Chapter Five APPLYING CONSUMER THEORY 1 Topics 1. Deriving Demand Curves 2. Effects of Changes in Income 3. Effects of a price change: Income and Substitution Effects 4. Cost-of-Living Adjustments 5. Labor Supply Curves 5-2 Deriving Demand Curve We will see how an individual demand curve is derived from the utility maximization problem. •Price Changes – Using the figures developed in the previous chapter, the impact of a change in the price of food can be illustrated using indifference curves – For each price change, we can determine how much of the good the individual would purchase given their budget lines and indifference curves 3 Deriving Demand Curve •To derive an individual demand curve from the utility maximization problem, consider the following situation. •Initial price of food: $2 •Price of clothing : $2 •The consumer’s income: $20 •Given those prices and income, the consumer’s utility maximizing consumption bundle is F=4 and C=6. 4 Deriving Demand Curve Clothing Assume: • I = $20 • PC = $2 • PF = $2, $1, $0.50 10 A 6 U1 5 Each price leads to different amounts of food purchased D B 4 U3 Figure 1 U2 4 12 20 Food (units per month) 5 Deriving Demand Curve By changing prices and showing what the consumer will purchase, we can create a demand schedule and demand curve for the individual From the example: Demand Schedule P Q $2.00 4 $1.00 12 $0.50 20 6 Deriving Demand Curve Price of Food Individual Demand relates the quantity of a good that a consumer will buy to the price of that good. E $2.00 G $1.00 Demand Curve Figure 2 $.50 H 4 12 20 Food (units per month) 7 Demand Curves The utility maximizing quantity as a function of prices and income is called the “demand function”. The utility maximizing quantity for food is a function of the price of food, income, and possibly the price of clothing. In the same way, the utility maximizing quantity for clothing is a function of the prices of clothing, food and income. The individual demand curve can be seen as the graph of the demand function for the own price, holding other variables constant. ◦ For example, the demand curve for food is the plot of quantity demanded against the price of food, holding the price of clothing and income constant. 8 Effect of a Price Change Price of Food When the price falls, Pf /Pc & |MRS| also fall E $2.00 • E: Pf /Pc = 2/2 = 1 = |MRS| • G: Pf /Pc = 1/2 = .5 = |MRS| • H:Pf /Pc = .5/2 = .25 =|MRS| G $1.00 $.50 H 4 12 20 Demand Curve Food (units per month) 9 Demand Curves – Important Properties The level of utility that can be attained changes as we move along the curve At every point on the demand curve, the consumer is maximizing utility by satisfying the condition that the |MRS| of food for clothing equals the ratio of the prices of food and clothing (|MRS|=PF/PC) 10 Deriving the demand curve from utility maximization problem [Exercise] Suppose the utility function for a consumer is given by U(x,y) = xy The budget for this consumer is $100 Let Px and Py be the prices of x and y respectively. Find the demand function (the equation for the demand curves) for x and y. 11 Effect of a Price Change Clothing 10 A 6 U1 5 D B 4 U3 The Price-Consumption Curve traces out the utility maximizing market basket for each price of food. Notice that when price of food changes, the quantity demanded for clothing can also change. This is because, if price of food changes, the purchasing power of income changes. For example, if price of food decreases, the ability to purchase both goods increases. U2 4 12 20 Food (units per month) 12 Substitutes & Complements Whether two goods are substitutes or complements can be inferred from the price-consumption curve. If the price consumption curve is downward-sloping, the two goods are considered substitutes. If the price consumption curve is upward-sloping, the two goods are considered complements They could be both. 13 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities Income Changes ◦ As already discussed changing income, with prices fixed, causes consumers to change their market baskets ◦ Three ways in which we can represent the relationship between Income and Quantity Demanded 14 Effects of Income Changes Assume: Pf = $1, Pc = $2 I = $10, $20, $30 Clothing (units per month) 7 D 5 U3 An increase in income, with the prices fixed, causes consumers to alter their choice of market basket. U2 B 3 U1 A 4 10 16 Food (units per month) 15 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities Income Changes ◦ The income-consumption curve traces out the utilitymaximizing combinations of food and clothing associated with every income level 16 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities Income Changes ◦ An increase in income shifts the budget line to the right, increasing consumption along the incomeconsumption curve ◦ Simultaneously, the increase in income shifts the demand curve to the right 17 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities Clothing (units per month) Income Consumption Curve 7 D 5 U2 U3 If income increases and prices are held constant, then budget line will shift outward in a parallel fashion, and the utility maximizing combination of goods changes. Then an incomeconsumption curve traces out the utility-maximization combinations of goods with every income level. B 3 U1 A 4 10 16 Food (units per month) 18 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities Price of food E $1.00 G H D3 D2 An increase in income, from $10 to $20 to $30, with the prices fixed, shifts the consumer’s demand curve to the right as well. Notice in this case, income consumption curve is upward sloping. This means that consumption of both goods increases as income increases. D1 4 10 16 Food (units per month) 19 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities •Engel Curves – A curve that shows the relationship between the quantity demanded of a single good and income, holding prices constant – The Engel curve is derived from the income consumption cure. – If the good is a normal good, the Engel curve is upward sloping – If the good is an inferior good, the Engel curve is downward sloping 20 Engel Curves Income 30 ($ per month) Engel curves slope upward for normal goods. 20 10 4 8 12 16 Food (units per month) 21 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities. Formally, Q %Q Q Y Q x %Y Y Y Q Y ◦ where Y stands for income. Example ◦ If a 1% increase in income results in a 3% decrease in quantity demanded, the income elasticity of demand is x = -3%/1% = -3. 5-22 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities Normal goods versus inferior goods oInferior goods: goods whose quantity demanded falls as income increases. oNormal goods: goods whose quantity demanded increases as income increases. Among normal goods, we can also distinguish “necessities” whose quantity demanded rises at a slower rate than income, and “luxuries” whose quantity demanded rises at a faster rate than income. 23 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities Income Changes ◦ Shape of the ICC for two goods tells us the sign of the income elasticities: whether income elasticities for those goods are positive or negative ◦ When the income-consumption curve has a positive slope: ◦ The quantity demanded increases with income ◦ The income elasticity of demand is positive ◦ The good is a normal good 24 Consumer Theory and Income Elasticities Income Changes ◦ When the income-consumption curve has a negative slope: ◦ The quantity demanded decreases with income ◦ The income elasticity of demand is negative ◦ The good is an inferior good 25 Housing, Square feet per year Income-Consumption Curves and Income Elasticities Food inferior, housing normal L2 ICC 1 a Food normal, housing normal ICC 2 As income rises the budget constraint shifts to the right. ◦ The income elasticities depend on…. ◦ …where on the new budget constraint the new optimal consumption bundle will be b L1 e c ICC 3 Food normal, housing inferior I Food, Pounds per year 5-26 When Gail was poor and her income increased.. (a) Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints All other goods per year A Good That Is Both Inferior and Normal Y3 L3 Y2 ◦ ….she bought less hamburger and more steak. e3 1 Y1 L I3 e2 ◦ …she bought more hamburger e1 I2 I1 Hamburger per year (b) Engel Curve Y, Income But as she became wealthier and her income rose… Income-consumption curve L2 Y3 E3 Y2 E2 Engel curve Y1 E1 Hamburger per year 5-27 Solved Problem Mahdu views Cragmont and Canada Dry ginger ales as perfect substitutes: He is indifferent as to which one he drinks. The price of a 12-ounce can of Cragmont, p, is less than the price of a 12-ounce can of Canada Dry, p*. What does Mahdu’s Engel curve for Cragmont ginger ale look like? How much does his weekly ginger ale budget have to rise for Mahdu to buy one more can of Cragmont ginger ale per week? 5-28 Solved Problem 5-29 Income and substitution effects 30 Income and Substitution Effects A change in the price of a good has two effects: ◦ Substitution Effect ◦ Income Effect 31 Income and Substitution Effects Substitution Effect ◦ Relative price of a good (PF/PC) changes when price changes (for example, PF). 32 Income and Substitution Effects Income Effect ◦ Consumers experience an increase in real purchasing power when the price of one good falls 33 Income and Substitution Effects Substitution Effect ◦ The substitution effect is the change in an item’s consumption associated with a change in the price of the item, with the level of utility held constant ◦ When the price of an item declines, the substitution effect always leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of the good 34 Income and Substitution Effects Income Effect ◦ The income effect is the change in an item’s consumption brought about by the increase in purchasing power, with the price of the item held constant (new budget line) ◦ When a person’s income increases, the quantity demanded for the product may increase or decrease depending whether it’s a normal or inferior good. 35 Income and Substitution Effects •Income Effect –For a normal good, the income effect is positive. In other words, an increase in income causes an increase in demand, and a decrease in income causes a decrease in demand. –For an inferior good, the income effect is negative. In other words, an increase in income causes a decrease in demand, and a decrease in income causes an increase in demand. 36 5-37 5-38 5-39 5-40 D, Movie DVDs, Units per year Substitution and Income Effects with Normal Goods Initial Values P2 = price of DVDs = $20 P1 = price of CDs = $15 Y = Income = $300. Budget Line, L 15 L1 P1 q1 q2 = P2 $300 - $15 q q2 = $20 1 $20 Y P2 e1 - I1 12 20 C, Music CDs Units peryear 5-41 ovie DVDs, Units per year Substitution and Income Effects with Normal Goods Initial Values D, P2 = price of DVDs = $20 P1 = price of CDs = $15 Y = Income = $300. Budget Line, L 15 L1 Y P2 q2 = L2 e2 e1 - P1 q1 P2 $300 - $15 $30 q q2 = $20 1 $20 I1 I2 6 12 Total effect = -6 20 Cq1, Music CDs Units per year P1 goes up… 5-42 Substitution and Income Effects with Normal Goods Initial Values PD = price of DVDs = $20 PC = price of CDs = $15 Y = Income = $300. D, Movie DVDs, Units per year What if we compensated Laura so she could afford the same utility she had before the price of CDs increased? L* ◦ In other words, how much income she would need to afford indifference curve I1, with the new price of CDs ($30) Budget Line, L PC C D= PD $300 - $30 C D= $20 $20 Y PD 15 L1 L2 e* - e1 e2 I1 I2 6 Income effect = -3 9 12 20 C, Music CDs Units peryear Substitution effect = -3 Total effect = -6 = Substitution Effect + Income Effect = -3 + (-3) 5-43 Income and Substitution Effects: Inferior Good Clothing (units per R month) Since food is an inferior good, the income effect is negative. However, the substitution effect is larger than the income effect. A B U2 D Substitution Effect O F1Total Effect U1 EIncome S Effect F2 T Food (units per month) 44 Income and Substitution Effects A Special Case: The Giffen Good ◦ a special type of inferior good ◦ The negative income effect may theoretically be large enough to cause the demand curve for a good to slope upward to overpower the positive substitution effect so that a fall in price causes an decrease in quantity demanded, in other words cause the demand curve for a good to slope upward! 45 Basketball, Tickets per year Giffen Good When the price of movie tickets decreases the budget constraint rotates out… L2 e2 L1 I2 e1 Total effect allowing the consumer to increase her utility. I1 Movies, Tickets per year Nevertheless, the total effect is negative. WHY? 5-46 Even though the substitution effect is positive…. Basketball, Tickets per year Giffen Good L2 ◦ …the income effect is larger and negative (since this is an inferior good). e2 L1 I2 L* e1 e* Total effect Substitution effect I1 Movies, Tickets per year Income effect 5-47 Homer Simpson, our representative consumer, consumes varying amounts of beer and pork rinds. Assume that B = quantity of beer consumed, and that R = quantity of pork rinds consumed. Homer’s utility function is given as: Assume further that the price of beer is $4, the price of pork rinds is $2, and that Homer’s income is $200. a)Find the optimal bundle for Homer. Now assume that the price of Pork increases from $2 to $4 b)Find Homer’s new optimal bundle c)What is the income and the substitution effect in part (b) d)What if the price of pork rinds goes up, but the government offers to compensate Homer for this loss of purchasing power. That is, Mayor Quimby offers to mail Homer a check, in an effort to keep Homer from feeling worse off. Homer still faces the higher pork rinds price, but doesn’t experience a change in utility. That is, for Homer to be no worse off after the price increase, the government check must be large enough to keep Homer on his original indifference curve as in part (a). By how much should the government compensate him? 5-48 Income and Substitution Effects We have already discussed that a price change has two effects: (If the price of good 1 falls) •Substitution Effect: Consumers will tend to buy more of the good that has become cheaper (good 1), and less of the good that has become relatively more expensive (good 2). •Income Effect: Because good 1 is cheaper, consumers enjoy an increase in real purchasing power. The trade-off between goods 1 and 2 has changed; another way to say this is that the relative prices have changed. 5-49 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) •Recall is the opportunity cost of good 1 in terms of good 2. •With old (original) prices p1=p2=$2, then you have to give up 1 unit of good 2 to get one more unit of good 1. (Same for good 2) •With the new prices p1=$1, then ; you only have to give up ½ unit of good 2 to get an additional unit of good 1 (So good 1 is now relatively cheaper). On the other hand so that you have to give up 2 units of good 1 to get an additional unit of good 2. Good 2 is relatively more expensive now, even though p2 has not changed 5-50 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) Good 2 m/p2 U’ U x1 m/p1 x’1 m/p’1 Good 1 5-51 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) •Originally, m=$20, p1= $2, p2=$2. If Cobb-Douglass preferences such that U=X1 ½ X2 ½, then from util max, we have X1*= 0.5m/p1 and X2*= 0.5m/p2 , so optimal bundle is X1*=5, X2*=5, bundle costs $20, and utility achieved =5½ 5½ =5. •If p1 falls so p1’=$1, then original bundle now costs only (5) ($1) + (5) ($2) = $15 •Fall in p1 has increased purchasing power (has $5 “extra” to potentially buy more of each good •Trade-off between good 1 and good 2 has changed because p1/p2 changed. 5-52 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) Back to numerical example: Now, p1=$1, p2=$2, m=$20 U(x1, x2) = x1 ½ x2 ½ X2 5 5 10 X1 then from util max, we have X1*= 0.5m/p1 and X2*= 0.5m/p2 , x1*=10, x2*=5 5-53 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) Numerically, how do we calculate the changes in demand due to the substitution effect and the income effect? When p1 falls from $2 to $1: The change in demand due to the substitution effect: p1 falls to p1’ p1 = $2 p1’=$1 p2 = $2 5-54 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) AB measures the change in demand due to the substitution effect. The slope of the original budget line is The slope of the intermediate budget is A B U’ For the intermediate budget constraint, we let the ratio of prices change (from 1 to 1/2) and we find the optimal bundle that gives the same utility as the original bundle. 5-55 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) •Recall: •At the original bundle “A”: •To calculate the new bundle “B” for the substitution effect, we use the following two conditions: •where is the utility achieved by the original optimal bundle “A”. This is the expenditure min problem!!! 5-56 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) •So the two conditions become •Solve for 1 and 2: x1**= x2**= (This is bundle “B”) •The income required to buy “B” (i.e. the income for the intermediate budget constraint is: •($1) (7.1) + ($2)(3.54) = $14.1 p1 x1** p2 x2** 5-57 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) Original bundle A: (x1, x2) = (5, 5) Substitution effect: Bundle B: (x1, x2) = (7.1, 3.54) Change in demand due to the substitution effect 5-58 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) X2 Red: Original BL Purple: Intermediate BL A C B 5 7.1 10 X1 To calculate the change in dd due to the income effect: BC shows the change in the dd for x1 due to the income effect. Going from the intermediate budget ($14) to the final budget ($20) represents an increase in “income” Δ m > 0 5-59 Income and Substitution Effects (numerical example) The change in demand due to the income effect: BC Bundle B: (x1, x2) = (7.1, 3.54) C: (x1, x2) = (10, 5) Δx1n = 10-7.1 = 2.9 All together: n Δx1 + Δx = 1 Total change due to p1 change Change in x1 due to the substitution effect Change in x1 due to the income effect 5-60 Cost of Living Adjustments 61 Inflation Indexes How accurately government measures inflation? Inflation - the increase in the overall price level over time. ◦ nominal price - the actual price of a good. ◦ real price - the price adjusted for inflation. How do we adjust for inflation to calculate the real price? 5-62 Inflation Indexes (cont.) Consumer Price Index (CPI) – measure the cost of a standard bundle of goods for use in comparing prices over time. ◦ We can use the CPI to calculate the real price of a hamburger over time. ◦ In terms of 2008 dollars, the real price of a hamburger in 1955 was: CPI for 2008 211.1 price of a burger 15 1.18 CPI for 1955 26.8 5-63 Cost-of-Living Indexes Long term contracts and government programs include COLAs which raise incomes in proportion to an index of inflation (e.g. salaries, pensions, social security payments etc) The CPI is calculated each year as the ratio of the cost of a typical bundle of consumer goods and services today in comparison to the cost during a base period. What you do in Intro Econ to calculate the CPI is: The amount of money at current year prices that an individual requires to purchase the bundle of goods and services that was chosen in the base year divided by the cost of purchasing the same bundle at base year prices. Slide 64 Let’s think Suppose in 2010, income is $80, food costs $5/unit and clothing costs $5/unit. If preferences are represented by the Cobb-Douglass utility function u(F,C) =F1/2C1/2. Then in 2010, the optimal bundle is F=8 and C=8. In 2015, food costs $6/unit and clothing costs $24/unit. a. Calculate the CPI (the way you do in Principles of Econ). b. If income is adjusted according to the CPI, what is the new income? What is the new optimal bundle? c. Does the CPI “do the job” correctly, i.e. does it make people as well off as they were before the price change? 5-65 Cost-of-Living Indexes What Do You Think? ◦ Does the CPI accurately reflect the cost of living for retirees? ◦ Is it appropriate to use the CPI as a cost-of-living index for other government programs, for private union pensions, and for other private wage agreements? Slide 66 Cost-of-Living Indexes Example ◦ Two sisters, Rachel and Sarah, have identical preferences. ◦ Sarah began college in 1990 with a $500 discretionary budget. ◦ In 2000, Rachel started college and her parents promised her a budget that was equivalent in purchasing power. Slide 67 Cost-of-Living Indexes 1990 (Sarah) 2000 (Rachel) Price of books $20/book $100/book Number of books 15 ? Price of food $2.00/lb. $2.20/lb Pounds of food 100 ? Expenditure $500 ? Slide 68 How much do we compensate Rachel? •Price indexes, like the CPI, use a fixed consumption bundle in the base period. – Called a Laspeyres price index •Suppose we give Rachel enough money in 2000 to buy the same bundle Sarah bought in 1990. That would be: $1,720 =100 x 2.20 + 15 x $100 But will Rachel buy the same quantities of goods as her older sister? 5-69 Cost-of-Living Indexes Books (per quarter) Using the Laspeyres index results in the budget line shifting up from I2 to I3. U1 25 20 A 15 C 10 Sarah bought bundle A. If the parents gave enough money to buy the same bundle, Rachel would buy bundle C L3 5 L2 L1 0 50 100 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 550 600 Slide 70 Food (lb./quarter) •The budget with the Laspeyres income adjustment passes through bundle A but has a different slope (the same bundle is affordable at both sets of prices). •But Rachel won’t buy the same bundle as her sister. She would buy bundle C (to equate MRS=MRT). •This puts Rachel on a higher indifference curve than her older sister. •The Laspeyres income adjustment OVERCOMPENSATES because it gives higher utility in the current period than base period. 5-71 Cost-of-Living Indexes The ideal cost of living index represents the cost of attaining a given level of utility at current (2000) prices relative to the cost of attaining the same utility at base (1990) prices. Slide 72 Cost-of-Living Indexes Books (per quarter) 25 For Rachel to achieve the same level of utility as Sarah, with the higher prices, her budget must be sufficient to allow her to consume the bundle shown by point B. U1 20 A 15 10 B 5 L2 L1 0 50 100 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 550 600 Slide 73 Food (lb./quarter) IDEAL Cost-of-Living Indexes Price of books 1990 (Sarah) Bundle A $20/book 2000 (Rachel) Bundle B $100/book Number of books 15 6 Price of food $2.00/lb. $2.20/lb Pounds of food 100 300 Expenditure $500 $1,260 Slide 74 Cost-of-Living Indexes Sarah’ Expenditure (at bundle “A”) $500 = 100 lbs. of food x $2.00/lb. + 15 books x $20/book Rachel’ Expenditure for Equal Utility (at “B”) $1,260 = 300 lbs. of food x $2.20/lb. + 6 books x $100/book Slide 75 Cost-of-Living Indexes The ideal cost-of-living adjustment for Rachel is $760. The ideal cost-of-living index is $1,260/$500 = 2.52 or 252. This implies a 152% increase in the cost of living. Slide 76 Cost-of-Living Indexes To do this on an economy-wide basis would entail large amounts of information. Price indexes, like the CPI, use a fixed consumption bundle in the base period. ◦ Called a Laspeyres price index Slide 77 Cost-of-Living Indexes Laspeyres Index The Laspeyres index tells us: ◦ The amount of money at current year prices that an individual requires to purchase the bundle of goods and services that was chosen in the base year divided by the cost of purchasing the same bundle at base year prices. Slide 78 Cost-of-Living Indexes Calculating Rachel’s Laspeyres cost of living index ◦ Setting the quantities of goods in 2000 equal to what were bought by her sister, but setting their prices at their 2000 levels result in an expenditure of $1,720 (100 x 2.20 + 15 x $100) Slide 79 Cost-of-Living Indexes Her cost of living adjustment would now be $1,220. The Laspeyres index is: $1,720/$500 = 344. This overstates the true cost-of-living increase. Slide 80 Cost-of-Living Indexes What Do You Think? ◦ Does the Laspeyres index always overstate the true cost-ofliving index? Slide 81 Cost-of-Living Indexes Yes! ◦ The Laspeyres index assumes that consumers do not alter their consumption patterns as prices change. Slide 82 Cost-of-Living Indexes Yes! ◦ By increasing purchases of those items that have become relatively cheaper, and decreasing purchases of the relatively more expensive items consumers can achieve the same level of utility without having to consume the same bundle of goods. Slide 83 Cost-of-Living Indexes The Paasche Index ◦ Calculates the amount of money at current-year prices that an individual requires to purchase a current bundle of goods and services divided by the cost of purchasing the same bundle in the base year. Slide 84 Cost-of-Living Indexes Comparing the Two Indexes •Both indexes involve ratios that involve today’s current year prices, PFt and PCt and base year prices PFb and PCb •However, the Laspeyres index relies on base year consumption, Fb and Cb. •Whereas, the Paasche index relies on today’s current consumption, Ft and Ct . Slide 85 Cost-of-Living Indexes Comparing the Two Indexes Let: ◦ PFt & PCt be current year prices ◦ PFb & PCb be base year prices ◦ Ft & Ct be current year quantities ◦ Fb & Cb be base year quantities Slide 86 Cost-of-Living Indexes Then a comparison of the Laspeyres and Paasche indexes gives the following equations: Slide 87 Cost-of-Living Indexes Comparing the Two Indexes Sarah (1990) Slide 88 Cost-of-Living Indexes The Paasche Index Sarah (1990) ◦ Cost of buying current year bundle at current year prices is $1,260 (300 lbs x $2.20/lb + 6 books x $100/book) ◦ Cost of the same bundle at base year prices is $720 (300 lbs x $2/lb + 6 books x $20/book) Slide 89 Cost-of-Living Indexes Sarah (1990) Comparing the Two Indexes Slide 90 Cost-of-Living Indexes The Paasche Index The Paasche index will understate the cost of living because it assumes that the individual will buy the current year bundle in the base year. Slide 91 Deriving Labor Supply Curves Previously, we used concepts like indifference curves, budget constraints and consumer equilibria to study the individual’s demand for goods We can also apply the consumer theory model to derive the supply curve of labor As the name implies, the two goods we will look at are consumption and leisure. We will continue to make the same preference assumptions we used before. We do so by using consumer theory to obtain a demand curve for leisure time and then using the demand curve to derive the supply curve of hours spent working Deriving Labor Supply Curves People choose between working to earn money to buy goods and services and consuming leisure: all their time spent not working for pay Jackie spends her total income, Y on various goods. For simplicity assume that the price of these goods is $1 per unit, so she buys Y goods Her utility, U, depends on how many goods, Y, and how much leisure, N, he consumes Labor-Leisure Choice Income can vary depending on how much the individual works. Instead, the individual is constrained by her time endowment, T, usually 24 hours (but we can make it less). Leisure - all time spent not working. Labor plus Leisure is always equal to the time endowment. The number of hours worked per day, H, equals 24 minus the hours of leisure or nonwork, N, in a day: H = 24 − N. 5-94 Labor-Leisure Choice: Example Jackie spends her total income, Y, on various goods. ◦ The price of these goods is $1 per unit. Her utility, U, depends on how many goods and how much leisure she consumes: U = U(Y, N). Jackie’s earned income (his wage times the number of hours he works) equal: wH. And her total income, Y, is her earned income plus her unearned income, Y* (such as from an inheritance or a gift from his parents): Y = wH + Y*. 5-95 Labor-Leisure Choice: Example Using consumer theory, we can determine Jackie’s demand curve for leisure once we know the price of leisure The wage, w, is the cost: what you would have earned from an hour’s work: the price of leisure is forgone earnings The higher the wage, the more an hour of leisure costs you The wage rate, w, is measured in $/hour. Y, Goods per day (a) Indifference Curves and Constraints Demand for Leisure Time constraint I1 Budget Line, L1 L1 –w1 Y = w1H Each extra hour of leisure she consumes costs her w1 goods. Y1 0 24 e1 N1 = 16 H1 = 8 24 0 N, Leisure hours per day H, Work hours per day (b) Demand Curve w, Wage per hour Y = w1(24 − N). 1 E1 w1 0 N1 = 16 H1 = 8 N, Leisure hours per day H, Work hours per day 5-97 Labor-Leisure Choice: Example We can solve this problem using calculus Jackie maximizes her utility subject to the time constraint and the income constraint By using the chain rule of differentiation, we find that the first-order condition for an interior maximum to the problem is: Y, Goods per day (a) Indifference Curves and Constraints Demand for Leisure L2 –w2 I1 1 e2 Y2 Budget Line, L1 Y = w1 H Y = w1(24 − N). L1 –w1 1 w 2 > w1 N2 = 12 H2 = 12 N1 = 16 H1 = 8 24 0 N, Leisure hours per day H, Work hours per day (b) Demand Curve w, Wage per hour Y = w2 H Y = w2(24 − N). e1 Y1 0 24 Budget Line, L2 Time constraint I2 E2 w2 E1 w1 Demand for leisure 0 N2 = 12 H2 = 12 N1 = 16 H1 = 8 N, Leisure hours per day H, Work hours per day 5-99 Labor-Leisure Choice: Example By subtracting Jackie’s demand for leisure at each wage - her demand curve for leisure - we construct her labor supply curve the hours she is willing to work as a function of the wage, H(w) Her supply curve for hours worked is the mirror image of the demand curve for leisure: For every extra hour of leisure that Jackie consumes, she works one hour less Supply Curve of Labor 5-101 Y, Goods per d ay Income and Substitution Effects of a Wage Change Time const raint I2 L2 Since income effect is positive, leisure is a normal good. I1 L* e2 e* L1 e1 0 N* 24 H* N1 N 2 H1 H2 24 N, Leisure hours per d ay 0 H, Work hours per d ay Substitution effect Total effect Income effect 5-102 Solved Problem Enrico receives a no-strings-attached scholarship that pays him an extra Y* per day. How does this scholarship affect the number of hours he wants to work? Does his utility increase? 5-103 Solved Problem 5-104 Income and Substitution Effects of a Wage Change We’ve seen that when the wage rate changes, leisure can increase or decrease depending on whether the income or substitution effects dominate. It could also be possible that at some wage rates the income effect dominates and at other wage rates the substitution effect dominates. It seems plausible that at low wage rates the substitution effect would dominate (upward sloping labor supply) and at high wage rates the income effect would dominate (downward sloping labor supply). If this were the case, the individuals labor supply curve would be backward bending. Labor Supply Curve That Slopes Upward and Then Bends Backward L3 (b) Supply Curve of Labor Time const raint I3 I2 I1 L2 E3 E2 e3 e2 E1 L1 24 Supply curve of labor w, Wage per hour Y, Goods per d ay (a) Labor-Leisure Choice e1 H2 H 3 H1 0 H, Work hours per d ay 0 H1 H3 H2 24 H, Work hours per d ay butlow At at high wages, wages, an increase an increase in the wage causes the worker worker to work to less…. work more…. 5-106