In the most recent decades, there have been major alterations in what is viewed and treated as private and what is considered and treated as public. Markets have been permitted to merge across national borders and develop into new product categories as a result of economic liberalization, technological progress, and privatization efforts. In addition to this, an ever-increasing number of privately held companies are opting to become publicly traded companies by offering their shares on public stock exchanges. As a result, the purpose of this essay seeks to examine the concept of private versus public goods through the use of example and illustrations. Furthermore, show how they can enhance development in Zambia. This essay's outline begins with defining critical terms before delving into the principal body. A conclusion based on the discussion presented in the essay needs to be presented in the final paragraph. Private goods are those that need a fee to obtain, and when one is used by another, the resource is effectively depleted. Therefore, if two people are competing for the same good and one person's consumption of it prevents the other from using it, the good in question is a private good. Private commodities include things like restaurant meals, grocery shopping, travel, and cell phones. In this sense, a private good is anything that can only be used or eaten by one person at a time. For instance, many everyday things fall under this category because they are not available to anyone who does not already have access to them. Consumables like food and toilet paper are two examples that are essentially destroyed or rendered useless for their intended use after usage; both are also regarded as private commodities. In a free market economy, nonpublic goods make up the majority of consumer purchases, and supply and demand helps determine their prices. Pure private goods are excludable and rivalrous due to both the ability of producers to exclude some customers based on their ability or willingness to pay as well as the reality that one person's use of a commodity impacts the amount accessible for consumption by another. In reality, the characteristics of private products are binary: either they are excludable or rivalrous (Bailey, 1995). Some goods and services will always be provided inefficiently because of market imperfections brought on by a lack of excludability and competition. Externalities and spillover effects can also result in inefficiencies in the creation and consumption of private goods. When a good or service is viewed as having a "positive externality" by those who benefit from its creation and use but are not directly involved in a market transaction. For instance, Zambias education makes people more knowledgeable and productive citizens, which benefits people both personally and collectively in a variety of ways. Zambia Private markets would underperform in the presence of such favorable externalities because the firm's production costs are inflated and the profits are understated (Chen, 2021). On the other side, negative externalities happen when producing or using a product places a hardship on a non- 1 participant. Air pollution and noise pollution are two examples of negative externalities. Private markets will overproduce when there are negative externalities because the firm's production costs are overstated and its revenues are inflated (Sandler, 2012). Due to the nature of private property, numerous issues of justice and fairness arise. It is undesirable to rely only on private markets for items like food and clean water, especially in countries where income is unequally distributed, as excludability means that different people will receive variable quantities of a good or service. In a similar vein, if health care is provided as a private good, the underprivileged and those without health insurance might not be able to purchase it. Many people consider access to health care to be a fundamental human right, and as such, they frequently support the government providing it. These conflicts show the necessity for public policy in determining which private assets should be designated as public and serve as illustrations of the tension that can develop when attempting to strike a balance between the requirements of the majority and the interests of the minority (Chen, 2021). A good or service that is accessible to all members of society is known as a public good. Governments often offer these kinds of services, and taxes pay for them. Water and fresh air are examples of necessities that fall under the category of public goods (Fernando, 2022). Both their non-excludability and their scalability set public goods apart (positive or negative externalities). Nobody can consciously choose to shirk their obligation. From a business standpoint, it is wasteful and unworkable to base a pricing model on a service that is only accessible to a small number of users. A good becomes accessible to anybody who wants some of it when the ability to privately possess it is lost (Hindriks & Myles, 2006). The second situation is non-rivalry, which happens when everyone gains from a product even though they did not contribute to its creation. Because they don't care, they lack the motivation to contribute to the common good in this situation. Theoretically, it is impossible to deny anyone access to something that benefits certain people without also granting those benefits to the rest of the populace. This concept was first put forth by economist Paul Samuelson in 1954: individual spending has no bearing on other people's consumption (Sandler, 2012). An excellent example of this is Zambia's national defense. Once the government decides to spend billions of Kwacha on national defense, everyone residing in the country, whether legally or illegally, will benefit from the freedom of being protected and homeland security, regardless of the level of defense they need or how much they value it. Additionally, the majority of things have finite quantities; once they're gone, none more will be made. A public good, on the other hand, has zero marginal cost 2 of production, allowing ever-increasing numbers of people to profit from it throughout time. Public goods include things like a mountain view, clean air, radio waves, and law enforcement (Smith, 2010). In the area of study and research, there is a second occurrence. In a more complex sense, education and research are public goods. It's easy to discourage students from attending school because a degree in engineering from a prominent university like the University of Zambia or Copperlbet is in high demand. Regardless of how much they (or the public) invest in their own education, individuals benefit from a more educated population in a non-excludable and non-rivalrous way. An educated culture makes it simpler for businesses to succeed, and a healthy economy helps everyone, not just those with a high level of education. A thriving economy makes it difficult to exclude others, because one person's gain is not lessened by another's. Scientific ideas also fall under the rubric of public goods (Boldrin & Levine, 2008). Once a newly formed idea (such a scientific theory) has been developed, it cannot be stopped from being profitable (unless a patent protects the concept; see below), and this profit is nonrivalrous. It is essential to recognize the distinction between a concept and its physical manifestation. For instance, while specific steam engines are excludable and competitive, the notion of a steam engine is a public asset (Chen, 2021). The most severe example of externalities is frequently regarded as being public benefits. Here, the question is whether or whether the public good produces externalities that are positive (like research and development) or negative (like criminality) (e.g., pollution). The issue is that every person has the power to alter the course of history, for better or worse. This cannot be avoided. Because of this, those who are harmed by pollution cannot demand that polluters make up for it, and people who profit from a positive externality shouldn't be taxed. Two classical economists, David Hume and Adam Smith, both argued that government action is required to supply products and services with societal benefits. These services cannot be adequately provided by volunteer groups or individual efforts. The government is supposed to correct market inefficiency. However, it has been suggested that public benefits result in waste and unexpected effects (Batina & Ihori, T, 2005). This is due to the possibility of market allocation inefficiencies when non-rivalry and non-excludability exist. The free-rider conundrum is a significant problem involving public goods. Free riders utilize a service without contributing anything to it, which can make it less available for other users. This is when people abuse a service. The risk lies in the fact that no one wants to supply the good because they can all free ride, therefore dependency develops as one person waits for the other to produce the good. As a result, in a free market economy, the good from which society benefits may be delivered insufficiently or not at all. This is somewhat disputed because free riding can only be considered an 3 economic problem when it results in Pareto inefficiency and either no production of public goods or production of those goods insufficiently (Chen, 2021). For instance, in Zambia, the National Health Service is mostly provided by the government and funded by regular taxation. Healthcare is similar to other public goods in that it has a low marginal cost when compared to the entire cost of providing care for a patient. Therefore, everyone has benefited from free, universal public healthcare, whether or not they have contributed to the system. But because it is challenging to stop someone from utilizing healthcare while paying taxes, this has led to the free rider issue. Excluding those who make no financial or other contributions to healthcare would be extremely expensive and unpopular, therefore they would still get free care. As a result of rising demand and falling supply, the market may become unbalanced (Sandler, 2012). A great public choice mechanism that encourages people to be upfront about their desire for spending is known as "demand transparency." Demand revelation has the drawback that if everyone uses the same item, it is hard to know how much of each person's preferred good they want. As a result, regardless of where and by whom a public good is produced, the issue of demand revelation still exists. By offering incorrect information, people may unintentionally mislead others or waste public resources while trying to enhance their own well-being through demand disclosure (Batina, Ihori, 2005). As a result, the market fails because customers' understanding of the value, quality, and other attributes of the goods they receive is incomplete and inaccurate, and society as a whole is unable to accurately reflect their true preferences. According to economist Paul Samuelson, consumers are willing to pay a range of prices for public goods of varied degrees of quality. As a result, the overall market demand for public goods is determined by vertically adding up each individual demand curve. The market demand can be used to determine how much consumers are willing to pay overall for each attainable level of public sound output. The allocation is efficient if the marginal cost of generating the public benefit is lower than the total willingness to pay for it. If and only if the marginal benefits of the public goods provided match the marginal costs of providing those benefits, then the allocation is considered optimal (Hindriks & Myles, 2006). The first line of defense against the free rider problem may be coercion and general taxes. Free riders can no longer use public services if there are mandatory costs. By regularly enforcing the collection of taxes, the government often participates in this process. Only when everyone is required to contribute will the public good be funded, putting an end to free riding. However, it may be argued that some individuals may really be in a worse situation now that the products are no longer given away for free. 4 However, it is believed that the only solution to the public good problem is coercive force (Fernando, 2022). The second choice is called the Coase Theorem, after the well-known economist Ronald Coase. He supported a system in which those who would benefit from a good public good may bargain with one another to come to a mutually beneficial agreement. Since there would be no transaction costs and at least one party would be the owner of the good, the assumption was made. He reasoned that with decreased transaction costs, it would be simpler for those who benefited from the public good to find one another and secure adequate output(ibid). In conclusion, Private and public goods are separated. Individuals and efficient markets can allocate private goods. Pure public goods, which are nonrival and non-excludable, cannot be divided. Because of these factors, public goods require a mechanism that prioritizes public interest over profit. Private and public goods aren't as distinct as once thought. Natural resources are rivalrous and non-excludable (common-pool goods), while toll roads and cable TV are non-rivalrous and excludable (club goods). In most cases, the government provides public goods requiring collective action. Even limitedgovernment scholars support state provision of public goods (such as a legal system and defense). Minimal-state theorists focus on public goods because the free market can't meet Pareto optimum. Because private companies cannot profitably provide some public goods (like national defense) because of the difficulty of imposing payment to recover the cost, or because the total costs and benefits to society cannot be incorporated into the market price of the good, governments are often the only viable providers (externalities). Failures and externalities justify government intervention. The state should address market imperfections and provide public goods the market can't. In order to provide public goods without excluding nonpayers, society needs a public agent. Private companies aren't willing to invest in public goods unless they can make a profit. As they are socially valuable, the public sector must provide public goods. 5 References Bailey, S, J. (1995). Public sector economics: Theory, policy and Practice. New York: Mcmillan . Batina, R, G., & Ihori, T,. (2005). Public goods: Theories and Evidence . Chen, J. (2021, January 03). Private Good. Retrieved from Investopedia: https://www.investopedia.com/terms/p/privategood.asp#:~:text=A%20private%20good%20is%20the,be%20consumed%20at%20no%20cos t. Fernando, J. (2022, March 20). Public Good. Retrieved from Investopedia: https://www.investopedia.com/terms/p/public-good.asp Hindriks, J., & Myles, G. D. (2006). Intermediate public economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Sandler, T. (2012). Collective action: Theory and applications. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Smith, A. (2010). The theory of moral sentiments. New York: Penguin Classics. 6