Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Tourism Management journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/tourman Being better vs. being different: Differentiation, competition, and pricing strategies in the Spanish hotel industry Manuel Becerra*, Juan Santaló, Rosario Silva IE Business School, Alvarez de Baena 4, 28006 Madrid, Spain a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t Article history: Received 4 October 2011 Accepted 23 March 2012 We study the effects of vertical and horizontal differentiation on pricing policy in a large sample of hotels in Spain. We show that hotels with more stars (i.e., vertically differentiated) offer smaller discounts over listed prices, in addition to charging higher prices. Similarly, hotels that belong to a branded chain (i.e., horizontal differentiation) also charge higher prices and provide smaller discounts. We show how the degree of local competition moderates the effect of differentiation on pricing policy, but only for vertical differentiation. Differentiation indeed protects hotels from the pressure to reduce prices as competition increases, but being better seems to be more effective than just being different. Ó 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Keywords: Differentiation Competition Prices Hotel industry 1. Introduction Product differentiation has been widely regarded as one way for firms to isolate themselves from the pressure of competitors and thus obtain superior performance (Bain, 1956; Dickson & Ginter, 1987; Porter, 1980). Defining long ago this critical concept in firm strategy, prominent economist Edward Chamberlin noted that “A general class of product is differentiated if any significant basis exists for distinguishing the goods of one seller from those of another and leads to a preference for one variety of the product over another” (Chamberlin, 1933: 56). However, despite its importance, there is only scarce empirical research that investigates which types of product differentiation isolate firms more effectively from competitive forces (Porter, 1980). In this paper we try to fill this gap by analyzing the effect of two distinct differentiation strategies, vertical and horizontal, on pricing policies in the hotel industry. Several empirical studies in the hotel industry have documented the benefits of differentiation (Baum & Mezias, 1992; GarrigósSimón & Palacios Marqués, 2004), which can be viewed as a barrier to entry or, more generally, a generic source of competitive advantage in sharp contrast to cost leadership. Some authors believe that all competitive strategies, including cost leadership, involve a certain differentiation of the firm’s products and services versus its competitors in some way (Mintzberg, 1988). Extant research has focused primarily on the contrast between cost leadership and differentiation, usually exploring whether they do exist * Corresponding author. Tel.: þ34 91 568 9600. E-mail addresses: manuel.becerra@ie.edu (M. Becerra), juan.santalo@ie.edu (J. Santaló), charo.silva@ie.edu (R. Silva). 0261-5177/$ e see front matter Ó 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.tourman.2012.03.014 as alternative choices for firm strategy and their implications for performance (Campbell-Hunt, 2000). The positive effects of differentiation in protecting firms from competition have been widely accepted since Porter (1980), but the conditions under which they do so have not been investigated empirically yet. We study the isolating effect of differentiation strategies from competitive pressures in the context of the Spanish hotel industry. According to the World Tourism Organization, Spain was one of the main destinations in the world in 2010 in terms of arrivals and the second in international tourism receipts after the US (World Tourism Organization, 2011). Tourism’s contribution to Spanish gross domestic product (GDP) is estimated at 10%, whereas worldwide is around 5%. Similarly, tourism’s contribution to Spanish employment represents 10.8% of the overall number of jobs, while worldwide is estimated in order of 6e7% (Instituto de Estudios Turísticos, 2011; World Tourism Organization, 2011). The Spanish hotel industry is a particularly appropriate context to conduct this study because it provides a rich setting across a large number of geographical locations with varying levels of competitive rivalry for which there are publicly available statistics of listed prices, discounts, and features for hotel differentiation. Looking at the extant literature, our knowledge is still limited with regard to how much the options for differentiation can isolate hotels from the negative effects of competition on prices. Though the effect of specific hotel features on room prices has been the subject of abundant empirical research (Bull, 1994; Espinet, Saez, Coenders, & Fluvià, 2003; Haroutunian, Mitsis, & Pashardes, 2005; Rigall-I-Torrent & Fluvià, 2011; Thrane, 2005), we do not know the extent to which alternative types of differentiation can protect hotels from the pressure to reduce prices when competition in their 72 M. Becerra et al. / Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 geographical area increases. Based on the differentiation literature in IO (Beath & Katsoulacos, 1991), we investigate how vertical differentiation (i.e., competing along one product dimension valued similarly by all customers, such as overall hotel quality) and horizontal differentiation (i.e., offering a unique combination of product features that satisfies the needs of a specific customer segment) can both be used to insulate hotels from an increase in the degree of competition in its location. In addition to finding support for the effects of both vertical and horizontal differentiation on room prices and discounts, our empirical results show that “being better” (i.e., vertically differentiated) allows hotels to resort less to room price discounts from their listed prices as competition increases than merely “being different” (horizontally differentiated). In the rest of the paper we develop several hypotheses about the effects of vertical and horizontal differentiation on hotel room prices and how competitive rivalry moderates these effects. We use a sample of 1490 hotels in 67 locations in Spain to test the hypotheses, which are generally supported. 2. Differentiation strategies 2.1. Literature review The concept of differentiation goes back to the seminal work on monopolistic competition of Chamberlin (1933), who highlighted that customers may have different preferences among available products within the same industry. Along this line, Porter (1980) later popularized the generic strategy of differentiation when a firm creates something tangible or intangible that is perceived as “being unique” by at least one set of customers. Thus, it is the customers’ perceptions what determines the extent of product differentiation. Differentiation has been regarded as an important generic strategy widely used across all industries (Beal & Yasai-Ardekani, 2000; Homburg, Krohner & Workman, 1999), but their performance consequences are not well understood yet (Campbell-Hunt, 2000). Furthermore, there seem to be many possible differentiation strategies. For instance, Miller (1986) argued in favor of two types of differentiation strategy: innovation and marketing, which was supported by Lee and Miller (1999). In a broader categorization of differentiation-based strategies, Mintzberg (1988) proposed six types: quality, design, support, image, price, and undifferentiated products, which obtained empirical support from Kotha and Vadlamani (1995). Recently, strategy researchers have explored the distinction between vertical and horizontal differentiation widely used in the IO literature (Ethiraj & Zhu, 2008; Makadok, 2010, 2011). In the case of vertical differentiation all customers would agree in a preference ranking of available products, if they were offered at the same price. In this case, competition among firms takes place along only one dimension with the most differentiated firm providing the highest level of such a dimension. For instance, by offering the highest overall quality, a hotel may become more attractive to all customers. In this case, even though customers have the same ranking of perceived product quality, products sell at different prices because customers have different willingness to pay for quality improvements, driven primarily by their differences in wealth (Beath & Katsoulacos, 1991). However, customers often have different preferences about the set of desirable features in a product or service, so that a single ranking along a quality index cannot be developed for the firms in the market for which all customers would agree. This is the case of horizontal differentiation in which, even if all products were sold at the same price, firms would obtain different market shares to the extent that their products have a unique combination of attributes that are preferred by one specific set of customers. For instance, through brand loyalty a firm becomes more attractive to a specific set of customers with similar needs, which limits the degree of substitutability among competing firms (Makadok, 2010). Most of the IO literature on product differentiation is based on this distinction between vertical and horizontal differentiation (Beath & Katsoulacos, 1991). However, strategy research has ignored this distinction until recently (Makadok & Ross, 2009). In a sequence of theoretical papers, Makadok and Ross (2009), Makadok (2010, 2011) predicted the performance consequences of both types of differentiation as well as their interaction effects, though there is scarce empirical research in strategy about both types of differentiation. In one of the few empirical studies on differentiation strategies, Ethiraj and Zhu (2008) show that competition is primarily based on horizontal differentiation in the early stages of industry development, which makes incumbents’ advantage relatively sustainable; however, as the industry matures, new entrants with greater vertical differentiation are more likely to beat incumbents. In the next section we will explain how the two main alternatives for differentiation, vertical and horizontal strategies, can be used to help us understand competition among hotels and its effect on prices; more precisely, how hotels can cope with the pressure to reduce room prices as the intensity of competition increases. 2.2. Differentiation and prices in the hotel industry Let us investigate now the connection between differentiation strategies and pricing policies in the specific framework of the hospitality sector. This topic is worthwhile studying because price planning is one of the most overlooked and poorly researched areas of marketing (Hoffman, Turley, & Kelley, 2002; Rowley, 1997). Furthermore, pricing decisions are particularly relevant in the hotel industry since hospitality prices are one of the main influences on accommodation selection decisions (Hung, Shang, & Wang, 2010; Lockyer, 2005). The existing literature in the hotel industry indicates that there are many attributes that influence the customers’ choice, such as location, room rate, service quality, reputation, security, and cleanliness (Chu & Choi, 2000). Similarly, hedonic pricing research has explored a large number of variables that determine room prices, such as location, hotel category and size, brand name, restaurant availability, distance to city center, room features, parking, and sport facilities (Bull, 1994; Carvell & Herrin, 1990; Espinet et al., 2003; Thrane, 2005; Wu, 1999). Any unique feature that is relevant for at least one set of customers is a potential source of differentiation (Dubé & Renaghan, 2000). Certain hotel characteristics, such as service quality, are arguably important for all customers, but some customers value certain features more than others. From the many possible features on which hotels can build their differentiation, we have chosen two important elements of a hotel’s strategy to conduct our study: hotel category (i.e., number of stars) and hotel chain (i.e., membership to a branded hotel chain), as critical choices for vertical and horizontal differentiation respectively. In the hotel industry there is one overall ranking of quality with which we would expect all customers to substantially agree, i.e., hotel category (1 through 5 stars, which is actually assessed officially in Spain by the proper agency). In other words, most people would agree that a five-star hotel is usually better than a four-star hotel and so on. It is reasonable to believe that, if customers were given the same rates for hotels, they would choose a higher category hotel. Thus, hotel category is an option for hotels to differentiate vertically and, indeed, it is regarded as an excellent proxy for overall hotel quality (Fernández & Marín, 1998). Of course, M. Becerra et al. / Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 customers do not necessarily choose hotels with a greater number of stars because hotels charge different prices and they may not be willing to pay extra for higher quality since their wealth differs. Obviously, we would expect a strong positive correlation between hotel quality and room prices, which has been well documented in the extant literature (Bull, 1994; Fernández & Marín, 1998; Israeli, 2002; Rigall-I-Torrent & Fluvià, 2011). Its economic rationale is straightforward and not controversial, because higher product quality is associated with higher costs, which pushes prices up. A differentiator faces a downward-sloping demand curve, which allows the firm to limit supply to only the less price sensitive customers, thus, setting a larger price and usually getting greater margin. Indeed, the existing empirical literature on differentiation across different industries has shown that differentiation is generally associated with higher prices (Caves & Williamson, 1985; Mazzeo, 2002) and greater market power (Bresnahan, 1987; Dranove, Gron, & Mazzeo, 2003). However, we want to go one step beyond and analyze the effect of hotel quality on discounts over listed prices (see Rowley, 1997, for discounts as pricing policies). In any industry, market prices are determined by a complex set of supply and demand factors. If we want to study how differentiation protects hotels from reducing their prices as competition increases, we should also use discounts over listed prices in addition to average room prices. Hotels usually set their prices for a double room as the reference listed price over which they may apply a variety of discounts, for instance, for single use of the room. In contrast to the obvious quality-price relationship in room prices, it is far from evident whether high or low quality hotels provide greater discounts for a single room. On the one hand, because less differentiated hotels compete more heavily on prices (Hung, Shan & Wang, 2010; Israeli, 2002; Rowley, 1997), they should have less cushion to provide additional discounts over their already low listed prices. To the contrary, if differentiation actually protects the firm from the pressure to reduce prices (Porter, 1980; Rowley, 1997), we would expect that hotels with more stars should provide less discounts. We believe that prices as well as discounts should be driven by similar determinants, including especially the extent of differentiation. In the preliminary interviews with hotel managers that we conducted in the early stages of this project, several managers indicated that they use specific discounts when the competitive pressure increases, but they eventually have to lower listed prices if the discounts were not sufficient to attract customers. Thus, we argue that the positive effect of differentiation on prices should also have an analogous effect in reducing the discounts offered to specific customers groups. Based on these arguments, we can formulate the following hypothesis regarding hotel category as a strategic choice for vertical differentiation: Hypothesis 1. Higher category hotels (a) charge higher prices for double rooms and (b) provide smaller discounts for single rooms. Turning now to horizontal differentiation, the benefits of large branded chains over independent hotels have been already explored in the literature (Holverson & Revaz, 2006). Empirical research has documented the higher survival chances of hotels that belong to a chain, identifying the chain reputation as one of the important advantages that these hotels receive (Ingram & Baum, 1997). Brand name has also been identified as one of the main hotel attributes that drive customer purchase decision because customers value the familiarity with the brand and its positive and distinctive image (Dubé & Renaghan, 2000). In this sense, customers that are familiar with a given chain are more likely that they stay loyal to it rather than take risks with an unfamiliar brand. Thus, other things being held equal, brand hotels will be attractive 73 for at least some customers, those who consider that the brand is more likely to satisfy their own needs. It seems reasonable that the set of customers that have a preference for a specific chain brand should push its room prices up. In fact, empirical research has shown a positive relationship between chain affiliation and room prices (Thrane, 2007). Hotels that are part of a chain may be expected to have somewhat higher prices than independent hotels, which in general have a less well-known brand behind them, even though the preferences toward specific brands vary across customers. Note that since hotel brands cannot be ranked in a strict order of preference valid for all customers, branding constitutes an example of horizontal differentiation. More importantly, we also expect that hotels differentiated horizontally through a chain brand should be less likely to use discounts, just like in the case of vertical differentiation. As Porter noted, “Differentiation provides insulation against competitive rivalry because of brand loyalty by customers and resulting lower sensitivity to price.” (Porter, 1980: 38). To the extent that a chain brand defends its hotels from the competitive pressure on prices, it should also affect the discounts that they provide to attract specific customers (Hanks, Cross, & Noland, 2002). Thus, we expect that hotels that belong to a branded chain will try and take advantage of the higher presumed loyalty of their customers and, consequently, they should provide lower discounts over their listed prices for double rooms. Thus, we can formulate the following hypothesis with regard to chain brand as a choice for horizontal differentiation: Hypothesis 2. Hotels that belong to a branded chain (a) charge higher prices for double rooms and (b) provide smaller discounts for single rooms. The IO literature has shown theoretically and empirically that an increase in the intensity of market competition translates into lower prices (Bresnahan & Reiss, 1991; Shaked & Sutton, 1982). We will argue that both vertical and horizontal differentiation should reduce the effect of competitive rivalry in prices and discounts. In other words, the degree of competition moderates the effect of differentiation in pricing policy, such that vertical and horizontal differentiation protects hotels from the pressure to reduce prices when competition increases. As discussed earlier, vertical and horizontal differentiation are essentially tools for the firm to escape from competitive rivalry, which in the hotel industry is primarily driven by the number of direct competitors and the geographical distance to them (Baum & Mezias, 1992). Differentiated hotels try to attract a certain clientele, while undifferentiated ones, whose main feature is low prices, place their emphasis on operating at full capacity to have minimum operation average costs. We expect that these two types of firms should react differently to an increase in rivalry. Differentiated hotels cannot react to an increase in competition with greater discounts because these discounts could jeopardize the value of intangibles, like quality reputation and chain brand, which are likely to be linked to room prices in the mind of customers. Lower prices and large discounts may destroy the image of uniqueness of hotels with higher category and branded chains. In contrast, non-differentiated hotels are more likely to use pricing policy to attract customers when competition increases, that is, when they have lower quality and are not part of a chain. Thus, we expect that the positive effects of differentiation on pricing policy hypothesized earlier will be stronger as competition increases. Hypothesis 3. The effect of both hotel category and chain brand on pricing policy becomes greater as the level of local competition increases. Fig. 1 summarizes the theoretical arguments developed above that we will test empirically in the next sections. 74 M. Becerra et al. / Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 Double Room Price Hotel Differentiation - H1: Category - H2: Chain Discount for Single Room H3: Competition among Hotels - Number of Hotels - Geographical Distance (reversed) Fig. 1. Model of hotel differentiation and competition. 3. Methodology 3.1. Data collection Our final sample consists in 1490 hotels in 67 distinct destinations all located in Spain. We used several sources of information to build a database of hotels for year 2005, including the Guía Oficial de Hoteles (published by Instituto de Estudios Turísticos) for hotel information, the Encuesta de Ocupación Hotelera (published by Instituto Nacional de Estadística, INE) for location information, and VisualMap for geographical distances among hotels within their location. From the entire population of hotels in Spain, we selected those located in the 135 locations for which the INE gathers visitor information, which account for 70% of all visitors and 56% of existing hotels. Thus, the initial sample consisted of 3456 hotels. After discarding hotels with missing data (often due to the impossibility to compute geographical distances to other hotels) and those locations with less than five hotels, the final sample was reduced to 1490 hotels in 67 locations. This final sample includes the most important Spanish cities that attract national and international visitors, such as Madrid, Barcelona, Valencia, Sevilla, the touristic centers in the Mediterranean and the Atlantic coast, and the Canary and Balearic Islands. The Guía Oficial de Hoteles gathers annual information about all hotels in Spain, including its name, category (1e5 stars), chain membership, location (city and address), number of rooms, prices for double and single rooms in peak and off-peak season, and other hotel features (e.g., age, picturesque location, and being close to the beach). Hotels send this information to the public Spanish agency Instituto de Estudios Turísticos, which is in charge of the promotion of tourism in Spain, both domestically and internationally. Hotel information, including room prices, comes from this guide, which is often used by researchers in the Spanish hotel industry (Fernández & Marín, 1998; Uriel & Ferri, 2004). The Guía is widely available to the general public, who often use it for planning their trips and choosing a hotel. To check the validity of the pricing data in the Guía, we manually collected hotel prices advertised by two tour operators on a random sample of 70 hotels and found a high correlation of .72 with those in the Guía, though tour operator prices were on average 11% lower. Overall, we were reasonably reassured of the reliability of the pricing data. 3.2. Variables We use the price of a double room during peak season as the basis for the dependent variables in the analysis (Room Price), as reported by the Guía. Hotels also report separately the price of a single room, so that we could compute the percentage discount of a single room over the price of a double room (Price Discount). Over 90% of the hotel rooms in the sample were double, but they can be rented by single individuals usually at a discount over the listed price (single occupancy of a double room). It should be noted that in two observations it was cheaper for the visitor the possibility of renting two single rooms than getting one double room and we dropped these two observations for the Price Discount analysis. The key independent variables were operationalized in the following way: - Category. The number of stars (coded 1 though 5) of the hotel is reported by the Guía Oficial de Hoteles. As a measure of vertical differentiation, this variable captures objectively the level of quality of the hotel based on regional regulations, which is officially assessed by the proper agencies and displayed prominently. - Chain. This is a dummy variable that represents whether the hotel is part of a chain as shown in the Guía (coded 1), such as NH, Barceló, and Sol-Meliá. It is a measure of horizontal differentiation that denotes the use of a common umbrella brand by the hotel. In contrast to vertical differentiation, the potential value of any single brand varies across customers based on their own experiences and preferences, so that no objective ranking of brands may be developed. - Local competition. We used two variables that capture the degree of direct competition that a hotel has to face in its local market. First, Number of Competitors is a straightforward measure of the number of hotels in the same category (i.e., same number of stars) that exist in each one of the 67 locations in the sample. Second, we computed the average Geographical Distance to these direct competitors in each location. We manually input the physical address of the hotels in VisualMap software to estimate the geographical distance based on their GPS coordinates between each hotel and all other hotels in its location with the same category. Because the 67 locations in the sample covered geographical areas of different size, we normalized the distance to the farthest hotel in the location to a value of 1 and, then, computed the average Euclidean distance to other hotels. In addition to the independent variables above, we also included the following control variables: - Beach Hotel. This dummy variable was coded as 1 when the Guía indicates that the hotel is located near the beach. This is a variable self-reported by the hotel that has intra-location variation. In other words, inside a given location some hotels are beach hotels while others located further inland are not. For instance, there are hotels in Marbella that are located directly on the beach as the Gran Hotel Don Pepe, while others are placed several kilometers far from the beach as Rio Real Golf Hotel or Incosol Hotel Medical Spa. We included this control variable because beach hotels are quite different with respect to their strategy and pricing policy. - Mountain. This dummy variable was coded as 1 when the Guía indicates that the hotel is located near a mountain area. Similar to the previous variable, this variable is self-reported by the hotel and it has intra-location variation. For instance, only some hotels located in Ronda (Málaga) report to be located near the mountain areas, as the Natural Park of Sierra de las Nieves or the mountain range of Grazalema. - Special. This dummy variable was coded as 1 when the Guía indicates that the hotel is located near a special picturesque spot, such as Madrid’s Museo del Prado or Barcelona’s Sagrada Familia Cathedral. M. Becerra et al. / Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 - Number of Rooms. We controlled for hotel size using the total number of rooms for the hotel. Just like firm size is usually a significant variable in strategy research, hotel size may be expected to affect pricing policy, for instance, as a result of economies of scale. - Age. We also controlled for the age of the hotel to account for the possible greater pressure of older hotels to lower their prices and possibly offer greater discounts. Because two of these control variables were skewed (Number of rooms and Age), we replicated the analysis using the log value of these two last variables. The conclusions from the empirical analysis did not change when their log values were used. 3.3. Statistical analysis We performed OLS regression analysis to test for the effect of hotel Category and Chain, as measures of vertical and horizontal differentiation respectively, on listed Room Prices and also on Price Discounts. First, we included the control variables and fixed effects for the 67 locations in the sample (Model 1), following Rigall-ITorrent and Fluvià (2007, 2011). Then, we added the independent variables that gauge hotel differentiation and local competition (Model 2). In the last step we included the hypothesized interactions. Because there was clear evidence of multicollinearity among the interaction coefficients based on their variance inflation factors, we standardized the four independent variables before computing the interactions (Model 3). Thus, the differentiation and competition variables were standardized in models 2 and 3. Though we controlled for location fixed effects that could drive the relationship between differentiation and prices, e.g., through demand shocks that affect different areas, there may still be an issue of endogeneity of the Number of competitors with our dependent variable Room prices. To explore this possibility, we tested whether Number of competitors was endogenous through a Hausman test (Durbin-Wu-Hausman test). An insignificant Chi square of .23 (1 d.f., p-value ¼ .63) showed that indeed the number of competitors is not endogenous. We explored the robustness of our conclusions in two ways. First, we replicated the analysis using structural equations modeling (SEM), which allowed us to account for measurement error in our latent construct of competition as well as to conduct subsample analysis in order to check the invariance of the coefficients across groups of hotels with different levels of differentiation. Second, we used pricing data for the hotels that reported separate prices for off-peak season and replicated the analysis over this alternative set of prices and discounts. As we will discuss later 75 on, these analyses confirmed the conclusions from the OLS regressions for peak season. 4. Results 4.1. Descriptive statistics Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics and the correlation table for the variables in the analysis. The average price of a double room was 115 euros with a discount of 25% for single rooms. Based on the zero-order correlations, hotels usually charge higher prices and offer smaller discounts when they are newer, larger, and not close to the beach. In line with the reputation of Spain as an affordable destination for beaches and sun, hotels located near the beach seem to attract the more price sensitive tourism. This result is in contrast with the findings of previous literature (Aguiló, Alegre, & Riera, 2001; Espinet et al., 2003; Rigall-I-Torrent & Fluvià, 2007, 2011; Rigall-I-Torrent et al., 2011) that report an increase in prices for those hotels located just in front of the beach. We believe that these different results are due to the fact that these studies analyze a sample of hotels located exclusively in beach-and-sun Spanish destinations (i.e., Costa Brava), whereas our sample comprises the whole of Spain including beach-and sun locations, but also other types of destinations like mountain resorts, big cities like Valencia and Barcelona, and destinations with other landscape-cultural attractions like Madrid or A Coruña. Being in front of the beach may drive a price premium in beach-and sun destinations as reported in Espinet et al. (2003), though this beach premium may not exist in other types of location, like Barcelona. Table 2 shows average prices and discounts for hotels with different categories and chain membership. On average, room prices increase from V60 for a one-star hotel to V280 for a five-star hotel, while discounts for single room decrease from 29% to 16% as the number of stars increases. Also, chain brand is associated with higher prices and smaller discounts. Preliminary analysis of variance based on ANOVA Bonferroni (not reported in the tables) showed that the differences in Room Price and Price Discount for the Chain and Category variables were highly significant and fully in line with hypotheses 1 and 2. 4.2. Regression analysis Table 3 shows the results for the regression analysis of Room Price for the 1490 hotels in the sample using fixed effects for the 67 locations, while Table 4 repeats the same analysis for Price Discounts. Model 1 includes only the control variables and the dummies for 67 locations, which explain 49% of the variance in prices and 23% of discounts. The key independent variables are Table 1 Means, standard deviations, and correlations. 1. Room Price 2. Room Discount 3. Beach 4. Mountain 5. Special 6. Size 7. Age 8. Category 9. Chain 10. Geographical distance (km) 11. Number of competitors y p < .10. *p < .05. **p < .01. N Mean St. Dev. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1490 1488 1490 1490 1490 1490 1490 1490 1490 1490 1490 115.61 .25 .32 .01 .31 96.51 11.90 2.84 .40 .62 21.18 60.85 .13 .47 .11 .46 88.72 10.81 .99 .49 .25 20.97 .32** .16** .09** .01 .32** .24** .67** .46** .10** .35** .22** .06* .07* .02 .19** .27** .29** .00 .11** .08** .03 .31** .14** .00 .09** .01 .02 .05 .08** .02 .09** -.10** .06* .08** .13** .02 .01 .09** .01 .10** .01 .47** .36** -.04 .18** .26** .19** .01 .07** .49** .04 .22** .02 .18** .26** 76 M. Becerra et al. / Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 Table 2 Mean prices and discounts by Hotel category and chain. Category 1 star 2 stars 3 stars 4 stars 5 stars Total chain Table 4 Results of regression analysis for room discount with location fixed-effects. Chain (Yes ¼ 1) Number of hotels Room price (V) Room discount (%) 0 1 Total 0 1 Total 0 1 Total 0 1 Total 0 1 Total 0 1 165 9 174 280 41 321 335 254 589 103 277 380 4 22 26 887 603 1490 59.54 74.05 60.29 73.54 93.68 76.11 101.43 126.52 112.25 161.17 170.88 168.24 303.85 275.51 279.87 92.69 149.32 115.61 29.43 25.75 29.23 29.27 24.87 28.71 28.28 23.05 26.03 24.15 18.34 19.92 14.35 16.99 16.58 28.26 20.83 25.26 Overall mean Model 1 Intercept Beach Mountain Special Size Age Competition Number of competitors Geographical distance Differentiation Category Chain Interactions Number of Competitors Category Number of Competitors Chain Geographical Distance Category Geographical Distance Chain City dummies R2 Adjusted R2 sε (.04) (.01) (.04) (.01) (.00) (.00) Model 2 Model 3 .25** .02* .03 .02** .00 .00** .25** .02y .03 .02** .00 .00** (.04) (.01) (.04) (.01) (.00) (.00) (.04) (.01) (.04) (.01) (.00) (.00) .00 (.01) .00 (.00) .01 (.01) .00 (.00) .02** (.00) .02** (.00) .03** (.00) .02** (.00) .01* .00 .01 .00 Yes .23 .19 .11 1488 N added in Model 2, which result in a significant increase in R2 of .24 for prices and .05 for discounts. There is strong evidence in favor of hypotheses 1 and 2 in Table 3 for room prices and Table 4 for price discounts. In favor of H1a, the number of stars has a large positive effect on Room Prices (b ¼ 36.43); similarly for H2a, hotels that are part of a branded chain are more expensive than independent hotels (b ¼ 4.63). Also as we expected, Price Discount is reduced as hotels obtain higher Category (b ¼ .02, supporting H1b) and Hotel Chains also charge smaller discounts for single rooms (b ¼ .02, supporting H2b). All of these coefficients are significant at 1% level. In addition to the regression results reported in the tables, we should note that Hotel Category has the largest effect on pricing policy, with a partial R2 of .412 for Room Prices (.013 for Hotel Chain) and .025 for Price Discounts (.020 for Hotel Chain). Each of the interactions of Hotel Category and Chain with the two measures of local competition is included in Model 3. The results provide only partial support for hypothesis 3. More .25** .02y .02 .02** .00** .00** Yes .28 .24 .11 1488 (.01) (.00) (.00) (.00) Yes .28 .24 .11 1488 y p < .10; *p < .05; **p < .01. Standard errors in parentheses. precisely, there is clear empirical evidence that greater competition measured by the number of competitors makes the effect of Hotel Category on both Room Prices and Price Discounts significantly stronger. This is shown by the interaction coefficients in Model 3 in Tables 3and 4. Hotels with more stars charge higher prices relative to lower category hotels when the number of competitors is larger (b ¼ 12.39, p-value < .01, Table 3) and they also provide relatively smaller discounts in those circumstances (b ¼ .01, p-value < .05, Table 4). However, competition interactions with Hotel Chain were usually insignificant. The only significant interaction for the Chain dummy variable (b ¼ 2.11, p-value < .05, Table 3) indicates that hotels that are part of a branded chain charge significantly higher prices when the number of direct competitors increases, which is in line with hypothesis 3. Yet, the two interactions between competition (i.e., number of competitors and geographical distance) and Table 3 Results of regression analysis for room Price with location fixed-effects. Model 1 Intercept Beach Mountain Special Size Age Competition Number of competitors Geographical distance Differentiation Category Chain Interactions Number of Competitors Category Number of Competitors Chain Geographical Distance Category Geographical Distance Chain City dummies R2 Adjusted R2 sε N y p < .10; *p < .05; **p < .01 Standard errors in parentheses. 120.20** 3.99 5.40 5.64* .27** 1.08** Model 2 (14.28) (4.54) (15.71) (2.76) (.02) (.11) 113.62** 2.80 8.31 2.37 .03* .33** Model 3 (10.59) (3.35) (11.53) (2.03) (.01) (.09) 110.81** .28 7.63 2.83 .03* .33** 10.02** (1.67) 1.08 (.98) 17.48** (1.77) 1.04 (.95) 36.43** (1.16) 4.63** (1.06) 42.38** (1.26) 4.41** (1.04) 12.39** 2.11* 1.15 1.62 Yes .49 .47 43.17 1490 (10.24) (3.26) (11.13) (1.96) (.01) (.08) Yes .73 .71 31.65 1490 Yes .75 .73 30.49 1490 (1.56) (.95) (1.02) (1.03) M. Becerra et al. / Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 chain are not significant in the regressions using discounts as dependent variable in Table 4. Overall, the results for vertical and horizontal differentiation paint a clear picture regarding the key relevance of Category in protecting hotels from reducing prices as competition increases. When we examine the size of the standardized coefficients and the partial r2 of the independent variables, the main effect of Hotel Category is the key driver of prices and discounts, which becomes even greater when the interactions with competition are considered. The expected effect of Hotel Category on Room Prices and Discounts becomes significantly stronger as competition increases. In contrast, Hotel Chain has a significant (though relatively smaller) main effect on Room Prices and Discounts as hypothesis 2 claimed, but such an effect is not moderated by the extent of competition when using discounts as dependent variable. 4.3. Robustness tests We replicated the entire analysis using SEM, which provided very similar results. The baseline model and the key results are depicted in Fig. 2. In model A, all the exogenous variables and the Competition latent variable determine both Room Price and Discount, whose errors are allowed to correlate. It should be noted that this correlation is insignificant in all models, so that the exogenous variables fully explain the observed correlation between both. As usual in SEM, all exogenous variables and the Competition 77 latent variable are allowed to correlate freely. For identification purposes of the Competition latent variable, two parameters are fixed to 1. All variables in the model were centered around their means for each location to obtain equivalent results to using location fixed effects, thus avoiding the inclusion of a large set of 67 dummy variables in the model. The key results for Model A are shown in the first column below Fig. 2. In line with H1and H2, the coefficients for the two types of differentiation, Category and Chain, are significant and positively associated with Price, but negatively with Discount. Note also that the Competition latent variable is significant and negatively correlated with Prices, though it is insignificant for Discounts. The high CFI (.999) and low RMSEA (.008) indicate a very good fit. Despite the large sample size, this model provides an insignificant Chi-squared with 9 degrees of freedom. To test the interactions of Competition with Category in Model B using group analysis, the Category variable was dropped from model A and the invariance of the Competition variable coefficient was tested across the two groups, 1 and 2 star hotels vs. 4 and 5 hotels, thus dropping the 3-star hotels from the dataset. This model still provides a good fit (CFI of .972 and RMSEA of .038), though slightly smaller than Model A. Note that an increase in competition results in lower prices for low category hotels (b ¼ 1.62, pvalue < .01), but an increase in prices for high quality hotels (b ¼ 1.17, p-value < .01). This is fully consistent with the literature on agglomeration effects (Canina, Enz, & Harrison, 2005). The test KEY RESULTS Model A Price <= Category Chain Competition Discount <= Category Chain Competition Chi-2 CFI RMSEA 1-2 stars Model B 4-5 stars Invariance Independent 36.65** 9.30** -.48** -4.51 -1.62** -27.24** 1.17** -11.61** 119.62** 34.04** --.31** 41.91** --.55** -.02** -.04** .00 9.90 .999 .008 --.04** -.00 -1.42 .05 -.02** -.00 -.03** --.00 19.70 .999 .011 -.06** -.00 29.96* .972 .038 Model C Chain Fig. 2. Structural equations analysis baseline Graphical Representation (Model A). Invariance 9.67** -2.11 .47 -2.15 78 M. Becerra et al. / Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 for group invariance between the two coefficients is highly significant (119.62, p-value < .01), so that differentiation indeed protects from the pressure to reduce prices as competition increases, thus providing support for hypothesis 3. Model C shows the group comparison of independent vs. chain hotels. In contrast to the results above, we can see that Competition has a similar negative effect on prices (.31 and .55, both significant at p-value < .01) for both groups, independent and chain hotels, so that there is no evidence of interaction between Chain and Competition (2.11, insignificant invariance across the coefficients in the two groups). We should also note that the coefficients for Competition and their invariance across groups were insignificant for Discount in both Models B and C. In sum, there is no support for hypothesis 3 regarding the moderating effect of competition on the chain/ pricing policy relationship. All the OLS and SEM analyses reported so far were based on prices and discounts during peak season for year 2005. We also tested the robustness of the conclusions using data for off-peak season. In many locations there is clearly a low season during which the nature of competition changes, but less so in big cities like Madrid and Barcelona. Many hotels do not report prices for low season and they may even close, particularly some beach-and mountain (skiing) hotels. Thus, the sample was reduced to 973 hotels during off-peak season. Similar results, though slightly weaker, were obtained from this analysis. The coefficient for Hotel Category was positive and significant for Room Price, though insignificant for Hotel Chain, and both coefficients Category and Chain were significant and negatively associated with Price Discounts, as claimed by hypotheses 1 a/b and 2 a/b. Regarding the moderating effect of competition, there was also partial evidence in favor of hypotheses 3 with respect to Hotel Category, though mostly insignificant results for Hotel Chain. In summary, using an alternative method to test the hypothesized main effects and interactions and using also an alternative dataset during off-peak season, we reached very similar conclusions to the main OLS analysis of prices and discounts during peak season. Namely, there was clear evidence that both types of differentiation, Hotel Category and Chain, are associated with greater prices and lower discounts, as H1 and H2 suggested. However, as competition increases, only Hotel Category protects relatively more from the pressure to cut prices and provide greater discounts. Thus, an increase in competition reinforces the effect of Category on pricing policy, but it moderates only mildly the effect of Chain. It should be noted that the moderating effect of competition is observable mostly for Number of competitors and not usually for average Geographical distance. 5. Discussion The results from this study confirm our expectations regarding the relationship between differentiation, competition, and pricing policy in the hospitality industry. Hotels use differentiation strategies to escape from the competitive pressure to reduce prices. The empirical evidence regarding main effects was generally supportive using different types of differentiation strategy (vertical and horizontal), measures of competition (number of direct competitors and geographical distance), and pricing policy (listed prices and discounts). Our empirical analysis discovered that vertical differentiation seems to be more important than horizontal differentiation in the understanding of pricing policy. Differences in hotel category explain a greater percentage of variance in both prices and discounts than hotel chain, as evidenced by the higher partial r2 and standardized coefficient size. Furthermore, the interaction of hotel category with competition reinforces its positive effect in tempering competitive pressures over prices, while the competition*chain interaction was usually insignificant. Thus, vertical differentiation seems to be a more effective way to cope with increases in competition. It appears that hotels with generally acknowledged superior quality are better prepared to deal with an increase in competitive rivalry than other organizations whose superiority is only perceived by a specific customer group. Certainly, horizontal differentiation that attracts a specific customer segment is an adequate way to reduce competitive pressure on prices, but being generally perceived as providing the best service is more effective. Based on our results, the managerial implications are straightforward. Differentiation indeed isolates companies from competitive pressures, but being better seems to be preferable to just being different, though vertical differentiation may trigger a strategic race to be the best that only a few hotels can win. Thus, increasing the objective quality of the services provided by a hotel, measured in our study by the number of stars, protects more from the pressure to reduce prices than mere membership in a hotel chain. 6. Limitations and future research Our paper is only a modest contribution to the relatively scarce empirical literature on differentiation strategies and competition. We explored two types of differentiation that are critical for hotel management, such as overall quality and chain brand, but other sources of differentiation should be studied as well to better understand how hotels can deal with an increase in competition. In addition, our empirical results are exclusively based on listed prices. Recent research has found that some particular service companies, as transportation and information technology, use different pricing policies -like negotiated pricing- along with list prices (Indounas, 2009). Though Avlonitis and Indounas (2007) report that list pricing is the pricing policy most commonly used by service companies, future research should investigate whether our reported linkage between prices, discounts, and differentiation strategies hold with other aspects of pricing policy. For instance, in the same hospitality industry both yield management and negotiated pricing are prevalent practices and it could well be the case that the effect of differentiation on these pricing policies might differ from the relationships we have uncovered in this paper. Methodologically, our results are robust to the use of distinct econometric techniques, including ordinary least squares and structural equation modeling. However, we have used a single cross section of the data and thus we are unable to estimate specifications with individual firm fixed effects. This means that we cannot completely rule out that our results may be partially driven by unobserved firm characteristics correlated both with differentiation strategies and pricing policies, though we have controlled for any location effects. Future research should confirm our findings in a panel data setting with estimations using firm fixed effects. Finally, future research may look at the differences in financial performance between hotels with different levels of quality and local competition, and whether hotels with generally acknowledged higher-quality products have been able to cope better with the most recent economic crisis than less differentiated hotels. Acknowledgment We would like to thank the Spanish Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación for the funding received for project ECO2009-10891. M. Becerra et al. / Tourism Management 34 (2013) 71e79 Appendix A. Supplementary material Supplementary data related to this article can be found online at doi:10.1016/j.tourman.2012.03.014 References Aguiló, P. M., Alegre, J., & Riera, A. (2001). Determinants of the price of German tourist packages on the Island of Mallorca. Tourism Economics, 7(1), 59e74. Avlonitis, G., & Indounas, K. (2007). An empirical examination of the pricing policies and their antecedents in the services sector. European Journal of Marketing, 41(7/8), 740e764. Bain, J. S. (1956). Barriers to new competition. Cambridge, M.A: Harvard University Press. Baum, J. A. C., & Mezias, S. (1992). Localized competition and organizational failure in the Manhattan hotel industry, 1898e1990. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37(4), 580e604. Beal, R. M., & Yasai-Ardekani, M. (2000). Performance implications of aligning CEO functional experiences with competitive strategies. Journal of Management, 26(4), 733e762. Beath, J., & Katsoulacos, Y. (1991). The economic theory of product differentiation. Cambridge University Press. Bresnahan, T. F. (1987). Competition and collusion in the American automobile industry: the 1955 price war. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 457e482. Bresnahan, T. F., & Reiss, P. C. (1991). Entry and competition in concentrated markets. Journal of Political Economy, 99(5), 977e1009. Bull, A. O. (1994). Pricing a motel’s location. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 6(6), 10e15. Campbell-Hunt, C. (2000). What have we learned from generic competitive strategy? A meta-analysis. Strategic Management Journal, 21(2), 127e145. Canina, L., Enz, C. A., & Harrison, J. S. (2005). Agglomeration effects and strategic orientations: evidence from the U.S. lodging industry. Academy of Management Journal, 48(4), 565e581. Carvell, S. A., & Herrin, W. E. (1990). Pricing in the hospitality industry: an implicit markets approach. FIU Hospitality Review, 8(2), 27e37. Caves, R. E., & Williamson, P. J. (1985). What is product differentiation, really? The Journal of Industrial Organization, 34(2), 113e132. Chamberlin, E. H. (1933). The theory of monopolistic competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Chu, R. K. S., & Choi, T. (2000). An importance-performance analysis of hotel selection factors in the Hong Kong hotel industry: a comparison of business and leisure travellers. Tourism Management, 21(4), 363e377. Dickson, P. R., & Ginter, J. L. (1987). Market segmentation, product differentiation, and marketing strategy. Journal of Marketing, 51(2), 1e10. Dranove, D., Gron, A., & Mazzeo, M. J. (2003). Differentiation and competition in HMO markets. Journal of Industrial Economics, 51(4), 433e454. Dubé, L., & Renaghan, L. M. (2000). Creating visible customer value. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 41(1), 62e72. Espinet, J. M., Saez, M., Coenders, G., & Fluvià, M. (2003). Effect on prices of the attributes of holiday hotels: a hedonic prices approach. Tourism Economics, 9(2), 165e177. Ethiraj, S. K., & Zhu, D. H. (2008). Performance effects of imitative entry. Strategic Management Journal, 29(8), 797e817. Fernández, N., & Marín, P. L. (1998). Market power and multimarket contact: some evidence from the Spanish hotel industry. Journal of Industrial Economics, 46(3), 301e315. Garrigós-Simón, F. J., & Palacios Marqués, D. (2004). Competitive strategies and firm performance: a study in the Spanish hospitality sector. Management Research: The Journal of the Iberoamerican Academy of Management, 2(3), 251e269. Hanks, R. D., Cross, R. G., & Noland, R. P. (2002). Discounting in the hotel industry. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 43(4), 94e103. Haroutunian, S., Mitsis, P., & Pashardes, P. (2005). Using brochure information for the hedonic analysis of holiday packages. Tourism Economics, 11(1), 69e84. 79 Hoffman, K., Turley, L. W., & Kelley, S. W. (2002). Pricing retail services. Journal of Business Research, 55(12), 1015e1023. Holverson, S., & Revaz, F. (2006). Perceptions of European independent hoteliers: hard and soft branding choices. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 18(5), 398e413. Homburg, C., Krohmer, H., & Workman, J. P. (1999). Strategic consensus and performance: the role of strategy type and market-related dynamism. Strategic Management Journal, 20(4), 339e357. Hung, W. T., Shang, J. K., & Wang, F. C. (2010). Pricing determinants in the hotel industry: quantile regression analysis. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 29(3), 378e384. Indounas, K. (2009). Successful industrial service pricing. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 24(2), 86e97. Ingram, P., & Baum, J. (1997). Chain affiliation and the failure of Manhattan hotels, 1898e1980. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(1), 68e102. Instituto de Estudios Turísticos. (2011). Balance del Turismo: resultados de la actividad turística en España. Madrid: Ministerio de Industria, Turismo y Comercio. Israeli, A. A. (2002). Star rating and corporate affiliation: their influence on room price & performance of hotels in Israel. Hospitality Management, 21(4), 405e424. Kotha, S., & Vadlamani, B. (1995). Assessing generic strategies: an empirical investigation of two competing typologies in discrete manufacturing industries. Strategic Management Journal, 16(1), 75e83. Lee, J., & Miller, D. (1999). People matter: commitment to employees, strategy and performance in Korean firms. Strategic Management Journal, 20(6), 579e593. Lockyer, T. (2005). Understanding the dynamics of the hotel accommodation purchase decision. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 17(6), 481e492. Makadok, R. (2010). The interaction effect of rivalry restraint and competitive advantage on profit: why the whole is less than the sum of the parts. Management Science, 56(2), 356e372. Makadok, R. (2011). The four theories of profit and their joint effects. Journal of Management, 37(5), 1316e1334. Makadok, R., & Ross, D. G. (2009). The strategic logic of product differentiation. Atlanta competitive advantage conference paper. Mazzeo, M. J. (2002). Product choice and oligopoly market structure. RAND Journal of Economics, 33(2), 221e242. Miller, D. (1986). Configurations of strategy and structure: towards a synthesis. Strategic Management Journal, 7(3), 233e249. Mintzberg, H. (1988). Generic strategies: toward a comprehensive framework. Advances in Strategic Management, 5, 1e67. Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York: Free Press. Rigall-I-Torrent, R., & Fluvià, M. (2011). Managing tourism products and destinations embedding public good components: a hedonic approach. Tourism Management, 32(2), 244e255. Rigall-I-Torrent, R., & Fluvià, M. (2007). Public goods in tourism municipalities: formal analysis, empirical evidence and implications for sustainable development. Tourism Economics, 13(3), 361e378. Rigall-I-Torrent, R., Fluvià, M., Ballester, R., Saló, A., Ariza, E., & Espinet, J. M. (2011). The effects of beach characteristics and location with respect to hotel prices. Tourism Management, 32(5), 1150e1158. Rowley, J. (1997). Principles of price and pricing policy for the information marketplace. Library Review, 46(3), 179e189. Shaked, A., & Sutton, J. (1982). Relaxing price competition through product differentiation. Review of Economic Studies, 49(155), 3e13. Thrane, C. (2005). Hedonic price models and sun-and-beach package tours: the Norwegian case. Journal of Travel Research, 43(3), 302e308. Thrane, C. (2007). Examining the determinants of room rates for hotels in capital cities: the Oslo experience. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management, 5(4), 315e323. Uriel, E., & Ferri, J. (2004). Aplicación del enfoque hedónico para medir la evolución del precio de los hoteles en España. Papeles de Economía Española, 102, 141e159. World Tourism Organization. (2011). UNWTO tourism highligths. Edition 2011. Wu, L. (1999). The pricing of a brand name product: franchising in the motel services industry. Journal of Business Venturing, 14(1), 87e102.