market to clear the market price needs to rise. The rise in price is a signal to consumers and producers in the olive oil market that market conditions are changing and provides them with information to make buying and selling decisions. The incentive function of price Once a price change has sent a signal to consumers and producers, they react to the price change based on the incentive to try and maximise their profits, in the case of producers and utility in the case of consumers. As the price of olive oil rises in diagram 2.12 producers have the incentive to increase the quantity they supply because the higher price means they can earn more profit from increasing the quantity supplied to the olive oil market. The quantity demanded of olive oil falls as the price increase means consumers receive less utility for each $ they spend on olive oil. When quantity demanded equals quantity supplied the market reaches an equilibrium price of $5 with 6 million litres traded. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Opportunity cost As the quantity supplied of olive oil increases more resources are attracted to the olive oil market. This is shown by a movement along the PPC in diagram 2.13. As more resources are allocated to the olive oil market output rises from 140 units to 200 units. This results in an opportunity cost of 30 units of corn oil as fewer resources are allocated to the corn oil market and output falls from 70 units to 40 units. Market efficiency Allocative efficiency Market allocative efficiency occurs when the quantity of resources allocated to a market maximises the community or social surplus in that market. This means resources are allocated so that the consumer and producer surplus are both maximised. This occurs when demand equals supply in a market. Consumer surplus The consumer surplus is the difference between the price the consumer is willing to pay for a good and the market price of that good. The demand curve expresses the price the consumer is willing to pay for the product. For example, the market price for hamburgers is $5 and this is shown in diagram 2.14. The demand curve shows that some consumers are willing to pay more than the market price of $5. Some consumers, for example, may be willing to pay $6 for a hamburger but they only need to pay the market price of $5, which is a consumer surplus of ($6 - $5) $1. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 The consumer surplus is shown by the green shaded area in diagram 2.14. The consumer surplus is an important concept and it has many applications in economic analysis. The consumer surplus can be calculated by working out the size of the green shaded area in diagram 2.14. In this example, the calculation is: ($9.00 – $5.00 x 600,000) / 2 = $1,200,000 Producer surplus The producer surplus is the difference between the price the producer is willing to sell their good for and the market price of the good. The price the producer is willing to sell for is expressed by the supply curve which is based on the cost of producing the good. The producer could sell for less than the equilibrium price, but it would not be rational to do this because the producer can make a higher profit by selling at the market price. A producer in our hamburger example might be willing to sell a hamburger for $2 which is a producer surplus of ($5 - $2) $3. The producer surplus is shown by the yellow shaded area in diagram 2.14. The producer surplus can be calculated by working out the size of the yellow shaded area in diagram 2.14. In this example, the calculation is: ($5.00 – $2.00 x 600,000) / 2 = $900,000 Social (Community) surplus Welfare is maximised in society when the social or community surplus in a market is maximised. This is where the benefit to society of the production and consumption of a good is equal to its cost. The social surplus is the sum of the consumer surplus and producer surplus in a market. In diagram 2.14 this is the total area represented by the green and yellow triangles. In this example, the calculation is: ($9.00 - $2.00 x 600,000) / 2 = $2,100,000 © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Unit 2.4(1): Behavioural economics (HL) What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • Rational consumer choice Assumptions of consumer rationality, utility maximization and perfect information Limitations of the assumptions of rational consumer choice Biases: rule of thumb, anchoring and framing Bounded: rationality, self-control, selfishness Imperfect information Choice architecture Nudge theory Rational consumer choice Behavioural economics considers consumer behaviour in a more complex way than classical economic theory. It introduces human psychology into the buyer decision-making process and considers how factors other than utility maximisation might affect whether someone buys a good or not. If, for example, you are going to the cinema you might not choose the film you think would give you the most utility. If you are with friends you may go to the film they want to watch to keep them happy, or you go to a film starring a particular actor out of habit even though you do not think the film will be that good. You might also be influenced by imperfect information about the film from a misleading '5-star' rating on the film's promotional poster which draws you to a film that is not as good as you think it will be. Biases Biases are the factors that influence individuals in decision-making situations and take them away from rational judgments. Herbert Simon (1916-2001) was a behavioural economist who believed that individuals who are confronted by complicated decision-making situations resort to heuristics. Heuristics simplify decision-making when individuals cannot work out the option that will give them the greatest utility. In buying situations people use mental shortcuts that allow them to make decisions in the time frame they are normally faced with. For example, when you are at the cinema you probably will not spend an hour researching all the films on offer, but spend a few minutes before deciding to watch the ‘crime thriller’ you know you would normally enjoy. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Rule of thumb This approach to decision-making in Economics is based on the belief people make quick judgments (heuristics) based on what they normally consider to be an expected outcome. When, for example, a person is in a Thai restaurant they might choose their favoured spicy option rather than base their decision on the expected utility of each item on the menu. By using a rule of thumb individuals are not making decisions based on perfect information so they are trying to optimise their utility from consumption rather than maximising their utility. By understanding how consumers use a rule of thumb when they are making buying decisions firms can make marketing decisions to increase their revenues. For example, a restaurant might anticipate what will be the most popular items chosen from their menu based on the way their customer's usual (rule of thumb) choices and make sure they produce enough of those items to meet anticipated demand. Anchoring bias Anchoring bias is a reference point in an individual’s mind based on the first piece of information an individual experiences and it strongly influences a decision they make. Anchoring is another aspect of how bias affects decisionmaking in behavioural Economics. Anchoring bias comes from a series of past experiences and it can even be formed in the mind of a consumer from their first experience of buying a good. When Apple first launched the iPad it was reported that the company would set a price of $999, but the actual launch price was $499. With a $999 'anchored' in the mind of potential consumers the $499 was a relatively attractive price and may well have led to higher initial sales than if the first reported price was $499. Businesses can use anchor prices in the mind of consumers to increase sales. For example, an electrical retailer might promote the normal price for a laptop computer at $500 and then discount it by 40 percent to a price of $300. It is a $300 computer but the anchor in the mind of the consumer at $500 and this makes them feel like they have got a good deal and they are more likely to buy the laptop. When individuals are buying personal computers, cups of coffee or cans of soft drinks, etc, the firms selling these products will build anchoring by consumers into the way they market these goods. Framing bias Framing bias is the way decisions made by individuals are affected by the way choices are presented to them. The important aspect of framing is the way information is presented in terms of the content of information and the use of language. In a supermarket, for example, you are faced with a low-fat chocolate mousse. The packaging could highlight, ‘20% fat’ or ‘80% fat-free’. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Research shows that most people will be attracted by the ‘fat-free’ label even though both options offer the same product. Framing is another example of behavioural bias. In this case, people may well see the benefit of losing 80 percent fat as more attractive than gaining 20 percent from buying the mousse. Research shows that framing something in positive terms is more attractive to consumers than in negative terms. Retailers often frame the word ‘free’ in marketing (buy one get one free, 40% extra free, etc) because it attracts consumers. Availability bias Availability bias considers how individual decision-making is affected by information that comes easily into our minds. This information is often based on our experience of recent events and how the outcomes of these recent events affect our decision-making. In many situations, our exposure to events distorts our view of the world and has too much influence on the decisions we make. For example, you are thinking of buying a train ticket and the probability of being delayed is 20 percent. You have made several train journeys over the last year, and you have not been delayed once so expect a good journey so you are more likely to book a train ticket. If, on the other hand, you have experienced several trips where delays have occurred then you might expect a delay on your next trip and be less likely to buy a ticket. In both cases, the probability of a delay is 20 percent but your decision to travel by train is likely to be influenced by your recent experience. Lottery ticket businesses, for example, will emphasise past winners when promoting tickets to consumers to make them think there is a better chance of winning than there actually is. Rationality Rational behaviour by individuals underpins much of traditional economic theory. Behavioural economists see this assumption as too simplistic, so they have developed alternative theories of rationality. Bounded rationality Bounded rationality is based on the theory that individuals make a decision that offers them a ‘good enough’ outcome rather than an ‘optimal’ or utility maximising outcome. The theory sees people as satisfiers, people who seek a satisfactory or acceptable outcome. If someone, for example, is in a fast-food restaurant like Macdonald’s they do not research their choice by asking other diners in the restaurant or by reading numerous online reviews, they might make a quick choice on what looks appealing and what they have eaten before. Consumers face three challenges when they are trying to make rational decisions in buying situations: • Consumers might have limited time to assess all the possible options when they are choosing a good. For example, when someone is rushing to buy a drink in a coffee shop in their break. • If there are too many choices on offer for the consumer they might opt for the most familiar option such as choosing a certain brand of biscuits in a supermarket. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 • A lack of information may also lead consumers to buy a product they know about rather than spending time researching alternatives. For example, when someone is choosing a novel to read they might choose the author they are familiar with rather than finding about a book by an author they do not know. Bounded self-control Bounded self-control is where individuals consume beyond the point where they maximise their utility when consuming a good. Utility theory predicts consumers will consume a good to a point where their total utility is maximised. There is, however, lots of evidence to show that consumers might not stop consuming a good even if it makes sense to do so. People, for example, might binge eat fast food beyond the point where they are still enjoying it. Online gambling firms often see their customers betting beyond the level they can afford. People often think in terms of current satisfaction when they are making buying decisions and do not consider the long-term implications of current consumption and how this might adversely affect their health and finances. A person might consume alcohol for the utility it gives them in present and ignore the future health consequences. Bounded self-control can be important to governments when they are trying to regulate the consumption of certain goods. For example, a government policy to try and reduce the consumption of 'fatty' food may need to account for bounded self-control. Bounded selfishness Bounded selfishness means individuals make decisions that benefit other people as well as themselves. Classical economic theory considers individuals to be concerned with their own welfare and satisfaction and not others. If people make choices to achieve the highest utility for themselves, there approach is a selfish one. Behavioural economists see this as a simplistic assumption because people often act with the welfare of others in mind. When, for example, a group of people is deciding on a restaurant for the evening, some individuals within the group may well accept the choice of others to make the whole group happy with the choice. Bounded selfishness is important for charitable organisations that rely on people acting in the interests of others rather than themselves. This can also be true when consumers buy fair trade products and pay a higher price for a good knowing it will benefit a fair trade producer. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Imperfect information When individuals make decisions, traditional economic theory assumes their decisions are made using perfect information. This means people buy goods and services and know what they are buying, and they can make an informed buying decision based on this. When, for example, you buy a loaf of bread for $1 you understand the nature of the good and the benefits it will bring to you. The $1 you pay reflects the money value of the utility you believe you will get from consuming the bread. People are, however, often in situations where they do not understand or know enough about the product they are buying and are therefore unable to put an informed valuation on the good. This is particularly the case in markets where products are very technical and difficult for uninformed consumers to understand. Computer virus software, for example, is difficult for buyers with a basic knowledge of computers to make an informed buying decision. A person may end up paying $100 for software that may not be worth that price. The products sold by the financial services industry such as pensions are often seen as services that people buy based on imperfect information. Choice architecture Choice architecture is where a business sets the layout, sequence, and range of choices available to a consumer in a particular way to encourage them to make a buying decision. Behavioural economists, Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein, researched how decision-making by individuals is influenced by the environment where a decision is taken. This environment is known as choice architecture and the person who designs the environment is known as a choice architect. Supermarkets, for example, are laid out to affect your buying decisions. Milk, for example, is often put at the back of the shop to make you walk through the store where you might make impulse purchases of other goods. The supermarket might also group complementary goods such as soft drinks and crisps together so you buy both goods. Another example is where shops put confectionery by the checkout might get you to buy a packet of sweets while you are waiting to be served. Default choices In this theory of behavioural economics, the default choice is the option the consumer selects as their normal course of action. This could be the brand of soft drink you always buy, the destination you always go to on holiday, or the news website you always use. The choice is normally the easiest one for the consumer and requires the least effort. Research shows consumers rarely change their default option and opt for an alternative. Choosing the default option in a decision-making situation strongly affects consumer behaviour. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Insurance companies often send out the details of a car insurance policy to existing customers before they have decided to renew their insurance. They often say someone's policy will continue next year if they ‘do nothing’. This is probably the easiest option for the consumer and the one many people decide to take. This default choice means an insurance company can more easily sell policies by offering customers automatic renewal. Insurance companies often increase the price of their car insurance for people who automatically renew their policy. Restricted choices Restricted choice is based on the theory of bounded rationality. If buyers are faced with too many choices they struggle to make buying decisions because they do not have the time to work their way through too many alternatives. This means it is easier for businesses to sell to consumers if they offer them a limited number of choices. For example, a retailer selling computer software to nonspecialist buyers might offer their customers a limited choice of software to make the buying decision easier for buyers. This also means the retailer can carry a narrower range of stock which reduces their costs. Mandated choices A mandated choice is one where the consumer is forced by law to choose an option before they take part in an activity. Mandated choices are important in aspects of government policy where the state wants people to decide on something. In the case of pensions, for example, people find it difficult to assess the benefits of a pension because they may not think about the long-term advantages of a pension and they also find the financial products associated with pensions difficult to understand. For this reason, governments in many countries force workers to choose a pension scheme from a set of alternatives. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Nudge theory Nudge theory is an area of behavioural economics developed by the Economists, Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstien in their book ‘Nudge’. Thaler won the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2017 for his work in this area. Nudge theory means using choice architecture (the way choices are presented to individuals) to encourage people to make decisions that will improve their own welfare and society’s welfare. A ‘nudge’ means changing any part of the choice environment an individual faces to affect their behaviour by making small alternations to the factors that affect their decisions. In the book Nudge, Thaler and Sunstien set out several examples of how nudge theory can be applied in different situations to solve economic problems. Here are three examples: The obesity problem Obesity is a major health problem in many countries. A major cause of this is how much people eat. Growth in portion sizes and the calorific content of food and drink has been an important contributing factor in causing people to put weight on. Obesity is associated with significant economic costs such as higher government spending on healthcare and reduced labour productivity at work. Tackling obesity is a problem for individuals. Low-fat diets, fitness programmes, and weight-loss drugs are some examples of how people try to reduce their weight. In the book, ‘Nudge’ Thaler and Sunstien put forward an alternative approach. They suggest people are creatures of habit and will unthinkingly do what they always do. For example, if people go to the cinema, they will always eat all the popcorn in the bucket they buy whether they are enjoying the remaining popcorn at the bottom of the bucket or not. The book also looks at an example of people consuming soup in an experiment where their soup bowls are automatically (unknowingly to the people in the experiment) re-filled. In the experiment, people kept on eating the soup beyond the amount they would normally consume because of a habit of consuming everything on their plate. The popcorn and soup examples show how out of habit people eat and drink what is put in front of them. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 The Nudge Theory approach to losing weight would be for people to buy smaller plates, reduce the quantity of food they buy and ‘keep less in the fridge’. This approach might be a useful guide for governments looking to promote weight loss in society. Saving money Saving for retirement is an important decision for individuals and governments. People need to have enough money to live on when they finish work so they can enjoy a certain standard of living. Saving for retirement is also important for governments that might have to support people who have not saved enough through the transfer payments the government will have to pay them. The economic problem of saving for retirement is that people tend not to save enough. Retirement is often seen as a distant point in the future for many people and they would rather enjoy a higher standard of living in the present than save for the future. Many employers set up retirement schemes where people can choose to save money in the scheme which often has some tax advantages. Employers will also top up an individual’s pension contribution with extra payments. This is a significant benefit for employees, but people often choose not to enrol in the pension scheme. In the book, ‘Nudge’ Thaler and Sunstein advocate an opt-out scheme rather than an opt-in scheme for pension contributions. In the opt-out scheme, someone who gets a job is automatically enrolled in the pension scheme and has to choose to not make payments. The ‘nudge’ associated with changing from opt-in to out-out works because people no longer have to ‘act’ to be in the pension scheme – it is easier for them to stay part of the pension scheme when they start work. To opt-out people are also more likely to look at the pension scheme arrangements and then make a more informed judgment about its benefits. The change from opt-out to opt-in can have an important effect on government pension scheme design when they are trying to encourage more people to save for their retirement. Reducing carbon emissions Climate change is one of the world’s most significant problems. Governments use a variety of different approaches to climate change through policies such as tax, regulation, and tradeable permits. A nudge theory approach to reducing carbon emissions would be a method that uses small changes to the choice environment that create incentives for firms and households to make decisions that encouraged them to cut their carbon emissions. A government could apply a ‘nudge’ by making firms sign up for a Greenhouse Gas Inventory where businesses have to report the amount of carbon they emit into the atmosphere. If this information is widely available to the public then companies that are the largest emitters would have an incentive to act. Being high up in the inventory league table would attract media attention and would bring bad publicity. Consumers may also choose to buy from firms who performed well in the inventory league table which would put even more pressure on the big polluters. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 The Greenhouse Gas Inventory would be a low-cost policy decision by the government to ‘nudge’ producers to reduce carbon emissions through a published league table. These examples of how nudge theory can be applied are useful to individuals, businesses, and governments in terms of making decisions about increasing a person’s welfare and overall welfare in society. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Unit 2.4(2): Business objectives (HL) What you should know by the end of this chapter: The following different objectives of businesses: • • • • • Profit maximisation Corporate social responsibility Achieving market share Satisficing Business growth Introduction An important influence over the allocation of resources in markets is the supply decisions firms make. Those supply decisions are based on the objectives businesses set when they are producing in different markets. There are a variety of different business objectives firms are influenced by when they are making a supply decision and the importance of these different objectives will vary between producers and markets. Profit maximisation Profit maximisation is a central theme of classical economic theory. Classical economists believe that business decision-making is guided primarily by an entrepreneur’s desire to achieve the highest possible profit their firm can make from producing its goods and services. Profit is important to entrepreneurs because it is the reward they earn from the risk of setting up and starting their business. We know that profit maximisation as a business objective is crucial in guiding the allocation of resources in free markets through the incentive function of price. Profit as an aim influences business decision-making across different markets and between businesses of different sizes. For example, profit will affect producer decision-making from a small firm operating as a sole trader right the way up to a large multinational company that distributes its profit in the form of dividends to its shareholders. For example, a local takeaway restaurant run by family owners might aim to make a profit of $50,000 per year whereas fast-food multinationals like McDonald's might aim for a profit of several billion dollars. The aim of profit maximisation has important implications for business decision-making. Producers in a market will set price and output that achieves the revenue and costs which give them the highest level of profit. This might mean, for example, a bicycle manufacturer using advertising and promotion to achieve the highest level of demand possible and negotiating the lowest price possible for the raw materials and components it uses in production. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Corporate social responsibility aims Corporate social responsibility (CSR) is a set of business objectives based on environmental, ethical and social factors. Many firms set environmental objectives because they have to follow government regulations. This is particularly the case in industries such as energy and agriculture where production can have a significant impact on the environment. Large numbers of firms also adopt environmental objectives because it is important to their stakeholders such as employees, customers and shareholders. The oil companies Shell and BP have, for example, set the objective of achieving carbon-neutral production by 2050. Many businesses often target the environment with one eye on sales and profits because having an environmental outlook gives them a positive image in the mind of the consumer. Airlines, for example, have a negative reputation for carbon emissions and might take action to offset carbon emissions and promote their environmental aims as a selling point to consumers. An ethical objective is where a business makes decisions to achieve positive moral outcomes. Starbucks, for example, buys Fair Trade coffee from suppliers in developing countries where lowincome farmers are paid a premium for their output to give them a better quality of life. Some firms have an ethical outlook because of the philanthropic outlook of their owners. Microsoft owner, Bill Gates, has set up a $50 billion foundation to support healthcare and education in developing countries. Similarly to environmental objectives, ethical aims often give an organisation a positive image in the mind of the consumer which can help sales and profits. Market share Market share is the percentage of total market revenue an individual firm's revenue accounts for. It is calculated as: individual firm’s total revenue/market’s total revenue x 100 = individual firm’s market share If, for example, a firm's total revenue is $25 million and total market revenue is $200 million then the market share would be: $25m / $200m x 100 = 12.5% © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Increasing market share is a useful objective for businesses to judge their relative performance compared to other firms in the same industry. If a business' market share rises then it suggests its performance is better than its competitors. Coca-Cola, for example, might judge its performance based on its market share of 43 per cent of the US soft drinks market as compared to Pepsi's 23 per cent share. Market share is an effective measure of relative performance whatever the market conditions. A business might have falling revenue, but its performance might be good if total market sales are falling in a recession. Increasing market share can also be useful to a firm looking to achieve greater market influence. A strong market share position might allow a firm to influence the market price, have promotional power over consumers and give it greater bargaining power when dealing with suppliers. The French supermarket retailer Leclerc, for example, has the largest share at 21 per cent, of the supermarket industry in France. This makes its presence very strong in the mind of French consumers and this gives it a strong bargaining position with its suppliers. In terms of market share, Samsung is a dominant business in the smartphone market. Last year, 25 per cent of all smartphones sold in the world were Samsung phones. Samsung has been among the top 5 smartphone producers in the world since 2009. As other firms such as Nokia have declined Apple and Samsung have become the two dominant businesses in the market. Samsung currently has the largest market share at 25 per cent. This gives the firm huge marketing power in the minds of consumers and buying power in the minds of its suppliers. Satisficing Satisficing is where a business sets an aim that is satisfactory rather than optimal. Instead of trying to maximise profits, a firm might set an acceptable profit objective. The firm can then meet the needs of its shareholders as well as its other stakeholders such as its employees and the local community. The owner of a small business that makes computer games may, for example, aim for a comfortable living for themselves and their small team of game designers ahead of maximising profits. Satisficing might give them time to enjoy a good quality of life, although there will be an opportunity cost in terms of lower profits and wages. Business Growth For many firms, the growth of their profit, revenue and market share is a key objective because it represents progress. A business that is reaching more customers, operating in more countries and has a higher asset value is often seen as successful in terms of growth. This is closely linked to profit maximisation but it is not quite the same. A firm, for example, may look to discount its products to achieve sales growth at the expense of short-term profitability. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Unit 2.5(1): Price elasticity of demand (PED) What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • Concept of elasticity Price elasticity of demand (PED) Degrees of PED: theoretical range of values for PED Changing PED along a straight line downward sloping demand curve (HL) Determinants of PED: number and closeness of substitutes, degree of necessity, the proportion of income spent on the good, time Relationship between PED and total revenue Importance of PED for business and government decision making PED of primary goods and manufactured goods Elasticity Elasticity is an economic concept based on change. It measures how consumers and producers respond to changes in variables that affect demand and supply. Elasticity is important because it allows us to analyse what happens to demand and supply in markets when change takes place and to evaluate the consequences of change. For example, when the price of electricity rises we can use elasticity to analyse how consumers and producers will respond to the rise in price. Definition and measurement of price elasticity of demand Price elasticity of demand is the responsiveness of quantity demanded for a good to a change in its price. It is measured by the equation: % change in Qd / % change in P For example, if the price of film and TV streaming services such as Netflix increases from $20 per month to $24 (20 per cent increase) and quantity demanded falls from 10 million subscribers to 7.5 million subscribers (25 per cent decrease). This is shown in diagram 2.15 and is calculated as: -25% QD / +20% P = -1.25 or 1.25 (PED) © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Interpretation of PED The value of PED is normally negative because of the law of demand. The negative value is often ignored because the PED value is nearly always negative. In future calculations, the PED will be expressed as a positive value. Price elastic demand If the PED value is greater than 1 then the good’s demand is price elastic. This means a change in price leads to a proportionately greater change in quantity demanded. In the film and TV streaming service example, the value is 1.25 which means for every 1% increase in price, the quantity demanded decreases by 1.25%. This is a price elastic relationship because the proportionate change in quantity demanded is greater than the proportionate change in price. Theoretically, the demand curve can be perfectly horizontal or perfectly elastic. This gives a PED of infinity. This is applicable in the theoretical market form of perfect competition. Unitary elasticity of demand If the PED value is 1 then PED is unitary. This means that for every 1 per cent change in price quantity demanded changes by 1%. It is unlikely a good will have a PED of 1 but the value could be close to 1. This is shown by a demand curve which is a rectangular hyperbola and is represented in diagram 2.16. Price inelastic demand If the demand for a good has a PED value of less than 1 then it is price inelastic. This means that a change in the price of a good leads to a less than proportionate change in quantity demanded. For example, if the price of rice rises from $0.50 to $0.55 and the quantity demanded falls from 4m units to 3.8m then the PED of rice is calculated as: -5% QD / +10% P = 0.5 (PED) © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 The PED value of 0.5 means for every 1% change in the price of rice, the quantity demanded changes by 0.5%. This is shown in diagram 2.17. In theory, a perfectly vertical demand curve represents perfectly inelastic demand. This gives a PED of 0. Demand curves with differing elasticities Diagram 2.18 shows demand curves of different slopes to represent different PEDs. A horizontal demand curve is perfectly elastic (D) and with a relatively flat gradient (D1) is relatively elastic. A vertical demand curve (D3) is perfectly inelastic and one which has a relatively steep gradient is inelastic. All demand curves (except the perfect ones) have a PED that changes from elastic to inelastic as the price of the good is reduced and this is shown in diagram 2.18. The demand curves that represent elastic and inelastic demand situations are useful for illustrating the effects of price changes. Elasticity along the demand curve As the price of a good decreases along the demand curve the PED value falls. Diagram 2.19 illustrates the demand curve for training shoes. As the price of the shoes falls from $50 to $45 the quantity demand increases from 2m units to 3m units. This is a PED of: +50% QD/ -10% P = 5 (price elastic) On the upper section of the demand curve, PED is price elastic. When the price of the training shoes is reduced from $20 to $15 the quantity demanded rises by 8m to 9m units. This is a PED of: +12.5% QD / -25% P = 0.5 (price inelastic) © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 PED falls as you move down the demand curve because a change in price at a relatively high price level has a greater proportionate effect on quantity demanded than the effect of a change in price at a relatively low price. On the upper section of the demand curve in diagram 2.19, PED is price elastic because of the way percentages are calculated. A $5 price reduction from a price of $50 is a smaller percentage change than a $5 price reduction from a $20 price. Similarly, a 1m quantity increase from 2m to 3m is a larger percentage increase than a 1m increase from 8m to 9m. When the PED is calculated it will have a greater value at higher prices on the demand curve and a smaller value at lower prices. Determinants of price elasticity of demand Number and closeness of substitutes The greater the number of close substitutes a product has the more price elastic its demand tends to be because consumers can easily swap between alternatives when the price of the good changes. This relates to the way you define the market for a good: the more precisely defined the market for a good, the more close substitutes it tends to have. There are many different brands of biscuits on the shelf of a supermarket, so any one brand of biscuit tends to be relatively price elastic. A rise in the price of Oreo biscuits, for example, may well lead to consumers switching to alternative brands such as Jaffa Cakes. If the market definition broadened from brands of biscuits to biscuits as a product, then there are fewer close substitutes (chocolate bars, crisps, cakes, etc.) and the demand for biscuits will be more inelastic. Luxury or necessity The demand for goods that are a necessity for a consumer tends to be more price inelastic than the demand for luxury products which tend to be more price elastic. This is because consumers need to keep buying necessity goods when their price increases. For example, if the price of electricity rises, quantity demand will fall by a proportionately smaller amount because people still need to use electricity to light their homes and run their appliances. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Consumers do not, on the other hand, need to keep consuming luxury products if their price increases. For example, if the price of long-haul air tickets increases, people can take fewer holiday flights and the quantity demanded would fall by a relatively greater amount. Proportion of income The demand for goods that account for a smaller proportion of household income tends to be more price inelastic. This is because any change in price will have a relatively small impact on household income. For example, consumers might spend a relatively small amount of their income on chewing gum each month, whereas they might spend a larger proportion of their income on train travel. A 20 per cent increase in the price of $1 a pack of chewing gum is likely to have a smaller impact on consumer income than a 20 per cent increase in the price of a $15 daily train ticket, so the PED of chewing gum tends to be more inelastic than the train tickets. Type of consumer High-income consumers tend to be less responsive to price changes for goods than people on lower incomes. This is because any price change will have a smaller real income effect on high-income consumers compared to low-income consumers. For example, if the price of a prestige watch rises from $2000 to $2500 then it may have little impact on a wealthy buyer who has an income of a million US$ per year. This is why the demand for luxury goods sold to wealthy individuals tends to be relatively price inelastic. The demand for high-end fashion labels such as Prada and Armani have relatively inelastic demand for their goods because they are targeted at wealthy consumers. Time Over time PED tends to become more price elastic because consumers can alter their consumption patterns in response to a price change. In the short run an increase in the price of petrol, for example, will lead to a relatively small decrease in the quantity demanded because petrol buyers can cut back on some leisure journeys, but they still have to get to work and take their children to school. In the long run, buyers could change to a more fuel-efficient car and move to a house nearer to where they work. Thus the demand for petrol becomes more price elastic in the long run. Diagram 2.20 shows how the PED for petrol increases from: -25% QD / +20% P = 1.25 PED to © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 -60% QD/ +20% P = 3 PED Price elasticity of demand and revenue Revenue is the value of income a business receives from selling a good. It is calculated by: price x quantity = total revenue For example, an airline sells 500,000 seats a year at a price of $200 then the total revenue is: 500,000 x $200 = $100,000,000 Firms can use an understanding of PED to increase their total revenue. When the demand for a good is price elastic, total revenue rises when the price is reduced and decreases when the price is increased. When the demand for a good is inelastic, total revenue rises when the price is increased and decreases when the price is reduced. An airline sells seats to a holiday destination. Ticket A is sold during the school summer holidays when demand is relatively price inelastic because families need to travel at that time and the seats are considered a relative necessity. Ticket B is sold outside school holiday time when demand is relatively price elastic because people do not have to travel at that time and seats are considered more of a luxury. The table shows the price, quantity and revenue for tickets A and B before and after a 20 per cent increase in the price of seat tickets from time period year 1 to time period year 2. The total revenue © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 for ticket A, which has price inelastic demand, increases by $128,000 and the total revenue for ticket B, which has price elastic demand, decreases by $84,000. Diagram 2.21 shows how an increase in price for seat ticket A leads to a rise in total revenue. Area EFBG shows the total revenue after the price increase which is greater than area ABCD, which is the total revenue before the price increase. Diagram 2.22 shows how an increase for seat ticket B leads to a fall in total revenue. Area ABCD shows the total revenue before the price increase, which is greater than area EFBG which represents the total revenue after the price increase. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 The impact on total revenue of changes in PED along the demand curve The business response to PED could be to make a judgement about the PED of the demand for the good they sell and then increase or decrease the price of their good to increase revenue and hopefully profits. It is important to remember that PED changes as you move along the demand curve and this will affect the revenue from a price change. In diagram 2.23 we can see that a rise in the price of the airline seat ticket with inelastic demand will lead to an increase in total revenue, but as PED raises the rate of increase of total revenue will slow down and peak when PED is unitary. Any increase in price as we move onto the elastic section of the demand curve will lead to a fall in revenue. The same thing happens if the price is reduced on the elastic section of the demand curve. Revenue rises and peaks when PED is unitary and then falls when PED is inelastic. Government decision-making and price elasticity of demand PED will be useful to governments when they are making policy decisions that affect the price of goods and services. PED will have an effect on tax, subsidy, maximum price and minimum price decisions made by governments. The specific effects of PED on these policies are covered in Unit 2.7 Governments and markets. The price elasticity demand of commodities compared to manufactured goods Economists are often concerned by the differences in PED between commodities and manufactured goods. The demand for agricultural goods tends to be relatively inelastic because they are often necessities and have fewer close substitutes compared to manufactured goods. If the price of a commodity such as rice increases then households reduce the quantity demanded by a proportionately smaller amount than the increase in price. This is because households depend on rice as part of their diet and there are relatively few close substitutes for it. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Manufactured goods such as personal computers (PCs) are often relative luxuries so the demand for them tends to be more price elastic. The demand for manufactured goods is also considered price elastic because of the number of substitutes they have. If the price of a PC rises people could buy a substitute for a PC like a new mobile phone or tablet computer. Evaluating price elasticity of demand PED is used extensively by businesses looking to increase revenue and profit from their pricing strategies. There are, however, some limitations to PED: • It can change over time as consumer behaviour changes. A new competitor might enter the market for a good which makes the PED for a good more elastic. • PED is based on the ceteris paribus assumption that price is the only variable that is changing. Income and the price of related goods, as well as other factors that affect demand, are all changing at the same time as the price of the good. • When a firm changes price there is always going to be uncertainty about how consumers will react. If the price of a good rises above its anchor point then the quantity demanded might fall more than expected. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Unit 2.5(2): Income elasticity of demand (YED) What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • Definition of income elasticity of demand (YED) Calculation of YED Measuring the YED of normal, necessity, luxury and inferior goods Importance of YED for firms (HL) Use of YED explaining changes in the sectoral structure of the economy. (HL) Definition and measurement of income elasticity of demand Income elasticity of demand is the responsiveness of quantity demanded to a change in household income. It is measured by the equation: % change in Qd / % change income = YED For example, if a 5 per cent increase in household income leads to a 7 per cent increase in quantity demanded for computer game consoles such as the Sony PlayStation the YED would be: +7% QD / +5% Y = +1.4 This means that for every 1 per cent increase in household income the quantity demanded of games consoles will increase by 1.4 per cent. This relationship is shown in diagram 2.24 where a rise in income causes the demand curve for game consoles to increase and shift to the right. Interpretation of income elasticity of demand Normal goods Normal goods have a positive YED. Quantity demanded rises as income rises, and quantity demand falls as income falls. The +1.4 YED value for computer games consoles shows they are normal goods. Most goods are normal because as incomes rise people will demand more of most goods, but the rate of increase will be different for different types of goods. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Necessity goods Necessity goods are normal goods that have a YED between 0 and 1. For example, if there is a 5 per cent rise in household incomes and the quantity demanded for electricity increases by 1 per cent. +1% QD / + 5% Y = +0.2 YED The demand for necessity goods such as basic food, energy and public transport will have YED values between 0 and 1. Luxury goods Luxury goods are normal goods and the demand for them has a YED of greater than 1. This means a rise in income will lead to a greater than proportionate increase in quantity demanded, and a fall in income will lead to a greater than proportionate fall in quantity demanded. If, for example, the quantity demanded for 5-star hotels increases by 8 per cent following a 6 per cent rise in incomes then the YED would be: +8% QD / +6%P = +1.33 This YED value means the quantity demanded for 5-star hotels increases by a more than proportionate amount relative to the change in income. Luxury goods such as prestige cars, designer clothing and exclusive restaurants will have YED values of greater than 1. Inferior goods The demand for inferior goods will have a negative YED because the quantity demanded for inferior goods fall as household incomes rise and rise as incomes fall. For example, the quantity demanded of dried packet soup falls by 3 per cent following a 4 per cent rise in household income. This is calculated as: -3% QD / +4% Y = -0.75. Inferior goods such as tinned food, bus travel and synthetic clothing will often have negative YEDs. Although this will vary between countries. The chart summarises the YEDs of inferior, necessity and luxury goods. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Engel Curve (HL) The nineteenth-century German economist, Ernst Engel studied how the demand for different goods and services changed with income over time. The Engel Curve relationship between income and demand is shown in diagram 2.24(1). In this example, the diagram shows how the demand for rice changes with income over time. When income increases for poorer households the demand for rice increases as rice is considered a normal or luxury good by households on low incomes. Beyond point A, households are on middle incomes where rice becomes a necessity good to these consumers. This means that any increase in income beyond A leads to a less than proportionate increase in the demand for rice. Once household incomes rise above point B any increase in income will lead to a fall in demand for rice because it is now considered an inferior good by the consumer. Above income level B, households will not demand as much rice and switch to luxury good alternatives. Individuals might substitute rice-based meals for meat-based meals. The Engel curve is useful in showing how the income elasticity of different goods changes over time. For example, the demand for goods such as smartphones would have been luxury goods when they were first launched with a YED of greater than one, but their YED falls as smartphones become a more established product amongst consumers. Very basic smartphones can become inferior goods over time. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Application of income elasticity of demand (HL) Structural changes in the economy YED data can be used to show how industrial structure changes in the economy over time, as household incomes rise when the economy grows. The YED for primary goods or commodities, which are often considered necessities, tend to have a YED of between 0 and 1. This means the demand for commodities tends not to grow as incomes rise in the economy over time. An economy that specialises in primary commodities, as some developing countries do, will experience slow growth as the world incomes rise. Manufactured goods such as cars and computers have greater positive YED values because consumers are more likely to buy this type of good as their income increases. When incomes increase over time, these industries may experience significant growth. Policymakers often see the development of manufacturing in developing countries as an effective way to deliver economic growth as world incomes rise. The service sector of an economy such as tourism and leisure tends to have the highest positive YED values. YED can be used to explain why the industrial structure of many economies is increasingly dominated by the service sector as household incomes rise. Business strategy Businesses respond to income changes by adapting what they sell. As incomes have generally increased over time in most economies, many firms have responded by improving the quality of the products they sell because the demand for these goods has a positive YED value. Ice cream brands like Haagen Das and Ben and Jerry's, have marketed their luxury good ice cream brands in response to rising incomes. In economic recessions when household incomes tend to fall, businesses that market inferior goods can see the demand for their goods rise as consumers switch to lower-priced inferior goods. Food producers, for example, might plan to increase the output of products that are inferior such as tinned, dried and frozen food. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Unit 2.6: Price elasticity of supply (PES) What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • Definition and measurement of price elasticity of supply (PES) Range of values for PES Determinants of PES: time, mobility of factors of production, unused capacity, ability to store, the rate at which costs increase Reasons why the PES for primary commodities is generally lower than the PES for manufactured products (HL) Introduction Price elasticity of supply (PES) changes the emphasis of elasticity away from the consumer to the producer. PES is the measurement of how producer supply responds to changes in the price of the product they sell. The value of the PES in a market is determined by the willingness and ability of producers in the market to change output in response to a change in price. Definition and measurement of price elasticity of supply Price elasticity of supply is the responsiveness of quantity supplied of a good to a change in its price. It is measured by the equation: % change in Qs / % change P = PES © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 For example, if the price of strawberries increases from $2 per kg to $3 per kg (50 per cent increase) and quantity supplied increases from 400,000 kgs to 500,000 kgs (25 per cent increase). This is shown in diagram 2.25 and is calculated as: +25% QS / +50% P = +0.5 Interpretation The value of PES is normally positive because of the law of supply. In the strawberry market example, the PES value of +0.5 means that for every 1 per cent increase in the price of strawberries, the quantity supplied increases by 0.5 per cent. Price elastic supply If the value is greater than 1 then the good’s supply is price elastic. This means a change in price leads to a proportionately greater change in quantity supplied. If, for example, a 10 per cent increase in the price of hairdresser haircuts leads to a 15 percent increase in the supply of hairdresser services, the PES would be: +15% QS / +10% P = +1.5 PES This means for every 1 per cent increase in the price of haircuts quantity supplied increases by 1.5 per cent. This is a price elastic relationship because the proportionate change in quantity supplied is greater than the proportionate change in price. This is shown in diagram 2.26. Theoretically, the supply curve can be perfectly horizontal or perfectly elastic. This gives a PES of infinity. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Unitary elasticity of supply If the value is 1 then PES is unitary. This means that for every 1 per cent change in price, quantity supplied changes by 1%. In reality, it is unlikely a good will have a PES of 1, but the value could be close to 1. Any straight-line supply curve that passes through the origin has a PES value of 1. Price inelastic supply If the supply of a good has a PES of less than 1 then its supply is price inelastic. This means that a change in the price of a good leads to a less than proportionate change in quantity supplied. For example, in diagram 2.26(1) the price of cement rises from $200 per unit to $300 and quantity supplied increases from 15m units to 18m units supplied then the PES of cement is calculated as: +20% QS / +50% P = 0.4 PES This means for every 1 per cent increase in the price of cement quantity supplied increases by 0.4 per cent. This is a price inelastic relationship because the proportionate change in quantity supplied is less than the proportionate change in price. Theoretically, the supply curve can be perfectly vertical or perfectly inelastic. This gives a PES value of 0. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Determinants of price elasticity of supply Time In the short run, the supply of a good tends to be inelastic. This is because producers find it difficult to increase output when the factors of production used to produce the good are difficult to change quickly when price changes. Over time, producers find it easier to respond to an increase in price because they can change the factors of production used to increase output, and supply becomes more price elastic. This is shown in diagram 2.27. If, for example, a house-builder knows that the price of new houses is increasing at an annual rate of 10 per cent then they can plan to build new houses, but it will be several months or even years before they can complete construction and increase supply. Diagram 2.27 shows an increase in quantity supplied in the short run of 5,000 houses or 5 per cent which is a PES of: +5% / +10% = 0.5 PES In the long run, the quantity supplied of housing increases by 20,000 houses or 20 per cent which is a PES of: +20% / +10% = 2 PES In the long run, the supply of new houses has become more price elastic. Availability of factors of production The easier it is for producers to access factors of production, the more elastic PES tends to be. Roadside car cleaning businesses are generally quick to set up and operate because the land, labour and capital needed to clean cars is relatively accessible. On the other hand, electricity supply through power stations has an inelastic PES because the resources needed to set up and operate a power station are more difficult to access. Where resources are relatively difficult to access, costs tend to rise quickly when producers try to increase output, and this will make the supply of electricity relatively inelastic. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Stock and used capacity Where producers have spare capacity and available stock, supply tends to be relatively price elastic. For example, in a recession, a car manufacturer may have plenty of spare capacity in production and a high level of unsold stock because of low demand for cars. If the price of cars increases the car manufacturer can increase supply by utilising unused production facilities and selling available stock which makes the supply of cars price elastic. Application of price elasticity of supply (HL only) Commodities The supply of primary commodities tends to be relatively inelastic because it is difficult for producers to respond to a change in price. The supply of the agricultural sector, for example, is limited by the growing seasons of farmers. If a coffee producer plants a coffee bush it takes 3 to 4 years before it can be harvested and coffee plants can only be harvested twice a year. This makes the supply of coffee relatively price inelastic. Manufactured goods The supply of manufactured goods is more price elastic in comparison to primary products because producers can change supply in response to a change in price more quickly. This is because manufacturers are not limited by growing seasons. Assuming a manufacturer of smartphones has spare capacity, they can increase supply almost immediately if there is a price increase. Manufactured goods can also be stored more easily than agricultural goods which tend to be perishable. If manufacturers hold a stock of goods then they can respond to an increase in price by releasing that stock onto the market. Similarly, if the price of a manufactured good decreases producers can hold their output in stock and relatively easily decrease quantity supplied. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Unit 2.7(1): Governments in markets - tax and subsidy What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • • Reasons for government intervention in markets: raise government revenue, support producers and consumers, and influence production and consumption Types of indirect taxes Reasons for the use of indirect taxes Effects of indirect tax on a market using graphical analysis Consequences of indirect taxes for different stakeholders and for welfare Subsidies Reasons for the use of subsidies Effects of subsidies on a market using graphical analysis Consequences of subsidies for different stakeholders and for welfare Importance of government intervention Governments play an important role in all economies. The table sets out government expenditure as a percentage of GDP for the world's 10 leading industrialised countries. With an average government spending in these countries of over 40 per cent of GDP, you can see how influential governments are in different countries. This is a macroeconomic way of looking at levels of government intervention, but governments are heavily involved at a microeconomic level as well through taxes and subsidies. Market failure and equity The IB Economics course looks in detail at the reasons why governments intervene in markets under the topics of market failure and equity. These reasons will be covered in detail in the market failure sections of this textbook in Unit 2.8(3). © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Reasons governments for government intervention Raise government revenue Governments raise revenue to pay for public services like health and education. Taxation is a very important source of government finance and indirect taxation of goods and services is a key part of this. In developed economies, indirect tax accounts for about 30 per cent of all tax receipts. Support to producers Many businesses and organisations in the economy are important to the overall welfare of society and are assisted by the government. Farming is supported by governments because food supply is crucial to a country’s population. This is particularly true when making food affordable for people on low incomes. Governments also look to help businesses involved in healthcare, education, energy and infrastructure, etc. Support for households on low incomes An objective of many governments is to improve equity and reduce income inequality in society. State support for households on low incomes by subsidising healthcare, energy and housing, etc. is one way of achieving this. For example, free healthcare gives households on the lowest incomes access to doctors, medicine and hospital treatment. If this improves the health of the poorest in society then it gives them the opportunity to make progress in other areas of life such as employment. Influence the level of production in a market Some industries can have a negative impact on welfare in society and the state often tries to reduce production in these industries. In recent years the use of fossil fuels is seen as increasingly negative to welfare because of their contribution to climate change. The Paris Climate Agreement has seen governments seek to reduce and phase out the use of coal, oil and gas. Conversely, the government looks to encourage production in other areas to increase welfare. This is true in markets like energy, healthcare and education. Many governments are now encouraging the use of renewable energy to combat climate change. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Influence the level of consumption in a market Governments intervene in markets to reduce consumption to protect the welfare of their citizens. For example, the market for recreational drugs is heavily regulated in nearly all countries. There are also situations where governments encourage the consumption of certain goods and services. This is in markets such as healthcare, where people are, for example, encouraged to get vaccinations because of the benefit to the individual and wider society. Indirect tax Definition An Indirect or expenditure tax is the tax added to the price of a good or service and collected by the firm selling the good or service and then paid to the government. It is an important source of revenue for governments and it allows the government to affect consumption and production in different markets. Types of indirect tax There are two main types of indirect taxation: • • Ad valorem tax is a fixed percentage tax added to the price of a good such as value-added tax (VAT). If you buy a computer for $960 you will pay $160 in VAT if the rate is 20 per cent. Specific tax or duty is a set money value of tax added to the price of a good. Specific taxes are placed (levied) on goods like petrol, alcohol and cigarettes. Reasons for the use of indirect tax Indirect taxation is an important source of government revenue. In many countries, it represents around 30 per cent of all tax collected. If all tax was put on household income it is likely this would adversely affect worker incentives. Governments also use specific taxes to reduce the consumption of goods that they think have significant social costs and negatively affect welfare*. * This aspect of tax is covered in detail in the chapter on market failure where we look at demerit goods and negative externalities. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Market analysis of an indirect tax Indirect tax affects supply in a market because it increases the costs of production. For example, an airline’s cost of supplying a flight is $700 and a $50 specific tax is imposed. The supply cost of that ticket will now be $750 ($700 + $50). This means the supply curve for airline tickets shifts vertically upwards by the specific tax of $50. Diagram 2.28 illustrates the impact of an indirect tax on the market for airline tickets. The effects of a specific tax of $50 levied by the government on the airline market would be: • The producer (airline) would like to pass on all the $50 tax to the consumer. But if they raise the ticket price from $700 to $750 there would be excess supply so the price falls to the new equilibrium at $720 where demand equals supply after the tax is levied. • The total tax collected by the government is calculated by multiplying the quantity sold multiplied by the indirect tax per unit. In this case $50 x 950,000 = $47,500,000 which is partly paid by the consumer and partly by the producer. • The consumer pays $20 x 950,000 = $19,000,000. This is known as the consumer incidence (yellow area) of the tax and it leads to a reduction in the consumer surplus. • The producer pays $30 x 950,000 = $28,500,000. This is known as the producer incidence (green area) of the tax and this means a reduction in the producer surplus. Importance of elasticity Price elasticity of demand and supply will affect the size of tax revenue received by the government as well as the incidences of tax paid by the consumer and the producer. Price elasticity of demand Governments often favour taxing goods with price inelastic demand because the revenue collected is high and the tax incidence falls more on the consumer than the producer. A higher incidence on the producer is more likely to result in a cut in output which could cause unemployment. In addition, if output falls significantly then the tax revenue will be lower. The example in diagram 2.28 has a PED of: 4.77 [-13.64% / +2.86%]. Diagram 2.28 shows price elastic demand in this case which means the producer incidence is greater than the consumer incidence. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 In diagram 2.29 an ad valorem tax of 20 per cent is put on the price of household electricity. Notice that when an ad valorem indirect tax is put on a good the supply curves diverge as the price increases. If the price of a good is $100 the indirect tax is $20 and if the good costs $500 the tax is $100. Because the PED of electricity is price inelastic the incidence of tax falls more heavily on the consumer (yellow area) relative to the producer (green area) and the tax revenue for the government is greater. Price elasticity of supply PES also affects the tax collected by the government and the size of the incidence on the consumer and the producer. When the PES of a good is greater than the PED the consumer incidence is greater than the producer incidence and when PES is less than PED the producer incidence is greater than the consumer incidence. For example, if a tax is put on agricultural goods like avocados which is a luxury item where PED is relatively elastic and PES is relatively inelastic then the producer has a higher incidence of tax. In diagram 2.30 a tax of 0.40c is levied on avocados where the consumer has an incidence shown by the yellow area and the producer the green shaded area. Impact on stakeholders Consumers Individuals who buy goods that have been taxed pay a higher price and experience a loss of consumer surplus. It can be argued that when people are buying goods associated with social costs like alcohol, the higher price reduces their consumption and this increases their welfare in the long term. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Producers Businesses in markets that are taxed must pay their incidence of tax and this reduces their producer surplus. This may lead to a fall in business profits which reduces long-term investment and this could lead to workers being made redundant. Government Governments benefit from the revenue they receive from indirect taxes which they can use to spend on public services. There may also be benefits from a reduction of goods associated with social costs such as alcohol. There may, however, be some negative political consequences from an industry badly affected by a tax. The collapse of an airline following the imposition of air passenger duty could be damaging to a government. Welfare When a tax is applied to a good it will change the allocation of resources in the market. Diagram 2.31 shows the welfare loss associated with a $0.40 tax on petrol. This is made up of two elements: Consumer welfare loss When the price increases from $1 to $1.30 consumer surplus of the people who would have bought the petrol at $1 but will not buy it at $1.30 disappears. This is called the consumer welfare loss and is shown in diagram 2.31 by the dark blue shaded area. Producer welfare loss The producer incidence of the tax in diagram 2.31 is $0.10c. When this is applied to the petrol market some producers will fail (go bankrupt) or will choose to leave the market. Their producer surplus will be lost to the economy and this is shown in diagram 2.31 by the brown shaded area. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Subsidy Definition A subsidy is an amount of money paid by the government to producers to encourage the consumption and production of a good or service. Examples of subsidies include those made to farmers to produce food, energy firms to produce renewable energy, and pharmaceutical businesses to produce new healthcare drugs. Reasons for subsidies Government use subsidies to support producers and consumers in different markets: Consumers Some goods and services carry significant social benefits to society and their consumption increases welfare in society. For example, governments often subsidise renewable energy because of the environmental benefits it brings to society. *Positive externalities and merit goods are often supported by subsidies and they are covered in Unit 2.8(2) on market failure. Producers Government step into markets to support producers in key industries like farming. Agriculture is often seen as a strategically significant industry because food supply is important for the security of the country. You could also consider industries such as steel and energy as strategically important. By paying a subsidy to producers the government protects supply in these important markets. Subsidies are also paid to industries because they are important for economic development and employment. Subsidies paid to larger manufacturing businesses to encourage investment can lead to long-term economic growth. Finally, subsidies are sometimes paid to domestic firms to protect them from foreign competition. *This is covered in Unit 4.2/4.3 on protectionism. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Effects of a subsidy on a market When a good is subsidised the supply curve shifts vertically downwards by the value of the subsidy paid to producers in the market. A subsidy reduces the costs of producing a good. For example, if the government decides to subsidise milk by $0.40c per litre then the cost of producing each litre of milk will be $0.40p per unit lower. This is shown in diagram 2.32. The effects of a subsidy of $0.40c per litre on the milk market would be: • The value of the subsidy paid by the government is calculated as $0.40c x 11m units = $4.4m. • As the market price of milk falls by $0.30c the consumer benefits from the lower price and an increase in consumer surplus. The yellow area in diagram 2.32 shows the increase in consumer surplus and this can be calculated as: ($0.30c x 10m) + ($0.30c x 1/2m) = $3.15m. • The producer also benefits from subsidies because they receive an extra $0.10c per litre for the milk they sell. Their gain in producer surplus is shown by the green shaded area in diagram 2.32 and this is calculated as: ($0.10 x 10m) + ($0.10 x 1m/2) = $1.05m. • When subsidies are applied there is a welfare loss because resources are drawn into the market by the subsidy that is not efficient enough to exist under normal market conditions. This is shown by the blue shared area in diagram 2.32 and can be calculated as: $0.40 x 1m/2 = $0.2m Importance of elasticity Price elasticity of demand and supply will affect the size of subsidy paid by the government as well as the subsidy benefits paid to the consumer and the producer. The PED and PES will also affect the size of the welfare loss of the subsidy. Price elasticity of demand The impact of the subsidy on milk shown above will be affected by the PED of milk. The more inelastic demand is the greater the reduction in price and the bigger the relative benefit to the consumer. The milk example shows this. As a relative necessity milk has inelastic demand which can be calculated as: [+10% / -25% = 0.40] which means the gain in consumer surplus is great than the gain in producer surplus. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 If demand is price elastic the gain in producer surplus is greater than the gain in consumer surplus. This is because the price does not fall as much as it would do if demand was price inelastic, which means the surplus gain is not as great for the consumer. In diagram 2.33 a subsidy is put on electric cars which have relatively elastic demand. The green shaded area is the gain in producer surplus and the yellow shaded area is the gain in consumer surplus. The blue welfare loss triangle is bigger when supply is inelastic because more inefficient producers are drawn into the market when demand is price elastic compared to inelastic. Price elasticity of supply The impact of a subsidy will also be affected by PES. If the PES of a good is more elastic than demand as in diagram 2.32 then consumers gain more surplus than producers. If PES is less than PED as in diagram 2.33 then producers gain more than consumers. For example, the market for rented housing is likely to have a higher PES than PED. If a subsidy is introduced by a government on rented housing and the quantity supplied increases as new landlords quickly enter the market then the price will fall more and less producer surplus will be available to each producer. The significant fall in price means there is a greater gain in surplus by the consumer relative to the producer. Impact on stakeholders Consumers Subsidies lead to a fall in prices in a market and this benefits consumers because they experience a rise in consumer surplus. If the good is bought widely by low-income households then the benefit to those consumers is likely to be significant. A subsidy, for example, on bread, rented housing or rice, is likely to benefit consumers more than a subsidy on the theatre or the opera. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Producers The gain in producer revenue and surplus that comes from a subsidy will help producers. The greatest benefit will be when subsidies are targeted at producers who may not be able to survive without a subsidy. If the subsidy is paid to a farmer who is a rich landowner then this will have less impact than the money paid to low-income farmers who struggle to survive. For example, Prince Charles receives significant amounts of farming subsidies from the EU. Government A subsidy needs to be paid for by the government which means there will be an opportunity cost of money that has been sacrificed from other areas of government expenditure. A subsidy on electric cars might mean there is less expenditure on the roads. Alternatively, a government might have to raise taxes to pay for the subsidy. There may also be a cost to the government in terms of managing and distributing a subsidy. Welfare Subsidies affect the allocation of resources in markets and this can either increase or decrease welfare. The blue shaded triangles in diagrams 2.32 and 2.33 show the welfare loss associated with the application of subsidies in markets. Producers and resources are drawn into markets that would not be there without the subsidy and the cost of those less efficient producers represent a welfare loss. Subsidies can, however, also increase welfare if the consumption and production of the goods subsidised bring significant wider benefits to society. For example, subsidies for the development of new healthcare drugs might bring much greater benefits to a country than the cost of the subsidy. *This subject is developed further in the positive externalities in Unit 2.8(1) on market failure. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 10 Unit 2.7(2): Governments in markets - price controls What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • • Price controls Maximum prices Reasons for the use of maximum prices Effects of a maximum price on a market using graphical analysis Consequences of maximum prices for different stakeholders and welfare Minimum price Reasons for minimum prices Effects of minimum prices on a market using graphical analysis Consequences of minimum prices for different stakeholders and welfare. Price controls In free markets where there is no government intervention, the price and output in a market are determined by demand and supply. Governments often intervene in markets when the market price and output do not maximise welfare in society. This could be a high price that negatively affects households on lower incomes or a low price that forces firms out of business in a strategically important market. Maximum prices (price ceiling) Definition A maximum price or price ceiling is a price set by a government or controlling authority to prevent the price of a good or service from rising above a fixed level. For example, rent controls in a housing market are a maximum price where market rents cannot rise above a certain price. Reasons for maximum prices Maximum prices are put in place to protect low-income consumers from prices rising in a market to a level they cannot afford. Maximum prices are normally put on goods that governments feel all people in society ought to be able to consume such as housing, basic food, healthcare and education. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Effects of a maximum price One of the most famous maximum prices or price ceilings are rent controls in New York City. Rent controls have existed in the city since the 1940s to protect low-income families. The number of houses and apartments subject to rent controls is around 22,000 at present with an average rent of about $1,300 per month. The average market rent would be around $2,500 per month. Diagram 2.33(1) illustrates the impact of a maximum price on rents in the New York housing market. Empirical evidence of the effects of a maximum price set below the equilibrium price would be: • If the price falls in the market from $2500 to $1300, the quantity demanded increases from 30,000 units to 36,000 units because of the income and substitution effects (more people can afford to rent and its cheaper to rent relative to buying a house). • The decrease in price reduces the quantity supplied when landlords withdraw from the market because they make less profit and fewer landlords can cover their costs. • Excess demand (shortages) for rented housing develops because the quantity demanded is greater than the quantity supplied of rented housing at the maximum price. • The rationing function of price no longer works effectively. The price cannot rise to clear the market because of the price ceiling. • Other methods of rationing develop such as: queueing (first come, first serve), preferential consumer selection (landlords rent to tenants they favour), regulations develop (landlords are forced to prioritise families) and lottery schemes develop (random selection of tenants). © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 • Parallel markets develop where consumers and producers try to find their way around the ceiling price controls. A landlord and tenant might officially agree on the rent ceiling of $1300 but also agree on a payment of $1000 per month to be paid unofficially. • The quality of rented housing declines because landlords do not have funds to make repairs and maintain their properties as well as they could do at the equilibrium price. • In the long-term new investment in rented housing falls because the market is not as profitable as it would be without the maximum price. Impact on stakeholders Consumers The consumers who buy the good or service at a maximum price benefit because they pay a lower price than the equilibrium price. The gain in consumer surplus these consumers receive is shown by the yellow shaded area in diagram 2.34. Some consumers who would have paid the market price and cannot buy the good at the maximum price because of a shortage lose out. Consumers may also lose out because of the time they might spend queueing for a good that is in short supply, or they might encounter extra regulations resulting from the price ceiling. Some consumers might enter the parallel market where they might have to pay a very inflated price and risk breaking the law. Producers In theory, producers lose when there is a maximum price because they receive less revenue and profit from selling their good or service. For the landlords in the rented housing market, the producer surplus is the green shaded which is smaller than the producer surplus at the normal market equilibrium price. It is, however, possible for some fringe producers to enter the parallel market and make high profits from selling their good illegally. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Governments Governments have the cost of setting up and enforcing the maximum price, as well as the loss of tax revenue that might come from lower sales in the market (although the good may not be subject to tax). There are, however, some political benefits from setting a price ceiling because it looks like an effective policy that reduces prices. This is why governments are often tempted to use them. Welfare Empirical evidence suggests maximum prices tend to lead to a loss of welfare because the benefits of the maximum price are concentrated amongst a relatively small number of consumers and there are wider dispersed costs on the rest of society. In New York, a relatively small number of tenants (sometimes wealthy) benefit from the maximum price, but many potential tenants lose out, landlords see a fall in profits and the government (taxpayers) have to pay for the system. Minimum prices (price floors) Definition A minimum price or price floor is a lower limit set by the government or controlling authority to stop the price of a good or service from falling below a certain level. Minimum prices have been used in the past in agricultural markets, although they are not used as much today. There are, however, still examples of minimum prices in agriculture in India on Kharif (autumn) crops. These are crops such as maize and rice. Reasons for minimum prices Governments use minimum prices or guaranteed minimum prices to protect producers in markets. This is often the case in agricultural markets where governments look to support farmers and protect the food supply. Producers in agricultural markets often struggle because of unstable prices because of the impact of the weather on their output. A price floor aims to offer them a more stable income. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Effects of minimum price (price floor) The European Union used minimum prices as part of their Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) in the 1970s and 80s. Diagram 2.35 is an example of how minimum prices might work in the market for wheat. In this example, the equilibrium price for wheat is €8 per bushel with 2 million units of output. A minimum guaranteed price is put in place at €11. Empirical evidence of the effects of a minimum price set above the equilibrium price would be: • As the price rises from €8 to €11 the quantity demand for wheat falls to 1.1m bushels. As the price increases quantity demanded decreases because of the income and substitution effects. Wheat is now less affordable, and buyers switch to cheaper alternatives. • Quantity supplied increases to 2.7m bushels because the higher price increases producer profits and covers the costs of higher production. • At the minimum price, the quantity supplied is greater than the quantity demanded and there is excess supply or surplus output. In diagram this is (2.7m – 1.1m = 1.6m units). • To maintain the minimum price the government or buying authority needs to purchase the surplus and put it into storage. If the surplus is allowed onto the market the price will fall – hence the term guaranteed price. The cost of the government intervention is 1.6m x €11 = €17.6m • The wheat needs to be stored and this is an additional cost of the scheme. This can be particularly expensive for goods that need to be refrigerated. • Additional agricultural producers are attracted to the market by the minimum price which leads to an increase in excess supply in the long run and reduces supply in other markets. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Impact on stakeholders Consumers Consumers lose out when a minimum price is set above the equilibrium price because they need to pay a higher price for the good and their consumer surplus falls. The loss of consumer surplus from the minimum price put on wheat is shown in diagram 2.36. The yellow shaded area shows the new consumer surplus following the increase in price from €8 to €11. The increase in the price of agricultural products affects poorer consumers badly because buying food is often a high proportion of their household expenditure. Producers Producers gain when a guaranteed minimum price is above the equilibrium price because their producer surplus increases. This means they will receive higher revenues and profits. The increase in producer surplus is shown by the green shaded area in diagram 2.36. In the wheat market, this may well fulfil the government’s aim of stabilising farming incomes and maintaining a long-term food supply. Government Minimum prices represent an opportunity cost to the government. The government or the authority buys the excess supply and has the considerable cost of purchasing the good, as well as the cost of storing any excess supply and managing the system. Welfare Minimum prices are not used very much anymore because they were expensive for the government to manage and the benefits of the system were less than its costs. They often led to a misallocation of resources in agriculture markets with huge surpluses developing at the expense of reduced production in other markets. There was also considerable waste with excess supply being destroyed when it could not be sold. In some instances, the European Union sold excess supplies to developing countries with disastrous effects on their farmers when prices fell in their markets. Like maximum prices, the gains tended to be concentrated amongst a certain group of stakeholders - in this case, producers, with dispersed losses for consumers and taxpayers. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Unit 2.8(1): Market Failure – Externalities What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • Explanation of market failure Allocative efficiency when the social/community surplus is maximised Social efficiency: marginal social cost (MSC) equals marginal social benefit (MSB) External costs / negative externalities of production and consumption External benefits / positive externalities of production and consumption Understanding of and calculation (HL) of welfare loss. What is market failure? Markets fail when the free market forces of demand and supply lead to an allocation of resources that does not maximise the welfare of a country’s citizens. It means that the marginal social costs that result from the production and consumption of a good do not equal the marginal social benefits. The concepts of social costs and benefits are covered later in this chapter. Economists often express market failure as a misallocation of resources or where resources have been allocated inefficiently. In the market theory we looked at in chapter 2.3, market failure occurs when the community/social surplus (consumer surplus plus producer surplus) is not maximised. Allocative efficiency Allocative efficiency is achieved in a market when the marginal benefit of consuming a good is equal to the marginal cost of producing it. This situation exists when demand equals supply, assuming there are no externalities in the market. External costs and benefits are explained in the next sections of this chapter. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 When demand equals supply in a market it is in equilibrium and the social/community surplus is maximised. This means the consumer and producer surpluses are maximised. If all markets in the economy achieve maximum social/community surplus the welfare of a country’s citizens will be maximised. Diagram 2.37 show the maximisation of the consumer surplus (green area) and producer surplus (yellow area) at the equilibrium price. This is allocative efficiency because the social/community surplus is maximised. Externalities Externalities are any impact that the production or consumption of a good or service has on a third party. A third party is someone other than the producers and consumers of a good or service in a market. Third parties are often stakeholders in a community who can be positively or negatively affected by the activity in a market. For example, the Glastonbury music festival brings benefits to the third parties (local residents and businesses) of this small town in Devon, England such as local tax income for better public services, and visitors who shop in the town’s retailers and improvements to the local road infrastructure. But it comes with costs to third parties as well. When the festival takes place there will be road congestion, increased amounts of litter and noise pollution. Economists divide externalities into: • External costs or negative externalities • External benefits or positive externalities © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 External costs or negative externalities External costs are the spillover costs that negatively impact third parties which result from the production or consumption of a good or service. They can be divided into two types: production external costs and consumption external costs. Production external costs (negative externalities) Production external costs arise from the production of a good or service. A chicken farm, for example, emits a very strong smell, which adversely affects residents who live within a mile of the farm, as well as people who travel past the farm. Marginal private costs When the eggs are produced the costs of resources used in their production determines the supply decision of the egg producer. These are the raw materials, labour and capital used by the egg farm. These are the private costs of production. Each extra unit produced by the farm is the marginal private cost. Marginal social costs The external costs (negative effects) on the local residents of the strong smell of producing the eggs are not included in the private costs of production. The social cost of producing the eggs is: marginal private cost (MPC) + external cost = marginal social cost (MSC) Production external costs and market failure We can use marginal cost and benefit analysis to examine how external production costs lead to market failure. Diagram 2.38 is used to illustrate this marginal analysis. If we assume the only externalities in a market are production external costs (there are no other production or consumption externalities) then demand or marginal private benefits from the consumption of the good equals its marginal social benefits. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 The market output is determined by demand and supply or where marginal private benefits equal marginal private costs. In the egg market example, this is set where the demand for eggs (MPB) equals the supply of eggs (MPC) at output Q and price P in diagram 2.38. Market output: MPB = MPC = output Q The socially efficient output is set where marginal social benefits equal marginal social costs at Q*, which is below the market output at Q. This is shown in diagram 2.38. Welfare loss A welfare loss to society occurs in a market when the output of a good or service means the social cost of production is greater than the social benefit of production. The yellow shaded area in diagram 2.38 shows the total welfare loss in the egg market example. At each level of output beyond Q* in diagram 2.38, MSC is greater than MSB, which means that the cost to society of each extra unit of eggs produced is greater than the benefit. Calculating the welfare loss (HL) A market’s welfare loss can be calculated by working out the area of the yellow welfare loss triangle in diagram 2.38. In this case, the data from the egg farm example is: • Q*: 300,000 units • Q: 500,000 units • MSB at Q: $2.00 • MSC at Q: $3.00 Calculation: (Q - Q*) x (MSC – MSB) / 2 = welfare loss (500,000 – 300,000) x ($3.00 - $2.00) / 2 = $100,000 Consumption external costs Consumption external costs exist when third parties experience the external cost from the consumption of a good or service. For example, when people smoke cigarettes, the smell and smoke from the cigarettes adversely affect other people who are not smoking. The rate of illness caused by cigarette smoking is also very high, which means that smokers take up more resources in a state-run health service than non-smokers do. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 The negative effects of consumption external costs, in this case smoking cigarettes, are not included in the demand curve or marginal private benefits of cigarette consumption, which means that the marginal social benefits of smoking are lower than the marginal private benefits. The marginal social benefits of consuming cigarettes lie to the left of the marginal private benefit or demand curve. This is shown in diagram 2.39. Marginal private benefit + external cost = marginal social benefit. Consumption external costs and market failure If we assume there are no externalities when producing the cigarettes, then supply equals the marginal social cost of producing the cigarettes. As a result, the output of the cigarette market is set where the demand for cigarettes equals the supply of cigarettes at price P and output Q. The socially efficient level of output for cigarettes is where marginal social benefits equal marginal social costs at output Q*. This is shown in diagram 2.39. In this case, the cigarette market is producing at output Q which is above the socially efficient level at Q*. This is a market failure because there is an over-allocation of resources in the cigarette market. Welfare loss The yellow shaded area in diagram 2.39 represents the welfare loss to society from the overallocation of resources in this example. At each level of output beyond Q* in diagram 2.39, MSC is greater than MSB which means that the cost to society of each extra unit of cigarettes consumed is greater than the benefit. Calculating the welfare loss (HL) A market’s welfare loss can be calculated by working out the area of the yellow welfare loss triangle in diagram 2.39. In this case, the data from the cigarette example is: • Q*: 3.6 million • Q: 4.8 million • MSB at Q: $9.00 • MSC at Q: $15.00 © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Calculation: (Q - Q*) x (MSC – MSB) / 2 = welfare loss (4.8m – 3.6m) x ($15.00 - $9.00) / 2 = $3.6 million External benefits or positive externalities External benefits are the spillover benefits that positively impact third parties as a result of the consumption or production of a good or service. They can be divided into two types: production external benefits and consumption external benefits. Production external benefits Production external benefits occur as a result of the production of a good or service. For example, if a major new car factory opens in a town. Marginal private benefits If a new car factory opens in a town it may employ local workers in the factory, use local businesses that provide services, and purchase raw materials and components from local producers. These are private benefits because they benefit the stakeholders directly associated with the location and operation of the car factory. External benefits The new car factory may also bring external benefits when it is set up in the town. For example, the workers from the car factory spend their income by using services in the town such as shops and restaurants. The car factory may also set up training schemes for local workers which is a private benefit to those workers, but an external benefit when those skilled workers become available to other businesses in the area. The car factory could also improve local infrastructure when new roads are built and broadband speeds are increased. These developments will also benefit the community in the town. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Production external benefits and market failure The external benefits are not included in the supply curve (private cost) for the car factory, but when the external benefit is added to the supply curve, the marginal social cost curve exists to the right of the supply curve. This is shown in diagram 2.40. We assume that there are no other external costs and benefits when consuming the cars. In the car factory example, the market output exists where demand equals the supply of cars at price P and output Q in diagram 2.40. The socially efficient output where marginal social cost equals marginal social benefit at output Q* in diagram 2.40. The market has failed because the socially efficient output Q* is above the market output Q. There is an under-allocation of resources in the market. Welfare loss The yellow shaded area in diagram 2.40 is the welfare loss to society because of the under-allocation of resources. The marginal social benefit from the car factory is greater than the marginal social cost at each level of output from Q to Q*. For extra units produced from Q to Q*, the benefit to society is greater than the cost. By only producing at Q society is missing out on the welfare more resources being allocated to the market would bring. Calculating the welfare loss (HL only) The car factory's welfare loss can be calculated by working out the area of the yellow welfare loss triangle in diagram 2.40. In this case, the data from the car factory example is: • Q: 50,000 units • Q*: 75,000 units • MSC at Q: $9,000 • MSB at Q: $12,000 © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Calculation: (Q* - Q) x (MSB – MSC) / 2 = welfare loss (75,000 - 50,000) x ($12,000 - $9,000) / 2 = $37.5 million Consumption external benefits Consumption external benefits occur when a good or service is consumed and there are spill-over benefits on third parties. For example, we often see external benefits in the market for healthcare goods and services when there are benefits to people beyond those who consume healthcare goods. Marginal private benefits For example, when people purchase a flu vaccination they benefit because they are less likely to catch the flu. This is a private benefit to these consumers, and each extra unit of the vaccination consumed is a marginal private benefit. Marginal social benefit Other people (third parties) in society also benefit because with fewer flu carriers, there are fewer people to catch the flu from. The people who are less likely to catch the flu because of other people’s vaccinations represent an external benefit from the consumption of the flu vaccine. Consumption external benefits and market failure The demand curve represents the private benefits from the flu vaccine. When we add the external benefits, we get the marginal social benefit curve. If we assume that there are no other externalities associated with the production of the flu vaccine, then the supply of the marginal private cost curve equals the marginal social cost curve. Diagram 2.41 illustrates the market for the flu vaccine. The market output is at the point where demand equals supply or marginal private benefit equals marginal private cost at output Q. The socially efficient level of output is where marginal social cost equals marginal social benefit at Q*. This means that the market output Q is below the socially efficient output at Q* and there is an underallocation of resources. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Welfare loss The yellow shaded triangle in diagram 2.41 represents the welfare loss to society from the flu vaccination. The marginal social benefit from the consumption of the vaccine is greater than the marginal social cost at each level of output from Q to Q*. This means from each extra unit of vaccine consumed between Q and Q*, the benefit to society is greater than its cost. By only producing at Q, society is missing out on the welfare from more resources being allocated to the market. The vaccine's welfare loss can be calculated by working out the area of the yellow welfare loss triangle in diagram 2.41. In this case, the data from the vaccine example is: • Q: 1.5 million units • Q*: 5.6 million units • MSB at Q: $8.00 • MSC at Q: $2.50 Calculation: (Q* - Q) x (MSB – MSC) / 2 = welfare loss (5.6m - 1.5m) x ($8.00 - $2.50) / 2 = $11.275m © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Unit 2.8(2): Market failure - merit goods and demerit goods What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • Theory of merit goods Under-consumption of merit goods as a market failure Theory of demerit goods Over-consumption of demerit goods as a market failure Introduction Merit goods, demerit goods and public goods are all associated with significant market failure. When this happens there is an important role for state intervention to correct these market failures. The concepts of merit, demerit goods and public goods were developed extensively by Professor Richard Musgrave (UCLA). His analysis of these goods is an example of why governments need to intervene in certain markets. Merit goods What is a merit good? Merit goods are goods that society says people should consume because they are associated with significant social benefits. Merit goods are a normative concept because they are based on a society’s judgement of what is or is not a merit good. Examples of merit goods Deciding what is or what is not a merit good is not that easy. Most textbooks focus on goods and services associated with health and education as merit goods and their provision is supported by most governments across the world. This can be broadened to include things like healthy food, recreation facilities, housing, museums and theatres. Where the examples of merit goods stop is difficult to say precisely and their existence is often influenced by political decision-making by governments. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Merit goods are an example of market failure because they tend to be under-consumed in free markets and this leads to an under-allocation of resources. Merit goods are often associated with significant external benefits to society from their consumption, and these are not accounted for in the free market allocation of resources. School education is a good example of how there would be underconsumption of a merit good in a free market without any government intervention. Remember, in the free-market model of the economy there would be no government-funded and managed state schools. There are three aspects to the under-consumption school education: External benefits When people are deciding to send their children to school, they do not consider the external benefits of school education. There are significant positive externalities associated with children attending school: they provide a more skilled workforce; they learn social skills that make them better citizens and they are likely to be healthier because they are taught how to live healthy lives. Diagram 2.42 illustrates the under-consumption of school education and its associated welfare loss. Undervalued private benefits Individuals make buying decisions based on their assessment of the private benefits the consumption of a good will give to them. People often under-value the benefits the consumption of a merit good will bring to them. Many people in society will value the education of their children very highly and will always send their children to school. Some people, however, might not see such a high value in education and would not be willing to pay for their children to go to school. Low incomes households School education is expensive, and some people would not be able to afford to send their children to school in a free market situation. The children of low-income households will miss out on the significant private benefits of attending school and society will not benefit from the positive externalities of educating the children of low-income households. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Demerit goods What is a demerit good? Demerit goods are goods that society says people should not consume because their consumption is associated with significant social costs. Like merit goods, demerit goods are a normative economic concept and are based on a society’s judgement of whether the consumption of a good should be discouraged. Examples of demerit goods Commonly used examples of demerit goods include alcohol, cigarettes, firearms and recreational drugs. But these examples can be extended to violent films, ownership of dangerous animals, junk food and gambling. As with merit goods, the distinction of what or is not a demerit good depends on where you are in the world and the political and cultural values of a country. Demerit goods as a market failure Demerit goods are an example of market failure because they tend to be over-consumed in free markets. Without any state intervention in a free market, there will be an over-allocation of resources. One of the key reasons for this is that demerit goods are associated with negative externalities. Alcohol is an example where there is over-consumption in a free market. Its over-consumption can be explained in two ways: External costs There is considerable evidence to show that the consumption of alcohol leads to negative externalities that adversely affect others in the form of poor behaviour by individuals in public places; drink driving; absenteeism and low level of productivity at work and domestic violence. In addition, people who consume large quantities of alcohol often use the healthcare system excessively and this reduces its availability to others. Diagram 2.43 shows how the over-consumption of alcohol and the associated welfare loss. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Overvalued private benefits Demerit goods like alcohol are also over-consumed because people do not consider the impact on their long-term welfare when consuming it. When individuals drink too much alcohol over a long period of time they might not factor in the impact it has on their physical and mental health. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Unit 2.8(3): Government intervention to manage externalities, merit and demerit goods What you should know by the end of this chapter Policies to deal with external costs and demerit goods: • Tax • Regulation • Tradable permits • Advertising • Education Policies to deal with external benefits and merit goods: • Subsidies • Regulation • State provision • Advertising • Education Reasons for government intervention We know from the previous chapters that cover externalities along with merit and demerit good that they lead to market failure. Without any government, intervention resources are misallocated and the welfare of a country’s citizens is not maximised. Governments intervene when there is market failure to affect resource allocation and improve the welfare of their country's citizens. Governments do this by trying to move output in markets where there is market failure closer to the socially efficient level where social costs equal social benefits. Policies for external costs The market failure associated with negative externalities leads to an over-allocation of resources and a resulting welfare loss to society. The government policies associated with dealing with negative externalities are based on the objective of trying to reduce the market output towards the socially efficient level where marginal social costs equal marginal social benefits. One of the central problems for any government trying to apply policies to reduce negative externalities and achieve the socially efficient level of output is the problem of measuring external costs and establishing where the socially efficient level of output is. For example, governments know there are negative externalities associated with the consumption of alcohol but it is very difficult to come up with an accurate measure of the extent to which resources are over-allocated in the market. This measurement is further complicated by the existence of positive externalities associated with the market for alcohol such as employment in related industries. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Demerit goods Many of the policies used to manage the market failure associated with consumption external costs can be used to deal with similar market failures associated with demerit goods. The application of indirect tax, regulation and demand-reducing policies can all be applied to demerit goods. Taxation (Pigovian tax) Tax on production external costs Where an industry is associated with significant negative externalities governments can impose indirect taxes on producers. An indirect tax adds to business costs causing an increase in the price of the good and leading to a fall in output towards the socially efficient level. This is illustrated by diagram 2.45, where an energy company pays a specific tax on the electricity it produces. The tax is called 'Pigovian' because it was developed from the work of the UK economist, Arthur Cecil Pigou who did significant amounts of research on market failure. In this example, the tax increases the market price to P1 and moves output from Q to Q1 which is at the socially efficient output at Q*. This removes the welfare loss associated with the electricity industry, although it should be pointed out that in reality achieving the exact socially efficient output is impossible. Tax on consumption external costs Tax can also be imposed on negative externalities of consumption. In many countries governments tax cigarettes to reduce their consumption and the associated social costs. Diagram 2.46 illustrates the impact of an indirect tax on cigarettes. The effect is similar to a tax on good on negative externalities of production, with the price of cigarettes increasing to P1 and the output of cigarettes being reduced from Q to Q* at the socially efficient output. The tax removes the yellow welfare loss triangle. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Advantages of using tax: • Tax revenue can be used to compensate affected third parties and to pay for the negative consequences of an externality. For example, the tax revenue from cigarettes can be used to pay for some of the healthcare costs of people who smoke. • Increasing price is an effective way of reducing consumption and production. Disadvantages of using tax: • Tax can reduce the welfare of low-income groups where the price of a good is a significant proportion of their income. For example, a tax on petrol can have a significant impact on the incomes of poorer households who rely on their cars. • Increasing business costs can lead to lower business profits and even business failure. Increasing tax can be particularly significant for small businesses. • If business costs rise in industries such as energy this could lead to a higher average price level in the economy and increase inflation. • The tax can make domestic firms uncompetitive on international markets and lead to a fall in exports. • If business output decreases because of the tax increase it can cause unemployment to rise in an industry. Regulation Regulation of production external costs The government can use legislation to regulate markets associated with external costs. Governments can regulate production externalities by requiring firms to meet certain criteria when they are producing goods and services. For example, airlines flying into international airports are not allowed to land and take off between 23.30 and 0600. The construction industry is subject to government regulations when it is planning building projects and needs to meet different planning regulations. There are regulations on certain substances such as asbestos that cannot be used in manufacturing processes. Regulation of consumption external costs The strictest form of regulation is to make the consumption and production of a good with significant external costs illegal. This is the case with recreational drugs like cocaine and heroin where consumption and production are illegal in most countries. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 It is also possible for governments to allow the consumption and production of a good but control the market. Alcohol, for example, is a legal recreational drug but its consumption is controlled in many countries in the form of age restrictions, licensing hours, licensed retailers, restricted consumption in public places, restrictions on advertising and the products need to have health warnings on their packaging. Advantages of regulation: • They can be targeted more specifically at a negative externality than taxation. If the main pollutant in the production of a good is a specific chemical, then a regulation can deal more specifically with that problem than a tax. • Whilst regulations can cause an increase in costs, they are less likely to lead to an increased price than a tax if the firm can comply with the regulation relatively easily. Disadvantages of regulation: • The cost of implementing legal restrictions can be significant for governments. For example, governments spend huge amounts of money on their anti-drug law enforcement programmes. • Parallel markets arise in regulated markets and the goods provided can be in the hands of criminal gangs. This is a particular problem in the recreational drugs market. • Regulations can drive up business costs increasing prices for consumers. For example, regulations on the burning of fossil fuels and CO2 emissions have increased the cost of electricity. • Firms can find their way around regulations. • Businesses often locate production facilities in countries with lower regulations, which adversely affects domestic employment and can move the externality problem to another country. Tradeable permits The last 20 years have seen the rise in the market for tradeable permits or cap and trade schemes, which are a market solution to the problem of external costs. The market for CO2 emission permits has become an increasingly important measure used to control the negative externalities associated with C02 pollution as a contributor to climate change. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 The system for carbon trading works in the following way: • The government sets a total limit on the carbon emissions it will allow from an industry. • The total of carbon emissions is then divided up amongst producers that emit carbon and they are allocated a CO2 allowance. • The producers are not allowed to emit more CO2 than their allowance. • This gives producers in the industry an incentive to reduce their CO2 emissions because they can sell any unused allowance they have to less carbon-efficient producers. • If the government reduces the number of permits their price and value rise and there is a greater incentive for producers to reduce their emissions. To be truly successful in addressing climate change the carbon trading system needs to be an international market and the emission limits need to be policed effectively. The current market for CO2 permits is worth about $82 billion. Advantages of tradeable permits: • Carbon credits create an incentive system that is more effective at reducing CO2 than a tax that firms need to pay whatever their carbon emissions. • Using an incentive-based system facilitates innovation and firms develop technology to reduce pollution. Disadvantages of tradeable permits: • The system is complicated and expensive to set up and administer. • The number of permits allowed needs to be tightly controlled at an international level to have any impact on CO2 emissions and some countries may not follow the system. • The permits add to business costs and lead to higher prices. Reducing demand An alternative way of dealing with negative externalities is to reduce the demand for the good associated with the negative externality to the socially optimum level of output. This can be done through government-financed advertising campaigns. Many countries run advertising campaigns that try to persuade people to give up smoking or taking recreational drugs. Similarly, governments run education programmes that inform people of the hazards associated with smoking, drinking alcohol and taking recreational drugs. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 It is also possible for governments to reduce the demand for goods associated with negative externalities by subsidising products that are substitutes for the ones with the negative externality. For example, subsidising public transport causes the demand for private car use to fall along with the negative externalities associated with the use of cars. Diagram 2.47 shows how an effective advertising campaign against drinking alcohol reduces its demand, which in turn reduces the external cost associated with its consumption. In this example, the welfare loss is removed as D shifts to D1. Advantages of reducing demand • Advertising does not add to business costs so the price of goods does not increase. • For some consumption negative externalities such as cigarettes and alcohol, this approach might be more effective as a long-term solution to the problem because it changes consumer behaviour. Disadvantages of regulation: • There is an opportunity cost to the government of paying for advertising, education and subsidies. • The effectiveness of advertising and educational programmes are difficult to measure and are sometimes questionable. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Policies for external benefits The market failure associated with positive externalities leads to an under-allocation of resources and a resulting welfare loss because society misses out on the potential welfare gain from producing at the socially efficient output. The government policies associated with dealing with positive externalities are based on the aim of trying to increase the market output towards the socially efficient level where marginal social costs equal marginal social benefits. One of the central problems for any government trying to apply policies to increase output to achieve the socially efficient level is measuring external benefits and establishing where the socially efficient level of output is. Merit goods Government policies aim to encourage the consumption and production of merit goods. This is the same set of policies discussed with positive externalities: subsidy, state provision, regulation, advertising and education are applied to merit goods. Subsidies Subsidies on external benefits of consumption When positive externalities exist in a market the government aims to increase market output to the socially optimum level. The payment of a subsidy provides a financial incentive for producers to increase output, and consumers to increase consumption of a good associated with positive externalities. For example, governments subsidise anti-malarial drugs to make them more affordable in developing countries. Diagram 2.48 shows the impact of the subsidy on anti-malarial drugs. Initially, the market output is at Q below the socially efficient level at Q*. There is a potential welfare gain equal to the yellow shaded area. When the subsidy is added by the government the price falls from P to P1 and output rises to the socially efficient level at Q* and welfare is gained. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Subsidies on production external benefits By subsidising the production of a good with positive externalities firms are encouraged to increase output towards the socially efficient level. Subsidies are often paid to firms who locate in areas of industrial decline because the positive externalities of their location help to stimulate regional economic growth. Diagram 2.49 illustrates the effect of a subsidy paid to businesses that locate in an area that has suffered from significant industrial decline. The price falls from P to P1 and output increases to the socially efficient output at Q*. Advantages of subsidies: • Subsidies create direct financial incentives that will increase output and capture the welfare gain from external benefits. • Low-income consumers benefit from lower-priced goods particularly if they are on necessity goods such as healthcare products. • Producers will be encouraged to increase output which creates employment. Disadvantages of subsidies: • There is an opportunity cost to the government of the subsidy in terms of other public services they could have financed. • The subsidy might take resources away from other products. A subsidy on, for example, anti-malaria drugs may take resources away from drugs for other illnesses such as HIV • Subsidies are often paid to high-income groups such as rich people benefiting from subsidised healthcare. • Subsidies can lead to a welfare loss where inefficient producers are drawn into the market. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 State provision The government could choose to take the provision of merit goods and other goods associated with significant positive externalities into the public sector and provide the goods themselves at the socially efficient level of output. This is particularly true in the healthcare and education markets where the provision of these merit goods is seen as being so important to society. Advantages of state provision: • Government provision of merit goods is the most direct way of increasing output towards the socially efficient level. • Many people believe the state is more likely than the private sector to make decisions about the provision of merit goods that are in the public interest. • Goods can be provided at the price (or zero price) that all households can afford. This is seen as particularly important in healthcare and education. Disadvantages of state provision: • The cost of providing a state-run healthcare and education systems is extremely high and carries a significant opportunity cost to the government • Some people believe that state provision is less efficient than private-sector provision because state-run organisations experience diseconomies of scale • State-run organisations are often subject to considerable political interference which compromises their benefits to society. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Regulation Governments believe that the consumption of some goods is so crucial to the welfare of individuals in society that the government forces people to consume them. This is particularly the case with primary and secondary school education where many countries make it compulsory for parents to send their children to school through the law. This is also the case with car insurance where individuals legally need to own third-party car insurance so people adversely affected by a car accident will be compensated. Advantages of regulation: • Laws compel individuals and businesses to make decisions that increase output to the socially efficient level. • Regulations can be targeted precisely at goods and services with positive externalities. Disadvantages of regulations: • There can be significant costs of policing the system and enforcing regulations. • Regulations add to business costs which can reduce employment and increase prices. • Some people avoid the regulations and parallel markets can develop. Increasing demand Governments can try to increase the demand for goods associated with positive externalities to move production and consumption towards the socially efficient level of output. For example, the state can fund the advertising of things like further education, healthy eating and exercise to increase the demand for goods and services in these markets and increase the resulting external benefits. Educational programmes can be used to increase the demand for merit goods by informing people of the benefits, for example, of vaccinating against diseases like measles. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 10 Diagram 2.50 illustrates the impact of a government advertising campaign to increase the consumption of fruit and vegetables as part of a healthy living policy. The demand curve for fruit and vegetable shifts to the right and market output increases from Q to Q1 which is closer to the socially efficient output Q*. As a result, some welfare is gained and is shown by the yellow area on the diagram. Advantages of increasing demand: • Education and advertising are not as expensive as using subsidies and do not have the management problems of regulation • The approach can be effective in altering human behaviour which is an effective long-run solution to the under-provision of goods associated with positive externalities. Disadvantages of increasing demand • The opportunity cost to the government of funding advertising and educational programmes. • It is not always easy to measure the effectiveness of advertising and educational programmes. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 11 Unit 2.8(4): Common pool (pool) resources What you should know by the end of this chapter: Common pool resources Tragedy of the commons Managing common pool resources through: • Property rights • Command and control regulation • Collective self-governance • Porter hypothesis • Carbon taxes • Tradeable permits • International agreements What is environmental economics? If economics is the study of how society allocates scarce resources to satisfy human wants, then environmental economics considers this statement in the light of how economic activity impacts the environment. We know from our study of market failure, that the external costs resulting from consumption and production in free, unregulated markets have a negative effect on the environment and that governments along with international organisations have an important role in correcting these failures. Common pool (pool) resources and sustainability What is a common pool resource? Common pool resources are resources that firms and individuals can pool in society without restriction. Common pool applies to resources like forests for timber, the sea for fish and areas of land for mineral deposits. Characteristics of common pool resources Common pool resources are associated with two characteristics: • Common pool resources are non-excludable because they occur naturally in the environment, and without government intervention, it is very difficult to limit access to them. Anyone can pool fish in the sea and cut down trees in a forest if there is no legal system to prevent people from doing this • Common pool resources are rivalrous because the consumption of them by one individual does reduce their availability to others. If someone takes fish from the sea or cuts down a tree it is not available to someone else. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Property rights Property rights exist when an individual or a firm has ownership of a resource. When a farmer owns a field they have property rights over that field and have the legal right to control its use. They can put a fence around it and other people cannot legally use the field. Common pool resources do not have property rights assigned to them and nobody owns them. For example, there are no property rights on the open sea. The lack of property rights makes common pool resources non-excludable. Sustainability This is where the use of resources in the economy meets the needs of the present generation without adversely affecting the needs of future generations. Unsustainable economic activity is often associated with the over-consumption of common pool resources which reduces their availability to people in future. They are also often associated with external costs which have a negative impact on people in the present and also people in the future. The way the burning of fossil fuels impacts the atmosphere as a common pool resource is an important example of this. Common pool resources and market failure Non-excludability and zero price The non-excludable nature of common pool resources means there is no price attached to their consumption. In many cases common pool resources are also used in production, so free pool to them at zero price means they are a zero cost to producers who use them. This leads to their exploitation. If an area of land can be freely pooled to cut down trees, people will clear a forest in an unrestricted way until significant deforestation has taken place and there is no forest for future generations to benefit from. The exploitation of common pool resources means they are being used in an unsustainable way. External costs When common pool resources are over-consumed there will often be significant external costs as well. Deforestation negatively affects third parties because it adds to climate change and reduces biodiversity. You can also make the externality argument when the use of common pool resources now reduces their availability to future generations. Over-fishing now means fish will not be available to people in the future who would be considered a third party. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Diagram 2.51 illustrates the external costs of overfishing the sea. The market output is at Q which is above the socially efficient output of Q*. There is an over-allocation of resources and the yellow shaded area represents the welfare loss to society. Developing countries The exploitation of common pool resources often takes place in less developed countries where property rights are not established effectively. People in poverty are often forced to exploit cheap resources available to them. Lots of deforestation takes place in developing countries when people are involved in illegal logging and mining to make enough income to survive. Tragedy of the commons The theory of the tragedy of the commons was put forward by an ecologist called Garrett Hardin. He argued that the use of common pool resources leads to a ‘shared-resource system’ where people over-produce goods using common pool resources because it is in their self-interest to do so. If a resource can be pooled at zero price then it is in the producer’s self-interest to make as much profit as they can from using a zero-priced resource. People are likely to overfish the sea or cut down a rainforest because of the profit they can make doing this. The tragedy of the commons shows how common pool resources are a market failure and are not sustainable. Free rider problem The free-rider problem also applies to common pool resources where some people choose to benefit from other people’s actions. All people in the fishing industry might accept there is a need to reduce fishing in the present to preserve stocks for the future and agree to cut current fishing. But as a voluntary agreement, some producers might keep fishing at the same level and free ride off the reduced fishing of others. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Policy approach to common pool resources Common pool resources need government intervention because their use leads to an overallocation of resources. This depletes resources for the future which is unsustainable and the overuse of common pool resources leads to negative externalities. Assigning property rights Economists often look at the problem of common pool resources as a property rights issue. A property right is an individual’s right to control what they own and to be compensated when that right has been infringed. If someone takes flowers from your garden, you can take legal action against the person who has taken them. The use of common pool resources is un-controlled because there are no property rights assigned to them. Anyone can pool a piece of common land, a river or a lake and extra resources without any legal restriction. By assigning property rights to a forest people who cut down trees have to pay the owner who can use the income to plant new trees. Without property rights, people will cut down trees and not replant them which means deforestation will take place. Advantages of property rights: • Property rights provide a market solution to the common pool resources problem. By allocating property rights common pool resources now have owners and can be made excludable. • Owners of common pool resources have an incentive to manage them sustainably or there will not be a long-term source of income from them. • Allocating property rights is a relatively low-cost way of dealing with the common pool resources problem. Disadvantages of property rights: • The owner might not have social efficiency as an objective of their ownership of a common pool resource. An owner of a forest might allow deforestation. • Some common pool resources are areas of natural beauty that society wants to be maintained in a particular way. National parks, for example, are owned and controlled by governments. • The legal costs associated with the resolution of property rights disputes can be significant. • It is not always practical to assign property rights. Many external costs are ‘air-borne and people can’t own the airspace around them. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Command-and-control regulation Endangered Species Act (ESA) The aim of command-and-control regulations is for government to set specific limits on environmental pollution. The regulations also set out how technology can be used to control pollution. Examples of command and control regulations come from the US in the form of The Clean Water Act, Endangered Species Act and The Clean Air Act. For example, the US has government-imposed regulations on power plants to use cleaning technology in their smokestacks that removed pollutants like sulphur dioxide. There is also an Endangered Species Act that prevents the hunting of certain wild animals. Advantages of command and control regulation • By using the law, it forces firms to take action that reduces the negative externalities of production that occur with the exploitation of common pool resources • It provides a set of regulations to form a national framework that reduces the environmental costs that are associated with common pool resources • Strict command and control regulations can induce firms to develop technology that allows them to meet the regulations set. This is known as the Porter Hypothesis, named after the economist, Michael Porter. Disadvantages of command and control regulation • There are no incentives for businesses to improve the quality of the environment beyond the standard set by the law. Firms do not need to improve their production methods if they are within the regulations set. • The regulations do not distinguish between firms that find it easy to meet the standards set and those that do not. For those that find it difficult, the regulations will come with a significant cost and those firms may even go out of business which will lead to unemployment. • Like any regulation, they will increase production costs which could cause unemployment and lead to higher prices for consumers. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Collective self-governance The collective self-governance approach to the negative environmental consequences of common pool resources is based on the work of Nobel Prize-winning Economist, Elinor Ostrom. Her theory viewed government-directed regulation as bureaucratic and less effective at achieving their environmental aims as ordinary citizens working together to solve environmental problems. Ostrom found evidence across the world of local people working together to solve the environmental costs associated with the tragedy of the commons. Left to themselves the local population would find solutions to environmental problems that met their own needs rather than those of a detached government imposing them from some distance away. An example of self-governance is Maine’s fishing community that specialises in lobster. In Main’s fishing towns the local people make and monitor their own rules and have their own set of punishments for people who break the rules. The fishing territory for lobster is broken up into set boundaries decided on by the fishing community and groups known as ‘harbour gangs’ are only allowed to fish in their allocated area. This approach to dealing with common pool resources is backed by formal government regulation on catching lobsters. Advantages of collective self-governance • This approach allows for the needs of local communities who know and understand the specific issues they face from common pool resources and are more likely to follow their regulations rather than those imposed on them. • By working at a local level, the negative externalities associated with the common pool resources can be targeted specifically rather than a ‘one size fits all’ national approach. • Collective agreements are more flexible than national regulations and can change as the environmental situation changes. If the lobster population suddenly declines the catch regulations can be tightened quickly. Disadvantages of collective self-governance • Without legal backing, the enforcement of rules relating to common pool resources relies on the goodwill of participants and this may not always be present. What happens if one business in Maine decides to catch lobsters outside of its area and refuses to follow local rules? © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 • Collective self-governance might work in the present but may not consider the future in the same way. If the incomes of people in the lobster industry start to fall, there would be pressure to catch more now which reduces the sustainability of the industry • Many common pool resource issues are global and cannot the effectively managed at a local level. Carbon tax Carbon taxes are imposed on the use of fossil fuels such as coal, oil and gas. Carbon taxes focus precisely on one of the most significant causes of climate change by directly trying to reduce CO2 emissions from the use of fossil fuels. The tax is levied on firms based on the amount of carbon they use to produce their good or service. The tax aims to get businesses and consumers to switch to energy generated by renewable sources such as solar and wind power. Some of the taxes levied on businesses would increase the price the consumer pays, but this could be repaid to consumers through a tax credit paid from the tax revenue collected by the government. Diagram 2.52 illustrates how a carbon tax affects the market for electricity. The tax causes the supply curve to shift to the left and cause the market price to rise to P1 and output Q to shift to Q1 which is closer to the socially efficient output at Q*. The welfare loss triangle is reduced from the yellow-shaded triangle to the smaller green triangle. Advantages of a carbon tax • The tax focuses on a major source of climate change and acts as an incentive for firms to switch to renewable sources of energy. • Revenue raised by the tax can be used to subsidise innovation in the development of renewable energy. Disadvantages of a carbon tax • A tax will increase the price of energy to consumers if producers pass on the tax increase. This could have a significant impact on low-income households. • As business costs are increased by the tax it reduces their profits which leaves businesses less money to invest in developing low-emission technology. • Higher production costs resulting from the tax could lead to a reduction in output and cause unemployment. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Tradeable permits The use of tradeable permits or carbon training is seen as an important ‘incentive based’ method for businesses to reduce CO2 carbon emissions. Air is a common pool resource and tradeable permits create a market that introduces a limit to the amount of CO2 pollution that can be emitted into the air. For detailed coverage of this policy see chapter 2.8(2) on policies to deal with external costs. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Unit 2.9: Public goods What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • The nature of public goods Concepts of non-rivalrous and non-excludable consumption Free rider problem leading to market failure Policy approach to the market failure associated with public goods State provision of public goods Alternative methods of provision by the private sector What is a public good? Public goods or pure public goods are goods that bring significant social benefits to society but cannot be provided by the free market. They are a market failure, which means the government needs to intervene in the market to ensure they are provided. Because they bring significant social benefits we also consider them to be merit goods. Public goods have two characteristics: Non-rivalrous Non-rivalrous means the consumption by one individual does not reduce the availability to others. For example, if a group of people are benefiting from a public good like street-lighting and an extra person comes along to take advantage of the light the availability to the existing consumers is not reduced. This means the marginal cost (the cost of providing the good to an additional consumer) of providing a public good is zero once it is set up and being produced. The extra person who benefits from street-lighting adds nothing to the cost of providing the streetlight. Non-excludable Once a public good is being produced it is impossible to stop people from benefiting from it. Once streetlights are turned on it is impossible to stop people from benefiting from them, assuming they can get to an area covered by the lights. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Examples of pure public goods There are not many examples of pure public goods, but economic theory would normally include flood barriers, sea defences, street lighting and national defence. Economists often distinguish between pure public goods and quasi-public goods. Quasi-public goods have some elements of being non-rivalrous and non-excludable but not in the precise way that defines pure public goods. Examples include roads, bridges and public parks. Roads have some of the characteristics of public goods, but the space on a road can be looked at as being rivalrous when too many cars use them, and they can be excludable if tolls are in place. Public goods as a market failure Public goods are considered an example of market failure in pure free markets because they would not be produced. This is because of the ‘free rider’ problem. Once a public good is set up and being produced it is impossible to prevent people from benefiting from it (non-excludability) even if they have not paid for the good: some individuals free ride 'on the back' of the consumption paid for by others. Consider the example of a town that keeps being flooded by a river. The town needs a flood defence. A group of people who live alongside the river think of pooling their money to pay for flood defences, but they do not have enough money to pay for the barrier unless the whole town contributes. Large numbers of people in the town choose not to contribute as they know that once the flood barrier is built they can benefit from it without paying – they can free ride on the consumption of those who do pay. This means the market price of the flood barrier will not be high enough for it to be provided. Public goods like flood barriers often have very high initial set-up costs so even wealthy philanthropic individuals would not be able to fund their provision. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Diagram 2.53 shows how the socially efficient output of the blood barrier at Q* where MSB equals MSC. The MSC curve in this case is horizontal at C because the marginal cost of an additional user of a flood barrier is zero. Once the flood barrier is set up the marginal cost of providing it to each additional consumer does not change as more consumers benefit from it. If the flood barrier costs $1Bn the cost will not change if two million people benefit from it or three million people benefit from it. Remember, this is hypothetical because in a free market the flood barrier would not be built. Because the output is zero in the market the whole yellow shaded area is the welfare loss. Government intervention to manage public goods The nature of pure public goods means that they will not be provided by the free market. Where a public good is something society should provide (street-lighting, defence and flood defences) the government can intervene through direct state provision. Quasi-public goods like parks, the police and street cleaning will be under-provided in a free market and governments intervene to produce quasi-public goods at the socially efficient level of output. State provision Where governments see the provision of a public good as crucial to society they will set up and provide the public good. Most countries have public goods that are set up and provided by the state. Public goods such as national defence, flood defences and street lighting are directly provided by the government and funded through taxation. Advantages of state provision: • Government provision of public goods is the only way they can be produced. Remember the free market will not generate a price that can support the production of a public good. • Government are more likely to provide quasi-public goods near the socially efficient output. • When the government is providing a public good it is more likely to make decisions in the public interest compared to private sector businesses that aim to make a profit. This could be important in the provision of quasi-public goods such as parks. • Governments can provide public goods at zero price so they are available to low-income households. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Disadvantages of state provision: • The cost of providing state-funded and managed public goods is extremely high and there is a significant opportunity cost to the government in terms of other areas of expenditure. • Some people question the efficiency of state-run organisations that provide public goods. • State-managed and organised public goods can be influenced by political decision making which may not be in the best interests of society. For example, expenditure on defence can be influenced by political rather than welfare factors. • It is impossible to accurately know the level of provision of the public good that is socially efficient. Private sector operation Governments can set up and pay for the provision of public goods that can then be managed by private sector organisations. This is particularly the case with quasi-public goods like street cleaning. In this situation, the government pays private businesses that are contracted to clean the streets and dispose of waste. Advantages of private sector provision: • This approach has the benefit of making sure the public good is provided, but the operational management may be more efficient than government-managed provision. • Private sector provision means political decision-making is less likely to take place in the management of the public good. The problems with this approach: • The cost of setting up the provision of the public good still needs to be paid for by the government which will come with an opportunity cost. • A private sector firm may provide the service putting profit ahead of welfare. Private sectoroperated prisons are sometimes criticised for cost-cutting management practices. • It is impossible to know the level of provision of a private sector-managed public good to achieve the socially efficient output. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Unit 2.10: Asymmetric information (HL) What you should know by the end of this chapter • • • • • • The nature of asymmetric information Adverse selection Moral hazard Asymmetric information as a market failure Market responses to asymmetric information Policy responses to asymmetric information through legislation and regulation What is asymmetric information? Asymmetric information is an imbalance of information that exists between buyers and sellers in a market that gives one side an unfair advantage in a transaction. For example, when someone goes to buy a used car the seller of the car will normally know more about the car than the buyer. The seller might know that the engine is unreliable but chooses not to tell the buyer about this. As a result, the seller receives a higher price, and the buyer pays a higher price than if this information had been made available to the buyer as well as the seller. Types of asymmetric information Adverse selection Adverse selection is an example of where asymmetric information leads to market failure. Adverse selection is where one party in a transaction has better information than another on which to make their buying or selling decision. This means the buyers and/or sellers make decisions that do not maximise welfare in a market and this leads to market failure. Buyer advantage When buying insurance, for example, the buyer has more information about their risk to the insurer than the insurance company selling them a policy. A buyer of car insurance might drive at high speeds and use their phone when driving, but the insurance company does not know about this because the buyer hides it from them. As a result, the buyer gets cheaper insurance and the insurance company receives a lower price than would be the case if the company had known about the buyer's risky driving. Other examples include, where an expert antique dealer buys antiques from inexperienced sellers, or a person takes out a loan from a bank and lies about their income. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Seller advantage Sellers often hold more information about the good or service they are selling than is available to the buyer. In markets for complex products, this puts sellers at a significant advantage. For example, a firm that sells anti-virus software knows how much protection their product offers the consumers who buy their software. It is very difficult for a buyer who is unfamiliar with this type of software to value what they are buying except by looking at competing products and assessing how much to pay to stop their computer from getting a virus. The product might cost the firm $10 to manufacture but they can sell it for $100 to an uninformed buyer. Other examples include when people buy complex financial products like pensions or a real estate agent selling a house with structural problems. Moral Hazard Moral hazard occurs when there is an incentive for people to change their behaviour because the negative consequences of their decisions are borne by others. For example, if you hire a car and it is covered by comprehensive insurance, it means that any accident you might have is covered by the insurance. Because of the insurance cover, you might drive the car much more recklessly than if it is not covered by the insurance. The costs of the repairs caused by your reckless driving will add to the insurance cost of the car hire firm and push up the hire price for everyone else. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Why is asymmetric information a market failure? Asymmetric information means buyers and sellers in a market make decisions on information that does not accurately reflect the value they put on the goods they are buying or selling. Seller advantage An example of seller advantage is where buyers of diesel cars made decisions about buying them based on the private benefits they received from owning a diesel car. Part of this decision may have been related to the low emissions associated with diesel cars. The car manufacturers knew that the emissions were higher than those they advertised. This buyer asymmetry means that the marginal social benefit curve of diesel cars is lower than the marginal private benefit curve. As a result of this, the socially efficient output of Q* is below the market output of Q, which is shown in diagram 2.54. Buyer advantage When businesses, for example, sell health insurance they set the price for their insurance based on the health risk of the people they insure. If someone is overweight, smokes and does not exercise, then they are more likely to be ill and claim on their insurance. These people should pay a higher price for their insurance, but if these buyers keep their unhealthy lifestyle hidden from the insurance company, they will pay a lower price than the true value of their insurance premium. This means the marginal social cost of providing the insurance is greater than the marginal private cost. This is shown in diagram 2.55 where the market output is at Q, but the socially efficient output is Q*. There is an over-allocation of resources and the yellow shaded area is the associated welfare loss. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Market responses to asymmetric information Signalling Buyers are wary of purchasing goods and services in markets where there is asymmetric information and they are at a knowledge disadvantage. Sellers know this and try to sell their goods in a way that makes buyers feel more confident about the goods they are purchasing. One way of doing this is to offer warrantees or guarantees that offer buyers the chance to get a replacement or their money back on faulty goods. The second-hand car market has many offers of warranties to attract buyers. Screening Buyers in asymmetric information situations can pay an agent or a lawyer who has good knowledge of a market to advise them on buying decisions. Most people use an estate agent and a lawyer when they are buying a house to advise them on such a significant purchase. Buyers can also do their own research to screen the sellers they are buying from. The growth of online independent reviews of hotels and restaurants is an example of this. Policies for asymmetric information Legislation and regulation When goods are being bought and sold in an asymmetric situation both buyers and sellers face regulations and laws that try to correct the asymmetry and the market failure associated with it. Buyers For the buyers, there is a considerable amount of consumer legislation that protects people in asymmetric situations when they buy goods and services. Governments set out rules that businesses legally need to follow such as: ‘goods of a satisfactory quality’, ‘fit for the purpose they are used for’ and ‘meet the seller’s description’. Laws will also state that buyers have a right to a refund or a replacement for goods if they do not meet necessary standards. Sellers When goods are being bought buyers also have to follow rules and regulations to give the seller complete information before they decided on a sale. For example, when you buy car insurance you need to give the insurance company accurate information about yourself so the company can make a judgement on the risk of insuring you. They will then set an insurance premium based on this. It is illegal to lie to an insurance company when you are applying for insurance. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Unit 3.1(1): Measuring the level of economic activity What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • • • • National income accounting as a measure of economic activity Circular flow of income model Income, output and expenditure approaches to national income Gross domestic product (GDP) Calculation of GDP (HL) Gross national income (GNI) Calculation of GNI (HL) Real GDP and real GNI Calculation of real GDP and real GNI (HL) Real GDP/GNI per capita at purchasing power parity (PPP) Business cycle National income as a measure of economic activity Economic activity is where scarce resources are allocated to produce goods and services to satisfy human wants. Macroeconomics is the study of economic activity from a whole economy perspective. For example, the German economy is well known for its highperforming manufacturing sector with famous names like Volkswagen, Daimler AG, Allianz and BMW. Microeconomics allows us to examine these individual businesses and the industries they operate in. Macroeconomics looks at Germany’s manufacturing sector in the context of the whole economy where it accounts for 47 per cent of the country’s GDP. So, any change in Germany’s manufacturing sector has a significant impact on its national output. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 The circular flow of income An economic model The circular flow of income is an economic model that illustrates the flow of money between firms and households at a macroeconomic level. It can be further developed to include foreign trade, government and banking sectors. Whilst the model has been around since the 17th century, its importance as an economic theory was developed by John Maynard Keynes in his book, General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money which was published in 1936. The circular flow model is a useful aid to economic forecasting and policymaking. How the model works The model we are going to use in our analysis of the macroeconomy is a simplified version of the model used by institutions such as banks, universities, hedge funds and governments, but it is still very useful as a method of understanding how the macroeconomy works. The flow of income is illustrated in diagram 3.1. It can be explained by considering the following principles: • The economy can be divided into two sectors, firms and households. • Firms combine the factors of production to produce goods and services and households buy the goods and services and consume them. This is shown by the blue flows on the circular flow diagram 3.1. • To produce the goods and services firms need to employ people from the households which include labour and entrepreneurs and in return, the firms pay the households an income. This is shown by the red flows in diagram 3.1. • Injections of funds come into the circular of an economy in the form of investment, government expenditure and exports. • Withdrawal or leakages of funds from the circular flow of income go out in the form of savings, tax and imports. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Injections to the circular flow Injections are the flow of funds into the circular flow that come from firms investing, government spending and exports resulting from foreign trade. The three injections are: • Investment by businesses when they buy capital such as new buildings and machinery • Government expenditure on public services such as health and education • Exports of goods and services to other countries lead to an inflow of funds. Withdrawals from the circular flow Withdrawals from the circular flow occur when money leaves the economy through household savings, taxation by the government and imports resulting from foreign trade. The three withdrawals are: • Savings by households of income they do not spend on goods and services • Taxation by governments on household income, business profits and indirect tax on goods and services • Imports bought by firms and households lead to an outflow of funds. Application of the model Like the other models we use in Economics, the circular flow model lets us analyse the causes and consequences of changes in economic variables. The demand and supply model helps us examine how, for example, changes in household income affect price and output in a market. Here are some examples of how the circular flow model can be used to analyse how a change in injections and withdrawals affect the macroeconomy. Consider the following examples: • An increase in the value of exports by an economy increases the value of funds in the circular flow which leads to increases in household incomes and consumption, output by firms and employment. • An increase in taxation in the economy reduces the value of funds in the circular flow. This leads to a decrease in household incomes and consumption, output by firms and employment. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Defining GDP A country’s GDP is the money value of all final goods and services produced by that country in one year. It is a statistic used to measure macroeconomic activity. The GDP of a country is normally considered an annual figure, but economists and governments also use quarterly figures to track economic growth over time so they can closely monitor what is happening to economic activity. The GDP is expressed in money terms using the country’s currency, although for international comparison the value in $US is used. Using final goods and services When the GDP of a country is being calculated only the value of final goods is used. The value of intermediate goods such as raw materials and components are not included because this would lead to ‘double counting’. If you included the value of a television produced when it is sold by the manufacturer to a retailer (an intermediate good) and then count it again when it is sold to the consumer as a final good then you would count the value of the television twice. Using the circular of income to measure GDP The circular flow of income gives us 3 ways of measuring the GDP. Income method This is the total value of income earned by households in one year in the form of: • Wages paid to labour • Interest paid to capital • Rent paid to land • Profits and dividends paid to entrepreneurs. It is important not to count income in the form of transfer payments where no economic activity has been engaged in to generate the income. Transfer payments include pensions, unemployment benefits and student grants, etc. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Output method This is calculated by taking the value-added of firms in different sectors of the economy. The sectors are: • Primary – commodities such as agricultural goods, mining, forestry and fishing, etc. • Secondary – manufacturing such as cars, mobile phones, pharmaceuticals and clothing, etc. • Tertiary – services such as education, restaurants, tourism and transport, etc. Value added is the method of calculating GDP to avoid ‘double counting’. Value added is the monetary difference between the purchase cost of the material inputs used to produce the good and its selling price. If a car manufacturer, for example, pays for the materials and components to produce a car valued at $4,000 and sells the car to a dealer for $10,000 then the value added is $6,000. If the dealer takes the car they have bought for $10,000 and sells it for $14,000 their valueadded is $4,000. The value-added of each sector is used to calculate the GDP by the output approach. Expenditure method This is calculated by aggregating the total expenditure of different sectors of the economy. There are four types of expenditure: • Consumption (C) spending by households on final goods and services • Investment (I) spending by firms on capital equipment • Government (G) spending on public services • Net Exports (X-M) The surplus of the value of exports over the value of imports The table sets out the GDP of the five largest economies in the world. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Gross national income (GNI) Calculating GNI The gross national income is the total income generated by a country and is calculated by adding net property income from abroad to the GDP. GDP + net property income = GNI Net property income from abroad Property income is money earned by households on different assets. This income comes in the following forms: • Interest on loans made • Profit from businesses owned • Rent on property owned. Net property income is income on domestic assets owned overseas that flow into the domestic income less income on foreign assets that flow out of the domestic economy. Examples of property income inflows to the UK economy include income sent back to the UK in the form of: • Interest on UK loans made to German companies • Profits made by a UK company in Russia • Rent paid to the UK-owned commercial property in the US. Examples of property income outflows from the UK economy would include income sent to foreign countries in the form of: • Profits made by a German car manufacturer in the UK • Interest paid on loans made by an Australian bank to UK businesses • Rent paid to Chinese owners of luxury property in London. GNI per capita GNI per capita is measuring GNI per head of population. GNI per capita is calculated as: GNI / population = GNI per capita Last year the GNI for the US was $20.84 trillion and the population of the US was 328 million © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 20,840,000 million / 238 million = $63,537 Economists like to use GNI per capita when analysing national income data because it allows them to make inter-country comparisons. A per capita figure is much smaller than the total GNI so it is an easier number to interpret. GNI per capita is particularly useful when measuring a country’s economic development. Adjusting for inflation Importance of real terms The value of a country’s GDP is adjusted for inflation to turn the GDP in nominal terms into GDP in real terms. Nominal GDP is expressing GDP with no allowance for inflation. Expressing economic values in real terms is important because inflation distorts data and makes it difficult to interpret. For example, if a country’s GDP rises by 3 per cent this would be an acceptable rate of economic growth. But if that country’s inflation is 3 per cent then the country would not have grown at all. Calculating real GDP Calculating real GDP is done by dividing the nominal GDP by the GDP deflator and multiplying by 100. The table below sets out the GDP data for a country. For 2014 the real GDP is: 1792/96 x 100 = 1867 The growth rate is calculated by working out the annual percentage change in real GDP. For 2015 this would be: 1870 – 1867 / 1867 x 100 = 0.16% © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Economic Growth Measuring growth Economic growth is the increase in a country’s real GDP over time. The economic growth rate of a country is the percentage increase in its real GDP over one year. GDP figures are released quarterly so a country’s economic activity can be continuously monitored. The annual growth rate is calculated by: GDP current year – GDP previous year / GDP previous x 100 = current year growth rate Business cycle (trade cycle) Economies do not grow at a constant rate because the rate of growth of a country rises and falls over time and this is called the business cycle. The average rate of growth over a number of years is called the trend rate of growth. Amongst more developed countries (MDCs) the trend rate of growth is normally around 2-3 per cent. Diagram 3.2 illustrates a conventional business cycle. Conventional business cycle Business cycles are all slightly different, but the conventional cycle normally follows the changes set out below: • The boom phase occurs when the rate of growth is above the trend rate. High rates of economic growth in a boom are normally associated with rising incomes, falling unemployment, and rising inflation. • The slowdown phase of the business cycle is when the economy goes past its peak rate of growth and the growth rate falls. Household incomes do not rise as fast, unemployment might start to rise and there is less pressure for inflation to increase. • The recession phase of the cycle is when real GDP falls. A recession is technically defined as a period of two consecutive quarters of negative growth in real GDP. Household incomes might fall, unemployment normally increases and inflation falls • The recovery phase of the business cycle is when the economy emerges from a recession and the real GDP starts to increase. The rate of economic growth is slow to start with and then it accelerates. Household incomes start to rise, unemployment starts to fall and there is upward pressure on inflation. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Unit 3.1(2): Measuring Economic Development What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • Defining and measuring economic development Appropriateness of using GDP or GNI statistics to measure economic well-being Use of national income statistics to make comparisons over time and between countries Alternative measures of well-being: OECD Better Life Index, Happiness Index, Happy Planet Index Defining economic development Economic development can be defined as the improvement of the well-being of a country’s citizens over time. Economic development is, however, difficult to define because it focuses on the improvement in the welfare or well-being of a country’s population. Welfare or well-being are subjective terms, which makes defining economic development as 'an improvement in well-being' an open-ended statement that is difficult to quantify. Economists often view economic development in a multi-dimensional way that takes into account a number of different factors. Characteristics of economic development Many economists look at improvements in welfare by considering the following characteristics: • Rising household incomes, which gives the population greater access to goods and services that improve their material quality of life • Falling levels of poverty so everyone in society can enjoy a basic level of welfare • Increased provision of public services like education and health to give people the ability to improve their well-being. Many other characteristics could be considered, but these provide economists with a basic framework to understand and measure economic development. The characteristics considered above are based on the UN Development Programmes, Human Development Index (HDI), which we will cover later in this chapter. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Measuring economic development Real GNI per capita The principle that the higher the real GNI per capita a country has the more advanced its economic development is based on the idea that countries with a higher real GNI per capita will have: • Higher average incomes and their households have greater access to goods and services • Lower levels of poverty as the poorest in society have more income. • Better healthcare and education provision as the government has more tax revenue to spend on public services. This means countries with a higher real GNI per capita will have a better level of welfare for their population than countries with a lower real GNI per capita. The table sets out GNI per capita for five More Economically Developed Countries (MEDCs) in 2020. Purchase power parity (PPP) An important element of using GNI per capita to measure economic development is to convert GNI numbers into a common currency so they can be used for international comparison. For example, to compare the GNI of European countries with the US, Euros need to be converted into US Dollars. We could use market exchange rates to do this, but market exchange rates are constantly changing from day to day because of demand and supply changes in the currency markets. A current market exchange rate would give a misleading GNI conversion. Countries use a method called purchase power parity(PPP) to convert their GNIs into US dollars. The PPP is a long-term exchange rate calculated by considering the ratio of prices in one country compared to another. A basket of goods is chosen in each country that represents the typical basket of goods consumers buy. Price of the basket of goods in the US/price of the basket of goods in the EU = PPP exchange rate © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Income distribution The GNI per capita is an average and that does not account for the disparity between the richest and poorest people in society. The GNI per capita of a country may be high, but this can give a misleading view of welfare if there is a high concentration of income amongst a small percentage of the richest people in society. The nature of goods produced Some goods produced and consumed in a country add more to welfare than others. For example, $20 million spent on a school may well create more welfare than the same amount spent on a very expensive yacht because the social benefit to society of the consumption of education is greater than a yacht. Countries, where a high proportion of output is spent on luxury goods compared to necessity or merit goods, may have lower levels of overall welfare amongst the population. Diagram 3.3 shows the production possibility curves for two economies, country A and country B. Country A could be said to have higher welfare amongst its citizens relative to country B because it allocates more resources to necessity goods. Changes in quality over time It can be argued that economic growth understates economic development because the quality of products produced by an economy improves over time. The cars, computers and mobile phones consumers buy now are superior to the cars, computers, and mobile phones they bought 10 years ago. This will not be reflected in the GNI figures because they only reflect the money value of the products bought by consumers. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Non-monetary factors Some factors in a country add to welfare but cannot be measured in money terms, and so will not show in the GDP/GNI figures. Here is a sample list of factors that can affect welfare and are not included in real GNI per capita data: • Crime rates - a high crime rate will reduce welfare in a country. • Political Freedom - greater political freedom in a nation is often seen to increase welfare. • Leisure time - societies, where people have more leisure time, can offer their population a greater quality of life. • Climate - favourable weather conditions can offer a better standard of living. • Family and cultural values - societies where people feel closer to friends and relatives are often viewed as happier. • Mental health - low levels of stress, anxiety and depression are indicators of good levels of welfare. • Gender and racial equality - more equal societies are often viewed as ones with higher welfare. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Alternative methods of measuring economic development The real GNI per capita figure offers economists an objective figure with which to assess the economic development of a country, but it has limitations in terms of its use to measure the welfare or well-being of a country’s population. To consider welfare data in a wider sense, economists have developed a range of broader-based methods of measuring economic development. Whilst these alternative measures look at welfare in society in a more sophisticated way than GNI, they do have weaknesses. As they are averages they do not reflect everyone’s well-being and they try to measure things that are very difficult to measure, like collective happiness. Human development index (HDI) The Human Development Index is used by the United Nations Development Programme to measure a country's economic development in terms of life expectancy, education, and material standard of living. The following criteria are used in the construction of the HDI: • • • Life Expectancy in years (health indicator) Mean years of schooling and expected years of schooling (education indicator) Real GDP per capita (income indicator) The three criteria are combined to give a numerical value from 0-1, where the HDI value is closer to 1 the more developed a country is. OECD Better Life Index The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development has developed a broader measure of well-being which looks at some of the key factors that affect the welfare of a nation’s population. The Better Life Index uses 11 criteria that are objectively measured in a country to form an index number. The criteria include: • • • • • • • • • • • Housing Income Employment Community life Education Environmental factors Governance Health Level of happiness Safety and security Work-life balance © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 World Happiness Report Along with the Human Development Index, the United Nations has also developed the World Happiness Report based on a survey of how people rate their own lives. The survey ranks national happiness using a survey that asks a sample of respondents to think of their happiness as a ‘ladder’, with the highest life rating being a 10 and the lowest life rating being a zero. The individuals who are part of the survey have to consider factors such as citizen engagement, communications, technology, education, health, emotion and diversity, etc when they are making their judgement about happiness. The responses of a sample of individuals within a country are then aggregated to form the index. Happy Planet Index The Happy Planet Index measures sustainable well-being for a nation’s population. It considers the welfare of a nation in terms of achieving sustainable lives for its citizens. It was introduced by the New Economics Foundation (NEF) and uses a weighted index that favours countries with smaller ecological footprints. There are four elements used to construct the Happy Planet Index: wellbeing (based on the World Happiness Report), life expectancy, inequality of outcomes (based on wellbeing and life expectancy) and ecological footprint (average impact a citizen on the environment). Costa Rica is a country that has always performed well in Happy Planet Index. Its relatively good scores on life expectancy, wellbeing, ecological footprint and inequality give it a Happy Planet Index score of 44.7 well above its richer neighbour, the United States. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Unit 3.2(1): Variations in economic activity - aggregate demand (AD) What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • Definition of aggregate demand Aggregate demand curve Components of aggregate demand Consumption Investment Government expenditure Net exports: exports minus imports Changes in aggregate demand caused by changes in its determinants Determining economic activity The level of economic activity in a country is measured by its real GDP which is determined by the interaction of aggregate demand and aggregate supply of the whole economy. Changes in aggregate demand and aggregate supply determine the rate of economic growth an economy achieves. For example, the value of the US GDP is over $19 trillion because of the interaction of aggregate demand and aggregate supply in the American economy. The application of aggregate demand and supply is another way of modelling the macroeconomy, similar to the circular flow of income model. The flow of income, output, and expenditure of an economy in the circular flow model is determined by the interaction of aggregate demand and aggregate supply. Definition of aggregate demand Aggregate demand is the total expenditure on all goods and services produced in the economy at a given price level and at a given point in time. Aggregate demand is made up of the following components: AD = consumption + investment + government expenditure + exports – imports AD = C + I + G + (X – M) © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 The Aggregate Demand Curve The Aggregate demand curve shows the relationship between the average price level of an economy and the demand for the real output or GDP of the economy. The average price level of the economy is the average price of all goods and services produced in an economy at a given point in time. The relationship between aggregate demand and the average price level can be viewed in the same way as the microeconomic theory of the law of demand for a good in a particular market. If the price of mobile phones falls, the quantity demanded increases. In the same way, a decrease in the average price level in the macroeconomy leads to an increase in the aggregate demand for the real output of the economy and if the average price level increases the aggregate demand for the real output decreases. One way of explaining this is that a fall in the average price level means households, firms, government, and the foreign sector can now buy more of the domestic output of the economy with the same real income. Diagram 3.3 shows how a fall in the average price level in an economy causes an increase in aggregate demand for the real output of the economy. If there is a rise in the average price level this means households, firms, government and foreign sectors can buy less of the domestic output of the economy with the same real income. Consumption (C) Definition of consumption Consumption is household spending on final goods and services. Some goods are intermediate such as manufacturers selling goods to retailers and this spending is not included in consumption. Consumption spending would be spending on goods and services like food, energy, consumer electronics products, cars and leisure activities, etc. Consumption spending in More Economically Developed Countries (MEDCs) accounts for around 70 per cent of total GDP and is even higher than this in Economically Less Developed Countries (ELDCs). © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Determinants of consumption Household income and consumption There is a positive relationship between consumption and household income. As household incomes rise, households spend more on normal goods. This includes necessities such as food and energy, as well spending on luxuries such as new cars and holidays. We know from our microeconomic analysis that the strength and type of relationship between income and consumption changes depending on the type of good and its income elasticity of demand. Interest rates An interest rate is the cost borrowers pay for borrowed funds and the reward lenders receive for lending funds (the cost of borrowing and the reward for lending). There is a negative relationship between consumption and interest rates. When interest rates rise consumption decreases and when interest rates fall consumption increases. The relationship between interest rates and consumption exists for the following reasons: • The cost of borrowing for expensive goods (cars, home improvements, etc.) increases when interest rates rise and spending for these types of ‘big ticket items’ falls. • The reward for saving increases as interest rates rise which increases households desire to save rather than spend. • The cost of existing borrowing, particularly mortgage payments for house purchase, increase as interest rates rise and this leaves households with less disposable income for consumption. Note: the opposite effect occurs when interest rates fall. Consumer confidence Consumer confidence is household expectations of their future economic prospects. Consumer confidence has a significant impact on current consumption spending. If households feel pessimistic about their job prospects or future incomes, they will reduce current consumption and consumption rises if they feel optimistic. Economists see consumer confidence as an important ‘leading indicator’ because it tells them what might happen to economic growth in the future. In the US consumer confidence is measured by the CCI which is a survey of households produced by the Conference Board. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 The ‘credit crunch’ in 2008 led to a huge fall in US consumer confidence which reduced household spending which in turn contributed to falling growth in GDP and this led to a recession in the US. Household indebtedness Indebtedness is the value of current household borrowing. The higher the value of debt households hold the lower their current level of consumption. This is because households have less money for current consumption if they need to repay debt and have high-interest payments to make on their outstanding debt. Wealth Household wealth is the value of assets households own. These are assets that can be held in the following forms: cash, property and shares, etc. The most important asset for most households in the economy is the house they own. When house prices rise people feel wealthier and this increases their consumption spending. House prices in the UK increased dramatically from 2011 until 2016 leading to a significant increase in household wealth which caused a rise in consumption spending in the UK. If house prices fall households feel poorer and this can lead to a fall in consumption. It was the fall in US house prices in 2006 that triggered a fall in consumption in the US which was one of the contributing factors to the recession in the US in 2008 and the subsequent global financial crisis. Inflation Inflation can have two different effects on consumption: • Rising prices can make consumers bring forward purchases and increase consumption. This is because waiting to buy goods when they will increase in price in the future makes the goods more expensive and households will consume more in the present. • If prices rise because of increasing costs, this erodes household disposable income and causes a fall in consumption spending. This is particularly the case if the price of necessities such as food and energy increases. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Investment (I) Definition of investment Investment is where resources are allocated to produce capital goods that can build up the future productive capacity of an economy. Investment is an injection into the circular flow of income. Economists normally consider investment in terms of firms buying new plant and machinery. For example, Apple’s investment spending last year was $16 billion. Types of investment Investment spending by organisations can be categorised in five different ways: • Fixed investment is where firms purchase plant and machinery. For example, Toyota plans to build a new electric vehicle plant worth $1.2 billion in the Chinese city of Tianjin. • Human investment means that firms allocate resources to education and training which are used to increase the productive capacity of labour. • Research and development is investment in new products and processes. Research and development account for 7.9 per cent of Apple’s revenue and it spent $14 billion on R&D last year. • Social investment involves allocating resources that can improve the future welfare of a country’s citizens. Building new schools and hospitals have significant social benefits for society in the long term. • Infrastructure investment means allocating resources to the major physical systems that serve a country’s population. Infrastructure investment is in areas like energy, transport, water and waste, flood management and digital communications. Determinants of Investment Economic growth and investment A certain amount of investment takes place in an economy and is not affected by changes in GDP. Firms often plan major projects years in advance and unless there is a significant drop in economic growth the projects go ahead regardless of changes in GDP. Replacement investment is also less affected by changes in economic growth. This is where firms have to replace worn-out capital and it needs to take place for a firm to operate efficiently. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Some investment is responsive to changes in GDP. As the economy grows (particularly if the rate of growth increases) businesses will invest in new capital because they need to increase output to meet an increase in demand. This is particularly true for firms that sell products with a high positive income elasticity of demand. For example, service sector businesses like restaurants, cinemas and gyms will increase investment in new capital to meet a rise in demand when household incomes rise. Business confidence Business confidence is manager’s expectations of future profits and sales. It is important in determining investment decisions. If managers anticipate a rise in future economic growth, they are much more likely to decide to open a new factory and buy capital equipment. Business confidence in different countries is often measured by using the Purchasing Managers Index (PMI) Availability of funds At a macroeconomic level, the funds available for the economy to invest in are determined by the level of savings. Household savings goes to the banking system and banks then lend these funds to firms to invest. The higher the level of savings of households the more funds there are for investment and the greater the amount of investment there will be at a macroeconomic level. The profits earned by businesses are a major source of funds for firms and the more profits businesses earn the higher the level of investment. The amount of bank lending affects how much money firms can access to fund investment projects. The financial crisis of 2008 saw banks cut their lending dramatically to businesses which reduced the level of investment in many economies. Interest rates Because so many investment projects are funded partly or entirely by borrowed funds the rate of interest has a major effect on their viability. At relatively high rates of interest the cost of borrowing increases which reduces the profit stream from an investment project which makes the project less likely to go ahead. High-interest rates also offer firms a relatively good rate of return on holding funds in the bank so the rate of return of a project has to be greater than the rate of interest funds could earn in the bank. If interest rates fall then investment rises because the cost of funding projects falls and the alternative return from holding funds in the bank decreases. Corporate indebtedness Indebtedness is the value of borrowing firms currently have. The amount firms can borrow is reduced if they carry a high level of debt. Large business debts have high-interest costs and make banks reluctant to lend to firms. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Government expenditure (G) Types of government expenditure Government expenditure has an important influence on macroeconomic activity. Most government spending accounts for between and 30 and 40 per cent of GDP. Government expenditure is an injection into the circular flow of income. There are three types of government expenditure in the economy: • Current expenditure on the day-to-day running of the government sector such as paying the wages of teachers, doctors and military personnel. • Capital expenditure on investment projects financed by the government such as roads, bridges and schools. • Transfer expenditure on welfare payments such as unemployment and housing benefits. It is important to note that government transfer spending is not included as part of aggregate demand because there is no productive return for the spending by the government. Determinants of government expenditure Fiscal policy Fiscal policy is where government expenditure and taxation are used to achieve a government’s economic objectives. These objectives include areas such as sustainable economic growth, price stability, full employment, and balance of payments equilibrium. Government plan their level of expenditure to achieve these objectives. For example, the government might increase expenditure to increase economic growth if the economy is in a recession. Taxation The amount of money a government can raise through taxation will have a major influence on the amount governments can spend. Rich developed countries collect more money through direct and indirect taxation and this enables them to spend more on public services like health and education than economically less developed countries. The more tax the government can raise the more it can spend. Borrowing When government expenditure is greater than tax revenue the government needs to borrow money. This is done by selling bonds in the financial markets. For example, if the US government sells $500 billion of government bonds, then it will raise $500 billion in funds to spend on health, education and defence, etc. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Investors buy bonds because they earn interest on them and they will be repaid in the future. The bonds can also be bought and sold on the financial markets. The budget deficit is one year’s government borrowing and accumulated government borrowing over time is called the national debt. The current US budget deficit is $2.5 trillion, and the national debt is $25 trillion. Political objectives The political objectives of the government will affect the level of expenditure. Left-wing governments tend to believe in more state involvement in the economy will spend more than rightwing governments. Net Exports (X-M) Defining net exports A country’s net exports are the value of its exports (X) less the value of its exports imports (M). A positive value for net exports leads to a net inflow of funds into the economy and a negative net export value leads to a net outflow of funds from the domestic economy. Exports Exports are domestically produced goods and services sold in overseas markets that generate an inflow of funds into the domestic economy. Exports are an injection into the circular flow of income. Imports Imports are goods and services produced overseas and sold in the domestic economy that generate an outflow of funds from the domestic economy. Imports are a withdrawal from the circular flow of income. Determinants of net exports Net exports will change if there is a change in the value of exports and imports. Economic growth in overseas markets If there is strong economic growth in overseas markets this will lead to a rise in exports as foreign households have more income to spend on imported goods (exports) from other countries. The reverse is true if overseas markets are in recession and foreign households have less income and buy fewer imported goods (exports) from other countries. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Economic growth in domestic markets If domestic economic growth rises households will have rising incomes and will spend more on imports and this will lead to a fall in net exports. If domestic growth falls household spending on imports will fall because households will have lower incomes and will buy fewer imported goods which leads to a rise in net exports. Exchange rate If the domestic exchange rate falls, domestic exports may rise as domestic export prices fall in overseas markets. A fall or (depreciation) in the exchange rate will also lead to a rise in import prices which may lead to a fall in import expenditure. If the exchange rate rises (appreciates) domestic goods will rise in price overseas and the demand for exports will fall. A rise in the exchange rate will cause a fall in the price of imports and a rise in demand for them. Trading strength Some countries perform better in international markets than others. China, Germany and Japan have very strong manufacturing sectors and have a positive next export value. On the other hand, countries like the US and UK have weaker manufacturing sectors and have a negative net export value. Changes in aggregate demand Aggregate demand will change if any one of consumption, investment, government expenditure and net exports change. A change in the components of aggregate demand will cause the aggregate demand curve to shift. Diagram 3.4 shows an increase in aggregate demand and the aggregate demand curve in the economy shifts from AD to AD1 changes. A decrease in aggregate demand is also shown by a shift in the aggregate demand curve from AD to AD2. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Examples of factors that may cause a change in AD: Decrease in interest rates If interest rates fall this leads to a rise in consumption and investment as households and firms respond to lower borrowing costs and this, in turn, leads to a rise in aggregate demand. AD shifts to AD1 in diagram 3.4. Fall in business and consumer confidence If households and firms become less confident about their future economic prospects, then households will reduce consumption and firms will reduce investment leading to a fall in aggregate demand and AD shifts to AD2 in diagram 3.4. Increase in government expenditure If government expenditure increases as part of expansionary fiscal policy this will lead to a rise in aggregate demand. This causes AD to shift to AD1 in diagram 3.4. Rise in net exports If a country’s exchange rate depreciates and it experiences a rise in exports and a fall in imports, then aggregate demand will increase, and AD will shift to AD1 in diagram 3.4. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 10 Unit 3.2(2): Variations in economic activity - aggregate supply (AS) What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • • • • Defining aggregate supply Short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve Determinants of short-run aggregate supply Changes in short-run aggregate supply Short-run equilibrium national income Monetarist/new classical view of the long-run aggregate supply curve (LRAS) curve Long-run equilibrium at full employment level of output Inflationary and deflationary/recessionary gaps Keynesian view of the aggregate supply curve Equilibrium in the Keynesian model Changes in aggregate supply over the long run Definition of aggregate supply Aggregate supply is the total quantity of all goods and services the economy can produce at a given price level and in a given time period. At a microeconomic level, we consider the supply of a particular good in a market produced by all the firms in that market. Aggregate supply adds together the supply of goods from all the markets in the economy. Aggregate supply is made up of the output of all the different types of producers in the economy from small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) up to multinational corporations (MNCs) and state-run industries. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Short Run Aggregate Supply (SRAS) Definition of the short run The short-run in this model is the time period when the price level in the economy can change but the cost of factors of production is held constant. The short-run aggregate supply curve There is a positive relationship between the average price level and the short-run aggregate supply curve. As the average price level rises firms will increase output to take advantage of higher profits from a higher price level and a higher price covers the cost of increasing output. Diagram 3.5 shows how an increase in the average price level from P to P1 leads to a movement along the short-run aggregate supply curve and real output increases from Y to Y1. Changes in the short-run aggregate supply The short-run aggregate supply curve will shift if there is a change in business costs brought about by a change in the price of resources. If wage rates or the cost of raw materials fall then the short-run aggregate supply curve will shift to the right from SRAS to SRAS1 in diagram 3.6. If wage rates rise or the cost of raw materials rises, then the short-run aggregate curve will shift to the left from SRAS to SRAS2 in diagram 3.6. Changes in indirect taxation can also cause shifts in the short-run aggregate supply. If a country increases its rate of VAT from 20 per cent to 25 per cent then aggregate supply will fall and the short-run aggregate supply curve will shift to the left. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Short-run equilibrium national income The short-run equilibrium national income is the real GDP of a country determined by the interaction of short-run aggregate supply and aggregate demand. When aggregate demand equals short-run aggregate supply in the economy achieves the equilibrium national income (real GDP) and the equilibrium average price level. Changes in short-run equilibrium A change in either aggregate demand or supply will cause a change in the equilibrium level of national income (real GDP). Change in aggregate demand For example, a reduction in income tax on households leads to a rise in their disposable income. This leads to an increase in consumption and a rise in aggregate demand. The aggregate demand curve shifts from AD to AD1 in diagram 3.8 leading to a rise in the average price level from P to P1 and an increase in real GDP from Y to Y1. Change in short-run aggregate supply For example, short-run aggregate supply might fall and shift to the left because of a rise in the minimum wage in an economy which increases business costs. This causes SRAS to shift to SRAS1 in diagram 3.9 and the equilibrium real GDP falls from Y to Y1 and the equilibrium average price level rises from P to P1. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Monetarist/Neo-Classical Long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) Definition of the short-run The long-run in this model is the time period when the price level in the economy can change and the cost of factors of production can change. This means short-run changes in aggregate demand and supply can lead to changes in the costs of factors of production which cause further adjustments in the average price level and real GDP. Full employment national income The long-run aggregate supply curve is based on the full employment income of the economy. This is the level of national income where all resources available in the economy are being fully utilised. We normally talk about this in terms of full utilisation of labour and capital. In reality, there is never zero unemployment or full utilisation of productive capacity such as shops, office space and factories. An economy at full employment will have a very low level of unemployment and a low level of under-utilisation of offices, factories and shops. The level of unemployment associated with full employment is called the natural rate of unemployment. In diagram 3.10 the full employment level of national income is shown by the vertical long-run aggregate supply curve at YFE. Long-run aggregate supply at full employment The long-run aggregate supply curve is vertical at the full employment level of national income because Monetarist/Neo-classical economists believe the short-run equilibrium level of national income will always adjust towards full employment in the long run. This adjustment process can be looked at from two short-run equilibrium situations. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 From a deflationary gap Diagram 3.10 shows how the economy adjusts back to full employment when there is a decrease in aggregate demand after initially being in short-run equilibrium at full employment: • Aggregate demand falls in the economy because, for example, there is a decrease in business and consumer confidence which causes consumption and investment to fall. • As aggregate demand falls the short-run equilibrium level of national income falls from Y to Y1 and the average price level falls from P to P1. • The economy now has a deflationary gap where short-run equilibrium national income is below the full employment level of national income and this is shown by the distance YFEY1. • Wages, business costs and prices fall in the long run because of the deflationary conditions in the economy. For example, a rise in unemployment means there is surplus labour supply and wages fall. • The fall in wages, costs and prices cause the short-run aggregate curve in the economy to increase and shift to the right from SRAS to SRAS1, causing the short-run equilibrium income to settle back at full the full employment income at YFE at price level P2. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 From an inflationary gap Diagram 3.11 shows how the economy adjusts back to full employment when there is an increase in aggregate demand in the economy when it has started at full employment: • Aggregate demand rises in the economy because of an increase in consumption and investment as a result of, for example, a cut in central bank interest rates • As aggregate demand rises the short-run equilibrium level of national income rises from Y to Y1 and the average price level rises from P to P1 • The economy now has an inflationary gap where short-run equilibrium national income is above the full employment level of national income. This means unemployment has fallen below its natural rate which could be from a rate of 4 per cent to a rate of 3 per cent • Wages, business costs and prices rise in the long run because of inflationary conditions in the economy. Low unemployment leads to a shortage of labour which drives up wages • The rise in wages, business costs and prices causes the short-run aggregate curve in the economy to decrease and shift to the left from SRAS to SRAS1, causing the short-run equilibrium income to settle back at full the full employment income YFE at price level P2. Movements of the long-run aggregate supply curve The long-run aggregate supply curve will shift if there is a change in the potential output of the economy. In most cases, this is a shift outwards as the potential output of the economy increases. Diagram 3.12 shows a shift in the LRAS curve to the right in response to an improvement in the productive capacity of the economy. As the LRAS shifts to the right, the real GDP of the economy rises from Y to Y1 and the average price level falls from P to P1. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Long-run aggregate supply can shift outwards if there is an: • Increase in the number of workers in the labour force because of migration. • Improvement in the skill level of the labour force because education and training increase labour productivity. • Increase in capital available in the economy because of new investment. • Improvement in production technology such as the use of artificial intelligence and robot technology on production lines. • Increase in the availability of a new natural resource such as the discovery of oil and gas. • Improvement in the output from existing natural resources resulting from technological improvement such as the use of genetically modified crops. The long-run aggregate supply curve can fall if the potential output of the economy goes down. This could have occurred if there was a war or a natural disaster where capital is destroyed. Keynesian aggregate supply curve The Keynesian aggregate supply curve was developed by the economist, John Maynard Keynes. It is different from the Neo-classical/Monetarist view which looked at aggregate supply in separate time frames. In the Keynesian theory, there is a single aggregate supply curve and it does not distinguish between time frames. Some economists refer to the Keynesian aggregate supply curve as a long-run aggregate supply curve. Phases of the Keynesian aggregate supply curve The Keynesian aggregate supply curve shown in diagram 3.13 can be broken down into 3 phases: Phase 1 When output is below Y in diagram 3.13, the economy has spare capacity and output can increase and decrease without any change in the price level. Below Y the economy has a deflationary gap and is operating below the full employment level of national income. In this situation the economy would have high unemployment and capital would be under-utilised. These macroeconomic conditions are typical of a recession. When aggregate demand changes on this section of the aggregate supply curve real GDP will change but the average price level will stay the same. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Phase 2 From Y to Y1 in diagram 3.13, the economy is approaching full employment and some industries are nearing full capacity. In this section, any change in aggregate demand will lead to a change in output and the average price level. If aggregate demand rises, real GDP will increase and so will the average price level. Rising demand in the economy on this section of the Keynesian aggregate supply curve will mean some industries nearing full capacity will experience price increases and this will increase the average price level in the whole economy. Phase 3 When the economy is at Y2 it has reached full employment. There is no spare productive capacity and the economy has very low levels of unemployment. The economic conditions in this phase of the aggregate supply curve are typical of an inflationary gap. When aggregate demand changes real output does not change but the price level does. If aggregate demand increases at Y2 there will be a significant increase in the average price level and a rise in inflation. Difference between the Keynesian and Neo-Classical/Monetarist view One of the key issues that arise from the Keynesian aggregate supply curve is that the economy cannot self-correct when there is a deflationary gap. This is the key difference between Keynesian and the Neo-classical/Monetarist aggregate supply model. Keynes argued that wages and costs do not fall when there is a deflationary gap because of minimum wage legislation, trade union activity and firms would prefer to cut jobs rather than wages in a recession. Keynesian economists say wages are ‘sticky downwards’ because these pressures stop wages from falling when aggregate demand decreases in a deflationary gap situation. This means the economy cannot self-correct as it does in the Neo-classical/Monetarist model where wages and costs fall causing the short-run aggregate supply to increase and the equilibrium income to return to full employment. Implication for policymaking Because the economy does not self-correct in the Keynesian model, Keynesian economists argue that the government has to intervene in recessions to bring the economy back to full employment by using expansionary fiscal policy. For example, if an economy goes into recession and gets into a negative feedback cycle where rising unemployment leads to falling aggregate demand then this might cause the economy to get stuck at a level of real income significantly below full employment. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 In this situation, there is a strong case for government intervention using expansionary fiscal policy to bring the economy back to full employment. It can also be argued that the Monetarist view that the economy self-corrects might take such a long time (a period of years) that it would be very damaging to the economy during the period when it is correcting. Once again, there is a case for expansionary fiscal policy. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Unit 3.3(1) Macroeconomic objectives: economic growth What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • Understanding economic growth Measurement of economic growth Short-term growth Actual output Long-term growth Potential output Interpreting growth using the PPC model Consequences of economic growth for living standards, the environment and income distribution. Understanding economic growth Economic growth is the increase in a country’s real GDP over a given time period. This is normally one year although governments release growth data quarterly so they can continuously monitor changes in macroeconomic activity. Economic growth means the money value of goods and services produced by an economy is increasing over time. Measuring economic growth The growth rate of an economy is measured as the annual percentage change in the real GDP of a country. The calculation of real GDP using the GDP deflator is covered in detail in Unit 3.1(1). The economic growth rate for a country in 2020 is calculated using the equation: real GDP 2020 – real GDP 2019 / real GDP 2019 x 100 = 2020 economic growth rate For example, if an economy had the following real GDP data: real GDP 2019 $960 billion, real GDP 2020 $983 billion $983 billion - $960 billion / $960 billion x 100 = 2.4% Short-run economic growth The short-run in macroeconomics is the time period when the price level in the economy can change but the cost of factors of production is held constant. Short-run economic growth is determined by changes in aggregate demand and short-run aggregate supply. When there is economic growth in the short run it is described as a change in actual output. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Actual output The actual output of the economy is the level of output the economy achieves with its current resource utilisation. It is the value of goods and services produced by an economy with the land, labour, capital and enterprise available. This increase in actual output can also be shown in diagram 3.14 with a movement from A to B inside the production possibility curve. A rise in actual output in the diagram could be caused by an increase in aggregate demand which shifts from AD to AD1 and this causes real GDP to rise from Y to Y1 in diagram 3.15. Actual output will increase if: • There is an increase in aggregate demand and firms produce more and this increases the utilisation of available resources • Firms experience a fall in production costs which causes the short-run aggregate supply to increase. Long-run economic growth The long-run in macroeconomics is the time period when the price level in the economy can change and the cost of factors of production can change. In the long-run economic growth occurs because of an increase in potential output. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Potential output The potential output of the economy is the output the economy can achieve if its resources are fully employed. This is the economy’s output from the full utilisation of labour and capital. In reality, the economy will not achieve this level of output because there will always be some unemployed labour and some unused capital. The economy is operating at its potential output on the production possibility curve which is shown in diagram 3.16 at point F on PPC and point G on PPC1. The potential output of an economy will increase if there is an increase in the available resources and an increase in the productivity of the existing available resources. An increase in the potential output which leads to long-run economic growth is shown by the shift outwards of the production possibility curve from PPC to PPC1 in diagram 3.16. It can also be shown by an outward shift in the longrun aggregate supply curve in diagram 3.17. The following factors could lead to an increase in potential output and long-run economic growth: • If new natural resources such as oil and gas are discovered or if existing resources can be exploited in a new way, such as the use of genetically modified crops. • When new labour becomes available in an economy through changes in the birth rate or immigration. • An improvement in labour productivity because of an increase in the skill level of the workforce through education and training. • New investment by firms (factories and equipment) and governments (infrastructure). • Improvements in the productivity of capital are brought about by technological advances in production such as the use of AI and robots on the production line. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Benefits of economic growth Household income Rising household incomes that result from rising real GDP mean people can afford to buy more goods and services and this increases their material standard of living. The circular flow of income model illustrates how a rise in real output will also lead to an increase in household incomes. Reduced levels of poverty Rising incomes for the poorest people in society may lead to a reduced level of poverty as people can afford the goods and services needed to satisfy their basic needs. Great availability of goods and services Economic growth means more goods are produced and are available for households to buy. The growth in the availability of televisions, mobile phones, washing machines cars and computers to people on average incomes shows how growth improves people’s material living standards. Improved public services Economic growth means firms and households earn more income and pay more direct tax and they also spend more and pay more indirect tax. The higher tax revenue earned by governments because of economic growth means there is more money for them to spend on public services like education, healthcare and infrastructure. Greater employment The output of businesses increases as the economy grows which means more jobs are created and this increases the level of employment in the economy. Costs of economic growth Sustainability Economic growth can increase consumption and production negative externalities. Businesses increase output which increases industrial pollution and increased consumption of goods and services by households leads to consumption external costs. This means current economic growth can have a negative impact on the welfare of people in the future. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Income disparities As economies grow income disparities often increase as higher-income households experience a rate of increase in income that is greater than the rate of increase in income of lower-income households. Without government intervention to correct inequalities through the tax and benefit system some of the richest countries in the world would have the widest income inequalities. Inflation An increase in real GDP that occurs because of an increase in aggregate demand will lead to an increase in the average price level in an economy. This may lead to an inflationary gap and demandpull inflation when the economy is operating close to or at full employment. Balance of payments current account deficit Economic growth caused by rising aggregate demand can lead to a balance of payments deficit. As economic growth leads to rising household incomes people will buy more goods and services and a proportion of them will be imported. The rise in imports can lead to an increased balance of payments current account deficit. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Unit 3.3(2) Macroeconomic objectives: unemployment What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • Measuring unemployment and the unemployment rate Difficulties of measuring unemployment Causes of unemployment: frictional, structural, demand deficient, seasonal, regional Natural rate of unemployment Costs of unemployment Understanding unemployment Unemployment is normally thought of as an economic problem that faces all countries to a greater or lesser extent. It is also a challenge to countries that are constantly changing over time. During recessions, unemployment tends to rise and can become a serious social and economic problem. In times of economic growth, unemployment can fall and not be such a significant issue. Long periods of high unemployment in countries can be very difficult for the individuals and communities affected by it. Definition of unemployment Unemployment is the count of jobless people in a country who are seeking work but who do not have a job. Unemployed people need to be in the labour market looking for work and not just be people of working age who are not working. For example, full-time university students are of working age and not working, but they are not unemployed because they have not entered the labour market to look for work. Rate of unemployment Unemployment can be expressed as a total number such as 3 million people in a country or it can be expressed as the percentage of the labour force (unemployment rate). The rate of unemployment is a better statistic to make comparisons of unemployment between countries and changes over time. The unemployment rate is the percentage of the labour force that is unemployed and is calculated as: Number of unemployed / working population x 100 = unemployment rate For example, if there are 28 million people in a country's labour market and the number of unemployed is 1.9 million then the unemployment rate would be: 1.9m / 28m x 100 = 6.8% © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 The labour-force The labour force is made up of people in work and people who are unemployed. In all countries, this leaves a proportion of people of working age who could work but who are not in the labour force. This is made up of: • Homemakers (housewives and househusbands) • Carers – people looking after elderly or disabled people • Students • Early retired • Discouraged workers (people who have given up looking for work) When people of working age are outside the labour market are added to the unemployed, we get what economists call the ‘economically inactive’. This is a somewhat misleading term as people who look after their children or elderly relatives are doing work that has significant economic value. Measuring unemployment Unemployment is difficult to measure. The labour market is constantly changing as people enter and leave work as well as enter and leave the labour force. For example, people enter the labour market when they finish school and university and leave the labour market when they retire. Taking a ‘snapshot’ picture of the number of unemployed at any one time is challenging. There are two ways of measuring unemployment: The claimant-count This is the number of people who are claiming unemployment benefits in a country. The claimant count unemployment figure for a country might be 3.65 million people. This measure, however, under-estimates the number of unemployed because many unemployed people do not claim benefits. This may be because they are only unemployed for a short period of time and do not want to spend time claiming benefits, alternatively, some people have too much money in savings which means they do not qualify for unemployment benefits. International labour force survey (ILO) The ILO measure of unemployment is a survey of households to establish how many people are unemployed. The survey reports a higher number than the claimant count because it includes those who cannot or choose not to claim benefits. It is, however, subject to a statistical error because it is impossible to survey the whole population. The current ILO measure for unemployment for a country with a claimant count number of 3.65 million might be 4.5 million. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Underemployment or hidden unemployment Some people in the economy may be working but their work might be considered underemployment and it can mask the true level of unemployment in a country. It can take the following forms: Part-time work This is where people work part-time but would like full-time or to work longer hours. These people will not be recorded in the unemployment data. Low marginal product Some people may work in a job that has such a low marginal product that they cannot be considered to be working in the normal way. People might be trying to make a living as street vevendorselling cheap gifts to tourists, but the money they earn is so small that it is difficult to count them as employed. Over-qualification Some highly qualified workers take jobs that are below their level of qualification. This might be someone who is a qualified doctor who cannot find work as a doctor so they take a job as a taxi driver instead. The problems of measuring unemployment Unemployment data is very important to governments and it is a key indicator of welfare in a country. Low unemployment is a government macroeconomic objective and it is used as a guide for policymaking. There are, however, problems with accurately measuring unemployment. These include: • Deciding who is in the labour force is problematic. Some students, for example, may take a university place because they cannot find a job which means they would not be recorded in the unemployment data. • The under-employed will not be in the unemployed data but they may be considered to be unemployed in all but name. A qualified lawyer, for example, who can only find part-time work in a bar. • The ILO measure is only a survey so it carries a statistical error. • The claimant account measure under-estimates the level of unemployment because some unemployed people do not claim benefits. • Some people claim unemployment benefits and be in the claimant count figure, but they are working illegally. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 • The unemployment figure for a country does not tell you about the concentration of unemployment in different parts of the economy. This could be by region, people of different genders and ages, along with people of different ethnic groups. The labour market The market for labour as a factor of production works in a similar way to the market for a good service. The price of labour (wage rate) and the number of people employed is determined by the demand and supply for labour. The labour market is in equilibrium when the demand for labour equals the supply of labour. The labour market can be looked at from the perspective of the whole economy or from individual markets within the economy. Diagram 3.18 shows the equilibrium in the labour market for the whole economy where the aggregate demand for labour equals the aggregate supply for labour. Demand for labour The demand for labour comes from firms and organisations that employ workers. Economists derive the aggregate demand for labour, ADL in diagram 3.18 by adding together the demand for all the different types of work in an economy such as doctors, journalists, taxi drivers and car manufacturing, etc. It is a derived demand because firms demand workers for what they can produce for them. The demand for labour can be defined as the number of workers a firm is willing and able to hire at a given market wage rate and at a particular point in time. In a similar way to the law of demand applies to the goods market, it also applies to the labour market. As the wage rate falls quantity demanded for labour rises and if wages rise the quantity demanded for labour falls. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Supply of labour The supply of labour is the number of people who will are willing and able to take a job at a particular market wage rate and at a given point in time. For analysis across the whole economy, we aggregate (total) the labour supply across all the different labour markets in the same way as demand. The aggregate supply curve for labour is shown as ASL in diagram 3.18. Similar to the law of supply in the market for goods and services, as wages rise the quantity supplied of labour increases. At higher wages there is a greater incentive for individuals to enter the labour market to take a job and workers will also be prepared to work longer hours. If wages fall the opposite is true and the quantity supplied of labour decreases. Changes in the labour market equilibrium If either the demand for labour or the supply of labour changes then the wage rate in the labour market and the quantity of labour employed will change. For example, if there is a fall in demand for workers across the economy in a recession the aggregate demand for workers will fall. In diagram 3.19 the demand for workers falls from ADL to ADL1 and the quantity of workers employed falls from QL to QL1 and the equilibrium wage rate falls from WL to WL1. Disequilibrium in the labour market Many governments in the world use a minimum wage to try and protect workers on low incomes and reduce income inequality in the labour market. This is shown in diagram 3.20. When the minimum wage is above the equilibrium wage rate the quantity supplied of labour is greater than the quantity demanded and a surplus exists in the labour market. This is shown by the distance QL1 – QL2 in diagram 3.20. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Some economists argue that minimum wages can lead to unemployment, although the evidence on this is mixed. Minimum wages are often used to prevent unscrupulous employers from paying very low wages and gaining a competitive advantage. Minimum wages can also increase wages in the economy and act as an incentive for individuals to take a job which reduces unemployment. Causes of unemployment Frictional unemployment The labour market is constantly ‘turning over’ as people leave one job and take time to find another. People leave jobs for a variety of reasons: they do not like their work, people get dismissed or they might be seeking a new employment challenge. This also applies to workers entering the labour market to find their first job after leaving full-time education. The search time unemployed people experience when trying to find another job means they will be unemployed for a period of time. It also takes time for employers to find the right people to fill vacancies. There is not a ‘frictionless’ movement of workers as they move between jobs. Frictional unemployment often occurs because there is imperfect communication in the labour market between potential employers and unemployed workers. It takes time for unemployed workers to get information about a new job and go through the process of getting that job. Frictional unemployment is often quite short term and people are often only unemployed for a matter of weeks or months. It has costs, but economists often see them as relatively minor relative to other types of unemployment. It is also possible to see the benefits of frictional unemployment as a pool of unemployed workers in the labour market for employers to fill particular job vacancies. Structural unemployment Structural unemployment occurs due to structural changes in the economy that cause workers to lose their jobs. Workers find it difficult to find new jobs because their skills are not easily transferable to new employment. Some economists see structural unemployment as a ‘mismatch’ of skills between unemployed workers and available jobs. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Structural change in the economy can happen for the following reasons: The decline in demand for a good or service The development of high-quality cameras on smartphones has led to a fall in the demand for conventional cameras. Many of the people who were employed in the conventional camera market would have lost their jobs as the industry contracted. Some of the workers in the camera industry would have found it difficult to find new jobs because their skills may not have been easily transferable. Diagram 3.21 shows how a fall in demand for cameras has led to a fall in the demand for labour in the camera market. Foreign competition Industry in a country may decline because of an increase in foreign competition. The US steel industry has come under increasing pressure in recent years because of low-priced steel from Asia and Eastern Europe. This has led to a fall in demand for US steel and a fall in demand for labour in the US steel industry. Technological changes Advances in production technology mean workers are often replaced by capital on the production line. For example, robot technology in car production has reduced the demand for labour in car manufacturing and led to structural unemployment. Demand deficient or cyclical unemployment Demand deficient unemployment occurs when the economy is going through a period of slow economic growth or a recession. This is typical of a deflationary gap situation where actual output is below potential output. As aggregate demand falls in a recession the demand for labour falls as firms reduce output as the demand for the goods they sell falls. Diagram 3.22 shows how a fall in aggregate demand from AD to AD1 leads to a fall in national income which causes unemployment to rise. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 The global economic slowdown following the global financial crisis in 2008 and the current Covid19 pandemic has caused significant amounts of cyclical unemployment in many countries as aggregate demand decreased. Seasonal unemployment Seasonal unemployment occurs when the demand for goods and services changes at different times of the year in the economy. The tourism industry is typical of this. Summer holiday destinations will experience a fall in demand for labour in the winter leading to a rise in seasonal unemployment. In the retail and hospitality sectors of the economy unemployment often rises in January and February following the Christmas season. Regional unemployment Regional unemployment occurs when unemployment becomes concentrated in a particular area of the country. This often happens when a region has been a major centre for a particular industry which goes into structural decline. The ‘Rust-Belt’ states in the US such as Pennsylvania, Ohio, Indiana, and Michigan which were all heavily dependent on heavy industry like steel-making have a relatively high level of unemployment caused by industrial decline over the last 20 years. Natural rate of unemployment The natural rate of unemployment is the rate of unemployment that exists in the long run in the economy and is predominantly made up of frictional and structural unemployment. Even when a country has full employment the natural rate of unemployment exists because people are always leaving jobs or entering the labour market to look for work. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Consequences of unemployment Economists focus on the costs of unemployment as a significant challenge for society and governments. The significance of these costs depends on the level of unemployment in a country. Unemployment constantly occurs in all nations, but once the rate of unemployment rises above a certain percentage for a significant period of time the costs of unemployment can be very damaging. Opportunity cost of the foregone output of the unemployed Labour is one of the resources used to produce output in the economy. If labour is unemployed then it is not producing goods and services, and this is the forgone output of the unemployed. This is what the unemployed workers could have produced if they were working and is the cost to society of unemployment. The foregone output is illustrated by diagram 3.23 where the actual output of the economy is below the potential output. Unemployment means the economy is producing inside the production possibility frontier at point X instead of point Y on the production possibility curve. In the diagram this means the economy foregoes 200 units of consumer goods and 150 units of capital goods. The welfare of the unemployed Unemployment can have a significant negative effect on the welfare of those who are unemployed. The significance of the cost will depend on the length of time someone is unemployed and their financial circumstances. A person from a low-income household who is out of work for over a year with little prospect of work will suffer more than someone with a higher income who is out of work for a few weeks as they wait to start a new job. The impact on the welfare of the unemployed can be looked at in terms of loss of income as well as its effect on the mental and physical health of unemployed people. High levels of long-term unemployment in a country are a major contributing factor to high levels of poverty, health problems and indebtedness. With low-income households suffering from long-term unemployment it can also widen the distribution of income. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Economic growth High unemployment can lead to a fall in aggregate demand and a decline in economic growth because falling household incomes reduce consumption. High unemployment also has a very negative impact on consumer confidence because of the ‘fear of unemployment’ and this further reduces consumer spending across the whole economy, not just amongst the unemployed. The flow chart above shows how high unemployment can lead to a negative feedback cycle where unemployment leads to a fall in consumption and economic growth which leads to more unemployment. Negative externalities High levels of unemployment in a region or a city can lead to significant social problems in terms of crime, use of recreational drugs and social unrest. These negative effects do not just affect the unemployed but also people in work who live in an area of high unemployment. Government finance High levels of unemployment have a negative impact on government finance. Unemployed workers do not pay tax which reduces government income and the benefits paid to unemployed workers increase government spending. This is made worse when there is demand deficient unemployment in a recession when government finance is already under pressure because of falling tax revenue and increasing government expenditure. For this reason, rising unemployment can increase the government’s budget deficit. Impact on business If there is high cyclical unemployment or high regional unemployment, then this will reduce demand in many markets and lead to falling sales for firms. This is likely to lead to some business failure and more unemployment. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 10 Positive consequences of unemployment Whilst unemployment is often looked at in negative terms by different stakeholders in the economy. It can, however, have some positive consequences: • There are more workers in the labour market to choose from which makes it easier for employers to find new workers. • There is less pressure on wages to rise which reduces business costs and can reduce inflation. • Workers who are worried about unemployment may work harder and be easier to manage by employers. Although some firms might exploit this. • Some people might use a period of unemployment to redirect their lives and find future work that is more fulfilling for them. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 11 Unit 3.3(3) Macroeconomic objectives: inflation and deflation What you should know by the end of this chapter • • • • • • Measuring the inflation rate using a consumer price index (CPI) Problems of measuring inflation Causes of inflation: demand-pull and cost-push inflation Costs of a high inflation rate Causes of deflation Costs of deflation Changes in the price level The overall price level or average price level of an economy is constantly changing. Managing the change in the average price level and achieving a low and stable inflation rate is a key objective of government macroeconomic policy. All countries experience changes in the average level of prices over time and when these changes become unstable it can be very damaging to the economy. For example, in the last 10 years, a 10 million per cent rate of hyperinflation in Venezuela or a daily rate of inflation in Zimbabwe of 98 per cent meant these economies could not really function. Inflation Inflation is the sustained increase in the general level of prices in an economy. For example, if an economy has a current rate of inflation of 1.5% it means that on average prices are 1.5% higher now than they were 12 months ago. Disinflation Disinflation is the fall in the rate of inflation in an economy. This means the rate at which the general level of prices is increasing falls. For example, a fall in the rate of inflation in the economy from 2.1%. to 1.5% would be disinflation. Deflation Deflation is the sustained decrease in the general level of prices in an economy. If a country has a rate of inflation of -1.6% then it has deflation and the average price level of the economy is falling. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Measuring inflation Measuring the rate of inflation is a difficult thing to do in an economy because of the number of goods and services being traded and the number of transactions taking place. Prices are constantly changing in the economy which also makes measuring inflation problematic. Governments use a price index to measure the rate of inflation and the example that follows is the method used by European Union to measure inflation and is called the Harmonised Consumer Price Index (HCPI). Harmonised consumer price index (CPI) This is how CPI is calculated: • The European Central Bank choose a representative basket of goods the average consumer buys. • The index has 700 products in the basket and the prices of the goods in the basket are measured monthly. • The index is weighted based on consumer expenditure. The higher the proportion of consumer expenditure on a product the higher its weighting will be and the greater impact its price change will have on the price index. Petrol price changes will have a greater impact on the index than a change in the price of toothpaste because most consumers spend a greater proportion of their income on petrol. • The annual percentage change in the index is the inflation rate. The current inflation rate for the Euro Area is 0.4%. Constructing a weighted price index (HL only) This is how the inflation rate is calculated using a weighted price index: Step 1 Goods and services are selected to be put into the index, and they are entered under different product categories like those set out in the table below. About 700 products are used in the European CPI. Step 2 Index numbers are used to calculate how the prices of each category of good have changed. An index number shows the relative change in the value of a variable between two points in time. The point in time is called the base year (this is given the value 100) and this is compared to another point in time called the current year. For example, if the price of bread in the base year is €1.20 and in the following year (current year) it is €1.30 then the index would be: current year price / base year price x 100 = price index value €1.30 / $1.20 x 100 = 108.3 © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Step 3 Once the index number for each category of good has been calculated we then assign weights to each category based on the percentage of income the average consumer spends on the category. In the table below the average consumer spends 22 per cent of their income on housing so housing is given a weighting of 22. The average consumer only spends 6 per cent of their income on alcohol and tobacco so the weighting for this is 6. Step 4 Each category of good in the price index is multiplied by its weighting. The sum of price multiplied by weighting for each category divided by 100 gives the weighted index. Σ (weight x price)/100 = weighted index In the table, the weighted index for 2020 is 104.37 Step 5 The rate of inflation for 2020 is calculated from the percentage change in the weighted index from 2019 to 2020. The weighted index for 2019 is 101.6 so the rate of inflation is calculated as: 104.37 – 101.6 / 101.6 = 2.73% Problems of measuring inflation We have already considered the challenge of measuring the rate of inflation from the sheer scale of the task of collecting price data that is constantly subject to change. Here are some more specific problems of measuring inflation. Average consumer The inflation rate is an average based on the spending patterns of the average consumer. This consumer does not exist in reality so different inflation rates will exist for different consumers. Young people who eat out in restaurants will have a different inflation rate compared to families that are more likely to eat at home because the price changes in restaurants are likely to be different to the price changes of people who primarily buy their food in supermarkets. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Regional variation Prices differ throughout the economy and so will inflation rates. Capital cities like Paris and Beijing will experience different inflation rates compared to provincial towns in those countries. Types of retailer Prices vary depending on where you buy a product. Large supermarkets will be much cheaper than small corner shops and the inflation rates between these different types of retailers are going to differ as well. This makes deciding which retailers to use in constructing the index problematic. Change in the quality of goods The quality of goods generally rises over time and this is not accounted for in the index. Computers are of better quality now than they were 5 years ago, but this will not necessarily be reflected in their price. This means inflation tends to overstate price increases because it does not allow for improvements in product quality. Variations between countries Different countries use different measures of inflation. The US consumer price index, for example, includes the change in the price of owner-occupied housing which is not included in the EU’s CPI measure. One-off changes in price Significant one-off changes in the price of a highly weighted good in the index can distort the inflation rate. A big increase in the price of petrol will cause a significant rise in the index although the price changes of other goods in the index may be relatively small. Economists try to factor this in by removing items with big, one-off price changes that distort the index. This is called the core or underlying rate of inflation. Predicting the rate of inflation Economists try to forecast the future rate of inflation and they will look closely at factors that could build inflation pressures like an increase in the price of oil or accelerating economic growth. They also look at indices like the producer price index which measures the percentage change in prices paid by firms for inputs like raw materials. If the producer price index is rising, then there is likely to be a rise in the rate of inflation. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Causes of inflation At the macro level, the causes of inflation can be looked at from a demand-side and supply perspective. In reality, it is difficult to separate them as causes of inflation because the factors that affect aggregate demand and aggregate supply are constantly changing. Economists do, however, often focus on periods of high inflation caused by changes either in aggregate demand or aggregate supply. Demand-pull inflation Definition Demand-pull inflation occurs when a rise in aggregate demand in the economy causes (pulls) the price level in the economy to increase. Diagram 3.24 illustrates how a rise in aggregate demand from AD to AD1 leads to a rise in the average price level from P to P1. Inflationary gap Periods of demand-pull inflation often lead to an inflationary gap. The diagram also shows an inflationary gap where the short-run equilibrium income is at a level of real GDP above the full employment level of income. This means actual output in the economy is above potential output. It is quite difficult to understand how this can happen. Remember that potential output or full employment is not zero unemployment because there are always some unemployed people and unused capital even when the economy is at full employment. In the short term, actual output can be above potential output and an inflationary gap occurs. The following factors can trigger an increase in aggregate demand which can lead to demand-pull inflation: • Reduced interest rates raise the level of consumption and investment. • A rise in house prices makes consumers feel wealthier and raises consumption. • High levels of business and consumer confidence stimulate consumption spending and investment. • Expansionary fiscal policy by the government is trying to stimulate economic growth. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Cost-push inflation Definition Cost-push inflation occurs when there is a reduction in the short-run aggregate supply in the economy and the price level is pushed up by rising costs. Diagram 3.25 illustrates how rising costs cause the short-run aggregate supply curve to shift from SRAS to SRAS1 leading to a rise in the average price level from P to P1 and a fall in the real output from Y to Y1. Reasons for cost-push inflation The short-run aggregate supply curve will shift to the left if the cost of any of the factors of production increases. Wage push inflation When wage rates rise faster than output unit or average costs rise, and this can lead to higher prices if firms choose to pass on the increase in unit costs as a higher price. This would happen if a trade union in a major industry like electricity supply negotiated a wage increase of 10 per cent and labour productivity only increased by 5 per cent. A wage-price spiral can be a dangerous situation for an economy where workers respond to a rise in inflation by asking for a wage increase which in turn feeds through to higher prices. Raw material costs Cost-push inflation can be caused by rising commodity prices which increase the cost of manufactured goods. Commodity price increases in oil, wheat, rice and metals have all triggered periods of cost-push inflation in economies in the past. Historically, oil price increases have caused significant periods of cost-push inflation. Where materials and other inputs are imported a fall in the exchange rate can trigger cost-push inflation as import prices rise with a lower exchange rate. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Capital costs If the price of machinery and equipment used by firms increases, this can lead to higher prices. Governments often respond to higher inflation by raising interest rates, but this can lead to higher business costs as firms have to pay more interest on loans they have taken out to fund investment spending. Entrepreneurial profit Businesses can add to their profits by increasing prices by more than their increase in costs. In industries dominated by large firms with significant market power, prices can increase because of a lack of competition. This is particularly true where a monopoly dominates a market. When you consider markets like energy, water and public transport are often dominated by large firms, it is possible to see how inflation can occur if they increase prices because demand is price inelastic and household spending on the products they sell is a high proportion of household income. The effects of inflation Inflation is present in nearly all of the world’s economies and many economists see low, stable inflation as beneficial. However, if inflation increases to high, unstable levels it leads to significant macroeconomic problems. Countries like Venezuela and Zimbabwe which have both experienced hyperinflation in the last 15 years have seen their economies collapse because of the price level increasing at such a fast rate. Impact on the cost of living As the price level rises in the economy the cost to households increases. If the price level rises faster than the increase in household incomes, then households will see a fall in their real incomes and material living standards. This type of effect is normally associated with cost-push inflation. Redistribution of income Fixed incomes Inflation has a negative effect on the disposable incomes of households whose wages cannot keep up with the increase in the average price level. These households are often made up of pensioners, people on government benefits and low-skilled workers in weak bargaining positions in the labour market. In many countries, households with below-average incomes saw their real wages fall after the financial crisis between 2009 and 2018 because the price level was rising faster than their wages. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Borrowers and lenders Inflation means the real value of money repaid by borrowers is worth less than the money they borrowed from lenders. If someone borrows $100,000 at 10 per cent inflation then the real value of the money they repay after one year will be $90,000. There is a redistribution of income from lenders to borrowers. Lenders can protect themselves against this by charging a rate of interest above the rate of inflation: Interest rate 6% - Inflation rate 4% = 2% real rate of interest The redistribution of income tends to occur if there is a sudden jump in the rate of inflation and lenders cannot act to protect themselves by increasing interest rates. This is called unanticipated inflation and at higher rates of inflation, there is a greater probability of unanticipated inflation because changes in the price level become more volatile. For example, when inflation rises above 10 per cent it becomes unstable and there is more likely to be unanticipated inflation. The increased risk unanticipated inflation poses to people saving money in banks means that inflation can lead to a fall in the savings in the economy which reduces the funds available for future investment. Investment One implication of higher real interest rates which come with high inflation is that the cost of borrowing money for investment projects increases and this leads to a fall in the level of investment. High inflation also makes the business environment more unstable which increases the risk element of investment projects and this also leads to a fall in investment. If inflation leads to a fall in the level of investment, then the long-term growth prospects of the economy will be adversely affected. Reduced international competitiveness If a country’s inflation rate is higher than its main international competitors then the country’s firms will struggle to compete in international markets leading to a fall in exports and a rise in imports. This could lead to a balance of payments current account deficit. The current account deficit can lead to a fall in the country’s exchange rate and this adds to inflation as import prices rise. Venezuela’s inflation rate is significantly higher than its main trading partners in South America which has led to a fall in its international competitiveness amongst if main international competitors. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Business costs An increase in the rate of inflation means that firms have to spend time changing prices as their costs increase. The time they spend changing prices represents an additional cost to business. This is particularly significant when inflation goes to very high levels and firms are forced to continuously change prices because they will lose money if they do not raise prices as costs rise. An economy with price stability and a 2 per cent rate of inflation will mean most firms will be comfortable changing their prices once a year. If inflation reaches levels above 10 per cent then prices need to be changed much more frequently. If inflation reaches 1000 per cent prices will need to be changed every day. Allocative inefficiency The price mechanism is the signalling system in the economy that guides the efficient allocation of resources. In countries with very high inflation, the price of all goods is rising significantly and it is very difficult for consumers and producers to interpret what changes in price tell them about market conditions on which to base buying and selling decisions. This leads to a breakdown of the signalling and incentive functions of price and resources will not be allocated as efficiently. For example, if inflation is 50 per cent in a country it is very difficult for consumers and producers to interpret why a price is rising in any particular market and how to respond to it. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Deflation Defining deflation Deflation is a negative rate of inflation where there is a sustained fall in the general level of prices in an economy. This is different to disinflation when there is a fall in the rate of inflation in the economy. Relatively few countries in the world experience deflation at any one time and the rate of deflation is normally less than 1 per cent. In historical terms, the United States suffered an average annual rate of deflation of 10 per cent per year between 1930 and 1933. Causes of deflation Demand-side deflation Deflation can occur because of a fall in aggregate demand and this typically occurs in a recession. The Japanese have experienced periods of deflation in the last 20 years caused by falling aggregate demand. Diagram 3.25(1) illustrates how a fall in aggregate demand from AD to AD1 leads to deflation as the average price level falls and there is a deflationary gap. Because this type of deflation occurs in a recession it is seen as damaging to the economy in terms of falling GDP and rising unemployment. Economists sometimes call this ‘bad deflation’. Supply-side deflation Deflation that occurs on the supply side arises when the aggregate supply curve shifts to the right and leads to a higher output at lower prices. Improvements in productivity in manufacturing have led to significant falls in prices in certain markets and this has had a ‘deflationary effect’ on the economy. In diagram 3.26 the shortrun aggregate supply curve shifts from SRAS to SRAS1 and the average price level falls. This is often called ‘good deflation’ because it is associated with a higher level of real GDP. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 10 Consequences of deflation The consequences of deflation depend to an extent on whether deflation is caused by changes in aggregate demand or supply. Reduced growth and recession If deflation is caused by falling aggregate demand, then it can lead to falling or even negative economic growth and rising unemployment. These are the negative consequences of a deflationary gap and they are often associated with a serious recession. Falling current consumption When prices are falling it is argued that households put off buying goods and services now because they believe they can wait to buy goods in the future when prices are lower. This fall in current consumption causes a further fall in aggregate demand and leads to more deflation. Redistribution of income Lenders gain at the expense of borrowers because the value of repayments rises when prices are falling. If you borrow $1000 now with 5 per cent deflation, the real value of the repayment will be $1050. This may mean firms and households are less willing to borrow and this reduces consumption and investment which in turn causes aggregate demand to fall. Rise in spending power As the price of goods falls consumers can buy more with their income. This is the benefit of supplyside or good deflation. Falling prices often applies to goods such as clothing, computers, TVs and mobile phones. International competitiveness If one country’s goods are falling in price relative to their trading partners, then this could increase that country's competitive advantage in international markets. It could lead to a rise in their exports and a fall in imports. Japan’s deflation over the last 20 years may well help its trading competitiveness. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 11 Conflict between macroeconomic objectives Low inflation and low unemployment One of the main macroeconomic policy conflicts governments have is the aim of achieving low inflation and low unemployment at the same time. The conflict can be illustrated by changes in aggregate demand in diagram 3.27(1). When aggregate demand increases the national income rises from Y to Y1 and this is normally associated with a fall in unemployment. But the increase in aggregate demand will also lead to a rise in the average price level from P to P1 and an increase in the rate of inflation. The opposite occurs if aggregate demand falls leading to a fall in inflation but a rise in unemployment as national income falls. The Phillips Curve The nature of the Phillips curve The Phillips curve describes the relationship between the rate of inflation and the rate of unemployment. It was established by the New Zealand-born economist William Phillips who studied the relationship between the rate of inflation and the rate of unemployment in the UK economy between 1861 and 1957. Phillips used the UK data to establish that as the rate of inflation decreased the rate of unemployment increased and as the rate of inflation increased the rate of unemployment decreased. Diagram 3.27(2) illustrates the basic Phillips Curve. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 12 Explaining the Phillips curve The negative relationship between the inflation rate and the rate of unemployment can be explained by aggregate demand and supply analysis. As aggregate demand increases from AD to AD1 in diagram 3.27(1) above, the national income increases leading to a fall in unemployment from 7 per cent to 5 per cent in diagram 2.27(2) as the demand for labour increases. This could be because of a fall in demand deficient unemployment. The rise in aggregate demand also leads to a rise in the average price from 2 per cent to 4 per cent in diagram 3.27(2) in the economy as demand-pull inflation increases the average price level. The Phillips curve only really works when aggregate demand changes. If there is a fall in aggregate supply then a rise in the rate of inflation may occur at the same time as a rise in unemployment as national income falls. Falling national income and rising inflation is sometimes referred to as stagflation. Policy use of the Phillips Curve The Phillips Curve was used by policymakers to guide demand-side fiscal policy policies in the 1960s and 70s. If governments saw a rise in the rate of unemployment, they would use expansionary fiscal policy to try and reduce unemployment and this would be traded off against higher inflation. Similarly, if inflation was too high contractionary fiscal policy would be used and falling inflation would be traded off against higher unemployment. This was called ‘fine tuning’ the economy. The Long-Run Phillips Curve The Phillips Curve relationship broke down in the 1970s when many developed economies started to experience rising inflation and rising unemployment – Stagflation. Monetarist and Neo-Classical Economist tried to explain this by using the theory of the Long Run Phillips Curve. The Long-Run Phillips Curve was based on the principle of the natural rate of unemployment which is covered in chapter 3.3(2). The natural rate of unemployment is important in understanding the long-run Phillips curve because the theory is based on the assertion that unemployment will always return to the natural rate in the long run. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 13 Monetarist Economists also referred to the natural rate of unemployment as the Non(N) Accelerating (A) Inflation (I) Rate (R) of Unemployment (U) – NAIRU. In other words, if unemployment is at this level the rate of inflation does not increase. This rate of unemployment is shown in diagram 3.27(3). Explaining the breakdown This is how Monetarists explain the breakdown of the Phillips Curve: • Monetarist economists believed that the traditional Phillips Curve is a short-run Phillips curve. The economy starts on Phillips curve PC with 2 per cent inflation and the natural rate of unemployment of 4 per cent at point A in diagram 3.27(3). • The government decides this rate of unemployment is too high and uses expansionary fiscal policy to reduce it by increasing government spending and cutting taxes. This works in the short run and unemployment falls from 4 per cent to 3 per cent, and the rate of inflation rises from 2 per cent to 4 per cent at point B. • Monetarists believe that when inflation rises to 4 per cent for any period of time it becomes established in the economy and becomes the expected rate of inflation by households and firms. They then build in the expected inflation rate into their decision making and the rate of inflation stays at 4 per cent. • Over time the rate of unemployment drifts back to the natural rate because some workers find their real wages are eroded by the higher rate of inflation and leave their jobs. The economy now moves to point C on diagram 3.27(3) with 4 per cent inflation and 4 per cent unemployment. • After a period of time, the government again believes the rate of unemployment is unacceptably high and once again uses expansionary fiscal policy to reduce it. The economy is now on PC1 and the rate of unemployment falls below 4 per cent again and the inflation rate rises to 8 per cent as aggregate demand rises. The economy is now at point D in diagram 3.27(3). © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 14 • The 8 per cent rate of inflation becomes expected by firms and households and in the long-run unemployment drifts back to its natural rate of 4 per cent at point E in diagram 3.27(3). • This process continues each time the government uses expansionary fiscal policy to reduce unemployment and the economy experiences higher and higher inflation with no long-term fall in unemployment. • It is important to remember that this analysis of the breakdown of the Phillips Curve took place after it had happened, and governments were unaware this process was occurring. Policymakers just thought over time (normally when there was an election looming) that unemployment needed to be reduced. The implication of the Long Run Phillips Curve One of the implications of the Long Run Phillips Curve is for macroeconomic policymaking. If a government tries to use expansionary demand-side policies to reduce unemployment below its natural rate it will lead to higher inflation in the long run with no reduction in unemployment. This means governments need to use supply-side policies to reduce the natural rate of unemployment. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 15 Unit 3.4(1) Economics of inequality and poverty What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • • • • Relationship between equality and equity The meaning of economic inequality Unequal distribution of income and wealth Measuring economic inequality using the Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient Construction of a Lorenz curve from income quintile data (HL) Meaning of poverty Difference between absolute and relative poverty Measuring poverty: international poverty lines, minimum income standards, Multidimensional Poverty Index (MPI) Difficulties in measuring poverty Causes of economic inequality and poverty Impact of inequality on economic growth, standards of living and social stability The difference between equality and equity Equality Equality in economics is the way the economic outcomes for different people in society are the same. We often consider equality in the way the income generated by the economic activity of a country is shared out amongst the country’s population. We know from the circular flow of income model that the GDP of a country produces an income that is distributed to different households of that country. But the model does not tell us how the income is shared out. Many economists, leaders in industry and politicians take the normative view that a more equal distribution of income in society is a good thing. The reality of the world economy is the widening of income inequality. All nations experience income inequality to a greater or lesser extent, where income is distributed unevenly amongst the population with a minority of high-income households accounting for a relatively high proportion of the income or wealth generated by a country. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Equity Equity in Economics is about fairness in terms of everyone in society having an equal opportunity to achieve an economic outcome. This is another normative economic concept and takes the view that all individuals should have the opportunity to achieve a certain economic outcome. This might mean an individual has the opportunity to get a job that allows them to achieve a certain quality of life. Inequity is unfairness in society that prevents individuals from achieving a particular economic outcome. This might mean a group in society cannot access certain jobs because of their ethnicity, gender or socioeconomic group. Inequality in the distribution of income and wealth In all countries, there is an unequal distribution of income and wealth. Although they are quite similar principles there is a distinct difference in terms of: • An unequal distribution of income means that a greater proportion of the income of the economy goes to the richest households than the rest of the population. • An unequal distribution of wealth means that a greater proportion of the value of assets incountry is owned by the richest households compared to the rest of the population. Income is the money a person earns, and wealth is the value of assets a person owns. Examples of the assets people own include houses, shares, bonds and money in the bank. Measuring economic inequality There is two indicators economist use to measure income inequality in a country. The Lorenz curve © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 The Lorenz curve is a graphical illustration of the income distribution of a country. The Lorenz curve divides the population into quintiles and then shows the cumulative percentage of income accounted for by each quintile. The table sets out the income data for Country A and Country B. Each country’s households are set out in ascending order from the poorest quintile to the richest quintile. The Lorenz curve graphs the distribution of income by plotting each quintile with the cumulative percentage income. These Lorenz curves for Country A and B are shown in diagram 3.28. From the data in the table, Country B has greater income inequality, and this is shown by the larger deviation its Lorenz curve has compared to Country A from the line of perfectly equal income distribution. Gini coefficient The Gini coefficient can be used to measure the size of a country’s income inequality. It can be calculated by using the Lorenz curve. In diagram 3.29 the area above the Lorenz curve and below the line of perfect income equality is calculated as a proportion of the total area below the line of perfect income equality. In diagram 3.29 this is calculated by the equation: area A / area A + area B = Gini coefficient © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 This Gini coefficient value can either be considered as a percentage or a value between 0 and 1. If the answer is 0 there is perfect equality and the closer the Gini-efficient is to 1 the more uneven the income distribution of a country. The table opposite shows the 10 countries in the world with the highest Gini coefficient values. Meaning of poverty The United Nations defines poverty as the ‘denial of choices and opportunities and a violation of human dignity. A household in poverty lacks the basic capacity to participate effectively in society’. This definition of poverty can be viewed as households in a country lacking the income needed to achieve a basic standard of living. Poverty can be considered in two ways: Absolute poverty Absolute poverty exists when household income is below the level needed to meet a person’s basic needs of life including housing, food, safe drinking water, education and healthcare, etc. It is difficult to state an income level where someone experiences absolute poverty, but an income of less than $700 a year or $2 a day is given by the UN, although this will vary from country to country because of different price levels. Relative poverty Relative poverty is where a household’s income is significantly below a country’s average income. Many countries define relative poverty as a person that earns less than 50 per cent of the average household income. Households in this position may not be in absolute poverty, but they often do not have enough income to afford anything more than the basic goods and services needed to sustain their lives. Measuring poverty Countries can measure poverty using the following approaches: Poverty lines A poverty line is the minimum level of income needed for a basic standard of living in a country. The World Bank international poverty line is set at an income of $1.90 per day. Different nations set their poverty lines based on relative poverty. For example, a country might set a relative poverty line at 50 per cent of average incomes and then the percentage of people who fall below this level is used to measure the level of relative poverty. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Multidimensional Poverty Index (MPI) The Multidimensional Poverty Index (MPI) uses a number of weighted criteria to measure poverty in a country based on a survey of households. This data is aggregated to give a national measure of poverty. The lower the MPI of a country the greater the level of poverty. The criteria used to measure the MPI are set out in the table. These criteria are used to measure poverty by applying a set minimum level for each indicator. For example, the standard of living poverty indicator, cooking fuel, would measure poverty based on the number of households cooking with dung, wood, charcoal or coal and the nutrition indicator would be based on the number of people in a household who are undernourished. Problems of measuring poverty The following factors make it difficult to measure the level of poverty in a country: • Like a lot of economic data, measuring poverty is based on a survey which means using a sample of households to represent the whole population. All samples come with a sampling error, so there is inevitably some inaccuracy in the data. • The variety of different methods used to define poverty such as relative and absolute poverty make it difficult to measure. Using the phrase ‘to meet a person’s basic needs’ is open to a variety of interpretations. We know access to basic food and shelter is a basic need but is owning a mobile phone? • Some of the most powerful human feelings associated with poverty are almost impossible to measure. The anxiety of not knowing where your next meal is going to come from is real, but measuring that anxiety is extremely difficult. • Governments draw lines of absolute and relative poverty, but they are very difficult to apply in reality. A certain level of income per day might be a very low but sustainable income in some countries, but completely inadequate to live on in others. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 • Poverty data is open to manipulation by governments who want to show a falling level of poverty in their country. The income value of absolute poverty should rise with inflation, but it is in the interests of governments not to do this because it might make the numbers in absolute poverty increase. • Attempts to use a weighted index to measure poverty, such as the MPI, are effective in representing the broad-based nature of poverty, but increasing the number of indicators and then weighting them is always going to create difficulties. For example, how do you decide on the weighting of asset ownership or sanitation in measuring poverty? Causes of inequality and poverty It is possible to combine the causes of inequality and poverty in society because the cause of both is so closely related. For example, if one person is the owner of a highly valued property then they might earn plenty of income from renting the property. If another person owns no property then instead of earning rent they will pay rent and this would lead to a high level of inequality between two people. The person who owns no property is also more likely to live in poverty. Inequality of opportunity Inequality of opportunity means people do not have the same access to a good quality of life in terms of income, education, employment and healthcare. Without these opportunities, people get stuck in low-paid work with little chance of progression, and this means they cannot access good healthcare and education. Lack of opportunity can come from a parental background, education, gender, ethnicity and social class. High-income households, for example, can pay for the best education for their children who will go on to the best universities, which in turn secures them highly-paid employment and they can then do the same for their own children. Resource ownership Low-income households own very little or no capital at all. This means their only source of income is from low-paid work. High-income households on the other hand often own assets and are holders of wealth. This can be in the form of property or shares in companies that earns them a stream of income in the form of rent on property and dividend on shares. Wealthy individuals can use their surplus income to buy more assets which earns them even more income. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Human capital High-income individuals tend to work in high-skilled jobs producing products for firms that can make those businesses high profits. Skilled workers in these situations are valued highly by the businesses that employ them and they are paid a high wage for the work they do. Low-income individuals are often in low-skilled jobs doing work that does not bring as much profit to the business that employs them, and they are paid a lower wage. Another important aspect of this is that highly skilled workers are scarcer in the labour market than the low skilled worker, which gives the highly skilled worker a stronger bargaining position when negotiating their wages. Discrimination Inequality can occur because of discrimination by employers. This can be based on ethnicity, gender, age and socioeconomic status. Women in most countries are paid significantly less than men partly because of discrimination. Inequality can also take place in education. Universities in some countries have been accused of not allowing access to students from ethnic minorities and low-income households. Status and power High-income individuals often reach positions of political influence. This can be done by directly running for office and gaining political power. Donald Trump and Hilary Clinton both come from wealthy backgrounds and spent about $100 million each on their campaigns for the last Presidential election in 2016. It is much more difficult for low-income individuals to reach positions of power. Wealthy people can also influence the political process by lobbying and financing politicians to make decisions that favour them and their organisations. Government policies Government can make policy decisions that can widen income inequality. Reducing direct taxation will normally favour high-income households because they earn much more taxable income than poorer households. Cutting income tax tends not to benefit low-income households that much because they are probably paying very little income tax anyway. Governments that cut spending on public services such as education and healthcare will have more effect on the poor who rely on these services than richer households. Low-income households will also be adversely affected when governments use market-based supply-side policies such as reducing the lower of trade unions and removing regulations that protect employees. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Globalisation Globalisation often involves greater competition in domestic markets from foreign competition as trade barriers are removed between countries. This increase in competition often favours producers in low-wage economies that outcompete producers in higher-wage countries. This often means producers who cannot compete either shut down or reduce wages in an attempt to compete. This process has the effect of driving down incomes in many countries, widening income inequalities and leading to poverty. Impact of income and wealth inequality Social stability Countries with very uneven income distributions often suffer from high crime rates. It can be argued that wide income inequality creates a sense of unfairness in society and this can lead to an increase in crime and social unrest. Poor people may also be more likely to be pushed towards crime because it may be the only way to make a sustainable living. For example, poor people might sell recreational drugs in communities where there are few job opportunities. Economic growth A high level of income and wealth inequality can restrict economic growth in two ways: Demand-side Domestic aggregate demand does not grow as quickly when there is wide inequality and a significant proportion of the population is on relatively low incomes. Low-income households tend to spend a high proportion of their income so if their income growth remains relatively low then this prevents aggregate demand from growing. Supply-side Where income and wealth inequality results in a high proportion of low-income households then this might slow the growth in aggregate supply. Low-income households may not able to access the education, training and healthcare needed to support them as productive workers. If people in the labour force do not have the income needed for effective education and training, then they will not be as skilled and as productive as workers. People on low incomes may also lack the financial incentive to be as productive as if they were able to earn higher wages. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Standards of living An uneven income distribution with a high proportion of low-income households can reduce the quality of life in a country. High levels of poverty amongst poorer households have a negative effect on their welfare in terms of their access to food, housing, health and education. There is also evidence that income inequality in society has a negative effect on mental health and personal happiness amongst poorer households. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Unit 3.4(2) Policies to improve equality, equity and poverty What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • The role of taxation to improve equality, equity and poverty Progressive, regressive and proportional taxes Average and marginal tax rates Direct taxes and indirect tax on equality Calculation of total tax and average tax rates from a set of data (HL only) Other policies to improve equality, equity and poverty include investment in human capital, transfer payments, targeted spending on goods and services, universal basic income, antidiscrimination laws and minimum wages The aims of the policies to improve equality, and equity and reduce poverty To a greater or lesser extent all governments see improving equity, income equality and reducing poverty as political and economic objectives. Achieving lower poverty rates along with greater equity and equality can bring significant benefits to a country in terms of economic growth, improving living standards, achieving greater social stability and delivering a fairer society. These are the policy options governments have to increase equality and equity and reduce poverty. Taxation Tax systems Direct and indirect tax can be used to redistribute income by taxing people on higher incomes more than those on lower incomes and then using the tax revenue to pay for public services and welfare payments that support lower-income households. When looking at different tax systems it is important to look at the two different ways of measuring the tax rate: Average rate of tax Average rate of tax is the percentage of tax paid on an individual’s total income and is calculated as: total tax / total income x 100 = average rate of tax © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 If a person’s income is $50,000 and they pay $10,000 in tax then their average rate of tax would be: $10,000 / $50,000 = 20% Marginal rate of tax The marginal rate of tax is the percentage of tax paid on each extra $ of income someone earns and is calculated as: change in total tax/change in income x 100 = marginal rate of tax If a person’s income rises from $50,000 to $60,000 and their total tax paid increases by $5,000 then the marginal rate of tax would be: $5,000 / $10,000 x 100 = 50% Progressive tax In a progressive system, the rate of tax rises as an individual’s income rises which means their marginal rate of tax increases with income. The table below sets out how a progressive tax system works in a country. One of the aims of a progressive tax is to achieve a more equitable distribution of income by taxing people on higher incomes at a higher rate than those on lower incomes. Individuals A, B and C earn different levels of income. The progressive tax system shown in the table sets out how the rate of tax increases as income increases. Each individual pays zero tax on their first $8,000 of income, 20 per cent on the next $32,000, 40 per cent on the next $40,000 and 50 per cent on any income above $80,000. The income levels where the rate of tax changes are called tax thresholds. The relationship between total tax paid and household income is shown in diagram 3.30. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Corporation tax on company profits is often progressive with a higher rate charged to more profitable businesses. Some politicians and economists have supported the use of a progressive wealth tax on the value of assets a household owns rather than on their income. Many high-income individuals can use tax avoidance schemes to reduce their income tax burden, but they would find it more difficult to avoid a one-off wealth tax. A wealth tax of 10 per cent on a household with a net asset value of $10 million would mean them paying $1 million in tax. Regressive tax A regressive tax is where the average rate of tax falls as an individual’s income rises. This applies to indirect tax where people on lower incomes spend a higher proportion of their income on goods where they have to pay indirect tax compared to people on higher incomes. The table below illustrates the situation of three individuals paying indirect tax. It is assumed that the only indirect tax paid by each individual is VAT set at 20 per cent. The amount of VAT paid by, for example, individual A calculated as: • Spending by individual A on VAT-taxed goods is $14,000 • 20% of the $14,000 is paid in VAT ($14,000 / 1.2 = $11,667) which means $11,667 individual A's spending is taxed • $14,000 - $11,667 = $2333 is the tax paid by individual A • $2,333 / $15,000 x 100 = 15.56% is individual A's average rate of tax. Diagram 3.30 shows the relationship between the total tax paid by an individual and the regressive tax they pay. Regressive taxes are seen to do little to correct inequalities because the average rate of tax for an individual falls as their income increases. The tax collected can, however, be used to spend on public services that do benefit poorer people in society. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Proportional tax (flat tax) A proportional tax is a direct tax system where the average rate of tax remains constant as income increases. In the example above, the individuals on $15,000, $60,000 and $100,000 would all pay the same rate of income at, for example, 20 per cent. Estonia, for example, uses a proportional tax system with a rate of 20 per cent. The relationship between progressive, regressive and proportional taxes and income is shown in diagram 3.30. Similar to regressive taxes, the proportional tax does little to correct inequalities, but again the tax revenue can be used to support low-income households. Problems of using tax to reduce inequality • High rates of tax on high-income groups can have a negative impact on this group’s incentive to work. This can be important for entrepreneurs who are crucial for starting new businesses which employ people on lower incomes. • If tax increases are concentrated on indirect tax then this has a very negative effect on poorer groups in society because they pay a higher proportion of their income on taxes like VAT, duties on alcohol, cigarettes and petrol. • Raising marginal tax rates too high can lead to a reduction in tax revenue because richer people avoid high taxes by leaving the country or by using tax avoidance schemes. This leaves less money for the government to spend on public services to benefit poorer groups in society. • Raising indirect tax pushes up the cost of producing goods which can lead to higher prices and this has a negative impact on low-income households. • If a country has relatively high tax rates compared to its international competitors, it may struggle to compete because domestic business firms will have higher costs and foreign direct investment is less likely to come to countries with high tax rates. This can negatively impact the employment prospects of low-income households. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 • Other policies to improve equality, equity and reduce poverty An alternative government policy approach to equity, equality and poverty is centred on the provision of public services, laws and regulation. Education and training Government policies that target the poorest people in the country are seen as important in creating the opportunity for individuals to access the types of skilled, high-paying jobs that take people out of poverty. Education and training policy can take the following forms: • Free access to primary and secondary education for all children. By making school attendance a legal requirement the government tries to make sure all children benefit from a school education. • Creating support structures for low-income families when their children are in school such as literacy and numeracy schemes. • Wide provision and funding of higher education for all low-income groups to enable everyone to have the opportunity to gain the qualifications needed for the most skilled work. • State funding and provision of employment training programmes to support low-income groups entering the labour force and improving their skills when they are in work. Healthcare Governments use wide healthcare provision to everyone in the country as a way of supporting the poorest in society and also as a way of creating economic opportunities. People often get stuck in poverty in countries that do not have widely available free healthcare. The cost of paying for healthcare is often expensive and poorer people spend a high proportion of their income on paying for doctors, hospital fees and drug expenses. These expenses can leave low-income individuals with little money to pay for other goods and services. In addition, low-income households may have low levels of productivity at work because of their health or they cannot go to work because of poor health. This would also apply to family members who cannot work because they are looking after dependents. Transfer spending Tax revenue collected by the government can be redistributed to low-income households through the benefits system. Unemployment, housing, and disability benefits can all be targeted at lowincome groups in society. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Capital spending Investment spending by the governments on infrastructure can be an effective way of creating opportunities for people in poorer households to improve their employment prospects and incomes. Better connectivity through public transport means people can have greater access to employment and education. Investment by the government in high-speed broadband is also a way households on lower incomes can gain access the employment opportunities and education to improve their future incomes and reduce inequality. Anti-discrimination To improve the income, employment and educational prospects of certain groups in society government can put in place laws and regulations that prevent employers, schools and universities from discriminating based on gender, ethnicity, religion, sexual orientation and age. Universal basic income Universal Basic Income is where a government makes an unconditional, regular payment to everyone in a country. This is a policy governments are investigating, but no government have fully put a universal basic income into place. Many economists are concerned that future advances in technology through artificial intelligence may lead to such significant job losses that a universal basic income will be needed to support the population. Employment protection laws and regulations Government can put in place specific laws and regulations that stop employers from exploiting lowincome workers. These regulations include: • Minimum wages to make sure all workers are paid a fair wage for the work they do. • Redundancy and dismissal regulations mean workers cannot be made redundant or dismissed by their employer without a fair procedure. • Protection and support of trade unions who act in the interest of their members. • The right to paid holiday, sickness benefit and leave for maternity and paternity. • Regulations to ensure the safety and security of working conditions for all employees at their place of work. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Problems of using these policies to reduce inequality • Government spending on policies such as infrastructure, health and education needs funds to pay for them. This can be paid for out of tax revenues by raising taxation or by cutting government expenditure in other areas which represents an opportunity cost. Alternatively, the funds can come from borrowing which has an interest cost and adds to the national debt. • Critics of government spending say that resources are allocated and used inefficiently. This is because governments might spend money on politically motivated projects and government enterprises do not have the pressure of competition or profit to make them efficient. People often criticise government training schemes for this reason. • Governments are such large organisations that they struggle to operate effectively at a micro level because of diseconomies of scale. Government bureaucracy can result in decisions in healthcare, education and infrastructure being slow and ineffective. • Increased workplace regulation to protect low-income workers can increase business costs, increase prices and reduce an economy’s international competitiveness. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Unit 3.5 Government management of the economy – monetary policy What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • • • Aims of monetary policy Control of money supply and interest rates by the central bank Monetary policy to achieve different macroeconomic objectives Money creation by commercial banks (HL) Tools of monetary policy (HL) Determination of interest rates through the demand and supply for money (HL) Real and nominal interest rates Expansionary monetary policy Contractionary monetary policy Evaluation of monetary policy The aims of monetary policy Governments have different economic tools they can use to target their macroeconomic objectives: • Sustainable economic growth • Low unemployment • External balance on the current account balance of payments • Low inflation or price stability The government can use demand management or a demand-side approach where it affects aggregate demand in the economy to achieve these objectives. The government demand management approach can be broken down into monetary policy and fiscal policy. This chapter considers how monetary policy can be used to try and achieve the government's macroeconomic objectives. Understanding monetary policy Monetary policy is where the government uses interest rates and the supply of money to achieve its macroeconomic objectives. For example, the central bank of a country uses interest rates and the supply of money to manage the rate of inflation. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Importance of the central bank The central bank in an economy is the key institution the government uses to apply monetary policy. In the US the central bank is the Federal Reserve, in the EU it is the European Central Bank and in Japan, it is the Bank of Japan. In recent years many countries have made their central bank independent from the government so it can apply monetary policy without too much political influence on decision-making. The central bank applies monetary policy by using the following tools: • Base interest (discount) rates • Quantitative easing • Open market operations • Minimum reserve requirements Determining the supply of money - credit creation (HL) Credit creation is the way commercial banks in an economy create money from the funds deposited with them. Credit creation has an important influence on the money supply of the economy and the way monetary policy works. The process of credit creation is based on the following assumptions: • One bank represents the whole banking system. In reality, the banking system is dominated by a number of large banks, but in this model, the whole banking system is considered to operate as one bank. • The firms and households that deposit money in banks will only withdraw a certain proportion at any one time to make transactions. This is realistic if you think about the way most people use their money. For example, we can assume that most customers will only withdraw 20 per cent of their deposit at any one time. • A minimum reserve asset ratio requirement is set based on the withdrawal rate of the bank's customers. In this case, it is 20 per cent. • The money withdrawn from the bank will be redeposited bank in the bank and not held outside the banking system. • Banks make a profit by charging a higher rate of interest to borrowers than they pay to depositors. Thus, banks have an incentive to lend as much as it is safe for them to do. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 The credit creation process Based on these assumptions This is how credit creation works in an economy where a single bank represents the whole system: Step 1 An initial deposit of $200,000 in cash is put into the bank. Step 2 The bank can use the $200,000 as a 20% reserve asset to cover cash withdrawals. In this case, it will use $40,000 of the initial $200,000 deposit to cover withdrawals from the customer who made the $200,000 deposit. The remaining $160,000 can be used to cover cash withdrawals from any loans the bank makes. Step 3 An individual asks for a loan from the bank to buy a house for $200,000. The banks will make this loan because they can use $40,000 of the $200,000 initial deposit as a 20 per cent reserve to cover a withdrawal that might occur from the $200,000 loan made. After the loan is made and the borrower buys the house, the individual they bought the house from will deposit the $200,000 back in the bank. As a result of this, the bank has created $200,000 of credit and this money is now circulating in the economy. Step 4 A firm applies for a $600,000 loan from the bank to buy a new machine. The bank has $120,000 of the initial deposit left ($200,000 - $80,000) to cover the 20% reserve asset ratio requirement for the loan for the $600,000 machine. Another $600,000 has been created with this loan so the total amount of credit creation of is $800,000 ($200,000 + $600,000). Step 5 The bank will not make any new loans now because it has reached its 20% reserve asset ratio limit where it has $200,000 backing $1,000,000 of funds ($200,000 initial deposit + $200,000 house loan + $600,000 machine loan). The money multiplier The money multiplier is the amount of credit that can be created from a certain quantity of money deposited. The money multiplier can be calculated by using the equation: 1 / minimum reserve requirement = money multiplier 1 / 0.2 = 5 5 x $200,000 = $1,000,000 This example of credit creation shows how an increase in bank deposits of $200,000 can lead to a $1,000,000 increase in the money supply when the reserve asset ratio is 20 per cent. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Interest rates The influence of the base rate The base interest rate has an important influence over the interest rates set throughout the economy by banks and other lending institutions. The base rate is the interest rate charged by the central bank to the commercial banking sector. The financial system in the economy is set up so that commercial banks need to continuously borrow money from the central bank. If the central banks change the base rate the commercial banks will pay a different rate and they will then pass on this change in interest rate to their customers and the interest rate change will filter through the economy. For example, if the base rate is increased it means commercial banks have to pay more to the central bank, they will then pass the interest rate increase to their customers and interest rates throughout the economy (personal loans, mortgage and credit card interest rates) will increase. Market interest rates The other important influence on interest rates in the economy is the interest rates set in the money markets. The market rate of interest is determined by the demand and supply of money. Demand for money Firms and households demand money because they need to make transactions when they buy goods and services. There is a negative relationship between the rate of interest and the demand for money because as the rate of interest increases the quantity demand for money falls as the cost of borrowing increases. This means firms and households borrow less and therefore demand less money to buy goods and services. This is particularly true of goods such as cars and goods associated with home improvements. As interest rates decrease the quantity demand for money increases as the cost of borrowing decreases. The demand for money is shown in diagram 3.38. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Supply of money The supply of money in the economy is set by the central bank and the banking system. The central bank controls the money issued to the banking system and the banking system creates credit that determines the amount of money circulating in the economy. The supply of money is fixed in a given time period and is perfectly inelastic. This is shown in diagram 3.38. Equilibrium interest rate The equilibrium rate of interest rate is set where the demand for money equals the supply of money in diagram 3.38. Changes in the market rate of interest The market interest rate will change if there is either a change in the demand for money or the supply of money. For example, if there is a fall in aggregate demand in a recession there will be fewer transactions and the money demand curve will fall from Md to Md1 causing a fall in the market of interest. This is shown in diagram 3.39. Nominal and real interest rates Nominal interest rates make no allowance for inflation. Most of the economic data used to report the state of the economy use interest rates stated in nominal terms. If a central bank increases interest rates from 1 per cent to 2 per cent this will lead to an increase in the nominal interest rate. The real interest rate makes an allowance for inflation. It is calculated as: Nominal interest rate – inflation rate = real interest rate If a country has a nominal interest rate of 5 per cent and the inflation rate is 2 per cent, the real interest rate is: 5% - 2% = 3% The real interest rate is used by firms and households to give them information about the returns they pay or receive on money borrowed or saved. For example, if an individual saves money at a nominal interest rate of 4 per cent and inflation is 5 per cent they know the real value of their savings will be falling. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 The tools of monetary policy (HL) The government has a number of monetary tools it can use to achieve its policy objectives. In many countries, the government sets the direction of monetary policy through its macroeconomic objectives and the central bank makes decisions on how the different policy tools are applied. The minimum reserve requirement The minimum reserve requirement is the quantity of cash banks must hold as a reserve or keep in deposit at the central bank. It is a safety net that protects banks in situations where depositors withdraw more money from their accounts than they normally do and threaten the bank's liquidity (the amount of cash it holds). If the central bank wants to reduce the money supply it can increase the minimum reserve requirement of commercial banks and this reduces their ability to create credit because they have to hold more cash. If the minimum reserves requirement is reduced by the central bank the banking system can create more credit and there is an increase in the money supply. Open market operations Open market operations are a monetary tool used by the central banks to regulate the money supply by buying and selling government bonds. If the government sells government bonds in the financial markets, buyers will purchase them using cash. As cash is taken out of the financial system there is less money for the banks to use to create credit and the money supply falls. If the central bank buys government bonds in the financial markets, more cash enters the system and the money supply increases. Quantitative easing Quantitative easing was used extensively by central banks following the global financial crisis to increase aggregate demand. Quantitative easing involves central banks using open market operations to increase the money supply by purchasing large quantities of government and corporate bonds. The banking system uses the additional cash from quantitative easing to create credit and the money supply increases which reduces interest rates. The impact of quantitative easing is shown in diagram 3.40. As market interest rates are pushed down by quantitative easing this increases consumption and investment which increases aggregate demand and economic growth. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Expansionary monetary policy Expansionary monetary policy is where the government reduces interest rates and increases the supply of money to increase consumption and investment to increase aggregate demand. Expansionary monetary policy is normally used to increase economic growth and reduce unemployment. How the policy works When the central bank reduces its base rate, it charges a lower interest rate to commercial banks and they pass on this reduction in interest rates to households and firms in the form of lower interest loans (personal loans, mortgages and credit cards). Lower interest rates will also mean less interest is paid on the money firms and households hold in banks. This causes consumption and investment spending to rise which increases aggregate demand. The increase in aggregate demand leads to a rise in GDP as firms respond by producing more. This also leads to an increase in employment. This is sometimes called the monetary transmission mechanism and is shown in diagram 3.41 where a rise in aggregate demand and the subsequent rise in the demand for labour reduces unemployment. Expansionary monetary policy also closes the deflationary gap. The flow diagram shows the monetary transmission mechanism as interest rates are reduced. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Evaluation of expansionary monetary policy Strengths • Expansionary monetary policy is relatively quick to apply which gives it flexibility in the way it can be applied. If the central banks have evidence of a rise in unemployment or a fall in economic growth they can respond by immediately decreasing base interest rates. • Monetary policy can be applied incrementally so it can be adjusted to changes in the economic growth and unemployment rate. If the growth rate is falling or unemployment is rising month by month, interest rates can be continuously adjusted to tackle the changes in those rates. • Because central banks are independent of governments in most countries they have some freedom from government political influence. An independent central bank can stop a government from using expansionary monetary policy to increase economic growth in the run-up to an election to create economic boom conditions which could lead to inflation. Weaknesses • When an expansionary monetary policy is being applied there may be a rise in average price level and an increase in inflation. This is particularly true if the rise in aggregate demand leads to an inflationary gap. This is shown in diagram 3.41 where the increase in aggregate demand leads to an increase in the average price level from P to P1. • When interest rates are very low and even close to zero the central bank has little room to reduce rates in response to a rise in unemployment or falling economic growth. • Commercial banks may not pass on an increase in interest rates. When the central bank uses expansionary monetary policy and interest rates are being reduced commercial banks can often increase their profits by not passing on the interest rate reduction. The interest rate reduction means commercial banks pay a lower interest cost to the central bank but can still receive the same interest rate from their borrowers if they do not decrease their own interest rate. • A decrease in the Interest rates in the economy relies on households and firms changing consumption and investment in response to the interest rate change. In a recession, low levels of business and consumer confidence may mean firms and households do not increase consumption and investment because they are worried about spending in an uncertain economic environment. This is particularly true of large investment projects by firms and the purchase of expensive items by consumers. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 • There are time lags in the application of monetary policy that make it difficult to manage. It is estimated that it takes 18 months for the full effects of an interest rate change to have an impact on the macroeconomy. This means there can be policy mistakes in the application of expansionary monetary policy. For example, a government might decrease interest rates and see little increase in consumption and investment in the short run so the government might cut interest rates again and this leads to a surge in consumption and investment which causes inflation. • An expansionary monetary policy where interest rates are reduced can lead to a depreciation in the exchange rate as currency investors sell the domestic currency because of the lower interest returns they receive from domestic banks. As the exchange rate depreciates it can make imports more expensive and this adds to inflation. Contractionary monetary policy Governments and central banks apply contractionary monetary policy when they increase interest rates and reduce the supply of money to reduce the rate of inflation. How the policy works If inflation rises in the economy the central bank raises its base rate which is the interest rate it charges to commercial banks. The commercial banks then pass on the higher interest rate to their customers and this raises interest rates throughout the economy. Households and firms start paying higher interest costs on loans and receiving greater interest returns on money held in banks. As the interest rates rise throughout the economy consumption and investment fall and this reduces aggregate demand. As aggregate demand falls in an economy the average price level falls from P to P1 and inflation falls. In diagram 3.42 the fall in aggregate demand closes the inflationary gap as output falls from Y to YFE. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 The flow diagram illustrates the monetary transmission mechanism of contractionary monetary policy. Evaluation of contractionary monetary policy Strengths • Contractionary monetary policy can be applied quickly which gives it flexibility as a policy. If the rate of inflation rises the central bank can react almost immediately to increase interest rates to reduce aggregate demand and inflation. • Contractionary monetary policy can be applied incrementally so it can be adjusted to changes in the inflation rate. If the inflation rate is rising month by month, interest rates can be continuously increased to tackle the problem. • Because central banks are independent of governments in most countries they have some freedom to apply contractionary monetary without political influence. For example, a rise in inflation might need a rise in interest rates but the government might not want to do this for political reasons, but an independent central bank can still increase the rate of interest to reduce inflation. Weaknesses • When a contractionary monetary policy is being applied the fall in aggregate demand may lead to a reduction in economic growth and even a recession and this will lead to a rise in unemployment. This is shown in diagram 3.42 when aggregate demand falls from AD to AD1 because of a rise in interest rates. • An increase in interest rates by the central bank in its application of contractionary monetary policy may not be passed on by the commercial banks. The lending market is competitive and if banks are competing to make loans to new customers, they might not pass on the increase in interest rates so they can keep attracting new borrowers with lower interest rates. • Similar to expansionary monetary policy, there are time lags in the application of the policy that makes it difficult to manage. The estimated 18 months it takes for the full effects of an increase in interest rate to have an impact on the macroeconomy leads to policy mistakes. If the government increases interest too much this can lead to a fall in economic growth and even a recession. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 10 • An increase in interest rates as part of contractionary monetary policy can lead to an appreciation in the exchange rate as foreign currency investors are attracted to the domestic currency by higher interest rates in domestic banks. As the exchange rate appreciates it makes export prices more expensive and import prices cheaper and this can lead to a balance of payments current account deficit. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 11 Unit 3.6 Government management of the economy – fiscal policy What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • • • Objectives of fiscal policy Sources of government revenue Types of government expenditure Expansionary and contractionary fiscal policy Keynesian multiplier (HL) Crowding out Strengths of fiscal policy Weaknesses of fiscal policy Automatic stabilisers The objectives of fiscal policy Governments can use fiscal policy as a demand-side policy to achieve their macroeconomic objectives in a similar way to the application of monetary policy. Fiscal policy involves governments using tax and government expenditure to achieve macroeconomic objectives. The tools of fiscal policy can be used to target the following objectives: • Sustainable economic growth • Low unemployment • External balance on the current account balance of payments • Low inflation or price stability • Achievement of a more equitable distribution of income Sources of government revenue Government can access revenue to fund its expenditure from the following sources: • Direct taxation on household incomes in the form of income tax and tax on business profits in the form of corporation tax. • Indirect taxation such as VAT and specific duties on goods and services. • Profit from the operations of state-run organisations. Many governments own organisations in the transport and energy sectors and make a profit from them. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 • Asset sales when governments privatise industries. When governments sell the assets of state-owned enterprises it leads to an inflow of funds to the state. Government borrowing Government borrowing is an important part of fiscal policy because it is needed when government expenditure is greater than taxation. Government borrowing is financed by selling bonds in the financial markets. For example, the Indian government might sell $200 billion of government bonds to raise $200 billion in funds to spend on health, education and defence, etc. The budget deficit is one year’s government borrowing. The current Indian budget deficit is $137 billion. The national debt is accumulated government borrowing over time. The current Indian national debt is $2219 billion. Types of government expenditure There are three types of government expenditure: • Current expenditure on the day-to-day running of the government sector such as paying the wages of teachers, doctors and military personnel. • Capital expenditure on investment projects financed by the government such as building roads, bridges and schools. • Transfer expenditure on welfare payments such as unemployment and housing benefits. The influence of the Keynesian multiplier on fiscal policy The application of fiscal policy by governments is affected by the Keynesian multiplier. This is because the application of fiscal policy in an economy involves changing the injections into the circular flow of income in the form of government expenditure and withdrawals out of the circular flow of income in the form of taxation. Defining the multiplier The government expenditure multiplier is the ratio of change in government expenditure to a change in national income. A multiplier effect occurs when a change in injections brings about a greater proportionate change in national income. The multiplier can occur because of a change in any one of the injections into the circular flow of income: investment(I), government expenditure (G) and exports (X). © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 The multiplier can be measured as the ratio of change in any one of these injections (J) to a change in national income (Y). multiplier = change in national income / change in injections The government expenditure multiplier involved with fiscal policy would be: government expenditure multiplier = change in national income/change in government expenditure Multiplier situations occur when funds are injected into the circular flow of income through investment, government expenditure and exports and this leads to a greater final change in the value of the national income than the value of the change in the injection. Diagram 3.31 shows the circular flow of income with injections (I, G and X) and withdrawals (S, T and M). The increase in injections causes a multiplier effect to take place, but the strength of the multiplier is determined by the level of consumption and the withdrawals from the circular flow, savings, tax and imports. For example, an increase in government expenditure will cause an increase in national income which will lead to a rise in consumption by households and also a rise in the amount saved, paid in tax and spent on imports. Calculating the value of the multiplier The value of the multiplier can be calculated by using the following equations: Multiplier = 1/(1-MPC) or 1/(MPS+MPT+MPM) Marginal propensity to consume (MPC) This is the proportionate change in consumption brought about by a change in income. It is calculated using the equation: MPC = ∆C/∆Y If household income rises from $10,000 and consumption rises by $6,000 then the MPC will be: +$6,000 / +$10,000 = 0.6 © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Marginal propensity to save (MPS) This is the proportionate change in saving brought about by a changing income. It Is calculated using the equation: MPS = ∆S/∆Y If household income rises by $10,000 and savings rise by $500 then the MPS will be: +$500 / +$10,000 = 0.05 Marginal propensity to tax (MPT) This is the proportionate change in tax brought about by a changing income. It Is calculated using the equation: MPT = ∆T/∆Y If household income rises by $10,000 and tax rises by $2,000 then the MPT will be: +$2,000 / +$10,000 = 0.20 Marginal propensity to imports (MPM) This is the proportionate change in imports brought about by a changing income. It Is calculated using the equation: MPM = ∆M/∆Y If household income rises by $10,000 and imports rise by $1,500 then the MPM will be: +$1,500 / +$10,000 = 0.15 Calculation In this case, the value of the multiplier would be: 1 / 0.05 + 0.20 + 0.15 = 2.5 © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Example of the multiplier The multiplier process can be explained using the following example where the government decides to spend $2 billion building a new bridge as part of the improvement in the infrastructure of a region of the country. These are the stages of the multiplier effect brought about by the rise in government expenditure: Stage 1 $2Bn is paid to factors of production to build the new bridge. This will partly be wages paid to labour who work directly on the construction of the bridge. Funds will also be paid to firms that supply construction equipment, raw materials and services like law and architects. These payments will generate income for the workers and for the owners of the businesses who supply factors of production to build the bridge. Stage 2 The $2Bn income paid to the factors of production to build the bridge will be partly spent as consumption expenditure and the rest will be leaked out of the economy in the form of savings, tax and imports. The size of the extra income consumed depends on the MPC of the economy and the amount leaked depends on the MPS, MPT and MPM of the economy. In our example the MPC is 0.6 so $1.2Bn will be consumption expenditure and the MPW is 0.4 so $0.8Bn will be withdrawn from the economy as savings, tax and imports. Stage 3 The $1.2bn of consumption spending by households will be on buying goods and services produced by firms and this will become income for the factors of production employed by these firms. The households that receive the $1.2bn of income will spend part of this income (0.6 x $1.2Bn = $0.72Bn) on consumption and the rest will be withdrawn (0.4 x $1.2Bn = $0.48Bn) from the economy as savings, tax and imports. Stage 4 The $0.72Bn is another spending round that works in the same way as the previous spending rounds with income to households which is partly spent on consumption and partly withdrawn out of the economy. This process continues with each spending round getting smaller and smaller until they no longer add to the total national income. Stage 5 The flow chart shows how adding together the income generated by each spending round gives us the final change in national income. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Calculating the final change in national income The final change in national income in this example is calculated using the equation 1/1-MPC or 1/MPS + MPT + MPM In this case: • MPS = 0.05 • MPT = 0.20 • MPM = 0.15 1/0.05 + 0.20 + 0.15 = 2.5 The final change in national income brought about by the $2 billion government expenditure on the bridge is calculated as: 2.5 x $2Bn = $5Bn The final change in national income resulting from the government expenditure of $2 billion on the bridge is $5 billion. Graphical interpretation of the multiplier When there is an increase in injections into the economy aggregate demand in the economy increases. In our example, when the government spends $2 billion on the bridge aggregate demand in the economy initially increases from AD to AD1 in diagram 3.32. The additional spending rounds cause aggregate demand to increase further and the final change in aggregate demand is at AD2 in diagram 3.32. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 Evaluation of the multiplier The Keynesian multiplier has strengths and weaknesses when it is applied to the economy. Strengths of the multiplier • It is useful for building models of the economy and analysing how changes in national income are affected by changes in government expenditure, investment and exports. • The multiplier can be used to improve economic forecasting. • The government can use the multiplier to analyse the impact of a change in government spending across the whole economy and at a local level. Weaknesses of the multiplier • The marginal propensities to consume, save, tax and import can be difficult to measure and can change over time. This makes establishing a multiplier value difficult. • Isolating the impact of a change of one item of expenditure is difficult to do because different items of expenditure are all changing at the same time. The government might be spending funds on a new bridge at the same time as firms are investing in new factories. • Many expenditure projects take place over a long time period so expenditure gradually comes into the economy rather than as one sum of expenditure all at the same time. The $2 billion of government expenditure on the bridge might take several years to be spent. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Expansionary fiscal policy Expansionary fiscal is where the government decreases taxation and increases government spending to increase aggregate demand. For example, the US government has agreed to a $2 trillion increase in expenditure to deal with the fall in economic growth caused by the Covid19 crisis. How the policy works As a component of aggregate demand, an increase in government expenditure will directly increase aggregate demand. Cutting direct and indirect tax will increase consumption as households have more disposable income to increase their spending and firms have more profit to fund increased investment. As consumption and investment increase aggregate demand increases. Diagram 3.33 shows how an increase in aggregate demand will shift AD to AD1 leading to an increase in national income from Y to YFE and the average price level increases from P to P1. The rise in national income also closes the deflationary gap. The rise in national income can increase the rate of economic growth and reduce unemployment. The flow chart shows the transmission mechanism of expansionary fiscal policy. Increased employment As aggregate demand increases there is a rise in real GDP which means businesses might produce more and employ more workers to do this. This is illustrated in the labour market diagram where the demand for labour increases from ADL to ADL1 and the rise in employment reduces unemployment. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Fiscal policy and crowding out An issue with expansionary fiscal policy is the impact it can have on interest rates in the financial markets. An expansionary fiscal policy can lead to an increase in the budget deficit that in turn leads to a rise in money market interest rates. This makes financing a budget deficit more difficult and can make borrowing costs increase throughout the economy. The crowding out process associated with an expansionary fiscal policy can be summarised in the following way: • Stage 1 - Expansionary fiscal policy leads to a budget deficit. • Stage 2 - To fund the deficit the government sells bonds in the money markets. • Stage 3 - The government needs to make the bonds attractive to buyers which means increasing the rate of interest paid on the bonds which pushes up market interest rates. • Stage 4 - As the government borrows more there is a higher demand for borrowed funds in the money markets which also pushes up market interest rates • Stage 5 - Higher market interest rates reduce consumption and investment, and this leads to a fall in aggregate demand. • Stage 6 - Where expansionary fiscal policy means higher government borrowing in the money markets this is seen as a situation where public sector spending ‘crowds out’ private sector spending. Credit rating Credit rating agencies can also look unfavourably on expansionary fiscal policy when it leads to an increase in the budget deficit. Credit rating agencies such as Moody's and Standard and Poor, are organisations that make judgements about the security of government borrowing. The credit rating agencies may look at very large government deficits unfavourably and downgrade the government credit rating, which makes the money markets charge higher interest rates to the government because they appear to be a greater risk. This happened to Greece and Spain in 2012 when they increased their budget deficits following the global financial crisis. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 9 Evaluation of expansionary fiscal policy Strengths • Fiscal policy is most appropriate for demand deficient unemployment in a recession where the fall in aggregate demand has caused the rise in unemployment and expansionary fiscal policy increases aggregate demand. • Increasing government expenditure and reducing taxation have a direct impact on the economy. Cutting taxation directly increases consumer incomes and an increase in government expenditure directing increases aggregate demand as it is one of the components of aggregate demand. • Fiscal policy does not affect the exchange rate in the way monetary policy does when interest rates are changed. A decrease in interest rates when an expansionary monetary policy is applied causes a country’s exchange rate to depreciate and this will not happen with an expansionary fiscal policy. Weaknesses • Cutting taxes and increasing government spending will lead to an increase in a country’s budget deficit and national debt. This may be particularly difficult for a government when there is already a budget deficit because the economy is in a recession where government transfer spending rises and tax revenues fall. • Crowding out of the private sector by public sector spending when a government budget deficit increases market interest rates. • Some economists question the effectiveness of tax cuts in a recession. Tax cuts rely on households spending the extra disposable income they receive, and they may save it when they are fearful of spending in a recession when households are uncertain about their employment. • Increasing government spending may lead to an inefficient use of resources. Government spending on projects just for the sake of spending may mean resources are used to improve roads that do not need improving or money gets lost in the bureaucracy associated with government expenditure projects. • Fiscal policy lacks flexibility because the government can only change tax and expenditure a certain number of times each year. The process of changing tax, for example, is difficult because firms and households need to be told of the proposed changes and they have to be worked through by the tax authorities. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 10 • Increasing aggregate demand through expansionary fiscal policy may lead to a rise in inflation. This is particularly true if the policy is used when unemployment is not that high and is not caused by falling aggregate demand. The economy could be operating at full employment and expansionary fiscal policy just leads to inflation. • Expansionary fiscal policy will only really tackle demand deficient unemployment. and fails with other types of unemployment such as structural and frictional unemployment because they are not directly caused by falling aggregate demand. Contractionary fiscal policy How contractionary fiscal policy reduces inflation A contractionary fiscal policy is where the government increases taxation and decreases government expenditure to reduce inflation and close an inflationary gap. A rise in taxation will reduce consumption if household income taxes rise and reduce investment if business taxes are increased. An increase in tax combined with a decrease in government spending leads to a fall in aggregate demand. This is shown in diagram 3.35 where AD shifts to AD1 which leads to a decrease in the average price level and inflation falls. There is also a decrease in real GDP from Y to YFE and the inflationary gap is closed. The flow diagram shows the transmission mechanism of contractionary fiscal policy. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 11 Evaluation of contractionary fiscal policy Strengths • Fiscal policy does not rely on a transmission mechanism in the same way monetary policy does and has a more direct effect on aggregate demand. For example, increasing taxation will directly decrease household income whereas an increase in interest rates relies on the banking system passing the increased interest rate on to households. • Because fiscal policy has a more direct effect on the economy compared to monetary policy there is a shorter time lag associated with the use of contractionary fiscal policy compared to monetary policy. • Changing tax and government expenditure does not affect a country’s exchange rate in the way a change in interest rates can change a country’s exchange rate. Contractionary monetary policy means increasing interest rates which can lead to appreciation in the exchange rate. • Fiscal policy can be targeted more specifically at different sectors of the economy to reduce inflation. For example, reducing indirect tax will directly reduce the price of goods and services. Weakness • Raising taxes may have a negative impact on the motivation of workers and entrepreneurs because of the potential reduction in their income. Reduced incentives might have a negative effect on the supply side of the economy if, for example, entrepreneurs are less likely to start businesses because of higher taxation. • Higher indirect taxes can add to business costs and higher direct taxes on workers might mean they ask for higher wages to make up for their reduction in income. Higher business costs may increase cost-push inflation. • Reducing government expenditure and increasing taxation can lead to austerity which has a negative effect on welfare in society. For example, reducing government expenditure may mean reducing the quality of public services like education and healthcare. • Fiscal policy lacks flexibility because it is difficult to change tax rates and government expenditure more than a certain number of times a year. On the other hand, interest rates can be changed much more regularly. • Increasing tax and cutting government expenditure can lead to a fall in aggregate demand which reduces the rate of economic growth and could even lead to a recession and rising unemployment. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 12 Automatic stabilisers Automatic stabilizers are a part of fiscal policy and occur because tax and government expenditure automatically change during the business cycle, and this has consequences of inflationary and deflationary gaps. Inflationary gap The boom phase of the business cycle may lead to an inflationary gap in an economy where inflation rises. Automatic stabilisers can reduce the strength of the inflationary effect in the following ways: • Direct tax rises in the economy because household income and business profits increase. • Government expenditure falls because there is less transfer spending on benefits such as unemployment payments. Diagram 3.36 shows how the rise in tax and fall in government expenditure causes aggregate demand to fall from AD1 to AD2 when the automatic stabiliser starts to work when there is an inflationary gap. Deflationary gap In the recession phase of the business cycle, there may be a deflationary gap and a rise in unemployment. Automatic stabilisers can reduce the strength of the deflationary effect in the following way: • The amount of direct tax falls as household incomes fall and firms make lower profits. The indirect tax also falls as households spend less. • Government expenditure on benefits increases as unemployment rises and the government pays more unemployment and related benefits. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 13 Diagram 3.37 shows how the fall in tax and rise in government expenditure causes aggregate demand to rise from AD1 to AD2 when the automatic stabiliser takes effect when there is a deflationary gap. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 14 Unit 3.7(1) Market-based supply-side policies What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • • • Aims of supply-side policies Use of the long-run aggregate supply curve to show the effect of supply-side policies Explanation of market-based policies: competition policy, deregulation, privatisation, trade liberalisation, monopoly regulation Explanation of labour market policies: reducing the power of labour unions, reducing unemployment benefits, reducing minimum wages Explanation of incentive-related policies: decreasing income tax and business tax Market-based supply-side policies to increase economic growth, reduce unemployment and achieve price stability Evaluation of market-based supply-side policies Aims of supply-side policies Government supply-side policies aim to affect aggregate supply and achieve the macroeconomic objectives of: • Sustainable economic growth • Low unemployment • External balance of the current account balance of payments • Low inflation or price stability Supply-side policies and long-run economic growth Long-term growth Supply-side policies are often viewed as a long-term strategic set of policies to facilitate future economic growth over a period of time. For example, increasing the numbers in university education to improve the skill level of the labour force may take 10 to 20 years to have a significant effect on the growth of the economy. Increasing productive capacity © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 To achieve long-term economic growth, supply-side policies are often targeted at improving the productive potential of the economy. This means using policies that increase potential output, shifting the production possibility curve and long-run aggregate supply curve of an economy outwards. This is illustrated by diagram 3.43 where the long-run aggregate supply curve increases from LRAS to LRAS1. A government spending programme on significant improvements to infrastructure in the economy would be aimed at increasing productive capacity. What are market-based supply-side policies? The market-based approach The market-based supply-side approach involves the government trying to increase aggregate supply by using policies that allow markets to function more efficiently and to achieve the macroeconomic objectives of sustained economic growth, price stability and low unemployment. Through marketbased supply-side policies, the government tries to create the market conditions needed to allow the private sector of the economy to find solutions to economic problems. Market-based supply side can be looked at as three distinct policy approaches: • Policies that encourage competition in markets. This is based on the assumption that more competition between businesses increases economic efficiency. • Policies that try to increase efficiency in the labour market. This is particularly important for employment and worker productivity. • Incentive-related policies to increase efficiency, investment and innovation. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Increasing potential output The increase in investment and innovation brought about by marketbased supply-side policies will cause the long-run aggregate supply curve to shift outwards from LRAS to LRAS1 in diagram 3.43. This can also be shown by a shift outwards in the production possibility curve from PPC to PPC1, which is shown in diagram 3.44. Increasing actual output The improvement in efficiency brought about by market-based supply-side policies can lead to an increase in actual output which is illustrated in diagram 3.45 by a shift from A to B as the economy moves closer to potential output. A market-based approach to achieve long-run economic growth Deregulation of markets Over time, markets can become increasingly regulated to protect workers, the environment, health and safety and the consumer. For example, a clothing manufacturer might be required by law to pay a minimum wage, put in place health and safety systems on the production line and use sustainable materials when manufacturing its products. Even though the aims of these regulations might be to improve welfare they can add to business costs and reduce productive efficiency by making decision making more complex. By reducing or removing regulations, business costs might fall and productive efficiency might increase. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Privatisation of industries Many industries have been owned and controlled by the government. This is particularly true in utilities such as energy and water, but also transport and communications. In the UK, for example, British Gas, Royal Mail, British Telecom, British Rail and British Airways have all been state-run enterprises in the past. Over the last 30 years, all these industries have been privatised. This means the assets have been sold to private investors and they have employed management to run the businesses. The theory of privatisation is that private sector organisations run more efficiently than public sector enterprises, and this increases overall efficiency in the wider economy. Trade liberalisation Most economists believe that free international trade increases efficiency in an economy through increased competition and specialisation of resources. Many countries use trade barriers, such as tariffs and quotas, to protect certain markets. When trade is liberalised and trade barriers are reduced or removed, this increases free international trade and the efficiency gains that go with it. The ASEAN free trade agreement, for example, between countries such as Indonesia, Malaysia, Singapore, Thailand etc, increases trade liberalisation and the efficiency gains that go with it. Monopoly and competition regulation When monopolies become established in markets they reduce competition and this leads to a fall in business efficiency. Section 2.11 of this book focuses on monopoly as a market failure and how the existence of monopolies reduces economic efficiency. As part of a market-based supply-side approach, the government puts in place laws and regulations that prevent monopolies from occurring or regulate monopolies if they do exist. The European Union, for example, has specific laws in its Single Market that prevent monopoly practices such as cartels occurring amongst member countries of the EU. Reducing the power of trade unions A trade union is where a group of employees join together to try to maintain and improve the wages and employment conditions of their members. Many economists who advocate a market-based supply-side approach believe that the power of trade unions should be reduced because they reduce business efficiency and prevent innovation and change. In 2019 many transport workers in France went on strike because of proposed changes to their working conditions. The French government were trying to push through market reforms that could reduce business costs and increase efficiency. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Changes in taxation Changes to tax rates and the tax system are seen as an important way of creating greater incentives in the economy to increase efficiency, investment and innovation. Cutting taxes means that workers will keep a larger proportion of their income, which may increase their incentive to work harder and improve productivity. Reducing corporation tax on businesses means they can keep a higher proportion of their profits, which they can use to fund new investment and research and development. Lower tax on businesses may also encourage new firms to start up in the economy. Evaluation of market-based supply-side policy to achieve economic growth Strengths • Market-based supply-side policies use the power of the market to achieve economic growth. The interaction of private business and consumers might be more powerful in affecting economic growth in the long run than interventionist supply-side policies. • The market-based approach does not involve the government expenditure costs of the interventionist approach. • Similar to interventionist supply-side policies, the market-based approach does not cause inflation in the same way as expansionary demand-side policies do. Weaknesses • A market-based approach can work in the long run, but it is relatively ineffective compared to expansionary demand-side policies in achieving an increase in the current rate of economic growth. The market-based approach will not be as effective in a recession when a government needs to respond quickly to a fall in economic growth. • If the deregulation aspect of the market-based approach involves reducing environmental laws, it can have a negative effect on the environment. • The market-based approach can have a negative impact on low-income workers who may see their incomes and working conditions negatively affected if the government decides to decrease minimum wages and cut back on employment protection. • If the market-based policy involves reducing income and corporation tax, this could widen income inequality in the country. • Trade liberalisation involves a country reducing trade barriers, which leads to some industries being exposed to low-cost foreign competition which could cause business failure and unemployment. • Privatisation of certain industries may lead to private sector monopolies which may cause prices to rise. In the energy and public transport markets, this can have a particularly negative impact on the consumer. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Market-based supply-side approach to unemployment Direct tax and benefits Reducing direct taxation creates a greater incentive for workers to take available jobs which can reduce the amount of unemployment. If governments reduce unemployment benefits this also increases the incentive for workers to accept jobs. A combination of lower direct tax and reduced benefits makes the opportunity cost of not accepting a job higher because the difference between someone’s income in work increases relative to the transfer payments they might receive if they are out of work. Trade unions Reducing the power of trade unions takes away some of the impediments that prevent firms from hiring new workers. This is particularly true where trade unions negotiate wages above their market equilibrium level and cause the quantity demanded of labour to fall. Minimum wages Minimum wages can cause a disequilibrium in the labour market, which means the quantity demanded for labour is less than the quantity supplied of labour. If a government reduces the minimum wage in the economy, the quantity demanded for labour rises and there is a decrease in unemployment. Reducing minimum wages is often seen as important to small businesses and this can encourage them to hire more workers. Labour market regulations Governments can reduce the amount of labour market regulation that prevents firms from taking on new employees. If there are over-protective regulations, such as statutory redundancy payments, then firms are less likely to take on workers because of the high cost of making workers redundant. Evaluation of market-based supply-side policy to reduce unemployment Strengths • Market-based supply-side policies can make the labour market more dynamic and reactive to change. For example, reducing regulations can make it easier for firms to take on workers more quickly when they are expanding. • There is evidence that the private sector is better at creating jobs than the public sector. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 • The increased incentives associated with market-based supply-side policies can increase worker productivity. Weaknesses • Market-based supply-side policies can have harsh effects on the unemployed. If unemployed people cannot find jobs in a recession, then cutting their benefits will lead to increased poverty. • Decreasing employment regulation can reduce the protection workers have in their jobs, which in turn leads to greater job insecurity and can cause the exploitation of workers. • Reducing direct tax might mean unscrupulous employers reduce pay rates because they know workers are going to receive a rise in their disposable income. • Taking away minimum wages legislation means pay rates will fall in certain industries, which can lead to greater levels of poverty. Market-based supplied policies to reduce inflation Monopoly and competition regulation Market-based supply-side policies that increase competition in the economy and reduce the power of monopolies can lead to increased efficiency and lower prices. This is illustrated in diagram 3.43 where the increase in long-run aggregate supply from LRAS to LRAS1 causes the average price level to fall and reduces the rate of inflation. Reducing the power of trade unions Trade union activity can push up wages in the economy, which increases business costs. This can lead to cost-push inflation. Market-based supply-side policies to reduce the power of trade unions mean that union activity is less likely to push up wage costs. Changes in taxation Reducing direct and indirect tax can lead to lower business costs and increase business efficiency, which leads to reduced inflationary pressures in the economy. For example, a reduction in VAT can directly reduce the average price level in the economy. Privatisation of industries The increased efficiency privatising key industries can bring to the economy can lead to lower prices and reduced inflation. Privatisation of energy companies can be particularly significant because gas and electricity costs are a major part of consumer expenditure and business costs. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 Deregulation of markets Removing and reducing regulations on businesses can increase efficiency and reduce business costs, which creates the conditions for lower prices and reduced inflation. Evaluation of market-based supply-side policy to reduce inflation Strengths • The market-based supply-side approach can reduce the average price level and inflation in the long run at the same time that national income increases. Contractionary demand-side policies reduce inflation, but often at the cost of falling national income. • Increasing economic efficiency and competition in markets can create the conditions for price stability in the long run. Weaknesses • A market-based supply-side approach is a long-run approach to achieving price stability and often a rise in inflation requires an immediate policy response. Governments normally use contractionary fiscal and monetary policy to achieve this. • Reducing inflation using a market-based approach can have negative consequences in terms of inequality, workers’ rights and increased foreign competition. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8 Unit 3.7(2) Interventionist supply-side policies What you should know by the end of this chapter: • • • • • Explanation of interventionist supply-side policies Types of interventionist supply-side policies include education and training, access to healthcare, research and development, provision of infrastructure and industrial policies How interventionist supply-side policies increase long-run aggregate supply and the production possibility curve The application of interventionist supply-side policies to increase long-run economic growth, reduce unemployment and achieve price stability Evaluation of interventionist supply-side policies What are interventionist supply-side policies? An interventionist supply-side policy is where the government becomes more actively involved on the supply side of the economy to achieve its macroeconomic objectives. Diagram 3.46 shows how the application of interventionist supply-side policies can increase the long-run aggregate supply curve from LRAS to LRAS1 through, for example, government investment in infrastructure. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 1 Methods of supply-side intervention to increase long-run economic growth The following methods are used as part of interventionist supply-side policies that can increase potential output in the economy and cause the production possibility curve in diagram 3.47 to increase from PPC to PPC1 increasing the potential output. Education and training Education is a crucial part of government intervention in the economy as an interventionist supplyside policy because it affects the productive potential of the labour force. This is also true of government-provided and funded training schemes. More skilled workers can achieve higher levels of productivity in their work which increases the overall productivity of the economy and increases potential output. Healthcare State involvement in healthcare is important in a similar way to education. A healthy population is likely to be more productive in employment because employees are less likely to be absent from work. In addition, physically and mentally healthier workers are likely to be more efficient when they are doing their jobs. There is also the effect of health on families where family members have to be carers when there is no effective healthcare. Family members who become carers are either taken away from the labour market or their productivity at work is reduced. Many governments invest a high proportion of their total expenditure in healthcare services to make sure the population has access to high-quality, low cost or free healthcare. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 2 Infrastructure State provision and funding for effective infrastructure is crucial to the supply side of the economy. Infrastructure is the capital and systems that support the overall functioning of a country's economy. Infrastructure can be in the following forms: • Transport systems like roads, bridges, ports, airports and rail services • Utility provision in the form of electricity, gas and water supplies • Communication networks such as mobile communications, broadband, digital services and postal services. Countries where governments have provided well-funded and planned infrastructure create the conditions for long-term economic growth. Good infrastructure means businesses can achieve higher levels of productivity, communicate efficiently, easily move their goods around and effectively access labour. Research and development Governments often use a supply-side approach to facilitate innovation and the development of new technology. This can be done through grants, subsidies and tax incentives for research and development. Innovation in production systems is very important in leading long-run economic growth on the supply side. Many economists regard government support for the development of information technology and communications as important in providing the conditions for significant advances on the supply side leading to long-term economic growth. For example, many governments are now providing large-scale support for the development of renewable energy to make economic growth more sustainable. Industrial policies As part of an interventionist, supply-side policy governments can use a targeted industrial policy as a strategic approach to certain industries to achieve long-run economic growth. Governments often try to change the structure of production in the economy and target industries that are the most likely to facilitate economic growth. For example, China and South Korea used a set of industrial policies in the 1980s and 1990s to focus on their manufacturing sectors so they could target growing export markets. The government are now looking to use industrial policies to support industries involved in artificial intelligence, robotics and automated vehicles. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 3 Evaluation of interventionist supply side to increase economic growth Strengths • Interventionist supply-side policies to increase economic growth can be targeted at areas of the economy in a way demand-side policies cannot. For example, demand-side policies cannot effectively deal with the problem of a shortage of skilled labour that is holding back economic growth, but a training and education policy can. • Expansionary monetary and fiscal policy used to increase economic growth often have the trade-off of increasing the rate of inflation. Supply-side policies do not have this as a disadvantage and can even lead to lower prices in certain sectors of the economy. • Demand-side policies increase the actual rate of economic growth whereas interventionist supply-side policies increase potential growth which is more likely to deliver economic growth in the long run. • There can be significant social benefits associated with an interventionist approach to increasing economic growth. Improving the provision and quality of healthcare and education brings with it external benefits and enhanced economic development as well as economic growth. Weaknesses • Interventionist policies can come at a significant opportunity cost to the government in terms of government expenditure in other areas and also the increased tax revenue needed to fund the policy. • Government intervention is often criticised for inefficiency and bureaucracy. State-managed enterprises and services often suffer from diseconomies of scale which reduces their efficiency. • All government involvement in the economy is subject to some political influence which might conflict with the economic benefits of the supply-side policy. For example, a government might provide funding for infrastructure projects in an area of the country where it needs to encourage support from voters. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 4 Methods of supply-side intervention to reduce unemployment Many of the policies used to achieve economic growth may also create employment, but there are also interventionist supply-side policies that are aimed specifically at reducing unemployment. Education and training Governments often use education and training to reduce structural unemployment. Where workers need to re-skill to find work, government-funded and managed training schemes can support unemployed workers as they try to transfer to new types of employment. Trade protectionism Country’s sometimes resort to trade barriers to reduce foreign competition for domestic firms which protects domestic employment. This has been a key policy of Donald Trump’s administration. The US government has used tariffs on many manufactured goods such as steel and cars to try and protect American workers. Employment agency Government-financed and run employment agencies to improve information flows in the labour market can particularly target frictional unemployment, although it can reduce all types of unemployment. Many government services in this area take place through the internet. For example, the Indian government has an employment service portal where potential employees can register for work and be matched with potential employers. Direct government employment Governments can try to reduce unemployment by directly employing workers in the public sector. This can be in state-owned and managed enterprises such as transport, postal services and healthcare. For example, over 40 per cent of China's and Russia’s working populations are employed by the state. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 5 Employment subsidies Employment subsidies involve the state paying part of the wages of workers employed by private-sector employers. This reduces the cost for firms of taking on employees and acts as an incentive for them to take on new workers. The impact of a wage subsidy is shown in diagram 3.47(1). The subsidy paid by the government in the labour market cause the labour supply curve to shift from SL to SL1. For businesses, this reduces the cost of employing workers and leads to an increase in employment from QL to QL1. The German government, for example, operates a scheme called Kurzarbeit. This is an employee subsidy scheme where the government pays up to 60 per cent of the wages of a worker who has had their working hours reduced. This means workers are not made redundant but employed on fewer hours by their employer. This subsidy prevents unemployment from rising in a recession and was used extensively during the recession in Germany caused by the Covid19 pandemic. Evaluation of interventionist supply side to reduce unemployment Strengths • Interventionist supply-side policies are effective at specifically targeting frictional and structural unemployment. Training and education and employment agencies are particularly good at doing this. • Supply-side policies can also have some impact on demand deficient unemployment in a recession. Employment subsidies and direct state employment can be used to target certain sectors of the economy when there is a recession. Weaknesses • Government training and employment agencies cost money to set up and operate and represent an opportunity cost in terms of other areas of government expenditure. • Government training schemes and employment agencies also cost money and can be bureaucratic and inefficient. • Trade protectionism often leads to retaliation from other countries so protecting jobs in one industry can lead to unemployment in another. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 6 • Employment subsidies cost the government money and can be abused by employers who take on workers with the subsidy rather than paying workers themselves. • On their own, interventionist supply-side struggle to deal with a significant rise in unemployment caused by a recession. Methods of intervention to reduce inflation Incomes policy An incomes policy involves the government setting a limit on wage increases to try and break a wage-price spiral. Diagram 3.48 shows how the application of an incomes policy reduces the rate at which short-run aggregate supply falls when there is cost-push inflation. With the incomes policy, SRAS only shift to SRAS1 rather than SRAS2 and the price level only reaches P1 rather than P2. This approach reduces the impact of cost-push inflation. Evaluation of interventionist supply side to reduce inflation Strengths • Incomes and price controls can be used to directly target cost-push inflation in a way monetary and fiscal policy cannot. • One of the main problems of applying contractionary fiscal and monetary policy is the way both policies reduce aggregate demand and economic growth. Interventionist supply-side policies do not reduce aggregate demand in the same way. Weaknesses • Controlling wages increases to workers when there is high inflation can reduce real incomes and can lead to poverty. • An incomes policy can lead to conflict and unrest where workers take industrial action such as going on strike because they cannot get a wage rise to cover inflation. • Firms can find their way around wage controls by changing job titles or offering fringe benefits like company cars. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 7 • Wage restrictions distort the operation of the labour market and can lead to labour shortages. • Firms can find their way around the price controls by changing the goods they sell such as altering the size or name of a product they sell. • Maximum prices distort the operation of the goods market leading to shortages and parallel markets. © Alex Smith InThinking www.thinkib.net/Economics 8