Chapter 3: Interdependence and the Gains from Trade Chapter 3 builds on the model we developed in Chapter 2 (Production Possibilities Frontier). The importance of the chapter is to motivate why trade is so ubiquitous. Every day, consciously or not, we engage in trade perhaps hundreds of times. I cannot think of anything that I consume that I do not depend on others to provide. My coffee is from somewhere near the equator, my orange juice starts in Florida (I guess) and somehow makes it to my local grocery store - never mind my iPhone, my car, my clothes etc. This is the interdependence that the book refers to. Note that in the examples above, the trades I refer to are all organized through markets where I pay a price for each good. And, to be honest, after this chapter we will begin thinking about trade (exchange between buyers and sellers) in these terms. For now, it will be easier to consider a simple economy. Trade, as I refer to it here, simply means the exchange of goods between two people. Let’s follow along with the example in the text. There are 2 people (Frank the farmer and Ruby the rancher) and two goods (potatoes and meat). Again, like the PPF model, the number of people and the number of goods is irrelevant to the intuition of the model. This simplifying assumption only allows us to more easily sketch out the graphs and see the underlying intuition. Further, there is only 1 resource, they each have 8 hours per day to work. I will also say that the incentives of each person is to consume as much as possible - More is better. The first thing we need to do is depict their respective PPFs. To do so we need to figure out how many potatoes and meat they can produce. In 8 hours, Frank can produce 8 ounces of meat (each ounce requires 60 minutes of work) or 32 ounces of potatoes (each ounce requires 15 minutes of work). Similarly, in 8 hours Ruby can produce 24 ounces of meat (each ounce requires 20 minutes of work) or 48 ounces of potatoes (each ounce requires 10 minutes of work). For simplicity, I am also going to assume that both Frank and Ruby can costlessly switch between tasks so that I can depict their PPFs as linear lines. Here we have meat on the vertical axis and potatoes on the horizontal. As explained above, if Frank spends all of his available time producing meat (potatoes) he would be able to produce 8 (32) ounces. These determine the endpoints of their PPFs. Because it is linear, I simply connect these endpoints and call it a PPF. Do the same for Ruby. Before we move on, let’s say that in isolation (in the absence of trade/exchange between Frank and Ruby) they each decide to split their time evenly. These points are depicted on the graphs above. They imply that Frank will produce and consume 4 meat and 16 potatoes while Ruby produces and consumes 12 meat and 24 potatoes. By the way, I am dropping the units (ounces) for the rest of this example. Since they are each on their PPF we know the outcome is efficient. They are each consuming all that they are able to given their resources (8 hours). This is the best they can do, anything outside the PPF is unobtainable. As suggested by the title of the chapter. The question is whether Frank and Ruby could be better off if they engaged in trade. It is not entirely obvious that they can. Ruby is able to produce a lot more meat AND potatoes than Frank. Why would she engage in trade? Well, the motivation for trade does not stem from how much you can produce. Rather, what matters is how much it costs you to produce. Let’s define two important terms. Absolute Advantage is the ability to produce a good with fewer inputs. Here the only input is time and Ruby produces an ounce of meat in 20 minutes versus 60 minutes for Frank. Because we have given each person the same amount of resources (8 hours), Absolute Advantage is easy to determine. It just means that Ruby can produce more meat than Frank. Here we would say that Ruby has the Absolute Advantage is both meat and potatoes. Comparative Advantage is the ability to produce a good at a lower opportunity cost (OC). This is the important concept. The nice thing about this model is that it makes OC really easy. The OC of meat is simply how many potatoes you give up to produce the meat. Let’s run through the example. Recall chapter 2. The OC is the slope of the PPF - here the slope is 8/32 = 1/4. The only problem is that you need to know which good has the OC of ¼. This isn’t terribly difficult but I have always found the following method (introduced in chapter 2) easier. The way I determined the OC in chapter 2 was to set up an ‘equation’ using the endpoints of the linear PPF. For Frank I would say that 8 meat = 32 potatoes and I would ‘solve’: The OC of 1 meat = 32/8 = 4 potatoes (just ‘divide’ both sides by 8) and The OC of 1 potato = 8/32 = ¼ meat. The OCs are always reciprocals of each other. By keeping the OC in sentence form it is easy to keep track of. It is worth interpreting these OCs. They mean that every time Frank decides to produce 1 meat he must give up 4 potatoes - that is, the cost of 1 meat is 4 potatoes. This makes complete sense; an ounce of meat requires 60 minutes while an ounce of potatoes only requires 15 minutes (¼ of 60). On the other hand, to produce 1 potato he only gives up ¼ meat. Doing the same for Ruby you should get the following: The OC of 1 meat = 48/24 = 2 potatoes The OC of 1 potato = 24/48 = ½ meat We would say that Ruby has the Comparative Advantage in producing meat. She produces meat at a lower OC. It only costs her 2 potatoes to produce meat while it costs Frank 4 potatoes to produce meat. Similarly, we would say that Frank has the Comparative Advantage in producing potatoes. Gains from Trade The gains from trade in this model stem from specializing in one’s comparative advantage. This is pretty intuitive, it just means that each person should specialize in the production of the good that they produce at lower OC. In this example, Frank would specialize in the production of potatoes and Ruby would specialize in the production of meat. Now, I should note that the extent of specialization cannot be completely determined - we don’t know their preferences. Recall that the purpose of the model is to show that Frank and Ruby can be better off with trade - again, their incentives are to increase their consumption. In this sense, all we need to show is that specialization and trade can increase their consumption. So, in the beginning we said that, in isolation, they split their time evenly. This means that we ended up with a total (Frank plus Ruby) of 16 ounces of meat and 40 ounces of potatoes. In order for trade to benefit both parties here they must collectively produce more of both goods. This will make the gains from trade unambiguous - more is better. Following the text, I will say that Frank completely specializes in potatoes and produces 32. Ruby shifts some of her effort towards meat and ends up producing 18 meat and 12 potatoes. Now, this simple economy produces 18 ounces of meat and 44 ounces of potatoes. I will continue to follow the text here and simply give you the exchange rate between meat and potatoes - we will discuss this a bit more below. Let’s say that they agree to exchange 5 meat for 15 potatoes - the implied price of 1 meat is 3 potatoes. This leaves Frank with 5 meat and 17 potatoes and Ruby with 13 meat and 27 potatoes. See depiction of their PPFs below. The point is that this specialization and trade allows them each to consume outside their respective PPFs. Recall that prior to specialization and trade they each consumed on their PPF (they were doing as best as they could). Now, suddenly, they are each consuming at a point which was unobtainable. This motivates some to think about trade as a type of technology - with the same resources (time) we are able to consume more. This picture suggests that each person (Frank and Ruby) are both unambiguously better off. They each are able to consume more of both goods than they would otherwise. In the above we set the price of trade at 1 meat for 3 potatoes (it is equivalent to say that the price of 1 potato is ⅓ meat). While we can’t determine where this price will end up we can provide a range for it. First, think about the max price that Frank will pay for meat in terms of potatoes (since Frank specializes in potatoes he wants to know how many potatoes each meat will cost him). For Frank, the cost of 1 meat is 4 potatoes so this is the most he will pay. On the other hand, Ruby specializes in meat and will be concerned with the price of potatoes in terms of meat. For Ruby the cost of 1 potato is ½ meat - she will not pay more than this. Turning this around would suggest 1 meat for 2 potatoes. Thus, their OCs provide the range of prices at which they can each gain from trade. Here 1 meat must trade for between 2 and 4 potatoes. In general, each party to this trade would like to increase the price in terms of their comparative advantage good. For example, Ruby would like to trade each meat for 3.5 potatoes - each meat that she produces becomes more valuable to her. Another Example There are 2 people stranded on an island. Their only resource is time (they each have 10 hours per day). Their only needs are Coconuts and Fish. Person A can produce 1 coconut/hour or 1 fish/hour Person B can produce 2 coconuts/hour or 0.5 fish/hour In the notes here I will sketch out the answer. You should be able to work through the previous example and replicate the provided answers. If not ask for help. 1. Sketch out their respective PPFs, put coconuts on the vertical axis. 2. Who has the Absolute Advantage in coconuts (fish)? 3. Assume that in isolation they each split their time evenly. Label this point on each PPF. How many coconuts and fish does each person produce and consume? 4. Who has the Comparative Advantage in coconuts (fish)? Show your work and how you calculated their OCs here. 5. Assume that each person completely specializes in their Comparative Advantage good. Label this point on each PPF. How many coconuts and fish does each person produce? 6. Assume that they agree to exchange 4 fish for 8 coconuts. How many coconuts and fish does each person now consume? Label this point on each PPF. You should find that person A consumes 6 fish and 8 coconuts while person B consumes 4 fish and 12 coconuts after they engage in trade. Applications of Comparative Advantage Perhaps the most important application of Comparative Advantage is to international trade. International trade implies the trade of goods and services between countries. Imports are goods produced abroad and consumed domestically Exports are goods produced domestically and sold abroad These definitions are fine for now but I would argue that they are overly simplistic. While the US may import cotton shirts from Vietnam we have to keep in mind that we may have exported cotton to Vietnam. This trade basically says that the US can grow cotton more cheaply than Vietnam and that Vietnam can make this cotton into clothes more cheaply than the US can (of course we mean firms within these respective countries – and let’s further ignore that we are really talking about multinational firms whose owners and workers are distributed across countries). For now, we will simply say that countries differ in their available resources and this drives variation in the OC of production. Because countries vary in their relative OCs there is a basis for trade using the concept of Comparative Advantage. For another example, let’s make up a simplified example comparing the US and Japan and wheat and electronics. Given the size of our economy I suspect that the US can produce more wheat and electronics than Japan can (we have an Absolute Advantage in both goods). But, who do you think produces wheat more cheaply? The US has a ton of good, arable, land while Japan has very little. The idea is that the US has a Comparative Advantage in growing wheat while Japan has a Comparative Advantage in electronics. By engaging in trade with Japan we are both able to consume more. It is as if our farmers have figured out a way to turn wheat into Sony Playstations and TVs. This is great for US farmers and US consumers – it is not so great for US producers of electronics as we will discuss in Chapter 9. This is the main reason that for an economist free trade is unambiguously good. Whether the trade is between Frank and Ruby or the US and China is irrelevant. That said, there are certainly valid concerns with trade which we discuss later. How would bowed out PPFs affect Comparative Advantage? Recall from chapter 2 that a bowed out PPF suggests that as you produce more and more of a particular good the OC rises. The intuition is that inputs into production are not perfectly substitutable. For this reason, we will not observe complete specialization in international trade. Think about how the OC relates to the price of exchange between goods.