See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/264088590 Sectoral herding behavior in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs Article in Venture Capital · July 2014 DOI: 10.1080/13691066.2014.921100 CITATIONS READS 16 244 2 authors, including: Pegah Dehghani Infrastructure University of Kuala Lumpur 2 PUBLICATIONS 18 CITATIONS SEE PROFILE All content following this page was uploaded by Pegah Dehghani on 07 July 2016. The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file. This article was downloaded by: [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] On: 21 July 2014, At: 18:12 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Venture Capital: An International Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/tvec20 Sectoral herding behavior in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs a b Pegah Dehghani & Ros Zam Zam Sapian a Graduate School of Business, National University of Malaysia, 43600 UKM Bangi, Selangor, Malaysia b Faculty of Economics and Management, National University of Malaysia, 43600, UKM Bangi, Selangor, Malaysia Published online: 16 Jul 2014. To cite this article: Pegah Dehghani & Ros Zam Zam Sapian (2014) Sectoral herding behavior in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs, Venture Capital: An International Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance, 16:3, 227-246, DOI: 10.1080/13691066.2014.921100 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13691066.2014.921100 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/termsand-conditions Venture Capital, 2014 Vol. 16, No. 3, 227–246, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13691066.2014.921100 Sectoral herding behavior in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Pegah Dehghania1 and Ros Zam Zam Sapianb* a Graduate School of Business, National University of Malaysia, 43600 UKM Bangi, Selangor, Malaysia; bFaculty of Economics and Management, National University of Malaysia, 43600 UKM Bangi, Selangor, Malaysia (Received 26 November 2013; final version received 18 April 2014) The Malaysian initial public offering (IPO) market is characterized by substantial uncertainties due to limited disclosure of information, ‘fixed-price pricing mechanism’, and cognitive biases of Asian investors. Together, these characteristics might induce investors to engage in herding behavior in the aftermarket of an IPO. This study investigates investors’ herding behavior in the IPO aftermarket from 2001 to 2011 using Christie and Huang’s [Christie, W. G., and R. D. Huang. 1995. “Following the Pied Piper: Do Individual Returns Herd Around the Market?” Financial Analysts Journal 51 (4): 31–37] method. The findings of this study show that for non-private placements, a negative and insignificant b1 coefficient, as an indication of herding, is reported for Technology sector. The herding behavior that is only constrained to technological firms during down market may be due to the risky nature of the new issues in the down market, rather than the uninformed characteristic of the individual investors. The findings of this study also show that for the private placement category, negative and insignificant coefficients of b1 and b2 are reported for Consumer Product and Technology sectors, respectively. Since the negative coefficients are not limited to the down market, with risky and uncertain shares, the results could be an indication of the herding of informed investors in the two mentioned sectors. Keywords: behavioral finance; herding; behavioral (cognitive) decision theory; IPO aftermarket; private placement; non-private placement; cross-sectional dispersion of return; Bursa Malaysia Introduction Companies raise capital through the issuance and sale of new shares in the initial public offering (IPO) market. Most of the past studies on IPOs are motivated by the two anomalies inherent in this market: the initial underpricing and the long-run underperformance. Underpricing refers to the positive difference between the offer price and the market price on the first day of listing. The long-run returns are generally called the cumulative return or buy-and-hold returns, one year or more after the date of listing. Empirical support on the long-run performance is inconclusive with the majority of the developed stock markets reporting underperformance, whilst their developing counterparts reporting overperformance. Prior literature provides an extensive review about underpricing and long-run underperformance anomalies of IPOs, for instance by Ritter (2003) and more recently by Yong (2007b) for Asian markets. With regard to the Malaysian IPO market, abundant studies have been carried out that relate some unique or specific features of IPO with underpricing anomaly. Among *Corresponding author. Email: zamzam@ukm.my q 2014 Taylor & Francis Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 228 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian these are firm size (Yong 1996), underwriter’s reputation (Jelic, Saadouni, and Briston 2001), oversubscription rate (Yong 1996; Yong and Isa 2003), offering size (Yong, Yatim, and Sapian 2002), main shareholders ownership (Abdullah and Taufil Mohd 2004), firm’s age (Abdullah and Taufil Mohd 2004), owners’ participation and lockup provision (Wan-Hussin 2005), government public policy and regulatory intervention (Prasad, Vozikis, and Ariff 2006), regulation (Mohd 2007), proportion of IPO shares allocated to Bumiputra investors (How et al. 2007), disposition effect and flippers (Chong 2009), flipping activity (Abdul Rahim and Yong 2010), Shari’ah-compliant (Abdul Rahim and Yong 2010), board structure (Yatim 2011), earnings management (Ahmad-Zaluki, Campbell, and Goodacre 2011), and intellectual capital disclosures in IPO prospectuses (Rashid et al. 2012). In addition, there are some studies that have applied the models used in the developed markets such as bandwagon effect, lawsuit avoidance, prospect theory, signaling hypothesis, speculative bubble hypothesis, and Winner’s curse to explain underpricing in the Malaysian IPO market. This includes studies by Annuar and Shamsher (1998), Chong (2009), Yong (2011b, 2013). Earlier IPO literature in Malaysia reveals that very few studies investigate the investors’ behavior in the immediate IPO aftermarket. For instance, Yong (2011a) studied the immediate behavior of the Malaysian IPOs, but concentrated on the first day of the trading only. Yong (2013) investigated the immediate IPO aftermarket for 20 trading days and analyzed the behavior of the investors across different listing boards only. Yong (2011b) studied the investor’s imitating behaviors, concentrating on the relation between these behaviors and underpricing. Accordingly, the present study fills these gaps and expands the previous literature by investigating whether the imitating behavior of the informed (private placement) and uninformed (non-private placement) investors exists in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs across different sectors from the second day until 30 days of trading. The past studies such as Yong (2011b) and Yong (2011a) reveal that research into the private placement type of IPO in Malaysia has only concentrated on its relations with underpricing. Theoretically and empirically, the past literature such as Miller (1977), Baron (1982), Ritter (1984), Beatty and Ritter (1986), Rock (1986), Miller and Reilly (1987), Megginson and Weiss (1991), Houge et al. (2001), and Lowry and Schwert (2002) supports the existence of a greater level of uncertainty in IPO stocks in comparison with other stocks. In addition to this general uncertainty regarding the IPO market, specific characteristics in the Malaysian IPO market could make it more uncertain. These include ‘fixed pricing’ method instead of book-building and limited disclosure of information. In this study, a ‘fixed-price’ pricing mechanism refers to a situation where the IPO price is fixed in advance between the promoter and the underwriter before being sold to the investors. In this case, the public investors do not participate in setting of the IPO price, thus widening the problem of asymmetric information faced by them. Due to the lack of historical records such as prices and volume of new issues, IPO investors will not be able to compute expected returns to gauge investment risk of an IPO investment. Thus, to estimate the risk and return relationship, they have to rely on public statements and filings of IPO companies or on information acquired during the book-building auction phase of the offering instead. However, in Malaysia, the dominant pricing method for IPOs is ‘fixed priced.’ Yong (2013) mentions that a higher level of uncertainty is expected for the Malaysian IPO market due to fixed-priced pricing mechanism rather than book-building or auction pricing mechanisms. In addition, Benveniste and Spindt (1989), Biais, Bossaerts, and Rochet (2002), Derrien and Womack (2003), and Chahine (2007) mention that book-building and auction types of IPO provide an opportunity to the investors to put forward bids and thus reveal their Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Venture Capital 229 assessment of the IPO value. Thus, for these types of issuance methods, the offer price reflects the investors’ opinion about the true value of the new issues, which is established during the bidding process. Contrary to book-building and auction methods, the ‘fixedpriced’ pricing mechanism, in which the price has been set before the allocation, lowers the investors’ chance to place bids; therefore, the offer price does not reflect the investors’ opinions or valuations of the new issues. Consequently, more asymmetric information exists among investors. Due to information asymmetry, there exists a prevailing uncertainty regarding the future return of the IPO and the performance of the new firms. The previous literature such as Antoniou et al. (1997) and Gelos and Wei (2002) mentions that a deficiency in corporate disclosure and information quality could also lead to uncertainty in the market. Disclosure is more important in the IPO market compared with other financial markets because of the lack of historical data and ‘fixed pricing’ method. According to Campos, Newell, and Wilson (2002), the Malaysian equity market has a limited degree of disclosure, thus creating illiquidity in the market. Due to an uncertain environment, limited information and the cognitive biases of Asian investors, investors tend to follow the actions of their peers in trading activities (Kallinterakis and Kratunova 2007), and these kinds of actions can constitute herding behavior. Kremer (2010) confirms that herding and uncertainty or availability of information is interrelated. He indicates that this possibility is greater for an emerging market due to imperfect regulatory frameworks particularly in terms of market transparency. In addition, a herding trading pattern has some negative consequences in the financial market. For instance, it tends to dilute the quality of information of stock prices, aggravate stock price volatility, and destabilize capital markets. These phenomena may lead or contribute to bubbles and crashes (Shiller 1989; Scharfstein and Stein 1990; Topol 1991; Orléan 1995; Morris and Shin 1999; Persaud 2000; Hirshleifer and Hong Teoh 2003; Hwang and Salmon 2004). Moreover, in investigating the causes of the 1997 financial crisis in Malaysia, Jomo (1998) reports that the Asian financial crisis was partly due to the herding behavior of the investors. The Malaysian IPO market is herd potential due to these characteristics, which would lead to negative consequences. However, no study has yet investigated whether the uncertainty faced by the IPO investors (informed/uninformed) and IPO shares would result in herding, which inhibits some preventive measures to be taken. The past literature suggests that the majority of the explanations on anomalies are based on the assumption that the market is efficient and rational; therefore, normative models are used to explain the behavior of new issues. For example, Annuar and Shamsher (1998) apply signaling process in explaining the underpricing of the IPO market in Malaysia. However, the inefficiency of the Malaysian market has been empirically demonstrated in the previous literature (Dawson 1987; Yong 1991; Ismail, Abidin, and Zainuddin 1993; Isa and Ahmad 1996; Yong, Yatim, and Sapian 1999; Leong, Vos, and Tourani-Rad 2000; Mat-Nor, Lai, and Hussin 2002; Lai, Guru, and Nor 2003; Abdullah and Taufil Mohd 2004; Cheng, Chan, and Mak 2005; Husni 2005; Ahmad-Zaluki, Campbell, and Goodacre 2007). Therefore, it would be more proper to examine such a market using behavioral theories. For instance, based on behavioral (cognitive) decision theory, generally, human judgment and choice do not support optimal decision models. Not all human behaviors are cost/benefit efficient and they are different from those dictated by normative models. This is due to the biases that occur during the decision-making process. Herding is such a behavior that could be considered as an irrational behavior. This is because during herding, individual investors ignore Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 230 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian their own information and follow the market consensus. This phenomenon could lead to some negative consequences such as incorrect and poor decision-making made by the whole populations due to the behavior patterns that are correlated across individuals (Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch 1992; Devenow and Welch 1996). In addition, as prices are influenced by the group decisions, they tend to depart from their equilibrium levels and investors are forced to transact at inefficient prices (Christie and Huang 1995). The herding behavior of the investors has been investigated in the equity market of many countries: Christie and Huang (1995) on US markets, Chang, Cheng, and Khorana (2000) on international shares, Gleason, Mathur, and Peterson (2004) on the Exchange Traded Funds, Demirer and Kutan (2006) and Tan et al. (2008) on the Chinese markets, Chiang and Zheng (2010) on developed equity markets (except the USA) and Asian Market, Demirer, Kutan, and Chen (2010) on Taiwanese stock market, Bhaduri and Mahapatra (2013) on Indian stock market, Ge˛bka and Wohar (2013) on 32 international markets categorized as emerging, developing, and developed markets, Hsieh (2013) on Taiwanese stock market, Kremer and Nautz (2013) on German stock market, and Yao, Ma, and He (2014) on Chinese A and B stock markets. Likewise, the study of herding behavior on the Malaysian equity market has been carried out by Lai and Lau (2004). They examined the existence of herd behavior among market traders of the Kuala Lumpur Stock Exchange (KLSE) for two sub-sample periods, bullish and bearish, and in different sectors. They investigate the herding behavior using monthly prices of all stocks listed on the Main Board of the KLSE from January 1992 to December 2001 using the Christie and Huang (1995) method. However, with regard to the Malaysian equity market, only a few studies have investigated the price behavior of the new issues based on behavioral theories, including, for example, disposition effect (Chong 2009), bandwagon effect (Yong 2011b), and speculative bubbles (Yong 2013). Nonetheless, a study of herding behavior has not been explored before in the Malaysian IPO market. Thus, this study is the first of its kind that focuses on the behavior of uninformed and informed investors during short-term immediate aftermarket of the Malaysian IPOs, based on behavioral theories such as herding and bounded rationality. The rest of this paper is organized as follows: ‘Literature review’ section discusses related literature. ‘Methodology and sampling’ section describes the data and methodology employed in this study. ‘Results and discussions’ section presents the results and finally ‘Conclusions’ section provides the conclusions of this study. Literature review In the late 1990s, the resurgence of behavioral finance led to increasing interest among researchers to examine the aftermarket trading behavior of investors, especially in the developed markets such as the US stock market. The main reason that prompted the resurgence of behavioral finance was the failure of the efficient market hypothesis to rationalize a number of anomalies as well as investors’ behavior on asset prices valuation. Behavioral finance relies on the commonly accepted belief that an investor’s behavior is not only influenced by how well informed he or she is but also by other psychological attributes or factors. Golberg and Nitzsch (2001), for example, mention that asset price and its movement reflect the behavior of market participants with regard to information interpretation and form of ideas or opinions after the interpretation. This means that the knowledge or information about an IPO will affect an investor’s behavior, and the overall investors’ behavior will in turn affect the IPO market performance. Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Venture Capital 231 Herding is an example of an anomaly in the area of behavioral finance. There are different definitions and models of herding proposed in the literature, and there is no commonly accepted meaning and method of measurement for this behavior. However, the literature distinguishes between irrational and rational herding. Irrational herding behavior is likened to a scenario of collective actions of individuals in uncertain conditions. Rational herding behavior is likened to a situation where the investors ignore voluntarily their own analyses and follow manager who possesses a source of more reliable information (Bikhchandani and Sharma 2001). Irrational herding moves the asset prices beyond the fundamental (Puckett and Yan forthcoming), whereas the rational herding has the potential to generate efficient prices and seize information in the asset prices more quickly. Most of the theoretical financial literature has focused on rational herding behavior. Rational herding could be due to different conditions and could have informational, reputational, and compensational reasons. Bikhchandani and Sharma (2001) classify the rational herding into three categories that are herding based on information, reputation, and compensation. The examples of some theoretical models are as follows. Herding based on information is attributed to the works of Banerjee (1992) and Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch (1992). Banerjee (1992) defines a herd as ‘everybody doing what everyone else is doing, even when their private information suggests doing something else.’ He analyzes a sequential decision model where each rational institutional decision-maker observes the decisions made by earlier decisionmakers. The model by Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch (1992), which is based on informational cascades, examines the behavior of rational institutional investors. Their model explains not only conformity but also rapid and short-lived fluctuations such as fads, fashions, booms, and crashes. They apply the concept of ‘perfect Bayesian equilibrium’ in explaining the investor’s herding behavior. Herding based on reputation and compensation describes the idea that the investors and more exactly the institutions who are subject to damage their reputation by acting differently from the crowd ignore their own information and herd. The model introduced by Scharfstein and Stein (1990) can be an example of herding behavior as the result of reputational concerns, ‘sharing-the-blame,’ unattractive outside opportunities, and dependence of the compensation on absolute rather than relative ability assessment. Scharfstein and Stein (1990) mention that managers simply imitate the behavior of other investment managers and ignore substantive private information, in certain circumstances. Their model is more appropriate to be used to the example of corporate investment rather than to the stock market, because it is assumed that the investments under consideration are available in perfectly elastic supply at a given price, which allows explicit avoidance of considering the feedback from investment demand to prices, thereby simplifying the analysis considerably. Due to its characteristic as non-quantifiable behavior, herding cannot be precisely quantified but can only be inferred by examining related measurable parameters. There are two distinguished categories to measure herding according to the nature of the defined data. The first model focuses on the trading activities of the individual investors. Herding is said to have occurred when the individuals purposely imitate the trading behavior of other investors over a period. Thus, to measure herding, data on the trading activities as well as the investment portfolio of the investors are collected. Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1992) and Wermers (1999) provide examples of such measures that are known as the LSV measure and the portfolio-change measure (PCM), respectively. The PCM is designed to capture both the direction and the intensity of investors’ trading. These measures are designed to estimate the intention of herding either by institutional or individual investors to buy (or to sell) simultaneously of any Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 232 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian particular securities (Grinblatt, Titman, and Wermers 1995; Oehler 1998; Wermers 1999; Voronkova and Bohl 2005; Wylie 2005; Walter and Weber 2006; Puckett and Yan 2007). In addition, these methods also intend to assess the strong changes of the securities fractions held by institutional investors (Nofsinger and Sias 1999; Sias 2004; Kim and Nofsinger 2005; Dasgupta et al. 2011). The presence of herding behavior is also being studied using other models, and it is identified by exploiting the information contained in the cross-sectional stock price movements. The methodology that investigates herding behavior by estimating the dispersion of returns of all the shares by the cross-sectional standard (or absolute) deviations of the returns includes Christie and Huang (1995), Chang, Cheng, and Khorana (2000), Gleason, Mathur, and Peterson (2004), Demirer and Kutan (2006), and Tan et al. (2008). This study investigates herding behavior of the investors in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs. The IPO immediate aftermarket is characterized by high initial returns as documented by several studies (Dawson 1987; Ismail, Abidin, and Zainuddin 1993; Mohamad, Nassir, and Ariff 1994; Yong 2011a); therefore, the immediate aftermarket can be considered as stressful period. Consequently, applying the Christie and Huang (1995) method is appropriate to investigate herding in this context as they define and measure herding during market stress or large price movement. They suggest that during the periods of unusual market movement, individuals are more likely to suppress their own belief in favor of the market consensus; therefore, security returns would not stray far from the market and herds form. In this case, herding can be measured through dispersion, which is defined as the cross-sectional standard deviation (CSSD) of return. Dispersion measures the average proximity of individual return to the mean. In this study, the terms of herding and fads are used interchangeably. The definition of the Goetzman (1995) for fad is very similar to the Christie and Huang’s (1995) definition of herding. According to Goetzman (1995), a fad occurs when stock prices are apparently moving together to a greater extent than normal. He mentions that during a fad, the cross-sectional variation would be expected to be low. He also claims that this condition is most likely to occur with investor mass pessimism, such as during a panic or crash. In addition, based on the definition of Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch (1992), fads is a drastic and seemingly unpredictable swing in mass behavior without obvious external stimulus. The simultaneous occurrence of such a shift for a large number of individuals remains, however, unexplained as mentioned by Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch (1992). This void could be filled by a theory of herding and a fad could be interpreted as the result of herding. Thus again, the two concepts, herding and fads, may be more closely connected in reality than suggested by their theoretical distinctiveness. This study uses bounded rationality as a general theory that supports investors’ irrational behavior and explains the decision-making of the investors. This theory which is based on rather a realistic situation is developed by Simon (1957) in direct response to the narrow view of decision-making offered by the economic versions of rational choice theory (RCT). The term ‘RCT’ is often used interchangeably with ‘public choice theory,’ ‘neoclassicism,’ ‘expected utility theory’ (Zey 1998), ‘rational actor theory’ (Zey 1998; Monroe 2001), and ‘utilitarianism’ (Zafirovski 1999). Derived from economics, RCT is a normative theory that provides an explanation of purposeful human action. The key to understand RTC lies in the concept of ‘optimization.’ Optimization occurs when actors make decisions and take actions after assessing all of the costs and benefits of each alternative with the objective of maximizing utility (James 1990). When the choice of action matches with the optimal choice, it is deemed to be rational. Venture Capital 233 Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Devenow and Welch (1996) mention that irrational herding behavior reflects a scenario whereby individuals perform collective actions in uncertain conditions. The investors prefer such a behavior to reduce the uncertainty and assure their needs to feel in confidentiality. Keynes (1936) describes irrational type of herding as ‘animal spirits’ or an inherent tendency of human behavior. Thus, one could similarly suspect such instincts to be present in humans without explaining the true motivation for this behavior. Such an explanation of irrational herding as used by Keynes seems to fit the fad hypothesis much better than the herding hypothesis. Keynes writes, for example, as follow: A conventional valuation which is established as the outcome of the mass psychology of a large number of ignorant individuals is liable to change violently as the result of a sudden fluctuation of opinion due to factors which do not really make much difference to the prospective yield. (1936, 154) Furthermore, Andersson (2009) indicates that the view of herding as irrational centers on investor psychology where the investors follow each other without rational analysis. Some regularities of human behavior observed in psychological experiments actually support the hypothesis of such an inherent herding instinct in humans. Particularly interesting in this respect is an experiment conducted by Asch (1952). He had subjects to compare the lengths of different line segments. The lengths of the segments were sufficiently different to make such comparison relatively straightforward. However, Asch was able to show that the outcome of this comparison depends crucially on the social context. If the subjects are alone in making their decision, they derive the correct size ranking. However, if other people (who are part of the experiment) are present and the subjects can observe their deliberately incorrect comparisons prior to their own decision, the result of the subject’s comparison is much more likely to be wrong and closer to the group judgment. Therefore, there seems to be a preference for conformity that directs human behavior. Sherif (1937) conducts an experiment similar to Asch’s. However, in contrast to Asch’s experiment, subjects do not seem to be aware of the influence of the group in the experimental set-up of Sherif. Thus, the conformity effect apparently goes beyond a conscious peer pressure effect. Consequently, it is expected that investors imitate each other’s investment decisions in the IPO market, as this context is characterized by substantial uncertainty and ambiguity due to the lack of the historical data and ‘fix-priced’ pricing method in Malaysia. Gleitman (1981) also mentions that the need for social comparison is especially large in situations that are ambiguous or frightening. Thus, irrational or behavioral herding may be especially relevant in economic decision-making, which is characterized by substantial uncertainties and ambiguities. In addition, during the periods of high stress, the individual’s capacity to make rational decisions is reduced (Holsti 1979). This behavior is opposite to the assumption of RCT as a normative theory that provides an explanation of purposeful human action. Investors do not assess all of the costs and benefits of each alternative with the objective of maximizing utility especially when they are during high period of stress. However, Simon’s (1957) bounded rationality theory can support it as he suggests that individual decision aims at providing satisfactory rather than optimal decisions, and in such an environment, investors are more satisfied to reduce their stress by following each other rather than maximizing their utility. Based on the earlier discussions, there are few studies that have analyzed the Malaysian IPO market using behavioral theories and herding behavior has not yet been tested in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs. Therefore, this study would shed light and expand knowledge on this area, especially in the context of developing or emerging Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 234 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian capital market. Specifically, this could be the first study that concentrates on herding behavior of private placement and non-private placement investors, in different industries in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs from 2001 to 2011 using the Christie and Huang (1995) method. The cross-sectional analysis is conducted based on the Bursa Malaysia sectoral classification as there is a tendency for a group to act as a herd if it is sufficiently homogeneous (Bikhchandani and Sharma 2001). In addition, Hirshleifer and Hong Teoh (2003) find that overpricing is observed in the US technology stocks in the 1990s. This finding suggests the possibility of herding in certain sectors such as technology due to their uncertain and risky natures. Thus, there is high possibility that herd formation will be observed at the point of investments in a group of stocks such as firm’s stocks categorized by industry or sector. The division of the data by the proportion of the IPOs subscribed by the institutional/ informed investors (private placement investors) as opposed to the proportion of IPOs subscribed by the individual/not well-informed investors (non-private placement investors) allows testing of herding behavior. The private placement IPOs consist of institutional investors who are well informed. These investors are widely regarded as being sophisticated (Michaely and Shaw 1994; Badrinath, Kale, and Noe 1995; Cohen, Gompers, and Vuolteenaho 2002; Nagel 2005). Chung, Firth, and Kim (2002) and Bos and Donker (2004) indicate that one of the characteristics of institutional investors is that they are more experienced and knowledgeable in processing information. Empirically, the past literature such as De Long et al. (1990), Shleifer and Summers (1990), Banerjee (1992), and Hirshleifer, Subrahmanyam, and Titman (1994) mentions that more experienced investors are those who are unlikely to behave irrationally or demonstrate cognitive biases. Institutional investors are expected not to show faddish behavior in their investment decision, as they would rely on their information for decision-making. Contrary to institutional investors, individuals are considered naı̈ve investors. Thus, their trading behaviors are often regarded as irrational and tend to form market anomalies. They are disadvantaged in information and are more prone to overreact toward new events occurring in the market, and thus individual investors are less rational among all investors (Chemmanur et al. 2010). According to Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler (1991), certain characteristics of individual investors such as ignorance, being uninformed, and trading based on sentiment are general features in the herding literature. In addition, according to Shiller (1984) and De Long et al. (1990), fad and fashion, rather than fundamentals, play important roles in investments decision-making of individual investors as limited source of information is available to them. Methodology and sampling Herding is a non-quantifiable behavior. It cannot be quantified directly but can only be inferred by studying related measurable parameters. The models to measure herding are developed according to how researchers define herding. Empirically, there are several methods to measure herding. The first one concentrates on the trading activities of the individual investors. Herding is said to have occurred when the individuals deliberately imitate the behavior of other investors in equity trading over a period of time. Thus, to measure herding, data are collected on the trading activities as well as the changes in investment portfolio of investors such as the LSV measure introduced by Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1992). Several applications of this methodology include Wermers (1999), Carpenter and Wang (2007), Uchida and Nakagawa (2007), and Kremer and Nautz (2013). In this method, they use an adjusted ratio of net buyers in a security over Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Venture Capital 235 the sum of net buyers and net sellers and examine the probability distribution of this ratio in order to make inferences on herding. This method is designed to capture both investors’ direction and intensity of trading. In the second method that is designed by Christie and Huang (1995), price data are utilized and cross-sectional behavior of returns within a group of securities is examined to assess the formation of herds among investors. The examples of studies that have applied this method include Gleason, Lee, and Mathur (2003), Lin and Swanson (2003), Gleason, Mathur, and Peterson (2004), Demirer and Kutan (2006), Tan et al. (2008), Zhou and Lai (2009), Chiang and Zheng (2010), Demirer, Kutan, and Chen (2010), and Yao, Ma, and He (2014). Chang, Cheng, and Khorana (2000) developed another model to capture herding behavior similar to Christie and Huang (1995), except that the return dispersion used in their model is based on cross-sectional absolute standard deviation (CSAD) of returns instead of CSSD as employed by the latter researchers. The difference between CSAD and CSSD is in terms of the relation between return dispersion and market return whereby CSAD and CSSD assume the relationships to be nonlinear and linear, respectively. CSAD is more suitable method to employ to capture herding behavior especially during periods of market stress if one expects that there is nonlinear association between return dispersion and market return. Hwang and Salmon (2004) develop a different methodology in which instead of return, cross-sectional variability of factor sensitivity is used to measure herding behavior. In their model, herding behavior is measured based on the relative dispersion of the betas for all assets in the market. The advantage of this method is that herding behavior could be examined not only during extreme market conditions but also during normal times. Thus, a detailed analysis on the evolution of herding can be performed over time. In a later study, Bhaduri and Mahapatra (2013) propose a new model to detect herding behavior that is known as cross-sectional absolute mean – median difference (CSMMD) model. CSMMD is an extension of a model developed by Chang, Cheng, and Khorana (2000) and is built with reference to the rational asset-pricing models. Rational asset-pricing models predict that the relation between return dispersion and market return is linear and in increasing function. However, the rational asset-pricing models will no longer be valid if the market participants instead of depending on their prior beliefs follow the behavior of the aggregate market in their equity trading especially during extreme average market movement. Among the aforementioned methods, this study employs the Christie and Huang (1995) method to investigate herding across different sectors during 30 days in the aftermarket of Malaysian IPOs. The previous literature shows that this method was used to investigate herding in the equity market in Malaysia (Lai and Lau 2004). It is appropriate to apply this method for the IPO market as well because the mentioned method examines herding behavior of the investors during the period of market stress, and IPO immediate aftermarket also has such a characteristic due to the high initial returns (Ritter 2003), which is an inherent characteristic of this market. Another contribution to the methodology is to capture herding behavior for the short-term immediate aftermarket (30 days). Herding behavior should be investigated in the short run because the feedback from rational investors offsets the signals provided to the market by the herders (Gleason, Mathur, and Peterson 2004) and also because the literature supports that the Malaysian IPO market stabilizes immediately (Yong 2013). Finally, this is the first study that investigates herding of uninformed and informed investors during the stressful immediate IPO aftermarket based on a different categorization of the IPO market according to different sectors. Yong (2013) investigates Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 236 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian the immediate IPO aftermarket for 20 trading days and concentrates on the short-term aftermarket behavior of the IPOs, based on the listing board categorization only. Theoretically, at the time of herding, equity return dispersions concentrate around aggregate returns of the market, with the assumption that individuals suppress their own beliefs and decisions on investment activities are based solely on the collective actions of the market, such that security returns would not deviate far from the overall market return. Accordingly, Christie and Huang (1995) focus on the dispersion that is the average proximity of individual stock return to the average return to come up with inferences on herding in a market. For this purpose, they first define return dispersion as the CSSD of security returns within a portfolio. Consistent with Christie and Huang (1995), the CSSD of return is measured with some modifications for the IPO market as Equation (1): sP ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi n 2 j¼1 ðr jt 2 rt Þ CSSDt þ ; n21 ð1Þ where n is the number of the IPO firms in the portfolio, r jt is the observed return on IPO j for day t, and rt is the cross-sectional average of the n IPO returns in the portfolio for day t. Accordingly, CSSD is examined to determine whether it is significantly different from average during both period of upper and lower extremes market movements or market stress by using Equation (2). Christie and Huang (1995) indicate that the tendency to mimic the behavior of others appears to be stronger during periods characterized by unusual market trends and phases of high volatility; therefore, these situations are characterized by high uncertainty. Accordingly, they suggest the values of CSSD calculated in Equation (1) during the periods of extreme market movements or high volatility is carried out using the following linear regression: CSSDt ¼ a þ bL DLt þ bU DU t þ 1t ; ð2Þ where DLt ¼ 1 if the return on the aggregate IPO portfolio on day t lies in the lower tail of the IPO return distribution and zero otherwise and DU t ¼ 1 if the return on the aggregate IPO portfolio on day t lies in the upper tail of the return distribution and zero otherwise. The a coefficient denotes the average dispersion of the sample excluding the regions covered by the two dummy variables. The dummy variables in Equation (2) seek to capture differences in return dispersions during the periods of extreme market movements. As a herd formation indicates conformity with market consensus, the presence of negative and statistically significant bL (for declining market) and bU (for rising market) coefficients would indicate herd formation by market participants. Equation (2) is estimated using the criterion to define extreme market movements. In this study, the herding behavior during market stress is tested using 10% criterion, in other words the heteroscedastisity consistent p-values are reported based on 10% criterions during extreme market movement. The 10% criterion restricts DLt ; and DU t to 10% of the lower tail and 10% of the upper tail of the IPO portfolio return distribution. In other words, the b1 coefficient indicates how much the dispersion changes, when the IPO portfolio return is in the bottom 10% of the IPO portfolio return distribution, which is also known as a lower market stress and the b2 coefficient indicates how much the dispersion changes in an upper Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Venture Capital 237 IPO portfolio stress context. The 10% criterion is adopted due to an arbitrary definition of an extreme market return (Christie and Huang 1995). In this study, the investors’ herding behavior in the short-term IPO aftermarket is investigated during a 30-day period. For 30 days to select the 10% criterion, the average aggregate cross-sectional IPO return of this period is arranged in ascending order and 10% from the lowest returns and highest returns (including 3 days of the lowest IPO returns and 3 days of the highest IPO return) are considered to carry the IPO portfolio stress, and the value of 1 is assigned to the dummies of the mentioned percentages. IPO return is calculated from the daily closing prices of new issues using Equation (3) as follow: r jt ¼ Pjt 2 Pjt21 ; Pjt21 ð3Þ where Pjt is the closing IPO price for day t and Pjt21 is the closing IPO price for day t 2 1. The return calculation begins from the second day of the listing as it is based on the closing price of day t minus the closing price of the previous day (i.e., day 1 of the listing). For some IPOs, the closing prices of the first or the first few days are not available, as a result the first day for which the closing price is available is considered as the first trading day of those IPOs and the return calculation is started from that day. This method seems to be appropriate to catch herding behavior at the time of new issues because the IPO immediate aftermarket is characterized by high initial returns (Dawson 1987; Ismail, Abidin, and Zainuddin 1993; Mohamad, Nassir, and Ariff 1994; Yong 2011a). High initial return is considered as period of large price swings. In addition, there is a lack of historical information regarding the new issues, which can create uncertainty and lead to market stress during IPO. Based on the theoretical and empirical discussions, it is hypothesized that herding takes place in non-private placement IPOs (implying by negative coefficients of DLt ; and DU t ) and no herding takes place in private placement IPOs (implying by positive coefficients of DLt ; and DU t ). Between January 2001 and December 2011, Bursa Malaysia statistics report 440 new listings. Out of 440 shares, 55 are labeled as dead and 5 as suspended. Thirteen IPOs that are categorized as real estate investment trusts (REITS), and eight IPOs that are categorized as right, special, restricted, bonus, and closed-end fund issues, are also excluded from this study. IPOs issued under the REITS category are excluded due to the different formats of presentation for their financial statements. As the occurrence of book-built issues is rare in Malaysia and also because the focus of this study is on fixed pricing of IPOs, five issues that apply book-built pricing method are also excluded from this study. The closing prices for seven companies were not available in Datastream. Eight companies have zero returns in 10 consecutive days, so they are also excluded from the sample. These companies are SKB Shutters Corporation Berhad, NTPM holding Berhad, Oriented Media Group Berhad, Guan Chong Berhad, MQ Technology Berhad, 1 Utopia Berhad, Uzma Berhad, and Sunzen Biotech Berhad. Accordingly, the number of companies with available closing prices narrows down to 339, of which 176 and 163 are categorized as private placement and non-private placement IPOs, respectively. This study also excludes the rare type of IPOs, for example restricted offer for sale, restricted public issue, offer for sale to eligible employees, restricted offer for sale to Bumiputra investors, special and restricted issue to Bumiputra investors, tender offer and special issue. The reason to exclude these companies with uncommon types of offer is due to the fact that the number of companies with these issues is very few, leading to less meaningful outcomes as suggested in Abdul Rahim and Yong (2010) and Yong (2007a). Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 238 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian Results and discussions In this study, several sectors are excluded for analysis. The excluded sectors under private placement category are Construction (three IPOs), Plantation (three IPOs), Properties (11 IPOs), and Finance (four IPOs). Meanwhile, for non-private placement category, the sectors that are excluded for analysis are Construction (five IPOs), Plantation (two IPOs), and Properties (two IPOs). These sectors with limited number of IPOs might not result in a meaningful analysis. Consequently, in this study, only Consumer, Industrial, Technology, and Trading and Services sectors are included in the analysis. Table 1 reports the sectoral descriptive statistics both for non-private placement and private placement of IPOs. The statistics are 30 days average level of dispersion, its associated standard deviation, and the number of firms for each category. Across different sectors for the non-private placement of IPOs, the level of dispersion ranges from 0.0354 for Trading and Services to 0.0649 for Industrial. Meanwhile, for private placement of IPOs, the range is from 0.0313 for Consumer to 0.0532 for Trading and Services. The lowest average return dispersion and associated standard deviation belongs to Consumer sector for private placement IPOs category, and the second lowest in the case of non-private placement of IPOs. These statistics reflect the stable nature of this sector. Lai and Lau (2004) confirm these results. They report the lowest average and standard deviation of dispersion for the Consumer sector in their entire samples and by sector over a period of 10 years from January 1992 to December 2001. Table 2 presents regression estimates across different sectors over a 30-day period. The heteroscedastisity consistent p-values reported are based on 10% criterions during extreme market movement. The b1 coefficients indicate by how much return dispersion changes when the return of the market lies in the bottom 10% of the return distribution of the market, which is also known as lower market stress. Meanwhile, the b2 coefficients indicate by how much the return dispersion changes during upper market stress. As there is an arbitrary definition for an extreme market return (Christie and Huang 1995), this study adopts 10% criterion for the analysis. In non-private placement and private placement IPOs, heteroscedasticity regression results are reported for the transformed dependent variable, except for Consumer and Technology sectors. For these two sectors, coefficients’ heteroscedasticity consistent pvalue was reported for untransformed data, as there was no heteroscedasticity problem and as a result no data transformation was conducted. For Industrial and Trading and Services sectors, the dependent variable reaches the desirable level of normality using the inverse values of the variable. Inverse transformation (1/x) makes very small numbers very large and very large numbers very small. This transformation allows reversing the order of the scores. Thus, in order for the result interpretation not to be Table 1. Summary statistics. Consumer Industrial Technology Trading and service Ave return dispersion non-PP SD of dispersion non-PP Number of firms non-PP Ave return dispersion PP SD of dispersion PP Number of firms PP 0.0382 0.0649 0.0459 0.0354 0.0188 0.0771 0.0433 0.0219 37 57 21 26 0.0313 0.0469 0.0500 0.0532 0.0116 0.0302 0.0184 0.0469 19 44 58 45 Note: PP, private placement; SD, standard deviation; Ave, average. Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Venture Capital 239 affected after inversing, the inversed value is multiplied by 2 1, and then a constant (1.0) is added to bring the minimum value back above 1.0. As a result, the ordering of the values will be identical to the original data (Osborne 2002). Based on the results in Panel A of Table 2, during a down market, not well-informed investors act as significantly rational in investing in the Consumer sector as indicated by a positive and significant b1 coefficient of 0.0340 (0.002). During an up market, they remain rational, but not significant as indicated by positive and insignificant b2 coefficient of 0.0034 (0.739). In the industrial sector, investors are significantly rational during down and upward movement of the market as shown by positive and significant b1 and b2 coefficients of 10.3369 (0.027) and 25.0599 (0.000), respectively. Technology sector’s not well-informed investors tend to herd and follow the market based on the negative b1 coefficient of 2 0.0131 (0.635) during down market movement. During an up market, a positive though not significant coefficient of 0.0019 (0.946), for not wellinformed investors, asserts their reluctance to follow the herd in investing in the Technology sector. Not well-informed investors in the Trading and Services sector tend to be rational during down market conditions as an insignificant positive b1 coefficient of 10.3043 (0.181) indicates. During an up market, not well-informed investors investing in the Trading and Services sector act rationally and significantly shown by positive and significant b2 coefficient of 20.9433 (0.010). The result of the sectoral analysis for not well-informed investors indicates that they show rational behavior during down market in Consumer, Industrial, and Trading and Services sectors. Their rational behavior is significant regarding the Consumer and Industrial sectors as significant positive b1 coefficients indicate. This result is in contrast with the suggestion of Bikhchandani and Sharma (2001) where a group is more likely to Table 2. Non-private placement and private placement daily dispersions (herding) during market stress categorized by sectors. 10% Criterion heteroscedastisity consistent p-value untransformed a b1 Panel A: non-private placement 30 days Consumer 0.0345 0.0340 p-Value 0.000 0.002*** Industrial p-Value Technology 0.0470 2 0.0131 p-Value 0.000 0.635 Trading and Services p-Value Panel B: private placement 30 days Consumer 0.0317 2 0.0041 p-Value 0.000 0.583 Industrial p-Value Technology 0.0470 0.0341 p-Value 0.000 0.001*** Trading and Services p-Value b2 0.0034 0.739 0.0019 0.946 0.0005 0.947 2 0.0039 0.686 10% Criterion heteroscedastisity consistent p-value transformed A b1 b2 2 27.7835 0.000 10.3369 0.027** 25.0599 0.000*** 2 36.8834 0.000 10.3043 0.181 20.9433 0.010*** 2 27.5345 0.000 5.2298 0.349 14.0103 0.017** 2 25.3810 0.000 2.5774 0.583 17.4477 0.001*** Notes: b1 denotes dispersion in the down market; b2 denotes dispersion in the up market; ***Significant at 1% level, **Significant at 5% level, and *Significant at 10% level. Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 240 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian herd if it is sufficiently homogeneous. During down market conditions, not wellinformed investors only show a tendency to follow the market in investing in the Technology sector based on an insignificant negative b1 coefficient, which confirms the finding that the possibility of occurring of herding in some sectors such as technology, as the nature of the companies listed in the Technology sector, which are small sized and risky ones, causes them to be more uncertain and leads investors to an imitating behavior. However, during upward movement of the market, this irrationality also fades away which is in line with the findings of Christie and Huang (1995) and Demirer and Kutan (2006) that herding is more expected during market downturn rather than upturn. The herding behavior reported in the Technology sector is consistent with the findings by Lai and Lau (2004) who report a negative b1 coefficient in 10 sectors during the period of market downturn of the Malaysian stock market, both based on 5% and 10% significant levels. They also find no evidence of herding during market upturn. According to the results given in Panel B of Table 2, Consumer sector’s wellinformed investors tend to herd and follow the market based on the negative, but nonsignificant b1 coefficient of 0.0041 (0.583) during down market movement. During up market, Consumer sector’s investors tend to be rational, though not significant as shown by b2 coefficient of 0.0005 (0.947). The reported b1 coefficient of 5.2298 (0.349) during down market movement for well-informed investors in the Industrial sector shows the rational tendency of these investors. During an up market, investors in the Industrial sector act rationally and significantly at 5% level as shown by b2 coefficient of 14.0103 (0.017). During a down market, well-informed investors act as significantly rational in investing in the Technology sector as indicated by a positive and significant b1 coefficient of 0.0341 (0.001). Surprisingly, well-informed investors tend to herd in the Technology sector during an up market as indicated by a negative, but not significant b2 coefficient of 2 0.0039 (0.686). Well-informed investors in the Trading and Services sector tend to be rational during down market conditions as an insignificant positive b1 coefficient of 2.5774 (0.583) indicates. During an up market, well-informed investors investing in the Trading and Services sector act rationally and significantly as shown by b2 coefficient of 17.4477 (0.001). In summary, for the private placement category, well-informed investors in the Industrial, Technology, and Trading and Services sectors show the tendency to act rationally during a down market as shown by the positive b1 coefficients. However, the investors’ rational behavior is only remarkable for the Technology sector as indicated by significant positive b1 coefficients. On the other hand, well-informed investors in the Consumer sector show a tendency to follow the market as shown by an insignificant negative b1 coefficient. During upward market movements, the well-informed investors in Industrial and Trading and Services sectors behave rationally. The investors who buy IPO stock in the Consumer sector also behave rationally as the market condition improves during upward market and investors are less likely to herd (Christie and Huang 1995; Demirer and Kutan 2006). However, the rational behavior of the Technology sector investors turns to irrational during an up market, as a negative b2 coefficient indicates. Conclusions This study examines the short-term herding behaviors of not well-informed (non-private placement) and informed (private placement) investors in the IPO immediate aftermarket during the periods of market stress, or exaggerated price movements. The findings of this study reveal that the not well-informed investors exhibit rational behavior during market Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Venture Capital 241 downturns for Consumer, Industrial, and Trading and Services sectors. However, the not well-informed investors in the Technology sector tend to follow the market movement during down market conditions. This scenario signifies the possibility of herding in some sectors such as technology, as the nature of the companies listed in the Technology sector of Bursa Malaysia are smaller in size, which makes them to be considered as risky ones by the investors. The results of this study reveal that the well-informed investors have the tendency to demonstrate herding behavior particularly for Consumer and Technology sectors during down and up markets, respectively. It can be implied that these investors have the tendency to follow the market because the negative coefficient is not limited to the downward market and to risky and uncertain shares. The previous literature also suggests that institutional investors often follow other institutional investors (Grinblatt and Hwang 1989; Nofsinger and Sias 1999; Wermers 1999; Wylie 2005; Walter and Weber 2006; Agudo, Sarto, and Vicente 2008; Andreu, Ortiz, and Sarto 2009), and such a trend is particularly apparent in the emerging markets (Lobao and Serra, forthcoming; Voronkova and Bohl 2005; Tan et al. 2008). As the IPO market is volatile and risky in comparison with seasoned equity markets, this situation can lead to herding behavior of the institutional investors. Furthermore, Shiller and Pound (1989) state that for volatile stocks, institutional investors emphasize the advice of other professionals on their buy and sell decisions. There is a common phenomenon whereby an investor’s behavior influences other investors’ behavior. In this scenario, investors may forego their own rational analysis. They tend to adopt behavior that is similar to the group. Note 1. Email: pegahdehghani@yahoo.com References Abdul Rahim, R., and O. Yong. 2010. “Initial Returns of Malaysian IPOs and Shari’a-Compliant Status.” Journal of Islamic Accounting and Business Research 1 (1): 60 – 74. Abdullah, N. A. H., and K. N. Taufil Mohd. 2004. “Factors Influencing the Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings in an Emerging Market: Malaysian Evidence.” IIUM Journal of Economics and Management 12 (2): 1 – 23. Agudo, L. F., J. Sarto, and L. Vicente. 2008. “Herding Behaviour in Spanish Equity Funds.” Applied Economics Letters 15 (7): 573– 576. Ahmad-Zaluki, N. A., K. Campbell, and A. Goodacre. 2007. “The Long Run Share Price Performance of Malaysian Initial Public Offerings (IPOs).” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 34 (1 – 2): 78 – 110. Ahmad-Zaluki, N. A., K. Campbell, and A. Goodacre. 2011. “Earnings Management in Malaysian IPOs: The East Asian Crisis, Ownership Control, and Post-IPO Performance.” The International Journal of Accounting 46 (2): 111– 137. Andersson, M. 2009. Social Influence in Stock Markets. Sweden: University of Gothenburg, Department of Psychology. Andreu, L., C. Ortiz, and J. L. Sarto. 2009. “Herding Behaviour in Strategic Asset Allocations: New Approaches on Quantitative and Intertemporal Imitation.” Applied Financial Economics 19 (20): 1649– 1659. Annuar, M. N., and M. Shamsher. 1998. “The Performance and Signaling Process of Initial Public Offers in Malaysia: 1980–1996.” Pertanika Journal of Social Sciences and Humanities 6 (2): 71–79. Antoniou, A., N. Ergul, P. Holmes, and R. Priestley. 1997. “Technical Analysis, Trading Volume and Market Efficiency: Evidence from an Emerging Market.” Applied Financial Economics 7 (4): 361– 365. Asch, S. E. 1952. Social Psychology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 242 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian Badrinath, S. G., J. R. Kale, and T. H. Noe. 1995. “Of Shepherds, Sheep, and the CrossAutocorrelations in Equity Returns.” Review of Financial Studies 8 (2): 401–430. Banerjee, A. V. 1992. “A Simple Model of Herd Behavior.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (3): 797– 817. Baron, D. P. 1982. “A Model of the Demand for Investment Banking Advising and Distribution Services for New Issues.” Journal of Finance 37 (4): 955– 976. Beatty, R. P., and J. R. Ritter. 1986. “Investment Banking, Reputation, and the Underpricing of Initial Public Offerings.” Journal of Financial Economics 15 (1– 2): 213– 232. Benveniste, L. M., and P. A. Spindt. 1989. “How Investment Bankers Determine the Offer Price and Allocation of New Issues.” Journal of Financial Economics 24 (2): 343– 361. Bhaduri, S. N., and S. D. Mahapatra. 2013. “Applying an Alternative Test of Herding Behavior: A Case Study of the Indian Stock Market.” Journal of Asian Economics 25: 43 – 52. Biais, B., P. Bossaerts, and J. C. Rochet. 2002. “An Optimal IPO Mechanism.” The Review of Economic Studies 69 (1): 117– 146. Bikhchandani, S., D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch. 1992. “A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades.” Journal of Political Economy 100 (5): 992– 1026. Bikhchandani, S., and S. Sharma. 2001. “Herd Behavior in Financial Markets.” IMF Staff Papers 47 (3): 279– 310. Bos, A., and H. Donker. 2004. “Monitoring Accounting Changes: Empirical Evidence from the Netherlands.” Corporate Governance: An International Review 12 (1): 60 – 73. Campos, C. E., R. E. Newell, and G. Wilson. 2002. “Corporate Governance Develops in Emerging Markets.” McKinsey on Finance: 15 – 18. Carpenter, A., and J. Wang. 2007. “Herding and the Information Content of Trades in the Australian Dollar Market.” Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 15 (2): 173– 194. Chahine, S. 2007. “Investor Interest, Trading Volume, and the Choice of IPO Mechanism in France.” International Review of Financial Analysis 16 (2): 116– 135. Chang, E. C., J. W. Cheng, and A. Khorana. 2000. “An Examination of Herd Behavior in Equity Markets: An International Perspective.” Journal of Banking and Finance 24 (10): 1651 –1679. Chemmanur, T. J., B. D. Jordan, M. H. Liu, and Q. Wu. 2010. “Anti-Takeover Provisions in Corporate Spin-Offs.” Journal of Banking and Finance 34 (4): 813– 824. Cheng, L. T. W., K. C. Chan, and B. S. C. Mak. 2005. “Strategic Share Allocation and Underpricings of IPOs in Hong Kong.” International Business Review 14 (1): 41 – 59. Chiang, T. C., and D. Zheng. 2010. “An Empirical Analysis of Herd Behavior in Global Stock Markets.” Journal of Banking and Finance 34 (8): 1911– 1921. Chong, F. 2009. “Disposition Effect and Flippers in the Bursa Malaysia.” The Journal of Behavioral Finance 10 (3): 152– 157. Christie, W. G., and R. D. Huang. 1995. “Following the Pied Piper: Do Individual Returns Herd Around the Market?” Financial Analysts Journal 51 (4): 31 – 37. Chung, R., M. Firth, and J. B. Kim. 2002. “Institutional Monitoring and Opportunistic Earnings Management.” Journal of Corporate Finance 8 (1): 29 – 48. Cohen, R. B., P. A. Gompers, and T. Vuolteenaho. 2002. “Who Underreacts to Cash-Flow News? Evidence from Trading Between Individuals and Institutions.” Journal of Financial Economics 66 (2): 409– 462. Dasgupta, A., A. Prat, and M. Verardo. 2011. “The Price Impact of Institutional Herding.” Review of Financial Studies 24 (3): 892– 925. Dawson, S. M. 1987. “Secondary Stock Market Performance of Initial Public Offers, Hong Kong, Singapore and Malaysia: 1978– 1984.” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 14 (1): 65 – 76. De Long, J. B., A. Shleifer, L. H. Summers, and R. J. Waldmann. 1990. “Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 98 (4): 703– 738. Demirer, R., and A. M. Kutan. 2006. “Does Herding Behavior Exist in Chinese Stock Markets?” Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 16 (2): 123– 142. Demirer, R., A. M. Kutan, and C. D. Chen. 2010. “Do Investors Herd in Emerging Stock Markets?: Evidence from the Taiwanese Market.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 76 (2): 283– 295. Derrien, F., and K. L. Womack. 2003. “Auctions Vs. Bookbuilding and the Control of Underpricing in Hot IPO Markets.” Review of Financial Studies 16 (1): 31 – 61. Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Venture Capital 243 Devenow, A., and I. Welch. 1996. “Rational Herding in Financial Economics.” European Economic Review 40 (3– 5): 603– 615. Ge˛bka, B., and M. E. Wohar. 2013. “International Herding: Does It Differ Across Sectors?” Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 23: 55 – 84. Gelos, R. G., and S. J. Wei. 2002. “Transparency and International Investor Behavior.” NBER Working Paper Series (9260), National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. http:// www.nber.org/papers/w9260 Gleason, K. C., C. I. Lee, and I. Mathur. 2003. “Herding Behavior in European Futures Markets.” Finance Letters 1: 5 –8. Gleason, K. C., I. Mathur, and M. A. Peterson. 2004. “Analysis of Intraday Herding Behavior Among the Sector ETFs.” Journal of Empirical Finance 11 (5): 681– 694. Gleitman, H. 1981. Psychology. New York: Norton and Company. Goetzman, W. 1995. “Discussion: On Fads, Crashes and Asymmetric Information.” In AngloAmerican Finance Systems: Institutions and Markets in the 20th Century, edited by Richard Sylla and Mike Bordo, 323– 328. New York: Irwin Publishers. Golberg, J., and R. Nitzsch. 2001. Behavioral Finance. London: John Wiley and Sons. Grinblatt, M., and C. Y. Hwang. 1989. “Signalling and the Pricing of New Issues.” Journal of Finance 44 (2): 393– 420. Grinblatt, M., S. Titman, and R. Wermers. 1995. “Momentum Investment Strategies, Portfolio Performance, and Herding: A Study of Mutual Fund Behavior.” The American Economic Review 85 (5): 1088 –1105. Hirshleifer, D., and S. Hong Teoh. 2003. “Herd Behaviour and Cascading in Capital Markets: A Review and Synthesis.” European Financial Management 9 (1): 25 – 66. Hirshleifer, D., A. Subrahmanyam, and S. Titman. 1994. “Security Analysis and Trading Patterns When Some Investors Receive Information Before Others.” Journal of Finance 49 (5): 1665– 1698. Holsti, O. R. 1979. “The Three-Headed Eagle: The United States and System Change.” International Studies Quarterly 23 (3): 339– 359. Houge, T., T. Loughran, X. S. Yan, and G. Suchanek. 2001. “Divergence of Opinion, Uncertainty, and the Quality of Initial Public Offerings.” Financial Management 30 (4): 5 – 23. How, J., R. Jelic, B. Saadouni, and P. Verhoeven. 2007. “Share Allocations and Performance of KLSE Second Board IPOs.” Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 15 (3): 292– 314. Hsieh, S. F. 2013. “Individual and Institutional Herding and the Impact on Stock Returns: Evidence from Taiwan Stock Market.” International Review of Financial Analysis 29: 175–188. Husni, T. 2005. “Price Randomness, Contrarians and Momentum Strategies: A Study of Return Predictability in the Malaysian Stock Exchange.” Thesis doctoral dissertation, Universiti Sains Malaysia. Hwang, S., and M. Salmon. 2004. “Market Stress and Herding.” Journal of Empirical Finance 11 (4): 585– 616. Isa, M., and R. Ahmad. 1996. “Performance of New Issues on the Malaysia Stock Market.” Malaysia Journal of Economic Studies 13 (2): 53 – 66. Ismail, K., F. Z. Abidin, and N. Zainuddin. 1993. “Performance of New Stock Issues on the KLSE.” Capital Markets Review 1 (1): 81 – 95. James, C. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Belknap. Jelic, R., B. Saadouni, and R. Briston. 2001. “Performance of Malaysian IPOs: Underwriters Reputation and Management Earnings Forecasts.” Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 9 (5): 457–486. Jomo, K. S. 1998. “Financial Liberalization, Crises, and Malaysian Policy Responses.” World Development 26 (8): 1563– 1574. Kallinterakis, V., and T. Kratunova. 2007. “Does Thin Trading Impact Upon the Measurement of Herding? Evidence from Bulgaria.” Ekonomia 10 (1): 42 – 65 Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Vol. VII. London: Macmillan. Kim, K. A., and J. R. Nofsinger. 2005. “Institutional Herding, Business Groups, and Economic Regimes: Evidence from Japan.” The Journal of Business 78 (1): 213– 242. Kremer, S. 2010. “Herding of Institutional Traders.” SFB 649 Discussion Paper 2010-025, Humboldt University, Berlin, Germany. Kremer, S., and D. Nautz. 2013. “Short-Term Herding of Institutional Traders: New Evidence from the German Stock Market.” European Financial Management 19 (4): 730– 746. Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 244 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian Lai, M. M., B. K. Guru, and F. M. Nor. 2003. “Do Malaysian Investors Overreact.” Journal of American Academy of Business 2 (2): 602– 609. Lai, M., and S. Lau. 2004. “Herd Behavior and Market Stress: The Case of Malaysia.” Academy of Accounting and Financial Studies Journal 8 (3): 85 – 102. Lakonishok, J., A. Shleifer, and R. W. Vishny. 1992. “The Impact of Institutional Trading on Stock Prices.” Journal of Financial Economics 32 (1): 23 –43. Lee, C. M. C., A. Shleifer, and R. H. Thaler. 1991. “Investor Sentiment and the Closed-End Fund Puzzle.” The Journal of Finance 46 (1): 75 – 109. Leong, K., E. Vos, and A. Tourani-Rad. 2000. “Malaysia IPOs Performance Pre- and Post Asian Crisis.” Paper presented at the ABN-AMRO International IPO Conference, Amsterdam. Lin, A. Y., and P. E. Swanson. 2003. “The Behavior and Performance of Foreign Investors in Emerging Equity Markets: Evidence from Taiwan.” International Review of Finance 4 (3–4): 189–210. Lobao, J., and A. P. Serra. 2002. “Herding Behavior: Evidence from Portuguese Mutual Funds.” Unpublished Working Paper. Instituto de Estudos Financieros e Fiscais, Portugal. Lowry, M., and G. W. Schwert. 2002. “IPO Market Cycles: Bubbles or Sequential Learning?” The Journal of Finance 57 (3): 1171– 1200. Mat-Nor, F., M. M. Lai, and A. M. Hussin. 2002. “Price Randomness, Fundamental Factors, and Stock Market Contrarian Strategy: Further Evidence on Malaysian Stock Market.” Proceedings of the 4th Malaysian Finance Association, Penang, Malaysia. Megginson, W. L., and K. A. Weiss. 1991. “Venture Capitalist Certification in Initial Public Offerings.” Journal of Finance 46 (3): 879– 903. Michaely, R., and W. H. Shaw. 1994. “The Pricing of Initial Public Offerings: Tests of AdverseSelection and Signaling Theories.” Review of Financial Studies 7 (2): 279– 319. Miller, E. M. 1977. “Risk, Uncertainty, and Divergence of Opinion.” The Journal of Finance 32 (4): 1151– 1168. Miller, R. E., and F. K. Reilly. 1987. “An Examination of Mispricing, Returns, and Uncertainty for Initial Public Offerings.” Financial Management 16 (2): 33 – 38. Mohamad, S., A. Nassir, and M. Ariff. 1994. “Analysis of Underpricing in the Malaysian New Issues Market During 1975– 1990: Are New Issues Excessively Underpriced.” Capital Markets Review 2 (2): 17 – 27. Mohd, K. N. T. 2007. “Regulations and Underpricing of IPOs.” Capital Markets Review 15 (1 – 2): 1 – 27. Monroe, K. R. 2001. “Paradigm Shift: From Rational Choice to Perspective.” International Political Science Review 22 (2): 151– 172. Morris, S., and H. S. Shin. 1999. “Risk Management with Interdependent Choice.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 15 (3): 52 – 62. Nagel, S. 2005. “Short Sales, Institutional Investors and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 78 (2): 277–309. Nofsinger, J. R., and W. Sias. 1999. “Herding and Feedback Trading by Institutional and Individual Investors.” The Journal of Finance 54 (6): 2263– 2295. Oehler, A. 1998. “Do Mutual Funds Specializing in German Stocks Herd?” Finanzmarkt und Portfolio Management 4 (1998): 452– 465. Orléan, A. 1995. “Bayesian Interactions and Collective Dynamics of Opinion: Herd Behavior and Mimetic Contagion.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 28 (2): 257– 274. Osborne, J. 2002. “Notes on the Use of Data Transformations.” Practical Assessment, Research and Evaluation 8 (6): 1 – 8. Persaud, A. 2000. “Sending the Herd Off the Cliff Edge: The Disturbing Interaction Between Herding and Market-Sensitive Risk Management Practices.” The Journal of Risk Finance 2 (1): 59 – 65. Prasad, D., G. S. Vozikis, and M. Ariff. 2006. “Government Public Policy, Regulatory Intervention, and Their Impact on IPO Under-Pricing: The Case of Malaysian IPOs.” Journal of Small Business Management 44 (1): 81 – 98. Puckett, A., and X. Yan. 2007. “The Determinants and Impact of Short-Term Institutional Herding.” Mimeo. http://rssrn.com/abstract=972254 Rashid, A. A., M. K. Ibrahim, R. Othman, and K. F. See. 2012. “IC Disclosures in IPO Prospectuses: Evidence from Malaysia.” Journal of Intellectual Capital 13 (1): 57 – 80. Ritter, J. R. 1984. “The “Hot Issue” Market of 1980.” Journal of Business 57 (2): 215– 240. Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Venture Capital 245 Ritter, J. R. 2003. “Investment Banking and Securities Issuance.” Handbook of the Economics of Finance 1: 255– 306. Rock, K. 1986. “Why New Issues Are Underpriced.” Journal of Financial Economics 15 (1 – 2): 187– 212. Scharfstein, D. S., and J. C. Stein. 1990. “Herd Behavior and Investment.” The American Economic Review 80 (3): 465–479. Sherif, M. 1937. “An Experimental Approach to the Study of Attitudes.” Sociometry 1 (1–2): 90–98. Shiller, R. J. 1984. “Stock Prices and Social Dynamics.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 15 (2): 457– 510. Shiller, R. J. 1989. Market Volatility. Cambridge: MIT Press. Shiller, R. J., and J. Pound. 1989. “Survey Evidence on Diffusion of Interest and Information Among Investors.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 12 (1): 47 – 66. Shleifer, A., and L. H. Summers. 1990. “The Noise Trader Approach to Finance.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 4 (2): 19 – 33. Sias, R. W. 2004. “Institutional Herding.” Review of Financial Studies 17 (1): 165– 206. Simon, H. A. 1957. Models of Man; Social and Rational. New York: Wiley. Tan, L., T. C. Chiang, J. R. Mason, and E. Nelling. 2008. “Herding Behavior in Chinese Stock Markets: An Examination of A and B Shares.” Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 16 (1): 61 – 77. Topol, R. 1991. “Bubbles and Volatility of Stock Prices: Effect of Mimetic Contagion.” The Economic Journal 101 (407): 786– 800. Uchida, H., and R. Nakagawa. 2007. “Herd Behavior in the Japanese Loan Market: Evidence from Bank Panel Data.” Journal of Financial Intermediation 16 (4): 555– 583. Voronkova, S., and M. T. Bohl. 2005. “Institutional Traders’ Behavior in an Emerging Stock Market: Empirical Evidence on Polish Pension Fund Investors.” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 32 (7 – 8): 1537– 1560. Walter, A., and F. M. Weber. 2006. “Herding in the German Mutual Fund Industry.” European Financial Management 12 (3): 375– 406. Wan-Hussin, W. 2005. “The Effect of Owner’s Participation and Share Lock-Up on IPO Underpricing in Malaysia.” Asian Academy of Management Journal 10 (1): 19 – 36. Wermers, R. 1999. “Mutual Fund Herding and the Impact on Stock Prices.” The Journal of Finance 54 (2): 581– 622. Wylie, S. 2005. “Fund Manager Herding: A Test of the Accuracy of Empirical Results Using UK Data.” The Journal of Business 78 (1): 381 –403. Yao, J., C. Ma, and W. P. He. 2014. “Investor Herding Behaviour of Chinese Stock Market.” International Review of Economics and Finance 29: 12 – 29. Yatim, P. 2011. “Underpricing and Board Structures: An Investigation of Malaysian Initial Public Offerings (IPOs).” Asian Academy of Management Journal of Accounting and Finance 7 (1): 73–93. Yong, O. 1991. “Performance of New Issues of Securities in Malaysia.” Malaysian Accountant: 3–6. Yong, O. 1996. “Size of the Firm, Over-Subscription Ratio and Performance of IPOs.” Malaysian Management Review 31 (2): 28 – 39. Yong, O. 2007a. “Investor Demand, Size Effect and Performance of Malaysian Initial Public Offerings: Evidence from Post-1997 Financial Crisis.” Jurnal Pengurusan 26: 25 – 47. Yong, O. 2007b. “A Review of IPO Research in Asia: What’s Next?” Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 15 (3): 253– 275. Yong, O. 2011a. “Investor Demand, Size Effect and the Immediate Post-Listing Behavior of Malaysian IPOs.” Universiti Tun Abdul Razak E-Journal 7 (2): 23 – 32. Yong, O. 2011b. “Winner’s Curse and Bandwagon Effect in Malaysian IPOs: Evidence from 2001– 2009.” Jurnal Pengurusan 32: 21 – 26. Yong, O. 2013. “When Do the Aftermarket IPO Prices Stabilize? Evidence from Malaysian Fixed Price IPOs.” International Review of Business Research Papers 9 (4): 77– 90. Yong, O., and Z. Isa. 2003. “Initial Performance of New Issues of Shares in Malaysia.” Applied Economics 35 (8): 919– 930. Yong, O., P. Yatim, and R. Z. Sapian. 1999. “Significance of Board of Listing and Type of Issue on the Under-Pricing and After-Market Performance of Malaysian IPOs.” Capital Markets Review 7 (1– 2): 47 – 74. Yong, O., Yatim, and Z. Sapian. 2002. “Size of Offer, Over Subscription Ratio and Performance of Malaysian IPOs.” Malaysian Management Journal 6 (1 – 2): 35 – 51. 246 P. Dehghani and R.Z.Z. Sapian Downloaded by [Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia], [Ros Zam Zam Sapian] at 18:12 21 July 2014 Zafirovski, M. 1999. “What Is Really Rational Choice? Beyond the Utilitarian Concept of Rationality.” Current Sociology 47 (1): 47 – 113. Zey, M. 1998. Rational Choice Theory and Organizational Theory: A Critique. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications. Zhou, R. T., and R. N. Lai. 2009. “Herding and Information Based Trading.” Journal of Empirical Finance 16 (3): 388– 393. View publication stats