MODELLING FINANCIAL CRASHES (AND BUBBLES) THROUGH THE ISING MODEL Balaji Harihar CID – 01511175 Name of supervisor – Dr. William Proud Name of assessor – Prof. Deeph Chana Word Count - 5608 Balaji Harihar Abstract To model financial crashes and bubbles, the market has been considered to be bistable, and the dynamics of the Ising model have been applied. The main modes of interaction within the market can be described by thermal-bath dynamics which tells us how the market situation can influence the whole world and also highlights the effect of macroeconomic factors on this market. The other mode of interaction is understood by considering long-range interactions as well as near-neighbour interactions between agents in the market. Nowadays, with the facility of mobile phones and computers, long-distance trading has become possible and hence its inclusion into the model. ο In the ordered ferromagnetic phase, there are 2 possible orientations of the magnetization and thus an agent could be in either of the 2 potential wells (c.f. “bistable model”); one where prices are going up in general (market growth) and the other where prices are going down (market decline), and these orientations are stable. A crash or bubble will happen when there is a sudden inversion in the average orientation of the agents. The paper postulates the cause for market crashes to be a small informationcarrying signal being enhanced by external noise. To test this idea, both numerical and theoretical analysis is carried out and an important approximation called mean-field approximation enables the theoretical analysis to be carried out with much ease, and not losing too much information in the process. This hypothesis turns out to be true in most cases as market crashes are difficult to anticipate (hinting towards a weak information signal) and just before the crash, there is too much entropy/noise in the market, which ultimately causes the event to occur. 1 Declaration I declare that the work in this essay titled “Modelling Financial Crashes (And Bubbles) Through The Ising Model” has been carried out by me. All the content in this piece of literature that has been derived from various sources has been rightly acknowledged in the list of references provided. Content Introductory chapter – (i) Motivation, aims and objectives, (ii) Bringing the physics into context Discussion of methods employed – (i) Overview of both the analysis, (ii) Theoretical analysis Results and discussion – (i) A detailed look at the results…, (ii) …and what do these results imply? Summary and conclusions Acknowledgements References Introductory Chapter Motivation, aims and objectives In a plethora of papers, it has been shown that an appropriate description of the price of a commodity over time follows a “complex stochastic process with non-Gaussian characteristics” [1-4]. In addition, the background features of the market like volatility clustering where the magnitude of change in price directly correlates to magnitude of change is returns can be understood by treating it as a collective phenomenon [5]. Based on this, numerical simulations of a manyagent market can be formed on lines of percolation theory, Ising model, multiplicative noise etc. but the reason to choose the Ising model to depict the behaviour is mainly because it was used in an infamous paper [6] to study the Japanese stock market crash of 1997. The primary focus of this paper is to look at financial crashes, which are defined as large and sudden negative returns when market prices are Balaji Harihar 2 generally growing and the exact opposite of what one would expect in volatility clustering. On the other hand, a bubble is described as huge positive price returns on decreasing market prices. non-interactive factors that affect decision-making (an example could be the facility of Google Finance to look at the variation of stock prices in the market). Upon some research, the physical concept that best explains crashes and bubbles (which many researchers agree upon too) is a phase transition where the average magnetization of the market is inverted spontaneously. Most, if not all these papers [7-10], attribute the cause of crashes to be a hidden force which is thought to be some piece of information available to the agents. Looking at the interaction strength term π΄ππ , the collective response of all the agents is underlined by it. When π΄ππ > 0, agents keep huge faith on the decision of other agents and go along with whatever trend is being followed by the market agents. On the contrary, π΄ππ < 0 represents low faith of an agent on the action of their partners and the agent rather follows his/her gut feeling. In this paper, it is postulated that this hidden force/information signal itself is too weak to cause the crash, but once it is amplified by external noise (inflation, interest rates and other macroeconomic factors being offset) and fluctuations within the market (various microeconomic factors being offset), magnetization inversion is possible through a process called “stochastic resonance” [11]. The orientation of the agent ‘i’ at an interval ‘t+1’ is updated using Fermi-Dirac statistics (given by probability ‘p’) to invoke the uniqueness of each agent and takes the uncertainty of predicting the agent’s decision by us into account. It is given by Eq. 2, Bringing the physics into context The stock market in this paper is based on the Ising model format adopted by Kaizoji in Ref. 6 since many features of the market are common to this model. In our finite lattice (market), there are ‘N’ agents (magnetic dipole moments) with 2 choices of spin orientation σπ = +1 or -1. When the orientation is +1, the agent decides to buy shares of a stock at regular intervals of time ‘t’ (general interval is weekly). Looking at the formulation of our model, it does look like an Ising model with the dynamics of a thermal bath (thermal bath assumes that this market does not affect the external environment, and on the other hand, the external environment is a source of information as well as decisionmaking factors). The resemblance to the Ising model and its success in understanding society is supported by the “empirical theory of opinion formation” [12-14]. Before the orientation of the agent at a time ‘t+1’ is known, it is important to introduce the local field πΌπ (t) which essentially forms the basis for the environment in which an agent ‘i’ works and includes the influence of his decision-making based on interaction with other agents and access to external information. This local field is given by Eq. 1, A useful quantity that can be obtained from the orientation of each agent is the magnetization, which is just the weighted average of the sum of the individual orientations. Denoting the price by S(t), its dynamics can be understood with the simple differential equation dS/dt ∝ xS, since market will be bullish if demand exceeds supply (and prices increasing in turn which is dS/dt > 0). If supply exceeds demand, we observe bearish behaviour and both sides of market behaviour are described well by the differential equation. In this equation, ‘z’ gives us the average amount of non-zero links between agents, π΄ππ is the interaction strength of agent ‘i’ with another agent ‘j’ and βπ (t) is the external field which highlights Recalling from the principle of volatility clustering that the price returns are proportional to the stock price, and in turn to the magnetization, we obtain the logarithmic equation R(t) = Balaji Harihar log[S(t+1)] – log[S(t)]. This model by itself is very tedious to solve by hand and is always coded into computers to be solved numerically. However, a key approximation, called the ‘mean-field approximation’ will be helpful in simplifying our model by taking advantage of the geometry of our problem, and makes way for a new kind of analysis to be performed on the model: theoretical analysis. In this approximation, we say that π΄ππ = A and βπ (t) = h(t) and we can justify this since the number of agents and the number of links in turn are extremely large, and in addition, the interaction strengths and external fields have a symmetric distribution about the mean value due to the randomness of the situation. Now, we require an expression for x(t+1) under this approximation such that the crash or bubble occurs at t = 0 and at times way before or after that, x(t) is a stable constant value. According to [15], the most appropriate equation that captures this behaviour is Eq. 3, A simple manipulation enables us to write π΄ππ as A + (π΄ππ – A), and plugging this into Eq. 1, one part of the interaction term contains (NA/z)x(t) and this varies proportionally with R(t) (c.f. R(t) ∝ x(t)). This manipulation is very helpful as that part of the interaction term also shows how agents react to the price changes, given by R(t). In a way, it also averages all the reactions of an agent to the decision of his partners over the course of time till now. If we neglect the external field h(t) for now, we can obtain a good physical picture of how the model correlates to market behaviour. In the regime that A < 1 (note A cannot be negative), x = 0 is a steady solution of Eq. 3 while for A>1, we have a bistable system with two symmetric solutions π₯+ > 0 and π₯− < 0. The x = 0 state is paramagnetic since there is no preferred orientation of spin, and in economic 3 terms, this corresponds to 0 price returns and thus represents the market being in equilibrium. Meanwhile the other 2 solutions for A > 1 represent increasing (π₯+ ) and decreasing (π₯− ) price returns and can be associated with a growing and falling market, respectively. For the purpose of modelling crashes and bubbles in the mean-field approximation, we will take A > 1 as that provides us with the bistable potential wells required for the switch of magnetization. A crash would be an average jump of the market from the π₯+ well to the π₯− well while a bubble would be an average jump from the π₯− well to the π₯+ well. The paper by Krawiecki (Ref. 15) takes the interaction strength to be of the form π΄ππ = A(1+aζππ ) with probability P and my analysis will also be based on this formulation of the strength. For completeness, π΄ππ = 0 with a probability of 1P, although P is taken to be extremely high in the mean field approximation so that we have a nearly well interacting model which makes sense in today’s time with the availability of technology. ζππ is a set of random and unrelated variables which take values between -0.5 and 0.5 and is the best possible way to determine the strength of the links due to randomness of model and unpredictability of humans. Now that a vivid picture of the market has been developed in the absence of the external field, it is useful to ponder upon how the external field and information-carrying signal look. As per many papers [1-15], the most appropriate choice for our information-carrying signal would be a periodic wave that causes stochastic resonance; this form of the signal is chosen only for simplicity and it does not imply a hidden periodicity involved in crashes and bubbles. Moving on to think about the form of the external field, it was hypothesized that the information signal being amplified by the noise causes crashes, and thereby a sum of both these terms must be present for βπ (t). Along with this, βπ (t) must also capture the “willingness” to go from bullish to bearish behaviour (or vice versa), or in physical terms, there is always a preferred Balaji Harihar orientation associated with ferromagnets where the energy is lowest. The two parts comprising this willingness would be the effective strength of the external field reaching the agent and the coefficient of reaction for each agent. Keeping all this in mind, the form of the external field and information signal are assumed to be Eq. 4, s(t) is the information signal and ξ(t) describes the noise within the market which is time dependent for obvious reasons. The amplitude of s(t), ‘q’, is too weak to cause a switch in magnetization by itself but when added to the noise function with a good enough noise intensity ‘D’, we observe jumps in both mean-field model as well as full microscopic model. Lastly, ‘b’ captures the coefficient of reaction centred around the 1 while χπ , just like ζππ , is a set of random unrelated variables in the range (0.5,0.5) and describes the willingness to switch orientation for an agent. Discussion of the methods employed Overview of analysis The main goal of the analysis, be it numerical or theoretical, is to investigate how the system responds to the information signal as a function of ‘D’ with a fixed interaction strength in the mean field model (A>1) and for different connection strengths ‘P’ in numerical analysis. The form of x(t) can be made simpler to work theoretically by introducing an output function y(t) = sign(x(t)) where the market crash is approximated to occur spontaneously and the market is stable otherwise, away from the time of crash (assuming the crash only occurs once and various factors in the market present are too weak to induce jumps, or in general, the factors causing bubbles and crashes are randomly and evenly spread and cancel out the effect of its counterpart, until our information signal arrives, amplified by 4 noise). The importance of the bistable consideration of our model is to ensure that when a crash occurs, its root cause lays in the information signal. The first set of qualitative analysis will be theoretical and performed in the mean-field approximation while numerical analysis will be carried out in both mean-field and full microscopic model. In simple words, the output signal measures the average response of the market to an external stimulus, making a simple approximation that there are only two possible states for a spin to take and that this inversion happens spontaneously. From the output signal, one can obtain the spectral density S(ω) by a Fourier transform and in doing so, we observe a wide noise background and the graph peaking at odd multiples of ππ . The parameter which will be varied with ‘D’ in order to determine the occurrence of a market crash under the phenomenon of stochastic resonance is the Signal to Noise Ratio (SNR) [11]. This ratio is calculated in the vicinity of the frequency ππ since we obtain peaks for the spectral density in that region, and stochastic resonance also occurs if the spectral density is at a maximum. In the numerical method, a frequency bandwidth of 2−12 Hz is used to normalize the SNR because as per simulations in [11] and [15], they have obtained the spectral density by averaging the values from a plethora of series of y(t), each of which contains 212 points. As the word itself suggests, the SNR should be a ratio of the residual signal intensity (perceived intensity to an agent sans the noise) to the actual noise intensity. The best way to formulate an equation is to use the logarithm of the ratio since we are dealing with many agents, so noise is expected to be exponential. A suitable way to express the SNR (in dB) is 10ππππ [(S(ππ )-ππ (ππ ))/ ππ (ππ )] Bringing the physics into context, plenty of papers have based their simulations on stochastic resonance to picturize response to an external stimulus in the Ising domain [16-17], and another application has been in the “Weidlich model of opinion formation” [18]. But the difference in these papers is that the reaction of agents to the stimuli is measured as a function of thermal Balaji Harihar fluctuations (keeping noise constant). However, this paper intends to look at the market response to noise and we thus take this slightly different approach as compared to the references by varying ‘D’ and keeping thermal fluctuations. Lastly, choosing A > 1 ensures ferromagnetism as spins want to align and we assume that we will witness rational behaviour from our agents (such behaviour of aligning with others was observed in the 1990s when the internet became a huge sensation, and everybody started investing in stocks in the internet share market). The spontaneity and ordering behaviour of the market makes it apparent that there is high stability, so spins are far away from critical point. Theoretical Analysis This analysis will purely be carried out under the mean field approximation to evaluate the SNR. The theory of stochastic resonance outlined in [11] shall be used. In this theory, for bistable systems, the SNR can be obtained if the dependence of the rate of escape from one symmetric stable state to the other with the noise is known, denoted by r(D). This dependence on the escape rate stems from the fact that reaction of agents (y(t)) (whose Fourier Transform gives the spectral density) causes a switch in orientation and a jump from one state to the other, and the measurable quantity in this jump is the number of agents switching in a specified amount of time, which is r(D). Ferromagnets undergo spontaneous symmetry breaking when the external field is applied since it acts as a perturbation to the Hamiltonian of the system [19]. Due to this, the analysis assumes that due to the signal, the escape rates now become asymmetric and time-dependent. This means that for one half of the cycle of the signal, the escape rate from, say, the “left state π+ (D,t)” is greater than the “right state π− (D,t)”, and vice versa for the other half of the signal. To think of a way to formulate an expression for our escape rate from the state π+ (π·, π‘), we must remember that the process of noise amplification is non-additive and thereby only a qualitative theoretical analysis can be carried out. Various other factors affect the escape rate, but they are 5 miniscule compared to noise, and it will thus be considered as a first-order effect/perturbation. We can apply a first-order Taylor expansion to the escape rate to give Eq. 5, The 1st order term π1 (D) is multiplied with the information signal in order to take the asymmetry of the overall escape rate into account, and it also ensures that the escape rate varies in full synchronization or anti synchronization with the information signal. π0 (D) is the symmetric escape rate which would be the sole escape rate in absence of the signal. According to [11], the SNR can now be calculated from this 1st order approximation, and is given by Eq. 6, As seen before, when no external field is applied, the system lies around the stable states π₯+ or π₯− . We have assumed that only the information signal can cause switch of magnetization and therefore, except for these large jumps, x(t) oscillates in the vicinity of the stable states. Keeping this in mind, for obtaining an estimation of the SNR for h(t) not equal to 0, a jump of mean orientation is only possible if stationary point of x(t+1) occurs to the right of π₯+ (crash) or to the left of π₯− (bubble). The problem with this approximation is that it understates the true value of the probability of jump since we do not consider the possibility of jumping under the influence of several noise pulses. With some simple calculations, we find the condition for switching to the negative orientation from positive to be ξ < ξ+ = (-Aπ₯+ - q cos(ππ t))/D and the escape rate π+ is just the probability distribution function, written as P(ξ < ξ+ ). Similarly, the escape rate in the other direction, from positive to negative, is given by P(ξ > ξ− ) where ξ− is given by (-Aπ₯− - q cos(ππ t))/D and the asymmetric modulation of the rates of escape by the periodic signal can be clearly seen. As per [11], in such a situation, the parameters π0 and π1 from Eq. 5 can be written as the given expressions in Eq. 7, Balaji Harihar 6 Results and Discussion Using this underestimating version of the escape rate will not suffice, and one way to overcome this is to somehow combine this method with another one which overestimates the actual probability of escape. In light of this, a second train of thought is developed where we assume the information carrying signal causes the stable states to disappear once a jump of magnetization occurs. The reason this is an overestimation is because at time t+1, the stable state may reappear due to the external field being weak in this step, and the jump does not happen after all. For our stables states to vanish, the conditions ξ < ξ+ = (-h0 - q cos(ππ t))/D as well as ξ > ξ− = (h0 q cos(ππ t))/D must be satisfied. The expression for h0 is given (after some mathematical manipulation in [11]) by Eq. 8, Finally, the second set of expressions for π0 and π1 is given by Eq. 9, We know that the signal itself cannot cause magnetization to flip without the presence of noise, and this is mathematically expressed by the condition q < h0 . From this condition, we can obtain a physical intuition of what h0 means; a minimum amplitude of the information signal so that it its amplification with noise can cause a crash or bubble. If q < h0 , the stable states x+ and x− will not disappear and neither will the jump of magnetization occur. By applying the condition q < h0 , and given that A > 1, substituting the expressions of Eq. 7 and Eq. 9 into Eq. 6 provides us with curves of SNR against D with a peak at D > 0 (will be shown in the results section), so we can anticipate the occurrence of stochastic resonance in the many-agent model as well which will be solved numerically and whose results will be directly reviewed without indulging too deeply into the computer code, since this is beyond the scope of this essay. A detailed look at the results… Fig. 1. (a) – SNR plotted against D. Parameters are A = 1.5, a = 2, b = 2 and q = 0.2. The solid line plots the theoretical model using Eq. 6 and 7. The dashed line plots the theoretical model using Eq. 6 and Eq. 9. Shaded dots show the numerical model under mean-field approximation while circles represent a full computational simulation of a market with N = 250 and P = 1. Fig. 1. (b) – Same parameters used as in (a), but only the full computational plots are drawn for various probabilities. Specifically, the squared points represent P = 0.05, diamonds represent P = 0.25, triangles represent P = 0.5 and circles represent P = 1. Solid line is line of best fit, just a visual aid for the reader. As shown in the graph, all the curves in Fig. 1(a) peak at a particular value of D > 0 and the results obtained from numerical method are very similar to the theoretically postulated model. We have obtained stochastic resonance in both models as expected and devoid of the fact that the meanfield theoretical model uses a small number of agents and a large range of interaction strengths ‘a’ and reaction coefficients ‘b’, the results from both trains of thought are comparable. The value of ‘A’ has been taken to be 1.5 (very deep in the bistable phase) rather than taking it to be close to unity (as has been done in many papers including [6]) because for this value of ‘A’, the magnetization jumps take place due to fluctuations within the system, which gives inaccurate responses in the theoretical mean-field limit for small N (the regime in which this essay operates) and simulations also take a very long time. Moving to Fig. 1(b), it portrays the effect of changing the interaction strength between agents. Increasing the strength ‘P’ does lead to the maxima of the SNR to shift to the left but for extremely small P (the squared points line), we observe no stochastic resonance at all, and the Balaji Harihar SNR only keeps decreasing as ‘D’ increases. This difference in behaviour at low ‘P’ can be attributed to the order-disorder transition at the critical probability Pπ ≈ 0.01 [20] where for regions around and below this value, we expect the system to be in an approximate paramagnetic state. In this case, a weak signal is enough to make the agents orient towards a preferred spin direction, without the need of any external noise. The ability of paramagnets to orient themselves quickly is known, and in a financial context, this implies that people have no way to access information into the stock market; the very first piece of information they receive is through the signal, and thus everybody spontaneously decides to believe that information and follow that trend. This kind of situation can be seen in the market of a newly discovered/invented commodity (like gold during the Gold Rush or computers in the 1970s where market was disordered due to little being known about how to market the commodity [21]). …And what do these results imply? Fig. 2 – The graph shows the distribution of normalized price returns G = (x - < π >)/√< ππ > −< π >π , where the term < π > denotes average over time procured from computational runs of the mean-field market with the same parameters as in Fig. 1 and D = 0.4 (near to the value of D where stochastic resonance occurs); only x > 0 part is evaluated due to symmetry of Eq. 3 which gives us that < π > = 0. In our model, we have taken this switching between magnetizations to be permanent, but this is not a pragmatic model, as depicted by Fig. 2. The cumulative distribution of probability ρ(G) has been plotted against G. As per the study conducted by [2], ρ(G) must have a maximum at x = 0 and subsequently, its tail decays according to a power law. The interpretation of this ‘real’ version of the market is that we expect the market to remain in equilibrium when we have small 7 returns, while the chances of having huge returns is very low. But from the mean-field simulation of the market in Fig. 2, there is a bimodality in the graph (due to the market being considered bistable), and this more importantly highlights a high likeliness of a bubble or crash occurring (large positive or negative price return). It is important to emphasise that a bistable form of the stock market was chosen with a periodic information signal for obtaining good statistics on the SNR, which in simple terms measures how the information signal is enhanced by noise as per most of the papers in the references. From Fig. 2, it is also apparent that the agents start working more synchronously over time as the graph rises exponentially as returns increase over time; one way to model this is increasing ‘A’ over time as long as we are in an ordered (growing or declining market) regime. As per [6], ordering of the market occurs in a similar fashion to the way described in this essay; it goes on to associate this ordering with the spontaneous market crash because everybody is placing the same order at the same time. The writer of this paper interprets that the market remains ordered for some time (rather than immediately crashing) and perhaps the unprecedented arrival of an insignificant piece of information rapidly inverts the magnetization due to amplification by noise, and this bit of information is the cause of the market crash. Once the crash or bubble has occurred, the market generally comes back to the equilibrium state through decreasing A as time progresses for example, and the symmetry of the market is restored too. Summary and conclusions In a nutshell, the behaviour of our microscopic market was encapsulated by the Ising model where the agents were considered as spins, and the physics was governed by thermal bath dynamics and long-range communications with the entire system being subject to the combined effect of an external signal and noise. In order to picture crashes and bubbles, we assumed that agents had strong interaction Balaji Harihar strengths between them and under this regime, the market was bistable with one stable state corresponding to a growing market and the other to a declining market. In the model, a crash was defined to be a jump from the growing market state to the declining market state (magnetization inversion) due to the arrival of an information signal. It was also made clear that a low amplitude signal can also affect the market by being amplified by noise through a process called stochastic resonance. This process occurs in both mean-field and many-agent models and its dynamics is explained qualitatively through the adiabatic theory of bistable systems under the influence of external noise. The key result from this model is that a supposed weak stimulus which agents may choose to ignore can have a large effect on the market by creating enormous returns if they are enhanced by noise. This weak information signal is taken to be the cause of the crash, even though no one anticipates crashes upon its arrival. For the switch of magnetization to occur, the market must be far from equilibrium and there must be a large-scale ordering of agents just prior to the crash or bubble. This model does not investigate the effect of a strong signal on the market because even though they have the capability of causing crashes, they are very unlikely since people can read the signal and act rightly to avoid a financial catastrophe. Another factor that could cause crashes and is not studied are external/internal fluctuations, but this is beyond the scope of the paper to examine since the cause for the crash/bubble itself is nearly impossible to find. Another unavoidable drawback of this model (or any model in general) is the randomness of the situation. The reaction coefficients and interaction strengths were just assigned random numbers between -0.5 and 0.5 and rather than coming up with a solution to tackle this, this randomness opens a new train of thought into thinking about how alike we are to simple magnetic dipole moments. With all the ability to think and make calculated decisions, a simple spin model possesses the ability to accurately describe our behaviour. As seen in this model, some time after the crash, we tend to 8 follow ordering behaviour again, even though this is the key propellor of crashes/bubbles so this should intrigue us into thinking how a single atom by itself is so difficult to understand and predict (just like a single human), but once many of these atoms or humans come together, the same Ising model can perfectly describe the behaviour of both. Are we ultimately just a pawn in nature’s quest to achieve what it wants to? Was the introduction of life in this universe solely to increase its entropy? Or on the other hand, do non-living things like the dipole moment in our model also have the ability to think after all? How are the subatomic particles working in the Ising market different from the ones in the human body? What makes us so different and are we even any different? Well, we are ultimately built up of all these subatomic particles (including the dipole moments) and our decision-making at the most fundamental level is left to the brain, which is again a combination of these atoms, and the ability to think is just them in action, leading us to make decisions. This model has made me question the most fundamental questions on our existence and worth along with also providing an adept comprehension of market crashes and bubbles with a touch of scientific intuition. Acknowledgements I would like to thank my supervisor Dr. William G Proud for providing me with very impactful insights into my research and posing non-trivial questions which made me dig deeper into my research. I would also like to thank Prof. Deeph Chana for being a wonderful examiner during my viva and giving extremely helpful feedback. Lastly, I also owe my gratitude to Charalampos, Rohima, Isabel, Fatima and Maeve for shedding light on their research during our weekly meetings and having fruitful discussions on the topic. References [1] - S. Ghashghaie, W. Breymann, J. Peinke, P. Talkner, Y. Dodge, Nature 381 (1996) 767. Balaji Harihar 9 [2] - P. Gopikrishnan, V. Plerou, L.A. Nunes Amaral, M. Meyer, H.E. Stanley, Phys. Rev. E 60 (1999) 5305. ses/PH4202/[Nigel%20Goldenfeld]%20Lectures %20on%20Phase%20Transitions%20and%20the %20Renormalization%20Group.pdf [3] - V. Plerou, P. Gopikrishnan, B. Rosenow, L.A. Nunes Amaral, H.E. Stanley, Phys. Rev. Lett. 83 (1999) 1471. [20] https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Karim_Osou li/post/Is_it_possible_to_observe_thermal_hysteri sis_upon_a_second_order_transition/attachment/5 9d61d9d79197b8077978840/AS%3A2718337717 73954%401441821629621/download/thesebookchap5.pdf [4] - F. Lillo, R.N. Mantegna, Phys. Rev. E 62 (2000) 6126. [5] - Mandelbrot, B. B., The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices, The Journal of Business 36, No. 4, (1963), 394-419 [6] - T. Kaizoji, Physica A 287 (2000) 493. [21] – D.W. Allen, Information Sharing During The Klondike Gold Rush, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 67, No. 4 (December 2007) [7] - D. Sornette, A. Johansen, J.-P. Bouchaud, J. Phys. I France 6 (1996) 167. [22] - B.M. Roehner, D. Sornette, Eur. Phys. J. B 16 (2000) 729. [8] - N. Vandewalle, Ph. Boveroux, A. Minguet, M. Ausloos, Physica A 255 (1998) 201. [9] - A. Johansen, D. Sornette, Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 10 (1999) 563. [10] - J.A. Feigenbaum, P.G.O. Freund, Int. J. Mod. Phys. B 10 (1996) 3737. [11] - B. McNamara, K. Wiesenfeld, Phys. Rev. A 39 (1989) 4854. [12] - B. Latanue, Am. Psychol. 36 (1981) 343. [13] - D. Helbing, Quantitative Sociodynamics, Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht, 1995. [14] - K. Kacperski, J.A. Holyst, Physica A 287 (2000) 631. [15] – A. Krawiecki, J.A. Holyst, Physica A 317 (2003) 597 – 608 [16] - J.J. Collins, C.C. Chow, A.C. Capela, T.T. Imho5, Phys. Rev. E 54 (1996) 5575 [17] - J. Javier Brey, A. Prados, Phys. Lett. A 216 (1996) 241 [18] - P. Babinec, Phys. Lett. A 225 (1997) 179. [19] https://students.iiserkol.ac.in/~mms15ms051/cour