S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 43 2 Evaluation Issues in Peace Implementation Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. GEORGE DOWNS AND STEPHEN JOHN STEDMAN Compared to the formidable scholarly literature dealing with the problem of negotiating peace agreements in civil wars, the literature devoted to the problem of implementing peace agreements is modest. This is somewhat surprising, as it is painfully clear that the distance between a peace agreement and anything that warrants the term real peace is as large as the distance between the ideals expressed in the most ambitious domestic program and their concrete realization. Many more peace agreements are signed than are actually put into practice, and once signed, the stakes are often far higher. A large part of the explanation for why the literature on the implementation of peace agreements in civil wars is not more well developed is that it is difficult to think of an environment that is less conducive to the conduct of evaluation research. The number of cases is small and the measurements of potentially important variables, such as the military capability and political goals of different parties, are often unreliable. Implementation strategies tend to be poorly specified and no two are ever identical. Worse, there are literally dozens of contextual variables—ranging from the amount of international resources available to the United Nations, to the salience of a given conflict for international public opinion—that vary widely across cases and inevitably influence both the choice and the success of an implementation strategy. All of this leaves both the policymaker and the analyst continually uncertain about what a given strategy actually comprises, what would have occurred had a strategy not been employed (the counterfactual), and whether the superiority of one strategy over another reflects the greater merits of the first or the fact that the second strategy had to cope with a more demanding context. In the absence of systematic evaluation, however, our understanding of 43 Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 44 4:16 PM Page 44 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES what does and does not work in peace implementation is prey to any number of fallacies, many of which are brought about by a tendency to separate strategy and context. What works in Guatemala is expected to work in Bosnia, even though the cases differ dramatically in most key respects. Practitioners frequently attribute successful outcomes to their actions and strategies, and attribute failure to the implementation context. Critics, on the other hand, tend to focus on incorrect strategies as causes of failure and attribute success to context or outside factors. This chapter examines three issues associated with the implementation of peace agreements in civil wars. First, we describe some of the difficulties that plague estimating the success of individual operations and how the international system as a whole has performed to date. Second, we conduct a very modest determinants study in order to see which contextual variables are associated with implementation success as well as to describe the difficulties associated with such studies. Finally, we discuss the problems associated with determining and improving the relative effectiveness of different implementation strategies. As we shall see, this raises a host of sensitive issues, many of which are associated with the uncomfortable fact that the strategy and resources needed to succeed in some cases are unavailable because no major or regional power sees it in their interest to provide them. We argue that cases of peace implementation differ dramatically in terms of the difficulty of the implementation environment and in the willingness of international actors to provide necessary resources and troops. We find that three of the most important environmental variables in determining failure are (1) the presence of spoilers (factions or leaders who oppose the peace agreement and use violence to undermine it); (2) neighboring states that oppose the peace agreement and funnel resources to potential spoilers; and (3) the domestic availability of valuable, easily marketable commodities such as gems or timber. With regard to the importance of such commodities, no civil war peace agreement has been fully, successfully implemented where these are present. On the willingness side, we find that the most important variable in accounting for successful implementation is the extent to which a major or regional power defines a particular case as in its national security interest. Only when such interest is present has peace implementation succeeded against the opposing efforts of spoilers and hostile neighbors. Evidence suggests that in the absence of such major or regional power interest, the United Nations can only succeed in the least difficult environments. Estimating Effectiveness: Measuring Success The first step in evaluating institutional effectiveness is to develop some reliable way to measure implementation success. Traditionally, this prob- Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 45 EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 45 lem has been approached by developing one or more outcome indicators, each of which measures the extent to which a goal that is considered central to the operation’s success has been achieved. In this section we discuss various measures that have been used to evaluate successful peace implementation and describe their potential pitfalls. We begin by focusing on mandate achievement as a measure of success, and then turn to various objective indicators, such as resolution of the underlying conflict. The evaluation of subgoals such as human rights, elections, disarmament, and refugee repatriation as measures of implementation success is also discussed. Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. Mandate Achievement Until relatively recently, the most common indicator of operation success was the degree to which an operation achieved the goals that were laid out in the UN’s mandate authorizing the mission. The fact that mandate accomplishment is defined by the United Nations itself makes it “endogenous.” This endogeneity may seem attractive, as it protects the measure from criticism that it represents a goal that the agent being evaluated never intended to accomplish in the first place, but this is actually less of a virtue than it might first seem because it makes evaluation the prisoner of ambition. This creates two quite different problems. One is that it allows an institution to be successful by doing nothing more than lowering its goals or by setting very modest goals in the first place rather than by accomplishing something substantive. Agencies and institutions that have considerable autonomy with regard to goal setting but are nonetheless operating in a politically charged environment often do this, particularly when they believe that failure may impact their funding level or future mission.1 A common criticism of the Implementation Force (IFOR) in effecting the Dayton Peace Agreements stems from how the U.S. military limited its mission to separation of the warring armies in Bosnia, and refused to take on the more ambitious tasks necessary for creating peace: the capture of war criminals, the protection of refugees who sought to return home to disenfranchised areas, and the disarmament of the contending armies.2 It makes little sense to declare IFOR a success when its aspirations are so low. While it is sometimes possible for organizations to inflate their success rate by purposely minimizing performance goals, agencies with little autonomy with respect to goal setting suffer from precisely the opposite problem. The political masters of these agencies use them as scapegoats by offloading their responsibilities onto the institution in the form of ambitious goals that the political masters want to get credit for having, but avoid the blame for not achieving. This has been a recurrent problem for the United Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 46 4:16 PM Page 46 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES Nations in the 1990s as the Security Council and member states have repeatedly demanded that the institution pursue ambitious policies, such as safe havens in Bosnia, or state- and nation-building in Somalia, without providing the requisite resources to succeed. The member states and the Security Council garner symbolic value for proclaiming morally worthy goals, and are able to blame the organization when it fails to achieve them. In either of these instances, the evaluator reaches conclusions about the agency’s success that are uninformative. They provide next to no information about how well the institution performs the tasks that compose its mission relative to other institutions or its own past performance. Perhaps just as bad, using mandate performance as a measure of success keeps evaluators from asking questions about the appropriateness of the mandate, such as the extent to which the mandate is sensible given the institution’s resources—questions that are regularly asked in connection with the performance of economic and military strategy. Mandate accomplishment as a measure of success also creates comparability problems. We cannot overlook the possibility that a mission that is only partly successful in fulfilling an ambitious mandate nonetheless may generate benefits far higher than those brought about by a mission that is nominally more successful by fulfilling a weak mandate. For example, the UN Transitional Authority in Cambodia (UNTAC) has come under extensive criticism for failing to achieve all of the political, military, and economic goals of its ambitious mandate.3 But there can be little doubt that UNTAC accomplished substantially more than did the U.S. mission Operation Support Hope in Rwanda, which, while described by a former high-ranking general as a success based on its limited mandate,4 did nothing to prevent or reduce armed hostilities in Eastern Zaire—hostilities that eventually led to hundreds of thousands of deaths, refugees, and displaced persons, and an interstate war involving the armies of eight different African states. This problem of noncomparability in mandate accomplishment is only exacerbated by the fact that today’s peace operations vary substantially. Peace implementation can include a wide array of tasks. UN peacekeepers have been asked to disarm and demobilize warring troops and repatriate refugees in Cambodia, Mozambique, Guatemala, and Angola; reform legal institutions in El Salvador and Bosnia; investigate human rights abuses in Cambodia, Angola, and El Salvador; hold elections in El Salvador, Mozambique, Namibia, Cambodia, and elsewhere; and oversee truth commissions in El Salvador and Guatemala. In ongoing civil wars where the consent of the warring parties for intervention has been absent—Somalia, Liberia, and Sierra Leone—soldiers have been asked to enforce peace and create the conditions under which peace implementation can go forward. Among the other important limitations of mandate fulfillment as a measure of success is the fact that mandates are often strategically ambigu- Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 47 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 47 ous and that this calculated ambiguity increases with the complexity of the operation. Michael Doyle, Ian Johnstone, and Robert Orr argue that experience has taught the military planners connected with large, multidimensional peacekeeping operations to anticipate that the mission will unfold in ways that were not anticipated when the decision to undertake the mission was made: parties will renege on their agreements, the tasks of relocation or disarmament will prove more difficult to achieve, and so forth.5 In order to reserve the capacity to flexibly adapt to these changing conditions, planners want mandates to be more ambiguous than they might be in a simpler, more traditional mission. This is entirely sensible from the planner’s standpoint, but it makes it much more difficult for the researcher to confidently gauge the degree to which a given mission achieves its mandate. Finally, mandates for peace implementation missions in the 1990s have suffered from inflation of goals—goals that have been included in the mandate less for realistic calculation of possible accomplishment, than as a way of appeasing nongovernmental organizations and domestic public opinion. As the 1990s progressed, the lobbying of NGOs, especially those involved in human rights, pressured member states to include more and more subgoals in UN peace operation mandates. The inclusion of such goals as accountability for war crimes, de-mining, stopping the use of child soldiers, improving the plight of women in society, and protecting civilians has become a kind of humanitarian “pork,” with each NGO striving to ensure that its single issue is included in operation mandates. But given the large number of such goals in most peace implementation mandates, and given the limited resources to achieve such goals, implementers inevitably must make decisions about which subgoals are most important to their overriding task of implementing a peace agreement. Nor are all good things achievable in the short term of peace implementation, a problem we will return to shortly in discussing objective indicators of success. Other Measures of Success The limitations of mandate accomplishment as the sole measure of peace implementation success have led researchers to supplement it with other indicators. Marjorie Brown suggests two others: whether or not the operation led to a resolution of the underlying disputes of the conflict, and whether or not the operation reduced conflict in the area.6 Paul Diehl looks at whether the operation limited armed conflict and the extent to which the operation facilitated conflict resolution.7 Duane Bratt uses four indicators of success: mandate performance; the degree of conflict resolution; whether or not the operation kept conflict from spreading in the region; and the extent to which the operation reduced both military and civilian casualties below the rates that existed before the operation began.8 All of these measures of success possess the virtue of being less susceptible than mission Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 48 4:16 PM Page 48 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES mandate to the problem of endogeneity. They prevent a mission from being declared a success simply because its mandate required very little, or from being declared a failure because it failed to achieve overly ambitious goals, even if it produced significant benefits. The new measures rely less on ambition and more on the kind of tangible accomplishments that dominate estimates of success in most other fields. If a conflict widens and increasing numbers of lives are lost or, conversely, if three democratic elections take place in succession over five years, it will be reflected in the level of success that these measures assign to an operation. Of course, no outcome measure is without its limitations, and these newer and more objective indicators of success have their own problems. One of these has to do with the decision about how the indicators are combined into a scale. This can be done by assuming that the indicators are equally important or by weighing them in importance. The decision is up to the analyst, and the fact that different analysts will decide the issue differently means that estimates about the overall success or failure of a given program are likely to vary more than they would in the case of an individual measure of success such as mandate accomplishment. In addition, a given multiple indicator has its own internal comparability problems in that although two separate missions are assigned the same score, it is based on the achievement of different things. Thus, Bratt, for example, classifies an operation as being partially successful if it achieves any one of three different objectives.9 This raises the potential problem that two partial successes may be as unalike as they are alike, especially with respect to the resources and strategies that were necessary to achieve partial success in the two instances. Another difficulty involves the number and breadth of indicators that are included in the multiple measure. Currently, there is an understandable tendency to include indicators that the analyst believes best characterize the successful elimination of factors that resulted in conflict in the first place. For example, a study carried out by DFI for the Pentagon requires that a successful peace operation lead to economic stabilization as well as to the installation of a second democratically elected government.10 There is no doubt that a peace operation that produced economic stabilization and two democratically elected governments would be more successful than one that simply produced a ceasefire. It is also true that one that produced economic stabilization, a growth rate of 5 percent or better, and three actively contested democratic elections would be better still. By this logic, it follows that the best measure of success and the one that will lead to the most nuanced understanding of what different peacekeeping missions have accomplished is the one that contains the most complete list of conditions believed to prevent the outbreak of conflict and improve the quality of life in a state torn apart by civil war. Yet this is almost certainly not the case. One reason lies in the fact that the passage of time is the enemy of inference. The passage of time intro- Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 49 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 49 duces the equivalent of noise in the form of a growing number of influencing factors that are not directly associated with a peace mission. The more time that passes from the conclusion of a peace mission, the more likely it is that any number of other extraneous factors (e.g., business cycles, famines, unusually good or bad weather, the policies of a neighboring state, the behavior of the first elected leaders) are actually responsible for what has taken place rather than the technology of the peace mission itself. As the potential impact of such exogenous factors increases, the quality of our inferences about the contribution of the peace operation itself tends to fall until the inferences reach the point where they break down completely. This is one of the reasons why elementary school educators tend to measure teacher and school performance by indicators such as student reading and math scores rather than by student success in getting into the college of their choice, getting a good job, or having a happy marriage. It is not that the educators value a fourth-grade reading score more than they do the impact of a high-quality university education or professional and personal success; they just believe that any correlation between the quality of fourthgrade instruction and these outcomes is likely to be more spurious than real. Some performance indicators, especially those suggested by scholars of peacebuilding, run the further danger of setting such high standards of success that we are left with a world of undifferentiated failure. Exemplary of this pitfall is the work of Roland Paris, who argues that one should judge the success of UN peace operations in the 1990s by the standard of “creating conditions that will allow peace to endure long after the peacekeepers have left” and asserts that by this standard only one operation—Namibia— can be judged a success. 11 Correspondingly, the list of failures then includes not only unmitigated disasters such as Rwanda and Angola, but also operations where war has ended, such as Mozambique, El Salvador, Bosnia, and Nicaragua. By failing to discriminate between catastrophic failures such as Rwanda and Angola, where hundreds of thousands die, and flawed successes such as El Salvador, Cambodia, and Mozambique, where war has ended but citizens face the mundane reality of life in povertyridden insecurity, Paris holds evaluation hostage to an unreasonable standard of success and ensures that it will yield very little information that can be used to improve future missions. It is not that we should avoid striving to attain good things like economic growth, equitable development, and good governance; it is that these goals form a useless standard for evaluating implementation actions that take place in a short period of time. Subgoal Achievement Given the problematic character of summary evaluations, analysts engaged in the task of assessing peace implementation often change their focus from overall mission objectives to mission subgoals such as demobilization, Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 50 4:16 PM Page 50 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES human rights, and refugee repatriation because they are more manageable. They require less information because they represent only one small subroutine in a much larger program. They also promise more robustness because there are fewer dimensions that have to be matched to another case. That is, it is frequently more plausible to argue that the task of repatriation in two given states was more similar than was the overall task of peace implementation. There is a limit to the extent precision is possible, of course. The processes connected with subgoals like human rights, demobilization, or repatriation are never exactly the same in any two cases, and an insistence that every detail of two such processes be the same in every case would doom any attempt to formulate generalizations before it got off the ground. Perhaps a bigger danger lies in the fact that different subgoals interact and success in one area can affect success in another area. The importance of this interaction will be missed when analyzing subgoals in isolation. This can lead to any number of mistaken inferences. For example, Human Rights Watch not too surprisingly asserts that the failure to protect and further human rights in Angola best explains the UN’s failure to implement peace there.12 But as Tonya Putnam demonstrates in Chapter 9, the protection and furtherance of human rights during peace implementation rest completely on the ability of the implementers to persuade the warring parties to demobilize their soldiers and turn their armies into political parties. In the absence of progress in those subgoals, implementers have little chance to achieve higher standards of human rights. Moreover, much of what we have said above about mandate achievement applies to evaluation of subgoals. Again, to use the human rights example, the ability of peacekeepers to successfully pursue human rights during implementation differs greatly according to the conflict environment. Pursuing human rights in Somalia, for example, where there was no existing rule of law, no civil society, and no functioning state, and where spoilers sought to destroy the peace agreement, was much more difficult than pursuing human rights in El Salvador, where the two warring parties agreed to make reform of judiciary and police institutions a key aspect of the peace agreement. Operationalizing Success and Failure In this project we chose to operationalize mission success by scoring two variables: (1) whether large-scale violence is brought to an end while the implementers are present; and (2) whether the war is terminated on a selfenforcing basis so that the implementers can go home without fear of the war rekindling. We assessed each case of peace implementation by these measures and then further subjected the cases to an informal, counterfactual analysis about the specific contribution of the implementers to the result. If Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 51 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 51 the peacekeepers could not bring large-scale violence to a close, as in Rwanda, Angola, Somalia, or Sri Lanka, the mission was coded as a failure. If the peacekeepers brought the war to a close, but could not leave for fear of the war restarting, as in Bosnia, we coded the case as a partial success. If the peacekeepers brought the war to a close and departed without the war restarting in a two-year period, as in El Salvador, Mozambique, Guatemala, and Nicaragua, we coded the case as a success. We then went further to ask what would have occurred in the program’s absence. It is the difference between this score and what occurred in the presence of the program that represents a mission’s impact. It makes no sense to credit outside implementers with achieving something that would have happened anyway or to blame them for being ineffective when without their efforts the situation would have become far worse. In the absence of an estimate of the counterfactual, the researcher is implicitly assuming that it was the status quo at the time the mission was initiated: everything that happened after that is assumed to have been caused by the implementers. Because the task of estimating the counterfactual in an area where both theory and data are scarce is so difficult, analysts in new fields such as peace implementation tend to omit any reference to it, partly on the implicit grounds that any such estimate would be arbitrary and thus have little credibility anyway. This makes sense given the circumstances, but it risks introducing a significant upward bias in our estimate of how successful a given institution has been in addressing the problem assigned to it. To understand why, one must keep in mind that most large-scale institutional interventions take place in contexts where there is some sort of crisis, such as a recession or epidemic. In the absence of intervention some of these crises will grow increasingly worse (for example, the recession will turn into a depression), but more often than not the situation will eventually get better by itself or “regress to the mean” and the atypical state of affairs is replaced by the typical. Does the lack of counterfactual analysis lead us to credit peace operations too much or to denigrate them unnecessarily? An examination of the sixteen peace operations in this study led us to alter our initial evaluations of two cases. In the case of Liberia, which would have been coded as a success based on the criterion of ending the war on a self-sustaining basis, we downgraded it to a partial success on the basis of evidence that the actions of the implementers actually delayed resolution of the war. In the case of Cambodia, which would have been coded as a failure based on the criterion of having ended the violence, we upgraded it to a partial success because the country was much more secure when the peace operation was terminated, even though violence continued at low levels. Finally, a case could also be made that in three of the cases, Nicaragua, El Salvador, and Guatemala, the wars would have ended at some point in the 1990s without UN involve- Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 52 4:16 PM Page 52 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES ment in the implementation of the peace agreements; at best, the role of outside implementers was to hasten the end of wars whose termination was ordained by a changed international and regional context. In the end, we rejected reclassifying the cases as less than successes because we felt that by quickening what may have come about in any case, outsiders contributed to saving thousands of lives and helped stabilize the agreements. Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. Evaluating Overall Institutional Effectiveness Evaluation of how the United Nations and/or the international system as a whole have performed to date in peace implementation also suffers from vexing problems. For people who are not very interested in program evaluation, this may not seem too troubling. Can’t one simply pick the set of outcome indicators that one believes is the most informative, measure the extent to which success has been achieved in each implementation mission that has been undertaken, add them up and calculate the average performance measure on each indicator, and then either take the average score over all the indicators or weigh them as one thinks best? The answer is that this is a good place to start, but a potentially dangerous and poor place to stop because it tells us less about the overall success that the UN and the international system have had than one might first think and may be of little predictive value. Evaluation of institutional effectiveness must consider that some missions are more difficult and costly to conduct than others, and the UN is likely to have a lower success rate in these. For example, implementing peace accords in Cambodia, where the fighters grudgingly signed a peace agreement and had over 120,000 men-at-arms, was much more difficult and expensive than implementing peace accords in Guatemala, where the guerrillas were small in number (estimated between 1,500 and 3,000) and were substantially defeated. Ending the civil war in Somalia, where the state had collapsed, militias had proliferated, and none had consented to intervention, was a far more difficult mission than bringing peace to El Salvador, where the warring parties supported UN participation in implementing a settlement that emerged after several years of negotiations and no factions used violence to undermine the peace. The fact that the success rate will vary with the mix of variously difficult missions that are undertaken and that this mix has been changing over time means that any simple estimate of trends in the institution’s average effectiveness will be fundamentally ambiguous. If that estimate shows that the UN has become less effective over time, it may mean that the organization is not functioning as well as it once was, or it could just as easily mean that the organization is functioning better but the level of mission difficulty has increased at an even faster rate. Variance in the difficulty of missions causes the same problems when it comes to forecasting the likely success Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 53 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 53 of a mission that the UN is undertaking. Unless the future mission is neither more nor less difficult than the average mission, the forecast will be too high or too low. The connection between mission type and mission difficulty also means that the UN’s overall success rate may depend more on which operations it chooses to undertake than on the strategic decisions it makes about how to conduct its operations. In itself this fact is unremarkable; the history of warfare makes it clear that whom one chooses to fight is at least as important as how one conducts the subsequent war. One should be cautious about interpreting data about trends in UN peacekeeping effectiveness as measured by mission accomplishment unless the nature of the mission is controlled for—something that is difficult to do and rarely attempted. The impact of variation in the difficulty of missions that the UN or the international system chooses to undertake on its overall success rate raises the important related question of how we should deal with peace implementation opportunities that have been selected out by the UN; that is, cases that it has chosen to pass up for whatever reason (e.g., Sudan or Chechnya). This is an important issue that can make a dramatic difference in our estimate of overall success, but the boundaries of what is often referred to as the potential treatment population (i.e., the number used in the denominator of the fraction that represents the program’s success rate) are not always obvious and depend on the use to which the statistic will be put. For example, if we are trying to estimate the effectiveness or success of an employment program, does it make more sense to measure it by the percentage of people graduating from the program who have found jobs, the percentage of those entering the program who have found jobs, or the percentage of those eligible for the program who have participated, graduated, and found jobs? The people who operate the program would always prefer that the first measure be used because the smaller base rate will yield a higher percentage or rate of success. If the program is a pilot project being used to determine how well a certain type of program is likely to work if it is widely employed, the sponsors of those funding the project would find the second statistic the most appropriate because program dropouts represent program failures. If the program is a national one charged with the task of providing the unemployed with job training, voters would probably feel that the third statistic is the one that is important because the program is supposed to serve all of the unemployed, not just some of them. In the case of peace implementation, the standard approach is to look at the success rate of the operations that are undertaken, but the justification for adopting this approach seems largely one of convenience. It implicitly assumes that it makes sense to equate the mission of the United Nations with whatever it chooses to do, and that intervention opportunities that are declined have been declined for good reason. But it is likely that there are Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 54 4:16 PM Page 54 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES systematic selection effects at work. Research by Michael Gilligan and Stephen Stedman indicates that the United Nations intervenes much less in civil wars in Asia than it does in other regions, and that it avoids civil wars where the government possesses a large army.13 The UN Security Council will never authorize an operation in one of the permanent five member states of the Security Council; civil wars such as Chechnya will never be addressed. The Security Council is loath to authorize peace missions when there is an absence of consent by the warring parties. It is unlikely that the Security Council would intervene in a civil war in a regional power such as India without the consent of that power. Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. In Search of the Determinants of Success Having devised outcome measures that they understand even if they do not trust them completely, evaluators usually turn to the task of trying to identify contextual factors that explain the variation in institutional performance that they reveal. This is considerably more difficult than devising outcome measures, for any number of reasons: the number of cases is small and difficult to handle statistically; the measurement of potentially important variables, such as extent of state authority and the extent to which parties are genuinely committed to finding a peaceful solution to their conflict, is often difficult and unreliable; and interaction and selection effects create any number of interpretation problems. With respect to interaction, the impact of a given factor is likely to vary across types of missions. To use an obvious example, the commitment of resources that are likely to be present when one or more major powers are interested in having a conflict resolved is likely to be much more important in cases where the implementers attempt to enforce rather than monitor compliance. If we decide not to worry about this and plunge ahead and obtain a regression estimate of the impact of major power interest, that estimate will be determined by the mix of consensual and enforcement missions that has accumulated to that point. Any estimate of the average effect of major power interest will be systematically too high or too low depending on the nature of the mission. To come close to an accurate prediction we would need to either estimate the impact of major power interest separately on consensual and enforcement missions or have a term in our predictive equation that represented the interaction between major power interest and mission complexity. The second technique has the advantage of conserving more degrees of freedom, but in a field where the number of cases is so small, any attempt to statistically estimate interaction is problematic. The related but more elusive problem of selection arises from the fact that peacekeeping choices are the residue of strategies. For example, suppose the United States and its major European allies have a policy of play- Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 55 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 55 ing a major military role in the implementation of peacekeeping only in cases where they believe their participation is absolutely essential in order to achieve success. If one is unaware of this fact or ignores it and looks at cases of peace implementation in the 1990s, one would see that those missions where the United States has played a preponderant military role— Bosnia and Somalia—have registered a failure and a partial success. Conversely, one would also see that U.S. military participation has been absent in the clear successes—Mozambique, El Salvador, Nicaragua, and Guatemala. The temptation is to conclude that the participation of the United States in peace operations is either irrelevant or detrimental to success when in fact its participation may have been essential to whatever was achieved in the most difficult cases and might have dramatically improved the results in the less difficult cases that were only marginal successes. In a study such as this one, where the sample is small and composed only of peace implementation missions that were undertaken, theory is too undeveloped for us to analyze the data against the backdrop of a reliable selection equation. The only way to deal with interaction and selection effects is to be extremely cautious in interpreting the findings and try to think about the effects that we might be missing. With that cautionary note in mind, we conducted a rough analysis of the determinants of the successful implementation of peace agreements in the sixteen cases included in the CISAC-IPA study. The general literature on policy implementation provides crucial insight into the conditions under which a peace agreement might succeed or fail. A policy implementation perspective requires that we pay attention to the environment surrounding implementation and recognize that some environments are more conducive to implementation than others. Such a perspective also looks to the coalitions that support implementation and their willingness to invest resources. As a first cut, therefore, our project ascertained what makes some peace implementation environments more difficult and challenging than others. Our second cut was to determine which cases get the most resources. Based on findings from the scholarly literature on peacemaking in civil war, we created a difficulty score for peace implementation based on the following eight variables: the number of warring parties; the lack of either a peace agreement before intervention or a coerced peace agreement; the likelihood of spoilers; a collapsed state; the number of soldiers; the presence of disposable natural resources; the presence of hostile neighboring states or networks; and demands for secession. • The number of warring parties. The difficulty of implementation increases when there are more than two warring parties. 14 Strategies become less predictable, balances of power become more tenuous, and alliances become more fluid. In Cambodia, for example, any action that the Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 56 4:16 PM Page 56 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES United Nations might have taken against the Khmer Rouge had to be weighed against the effects such action would have had on the National United Front for a Cooperative, Independent, Neutral, and Peaceful Cambodia (FUNCINPEC), which relied on the Khmer Rouge to balance against the State of Cambodia.15 In cases where a proliferation of warring parties occurred, as in Somalia and Liberia, implementers constantly found it difficult to craft solutions that would address the concerns of all the warring factions. Where any factions found themselves excluded, the peace agreement faced their violent opposition. • The absence of a peace agreement signed by all major warring parties before intervention and with a minimum of coercion. The United Nations has usually required a detailed peace agreement among the warring parties—as a sign of their consent to a peace mission—as a precondition for UN involvement. In the 1990s, however, the United Nations intervened in many ongoing wars and, in several instances, either it or a regional organization or a state intervened in the hope of using force to compel a peace agreement: the UN in Somalia, the Economic Community of West African States Cease-Fire Monitoring Group (ECOMOG) in Liberia and Sierra Leone, India in Sri Lanka, the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) in Bosnia, and Syria in Lebanon. Intervention in the absence of a peace agreement likely will trigger violent opposition by parties who value the preintervention status quo. The absence of a peace agreement implies a lack of problem solving and trust- and confidence-building among the warring factions, thus producing a more difficult implementation environment. • The likelihood of spoilers. The presence of spoilers in peace agreements poses daunting challenges to implementation.16 One critique of the spoiler concept, however, is that spoilers are only recognized after the fact. This criticism can be addressed by attempting to gauge whether prospective implementers judged that they were likely to face violent challenges during implementation. A more sophisticated criticism of the spoiler concept is that potential spoilers are always present and whether an actor actually engages in spoiling behavior depends on the existence of a special opportunity structure.17 There is, as we shall see, some evidence that this is at least partially the case. • Collapsed state. The lack of state institutions and governing capacity places great demands on peace implementers. In addition to bringing fighting to a close, the implementers must create and build up a modicum of state capacity in order for the peace to have a chance to sustain itself. • Number of soldiers. At some level, numbers matter. High numbers of soldiers pose greater demands for verification and monitoring and, hence, a greater potential for successful cheating. Moreover, greater numbers of soldiers require more personnel for monitoring and more resources for demobilization. We scored cases where there were more than 50,000 soldiers as being difficult to implement. Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 57 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 57 • Disposable natural resources. If warring parties have access to disposable resources such as gems, minerals, or timber, implementation becomes more difficult. Such resources not only provide armies with a means for continued fighting, they also become the reward against which they weigh the benefits of peace.18 A key difference between Mozambique and Angola is that, in the latter country, the Union for the Total Independence of Angola (UNITA) had access to diamonds, which emboldened its spoiler behavior, whereas the Mozambique National Resistance (Renamo) lacked access to such resources, which effectively limited the benefits of returning to war.19 • Hostile neighboring states or networks. Civil wars rarely take place in otherwise stable regions. As Peter Wallensteen and Margareta Sollenberg observe, many civil wars today intersect with regional conflicts and interstate competition.20 From this it would follow that the attitude of the surrounding states toward a peace agreement in a neighbor’s civil war plays a key role in supporting or undermining the prospects of peace. Spoilers to a peace agreement, for example, are likely to be much stronger and more vocal if they are confident that they can count on neighboring states for sanctuary, guns, fuel, and capital.21 Likewise, in regions where weak states have little control over borders, well-organized private or semiofficial networks can allow neighboring states to take advantage of such state decrepitude to support spoilers in the war-torn country. • Wars of secession. There is a plausible argument that negotiated settlements are more difficult to attain and implement where civil wars are fought over national sovereignty.22 Such conflicts often revert to all-ornothing struggles that make the job of would-be implementers more difficult than in cases where warring parties share a common identity and at least agree on a unitary future for their country. The more these indicators are present, the greater the difficulty of bringing the conflict to an end. The conflict environment, however, is only one aspect of implementation success or failure. International willingness is also crucial; low degrees of interest and commitment lead either to no intervention or, alternatively, to an intervention with an extremely limited strategy set in the sense that implementers will be constrained by the resources they can deploy and the range of subgoals they can pursue. Constraints on the strategy set need not be a problem when the implementation environment is easy. But difficult environments and constrained strategy sets can be a recipe for disaster, for example, when the Security Council authorizes a mission to implement a peace agreement in Somalia or Angola, but does not provide adequate resources. We scored our cases on three indicators of interest and commitment, what we refer to as a “willingness score”: major or regional power interest, commitment of resources, and acceptance of risk of casualties to soldiers. Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 58 4:16 PM Page 58 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. • Major or regional power interest. A key sign of a high commitment to a mission is whether large, powerful states support intervention and publicly define the conflict as important to their own vital security interests. The more remote a mission is from a powerful state’s vital security interests, the more likely it is being undertaken for symbolic reasons that are unlikely to inspire the outlay of more than a very modest amount of resources. We created a simple estimate of security interest based on whether or not a civil war was geographically proximate to a major or regional power and whether there were statements by major or regional powers at the time of intervention that enunciated security, as opposed to humanitarian, motivations for intervention. • Resource commitment. Crucial for successful implementation is the willingness of states to provide adequate financial resources for a mission. But such resources vary by case, and this is often known before a mission even begins. In Cambodia, for example, the Security Council provided extreme leeway to planners to judge what resources were needed for a successful mission. In Rwanda, on the other hand, the Security Council rejected the figures provided by its own field mission, and instead imposed extreme limits on resources available. • Acceptance of risk to soldiers. We scored this separately from financial resource commitment because policymakers evaluate the risk to their own troops differently than they evaluate financial resources. Table 2.1 lists the cases in our study, the principal implementer, the conflict difficulty score, the international willingness score, and the outcome. The higher the difficulty score, the more difficult the implementation environment; the higher the willingness score, the greater the willingness of international actors to commit to the effort. If we just look at the bivariate regressions of implementation outcome on each of these variables, we find that only four variables are significant at the 0.01 level. These are the existence of a spoiler, the presence of disposable resources, the presence of a neighboring state that is hostile to the peace agreement, and the presence of major power interest. Consistent with expectations, the presence of the first three factors reduces the chances of successful implementation, and the last improves it. The summary variables, conflict and willingness, together explain about 65 percent of the variance in mission outcome. All of the other variables have an impact that is in the predicted direction but not significant with the small number of cases. Since we were curious about the extent to which the role of spoiler was itself an endogenous strategy, the selection of which partly depends on the availability of financial resources, we also looked at the extent to which the presence of spoilers can be predicted by the presence of disposable resources and/or the presence of a hostile neighboring state. The prevalence Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 59 59 EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION Table 2.1 Peace Implementation Cases Zimbabwe Sri Lanka Namibia Nicaragua Lebanon Liberia Angola I Cambodia Mozambique El Salvador Somalia Rwanda Angola II Bosnia Guatemala Sierra Leone Time Period Principal Implementer Difficulty Score Willingness Score Outcome 1980 1987–1989 1989–1990 1989–1990 1990– 1990–1998 1991–1993 1991–1994 1992–1995 1992–1994 1993 1993–1994 1994–1999 1995– 1996–1997 1996–1998 Great Britain India UN UN Syria ECOWAS UN UN UN UN UN UN UN NATO UN ECOWAS 4 6 0 1 5 6 4 5 3 1 5 3 4 6 0 6 1.0 1.7 1.7 1.5 2.7 2.1 0.4 2.2 1.2 1.5 1.4 0.4 0.9 2.2 1.5 0.7 Success Failure Success Success Partial success Partial success Failure Partial success Success Success Failure Failure Failure Partial success Success Failure Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. Notes: Difficulty score: 0 = lowest, 8 = highest. Willingness score: 0 = lowest, 3 = highest. of spoilers makes this a little like reading tea leaves, but the presence of disposable resources appears slightly related, and the presence of a hostile neighbor more strongly so. In every case where there is a hostile neighbor, there is a spoiler, and in the six cases where there is no hostile neighbor, spoilers appear only twice. Of course, one cannot overlook the possibility that instead of a hostile neighboring state providing the resources that allow a spoiler to survive, the existence of a spoiler gives a potentially hostile neighboring state reason to believe that it can effectively subvert the peace agreement. Figure 2.1 illustrates the intersection of conflict difficulty, the degree of major or regional power interest, and implementation outcome. The cases of Guatemala, El Salvador, Namibia, and Nicaragua all scored as low on difficulty of implementation contexts and high on great or regional power interest. Not surprisingly, all were successful. Mozambique and Zimbabwe fell in the low-to-medium range of implementation difficulty and, although their interest scores were not as high as the cases mentioned above, their peace agreements were successfully implemented. To the right of the graph are the more difficult cases. Where major or regional power interest was low, as in Angola, Somalia, and Rwanda, or high, as in Sri Lanka, implementation failed. In the most difficult cases, substantial major or regional power interest was enough to compensate for the difficulty of environment to produce partial success in Cambodia, Lebanon, Bosnia, and Liberia, but was not enough to avoid failure in Sierra Leone. Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 60 60 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES Figure 2.1 Interest and Difficulty: Case Outcomes Nicaragua El Salvador 1 ● ● Guatemala Cambodia Lebanon Bosnia ■ ■ 0.8 Namibia Interest score ● Mozambique ● ● Zimbabwe 0.6 Liberia ■ ▲ Sierra Leone ▲ Sri Lanka 0.4 Rwanda ▲ 0.2 ▲ Angola I Angola II Somalia ▲ 0 0 2 4 6 8 Difficulty score Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. ● success ■ partial success ▲ failure In terms of interaction, it is interesting to note that both cases where the level of conflict was high (i.e., where the aggregate conflict scores were 5 or 6), and where little major power interest was manifest, were total failures, while only one of the five high-conflict cases where major power interest was present was a total failure. Major or regional power interest may not be able to guarantee complete success in difficult environments, but it is usually able to guarantee at least partial success. More unsettling from the standpoint of the UN as an international body and the evolution away from realpolitik is the fact that in the absence of such interest, there is no evidence of even partial success. One might expect that the role of major powers on the Security Council acts to regularly select out difficult missions in preference to easier and less costly ones. Not much can be said about this in the absence of knowing what proportion of the total number of potential peacekeeping opportunities fall into the challenging category (and knowing whether there are other attributes that seem likely to contribute to the difficulty of a case but are entirely “selected out”), but it is nonetheless the case that almost half of the cases in the sample are classified as difficult. If major powers don’t seem to go out of their way to avoid highconflict cases, they do appear to be slightly more discriminating with respect to which cases are undertaken. The average major power interest in high-conflict cases is 0.72 as opposed to 0.58 for lower-conflict cases, and Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 61 EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 61 these figures underestimate the extent of discrimination since four of the low-conflict cases are in Central America, where the United States could be expected to be interested in any case. If these are eliminated, the major power interest score of the low-conflict cases drops to 0.38. Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. Strategies and Implementation Success The majority of peacekeeping researchers and practitioners are less interested in the broad issue of the determinants of successful implementation than they are in the comparative effectiveness of different peacekeeping strategies. Unfortunately, the comparative evaluation of strategies is even more problematic than are determinants studies. One reason for this is that the term strategy can refer to virtually anything, from the UN’s decisions about which missions to undertake, to its decisions about what goals to pursue, to its decisions about how to pursue them. Moreover, while strategies often share much in common, they invariably differ in any number of details. This leaves the evaluator uncertain about what it is that should be evaluated as well as what has been evaluated, and creates a lot of confusion about what the conclusions of a given study actually mean. Another reason why strategic evaluation tends to be more problematic is that selection and interaction effects are often ignored or dealt with poorly. In many ways this makes little sense. The operation of selection and interaction is usually far more obvious in the case of strategy choice than it is in the operation of a given determinant. At an abstract level researchers and policymakers know that strategies are usually tailored to fit a specific context rather than the result of historical serendipity, and that when comparing strategies this makes it difficult to sort out the impact of context and strategy. They are well aware of the fact that education researchers worry that the success rates of top-rated schools or special experimental programs may have more to do with the background of the children who gravitate to good school districts or enroll in voluntary experimental programs than with the quality of the schools or programs themselves. Peacekeeping researchers know they must also worry about whether the greater success rate of one particular strategy stems from its greater superiority or the fact that the missions in which it was employed were easier than those where other strategies were used. Too often, however, individual psychology, organizational interest, and strategic misrepresentation lead policymakers and researchers to forget this. In the case of peace implementation the tendency is to look at the correlation between a grand strategy of confidence-building (reminiscent of traditional peacekeeping) and success in places like El Salvador, Guatemala, Mozambique, and Namibia, and the correlation between a Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 62 4:16 PM Page 62 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES grand strategy of coercion (compellence or deterrence) and failure in places like Sri Lanka, Somalia, and Sierra Leone and only partial successes in Lebanon and Bosnia, and therefore to assume that confidence-building is a superior strategy to coercion. This, of course, ignores that the cases represent radically different implementation contexts, ignores the deadly failures of confidence-building in Rwanda and Angola, and fails to ask the counterfactual—whether confidence-building would have led to stable peace in Somalia or Sri Lanka. To put it differently, evaluations of peacekeeping in the 1990s often suffered from a belief that the UN should always employ small numbers of lightly armed troops on the basis that the rate of mission failure is correlated with troop strength and the heaviness of armor. There are exceptions, of course, but most of them are relatively recent. For example, both Doyle and Stedman make the normative case that choice of strategy should be determined by the difficulty of the case and the threat posed by spoilers.23 In Doyle’s work, as the environment of peace implementation becomes more difficult, the amount of transitional authority exerted by implementers and their willingness to act coercively must increase. In Stedman’s work, when implementers are faced with violent challenges by powerful leaders or factions who are unalterably opposed to a specific peace agreement or whose demands on the peace process are too high, implementers will have to choose coercive strategies to prevail. Confidence-building is an inappropriate strategy against ethnic extremists who are willing to commit genocide, as in Rwanda, in order to undermine a peace agreement. Nonetheless, a skeleton account of international effectiveness in peace implementation in the 1990s demonstrates a reluctance to connect strategy and context when thinking about the effectiveness of strategies. What jumps out of the data is the fact that the UN’s earliest successes in peace implementation occurred in the least difficult cases: Namibia (1989), Nicaragua (1989), and El Salvador (1990–1994). Each of these cases scored low in conflict difficulty and moderate to high in international willingness. Possibly because there was so little variance in peacekeeping context, lessons that were learned from these cases tended to emphasize the effectiveness of one universally applicable strategy. As a consequence, peacekeepers emerged with the belief that traditional peacekeeping— impartiality, neutrality, and consent—and its theoretical underpinning of confidence-building could be successfully applied to any case or mandate. This overconfidence in the ability of the United Nations to implement peace agreements led to overcommitment. Between 1991 and 1994, the United Nations authorized implementation missions to Angola, Cambodia, Guatemala, Mozambique, Rwanda, and Somalia, devoting little apparent thought to the extent to which these cases resembled those where the earlier successes took place. In short order, and with the exceptions of Guatemala Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 63 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 63 and Mozambique, the United Nations found itself in much more dangerous situations, using inappropriate strategies without adequate resources. In Somalia, the one case where the United Nations followed a coercive strategy, the institution interpreted its experience as a failure of strategy— that coercion is incompatible with peace implementation. Just as it ignored context in the case of success, it ignored context in the case of failure. By the end of 1993 the UN updated its selection of strategies based on their relative success—that is, it employed more frequently those strategies that experience had shown to be the most successful. Because the strategy associated with the most difficult case—coercion—had the lowest success rate, the UN found itself applying strategies suited to relatively easy missions in every case, with the effect of reducing the organization’s overall success rate. It was as if a hospital suddenly decided to suspend bone marrow treatments on the grounds that the patients who received them had a higher mortality rate than those who did not without bothering to figure out that part of the justification for giving a patient a very expensive and debilitating cure might be the fact that the patient is much sicker than the average person with the disease. While it is possible to attribute part of the UN’s overconfidence in the traditional peacekeeping model to its string of early successes, the decision to ignore the great contextual differences between Somalia and the other peacekeeping failures on the one hand and the early successes on the other likely stemmed from causes other than a lack of experience or analytic bewilderment. Two other closely related factors are likely to have played a role: the norms of UN decisionmakers and the nature of the UN organizational routines that they create. With respect to their personal value system, individuals are often attracted to a career at the UN in the first place because they esteem neutrality, nonpartisanship, and roles of mediator and peacemaker. They do not want to be viewed as, or view themselves as, part of a partisan militia allied against one side. As a consequence, they have a motivated bias in favor of traditional peacekeeping methods that makes them reluctant to acknowledge the limitations of their preferred intervention technology or the virtues of methods that they abhor and that invariably limit their operational autonomy. Strategic misrepresentation also seems to be operating in some of these cases. As much as UN decisionmakers are drawn to the traditional peacekeeping process, they are even more drawn to ending conflict and playing a central role in conflict intervention wherever it takes place. Both of these goals were placed in jeopardy by the failures of the 1990s, and the UN responded to this crisis in ways that were not always productive. As a consequence of the mounting number of peacekeeping failures and the UN’s failure to protect safe havens in Eastern Bosnia in 1995, leading to the slaughter of 7,000 Muslim men and boys, the United States made it a point Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 64 4:16 PM Page 64 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES to exclude the UN from any substantive role in implementing the Dayton Accords in Bosnia. Regional intervention—along the lines of Nigeria and ECOMOG in Liberia and Sierra Leone—was advocated as a replacement for UN missions. As the 1990s were coming to a close, a new SecretaryGeneral, Kofi Annan, fought against what he perceived to be the marginalization of the United Nations in peace operations, and the Secretariat fought for inclusion in some of the most controversial operations of the decade: Kosovo, East Timor, Sierra Leone, and the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC)—all extremely difficult operations that posed major challenges. One can see this as an attempt to ensure that the United Nations would regain a central role in peace implementation, but the fact that at least three of these operations are unlikely to have ever received the attention of any major or regional power without the efforts of the Secretary-General suggests that another motivation is at work. In cases such as East Timor, Sierra Leone, and the DRC, many strategic options that are theoretically available to the UN are not “incentive compatible,” in the sense that they are policies that are not in the self-interest of critical actors to implement. In more conventional language, they are not politically feasible. The fact that great and/or regional powers must play a key role in implementation creates potential incompatibilities between the strategies that the UN might like to see employed and the incentives of the major powers to support those strategies. As the difficulty of the implementation environment increases, there is a need for greater scope and assertiveness of the transitional authority that is supplied by international actors. Similarly, the greater the difficulty of the implementation environment, the greater the need for coercive strategies of implementation. This means that the strategies that are available to international implementers are a function of great and regional power interest: selection acts to truncate the strategy set. When great or regional powers do not see a particular case as affecting their security interests, they do not provide the resources and commitment necessary for coercive strategies. Incentive compatibility not only affects choice of grand strategy, but also the availability of mechanisms that are needed to provide strategic coherence and coordination. As Bruce Jones argues in Chapter 4, the more difficult the implementation environment, the greater the need for strategic coordination. When international actors suffer from a lack of unity or do not fully support an operation, would-be spoilers can take advantage of international splits to attack the peace process and threaten would-be peacemakers. Similarly, the more coercive the strategy, the greater the civil-military tensions in implementation.24 When international troops are at risk, troop-donating states tend to insist on greater day-to-day interfer- Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 65 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 65 ence in the political conduct of the mission. Such interference can defeat the ability of an implementation force to diagnose and respond effectively to spoilers. As Jones points out, strategies such as “Friends of the SecretaryGeneral” are fundamentally a function of great and regional power interest. The willingness of states to join a “Friends” groups is indicative of a prior judgment that the specific case is in the state’s interest. The result is that such mechanisms for coordination will be unavailable in some cases: there were no Friends of Somalia, as there were no great or regional powers who had security interests in a peaceful Somalia. Incentive compatibility and the gap between what is needed in some missions and what the great or regional powers are willing to provide has led to organizational pathologies within the United Nations that, unless addressed, may lead to the end of UN involvement in making peace. The Secretariat seems to have learned that there are some cases where the Security Council will only authorize a mission if it perceives that the case will be safe and easy. Where threats or dangers appear, the reaction of the Security Council is to avoid deployment altogether or to cut and run. Faced with such knowledge as early as Rwanda, UN bureaucrats became reluctant to share worrisome conflict assessments and tended only to “ask for what the traffic will bear.”25 This led to UN intervention in cases where, if anything went wrong, the UN would fail. The need to present optimistic scenarios to the Security Council precluded contingency planning, since the basic premise of such planning is that less-than-optimistic scenarios are possible. In some cases the need for the UN to present a successful face to its political masters led missions such as Angola in 1997 and Sierra Leone in 1999 to ignore blatant noncompliance by the warring parties. At its worst, as in East Timor in 1999, the UN Secretariat engaged in reckless gambling by selling the Security Council on a mission by downplaying its difficulty, in the hopes that if it went bad, the Security Council and the member states would be embarrassed into response. Conclusion On the basis of the findings of this chapter, we recommend the following: • When selecting what peace agreements the UN should implement, objective assessments must be made of the degree of difficulty of the case, the appropriate strategy that is necessary for success, and the likelihood of major or regional powers supplying the appropriate resources. • When selecting what peace agreements the UN should implement, major power or regional power interest should be treated as a hard con- Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 66 4:16 PM Page 66 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. straint. This means that without major or regional power interest, the United Nations should be extremely cautious in trying to implement cases where spoilers are present, neighboring states are hostile, and disposable resources are available. Experience suggests that UN intervention can make a bad situation on the ground even worse, and failure may both jeopardize the UN’s role in peacekeeping and increase the severity of incentive compatibility problems. • Given the importance of judgment about difficulty of implementation environment, there is a need at the United Nations for better strategic assessment concerning possible peace implementation missions. The Secretariat must act more like Consumer Reports and less like used-car salesmen, attempting to sell the Security Council every mission that arises. • Given the importance of the role that spoilers play in implementation failure, there is a need for intelligence gathering and assessment concerning the motives, intentions, and capabilities of parties who sign peace agreements and parties who are omitted from peace agreements. • Given that such intelligence is fallible and that there will be missions where unanticipated violent challenges may erupt during implementation, there is a need for the United Nations to improve its contingency planning for peace operations. • Before attempting to implement a peace agreement in a country where there are easily marketed valuable commodities (spoils) or that is adjacent to a state hostile to the peace process, the implementer should have the strategy, resources, and commitment to regulate these commodities and the inflow of assistance to spoilers. There is no easy answer to any of the connections between the UN’s success rate and the difficulty of the potential missions that arise. Regardless of how we categorize missions, some are more difficult and costly to conduct than others and the UN is likely to have a lower success rate in connection with these even with selection operating. It follows that if the UN wants to increase its success rate, the easiest way to do so will be to focus on cases where there are only two parties, a functioning state exists, the numbers of combatants are low, and there are no expected spoilers. Is this a sensible strategy? On the one hand, the answer seems obviously no. It seems like the equivalent of a hospital choosing to turn away cancer patients and people in need of transplants in favor of orthopedic procedures and gall bladder operations. On the other hand, if the UN is under constant financial pressure and there are situations where the probability of success is virtually nonexistent, there is no more to be gained by ignoring these facts in the context of peacekeeping than there is in the context of healthcare. Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 Appendix 2.1 Coding of Cases by Difficulty and Willingness Variables Difficulty Bosnia Liberia Sierra Leone Sri Lanka Lebanon Cambodia Somalia Angola I Angola II Zimbabwe Rwanda Mozambique El Salvador Nicaragua Guatemala Namibia 50,000 soldiers yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes Likely Hostile spoilers neighbors yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes More than two Disposable Weak Collapsed Difficulty Power Resource Risk Interest commitment lives parties resources agreement state Secession scoreb yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes 6 6 6 6 5 5 5 4 4 4 3 3 1 1 0 0 Notes: a. Outcomes: 0 = failure, 1 = partial success, 2 = success. b. The higher the conflict score, the higher the level of difficulty. c. The higher the willingness score, the higher the willingness of international actors to end the conflict. 1.0 0.7 0.7 0.5 1.0 1.0 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.5 0.2 0.5 1.0 1.0 1.0 0.7 1.0 0.7 0.7 0.5 0.7 1.0 1.0 0.2 0.7 0.5 0.2 0.7 0.5 0.5 0.5 1.0 0.2 0.7 0.7 0.7 1.0 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Page 67 Civil War Outcomea Willingness Willingness scorec 2.2 2.1 2.1 1.7 2.7 2.2 1.4 0.4 0.9 1.0 0.4 1.2 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.7 4:16 PM Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 2 0 2 2 2 2 2 S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM 68 Page 68 EVALUATING IMPLEMENTATION STRATEGIES Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. Notes 1. George Downs and Patrick Larkey, The Search for Government Efficiency: From Hubris to Helplessness (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1986). 2. See Chapter 18 on Bosnia by Elizabeth Cousens in this book. 3. See Chapter 17 on Cambodia by Sorpong Peou in this book. 4. George A. Joulwan and Christopher C. Shoemaker, Civilian-Military Cooperation in the Prevention of Deadly Conflict: Implementing Agreements in Bosnia and Beyond (New York: Carnegie Corporation of New York, 1998), pp. 19, 23–24. 5. Michael W. Doyle, Ian Johnstone, and Robert C. Orr, “Strategies for Peace: Conclusions and Lessons,” in Doyle, Johnstone, and Orr, eds., Keeping the Peace: Multidimensional UN Operations in Cambodia and El Salvador (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), pp. 388–389. 6. Marjorie Ann Brown, “United Nations Peacekeeping: Historical Overview and Current Issues,” report for Congress (Washington, D.C.: Congressional Research Service, 1993). 7. Paul Diehl, International Peacekeeping (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1993). 8. Duane Bratt, “Assessing Peacekeeping Success,” in Michael Pugh, ed., The UN, Peace, and Force (New York: Frank Cass, 1997), pp. 64–81. 9. Ibid. 10. Barry M. Blechman, William J. Durch, Wendy Eaton, and Julie Werbel, Effective Transitions from Peace Operations to Sustainable Peace: Final Report (Washington, D.C.: DFI International, September 1997). 11. Roland Paris, “The Perils of Liberal International Peacebuilding,” International Security 22, no. 2 (fall 1997), pp. 54–89. 12. Human Rights Watch, Angola Unravels: The Rise and Fall of the Lusaka Peace Process (New York: Human Rights Watch, 1999). 13. Michael Gilligan and Stephen John Stedman, “Where Do the Peacekeepers Go?” paper prepared for the World Bank, October 29, 2001. 14. Gerardo L. Munck and Chetan Kumar, “Civil Conflicts and the Conditions for Successful International Intervention: A Comparative Study of Cambodia and El Salvador,” Review of International Studies 21, no. 2 (1995): 159–181; and Michael W. Doyle and Nicholas Sambanis, “International Peacebuilding: A Theoretical and Quantitative Analysis,” American Political Science Review 94, no. 4 (December 2000): 779–801. 15. See Chapter 17 on Cambodia by Sorpong Peou in this book; and Stephen John Stedman, “Spoiler Problems in Peace Processes,” International Security 22, no. 2 (fall 1997): 32–36. 16. Stedman, “Spoiler Problems.” 17. Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler have made a similar argument in connection with the factors that inspire rebellion in the first place. See Greed and Grievance in Civil War, Policy Research Working Paper no. 2355 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, Development Research Group, May 2000). 18. There is a burgeoning literature on the political economy of civil wars and its effect on prospects for war termination. See, for example, Mats Berdal and David Malone, eds., Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 2000). 19. Stedman, “Spoiler Problems,” pp. 47–48. 20. Peter Wallensteen and Margareta Sollenberg, “Armed Conflicts, Conflict Termination, and Peace Agreements, 1989–96,” Journal of Peace Research 34, no. 3 (fall 1997): 339–358. Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. S-2 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 69 EVALUATION ISSUES IN PEACE IMPLEMENTATION 69 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. 21. Stedman, “Spoiler Problems,” p. 51. 22. Chaim Kaufmann, “Possible and Impossible Solutions to Ethnic Civil Wars,” International Security 20, no. 4 (spring 1996): 136–175. 23. See Chapter 3 by Michael Doyle in this book; and Stedman, “Spoiler Problems.” 24. Karen Guttieri, “Civil-Military Relations in Peace Implementation,” draft prepared for this project. 25. See Chapter 16 by Gilbert Khadiagala in this book. Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27. 11/24/09 4:16 PM Page 70 Copyright © 2002. Lynne Rienner Publishers. All rights reserved. S-2 Ending Civil Wars : The Implementation of Peace Agreements, edited by Stephen John Stedman, et al., Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2002. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/columbia/detail.action?docID=6191482. Created from columbia on 2023-02-13 00:49:27.