STAFF PAPERS MARGARET R. KELLY Chair, Editorial Committee IAN S. McDoNALD Editor and Deputy Chair RozLYN CoLEMAN Assistant Editor Editorial Committee Mohsin S. Khan Mario I. Blejer Guillermo A. Calvo G. Russell Kincaid Jose Fajgenbaum Malcolm D. Knight Yed P. Gandhi Paul R. Masson Susan M. Schadler David J. Goldsbrough Peter lsard Subhash M. Thakur Among the responsibilities of the International Monetary Fund, as set forth in its Articles of Agreement. is the obligation to "act as a centre for the collection and exchange of information on monetary and financial problems." Staff Papers makes available to a wider audience papers prepared by the members of the Fund staff. The views presented in the papers are those of the authors and are not to be interpreted as necessarily indicating the position of the Executive Board or of the Fund. To facilitate electronic storage and retrieval of bibliographic data. Staff Papers has adopted the subject classification scheme developed by the Journal ofEconomic Literature. Subscription: US$50.00 a volume or the approximate equivalent in the currencies of most countries. Four numbers constitute a volume. Single copies may be purchased at $16.00. Individual academic rate to full-time professors and students of universities and colleges: $25.00 a volume. Subscriptions and orders should be sent to: International Monetary Fund Publication Services 700 19th Street. N. W. Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A. Telephone: (202) 623-7430 Telefax: (202) 623-7201 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS Vol. 40 No. 3 SEPTEMBER ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 1993 EDITOR'S NOTE The Editor invites from contributors outside the Fund brief comments (not more than I ,000 words) on pub­ lished articles in Staff Papers. These comments should be addressed to the Editor, who will forward them to the author of the original article for reply. Both the com­ ments and the reply will be considered for publication. The term "country," as used in this publication, may not refer to a territorial entity that is a state as understood by international law and practice; the term may also cover some territorial entities that are not states but for which statistical data are maintained and provided internationally on a separate and independent basis. <e 1993 by the International Monetary Fund International Standard Serial Number: lSSN 0020-8027 The U.S. Library of Congress has cataloged this serial publication as follows: International Monetary Fund Staff papers- International Monetary Fund. v. 1- Feb. 1950[Washington) International Monetary Fund. v. tables. diagrs. Three no. a year. 23 cm. 1950-1977: four no. a year. 1978- lndexes: Vols. 1-27. 1950-80. ISSN 0020-8027 I. Foreign = I v. Staff papers - International Monetary Fund. exchange-Periodical s . 2. Commerce-Periodicals. 3. Currency question-Periodicals. HG3810.15 332.082 53-35483 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CONTENTS Vol. 40 No. 3 SEPTEMBER 1993 Auctions: Theory and Applications ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA • 485 Testing the Neoclassical Theory of Economic Growth: A Panel Data Approach MALCOLM KNIGHT, NORMAN WAYZA, and DELANO V ILLANUEVA • 512 Capital and Trade as Engines of Growth in France: An Application of Johansen's Cointegration Methodology DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM • 542 French-German Interest Rate Differentials and Time-Varying Realignment Risk FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA • 567 Stabilization Programs and External Enforcement: Experience from the 1920s JULIO A. SANTAELLA • 584 Risk Taking and Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Nontradable Human Capital ZULJU HU • 622 Cash-Flow Tax PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRIST IAN SCHUTTE • 638 Portfolio Performance of the SDR and Reserve Currencies: Tests Using the ARCH Methodology MICHAEL G. PAPAIOANNOU and T UGRUL TEMEL • 663 lnterenterprise Arrears in Transforming Economies: The Case of Romania ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN • 680 Shorter Paper The Budget Deficit in Transition: A Cautionary Note VITO TANZI • 697 lll ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CONTENTS IMF Working Papers • 708 IMF Papers on Policy Analysis and Assessmellf • 709 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF Staff Papers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) ll:> 1993 International Monetary Fund Auctions Theory and Applications ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA • This paper assesses alternative auction techniques for pricing and allocat­ ing various financial instruments, such as government securities, central bank refinance credit, and foreign exchange. Before recommending ap­ propriate formats for auctioning these items, the paper discusses basic auction formats, assessing the advantages and disadvantages of each, based on the existing, mostly theoretical, literature. It is noted that auction techniques can be usefully employed for a broad range of items and that their application is ofparticular relevance to the impetus in many parts of the world toward establishing mDrket-oriented economies. [JEL C70, D40, D44, D60, P21, P23, P50] UCfiONS an important role in economics. In their most basic form, they are one of the ways in which various commodities and A financial assets are allocated to individuals and firms, particularly in a PLAY market-oriented setting. Examples of items that are commonly auctioned include original art, livestock, fresh fish, used cars, construction con­ tracts, and a range of financial assets such as government securities, central bank refinance credit, foreign exchange, and equity shares. These *Robert A. Feldman is Assistant to the Director of the IMP's Research Department and holds a Ph.D. in economics from the University of Wisconsin. RaJnish Mehra is Professor of Finance at the University of California at Santa Barbara and holds a Ph.D. in finance from the Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie-Mellon University. A first draft of this paper was completed while Professor Mehra was a visiting scholar in the Research Depart­ ment. The authors would like to thank Eduardo Borensztein, V.V. Chari, Edward Dumas, Chi-Fu Huang, Peter Isard, Mohsin S. Khan, Paul Milgrom, Merton Miller, Edward Prescott, Cheng-Zhong Qin, and Vincent Reinhart for numerous helpful discussions and suggestions. 485 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 486 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA items exhibit considerable diversity, but a common denominator among them is that the valuation of each item varies enough to preclude any direct pricing schedule. The use of auction mechanisms to guide price determination and the allocation process can offer certain advantages, which this paper dis­ cusses. The major effort taking place in many parts of the world to establish market-oriented institutions makes a paper on these mecha­ nisms opportune. Against this background, one of the main goals of this paper is to survey the extensive literature on auctions in order to shed some light on the advantages and disadvantages of various auction tech­ niques. 1 A second main goal is to assess the application of alternative auction techniques to various financial instruments, using the three examples of government securities, central bank refinance credit, and foreign exchange. We emphasize that the implications of theoretical models do not easily carry over into real world settings. Therefore, our recommendations on the appropriate auction technique for different assets depend heavily on individual country circumstances. Indeed, the array of country experi­ ences would suggest no clear-cut answer to the question of which is the appropriate auction technique. In this connection, it is instructive to note that in looking at individual country experiences across a range of countries-both industrial and developing-techniques used to auction similar items vary considerably. This experience includes several countries that in auctioning govern­ ment securities have awarded them at whatever price was bid (including France, Germany, Japan, and the United Kingdom) and others that have charged a single, market-clearing price (Denmark and Switzerland).2 Some countries have recently changed the way they run their auctions. Mexico in 1990 shifted from a multiple-price to a uniform-price approach for treasury bills and then in 1993 shifted back.3 Italy in 1991 switched · 1 Reviews of the literature on auctions in different contexts can be found elsewhere, and our paper builds on the insights of these authors. See Maskin ( 1992 ) , McAfee andMcMillan (1987), Milgrom (1987, 1989), Milgrom and Weber ( 1982 ) , and Smith (1987). In relation to recent assessments of the U.S. govern­ ment securities market, excellent reviews of selected aspects of auction tech­ niques are contained in Bikhchandaoi and Huang (1992), Chari and Weber (1992), Reinhart (1992), and the Joint Report on the Government Securities Market (1992). 2 The former is called a discriminatory or multiple-price auction and the latter a uniform-price auction. Definitions of different auction formats are provided in the next section of this paper. For the industrial countries, a very useful summary of the auction techni ques used to sell government debt is found in the Joint Report on the Government Securities Market (1992), pp. B-29-B-40. 3 See Umlauf (1991) and Hernandez (1993). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCTIONS from uniform to multiple pricing in its local-currency treasury bill auc­ tions, but has auctioned its treasury bonds and ECU-denominated bills on a uniform-price basis. Currently, in the United States, the U.S. Trea­ sury is experimenting with uniform-price auctions for some government securities while also running discriminatory auctions. Relevant examples are also found for foreign exchange and refinance credit. Several countries have conducted discriminatory-price or Dutch auctions for refinance credit (Romania) and for foreign exchange (Bolivia, Ghana, Jamaica, and Zambia). Other countries have used uniform-price auctions for refinance credit (the former Czechoslovakia) and for foreign exchange (Guinea, Nigeria, and Uganda).4 Double auctions have been used for foreign exchange (Romania). I. Types of Auctions An auction is simply an allocative mechanism. Since auctions can play valuable role in the price discovery process, they are most useful in a situations where the item being auctioned does not have a fixed or determinable market value or where the seller is uncertain about the market price. These situations typically involve some degree of informa­ tional and cost asymmetries in the sense that economic agents differ in their access to, and evaluation of, information pertaining to the auctioned commodity. Auctions may be for a single object or unit-as is typical in the proceedings of such well-known auction houses as Sotheby's and Christie's-or for a "lot" of nonidentical items, as with land tracts (a practice in many countries) or used cars (a practice in the wholesale U.S. automobile market). Alternatively, auctions may be for multiple units of a homogeneous item, such as gold or treasury securities. Our concern in this paper is mostly with auctions for multiple homo­ geneous assets, such as government securities, refinance credit, and foreign exchange. The theoretical literature relies frequently, however, on the assumption of a single unit being auctioned. Partly for this reason, the definitions given below cover both single- and multiple-unit auctions. Of course, auctions of single units are also relevant in economics. For example, countries' efforts to privatize may involve auctioning a single item, such as a public enterprise. Following the pioneering work of Vickery (1961), we distinguish be• These examples for foreign exchange are from Quirk and others (1987). It is interesting to note that when the International Monetary Fund auctioned part of its gold stock in 1976-80, the auctions were divided between discriminatory first-price and uniform second-price formats. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 488 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA tween four primary types of auctions, classifying each according to its corresponding institutional arrangement. Each of the following classifi­ cations entails its own set of rules that affects the bidding strategies of the auction participants and therefore the outcome of the auction itself. English auction. This type of auction is also referred to as an ascending­ price auction and is commonly seen in the art world. It is perhaps the most familiar form of auction. Starting with a low first bid or a specified reservation price-that is, a price below which the item will not be sold-the auctioneer solicits increasingly higher bids. As the bid price increases, there are normally fewer takers. The process continues in the case of a single item until that item is "sold!" to the last and highest bidder for the amount bid (see Figure la). In an auction involving multiple units, the process continues until arriving at a price at which the fixed amount supplied at auction is just matched by total demand. Dutch auction . This type of auction is also referred to as a descending­ price auction . It gets its name from the technique used in the Netherlands for auctioning produce and fresh flowers. The bidding commences at a high level and is progressively lowered until a buyer claims the item being auctioned by shouting "mine!" (see Figure lb). Practitioners have long since streamlined the proceedings through the use of an automated "clock" with a hand running counterclockwise through progressively lower prices. Any buyer can stop the descent by pressing a button when an acceptable price is reached. When multiple units are being auctioned, there are normally more willing takers as the price declines; this process continues until arriving at a price whereby the fixed amount supplied is just matched by total demand. First-price auction. This type of auction is an example of a sealed-bid auction, as opposed to the above two formats, which are open auctions. The term "first price" is commonly used when referring to the sale of a single item. The highest bidder is awarded the item at a price equal to the amount bid. When multiple units are auctioned at the same time, this procedure is called a discriminatory auction. The sealed bids are sorted from high to low, and the auctioned items are awarded at the highest bid prices until the supply is exhausted. Thus, the auction discriminates among bidders in the sense that they can pay different prices according to the amount they bid (see Figure lc). The terminology "first-price" or "discriminatory" auction follows the academic literature. In the financial community-and here is where one source of confusion may arise-this type of auction is referred to as an English auction; an exception being in the United Kingdom where it is called an American auction. This type of auction is also referred to as a multiple-price (or, in some cases, a multiple-yield) auction. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCTIONS 489 Figure I. Auction Formats a. Ascending-price (English) auction Price b. Descending-price (Dutch) Price Awarded price Awarded price Quantity Quamity d. Uniform-price auction c. Discriminatory auction Price auction Awarded prices : D Auction size /I I I I I Price Au,·tion siu :/ Awarded price J I I I I i I I I I Source: Reinhan ( 1992). Quantity Quantity ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 490 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA Second-price auction. This type of auction is also a sealed-bid auction. When a single item is auctioned, the highest bidder is awarded the item at a price equal to the highest unsuccessful bid-hence, the name second price. The multiple-unit extension of the second-price, sealed-bid auction is referred to as a uniform-price auction (or competitive auction), since all winning bidders receive the auctioned items at the same price (see Fig­ ure ld). Here, some confusion in terminology also arises from the use of the term "second price" or "uniform price" auction because in the finan­ cial community these auctions are referred to as "Dutch auctions," although this would appear to be a misnomer.5 This type of auction is also referred to as a marginal-price auction. A final type of auction worthy of mention is a double auction. Using this format, both sellers and buyers submit bids, which are then ranked from highest to lowest to generate demand and supply profiles. From these profiles, the maximum quantity exchanged can be determined by matching sell offers, starting with the lowest price and moving up, with demand bids, starting with the highest price and moving down. The "equilibrium" price may, however, be indeterminate using this method­ ology. 6 An example of a double auction is the market-clearing mechanism in organized exchanges, Like stock exchanges and commodity markets, where a specialist matches bid and ask prices in a "specialist's book," making the market for a particular security traded on the exchange. In addition to the institutional arrangements governing the workings of a particular type of auction, a second aspect of classifying different auction mechanisms concerns how each bidder values the item(s) on the auction block. Economists customarily distinguish between "private­ value" auctions and "common-value" auctions. The former term refers to objects acquired for personal consumption with no primary motive to resell. The bidder therefore has a personal maximum that he or she would be willing to pay, quite independent of the valuations of rival bidders. If this is the case, one speaks of the bidder as displaying "independent private values." A frequently cited example is an object of art purchased for personal pleasure rather than for profitable resale. The same painting, however, can be purchased to be resold. The bid 5 The traditional Dutch auction follows a discriminatory, not a uniform, multiple-unit pricing procedure. 6 This is most easily illustrated by a simple example. Suppose (i) there are four sellers of foreign exchange who each offer to sell one unit at the respective prices of 100, 200, 300, and 400 units of domestic currency and (ii) there are four demanders of foreign exchange who each demand one unit at the respective prices of 400, 300, 250, and 50 units of domestic currency. In this example, supply and demand would match at three units of foreign exchange; the equilibrium price would be indeterminate in the sense of lying between 200 and 250. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCTIONS 491 is then predicated on both personal valuation and the valuation of prospective buyers in the secondary market. This situation is referred to as the common-value assumption because each bidder places the same value on the object-that is, each one tries to estimate what the object is ultimately worth on the basis of the same objective standard. This common value may be an unobservable variable at the time of the auction, as would be the case when a government security is purchased to be resold later in the secondary market. In general, aU auctions are "correlated-value auctions," a category that includes the common-value and private-value auctions as polar ex­ amples. This concept of correlated values captures the notion that in each auction situation, bidders' values are to some extent related to each other: they are correlated. Milgrom and Weber (1982) use the term "affiliation" to express the same idea more precisely. However, as Ras­ musen (1990, p. 246) points out, "as always in modeling, we must trade off descriptive accuracy against simplicity, and private value versus com­ mon value is an appropriate simplification." We retain this distinction throughout the paper. For the four basic types of auctions just defined, Table 1 summarizes the rules associated with each institutional arrangement (see Rasmusen (1990)).7 It also outlines some simple aspects of the bidder's strategy, which are implied by the rules and payoffs to the bidder. II. Auction Theory Since auctions follow well-defined rules, they can be viewed as "games," making the application of game theory an appropriate paradigm for gaining insight into their dynamics. 8 But to gain these insights, the theoretical literature relies on a number of simplifying assumptions. Although these assumptions allow one to derive key results, they make the application of auction theory to real world settings an 7 In contrast to what we term the four basic auction types, the theoretical literature on double auctions is sparse and the strategy and payoffs associated with them are difficult to summarize, as is done for the others in Table 1. Because of these considerations, we exclude double auctions from the next section, which focuses on theory. 8 Although double auctions are excluded from this section, the interested reader can turn to Wilson (1979, 1986), Friedman (1984), and Easley and Ledyard (1982) for technical articles that demonstrate the problems of modeling strategic behavior in this framework. Double auctions are applicable, as we will see, to foreign exchange fixings. More broadly, however, the operations of such well­ established markets as those for equities, in which dealers and brokers match supply and demand in their books, can be viewed as examples of double auctions. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 492 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA Table 1. Characteristics of Different Types of Auctions Expected payoffs Bidder's valuation of auctioned item(s) minus his or her highest bid. Type English, or ascending-price, open-bid auction Rules Seller announces initial low bid, which is progressively increased until demand falls to match the fixed amount at auction. It is important to note that bidders are able to reassess bids during the bidding process. Strategy Bidder's strategy is a function of (a) personal valuation, (b) prior assessment of rival valuations, and (c) new information obtained from the bidding process. Dutch, or descendingprice, open-bid auction Seller announces initial high bid, which is progressively lowered until demand rises to match the fixed amount at auction. Strategy is a function of (a) personal valuation, (b) prior assessment of rival bids, and (c) no new information being obtained from the bidding process. Bidder's vatuation of the auctioned item(s) minus his or her actual bid. First-price, sealed-bid auction; or, with multiple objects, discriminatory auction Bidders submit written bids in ignorance of all others. Highest bidder wins the item and pays the amount bid. Same as for Dutch auction above. Same as for Dutch auction above. Second-price, sealed-bid auction; or, with multiple objects, uniform-price auction Bidders submit written bids in ignorance of all others. Highest bidder wins the item and pays the amount of the second highest bid. Same as for Dutch auction above. Bidder's vaJuation of the auctioned item minus the second highest bid. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCTIONS 493 exercise to be undertaken with caution. In addition to reviewing some common assumptions, this section discusses auction strategy, first from the bidder's and then from the seller's perspective, before turning to issues of economic efficiency and the incentives to collude under different auction formats. The assumptions most commonly used, depending on the context, are (1) Bidders are risk neutral;9 (2) Either the independent private-value assumption applies or the common-value assumption applies; and (3) The bidders are symmetric-that is, they use the same distri­ bution function to estimate their valuations-implying bidders cannot discern differences among their competitors. Following the earlier theoretical literature, it is initially assumed that one item is being auctioned. 0 Bidder's Perspective 1 We briefly examine bidding strategies that emerge from the intersec­ tion of auction format rules with the earlier stated assumptions regarding bidder values. Private-Value Assumption If, as is fairly standard, the English auction has a specified bid incre­ ment, then, in the limit, as the increment becomes infinitesimal, the English and second-price formats result in the same price and allocation, or more formally in the same "normal form." Similarly, the Dutch auction is strategically equivalent to the first-price, sealed-bid auction since there is a one-to-one mapping between the strategy sets and the equilibrium of the two games. In both of the latter formats, no relevant information is revealed in the course of the proceedings, only at the conclusion of the auction when it is too late for any bidder to act upon or change a bid. In the first-price format, the bid is relevant only if it is the highest. Likewise, in the Dutch format, the stopping price or bid is irrelevant unless it is the highest (the winning bid stops the price descent). 9Risk neutrality is assumed in order to focus on profit-maximizing behavior. Many of the theoretical results do not hold when risk aversion is introduced. 1° Clearly, any auction needs to ensure the q uality of the bidding participants (such as their credit risk) to avoid problems li ke adverse selection, whereby the riskiest bidders always bid the highest prices. The theoretical literature, by comparison, assumes auction participants are homogeneous. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 494 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA Common-Value Assumption Under this assumption the equivalence between the English and the second-price auction does not hold, a although between the Dutch and first-price auctions it continues to hold. See Milgram and Weber (1982) and Smith (1987). What optimal strategies evolve in the course of the competitive bidding process under the common-value assumption? Take the example of com­ petitive bidding for a construction contract. In this case, the contract is awarded to the lowest bidder. Assume that bidders are identical except that their valuations are based on information to which they (differen­ tially) have access. In calculating his or her bid, each player faces a trade-off between the probability of winning the contract and the ex­ pected profit if he or she does. If all contenders specify their bids by adding a markup to their estimated costs, the winning bid will have the lowest estimated project costs and will, on average, be too low. In the case of auctions for items such as art or mining rights, where the highest bidder wins, the winning bidder is faced with the realization that his or her assessment of the item's value exceeded all other bidders' assessments. That is to say, the highest bidder wins the auction but loses by decreasing his or her expected profit! This contrary observation is termed the "win­ ner's curse." The best-known study in economic literature of this phe­ nomenon is by Capen, Clapp, and Campbell (1971), who look at the bidding for offshore mining rights auctioned by the U.S. Government. One implication of the "winner's curse" is that inexperienced bidders profit less than expected since such bidders are more likely to place the highest bid when they have overestimated the value ofthe item. A bidder would be disconcerted to discover that he or she bad outbid 20 experts! Experienced bidders are aware of the winner's curse and factor it into their calculations. The winner's curse has several implications for optimal bidding strate­ gies. In a first-price auction, for example, the winner by implication can expect a lower profit when he or she attempts to resell, since competing bidders display a lower valuation of the object. Being aware of this possibility, bidders are likely to "shade" their bids below their own estimates in an effort to move closer toward the market consensus. 12 Other things being equal, as the number of bidders increases, it is prudent to bid more conservatively, since the range of the distribution of bids, and 11 In an English auction, as noted in Table 1, new information is obtained from the bidding process, which is not the case with a second-price auction. 12 Because it is advantageous to better anticipate the market consensus, market participants may be encouraged to devote resources to the competitive assessment of rival bids and information. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCTIONS 495 thus the highest bid, is likely to expand with the number of bidders. Thus, the winner's curse is reinforced as the number of bidders increases, creating a greater shading of bids below their true estimate. Second, the gap between the highest bid and the "true" value of the item decreases as the amount of information available about the auc­ tioned item rises. The winner's curse is therefore muted by increasing information about the value of an auctioned item. With the curse muted, it is optimal for bidders to be less conservative in their bids, implying that, as more information is available, bidding will become more aggressive and the selling price will, on average, be higher. Milgrom (1987, p. 6) provides a useful summing up: "The most impor­ tant lessons to be learned . . . are that the returns in bidding come from cost and information advantages, that naive bidding strategies can squan­ der these advantages and that bidders without some advantage have Little hope of earning much profit, but could with a little bit of carelessness suffer large losses." Seller's Perspective The two assumptions described above also influence and modify seller behavior. Private-Value Assumption Under specific assumptions, the theoretical literature demonstrates that all four basic types of auctions will yield the same expected price and revenue to the seller. 13 This central result in auction theory, termed "the revenue equivalence theorem" (Vickery (1961)), assumes that bidders display symmetric and independent private values in auctions that are free of distortions and that have only a single unit sold. The theorem does not imply that every realization of the game, independent of the auction type, will yield the same price and revenue, only that the expected price and revenue are the same. The revenue equivalence theorem does imply, however, that the specific auction format chosen by the seller in this stylized theoretical world is not crucial, since each format yields, on average, the same payoffs to the seller. A construct termed the "revelation principle" is used to prove a num­ ber of theoretical propositions in auction theory, including the revenue equivalence theorem. It describes the optimal mechanism from the 13This section is partly based on Chari and Weber (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 496 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA seller's point of view.14 The term "mechanism" in this context acts as a black box: a process that takes bi:ds as inputs and produces the winning bidder and the winning price as outputs. Thus, each of the auction forms can be viewed as a mechanism. In a direct mechanism, each bidder is simply asked to report his or her personal valuation of the item. A mechanism is termed "incentive compatible" if the auction is structured in such a way that it is in the bidder's interest to state honestly his or her personal valuation of the object-for example, if the proceedings require each bidder to state a valuation and the object is awarded to the bidder with the highest valuation. Under the assumption of private value, this is precisely what occurs in the first-price, sealed-bid auction. Each bidder is optimizing when he or she submits the bid, and the revelation principle designs the payoff structure so as to make it optimal to be honest. Note that the revelation principle is a purely theoretical construct, and few, if any, resource allocation procedures used in practice are direct incentive-compatible mechanisms. Its main application is to facilitate the search for a resource allocation mechanism that is optimal, subject to the constraints of asymmetric information. 15 Common-Value Assumption Under the set of common-value assumptions, we see different results and also move closer to some of the auctioned items with which we are concerned, such as government securities; in these auctions, assets are acquired with the intention of profitable resale in secondary markets. More specifically, it can be shown that the revenue equivalence theorem does not necessarily hold under the assumption of common values when, in determining a bid, an individual bidder faces common uncertainties, such as energy prices, pollution considerations, and changing consumer tastes, that might impinge on possible resale values. In these circum­ stances, Milgram and Weber (1982) demonstrate that the expected reve­ nue from selling a single object in one of the four auction formats can be ranked from highest to lowest: (1) The English, ascending-price auction; (2) The second-price, sealed-bid auction; 14 The literature distinguishes between direct and indirect mechanisms. The direct revelation principle states roughly that corresponding to an eq uilibrium outcome of an in direct mechanism there is a direct mechanism that will generate the same outcome. 15 A detailed discussion of the optimal auction mechanism when the indepen­ dent private-value assumption is relaxed is beyond the scope of this paper. For an expanded discussion, see Cremer and McLean (1985a, 1985b). They provide a method, based on an assumption of correlated values, that involves the use of a lottery plus participation in a subsequent second-price auction. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCflONS 497 (3) Tied: The Dutch auction and the first-price, sealed-bid auction. The rankings clearly illustrate the advantage of increased information. As an English auction proceeds, it reveals information about rival bidders' valuations and permits a dynamic updating of an individual bidder's personal valuation. This updating results in more aggressive bidding, thereby raising the seller's revenue. A first-price (discrimina­ tory) auction awards the object to the highest bidder. Thus, other bidders place a lower value on the object, reducing the profit that the winning bidder can hope for in the resale market. In response, bidders in first­ price auctions will tend to shade their bids well below their estimates, resulting in reduced revenue for the seller. The same reasoning applies to the strategically equivalent Dutch auction. In the second-price (uni­ form), sealed-bid format, by contrast, the winner pays the bid of the next highest bidder. Hence, bidders would tend to offer higher bids than in a first-price auction bid, secure in the knowledge that they will not be disadvantaged if rival bidders' valuations are much lower. As we have seen, the theoretical analysis deals with bidders who demand only one indivisible unit of the commodity being auctioned. If bidders want more than one unit-as in the government securities market-and are allowed to submit bids for different quantities at differ­ ent prices, then the above results need not hold. In particular, Maskin and Riley (1989) show that in the independent and private-value models the unit-demand assumption (in which each buyer wishes to purchase at most a single unit) is crucial for revenue equivalence results. The theoret­ ical situation in which this assumption does not hold has not been fully worked out, but it is conjectured that the economic logic of the arguments for the single-object environment will carry over. No proposition states, however, that the revenue rankings given above will hold when the unit-demand assumption is relaxed. 16 Hence, on purely theoretical grounds one cannot assert that a particular auction format is superior to another. Indeed, one cannot overemphasize that the nuances and details of any particular auction are exceedingly important in deciding which format to use. A number of theoretical studies have also suggested that uniform pricing is revenue superior to discriminatory pricing. 17 The crux of the 16 In a recent paper, Back and Zender (1992) prove formally that if the unit­ demand assumption is relaxed it is possible that discriminatory-price auctions can yield higher revenues than the uniform-price auction. 17 See, in particular, Milgrom and Weber (1982), who offer a formal proof for the superiority of second-price over first-price common-value auctions. Reinhart (1992) provides an excellent discussion of the issues involved in the context of the U.S. treasury bill market. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 498 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA matter is that in using a uniform-price format, the winner's curse is muted, owing to the linkage of the final auction price to the highest losing bid. Put simply, the essence of the "linkage principle" is that auctions yielding the highest payoffs to the seller are those that are most effective in undermining the benefit to bidders of holding private information, thus transferring some of the profits from bidder to seller. As Milgram (1987, p. 4) puts it, "privacy is undermined by linking price to information other than (but correlated with) the winning bidder's private information." In any auction format, the seller can influence bids, and hence the final payoffs, by revealing information about the auctioned object. Intuitively, an individual bidder's expected profit is highest when he or she can exploit information asymmetries-that is, when the bidder has access to useful information about the object's "equilibrium" value that is not held by other auction participants. In general, more accurate information about the item's "equilibrium" value mitigates the effect of the winner's curse, and hence the price-dampening effect of bidder caution. 18 Thus, the seller's optimal strategy is to reveal all available information and to link the price to exogenous indicators of value. If a seller adopts a policy of revealing information, the price becomes linked to the seller's informa­ tion; this undermines the winner's surplus value, siphoning off some portion to the seller. 19 Efficiency Considerations The theoretical literature on auctions puts less emphasis on economic efficiency than on other aspects of the various auction formats, such as their revenue-generating potential. Nevertheless, it is extremely impor­ tant to underscore the efficiency of auctions.20 Available evidence indi­ cates that auctions, in the absence of distortions, function efficiently­ that is, they ensure that resources accrue to those that value them most highly (and where they will be most productive) and that sellers achieve the maximum value for the auctioned item. It can be shown on theoretical 18 Gilley and Karels (1981), in a study of bidding in oil-rights auctions, find that the smaller the variance in the initial estimates of a tract's value, the higher the bids. With high investments at stake, oil firms evidently recognize and avoid the winner's curse. 19 As Milgrom points out, the linkage principle implies that sellers should use royalties when auctioning mineral or publication rights, thus linking the price paid to actual value, and, on average, increasing the seller's profit 20 See Holmstrom and Myerson (1983) for a discussion of efficiency in games with incomplete information. They propose ex ante, interim, and ex post efficiencies. . ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCriONS 499 grounds that there exists an equilibrium, arising from the competitively submitted bids, in which the auctioned item is allocated endogenously in an efficient way when the price of the item is unknown. Empirical evidence also suggests that, in the absence of distortionary factors, auc­ tions function efficiently.21 In addition, the auction mechanism can achieve this objective more effectively than alternative trade arrange­ ments, such as price setting by the seller or negotiation between buyer and seller. Of the four auction formats, the English and second-price settings result in an efficient or Pareto-optimal allocation in the case of private­ value auctions.22 Complications arise in the case of the first-price, sealed­ bid auction and the Dutch (descending-price) auction. In the most commonly analyzed case of "symmetric" environments-where bidders are identical, draw their information from the same distribution, and cannot differentiate among their competitors-these auction formats are efficient. In general, however, with first-price, sealed-bid and Dutch formats, it is not optimal to bid one's reservation price, a condition that results in bid shading and consequently an inefficient allocation.ll In the case of common values, efficiency also requires the assumption that all bidders base their strategies on information drawn from the same distribution, as opposed to asymmetric information. Under the more realistic assumption that different bidders have private information, the analysis is not so straightforward. In particular, Maskin (1992) distin­ guishes between two cases: (a) where private information can be modeled as a scalar (that is, as a single item of information); and (b) where the bidders' private information can be represented by a vector (that is, by multiple units of information). In the former case, under fairly general conditions, the English auction is efficient but the uniform-price (second­ price, sealed-bid) format is efficient only if there are two bidders. In this case, the first-price and the Dutch auctions will typically not be efficient except in highly restrictive cases. In the second case, when bidders have several items of private information, efficiency is unattainable in any auction format. It can be shown, however, that when the informational asymmetry among bidders is not too great, the English and second-price auctions function better than alternative formats. 24 To summarize the evidence on efficiency, the auction of choice would hf! the English auction followed closely by the second-price, sealed-bid 21 Smith (1987). 22 See In both these formats, bidders bid their reservation price since, in both cases, this is the dominant strategy to pursue; thus, both formats are efficient. 23 See Milgram (1987) for an illustrative examp le. 24 See, in particular, Section 4b of Maskin ( 19 9 2). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 500 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA auction. The two formats are identical only in the case where there are two bidders. Collusion The extent to which incentives to collude vary under different auction formats can be of great practical concern in deciding on which type of auction to use. Indeed, the indictment in the United States of a primary securities dealer in 1991 for fraudulent activities in the government secu­ rities market has focused attention on the collusive potential of standard auction formats. These concerns are briefly dealt with below. It is im­ portant to keep in mind that all auctions are susceptible to collusive behavior-what we review here is the comparative incentive for collusion under different auction formats. A basic hypothesis, first formulated in the literature by Mead (1987), is that ascending-bid formats are more susceptible to collusion than sealed-bid auctions. This belief may explain the popularity of sealed bidding, even though the ascending-bid format has superior revenue­ generating potential. Intuitively, auction formats where covert "side deals" are possible are more likely to support bidder manipulation. Thus, an open-bid English auction is particularly vulnerable to manipulation, since a subset of bidders (a "ring") must simply agree not to outbid each other to effectively lower the winning bid. The item can then be re­ auctioned among the ring members, and the profits shared. The open format inculcates adherence to the agreement since any ring member attempting to exploit the ring by a side deal of his or her own would, effectively, negate the ring and restore the auction to a competitive footing. The open format ensures that compliance among ring members is easily monitored. It should be noted, however, that the problems with collusion under the English format should diminish as either the actual number of bidders or the potential number of bidders increases. Intu­ itively, for a ring to be successful it must have a significant proportion of the total number of bidders under its control. To achieve this result, it is advantageous to have no new bidders entering the auction. Further, with a higher number of actual bidders, it becomes more difficult to control a significant proportion of them, and more than one ring can form and try to outbid the others. Sealed-bid auctions, by comparison, are vulnerable to collusion that involves the auctioneer-that is, between the auctioneer and one or more bidders, or between the auctioneer and the seller.25 This format is, 25This vulnerability reflects the fact that fraudulent activity by the auctioneer is easier to hide when bids are sealed than when they are open. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCTIONS 501 however, less prone to rings, since sealed bidding tempts the participants in any conspiracy to bid just above the agreed-on price, effectively dissolving the cartel. This result also holds true for the Dutch format. even though it is an open, instead of sealed-bid, auction, since the first bidder to defect from the ring ends the auction. As Smith (1987. p. 52) points out, the Dutch auction is perhaps most effective against collusion: "In this auction, since none of the losing bids is known to anyone. they cannot even be leaked let alone announced and conspiracy is therefore infeasible.'· Milgram (1987, p. 27) succinctly states that "collusion is hardest to support when secret price concessions are possible. and eastest . to support when all price offers must be made publicly . . Theoretically at least, the four formats can be ranked from most prone to collusion to least prone: (1) (2) (3) (4) English auction; Uniform second-price auction� Discriminatory first-price auction; Dutch auction. The English auction is potentially the most susceptible to collusion because there is no incentive to betray the ring-more aggressive bidding does not win the item-and such attempts are highly visible to the other members of the ring. On the other hand . the Dutch. descending-price. auction is potentially the least susceptible to collusion because of the difficulties that ring members would have supporting and enforcing col­ lusive behavior. Once a ring member bids more aggresshely than '"•" agreed, his or her actions are not only obvious but the auction ts won before the others can react. III. Applications This section discusses three applications of the various mechant"m" for auctioning different items. taking in turn the auction of go,·ernmcnt securities, refinance credit. and foreign exchange. At the outset ot thl" section, it should be emphasized that there is no unambiguou., an"''W tn the question of which is the "best" auction technique to u<.e. This con­ clusion reflects the difficulties of applying the theoretical literature to real world settings as well as the importance of individual countn· circumstances. Government Securities There is considerable controversy over the type!> of auction� that arl;! most suitable for selling government securities. As \\'C have "�en the ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 502 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA theoretical analysis deals with bidders who demand only one indivisi­ ble unit of the commodity being auctioned. However, frequently in the case of auctioning government securities, bidders may submit bids for multiple units of the security, and they may also be permitted to submit multiple bids-in effect, demanding differing quantities and prices at the same auction. In such circumstances, theoretical models can offer only limited insight, and care must be taken in applying theoretical results to real world settings. Consider first the U.S. government securities market. The weekly auction of treasury securities by the U.S. Government is structured differently from the simpler theoretical formats discussed earlier and offers an excellent example of the gap between stylized models and real world settings. In addition, this market has been subject to much recent analysis and proposed changes; accordingly, the details of the market are readily available. The U.S. Treasury's offering of some two and a half trillion dollars in new debt annually is auctioned in a multiple-price, sealed-bid auction with active, open trading both preceding and following each event. Thirteen- and 26-week maturities are auctioned weekly; longer matu­ rities are offered several times a year. The Department of the Treasury publicly announces the amount of debt securities it is offering, which are traded in an active "when-issued" market. This market is essentially a forward market for the securities, in which the actual issue date is the delivery date for the forward contract. This "forward market" serves two important functions: allocative and evaluative. In the latter, it provides insight into the participant's common-value beliefs about the securities' marketability. At present, there are 39 bidders-"primary dealers"-who can partic­ ipate in the U.S. Treasury auction. They submit sealed bids specifying a price and the number of securities they are willing to purchase at that price. These are referred to as "competitive bids" and approved dealers can submit them in several price-quantity combinations. In addition, the proceedings are open to the general public and individual investors through the submission of "noncompetitive" bids that specify a quantity sought, up to a fairly conservative maximum, determined by the Treas­ ury. The price paid by these noncompetitive bidders is a quantity­ weighted average of the winning competitive bids. To the highest com­ petitive bidder, the Treasury awards the amount specified at the stated price; the next highest bidder is awarded the amount demanded at his or her stated price; and so on until the supply is allocated. Winning bidders thus pay their bid, and all of them may pay different prices. The securities are delivered within a few days and may be resold in active secondary ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCfiONS 503 markets. Recently, starting in September 1992, the Treasury began selling two- and five-year bonds using a uniform-price auction on an experimental basis. In addition to the forward market, there is a "repurchase and reverse" market in treasury securities, in which short-term borrowing and lending are collaterized by these instruments. One can borrow funds overnight by selling securities with an agreement to repurchase them the next day at a predetermined price, with the difference between the buying and the selling price being the return earned. The potential for profit in Treasury auctions lies at the intersection of the three trading forums-the auction itself, the forward market, and the repurchase and reverse market. Sealed bidding combined with multiple prices creates the potential for any determined bidder to corner the postauction market. Well-informed and deep-pocketed groups can, by submitting deliberately high-valued bids, receive the bulk of awarded securities. Unsuccessful bidders who have taken a position in the "when­ issued," or forward, market are caught in a "short squeeze," where they are forced either to pay heavily to close their positions or to purchase securities at a premium in the repurchase market to honor their commit­ ments. Under current Treasury auction procedures, the winner's curse places a premium on information regarding competitive bids (an impor­ tant outcome of the "when-issued" market), creating the basis for a bid that will corner the primary auction and squeeze the postauction market. Having described how the market works, we look at the arguments in favor of switching to a uniform second-price auction. One main argument rests on the belief that it will probably increase the revenue to the Treasury because, following the theoretical section, the new format would mute the "winner's curse," leading to more aggressive bidding. The magnitude of this increase may, however, be small in the United States. 26 In any case, it is not clear that revenue maximization is an appropriate goal for the U.S. Treasury. Economic efficiency seems to be more appropriate. Another often cited advantage of uniform auctions is that they increase participation, and hence competition, since the winner's curse is muted. It can, however, be argued that the number of bidders (n) participating in a Treasury auction is endogenously determined. The potential number of competitive bidders includes the primary dealers (39) and all deposi­ tory institutions (a couple of thousands). There is nothing to prevent the (n + l)th bidder from entering. Clearly, the intramarginal investor does not think it profitable to bid. It is possible that this is related to the costs 26 See Vogel (1993). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 504 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA of "certification" and of establishing "creditworthiness." These costs are unlikely to change if one changes auction formats. Hence, we would not expect any significant increase in the number of competitive bidders if the Treasury moved to a uniform-price auction. 27 The recent experiences in Mexico, when it moved to a uniform-price auction from a discriminatory auction, and in Italy, when it moved from a uniform to a discrimina­ tory auction, bear this out. The number of primary dealers in either country has not changed significantly. A third advantage of a uniform-price auction is that it reduces socially suboptimal information gathering. The incentive to collect information diminishes in a uniform auction. Since gathering this information only redistributes wealth among bidders, it adds nothing to society as a whole. This, we believe, is a strong argument in favor of a uniform auction: it promotes economic efficiency. A final consideration is that it may be easier to implement. Hence, any policy recommendation must be country specific. If a fairly active (competitive) market exists, a uniform-price auction would seem appropriate, since collusion is minimized and there could be some gain to society from less information acquisition. Revenues to the government may also increase.28 If the market in a particular country is thin and subject to collusion, a discriminatory auction would seem more appropriate. The benefits would exceed the deadweight loss implied by excessive information gathering. In an immature market, information collecting encouraged by the discriminatory format may be useful in the initial stages of market development. Nevertheless, if concerns about collusion are minimal, a later shift to a uniform format would be desirable. Needless to say, we would recommend measures to increase participation to make the market more competitive and safeguard against monopoly positions. These mea­ sures might include lowering barriers to entry and increasing the number of participants. In some situations, English auctions might also be chosen, particularly in situations where it is possible to run a centralized, open auction (as in 27 Bear in mind, however, that even if the number of bidders were not to increase, there may still be more ag�ressive bidding. It should also be noted that discnminatory pricing provides real incentives, because of the winner's curse, to know the market consensus, and may therefore create a concentration of information among more experienced auction partici­ pants, with less specialized bidders deferring to those holding information. In such a situation, primary dealers have some information advantage reflecting the added information on the distribution of bids from their customers. When infor­ mation becomes overly concentrated, there is the possibility of collusion and market manipulation. Uniform auctions would help mitigate this concern. 28 As noted earlier, such increases may be small in the case of the United States. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCTIONS 505 a small country where all direct auction participants could meet in one location, as, for example, with the foreign exchange auction in Roma­ nia).29 In such a situation, a Dutch auction may also constitute a feasible and desirable option. Refinance Credit Another situation in which auction techniques can be usefully applied is in the allocation of refinance credit. In general terms, refinance credit represents direct lending by a central bank, usually to the financial sector but sometimes directly to ultimate users. Lending to the financial sec­ tor can be for the specific purpose of implementing monetary policy-for example, by providing liquidity to commercial banks to meet specified monetary targets. It can also represent "targeted" lending-for example, in some developing countries to support investment and economic devel­ opment in key sectors-in which the central bank provides funds to the financial sector for on-lending to targeted activities. When collateral (such as government securities) is required to obtain refinance credit, such credit is more likely to be called a repurchase agreement. 30 In this case, instead of extending a simple credit, the transaction entails an agreement that the borrower sell to the central bank a given security and later buy it back at the maturity date specified in the repurchase agreement. Alternatively, "refinance" facilities are also referred to as "rediscount" facilities when lending takes place against securities. 31 A main issue that arises with refinance credit is how to allocate it. One nonprice, less market-oriented approach has been to set the price of refinance credit at a given interest rate and provide the credit on a first-come, first-serve basis up to some quantity limit. Some countries allocate refinance credit entirely on an administrative basis, directing such credit and setting its price. Frequently, when such lending is at administered rates, a substantial subsidy js involved because the adrnin29This alternative has been proposed recently by Reinhart (1992) for the U.S. government securities market. However, the approach is different from what is being discussed here because the institutional setting does not rely on the auction physically taking place at one location but rather in a computer-based setting. The development of such a computer-based setting may be many years off in the United States because of the current state of technology, and may therefore be im�ractical for less technologically advanced countries. A similar transaction, but one that involves commercial bank lending to the central bank, and therefore a drain of liquidity, is a reverse repurchase agreement. 31 Some might say that "rediscount" is a misnomer in this case, as the term may refer only to buying a security and holding it until maturity. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 506 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA istered rate is low compared with market-based interest rates. Opera­ tionally, in these cases, commercial banks have recourse (sometimes automatically) to the refinance facility at the central bank at below market-related interest rates for loans to specified sectors. Direct con­ trols are sometimes used, instead of the first-come, first-serve approach, to achieve the desired distribution of credit and deal with the excess de­ mand that would arise. In any event, the types of transactions described above can create significant distortions in the financial system. Auction techniques may be viewed as a mechanism to allocate refi­ nance credit. 32 They have the advantage of tying the refinance rate to market conditions and of improving efficiency. A potential added benefit is that auctions may improve transparency while lessening discretion in the allocation of credit. Although a topic outside the realm of this paper, it should be noted that to the extent that refinance credit is directed toward development objectives-for example, by providing subsidized credit to key sectors of the economy-such policy actions might more appropriately be handled as a fiscal matter, with subsidies being budgeted directly instead of implemented through interest rate policy. Otherwise, the central bank may be carrying quasi-fiscal operations on its balance sheet, potentially generating central bank losses and complicating mon­ etary policy, as well as disguising the underlying fiscal position. In any event, whether the lending takes place through the fiscal authority or the central bank, auction techniques would be useful.33 The discussion of auction techniques in the context of auctioning government securities is largely applicable to refinance credit. Thus, much of the analysis presented earlier on government securities is rele­ vant here, although an important qualification deserves emphasis. Auc­ tioning refinance credit may differ in that payment to the seller of the auctioned item may not be required upfront as is the case with govern­ ment securities. Instead, payment is effectively made when the refinance credit matures, thus subjecting the seller to the risk of nonpayment in the interim. Collateral requirements would reduce this risk, as would an appropriate evaluation of the creditworthiness of the auction participants and associated certification. A concern is to avoid the problems of ad­ verse selection: allocating credit by price alone may create a situation where borrowers with the poorest credit risk always place the highest bids. Such a situation might arise, for example, when demanders of 32The former Czechoslovakia, Indonesia, Romania, and Tunisia are examples of countries that use an auction approach. 33The World Bank and the Inter-American Development Bank have begun to allow some of their on-lent funds to be auctioned. See, for example, Guasch and Glaessner (1992b) for the case of Chile. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCfiONS 507 refinance credit have strong incentives to seek credit at higher prices because they themselves hold "nonperforming" assets in their portfolios and are ready to go under. 34 Foreign Exchange Countries adopting market-related arrangements for their exchange rate have been confronted with two basic choices: operating an interbank type of market within the private sector, which may, in addition to commercial banks, include other licensed foreign exchange dealers; or an auction system, whereby foreign exchange is surrendered to the central bank for auction to the highest bidders. 35 As noted earlier, under the auction system countries have used differ­ ent techniques, which basically divide into discriminatory-pricing (in­ cluding Dutch auctions) and uniform-pricing approaches. A possible difficulty with discriminatory pricing is that it may discourage potential participants from entering the market or impede more aggressive bidding because of the winner's curse. 36 Other difficulties, using this format, con­ cern the appropriate exchange rate to be used for transactions outside the auction (such as for: government transactions and customs purposes).37 Uniform pricing would deal with some of these difficulties and more closely match how private foreign exchange markets work. In any event, based on country experience, the interbank approach has gained compar­ ative favor because it involves less government control over the availabil­ ity of foreign exchange to the private sector than is implied by auctions, which rely on the government specifying the quantity available, at times meeting its own needs first. The double auction is less restrictive in terms of limiting the supply of foreign exchange, as it brings in the private sector on both the supply and demand sides. This technique is implicit in an interbank market when brokers match the supply and demand orders that they receive. A main difference is that rather than being a continuous market, as with an inter­ bank market, a double auction is run at discrete points in time-like a fixing session. Such an approach may be appropriate when a country has 34 Guasch and Glaessner (1992a) discuss institutional approaches to dealing with adverse selection. 35 Quirk and others (1987) reviews the experience with these two arrangements up to January 1987. 36Some countries have argued that this result can be advantageous in deterring speculators or at least in ensuring that they pay the full price for their bids. See Quirk and others (1987, p. 12). 37 See Quirk and others (1987). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 508 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNISH MEHRA insufficient institutional capacity or experience to operate an interbank market, but some of the flexibility of the interbank approach is desirable. IV. Summary and Conclusions Auctions play a useful role in price discovery and resource allocation and are routinely used in market economies. This paper has focused on three applications of auction techniques, namely, auctioning government securities, refinance credit, and foreign exchange. In assessing the pros and cons of different auction formats, our starting point was to survey the theoretical literature. We described how auctions offer the advantage of simplicity in determining market-based prices where markets may be thin or nonexistent and in allocating the auctioned items efficiently. The appropriate choice of an auction format is less clear-cut. This ambiguity stems from the difficulties of applying theoretical results to real world settings and from the importance of individual country circumstances. Based on our earlier discussion, we conclude that there are no unam­ biguous answers to the question of which is the "best" auction technique to use. We attempt to provide broad guidelines to appropriate auction formats in different circumstances. Our survey indicates that uniform second­ price auctions, because of their administrative simplicity, economic efficiency, and revenue-enhancing potential, are perhaps the most widely applicable format. The ascending-price, English auction may be preferred in auctioning government securities or refinance credit. How­ ever, unless individual country circumstances provide for a bidding forum conducive to the open-outcry format, this mechanism is technically in­ feasible. In addition, the English auction is, potentially, the most prone to collusive agreements and should be avoided if prevailing insti­ tutional arrangements are conducive to "side deals. "38 We emphasize that, independent of the chosen format, auctions should be conducted competitively, with stringent safeguards against monopoly positions. Some of the arguments need to be qualified in the case of foreign exchange auctions, in part because auctions may not be desirable in the first place. In using any of the four basic formats, the government retains a great deal of discretion in determining the amount of foreign exchange to be auctioned. This discretion can be disadvantageous at a time when the thrust of the reform effort is to develop the private sector. Double 38In recommending the English, ascending-price format for auctioning U.S. Treasury securities, Reinhart {1992) argues that collusion is not a problem. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCfiONS 509 auctions offer a favorable alternative, as the government participates on the same bas�s as the private sector. Nevertheless, the end goal is to encourage foreign exchange trading among participants of double auc­ tions, and other participants in the economy, not only at the time of the auction but on a more continual basis. Thus, while auctions, especially double auctions, may be a useful intermediate step, development of an interbank market should ultimately be pursued under a floating-rate system. In closing, we emphasize that there is a wide range of potential appli­ cations for auctions, both in terms of the specific items to be auctioned and across country groupings. In this regard, auctions can have an impor­ tant role to play in the emerging market economies of the former Soviet Union and elsewhere. At present and to varying degrees, the institutional structures in these countries may not be conducive to free-market eco­ nomic arrangements, and the advantages accruing from the use of auction techniques could be productively exploited. Indeed, auctions can play a pivotal role in acclimating economic agents to decisionmaking in a world of market-determined, changing prices and in efficiently allocating re­ sources in the absence of alternative market mechanisms. More gen­ erally, the usefulness of auction mechanisms as a way to guide price determination and resource allocation applies to developing as well as industrial countries. Among the potential applications of auction tech­ niques-in addition to those already discussed-are the privatization of state assets and the auctioning of quotas or trade licenses. As stressed earlier, the choice of an appropriate auction format de­ pends crucially on the specific item being auctioned and on the institu­ tional arrangements prevailing in the country choosing between different auction techniques. REFERENCES -Back, Kerry, and Jaime Zender, "Auctions of Divisible Goods," Working Paper (St. Louis: Washington University, 1992). Bikhchandani, Sushil, and Chi-Fu Huang, "The Economics of Treasury Securi­ ties Markets," Sloan School of Management Working Paper (Cambridge, Mass.: Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1992). Capen, E.C., R.B. Clapp, and W.M. Campbell, "Competitive Bidding in High Risk Situations," Journal of Petroleum Technology, Vol 23 (June 1971), pp. 641-53. Chari, V.V., and Robert J. Weber, "How the U.S. Treasury Should Auction Its Debt," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review (Fall 1992), pp. 3-12. . ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 510 ROBERT A. FELDMAN and RAJNJSH MEHRA Cremer, Jacques, and Richard P. McLean {1985a), "Full Extraction of the Surplus in Bayesian and Dominant Strategy Auctions," CARESS Working Paper No. 85-17 (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania, 1985). (1985b), "Optimal Selling Strategies Under Uncertainty for a Discrimi­ nating Monopolist When Demands Are Independent," Econometrica , Vol. 53 (March 1985), pp. 345-61. Easley, David, and John Ledyard, "A Theory of Price Formation and Exchange in Oral Auctions," Technical Report No. 461 (Evanston, 111.: Northwestern University, 1982). Friedman, Daniel, "On the Efficiency of Experimental Double Auction Mar­ kets," American Economic Review, Vol. 74 (March 1984), pp. 60-72. Gilley, Otis, W., and Gordon V. Karels, "The Competitive Effect in Bonus Bidding: New Evidence," Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 12 (Autumn 1981), pp. 637-48. Graham, Daniel, and Robert Marshall, "Collusive Bidder Behavior at Single­ Object Second-Price and English Auctions," Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 95 (December 1987), pp. 1217-39. Guasch, J. Luis, and Thomas Glaessner (1992a), "Auctioning Credit," World Bank Working Paper, Report No. 15 (Washington: World Bank, 1992). -- (1992b), "Auctioning Credit: The Case of Chile," World Bank Working Paper, Report No. 15 (Washington: World Bank, 1992). Hernandez, Jaime Arias, "Nueva Subasta de Tasas Multiples de Cetes," Excel­ sior, January 21, 1993. Holmstrom, B., and R.B. Myerson, "Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information," Econometrica, Vol. 51 (1983), pp. 1799-1819. Joint Report on the Government Securities Markel (Washington: U.S. Depart­ ment of Treasury, Securities and Exchange Commission, and the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1992). Laffont, Jean-Jacques, and Eric Maskin, "Optimal Reservation Price in the Vickrey Auction," Economic Letters, Vol. 6 (1980), pp. 309-13. Maskio, Eric, "Auctions and Privatization," in Privatization Symposium in Honor of Herbert Giersch, ed. by Horst Siebert (Kiel: lnstitut fur Weltwirt­ schaft an de.r Universitat Kiel, 1992) Maskin, Eric, and John Riley, "Optimal Multi-Unit Auctions," in The Econom­ ics of Missing Markets and Information , ed. by F. Hahn (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1989). McAfee, R. Preston, and John McMillan, "Auctions and Bidding," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 25 (June 1987), pp. 699-738. Mead, Walter J., "Natural Resource Disposal Policy: Oral Auction Versus Sealed Bids," Natural Resources Journal, Vol. 7 (April 1987), pp. 195-224. Milgrom, Paul, "Auction Theory," in Advances in Economic Theory , 1985: Fifth World Congress , ed. by Truman Bewley (London: Cambridge University Press, 1987). Milgram, Paul, and Robert Weber, "A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding," Econometrica, Vol. 50 (November 1982), pp. 1089-1122. -- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution AUCTIONS 511 Quirk, Peter J., and others, Floating Exchange Rate in Developing Countries: Experience with Auction and Interbank Markets, Occasional Paper No. 53 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1987). Rasmusen, Eric, Games and Information (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1990). Reinhart, Vincent, "An Analysis of Potential Treasury Auction Techniques," Federal Reserve Bulletin (June 1992), pp. 403-13. Robinson, Marc S., "Collusion and the Choice of Auction," Rand Joumal of Economics, Vol. 16 (Spring 1985), pp. 141-45. Satith, Vernon, "Auction Theory," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Eco­ nomic Theory and Doctrine, ed. by J. Eatwell, J.M. Milgate, and P. Newman (London: Macmillan, 1987). Umlauf, Steven R., "An Empirical Study of the Mexican T-Bill Auction," London Business School Working Paper (London: London Business School, 1991). Vickery, William, "Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders," Journal of Finance, Vol. 16 (March 1961), pp. 8-37. Vogel, Thomas T., Jr., "Dutch Auctions Appear to Be MixedBlessing for U.S.," Wall Street Journal, January 4, 1993, p. C l . Wilson, Robert, "Auctions of Shares," Quarterly Journal of Economics , Vol. 93 (November 1979), pp. 675-90. ---, "Double Auctions," in Information, Incentives, and Econometric Mech­ anisms: Essays in Honor of Leonid Hurwicz, ed. by T. Groves, R. Radner, and S. Reiter (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1986). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF StaffPapers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) @ 1993 International Monetary Fund Testing the Neoclassical Theory of Economic Growth A Panel Data Approach MALCOLM KNIGHT, NORMAN LOAYZA, and DELANO VILLANUEVA* Recent empirical studies have examined the determinants of economic growth using country-average (cross-sectional) data. By contrast, this paper employs a technique for using a panel of cross-sectional and time series data for 98 countries over the 1960-85 period to determine the quantitative importance for economic growth ofboth country-specific and time-varying factors such as human capital, public investment, and out­ ward-oriented trade policies. The empirical results support the view that thesefactors exert apositive and significant influence on growth. They also provide estimates ofthe speed at which the gap between the real per capita incomes of rich and poor countries is likely to be reduced over the longer term. [JEL 041, C23] HE neoclassical model of Solow (1956) and Swan (1956) has Tbeen the workhorse of economic growth theorists for the past three BASIC and a half decades. Its simple assumptions and structure-a single homogenous good, a well-behaved neoclassical production function, ex­ ogenous labor-augmenting technical progress, full employment, and * Malcolm Knight, Senior Adviser in the Middle Eastern Department, holds a doctorate from the London School of Economics and Political Science. Norman Loayza, a doctoral student at Harvard University, was a Summer Intern in the Developing Country Studies Division when this study was prepared. Delano Villanueva, Assistant to the Director, Middle Eastern Department, received his Ph.D. from the University of Wisconsin. The authors wish to thank Professors Zvi Griliches and Gary Chamberlain for helpful advice on the econometric methodology, J ong-Wha Lee for providing the data on tariffs, Jose De Gregorio, Graham Hacche, Manmohan Kumar, and Julio Santaella for valuable comments, and Ravina Malkani for excellent research assistance. 512 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 513 exogenous labor force growth-provide an elegant solution to the "knife­ edge" problem posed by Harrod (1939) and Domar (1946) and ensure the attainment of a balanced equilibrium growth path (Hacche (1979)). The Solow-Swan growth model predicts that in steady-state equi­ librium the level of per capita income will be determined by the prevailing technology, as embodied in the production function, and by the rates of saving, population growth, and technical progress, all three of which are assumed exogenous. Since these rates differ across countries, the Solow­ Swan model yields testable predictions about how differing saving rates and population growth rates, for example, might affect different coun­ tries' steady-state levels of per capita income: other things being equal, countries that have higher saving rates tend to have higher levels of per capita income, and countries with higher population growth rates tend to have lower levels of per capita income. Recently, the Solow-Swan model has come under attack by the new growth theorists, who dismiss it in favor of "endogenous growth" models that assume constant or increasing returns to capital. These critics allege that the standard neoclassical model fails to explain observed differences in per capita income across countries. The different implications of the two growth models have led to renewed empirical work in recent years. A major concern of this work has been whether one should see a long-run tendency toward convergence of per capita income levels across coun­ tries. "Unconditional convergence" imp[jes that in a cross-country sam­ ple the simple correlation between the growth rate of real per capita GDP and the initial level of real per capita GDP is negative. In other words, the lower the starting level of real per capita income, the higher is its subsequent rate of growth. In a recent cross-section study, however, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992) find that this simple correlation is positive rather than negative, albeit statistically insignificant. In itself, the empirical evidence against unconditional convergence is not inconsistent with the implications of the neoclassical growth model. The Solow-Swan model does not predict unconditional convergence of per capita income across countries; rather, it predicts convergence only after controlling for the determinants of the steady state (that is, it predicts "conditional convergence"). Recent work by Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! (1992) contends, using a cross-sectional approach, that the Solow-Swan model's predictions are indeed consistent with the empirical evidence. They also find, however, that if human capital is not accounted for in the model the quantitative implications of different saving and population growth rates are biased upward (in absolute value), since human capital is positively correlated with both saving and population growth. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 514 KNIGHT, LOAYZA. and VILLANUEVA Accordingly, in an effort to understand the quantitative relationships among saving, population growth, and income, Mankiw, Romer, and Weil augment the Solow-Swan model to include human capital accumu­ lation. They find that this variable is indeed correlated positively with saving and population growth. Relative to estimates based on the text­ book model, this augmented Solow-Swan model implies smaller effects of saving and population growth on per capita income growth and ex­ plains about 80 percent of the cross-country variation in per capita income. Despite the evidence on the failure of per capita income to converge across countries-the failure of the "unconditional convergence" hy­ pothesis-Mankiw, Romer, and Weil find evidence of conditional con­ vergence at about the rate predicted by the Solow-Swan model once cross-country differences in saving and population growth rates are taken into account. Moreover, they interpret the available evidence on cross­ country variations in the rates of return to capital as being consistent with the Solow-Swan growth model. Thus, their work provides empirical support for the model and casts doubt on the new endogenous growth models that invoke constant or increasing returns to capital. This paper extends the Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! analysis in two directions. First, a panel of time series cross-sectional data is used to determine the significance of country-specific effects that are assumed away in the cross-sectional approach employed by Barra and Sala-i­ Martin (1992) and Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! (1992), as well as nearly all other studies. In order to exploit the additional information contained in these panel data, we extend the econometric analysis by applying an estimation procedure outlined in Chamberlain (1984). Second, we as­ sume that labor-augmenting technical change is influenced by two poten­ tially important factors: (1) the extent to which a country's trade policies are outward-oriented-whether they increase or decrease its openness to international trade (see Edwards (1992)); and (2) the stock of public infrastructure in the domestic economy. As already noted, our first extension of the Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! analysis refers to the econometric treatment of the data. In the empirical part of their paper, they use cross-sectional data for various groups of countries. Essentially, they take averages of the relevant variables over the whole period, 1960-85. Since only one cross-section of countries is used for the entire time period, they are obliged to make some restrictive assumptions about the nature of the shift parameter (technology) in the neoclassical production function and its relation to other variables. Specifically, all unobservable factors that characterize each economy (and are contained in the shift parameter) are assumed to be uncorrelated ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 515 with the available information. Econometrically, this means that "coun­ try-specific" effects are ruled out by assumption. Our procedure, on the other hand, allows for a more general econometric specification of the model by appropriately using panel data to account for important coun­ try-specific effects. Tbis approach yields a number of interesting exten­ sions to the empirical results of Mankiw, Romer, and Weil, particularly when the estimates for the full sample of both industrial and developing countries are compared with those for developing countries only.1 Provided the assumptions required for using the panel data hold, our approach also improves the efficiency of the estimates by using more information.2 Our second, related, extension of Mankiw, Romer, and Weil's empir­ ical analysis refers to the country-specific variables-trade policies, hu­ man capital, and government fixed investment-that we include in the model. Policies that foster more openness in a country's international trade regime help to stimulate labor-augmenting technological change in two ways. 3 First, the import-export sector serves as a vehicle for technol­ ogy transfer through the importation of technologically advanced capital goods, as elucidated by Bardhan and Lewis ( 1 970), Chen ( 1979), and Khang (1987), and as a channel for intersectoral external economies through the development of efficient and internationally competitive management, the training of skilled workers, and the spillover conse­ quences of scale expansion (Keesing (1967) and Feder (1983)). Second, rising exports help to relieve the foreign exchange constraint-that is, a country's ability to import technologically superior capital goods is aug­ mented directly by rising export receipts and indirectly by the higher flows of foreign credits and direct investment caused by the country's increased ability to service debt and equity held by foreigners.4 As regards government fixed investment, it is reasonable to assume that an expansion in the amount of public goods concentrated in physical infrastructure (such as transport and telecommunications) will be associ­ ated with greater economic efficiency. Empirical studies that emphasize 1 Our sample of industrial countries consists of the 21 developed countries that are members of the OECD; our sample of developing countries consists of 76 non-OECD developing countries. See the appendix. 2 The panel data set increases the number of observations from 98 to 490-that is, 98 countries multiplied by five time periods of five years each. 3 See the discussion on the production linkage summarized by Khan and Vil­ lanueva (1991). See also Edwards (1992), Roubini and Sala-i-Martin (1992), and Villanueva (1993). 4Tbe transfer of efficient technologies and the availability of foreign ex­ change have featured I?rominently in recent experiences of rapid economic growth (Thirlwall (1979)). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 516 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA other productive public expenditures, such as education and health spending, include Diamond (1989), Otani and Villanueva (1990), and Barra (1991); those that focus on fixed investment include Diamond (1989), Orsmond (1990), and Barra (1991). I. The Model The Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! model is an augmented neoclassical Solow-Swan model that accounts for human capital in the production function and saving decisions of the economy. Consider the following Cobb-Douglas production function: (1) where Y is real output, K is the stock of physical capital, H is the stock of human capital, L is raw labor, A is a labor-augmenting factor reflecting the level of technology and efficiency in the economy, and t refers to time in years. We assume that a + 13 < 1, so that there are constant returns to factor inputs jointly and decreasing returns separately. Raw labor and labor-augmenting technology are assumed to grow according to the following functions, L, = Loent, A, = Aoegrpe,peP, (2) (3) where n is the exogenous rate of growth of the labor force, g is the exogenous rate of technological progress, F is the degree of openness of the domestic economy to foreign trade, and P is the level of government fixed investment in the economy. (For simplicity, we normalize L0 to unity.) Thus, our efficiency variable A differs from that used by Mankiw, Romer, and Weil in that it depends not only on exogenous technological improvements but also on the degree of openness of the economy (with elasticity e1) and on the level of government fixed investment (with elasticity eP). We believe that this modification is particularly relevant to the empirical study of economic growth in developing countries, where technological improvements tend to be absorbed domestically through imports of capital goods and where the productive sector's efficiency may depend heavily on the level of fixed investment undertaken by the government. As in the Solow-Swan model, the savings ratios are assumed to be exogenously determined either by savers' preferences or by government policy. Thus, physical and human capital are accumulated according to the following functions, ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 517 where sk ands" are the fractions of income invested in physical capital and human capital and o is the depreciation rate (assumed, for simplicity, to be the same for both types of capital). To facilitate analysis of the steady state and the behavior around it, we redefine each variable in terms of its value per effective unit of labor, by dividing each variable by the efficiency-adjusted labor supply. Lower­ case letters with a hat represent quantities per effective worker: for instance, output per effective unit of labor (.9) is equal to YIAL. We now rewrite the production and accumulation functions in terms of quantities per effective worker: A k." Yr = r hA��r , (1') (4 ') and (5 ' ) The Steady State In the steady state, the levels of physical and human capital per effective worker are constant. (Variables in the steady state are represented by a star superscript.) From equations (4') and (5'), this assumption implies (n +stgfls+g o)!11-a-f!' a 1-ah )111-a-fj' h* sks =( n +g+o k.* = (6) and lny* = -(1 �:� ) ln(n + g + o) + (1 + (r ! ) ln(s11). � _ _ _ : _ ) ln(sk) � � ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 518 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA Furthermore, in the steady state, output per worker (y) grows at the constant rate g (the exogenous component of the growth rate of the effi­ ciency variable A). This result can be obtained directly from the definition of output per effective worker: loy, = ln 1-; - lnL, - lnA, = lny, - lnA0 - gt - e1 ln F - eP lnP. (7) Taking time derivatives of both sides of the equation gives d lny, dt d lny, dt -- = -- - g . Therefore, in the steady state, when the growth rate of output per effective worker is zero, the growth rate of output per worker is equal to g: d lny;" (f t = g. Dynamics Around the Steady State Following Mankiw, Romer, and Wei!, we do not impose the restriction that the economy is continuously in the steady state. However, we do assume that the economy is sufficiently close to its steady state that a linearization of the transition path around it is appropriate. Such a linearization produces the following result:5 d lny, dt = 'T) A* (ln y - ln y,)' (8) A where 'TJ = (n + g + 5)(1 - a - [3). The parameter 'TJ defines the speed of convergence: how fast output per effective worker reaches its steady state. We want to obtain an expression that can be treated as a regression equation for our empirical study. Accordingly, we integrate equation (8) from t = t0 to t = t0 + r: ln.Yro + r = (1 - e-11') lny* + e-11' ln.Y,o· 5The linearization of the transition path around the steady state is derived in Appendix I of our original working paper (Knight, Loayza, and Villanueva (1992)). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWfH 519 Next, we substitute for In :9*, lny,0 + , = -(1 - e-11') ( 1 �:� 13) ln(n + g + 8) (1 ; 13) lnsk l3 + (1 - e-11')( ) lnsh + e-'lr lny, . 1 - a - 13 + (1 - e-11') _ _ o For purposes of estimation, we need an expression in terms of output per worker rather than output per effective worker. Accordingly, follow­ ing Mankiw, Romer, and Wei!, we substitute for loy, using equation (7). Finally, we rearrange terms to get the change in the natural logarithm of output as the left-hand variable: ( �:� 13) ln(n + g + 8) C _; 13) lnsk + (1 + (1 - e-'�')C ! 13) lns11 lny,0 + r - lny,0 = -(1 - e-'�') 1 _ e-'�') _ _ + (1 - e-'�')61 In F + (1 - e-'�')6p In P - (1 - e-'�') lnyr0 + [(1 - e-11')(to + r)g + e-'�'rg] + (1 - e-'�') lnAo. (9) Equation (9) provides a useful specification for our empirical study.6 We will use it as a guide but not apply it literaJiy. The growth effects that we next discuss apply to the transition to the steady state. As noted earlier, in the steady state, output per capita grows at the exogenous rate g. If the speed of convergence TJ is positive (as we expect), we can predict the sign of the coefficients in equation (9). The 13 fust coefficient indicates that for given a, , 8, and g the rate of growth of per capita output is negatively related to the growth of the working-age population. The second and third coefficients indicate that the more a country saves and invests in physical and human capital, the more rapidly it grows. The fourth coefficient is positive if e1 is positive, meaning that 6 Note that as t0 goes to infinity, both sides of equation (9) go to the value rg. This is so because in the limit (steady state), the growth of per capita output is equal to g, the exogenous growth rate of technology. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 520 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA greater openness to international trade-by contributing to the efficiency of production-raises the rate of economic growth. A similar analysis holds for the fifth coefficient, which applies to the level of government fixed investment. The sixth term indicates that countries grow faster if they are initially below their steady-state growth path, what is known as "conditional convergence" in the growth literature (Barro and Sala-i­ Martin (1992), Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992), and Loayza (1992)). Next, the term in brackets suggests the presence of a time-specific effect on growth. The last term contains A0, which represents aU the unobserved elements that determine the efficiency with which the factors of produc­ tion and the available technology are used to create wealth. Of course, the greater is such efficiency, the higher the growth rate of the economy. This last term suggests the presence of a country-specific effect, which may well be correlated with the other explanatory variables considered in the model. The above interpretation of equation (9) suggests a natural specifica­ tion for the regression that can be used to study output growth and its determinants using panel data for a sample ofdifferent countries and time periods. Let us write a more general form of equation (9) for a given country i: Lny;,, - lny;,r-L = el ln(nl. t + g + 8) + 82 lnski,t + e3 lnsh, + 64 ln F; + 65 In P; + 'Y lny;,r- L + � + f.l.; + €;,,, (10) where �� and f.l.; represent time-specific and country-specific effects and where St. . . , 65 and 'Y are parameters to be estimated. The use of the time index requires some explanation. First, we have normalized the "time length" between the first and last observations for each period to equal unity (in equation (9), r = 1). Second, we are indexing the physical capital investment rate sk by time to allow it to change from period to period. Notice that the rate of human capital investment sh, the level of openness F, and the stock of government fixed investment P may differ from country to country, but owing to the limited availability of data their levels in each country are assumed to remain unchanged for all time periods in the sample.7 Notice also that neither the value for g nor that for 8 is specific to each country. In essence, we assume that, conditional on the other variables in the model, the exoge. 7This refers to available. those data in our study for which only cross-sectional data are ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 521 nous rate of technological change and the rate of depreciation are equal across countries. 8 The disturbance term E;.1 is not assumed to be identically and inde­ pendently distributed. Thus, the model does not impose either condi­ tional homoskedasticity across countries or independence over time on the disturbances within each country. We want to allow for serial corre­ lation in the error term because there may be some excluded variables that result in short-run persistence. The IJ.; component accounts for long-run persistence in excluded variables that are correlated with the independent regressors. IT. Panel Data Estimation As we have noted, previous empirical studies of long-run growth have made use of cross-sectional data. This practice forced the use of some rather restrictive assumptions in the econometric specifications. For in­ stance, Mankiw, Romer, and Weil, who take averages of the relevant variables over the period 1960 to 1985, assume that lnA0 is independent of the investment ratios and growth rates of the working-age population. This amounts to ignoring country-specific effects. For example, their assumption implies that government policies regarding taxation and in­ ternational trade do not affect domestic investment and that the en­ dowment of natural resources does not influence fertility. Furthermore, since only one cross-section is considered, the time-specific effect be­ comes irrelevant. Fortunately, panel data are available for most vari­ ables of interest. Thus, we exploit the additional information contained in the panel data to analyze regression equation (10), using a technique suggested by Chamberlain (1983). We rewrite equation (10) as follows: z;.1-1 = O'v;. , + "{Z;. ,-J + � + !J.; + E;., (10') wherez;. , = ln(y;.,); v;.1 = [ln(nu + g + 8), ln(sk,), ln(s�r,), In F; , In P;]'; and 9 = (e�> . . . , 65)'. First, we need to process the data to eliminate the time effects, which we do by removing the time means from each variable. The �,'s can then be ignored, and the regression can be estimated without constants (McCurdy (1982)). Taking account of the country-specific effects is not so simple. If the Z;., - 8This assumption corresponds to that in Mankiw, Romer, and Weil. The value for g + B that JS used in the estinoation procedure actually matched the available data. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 522 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA fJ.;'s are treated as fixed (as in a fixed-effects model), we may be tempted to use the "within" estimator procedure, which is obtained by removing the country means prior to least-squares estimation.9 However, this pro­ cedure would result in inconsistent estimators because of the presence of a lagged dependent variable in the right-hand side of the regression equation. The inconsistency comes from the fact that the error term obtained after removing the country means is correlated with lagged output. Our chosen estimation method is the fi matrix approach outlined in Chamberlain (1983). Chamberlain's fi matrix procedure consists of two steps. In the first step, we estimate the parameters of the reduced­ form regressions for the endogenous variable in each period in terms of the exogenous variables in all periods. Thus, we estimate a multi­ variate regression system with as many regressions as periods for the endogenous variables we consider. Since we allow for heteroskedasticity and correlation between the errors of all regressions, we use the seem­ ingly unrelated regression (SUR) estimator. As a result of this first step, we obtain estimates of the parameters of the reduced-form regressions (the elements of the fi matrix) and the robust (White's (1980) hetero­ skedasticity-consistent) variance-covariance matrix of such parameters. The specific model we are working with implies some restrictions on the elements of the n matrix: the parameters of interest are functions of the fl matrix. This takes us to the second step in the procedure: we estimate the parameters of interest by means of a minimum-distance estimator using the robust variance-covariance of the estimated n as the weighting matrix: min[vec fl - f('\lt)]'O[vec fl - f('\lt)], where $ is the set of parameters of interest and a is the robust variance­ covariance of the fi matrix. Chamberlain (1982) shows that this procedure obtains asymptotically efficient estimates. In order to use this method, we need to make explicit the restrictions that our model imposes on the IT matrix. After removing the time means, our basic model in equation (10') can be written as (11) = 6'v;,1 + 'YZi. r-1 + f.l.; + E;,. At this point it is necessary that we distinguish the two kinds of variables contained in the vector V;,,: those that are both country and time specific (Jn[n;,, + g + 8] and ln(sk;,,]) and those that are only country Z;,1 - Z;, r-1 9 References on the "within" estimator include Mundlak (1978) and Greene (1990, chapter 16). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWfH 523 specific (ln[s"1], ln[F;) and ln[P;]). Then we rewrite equation (11) as follows: (12) Z;,t - Z;,r- 1 = a; X; r + a,; W; + 'YZt,t- 1 + IJ.; + E;,, . where X;,/ [ln(nu + g + 8), ln(sk1)]', w; = [ln(s".), In F;, In P;)', aa={8t, 82 )', and ab = (83, 84, 8s)'. By recursive substitution of the z,_1 term in each regression equation, we bave10 Z;. 1 Z;.o = a; X;.1 + a,; W; + 'YZ;.o + IJ.; + Wi.J, = - Z;. 2 - Z;. 1 = -ya; X;, 1 + a; X;, 2 + (1 + -y)ab W; + -y(1 + -y)z;,O Z;, 3 - Zt,2 + (1 + 'Y) IJ.; + W;. 2, = -y(1 + -y)a; X;. 1 + -ya; X1. 2 + a; X1.3 + (1 + -y)2 a,; W; + -y(1 + 'Y)2 Z1,o + (1 + 'Y)21J.; + W1. 3 , Z;,T - Z;,T- 1 = -y(1 + -yf-2 a; xi. l + -y(1 + 'Y)T-Ja; xi. 2 + + -y(1 + -y)a; X;. T-2 + -ya� X;. T-1 · · · T T + a; Xr + (1 + -y) - I ab W; + -y(l + -y) - l Z;.o + (1 + -yf-l f..L; + w;. r, E*(w;,, I X;, t, . . . , X;. r, w1) = 0, for t = 1, . . . , T. Chamberlain (1983) proposes to deal with the correlated country-specific effect IJ.; and the initial condition z1.o by replacing them by their linear predictors: E* (IJ.; I x1•1, X1,2 , • • • , x1. r, w1) = T( x1• 1 + T2 x1• 2 + · · · + Tr X; T + T� W;; , E*(z1. o l x1.h xi.2, . . . , x1.r, w1) = A.;xi.l + A.2 x1• 2 + · · · + ATX;, T + A� W;. In order to identify the coefficients of the variables for which we have only cross-sectional data (sh,, F;, and P;), it is necessary to assume that T' w = 0. This assumption is not very restrictive if one believes that the partial correlation between w1 and IJ.; is low, given that the panel data variables x1.1 are accounted for. As Chamberlain points out, assuming that the variances are finite and 10ln the term z,_�, the index "1" refers to five years. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 524 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA that the distribution of (x;, h . . . , x;. r, w;, f..L;) does not depend on i, then the use of the linear predictors does not impose any additional restric­ tions. However, using the linear predictors does not account completely for the presence of country-specific effects when the correct specification includes interactive terms (that is, nonlinear terms including products of the observed variables and the country-specific factors). Of course, we assumed away such a possibility when we declared that equation (10) represented our maintained model. We now write the IT matrix implied by our model. As will be seen in the next section, our panel data consist of five cross-sections for the variables (z;, , - z;.t-I) and X;,,, six cross-sections for the variable Z;,, (the additional cross-section being the initial condition z;.o), and one cross­ section for the variables W; . Thus, the multivariate regression implied by our model is Z;.o Zi.l - Z;,o Z;.2 - Z;, l Z;, 3 - Z;,2 Z;, 4 - Z;, 3 Z;. s - Z;,4 IT = X;, I = IT X;, 2 X;,3 X;,4 X;,s (13) W; [B + 'ItA.' + 4>-r'], 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 9� 0 0 9� )'9� B= 0 e� 'Y(1 + )')9� )'9� 9; )'9; 'Y(1 + 'Y? 9; 'Y(1 + 'Y)9; 'Y(1 + 1)3 9; -v(1 + -v)2 9; -v(1 + 'Y)9; -y9� 0 0 0 0 0 e; 0 6b (1 + 'Y)9i (1 + 'Y)2 9k ' (1 + 'Y)3 9i (1 + -y)49i 1 'Y 'ItA.' = 'Y(1 + -y) [A.; A-2 A-3 A-4 As A�), 'Y(1 + -y)2 'Y(1 + -v? -y(1 + 'Y)4 0 1 -y) + (1 [T1 T2 Tl T4 Ts Tw' ] . 4>-r' = (1 + 'Y)2 (1 + 'Y)3 (1 + -y)4 I I I I I ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 525 NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH III. Data and Results We consider three different specifications of the growth model in our econometric analysis. The first is a simple Solow-Swan model; the second is a version of the Solow-Swan model that includes investment in human capital; and the third, which was presented in Section I, is a version that includes human capital investment, openness to foreign trade, and the stock of public infrastructure. The first two models can be obtained by applying appropriate exclusion restrictions to the third model. Thus, the basic Solow-Swan model is obtained from equation (9) by setting � = e1 = eP = 0. Its corresponding regression equation is ln y,, , - lnyi,t1 = el ln(n;,, + g + 8) + e2 lnsk;, , + -y ln y;. t- t + �' + f.L1 + (10") E,,,. The second model can also be obtained from equation (9) by setting e, = ep = 0. Its regression equation is ln y1, , - lny1,t-t = 81 ln(n;, , + g + 8) + 62 lnsk1., + 63 lnsh1 + "' In Y1.t- 1 + �' + J.L; + E1.c· (10111) We will consider an alternative specification for this second model in which panel data rather than cross-sectional data are used as a proxy for the ratio of human capital investment to GDP. The regression equation for this alternative model is the same as equation (10111), except that the investment ratio for human capital is also indexed by time. The definitions and sources of the data used for estimation are de­ scribed in the appendix. Our sample extends over the period from 1960 to 1985. We work with regular nonoverlapping intervals of five years. Thus, our five cross-sections correspond to the years 1965, 1970, 1975, 1980, and 1985. For the variables y, and sh,, the observations for each cross-section correspond exactly to the year of the cross-section. For others-such as n, and sk,-such observations correspond to averages over the previous five years. For the variables sh and P, the observations correspond to averages over the whole period 1960 to 1985. For the openness variable, F, the observation for each country is taken from various years in the first part of the 1980s. Each of the variables under consideration is now explained in more detail. The dependent variable is the five-year difference in the natural , logarithm of real GDP per worker-that is, ln(Yi.6s) - ln(y,. 60), In(y1.85) - In(y1, 80). As noted above, the most general model considers six explanatory variables. The first is the natural logarithm of the average growth rate of the working-age population, plus (g + 8); we follow Mankiw, Romer, and Weil in assuming that (g + 8) = 0.05. The average • • ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution • 526 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA growth rate of the working-age population is taken over the preceding five-year interval. Thus, we also have five observations of this variable for each country-that is, ln(n,, 65 + 0.05), . . . , Ln(n,,85 + 0.05). The second explanatory variable is the natural logarithm of the average ratio of real investment (including government investment) to real GDP. These averages are also taken over the preceding five-year intervals, so that we have five observations for each country-that is, log(sk,. 65), , log(sk1.ss). The third explanatory variable is a proxy for the ratio of human capital investment to GDP. Specifically, following Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! (1992), we use the percentage of the working-age population that is enrolled in secondary school, a measure that is approximated by the product of the gross secondary-school enrollment ratio times the fraction of the working-age population that is of secondary-school age (aged 15 to 19). 11 In the.main specifications of the second and third models, we use cross-sectional data for this variable: its average over the whole period from 1960 to 1985. In the alternative specification of the second model, we use panel data for the proxy of the human capital investment ratio­ that is, for each country we have five observations, namely ln(s�r,. 65), , ln(s�r,.ss). The fourth variable, In F, is a proxy for the restrictiveness of the economy's foreign trade regime: it is a weighted average of tariff rates on intermediate and capital goods. The weights are the respective import shares, and each tariff rate is calculated as the percentage ad valorem import charge. Thus, the larger the value of this variable, the less open is the domestic economy. We obtain the data from Lee (1993). This measure of openness to trade is used because we are interested in the relation between the availability of foreign technology (embodied in intermediate and capital goods) and the efficiency parameter in the production function. Lee points out that there are some problems with this measure of the weighted-average tariff rate, the most important of which is that the data refer to various years in the first part of the 1980s and thus may not be representative of our entire sample period (1960 to 1985). Nevertheless, we believe that this simple proxy is likely to be inversely correlated with openness for the majority of countries under consideration during our sample period. The fifth variable, In P , is a proxy for the level of the public capital stock; it is defined as the average level of the ratio of general government fixed investment (central government plus public enterprises) to GDP in • • • . • • 11 For a discussion of the appropriateness of this proxy, see Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 527 each five-year period. There are obvious problems in using this flow variable as a proxy for the stock of public capital. It does not account for the initial level of public capital (in our case the 1960 level). Nor does it allow for country-specific differences in depreciation rates or in the quality of investment expenditures. Nevertheless, it is likely that our proxy is positively correlated with the level of public capital, and the omitted factors discussed above will be reflected in the country-specific constants. The sixth explanatory variable is the natural logarithm of real GDP per worker, lagged one "period" (that is, five years back). The observations for each country are therefore ln( Y;.oo), . . . , ln( Yt. so). The appendix lists the countries used to obtain the empirical estimates for each of the three models of interest. The sample includes all industrial and developing countries for which data are available and for which petroleum production is not the primary economic activity.12 Excluding the countries for which data are not available may create sample selectiv­ ity problems, particularly since these countries are frequently the poorest ones. Thus, it is not appropriate to assume that the results could be extrapolated to those economies that bad to be excluded from the sample owing to data problems, most of which are also in the lowest-income category. We estimate each of the models using two samples of countries. The first is the full sample of 98 countries (22 industrial OECD-member countries and 76 developing countries), and the second consists of the 76 developing countries only. Hence, a second aspect of the empirical work is a comparison of the estimated coefficients obtained from the two samples. Our main results are presented in Tables 1, 2, and 3. In all models, time-specific and country-specific effects are deaJt with using the methodology outlined in Section II above. Before presenting the results, we need to clarify the meaning of the "country-specific effects" in each of the estimated models. All empirical growth models implicitly assume that the excluded variables can be grouped into a single factor that affects the included variables in a given uniform way. This is rather restrictive, since each unobserved variable may affect the included variables in a different way. Thus, grouping them together introduces biases and inefficiencies. Much is gained by identify­ ing and obtaining information on the different components of the coun­ try-specific factor. This is precisely our intention when we go from the first to the second and third models. In a sense, adding information on 12 It is well known that standard growth models do not account for growth in economies that specialize in the extraction of depletable resources (see Sala-i­ Martin (1990)). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 0.05) a 167.21 0.0000 1.093 0.2959 164.53 0.0000 0.798 0.3718 -0.2782 ( -6. 37) -0.1401 ( -9. 52) 0. 1401 (9.52) 0.0652 (5.39) 0.335 -0.2707 (-6.47) -0.1474 ( -6.64) 0. 1 184 (7.03) 0.0631 (5.50) (n = 98) All countries Developing countries (n = 76) = 76) -0.2660 ( -6.63) -0.12&5 ( -9.55) 0.1285 (9.55) 0.0619 (5.66) 0.326 (n Developing countries ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution .. Ln(yH) is the logarithm of real GDP per worker lagged one period (five years). Ln(n, + 0.05) is the logarithm of the 3\'erage growth rate of the working-age population plus the sum of technological progress and depreciation. Ln(s.t,) is the logarithm of the average ratio of real investment to real GDP. lmplied 11 is the speed of convergence per year. T-ratios are in parentheses. Implied a is the incom e share accruing to nonhuman capitaL b These estimates are obtained by imposing the restriction implied by the Cobb-Douglas assumption-namely. that -81 = 92. Wald test for uncorrelated effects (P-value) Wald test for 91 = -9� in equation (10") (P-value) Implied Implied 11 ln(st,) ln(n, + ln(j·,-1) (n = 98) -0.2686 (-5 .90) -0. 1220 ( -4. 90) 0. 1489 (8.36} 0.0626 (5.03) All countries Simple restricted Solow-Swan modelb 1 . Two Ver.sions of the So/ow-Swan Model Simple Solow-Swan model Table r r > z c m < > :s "' ::l c.. > -< N > b .-1 :r: 6 " z NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 529 human capital, public capital, and openness to the simple Solow-Swan model may be viewed as an attempt to disaggregate the components of the all-inclusive country-specific factor assumed in the first model. Specifically, in the second model we identify the human capital compo­ nent of the country-specific factor, while in the third model we add prox­ ies for public capital and openness to disaggregate the country-specific effects further. We begin with the simple Solow-Swan model (regression equation (10'')). Results for this specification are reported in Table 1 . Using a Cobb-Douglas production function in the Solow growth model, we ex­ pect the estimated values of 'Y to be negative, those for 01 to be negative, and those for e2 to be positive; furthermore, we expect el and e2 to have approximately the same absolute value. As can be seen from Table 1, all these predictions of the Solow-Swan model hold true for the sample that includes all countries, as well as for that including developing countries only. Moreover, our estimated values for the speed of convergence 11 are 0.0626 a year for the sample containing all 98 countries and 0.0631 for that containing developing countries, implying that the economy moves halfway to the steady state in about 11 years. 13 These estimates are much larger than those reported in Barro (1991) and Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! (1992), but similar to the predicted value of the simple Solow-Swan model (see the formula for 11 in equation (8), setting 13 = 0 and using sensible values for n, g, and 8). Mankiw, Romer, and Weil find that the implied estimate for the speed of convergence to its steady-state growth path is 0.0137 a year. Barro (1991), using variables such as school enrollment ratios, the government consumption expenditure ratio, proxies for polit­ ical stability, and a measure of market distortions, finds an estimated speed of convergence equal to 0.0184 a year. These estimates correspond to a half-life for the logarithm of output per effective worker of between 37 and 50 years. 14 We believe that the large difference between their estimates and ours can be explained by the fact that their studies do not account for the correlation between the country-specific effects and the independent variables in the model, thus producing biased coefficients. Specifically, when country-specific effects are ignored, the coefficient on lagged output is biased toward zero because there is a positive correlation between country-specific effects (defined to be positive) and the initial levels of income in every interval (lagged output). 13 Note that in the estimating equation (9) the parameters lJ and r appear on both sides; we set r = 5 years in our panel data regressions. 14The half-life formula is T = ln(2)/lJ, where T is number of years. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution TJ 0.05) -0.2095 ( -4.27) (-3.86) 0.0844 (5.54) 0.0995 (5.38) 0.0470 (3.79) 178.&5 0.0000 -0.1775 ( -3.41) -0.0873 ( -3.02) 0.1061 (6.60) 0.1064 (4.91 ) 0.0391 (3.09) 87.91 0.0000 12.31 0.0000 5. 16 0.02317 -0.1007 Developing countries (tl = 76) (n = 98) All cotmtries Using cross-sectional data for human capital investment 12.23 0.0000 3249.00 0.0000 O.D7 0.7974 60274.42 0. 0000 -0 . 1 108 ( - 13 .26) -0.0652 (-5.09 ) . 1 2%1 ( - 95.73) -0.0114 (1 .45 ) 0. 1048 (10. 16) - Developing countries (n = 75) - 1 .0383 (-34.55) -0.0389 (-5.25) 0.02.33 (1 .61) All countries (n = %) Using panel data for human capital investment Solow-Swan Model Augmented 10 Include Human Capital lnvesrment • ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Ln(y,-1) is the logarithm of real G DP per worker lagged one period (five years). Ln(n, _... 0.05) is the logarithm of the average growth rate of the working-age population plus the sum of technological progress and depr-eciation. Ln (sk, ) is the logarithm of the average ratio of real investment to real GDP. Ln(sh,) is the logarithm of the ratio of human capital investment to GDP, proxied by the product of gross secondary-school enrollment ratio times the fraction of the working-age population aged 15 to 19. T-ratlos are in parentheses. Wald test for uncorrelated effects (P-value) Wald test for El1 = -(EI1 .,- e3) in equation (10"') (P-value) Implied ln (sh, ) ln(s� ) ln(sk.) ln(n, + Jn(yH ) Variable• Table 2 . � m r r > z c: .::: <.; :::> 0. N > ?< r 0 :=i 0 z ;>:: NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 531 We can test for the presence of such a correlation. Consider the null hypothesis of "uncorrelated effects," which means that the country­ specific effects have no correlation with the independent variables. From the equation for the linear predictor of 1-L; and equation ( 16). it is evi­ dent that the null hypothesis of uncorrelated effects. in the framework. of our maintained model, is equivalent to H0: At = · · · = As = 0. As can be seen in Table 1, the Wald test strongly rejects the null hypothesis of uncorrelated effects. In Table 1, we also report the results of an estimation that assume� the coefficients on In(n, + 0.05) and ln(sk, , ) are the same in absolute valu� but opposite in sign (8 = -82). We do this in order to obtain estimates for the implied capital share, ex, in the Cobb-Douglas production func­ tion. The estimates for ex are 0.335 for all countries and 0.326 for de\ el­ oping countries. These estimated capital shares are very close to the value of 0.350 that Maddison (1987) obtains for the share of nonhuman capital in production. Our estimated nonhuman capital shares imp!� that diminishing returns set in quickly, which explains the rapid convergence predicted by the model. Table 1 also allows us to examine the differences in the estimated coefficients obtained using the two samples. For the sample of developing countries, the absolute value of the coefficient on population growth is larger than that for the sample of all countries. This can be explained b) the fact that the developed industrial countries have tended to sh<)\\ relatively steady per capita growth over the sample period while expcn­ encing relatively low population growth. Accordingly. when the� are excluded from the sample the estimated effect of population gro\\ th i-, larger. Our estimates also suggest that investment in physical capital is less productive for developing countries than for developed countries. The fact that we do not obtain the same parameter estimates using the two different samples has to do with sampling error and with the inabillt) to control completely for the country-specific effects. Table 2 presents the econometric estimates for the second vers1on nf 1 15 1" 15 Somehow contradicting our finding that the capital share in production i� approximately the same for both industrial and developing countries. De Grego­ rio (1992) finds an estimate for the capital share of about 0.5 for a sample of Latrn American economies. 16There are two basic reasons for this imperfection. The first has to do w1th the fact that we are grouping together all unobservable factors into the countn·­ specific effects; thus, if an unobserved variable affects the two �ample� differ­ ently, we obtain sharper estimates by separating the two samples. The second reason may be the presence of nonlinear interactions between physical cap1tal investment and the variables that are left out of the first model, such a� educat ion. public infrastructure, and openness to trade (linear interactions are accounted for by our methodology). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 532 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VlLLANUEVA the Solow-Swan model (regression equation (10"')). As might be ex­ pected, the inclusion of a proxy for the ratio of human capital investment to GDP has the effect of lowering the absolute value of the estimated coefficients on the other variables in both the full sample and the devel­ oping country subsample. However, the changes are relatively small, apparently because most of the effect of human capital investment has already been captured by the country-specific effects in the estimates of the first model. As also expected, the coefficient on the proxy for the human capital investment ratio is significantly positive. In tbis second model, a Cobb-Douglas production function implies that -81 = 82 + 83 in equation (10'"). This restriction, however, is rejected by the data on the basis of the Wald test. This result may be due to the fact that education is more closely related to the efficiency variable than to human capital proper as an accumulatable factor of production. The reason why this assumption does not appear to be consistent with the sample data could be that the aggregate production function is more complex than the Cobb-Douglas form allows. It is also interesting to note that for both samples the speed of convergence is now estimated to be lower than in the first model. We believe this is due to higher returns to capital broadly defined to include human capital. In fact, when only physical capital is accumulated its marginal productivity decreases rapidly. Thus, the steady state is achieved more quickly but at a lower per capita output level (see the definition of TJ in equation (8) and set the share of human capital 13 at a positive level). Table 2 also reports the results of the second model when panel data for the human capital proxy, rather than only cross-sectional data, are used. We find that the estimated coefficient on this proxy is now signif­ icantly negative for both samples. This result is at first surprising. Why does the addition of the time series dimension to the proxy for human capital change the sign of its effect on growth? Our explanation for this result is that when we incorporate time series data on education for each country we use not only the cross-country differences in the relation between education and growth but also the effect of changes in the human capital proxy over time in each country. This temporal relationship has been negative over the years, especially in developing countries (see Tilak (1989) and Fredriksen (1991)). In other words, adjusted secondary­ school enrollment ratios rose steadily in most developing countries during 1960-85, sometimes by large amounts, while output growth remained 17 17 De Gregorio (1992) reports similar results for a sample of Latin American countries. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWfH 533 stable or fell. Apparently, this time series relation is strong enough to override the cross-sectional effects in the estimation. This empirical result points to the possibility that the adjusted sec­ ondary-school enrollment ratio may not be a good proxy for the ratio of human capital investment to GDP when relatively short intervals (in our case, five-year intervals) are compared. The length of the interval is important for the quality of such a proxy because there is a considerable lag between the completion of education and its appropriate use as a factor of production (see Psacharopoulos and Ariagada (1986)). There­ fore, cross-sectional data (data where the observation for each country is an average of its respective time series observations) may be the preferred proxy in estimating the growth effects of human capital invest­ ment. The implication is that when the secondary-school enrollment ratio is used as the proxy, we can obtain good estimates of cross-country differences in human capital investment but not of changes in the rate of human capital investment within a country over time. Table 3 reports the results for the third augmented version of the Solow-Swan model. Its corresponding regression is represented by equa­ tion (10). Considerations of data availability obliged us to restrict the sample of countries used in this last estimation (see the appendix). Therefore, one would have to be particularly cautious about extrapolat­ ing the results described below to countries that are not included in the sample. The negative sign of the coefficient on lagged output indicates "conditional convergence," which means that-controlling for the de­ terminants of the steady state across countries-poor countries would tend to grow faster than rich ones (see Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992)). By including the investment ratios as well as the proxies for openness and public infrastructure in the regression equation, we appropriately condition for different preferences and technologies. The growth rate of the labor force is estimated to be negatively re­ lated to per capita output growth, especially when the estimates come from the sample that includes only developing countries. Investments in both physical capital and human capital are strongly and positively cor­ related with growth. When proxies for openness and public capital are included in the model, the coefficient on the rate of investment in physical capital becomes twice as large as it was in the second model, for both samples. This seems to indicate that the quality of physical investment increases when the international transfer of technology is allowed and when better public capital is provided. We believe that this has to do with the fact that greater openness and better public services create a market environment where allocative efficiency is enhanced. In addition, the rate of investment in human capital becomes much stronger in the case ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 534 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA Table 3. Solow-Swan Model Augmented to Include Human Capital Investment, Openness to Foreign Trade, and Public Infrastructure Variable• ln{y,-t) In(n, + 0.05) ln(sk,) In(s�r,) In(F) In(P) Implied Tt Wald test for uncorrelated effects (P-value) Wald test for 61 = -(a. + 63) in equation (10) All countries (n 81) Developing countries (n = 59) -0.2208 ( -9.45) -0.1470 ( -12.52) 0.2013 (18.17) 0.0945 (8.18) -0.0650 (-11.76) 0.0128 (0.78) 0.0499 (8.32) -0.6836 (-17.75) -0.1760 ( -9.01) 0.2057 (14.24) 0.3197 (18.15) -0.0820 (-15.97) 0.0978 (6.47) 0.2301 (9.45) 526.03 0.0000 5596.77 0.0000 = 61.76 238.19 0.0000 0.0000 • Ln(y,-t) is the logarithm of real GDP per worker lagged one period (five years). Ln (n , + 0.05) is the logarithm of the average growth rate of the working­ (P-value) age population plus the sum of technological progress and depreciation. Ln(sk,) is the logarithm of the average ratio of real investment to real GDP. Ln(s11,) is the logarithm of the ratio of human capital investment to GDP, prox.ied by the product of gross secondary-school enrollment ratio times the fraction of the working-age population aged 15 to 19. Ln(F) is the logarithm of the "closedness" of the economy, proxied by the weighted average of tariff rates on imported intermediate and capital goods. Ln(P) is the logarithm of the ratio of public infrastructure to GDP, proxied by the average ratio of general government fixed investment (central government plus public enterprises) to GDP. T-ratios are in parentheses. of the developing country sample when the aforementioned proxies are included. The variable F, defined as the weighted average of tariffs on interme­ diate and capital goods, has a significant negative effect on output growth. This measure of openness ("closedness" may be a better term given how this variable is defined) affects growth not only through the investment ratios, as indicated above, but also through the efficiency term, which accounts for technological improvement. The evidence of such an independent role for openness, combined with the fact that the absolute value of the coefficient's point estimate is larger for the devel- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 535 oping countries, lends support to the view that for many countries, particularly developing ones, liberal trade regimes provide a source of technological progress via the freedom to import sophisticated goods from the most technologically advanced nations. At a broader level, this result provides a measure of empirical confirmation for the familiar argu­ ment that outward-oriented trade strategies tend to promote economic growth in developing countries. The ratio of government fixed investment to GDP (the variable P) has a positive coefficient for both samples, but this coefficient is statistically significant at the 95 percent level only for the developing country sample. The statistical insignificance of this coefficient in the full sample may be due to the fact that our proxy for public capital is based on flow data that do not account for the initial level of the associated stock. This is espe­ cially important for the industrial countries, which by 1960 had accumu­ lated substantial stocks of public capital, relative to those in developing countries. In that sense, our proxy is better suited to developing coun­ tries, which may explain why we find a much larger and highly significant coefficient in the sample for the latter group. As in the case of the openness variable, it is interesting to note that, at least for the latter sample, the proxy for public capital has an independent role in economic growth, even when physical and human capital are already included. IV. Concluding Remarks This paper has extended the work of Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! (1992) in two directions. Unlike their analysis, which relies exclusively on cross­ sectional data, we find evidence of significant country-specific effects, which our panel data estimation procedure is able to detect. One impor­ tant consequence of this result is the faster rate of conditional conver­ gence that we find in our model, relative to that estimated by Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! and by Barro (1991). We surmise that this difference occurs because the latter studies do not take into account the correlation between country-specific effects and the independent variables in the growth equation. The other new result is that overall economic efficiency is influenced significantly and positively by the extent of openness to international trade and by the level of government fixed investment in the domestic economy. Like Maokiw, Romer, and Weil, we find that the Solow-Swan model's predictions are consistent with the evidence. These include the positive effects of saving ratios and the negative effects of population growth on the steady-state level and on the transitional growth path of per capita GDP. We also find (conditional) convergence to be approximately the ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 536 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA rate predicted by the Solow-Swan model. We estimate the share of capital at about one-third, which is close to the value estimated by Maddison (1987) for the share of nonhuman capital in GDP. Our estimated capital shares imply that diminishing returns to physical capital set in quickly, explaining the rapid convergence predicted by our model. Comparing the results between the two samples of industrial and developing countries, we find that the absolute value of the estimated coefficient on population growth is larger for our sample of developing countries alone, reflecting the fact that many countries in this group have tended to exhibit slow growth in per capita terms while experiencing rapid rates of population growth. Moreover, there is evidence that investment in physical capital has been less productive for those developing countries that have had lower initial stocks of human capital and of government fixed investment as well as higher rates of effective protection, aU of which have tended to reduce the overall efficiency of physical investment. Our results on the growth effects of a country's openness to interna­ tional trade and on government fixed investment deserve some elabora­ tion. When openness and the level of public infrastructure are taken into account, physical investment becomes quantitatively more important in the growth process, implying that a better quality of investment is encour­ aged by a more liberal international trade regime and by more govern­ ment fixed investment. Particularly for the developing countries, invest­ ment in human capital also becomes more quantitatively important when a more open trading environment and a better public infrastructure are in place. There are two channels through which the negative impact on growth of a restrictive trade system (proxied by the weighted average of tariffs on intermediate and capital goods) is transmitted, particularly in devel­ oping countries where the capital goods industries are in their infancy or nonexistent: through the rate of investment and through its efficiency. A high tariff structure discourages imports of capital goods and leads to less technology transfer, and thus to less technological improvement. The strong statistical significance of the proxy for "closedness" provides evidence that outward-oriented development strategies have a positive impact on economic growth. The government fixed investment variable is statistically and positively significant only in the developing countries, and appropriately so. This can be explained by the failure of our proxy for public infrastructure to account for its initial level. Among the industrial country group, the level of public infrastructure in 1960 was a large multiple of the level in the developing country group. As in the case of the outward orientation of development strategies, better provision of public infrastructure exerts an independent influence on the rate of economic growth. This may mean ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 537 that the government is in a better position to provide infrastructure than the private sector. In other words, either the private sector, if it had the resources, would tend to underinvest in infrastructure or the marginal productivity of public sector resources devoted to infrastructure is higher than that of private sector resources (presumably owing to significant externalities). APPENDIX Data Sources, Definitions, and the Sample of Countries The basic data used in this study are annual observations for the period 1960 to 1985. The following variables were taken from Penn World Tables in Summers and Heston (1991): y = real GDP per worker; sk = real investment to GDP ratio (five-year average); n = growth rate of the number of workers (five-year average). The following variable was taken from Mankiw, Romer, and Wei! (1992): sh = percent of working-age population enrolled in secondary school (average for the 1960-85 period). Panel data for the proxy of human capital investment were obtained from the UNESCO Statistical Yearbook 1991 and were adjusted for age using population data from UN Population Division (1991). Data on tariffs were taken from Lee (1992): F = import-share weighted average of tariffs on intermediate and capital goods (from various years in the early 1980s). The DEC Analytical data base from the World Bank (1991) was used to obtain a proxy for public infrastructure: P average ratio of general government fixed investment to GDP. The sample of countries was as follows. = Industrial countries 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany (West) Greece Ireland Italy 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland Turkey United Kingdom United States ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 538 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA Developing countries 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. 31. 32. 33. 34. 35. 36. 37. 38. Algeria Angola Argentina Bangladesh Benin Bolivia Botswana Brazil Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Central African Republic Chad Chile Colombia Congo Costa Rica Cote d'Jvoire Dominican Republic Ecuador Egypt El Salvador Ethiopia Ghana Guatemala Haiti Honduras Hong Kong India Indonesia Israel Jamaica Jordan Kenya Liberia Madagascar Malawi Malaysia 39. Mali Mauritania 41. Mauritius 42. Mexico 43. Morocco 44. Mozambique 45. Myanmar 46. Nepal 47. Nicaragua 48. Niger 49. Nigeria 50. Pakistan 51. Panama 52. Papua New Guinea 53. Paraguay 54. Peru 55. Philippines 56. Republic of Korea 57. Rwanda 58. Senegal 59. Sierra Leone 60. Singapore 61. Somalia 62. South Africa 63. Sri Lanka 64. Sudan 65. Syrian Arab Republic 66. Tanzania 67. Tb.ailand 68. Togo 69. Trinidad and Tobago 70. Tunisia 71. Uganda 72. Uruguay 73. Venezuela 74. Zaire 75. Zambia 76. Zimbabwe 40. Tables 1, 2, and 3: The sample in these tables covers all of the 98 industrial and developing countries listed above. Table 4 (96 countries): The sample in this table is the same as that for Tables 1-3, except that South Africa and Switzerland have been dropped owing to the unavailability of data. Table 5 (81 countries): In the sample in this table, the following countries have been dropped from the sample of Tables 1-3 for the same reason: Botswana, Cameroon, Central African Republic, Chad, Cote d'Ivoire, Dominican Repub­ lic, Honduras, Israel, Liberia, Mali, Mauritania, Mozambique, Myanmar, Niger, Panama, South Africa, and Togo. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 539 REFERENCES Bardhan, Pranab, and Sydney Lewis, "Models of Growth with Imported Inputs," Economica, Vol. 37 (November 1970), pp. 373-85. Barro, Robert J., "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106 (May 1991), pp. 407-43. Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, "Convergence," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100 (April 1992), pp. 223-5 1. Chamberlain, Gary, "Multivariate Regression Models for Panel Data," Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 18 (January 1982), pp. 5-46. , "Panel Data," in Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. II, ed. by Zvi Griliches and Michael D. lntriligator (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1983), pp. 1248-1318. Chen, Edward K.Y., Hyper-Growth in Asian Economies: A Comparative Study of Hong Kong, Japan, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan (New York: Harper Hall, 1979). De Gregorio, Jose, "Economic Growth in Latin America," Journal of Develop­ ment Economics , Vol. 39 (July 1992), pp. 59-84. Diamond, John, "Government Expenditure and Economic Growth: An Empir­ ical Investigation," IMF Working Paper 89/45 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989). Domar, Evsey D., "Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and Employment," Econometrica, Vol. 14 (April 1946), pp. 137-47. Edwards, Sebastian, "Trade Orientation, Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 39 (July 1992), pp. 31-57. Feder, Gershon, "On Exports and Economic Growth," Journal of Developmenr Economics, Vol. 12 (February IApril 1983), pp. 59-73. Fredriksen, Birger J., An Introduction to the Analysis of Student Enrollment and Flow Statistics, Report No. PHREE/91/39 (Washington: Population and Human Resources Department, World Bank, 1991). Greene, William H., Econometric Analysis (New York: Macmillan Publishing Company, 1990). Hacche, Graeme, The Theory of Economic Growth: An Introduction (New York: St. Martins Press, 1979). Harrod, Ray F. , "An Essay in Dynamic Theory," Economic Journal, Vol. 49 (March 1939), pp. 14-33. Keesing, Donald B., "Outward-Looking Policies and Economic Development," Economic Journal, Vol. 78 (June 1967), pp. 303-20. Khan, Mohsin, and Delano Villanueva, "Macroeconomic Policies and Long­ Term Growth," Special Paper 13, (Nairobi: African Economic Research Consortium, May 1991). Kbang Chulsoon, "Export-Led Economic Growth: The Case of Technology Transfer," Economic Studies Quarterly , Vol. 38 (June 1987), pp. 131-47. Knight, Malcolm, Norman Loayza, and Delano Villanueva, "Testing the -- , ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 540 KNIGHT, LOAYZA, and VILLANUEVA Neoclassical Theory of Economic Growth," IMF Working Paper 92/106 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992). Lee, Jong-Wha, "International Trade, Distortions, and Long-Run Economic Growth," Staff Papers, [nternational Monetary Fund, Vol. 40 (June 1993), pp. 299-328. Loayza, Norman, "A Test of the Convergence Hypothesis Using Panel Data" (unpublished; Harvard University, January 1992). McCurdy, Thomas E., "The Use of Time Series Processes to Model the Error Structure of Earnings in a Longitudinal Data Analysis," Journal of Econo­ metrics, Vol. 18 (January 1982), pp. 83-114. Maddison, Angus, "Growth and Slowdown in Advanced Capitalist Economies: Techniques of Quantitative Assessment," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 25 (June 1987), pp. 649-98. Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil, "A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107 (May 1992), pp. 407-37. MundJak, Yair, "On the Pooling of Time Series and Cross Section Data," Econometrica, Vol. 46 (January 1978), pp. 69-85. Orsmond, David W.H., "The Size and Composition of the Public Sector and Economic Growth: A Theoretical and Imperical Review" (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990). Otani, Ichiro, andDelano Villanueva, "Long-Term Growth in Developing Coun­ tries and Its Determinants: An Empirical Analysis," World Development, Vol. 18 (June 1990), pp. 769-83. Psacharopoulos, George, and Ana-Maria Ariagada, "The Educational Compo­ sition of the Labor Force: An International Comparison," International Labor Review, Vol. 125 (Sept.-Oct. 1986), pp. 561-74. Roubini, Nouriel, and Xavier J. Sala-i-Martin, "Financial Repression and Eco­ nomic Growth," Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 39 (July 1992), pp. 5-30. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier J . , "Lecture Notes on Economic Growth (I)," NBER Working Paper No. 3563 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1990). Solow, Robert M., "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics , Vol. 50 (February 1956), pp. 65-94. Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston, "The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988," The Quarterly Journal of Economics , Vol. 106 (May 1991), pp. 327-61. Swan, Trevor W., "Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation," Economic Record, Vol. 32 (November 1956), pp. 334-61. ThirlwaU, A.P., "The Balance of Payments Constraint as an Explanation of International Growth Rate Differences," Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quar­ terly Review , Vol. 128 (March 1979), pp. 45-53. Tilak, Tandhyala B.G., "Education and Its Relation to Economic Growth, Poverty, and Income Distribution: Past Evidence and Further Analysis," Discussion Paper 46 (Washington: World Bank, 1989). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution NEOCLASSICAL THEORY OF ECONOMIC GROWTH 541 UNESCO, Statistical Yearbook 1991 (Paris: UNESCO, 1992). United Nations· Population Division, Global Estimates and Projections of Popu­ i (New York: United Nations, 1991). lation by Sex and Age: The 1990 Revsion Villanueva, Delano, "Exports and Economic Development," IMF Working Pa­ per 93/41 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993). White, Halbert, "A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity," American Economic Review, Vol. 48 (May 1980), pp. 817-38. World Bank, DEC Analytical Database (Washington: International Economics Department, Analysis and Prospects Division, World Bank, 1991). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF Staff Papers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) Q 1993 International Monetary Fund Capital and Trade as Engines of Growth in France An Application of Johansen's Cointegration Methodology DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM* An aggregate production function is estimated using recent cointegrating techniques particularly appropriate for estimating long-run relationships. The empirical results suggest that the growth of output in France has been spurred by increased trade integration within the European Community and by the accumulation not only of business sector capital-the only measure of capital included in most empirical studies-but also by govern­ ment infrastructure capital, residential capital, and research and develop­ ment capital. Calculations of potential output indicate that trade and capital-broadly defined-account for all of the growth in the French economy during the past two decades. [JEL E23, F15, 032, 052] HE IMPORTANCE of trade and capital as determinants of trend or Tpotential economic growth is widely acknowledged. The collapse of world trade following the passage of the Smoot-Hawley tariffs in the United States in 1930 helped to trigger the great world depression of the 1930s. By contrast, the brisk expansion of world trade in the 1950s and 1960s contributed to unusually rapid growth in the industrial countries. More recently, the fast-growing economies of Southeast and East Asia * David T. Coe is in the Research Department and holds a doctorate from the University of Michigan. Reza Moghadam is in the European I Department and holds a doctorate from the University of Warwick. The authors thank Julia Darby, Robert Ford, John Ireland, Flemming Larsen, Paul Masson, Mark Taylor, Hari Vittas, and Simon Wren-Lewis as well as analysts from Directions de Ia Prevision and INSEE and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions, and Toh Kuan for research assistance. 542 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWfH IN FRANCE 543 have built their success on an outward orientation and rapid increases in intraregional trade. High rates of capital accumulation also spurred growth in the industrial countries in the postwar period and in the dy­ namic economies of Asia more recently. The slowdown in growth after the mid-1970s in France and other industrial countries coincided with a moderation in the growth of world trade and, in some countries, with a reduced pace of capital formation, particularly by the business sector.1 Although, empirical studies based on aggregate production functions have always emphasized the importance of capital accumulation by the business sector, the importance of other types of capital accumulation has received considerably less emphasis; the role of trade has generally been emphasized only in empirical studies based on computable general equilibrium models. This paper presents new estimates of an aggre­ gate production function for France, focusing on the role of trade and the importance of capital accumulation by government, households, and businesses, including their expenditures on research and development (R&D). The production function is estimated with recent cointegrating tech­ niques suggested by Johansen (1988). This methodology emphasizes the identification of long-run relationships, and hence is particularly appro­ priate for studying the determinants of potential output. The empirical results suggest that increased trade within the European Community has raised efficiency and productivity in France. The empirical results also indicate that in addition to the stock of business sector capital-which is the only measure of capital included in most empirical studies-the stock of government infrastructure capital, the stock of residential capital, and the stock of R&D capital have also contributed to the growth of output in France. The estimated production function is used to calculate potential output. These calculations indicate that trade and capital-broadly defined­ account for all of the growth in the French economy in the two decades 1971-91. Although labor input is also an important determinant of out­ put, its contribution to growth has been nil over the 1971-91 period. Thus, during the past two decades, trade and capital have been the engines of growth in France. The growth of· potential output is esti­ mated to have averaged about 2\12 percent a year in 1984-91 and to continue at about 21;2 percent a year in 1992-97. To foster more robust 1 This slowdown has rekindled interest in the determinants of growtb and in growth theory, as evidenced by the recent emergence of a large and expanding literature on endogenous growth. See Lucas (1988), Sala-i-Martin (1990), and Helpman (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM 544 growth, France must encourage capital accumulation, implement labor market policies to reduce unemployment, and take steps to revitalize the trade liberalization process. I. Johansen's Cointegration Methodology Over the past few years, important advances have been made in co­ integration techniques to estimate long-run relationships.2 The basic idea of cointegration is that two or more variables may be regarded as defining a long-run equilibrium relationship if they move closely together in the long run, even though they may drift apart in the short run. This long-run relationship is referred to as a cointegrating vector. Because there is a long-run relationship between the variables, a regression containing all the variables of a cointegrating vector will have a stationary error term, even if none of the variables taken alone is stationary. Stock (1987) demonstrates that, in the case of cointegrated nonstation­ ary series, ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of the cointegrating vector are not only consistent but they converge on their true parameter values much faster than in the stationary case. This property is referred to as "super consistency. "3 The proof of consistency does not require the assumption that the regressors be uncorrelated with the error term. In fact, the estimates will remain (super) consistent if any of the variables in the cointegrating vector is used as the dependent variable. More generally, most of the classical assumptions underlying the gen­ eral linear model are not required in order for OLS or maximum likeli­ hood estimates of the cointegrating vector to have desirable properties. This is particularly important because errors in variables and simul­ taneity-both of which would normally be cause for concern in the data set used here-will not affect the desirable properties of the estimates. Moreover, because the cointegration approach focuses on long-run rela­ tionships, problems associated with variations in factor utilization and with autocorrelation do not arise. A popular approach to cointegration has been to use unit-root tests, 2 Cuthbertson, Hall, and Taylor (1992) present a survey of cointegration. 3The intuition behind the super-consistency result is that, for values of the parameters that do not cointegrate, the residual series will itself be nonstationary and therefore have a very large estimated variance. When the estimated parame­ ters are close to the true cointegrating parameters, the residual becomes station­ ary and its variance shrinks. Since least squares and maximum likelihood methods essentially minimize the residual variance, they will be extremely good at picking out the cointegrating parameters if they exist. The super-consistency result does not hold if there are multiple cointegrating vectors. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTH IN FRANCE 545 such as the Dickey-Fuller (DF) or the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test (Dickey and Fuller (1981)), to determine the degree of integration of the relevant variables and then to apply the Engle and Granger (1987) two-step procedure, which is based on an OLS estimate of the cointe­ grating vector and a unit-root test of its residuals. Although it is easy to implement, there are a number of problems with the Engle and Granger two-step procedure. Banerjee and others (1986) show that there may be significant small-sample biases in such OLS estimates of the cointegrating vectors, and Hendry and Mizon (1990) illustrate that conventional DF and ADF tests generally suffer from parameter instability. In addition, the limiting distributions for the DF and ADF tests are not well defined, implying that the power of these tests is low (Phillips and Ouliaris (1990)). Perhaps most damaging is the possibility that any given set of variables may contain more than one long-run relationship: there may be multiple cointegrating vectors. OLS estimates of the cointegrating vector cannot identify multiple long-run relationships or test for the number of cointe­ grating vectors. Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990) present a cointegra­ tion estimation methodology that overcomes most of the problems of the two-step approach. The Johansen procedure is based on maximum likeli­ hood estimates of all the cointegrating vectors in a given set of variables and provides two likelihood ratio tests for the number of cointegrating vectors. Johansen and Juselius (1990) consider the following general model: X, = II1 Xr- 1 + · · · + IIk Xr-k + fl. + e,, for t = 1 , . . . , T, (1) where X, is a vector of p variables; e�> . . . , e, are independent normal errors with mean zero and covariance matrix A; Xr-ko . . . , X0 are fixed; and fl. is an intercept vector. Economic time series are often nonstation­ ary, and systems such as the above vector autoregressive representation (VAR) can be written in the conventional first-difference form: AX, = fk-1 AXr-k+l + IIX,_k + fl. + e,, (2) where f; = -(1 - 111 - • • • - II;), for i = 1, . . . , k - 1 , and II = -(I - Il1 - · · · - Ilk)· The only level term in equation (2) is IIXr-k. Thus, only the matrix II contains information about the long-run relationships between the vari­ ables in the data vector. There are three cases: ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 546 DAVlD T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM 1 . If the matrix II has rank zero, then all the variables in X, are integrated of order one or higher and the VAR has no long-run properties; 2. If II has rank p (it is of full rank), the variables in X, are stationary; and 3. If II has rank r (0 < r < p ), II can be decomposed into two distinct (p x r) matrices a and Jl such that II = afl'. The third case implies that there are r cointegrating vectors. The parame­ ters of the cointegrating vectors are contained in the Jl matrix. Therefore, Jl'X, is stationary even though X, itself is nonstationary. The a matrix gives the weights with which the cointegrating vectors enter each equa­ tion of the system. To determine the number of cointegrating vectors, r, Johansen and Juselius describe two likelihood ratio tests. In the first test, which is based on the maximal eigenvalue, the null hypothesis is that there are at most r cointegrating vectors against the alternative of r + 1 cointegrating vectors. In the second test, which is based on the trace of the stochastic matrix, the null hypothesis is that there are at most r cointegrating vectors against the alternative hypothesis that there are r or more cointegrating vectors. The first test is generally considered to be more powerful because the alternative hypothesis is an equality. These tests can also be used to determine if a single variable is stationary by including only that variable in X,. Johansen demonstrates that the likelihood ratio tests have asymptotic distributions that are a function only of the difference between the number of variables and the number of cointegrating vectors. Therefore, in contrast with the DF and ADF tests, the Johansen likelihood ratio tests have well-defined limiting distributions. Johansen and Juselius also provide a methodology for testing hypotheses about the estimated coef­ ficients of the cointegrating vectors based on likelihood ratio tests with standard chi-squared distributions. n. Production Function We estimate a Cobb-Douglas-type production function augmented to include R&D capital as a distinct factor of production and to allow a measure of trade to influence the productivity of the factors of produc­ tion. More specifically, we estimate the long-run relationship between real value added in the nonfarm business sector (y ), hours worked in the ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWfH IN FRANCE 547 nonfarm business sector (h), the stock of capital (k), the stock of R&D capital (k'&d), and intra-EC trade as a percent of total EC output (EC) : y = ah + �k + -yk'&d + SEC + constant, (3) where variables represented by lower-case symbols are logarithms. The production function has some novel features. One unusual feature is the inclusion of a measure of European trade integration as a determi­ nant of the productivity of capital and labor in France. The theoretical justification for including a measure of trade integration has recently been developed by Grossman and Helpman (1991) and Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991). The EC variable captures the beneficial effects of trade integration in the European Community on French enterprises from heightened competition, increased specialization, exposure to new ideas and techniques, and increasing returns to scale in production and in research and development (Figure 1). As noted below, the same variable has been used to explain long-run developments in total factor productiv­ ity in Germany; a similar variable (per capita trade) is used by Mao and Rivera-Batiz (1993) in their study of growth and regional convergence in China. A second unusual feature is the treatment of capital. The physical capital stock is broadly defined to include the stock of government infrastructure capital and residential capital, in addition to the capital of private and public enterprises (Figure 2). The potentially important role of infrastructure capital in increasing productivity and output has re­ ceived considerable attention recently, although it has proven difficult to estimate separate elasticities for infrastructure capital.4 Including resi­ dential capital is appropriate since value added in the business sector includes imputed services from the housing stock. More generally, hous­ ing is an important aspect of an economy's infrastructure, which, like roads, bridges, and nonresidential structures, contributes to its ability to produce real goods and services. 5 This focus on a very broad definition of capital differs from most empirical studies, which typically consider only the business sector capital stock. Although infrastructure capital may not be an important determinant of short-run movements in output, it is particularly important to include infrastructure capital when studyin� the long-run determinants of output. In addition to the stock of physical capital, the stock of R&D capital 4See the cross-country evidence presented in Ford and Poret (1991) and the evidence for the United States presented in Munnell (1990). 5 An increase in the stock of housing, for example, may increase labor mobility. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 548 DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM Figure I . EC Integration (In percent) 1 5 r- ----� 14 lntra-EC trade as a percent ofEC output "" 13 12 II 10 1975 1977 1979 1981 198;\ 1985 1987 1 989 1991 is included as a distinct factor of production. This allows the process of technological progress to be modeled explicitly, as suggested by Griliches (1988). The importance of R&D capital, which is complementary to human capital, has been emphasized in endogenous growth theories (Lucas (1988) and Helpman (1992)). A final unusual feature of the production function is that the coeffi­ cients on capital and labor are neither constrained to sum to unity nor constrained to equal their factor shares, in which case the production function becomes a total factor productivity equation. One reason to freely estimate the coefficients on capital and labor is that R&D capital is included as an additional factor of production, and it is not clear how its factor share would be calculated. More generally, the elasticities of output with respect to each factor of production will only be equal to factor shares if factor markets are perfectly competitive, and this is not ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTH IN FRANCE 549 Figure 2. Capiral Srocks 1 9 7 1 : I= I 00) (In logarithms, 100 �------� 180 170 160 150 140 130 Srock ufR&D capiro/ . · • 120 1 10 1 00 .------. Residenrial capiro/ 180 170 160 150 ... ... ... ... ... ... ... Business secrur capiro/ 140 130 120 110 alncluding business sector, residential, and government capital stocks. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 550 DAV[D T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM assumed here. In addition, endogenous growth theories have questioned the assumption of constant returns to scale, and some have argued that the coefficient on capital should be much larger than suggested by its factor share. 6 m. Empirical Results The production function has been estimated using quarterly data for France from 1971:1 to 1991:4 (84 observations). Estimation results based on alternative specifications are discussed below and data sources and definitions are reported in the Appendix. Table 1 reports the results of tests for the order of integration of the basic set of variables. The results in Table 1 have been obtained using the Johansen procedure, which, as noted above, has well-defined limiting distributions. These tests for the orders of integration do not suffer from the parameter instability associated with the DF and ADF tests and are consistent with our use of the Johansen procedure to estimate the co­ integrating vectors. The null hypothesis that the levels of the variables are stationary is rejected, but the null hypothesis that the first differ­ ences are stationary cannot be rejected. Therefore, all series appear to be integrated of order one. The test statistics and the estimated cointegrating vectors from the Johansen procedure are reported in Table 2, where r denotes the number 7 Table 1 . Johansen Maximum Likelihood Tests for the Order of Integration (1971:1 to 1991:4, maximum of four lags in VAR) Variable y h Test statistic Variable Test statistic 13.34 1.53 L\y L\h 1.96 9.25 k L\k 4.31 2.04 £\kr&d kr&d 0.23 7.48 EC 3.44 L\EC 4.44 Note: The null hypothesis is stationarity. The critical values are 3.76 at the 95 percent confidence level and 2.69 at the 90 percent confidence level. Delta is the fi rst-difference operator. 6 See, for example, Romer (1987) and Sala-i-Martin (1990). There are a number of practical problems with imposing factor shares, one of which is that they are not constant over the sample period. In addition, there are a variety of ways to calculate factor shares, depending, for example, on the way that self-employment income is allocated to capital or labor. 7 The DF and ADF tests give the same result. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 551 CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTH IN FRANCE Table 2. Johansen Maximum Likelihood Tests and Parameter Estimates (1971:1 to 1991:4, maximum of four lags in VAR; eigenvalues in descending order: 0.34, 0.21, 0.18, 0.14, 0.13E-5) A. Cointegration likelihood ratio test based on maximal eigenvalue of the stochastic matrix Null r=O r :5. 1 r :5. 2 r :5. 3 r :5. 4 Hypothesis• Alternative r=1 r=2 r=3 r=4 r=5 Test statistic 35.27 20.14 17.15 12.43 0.0001 95 percent critical value 33.32 27.14 21.07 14.90 8.18 90 percent critical value 30.84 24.78 18.90 12.91 6.50 95 percent critical value 70.60 48.28 31.52 17.95 8.18 90 percent critical value 66.49 45.23 28.71 15.66 6.50 B. Cointegration likelihood ratio test based on trace of the stochastic matrix Null r=O r c5. 1 r c5. 2 r :5. 3 r :5. 4 Hypothesis• Alternative r�1 r�2 r�3 r�4 r =5 Test statistic 85.00 49.73 29.58 12.43 0.0001 C. Estimated cointegrating vectors (coefficients normalized on y in parentheses) y h k k'&d -10.76 7.66 1.80 5.71 ( -1.00) (0.17) (0.53) (0.71) -2.64 3.17 8.40 -7.60 2 (-2.88) (3.18) (1 .20) ( -1.00) •The number of cointegrating vectors is denoted by r. Vector 1 EC 0.34 (0.03) -0.10 ( -0.04) of cointegrating vectors.8 Panel A reports the maximal eigenvalue test of the null hypothesis that there are at most r cointegrating vectors against the alternative of r + 1 cointegrating vectors. Starting with the null hypothesis that there are no cointegrating vectors (r = 0) against the alternative of one cointegrating vector (r = 1), the test statistic (35.27) 8The Johansen procedure involves the simultaneous estimation of dynamic vector autoregressive (VAR) equations, for which fourth-order Jags were in­ cluded. It is assumed that the variables have linear deterministic trends. Estima­ tion has been done on Microfit 3.0, see Pesaran and Pesaran (1991). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 552 DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM is greater than the 95 percent critical value (33.32), rejecting the null hypothesis and indicating that there is at least one cointegrating vector. The null hypothesis of r ::::; 1 against r = 2, however, cannot be rejected, suggesting that there is a unique cointegrating vector. Panel B reports the trace test of the null hypothesis that there are at most r cointegrating vectors against the alternative that there are more than r vectors. Both the null of r = 0 against r � 1 and the null of r ::::; 1 against r � 2 are rejected. However, the null of r ::::; 2 against r � 3 cannot be rejected, indicating that there are at most two cointegrating vectors. 9 Panel C of Table 2 presents the two estimated cointegrating vectors. The coefficients in parentheses are normalized on y. In th·e first cointe­ grating vector, all of the estimated coefficients have the expected signs and are of reasonable magnitudes, although the normalized coefficients for labor and capital are both somewhat higher than their factor shares (see below). In the second cointegrating vector, the estimated coefficients are either implausibly large in terms of factor shares, incorrectly signed, or both. In light of these results, and given that the existence of two cointegrating vectors is rejected by the maximal eigenvalue test, we take the first cointegrating vector as our preferred estimate of the production function. Compared with the estimated parameters on the labor and capital inputs, it is more difficult to judge the plausibility of the estimated parameters on the stock of R&D capital and the variable for EC trade integration. The estimated coefficient on R&D capital is similar to those found in comparable studies for the United States, Japan, and Germany, but is somewhat larger than typically found in studies based on firm- and industry-level data, perhaps because the estimation of an aggregate pro­ duction function is better able to capture spillovers that increase the social, and hence the aggregate, return to research and development. 10 Turning to the estimated coefficient on the EC variable, Coe and Krueger (1990) find the same variable to be a determinant of total factor productivity in the Federal Republic of Germany, although the estimated coefficient for France is somewhat larger than that for Germany. The fact that this variable helps to explain medium- to long-term output develop­ ments in other European countries suggests that it is a good proxy for the 9 Studies using the Johansen procedure often obtain much less clear-cut results; see, for example, Moghadam and Wren-Lewis (1990), Boughton (1991), and MacDonald and Taylor (1993). 10 Recent studies at the aggregate level for the United States, Japan, and Germany find an elasticity of abo�t 0.13; see Adams and Coe (1990), Citrin (forthcoming), and Coe and Krueger (1990), respectively. Griliches (1988) re­ ports that estimated elasticities from firm- and industry-level data tend to lie between 0.06 and 0.1. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTI-l IN FRANCE 553 economic impact of European integration. Moreover, as discussed be­ low, the estimated impact on French growth of European integration is consistent with Baldwin's (1989) estimates of the impact of the single market on EC growth. An important question is whether the stock of R&D capital and the proxy for EC integration are necessary for cointegration. The likelihood ratio test that the coefficients on k'&d and EC are zero is strongly rejected (chi-squared (2) = 14.9; 95 percent critical value = 5.99).11 If either k'&d or EC is omitted, both of the Johansen likelihood ratio tests of the null hypothesis that there are no cointegrating vectors cannot be rejected. Thus, output, labor, and capital are not by themselves cointegrated; both R&D capital and EC integration are necessary additional variables for cointegration. As discussed above, the measure of physical capital used in the esti­ mated equations includes not only the stock of business sector capital but also the stock of government infrastructure capital and the stock of residential capital. The specification of the equation does not, however, allow the different components of capital-government infrastructure, public enterprises, private business, and residential capital-to have different impacts on output. Specifications that entered some or all of the components of capital separately yielded implausible results.12 Because it is much more common to include only the stock of business sector capital (kb), Table 3 reports estimation results using it instead of the stock of total capital (k). 13 The two tests for the existence of a cointegrating vector give conflicting results. At the 95 percent confidence level, the test based on the maximal eigenvalue (Panel A) indicates that there are no cointegrating vectors (test statistic of 31.96 against a critical value of 33.32), whereas the test based on the trace (Panel B) indicates 11 A number of other tests were performed to check the robustness of this result: (i) k'"'d and EC were excluded and a trend was added; (ii) EC was dropped and a trend was included; and (iii) a trend was included along with the other variables. None of these specifications resulted in a cointegrating vector with sensible coefficients. 12 In theory it is possible to enter the components of the capital stock sepa­ ra�y _and _test the su_!!Hni.J.lg �striction-for example, <X ln(X + Y) = [<XX !(X + Y) lnX) + [<XY !(X + Y)ln Y], where a bar indicates the sample mean. However, entering the components of capital separately led to multiple cointegrating vectors. Since the "structural" model can consist of a linear com­ bination of the Johansen vectors, the restrictions must be tested across all vectors; when this was done, however, the likelihood ratio tests did not converge. 13 De Long and Summers (1991), based on cross-country data for industrial and developing countries, find equipment investment has a stronger association with gbrowth than other components of investment. Estimates using only the stock of usiness equipment capital were not possible since this variable is not readily available for France. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 554 DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM Table 3. Johansen Maximum Likelihood Tests and Parameter Estimates with the Business Sector Capital Stock (1971:1 to 1991:4, maximum of four lags in VAR; eigenvalues in descending order: 0.33, 0.25, 0.20, 0.13, 0.01) A. Cointegration likelihood ratio test based on maximal eigenvalue of the stochastic matrix Null Hypothesis" Alternative r=O r :s 1 r :s. 2 r=1 r=2 r=3 r :s. 4 r r53 r=4 = 5 Test statistic 95 percent 90 percent critical value critical value 33.32 27.14 21.07 30.84 24.78 18.90 8.18 6.50 31.96 22.77 17.61 11 . 09 0.78 14.90 12.91 B. Cointegration likelihood ratio test based on trace of the stochastic matrix Null Hypothesis" r=O r :s 1 r :s. 2 r :S. 3 r :s. 4 Alternative r :2:: 1 r :2:: 2 r :2:: 3 r :2:: 4 r =5 Test statistic 95 percent critical value 84.21 52.24 29.48 11.87 0.78 70.60 48.28 31.52 17.95 8.18 90 percent critical value 66.49 45.23 28.71 15.66 6.50 C. Estimated cointegrating vectors (coefficients normalized on y in parentheses) h kb kr&d y -9.83 9.31 2.87 3.50 (-1 .00) (0.23) (0.95) (0.36) -3.26 -10.69 -4.07 15.47 2 ( -1 .00) (0.21) (0.69) (0.26) The number of cointegrating vectors is denoted by r. Vector 1 EC 0.32 (0.03) 0.12 (-0.008) • that there are at most two cointegrating vectors. Panel C reports the coefficient estimates from the two possible cointegrating vectors. Al­ though the estimated coefficients (normalized on y in parentheses) on h, kb, and k'&d are correctly signed, their magnitudes are less plausible than in the specification using total capital (Table 2). Table 4 reports the results of testing the first cointegrating vector reported in Table 2 for a number of restrictions on the estimated coeffi­ cients of the three factors of production: labor, capital, and R&D capital. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 555 CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTH IN FRANCE Table 4. TestS of Parameter Restrictions (y = cxh. + l3k + -yk'&.d + OEC + constant) Parameter restrictions a + 13 1.0 a = 0.6 13 = 0.4 a + 13 + -y = 1.0 13 + -y = 1.0 = Chi-squared test Unrestricted statistic (degrees Critical values estimates of freedom) 1.24 a = 0.71 13 0.53 1.41 0.70 1.03 (1) 11.45 (4) 95 percent 3.84 9.49 3.86 (1) 9.83 (1) 3.84 3.84 = 90 percent 2.71 7.78 2.71 2.71 The restriction that the sum of the coefficients on h and k is unity cannot be rejected. However, the restriction that the estimated coefficients on h and k are equal to the sample average of their factor shares (0.6 and 0.4, respectively) is rejected. The restriction that the estimated coeffi­ cients on all three factors sum to unity is also rejected; the fact that the estimated coefficients sum to 1.4 suggests that there are increasing re­ turns to scale with respect to labor, capital, and R&D capital. Finally, the restriction that the estimated coefficients on the two factors of pro­ duction that can be accumulated-physical capital and R&D capital­ sum to unity is rejected. In Sala-i-Martin's (1990) discussion of economic growth, this condition is necessary for endogenous growth. This is be­ cause a sum of the coefficients on physical and R&D capital of less than unity implies decreasing returns to capital, which in turn implies-in the absence of exogenous technological progress-zero steady-state growth of per capita output. A number of alternative specifications of the production function were estimated. A demographic variable measuring the proportion of youth (15-24 years old) in total employment was added to capture the effect of possible changes in the quality of labor input. Inflation was included to test the hypothesis that high inflation diverts resources from productive activity. The total stock of R&D capital in 21 of France's trading partners was included to test if France benefited from R&D performed abroad. 14 None of these formulations generated meaningful cointegrating vectors­ either there was no cointegrating vector or there were multiple cointe­ grating vectors, the estimated coefficients of which had incorrect signs, implausible magnitudes, or both. Alternative measures of trade were also tried. To test whether the EC variable was capturing the effect of increased world-rather than 14 Empirical evidence of the importance of international R&D spillovers is presented in Coe and Helpman (1993). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 556 DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM European-integration, world trade as a percentage of world GDP was included both with and without the EC trade integration variable, but we were unable to obtain a cointegrating vector. If France's EC trade either as a percent of total French trade or as a perceht of French out­ put is included instead of the EC variable, the two likelihood ratio tests for the existence and uniqueness of a cointegrating vector give incon­ sistent results. However, in both cases the estimated coefficients in the vector with the largest eigenvalue were correctly signed and of plausible magnitudes.15 IV. Potential Output In the long run, actual output should equal potential output, and hence the estimated cointegrating vector in Table 2 provides a direct and simple means of calculating potential output (y*) : 16 y* = 0.71h + 0.53k + 0.17k'&d + 0.03EC - 0.39. (4) Because potential output is commonly thought to be relatively stable compared with actual output, short-run fluctuations have been re­ moved from hours worked and from the EC integration variable in order to calculate potential output-though not to estimate the production function-in the case of the EC variable by estimating a cubic trend (see Figure 1). The sources of the cyclical movements in hours worked can be revealed by decomposing it into hours per employee (hie), the employment ratio (ellf), the participation ratio (If/pop), and population (pop): in loga­ rithms, h = (hie) + (e/lf) + (if/pop) + (pop).17 Cyclical variations in hours worked mainly reflect movements in the employment ratio and in the participation ratio (Figure 3). A polynomial trend has been used to remove cyclical variations in hours per employee and in the participation ratio. Cyclical movements in the employment ratio mainly reflect de­ viations of the actual rate of unemployment from the natural rate of unemployment. Since it lies beyond the scope of the present study to estimate the natural rate of unemployment for France as a function 15 According to one of the tests, the null hypothesis that there are no cointegrat­ ing vectors cannot be rejected. 16 See the references cited in the box on potential output in IMF (1991, p. 43); and Torres and Martin (1990). The constant in eq uation (4) has been calculated so that the average error over the sample period is zero. 17 Although hours and employment refer to the nonfarm business sector, labor force and population refer to the full economy. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 557 CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTH lN FRANCE Figure 3. Hours Workeda (In logarithms, 1971: I = I 00) 106 104 102 100 Hours 11·orked assuming unemploymem ar rhe natural raft' 98 Hours 11·orked (h) 96 94 92 Hours worked with 90 cyclical variations removed 88 1977 1979 1981 198� 1987 1989 1991 120 1 16 1 12 108 104 100 ' .... 96 _ .... Participation ratio _ (/jlpop) _ _ _ , _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ ..... 92 ···· ·· Employmem ratio 88 (eflj) 84 1 97 1 "Nonfarm business sector. The decomposition of hours worked in the lower panel is calculated from in logarithms. h=(hle)+(ellj)+(lftpop)+pop, where all variables are ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 558 DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM of its structural determinants-two estimates of potential output are presented corresponding to two assumptions about the natural rate of unemployment. One estimate of potential output uses the actual (cyclically adjusted) employment ratio, on the assumption that the actual unemployment rate is not too different from the equilibrium natural rate. This assumption is consistent with a hysteresis view of equilibrium unemployment and with the persistence of high unemployment and broadly stable wage inflation during the past three to four years in France. The second estimate of potential output incorporates an adjustment for hours worked based on a very simple and straightforward estimate of the natural rate of unemployment. 18 This estimate of the natural rate reflects two assump­ tions: that the actual unemployment rate was about the same as the natural rate in the early 1970s and that increases in the natural rate thereafter can be proxied by trend increases in the unemployment rate for prime-age males (Figure 4). 19 The two estimates of potential output are shown in Figure 5. After slowing from the mid-1970s to about 1986, the estimated growth of potential output increases to a little more than 3 percent in the early 1990s.20 Since the mid-1970s, the estimated level of potential output incorporating hours worked at the natural rate of unemployment is higher than the estimate using actual hours worked, reflecting the assumption of greater labor input. By the mid-1980s, when the gap between the alternative estimates of the natural rate reached its maximum, the gap between the two estimates of potential output was about 2V4 percent. In terms of growth rates, however, the two estimates of potential output are broadly similar. From the early 1980s until about 1988, both measures of potential output exceeded actual output, and this contributed to the sustained declines in inflation from double-digit levels in 1980 to less than 18 Using an asterisk to indicate that a variable has been cyclically adjusted or that the unemployment rate (U) is at its "natural" level, the adjustment for hours worked is h - h* ( U* - U) /100, which is obtained by substituting e /If= log(1 - U/100) - U 1100 into the equation used to decompose h and making a similar substitution for (e !If)* into an equation for h*. 1 9 Although the prime-age male unemployment rate is often used in estimated wage equations instead of the aggregate unemployment rate (see Cotis and Loufir (1990)), we simply use this vanable to capture the trend increase in the natural rate since the early 1970s. The natural rate of unemployment is estimated as a qduadratic trend on the male unemployment rate for 24-50 year olds plus the ifferential between the aggregate and the prime-age male unemployment rates in the early 1970s. The estimate of the natural rate at the end of the sample is in line with estimates typically found in models of the French economy, which are on the order of 7-8 percent. 20This may be a slight overestimate as the GDP figures for 1991 have recently been revised downward. = = ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 559 CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTH IN FRANCE Figure 4. Unemployment Ra1es (In percent of labor force) II 10 9 8 7 , ,-.I 6 " I I I Males aRed 25-50 years 5 I 4 3 2 1973 197 1 1 977 1975 1979 1 98 1 1983 1985 1987 1 989 1991 3 percent in 1988. Inflation rose to about 3Y2 percent in 1989-90 when actual output rose above both estimates of potential output. Since 1990:4, actual output has again fallen below both estimates of potential output, and inflation has fallen back to about 3 percent. This relationship be­ tween the level of the output gap and changes in inflation is statistically significant.21 21 Regressing the change in consumer price inflation (!12 p) against the output gap, assuming hours worked at the estimated natural rate (y - y*), gives !12p = 0.001 + 0.07(y - y*)-t - 0.45!12P-t - 0.29112P-2 - 0.26112P-3; (2.36) (2.49) (4.04) (2.45) R2 0.20, s.e.e. 0.006, DW 2.03, LM[x2(1)] 0.30, LM[x2(4)] 5.23. The regression has been estimated using OLS, and t-statistics are in parentheses. = = = = = Regressions with the output gap assuming actual hours worked gave similar results. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 560 DAVTD T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM Figure 5. Ourpuru (In logarithms, actual output = I 00 in 197 1 : I ) 170 r-------. 160 Polential (based on hours ll"orked ISO assumin[i •memploymenl a/ 1he na/ura/ rare) 140 Polential 130 (based on amwl hours 11·orked) 120 110 1 00 / " / / / 1971 " " " " 1973 " 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 19 89 199 1 aReal value added in the nonfarm business sector. Turning to the estimated sources of potential output growth summa­ rized in the top section of Table 5 and Figures 1-3, it is clear that capital and trade have been the engines of growth in France during the past two decades. The slowdown in growth from the mid-1970s to the mid-1980s is accounted for by the sharp reduction in hours worked and by the slowdown in physical capital formation-real gross fixed capital forma­ tion actually declined in six of the ten years from 1975 to 1984. Increases in R&D capital account for more than 15 percent of the total increase in potential output over the 1971-91 period. The contribution of R&D capital to the growth of potential output increased slightly in the late 1980s. The estimation results suggest that European trade integration has given a substantial boost to the growth of potential output in France. The ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 561 CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWfH IN FRANCE Table 5. Potential Output Growth" (Annual percentage changes) 1971-91 1971-75 1976-83 1984-91 Nonfarm business sector 2.4 5.2 3. 1 2.4 Potential outputb due to: 2.9 2.0 1.4 Physical capital 2.0 R&D capital 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.5 1.3 0.7 0.3 European trade integration 0.7 -0.7 -0. 1 0.5 Hours workedb 0.1 3.7 2.3 Actual output 2.8 2.6 Gross domestic product" 2.5 4.9 Potential output 2.3 3.0 2.5 2.7 2.5 Actual output 3.4 Memoranda items Unemployment rate (end year) 8.4 4.2 9.4 Actual 9.4 3.2 Natural 8.1 6.6 8.1 Nonfarm business output as a -0.1 0.3 0.1 share of GDP 0 .1 • Calculations are based on annual data. b Assuming unemployment is at the natural rate. "The growth of GDP is equal to the growth of output in the nonfarm busi­ ness sector minus the growth of nonfarm business output as a share of GDP. beneficial effects of European integration were most pronounced in the early 1970s when intra-EC trade was increasing much more rapidly than it has in the more recent period. As noted, Coe and Krueger (1990) report a similar result for the Federal Republic of Germany.22 It is interesting to note that Baldwin (1989) estimated that the 1992 single market pro­ gram would increase the EC's long-term growth rate by 0.2 to 0. 9 percent­ age points. This estimate, which is based on a completely different methodology from the one used here, is consistent with our estimate of the impact that European integration has had, and is likely to have in 1992-97, on growth in France. Declines in hours worked contributed to a slight reduction in potential output growth over the 1971-91 period. The drop in hours worked re­ flected sharp declines in hours per worker up to the early 1980s and, to 22The share of potential output growth over the past two decades attributable to closer European integration is estimated to have been less in Germany than in France, reflecting the somewhat less open French economy at the start of the 1970s. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 562 DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM a lesser extent, declines in the employment rate from the mid-1970s to the mid-1980s and in the participation rate in the 1980s (see the lower panel of Figure 3). Population increased by an annual average of about ¥4 percent during the full 1971-91 period. In 1984-91, hours per worker and the participation rate remained broadly stable and population growth more than offset the relatively small increase in the natural rate of unemployment, implying a small positive contribution of hours worked to the growth of potential output. To calculate potential output for 1992-97, it has been assumed that weekly hours remain broadly stable. The contribution of capital reflects the medium-term projection for fixed investment and an assumption that the depreciation rate remains unchanged from the 1990-91 average. The contribution of R&D capital is based on a regression relating real R&D expenditures to real output.23 Given the completion of the single market at the end of 1992, it is assumed that the contribution of intra-EC trade as a percent of EC output to potential output growth will remain the same as in the 1984-91 period but well below its contribution in 1971-83. These projections and assumptions imply an average annual growth of potential output of about 2.5 percent for 1992-97. The estimate of potential output growth is similar to Artus's (1992) estimate for 1992-93 and is almost the same as the 2.6 percent projected for 1989-95 in Adams, Fenton, and Larsen (1987). The IMF staff's medium-term projections for 1992-97 are based, in part, on the projection for potential output presented hereY Below­ potential growth in the 1991-93 period results in a substantial widening of the output gap. Growth is expected to recover during 1994 and to grow above potential in 1995-97, thereby reducing the gap. V. Concluding Remarks Recent cointegrating techniques that focus on the identification of long-run relationships are particularly appropriate to the study of long­ run growth. The application of these techniques to French data has yielded a number of interesting empirical results, two of which relate to the role of capital. The first is the relatively large estimated elasticity of 23 The estimated regression is log(R&D expenditures) l . l log(output) + 0.8, for annual data 1970-89. The stock of R&D capital was then calculated for 1992-97 by cumulating R&D expenditures with an assumed obsolescence rate of 5 percent. 24The medium-term projections are summarized in Annex II of the IMF (1993). constant , R2 = = ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTH IN FRANCE 563 output with respect to R&D capital. The second is that a broad concept of physical capital-<>ne that includes public infrastructure, residential and nonresidential structures, and plant and equipment capital-per­ forms better than the more common, narrower concept of business sector capital. A third important-and new-result is the empirical estimate of the beneficial effects of European trade integration on French growth. The estimated production function is not, strictly speaking, character­ ized by endogenous growth. The factors of production that can be accu­ mulated-physical capital (broadly defined) and R&D capital-exhibit decreasing returns to scale. As Sala-i-Martin (1990) emphasizes, this implies, in the absence of exogenous technological progress, a steady­ state growth of per capita output of zero. More generally, the underlying relationships are between the level of output and the levels of the factor inputs and the degree of trade integration. Although capital accumula­ tion and increased trade have boosted growth, a higher level of capital or trade integration will not, in the long run, have an impact on the growth of output. These results have a number of policy implications. European integra­ tion has boosted French growth in the past, and steps to accelerate the process of integration can be expected to enhance potential growth in the future. The large increases expected in the services trade with the com­ pletion of the single market, additional steps toward closer economic and monetary union, and closer integration with central and eastern Eu­ ropean countries may result in a substantially larger contribution to future potential output growth in France than assumed above. Similarly, government infrastructure investment and policies that encourage-or create an environment conducive to-productive investment and re­ search and development will also increase potential output. Finally, labor market policies that reduce the natural rate of unemployment over the medium term, thereby increasing labor input, will boost potential output growth. The empirical results suggest a number of areas for further study. In order to fully appreciate the implications for inflation, it is necessary to combine the estimates of potential output with a more satisfactory esti­ mate of the natural rate of unemployment in the context of a fully specified wage-price system. A second area for further study is the determinants of R&D expenditures and the extent to which R&D con­ tributes to endogenous growth. Finally, there is a need for further study of the impact on growth of other structural features of the French econ­ omy, such as the Common Agricultural Policy, and how structural reform would affect medium-term growth prospects in France. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 564 DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM APPENDIX Data Sources and Definitions Real value added, hours worked, and employment in the nonfarm business sector are from the INSEE data tape, in each case subtracting the farm sector (secteur agriculture, sylviculture, peche) from the total for the business sector (secteurs marchands). The relevant INSEE codes for real value· added are PNLV008 and PNLU018; for hours worked, ACM_VOOl and ACM_UOll; and for employment, EFM_V001 and EFM_UOll. The stock ofbusiness sector capital, the stock ofresidential capital, labor force, and population are from the OECD Analytical Data Bank. The stock of infra­ structure capital is taken from the annual estimates of Ford and Poret (1991), reported by them as INF.N (p. 80), interpolated to a quarterly frequency. The share of the labor force aged 15-24 is calculated from the OECD's Labour Force Statistics . The stock of R&D capital is calculated analogously to the stock of physical capital with an assumed obsolescence rate of 5 percent: k'&d = k:�d(1 - 0.05) + (real R&D expenditures). A benchmark for k'&dwas calculated using the proce­ dure suggested by Griliches (1980). Real R&D expenditures are gross domestic expenditures on R&D deflated by an average of the GDP deflator and an index of business sector wages. R&D expenditures are from the OECD's Main Science and Technology Indicators (1991:1, p. 16). R&D expenditures for 1991 were estimated using the same procedure reported in the text to project R&D expen­ ditures for 1992-97. Annual data for the stock of R&D capital were interpolated to a quarterly frequency. Data to construct the EC variable are from the IMF's Direction of Trade Statistics. The EC variable is constructed with data for all 12 current members of the EC, even though not all 12 countries were members during the full 1971-91 period. World trade as a percent of world output was constructed from the IMF World Economic Outlook data base. Annual data were interpolated to a quarterly frequency. · REFERENCES Adams, Charles, and David T. Coe, "A Systems Approach to Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment and Potential Output for the United States," StaffPapers , International Monetary Fund, Vol. 37 (June 1990), pp. 232-93. --, Paul R. Fenton, and Flemming Larsen, "Potential Output in Major Industrial Countries," StaffStudies for the World Economic Outlook, Inter­ national Monetary Fund (August 1987), pp. 1-26. Artus, Patrick, "QueUe est I'evolution de Ia production potentielle en France?" Caisse des Depots et Consignations, Document de Travail No. 1992-04/E. Baldwin, Richard, "The Growth Effects of 1992," Economic Policy , Vol. 4 (1989), pp. 247-81. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CAPITAL AND TRADE AS ENGINES OF GROWTH IN FRANCE 565 Banerjee, Arindya, and others, "Exploring Equilibrium Relationships in Econo­ metrics Through State Models: Some Monte Carlo Evidence," Oxford Bul­ letin of Economics and Statistics , Vol. 42 (1986), pp. 253-78. Boughton, James M., "Long-run Money Demand in Large Industrial Coun­ tries," Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 38 (March 1991 ), pp. 1-32. Coe, David T., and Elhanan Helpman, "International R&D Spillovers" (unpub­ lished; Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993). Coe, David T., and Thomas Krueger, "Why is Unemployment so High at Full Capacity? The Persistence of Unemployment, the Natural Rate, and Poten­ tial Output in the Federal Republic of Germany," IMF Working Paper 90/101 (Wasrungton: International Monetary Fund, 1990). Cotis, Jean-Phillippe, and Abderrahim Loufir, "Formation des salaires, ch6mage d'equilibre et incidence des cotisations sur le cout du travail," Economie & Prevision , No. 92-93 (1990), pp. 97-110. Citrin, Daniel, "The Natural Rate of Unemployment and Potential Output in Japan," IMF Working Paper (forthcoming; Wasrungton: International Mon­ etary Fund, 1993). Cuthbertson, Keith, Stephen G. Hall, and Mark P. Taylor, Applied Econometric Techniques (Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press, 1992). De Long, J. Bradford, and Lawrence H. Summers, "Equipment Investment and Economic Growth," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106 (1991), pp. 445-502. Dickey, David A., and Wayne A. Fuller, "Likelihood Ratio Statistics for Autore­ gressive Time Series with a Unit Root," Econometrica, Vol. 49 (1981), pp. 1057-72. Engle, Robert F., and Clive W.J. Granger, "Co-integration and Error Correc­ tion: Representation, Estimation, and Testing," Econometrica, Vol. 55 (1987), pp. 251-76. Ford, Robert, and Pierre Poret, "Infrastructure and Private-Sector Productiv­ ity," OECD Economic Studies, No. 17 (1991), pp. 63-90. Griliches, Zvi, "R&D and the Productivity Slowdown," American Economic Review, Vol. 70 (1980), pp. 343-48. , "Productivity Puzzles and R&D: Another Nonexplanation," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 2 (1988), pp. 9-21. Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman, Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1991). Helpman, Elhanan, "Endogenous Macroeconomic Growth Theory," European Economic Review, Vol. 36 (1992), pp. 237-67. Hendry, David F., and Grayham E. Mizon, "Evaluating Dynamic Econometric Models by Encompassing the VAR," University of Oxford Applied Eco­ nomics Discussion Paper No. 102 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990). INSEE, "La Productivite," Economie et Statistique, No. 237-238 (1990). International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook (Washington: Interna­ tional Monetary Fund, 1991, 1993). -- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 566 DAVID T. COE and REZA MOGHADAM Johansen, S0ren, "Statistical Analysis of Cointegrating Vectors," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 12 (1988), pp. 231-54. Johansen, S0ren, and Katarina Juselius, "Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration-With Applications to the Demand for Money," Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 52 (1990), pp. 169-210. Lucas, Robert E., Jr., "On the Mechanics of Economic Development," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 22 (1988), pp. 3-42. MacDonald, Ronald, and Mark P. Taylor, "The Monetary Approach to the Exchange Rate: Rational Expectations, Long-run Equilibrium and Forecast­ ing," Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 40 (March 1993), pp. 89-107. Mao, Zhirong, and Luis Rivera-Batiz, "Growth and Regional Convergence in Transitional Regimes: China" (unpublished; University of California, San Diego, 1993). Moghadam, Reza, and Simon Wren-Lewis, "Are Wages Forward Looking?" Centre for Labor Economics, LSE Discussion Paper No. 375 (London: London School of Economics and Political Science, 1990). MunneU, Alicia H., ed., Is There a Shortfall in Public Capital Investment? (Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1990). Pesaran, Hashem M., and Bahram Pesaran, "Microfit 3.0: An Interactive Econo­ metric Package" (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991). Phillips, Peter C.B., and Sam Ouliaris, "Asymptotic Properties of Residual Based Tests for Cointegration," Econometrica, Vol. 58 (1990), pp. 165-93. Rivera-Batiz, Luis, and Paul Romer, "Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106 (1991), pp. 531-54. Romer, Paul M., "Crazy Explanations for the Productivity Slowdown," NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1987), pp. 163-210. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, "Lecture Notes on Economic Growth (I): Introduction to the Literature and Neoclassical Models," NBER Working Paper No. 3563 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1990). Stock, James H., "Asymptotic Properties of Least Squares Estimations of Co­ integrating Vectors," Econometrica, Vol. 55 (1987), pp. 1035-56. Torres, Ramon, and John P. Martin, "Measuring Potential Output in the Seven Major OECD Countries," OECD Economic Studies, No. 14 (1990), pp. 127-50. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF Staff Papers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) C 1993 International Monetary Fund French-German Interest Rate Differentials and Time-Varying Realignment Risk FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA* This paper explores the determinants of realignment expectations for the French franc-deutsche mark exchange rate. Expected changes in the cen­ tral parity are estimated by adjusting short-term Euromarket interest rate differentials for the expected rate ofchange in the exchange rate within the ERM fluctuation band and by the yield differential on long-term gov­ ernment bonds. The results indicate that the exchange rate within the band is mean reverting and that expected changes are sizable. Realignment expectations are found to be related to the evolution offundamental eco­ nomic variables and, for shorter horizons, the position ofthe franc in the fluctuation band. (JEL E43, F31, F33] INCE of currencies in the exchange rate mechanism (ERM) of the European Monetary System (EMS) in January 1987, S the differential between French and German interest rates has narrowed THE REALIGNMENT considerably.1 Nevertheless, the continuing existence of a differential • Francesco Caramazza, a Senior Economist in the Monetary and Exchange Affairs Department, was a Senior Economist in the European I Department when this paper was written. He holds a doctorate from Johns Hopkins Univer­ sity. The author would like to thank Michael Deppler, John Green, and Harilaos Vittas for helpful comments and Susan Becker for research assistance. 1 Short-term interest rate differentials widened sharply in September 1992 and in the months following the ERM crisis. Recently, short-term differentials have narrowed significantly. 567 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 568 FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA suggests that market participants do not rule out a realignment of central parities in the EMS before exchange rates are irrevocably fixed in the final stage of economic and monetary union (EMU). Specifically, the positive interest rate differential in favor of Germany across the maturity spectrum implies a perceived risk of devaluation of the franc-mark exchange rate. Indeed, attempts to quantify the various factors that might explain the French-German interest rate differential find that they account for only part of the differential.2 The persistence of a positive interest rate differential suggests that an announced commitment to a fixed exchange rate may not be sufficient to eliminate devaluation risk completely. Economic performance and the authorities' policy approach also influence investors' expectations. Thus, exchange rate policy may not be fully credible if, for instance, problems of unemployment, a weak external position, or other perceived weak­ nesses cast doubt on the authorities' ability to maintain their com­ mitment. In the same vein, a policy of keeping the exchange rate close to the upper (weak) edge of the fluctuation band may also diminish credibility. This paper examines expectations of a realignment of the franc-mark central parity over the period February 1987 to November 1991. The aim is to estimate the expected rate of realignment and to attempt to identify the factors that might influence market participants' expectations of parity changes. A commonly used measure of the expected rate of realignment of a currency is the differential between the interest rates on assets denomi­ nated in the domestic currency and those denominated in a foreign currency. This measure is imprecise, however, especially for interest rates at the short end of the maturity spectrum, because interest rate differ­ entials are affected by expected exchange rate changes within the fluctu­ ation band of the exchange rate mechanism. In what follows, estimates of the time-varying expected rate of realignment are first constructed by adjusting interest rate differentials on 3-, 6-, and 12-month Eurofranc and Euromark deposits for the expected rate of change of the franc-mark exchange rate within the fluctuation band. The latter, in turn, is obtained by assuming that the exchange rate inside the band follows a mean­ reversion process. The calculated expected parity changes are then re­ gressed on a number of macroeconomic variables that agents are thought to consider in forming expectations of a currency's possible realignment. A similar analysis is also conducted with long-term government bond yields. Inflation differentials, competitiveness, unemployment rates, relative fiscal situations, and the position of the exchange rate within the 2 See, for instance, Artus (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FRENCH-GERMAN INTEREST RATES AND REALIGNMENT RISK 569 band are found to play an important role in the formation of exchange rate expectations. I. Interest Rate Differentials, Exchange Rate Bands, and Credibility Under current EMS arrangements, interest rates on financial assets that differ only in their currency of denomination can diverge because of the discounting of two types of exchange rate uncertainty: the day-to­ day fluctuations in exchange rates within the ERM bands and the possi­ bility of a realignment ofthe central rates. It is widely accepted that since the January 1987 realignment the EMS target zones have become much more credible. This bas allowed devaluation risk premia to decline and interest rate differentials to narrow considerably. For example, the differ­ ential on 12-month Eurofranc and Euromark interest rates (Figure 1) Figure I . Parity Deviations of Franc-Mark Exchange Rate and 12-Month Interest Rate Differential (In percem) 6.0 12-momh imerest rate dijJeremia/u 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 . . 0 -1.0 ·.. .· · . . . ·· Del'iation ojfranc-mark exchanKe ratefrom central rtaet> -2.0 -3.0 L_ _ _ _ _I L_ _ _ _ _i_ _ _ _ __l _ _ _ _ _.J. _ _ _ _ __l.. __..j 1987 198! 1989 1990 1991 aEurofranc rate minus Euromark rate. bPercent deviation. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 1992 570 FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA declined from a mean differential of 4. 7 percentage points in 1987 to 0.25 percentage points in 1991. A simple way to test the credibility of the EMS target zones is tc suppose that investors at time t expect with certainty that there will b€ no realignment (or change in the width of the exchange rate band) up tc time t + m, the time of maturity of a given asset. Then, at time t + rr the spot exchange rate is expected with certainty to be bounded by SL s u u F�' S, (1 where S is the domestic currency price of foreign exchange (franc /mark and and are the lower and upper marginsofthe exchange rate band Hence, the net profit from a forward sale of one unit of foreign currenc: is bounded by - ::; F�' - S,+m ::; F�' - (2) S�, where F;n is the forward exchange rate at time t for maturity m (measured in years). Further assuming that arbitrage eliminates certain positive minimum profits, it follows that if the forward exchange rate lies outside the exchange rate bands, then the target zone is not credible. If the forward exchange rate lies within the exchange rate band, then the test is inconclusive. 3 Alternatively, invoking covered interest parity, the domestic interest rate under full credibility is bounded by [ {1 + ii'm)(SSL)Jtm 1] i, [(1 i;'m)(SS u)um 1] , (3) , , where i;n and i,*m are the domestic currency (franc) and foreign currency (mark) interest rates on assets of the same default risk and maturity m , - :5 :5 + - expressed as annualized rates of return. If at any time t the domestic interest rate is outside these "credibility bounds," then agents expect with positive probability · that over the time to maturity, t + m , the exchange rate band will shift by way of either a realignment or an increase in the band's width. Eurofranc interest rates for 3-, 6-, and 12-month maturities and their corresponding "credibility bounds" are shown in Figure 2. The three­ month interest rate was almost always within its credibility bounds; hence, the exchange rate band may or may not have been credible. The one-year interest rate, however, was consistently above the upper bound from January 1987 to March 1990, and thereafter consistently inside the 3 This test of target zone credibility was first applied by Svensson (1990) to the Swedish krona and has since been applied to a number of currencies by Giovannini (1990), Koen (1991), and Geadah, Saavalainen, and Svensson (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FRENCH-GERMAN 1NTEREST RATES AND REALIGNMENT RJSK 571 Figure 2. Eurofranc /merest Rates and "Credibility Bounds" (In percent) 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0 -5.0 - 1 0.0 -15.0 1987 1988 1989 1 990 199 1 1992 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1989 1990 1991 1992 15.0 10.0 5.0 0 -5.0 12.0 12-month imerest rate 10.0 8.0 .· • • • . . .. . . I 0 . . . · ·.. 6.0 4.0 2.0 0 1987 1988 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 572 FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA bounds. Thus, it may be inferred that until March 1990 agents expected with positive probability a devaluation of the franc-mark exchange rate. In the case of one-year interest rates, the test is less inconclusive as the credibility bounds are significantly narrower than those for three-month interest rates. The next section outlines a more precise empirical method (from Bertola and Svensson (1991)) for extracting the implicit expected rate of realignment from exchange rates and interest rate differentials.4 II. A Model of the Expected Rate of Realignment Let s, sL , and su denote the natural logarithms of S , S L, and S u (the franc-mark spot exchange rate and its lower and upper intervention rates, respectively). By definition, the exchange rate can be decomposed as s, = c, + s,, (4) where c, = (s� + ) 12 is the log of the central parity of the franc-mark exchange rate and s, is the deviation of the franc from the central parity. Taking first differences of equation (4), the total expected rate of change of the franc from time t to t + m, conditional on information available at time t, is equal to the expected rate of realignment (that is, the change in the central parity) plus the expected rate of change of the franc within the band: u s, E,tls,+mlm = E,�Cr+mlm + E,M,+mlm. (5) Assuming uncovered interest parity (UIP) (6) it follows that - (l,'" A"'r+m Im . EI A ' - l,'*nl) - E, L.1.) L.lCc+ m Im - (7) UIP is an appropriate assumption if the foreign exchange risk premium is small. Theoretical support is provided by Svensson (1990), who argues that the risk premium is likely to be small in exchange rate target zones, even in the presence of devaluation risk. Empirical support of UIP for the franc-mark rate is provided by Rose and Svensson (1991), Andersen and Sorensen (1991), and, indirectly, Frankel and Phillips (1991). From equation (1) and the definition of s,, it can be shown that the rate of change of the exchange rate within the band is bounded by (8) 4 For an app lication to the Swedish krona, see Lindberg, Svensson, and Soderlind (1991). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FRENCH-GERMAN INTEREST RATES AND REALIGNMENT RISK 573 which combined with equation (7) gives the following maximal bounds for the expected rate of realignment: (i;" - ii"') - (s,u - s,)lm :S :s E, t:..c,+mlm (i;" - i,*"') - (s,L - s,)!m. (9) These bounds are shown as the solid lines in Figures 3 and 4. As can be seen, the bounds for the expected parity changes are wider the shorter the maturity. This reflects the fact that the maximal bounds for the expected rate of change of the exchange rate within the band are wider for shorter maturities. III. Estimation of Expected Exchange Rate Changes Within the Band To calculate the expected rate of realignment from equation (7), it is necessary to filter out expectations of exchange rate changes within the fluctuation band. As noted earlier, the simplest procedure is to assume that the expected change in the exchange rate within the band is zero­ that is, E, t:..s,+m lm 0-in which case the expected change in the central parity is simply equal to the interest rate differential. This case can be ruled out a priori, however, since the exchange rate within the band cannot follow a random walk. Indeed, an augmented Dickey-Fuller test rejects the hypothesis that s has a unit root.5 An alternative procedure, following Bertola and Svensson (1991), Svensson (1990, 1991), and Rose and Svensson (1991), assumes initially that the future exchange rate within the band may be well approximated by the current exchange rate.6 The change in the exchange rate within the band, conditional upon no realignment, may thus be estimated from = (10) Estimates of the above equation are presented in Table 1 and plotted in Figure 3. Two points about the estimation of equation (10) should be noted. One, a consequence of the target zone model is that the conditional distribution of the exchange rate within the band is heteroskedastic. Two, the projection horizons employed (m 3, 6, and 12 months) are longer than the sampling interval of the data (monthly). The use of overlapping = 5 The regression of f:..s, on $,_ " three lags of f:..s , and a constant yiel ds a DF statistic of -2.312 with a corresponding p-value of 0.46, so that the null of cointegration is accepted. 6Supporting evidence is also reported by Chen and Giovannini (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA 574 Figure 3. Expected Rate ofChange of Franc-Mark Exchange Rate Within the Intervention Band (In percent) 15.0 10.0 5.0 0 -5.0 - 1 0.0 -15.0 -20.0 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1987 1988 1 989 1990 1991 1992 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 0 -2.0 -4.0 -6.0 -8.0 - 10.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0 -1.0 -2.0 -3.0 -4.0 -5.0 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FRENCH-GERMAN INTEREST RATES AND REALIGNMENT RISK 575 observations implies that the error terms will follow a moving-average process of order m - 1. Ordinary least squares will give consistent esti­ mates of the coefficients, but their standard errors will be inappropriate. Consequently, generalized method of moment (GMM) estimates have been used for the standard errors, which are robust to heteroskedasticity and serial correlation as in Newey and West (1987). The results indicate that the exchange rate within the band is mean reverting: within the band, the expected exchange rate is closer to the long-run mean of the exchange rate at longer time horizons. The esti­ mated slopes are negative for all maturities, as implied by mean rever­ sion, and are large relative to their standard errors. Moreover, the longer is the maturity, the larger is the estimated slope in absolute value. The estimates also show that the expected change of the franc-mark exchange rate within the band has narrowed over the January 1987 to March 1992 period and has gradually turned from an expected depreciation to an expected appreciation by the end of the period (Figure 3). An attempt was made to refine the estimates in Table 1 by the inclusion of additional explanatory variables in equation (9). First, s2 and s3 were included so as to capture possible nonlinearities in the relationship. They were found to be insignificant. Second, the mark-dollar interest rate differential for the corresponding maturity was included on the assump­ tion that its movements may affect the franc-mark exchange rate (Artus and others (1991 )). This, too, proved insignificant. The estimates in Table 1. Estimated Expected Change in the Franc-Mark Exchange Rate Within the Intervention Band, January 1987-December 1991 (s,..m - s, = 13o + 13a s, + E,) Maturity (m) Coefficient 13o 13t 3 months 6 months 12 months 0.454 (2.553) -0.443 ( -3.073) 0.768 (3.756) -0.732 (-3.792) 1.033 (7.628) -0.943 (-15.541) Summary statistics 0.633 Standard error 0.577 0.550 0.269 0.444 R-squared 0.652 43.93 91.64 £-statistic (13t 0) 21.34 57 Number of observations 51 60 Note: T-statistics are in parentheses. The franc-mark rate within the band (s) is measured in log deviations from the franc-mark central parity. The standard errors of the coefficients are GMM estimates allowing for heteroskedastic and serially correlated error terms using the method of Newey and West (1987). = ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 576 FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA Figure 4. Bounds for Expected Rare ofRealignme111 ofFranc-Mark Exchange Rare (In percent) 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0 -5.0 -10.0 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1987 1988 1989 1 990 1 991 1992 987 1988 1 989 1990 199 1 1992 14.0 12.0 10.0 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 0 -2.0 -4.0 10.0 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 0 -2.0 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FRENCH-GERMAN INTEREST RATES AND REALIGNMENT RISK 577 Table 1 are thus used to calculate the expected rate of realignment of the franc-mark exchange rate. It is shown in Figure 4 for different maturities. IV. Explaining the Expected Rate of Realignment This section examines whether the calculated expected rate of re­ alignment can be explained by generally observed macroeconomic vari­ ables. 7 It is assumed that in forming expectations of a currency's possible realignment, agents consider a number of factors, at home and abroad, that may cause a change in the central parity. These include inflation differentials, changes in foreign exchange reserves, fiscal developments, unemployment rates, relative money supply growth, and other macro­ economic variables. They may also include other factors that influence market sentiment, such as the authorities' perceived policy behavior or commitment. The results of regressing the calculated expected rates of realignment on a selected set of macroeconomic variables that are believed to enter agents' information sets are shown in Table 2. 8 For all three maturities the results are quite similar. More than 70 percent of the variation in the expected rate of devaluation is explained by the change in foreign ex­ change reserves, the government financing requirement (as a ratio to GDP) of France relative to Germany, the inflation differential, France's export price competitiveness relative to Germany's, the unemployment rate, and the position of the franc-mark rate within the fluctuation band. 7The two-ste p estimation procedure used in this paper, namely first estimating the expected ch ange in the exchange rate within the intervention band and, subsequently, estimating the determinants of the expected rate of realignment (constructed by adjusting interest rate differentials for the estimates from the first step), is not the only possible estimation strategy. For instance, one could esti­ mate simultaneously the expected change in the exchange rate within the band and the determinants of the expected rate of realignment by estimating (i;n - i: m) - (.ft+m - Sr) /m on the rational expectations assumption that E,(s,+m - f,), conditional on no realignment, is equal to (f,...m - f,). In this case, the disturbance of the estimated equation would include the expectations error f,+m - E,(f,+m)· The point to note is that, whether in two steps or simultaneously, estimation of the expected rate of realignment requires an estimate of the expected change in the exchange rate within the band. Tests of hypotheses of the determinants of expected changes in the central parity are thus jomt tests of the expected changes in the exchange rate within the band. It should also be noted that the estimated standard errors are conditional on the estimated series of realignment risk. 8 Since numerous variables can be considered, the results reported in this section should be regarded as an examination of some plausible determinants of market expectations. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 578 FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA Table 2. Determinants of the Expected Rate of Realignment Based on Filtered Euromarket Interest Rate Differentials, February 1987-November 1991" Maturity (m) Variableb Change in foreign exchange reserves Government financing requirement< Inflation differentiala Export price competitivenesse Unemployment rate 3 months -0.118 ( - 1.42) 0.939 (2.86) 0.744 (5.36) -0.245 (-5.10) 1.284 (4.31) 1.502 (6.63) 6 months -0.097 ( -1.29) 0.853 (2.38) 0.794 (7.70) -0.249 ( -5.58) 1.376 (5.34) 1.256 (6.41) 12 months -0.088 ( -1.23) 0.733 (2.18) 0.842 (10.21) -0.243 (-7.79) 1.400 (6.75) 0.800 (4.61) Deviation of franc-mark rate from upper edge of band Summary statistics Standard error 0.91 0.71 0.83 0.73 0.76 R-squared 0.81 F-statistic (6, 51) 22.75 26.32 36.41 Number of observations 58 58 58 Note: T-statistics are in parentheses. The expected rate of realignment is defined as the French-German Euro­ market interest rate differential minus the estimated expected rate of deprecia­ tion within the band. The standard errors of the coefficients are GMM estimates allowing for heteroskedastic and serially correlated error terms using the method of Newey and West (1987). bAll variables enter the estimated equations with a one-period lag, except the governmentborrowing requirement variable, which enters with a two-period lag. The regression equations also include a constant term, which is not reported. 0Tbe percent ratio of the government borrowing requirement to GDP in France relative to Germany. d Differential in the annual rates of change of consumer prices. Annual rate of chan�e of real exchange rate in terms of export prices. An increase represents an unprovement in France's competitiveness relative to Germany's. • e Relative money supply growth rates and the trade balance were also included, but they were found to have no additional explanatory power. The government financing requirement and inflation variables are found to be positively related, and the competitiveness variable nega­ tively related, to the expected rate of realignment. Thus, decreases in France's government financing requirement and in its inflation rate relative to Germany's lower the expected rate of devaluation of the franc, as does an improvement in France's export price competitiveness relative to Germany's. Moreover, the null hypothesis that the coefficient on the ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FRENCH-GERMAN INTEREST RATES AND REALIGNMENT RISK 579 inflation differential is equal to one cannot be rejected at the 5 percent significance level. The change in foreign exchange reserves enters the equations for the expected rate of realignment with the expected negative sign: an increase in reserves decreases the expected rate of devaluation. Its statistical significance, however, depends on the specification of the equation. In particular, when the unemployment rate is also included its statistical significance declines considerably. The unemployment rate itself, however, is highly significant.9 This raises an interesting point. In a recent paper, Drazen and Masson (1992) extend the notion of policy credibility to encompass not only the role of government policies in signaling the "type" of government (how "tough" it is, to use their terminology) but also the situation in which a government finds itself­ since in very adverse circumstances even a policymaker with a reputation for being "tough" may renege on a commitment. Applied to the EMS, this suggests that the increased credibility of the EMS reflects the dom­ inance of the signaling motive for setting policies as governments main­ tain their commitment not to realign. However, under the Drazen­ Masson notion of credibility, expectations of realignment also reflect pressures to increase employment and growth after a period of restrictive policies. The expected rate of devaluation will, therefore, be positively correlated with the rate of unemployment. The position of the exchange rate within the fluctuation band­ expressed as the deviation of the franc-mark rate from the upper (weak) edge of the band-may be interpreted as capturing intangible market sentiment about the credibility of the target zone. Its statistical signifi­ cance suggests that when the franc trades close to the upper intervention margin, market expectations of a realignment intensify and a devaluation risk premium is built into franc interest rates. As an alternative way of capturing market sentiment, the deviation of the franc-mark rate from the upper band was replaced "in the regression equations by a dummy variable that takes increasing values as the exchange rate approaches the upper intervention margin.10 The results were not qualitatively differ9The unemployment rate is more appropriately measured with respect to its natural rate. But assuming that over the sample period the natural rate is con­ stant, it makes no difference-except for the constant term-whether the actual unemployment rate or its deviation from the natural rate is used. In the regression using the 12-month Euromarket rates, for example, the estimated constant term is - 0.95 when the natural rate is assumed to be 8.5 percent and -0.25 (and not significantly different from zero) when the natural rate is assumed to be 9 percent. In view of the uncertainty about the perceived value of the natural rate, and since it makes no difference for the other coefficients, the constant term is not reported. 10 Specifically, the dummy variable takes values of one when the franc-mark rate is in the top half of the intervention band, two when it is in the top quarter, and three when it is in the top eighth. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 580 FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA ent.11 The statistical significance of these variables suggests that the recent policy of allowing the franc to strengthen in the ERM may pay off by way of reducing the devaluation risk premia on French short-term interest rates. One interpretation of these results is that agents may consider it more difficult to defend a currency that is close to the weak edge of the band by sales of reserves (since reserves are limited) than it is to sterilize capital inflows when a currency is at the strong edge of the intervention margin. In the event of a shock, therefore, a country whose currency is in the weak part of the band may have to raise interest rates in order to maintain its currency within the band. If this is seen as introducing a conflict between the domestic and the exchange rate objec­ tives of monetary policy, the credibility of the central parity may suffer. The analysis thus far has been conducted using short-term Euromarket deposit rates. Euromarket rates have the advantage over domestic money market rates of not being affected by the existence of capital controls. Since capital controls were being phased out over the sample period, it seemed preferable to use Euromarket rates. 12 Euromarket rates are not available for long maturities, however, and the latter have an advantage in that the expected rate of mean reversion of the exchange rate within the band becomes very small at long horizons.13 Since E, t:J.S is bounded, the term E, t:J.S,+mlm in equation (7) becomes progressively smaller as the forecast horizon lengthens, so that the expected rate of devaluation is well approximated by the interest differential. Table 3 reports the results of regressing the differential in the yield on long-term government bonds on the same set of macroeconomic variables used in the equation for the expected rate of realignment derived from Euromarket rates. The results are broadly similar. The inflation rate, competitiveness, and the unemployment rate are again the major factors influencing devaluation expectations. 14 The relative government financ­ ing requirement, however, is not as significant as in ·the regression equa11 The estimated coefficients on the dummy variable (with t-statistics in paren­ theses) i.n equations using the 3-, 6-, and 12-month interest rates, respectively, are 1.205 (6.89), 1.00 (6.41), and 0.66 (5.33). 12 Regulations other than capital controls, political and default risk, informa­ tion and transaction costs, and other factors may also introduce a wedge between domestic market and Euromarket rates. Changes in domestic market rates may, therefore, be due to actual or anticipated changes io these characteristics rather than in exchange risk. Empirically, however, capital controls have been found to constitute the major explainable component of spreads between Euromarket and domestic market rates. 13 The results in the preceding section indicate that the expected rate of mean reversion decreases as the horizon lengthens. 14 In contrast to the results in Table 2, however, the null hypothesis that the coefficient on the inflation differential is equal to one is rejected in the second of the equations reported in Table 3. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 581 FRENCH-GERMAN INTEREST RATES AND REALIGNMENT RISK Table 3. Determinants of the Expected Rate of Realignment Based on Long­ Term Interest Rate Differential, February 1987-November 1991 Regression Variable Change in foreign exchange reserves Government financing requirement Inflation differential Export price competitiveness Unemployment rate (1) -0.123 (-2.21) 0.562 (1. 73) 0.967 (8.17) -0.150 ( -2.90) (2) -0.055 ( -1.37) 0.179 (1.25) 0.538 (9.55) -0.169 (-8.44) 1.065 (8.52) Deviation of franc-mark 0.086 (0.61) rate from upper edge of band Summary statistics Standard error 0.52 0.34 0.92 0.80 R squared 41.49 F-statistic (5, 52) 116.41 Number of observations 58 58 Note: T-statistics are in parentheses. Interest rates are yields on 7-10 year government bonds. The method of estimation is OLS; robust standard errors are estimated using a spectral density kernel. The coefficient for the constant term is omitted. Variables are define d as in Table 2. - tions based on short-term rates, and the market sentiment variables are insignificant. This last result is not surprising, as the current position of the franc in the intervention band should be of little relevance in forming expectations of exchange rates several years hence: views of the long­ term viability of the central rate are shaped by the unfolding of more fundamental economic factors. V. Conclusions The differentials between French and German interest rates have narrowed considerably since the EMS realignment in January 1987 as the franc-mark exchange rate band has become increasingly credible. Expec­ tations of realignments of the centraJ parity have been found to be influenced by the evolution of fundamental economic factors such as inflation differentials, competitiveness, unemployment, government fi­ nancing requirements, and foreign reserves. France's favorable economic performance, especially with regard to inflation, the external position, ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 582 FRANCESCO CARAMAZZA and its fiscal situation, has allowed the implicit expected rate of de­ valuation to decrease considerably. The results further suggest that the devaluation risk premium on franc interest rates could be reduced further and differentials with respect to Germany additionally narrowed by an improved labor market performance and, in the case of short-term rates, by a strengthened position of the franc in the ERM band. APPENDIX Data Sources Consumer prices: IMF, International Financial Statistics, line 64. Exchange rates: IMF, average of daily observations. Export prices: IMF, International Financial Statistics, line 74. Foreign exchange reserves: IMF, International Financial Statistics , line 1l.d (total reserves minus gold). Gross domestic products: IMF, International Financial Statistics, line 99b.c for France, line 99a.c for Germany (monthly values obtained by interpolating from industrial production index). Government financing requirements: IMF, International Financial Statistics , line 84. Industrial production indices: IMF, International Financial Statistics, line 66c. Interest rates (Euromarket rates): IMF; 7-10 year government bond yields: Banque de France (average of daily observations). Unemployment rates: OECD, Analytical Data Base. REFERENCES Andersen, Torben M., and Jan Rose Sorensen, "Exchange Rate Risks, Interest Rates and European Monetary Integration," Memo 1991-18 (Aarhus: Cen­ tre for International Economics, University of Aarhus, 1991). Artus, Patrick, "Peut-on comprendre l'ecart de taux d'interet entre Ia France et l 'Allemagne?" Document de Travail No. 1992-01 /E (Paris: Caisse de Depots et Consignations, 1992). Artus, Patrick, and others, "Transmission of U.S. Monetary Policy to Europe and Asymmetry in the European Monetary System," European Economic Re­ view, Vol. 35 (1991), pp. 1369-84. Bertola, Giuseppe, and Lars E.O. Svensson, "Stochastic Devaluation Risk and the Empirical Fit of Target-Zone Models," NBER Working Paper No. 3576 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1991). Chen, Zhaohui, and Alberto Giovannini, "Estimating Expected Exchange Rates Under Target Zones," NBER Working Paper No. 3955 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution FRENCH-GERMAN INTEREST RATES AND REALIGNMENT RlSK 583 Drazen, Allan, and Paul R. Masson, "Credibility of Policies Versus Credibility of Policymakers" (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992). Frankel, Jeffrey, and Steven Phillips, "The European Monetary System: Credible at Last?" NBER Working Paper No. 3819 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1991). Geadah, Sarni, Tapio Saavalainen, and Lars E.O. Svensson, "The Credibility of Nordic Exchange Rate Bands: 1987-91," IMF Working Paper 92/3 (Wash­ ington: International Monetary Fund, 1992). Giovannini, Alberto, "European Monetary Reform: Progress and Prospects," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (1990), pp. 217-91. Koen, Vincent, "Testing the Credibility of the Belgian Hard Currency Policy," IMF Working Paper 91 /79 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991). Lindberg, Hans, Lars E.O. Svensson, and Paul Soderlind, "Devaluation Expec­ tations: The Swedish Krona 1982-1991," Seminar Paper No. 495 (Stock­ holm: Institute for International Economic Studies, 1991). Newey, Whitney K . , and Kenneth D. West, "A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix," Econometrica, Vol. 55 (1987), pp. 703-8. Rose, Andrew K., and Lars E.O. Svensson, "Expected and Predicted Realign­ ments: The FF /DM Exchange Rate During the EMS," International Fi­ nance Discussion Paper No. 395 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1991). Svensson, Lars E.O., "The Foreign Exchange Risk Premium in a Target Zone with Devaluation Risk," Discussion Paper No. 494 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1990). Svensson, Lars E.O., "Assessing Target Zone Credibility: Mean Reversion and Devaluation Expectations in the EMS," IMF Working Paper 91/96 (Wash­ ington: International Monetary Fund, 1991). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF Stoff Papers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) Cl 1993 International Monetary Fund Stabilization Programs and External Enforcement Experience from the 1920s JULIO A. SANTAELLA* Credibility and financing problems are important reasons why countries may seek to involve external institutions in the design and implementation ofstabilization programs. In particular, governments may rely on external institutions to "enforce" programs that would otherwise lack credibility. This paper analyzes six European currency stabilizations sponsored by the League of Nations in the 1920s. It emphasizes the means by which the League provided a "commitment technology" and enforced compliance, thereby helping to ensure successful stabilizations. Empirical evidence indicates that countries with greater credibility problems relied more heavily on external enforcement to stabilize their currencies. [JEL E61, F33, N14] of the international debt crisis in the early 1980s, Smany developing countries have been striving to stabilize and adjust their economies. More recently, Eastern European countries and states INCE THE ADVENT of the former Soviet Union have been facing an equally challenging task: to achieve domestic and external stability while simultaneously trans­ forming their economies from central planning to market-oriented sys­ tems. Some countries have undertaken adjustment and reform on their * Julio A. Santaella is an Economist in the Research Department. He holds a Ph.D. from the University of California, Los Angeles. This p aper draws on two chapters of the author's Ph.D. dissertation. Comments by Se b astian Edwards, Jeffrey Frieden, Arnold Harberger, Daniel Heymann, Malcolm Knight, Axel Leijonhufvud, Kenneth Sokoloff, and Jean-Leaurant Rosenthal are gratefully acknowledged. 584 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 585 own, but many others have embraced stabilization and structural pro­ grams endorsed by the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and other institutions. As a result, there has been a very substantial increase in the number of countries implementing stabilization and re­ form programs under IMF arrangements during the past decade, as well as in the level of financial resources committed by international organi­ zations and bilateral donors. The widespread recourse to these programs by developing countries is unlikely to abate in the near future. Although considerable progress has been achieved in resolving the debt crisis of the middle-income countries, many low-income developing countries, as well as formerly socialist economies, are now initiating adjustment and seek­ ing financial assistance. It is, therefore, a propitious time to examine the role that external institutions can play in assisting an adjusting country and to ascertain the general factors that can influence the success or failure of such programs. For the adjusting nations and for the international institutions that have been involved in the process, there are many interesting lessons to be drawn from past experience. One episode that is particularly rich in insights for today's adjustment efforts is the currency stabilizations that were implemented by a number of European countries during the 1920s. Most of the features of these post-World War I European stabilizations have already been extensively discussed in the literature. 1 Yet a central aspect of these episodes, which has received much less discussion, is the extent of foreign assistance and external enforcement that were involved in these early but comprehensive macroeconomic adjustment programs. During the 1920s, six European countries undertook macroeconomic adjustment programs under the auspices of the League of Nations: Aus­ tria, Hungary, Greece, Bulgaria, Estonia, and Danzig.2 Why did these countries resort to the League for external enforcement of their currency stabilization programs, while others, in fact the majority of the European countries, stabilized their currencies without recourse to external loans or the discipline of the League? This paper addresses some issues that are raised by this question and their relevance for current adjustment pro­ grams. The paper's central purpose, then, is to examine the role that an external institution can play in adjustment-in particular, the effective­ ness of the League of Nations in enforcing and making credible the stabilization programs it endorsed during the 1920s. 1 A recent study of the economic history of the 1920s can be found in Eichen­ green (1992). 2There has been a recent interest in the dissolution of the Austro Hungarian empire and the similarities with the former Soviet Union. See Garber and Spencer (1992) and Dornbusch (1992). - ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 586 JULIO A. SANTAELLA To tackle these issues, the paper first reviews the theoretical justifica­ tion for an external agent's intervention in a macroeconomic adjustment program. The paper discusses a number of arguments that go beyond the standard explanation, which has focused almost exclusively on the tech­ nical advice and financial support that external institutions can provide. The paper finds that credibility and financing problems play an important role in explaining reliance on external institutions. A major reason why countries may seek external intervention is that they lack the credibility or "reputation" needed to ensure the success of their stabilization efforts. An external agent may be able to provide a "commitment technology" that enhances the credibility of the program. The credibility problem and the role of external enforcement are illustrated with a simple model. In particular, the paper argues that the extent of nominal instability is likely to be an important determinant of external participation in a stabilization program. Once the theoretical framework has been outlined, the paper analyzes the experience with stabilization programs endorsed by the League of Nations during the 1920s. The comprehensiveness of the economic re­ forms is emphasized. A brief analysis of the general macroeconomic accomplishments of the programs is also presented. Furthermore, be­ cause the credibility of the commitment to stabilize the economy appears to have been a crucial element in a program's success, this paper places special emphasis on the instruments of control that the League of Nations employed to enforce its programs. A program that is not expected to be enforced will not be credible; in turn, a noncredible stabilization program is less Likely to be successful. An empirical assessment of the enforcement by the League is undertaken based on the outcomes of several programs. By contrasting the European currency stabilizations that had recourse to external enforcement with those that did not, the paper attempts to test the theoretical explanations that have been offered for the reliance of some adjusting countries on external institutions. The paper presents empirical evidence to support the view that enhancing credibility and resolving financing problems were important determinants of a nation's decision to rely on an external agent to carry out its stabilization. Policy implications can be drawn from this experience for both coun­ tries and external agents. The importance of fiscal adjustment and mone­ tary discipline are confirmed by these episodes. In addition, the experi­ ence of the 1920s highlights the necessity of undertaking fundamental institutional reform to establish macroeconomic stability. The analysis suggests that the League of Nations enforced such regime changes with remarkable success. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 587 I. Theoretical Arguments for External Enforcement This section analyzes the reasons why external institutions may become involved in a country's macroeconomic stabilization and the specific role they can play in its implementation and enforcement. These issues have not been dealt with in detail by the theoretical and empirical literature on macroeconomic stabilization. For the most part, this literature has been concerned with the instability of nominal variables, as well as the proper way to carry out the stabilization and adjustment.3 Beyond the traditional explanation, which stresses the technical advice that external institutions can give, two conceptually distinct but not mutually exclusive arguments have been advanced to explain a country's recourse to external assistance: (1) an external agent can help solve a national authority's credibility problems, and (2) an external institution can ease a country's external position through financing. Credibility, External Enforcement, and Financing Beginning with the seminal papers by Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Calvo (1978), the theoretical literature on stabilization policies has em­ phasized the time inconsistency problem-that is, the conflict between the ex ante and ex post optimality of economic policies in rational expectations models. In the case of monetary policy, this problem occurs because the government has an ex post incentive to renege on an an­ nounced policy that was optimal ex ante.4 The time inconsistency prob­ lem undermines the credibility of any announcements that are made about future policy because rational private economic agents anticipate that the authorities may later have an incentive to deviate from the announced course of policies. Time inconsistency can impart an infla­ tionary bias to monetary policy, thus making stabilization of the aggre­ gate price level more difficult. However, the time inconsistency problem will only emerge if the authorities have the opportunity to reoptimize later, after announcing their policy stance-that is, only if they operate under a discretionary regime. On the contrary, if the government finds itself with a binding commitment that prevents the reoptimization in the future, then the rational expectations policy that was optimal originally will remain optimal in subsequent periods. Thus, under a commitment �Dornbusch, Sturzenegger, and Wolf (1990) describe these issues. In this section, the terms stabilization and adjustment are used interchangeably. 4 See Barro and Gordon (1983a). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 588 JULIO A. SANTAELLA regime there are no surprises and the inflationary bias of monetary policy can be avoided.5 This kind of regime can be established, in principle, by imposing various institutional checks on the government's conduct of monetary policy. The literature on repeated games provides some solutions to the time inconsistency problem.6 In this framework it is possible for a government to build a reputation as a low-inflation policymaker. Unfortunately, the reputation-building process found in the game-theoretic literature is not generally available to the authorities of a country that is suffering from a macroeconomic disequilibrium involving nominal instability. The exis­ tence of strong inflationary pressures reflects the government's lack of reputation as a tough inflation fighter. Under these circumstances, a gov­ ernment that wants to stabilize the economy in the context of a monetary regime characterized by discretion may have to change regimes, specifi­ cally shift to a commitment regime that embodies consistent low-inflation policies. A change of regime requires a fundamental redirection of the policy strategy or the rules that determine the whole sequence of mone­ tary and fiscal policies, and not simply an isolated shift in policy measures (Sargent (1986)). In order to change a monetary regime, it is necessary to modify not only the nature of monetary policy itself but also the expec­ tations held by economic agents about that policy.7 In order for this al­ ternative solution to be successful, it is necessary that both the announce­ ment of and the commitment to a regime change are credible to economic agents. Only then will they adjust their inflationary expectations to conform with the new monetary rules. A stabilization program is said to "lack credibility" if it is not perceived as a definite and permanent change in the way economic policy is deter­ mined. If the credibility of a stabilization program is in doubt, the attempt to stabilize can entaiJ heavy costs in terms of higher unemployment, lower levels of economic activity, capital flight, and higher interest rates. In these circumstances, the government may have to support the announce­ ment of a regime change with some signaling behavior. This action is needed in order to influence expectations favorably by convincing eco­ nomic agents that the "rules of the game" have indeed been modified. If economic agents believe in the attempt, stabilization can be achieved 5 On the outcomes under different regimes, see Sarro and Gordon (1983b) and Fischer (1980). 6See Barro (1986) and Backus and Driffill (1985). Blackburn and Christensen (1989) survey the literature. See also Persson and Tabellini (1990) for a compre­ hensive review of the literature on time inconsistency and modern political economy. 7 See Leijonhufvud (1983, 1984) for a definition and discussion of a monetary regime. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 589 at a lower cost. It is precisely at this point that the presence of an external agent in the stabilization effort is justified: one way for the monetary authority to "signal" that it is really altering the policy regime is by committing to a stabilization program that is endorsed by some external or international agency, especially some agency that bas an established reputation as a firm enforcer of stabilization. Sachs (1989) and Edwards (1989) suggest that the role played by the external agent is to provide the government with a commitment technology and, hence, to improve the chances of resolving its credibility problems. 8 Of course, it is not necessary for the commitment technology to be supplied by an external agent. For example, domestic institutions could be altered by setting up institutional checks that establish a commitment regime giving the monetary authority the credibility it requires. In many countries, however, the combination of economic, social, and political disorder, as well as institutional weaknesses, is such that credibility problems plague not only the economic authorities themselves but also the economic policymaking institutions. The widespread existence of credibility problems confronting national governments suggests that achieving the needed commitment technology solely from domestic sources will often be difficult or infeasible. In such cases, reliance on an external institution may be a viable option for restoring credibility. In most analyses, the commitment technology is simply assumed to be exogenous. It is possible, however, to forn1Ulate a weaker version in which the credibility is not assumed at the outset but instead is derived endogenously in a (subgame perfect) equilibrium. This weaker version can be used to explain the involvement of an external agent in a country's stabilization program, provided the external agent is credible in that it possesses all the necessary means to enforce adjustment and guarantee full compliance with the stabilization scheme. In order to deter the government from violating its commitments, the external agent must provide compliance incentives. In general, an optimal combination of these would include a combination of "carrots and sticks" that constitutes a credible threat to the government. The intervention of an external agent can also entail some costs for national policymakers. To the extent that an external agent imposes simple rules for the behavior of national authorities rather than optimal rules that are contingent on the state of nature> the rules will lack a discretionary regime's flexibility in reacting to unanticipated shocks. Moreover, intervention by an external institution in a country's domestic affairs is likely to generate a political burden on the government that 8 Also see the recent work by Dominguez (1993). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 590 JULIO A. SANTAELLA requests the intervention. Accordingly, only in cases of extreme crisis will an external institution be sought; these cases are exactly the ones where credibility problems are most severe. A second reason for recourse to an external agent is that the agent can provide the resources to finance an external imbalance, as well as serve a catalytic role in mobilizing other credits. Of course, the credibility and financing arguments for seeking external enforcement, though different in nature, are not mutually exclusive. In order to obtain external re­ sources, the government may first need to resolve its credibility problem so that external creditors are more willing to extend credits.9 The latter reasoning implies that the government's credibility problem is multi­ dimensional: it has a domestic aspect-the need for the government to establish credibility with its own citizens and economic agents; and it has an external aspect-the need for credibility in the eyes of foreign creditors and the international community. 10 In practice, the existence of credibility problems and the need for financial assistance are so intertwined that the empirical section does not test for them separately. Most economists agree that the urgency of needed macroeconomic adjustment is greater for economies facing high nominal instability and large macroeconomic disequilibria than for economies with milder infla­ tions and smaller imbalances. When macroeconomic disequilibria are large, a stabilization strategy that relies on reputation-building strategies alone will be more difficult to implement than if the imbalances were small. It follows that the greater the degree ofnominal instability, the more likely it is that the authorities will be nclined i to stabilize the economy through a regime change, rather than through a gradual buildup of reputation. In particular, if the authorities are truly concerned about stopping inflation they will try to switch to a new regime that embodies low inflation rules or commitments; this, in turn, may cause them to seek enforcement of the adjustment program by an external institution. The greater the costs imposed by the nominal instability, the more likely it is that they will exceed the costs of intervention by an external agent. In summary, the general explanation for why some countries resort to external agents to stabilize their economies is that the latter may help See Sachs (1989). The credibility and financing arguments for external intervention are not the only possible explanations. Countries can also rely on an external agent to get technical assistance, in fiscal, monetary, or other areas. A different explanation from the public choice literature suggests that governments use external agents as scapegoats and blame them for undertaking painful adjustment programs and other "dirty work." See, for example, Vaubel (1986). 9 10 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABlLlZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 591 to ease adjustment in two ways. First, an external agent can restore credibility to a stabilizing authority by providing a commitment tech­ nology. Second, the external institution may lend new resources to finance the stabilization effort, thereby making the adjustment less dras­ tic than it otherwise would have been. Both credibility and financing problems seem more pressing in high-inflation countries; therefore, these countries are more likely to appeal to an external agent to stabilize their economies. It is shown below that both arguments seem to have played a role in the European stabilizations of the 1920s, helping to explain the reliance of some countries on the external enforcement of their adjustment programs. Modeling Credibility Problems and External Enforcement A simple model is provided here to illustrate the credibility argument associated with external enforcement of a stabilization program. The model allows a comparison of the different outcomes, in terms of mon­ etary expansion and rates of inflation, of two regimes: commitment and discretion. The stabilization is understood as a change of regime from discretion to rules. The framework stresses the role of inflation in financ­ ing a fiscal deficit and is based on a simplified version of the model in Barra (1983). In this model, there is a natural interpretation of the role of external enforcement. The model uses standard notation and the convention that upper-case letters denote levels of a variable (or parame­ ter) and lower-case letters denote its logarithm. In this model, the government wants to find the rate of growth of the money supply f.Le = me - me-J that minimizes its loss function. In partic­ ular, the problem of the government is given by . (kl) for k t. k2, b' e > 0, mJO Z, = b exp(b'TTe) + b exp(b1r�+ 1) - eRe, (k2) (1) where 1r1 :=; p, - Pe-t is the actual rate of inflation and 1r�+L = E(Pt+J I I�) Pt-t is the expected rate of inflation in period t + 1 condi­ tional on the available information at time t. The first two terms of the loss function (1) are intended to capture two different kinds of costs associated with inflation. The term 1r�+J represents the usual distortionary costs of inflation, while the term 1T1 reflects other costs, such as the so-called menu costs of changing nominal prices or the costs derived from the fiscal lag (Tanzi effect). The last term in equation (1) represents the - ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 592 JULIO A. SANTAELLA benefit the government obtains from inflation; it is proportional to the revenue from inflation R, defined as , R = M, - M,_ t = M, (M•-)t (P•-t). (2) P, P, P.- t P, The demand for real money balances is of the Cagan type and given by m� - = - a1r�+t. for a, "' > 0. (3) _ p, "' Taking first differences in equation (3), the inflation rate that clears the money market is given by (4) The rate of money growth J.L, can be found from equation (4) and substi­ tuted into the loss function (1) to solve the optimization problem faced by the government; alternatively, one can solve for 1r, and find the rate of money growth implied by equation (4). The assumption that er > kt + k2 implies that the equilibria are characterized by positive rates of inflation. The solution for the discretionary regime is characterized by the fact that the government cannot make binding commitments about its future behavior; hence it will be solving loss function (1) in every period. Under these circumstances, the government will not take into account the effect of its current behavior on the future expectations of private agents, and as given. In other words, the government will be playing it will take Nash. After substituting equations (2) and (3) into (1) and using the fact that o7r,/oJ.L1 = 1 from equation (4) and that o7r�+ 1 /oJ.L, = 0 (because is taken as given), the first-order condition is 1r�+t 1r�+t (5) kt exp(b7r,) = er exp( -a'Tr� - 7r,). Private agents understand the government's behavior. Therefore, to obtain the expected inflation rate the mathematical expectation operator E( I I,) is used in equation (5) conilitional on E I,. The expres­ sion for 'IT� can then be substituted back into the logarithm of equation (5) to find the inflation rate that will prevail under discretion. In this equilibrium the full solution is {M, P,} . . dLScretwn: 1r, = 1r, = • J.L, = 1 + 1 b +a ( ) er > 0. 1og "k; (6) On the other hand, in the rules regime the government is able to make binding commitments about its future behavior. Thus, it will take into account the effect of its current decision on the future expectations of private agents when choosing the (constant) rate of monetary expansion, ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 593 which is to be in place forever. In other words, the government will be playing like a Stackelberg leader. To find the rate of inflation under this regime, it is easier to impose the equilibrium condition 1r, 1r� IJ., in loss function (1) and then to take the first-order condition. To sim­ plify the algebra, the approximation that log[(1 + a) exp(-1r) - a]= -(1 + cx)1r around zero is used and then the full equilibrium for the regime under rules is = ( ) 1 ar log rules: 1T, = 1T� = IJ., = > 1 + b + 2cx kl + k2 0. = (7) Using superscripts D for discretion and R for rules to denote the regime in place, it is straightforward to see from equations (6) and (7) that 1r0 > -rrR. The reason is simply that under the commitment regime, the government internalizes the effects of its actions on the behavior of the private agents. In particular, the government understands that by com­ mitting to a lower rate of monetary expansion it can alter the inflationary expectations of the private sector and hence achieve a lower rate of inflation. Moreover, after some manipulations it is easy to show that Z(1r0) - Z(1rR) > 0, the rules regime is Pareto superior to the outcome under the discretion regime. The government is worse off with the equi­ librium inflation rate obtained in the discretion regime than with that obtained under the rules regime. In this model, there is a straightforward role for external enforcement of a stabilization program. It is clear that a government that finds itself under a discretionary regime will want to switch to a rules regime. However, it can only do so by being able to make a credible commitment to follow a binding rule forever. If the external agent is capable of guaranteeing compliance with this commitment, then external enforce­ ment restores the government's credibility and the involvement of the external agent becomes an alternative to effecting a regime change do­ mestically: the external agent provides the commitment technology. To sharpen the analysis further, assume that the presence of an external agent imposes a fixed and positive cost C on the government. This cost may be a fee paid to the external institution, a political penalty involved in accepting foreign intervention in domestic affairs, or the loss to the government from the diminution of its "sovereignty." Then it is obvious that the government will seek external enforcement of the stabilization if (8) Note that, as argued above, the higher the inflation under discretion relative to rules, the higher will be the likelihood of an external agency's involvement. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 594 JULIO A. SANTAELLA II. Stabilization Programs Implemented with the League of Nations During the 1920s The stabilizations in a number of European countries following World War I can be better understood in light of the previous section's analysis of why a government might choose to rely on an external institution to enforce the stabilization of its economy. In particular, it is important to determine whether the two arguments mentioned earlier can throw some light on the involvement of the League of Nations. During the 1920s, the League endorsed six macroeconomic adjustment programs, or "recon­ struction schemes" as they were then called, which were supported with foreign loans and credits. In the programs in Austria (1922) and Hungary (1924), the reforms tackled the financial reconstruction of two countries, which had been devastated by war, dissolution, and hyperinflation. In Greece (1923) and Bulgaria (1926), the initial involvement of the League was in refugee settlement schemes; it took on a financial character later (in 1927 and 1928, respectively). Other programs under the auspices of the League included the mortgage loan to Danzig (1925) and the currency reform loan to Estonia (1927). In all six cases, the government voluntarily appealed to the Council of the League of Nations for assistance to tackle a given macroeconomic problem. After an agreement was reached, the League endorsed the reconstruction scheme. In order to assess the effectiveness of these programs in resolving credibility problems one needs first to understand the policy content of these schemes as well as the means of enforcement that the League possessed. Together, the contents of each scheme and the enforcement of the program determined the force of the commitment technology. The procedures and workings of the League's adjustment programs are explained in detail in League of Nations (1930), but a summary of the relevant elements is provided below.1 1 Policies Recommended by the Lea gue of Nations In each financial reconstruction scheme, the Financial Committee of the League of Nations closely followed the guiding principles of the International Financial Conference that had been convened in 1920 by the Council in Brussels. The basic premise was simply that, in order to 11 Garber and Spencer (1992) describe the League's involvement in Austria and Hungary. This paper emphasizes the enforcement of each of the six reconstruc­ tion schemes as a necessary condition to increase the likelihood of the program's success in effecting a change of regime. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 595 stabilize a currency, fiscal equilibrium was of paramount importance. If the budget was balanced, there was no need for the central bank to extend credits to the government or to increase the note iss-ue beyond the amount that was demanded at a stable price level. Thus, the centerpiece of financial reconstruction was a set of fiscal and administrative reforms intended to eliminate the budget deficit. The reforms included a number of measures to increase tax and nontax revenues, eliminate subsidies, reduce the size of the bureaucracy, and cut other expenditures. In prin­ ciple, the League only set targets for aggregate tax collections, leaving government officials free to decide which taxes were to be raised. The administrative reform also comprised the establishment of domes­ tic institutions and practices permitting better control and monitoring of the public finances by a central authority. Among the institutions estab­ lished or reformed were the central bank and other accounting or audit­ ing offices. Through these reforms, policies to achieve fiscal balance were complemented by monetary discipline. The creation of money through note issue was to be halted, especially that of monetization through advances to the public sector. In order to enforce this discipline, the League's schemes viewed the central bank of issue as constituted of pri­ vate capital and independent of the government. To achieve the needed degree of monetary discipline, it was recommended that the central bank should try to maintain the following guidelines: (1) central bank indepen­ dence; (2) monopoly of note issue; (3) prudence in lending and discount­ ing operations; (4) limits on new advances to the government (sometimes even an overall reduction in the stock of public debt held by the central bank); (5) centralization of the monetary transactions of aU public sector entities in the central bank; and (6) proper cover and reserve backing for the note issue. 12 In most cases, the financial reconstruction included a currency reform, the main purpose of which was to consolidate the stabilization of the currency by implementing a gold exchange standard. As is evident from this brief description, programs undertaken with the support of the League were very comprehensive in that the attack on inflation and currency depreciation was undertaken simultaneously on various fronts: fiscal, monetary, currency, financial, and administrative reforms were incorporated. Special emphasis was given to establishing institutional structures that would give the government both the needed incentives to stabilize and enough policy instruments to maintain sound public fi­ nances. In order to implement such comprehensive schemes, govern­ ments were asked to appeal to their parliaments for special emergency powers. 12 See League of Nations (1930). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 596 JULIO A. SANTAELLA The League of Nations stressed that the reconstruction schemes imple­ mented under its auspices were not all the same. But it acknowledged that when circumstances were similar, adjustment schemes were also similar. These similarities were evident for the financial reconstruction schemes followed by Austria and Hungary and for the refugee settlement pro­ grams and later financial restructurings of Greece and Bulgaria. Other programs of the League, such as those for Danzig and Estonia, differed in both scope and content. Structure of the League and Its Instruments of Control The ultimate responsibility for a financial reconstruction scheme under the sponsorship of the League of Nations fell on the Council of the League. However, the Council instructed either the Secretariat or the Financial Committee to carry out the detailed work. The duties of these organs included preliminary investigations, negotiations with the govern­ ments and institutions involved (both debtors and potential creditors), the design and formulation of the actual stabilization program, prepara­ tion of the draft resolutions, and supervision of the scheme. The Council also set up special committees to address certain international politi­ cal problems that needed to be cleared up before the adjustment agreement-the Protocols-could be signed. The League recognized that the execution of the program was as crucial as its design in restoring confidence in the adjustment effort. Moreover, the League was keenly aware of the repercussions that sponsoring a stabilization program would have on its own reputation. 13 For this reason, it took care to arrange various means to guarantee the enforcement of its program, as well as safeguard the interests of for­ eign creditors. Basically, there were three direct aspects of control in the Protocols and other official documents of the League's financial reconstruction schemes. The first was the appointment by the Council of a League Commis­ sioner to the country undertaking the League-sponsored stabilization. The Commissioner, whose tenure was to last until the reconstruction was completed, controlled two important instruments: the external loan ac­ count and the security revenues account. The external loan account was extended to the debtor government by the foreign creditors to cover fiscal deficits during the transition period. 14 The authorities of the country were 13 See League of Nations (1930, p. 24). 14The financing for the refugee settlement schemes specific expenses to settle them . was aimed at meeting ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 597 not allowed to draw on this account without the consent of the Commis­ sioner, who in tum would only authorize disbursements when the funds were to be spent on an agreed objective. The second account under the control of this League official held all the proceeds from those revenue sources that were set as security for the foreign loan. Security revenues usually included customs receipts or income from state monopolies. The Commissioner would set aside enough funds to service the external obligations, plus any precautionary margin, and refund the rest to the government only if the program was being carried out in conformity with the agreement. Furthermore, the Commissioner usually had the power to veto any government action that would endanger the value of the revenues assigned as security for the loan or even to call for additional receipts to serve as collateral. The Commissioner was to be assisted in his duties by the domestic government and provided with all relevant infor­ mation. This official had enough power to control public finances and to influence the behavior of the government. In principle, he could be reappointed if the Council decided to reinstall control over the authorities when the achievements of the reconstruction scheme were being com­ promised. In modern game-theoretic parlance, the presence of the Commissioner represented a credible threat to the government. The second instrument of control by the League was the nomination of an Adviser to the central bank. Although this official was a bank subordinate and not part of the Financial Committee staff, in practice he maintained close contact with League representatives. His duties were established in the statutes of the central bank, which were drawn up by the Financial Committee. They included supervising the bank's adminis­ tration by the Board of Management and Board of Directors, in par­ ticular ensuring that the domestic component of the monetary base was not unjustifiably expanded. To enforce this discipline, the Adviser was sometimes entrusted with a veto in the Board of Directors. The final aspect of control by the League of Nations was the Trustees of the external loan, who represented the interests of the foreign bond­ holders. Their usual duties were minor, such as the delivery of interest payments or the control over those revenues meant to service the ex­ ternal debt once the Commissioner's tenure had ceased. Their major role was in the case of default, a contingency that was foreseen in the official documents of the reconstruction scheme. If default occurred, the Trustees could make good the payment using the entire assigned revenues. Other support functionaries with different control capabilities were sometimes appointed, such as experts to supervise the conditions of the foreign loan subscriptions or special committees to address certain issues during the preparation and execution stages. As with the design of the ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 598 JULIO A . SANTAELLA financial reconstruction schemes, not all the programs used the same in­ struments of control. Again, variations were made depending on the gravity of the economic situation and institutional structure; not all the programs had a Commissioner and not all schemes endowed the central bank Adviser with the same powers. 15 Effectiveness of External Enforcement As discussed earlier, the degree of credibility attached to a stabilization program depends on firm enforcement of the new rules. Thus, it is important to evaluate the League's effectiveness in inducing compliance with its stabilization programs. Although it is difficult to make a precise assessment, there are signs that the League was a tough enforcer of its programs. For example, there was no recorded instance of an appointed Commissioner having to withhold a portion of a loan in order to exercise the League's prerogatives. Similarly, the legal veto powers of the central bank Adviser were never brought into play. Nor was it deemed necessary to apply sanctions on any government. 16 In itself, the absence of such sanctions does not necessarily imply that enforcement was fully credible. However, as shown below, the economic outcomes of the programs were so remarkable that one can safely dismiss the case of a noncredible enforcement. Another clue to the credibility of the League's enforcement is provided by one incident involving the Austrian program. In 1924, the Austrian government asked to use some part of the reconstruction loan for a purpose other than that of meeting its budget deficit. The government wished to use some of the loan proceeds for productive investment to stimulate the Austrian economy. But the Financial Committee and the Commissioner denied such a release of funds, arguing that it was incon­ sistent with the reconstruction program and with ensuring the security of the bondholders' investment. 17 The degree of control exercised by the League was so strict that the number of countries willing to undertake its programs remained small. 15 For example, in the two Greek schemes the International Financial Commis­ sion, which had been used by foreign creditors since 1898 to control some state revenues assigned as security to foreign loans, continued to function during the period of the League's involvement. In the case of Danzig, a High Commissioner had already been appointed by the League to reside there, because, according to the Treaty of Versailles, Danzig was made a free city under the protection of the League. '6 League of Nations (1930, 1945). 17See League of Nations (1926a, pp. 58-59) and Pietri (1983). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 599 In 1928, for example, Portugal refused to sign an agreement even though all the preliminary investigations and recommendations had taken place. The loss of sovereignty and policy discretion under the program was unacceptable to the Portuguese government. 18 The cases of Poland and Romania appear to be similar. The Polish authorities tried to avoid the intervention of the League in the issuance of their stabilization loan, perhaps because they did not want to be identified with the losing parties of World War I that had programs with the League. 19 The enforcement of, monitoring of, and compliance with the original programs were far from perfect. In the case of Austria in 1924, for example, the League felt that the reduction of expenditures and the dismissal of government employees did not proceed at the expected pace.20 This perceived delay in the reform caused further program adjust­ ments and a prolongation of the League's control beyond the original schedule in the Protocols. In addition, the League was not fully satisfied with the performance of the Austrian and Hungarian central banks because the proportion of short-term paper in the assets of the banks was thought to be excessive. The only major enforcement difficulty of the reconstruction programs came to light not during the 1920s but years later when, in 1931, Hungary, Bulgaria, and Greece defaulted on their international reconstruction loans. However, by that time most of the financial reconstructions were regarded as complete and the League was not in a position to intervene effectively. Macroeconomic Performance Under League Programs This section provides a general evaluation of the macroeconomic out­ comes of programs endorsed by the League of Nations during the 1920s. Clearly, the overall assessment of League programs is favorable: they were able to stop the Austrian and Hungarian hyperinflations; resettle more than 750,000 refugees in Greece and Bulgaria; establish or re­ form central banks in all six countries; and stabilize six national curren­ cies. A more detailed account of the performance of the economies under these programs is given in Figure 1 and Tables 1-6. Although only a small number of indicators are shown, they give a general sense of 18Portugal carried out a program of its own, which was similar to the one recommended by the Financial Committee. See League of Nations (1930) and Derartrnent of O verseas Trade (1930). 1 Meyer (1970) discusses in detail the Polish and Romanian cases. 20 League of Nations (1926a), De Bordes (1924), and Pietri (1983). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 600 JULIO A. SANTAELLA Figure I . Exchange Roles and Price Levels E:.•·clwnfir l'me (leji scale) •·•·· Priu le•·el (riglu sctlie) 1 9 1 4:7=1 34 160 (logarithmic scale) 100 10 0.01 100 22 80 0.001 1919 •' 1 921 1923 1927 1925 1 914=1 1.8 Gulden/US dollar 6.0 Danzig. 1924-28 60 1922 1.6 5.6 5.4 1.4 5.2 1 924 18 1930 1928 1926 Eesri kroon/US dollar 4.6 4.2 5.8 1913=1 1.5 E�tonia. 1921-29 3.8 . . .. 3.4 1 .3 1. 1 3.0 1925 1926 DrachmaiNS dollar Greece. 1921-29 80 1927 2.6 1921 1 928 19 14:7=1 20 . . ..... •' 1923 1925 1927 1929 0.9 19 14:7=0.1 ---------• 1000 .Hu ngary. 1920-26 PengoNS dollar I0 (logarithmic scale) 100 16 60 40 20 26 120 0.1 1 OO 30 140 ·. _.,·. : . . � � -� � � -� � ? L � I� 92 1923� 1 92 S 1927 1929 10 12 8 0.1 1924 1926 Sources: League of Nations, lnrernational Statistical Ye01·hook (various years), and Young ( 1 925). Notes: Exchange rates as quoted in New York; the price level refers to retail prices for Austria. Bulgaria. Greece, and Hungary ( 192 1-23) and to wholesale prices for Danzig, Estonia, and Hungary ( 1924-26). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 0.1 -39.6 490.8 100.4 5.9 0.6 1921 -18.5 81.3 1 ,991.3 -68.0 74.7 54.1 9.0 62.3 1923 2,153.6 81.9 7.7 0.0 1922 1920-27 9.2 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution -4.6 9.4 6.1 6.3 30.3 82.6 1927 on Public - 13.8 21.2 10.7 28.9 - 1 .4 6.4 34.4 7.5 77 . 6 1926 6.1 48.3 10.9 65.5 1925 17.7 69.6 1 1 .6 44.8 1924 Sources: Estimates are based on data from League of Nations. international Statistical Yearbook, Memorandum Finance, and Memorandum on Currency and Cen.fral Banks; League of Nations (1926a); and Young (1925). • The figure for 1920 was es.timated using fiscal years 1919/20 and 1920121. -59. 1 77.6 5.0 3.3 1920 Austria: Monetary and FIScal indicators, Fiscal balance'" (percentage of government expenditure) FIScal policy Note circulation (annual rate of growth) Money supply (M1) (annual rate of growth) Monewry policy Rate of discount Discounts, loans, and advances (percentage of note circulation) Gold and foreign assets reserves (percentage of note circulation) Central bank Table 1. 0 ;:c n m :: [t! z .... 'Ti [t! z r rri ;:c z > � > z Cl [t! v: z '"<1 ;o 0 Cl ;o > :: � c N )>; ...., i3 � 139.3 6.7 -2.3 - 1 .7 9.4 142.6 9.4 20.0 1924 -2.3 4.6 2.3 - 1 1.3 -4.8 195.3 10.0 -8.8 1926 - 19.3 179.5 10.0 9.8 1925 -0.1 16.4 7. 1 168.4 10.0 10.8 1927 -7.4 28.6 12.0 1 27.2 10.0 67.9 1928 - 18.6 -3.1 2.8 -35.8 -8.7 1 19.9 10.0 25.7 1930 - 13.5 141.3 9.5 33.5 1929 • � ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Sources: Estimates are based on data from League of Nations, international Sraristical Yearbook. Memorandum on Public Finance, and Memorandum on Currency and Central Banks. Fiscal year beginnin that calendar year. The fiscal balance includes expenditure incurred as a consequence of the 1923-25 war. and paid by advances om the National Bank. For 192&-30 it includes special funds incorporated in the budget. Fiscal balance (percentage of government expenditure) Monetary policy Note circulation (annual rate of growth) Money supply (M1) (annual rate of gr owth) Fiscal policy 6.5 1 .0 Gold and foreign Discounts, loans, and advances (percentage of note circulation) Rate of discount 1923 assets reserves (percentage of note circulation) Central bank Table 2. Bulgaria: Monetary and Fiscal Indicators, 1923-30 ')> m rr > z _, > u: c 0 > c '- 27. 2 9.2 2 .9 77. 1 53. 1 1 1.3 9.-+ 60.9 108.3 1926 90.ti 1925 O.fl 6.8 46. 1 9-U 1927 � 8 ..J Yearbook :!6.9 5.8 1 10.3 1928 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Sources: Estimate.; are ba�ed on data from Lea!!ue of �ation�. Jmemarional Sratistical Finance . and \lemorandum 011 Crtrrcnc_l and Cemial Ba11f.s. Gold and foreign assets resen·es (percentage of note circu lation) Discountl.. loan�. and ad\'anct:� (percentage of note circulation) Rate o f di�rount .\fonetary poiiC} Note circulation (annual rate of gro" t h ) Central bank 1 92-l Table 3. Danzig: Jlonerar y and Fiscal lndicacors, 1914-30 . 0.0 Public -2.6 .\Jemorandum on 5.0 1 1 .8 liSA 1930 6.5 27.1 107.9 1929 :;<:! n m s:: m z -l Cl ;-n z 183.2 10.0 146.2 8.9 4.6 4.7 0.9 156.0 8.0 -7 .6 6.0 4.8 4.5 6.9 -2.8 37. 1 1925 36.1 1924 40.7 1923 . 2 9 3.2 14.5 - 189.6 9.5 41.2 1926 2.9 26.8 14.7 75.9 8.0 56.4 1927 1.5 17.8 -7.7 86.4 7.5 86 . 1 1928 -4.6 0.0 -5.6 109.7 7.6 79.4 1929 -7.4 5.7 -5.9 74.7 7.8 71.9 1930 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Sources: Estimates are based on data from League of Nations, International Statistical Yearbook , Memorandum on Public Finance, and Memorandum on Currency and Central Ban ks; and Pullerits. The Estonian Yearbook (various issues). Central bank Gold and foreign assets reserves (percentage of note circulation) Discounts, loans, and advances (percentage of note circulation) Rate of discount Monetary policy Note circulation (annual rate of growth) Money supply (Ml) (annual rate of growth) Ftscal policy Fiscal balance (percentage of government expenditure) Table 4. Estonia: Monetary and Fiscal Indicators, I923-30 r � [rt r -l )> z > "' 0 ?> ..... c r 165.4 7.5 151 .6 7.5 48.7 183.9 6.5 45.7 4.0 35.9 1924 38.0 1923 31.9 1922 9.7 164.5 8.7 39.3 192.5 166.9 10.4 2.1 -8.9 50.3 1927 171.5 10.5 50.0 1926 1922-29 14.6 68.5 9.9 74.5 1928 -8.7 75 .5 9.0 60.0 1929 • ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution -4.1 - 17.2 - 19.2 -21.2 -15.0 -49.7 13.3 -33.4 Sources: Estimates are based on data from League of Nations, International Statisrical Yearbook. Memorandum on Public Finance, and Memorandum on Currency and Cemral Banks; and Mazower (1991). Hscal year ending that calendar year. Proceeds and utilization of various loans that ,-.·ere not formerly entered into the budget were accounted for in 1929. Central bank Gold and foreign assets rer.erves (percentage of note circulation) Discounts, loans, and advances (percentage of note circulation) Rate of discount Monetary policy Note circulation (annual rate of growth) FiScal policy Fiscal balance� (percentage of government expenditure) Table 5. Greece: Monetary and Fiscal indicators, expenditures) 727. 6 142. 2 64.3 -26.4 1 , 126.8 201. 4 76.0 -39.0 105.7 14.0 97.4 6.5 1 1 1 .8 6.0 -48 .0 34.9 0.0 1923 0.1 1922 -45.9 693.7 385.0 84.7 14.1 64.5 1924 8.5 57.0 15.2 69.7 9.8 97.4 1925 7.7 42.5 13.2 74 . 9 6.7 88. 7 1926 1 2. 1 34.2 3.4 91.0 6.0 83.2 1927 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Sources: Estimates are based on data from League of Nations, lncernarional Statistical Yearbook . Memora11dum on Public Finance , and Memorandum on Currency and Cenrral Ba11ks : League of Nations (1926b) ; and Young (1925). • Fiscal year ending that calendar year. Fiscal balance• (percentage of government Cenrral bank Gold and foreign assets reserves (percentage of note circulation) Discounts. loans, and advances (percentage of note circulation) Rate of discount Monetary policy Note circulation (annual rate of grmvth) Money supply (Ml) (annual rate of growth) Fiscal policy 1921 Table 6. Hungar-y: Monetary and Fiscal Indicarors, 1921-27 > en r r > z -l > "' '- c c 0 > STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 607 the macroeconomic performance of the countries that undertook the programs sanctioned by the League of Nations. The first and clearest characteristic apparent in Figure 1 is that the programs succeeded in stabilizing the exchange rates. Under the pro­ grams, all six currencies were brought onto a gold exchange standard. In the cases of Estonia and Bulgaria, stability was achieved in 1924, before the intervention of the League in financial matters, but was consolidated under the auspices of the League. The behavior of the price level also reveals that the programs endorsed by the League were disinflationary. Prices in Austria and Hungary were quickly stabilized-in 1922 and 1924, respectively. The cases of Greece and Bulgaria also show how rates of inflation were reduced; the price level actually fell in Bulgaria. Interest­ ingly, some of the disinflation in the latter two cases began with the League's intervention in the settlement of refugees (1923 for Greece and 1926 for Bulgaria). Although these schemes were not dealing strictly with a macroeconomic problem, the League insisted that governments should make every effort to balance their budgets. Price stability in Greece seems to have been reaffirmed with the subsequent financial re­ construction of 1928: inflation, which had exceeded 80 percent in 1923, was .reduced from an average 15 percent during 1925-26 to about 7 percent during 1927-28. In the cases of Estonia and Danzig, no dra­ matic price instability was evident before the League's intervention, and the programs preserved this stability. One important feature of the League's programs was their emphasis on reestablishing sound fiscal and monetary policies. In order to make a currency convertible, it was necessary to reshape the balance sheet of the monetary authority into a more conservative and orthodox composi­ tion. Tables 1-6 show how, as the central bank was being established or reformed in each country, the program involved a portfolio reshuffling, away from domestic credit granted by the central bank toward gold and other external or metallic assets. In some cases, the change in the balance sheet of the monetary authority was quite spectacular: the Austrian central bank's ratio of gold and foreign reserves to note circulation went from almost nil to more than 75 percent by the end of the program (Table 1); conversely, the ratio of discounts by the central bank went from 100 percent of note circulation in 1921 to only 34 percent by 1926. With respect to rates of monetary expansion, there are some interest­ ing features. First, in cases where there was initially hyperinflation, money growth was substantially reduced but never eliminated. In fact, the money supply grew 81 percent in Austria during 1923 (Table 1) and 57 percent in Hungary during 1925 (Table 6). The monetary expansion immediately after the stabilization of the exchange rate and the price level ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 608 JULJO A. SANTAELLA permitted a replenishment of real money balances. Second, in the cases where there was no initial hyperinflation, the rates of monetary expan­ sion were kept under control for most of the stabilization period, except for small increases in Bulgaria, Estonia, and Greece during the reform years. The money supply increased 29 percent in Bulgaria during 1928 (Table 2) and 27 percent in Estonia during 1927 (Table 4), and the circulation of notes increased almost 15 percent in Greece during 1928 (Table 5). Given the relatively stable behavior of prices, these rates of money growth may also be explained by upward shifts in the demand for real money balances caused by the new regime, with its lower antici­ pated inflation. Finally, it is also worth mentioning that well before the League's financial intervention in Greece its rate of monetary expansion was substantially reduced. In fact, the reduced growth in note circulation, from 49 to 4 percent after 1924 (Table 5), coincided with implementation of the refugee program, which was also under the control of the League of Nations. The fiscal data that are presented in the tables tend to confirm the movement toward more conservative macroeconomic policies, including balanced budgets. This is particularly striking in the cases of Austria and Hungary (Tables 1 and 6), where budget balances were substantially improved. In other cases, the movement was not so drastic. Nevertheless, in some cases, such as Greece in 1929 (Table 5), accounting practices distorted the fiscal data to the extent that a precise assessment is difficult. Ill. Determinants of External Enforcement: Empirical Evidence The previous theoretical discussion predicts that countries with more severe credibility problems and more pressing financial needs should be more prone to rely on an external agent to help stabilize the economy. Moreover, it also argues that both kinds of problems should be more acute in economies with high nominal instability. This section provides some empirical evidence on the experience of countries that relied on external agents during the European currency stabilizations of the 1920s. The theoretical arguments are compared with the empirical evidence in two stages. The first stage involves casual observation of the relations among the degree of nominal instability, the issuance of external loans, and the external enforcement of stabilization. The second stage is more rigorous and attempts to test the credibility-financial problems hypothesis using discriminant and probit analyses. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 609 Nominal Instability, Loans, and External Enforcement During the 1920s, most of the European countries returned to the prewar gold standard and stabilized their currencies. World War I had left these countries with relatively high rates of inflation and currency depre­ ciation, which had been ignited by rapid monetary expansion to finance large continuing fiscal deficits. The gold standard was attractive because it had eliminated currency instability from the international financial system before World War I ; therefore, almost every country tried to establish convertibility of its currency into gold. The third column of Table 7 gives an idea of the magnitude of nominal instability suffered by various European countries, as proxied by the level at which these cur­ rencies were stabilized with respect to their prewar gold value. There were only six countries whose currencies returned to the pre-World War I gold value, and they were mostly nations that had remained neutral during the war. These countries were only able to achieve this objective by deflating prices enough to compensate for the decline in the purchas­ ing power of money that bad occurred during the war years. At the other extreme of nominal instability, five countries suffered hyperinflations and had to implement draconian reforms to stabilize their currencies.21 Between these two extremes, the table shows that the currencies of 15 countries were stabilized at levels ranging from! to � 1 5 of their prewar gold values. Table 7 also indicates whether there was external enforcement during these episodes. The six countries with programs endorsed by the League, together with Germany, are shown as having external enforcement. The German case is interesting because it is another instance during this period where stabilization was supported by external enforcement. The German hyperinflation was stabilized in 1923 without any initial external support. However, the final consolidation of a stable currency was at­ tained with the assistance of a foreign loan floated under the Dawes Plan. This plan was formulated by a committee of experts appointed by the Reparation Commission to study German reconstruction and reparation problems. The monetary restraint envisaged by the Dawes Plan was enforced through two different channels. The first was foreign interven­ tion in the German central bank (Reichsbank): half of the 14 members of the General Board would be foreigners, who would monitor the 21 Some studies of the hyperinflation experiences can be found in the seminal paper by Cagan (1956) or the more recent ones by Sargent (1986), Dornbusch and Fischer l1986), and Heymann (1986). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 1922 1926 1924-28 1923 1923 1926 1924-27 1923 1926-28 1923-24 1928 1924 1927 1922 1922 1924 1928 1926-27 1929 1927-29 1 92 2 1922-24 1924 1925 1925-31 Austria Belgium Bulgaria"' Czechoslovakia lfll 13 X 7 X X X X X X l X X X X X X X X X X X X credits Temporary X Dawes Plan League of Nations League of Nations League o f Nations League of Nations League of Nations No credits I .1 Hyperinflation 1 122 1 133 Hyperinnation I 1 Hyperinflation 114 1 n zs New currency l/15 Hyperinflation 1 15 1 /8 New currency 1 1 190 tn 1 127 1n League of Nations External agent of enforcement No specific loans c ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 5 X X X Jl 5 X X Jl 9 X X X X X X X X 11 Jl X X X Jl Jl X X X X loans Specific X X credits Temporary X X credits No No specific loans Final stabilization and currency reform X loans Specific Sua:essful preliminary stabilization Source: Elaborated from League of Nations (1946). " The serond year is the de jure stabilization when different from the actual stabilization. b Second stabilization (first attempt was unsuccessful). Stabilized in 1924 but abandoned in 1925. d Stable currency during 1925-28. Total Netherlands Norway Poland' Portugald Romania Soviet Union Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom Yugoslavia Lithuania Latvia Italy Germany Greece Hungal)' France Danzig Denmark Estonia Finland value Year of stabilization� Country Hyperinflation stabilization relative to prewar gold currency Level of Table 7. European Stabilizations of the 1920s > );! r r [':1 til > z ?> 0 c c ..... 0 ,_ 0\ STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 611 Reichsbank's note issue. The second was an agent appointed by the Reparation Commission to monitor Germany's currency policyY Although the Polish case is similar to the German experience, Poland is not shown as having external enforcement in Table 7. Like Germany, Poland relied entirely on monetary and fiscal reforms to stabilize its currency in 1924, after a terrible hyperinflation, with no external support. However, inflationary pressures recurred and a second stabilization took place in 1927, this time assisted by foreign credits. The difference from the German case is that foreign interests were not directly represented on the board of the central bank. The presence of external agents in Poland was reduced to an American financial adviser sent by the Kemmerer mission in 1926.23 This external involvement was so minimal that Poland is not classified as having external enforcement in Table 7. Table 7 also shows external involvement through the provision of external credits. It indicates that in only 5 of 25 countries were specific currency stabilization loans involved. This is reproduced in the seventh column and refers to preliminary or de facto stabilization-that is, when the monetary authority is defending the parity. Temporary credits were extended to seven countries, though they were not necessarily used for the purpose of stabilizing their currencies. By contrast, 13 countries did not have recourse to foreign loans to stabilize their currencies. With respect to the final legislation of the parity, nine countries had temporary credits but hardly made any use of them. Only 5 consolidated their stabilization without any access to specific credit arrangements, while 1 1 adopted an official parity with the aid of specific loans. Although the majority of European countries achieved preliminary stabilization without specific financial assistance from abroad, the foUow­ ing observations are relevant. First, the 11 countries that received loans for the final stabilization were among those with the highest rates of currency depreciation and included 4 economies that were suffering from hyperinflation. In fact, after applying the straightforward nonparametric test of medians, it turns out that the median currency depreciation in countries with specific external loans (tenth column of Table 7) was sig­ nificantly higher than the median currency depreciation in countries with­ out specific loans.24 This suggests that nations with higher nominal insta22 See Schacht (1925, 1927) and Heymann (1986). Meyer (1970). Dornbusch and Fischer (1986) also mention the presence of a British adviser to Polish authorities before the Kemmerer mission. 24The significance level is 0.002. The test was performed by ordering the countries according to their percentage currency depreciation during the period of nonconvertibility (third column of Table 7) and sorting the countries that were above and below the median country. The test then analyzed the relative position of countries with and without external loans with respect to the median country 23 See ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 612 JULIO A. SANTAELLA bility relied more heavily on external credits to stabilize their currencies than nations with lower nominal instability.25 Second, there was external monitoring of stabilization programs in six of the countries: Austria, Bulgaria, Danzig, Germany, Greece, and Hungary.26 As before, these six countries were among those with the highest rates of nominal instability as measured by exchange rate depre­ ciation. Again applying the test of the medians, it turns out that the median currency depreciation for the countries with external enforce­ ment was higher than that for countries with no external enforcement. 27 This observation supports the assertion that countries with higher nom­ inal instability sought external enforcement to stabilize their currencies more frequently than countries with lower instability. Third, one must take into account the possible effect that anticipated future external assistance may have on the initial stabilization of the currency. For instance, Llach (1987) argues that the announced forma­ tion of a commission of experts on the problem of war reparations contributed to the success of the German hyperstabilization. Similarly, in the Austrian case, the anticipation of a League of Nations' reconstruc­ tion scheme appears to have stabilized the Austrian crown.29 Thus, even if 13 countries did not actually have recourse to foreign loans to stabilize their currencies, the fact that in 8 of them some future credits were anticipated may have helped to effect the stabilization. Finally, it is interesting to note that four of the five countries that experienced hyperinflation during the 1920s (Austria, Germany, Hun­ gary, and Poland) had access to foreign loans and to external enforcement of the conditionality attached to these loans. 30 The sole exception was the stabilization of the Soviet Union in 1922. This latter case suggests, con­ sistent with the view in the League's own 1946 report, that external loans 28 to determine if their currency depreciation was the same (null hypothesis). Those countries that issued a national currency for the first time (Danzig and Lithuania) were excluded. 25 Further support for this statement comes from the fact that there was re­ course to external loans in all the high-inflation episodes studied by Dornbusch and Fischer (1986). 26The Eesti mark of Estonia was stabilized in 1924, well in advance of the 1927 loan obtained by Estonia through the League. It is thus plausible that the external involvement was not anticipated at the moment of the stabilization. Danzig was drop.ped from the analysis owing to a lack of data for 1923. he significance level is 0.024. 2 T 28The same is admitted by the Reparation Commission (as quoted in Bresciani­ Turroni (1937, p. 339)). 29 See Sargent's (1986) interpretation of Pasvolsky (1928) and Dornbusch and Fischer (1986). 30The degree of external control in the Polish case seems very mild. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 613 and foreign enforcement are not strictly necessary to implement a hy­ perstabilization. 31 Later episodes in Hungary (1945) and China (1949) furnish additional examples of socialist stabilization without external intervention. Discriminant and Probit Analysis The basic hypothesis that emerges from the earlier theoretical dis­ cussion is that economies that face more severe credibility problems or more pressing financial needs are more likely to require external enforce­ ment. Moreover, the preceding analysis of the League's programs sug­ gests that those programs were characterized by binding commitments that enhanced the credibility of the stabilization attempts. Hence, it seems natural to test whether countries with greater credibility problems and financial needs did indeed rely more heavily on external agents to stabilize their economies. The previous subsection indicated that coun­ tries with higher nominal instability did have recourse to such external involvement. Unfortunately, the observed counterpart of a "credibility problem" is hard to find, and the investigator is forced to rely on proxies that may indicate the existence of such problems. The difficulty in finding suitable variables to measure the degree of credibility is exacerbated by the lack of reliable data for the 1920s. Moreover, as discussed above, credibility problems and financial needs are likely to appear together, increasing the difficulty of finding a proxy that isolates a credibility problem. Therefore, they are handled as a single hypothesis. Given these Limitations, three variabLes have been chosen to serve as proxies for the "credibility" of the economic policymaking authority. The first variable, BACK" is the ratio of the sum of gold and net foreign assets held by the central bank to the amount of note circulation. The idea is that lower values of BACK, should mean that the government is less able to defend a given exchange rate objective. This measure was emphasized by the League itself as a good indicator of sound financial practices. The second variable, FISC" is the ratio of the fiscaL balance to the level of government expenditures. The value of FISC, is intended to capture the degree of sustainability of fiscal policy: lower values should mean less sustainable (and credible) policies. This variable can also be interpreted as a measure of the severity of the financial needs that a government faces. Finally, the third value consid31 League of Nations (1946). The Soviet stabilization was of a different type. Llach (1987) calls it stabilization "by coercion" as opposed to other cases that were "by consent." ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 614 JULIO A. SANTAELLA ered, DEPR, is the percentage rate of depreciation in the end-of-period vaJue of the domestic currency (as observed on the New York market); the logic is that a higher rate of depreciation suggests that markets displayed less confidence in the policies followed by that country. All variables are measured for the year in which the stabilization took place. An endogenous binary variable is used to classify the episodes. This dummy variable takes a value of unity if the country stabilized during-or in clear anticipation of-participation by an external enforcing agency, and zero if not. The countries for which this dummy takes a value of unity are Austria, Bulgaria, Germany, Greece, and Hungary. Descriptive statistics for the three variables and data sources are provided in Table 8, where the countries are classified according to whether or not there was external enforcement. Notice that the credibility measures of countries that stabilized without external enforcement clearly dominate (first-order stochastically) the credibility measures of countries with external en­ forcement. Indeed, countries with external enforcement not only per- Table 8. Summary Staristics of the Credibility Indicators Without external With external enforcement Variable enforcement Banking variable (BACK) 32.9 10.2 First quartile 57.4 38.3 Median 71.7 Third quartile 69.5 39.5 53.6 Mean 26.6 30.7 Standard deviation Fiscal variable (FISC) -78.5 -10.2 First quartile -2.9 -45.9 Median 1.9 -10.7 Third quartile -5.0 -44.8 Mean 8.6 Standard deviation 35.0 Depreciation variable (DEPR) -22.1 11.4 First quartile -11.2 688.2 Median 17.9 6,916.6 Third quartile 2,908.8 Mean -0 .7 29.3 5,279.0 Standard deviation Note: See text for definition of the variables. Sources: League of Nations, International Statistical Yearbook, Memorandum on Public Finance, and Memorandum on Currency and Central Banks ; Pullerits, The Estonian Yearbook (various issues); League of Nations (1926a, 1926b, 1927); Young (1925); Mazower (1991); Department of Overseas Trade (1929); Lithu­ anian Ministry of Finance (1924); and Mitchell (1980). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 615 STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT Table 9. Discriminant Analysis of the European Stabilizations of the 1920s (Number and percentage of observations) Actual classification Without external enforcement With external enforcement Total Predicted classification Without external With external enforcement enforcement 1 15 (6.25) (93.75) 2 (40.00) 17 (80.95) Total 16 (100.00) 3 (60.00) 5 (100.00) 4 21 (100.00) (19.05) Classifying variables: BACK, FISC, and DEPR,. Note: Percentages are in parentheses. formed worse, on average, according to the distributions in that table, but they also suffered from a greater degree of variability. A first step in testing the credibility and financial needs hypothesis of external involvement is implemented through a discriminant analysis. The objective is to determine whether countries can be classified into those that did and those that did not rely on external assistance on the basis of the three variables described. The classification is carried out using the generalized squared distances between the two groups of countries, assuming equal prior probabilities. The results presented in Table 9 are very suggestive and indicate that most of the countries can indeed be identified through the use of these three variables. In par­ ticular, 15 of the 16 countries that did not rely on external enforcement are correctly classified by the discriminant analysis, and 3 of the 5 that were supported by international institutions are also identified. The only countries that are rnisclassified are Bulgaria, Greece, and ltalyY The second step in testing the credibility and financial needs hypothesis is to carry out a probit analysis to verify the robustness of the results obtained from the discriminant analysis. This approach also provides a. way to estimate the predictive powers of each of the three variables chosen in the forecast of the dummy variable. The results of this probit estimation (Table 10) are very interesting. All of the variables have the expected signs, except for BACK, in equation (5); both FISC, and DEPR, 32 Bulgaria and Greece are probably misclassified because they did not exhibit exchange rate depreciations as large as those in the hyperinflation countries. In the case of the Italian misclassification, it is likely due to the substantial fiscal deficit. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution - 1 . 184 BACK, 23 1 . 098 0.046 78.3 1 1.079 0.470 86.4 22 - 6.108 (-2.020) - 1.697 ( - 3 . 181) (2) 11.437 0.485 86.4 22 - 1 . 176 ( - 1 . 196) - 0.960 ( - 0.588) -6.324 ( -1. 961) (4) Equation 0.208 (2.313) 6.940 0.301 90.5 21 - 1 .253 ( - 1 .533) 0. 170 (0.118) (5) ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 0.205 (2.437) 7.384 0. 320 90.5 21 - 1 .170 (-3.221 ) (3) (Maximum likelihood estimates) Probit Analysis of the European Stabilizations of the 1920s T-statistics are reported i n parentheses. a Log of likelihood ratio times -2. 2 b McFadden pseudo-R • c Percentage of accurate predictions. Note: Acc:uracyc N LRa Rz b DEPR, FISC, -0.220 ( -0.360) I n te rcept ( - 1 . 017 ) (1) Variable Table 10. -3.77 7 ( - 0.895) 0.245 (0.795) 1 1 .014 0.478 90.5 21 - 1 .502 ( - 2.656) (6) - 1 . 192 ( - 1 . 189) -0.640 ( -0.365) -4.132 ( - 0.952) 0.242 (0.744) 1 1. 1 15 0.482 90.5 21 (7) > m rr- � > z "' > 0 .... c r STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 617 are always statistically significant when they are not in the same regres­ sion. The likelihood ratio tests whether the coefficients on those variables other than the intercept are all equal to zero; this null hypothesis is rejected for all specifications except equation (1). The results are further corroborated by McFadden's R2•33 More interesting is the predictive power of the explanatory variables: more than 78 percent of the observations are classified correctly in the worst specification. In this respect, it is worth noting that the fiscal balance has 86 percent of the observations as correct predictions. The countries that are not correctly classified by FISC, are Bulgaria, Greece, and Italy. When the fiscal balance variable is supplemented by the rate of depreciation, the percentage of correct predictions increases to more than 90 percent, and Italy is no longer misclassified. However, BACK, is an indicator that performs poorly.34 In sum, the empirical tests described here support the hypothesis that the presence of credibility problems and financial needs, when proxied by the fiscal inconsistency and instability of the exchange rate, did influ­ ence the decision to rely on external agents. Of course, the interpretation of the results presented here does not make a strong distinction between the two different arguments. However, the need for financing is often aggravated by credibility problems, so even though the two explanations are conceptually different, in practice it is difficult to disentangle them. IV. Conclusions and Lessons from the 1920s There are two main reasons why a government may rely on external assistance to stabilize its economy. The first is that an external agent can restore credibility to the government's macroeconomic stabilization ef­ forts: this has been referred to as the "commitment technology" argu­ ment. The second explanation is that external assistance, in the form of foreign loans and credits, can help to finance both the imbalances of an economy in disequilibrium and the stabilization confronting the econ­ omy. This paper has argued that both these incentives to rely on external 33 Similar results are obtained by running logit regressions instead of the probit specification, as well as by lagging the variables one period instead of using current values. 34 This performance seems to be compatible with the evidence found by Harberger and Edwards (1980) in their study of modern devaluation episodes. They found that countries that abandoned a fixed exchange rate reacted to a decrease in their equivalent measure of BACK only after it had reached a critical level. A similar scenario in which a critical value of BACK triggers external enforcement of a stabilization program may be possible in this sample. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 618 JULIO A. SANTAELLA intervention are likely to be more pressing in those countries experiencing high nominal instability. The broad conclusion that emerges from the analysis of the reconstruc­ tion schemes carried out by the League of Nations in the 1920s is that for a stabilization effort to succeed it must be effected through a fundamental change in the fiscal and monetary regime. To achieve such a regime change, the League of Nations supported a comprehensive series of reforms in each country where it was involved. Of vital importance in these countries was the goal of achieving sound and sustainable public finances, the establishment of independent central banks, and the return to convertible currencies. Nevertheless, the attempt to carry out all of these reforms might have been in vain if the League had not had the means to control and monitor enforcement of the programs. The control machinery, together with the League's concern to protect its own repu­ tation, appears to have ensured that the League's reconstruction schemes constituted credible changes of regime. In sum, the stabilization pro­ grams of the League achieved an impressive record of success, at least in the period before the Great Depression. This study of the historical experience of the currency stabilizations of the 1920s yields suggestive results in several areas. The paper finds preliminary evidence that, consistent with the analytical argument in Section I, countries that suffered from higher nominal instability dis­ played a higher reliance on both external loans and external enforcement. The empirical analysis of the role of external assistance compared indi­ cators of the credibility and financial needs of countries that resorted to external intervention with those of countries that did not. The results support the hypothesis that the presence of credibility problems and financial needs, especially when proxied by fiscal unsustainability and exchange rate instability, influenced the decision of European countries to rely on an external agent to help enforce their currency stabilizations. The currency stabilizations of the 1920s, in particular the experience of programs implemented with the support and assistance of the League of Nations, provide several lessons for current problems. First, these episodes suggest the appropriate procedure for impleme�ting a monetary stabilization: programs should be comprehensive and should place spe­ cial emphasis on the right institutional setting in order to provide lasting stability. Second, these episodes give some insight into the sorts of circumstances where external involvement becomes more desirable. Countries with economies in profound disarray and that suffer credibility and financing problems are more likely to require external enforcement of an adjustment program. Third, the experiences also illustrate the degree of sacrifice needed in terms of a country's sovereignty and discre- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 619 tion in order to enable the external enforcer of a stabilization to achieve the objectives of the program. The analysis suggests that in cases where policymakers are willing to forgo the flexibility of a discretionary regime in favor of a commitment regime, they are more likely to succeed in implementing a credible, and hence successful, stabilization program. REFERENCES Backus, David, and John Driffill, "Inflation and Reputation," American Eco­ nomic Review , Vol. 75 (1985), pp. 530-38. Barro, Robert, "Inflationary Finance under Discretion and Rules.·· Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 16 (1983), pp. 1-22. , "Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy with Incomplete Informa­ tion," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 17 (1986), pp. 3-20. Barro, Robert, and David Gordon (1983a), "A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model," Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 91 (1983), pp. 589-609. -- (1983b), "Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12 (1983), pp. 101-22. Blackburn, Keith, and Michael Christensen, "Monetary Policy and Policy Cred­ ibility: Theories and Evidence," Journal of Economic Literature . Vol. 27 (1989), pp. 1-45. Bresciani-Turroni, Constantino, The Economics of Inflation (London: Allen & Unwin, 1937). Cagan, Phillip, "The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation," in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money , ed. by Milton Friedman (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956). Calvo, Guillermo, "On the Time Consistency of Optimal Policy in a Monetary Economy," Econometrica, Vol. 46 (1978), pp. 1411-28. De Bordes, Jan van Wain�, The Austrian Crown: Its Depreciation and Stabiliza­ tion (London: P.S. King, 1924; reprinted by Garland Publishing, ew York, 1983). Department of Overseas Trade, Economic Conditions in Poland (London: H.M. Stationery Office, 1929). , Economic Conditions in Portugal (London: H.M. Stationery Office. 1930). Dominguez, Kathyrn, "Role of International Organizations in the Bretton Woods System," in A Retrospective on the Breuon Woods System . ed. by Michael Bordo and Barry Eicheugreen (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, for NBER, 1993). Dornbusch, Rudiger, "Monetary Problems of Post-Communism: Lessons from the End of the Austro-Hungarian Empire,'· Weltwirtschafrliches Archi1·. Vol. 28 (1992), pp. 391-424. -- -- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 620 JULIO A. SANTAELLA Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Stanley Fischer, "Stopping Hyperinflations Past and Present," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv , Vol. 122 (1986), pp. 1-47. Dornbusch, Rudiger, Federico Sturzenegger, and Holger Wolf, "Extreme Infla­ tion: Dynamics and Stabilization," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , Vol. 2 (1990), pp. 1-64. Edwards, Sebastian, "The International Monetary Fund and the Developing Countries: A Critical Evaluation," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 31 (1989), pp. 7-68. Eichengreen, Barry, Golden Fetters: The GoldStandard and the Great Depression 1919-1939 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992). Fischer, Stanley, "Dynamic Inconsistency, Cooperation and the Benevolent Dissembling Government," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 2 (1980), pp. 93-107. Garber, Peter, and Michael Spencer, "The Dissolution of the Austro-Hungarian Empire: Lessons for Currency Reform," IMF Working Paper 92/66 (Wash­ ington: International Monetary Fund, 1992). Harberger, Arnold, and Sebastian Edwards, "International Evidence on the Sources of Inflation" (unpublished; University of Chicago, 1980). Heymann, Daniel, "Las Grandes Inflaciones: Caracterfsticas y Estabilizaci6n," in Tres Ensayos sobre Jnflaci6n y Estabilizaci6n (Buenos Aires: CEPAL, 1986). Kydland, Finn, and Edward Prescott, "Rules Rather than Discretion: The In­ consistency of Optimal Plans," Journal ofPolitical Economy, Vol. 85 (1977), pp. 473-91. League of Nations (1926a), The Financial Reconstruction of Austria (Geneva: League of Nations, 1926). (1926b), The Financial Reconstruction of Hungary (Geneva: League of Nations, 1926). , Banking and Currency Reform in Estonia (Geneva: League of Nations, 1927). ---, Principles and Methods of Financial Reconstruction Work Undertaken Under the Auspices of the League of Nations (Geneva: Secretariat of the League of Nations, 1930). ---, The League of Nations Reconstruction Schemes in the Inter-war Period (Geneva: Publications Department of the League of Nations, 1945). , The Course and Control of Inflation (Geneva: Publications Department of the League of Nations, 1946). ---, International Statistical Yearbook (Geneva: League of Nations, various issues). , Memorandum on Currency and Central Banks (Geneva: League of Nations, various issues). ---, Memorandum on Public Finance (Geneva: League of Nations, various issues). Leijonhufvud, Axel, "Keynesianism, Monetarism and Rational Expectations: Some Reflections and Conjectures" in individual Forecasting and Aggregate -- --- --- --- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution STABILIZATION PROGRAMS AND EXTERNAL ENFORCEMENT 621 Outcomes , ed. by Roman Frydman and Edmund Phelps (New York: Cam­ bridge University Press, 1983). , "Inflation and Economic Performance," in Money in Crisis, ed. by Barry Siegel (Cambridge: Ballinger, 1984). Lithuanian Ministry of Finance, Economic and Financial Situation of Lithuania n i 1924 (Kaunas: State Printing Office, 1924). Llach, Juan, "La Naturaleza Institucional e Internacional de las Hiperestabiliza­ ciones," Desarrollo Econ6mico , Vol. 26 (1987), pp. 527-59. Mazower, Mark, Greece and the Inter-war Economic Crisis (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1991). Meyer, Richard, Banker's Diplomacy: Monetary Stabilization in the Twenties (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970). Mitchell, Brian, European Historical Statistics, 1750-1975 (New York: Facts on File, 1980). Pasvolsky, Leo, Economic Nationalism of the Danubian States (New York: Macmillan, 1928). Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini, Macroeconomic Policy , Credibility and Politics (New York: Harwood Academic, 1990). Pietri, Nicole, "L'reuvre d'un Organisme Technique de Ia Societe des Nations: Le Comite Financier et Ia Reconstrution de l'Autricbe (1921-1926)," in The League of Nations in Retrospect (Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, 1983). Pullerits, Albert, The Estonian Yearbook (Tallinn: Central Bureau of Statistics of Estonia, various issues). Sachs, Jeffrey, "Conditionality, Debt Relief, and the Developing Country Debt Crisis," in Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance, ed. by Jeffrey Sachs (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, for NBER, 1989). Sargent, Thomas, Rational Expectations and Inflation (New York: Harper-Row, 1986). Schacht, Hjalmar, "The New German Currency" in European Currency and Finance, ed. by John Young (Washington: Commission of Gold and Silver Inquiry, U.S. Senate, 1925). , The Stabilization of the Mark (New York: Adelphi, 1927). Vaubel, Roland, "A Public Choice Approach to International Organizations," Public Choice, Vol. 51 (1986), pp. 39-57. Young, John, ed., European Currency and Finance (Washington: Commission of Gold and Silver Inquiry, U.S. Senate, 1925). --- -- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF S/4/f Papers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) il:l 1993 International Monetary Fund Risk Taking and Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Nontradable Human Capital ZULIU HU* This paper demonstrates that the stream of uncertain income from human capital has systematic effects on the demand for risky physical capital assets. Iflabor supply is inelastic and real wages are known with certainty, then a labor income tax will reduce holdings of the risky physical asset. However, if labor income fluctuates randomly, a labor income tax may actually raise demand for the asset if human capital risk and physical capital risk are positively correlated. The idiosyncratic risk and nontrad­ ability of human capital also have implicationsfor optimal taxation. [JEL G l l , H21) have long been concerned with the effects of taxation Eon entrepreneurs' risk-taking behavior. Since the seminal essay by CONOMISTS Damar and Musgrave (1944), such issues have been analyzed in a pure portfolio choice framework. See Tobin (1958), Mossin (1968), Feldstein (1969, 1976), Stiglitz (1969), Sandmo (1969), and Dreze and Modigliani (1972). Presumably more risk taking leads to greater demand for risky assets and thus lowers the cost of risky capital. In the long run, such behavior helps to increase the economy's capital stock and national income. Although this literature bas succeeded in dispelling the popular per­ ception that taxing the returns on risky assets will necessarily reduce risk * Zuliu Hu was an Economist in the Research Department when this paper was written. He has since moved to the Fiscal Affalfs Department. He holds a doctorate from Harvard University. The author is grateful to Robert Flood, Robert Merton, and Larry Summers for helpful comments. 622 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution RISK TAKING, TAXATION, AND HUMAN CAPITAL 623 taking, it suffers from some serious limitations. Chief among them is that the earlier work Largely ignores some important and closely related decisions, such as individuals' saving-consumption and labor-leisure choices. Moreover, even if labor income is aJlowed, in addition to income from capital assets, the pure portfolio choice model usually takes such income as exogenously given (the labor supply is fixed) or assumes that individuals receive a certain stream of wage income. Ignoring labor income fails to capture the crucial role of human capital in consumption and investment decisions, as human capital is often the more important form of wealth for most individuals. 1 An extreme case is that in the absence of bequests the young are endowed with only human capital and no financial wealth. To assume an exact stream of wage income is also unsatisfactory because in reality individuals cannot foresee the flow of their future labor income with certainty. For example, real wages are uncertain when the prices of consumption goods are uncertain. For some people, their other­ wise smooth and continuous flow of labor income may contain jump components over the life cycle if they face a positive probability of temporary layoff or sudden loss of earning ability owing to health prob­ lems. Thus, like its physical counterpart, human capital is a risky asset. The risk of human capital income probably has important interactions with the risks of financial assets. Moreover, unlike physical capital, human capital cannot be traded for obvious moral hazard reasons. No claims on future wage income are actual1y traded on financial markets. This feature of human capital will undoubtedly affect society's efficient risk pooling and risk sharing. Consequently, an analysis of the effects of taxation on risk taking should explicitly account for the riskiness and nontradability of human capital.2 This paper recognizes the existence of risky, nontradable human cap­ ital income and attempts to offer an integrated treatment of individuals' intertemporal consumption and labor supply as well as of their portfolio choices. The paper presents a basic model and first considers the simplest case with fixed labor supply and deterministic wage rate. Endogenous labor income is then introduced. The paper then turns to analyze the case when income from human capital follows geometric Brownian motion. Finally, it explores the implications of the risk and nontradability of human capital for efficient taxation. 1 Williams (1978) examines the effect of human capital on portfolio choice. In addition, Williams (1979) analyzes individuals' decisions about their investment in human capital through their level of education. 1In a similar model without human capital, Hamilton (1987) examines how taxation of risky financial assets, such as dividend and capital gains taxes, can affect individuals' risk-taking behavior. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 624 ZULIU HU I. Basic Model It is assumed that the uncertainty in the economy is generated by a two­ dimensional stochastic process {dz, dq}, where dz and dq are standard Brownian motions and where dz dq = TJzq dt (TJzq being the instantaneous coefficient of correlation between dz and dq). Individuals have two investment opportunities in this economy. One is investment in a risk-free asset with an instantaneous rate of return, r(t), and the other is investment in a risky capital asset, which may be viewed as a real production possibility. The consideration of this two-asset case proves convenient because it provides a well-defined measure of risk taking, given by the portfolio share of the single risky asset. Moreover, under certain conditions (such as with a constant consumption and invest­ ment opportunity set or with logarithmic utility functions), the continu­ ous-time version of the Sharp-Lintner-Mossin capital asset pricing model (CAPM) obtains, and all individuals will hold the market portfolio, so that the many-asset case can be simplified as if the market were the only risky asset. The price of this risky asset can be modeled as an Ito process: dP = aPdt + aPdz, (1) where a and a are the instantaneous mean and standard deviation of the rate of return on the risky asset. With constant a and a, equation (1) implies that the price of the risky asset is log-normally distributed. The flow of stochastic real wage income can be written as dY = fl.y Ydt + ay Ydq. (2) Consider an individual who lives for T years and whose preference is described by a time-additive state-independent utility function, U[c(t), L (t)]. Assume that U[c(t), L(t)] exhibits the standard properties of monotonicity and concavity in consumption and leisure: that is, Uc > 0, u�. > 0, Ucc < 0, and u�.�. < 0, where the subscripts on U denote the first-order and second-order partial derivatives with respect to c(t) and L(t), respectively. At each point in time during the life cycle, the risk-averse individual chooses the rate of consumption c(t), the current leisure L(t), and a portfolio rule through which he or she can transfer wealth over time and across the states of nature.3 Let w(t) denote the proportion of wealth to 3 This paper abstracts from the individual's retirement decision so that the indi­ vidual has an active working life until the termination date T. The retirement problem has been extensively studied in the public finance and labor economics literature, see Diamond and Mirrlees (1978). One can similarly explore the problem of retirement with uncertainty ill this continuous-time framework. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution RISK TAKING, TAXATION, AND HUMAN CAPITAL 625 be invested in the risky asset. The general problem of intertemporal optimization is max E0 J T U(C, L,) dt subject to a budget equation, 0 (3) where Eo denotes the expectation conditional on the information avail­ able at time 0. With income derived from human capital, dl, the budget constraint can be written as a stochastic differential equation:4 dW = {[w(a - r) + r]W - c}dt + d! + wWcrdz. (4) Assume that labor income is subject to a proportional tax rate ,., with the government tax revenue being used to finance a public good that enters the utility function separately. If the individual consumes a fixed amount of leisure r and wage flow is deterministic (that is, dY Y(t) dt), then the stream of after-tax labor income is dl = 6(1 - L)Y(t) dt, where 6 = ( 1 - T). Thus, the problem of equation (3) reduces to one with a single consumption good and with exogenous risk-free labor income. Defining the derived utility function of wealth as = J(W,t) = maxE, r U[c(t), L(t)]dt I (5) and the Bellman equation as 0 = max [ U[c(t), L] C.OJ + J, + lw{[w(a - r) + r]W 1 + 6(1 - L )Y - c}dt + 2 lww w·? W2ll, (6) one can write the first-order conditions for this problem: Uc = lw, 0 = lw(a - r) + lwwwWa2, (7) (8) where the subscripts on U and J denote partial derivatives with respect to c, W, and t, respectively. From equation (8), the share of the portfolio in the risky asset can be written as lw a - r w* - - -- -(9) - Wlww cr2 In general, the optimal proportion of wealth held in the risky asset depends on the investor's risk preference, wealth endowment, and age as well as on the parameters of the returns on traded assets a, r, and cr2. 4 See Merton (1971) for a detailed derivation. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 626 ZUUU HU The individual's investment in the risky asset is determined by his or her desire to attain a preferred risk-return trade-off in wealth. The more risk the smaller averse is the individual (the smaller the term is his or her portfolio share in the risky asset. On the other hand, the larger the premium on the market, a - r, or the smaller the market risk, cr' the larger is the proportion of his or her wealth that the individual will hold in the risky asset. Note that a labor income tax affects the optimal portfolio demand by changing individuals' risk-averse behavior and total wealth. To see this, consider the case of a utility function with constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) of consumption.5 Merton (1971) first derived explicit consump­ tion and portfolio rules for the CRRA utility function: 9(1 - L)Y{1 - exp(r(t = + (10) ' cr 8 r -lwi[Wlww]), T)]}] w*W �[ w where is the reciprocal of the relative risk aversion of consumption. Let WH denote the value of human capital; then, - T))} WH = J,r exp(-r(s - t)]ds = Y{1 - exp(r(t (11) r 8 Y, . In other words, the value of human capital is the present value of the lifetime flow of maximal labor income discounted at the risk-free market rate of interest. The crucial point here is that although human capital is not directly traded the individual can, in effect, sell his or her risk-free future labor income for present consumption by trading (shortselling) financial assets. Thus, equation (10) can be rendered w*W = a - r (W + 9(1 - L )WH]· (12) If there is only investment income (WH 0), the individual will wish to maintain a constant share of the risky asset, w*, in his or her portfolio cr2 8 - = over the life cycle. Then, the demand function for the risky asset is linear in the level of wealth. Thus, one obtains the usual separation theorem, wruch states that w* should be independent of the investor's wealth and age for the case of the CRRA utility function. If the individual also receives labor income, he or she will treat his or her net worth of human capital as an addition to the current stock of wealth, and the inQ.ividual's portfolio share of the risky asset will be age dependent. The individual is willing to take more risk by investing more in the risky asset when he or she is young since the value of human capital is greatest in the early 5Tbe constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) or isoelastic utility function belongs to the family of hyperbolic absolute risk-aversion utility functions. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution RISK TAKING, TAXATION, AND HUMAN CAPITAL 627 stage of Life. As a person gets older, his or her ratio of WH to W will decline, and he or she will take a smaller position in the risky asset. A labor income tax reduces the value of human capital and therefore decreases an individual's holding of the risky asset. Fiscal policy is not neutral with respect to the individual's risk-taking behavior. A current tax cut matched by a future tax increase tends to encourage invest­ ment in the risky asset. Since the government does not share the invest­ ment risk faced by private agents through a labor income tax, total (social) risk taking must also be reduced. II. Interaction Between Labor Supply and Portfolio Choice This section introduces the labor-leisure choice into the individual's decision problem but continues to assume that income from human capital is nonstochastic. The individual's problem now is max £0 s.t. dW = JT U(c,, L,) dt (13) 0 {[w(a - r) + r] + 0(1 - L)Y - c}dt + crwWdz . From the Bellman equation, 0 = max[U(c, L) + J, + J111{[w(a - r) + r]W 2 1 + 0(1 - L)Y - c} + 2lww cr w W2D, (14) the first-order conditions are Uc = lw (15) and = OYlw. Combining equations (15) and (16) gives UL = eYUc. UL (16) (17) Differentiate equation (17) with respect to T and assume that U is sepa­ rable in c and L; then, dL dT ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution (18) 628 ZULIU HU Thus, an uncompensated increase in the tax on riskless labor income unambiguously discourages the individual's labor supply when his or her preference is separable in the consumption good and leisure. The optimal demand for the risky asset given by the first-order condi­ tions takes the same form as equation (9). To derive a closed-form solution, a two-stage procedure is used. First, solve the following static optimization problem at each t: max V[c(t), L(t)] dt s.t. C = c + eYL. (19) Define U(C,t) = V[c* (C,t),L*(C, t)]. Because real wages are non­ stochastic, there is no intertemporal uncertainty in the price of leisure relative to the consumption good. Therefore U( C, t) remains state inde­ pendent. Then proceed to solve the following dynamic optimization problem: max £0 s.t. dW = r U(C , t ) dt {[w(a - r) + r]W + eY - C}dt + wWadz. (20) Note that the leisure variable, L(t), no longer enters the budget con­ straint in equation (20). The problem now is formally identical to the one with a single consumption good. For a CRRA utility function, the optimal portfolio rule has the familiar form: w**W = a;;'6r (W + eWH), (21) where wfl is given by equation (11). Note that w** > w*. For the same ratio of human wealth to current wealth, the individual takes more risk with an elastic labor supply than with a labor supply fixed at (1 - L).6 Intuitively, the ability to adjust labor supply conditional on investment performance provides insurance for the individual's investment risk. The effect of a proportional labor income tax, however, is to reduce private (and therefore social) risk taking, as in the case with fixed labor supply. 6ln a closely related analysis, Bodie, Merton, and Samuelson (1992) show that the ability to vary labor supply ex post induces the individual to assume greater risks in his or her investment portfolio ex ante. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution RISK TAKING, TAXATION, AND HUMAN CAPITAL 629 ill . Uncertain Income from Human Capital The presence of risky income from human capital complicates the problem in two ways. First, it introduces uncertainty into the relative price of leisure (denominated in the consumption good). As a result, the utility function becomes state dependent, with the state variable repre­ sented by the wage variable, such that U = U(C, Y, t), where Cis rede­ fined from equation (19) as the consumer's aggregate expenditure, inclu­ sive of the value of leisure measured in terms of the consumption good. Second, the presence of risky labor income has a wealth effect. It affects the dynamics of wealth accumulation, so that both the drift and the diffusion terms in the investor's budget constraint are modified. Assume that the stochastic behavior of wage income is as specified in equation (2): the wage income follows the geometric Brownian motion.' Formally, the stochastic dynamic programming problem is max Eo r U[C(t), Y(t), t] dt (22) s.t. dW = {[w(a - r) + r]W + 6Yfl.y - C}dt + crwW dz + 6Ycrydq. From the Bellman equation, 0 = max[U(C, Y,t) + It + fw{[w(a - r) + r]W + 6Yfl.y - C} 1 + ]y 6Yfl.y + 2 fww(w2� Wl + 2wW6Ycr,q + 62 Y2cr;) (23) where CTzq = crcry "Y"Jzq is the covariance between the return on the risky asset and income from human capital. Then, the first-order conditions follow: Uc(C* , Y, t) = lw(W,Y,t); (24) and 7Merton {1971) solves a problem in which the wage income is given exoge­ nously and is a Poisson process. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 630 ZULIU HU The optimal demand for the risky asset can now be derived: w*W = JY '.v 6Y�. (- lw )�- 6Y� - lww lww rr rr rr (26) The optimal demand for the risky asset consists ofthree terms. The first term, (-lwllww)(a - r) la.z, is the usual speculative demand for the mean-variance maximizer.8 The second term, -6Ya,qla2 , is a labor income hedging demand. The last term, -6Y(1Y'.vflww)(a,qlrr), is the state-variable hedging demand. These hedging terms arise from the nontradability of risky human capital. When the individual has human capital income as well as financial investment income, the risk of human capital income will play a role in determining his or her optimal portfolio behavior. In other words, the interaction between the human capital risk and the financial risk will affect the individual's optimal holding of the risky asset. Compared with the case of riskless labor income in the previ­ ous sections, one can see that now, in addition to holding the risky market portfolio to attain the desired risk-return trade-off in wealth, the individ­ ual also uses the risky market portfolio to hedge against the unanticipated and possibly unfavorable changes in his or her labor income. From the first-order condition (24), Vee aC laW = lww (27) Vee aC laY + Vey = lwy. (28) and If Vey = 0-that is, the direct utility function is state independent­ then JWY!lww = (aC laY) l(aC laW) > 0, because the propensities to con­ sume out of income and wealth are both positive. Then, the signs of both the hedging terms depend on the sign of the covariances between the return on the risky asset and wage income, azq· If the return on the risky asset and that on wage income are negatively correlated ('l'Jzq < 0), the existence of the risky human capital income produces a positive hedging effect on the demand for the risky asset. The same observation was made by Fischer (1975) in his exposition on demand for indexed bonds with a state-independent utility function. Since a(w*W) a,. = Y rr ( 1 + lww JY'.v) zq ' (29) (] 8 With continuous trading, the r isk premium on the traded asset, a r, is determined by Breeden's (1979) consumption f3 model even with the existence of nontraded human capital, as long as both the asset prices and the consumption rate follow the Ito processes, as shown by Grossman and Shiller (1982). - ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution RISK TAKING, TAXATION, AND HUMAN CAPITAL 631 the effects of labor income taxation on risk taking will in general depend on the covariance of human capital risk and physical capital risk. The standard result under riskless real wage income no longer holds for the more general case of an uncertain income stream from human capital. If wages and the return on investment in physical capital are negatively correlated, then a proportional labor income tax will reduce the hedging demand for the risky asset. Because part of the labor income risk is now shifted to the government,9 the individual then needs less of the risky asset in order to hedge the risk of nontradable human capital. If the instantaneous rate of return on the risky financial asset is posi­ tively correlated with the unanticipated changes in wage income ('Tlzq > 0), then the individual's hedging demand for the risky asset is nega­ tive: reverse hedging occurs. A labor income tax will actually encourage risk taking in this case. If the return on the risky asset and that on wage income are uncorre­ lated (TJzq 0), then both the hedging terms in equation (26) will vanish. In this case, the individual's labor income risk is idiosyncratic. Holding the risky financial asset cannot provide insurance against unanticipated changes in labor income. Although the idiosyncratic labor income risk will affect the individual's risk aversion and consumption behavior, it does not affect his or her demand for the risky asset. 10 Therefore, the hedging demand for the risky asset will be zero. In this case, the only mechanism for sharing and pooling individuals' idiosyncratic labor income risk is the government's taxation on labor income. Which of these possibilities is empirically more relevant remains a subject for further research. Fama and Schwert (1977) study the role of human capital in the classical CAPM. They found that the relationships between the returns on human capital and the returns on various port­ folios of traded assets are weak, so that the presence of human capital does not significantly affect the measurement of risk for traded capital assets. However, as the authors themselves acknowledged, their results cannot be viewed as definitive because of a number of measurement and estimation problems. In addition to these hedging effects, the existence of labor income also produces a wealth effect. The risky stream of labor income, when appro­ priately capitalized, is treated as part of wealth in the consumption and portfolio demand functions. = 9 Implicitly, it is assumed that the tax code contains full loss-offset provisions. A lthough the idiosyncratic labor income risk itself does not affect the demand for the risky asset, the presence of human capital and labor income taxation will still produce a wealth effect and financial risk taking will be affected. 10 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 632 ZULIU HU IV. Optimal Taxation with Nontradable Risky Labor Income The analysis above points to the importance of the interaction between the risks of financial assets and those of human capital income. The individual will invest more of his or her wealth in the risky capital asset if the return on the asset is negatively correlated with his or her labor income. In effect, the financial market can provide insurance against the labor income risk. This interaction between the individual's nonhuman capital risk and human capital risk will, in addition to its effects on portfolio choice and risk-taking behavior, have implications for efficient income taxation, to which the discussion now turns. Because human capital is nontradable, it clearly improves welfare to have some kind of social scheme that pools and shares the human capital risk when the private market fails to provide insurance instruments for individuals to hedge against the uncertain stream of labor income. The government, through its ability to tax, can play precisely such a role in diversifying the idiosyncratic human capital risk. Indeed, it is tempting to suggest a 100 percent wage tax combined with a lump-sum transfer. In reality, however, this type of public insurance program is unlikely to work because of its disincentive effect on labor supply. Therefore, one needs jointly to consider the insurance and efficiency aspects of labor income taxation. Assume that a large number of individuals in the economy are identical in preferences, beliefs, initial endowments, and abilities, so that varia­ tions in labor income arise only from differences in "luck. "1 1 In other words, the random fluctuations in labor income are caused by "idiosyn­ cratic" risks that are uncorrelated among individuals. Formally, for each individual i, the uncertain stream of wage income is represented by equation (2), with dq;dz Tlqzdt, Vi and dq;dqj = 0, Vi :/= j. Consider a representative consumer who chooses his or her optimal consumption, labor supply, and portfolio share at each point in time, taking the tax rate on labor income, -r, as given. The individual essentially faces the following problem: = max £0 Lr U[C(t), L(t)] dt (30) s.t. dW = {[w(a - r) + r]W + 6(1 - L)Y!-1-r - c}dt + wW<Tdz + 6(1 - L)Ycrydq. 11 Stiglitz (1982) examines the problem of Pareto-efficient taxation when indi­ viduals differ in their productivities and the government has imperfect informa­ tion about the "true" distribution of abilities across people. The assumption here is similar to that employed by Barsky, Mankiw, and Zeldes (1986), who examine the interaction between individual income uncertainty and income taxation in the face of a debt-financed tax cut. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution RISK TAKING, TAXATION, AND HUMAN CAPITAL 633 One can write the following first-order conditions with respect to c, L, and w, respectively: U, = lw, (31) UL = 6Yf..Lylw + [wW6Ya,q + 82 Yl(l - L)a;]Jww, (32) and wW = -� .!.:t:_ - 8Y(l - L) �� ' � lww (33) where e 1 T' where J = J(W' t) is the derived utility function of wealth, and where O"zq = aay lJ:q is the covariance between the individual's financial risk and human capital risk. How might the uncertainty about future wage income affect an individ­ ual's labor supply decision? To see this, consider some simple cases. Substituting equation (33) into the first-order condition (32), = - [ UL = eY f..Ly - ? (a - r)] lw + 82 Yl(1 - L*)a; (1 - l);q)lww· (34) Suppose that the individual's utility function is additively separable in the consumption good and leisure. If the individual's human capital risk and financial risk are perfectly correlated (that is, IYJzql = 1), then differentiating equation (34) with respect to T gives [ - 2 (a - r) J a aL * ULL- = -Ylw f..Lr aT a :::.El . (35) Note that the term in the square bracket is positive. To see why, imagine there is a traded asset that replicates the income from a unit of human capital. At equilibrium, this traded asset is priced by the continuous-time CAPM: f..Ly - r = ?<a - r), (36) where f..Ly is the instantaneous rate of return on the traded asset. It is then easy to see that the square-bracketed term in equation (35) is positive when the rate of return on the riskless asset r is greater than zero. According to the standard assumptions about the utility function U[c(t), L(t)], it can be established from equation (35) that aL* faT > 0. Therefore, just as in the case of risk-free labor income, an increase in the proportional wage tax will unambiguously reduce labor supply when the labor income risk and investment income risk are perfectly correlated. If, as a polar case, the human capital risk and the financial risk are ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 634 ZULIU HU uncorrelated ('llzq = 0), then differentiating equation (34) with respect to ,. gives iJL* (ULL + 02 Jl2o-;lww) a:;:- = [ - Ylw J.Ly _ 20o-; Y(1 ;L*) ( _ wj;v)] . (37) Equation (37) clearly shows the possibility of a positive response of labor supply to an increase in the proportional wage tax. The greater the nondiversifiable labor income risk, the larger the share of current labor income in wealth, and the more risk-averse the individual, then the more likely it is that the right-hand side of equation (37) will turn positive and that the individual will increase his or her labor supply in the face of a higher wage tax. This surprising result arises because the government's taxation of income provides insurance against the individual's labor income risk. Suppose that the government chooses a linear income tax schedule. At each point in time, the government taxes each individual's labor income at the proportional rate ,. and makes a lump-sum income transfer dS(t) to each individual. The government faces the following intertemporal budget constraint: dS = ,.(1 - L)E,(dY) - dG = ,.(1 - L)YJ.Lrdt - dG, (38) where dG is the government revenue requirement. The government wishes to maximize the representative consumer's lifetime utility given its budget constraint (38) so as to determine the optimal tax rate ,.*. In other words, max £0 r U[C(t), L(t)] dt (39) s.t. dW = {[w(a - r) + r]W + 0(1 - L)YJ.Ly - c}dt + dS + wWo-dz + 0(1 - L)Yo-ydq. From the Bellman equation, the first-order condition with respect to ,. is iJL* iJL* Vca;- = {YJ.Lyfw + OY[wW<T,q + OY(1 - L*)cr;)Jww}a:;:+ Y(1 - L*)[wWa,q + OY(l - L*)a;]fww· (40) The other two first-order conditions with respect to c and w are not ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution RISK TAKING, TAXATION, AND HUMAN CAPITAL 635 presented here because they take the same forms as equations (31) and (33). Using these first-order conditions from the individual's maximization problem, one can, after some manipulations, obtain ,.y1-Lyfw 2 )lww iJL* e u '2( 1 * )2 2 (1 - "Tlzq a:;:- + I- - L IJy c:x. - r 2 IJzq Y(1 - L* )Jw = 0. - -(j (41) Let F(T) denote the left-hand side of equation (41). Obviously F depends on the interaction between the labor income risk and financial risk ("Tlzq) as well as on the labor income risk itself (1J;). Suppose that individuals' labor income is risk free (<1, = 0), then F(O) = 0. That is to say, the optimal taxation structure implies a zero tax rate on wages if labor supply is elastic and if individuals do not face human capital risk; this is for the usual reason that, under certainty, one can have lump-sum taxation when all individuals are identical. In general, a zero tax on wages cannot be optimal. Consider the case when the human capital risk and financial risk are uncorrelated ("Tlzq 0). The expression of F becomes = (42) Because evaluating F at T = 0 gives F(O) = Y2(1 - L*)21J;_,ww < 0, (43) the first-order condition cannot be satisfied at a zero tax rate. In fact, if F(T) = 0, then equation (41) yields T* l w'--L *"'---'Y2)(1 w "'----' '-'....:.;_:; - )2if (iJL * 2 YJ.Lyfwa:;:- - Y2( 1 - L * )2IJ>Jww = - (44) Therefore, if labor supply responds negatively to changes in the wage tax (iJL * /iJT > 0), the optimal marginal tax rate should lie strictly between 0 and 1 . For the case of perfect correlation, it is straightforward to show that 0 < T* < 1 if "Tlzq = + 1 and that it may be optimal to have a wage subsidy, T* < 0 if "Tlzq = - 1 . Therefore, even when individuals can diversify the risk of human capital by holding a risky financial capital asset, the optimal tax on their labor income is usually not zero. These results closely parallel those obtained by Eaton and Rosen ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 636 ZULIU HU (1980), who use a static model of uncertainty with endogenous labor supply. 12 They do not consider the interaction between investment risk and wage risk because the nonlabor income in their paper is assumed to be nonstochastic. V. Conclusion This paper has reexamined the effects of taxation on risk taking and on labor supply in a continuous-time life-cycle model. It has shown that the existence of income from human capital has systematic effects on individuals' optimal portfolio choice and that the risk and nontradability of human capital have implications for an efficient income tax structure. Further work, especially empirical study, is needed to better understand how taxation affects individuals' lifetime saving and portfolio decisions. REFERENCES Barsky, Robert, Gregory Mankiw, and Stephen Zeldes, "Ricardian Consumers with Keynesian Propensities," American Economic Review , Vol. 76 (1986), pp. 676-91. Bodie, Zvi, Robert C. Merton, and William F. Samuelson, "Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Choice in a Life Cycle Model," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 16 (1992), pp. 427-49. Breeden, Douglas, "An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Con­ sumption and Investment Opportunities," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 7 (1979), pp. 265-96. Diamond, Peter, and James Mirrlees, "A Mode of Social Insurance With Variable Retirement," Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 10 (1978), pp. 295-336. Domar, E.D., and Richard A. Musgrave, "Proportional Income Taxation and Risk Taking," Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, Vol. 58 (1944), pp. 388-422. Dreze, Jean, and Franco Modigiani, l "Consumptions Decisions Under Uncer­ tainty," Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 5 (1972), pp. 308-35. Eaton, Jonathan, and Harvey S. Rosen, "Labor Supply, Uncertainty, and Effi­ cient Taxation," Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 14 (1980), pp. 365-74. Fama, Eugene, and William Schwert, "Human Capital and Capital Market Equilibrium," Journal of Financial Economics , Vol. 4 (1977), pp. 95-125. Feldstein, Martin, "The Effects of Taxation on Risk-Taking," Journal ofPolitical Economy, Vol. 7 (1969), pp. 755-64. 12 Varian (1980) also examines the social insurance aspect of redistributive taxation in a static model of uncertainty. He does not explicitly consider the incentive effect of taxation on labor supply. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution RISK TAKING, TAXATION, AND HUMAN CAPITAL 637 , "Personal Taxation and Portfolio Composition: An Econometric Anal­ ysis," Econometrica, Vol. 44 (1976), pp. 631-50. Fischer, Stanley, "The Demand for Index Bonds," Journal ofPolitical Economy , Vol. 83 (1975), pp. 509-34. Grossman, Sanford, and Robert Shiller, "Consumption Correlatedness and Risk Measurement in Economies with Non-traded Assets and Heterogenous Information," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 10 (1982), pp. 195-210. Hamilton, Jonathan, "Taxation, Savings, and Portfolio Choices in a Continuous Time Model," Finances Publiques/Public Finance, Vol. 42 (1987), pp. 264-82. Merton, Robert, "Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous­ Time Model," Journal of Economic Theory , Vol. 3 (December 1971), pp. 373-413. Mossin, Jan, "Taxation and Risk-Taking: An Expected Utility Approach," Eco­ noniica, Vol. 35 (1968), pp. 74-82. Sandmo, Agnar, "Capital Risk, Consumption, and Portfolio Choice," Econo­ metrica, Vol. 37 (1969), pp. 586-99. Stiglitz, Joseph, "The Effects of Income, Wealth and Capital Gains Taxation on Risk-Taking," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 83 (1969), pp. 262-83. , "Self-Selection and Pareto Efficient Taxation," Journal of Public Eco­ nomics, Vol. 17 (1982), pp. 213-40. Tobin, James, "Liquidity Preferences as Behavior Towards Risk," Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 25 (1958), pp. 65-86. Varian, H.R., "Redistributive Taxation as Social Insurance," Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 14 (1980), pp. 49-68. Williams, J., "Risk, Human Capital, and the Investor's Portfolio," Journal of Business, Vol. 51 (1978), pp. 65-89. --, "Uncertainty and the Accumulation of Human Capital over the Life Cycle," Journal of Business , Vol. 52 (1979), pp. 521-48. -- --- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF Staff Papers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) @ 1993 International Monetary Fund Cash-Flow Tax PARTHASARATHI $HOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE* The cash-flow tax has been proposed as an alternative to the corporate income tax on grounds that it would define the tax base more clearly and more simply in the face of widespread departures from the comprehensive income tax of actual practice. The cash-flow tax, and its variants, would require careful design. Simplicity may prove elusive because ofanticipated administrative problems related to tax avoidance and evasion through transfer pricing, to inflation adjustments, and to incompatibility with exist­ ing international tax regimes. Thus, the tax remains theoretically attractive but difficult to implement. [JEL H24, H25, H87] surveys some practical issues relating to an alternative Tform of corporate taxation: the cash-flow tax. Cash-flow taxation HIS PAPER 1 has long been discussed as an alternative to the taxation of income, both at the personal and the corporate levels. There has been a renewed policy interest in such proposals recently, motivated by long-standing concep­ tual arguments and increasingly by administrative reasons. It is argued that despite a renaissance of the comprehensive income tax as an ideal in many tax reform endeavors of the· 1980s, it is only poorly approxi­ mated in the existing tax codes. Cash-flow taxation might be a viable alternative to the "uneasy compromise" (Aaron, Galper, and Pechman (1988)) of a "hybrid income-consumption tax." * Partbasarathi Shome is Chief of the Tax Policy Division in the IMF's Fiscal Affairs Department. Christian Schutte was a summer intern in 1992 in the same division when the paper was written; at the time, he was pursuing a master's degree at the Kennedy School of Government at Harvard University. The authors would like to thank Milka Casanegra de Jantscher, Ved Gandhi, David N�ll?r, . and Howell Zee for many helpful comments. Remammg Emil Sunley, Vito Tanzt, errors are the responsibility of the authors. 1 In the literature, the tax is sometimes referred to as the Brown tax, after its first classic proponent Brown (1948). 638 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 639 Conceptually, cash-flow taxation is based on consumption; thus, it is neutral with respect to capital formation. The practical advantages of cash-flow taxation-its definitional clarity and its simplicity of measure­ ment-were first forcefully argued by Andrews (1974), as weU as dis­ cussed in a U.S. Treasury report (1977). Perhaps they have received more interest recently as tax theorists have come to emphasize the implemen­ tation and administration of tax policy (Kay (1990), Slemrod (1990), and, for developing countries, Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and Shah (1991)). The classic Haig-Simons ideal of a comprehensive income tax, based on consumption plus net accrual of wealth, seems to be rather problematic when judged by these criteria. It has been argued that the hypothetical nature of the accrual concept tends to create complexities in the tax code, increase the burden of administration and compliance, and foster avoid­ ance and distortion (Kay (1990), p. 67). Under these circumstances, a cash-flow tax seems a promising alternative especially at the corporate level, where equity concerns about exemption of capital income are irrelevant and where some technical problems are less salient. 2 Opponents of the cash-flow tax question the superiority of its tax base on equity grounds. Also, they are usually not optimistic about the admin­ istrative advantages of the tax. Regarding the corporate sector, they decry it primarily because of implementation problems and the Jack of international experience and coordination. The doubts emanate from perceived difficulties in containing tax evasion, because of transfer­ pricing practices, and tax avoidance, because of intracompany leasing arrangements, as well as because the tax may not be creditable in those countries that export capital until they themselves introduce the tax. Therefore, the tax may not be compatible with the existing international tax regime. In addition, political forces that lead to the erosion of the corporate income tax (CIT) base are also likely to affect the corporate cash-flow tax (CCFf) base. Although the cash-flow tax may address some inherent shortcomings of the income tax, it is not any less vulner­ able to the political pressures working to undermine the system through special provisions and targeted incentives.3 The objective of this paper is to survey some of the practical problems 2 Among the problems confined to personal taxation are the treatment of consumer durables, education, and gifts and bequests. For a discussion of these and other problems of a cash flow-based personal consumption tax, see Pechman (1980). 3 For instance, claims have been made that the CCFf is "an alternative way to attain the obj ective of fiscal neutrality without a significant erosion of the tax base" (King (1986), p. 2) and that it "avoids the Eroblem of targeted incentives; the need to pick winners and losers" (McLure (1991), p. 15). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 640 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE associated with the introduction of a CCFf-namely, its effects on rev­ enue, the possibilities for tax avoidance and evasion, the international compatibility of the tax, and transition issues. We begin by discussing the conceptual background of the tax and pointing to some of the advantages and disadvantages that arise from its definition. We next assess the CCFf on practical grounds rather than on its conceptual merit, addressing issues that would arise in the transition to a CCFf, as well as consider­ ations of a more general nature. Among the latter are the revenue effects arising from the CCFf's impact on investment, the often express�d preoccupations regarding increased tax avoidance and evasion, and the implications of the relatively uncoordinated cross-country tax arrange­ ments that currently prevail. However, many of the difficulties associated with administration of the cash-flow tax are not reviewed in any detail. Finally, many middle-income developing countries, especially in Latin America, are considering the introduction of a cash-flow tax. Therefore, the paper, at several points, gives specific consideration to issues relevant for them. I. Conceptual Elements Conceptually, the CCFf has been discussed as a supplement to a personal expenditure tax, a personal income tax, and a value-added tax (VAT), and as a tax on economic rent. The CCFf base also varies in conception, reflecting whether real transactions or real and financial transactions are taxed. These and related issues are discussed below. What Is a CCFf? Although the focus seems to have shifted over time, the CCFf rests within a tradition of consumption tax proposals (Sunley (1989)). Thus, it is usually advocated first as a supplement to a personal expenditure tax (ET) that is designed (1) to withhold tax on economic rents and nonwage labor income,4 (2) to discourage evasion of the ET by individuals through business activities, and (3) to capture foreign capital income. It would also curtail the windfall capital gains accruing to shareholders if an ET were adopted. Second, the CCFf has been discussed as a separate corporate tax alongside a personal income tax system. Such a system would fall short of the ideal consumption tax "package." But given the difficulties of an 4Note here its similarity to the value-added tax, a point taken up below. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 641 ET, a CCFf may be a second-best alternative, correcting the administra­ tive and economic shortcomings of the CIT (Mintz and Seade (1991), King (1986)). Third, the CCFT was suggested, in an array of variants, as a tax on economic rent. For example, it has been recommended as an ideal resource tax (Garnaut and Clunies Ross (1983)). 5 Fourth, there seems to be an argument for combining the cash-flow tax with the VAT. Thus, if a VAT is calculated using the subtraction method, the same tax return could be used to deduct wages and investment in order to compute the cash-flow tax. The following discussion is not confined to any particular form of the CCFf. For practical purposes, the most relevant option seems to be the CCFT as a complement to a personal income tax. However, most of the points raised will be equally valid for other variants. CCFr Tax Base Following Meade (1978), there are three types of CCFTs: -The R-based CCFT is one in which the tax base is net real trans­ actions-that is, the difference between sales and purchases of real goods and services. As opposed to an income tax, the distinctive features of such a tax base are the immediate expensing of capital outlays and the nondeductibility of interest payments. At the same time, interest received is no longer taxable. -The RF-based CCFT (real plus financial) is one that also includes nonequity financial transactions-that is, the difference between borrow­ ing and lending. Interest and retirement of debt would be deductible, but borrowing and interest received would be taxable: RF base = (sales + borrowing + interest received) - (purchases + interest paid + debt repaid). -The S-based CCFT taxes the net flow from the corporation to shareholders-that is, S (dividends paid + purchases of shares issues of new shares).6 The S base is conceptually equivalent to the RF base minus the CCFT, as can be seen from a basic accounting identity: any difference between total business inflows and outflows has to be paid out either to shareholders or as tax, RF = S + CCFT. Since taxes enter = 5 Cash flow-based rent resource taxes have actually been used for mining l?rojects in Papua New Guinea, Tanzania, and several other developing countries ( Garnaut and Clunies Ross (1983)). 6 Since share transactions between corporations cancel out, the aggregate S base represents the net flow from the corporate sector to shareholders. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 642 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTrE into the sources and uses-of-funds statement, the rate of the RF-based tax would be tax inclusive. The S-based rate would be tax exclusive-it could well be higher than 100 percent. The S base was favored by Meade (1978) because it was perceived as administratively simpler. However, the conceptually equivalent RF base is closer to current tax base configurations and is therefore more com­ monly discussed as an alternative to the CIT. Nevertheless, an R-based CCFT system has been advocated recently by McLure (1991) and by McLure and others (1990), who suggest it as part of a simplified alternative tax, which is essentially a consumption-flow tax for business and personal taxation. McLure argues that the exclusion of financial transactions makes an R-based tax easy to administer. On the other hand, the exclusion of the financial sector from the R-based CCFT is an obvious drawback. Further, it increases the problems of transition and seems particularly prone to tax avoidance schemes, points that are elaborated upon later. Selected Characteristics A classic interpretation of the CCFT is that government acts as a "silent partner" in an investment (Brown (1948)). This is most clearly seen for the S base where the government sustains tax losses from the equity raised and receives revenue from the distributed earnings. Alternatively, with immediate expensing and a tax rate tc, capital outlays K produce a tax loss of tcK· This can be interpreted as a reduction in the corporation's own investment outlay, so that its effective financing becomes (1 - tc)K. If one assumes a constant tax rate, government will then share a proportion tc of all subsequent inflows. As outflows and inflows for the corporation are reduced proportionately by the "silent partnership," the rate of return on an investment remains unaffected by taxation. The "silent partnership" enables the government to appropriate a share of the above-normal returns that are generated in the economy. Those returns may be economic rents from entrepreneurial activity, from nonrenewable resources, or from monopoly, but can also be investors' compensation for risks, which on average will be positive. Hence, the CCFT can also be interpreted as a tax on pure profits and on returns to risk taking (Stiglitz (1976)). For marginal projects that just cover the opportunity cost of capital, the present values of initial tax losses and of subsequent CCFT payments just offset each other.7 'For illustration, consider a simple two-period investment project of K 1, which yields a pretax return of r. The present value of the CCFT payments from = ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 643 The marginal effective tax rate of zero is a crucial implication of the CCFf. The tax is neutral with respect to the employment of capital. In itself, the tax would not discourage any project that might have been undertaken in its absence. From a theoretical perspective, there are a number of other attractive features of a CCFf (King (1986)): -The exemption of marginal returns implicit in immediate expensing does not discriminate between debt and equity.8 The income tax favors debt over equity by allowing deduction of interest only. Partial inte­ gration of corporate and personal income taxation does not solve this problem as long as there is a substantial spread between marginal investor tax rates. -Immediate expensing also ensures neutrality with respect to the rank ordering of projects. Under the income tax, any divergences between the profiles of "economic" and "tax" depreciation-which are virtually inevitable-result in positive or negative tax wedges that distort this ordering (Samuelson (1964)). -Except for situations of hyperinflation (where even annual expens­ ing faUs short of a full deduction of real investment), the cost of capital is not affected by inflation under the CCFf. -If the CCFf is introduced alongside a personal income tax, there is no need to integrate the two taxes. Because capital income is effectively exempt at the corporate level under the CCFf, the appropriate treatment would be the classical system under which the corporation is treated as a separate entity and no effort is made to attribute its earnings to equity holders. -The CCFf is based on current transactions and hence avoids the timing problems of a typical income tax: expensing replaces the calcula­ tion of "true economic depreciation" as well as the need for an inflation adjustment of inventory and asset replacement values. The problem of capital gains is irrelevant. this project is given as (r - i)tcl(l + i), Tc = -tc + (1 + r)tc/(1 + i) (1) where -tc is the tax benefit from initial expensing and (1 + r) is the cash inflow in the second period; i is the risk-free market rate of interest, equal to the government discount rate, so that (1 + i) is the discount factor. As can be seen, revenue is raised on the difference r - i, that is, on above-normal returns. A marginal project, with r = i, is effectively untaxed. 8 Financial decisions under the CCFT may still be d istorted by the personal i , if there is differential treatment of capital gains and dividend income tax-that s income. = ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 644 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE For practical purposes, however, two critical assumptions underlying the theoretical neutrality results need to be stressed: it is assumed that tax rates are constant and that taxable inflows are always sufficient to offset expenses, so that an investment will actually produce an initial tax reduction. These points are considered next. Rates of a neutral CCFf must not be progressive and must be stable over time. The latter, especially, may be a problem, since governments have a short-run incentive to raise rates once investors have committed themselves (King ( 1986)). 9 An unexpected rate hike in itself will not affect the allocation of capital but only generates windfall-tax revenue. How­ ever, the effects of a CCFf on investment activity will depend crucially on the credibility of the government's pledge not to change rates in the future. If inflows are insufficient to offset expenses, a cash refund for unused deductions would be required to make an ideal CCFf work. Alterna­ tively, a provision to carry forward losses at an appropriate interest rate could be used to preserve the present value of the initial deduction. Following the silent-partner interpretation, one might also say that with a loss-carry forward provision the government's "equity share," tc, is effectively financed by a forced loan from the firm. For the CCFf to remain neutral, the loss then has to be carried forward at the firm's discount rate. Timing issues obviously would sneak in through the back door if loss-carry forwards are used. Grossing them by firm-specific discount rates is hardly possible. Thus, there seems to be a clear trade-off between practical and conceptual considerations in some important aspects of the application of a CCFf. II. Practical Considerations While the CCFf cannot be strongly criticized for lacking theoretical foundations, it does come up against some practical hurdles. The im­ portant practical considerations for the CCFf fall into two categories: those that involve the transition phase and those that involve its general implementation. 9 This incentive is particularly strong under the CCFf because t�ation con­ sists of two separate stages: first the government contnbutes to an mvestment by granting expensing ; then it collects revenue from the inflows. Defecting from initial tax rules after the first stage is more attractive than in the case of the income tax, where depreciation allowances and tax payments are calculated simultaneously over the lifetime of the project. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 645 Transition Issues There are numerous concerns that arise during the transition from a CIT to a CCFr. First, a "cold turkey" transition would produce windfall­ tax revenue by denying companies their existing depreciation allowances. On the other hand, allowing immediate expensing of remaining depreci­ ation could adversely affect revenue. A hybrid of allowing continued depreciation might be the only practical solution. As Sunley (1989) points out, however, such "transitional" arrangements may have to last for a number of years. Most authors (Gordon (1989), Sunley (1989)) suggest that a short-term revenue loss is likely during the transition. Various arrangements could accommodate the amortization of old investment, while new investment could generate substantial tax losses. In order to mitigate this effect, one may resort to "present value expensing" (McLure and others (1990))-­ that is, during the transitional period, deductions for new investments could be spread out over several years, grossed so that their present value would still equal the initial outlay. This obviously would raise the issue of using the right discount rate. The particular choice of the CCFT base and transitional provisions would obviously affect the financial position of firms (King (1986)). Under an R-based CCFr, leveraged firms could face financial distress because interest would no longer be deductible. Yet, continued interest deductibility for old debt might be prone to manipulation. The solution, therefore, would seem to be an RF-based CCFT. In the very short term, the tax may have undesirable announcement effects. Investment might collapse in anticipation of future expensing unless the tax can be introduced retroactively. If the prospective CCFr is RF based, firms may increase borrowing and later repay debt by raising equity. Whether retroactive enactment is possible could depend on political factors (King (1986)). General Issues Under a CCFT, issues such as the stability of revenue, a high possible incidence of tax avoidance and evasion, and international compatibility assume particular importance. These are addressed below. Revenue Implications The CIT is an important source of revenue in many developing coun­ tries. Following a bell-shaped curve, its share of GDP and total revenue ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 646 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE generally increase in the initial stages of development, 10 so that for different income groups in developing countries the CIT makes up be­ tween 1 1 and 23 percent of total the revenue. In a few cases, tax CIT accounts for more than one-fourth, even more than one-half, of total revenue (Tanzi (1990)). The revenue implications of any change in corporate taxation have to be weighed very carefully in this context-even if one were to argue that, in the long run, the CCFf is likely to foster growth through increased investment and improved capital allocation and that the government would participate in such growth. If we leave aside both the purely transitional issues and the longer-term structural and dynamic effects, what can be said about the revenue implications of the CCFf? Smaller Tax Base? There are conflicting views about the likely differ­ ences in the size of the corporate tax base under a CIT and a CCFf. The straightforward argument against the CCFf is that full and immediate expensing seems to reduce the tax base. The government forgoes tax on the marginal returns to capital, and one would therefore expect the CCFT rate to be higher than the initial income tax rate if present-value revenue is to be sustained. 11 On the other hand, proponents of the CCFf have based their case partly on the massive erosion of the tax base under the CIT (Kay (1990), King (1986)). They argue that most marginal returns escape taxation anyway. Firms find it advantageous to finance their investments through debt, as nominal interest payments are deductible. Foreign investors may choose "thin capitalization" to shield their income from host country taxation and to facilitate repatriation. Legislative rules against excessive interest deductions often are not fully effective. Firms may also avoid taxation of capital income by making use of special incentives, such as accelerated depreciation, tax arbitraging, tax-preferred activities, and investing abroad. 10 11 In industrial countries, the CIT has become relatively unimportant over time. If total returns r constitute the tax base of the CIT, above-normal returns (r i) form the base of the CCFf, I; and lc are the respective tax rates, and T; and X are the present value of revenue under both taxes, then revenue neutrality requiring Tc T; implies tc(r - i) = I1 r . - = Thus, the revenue-neutral CCFf rate is lc l;[rl(r i)]. = - The right-hand expression in brackets, which is the ratio of total returns to above-normal returns, will obviously decrease for increasing r, as above-normal tion of total returns. If the CIT allows initial returns make up an increasingpropor expensing of a proportion a ( 0:s a < 1), its base reduces to (r - ai): that is, the necessary rate increase will also be smaller. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 647 The tractitional view of the CIT as a tax on the use of capital in the corporate sector becomes questionable. According to the "new view," the CIT is instead a tax on immobile production opportunities in the corporate sector. The CCFT is the "logical counterpart" (Kay (1990), p. 29) of this "new view," since it would tax the same base while elimi­ nating the excess burden of the present system, for example, by restoring debt-equity neutrality . 12 Empirical work on developed countries suggests that the CCFT and the current income tax base would not be very different in many cases. Assuming unchanged behavior on the part of firms, and ignoring tran­ sitional issues, several rough estimates of the potential yield from a CCFT in the United Kingdom, the United States, and Canada indicate that even for stable tax rates the revenue loss should not be a serious problem (King (1986), Daly, Jung, and Schweitzer (1986)). Gordon and Slemrod (1988) found that by 1983 the U.S. tax code offered so many tax arbitraging opportunities that exemption of capital income through adop­ tion of a "pure" cash-flow tax would have increased revenue, even after transitional losses were taken into account. 13 In developing countries where the corporate sector is dominated by large mineral exporters, local cartels, monopolies, and debt-financed foreign corporations, the existing CIT may also be fairly close to a pure profits tax, as the tax base consists mainly of above-normal returns. 14 Mintz and Seade (1991) suggest that, in many cases, the CCFT might actually increase revenue, because existing tax codes already provide generous investment incentives. With fast write-offs and tax holidays, income taxation is similar to the CCFT. Investment and Current Revenue. The tax yield under the CCFT would also tend to be very sensitive to investment. Under an income tax with "true economic depreciation," gross returns and offsetting capital allowances on an investment follow the same time pattern. But, under the CCFT, taxable inflows from past investments are partly offset by the expensing of new outlays. Hence, current revenue will depend on the 12 A classic reinterpretation of the CIT is Stiglitz (1976, p. 310): "In my interpretation of the U.S. tax system the dominant feature [of the corporation tax] IS the interest deductibility provision . . . . [The corporation tax] is partly a tax on pure profits, partly a tax on entrepreneurship and partly a return on an implicit government partnership in risk-taking. Quantitatively, I suspect that the third role is the most important." 13 The strength of this argument should have declined after the 1986 tax reform. 14Economic rents (such as in the cases of monopoly and mineral deposits) constitute a common tax base for the CIT and CCIT. Debt-financed corporations can shield marginal returns by deducting them as interest under the CIT. Thus, the CCIT and CIT become similar. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 648 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE difference between the average rate of return and the rate of growth of the capital stock. During periods of rapid expansion-which, for instance, may follow structural adjustments in reforming socialist economies­ revenue could dry up or even become negative, at least theoretically. 15 In other words, revenue could drop during upswings in economic activity, making the tax procyclical. This does not imply that revenue would be permanently postponed. In the long term, the capital stock would not, on average, grow faster than the average rate of return on it. Nevertheless, the sensitivity of revenue to investment is undesiiable both in terms of fiscal liquidity and business­ cycle effects. As far as the latter is concerned, the CCFf would tend to generate more revenue during the downside of a business cycle since investment would tend to be low, even as returns from earlier investments could flow into the tax base. However, to the extent that existing tax codes have special investment incentives, such as accelerated depreciation or investment tax credits, similar problems do arise under an income tax. Because of administrative problems and collection lags, the stabilizing effects of corporate income taxation are also less clear than they appear in theory. On the whole, however, it seems that the ramifications of incentives and collection lags under the income tax should be less pronounced. Revenue Risk. As the government assumes the "silent partner" role with full loss offset, revenue from individual projects becomes more risky-though its expected value is still positive if investors are risk averse. Still, the "silent partnership" should not cause substantial varia­ tions in total revenue as long as the independent risks of many projects can be pooled. But in the case of a small country with only a few major projects, or in the case where risks are correlated, variability of revenue may be an additional concern.16 Other Effects. Two other revenue-related points deserve mention. First, the introduction of the CCFf may require substantial improve­ ments in the loss-offset provisions of the existing CIT. Such improve15 Assume a sequence oftwo-period projects lf total investment in the previous period was 1 but grows at rate g-so current investment is (1 + g}-then under the CCFT current government revenue Rc is . Rc = tc(1 + r) - tc(1 + g) = tc(r - g). Contrast this with an income tax that allows expensing of proportion a. Current revenue R1 is R1 = t1[(l + r) - (1 - a)] - t;a(l + g) = t;(r - ag). For a = 0 (no expensing), current revenue R1 is completely independent of g. 16 This argument may be an imJ?ortant element in the reluctance of governments to use the cash-flow base for mmeral taxation. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 649 ments may be costly in terms of revenue if previous loss trading between corporations was imperfect. Second, there may also be a revenue-increas­ ing effect if the CCFT actually improves the administration of taxes on small businesses and other hard-to-tax groups. To conclude, the revenue effect of replacing a CIT with a CCFT remains an empirical question. Whether or not a revenue-neutral CCFT would require higher rates depends on the particular income tax laws to be replaced, the value of economic rents earned in the corporate sector, and the current debt-equity compositions of corporate portfolios. Tran­ sition rules might be needed to soften any adverse revenue effect of the conversion, and such rules may have to be applied for a considerable period of time. Tax Avoidance and Evasion The above discussion of revenue effects excluded possible behavioral responses by corporations. However, as firms try to exploit any new "loopholes" in the CCFT, revenue could be lost and tax administration might face new challenges. A number of new possibilities for "gaming the system" under the CCFT have been discussed in the literature (Sunley (1989), McLure and others (1990), Gordon (1989), Mintz and Seade (1991), Tait (1992)). Like any avoidance scheme, the problems are enunciated by, and based on, differences in tax rates between activities, jurisdictions, institutions or individuals, legal forms, and points in time, all of which make arbitraging profitable (Stiglitz (1988)). This section surveys some possible avoidance and evasion schemes. It also discusses the related tax-exhaustion prob­ lem, the merits of the R base versus the RF base, and some general issues. Gaming the System. Some tax avoidance possibilities are specific to the R-based CCFT, as there is an entire class of schemes exploiting the crucial difference between taxable real flows and tax-free financial transactions (Sunley (1989)): -Installment sales to a tax-exempt party may understate the taxable purchase price but overstate the tax-free interest component of seller financing. -Labor, goods, and services may be sold at low prices and assets leased at low rates to a tax-exempt party, who in return would provide a low-interest loan to the employee, seller, or lessor; prearranged de­ faults and loan forgiveness would be extreme cases of such low-interest loans, unless they are included as imputed flows in the tax base. -Companies using different accounting years may reduce their tax bases by increasing purchases from each other. At the end of its account­ ing year, company A could make large purchases from company B and ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 650 PARTHASARATHT SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE vice versa. These intercompany transactions could be debt financed without tax consequences. -To circumvent nondeductibility of interest payments, financing may be provided by a tax-exempt seller or lessor. Interest payments would be transformed into deductible leasing payments or purchases. In order to contain these arrangements, McLure and others (1990) suggest that for tax deduction purposes, ceilings and floors may need to be imposed on interest rates. Under both the R and RF bases, taxpayers may try to shift the tax base to an affiliated low-tax party, for instance a tax-exempt pension fund or a foreign corporation with a lower rate. 17 Expensable capital outlays would be allocated to the high-tax party, and subsequent cash inflows would be directed toward the low-tax party. Such base shifting may take the form of -transfer pricing through the purchase of inputs from the low-tax party at inflated prices, and the sale of goods at understated prices; -low-rate leasing of capital acquired and expensed by a high-tax party to a low-tax party; and -selling expensed assets at understated prices to the low-tax party. 18 Such schemes could be operated under the income tax as well, but the incentive for them is much more powerful under the CCFr. This is because expensing makes the present value of deductions on any asset equal to the purchase price. Under any other depreciation scheme, the present value of deductions decreases with the longevity of an asset and with the discount rate used by the corporation. 19 Also, because the entire deduction is available up front under the CCFr, immediate sale of the asset at an understated price becomes much more attractive. Under an income tax, the high-tax party would have to hold on to the asset to benefit from available depreciation. A CCFr will hence increase the incentive for tax-saving leases and for mergers between corporations with different tax rates. Foreign corpora1 7 This holds provided that international tax differentials are not washed out by tax credit mechanisms. 1 8 The roblem arising from the ossibility that firms may move once they have p p expensed an investment (Tait (1992)) could be alleviated by taxing them upon migration. Since they previously benefited from expensing, such a tax should not conflict with free international capital movement. 19There is very little to be gained from shifting long-lived assets under the income tax. Think of land as the most extreme case. It is not depreciable under the income tax-but should be expensable under CCIT. The difference between expensing and straight-line depreciation for different i illustrated below. For example, an asset depreciated over ten years parameters s by a firm using a 4 percent discount rate produces a present value of deductions ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 651 tions may set up subsidiaries in the CCFT country only to take advantage of expensing, then channel inflows to a lower-rate jurisdiction. Manipulation of reported transactions may also be an important chan­ nel of tax evasion. Companies could try to overstate asset prices upon purchase to the tax authorities. They could also buy equipment, take the deduction, and immediately resell, concealing or understating the price. These possibilities also arise under the income tax. Again, however, expensing, which grants tax savings up front, increases their attractiveness. To counter base-shifting schemes, arm's-length prices and rates for transactions between affiliates have to be enforced. But such monitoring is notoriously difficult. Perhaps certain types of transactions, such as leasing to foreigners or tax-exempt institutions, would need to be prohib­ ited. If there is a system of wealth taxation, it may put some checks on the valuation of transferred assets. However, all such requirements would result in considerable complications, essentially eroding the tax's main characteristic, simplicity, on which proponents base its attractiveness. Some general lessons from the income tax apply even more so to the CCFT in this context. Tax treatment of activities and institutions should be uniform to reduce arbitraging opportunities. For instance, some busi­ ness activities of tax-exempt institutions may be taxed. The rate structure should be flat and low to the extent possible (given revenue needs), since it determines the taxpayer's per-dollar savings from reducing or shifting the tax base. Tax Exhaustion and Tax Avoidance. A special case of uneven rates arises from tax exhaustion, where available deductions exceed taxable inflow. A tax-exhausted corporation has a marginal tax rate of zero, that is roughly 80 percent of its initial value. The CCFT always provides a 100 percent deduction. Present Worth of Straight-Line Depreciation Deductions (As a percent of asset's cost) Economic life (years) Annual deduction (in percent) 5 10 20 50 20 10 5 2 Present worth of depreciation discounted at interest rate (annually compounded) 2 percent 4 percent 8 percent 6 percent 94.3 89.8 81.8 62.8 89.0 81.1 68.0 43.0 84.2 73.6 57.3 31.5 79.9 67.1 49.1 24.5 Note: Straight-line depreciation is cost divided by length of life, assuming scrap value. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution no 652 PARTHASARATHJ SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE though its statutory rate may be quite high. It is unable to benefit from capital allowances. Excess allowances (through tax losses) are likely to be much larger and more frequent under the CCFT. However, especially with an R base, whether the resulting lumpy tax profile will foster additional arbitraging and mergers largely depends on the loss-offset provisions. To the extent that such provisions ensure symmetrical treatment of profitable and loss-making corporations, profitable arbitraging would be curtailed. Loss offsets are crucial to the CCFT in conceptual terms as well, and a refund would be the straightforward solution. Refunds may be prob­ lematic, though, in that they aggravate the problem of "hobby farms": businesses set up solely to generate tax losses on consumptive, non­ profit-oriented activities. Rules against such abuses under the income tax would have to be carried over to the CCFT (Gordon (1989)). If statutory provisions are insufficient, additional tax arbitraging through leases or mergers could take place. The objection against such arrangements should not be that they cost revenue; in fact they could be interpreted as a "market solution" to the tax exhaustion problem (King (1986), Stiglitz (1988)), ensuring equitable treatment of loss-making and profitable firms and preserving the investment incentive of the CCFT. But the objection is that such solutions would be inefficient, because they tend to distort economic activity through reduced competition and "par­ asitic tax-based industries" (Weeden (1988)). If full statutory loss-offset provisions cannot be obtained, a second-best strategy for government may be to facilitate loss trading.20 To conclude this section on tax avoidance and evasion, a summary assessment of the R and RF bases may be called for. The administrative advantage of the R base is that financial transactions can be entirely ignored. This actually reflects the basic concept of the CCFT-equaJ treatment of debt and equity. On the other hand, the R base is vulnerable to the above-mentioned tax avoidance schemes. With the RF base, the tax profile is less lumpy, and incentives for base shifting and evasion are reduced. However, the RF base creates an incentive to raise capital as equity and disguise payouts as interest payments, a problem that is shared under the income tax. Therefore, the existing CIT provisions to amelio­ rate these problems would have to be carried over to an RF-based CCFT. 20 The so-called safe-harbor leases (legalization of purely tax-motivated leasing arrangements) in the United States and flow-through shares (option to pass losses on to shareholders) in Canada were controversial attempts in this direction (Daly, Jung, and Schwettzer (1986), Stiglitz (1988)). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 653 International Issues Since the CCFT is an untried tax, many legal and economic questions remain with respect to its international compatibility, especially where tax treatment of foreign investment income is concerned. Basic Concerns. The introduction of the CCFT raises serious ques­ tions about international compatibility. These questions have legal as well as economic aspects. As the CCFf might not legally qualify as an income tax, its adoption could require the renegotiation of tax treaties. Such negotiations could take many years and hence imply considerable transactions costs and transitory arrangements. Moreover, tax treaties for many host countries offer a stability that they may not want to risk. Reforming socialist countries that ultimately want to join the European Community (EC) may find the CCFT unacceptable simply because it would not conform to the EC requirement for the CIT.2 1 Host countries are worried about losing existing options for ··soaking up" foreign tax credits. Also, there has been an overriding concern that home countries-in particular, the United States-might not grant for­ eign tax credit for the CCFf and that this might discourage foreign investment. The creditability problem was the major obstacle for the adoption of CCFf proposals in Canada, Mexico, Sweden. and Colombia (Boskin and McLure (1990)). Principles for Taxing Foreign Earned Income. Briefly recalling the basic principles applied to the taxation of foreign income (OECD (1991 ), Slemrod (1992), Leechor and Mintz (1991)), three regimes can be distinguished: -Exemption: Home countries impose no tax at all on income earned abroad. This is sometimes referred to as the territorial system. Income is only taxed by the host country (source principle). -Taxation upon accrual: Home countries reserve the right to tax worldwide income of their resident corporations (residence principle). and foreign income is taxed as it is earned. Taxation upon accrual is typically applied to foreign branches of resident corporations. -Taxation upon repatriation: Home countries apply the residence principle. However, corporations can defer their domestic tax liability by 21 As a consequence of growing economic integration, the coordination of capital income taxation will become even more important in the European Community. Although there are advocates of ··spontaneous coordination" through increased competition of tax systems, this approach has serious prob­ lems. Rather, the European countries will want to increase managed harmoniza­ tion of existing CIT systems (Tanzi and Bovenberg ( 1990)). A CCFT would hardly fit into this process. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 654 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE retaining earnings abroad. Because of the time value of money, deferral reduces the effective domestic tax rate. This type of tax is typically applied to subsidiaries. If borne countries apply the residence principle, foreign income is potentially subject to double taxation in the host and borne countries. Double taxation can be mitigated in different ways. First, the home country can allow deduction of taxes paid abroad. This is an efficient policy, since foreign taxes represent a social cost to the home economy. If the deduction is granted, resident corporations will equalize the after­ tax foreign return to the pretax domestic return. However, tbis is not optimal from a global point of view, since capital exports are discrimi­ nated against. To ensure capital-export neutrality, many home countries grant a tax credit against foreign taxes paid. Corporations then equalize the pretax rate of returns. In terms of revenue, the tax credit implies that home countries bear the foreign tax burden of their resident corpora­ tions. Unless additional tax treaties impose restrictions, the host country can "soak up" these tax credits-that is, it can tax foreign investors without deterring them. However, the tax credit is usually limited to domestic tax liability (on the sum of domestic and foreign incomes), so that corporations ultimately face the higher of the (average) foreign or domestic tax rate. If the domestic rate is higher, the corporation will face the same effective tax rate at home and abroad. If the foreign rate is higher, the corporation may accumulate excess tax credits. Under a system of tax credit by source, such offsets are limited to income from a particular host country. Under the more generous worldwide system, excess tax credits may be used against tax on income from any host country. In this case the corporation actually faces the higher of the domestic and the average foreign tax rate.22 CCFT and Foreign Direct Investment. Here, two regimes can be identified. -Exemption at home: The concerns about revenue and creditability are irrelevant for foreign investment from home countries that grant an exemption for foreign dividend income; in this case the CCFT host · 22 Countries often do not apply one principle consistently but have special provisions for different circumstances. In general, tax exemption for foreign­ i provided by the source dividend income, at least that from tax-treaty countries, s following countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Sweden, and Switzerland. The tax credit system for foreign dividends is used by Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Turkey, the United Kin g ­ dom, and the United States. Iceland, Japan, and the United States provide worldwide tax credit; all other countries use the more restrictive credit by source (OECD (1991), p. 63). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH·F.LOW TAX 655 country will attract additional foreign investment until the pretax rate of return is equal to the after-tax rate of return in the home country. -A creditable CCFf: What if the home country taxes foreign earn­ ings? Let us first assume that the CCFf would be creditable. Another crucial distinction has to be made between corporations whose available tax credits are less than their domestic liability on foreign earnings (their so-called excess limit position) and those who have excess credits. If corporations are in an excess limit position, the tax credit mechanism would wash out the effects of host country tax policy. The revenue argument against the CCFf is based on this point. While the investment incentive of the CCFT would be neutralized, revenue is forgone, simply to be picked up by the home country. Note, however, that this argument does not hold in the presence of"tax sparing." Under tax sparing, the home country assumes that the full tax has been paid in the foreign (host) country, in effect calculating foreign tax credit on the basis of regular foreign tax rates regardless of the actual taxes paid (on the basis of preferential treatment). This approach protects host country tax incentives. With the notable exception of the United States, many capital-exporting countries (such as Japan and the United Kingdom) have signed tax-sparing treaties with developing countries. Note also that under a "deferral system," retained earnings are tax exempt in the home country. The investment incentive of the CCFf may therefore remain effective. Hartman (1985) has argued that under defer­ ral the home country tax is in fact a tax on repatriation rather than on foreign income. This "repatriation tax" is ultimately unavoidable and therefore affects neither marginal investment decisions nor decisions to retain or repatriate profitsY Hence, a corporation considering reinvest­ ment of funds earned abroad will compare after-tax rates of return just as it would under the source principle. A tax credit will still alleviate the overall tax burden but does not wash out the effects of host country tax policy. The "new view" of host country tax policy under the deferral system has been criticized in the literature, however.24 The criticism does not apply to "immature" investment-investment funded at the margin by transfers from abroad, which may be predominant in many, especially ex-socialist, economies. It bas also been pointed out that the formulas used for the calculation of the domestic tax are such that the investment 23 However, it does affect the initial investment decision. Also note that the argument regarding marginal decisions not being affecte? should be qualified by the possibility that foreign income may never be repatnated. 2A Hines (1992) has a brief survey of this debate. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 656 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE and financing decisions of the subsidiary do affect the total liability on repatriated earnings. 25 To preserve the incentive for "mature" investment but still "soak up" the foreign tax credit, the CCFT country may want to adopt a supplemen­ tary withholding tax on repatriated earnings (Sunley (1989), Mintz and Seade (1991)). Such a tax would introduce some administrative compli­ cations, because foreign corporations' income would have to be calcu­ lated in order to distinguish dividends from the return on capital (Sunley (1989)). Also, the tax should not apply to foreign investors whose earn­ ings are tax exempt at home. But discrimination between corporations hardly seems feasible (Slemrod (1992)). Finally, the creditability of such a tax is uncertain. It will probably depend on the creditability of the CCFT itself (McLure and others (1990), Sunley (1989)). If corporations have excess tax credits, their foreign earnings at the margin are effectively shielded from domestic taxation. They do not trigger any additional liability in the home country. Host country tax policies therefore "matter" as they do under the source principle. Since the Tax Reform Act (TRA) of 1986, whose main feature was a reduction ofU.S. statutory rates, many U.S. corporations have accumulated excess tax credits. This suggests that investment incentives of developing coun­ tries are likely to be more effective in the future, but some qualifications are in place. Not all foreign investors are in an excess credit position. For non-U.S. multinationals the lowering of U.S. rates has meant a reduction of excess credit positions at home. Those who have excess credits are likely to adjust their behavior in order to make profitable use of them. 26 In the long run, an excess credit situation may not be stable because (1) the home country, in this case the United States, may raise its tax rates since it does not collect revenue from corporations with excess tax credits; and (2) other host countries may lower their rates to attract additional investment. Host country tax competition may ultimately lead back to the usual situation, in which tax credits neutralize host country policies. Arguments based on the excess credits of foreign investors can thus be easily overstated. "The TRA 1986 may have created a temporary disequi:zs See Leechor and Mintz (1991) who develop a model to quantify empirically the effects of host country policy on effective tax rates and multinational invest­ ment. Using a related framework , Mintz and Tsiopoulos (1992) have estimated the incentive value of a cash-flow tax in central eastern European countries for U.S. corporations. They found that it would be reduced by about two-thirds on average. 26 Possibilities for such adjustments are outlined by Slemrod (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 657 librium" (Slemrod (1992), p. 13) rather than a fundamental change in the international environment for developing country tax policy. -A noncreditable CCFT: So far, it has been assumed that the home country would grant foreign tax credit for the CCFT. Possible noncred­ itability of the CCFT in home countries, however, especially in the United States, has been a major concern in countries considering the tax. There is no clear answer in advance to the legal question of creditabil­ ity. Conceptually, the CCFT is based on cash flow rather than on income, and thus seems likely to fail the "substitution test" required, for instance, by U.S. legislation. However, while the United States grants tax credit for income taxes, it also grants credit for taxes imposed "in lieu" of income taxes (Sunley (1989)). In fiscal terms, the CCFT makes home countries better off to the extent that they recover tax on marginal foreign returns. Therefore, there should be no reason for them to deny creditabil­ ity (McLure (1991)).27 Also, home countries agreeing to protect host country incentives through tax sparing should be willing to grant foreign tax credit for the CCFT (Sunley (1989)). What if the CCFT were not creditable? Would double taxation dis­ courage foreign investment? McLure (1991) points at three qualifications to this common argument, two of which were discussed above. First, "mature investment" may still be attracted by the CCFT because a repatriation tax does not affect rates of return at the margin. Second, corporations may have excess tax credits and therefore be back to source­ based taxation at the margin. However, lasting excess credit "protection" of a noncreditable CCFT is only possible if the home country has a worldwide credit system, such that new credits may be earned in high-tax countries. If the home country grants credit only by source, excess tax credits are available only from the previous income tax regime and will be used up after some time. Third, it may be argued that a tax with a marginal effective rate of zero "even when combined with a (home country) tax on repatriated earnings is unlikely to have much disincen­ tive effect on investment in the host country" (McLure (1991), p. 21). A noncreditable CCFT will not distort investment at the margin, because for projects just earning the opportunity cost of capital net CCFT payments will simply be zero.28 For a project earning above-normal returns, the CCFT burden that is deductible but not creditable at home will become an additional cost. To 27The Internal Revenue Service may have a different view. 23This is most clearly seen for a marginal project that uses perfect loss-carry forward. As cash inflows are just suffictent to offset the loss-carry forward, the corporation never makes any actual payment to the host country. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 658 PARTHASARATHT SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE the extent that such investment is mobile, it will be discouraged by the CCFf. One may argue, though, that above-normal returns on invest­ ments in developing countries are often earned on immobile production opportunities (for example, the extraction of mineral resources or the exploitation of a local monopoly by a multinational trademark). In these cases, the noncreditability of a tax on pure profits will have no effect. Note, however, that the noncreditability of the CCFf is likely to entail the noncreditability of any supplementary withholding taxes. A noncred­ itable withholding tax would clearly introduce a distortion even for marginal investment. 29 m. Conclusions The CCFf has the drawback of any untried tax innovation, simply that "no one does it" (McLure (1991), Mintz and Seade (1991)). There is no experience or administrative know-how about the possibly complex de­ tails of a transition to the CCFf, its operation, and the avoidance schemes that might emerge. No official ruling on the critical question of the creditability of the CCFf has been required so far. The uncertainty costs of experimenting with the tax may be reason enough for a developing country or an economy in transition not to implement the CCFf. The 29The effects of a noncreditable CCFf and withholding tax can be illustrated algebraically as follows: 1. The after-tax rate of return of a domestic investment is ard = (1 - td)r. Compare this with investment in a foreign country that has the CCFf. Domestic tax liability if foreign taxes are deductible is 41 = td(r 7[), where foreign taxes are 7f t1(r - i), assuming that a loss-carry forward bears interest at rate i. The after-tax rate of return on foreign investment is ar1 = (1 td)(r 7[), and the wedge between the domestic and foreign after-tax rates of return is [ard - ar1] lard [(1 - td)r - (1 - td)(r - 7[)] /(1 - td)r] - = - - = = 7[/r = t1(r - i)lr. (1) If r > i, foreign CCFf payments 7fare an additional cost and hence discourage investment abroad. 2. A supplementary withholding tax with a rate oft... would increase foreign-tax liability by t.,(r - tJ(r - i)], where the term in brackets represents repatriated after-CCFf earnings. After a rearrangement of terms, total foreign tax liability becomes 7f t1((r - i)(1 - t...)] + t... r, and, from equation (1), the new wedge is 7[/r t.., + t,((r - i)(1 - t )]tr; which is positive even for marginal investments, where r = i. For numerical illustrations of the effects of a noncreditable CCFT, see McLure and others (1990). = = ... ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 659 purpose of this paper, however, is to identify potential sources of prob­ lems and to understand better the conditions for a successful experiment with a CCFT. It seems clear that, depending on the existing CIT struc­ ture, the structure of the corporate sector, the relative importance of foreign investors, and the mix of countries they come from, some coun­ tries may find the CCFT less attractive than others. The key conclusions of the paper may be summarized as follows: 1. The theoretical pros of the CCFf seem clear. It can be interpreted as a "silent partnership" of the government in any investment, and as such it is generally neutral with respect to the financial and real decisions of corporations. The neutrality result has to be taken with a grain of salt as the loss-offset provisions are likely to be imperfect and some erosion of the tax base through lobbying and other political pressure is probably unavoidable. Expectations of future rate changes may also modify the results. Still , in a closed economy, the CCFf would tend to increase investment and improve the allocation of capital. On the administrative level, a tax based on observable cash flows rather than on a hypothetical concept of the accrual of income promises to be simpler and more robust (again, theoretically speaking). It would do away with the problems of defining "true economic depreciation," measuring capital gains, costing inventories, and accounting for inflation. 2. Possible revenue effects are an important aspect of the CCFf, especially in developing countries, since the CIT to be replaced is often a major source of revenue. Revenue losses are likely during the transition period, but they need not be prohibitive if the transition is carefully designed and tax rates are appropriately adjusted. However, a more fundamental issue is that the CCFf as a tax on above-normal returns may have a significantly smaller tax base than the comprehensive CIT. With expensing, the tax base may also be more volatile. Nevertheless, the actual difference between the CCFT and CIT bases remains an empirical question, depending on the particular income tax laws to be replaced as well as on the current compositions of corporate portfolios between debt and equity. In some cases, the two bases may be fairly similar. 3. Tax-base erosion through tax avoidance and evasion may be a serious problem for the CCFT. By choosing an RF-based CCFf over an R-based one and by carefully designing the tax code, some of the CCFT schemes could probably be contained at reasonable administrative cost.30 30 This is not to say that the R-based CCFf has no advantages over the RF-based variant. After all, one attractive feature of the cash-flow tax is the nondeductibility of interest, which eliminates incentives for debt financing over equity financing and obviates any need for inflation adjustments to calculate real interest. These are properties of the R-based, rather than of the RF-based, CCFf. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 660 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE But the large up-front deduction that results from the expensing of capital assets would create a powerful incentive for base-shifting schemes. The administrative efforts required to contain these schemes could be consid­ erable and would involve the enforcement of arm's-length prices, which is notoriously difficult. The "simplicity" argument for the CCFf has to be qualified accordingly. 4. Any answer to whether international considerations favor the CCFf would be complex. To the extent that host country tax policies matter, a country with the CCFf may attract additional investment. This is most clearly the case if home countries exempt the foreign earnings of their multinationals-as do many Western European countries. Other important capital-exporting countries, such as Japan, the United States, and the United Kingdom, apply the residence principle with a foreign tax credit. This system tends to neutralize host country tax policy, but not entirely. The incentive offered by the CCFf is likely to remain effective for those investors who benefit from tax sparing, which is granted by many countries but not by the United States. The CCFf is also likely to attract additional "mature" investment and investors who have excess tax credits. Recently, many U.S. corporations have accumulated such credits, although this position may not be stable in the long run. To the extent that the effect of the CCFf is washed out by the tax credit mechanism, the host country will lose. Tax forgone on marginal returns is merely picked up by the home country. In the case where the home country denies tax credit for the CCFT, some foreign investment would be discouraged. The creditability of the CCFf is an issue related mainly to the United States, since most other developed countries either exempt foreign earnings or grant some form of tax sparing. To conclude, at this point the CCFf remains a theoretically at­ tractive option with some practical disadvantages. Moreover, many un­ answered questions remain for its implementation by a single country­ especially a developing one-in an environment that will not necessarily accommodate its smooth and effective operation. REFERENCES Aaron, Henry J., Harvey Galper, and Joseph A. Pechman, eds., Uneasy Com­ promise. Problems of a Hybrid Income-Consumption Tax (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1988). Andrews, W.D., "A Consumption-Type or Cash Flow Personal Income Tax," Harvard Law Review, Vol. 87 (April 1974), pp. 1113-88. Boskin, Michael J., and Charles E. McLure, eds., World Tax Reform: Case ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution CASH-FLOW TAX 661 Studies of Developed and Developing Countries (San Francisco: Interna­ tional Center for Economic Growth, 1990). Brown, E.C., "Business-Income Taxation and Investment Incentives," in In­ come, Employment and Public Policy , Essays in HonorofAlvin Hansen , ed. by Lloyd A. Metzler and others (New York: W.W. Norton, 1948). Daly, Michael J., Jack Jung, and Thomas Schweitzer, "Toward a Neutral Capital Income Tax System," Canadian Tax Journaf, Vol. 34 (November-December 1986), pp. 1331-76. Gamaut, Ross, and Anthony Ian Clunies Ross, Taxation of Mineral Rents (Ox­ ford: Clarendon Press, 1983). Gordon, Roger H., Notes on Cash-Flow Taxation , World Bank Country Econom­ ics Department, Working Paper No. 210 (Washington: World Bank, 1989). Gordon, Roger H., and Joel Slemrod, "Do We Collect Any Revenue from Taxing Capital Income," in Tax Policy and the Economy, Vol. 2, ed. by Lawrence H. Summers (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1988). Hartman, David G., "Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment," Journal of Public Economics , Vol. 26 (February 1985), pp. 107-21. Hines, James R . , "Credit and Deferral as International Investment Incentives," NBER Working Paper No. 4191 (Cambridge, Mass. : National Bureau of Economic Research, 1992). Kay, John A., "Tax Policy: A Survey," Economic Journal, Vol. 100 (March 1990), pp. 18-75. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi, Javad, and Anwar Shah, eds., Tax Policy in Developing Countries (Washington: World Bank, 1991). King, Mervyn A., "The Cash Flow Corporate Income Tax," NBER Work­ ing Paper No. 1993 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1986). Leechor, Chad, and Jack Mintz, "Taxation of International Income by a Capital Importing Country: The Perspective of Thailand," in Tax Policy in Develop­ ing Countries, ed. by Javad Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and Anwar Shah (Washing­ ton: World Bank, 1991) McLure, Charles E., A Consumption-Based Direct Tax for Countries in Transi­ tion From Socialism, World Bank Country Economics Department, Work­ ing Paper No. 751 (Washington: World Bank, 1991). . McLure, Charles E., and others, The Taxation of Income from Business and Capital in Colombia (Durham: Duke University Press, 1990). Meade, James E., The Structure and Reform of Direct Taxation (Boston: Allen and Unwin, 1978). Mintz, Jack M., and Jesus Seade, "Cash Flow or Income? The Choice of Base for Company Taxation," World Bank Research Observer (Washington: World Bank, July 1991), pp. 177-90. Mintz, Jack M., and Thomas Tsiopoulos, Corporate Income Taxation and Foreign Direct Investment in Central and Eastern Europe (Washington: World Bank, 1992). Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, Taxing Profits in a Global Economy: Domestic and International Issues (Paris: OECD, 1991). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 662 PARTHASARATHI SHOME and CHRISTIAN SCHUTTE Pechman, Joseph A., ed., What Should Be Taxed: Income or Expenditure? A Report ofa Conference Sponsored by the Fundfor Public Policy Research and the Brookings Institution (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1980). Samuelson, Paul, "Tax Deductibility of Economic Depreciation to Insure Invari­ ant Valuations," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 72 (December 1964), pp. 604-06. Slemrod, Joel, "Optimal Taxation and Optimal Tax Systems," Journal of Eco­ nomic Perspectives, Vol. 4 (Winter 1990), pp. 157-78. , "Developing Country Tax Policy Toward Foreign Direct Investment in the Light of Recent International Tax Changes," in Fiscal Incentives for Investment in Developing Countries, Vol. 1, ed. by Anwar Shah (Washing­ ton: World Bank, 1992). Stiglitz, Joseph E., "The Corporation Tax," Journal ofPublic Economics, Vol. 5 (April/May 1976), pp. 303-11 . , Economics of the Public Sector (New York: W.W. Norton, 1988). Sunley, Emil M., The Treatment of Companies Under Cash-Flow Taxes: Some Adminstrative, i Transitional and International Issues, World Bank Country Economics Department, Working Paper No. 189 (Washington: World Bank, 1989). Tait, Alan A., "A Not-So-Simple Alternative to the Income Tax for Socialist Economies in Transition: A Comment on McLure," World Bank Research Observer (Washington: World Bank, July 1992), pp. 239-48. Tanzi , Vito, "Quantitative Characteristics of the Tax Systems of Developing Countries," in Taxation in Developing Countries , fourth edition, ed. by Richard M. Bird and Oliver Oldman (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1990). Tanzi, Vito, and Laos Bovenberg, "Is There a Need for Harmonizing Capital Income Taxes Within EC Countries?" lMF Working Paper 90/17 (Washing­ ton: International Monetary Fund, 1990). U.S. Treasury, BlueprintsforBasic Tax Reform (Washington: Government Print­ ing Office, 1977). Weeden, R., "The Effect of Introducing Cash-Flow Taxation for Companies in the United Kingdom," in John A. Kay, The Implementation of a Cash Flow Corporation Tax , prepared for a World Bank seminar on implementation problems of the cash-flow tax (Washington: The World Bank, June 1988). --- -- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF StaffPapers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) © 1993 International Monetary Fund Portfolio Performance of the SDR and Reserve Currencies Tests Using the ARCH Methodology MICHAEL G. PAPAJOANNOU and TUGRUL TEMEL* In evaluating theirforeign exchange exposure, international nvestors i often compare actual portfolios with those calculated under the assumption that the variability ofreturns on various currency assets is time invariant. This paper uses autoregressive conditional heteroskedastic (ARCH) models to test that assumption. For major reserve currencies, including the SDR, we find evidence that the variances of returns do vary over time and that ARCH models that specify changing variances are superior to models that assume constant variance. By incorrectly assuming a constant variability ofreturns, the error introduced is smaller with the SDR than with any other national currency. [JEL Gll, C22] N CALCULATING optimal fixed-income portfolios, the standard assump­ Ition is that historical volatilities of returns from multicurrency invest­ ments in government securities remain constant over time. It' is an as­ sumption that is often used both by investors to determine the "best" allocation of their wealth in terms of fixed-income investment instru­ ments and by some central banks to manage their external reserve assets. The same assumption is also made in the capital asset pricing model and * Michael G. Papaioannou is an Economist in the Treasurer's Department and holds a Ph.D. from the University of Pennsylvania. Tugrul Temel, a doctoral candidate in applied economics at the University of Minnesota, was a summer intern in 1991 in the Treasurer's Department. The authors would like to thank Lawrence K. Duke, Szeina Lurie, Inci Otker, Anthony Richards, Orlando Roncesvalles, George Tavlas, George Tsetsekos, and Michael Wattleworth for helpful comments and suggestions. 663 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 664 MlCHAEL G. PAPAIOANNOU and TUGRUL TEMEL modern portfolio theory when calculating the diversification benefits from investing in multiple assets; it also enters into the Black-Scholes model when calculating option pricing formulas. The implications of incorrectly assuming a constant variability of returns are a loss of effi­ ciency in terms of portfolio allocations and inappropriate decisions in terms of hedging the associated risk. Recent empirical work has shown that large changes in equity returns and exchange rates, using high­ frequency data, tend to be followed by large changes of sign; that is, the variance of returns and exchange rates is not constant, and the traditional assumption of constancy in many standard models of portfolio allocation does not hold. Very few studies, however, have addressed the issue of returns from multicurrency investments in fixed-income assets. A suitable model for dealing with nonconstant volatilities of returns is the ARCH model. 1 This paper attempts to model total fixed-income investment returns for a U.S. dollar-based investor as a univariate auto­ regressive conditional heteroskedastic process, as an alternative to the more common portfolio model that assumes the variance of returns from multicurrency-deoominated assets to be stationary or time invariant. The ARCH model expresses the current conditional variance of a time series of total returns as a linear function of its past residuals squared. ARCH models can be used to predict changes in the conditional variance of asset returns on different currencies but not the changes in the unconditional mean value of asset returns. Knowledge of the statistical properties that generate the observed rates of return on various investments-in partic­ ular how the process depends on developments in the financial markets­ is important for characterizing asset return volatility and for modeling optimal portfolios of multicurrency assets. Traditional models assume a constant one-period forecast variance and covariance matrix for the returns on different investments. This assump­ tion can be generalized to introduce a new class of stochastic processes called ARCH processes. These processes imply serially uncorrelated errors with zero means and nonconstant variances conditional on past returns. To test whether the error terms follow an ARCH process, the autocorrelation of the squared ordinary-least-squares (OLS) residuals has been calculated. After the detection of ARCH effects based on the autocorrelation statistics, a factor ARCH model can be used to reduce the number of parameters to be estimated. Our empirical results show that the variability of returns from investing in various currencies and currency composites is affected by lagged residuals, although the number of lags differs among currencies. The 1 See Engle and Rothschild (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE OF RESERVE CURRENCIES 665 estimated constant terms in the ARCH specification, o:0, are significant and nonnegative for all currencies, indicating a positive autonomous conditional volatility for the returns on these assets. Further, the esti­ mated parameters of the lagged squared residuals in the ARCH process, o:;, exhibit strong statistical significance for returns on all currency assets, , indicating that the stochastic processes generating these returns have nonstationary variances. Investment in SDRs, however, provides greater insulation to investors than investing in any other currency with one Jag of ARCH effects, as SDR returns demonstrate the lowest transmission of unexpected weekly shocks into volatility.2 In these circumstances and as already noted, an ARCH specification is a more efficient approach for modeling these asset returns than is the OLS approach. Finally, the Lagrange multiplier statistic for first-order ARCH specification is signif­ icant for all currencies, which also indicates that the conditional variances are not constant through time. In addition, the results of several diagnostic checks on the distribu­ tional properties of total returns indicate that they deviate from the normal distribution. In particular, the kurtosis statistics on the probabil­ ity distribution of returns on all currency investments are substantially larger than those from a standard normal distribution, indicating that these returns are Jeptokurtic (fat tailed). This result is further supported by Bera-Jarque tests, which indicate not only a highly significant non­ normality of the probability function for returns on these currencies but also a significant likelihood that the variance of these returns is not constant over time. The BJ test for normalitf is highly significant for the deutsche mark, the pound sterling, the French franc, the Japanese yen, the European currency unit (ECU), the SDR, and gold with ARCH(1, 1) as well as for the U.S. dollar with ARCH(6, 2). Only the BJ test for the average composite index with ARCH(1, 1) is not statistically significant. I. Brief Literature Review The uncertainty of speculative prices has been observed to change through time (Mandelbrot (1963) and Fama (1965)). The tendency of large (small) price changes in high-frequency financial data to be followed by other large (small) price changes is often called "volatility clustering." 2 Although the estimated coefficient a1 for the average composite index (ACI) is lower than that for the SDR, the sum of the estimated coefficients a; (i = 1 , . . . , 5) for the ACI process is greater than the estimated coefficient a1 for the SDR. 3 For the use of this test, see Table 2. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 666 MICHAEL G. PAPAJOANNOU and TUGRUL TEMEL One specification that has emerged for characterizing such changing variances is the ARCH model (Engle (1982)) and various extensions of it. In his seminal paper, Engle suggests that one possible parametrization for variances is to express them as a linear function of squared past values of the errors of the model. With financial data, the ARCH model cap­ tures the tendency for volatility clustering, and numerous empirical applications of the ARCH methodology to asset return variances and covariances have already appeared in the literature. ARCH effects have generally been found to be highly significant in equity markets-for example, highly significant test statistics for ARCH models have been reported for various individual stock returns (Engle and Mustafa (1989) ). In a series of papers, the ARCH model has been analyzed, generalized, extended to the multivariate context, and used to test for time-varying risk premia in financial markets. These papers include Engle (1983) and Engle and Kraft (1983). The ARCH model was extended to the multi­ variate framework in Kraft and Engle (1983). Diebold and Nerlove (1989) use a multivariate approach exploiting factor structure, a method that facilitates tractable estimation via a substantial reduction in the number of parameters to be estimated. The factor structure captures commonal­ ity in the volatility of movements in financial data over time. Engle, Ng, and Rothschild (1990) suggest using the factor ARCH model to describe the conditional covariance matrix of excess asset returns. One- and two-factor ARCH models have been applied to the pricing of treasury bills, with the results showing reasonable stability over time. The importance of ARCH models in finance comes partly from the direct association of variance and risk and from the fundamental trade-off between risk and return. The ARCH-M (in mean) model developed by Engle, Lilien, and Robins (1987) expresses the conditional mean as a function of the conditional variance of the ARCH process. It thus pro­ vides a tool for estimating the (possibly) linear relationship between the returns and variances of a given investment portfolio. Another interesting observation in financial data is that the uncondi­ tional price and returns distributions tend to have fatter tails than the normal distribution (they are Jeptokurtic) (Mandelbrot (1963) and Fama (1965)). Ignoring the fat tails and the time-varying variances could lead to erroneous detection of abnormal returns (De Jong, Kemna, and Kloeck (1990)). Stock returns tend to exhibit nonnormal unconditional sampling distributions, both in the form of skewness and excess kurtosis (Fama (1965)). For many financial time series, the leptokurtosis cannot be fully explained. The conditional normality assumption in ARCH generates some degree of unconditional excess kurtosis, but it is typically less than adequate to account fully for the fat-tailed properties of the ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE OF RESERVE CURRENCIES 667 data. One solution to the kurtosis problem is the adoption of conditional distributions with tails fatter than the normal distribution. Skewness and kurtosis are shown to be important in characterizing the conditional density function of returns on stocks (Engle and Gonzales-Rivera (1989)). In addition to the leptokurtic distribution of stock return data, Black (1976) noted a negative correlation between current returns and future volatility. The linear generalized ARCH(p, q) model, where the variance depends only on the magnitude and not on the sign of the estimated residuals, cannot capture this negative relationship since the conditional variance is linked only to past conditional variances and squared innova­ tions; hence, the sign on returns does not affect the volatilities. This limitation of the standard ARCH formulation is one of the primary motivations for the exponential GARCH(p, q) model by Nelson (1991). In this type of generalized ARCH model, the volatility depends not only on the magnitude of the past surprises but also on their corresponding signs. Bollerslev, Engle, and Wooldridge (1988) first estimated a multivariate GARCH(p , q) process for returns on bills, bonds, and stocks where the expected return was assumed to be proportional to the conditional covari­ ance of each return from a fully diversified or market portfolio. They found that conditional covariances are quite variable over time and are a significant determinant of the time-varying risk premia. Bollerslev (1990) also applied a multivariate GARCH model to short-run nominal exchange rates. Hall, Miles, and Taylor (1988) similarly undertook a multivariate GARCH-M estimation of the capital asset pricing model. Pagan and Schwert (1990) compared several statistical models for monthly stock return volatility and showed the importance of nonlinear­ ities not captured by conventional ARCH or GARCH models. They also showed the nonstationarity of the volatility of stock returns. Vries (1991) compared stable and GARCH methods of modeling financial data and showed that the unconditional distribution of variables generated by a GARCH-like process, which models the clustering of volatility and ex­ hibits the fat-tail property, can be stable. Further, Bollerslev (1987) extended the ARCH and GARCH models, called an integrated GARCH model, to explain the persistence of variance over time. II. Estimation and Testing for ARCH Effects Autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models account for the empirical observation that large changes in asset returns tend to be followed by further large changes in these returns, although the sign is ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 668 MICHAEL G. PAPAIOANNOU and TUGRUL TEMEL unpredictable; also, small changes in asset returns tend to be followed by small changes, thus leading to periods of persistently high or low volatil­ ity. We utilize the ARCH model by assuming that the conditional mean, E(y, lyt-1), of each asset return, y,, is linearly unpredictable, while its conditional variance, h,, is predictable by an ARCH model. It is well known that the unconditional distribution of ARCH processes have thicker tails, even though their conditional distributions are normal.4 The first-order autoregressive model, AR(1), for y,, combined with ARCH(1, 1) errors, can be written as5 = <l>o + <I>1 Yr-1 + where E(e, IYr-1) = 0 , var(e, I Yr-t) = E(e� IYr-1) = h, and h, = o:o 0:1 E�-1 · Yr E,, + (1) (2) For the regression to be stable, l<!>tl is assumed to be less than one. To ensure that h, is positive and that the process is stationary, we must have o:a � 0 and 1 � o:1 � 0. Intuitively, o:0 can be interpreted as a "normal" stationary element in the series on asset returns and o:1 as the hetero­ skedastic coefficient, which shows the correlation between changes in returns and their corresponding volatilities in the previous period. As an illustration, for a U.S. dollar-based investor, y, would denote asset re­ turns in U.S. dollars obtained by investing in various currency assets; it would be defined as the product of the three-month treasury bill rate for each asset multiplied by the percentage change of the corresponding U.S. dollar exchange rate, all expressed on a weekly basis.6 The generalization of the ARCH(p, q) model for asset return y, is as follows: = <l>o + <I>1 Yr-1 + + <l>pYr-p + E,, (3) where <I>P(L) = 2:f= t <!>; L; is the polynomial autoregressive lag operator. Note that ··· Yr y, - N[<l>p(L)y, h,] (4) with h, = o:o + 2: o:; E�-;, (5) q {;;;l 4 See Engle (1982). 5That is, an AR(l) model means that y, depends on Yr-1 but not on earlier (y,-2,Yr-3, . . . ) observations. An ARCH(l, 1) model means that y, depends on Yr- 1 but not on earlier (Yr-z,y,-3, . . . ) observations and that h, depends on E�- 1 but not on earlier square d errors (E�-2, E:_3, . . . ). 6 In calculating returns, we have omitted capital gains or losses resulting from changes in the prices of bills, on the assumptton that such short-term securities generally have relatively small price variations over the course of a week. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE OF RESERVE CURRENCIES 669 where E1 follows a white noise process defined by E(Er) = 0 for all t, E(e, es) = 0 for t =I= s, and E(e?) = a-2 for all t. The conditional variance of E�o h,, is allowed to vary over time and is a linear function of past residuals squared. Testing for ARCH effects requires a test of the null hypothesis that the conditional variance h, is constant over time: Ho: H1 : at = a2 = · · · = aq = at • • =/: a2 =/: • =I= aq 0 (no ARCH effects); =/: 0 (ARCH effects exist). To test the null hypothesis H0, we have utilized the following procedure: first, the residuals €, are estimated from equation (3) using ordinary least squares; second, the number of lags of e, is determined, using all available information, through maximization of its log-likelihood function; and third, estimates of a0, , aq are obtained by applying OLS to q h, = ao + 2: a; €.7-;. • . • i•l In order to test for an ARCH process of order q, we form the regression E(€7) = h, = ao + q L i-=-1 a; €.7-;, (6) where e.; is the square of the OLS residuals obtained from equation (3).7 To test for higher-order ARCH specifications and the joint significance ofthe coefficients attached to equation (6), the Lagrange multiplier (LM) statistic is calculated as T R2 (where R2 is the coefficient of determina­ tion and Tis the sample size), which has an asymptotic x2(q) distribution. Significantly large values of the statistic will lead to the rejection of the null hypothesis H0 of homoskedasticity in favor of an ARCH process of order q. Finally, if ARCH effects are detected, maximum likelihood estimation rather than OLS should be applied,8 and the additional assumption of (conditional) normality of returns should be employed in the third step of the above procedure. · ill. Empirical Results In this section, the univariate ARCH model using weekly data is estimated for a U.S. dollar-based investor. The data set contains returns on short-term securities denominated in the U.S. dollar, the deutsche 'See Diebold (1988, p . 19); Greene (1990, 8See Engle (1982, pp. 996-99). p. 417). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Note: * .. 10.99* -84s.n 1 .355 (12 .767)* 0 .144 (2.473)* · 6.09* -829.02 1 . 25 (15.332)* 0.17 (4.74W 0.135 (2.406) .. 0.347 (7.394)* Japanese yen · 8.18* -857.23 1 .374 (14.310)* 0.181 (3.870)* 0.118 (2.038)* 0.311 (7.679)* Pound s.terling 19. 15* -841.03 4.45* -503 . 10 0.369 (13.072)* 0.114 (2.002)* 0.082 (2.883)* 0.330 (7.500) * 0. 136 (2.458)* 0.332 (8.119)* 1 .270 (14.431)* 0.197 (3.107)* SDR franc French 10.21* -755.69 l.l63 (10.963)* 0.203 (3.065)* 0.095 ( 1 .714)* 0.302 (7.134)* ECU · + 41pYr-p + E, and h, = Qo + alE;_, + · · · + aq E;_q) ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 16.69* 158.17 0.018 (5. 368)* 0.106 (1 .726)* 0.074 ( 1 .467)** 0.108 ( 1.452)** 0.130 (2.179)* 0.037 (0.708) 0.016 (1.939).. 0.362 (7.829)* -0.105 (-2.094)* 0. 102 (1. 999) * -0.039 ( -0.816) Average composite index 1982:5-1991:50 denote statistically significant t-statistics at the 0.05 and 0. 10 levels, respectively. 112.72* 2,234.24 and Lagrange multiplier Log likelihood as <4 al a2 a, ao � 4-s 4>· 4>. ck �1 4>., 0. 126 (2.262)* 0.331 (8.087)* mark 0.001 (2.889)* 1 . 191 (27.0?...6 )* -0.291 (-4.597)* 0.212 (4.184) .. 0.009 (0.211) 0.055 ( 1 .565) -0. 187 (-8 .73W 0.000 ( 1 1 . 199)* 0.538 (9.665)* 0.162 (2.944)* DeuiSche u.s. doUar + ARCH(p, q) Esrimation Results for Total Remrn.s, Weekly Data, (y, = lbo + <!J,y,-1 Table 1. Gold 0.60 - 1 ,081.92 3.329 (22.932)* 0.194 (4.369)* -0.059 (-0.062) 0.248 (5.454)* ;::; m r -1 m 3:: r -1 c: 0 ;:o c: 0.. 5 > z z 0 c: 0 > "C > ., 0 r :I: > m s:: 0.. -..l c PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE OF RESERVE CURRENCIES 671 mark, the Japanese yen, the pound sterling, the French franc, the SDR, the ECU, an average composite index (ACI), and gold. The ACI repre­ sents the average share of currencies in official holdings of foreign ex­ change reserves of IMF member central banks for the 1981-87 period. Our sample spans the period February 1982 to December 1991. The data set is described in the Appendix. For given values of past-realized investment returns, a0 and a; (i = 1 , . . . , 5) were estimated for the total return on each of the nine types of currency assets (see Table 1). All estimated coefficients, &0 and &;, are nonnegative, thus ensuring that a positive variance is obtained. Furthermore, the summation of a;'s (i � 1) is always less than one, indicating that the estimated variance is finite. The optimal lag length, q, is determined as the value that maximizes the log-likelihood function in a grid search over lags 1 to 6. To maximize the likelihood function, an iterative procedure based on the method of BHHH9 was used. As can be seen from Table 1 , the optimal lag length is one for the deutsche mark, the pound sterling, the French franc, the Japanese yen, ECU, SDR, and gold; two for the U.S. dollar; and five for the average composite index. The difference in the optimal lag length between the U.S. dollar and the rest ofthe employed currencies, except the average composite index, may be attributed to the fact that U.S. dollar returns comprise only interest earnings on the respective assets, without taking into account any coun­ teracting movements in the exchange rate as is the case with the other currencies. The ARCH coefficients for almost all currency returns are significantly greater than zero, as indicated by the asymptotic t-statistics given in parentheses. The specification test for qth-order ARCH disturbances is based on the qth-order autocorrelation of the squared residuals. The presence of first-order ARCH effects is accepted at the 5 percent level for the deutsche mark, the Japanese yen, the pound sterling, the French franc, SDR, and ECU returns. The null hypothesis of no second-order ARCH effects is rejected for returns on the U.S. dollar; that of no fifth-order ARCH effects is rejected for average composite investment returns. These results appear to provide statistical evidence that the variances of the respective currency returns are not independent over time, in that they are related through the square of past residuals. With regard to gold returns, the evidence is inconclusive, since the t-statistic of the corre­ sponding ARCH coefficient is statistically significant but the LM statistic suggests the absence of ARCH effects. 9The Berndt and others (1974) iterative algorithm. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 672 MICHAEL G. PAPAIOANNOU and TUGRUL TEMEL Table 2. Preliminary Data Analysis on Total Returns• Skewness Kurtosisb Bera-Jarque Augmented Dickey-Fuller -20.929* 4817.583* 10.506 0.998 U.S. dollar - 17.363* 9.197* 3.133 0.281 Deutsche mark -22.918* 220.964* 3.190 0.899 Japanese yen - 12.918* 65.608* 3.218 0.443 Pound sterling -17.542* 14.496* 3.264 0.074 French franc - 12.293* 4.519* 3.081 -0.226 SDR -16.671* 10.524* 3.282 -0.209 ECU Average composite -12.381* 2.689 3.245 0.070 index -22.367* 1158.280* 3.254 0.651 Gold Note: • indicates that statistic is significant at the 5 percent level. The number of observation is 496. b For the calculation of the kurtosis statistic, see Diebold (1988, pp. 8-11). • The significance tests for the ex; parameters and the LM statistics are corroborated by several additional diagnostic tests on the distributional properties of total returns (see Table 2). These statistics indicate that most currency returns, except for the ECU and the SDR, display a negative skewness. This characterizes a distribution of returns in which negative changes are less than positive ones. A small negative skewness indicates that large negative changes are outnumbered by positive ones of smaller magnitude. Moreover, all of the currency returns considered here exhibit high leptokurtosis, which commonly appears in high-frequency exchange rate data. 10 As mentioned above, when the conditional distribution is normal with ARCH disturbances, its unconditional distribution is known to be leptokurtic, 11 implying that an ARCH model could partly eliminate the associated leptokurtosis. The kurtosis statistics for all currency re­ turns are significantly larger than three, which is inconsistent with. a standard normal distribution of total returns on these assets. In addition, the Bera-Jarque (BJ) test statistic12 for the deutsche mark, the pound sterling, the French franc, the Japanese yen, ECU, SDR, and gold with ARCH(l , 1) is highly significant. Furthermore, the BJ tests for the U.S. dollar with ARCH(6, 2) and for the average composite index with ARCH(4, 5) are also significant. The resulting high negative values 10 See Diebold (1988, p. 5). See Engle (1982); Diebold (1988, pp. 8-11); Kroner and Claessens {1991, p. 136). 12The Bera-Jarque test statistic is approximately distributed as a central x2(2) under the null hypothesis of normality in the underlying distribution of returns (see Hendry (1989 , pp. 32-33)). 11 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE OF RESERVE CURRENCIES 673 for the augmented Dickey-Fuller tests imply that the characteristic roots of the Taylor expansion of the unconditional variance of €.� lie outside the unit circle for all currency returns. 13 The finding that the LM statistic for the testing of ARCH effects is significant for all currency returns (except gold) suggests that investment in these currencies will result in increased estimated variances-and therefore in increased risk during periods of large unexpected shocks to returns and in diminished risk during periods of relative stability. This result indicates that it might be desirable to split the sample into periods of high and low variability of returns and examine whether ARCH effects persist. The values for the parameter a0 range from zero for U.S. dollar returns to 3.329 for gold, and all are statistically significant. The parame­ ter a; (i = 1 , . . . , 5) represents the relative contribution of the previous period's squared error of returns to their conditional variance in the cur­ rent period. The parameter values of a1 range from 0.106 for the average composite index to 0.538 for U.S. dollar returns, and all are statistically significant at the 5 percent level. In the case of the U.S. dollar, this means that about 54 percent of a week's disturbances is carried over into the following week. Among currency returns displaying one lag of ARCH effects, returns on the SDR demonstrate the lowest transmission of weekly deviations from the mean into volatility of SDR returns, while ECU returns had the highest. This result suggests that shorter-term investment periods are likely to prove more "successful" for the SDR than for the ECU and the rest of the currencies, in terms of achieving a predicted risk-return trade-off. The result for the ECU may be attributed to the fact that the currencies in its basket have higher volatilities than those in the SDR basket. The constant term, <j>0, takes into account a possible nonstationary element (drift), like a time trend, in total returns. Under the null hy­ pothesis, currency returns would allow an autoregressive structure with constant-variance residuals. Under the alternative, an ARCH structure on the residuals is imposed. During the sample period, the constants on all currency returns, except that of gold, were positive, and only those on gold returns were not significantly different from zero. These terms may be interpreted as mean weekly returns. Thus, the intercept (con13The augmented Dickey-Fuller test is a stationarity test, in which the coeffi­ cient of the Jagged deJ?endent variable is tested to see whether it is equal to or greater than umty (umt-root test). A coefficient that is Jess than one indicates a stationary time series. If the augmented Dickey-Fuller statistic is significant, the existence of a characteristic root outside the unit circle cannot be rejected, and therefore the respective autoregressive series is considered nonstationary. The statistic is robust to ARCH specification. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 674 MICHAEL G. PAPAIOANNOU and TUGRUL TEMEL stant) for deutsche mark returns indicates that the annualized average weekly returns on deutsche mark investments were 10.28 percent.14 Fur­ ther, since for all currency returns <1>1 is less than one, it would seem that all returns are stable. Note that U.S. dollar returns exhibit a different pattern of generating process from other currency returns owing to the fact that returns on U.S. assets consist only of the respective interest earnings. Such dollar returns at time t are found to be affected by a six-lag structure, although the coefficients on the fourth and fifth lags are not statistically significant. However, the coefficient on the sixth lag of the dollar returns process is highly significant, indicating an apparent cycli­ cality to U.S. interest rates of a similar periodicity (a six-week cycle). Since the sum of the six coefficients in the lag structure is 0.989, U.S. dollar returns also appear to be stable. For most currency returns, the lagged squared errors contribute siz­ ably to the conditional variance, as indicated by the significant a; coeffi­ cients, which imply that currency returns are generated by processes with nonconstant unconditional variance. Because the principal assumption of constant variances of the error terms in an OLS estimation is violated, the latter methodology should not be used as an estimation procedure for currency returns. Furthermore, the coefficient structure in the ARCH model of U.S. dollar returns is monotonically decreasing, indicating that a squared error from the previous week has a greater effect on current conditional variance than a squared error from two weeks ago. An important observation on the statistical properties of the stochastic process followed by SDR returns is that the conditional variance of the SDR returns displays an optimal lag length of one, as only the coefficient on the first-period (squared) residual is statistically significant. Thus, the data indicate an ARCH process of order one. The estimated SDR returns have finite variance since the coefficient on the lagged residuals is less than one. The resulting ARCH effects for the SDR returns are further supported by their distributional properties of high leptokurtosis and the highly significant Bera-Jarque tests indicating � nonnormal distribution 14The implied annualized average weekly returns are calculated as [( 1+ �t - 1J wo, 1 0 where y = <l>o �� <j>;. Accordingly, the implied annualized average weekly returns for U.S. dollar inve�tm�nts are 4.84 percent, Japanese yen investments 11.34 percent, pound �terling mvestments 9.30 percent, french franc investments 11.15 fercent, SDR mvestments 6.56 percent, ECU mvestments 7.33 percent, AC investments 1.23 percent, and gold 0.96 percent, during the period February 1982 to December 1991. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE OF RESERVE CURRENCIES 675 for these returns. These empirical findings indicate that the conditional variance of the SDR returns is not constant over time and that optimiza­ tion of a portfolio that includes the SDR requires the use of techniques such as the ARCH methodology to measure risk or variance accurately. IV. Conclusions This paper provides empirical evidence that would permit investors, including central banks, to make more accurate calculations of optimal strategies in the management of their reserves. The gains in accuracy depend directly on how the variance, or risk, measures of the returns on various currency investments change over time. To test whether the variability of returns is constant, we employ the ARCH model, which was further used to estimate the variability of the returns on various currency investments. On the basis of weekly data for returns on nine types of currency and gold investments for the period February 1982 to December 1991, we show that the variances of total returns on all currencies and gold change significantly over time. Evidence of positive and highly significant auto­ correlation of the weekly returns on those assets and of their predictable level of variability is not consistent with the assumption of constant (time-invariant) risk that is often used in asset allocation models. The empirical results presented in this paper generally suggest that for a U.S. dollar-based investor an ARCH model that takes into account the non­ stationarity of return variability provides more accurate estimates of the variability of total returns on multicurrency investments than ordinary least squares models. In particular, the sign of the intercept in the ARCH specifications is nonnegative for all currencies, indicating that the variability of asset returns would increase in the absence of any influence from the previous period's returns. Another interesting empirical result is that the volatility of returns from investing in the deutsche mark, the pound sterling, the French franc, the Japanese yen, the ECU, the SDR, and gold is affected by the square of the residuals lagged one period, while the variability of returns on U.S. dollar assets is affected by the square of the residuals Jagged two periods and that of average composite index by the square of the residuals lagged five periods. This result means that for individual currencies the future effect of changes in variability lasts only a short period and diminishes over time. The variability of returns on U.S. investments may be attributed to the fact that they comprise only interest earnings on the respective assets. Interest rates, as opposed to exchange ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 676 MICHAEL G. PAPAlOANNOU and TUGRUL TEMEL rates, tend to exhibit longer persistence: they are influenced by longer lags. For a currency-composite investment, however, the effect lasts for a significantly longer period. The returns on investments in the SDR and ECU follow an ARCH process of order one, and their probability distributions appear to be highly leptokurtic. These results are broadly similar to those for individ­ ual currencies. In particular, the effect of the past-period error on the variance of SDR returns is smaller than that found for any of the other currency returns, largely owing to the built-in diversification of currencies in the SDR basket. In contrast, ECU returns exhibit the highest transmis­ sion of unexpected weekly shocks into returns volatility during the sample period. The difference between the statistical results for the SDR and those for the ECU could be attributed to the fact that the ECU contains more volatile currencies than those in the SDR. Further study of the SDR and ECU returns might shed some light on more fundamental differences between these two composite reserve assets. APPENDIX Calculation of Asset Returns This Appendix describes the various calculations used to develop our returns data. Asset Returns in Different Currencies Since exchange rates are expressed bilaterally against the U.S. dollar, our analysis is dollar based. The same procedure could be repeated for the mark-, yen-, or franc-based investors. We define dollar-based returns as follows: Yt. k = where e,,k [(1 + i,-u)(1 + e,. k) - 1]100, = (E,.k - E,-u)IE,-I.k; and y,,k = U.S. dollar-based returns on investments in currency k at time t; i,- 1,k = e,,k = E,,k = three-month treasury bill rate, on a weekly basis, for the country corresponding to currency k at time t 1; - rate of appreciation or depreciation of currency k against the U.S. dollar at time t; spot rate, defined as U.S. dollar per unit of local currency k at time t. The source for exchange rate and interest rate data for the various countries is the IMF Treasurer's Department data base. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE OF RESERVE CURRENCIES 677 Gold Returns in Different Currencies The formula used in the calculation of returns on gold is g, = ((G, - G,_ .) /G,_.)lOO, where g, and G, denote, respectively, the weekly percentage change in the U.S. dollar price of gold and the level of the U.S. dollar price of gold at time t. Further, we define GR,,k = g, + e,.k 100, where GR,.k denotes the weekly gold returns in U.S. dollars by investors of currency kat time t. The source for gold prices is the IMP Treasurer's Department data base. Average Composite Exchange and Interest Rates The hypothetical currency basket consists of seven currencies: the U.S. dollar (US), the pound sterling (PS), the deutsche mark (DM), the French franc (FF), the Swiss franc (SF), the Netherlands guilder (NG), and the Japanese yen (JY). A prespecified amount15 of these currencies and an average of their exchange rates (the noon quotations from London in terms of U.S. dollar) for the 1981-87 period are used to calculate the weight of each currency in the average composite exchange and interest rate. Calculation of Weights for the Composite Exchange and Interest Rates U.S. dollar Pound sterling Deutsche mark French franc Swiss franc Netherlands guilder Japanese yen Amount of currency in the basket 0.7217 0.0118 0.2775 0.0576 0.0423 0.0225 12.7213 Exchange rate (noon quotation from London) (US/US =) 1.000 (PSIUS =) 0.420 (DMIUS =) 1.974 (FFIUS =) 4.560 (SF/US =) 1.781 (NGIUS ) 2.142 (JYIUS =) 202.870 = Weights = amount /rate (wl ) 0.721654 (w2 =) 0.028120 (w3 =) 0.140601 (w4 ) 0.012631 (w5 =) 0.023759 (w6 =) 0.010526 (w7 =) 0.062706 = = The formulas by which the average composite exchange rates (ACE) and the average composite interest rates (ACI) are computed follow: ACE, = [w1( US IUS), + · · · + w7(JYIUS),] ACI, = [w1(USJ), + w2(PSJ), + · · · + w7(JYI),] where (US/), (PSI), . . . , (JYI) denote three-month treasury bill interest rates in the United States, United Kingdom, . . . , Japan, respectively. 15 It represents the average share of currencies in total official holdings of foreign exchange reserves for the 1981-87 period. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 678 MICHAEL G. PAPAIOANNOU and TUGRUL TEMEL REFERENCES Berndt, E.K., and others, "Estimation Inference in Nonlinear Structural Models," Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, Vol. 3 (1974), pp. 653-65. Black, Fisher, "Studies in Stock Price Volatility Changes," Proceedings of the 1976 Business Meeting of the Business and Economic Statistics Section, American Statistical Association (1976), pp. 177-81. Bollerslev, Tim, "A Conditional Heteroskedastic Time Series Model for Specu­ lative Prices and Rates of Return," Review of Economics and Statistics , Vol. 69 (1987), pp. 542-47. , "Modelling the Coherence in Short-Run Nominal Exchange Rates: A Multivariate Generalized ARCH Model," Review of Economics and Statis­ tics, Vol. 72 (1990), pp. 498-505. Bollerslev, Tim, Robert F. Engle, and Jeffrey M. Wooldridge, "A Capital Asset Pricing Model with Time-Varying Covariances," Journal of Political Econ­ omy, Vol. 96 (1988), pp. 116-31. De Jong, Frank, Angelien Kemna, and Teun Kloeck, "The Impact of Option Expirations on the Dutch Stock Market" (unpublished, Erasmus University, -- 1990). Diebold, Francis X., Empirical Modeling of Exchange Rate Dynamics (Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 1988). Diebold, Francis X., and Marc Nerlove, "The Dynamics of Exchange Rate Volatility: A Multivariate Latent Factor ARCH Model," JournalofApplied Econometrics, Vol. 4 (1989), pp. 1-21. Engle, Robert F., "Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity with Esti­ mates of the Variance of United Kingdom Inflation," Econometrica, Vol. 50 (1982), pp. 987-1007. , "Estimates of the Variance of U.S. Inflation Based on the ARCH Model," Journal of Money , Credit, and Banking, Vol. 15 (1983), pp. --- 286-301. Engle, Robert F., Victor Ng, and Michael Rothschild, "Asset Pricing with a Factor-ARCH Covariance Structure," Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 45 (1990), pp. 213-37. Engle, Robert F., and Dennis F. Kraft, "Multiperiod Forecast Error Variances of Inflation Estimated from ARCH Models," in Applied Time Series Anal­ ysis of Economic Data, ed. by A. Zellner (Washington: Bureau of the Census, 1983), pp. 293-302. Engle, Robert F., David M. Lilien, and Russell P. Robins, "Estimating Time­ Varying Risk Premia in the Term Structure: The ARCH-M Model," Econo­ metrica, Vol. 55 (1987), pp. 391-407. Engle, Robert F., and Chowdhury Mustafa, "Implied ARCH Models from Options Prices" (unpublished; University of California, San Diego, 1989). Engle, Robert F., and Gloria Gonzales-Rivera, "Semiparametric ARCH Mod­ els" (unpublished; University of California, San Diego, 1989). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE OF RESERVE CURRENCIES 679 Engle, Robert F., and Michael Rothschild, eds., "ARCH Models in Finance," Journal of Econometrics , Vol. 52 (April/May 1992). Fama, Eugene F., "The Behavior of Stock Market Prices," Journal of Business , Vol. 38 (1965), pp. 34-105. Greene, William H., Econometric Analysis (New York: Macmillan, 1990). Hall, Steven G., David K. Miles, and Mark Taylor, "A Multivariate GARCH in Mean Estimation of the Capital Asset Pricing Model," Discussion Paper Technical Series No. 19 (London: Bank of England, 1988). Hendry, David F., PC Give: An Interactive Econometric Modelling System, Version 6.0/6.01 (Great Britain: Bidolles Ltd., Guildford and King's Lynn. January 1989). Kraft, Dennis F., and Robert F. Engle, "Autoregressive Conditional Het­ eroskedasticity in Multiple Time Series" (unpublished; University of Califor­ nia, San Diego, 1983). Kroner, F. Kenneth, and Stijn Claessens, "Optimal Dynamic Hedging Portfolios and the Currency Composition of External Debt," Journal of lmernarional Money and Finance, Vol. 10 (1991), pp. 131-48. Mandelbrot, Benoit B., "The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices,'· Journal of Business, Vol. 36 (1963), pp. 394-419. Nelson, Daniel B., "Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns: A New Approach," Econometrica, Vol. 59 (1991), pp. 347-70. Pagan, Adrian R., and G. William Scbwert, "Alternative Models for Conditional Stock Volatility," Journal of Econometrics , Vol. 45 (1990), pp. 267-90. Vries, Casper G., "On the Relation Between GARCH and Stable Processes:· Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 48 (1991), pp. 313-24. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF Staff Papers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) Q 1993 International Monetary Fund Interenterprise Arrears in Transforming Economies The Case of Romania ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN* This paper reviews Romania's experience with interenterprise arrears during 1991 with the purpose of extracting lessons that might prove useful for other economies in transition to market-based systems. The rapid growth of interenterprise arrears poses a serious policy problem in many of the transforming economies of Eastern Europe, as well as in the re­ publics of the former Soviet Union. Among the more striking cases is that of Romania, where gross interenterprise arrears grew almost 18-fold (to about 50 percent of GDP) in only one year. This paper discusses the de­ velopment of these arrears and the policies implemented by the authorities to try to resolve the problem. [JEL E51, E65] RAPID GROWTH of interenterprise arrears poses a serious policy THEproblem in many of the transforming economies of Eastern Europe, a phenomenon that is now evident as well in the republics of the former Soviet Union. 1 Undoubtedly, some part of these arrears can be consid­ ered "voluntary" credits, in the sense that they represent credit extended * Eric Y. Clifton, Deputy Division Chief in the European I Department, holds a doctorate from Indiana University. Mohsin S. Khan, Deputy Director of the Research Department, is a graduate of Columbia University and the London School of Economics and Political Science. The authors are grateful to Daniel Daianu, Luis Mendon�a. and Erik Offerdal for helpful discussions and comments. 1 See, for example, the studies by Begg and Partes (1992) for Czechoslovakia, Daianu (1993) for Romania, Ickes and Ryterman (1993) for Russia, and Ros­ towski (1992) for Poland and Russia. 680 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution INTERENTE RPRISE ARREARS IN ROMANIA 681 by one enterprise to another as part of normal business practice, much like trade credit is used in market-based economies. However, it is gen­ erally acknowledged that most ofthe arrears are involuntary, with enter­ prises simply not making payments to each other (or to the banks and government), and creditors unwilling or unable to enforce the due pay­ ments. Given the interlocking nature of enterprises in Eastern European countries-a legacy of the centrally planned system-such involuntary credits can rapidly balloon out of control, as they have in several of these countries. Many reasons have been advanced to explain the phenomenon of interenterprise arrears in the transforming economies. They range from financial underdevelopment and credit market failures, which cause en­ terprises to assume banking-type functions (Begg and Partes (1992), Ickes and Ryterman (1993)); tight credit policies, which create a liquidity crunch (Calvo and Coricelli (1992)); lack of credibility of the govern­ ment's reform program (Rostowski (1992)); and the particular structure of industry in a command economy, which is based on chain links between enterprises (Daianu (1993)). It is clear that no one explanation domi­ nates, and it would be fair to say that interenterprise arrears are due to a combination of factors, the relative weights of which vary from country to country. If allowed to grow unchecked, interenterprise arrears can, as argued recently by Begg and Partes (1992), place the entire reform process in jeopardy. In particular, hard budget constraints are softened for enter­ prises, and relative price changes become less meaningful. As a result, enterprises continue to behave as in the past and the restructuring to conform to market realities is delayed. This delay in the structural trans­ formation of the economy and the weakening of contract enforceability are perhaps the most important adverse effects of interenterprise arrears. In addition, interenterpri'se arrears have significant macroeconomic consequences. First, arrears can undermine monetary control and thus limit the effects of tight credit policy on inflation and the balance of payments. More specifically, recourse to arrears to finance expenditures can lead to shifts in the demand for bank credit and in the income velocity of money, making it more problematic for the authorities to design and execute monetary policy. Second, interenterprise arrears can lead to inefficiencies in, and the eventual breakdown of, the payments mecha­ nism, with obvious adverse effects on production and output. As enter­ prises bypass the banking system and arrears begin to reach a level they consider undesirable, cash transactions become more and more preva­ lent. This "cash-in-advance" constraint on transactions becomes binding and, if the authorities are unwilling to provide the needed currency, ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 682 ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN production begins to suffer. 2 Finally, the arrears of state-owned enter­ prises represent a potential fiscal liability of the government. At some point in time, the government would have to cover these quasi-fiscal deficits, thereby affecting private sector behavior both now and in the future. Since large-scale restructuring, involving closures and privatization, does not seem to be in the cards in the short run-indeed it is the absence of such restructuring that has caused arrears to emerge and grow as they have-the government has to find a solution. But it is very important that this solution not give rise to a moral hazard problem. A generalized "bailout" runs the risk of creating expectations of future bailouts, with enterprises having an incentive to run up arrears again. Of course the government could ignore the problem, letting it resolve itself over time as arrears eventually stop growing and some type of adjustment occurs, but this adjustment is bound to be disorderly. All enterprises, viable and nonviable alike, would suffer from the chain reaction of closures that would occur. Widespread production collapses and soaring unemploy­ ment would certainly create difficulties for the reform process. Thus, governments in the transforming economies are placed in the position of having to find an optimal solution that falls somewhere between the two undesirable extremes of a general bailout and doing nothing. While the interenterprise arrears problem is evident in other Eastern European countries, the case of Romania during 1991 is perhaps the most striking.3 Gross interenterprise arrears grew almost 18-fold4-from lei 100 billion to nearly lei 1,800 billion-in a span of only 12 months, giving rise to many of the adverse consequences mentioned above: inflation was substantially higher and output much lower than had been expected at the beginning of 1991. Also, at the end of the year the authorities were forced to take actions to clear these arrears. This paper reviews the Romanian experience of 1991 with the express purpose of extracting lessons-both positive and negative-that might prove useful for other economies in transition. 2 Although lack of credit may be a factor in the decline in output, as ar�ued by Calvo and Coricelli (1992), arrears can compensate for this, at least parttally. Eventually, however it is the lack of currency that becomes the relatively more important factor. 3 In many respects, as argued by Rostowski (1992), the Romanian situation is more akin to that of Russia than to the other Eastern European cases of Czechoslovakia and Poland. 4 Gross arrears are the total stock of arrears before netting out bilateral and multilateral payables and receivables. , ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution !NTERENTERPRISE ARREARS IN ROMANIA 683 I. Developments in Interenterprise Arrears This section reviews the history of interenterprise arrears in Romania during the centrally planned regime and subsequently. Practices Under the Centrally Planned Regime5 Under the strict system of central planning that operated in Romania until December 1989, the Government had virtually complete control over enterprise management and finances. The authorities also had com­ plete discretion in determining the tax burden on individual enterprises. Thus, the distinction between whether state-owned enterprises-which covered virtually all means of production except for a small proportion of land cultivated by private farmers-were actually paying taxes or just transferring to government the profits that already belonged to it in its capacity as owner of the enterprises was not clear. The tax burden of enterprises steadily increased during the 1980s as the Government needed to generate large fiscal surpluses as part of the policy to repay the external debt. 6 As a result, enterprises were left with inad­ equate funds to finance current operations and investment, and often with substantial after-tax losses. These losses were financed by the exten­ sion of bank credit, but to the extent that these loans were unserviceable the quality of the banks' balance sheets eroded. In addition, bank credit was typically extended to clear domestic payments arrears. Thus, under the centrally planned regime there were no interenterprise arrears as such. All arrears were to banks since they automatically provided credit to those enterprises that were unable to make their payments to other firms and creditors. The arrears, then, simply showed up as bad debts on the books of the banking system. Developments Since 1990 From December 1989, policymakers in Romania have had to deal with the twin problems of bad debts of enterprises to banks and arrears with other enterprises. 5 For details of economic developments and policies during the pre-reform period, see Demekas and Khan (1991). 6Tbis tax came to be known as the "Ceaucescu tax." ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 684 ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN Unserviceable Bank Loans After the change of government in late 1989, the bad debts of enter­ prises to banks resulting from the practices of the centrally planned regime started being written off against government bank deposits from past fiscal surpluses. In this way, all enterprise bad debts from before 1989 and most from 1989 (a total of lei 265 billion) were eliminated. After government deposits were exhausted in mid-1990, lei 96 billion of bad debts from 1989 remained on the books of banks carrying a 0.5 percent interest rate. These credits were refinanced by the National Bank of Romania (NBR) at the same rate. Part of the debt (about lei 5 billion) was cleared in the last two months of 1990, leaving lei 91 billion of the bad 1989 debts (already refinanced by the NBR) with banks. Enterprises realized further losses in 1990, some of which (especially in the mining and energy sectors and in the food industry) were covered by budgetary subsidies. The subsidies did not cover all enterprises, how­ ever, and lei 41 billion of 1990 losses was l�ft. This balance was mostly covered by automatic bank credit (about lei 31 billion), as in the past. Thus, at end-1990, there were about lei 122 billion of enterprise bad debts to banks (lei 91 billion from 1989 and about lei 31 billion from 1990). In 1991, the amount of bad debts outstanding declined as enterprises were forced to clear their overdue bank debts using the proceeds from sales of revalued stocks. In order to increase the effectiveness of credit policy and to ensure that the past losses of enterprises were not a burden on the financial system, the authorities decided to eliminate the remaining amount of 1989 and 1990 unserviceable bank loans from bank balance sheets with the issuance of long-term government debt instruments. This operation began in August 1991 and was formalized on February 5, 1992, when the Roma­ nian Parliament approved Law 7 , transforming 90 percent of these claims on enterprises into a special public debt account. The other 10 percent of the loans were charged off against banks' profits. The sale of state assets and the recovery of outstanding claims of enterprises are to cover the principal and interest payments. Interenterprise Arrears Starting in late 1990, enterprise payments difficulties-in addition to the problem of bad debts to banks-appeared in the system. They were reflected in mounting interenterprise payments arrears, which on a gross basis at end-1990 reached an estimated lei 100 billion.7 As banks became 7 No information is available on interenterprise credits as distinct from arrears. Starting in late 1990 direct payments between enterprises stopped being docu­ mented by the banking system. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 685 fNTERENTERPRISE ARREARS IN ROMANIA Table 1. Romania: Money, Credit, lnterenterprise Arrears, and Industrial Production (In billions of lei) Period December 1990 January 1991 February March April May June July August September October November December January 1992 Broad money Credit to nongovernment Interenterprise arrears 514 519 546 517 525 568 567 595 600 602 671 815 885b 1,066c 684 703 731 756 765 788 811 839 806 749 839 899 954b 1 ,312c 100 206 307 400 482 550 600 637 691 800 1,000 1,317 1,777b Industrial production" 100.0 79.8 79.8 86.1 90.0 90.6 92.6 83.8 80.9 81.3 77.9 70.1 68.2 69.8 Sources: Romanian authorities and IMF staff estimates. • Index, December 1990 100. b Excludes the effect of the global compensation of December 1991. c Includes the effect of the global compensation of December 1991. = more selective in granting credit, partly because of the tight credit policy implemented through bank-specific credit ceilings, enterprises started to run arrears among themselves as a way of financing current opera­ tions. By end-March 1991, interenterprise payments arrears reached an estimated lei 400 billion (see Table 1 and Figure 1). The growth of arrears accelerated sharply in the second half of 1991, primarily because of two factors. First, price increases resulting in part from the elimination of price controls and the removal of subsidies were much higher than projected, while credit expansion through September was kept on target (consistent with the lower projected rate of inflation). Real credit thus declined far more than had been envisaged and enter­ prises came under considerable strain. Second, from about midyear it became increasingly evident that the Government would need to arrest the progressively deteriorating economic situation. Output continued to fall, and its slide was partly attributable to the so-called blockage of the payments system brought about by interenterprise arrears (see Table 1).8 8 As mentioned earlier, cash transactions became more prevalent. For exam­ pble, the ratio of currency to deposits rose from 20 percent in January to 32 percent y September-October. For a discussion of the factors behind the decline in output, see Borensztein, Demekas, and Ostry (1993). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 686 ERIC V. CUFfON and MOHSIN S. KHAN Figure I . Romania: Broad Money, l111eremerprise Arrears, and Consumer Price Index Billions of lei 2500 Index. October 1990-100 450 2000 380 Consumer price index (rif/111 scale) 1500 310 ... . .. 1000 Arrrars (left seait!) . .... ... soo 240 170 Broad money (leji Sc(l/1.') 0 D 1990 F M A A M s 0 N D 100 1991 Sources: Romanian authorities and JMF staff estimates. In July, for example, industrial production fell by nearly 10 percent, and again in August by another 3.5 percent. Enterprises were very vocal at the time in blaming the financial payments blockage for these develop­ ments and began pressing hard for a resolution. Thus, a bailout looked likely, and by September-October the issue was even being discussed in Parliament. Enterprises therefore had an incentive to increase arrears further, and did so in the expectation that they would receive government assistance to cover their debts. On a gross basis, arrears rose to lei 1,777 billion at end-1991, represent­ ing about 50 percent of GDP valued at December 1991 prices. Net arrears-the amount of payments owed by net debtor enterprises to net creditor enterprises, plus arrears to the state (largely for tax payments)- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution INTERENTERPRISE ARREARS IN ROMANIA 687 were lei 426 billion at end-1991.9 (The tax arrears amounted to about lei 40 billion.) The growth of gross interenterprise arrears closely matched the rise in the consumer price level during 1991 (Figure 1). Indeed, it appears that the arrears were implicitly indexed to the price level, in that when creditor enterprises were not paid on time they would rebill the debtor enterprises at the new, higher prices. Reflecting a tight monetary policy stance, broad money grew by 17 per­ cent through September 1991, while bank credit to the nongovern­ ment sector grew by 10 percent (inflation was 132 percent over the period). Starting in October, however, the NBR began to allow an expansion of bank credit to enterprises to reduce the problem of inter­ enterprise arrears, and bank-specific credit ceilings were suspended. Through December 1991, broad money grew by 71 percent and credit to the nongovernment sector grew by 40 percent (compared with a cumula­ tive inflation of 223 percent). At end-1991, gross interenterprise arrears were equivalent to 208 percent of broad money and 194 percent of credit to the nongovernment sector. The income velocity of broad money rose from about 1.8 in 1990 to 4.0 in September 1991 before falling back to 3.7 in December 1991 (Fig­ ure 2). Interenterprise arrears were, of course, also liquidity being pro­ vided to the system in addition to the normal money supply. The effects of the additional liquidity can be judged by adding interenterprise arrears to broad money. The ratio of GDP to the sum of gross interenterprise arrears and broad money was 1.2 in December 1991 (Figure 2). A similar calculation using net interenterprise arrears yields a value of 2.5, which is close to the average velocity observed during the early 1980s and considered to be "normal" velocity. II. Policies to Control and Clear Interenterprise Arrears To combat the interenterprise arrears problem, a series of selec­ tive measures was considered and adopted starting in May 1991, culmi­ nating in a generalized scheme, termed "global compensation," in late December 1991. Early Attempts To reduce the interenterprise arrears problem, on May 8, 1991, the a refinancing line of lei 15.5 billion for banks, which were NBR opened 9Historically, net arrears have been approximately 20-30 percent of gross arrears. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 688 ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN Figure 2. Romania: Income Ve/ociry ofMoney. 1980-9/ GOP/broad money ratio 4.0 .-------,,--, .l5 ExdudinK imerenrerprise arrears" 3.0 2.5 . 20 lndudill8 imerenterprise arrearsa 1.5 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 , .. . 1991 Sources: Romanian authorities and IMF staff estimates. "Monthly data for 1991. instructed to extend credit to net debtor enterprises. These credits were extended through special accounts, so that the banks could ensure that the credits were used solely for the clearance of arrears. The operation was to last through June, by which time banks were to have closed the special accounts and repaid the lei 15.5 billion to the NBR. In the two weeks following the scheme's introduction, lei 10.5 billion of credits were extended to enterprises. The operation did not work as expected, how­ ever. About lei 65 billion of gross arrears were cleared by end-June, but the special NBR credits-plus an additional lei 5 billion extended through the same special accounts in June-were not repaid as planned. In effect, the arrears shifted from the enterprise sector to the banking system and ultimately to the NBR. By the end of June 1991, gross interenterprise arrears had reached an estimated lei 600 billion. In July, the authorities developed another plan to clear interenterprise ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution INTERENTERPRISE ARREARS LN ROMANIA 689 arrears. The new scheme aimed to cover all losses and arrears through bank credit refinanced entirely by the NBR and extended through special accounts. After banks recorded all enterprise claims against each other (a process that was to be completed by end-July), they were to extend as much credit as necessary to enable all enterprises to service the claims against them through a special "compensation" account. The settlement of interenterprise claims was to take place in the first two weeks of August. By August 15, all enterprises were to have no claims outstanding against each other. As a result, some would hold a net creditor position in their compensation accounts with banks; others would hold a net debtor position. By August 28, banks were to close the compensation accounts by consolidating them with the current accounts of enterprises. Net creditor enterprises would then find their overall bank debt reduced by the amounts available to them in their compensation accounts, whereas compensation credit extended to net debtor enterprises would be reclassified as regular credit, and normal interest rates would apply. It was estimated that clearing the interenterprise arrears through this scheme would require a net infusion of credit on the order of lei 150-300 billion. 10 The authorities decided not to implement the scheme, however, until more accurate estimates of the size of interenterprise arrears were avail­ able. The NBR was instructed to collect data on gross interenterprise arrears and to reconcile them with independent estimates from the Ministry of Industry (which were substantially smaller). It was then to estimate the net position of the enterprise sector vis-a-vis the banking system and the Government, as well as to identify the "worst offend­ ers"-those enterprises with large net debtor positions. Once this infor­ mation was available, the NBR was to determine the amount of bank credit needed for the operation. Moreover, the compensation scheme was to be combined with the closing down of insolvent enterprises. A scaled-down version of the arrears-clearing scheme was imple­ mented in late August 1991. Affected enterprises deposited 10 percent of their current receipts into a special account, which was used to clear overdue payments between enterprises. 11 These deposits, together with certain payments by the Government and very short-term credits ex­ tended by banks, were used to clear about lei 150 billion of gross inter­ enterprise arrears. However, the authorities estimated that arrears con10 Gross interenterprise arrears were estimated at the time to be around lei 600-700 billion (Table 1). 11 The affected enterpri ses covered all but 100 of the some 6,000 enterprises in Romania. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 690 ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN tinued to rise, so that the balance of gross arrears at the end of September was about lei 800 billion. In the authorities' view, the operation was not a success because it was basically a voluntary operation on the part of enterprises and the net amount of credit that was injected into the system was considered too little. Global Compensation On December 23, 1991, Parliament passed Law 80 calling for a gener­ alized expansion of bank credit to clear all interenterprise arrears. This operation, termed "global compensation," was completed on Janu­ ary 27, 1992. Under the global compensation scheme, enterprises were asked to list their arrears to other enterprises and to the state, and banks were instructed to expand credit, carrying a government guarantee, to clear the gross amount of interenterprise arrears. The initial bank credit extended under the scheme was lei 1,777 billion. All payments under the scheme were made as overdrafts from special "compensation accounts," and the same accounts were also debited with the payments received by enterprises. Thus, the gross amount of credit extended was automatically transformed into the net amount. The net amount of arrears-lei 426 billion-was retroactively reflected in bank balance sheets as of end­ December 1991. Of the net credit extended under the global compensa­ tion scheme, only lei 163 billion was refinanced by the NBR at the normal refinance rate; the rest was financed by banks out of deposits. The compensation credits had a six-month maturity with interest rates at market levels. 13 Because many enterprises that were net creditors to other enterprises were net debtors to the banking system, much of the net credit extended under the scheme went initially toward reducing overdrafts with banks. Some enterprises-mostly agricultural cooperatives-chose not to par­ ticipate in the scheme since they were receiving, in effect, an interest-free loan in the form of arrears. It is believed, however, that the number of debtor firms that refused to participate in the global compensation was small, and all large enterprises participated in the scheme. As a result, almost all known interenterprise arrears were eliminated. Following from the global compensation operation, the money supply increased by an additional lei 149 billion in December to reach lei 1,033 12 12Basically Law 80 was closely related to the July scheme that bad been considered and then rejected by the Government. 13 It is worth noting in this regard that at end-1992 some of these credits were still outstanding. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution lNTERENTERPRJSE ARREARS IN ROMANIA 691 billion by year end. Thus, the increase in broad money over the year was 99 percent. Also, through end-December, the net domestic assets of the banking system increased by lei 522 billion. The rise in prices over the year was 223 percent, compared with a projected increase of 105 percent. Resolving the Liquidity and Moral Hazard Problems The first order of business after the global compensation scheme had been completed was to sterilize the injection of liquidity to prevent an upsurge of inflation. In February 1992, the authorities introduced a 10 percent reserve requirement on deposits in the banking system. This move was followed by additional measures, including requiring some enterprises and banks to repay certain credits that had not yet matured and requiring importers to make payments to cover letters of credit that had been guaranteed by the Government. As a result of these sterilization measures, the money supply rose by only 4 percent from December 1991 through April 1992 in the face of cumulative inflation of 54 percent. Bank credit to the nongovernment sector declined by 6 percent over the same period. Although controlling the expansion of liquidity was necessary, the moral hazard problem was the more serious consequence of the global compensation. At issue was how to convince enterprises that there would be no future compensations and that the Government was determined to control interenterprise arrears. Toward this end, the authorities insti­ tuted a system to monitor arrears and introduced legislation designed to control the arrears. As part of a general reporting system established in 1991, all of the 6,000 state-owned enterprises are required to provide the Ministry of Economy and Finance with operating accounts on a monthly basis, balance sheets on a quarterly basis, and more detailed accounts annually. This reporting system was expanded in 1992 to coverarrears. The buildup of new arrears is now reported on a monthly basis for domestic suppliers (interenterprise arrears), foreign suppliers, other credits (including wage arrears), and foreign services (such as freight charges). Overdue pay­ ments to domestic suppliers are reported in three categories: more than 30 days overdue, more than 90 days overdue, and more than one year overdue. Information on arrears on loans to banks is reported monthly by commercial banks through the NBR. With these reporting systems in place, the authorities have up-to-date information on the financial posi­ tion of each enterprise, including any arrears, and thus can take selective action against those enterprises running arrears. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 692 ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN Possible actions are spelled out in a new law on enterprise financial discipline (Law 76).14 This law specifies the procedures to be followed by all enterprises irrespective of their form of ownership. The more salient items in the law include the following: i. Economic agents with overdue payments obligations that remain un­ settled for more than 30 calendar days after the due date shall be considered insolvent. Payments insolvency must be communicated to the debtor by any creditors, including the state, after the period of 30 days has expired (Article 9). ii. Following a court decision confirming insolvency, creditors can take action to "liquidate" the unsettled claims they have on their debtors. Eco­ nomic agents having unsettled claims shall be sued and subjected to "forced" payment or the sale of their assets in the following order: monetary means, including deposits in banks; inventories of raw materials and finished prod­ ucts; claims and fixed assets; and other estate items (Article 10). iii. The list of economic agents declared insolvent shall be made public (Article 12). As passage of Law 76 by Parliament took considerably longer than expected, the Government adopted two decisions (Decision 82 and De­ cision 162) to enforce the provisions of the new law. Under these deci­ sions, if enterprises are unable to reach agreement on overdue payments, creditors can initiate bankruptcy proceedings against debtors under the provisions of the existing commercial code, with the Government actively involved in the process. The largest and most important arrears problems can be considered by the Cabinet, which can decide on measures to be taken against the defaulting enterprise-including accelerated privatiza­ tion, full or partial liquidation, directed labor shedding, financial restruc­ turing, and management changes. The Government also launched a public campaign to convince enterprises that arrears are to be avoided and no further bailouts are likelyY The delays in the passage of the law on financial discipline, and more fundamentally the inability and unwillingness of the Government to move forcefully and quickly to improve the financial discipline of enter­ prises, meant that the moral hazard issue was not resolved. Enterprises 14The full title of the new law is "Concerning Measures to Reimburse Credits Extended in Connection with the Global Compensation Operation, to Introduce a New Regime of Payments for Economic Agents, to Prevent Payments Insol­ vency and Financial Blockage." It was enacted on July 16, 1992. 15 In addition, a World Bank Structural Adjustment Loan also puts a condition on the level of arrears for second-tranche release-the ratio of arrears of state­ owned enterprises to state-owned enterprise turnover should not exceed 7.5 percent. Since turnover is approximately twice nominal GDP, this condition would imply that gross arrears could not exceed 15 percent of GDP (as compared with 50 percent of GDP in 1991). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution INTERENTERPRTSE ARREARS IN ROMANIA 693 continued to behave largely as before, presumably confident that the Government would do nothing drastic in terms of closures or downsizing and that there was every likelihood of future bailouts. Arrears, therefore, grew once again in 1992, although at a somewhat slower pace as com­ pared with the previous year. By December 1992, gross interenterprise arrears were approximately lei 1.9 trillion (20 percent of GDP valued at December 1992 prices). This time, however, the Government has not contemplated any kind of global compensation and has made public statements to this effect. Also, in mid-1993, the Parliament passed an amendment to Law 76, which would impose interest penalties on overdue obligations and establish an expedited judicial procedure to enable cred­ itors to obtain payment. Nevertheless, the question of how to resolve the stock problem of existing arrears and the flow problem of new arrears is again confronting the Government. More generally, changing the culture of nonpayment, which was pervasive in 1991 and continued through 1992, remains the major task for the Romanian Government. III. Conclusions Transforming the enterprise sector in Romania, as in other formerly centrally planned economies, has proved a much slower process than originally expected. Three years into the reform effort, a network of large state-owned monopolies still dominate the economy. The down­ sizing, restructuring, technological upgrading, and reorienting required of Romania's production sector remain to be done. One of the major fallouts of the slow transformation was the phenom­ enal rise in interenterprise arrears in 1991. Enterprises, faced with a new environment in which banks were no longer willing to supply credit passively, in effect created their own means of payment. Running arrears became a substitute for bank financing, with obvious adverse impli­ cations for the stabilization effort. Output eventually suffered as the payments system became progressively inoperative and cash transfers became the principal means of settlement. The global compensation scheme implemented by the Government at the beginning of 1992 was successful in clearing most of the interenter­ prise arrears and thus in unblocking the payments system. The particular way this scheme was designed minimized the net injection of liquidity into the economy, and even that liquidity was largely sterilized by the author­ ities. All in all, the monetary consequences of the operation were fairly small relative to the size of the gross interenterprise arrears. To combat the moral hazard consequences of the global compensation scheme, the ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 694 ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN Government introduced a new law that laid out specific procedures for controlling any future interenterprise arrears and thus the need for any further compensation operations. The provisions of this law, however, have yet to be effectively implemented, and the problems with arrears remain. A permanent solution to the problem of interenterprise arrears must involve the restructuring and privatization of state-owned enterprises. The Government of Romania is proceeding in this direction. It has selected a number of major enterprises for restructuring, primarily in the chemical, metallurgy, and machine-building sectors, and is implementing the Law on Privatization, which was passed in 1991. Under the Jaw, "vouchers" for 30 percent of the share capital of enterprises were dis­ tributed in 1992 to Romanian citizens. Further, the State Ownership Fund (which holds the Government's 70 percent share) and the National Agency for Privatization are responsible for developing the privatiza­ tion strategy with the aim of promoting a more competitive industrial structure through enterprise restructuring. Jointly, the restructuring and privatization plans are expected to re­ store the financial health of enterprises in Romania. Once they are achieved, and the appropriate legal framework established and operative, the interenterprise arrears problem will presumably take care of itself, as in Western economies (Begg and Portes (1992)). This is not to suggest that government-sponsored bailouts will never occur. Even in the most developed market economies, governments have needed to intervene financially to support financial sector institutions and other large enter­ prises. This intervention has been selective rather than industry wide, however, and can be rationalized on a variety of grounds. The Romanian experience of 1991 with interenterprise arrears and the attempts to resolve the problem have lessons for other countries that bear spelling out. • The problem of interenterprise arrears is a serious one; if not ad­ dressed, arrears can explode and create serious difficulties for the stabi­ lization and reform efforts. As the owner of the enterprises running arrears against one another, the state has a direct responsibility to intervene; it cannot take a hands-off approach. • However, once the government has decided on a course of action to resolve the arrears situation, it should proceed rapidly to imple­ ment the chosen measures. Public discussion over an extended period of time, as the Romanian experience shows, creates obvious incentives for enterprises to run larger arrears. • The selected scheme should aim to clear most or all arrears or it should not be undertaken at all. Too limited a scheme will leave the ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution INTERENTERPR1SE ARREARS IN ROMANIA 695 problem unresolved and set up expectations of further extensions and repetitions. • In any scheme to eliminate arrears, the monetary consequences of the operation must be taken into account. It must also be clear who is to pay for the operation-enterprises, the banking system, or the budget. Otherwise, behavior will not change, as each group will expect the others to bear the cost. • The scheme also must be designed so that credits are extended only toward the clearance of arrears and so that there are no leakages. The use of special compensation accounts in the Romanian operation pre­ vented enterprises from using credits to finance current expenditures and make wage payments. • To minimize the moral hazard problem, a method of ensuring that arrears do not reappear must be adopted in conjunction with any chosen scheme. Closing down a large, nonviable enterprise may provide an important signal of the government's commitment to enforcing financial discipline. This step has proven extremely difficult in all transform­ ing economies, however. Nonetheless, some way must be found to demonstrate that the government's statements about future bailouts are credible. • The government will have to take the lead in initiating bankruptcy proceedings against defaulting enterprises. Experience has shown that banks and other creditors are highly unlikely to take debtor enterprises to court. Regardless of the fact that the state owns the enterprise, the government must become involved anyway when it comes to enter­ prises considered "too big to fail." In Romania, for example, past policies have emphasized the geographical dispersion of enterprises, leaving many towns hostage to the fortunes of one or two large enterprises. Liquidation of these large "Kombinats" would cause serious unem­ ployment and severe regional distress, making government intervention necessary anyway. • Ultimately, privatization is the solution-the faster this occurs, the faster arrears will disappear. In a largely private system, interenterprise credits will be part of normal business, and overdue payments will be handled appropriately through the legal system. REFERENCES Begg, David, and Richard Portes, Enterprise Debt and Economic Transforma­ tion: Financial Restructuring in Central and Eastern Europe" (unpublished; Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1992). " ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 696 ERIC V. CLIFTON and MOHSIN S. KHAN Borensztein, Eduardo, Dimitri Demekas, and Jonathan D. Ostry, "An Empirical Analysis of the Output Declines in Three Eastern European Countries," Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (March 1993), pp. 1-31. Calvo, Guillermo, and Fabrizio Coricelli, "Stabilizing a Previously Centrally Planned Economy: Poland 1990," Economic Policy, Vol. 14 (1992), pp. 176-226. Daianu, Daniel, "Inter-Enterprise Arrears in Post Command Economy: Thoughts from a Romanian Perspective" (unpublished; International Mon­ etary Fund, 1993). Demekas, Dimitri, and Mohsin S. Khan, The Romanian Economic Reform Program, Occasional Paper No. 89 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991). Ickes, Barry W., and Randi Ryterman, "Inter-Enterprise Arrears and Financial Underdevelopment in Russia" (unpublished; International Monetary Fund, 1993). Rostowski, Jacek, "The Inter-Enterprise Debt Explosion in the Former Soviet Union: Causes, Consequences, Cures" (unpublished; International Mone­ tary Fund, 1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF StaffPapers Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) Q 1993 International Monetary Fund Shorter Paper The Budget Deficit in Transition A Cautionary Note VITO TANZI* This paper discusses major fiscal issues faced by the previously centrally planned economies in their transition to market economies. It focuses on the extent to which the budget deficit should guide policy and the in­ teractions between fiscal policy and other aspects of the macroeconomy. [JEL H2, H3, HS, H6, P2, P3) D URING CENTRAL PLANNING, it was not really meaningful to speak of since these concepts imply the exis­ tence ofprivate finance and thus a significant private sector. 1 In that era, all was public in a way. However, many "fiscal" functions, as defined in market economies, were carried out not by government but by state enterprises. These enterprises often provided to their workers housing, hospital care, vocational training, kindergarten facilities, shops, pen­ sions, various forms of welfare assistance, employment, and so forth. They were also responsible for much "public" investment. Because the state enterprises were required to hire workers even when they did not need them, official unemployment was nonexistent. As a consequence, no programs existed to protect unemployed workers. In economies in transition, state enterprises are still carrying out many of these fiscal fiscal policy and public finance * Vito Tanzi is Director of the Fiscal Affairs Department. He holds a doctorate from Harvard University. Very useful comments were received from S .J. Anjaria, Gerard B elanger, Guillermo Calvo, Carlo Cottarelli, Manuel Guitian, George ling-Smee, and several colleagues within the Fiscal Affairs Depart­ lden, John O d ment. The author is solely responsible for the views expressed. 1 Recall that, in market economies, p ublic sector activ1 ty is largely justified by (private) market failure See Stiglitz (1989) and Musgrave (1959). . 697 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 698 VITO TANZI functions and are still hoarding workers. For the transformation to mar­ ket economies to be completed, most legitimate social functions must be shifted from the state enterprises to the government. As this shift takes place, spending by the enterprises will fall and spending by the government will rise. 2 In spite of occasional divergent views, most economists agree that, in market economies, the fiscal deficit is a useful guide for assessing fiscal policy. A large deficit indicates that (unless a strong case to the contrary can be made) fiscal policy should become more restrictive. The concept of fiscal deficit implies that government activities can be sharply delin­ eated from those of the private sector.3 Thus, expenditures and revenues are either public or private. The measure of the fiscal deficit requires that the difference between what the public sector spends and what it collects can be accurately calculated. With full employment, if the public sector spends more, the private sector must spend less, unless the economy is able to attract foreign saving. Thus, the existence of a fiscal deficit implies some (unwanted) crowding out of the private sector unless Ricardian equivalence or a Keynesian multiplier can be assumed to operate. I. Budget Deficit Limits and Perverse Incentives There are several reasons for caution when using this concept to guide policy action during the transition. Some of these reasons are conceptual. Others deal with measurement problems. Still others originate from the possibility that strict limits on an inadequate measure of the fiscal deficit may create perverse incentives, which may slow down the transformation. Transferring Social Expenditure Responsibility State enterprises in economies in transition continue to dominate eco­ nomic activity and provide social services to workers and their families. Some of these services are provided in place of higher money wages. Others are provided in place of higher budgetary expenditure. In other words, these enterprises continue to perform some functions that in market economies are financed through the government budget. The transition to a market economy requires that the budget assume the responsibility for those social functions that the country wishes to 2 This does not imply that the government needs to assume all the functions now carried out by the enterprises. 3 It also implies that the fiscal activities of the government can be separated from the monetary activities. For example. the fiscal activities of central banks must be assessed as part of fiscal policy. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 699 BUDGET DEFICIT IN TRANSITTON finance publicly.4 This transfer to the budget should occur regardless of whether the state enterprises are privatized or not. The faster it occurs, the easier it will be for the enterprises to be privatized or to become economically viable while remaining state owned. The transfer of these functions to the budget will increase budgetary expenditure and, unless revenue is raised correspondingly, will also in­ crease the budget deficit.5Thus, the transfer should also reduce the credit needs of the state enterprises. For most of these countries, however, there is little solid knowledge about the potential impact on the budget of a total or partial transfer of these functions.6 In Russia, "the government appears not to have quantified the dimensions of this problem or planned a solution" (Wallich (1992, p. 7)). The more important are these func­ tions and the faster and the larger is their transfer to the budget, the greater will be the growth of budgetary expenditure. Thus, ex ante limits on the size of the budget deficit should explicitly allow for the budgetary cost of transferring some of these functions from the state enterprises to the budget.7 The possibility must be recognized that a limit on the budget deficit that ignores this transfer might be met by the government delaying the transfer of these social functions from the enterprises to the budget. This delay would slow down the process of transformation but would not reduce credit expansion if the banking system continues to react to the needs of the enterprises. If a decision were made to subsidize some loss-making state enter­ prises, it would be better economic policy if they were subsidized through the budget rather than through soft and cheap loans from the banking system.8 However, subsidies financed through the budget increase the budget deficit, and cheap loans do not. It would be unrealistic to assume that subsidies to enterprises, whether 4 The functions not taken over by the budget should no longer be the re­ sponsibility of the public sector and the state enterprises. By adJUSting money wages, workers could be given greater discretion over the use of the total compen­ sation they receive while the state enterprises could stop having to provide social services. 5Throughout the paper, the term "budget deficit" is used for that part of the fiscal deficit that is actually accounted for by the budget. This is the measure of deficit normally reported in newspapers and in government reports. The theoret­ ical concept of the fiscal deficit is much more comprehensive and much more difficult to measure (see various papers in Blejer and Cheasty (1993)). It extends to the whole public sector and includes quasi-fiscal deficits. 6There is no available estimate of the magnitude of these social functions. The World Bank is attempting to quantify them for Russia. The assumption is that they are quite important. 7These limits may be self-imposed or negotiated with international institutions or other creditors. 8The current situation in Russia, where the central bank continues to subsidize the state enterprises in particular sectors through subsidized credit and, in the process, creates inflationary pressures. shows the importance of this issue. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 700 VITOTANZI through the budget or through cheap and soft loans, could be completely and permanently abolished in the short run. Some of these enterprises (especially those in the defense industry) will be able to restructure and become economically viable only if they receive financial support for some time. It would also be unrealistic to assume that those who make or influence economic policy would look at cheap credit given directly through the banking system in the same way as they look at subsidies financed through the budget. 9 Thus, the argument that has occasionally been made-that the provision of subsidies through the banking system or the budget is only an accounting issue and would disappear if one measured the fiscaJ deficit in a comprehensive and economically sound way10-ignores the important point that economic policy is not always guided by the most economically correct concepts and that, in any case, the measurement of the all-embracing fiscal deficit is next to impossible under the circumstances prevailing in these countries. Thus, the mea­ sured (budget) deficit is likely to continue exerting more influence on policymakers and public opinion, both within and outside the countries, than the true but unknown (fiscal) deficit. For this reason, policymakers have an incentive to show a smaller budget deficit even when this action may conflict with other important economic and social objectives, such as the speed of transition to a market economy. If the government raised taxes on state enterprises' profits at the same time that the banking system extended cheap or soft loans to these enterprises, the budget deficit would fall expansion. without reducing monetary This implies that focusing on the budget deficit may lead observers and policymakers to miss the underlying cause of monetary expansion and could lead to the apparently anomalous situation (experi­ enced by Poland and, especially, Yugoslavia) of high inflation with the budget in surplus. Budget Deficit and Inflation The relationship between inflation, the budget deficit, and the public debt is also relevant to this discussion. To the extent that there is a 9 For one thing, it is difficult to calculate the subsidy element of subsidized credit. See, for example, the paper by Michael Wattleworth, "Credit Subsidies in Budg etary Lending: Computation, Effects, and Fiscal Implications," in Blejer and Chu (1988). Also, subsidies, given through the budget, would most likely be associated with more careful, or at least more politically debated, decisions about which enterprises should be subsidized. 10This measure would count the social expenditure by state enter rises in the p same way as budgetary expenditures. It would also count the subsidies given by the banking system as public spending. See, for example, Begg and Portes (1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 701 BUDGET DEFICIT IN TRANSlTION domestic public debt, an increase in the nominal interest rate paid on the public debt will be reflected in government expenditure and in the size of the budget deficit even if the rate of the increase matches exactly the increase in inflation-in other words, even if the real interest rate does not change. Given a significant public debt and a potentially high but unknown future rate of inflation, it is difficult to predict the effect on the deficit if the government pays a given real interest rate on its debt. Given a real rate of interest, the rise in the deficit will be a direct function of the size of the debt and the level of the nominal interest rate, which, in turn, will depend on the inflation rate. The potential effect of a change in the rate of inflation on the conventionally measured budget deficit could be very large. 11 In the situation described above, a government that has an interest in showing a smaller budget deficit might be tempted to repress nominal interest rates, thus creating difficulties for the development of the finan­ cial sector and for the allocation of financial resources. Under inflation­ ary conditions, concepts such as the operational or the primary deficit, which attempt to eliminate the impact of inflation on the deficit, may have to be used. But they will only correct the budget deficit rather than measure the true fiscal deficit. Furthermore, these concepts have their own limitations. Budget Deficit and the Unemployment Rate If state enterprises lay off redundant workers in order to improve their efficiency and, as a consequence, the government's spending for unem­ ployment compensation increases, the change will cause the budget deficit to rise. The rise will depend on the level of unemployment com­ pensation per worker and on the number of unemployed workers. For a given level of unemployment compensation per worker, the larger the adjustment in the work force by the state enterprises, and thus the greater the number of unemployed workers, the larger will be the potential impact of this adjustment on the budget deficit. Should the government be excessively concerned about the size of its budget deficit, it may encourage the state enterprises to continue hoarding workers. The potential impact of this factor on the budget deficits of countries in transition can be appreciated by the fact that falls in output that have, at times, been as large as, or larger than, 30 perc ent of GDP have 11 The relationship between the fiscal deficit, public debt and the inflation rate discussed in Tanzi, Blejer, and Teijeiro (1987). For references to the impact of this factor on the fiscal deficit of Latin American countries, see Tanzi (1992). was , ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 702 VlTOTANZI generally not resulted in corresponding increases in unemployment.12 If these countries had behaved like market economies, they would have experienced unemployment rates not seen since the Great Depression of the 1930s. 13 As long as the state enterprises continue to hoard workers, they will not be able to restructure and become efficient and competitive. It will also be more difficult to privatize them. 14 However, when the enterprises fully adjust their employment to their greatly reduced pro­ duction needs, and the governments take responsibility for financing the cost of unemployment, budgetary expenditures will go up. This increase must be taken into account in setting ex ante limits on the deficit, but it may be very difficult to forecast. Budget Deficit and the Exchange Rate If a country devalues its official exchange rate, its interest payments on foreign debt measured in domestic currency will rise, thus increasing public spending, and government expenditure on imports measured in domestic currency will also rise. Both of these factors would tend to raise the budget deficit.15 On the other hand, the devaluation will also increase the domestic value of exports by the public sector and the revenue from some taxes. However, if the proceeds from the public sector exports are outside the budget, even if the exporters are public institutions, the improvement will not be reflected directly in the budgetary accounts unless the exporters contribute significantly to tax revenue.16 In other words, the budget deficit will rise, and the rise will depend on the size 12 The situation is changing. For example, the unemployment rate in Hungary has risen from less than 1 percent in the first half of 1990 to more than 11 per­ cent in September 1992. In Bulgaria, it has risen from 1.6 percent in 1990 to 14 percent in 1992; in Poland, from 6.3 percent in 1990 to 13.5 percent in October 1992; and in Romania, from zero in 1990 to 10 percent in 1992. For the fall in output up to 1991, see IMF {1992a, p. 46). For the estimated fall in 1992, see IMF (1992b, p. 19). 13 Rates of 25 percent or higher were recorded. 14 In fact, privatization may in some cases raise the size of the fiscal deficit if the social expenditures that the government has to take over from the state enterprise exceed the revenue from the sale of the enterprise. 15 If the government is unable to pay the interest on the foreign debt, there will be a difference between accrued and cash measures of the budget deficit. Domes­ tic arrears to and from the government also create differences between cash and accrued measures of the budget deficit. 16The difficulties of the central governments of many of these countries, in controlling the accounts and the actions of the whole public sector, indicate that the budget may not be the beneficiary of devaluation. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution BUDGET DEFICIT IN TRANSITION 703 of the devaluation. 17 Rigid ex ante limits on the measured size of the fiscal deficit (that is, limits on the budget deficit) might encourage the author­ ities to delay the needed exchange rate adjustment especially when the external debt is large and the government's imports are significant. Shifting Expenditures out of the Budget Another perverse incentive that may arise from the attempt to show a smaller budget deficit or to stay below a too rigid limit is that of pushing expenditures out of the budget and into other parts of the public sector, whether extrabudgetary accounts or lower levels of government. Indeed, extrabudgetary accounts have proliferated in many economies in transi­ tion, though information on them has been elusive. Also, sizable expen­ ditures have been shifted onto local government. In this context, it may be worthwhile to cite from a study on fiscal decentralization in Russia by Christine Wallich (1992, p. 3): In the fiscal program for 1992, most of the major cuts were made in central government expenditures-centrally financed enterprise investment, pro­ ducer and consumer subsidies, and defense. These cuts were followed by a decision to delegate an important part of social expenditures (early in 1992), and investment outlays (later on) to the subnational level. On the tax side, the budget envisages a marked increase in taxes, primarily on petroleum products and foreign trade. Thus, virtually all additional revenue will accrue to the federal government, while most of the additional social expenditures will emerge at the subnationa/ level (italics in original). Wallich's conclusion is also worth citing: The basic strategy has been to · push the deficit downward'. by shifting unfunded expenditure responsibilities down in the hope that the subnational level will do the cost cutting (pp. 3-4). ' These are just a few examples of the possibilities that call for caution in the use of the budget deficit in guiding economic policy during the transition. They do not exhaust the possibilities. 18 They all point to the 17This discussion points to the importance of bringing the foreign trade area within the tax net. For example, it is important for imports to be subjected to the value-added tax. 18For example, a solution to the bad debt problem of the commercial banks and the arrears among enterprises might be delayed by the fact that the solution would raise the budget deficit. Begg and Portes (1992) have argued that if the deficit were properly measured, these policies would not change its size. How­ ever, the assumption of the bad debt of the banks by the government, by replacing bad assets with good assets would allow them to give more loans that might increase th e liquidity of the economy. , ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 704 VITOTANZI need to ensure that perverse incentives are not created by reliance on narrow concepts ofthe deficit. These incentives will exist when the deficit covers only a part of the public sector and when the limits imposed on it are too rigid. In this case, there will be an incentive to "park" the deficit where it cannot be measured or to postpone structural adjustments that may tend to increase the size of the measured deficit. 19 11. Need to Separate Fiscal from Monetary Policy A total and sharp separation between fiscal and monetary policy is next to impossible in any economy. There are always overlapping areas. For example, when central banks change the discount rate or engage in open market operations, these actions have an impact on the budget deficit. In general, these two policies are less clearly separated in developing countries than in industrial countries. In Latin America, for example, the central banks have, in several cases, engaged in activities that have caused them to experience large quasi-fiscal deficits.20 In Chile, for example, a quasi-fiscal deficit arose during the 1980s as a result of the central bank assuming the bad debts of the commercial banks. This assumption was clearly a fiscal operation that could have been carried out by the budget if budgetary conditions at the time had been more sound. In other cases, the central banks assumed the foreign debt of enterprises. In general, the less developed the institutions of a country, the more difficult it is to separate monetary and fiscal policies and the more difficult it is to measure the true size of the fiscal deficit. More often than not it is the weakness ofthe fiscal institutions (for example, the inability to raise needed revenue) that forces the monetary institutions to assume a fiscal role. However, making the budget deficit look better than it is also plays a role. Normally, economic policy is improved when monetary and fiscal policies are pursued according to their own specific roles. In this case, if an enterprise needs to be subsidized, the subsidy should be given through the budget. If this results in a budget deficit, the deficit should be financed by the country's treasury through the sale of bonds carrying market 2 interest rates. 1 19There will also be an incentive to reduce the cash deficit by postponing palcments, thus increasing arrears. 0 See the recent paper by Fry (1993). 21 When the financial market is not well developed, or when the credibility of the government is not good, this source of financing is not available. However, if the deficit is to be financed through inflationary finance, it may still be better if this finance is directJy allocated to the budget and the budget finances the various activities includmg subsidies to state enterprises. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution BUDGET DEFICIT IN TRANSITION 705 The budget deficit is a highly watched economic barometer. A larger deficit always sends warning signals, both domestically and internation­ ally. Therefore, countries have an incentive to limit its size either by genuine fiscal adjustment or by pursuing second-best policies, the result of which may be even more damaging than if the budget deficit had been allowed to rise. In other words, the bias is almost always for showing a budget deficit that appears smaller than it would be if the true fiscal deficit were correctly measured. At times, this reduction is achieved through policies that do not reduce the real or underlying fiscal deficit but only the measured budget deficit. In other words, gimmicks are used to lower the budget deficit artificially.22 During the transition, to the extent possible, it is important to contain the inflation rate without resorting to direct price controls.23 To achieve this objective, the most important macroeconomic instrument for both market economies and economies in transition is credit expansion, not the budget deficit. Once total credit expansion is determined, the coun­ tries should be encouraged to continue improving the efficiency of the economy as well as the fiscal accounts. They should be encouraged to reduce particular categories of public expenditure, to make others more productive, and to raise government revenue in an efficient way to contain the public sector fiscal deficit. They should also be encouraged to speed up the various adjustments mentioned above, even when these adjustments may result in increases in (measured) budget deficits. Impor­ tant among these adjustments is the transfer to the government of the essential social functions shouldered by the state enterprises. Another important point to recognize is that which makes the economies in transition different from normal market economies: for given total credit, an increase of the (measured) budget deficit does not necessarily crowd out what, in market economies, is the private sector. Much of the credit expansion goes to the state enterprises and the government, and only a small residual goes to the emerging private sector. A large reallocation of credit between the budget and the state enterprises can take place without necessarily affecting the private sector. This reallocation could be fully consistent with the objectives of the trans­ formation. If state enterprises (a) shed redundant workers, (b) transfer to the government the responsibility for essential social functions, (c) no longer finance nonessential social functions (such as vacation for work22This is not only a problem of economies in transition. In fact, it has been a fre uent problem m adjustment programs. See Tanzi (1989). JHowever, because of the changes in relative prices during the transition, it may not be wise to aim for an inflation rate that is too low since this would require a fall in prices in some sectors. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 706 VITOTANZI ers), and (d) compensate the workers for a fraction of these reductions through some adjustment in the level of nominal wages, then the net result of these changes could very well be a larger budget deficit more efficient economy. with a This change could also be achieved without additional credit expansion if the additional credit to the budget to finance its new responsibilities were compensated by lower credit to the state enterprises to reflect their reduced social responsibilities. Ill. Concluding Remarks The paper has shown that in situations where the role of the govern­ ment has not yet been determined, where the budget must assume some responsibilities now carried by state enterprises, and where "property rights" within the public sector are ill-defined, the budget deficit, which is calculated by looking at the behavior of budgetary revenue and expen­ diture, has less informational value than generally assumed. This deficit may often widely differ from the true fiscal deficit for the whole public sector and may even move in a different direction. The true fiscal deficit would include the fiscal activities of the state enterprises and the central bank. Under particular circumstances, containing the budget deficit will not necessarily make more resources available to the private sector and may even slow down the structural reforms necessary to make the transition successful. The above conclusion should not, however, be understood to mean that fiscal policy is irrelevant. If there is a message that follows from the discussion, it is (a) that the most comprehensive and economically sound measure of the fiscal (not budget) deficit should be used to guide policy and (b) that the transfer of functions from state enterprises to the government will need to.be taken into account in setting limits to the size of the deficit. If this is not possible, then the budget deficit should be deemphasized. In any case, structural reforms and total credit expansion must receive the full attention they deserve. REFERENCES Begg, David, and Richard Portes, "Enterprise Debt and Economic Transforma­ tion: Financial Restructuring of the State Sector in Central and Eastern Europe," CEPR Working Paper No. 695 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution BUDGET DEFICIT IN TRANSITION 707 Blejer, Mario, and Adrienne Cheasty, eds., How to Measure the Fiscal Deficit: Analytical and Methodological issues (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993). Blejer, Mario, and Ke-young Chu, eds., Measurement ofFiscal Impact: Method­ ological Issues, IMF Occasional Paper No. 59 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988). Fry, Maxwell, "The Fiscal Abuse of Central Banks,'' IMF Working Paper No. 93/58 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993). International Monetary Fund (1992a), World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1992). -- (1992b), World Economic Outlook, Interim Assessment (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1992). Musgrave, Richard, The Theory of Public Finance (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1959). Stiglitz, Joseph, The Economic Role of the State (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1989). Tanzi, Vito, "Fiscal Policy and Economic Reconstruction in Latin America," World Development, Vol. 20 (May 1992), pp. 641-57. ,·'Fiscal Policy, Growth, and the Design of Stabilization Programs,·· in -- Fiscal Policy, Stabilization, and Growth, ed. by Mario Blejer and Ke-young Chu (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989). Tanzi, Vito, Mario Blejer, and Mario 0. Teijeiro, "Inflation and the Measure of Fiscal Deficits," Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 34 (December 1987), pp. 711-38. Wallich, Christine I., Fiscal Decentralization: lntergovernmemal Relations in Russia (Washington: World Bank, 1992). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF StaffPapen Vol. 40, No. 3 (September 1993) � 1993 International Monetary Fund IMF Working Papers Staff Papers draws on !MF Working Papers, which are research studies by members of the Fund's staff. A list of Working Papers issued in 1993:2 follows. "Labor Market Issues in Belgium: An International Perspective," by Reza Moghadam [93/32] "Net Foreign Assets and International Adjustment: The United States, Japan, and Germany," by Paul R. Masson, Jeroen Kremers, and Jocelyn Home [93/33] "Do Capital Flows Reflect Economic Fundamentals in Developing Countries?" by Atish R. Ghosh and Jonathan D. Ostry [93/34] "Reserve Requirements and Monetary Management: An Introduction," by Daniel C. Hardy [93/35] "Experience with Floating Interbank Exchange Rate Systems in Five Developing Economies," by Vicente Galbis [93/36] "Private Saving, Public Saving, and the Inflation Tax: Another Look at an Old Issue," by A. Javier Hamann [93/37] "Real Exchange Rate Targeting Under Imperfect Asset Substitutability," by J. Saul Lizondo [93/38] "Economic Reform in Arab Countries: A Review of Structural Issues for the Remainder of the 1990s," by Mohamed A. EI-Erian and Shamsuddin Tareq [93/39] "Toward an Economic Theory of Multilateral Development Banking," by Gerd Schwartz (93/40] "Exports and Economic Development," by Delano Villanueva [93/41) "Poland: The Social Safety Net During the Transition," by Xavier Maret and Gerd Schwartz [93/42] "On Improving Public Expenditure Policies for the Poor: Major Informational Requirements," by S. Ehtisham Ahmad and Nigel Chalk (93143] "The Relation Between Skill Levels and the Cyclical Variability of Employment, Hours, and Wages," by Michael Keane and Eswar Prasad (93/44] "The Behavior of Nontradable Goods Prices in Europe: Evidence and Interpre­ tation," by Jose De Gregorio, Alberta Giovannini, and Thomas H. Krueger (93/45] "Viet Nam: Reform and Stabilization, 1986-92," by Gabrielle Lipworth and Erich Spitaller [93/46] "Price Reform and Durable Goods in the Transition to a Market Economy," by Pierre-Richard Agenor (93/47] "DEER Hunting: Misalignment, Debt Accumulation, and Desired Equilibrium Exchange Rates," by Michael J. Artis and Mark P. Taylor (93/48] 708 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution IMF WORKING PAPERS 709 ''Introduction of a New National Currency: Policy, Institutional, and Technical Issues," by Richard K. Abrams and Hernan Cortes-Douglas (93/49] "Optimal Tariffs: Theory and Practice," by Arvind Subramanian, Ali Ibrahim, and Luis A. Torres-Castro [93/50] "Public and Private Investment and the Convergence of Per Capita Incomes in Developing Countries," by Mohsin S. Khan and Manmohan S. Kumar [93/51] "Revisiting Japan's External Adjustment Since 1985," by Guy Meredith [93/52] "An Analytical Framework of Environmental Issues," by Jonathan Levin [93/53] "Lessons in Fiscal Consolidation for the Successor States of the Soviet Union," by George Kopits [93/54] IMF Papers on Policy Analysis and Assessment Papers on Policy Analysis and Assessment, a new series of research papers, are intended to make staff work in the area of policy design available to a wide audience. A list of all PPAAs issued in 1993:2 follows. Papers may also be considered for inclusion in the journal. "Restructuring of Commercial Bank Debt by Developing Countries: Lessons from Recent Experience," by Charles Collyns [93n] An annual subscription to IMF Working Papers is available for US$200.00. It includes 12 monthly shipments and priority mail delivery. Requests should be made to: International Monetary Fund Publication Services Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A. Telephone: (202) 623-7430 Telefax: (202) 623-7201 Inquiries about individual IMF Papers on Policy Analysis and Assessment should also be directed to the address above. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution This page intentionally left blank ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution In statistical matter throughout this issue, dots (... ) indicate that data are not available; a dash (-) indicates that the figure is zero or less than half the final digit shown, or that the item does not exist; a single dot (.) indicates decimals; a comma (,) separates thousands and mi 11ions; ''billion'' means a thousand million, and "trillion'' means a thousand billion; a short dash(-) is used between years or months(for example. 199 1-93 or January-October) to indicate a total of the years or months inclusive of the beginning and ending years or months; a stroke(/) is used between years(for example. 1992/93) to indicate a fiscal year or a crop year; a colon (:) is used between a year and the number indicating a quarter within that year (for example, 1993:3); components of tables may not add to totals shown because of rounding. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution