Lecture 1 Econ 0050 Economics of the Public Sector Dr Silvia Dal Bianco s.dalbianco@ucl.ac.uk Introduction and overview Scope, scale and trends in government spending and taxation. The role of the public sector: positive and normative perspectives. THE ECONOMICS OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR OR PUBLIC ECONOMICS Public Economics • Public economics is the study of the role of the government in the economy • Three key questions: 1) When should the government intervene in the economy? 2) How might the government intervene? 3) What is the effect of those interventions on economic outcomes? WHAT ARE THE ROLES OF GOVERNMENT AS AN ECONOMIST WOULD THINK ABOUT • Role: achieving a better outcome than the market; Economic mechanism/rationale/justification: the market mechanism is intrinsically imperfect and there are market failures (Examples: public goods, asymmetric information, externalities) • Role: redistributing income and wealth; Economic rationale: behavioural, we (as society) prefer to live in an equitable world (i.e. poverty and inequality) • Role: stabilizing the economy in the case of a shock; Economic rationale: getting the economy back on track (i.e. monetary and fiscal policy) THE ECONOMIC FUNCTIONS OF GOVERNMENTS The US public economist Richard Musgrave defined three functions of government: Allocative: economic efficiency Distributional: equity (fairness between rich and poor) Stabilisation: macroeconomic management What is the public sector? Government functions? • • Public spending Public revenues - taxation, borrowing, user fees, etc • • More broadly the role of government intervention in the economy Public spending, taxation and regulatory actions by government can be substitutes, or complementary, and understanding the impact of government on the economy may require us to look at these together. • The US public economist Richard Musgrave defined three functions of government: • Allocative - economic efficiency • Distributional - equity (fairness between rich and poor) • Stabilisation - macroeconomic management • This course is primarily about the first two, and we will cover issues of macroeconomic management in Lecture 2 WHAT IS THE RIGHT SIZE/SCOPE FOR GOVERNMENT? NORMATIVE AND POSITIVE STATEMENTS Analysing the public sector – two perspectives • Positive What explains economic behaviour in the public sector? • Normative What should be the role of the public sector in the economy? • “IS” and “OUGHT” are VERY DIFFERENT PERSPECTIVES • The two perspectives interact. • One reason we have a public sector is that it is useful. • But we need to be realistic about how governments behave, and what they can achieve. The normative perspective • Where should we draw the economic “borders” of the state? • What should the private sector do? • What should the public sector do? • Economists typically think of this in terms of market failure. • The public sector should do the things that the private sector does badly or gets wrong. • "The best way to understand market failure is to first understand market success" (Ledyard, 1987) • This helps to identify precisely what is meant by market failure. ALLOCATIVE FUNCTION OF THE GOVERNMENT The market economy and the “common good” • Adam Smith, in The Wealth of Nations, (1776) argues that a market economy has a remarkable property: • "Every individual ... generally ... neither intends to promote the public interest nor knows by how much he is promoting it. By ... directing ... industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention…. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than where he really intends to promote it" • Roughly-speaking, Smith argues that the pursuit of self-interest in a market context promotes the common good. • • Why might this be true? Why, and where, might markets fail, and policy intervention be required? Markets and voluntary transactions • Markets provide a mechanism for allocating scarce resources to their most highly-valued uses • Maximising the value of output, given resource constraints • Through a succession of voluntary transactions, by self-interested individuals, resources are allocated to their highest-valued uses, and the value of total output is maximised. • Voluntary exchange is Pareto-improving, in the sense that at least one party to the transaction is made better-off, and neither is made worse off by the transaction. • Prices play a key role • Prices transmit information about costs and values • In a competitive market economy, prices (of resources, goods, etc) reflect their opportunity costs (- ie their value in their nextbest use) The fundamental theorems of welfare economics • First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics • A perfectly-competitive market economy leads to a Pareto optimum, provided that certain conditions are met. • • • This is a claim about efficiency (in a specific sense). A market economy, under specified conditions, maximises the value of output. It makes no claims about the equity (“fairness”) of the outcome. Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics • After a suitable redistribution of initial wealth, any desired Pareto-efficient allocation can be achieved by a perfectlycompetitive market economy, provided that certain conditions are met. • • This is a claim about both efficiency and equity. If we think that the outcome of a market economy is inequitable (in a distributional sense), we can choose between a whole range of efficient outcomes, differing in terms of the distribution of welfare between people, and can implement these through initial redistributions of wealth, coupled with the market economy. Defining market failure • Stating the First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics more rigorously: If….. • there is a complete set of markets with well-defined and costlessly-enforced property rights, such that buyers and sellers can trade freely in all current and future goods and contingencies; • producers and consumers behave in an optimising manner, by maximising their benefits and minimising their costs; • all markets are perfectly-competitive, and market prices are known by all individuals and firms; • transactions costs are zero, so that the use of the price mechanism does not, in itself, consume resources; …..then the allocation of resources will be a Pareto optimum. • If the above conditions do not hold then the outcome of a market economy may not be Pareto optimal. There is "market failure". • Sources of market failure include: • the presence of monopoly power on the part of either buyers or sellers in a market • incomplete or asymmetric information, which means that some potentially Pareto-improving trades do not take place • the absence of markets for certain types of commodity, such as "public goods“ and "externalities" Public goods • Private goods are “rival” and “excludable”. • Rival: An individual's consumption of the good has an opportunity cost, in that it reduces the amount available for consumption by others. • Excludable: It is possible to prevent someone consuming the good. This means that supply of the good can be restricted to those who pay. • Public goods are non-excludable and non-rival. • Non-excludable: Once the good has been provided to one individual it is impossible to prevent others benefitting from it. • Non-rival: An individual's consumption of the good has zero opportunity cost (ie does not reduce the amount of the good available for consumption by anyone else). • • • Examples include street lighting, public order policing, the classic textbook example of a lighthouse to guide shipping, etc Non-excludability implies public goods cannot be provided by normal private sector mechanism (supplying the good in exchange for payment) Non-rivalry implies exclusion would be inefficient, even if practicable. Externalities • Externalities arise where the utility of an individual or the production function of a firm is directly affected by the decisions of another agent in the economy (individual or firm), and where this effect occurs without their consent. • Since individuals experience externalities without their consent, their interests in the matter may not be taken into account • no way they can express their preferences • An unregulated market economy will tend to have excessive levels of activities that generate negative externalities (eg pollution) à a case for regulation to correct this market failure • a caveat: the Coase Theorem indicates that sometimes individuals may be able to bargain with polluters, and this may correct externalities without the need for public intervention. Market failures due to information problems • Asymmetry of information between buyers and sellers in markets can lead to inefficient outcomes (ie market failure). • For example, people may wish to insure against major risks to their well-being, such as sickness or unemployment But if individuals face very different risks of these events, and if they know more about the risks they face than the insurer, full insurance may not be offered by private insurers. • • There may be a role for public policy in correcting this market failure • Either by regulating private insurers, • Or by providing public insurance. Equity (fairness) and the case for intervention • • A market economy leads to efficiency (ie maximising the total value of output) But it does not guarantee that the distribution of output will be equitable. • The second fundamental theorem indicates that if there are public objectives of equity, these can be dealt with through initial redistribution. • Why might people care about equity (eg about the distribution of income, or about poverty)? • Moral values: a sense of fairness • Social cohesion: ensuring that everyone feels they have a stake in society • Safety net: anyone could find that one day they are poor, sick, old, etc, and need help. What normative arguments might apply to different areas of public spending and public policy? • This is an area of considerable controversy and political disagreement. Ultimately it is a matter of judgement how far the various market failures justify public sector involvement, and whether they outweigh the disadvantages of public provision. • Examples of where each of the normative arguments for public intervention might apply include: • Public goods • Defence, policing, public infrastructure (paving, street lighting, roads, etc). • But some of these (eg certain aspects of policing, some roads, etc) have the character of private goods, and could be privately provided (private security, road tolls, etc) • Externalities • environmental policy, public transport (congestion-reducing impact), education (we all gain from living in a more educated community). • Information • Health-care, education, social care for the elderly • consumers cannot always make informed choices about quality etc • Equity • Health-care, low-income benefits, state pension, social care for the elderly, public transport, education • All involve significant redistribution when tax-financed • By the end of the course we will have seen how to weigh up these arguments more thoroughly. There is scope for government intervention but WARNING there are limitations of government • Informational limitations Doing better than the market may be possible in theory, but may sometimes require unrealistic information. • Decision-making limitations The outcome of majority voting will not please everyone, and some might have preferred the non-government outcome. • Implementational limitations Voters may not be able to ensure that the government does what they want. A principal/agent problem arises from information asymmetry, and it may be difficult to resolve this by any appropriate incentive structure. • Financing limitations Raising taxes to pay for public action can cause collateral damage in the form of the excess burden of taxation (distortionary cost). The positive perspective: What explains economic behaviour in the public sector? • This is a matter of description and explanation. The analysis can be objective, based on evidence. • People with different views about underlying social objectives (eg with different views about equity) should in principle be able to weigh up the evidence in the same way. • Philosophers sometimes characterise this form of analysis as questions of “is” rather than “ought”. • By contrast, normative issues are about what “ought” to be done. • One example of a “positive” rather than “normative” question is: What explains the growth in the scale of the public sector in the 20th century? • • • People might differ about whether they think this growth is a good thing. It is true that certain explanations tend to be more popular with people who this this growth is a bad thing (and vice versa) But in principle it’s a question about explanation of matters of fact, rather than about moral judgement Theories about the growth of government • Numerous theories, not always mutually exclusive • • • • Stage-of-development models Wagner’s Law Baumol’s Law Various models of political competition, eg • Responding to voter preferences • “Log-rolling” models (bribing voters) Ratchet effect Bureaucratic models ….and more • • • Development models and Wagner’s Law Various “stages” of development Early stage Middle stage Developed stage • Movement to urban areas • Private sector complementary to infrastructure • Increased social problems • Increased complexity of economy • Equity considerations • Social fragmentation • More infrastructure investment • New laws and legal structure • Transfer payments, public pensions, health, education, etc • Public care for elderly • Public sector spending on infrastructure investment • Also, in Wagner’s Law: • • Behavioural explanation Public spending has high income elasticity of demand Education, recreational facilities, health-care, social insurance Public expenditure rises with income as demand increases • • • Empirical support? Causality? Baumol’s Law • • • • • Explains rising costs of public sector in terms of characteristics of production technology in the public sector • Labour intensive relative to private sector • No scope for substitution between capital and labour But wage rates in public and private sector must be similar Increasing use of capital-intensive technology in the private sector à higher labour productivity à higher wages Maintaining a constant level of public sector output means higher costs How plausible is this as an explanation for the growth in public spending? • Is everything driven by technology? • Where does the political process come in? • Is there really no scope for cost-reducing technology in public sector? Federal government spending in the United States over two centuries • Thomas A. Garrett and Russell M. Rhine (2006), " On the Size and Growth of Government", Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review The ratchet effect • The model works like this: • Citizens like public spending, but dislike paying taxes • Governments (politicians?) are always happy to spend more, but in normal times are constrained by the desire to be re-elected, and so must pay attention to citizen preferences. • • Citizens consent to higher spending during wartime or other major crises (the re-election constraint becomes less binding) After the crisis, expenditure does not fall back to its previous level. • Why? • Citizens become accustomed to higher spending • Cutting spending is much harder than increasing spending (the losers protest louder than the gainers) • Higher borrowing during crisis means that higher debt service costs • Promises of a better world during war or crisis • Model gives constant spending until crisis, and then higher spending afterwards Explains what happened. Fits the data. • A model of bureaucracy (Niskanen, 1971) • • • Underlying mechanism: Government bureaucrats are able to influence spending (due to principal:agent failure), and have an interest in maximising their agency’s budget (higher salary, prestige, power). Bureaucrats’ preferences push public spending above the level warranted by voters’ preferences. • Key feature in these models is monitoring failure (principal:agent failure). • Voters, politicians and senior public sector managers cannot measure output accurately, and therefore cannot judge efficiency. • Bureaucrats know their true costs of producing output, but the people involved in the budget allocation process do not. Bureaucrats make requests for funding on a take-it-or-leave-it basis. • Absence of competitive pressures (which would drive agencies out of business if they operated like this) • Model is a rather unsophisticated view of bureaucratic behaviour. Public sector has various mechanisms (eg audit agencies), to improve monitoring and reduce budgetmaximising behaviour. • See Mueller (2003), chapter 16 To summarise • The public sector is a large part of the economy in all developed countries, and has grown rapidly in most developing countries. • We can analyse the role of the public sector – and government intervention in the market economy more generally – from various perspectives. There is an important distinction between normative and positive analyses: ie between those that discuss what role the public sector should have, and those which analyse how the public sector operates. • From a normative perspective, government can play a role in enhancing efficiency, by correcting various forms of market failure (eg through the supply of ‘public goods’). Equity objectives may also be pursued through public spending: redistributive social spending has grown rapidly in many industrialised economies. • From a positive perspective, we can identify various factors and processes which may explain the growth of public spending. Not all of these imply improvements in efficiency. Some indicate that government failure may be important. • The role of public spending in the economy is an area of intense political controversy in most countries. While this course will focus on the key economic issues, we should not lose sight of the crucial political dimension underlying government behaviour and public attitudes.