Introduction to the New Methods for Project Valuation: The Real Options Approach © Paulo Pereira, 2010 “For most investments, the usefulness of NPV rule is severely limited…, [modern finance] is now obliged to treat all major investment decisions as option pricing problems” (Stephen A. Ross, MIT) © Paulo Pereira, 2010 1 “Discounted cash flow is going to look at an average scenario. (…) But if you talk to any manager, that's not how they think. They think about contingencies — what's going to happen, how would we react. And even if they don't think that way, once it's presented to them that way, they say, 'Yeah, that's the way we should be thinking.'" CFO Magazine, “Will Real Options take roots?”, July 2003 © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Limitations of Traditional Methods • Rigid methods; – The cash flows follow a rigid pattern and can be forecasted for long periods of time. • They assume “now or never” projects, ignoring the chance for postponing the investment decision; – Benefits from postponing: obtain more information about the project, the market, competitive environment,… In a word: reveal new relevant information… – However, the uncertainty will never be totally eliminated. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 2 Limitations of Traditional Methods • Assume a passive attitude of the manager; – … as if no decisions would be necessary after implementing the project; – … as if the manager would only be needed for taking the investment decision!! © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Limitations of Traditional Methods • The traditional methods ignore the capacity for modifying the projects as time passes and new information is revealed; – ...i.e., ignore the capacity to adapt the project to the new reality, if that is needed. • Accordingly, they don’t capture the flexibility of the project. • As we will see, this flexibility corresponds to a set of option embedded in the project. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 3 Limitations of Traditional Methods • Assume no connection between current projects and future investment opportunities; • ... or, at least, do not treat those links in a adequate manner; • Basically, because those future investment opportunities are options, and the NPV is not an adequate method for evaluating them. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Limitations of Traditional Methods • Those methods were initially developed for valuing quasi-certain assets (and later adapted for project valuation); • They seem to work properly when the environment is stable and the future is predictable. • Do we live in this stable and predictable environment? © Paulo Pereira, 2010 4 Limitations of Traditional Methods • For the traditional methods, more uncertainty mean more risk premium and a higher discount rate, ... decreasing the value of a project. • The new approach should consider that investment projects are, essentially, “options” or sets of “options”, where the risk not always is a “value-destroyer”. • … the owner of an option only cares about the up-side of the possible payoffs. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Financial Options? • A financial option gives the owner the right to buy or to sell a given financial asset, the underlying asset (e.g., a share), for a pre-determined price, the exercise price. • To have this right, the investor must pay a premium (the value of the option); • The option to buy is a call. The option to sell is a put. • Options can be European (the right can only be exercised at the maturity date) or American (the right can also be exercised anytime, prior maturity). © Paulo Pereira, 2010 5 Financial Options? • At maturity date, the payoff of a call option is: max[ST − X, 0] • Notice that, at maturity: – is always positive, or zero (never negative); – the value of the options corresponds only to the intrinsic value; – i.e., in that date, the time value of the option is zero. • Before the maturity date, the value of the option corresponds to the sum of the Intrinsic Value (I.V.) and Time Value (T.V.), Options Value = I.V. + T.V. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 What about the Investment Projects? • According to the NPV, one should invest if the Present Value of Cash Flows (PVCF) > Investment Cost (I). • So, the payoff is: max[PVCF − I, 0] • Notice that this is similar to the payoff of a call option: – – – – Zero is the lower-bound for the payoffs; The value is given by the intrinsic value (i.e., the NPV); At maturity the time-value of the option is zero; However, before that moment, the time value of the option ca be positive. • But, • ... what’s the maturity of a project? • ... and, what’s the time-value of the project? © Paulo Pereira, 2010 6 Maturity if a Project? • The maturity of a project corresponds to the moment when the investment opportunity disappears..., after which it’s impossible to undertake the project. • Reasons for that? – Contractual reasons (licences, concessions, patents, ...); – Competitive reasons (the entrance of a competitor into the market may completely destroy the chance to invest for the other firms); – There are some situations where the companies have some special rights over the projects, traducing in perpetual options: control over a technology, businesses with significant entry barriers,… • Example: the owner of a vacant land has the right to develop there a real estate project. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Time Value? • The time value corresponds to the value of the option to defer the project implementation; • If the project is not at maturity, the option to defer can be exercised; • Two important questions arise: – How to value the option to defer? – What’s the optimal timing for implementing the project? • Later on we’ll answer to this questions. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 7 Real Options • The are similarities between financial options and real options: – Both give rights to the firm ( without obligation counterparts); – … which correspond to the capacity to modify the project as time passes. • According to Copeland and Antikarov (2001), “a real option is the right, but not the obligation, to take an action (e.g., deferring, expanding, contracting, or abandoning) at a predetermined cost called the exercise price, for a predetermined period of time - the life of the option.” © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Types of Real Options Uncertainty, Flexibility, and Real Options 163 Table 5.3 Common real options Real option type Description Relevant industries Deferral or waiting option Management can wait before making the investment to see how the market unfolds. Resource extraction industries, real-estate development, capitalintensive industries. Staging or time-to-build option When a managerial decision takes time or is done in stages, management can default if market prospects prove worse than expected. Technology-based firms (R&D), longdevelopment capitalintensive industries (e.g., electric utilities), startup ventures. Expand or extend option If the project turns out better than expected, management can spend more to expand the project scale or it can extend the project’s useful life. Natural-resource industries (e.g., mining), real-estate development. Contract or abandon option If the market prospects are worse than expected, managers can contract or abandon it for salvage. Capital-intensive industries (e.g., airplane manufacturers), new product introductions. Switching option Management can select among the best of several alternatives, e.g., inputs, outputs or locations, under the prevalent market conditions. Multinational firms with production facilities in different currencies, platform strategy in the automotive sector. Compound option If investment takes place in stages, the first project can be valued in view of the future growth options it creates. High-tech, R&D, industries with multiple product generations, strategic acquisitions. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 As summarized in table 5.3, management can benefit from different types of real options. We here discuss common types of real options in the context of an electric utility. The necessary tools to quantify the values of such real options are discussed in the subsequent section. Deferral or timing option Management is not always confronted with a now-or-never investment decision. Often it might have the flexibility to time its investment decision after observing how events unfold. Suppose that French utility EDF has identified that in the Brittany region reserve margins are falling to such low levels that they may jeopardize power supply security. EDF, being authorized to open up nuclear power plants in France, resolves to operate such a plant in Brittany if it is deemed worthwhile. Since the involved capital investment cost I is 8 Real Options • Analogy between Financial Options and Real Options: Financial Options Real Options Price of the underlying asset Gross project value (PVCF) Exercise price Investment cost Time to maturity Time until when the project can be deferred Volatility of the underlying asset Volatility of the PVCF Risk-free interest rate Risk-free interest rate Dividend-yield Opportunity cost of deferring © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Real Options • Fundamental difference: financial options give the owner an exclusive right; however, real options are, commonly, rights shared with the competitors. • This aspect turns the real options models different (and normally, more complex) from those developed for valuing financial options. • In this course we only use some basic models: binomial at B&S. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 9 The roles of uncertainty, irreversibility and flexibility • The real options value comes from three important characteristics, which are common to a major part of the real world investment opportunities: – Investment decisions are taken under uncertainty, and so the future about the project cannot be fully predicted; – Projects have some degree of flexibility which gives the firm, not only, the possibility to delay the project implementation, but also to modify the original plans, if and when necessary; – The investment cost is, at least in part, irreversible, which means that the investment cost cannot be totally recovered, if the project performs worse than initially expected. – If one of these characteristics is not there, the real options approach is unnecessary, and the traditional NPV becomes an appropriate method. Why? © Paulo Pereira, 2010 The roles of uncertainty, irreversibility and flexibility • Why? – If there is no uncertainty surrounding the project, no future contingent decisions are necessary. In fact, without uncertainty, the firm can predict the future and can plan all the decisions/actions accordingly, being none of them contingent to some random event; – If a project is totally non flexible the investment decision cannot be deferred, or, once implemented, no decisions can be taken in order to modify it. If this is the case in a given investment opportunity, it means that the project has no options, and so no additional value exists, compared to the traditional NPV; – If a project can be abandoned giving the firm the possibility of a total recovery of the capital that was spent, then there is no opportunity cost for investing today (giving up the chance to postpone the decision), since the firm can jump out without penalty.. • Notice that these arguments do not reduce the situations where real option can be applied. In fact, an exception would be a project without these characteristics. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 10 What influences the timing? • A central aspect is: what’s the optimal moment for implementing a project? • Notice that the NPV ignores this question. • The determination of the optimal moment comes from the equilibrium between the aspects that contribute to the deferment and those aspects that contribute to the anticipation. • Which aspects? © Paulo Pereira, 2010 What influences the timing? • Deferment “costs”: – Lost cash flows (why?) – Competitive damage (why?) • Benefits from deferring: – More information about market conditions: demand, price, costs, competitors, technology, legal environment… © Paulo Pereira, 2010 11 Descrete-time model: the binomial method © Paulo Pereira, 2010 The Binomial Model u = es Dt 1 d= u ( 1 + rf ) - d p= u-d q = 1- p p u xV V q d xV Where: - s represents the volatility; - rf represents the risk free rate; - Dt represents the time-step (if s and rf are annual, Dt=1); - p e q represent the probabilities for an up and down movements; - u e d represent the “dimension” of the up and down movements. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 12 The Binomial Model © Paulo Pereira, 2010 The Option to Defer © Paulo Pereira, 2010 13 CASE 1 Assume a company facing the chance to invest real estate project. The gross project value (present value of the future cash flows) is e12.5 million and the investment cost is e10 million, which increases 10% if deferred for a year. The firm estimates that the volatility of the gross project value is about 35% (per annum). The investment decision can be deferred for one year, after which the investment opportunity disappears. Additionally, the firm knows that the risk-free rate is 5% (per annum continuously compounded). Questions: 1) What’s the project value according to the NPV method? And what it says about the timing of the investment? 2) What type of flexibility the firm has? Is that an option? 3) What’s the true value of this investment opportunity? 4) What’s the value of the option identified in 2)? 5) Where (and why) the NPV fails? Solution: The inputs: u = es Dt = e 0,35 1 = 1,4191 1 d = = 0,7047 u (1 + r f ) - d (1 + 0,05) - 0,7047 p= = = 48,34% u-d 1,4191 - 0,7047 q = 1 - p = 51,66% © Paulo Pereira, 2010 14 Solution: u = 1,4191; d = 0,7047; p = 48,34%; q = 51,66% Next year the PVCF can increase upto 17,7m€ (w/ prob. = 48,3%) or decrease to 8,8m€ (w/ prob. = 51,6%) Payoff of the decision to invest In this situation 17,7 6,7 the company invests (17,7 – 11 = 6,7) 0,0 In this situation the company do not invest (8,8 < 11). p 3,10 12,5 q t=0 8,8 t=1 t=0 t=1 Value of the option to invest within 1 year: (6,7 x 0,4834 + 0 x 0,5166)/1,05 = 3,1 m€ Solution: NPV = 12,5 – 10 = 2,5m€ Value of the option to invest next year: 3,1m€ How to interpret the results? It is more valuable to keep the option to invest alive, instead of investing immediately; so the correct decision is to defer the implementation of the project. What is the value of the Option to Defer (OD)? Corresponds to the time-value of the option: 3,1m€ - 2,5m€ = 0,6m€ 15 The binomial method for valuing the option to abandon and the option to expand © Paulo Pereira, 2010 A company is going to invest in highly volatile market, which, in the next two years, can perform good or badly. Assume that the present value of the expected cash flows is €1M and investment cost is €0.9M. The firm can, in next two years, either expand the business (by increasing the global cash flows in about 30% at a cost of €0,42M) or abandon the market (for a salvage value of €0.7M). Additionally, the firm estimates the volatility as being 30%, and knows that the risk free rate is 5%. Questions: 1) What type of options the firm has? 2) What’s the value of the project according to the standard methods? 3) What’s the value of the options identified in 1)? 4) What’s the true value of the project? 5) Assume now the salvage value is €0,8M. What is, in these circumstances, the value of the option to abandon the market? © Paulo Pereira, 2010 16 The value of the project? NPV = 1000 – 900 = 100k€ But, what’s the value of the project knowing the company can: a) Abandon if the “environmnt” becomes unfavorable; b) Expand if the “environmnt” becomes favorable. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 The Value of the Option to Abandon © Paulo Pereira, 2010 17 Solution: The inputs: u = es Dt = e 0,3 1 = 1,34986 1 d = = 0,74082 u (1 + r f ) - d (1 + 0,05) - 0,74082 p= = = 50,77% u-d 1,34986 - 0,74082 q = 1 - p = 49,23% © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Solution: u = 1,34986; d = 0,74082; p = 50,765%; q = 49,235% 1000,00 1349,86 max(1349,86; 700) Do not Abandon 740,82 max(740,82; 700) Do not Abandon 1822,12 max(1822,12; 700) Do not Abandon 1000,00 max(1000; 700) Do not Abandon 548,81 max(548,81; 700) Abandon © Paulo Pereira, 2010 18 Solution: u = 1,34986; d = 0,74082; p = 50,765%; q = 49,235% 1000,00 1349,86 max(1349,86; 700) Do not Abandon 740,82 max(740,82; 700) Do not Abandon 1822,12 max(1822,12; 700) Do not Abandon 1000,00 max(1000; 700) Do not Abandon 700,00 max(548,81; 700) Abandoning CF © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Solution: u = 1,34986; d = 0,74082; p = 50,765%; q = 49,235% 1000,00 1349,86 max(1349,86; 700) Do not Abandon 811,71 max(740,82; 700) Do not Abandon Value incorporating the option to abandon (1000 x 0,50765 + 700 x 0,49235)/1,05 1822,12 max(1822,12; 700) Do not Abandon 1000,00 max(1000; 700) Do not Abandon 700,00 max(548,81; 700) Abandoning CF © Paulo Pereira, 2010 19 Solution: u = 1,34986; d = 0,74082; p = 50,765%; q = 49,235% Value incorporating the option to abandon 1033,24 1349,86 max(1349,86; 700) Do not Abandon 811,71 max(740,82; 700) Do not Abandon 1822,12 max(1822,12; 700) Do not Abandon 1000,00 max(1000; 700) Do not Abandon 700,00 max(548,81; 700) Abandoning CF © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Solution: A different way for valuing the option to abandon: Payoff of abandoning= 700 – 548,82 = 151,19 Value of the Option to Abandon: -2 = 151,19 x 0,49235 x 0,49235 x 1,05 = 33,24 k€ © Paulo Pereira, 2010 20 The value of the Option to Expand © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Solution: Expand! 1822,12 max(1822,12; 1,3 x 1822,12 - 420) 1349,86 max(1349,86; 1,3 x 1349,86 - 420) 1000 max(1349,86; 1334,82) 740,82 max(740,82; 1,3 x 740,82 - 420) max(740,82; 543,07) max(1822,12; 1948,76) 1000 max(1000; 1,3 x 1000 - 420) max(1000; 880) 548,81 max(548,81; 1,3 x 548,81 - 420) max(548,81; 293,45) © Paulo Pereira, 2010 21 Solution: The value of the Option to Expand? Expansion Payoff = (1,3x1822,12 – 420) – 1882,12 = 126,64 Value of the option to expand -2 = 126,64 x 0,50765 x 0,50765 x 1,05 = 29,60 k€ © Paulo Pereira, 2010 What’s the value of this project? Project Value = NPV + Value of the Options = NPV + Value OA + Value OE = 100k€ + 33,24k€ + 29,60k€ = 162,88k€ Conclusion? The NPV undervalue the project by not considering the flexibility (the options) the project has. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 22 Challenge: Determine the value of the option to abandon for a salvage value of 800k€. © Paulo Pereira, 2010 Challenge u = 1,34986; d = 0,74082; p = 50,765%; q = 49,235% 1349,86 max(1349,86; 800) Do not abandon 1000 ? 740,82 max(740,82; 800) Abandon 1822,12 max(1822,12; 800) Do not abandon 1000 max(1000; 800) Do not abandon 548,81 max(548,81; 800) Abandon © Paulo Pereira, 2010 23 What is the optimal timing for abandoning? (...) (...) 251,19 x 0,4923 x 1,05 740,82 max(740,82; 800) Abandon 0 1 Payoff OA1 = 59,18 -1 548,81 max(548,81; 800) Abandon 2 Payoff OA2 = 251,19 Value of the OA1: 59,18 Value (at moment 1) of the OA2: 117,78 What is the optimal timing for abandoning? Value of the OA1: 59,18 Value (at moment 1) of the OA2: 117,78 If we abandon in moment 1 we “kill” the option to abandon in moment 2: we incur in an opportunity cost! Question: The payoff of OA1 more than compensate that opportunity cost? No! Then, the option to abandon should not be exercised in moment 1. We should defer the decision and eventually abandon in moment 2. 24