Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 I. Agency A. Formation B. Termination C. Liability in Contract D. Liability in Tort E. Governance of Agency II. Partnership & Limited Liability Companies (33-73) A. Formation B. Relations with Third Parties C. Governance D. Termination 1. Partners can design own dissolution rules 2. Dividing residual value when partner leaves or partnership is dissolved 3. Fiduciary Duties limit opportunistic dissolution E. Conflicts/ Fiduciary Duties F. Limited Liability Successors III. The Corporate Form (75-101) A. Basic Characteristics B. Legal Personality of Corporations C. Limited Liability D. Transferable Shares E. Centralized Management IV. Creditor Protection (103-141) A. Mandatory Disclosure B. Capital Regulation 1. Distribution Constraints 2. Minimum Capital Requirements C. Standard-Based Duties 1. Director Duties 2. Fraudulent Transfers 3. Shareholder Liability V. Shareholder Voting (163-227) A. Election of Directors B. Removing Directors C. Proxy Voting D. Class Voting E. Separation of Control from Cash Flows 1. Circular Voting 2. Vote Buying 3. Controlling Minority Structures F. Federal Proxy Rules VI. The Duty of Care A. Liability Shields for Directors 1. Business Judgment Rule 2. Liability Waivers for Breach of Fiduciary Duties 1 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 3. Indemnification 4. D&O Insurance 5. Mandatory Reimbursement of Legal Expenses B. Liability for Omissions: Duty to Monitor C. Knowing Violations of the Law VII. The Duty of Loyalty A. Regulation of Self-Dealing Transactions 1. Self-Dealing Transactions Involving D&Os 2. Self-Dealing Transactions Involving a Controlling Shareholder B. Corporate Opportunities Doctrine C. Duty of Loyalty in Close Corporations VIII. Executive Compensation A. Agency Costs in Executive Compensation 1. Pay-for-Performance Tools to Mitigate Agency Costs B. Judicial Review of Executive Compensation IX. Shareholder Litigation A. Procedural Requirements in Derivative Suits 1. Standing 2. Demand Requirement 3. Special Litigation Committees 4. Standing 5. Exclusive Forum Provisions X. Transactions in Control A. Sales of Control Blocks 1. Market Rule 2. Exceptions to the Market Rule B. Tender Offers 1. Early-Warning System 2. Regulation of Tender Offers XI. Mergers and Acquisitions A. Transactional Forms B. Appraisal C. Controlled Mergers XII. Contests for Corporate Control A. Judicial Review of Antitakeover Defenses B. Choosing a Merger Partner: Judicial Review of Board Actions (Active Battle or When Company is Up for Sale) C. Deal Protection Devices D. Corwin Cleansing Effect E. State Antitakeover Statutes F. Proxy Contests for Corporate Control 2 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 I. Agency (7-32) Agency: fiduciary relationship that arises when a Principal manifests assent to an Agent to act on the Principal’s behalf and subject to the Principal’s control. Arises out of consent (RTA, §1.01) A. Formation B. Termination C. P’s liability for A’s authorized and unauthorized contracts D. P’s liability for (some) torts committed by A E. A’s duties to P (“governance” of agency) A. Formation Agency is formed by consent. 1. SCOPE - Special agents: limited to single transaction - General agents: authorized to perform series of transactions/ actions necessary to achieve specific goal. 2. 3rd PARTY DISCLOSURE - Disclosed: 3P knows that A acts on behalf of specific P - Undisclosed: 3P does not know that A is an agent - Unidentified Principal: 3P knows A is an agent, but not identity of P 3. CONTROL - Employee: P has detailed control. P controls A’s work (RTA §7.07) - Contractor: Less extensive control Agency may be implied even when not explicitly agreed to: Jenson Farms v. Cargill: Cargill provided financing to Warren Grain and Cargill reviewed contracts & financials, had right of first refusal, offered biz advice, exercised control. When warren defaulted, Cargill held jointly liable. Holding: Agency is created through course of conduct where the facts show that one party has manifested consent that the other is its agent, and parties behave as agent and principal. Agency created even if parties did not call it so. B. Termination Because agency is formed by consent, it may be terminated at any time. C. P’s liability in contract Inherent authority (below) v. approach in Third Restatement (P must have some notice of A’s conduct) - Liability by estoppel (§2.05 RTA): P is liable if (1) P intentionally or carelessly caused belief that P was principal; or (2) P is aware of the belief and didn’t take steps to notify 3P. - Liability of undisclosed principal (§2.06 RTA): P liable if A acts without actual authority and (1) P has notice of A’s conduct and (2) doesn’t take reasonable steps to notify 3P. 3 Business Associations - Restrepo—Spring 2021 Apparent Authority (§2.03 RTA): P liable if a reasonable person in 3P’s position could infer from manifestations of P that P is a principal. D. P’s liability in tort Employers are liable for employees’ torts if employee is acting within the scope of employment (RTA §2.04, 7.07) Key elements of liability: 1. Principal’s control 2. Tort w/in scope of employment **Policy arguments: Incentives, fairness. Monitoring costs, efficiency issues if strict liability.** Humble Oil v. Martin: Employee of service station found liable in auto accident, and oil company also liable because contractor relationship broke down to a master/servant relationship since operator of service station had little authority except hiring/firing. Holding: Humble liable bc acts as P to Schneider’s A. A party may be liable for contractor’s torts if he exercises substantial control over contractor’s operations. Hoover v. Sun Oil: Customer burned at gas station sought to hold franchisor (oil company) responsible. Holding: Franchisee retained control of inventory and day-to-day operations, so was independent contractor. Oil company not liable. **Policy: franchise agreements protect market share, develop customers, provide consistency, while tort liability protections reduce monitoring costs. Oil companies should be subject to liability in some cases because agents may be judgment proof and it incentivizes P to control. 4 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 From social welfare perspective, parties will negotiate allocation of costs amongst themselves, so if doesn’t matter where we place liability.** E. Governance of Agency (A’s duties to P) Principal/agent relationship is fiduciary, meaning: 1. Duty of Obedience 2. Duty of Care: - Duty to act as a reasonable person would do in similar circumstances in becoming informed and exercising power 3. Duty of Loyalty: - Duty to exercise power in manner that is best to advance interests of the principal, not for personal benefit. - A may not acquire material benefit form 3P through use of A’s position - A may not use P’s property for own purposes - Owed by agent to principal (not owed by principal to agent) **We allow personal transactions that could be conflicts because prohibiting them could eliminate Kaldor-Hicks efficiencies** II. Partnership & Limited Liability Companies (33-73) A. Formation Partnership: association of two or more people to carry on as co-owners of a biz for profit, whether or not people intended to form a partnership (RUPA & UPA) Characteristics - Separate legal personality - Tenancy in partnership - All owners (partners) are liable as principals - All partners are general agents of the partnership - All general partners are jointly and severally liable - All partners share equally in control (unless otherwise agreed) Benefits - Cost of debt may be higher than selling an ownership stake - Partner’s human capital, with aligned incentives Is it a Partnership? Courts consider: (1) profit sharing; (2) control; and (3) intent of parties - RUPA: common property insufficient to show partnership, even if co-owners share profits from use of property; sharing net profits—but not gross returns—is prima facie evidence of partnership, unless payments are for: debt; IC/ employee svcs; rent; loan interest or fee. **Net profits shows control, but gross does not** Vohland v. Sweet: apprentice gets 20% of net profits erroneously called “commission.” Cost of maintain stock was assigned to expenses prior to payout. No capital contribution, but had managerial/ supervisory roles. Sued to dissolve partnership and distribute proceeds. Holding: Sharing net profits is prima facie evidence of partnership. 5 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 B. Relations with Third Parties Rights of Partnership Creditors (RUPA) - Partners jointly & severally liable on partnership torts and contracts - Creditors must exhaust biz assets before pursuing personal assets Issues 1. Who is a partner (who can be pursued)? 2. When can ex-partner escape debts? 3. What are the third-party claims against partnership property? 4. How are partnership creditors placed w/r/t partner’s individual property? When can ex-partner escape debts? Departing partners remain liable but lack control. - RUPA §701 (UPA §36(2)) releases departing partner if court can infer an agreement - RUPA §703 (UPA §36(3)) releases departing partner if creditor: (1) knows partner is leaving; and (2) agrees to material alteration of time/payment of credit. How are partnership creditors placed w/r/t partner’s individual property? C. Governance A partnership is bound by actions of the partners when: - Partner has actual or apparent authority, meaning action is in ordinary course of biz = binding, unless; o Partner was not authorized o The third party knew - Other matters are only binding if there is actual authority (authorized by partners) Ordinary biz needs majority vote, and other matters need unanimous vote. National Biscuit v. Stroud: *What is “majority* when there are only two partners?* One partner told supplier that biz would not be liable for any bread delivered after certain date. Other partner keeps buying bread. Partnership dissolves and bread company wants to collect. Holding: 1 partner in a 2-partner partnership is not a majority, so not binding on ordinary biz. D. Termination 6 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Dissociation - RUPA: partner leaves partnership o Involuntary withdrawal o Special events (expulsion, death) Dissolution - RUPA: onset of liquidation of partnership assets & winding up of affairs o At-will withdrawal o Special circumstances (term ends, agreement, purpose fulfilled) - UPA: any change in partnership relations (exit) o Withdrawal (any partner has right to demand dissolution/ wind-up) o Special events (term ends, agreement, purpose fulfilled) Termination - RUPA: winding up is complete - UPA: partnership ceases entirely at end of winding up Winding Up - UPA: Orderly liquidation and settlement of affairs Partnership Exit Principles 1. Partners can design own dissolution rules (Adam v. Jarvis) 2. Dividing residual value when partner leaves or partnership is dissolved 3. Fiduciary Duties limit opportunistic dissolution (Page v. Page) 1. Partners can design own dissolution rules Adam v. Jarvis: withdrew from partnership and claimed that withdrawal = dissolution and thus right to require a winding up under UPA §38. Holding: entitlement to statutory winding up not allowed if withdrawal is in contravention to partnership agreement (unless otherwise agreed to). Here, agreement said withdrawal shall not terminate partnership. 2. Dividing residual value when partner leaves or partnership is dissolved Procedure - Physical division of assets (rejected by courts in Dreifuerst v. Dreifuerst) - Court-appointed appraiser (not in statutes) - Biz sold as intact, going concern or in parts at judicial auction Fair Value that Partners Receive - UPA: Liquidation value. Proportional share in cash of total assets – total liabilities - RUPA: Higher of: proportional share in going concern or the liquidation value Page v. Page: One partner seeks dissolution at time that is bad for biz but good for himself. Holding: Partnership is at-will and can be dissolved lacking evidence of an implicit term. BUT, fiduciary duties protect remaining partner, so if departing partner attempts to appropriate new prosperity of partnership for won use, dissolution would be wrongful and departing partner would be liable for damages. E. Conflicts/ Fiduciary Duties 7 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Meinhard v. Salmon: One (of two) partner takes 20-year lease for office space and holds in his name while running the biz. Other partner is passive investor and supplies 50% capital, gets 40% for first 5 years then 50% of profits thereafter. First partner re-signs for himself, cutting out second partner in 80-year deal. Holding: “A trustee is held to something stricter than the morals of the marketplace.” Salmon breached fiduciary duty of loyalty to partner to allow him to compete on other projects (right to be informed, not necessarily to participate). F. Limited Liability Successors III. The Corporate Form 1. Basic Characteristics - Independent legal personality - Limited liability - Transferable shares - Centralized management under the board Variations - Closely-held vs. public - Controlled vs. widely-held Primary Sources of Corporate Law - Revised Model Business Corporation Law (RMBCA) - Delaware General Corporate Law (DGCL) 2. Legal Personality of Corporations Economic Benefits: - Ability to enter into contracts reduces transaction costs - Separate pool of assets reduces monitoring costs - Infinite life increases stability Governing Documents Articles of Incorporation (Charter) o Name, purpose, capital structure o Amendment requires a board-initiated shareholder vote o Usually flexible Bylaws o Operating rules: Shareholder meetings, board of directors, officers o Can be amended by shareholders, or possibly by board 3. Limited Liability Economic Benefits - Decreases monitoring costs - Shares become fungible - Facilitates diversification - Facilitates takeovers Costs - Less care in preventing torts 4. Transferable Shares Economic Benefits 8 Business Associations - Restrepo—Spring 2021 Shareholders can leave without disrupting company Facilitates takeovers Facilitates development of large capital markets/ promotes investment 5. Centralized Management Board of Directors: Nature and Powers (wide) - Appoint/ remove officers - Declare and pay dividends - Amend bylaws - Create committees - Exclusive authority to initiate major decisions (mergers, sale of assets, dissolutions, charter amendments) - Make major biz decisions (product lines, prices, financing) Structure & Operation of Board - Elected at annual meeting or staggered/ classified - Operate via formal resolutions at board meetings (some states permit unanimous written consent) Benefits of delegation - Expertise - Minority protection - Efficient decision making Costs - Agency costs o Mitigated via disclosure & voting (shareholders elect/ remove directors who elect managers) Automatic Self-Cleaning Filter: Group of shareholders totaling 55% of ownership want to sell assets. Charter requires 75% approval, so measure fails. Group petitions court to order board to sell. Holding: Directors are not simply agents, and simple majority cannot override board’s authority if charter requires 75%. Jennings v. Pittsburg Mercantile Director instructs real estate broker to solicit offers for sale & leaseback of company property and says the executive committee he is on has the power to accept offer and board approval would be automatic, but board then rejected offer, so broker sued for commission. Company claimed not bound bc director did not have authority, broker claims company is bound by apparent authority. Holding: No actual authority bc transaction is not in ordinary course of business and no apparent authority bc principal never represented that he had authority. IV. Creditor Protection (103-141) A. Mandatory Disclosure: Required by Federal and sometimes state law, FBO shareholders B. Capital Regulation 1. Distribution Constraints: constrain ability of directors to distribute money to shareholders Shareholders Equity=Stated Capital + Capital Surplus + Retained Earnings=Assets – Liabilities 9 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Stated Capital = par value * # of shares Capital Surplus = Mkt value – Par Retained Earnings = Net Profits Nimble Dividend Test (DGCL §170(a)): Directors may pay dividends out of Surplus (Capital Surplus + Retained Earnings) OR, if that’s less than zero, out of Net Profits for either current or preceding fiscal year. Board may also transfer stated capital to capital surplus. **Weak protection for creditors, but allowed bc it rewards biz on upward trajectory** 2. Minimum Capital Requirements Used in EU but not US bc the protection is rigid (might deter entrepreneurship, inefficiently force liquidation, or otherwise inefficiently interfere with biz decisions) and might be meaningless. C. Standard-Based Duties 1. Director Duties (in zone of insolvency) Credit Lyonnais: In vicinity of insolvency, directors owe duty to consider “community of interests” of the corporation, not just the shareholders. Problems: Relies on ex post analysis— maybe creditors protected themselves already; Zone of insolvency is hard to define. 2. Fraudulent Transfers - Applies to all debtor-creditor relationships Regulated by Uniform Fraudulent Conveyance Act (UFCA) and Uniform Fraudulent Transfers Act (UFTA) Remedy: transfers made by insolvent debtors are VOID Conditions: Debtor transfers with actual intent to defraud; OR Constructive fraud (debtor did not receive “reasonably equivalent value” in exchange; and remaining assets of debtor are “unreasonably small”) 3. Shareholder Liability Equitable Subordination : Major shareholder makes loan to corporation, and in so doing, behaved unfairly to creditors and corporation. Transaction based (like fraudulent transfers) Remedy - Available through common law and Bankruptcy Code - Prioritizes outside creditors over the shareholder in distribution of corporate assets **Unlike partnerships (under RUPA) subordination is not the default. We do not prohibit these transactions bc they might be efficient** Costello v. Fazio: Partners deliberately converted part of their equity into notes, transforming partnership to corporation specifically to escape liability and “cut in line” ahead of biz’s creditors. Holding: No fraud, but gross undercapitalization (not sufficiently damning on its own) and inequitable conduct towards creditors (damning). 10 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Piercing the Corporate Veil: legal decision to treat the rights or duties of a corporation as the rights or liabilities of its shareholders - Lack of separation btwn shareholder and corporation. Presumes: o Dominance of corp decision o Disregard of corp formalities o Undercapitalization o Co-mingling of assets - Corp form used as instrument for “unfair or inequitable conduct” (vague) o Incorporating to avoid liability (Costello) o Shifting assets to another corporation o Misrepresenting assets Sea-Land v. Pepper Source *Shifting assets and dissolving ex post* Sea-land obtains judgment against Pepper Source for unpaid bill, but Pepper source dissolves and has no assets, so Sea-Land seeks to pierce corporate veil to reach holding company’s assets, and then reversepierce to reach subsidiary assets. Holding: Remanded for factual determination on second prong, but YES to first prong, lack of separation bc no formalities, co-mingling of assets. Court says second prong examples are: incorporating to evade liability, misrepresenting assets, shifting assets to subsidiary. N.B. (Restrepo): Even if no fraud, could still satisfy prong if dissolution was strategic behavior intended to avoid liability ex post bc that would violate creditors’ reasonable expectations. **Reverse piercing raises concerns of no asset partitioning higher monitoring costs.** Kinney v. Polan: *Creditor knew about undercapitalization ex ante* Kinney sublets remaining 10 years of 25-year lease to Polan, through his company Industrial, which fails to make payments. Holding: OK to Pierce. Two-prong Laya test satisfied bc no capital contribution, no minutes, no officers (clearly a “paper curtain” to avoid liability). Court ignores 3rd prong. Veil-Piercing for Involuntary Creditors Tort creditors do not have a contract, so cannot monitor firm/ negotiate protections ex-ante. 11 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Walkovszky v. Carlton: Man hit by cab wants to hold owner of corp personally liable bc each cab (treated as individual subsidiary) had limited insurance. Holding: Veil not pierced. In order to maintain a cause of action for piercing the corporate veil, the plaintiff must allege that a shareholder used the corporate form to conduct business in his individual capacity. Corp. was not a dummy corp in service to shareholder(s). ** Limited liability creates incentives to underinvest in safety** V. Shareholder Voting (163-227) Corporate voting systems address the collective action problems inherent in widely-held corporations. Shareholders vote on: - Election of directors (all corps must have a board under DGCL §14(a)) - Fundamental changes o Amendments to corporate charter o Transformational transactions (mergers, substantial sale of assets, dissolutions) - Shareholder resolutions Shareholder voting rules: - One-share-one-vote (unless otherwise specified in charter) - Mandatory annual shareholder meeting - 10 day minimum/ 60 day maximum notice of shareholder meeting - Default quorum: majority of shares - Proxy system: if shareholder cannot attend ASM, can find proxy to vote on her behalf A. Election of Directors 1. Types of Boards Unitary board: single-class board where all directors are elected at ASM Staggered/ Classified board: different classes (3 max in Delaware). Each year, shareholders can elect only one class. Can be adopted by charter, initial bylaw, or bylaw adopted by special shareholder vote. Have antitakeover effect. 2. Types of Voting Straight voting: Plurality: Directors that receive the largest number of votes in favor are elected. Contested election: If votes for dir. A > votes for dir. B, then dir. A is elected. Uncontested: Director is elected if pro-votes >0 Majority: Director elected if obtains majority votes (common for uncontested) Majority of shares present & entitled to vote: Elected if votes for > (votes withheld + votes against) Majority of votes voting: Elected if votes for > votes against 12 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Cumulative voting: Each shareholder gets votes equal to number of shares owned times number of seats to be filled. Permits opt-in via charter. Relevant in contested elections. Pro: Improves likelihood of minority representation on board; Con: could undermine collegiality of board. B. Removal of Directors Basic Rules: - DGCL: Director may be removed with or without cause unless: (1) staggered board (unless charter provides otherwise); OR (2) cumulative voting - Poor business decisions alone usually insufficient cause for removal - RMBCA: directors can be removed with or without cause whether or not board is staggered. Timing: - Annual Meeting (quorum needed) - Special Meeting o DGCL: called by board and others authorized in charter or bylaws o RMBCA: called by board or 10% of shareholders - Written Consent o DGCL: approval requires votes needed to pass resolution to meeting o RMBCA: approval requires unanimous consent C. Proxy Voting Who pays? Froessel rule: requires challengers to identify larger corporate gains before investing in a proxy fight. Rosenfeld v. Fairchild: shareholder with 25 shares attempts to force both sides in proxy contest. Both sides reimbursed themselves from corporate treasury. Holding: board is entitled to full reimbursement for reasonable proxy expenses made in deference to corporate policies. Insurgents will be reimbursed only if the decision is ratified by shareholders (as here). D. Class Voting Different classes of stock may have different rights to vote. - DGCL: requires class voting if charter amendment changes (1) legal rights of the class, OR (2) par value or number of shares of the class. Class voting not required for mergers. - RMBCA: Class voting in more cases. Generally, when an amendment changes the economic or legal rights of the class. Includes mergers. E. Separation of Control from Cash Flows **We give voting rights to shareholders because they are the residual claimants of the corporation, so they have incentives to maximize long-term value** 1. Circular Voting DGCL: Corporations can’t vote (or count toward quorum) two kinds of shares: (1) treasury shares (2) shares held by a subsidiary in which the corp owns a majority of the voting stock 13 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Speiser v. Baker: Court adopts expansive interpretation to find circular voting because company held 95% of subsidiary’s equity, even though company only held 42% of voting power. 2. Vote Buying Vote buying is prohibited because pricing would be incorrect since shareholders would sell for any non-zero value. Schreiber v. Carney: Def wanted to exercise warrants but could not afford to, so voted to block merger. Another party offered to lend money to exercise the warrants so that merger could proceed. Holding: Corporate vote buying is illegal only when done for improper purpose. Voidable only if it does not satisfy intrinsic fairness. Here, shareholder approval after full disclosure precludes voiding transactions. 3. Controlling Minority Structures - Stock pyramids Cross-ownership Dual-Class Shares o Allows founders to obtain equity but retain control o Insulates from takeovers o Potential abuse of power Mitigating Collective Action Problems: - Diffusion leads to collective action problems - Institutional shareholders are partial solution, but research is costly, diversification undermines incentives to monitor, and institutions have their own agency problems. - Hedge funds have high incentives to monitor bc of 20% incentive fee and greater concentration of holdings in fewer companies. But may have incentives to generate shortterm performance at expense of long-term value. F. Federal Proxy Rules Virtually all companies with >$5M in assets or >500 shareholders must register under Exchange Act. 1. Regulatory Requirements for Proxy Solicitation Under Exchange Act §14(a), it is unlawful to solicit proxies except in compliance with SEC regulations: - Rule 14a-1(1)(1)(iii): Solicitation = any communication reasonably calculated to procure proxy. - Rule 14-a-3(a): may not solicit proxy unless you provide a proxy statement w/ Sched 14A info unless exempt bc: o Solicitation does not seek directly or indirectly the power to act as proxy o Solicitation to 10 or fewer other shareholders - BUT: even if exempt, shareholder must file communication and notice of exempt solicitation after sending. 14 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 2. Short Slates: may benefit company but is less disruptive. Dissidents may want some influence but not control. Director must consent to be on proxy card. When dissidents run a short slate proxy contest, dissidents’ card can be rounded by adding some of incumbent directors. 3. Shareholder proposals: under certain conditions, shareholders can submit proposals to other shareholders through company’s proxy materials. Rule 14a-8: Must be long-term shareholder: $2k for 3 yrs, $15k for 2 yrs, OR $25k for 1 yr Rule 14a-8(i): Company may exclude proposals from proxy materials if: - It is improper under state law - Relates to ordinary matter of business - Relates to matter that represents < 5% of biz - Conflicts with company’s proposal - *Burden is on company to prove* N.B.: CSRs, expense reimbursement, access 4. Antifraud Rules Rule 14a-9: shareholders have right to recover for false or misleading proxy solicitations if: - Materiality: reasonable shareholder would consider it important when voting (TSC Indus v. Northway) - Culpability: Negligence or scienter depending on jurisdiction - Causation & Reliance: need not prove actual reliance, and causation is presumed if misrepresentation is material and solicitation was an essential link in accomplishment of transaction. Virginia Bankshares v. Sandberg: Freeze-out merger of bank into Virginia Bankshares, which board supports. Dissenting shareholder claims 14a-9 violation because valuation was improper. Holding: Materiality = yes (board opinion and underlying facts) but Causation = no because transaction would have been approved anyway since minority shareholder votes were not required for corp action under bylaws. Narrow approach to essential link analysis. 5. Fiduciary Superintendence of Voting D&O have duty to not unfairly manipulate the voting process for their own advantage. Schnell v. Chris-Craft Industries: directors amended bylaws to move ASM up in order to give dissidents insufficient time to organize and solicit proxies. Holding: mgmt. violated duty not to unfairly manipulate voting process by attempting to use corporate machinery for its own benefit. VI. The Duty of Care Duty of Care: D&O has duty to corporation to perform functions: (1) in good faith; (2) in a manner she reasonably believes to be in best interests of corporation; (3) with the care that ordinarily prudent person would exercise in a like position and under similar circumstances. A. Liability Shields for Directors 15 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Types of liability shields in Delaware: - BJR: presumes duty of care was met - Waiver of Liability: corp can eliminate directors’ liability for duty of care violations - Indemnification: corp may indemnify D&Os if D&Os actions were in good faith - D&O Insurance: corp may buy D&O insurance whether or not corp would have pwr to indemnify - Reimbursement of Legal Expenses: even if not in good faith, succss in legal action requires indemnification for legal expenses. 1. Business Judgment Rule BJR: D&O who makes biz judgment in good faith fulfills duty of care if D&O: (1) is not interested in subject of the biz judgment; (2) is informed w/r/t subject; and (3) rationally believes that biz judgment is in the best interests of the corporation. Pros: BJR encourages valuable risk-taking, encourages board members to serve, directors usually in better position to decide bc they are experts and stakeholders, reduces cost of judicial intervention. Kamin v. American Express: In derivative action, minority shareholders wanted Amex to withhold stock dividend because it would offer tax shield, and that to continue to issue was a waste of corp assets and breach of duty of care. Holding: No self-dealing, so court not going to evaluate biz decisions. Courts will not interfere with a business decision made by directors of a business unless there is a claim of fraud, bad faith, or self-dealing. Smith v. Van Gorkom: There is a rebuttable presumption that a business determination made by a corporation’s board of directors is fully informed and made in good faith and in the best interests of the corporation. But directors of a corporation may be liable to shareholders under the BJR for approving a merger without reviewing the agreement and only considering the transaction at a two-hour meeting. Holding: directors liable for breach of duty of care. Standard of judicial review for business judgment rule: • Is the director disinterested? If he is interested, the standard of judicial review shifts to entire fairness review (see Duty of Loyalty). • Is the director informed? Did he consider “all material information”? • BJR rebutted if there is gross negligence in becoming informed (Aronson). • If there is liability waiver under §102(b)(7), plaintiff must prove bad faith. • Was the transaction “rational”? Is there evidence indicating that the transaction was so irrational, so extremely poor, that it is unlikely that the director acted in the belief that it was in the best interest of the corporation? In practice, the question is whether the action constitutes waste (exchange of corporate assets for consideration so disproportionally small as to lie beyond the range at which any reasonable person might be willing to trade) A more general condition of the BJR is good faith. o Doctrinally, bad faith is more egregious than gross negligence. DGCL §102(b(7), in fact, allow firms to waive liability for breach of the duty of care unless there is bad faith. 16 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 2. Liability Waivers for Breaches of Fiduciary Duties In response to Van Gorkum, DGCL allows corporations to waive liability for breaches of fiduciary duty. Charter may include personal liability waiver for a director to the corporation or the shareholders for monetary damages for breach of fiduciary duty of a director provided that the waiver does not eliminate liability for: - Breach of duty of loyalty - Acts or omissions not in good faith involving misconduct or knowing legal violation - For any transaction from which director derived improper personal benefit - *Shareholders approve charter* 3.Indemnification DGCL 145(a) permits corporation to indemnify D&O except if: not in good faith; in criminal proceeding, director had reason to believe conduct was unlawful (courts interpret as director is convicted). Indemnification is not exclusive of other rights to which those seeking indemnification may be entitled under any bylaw, etc. (but charter/ bylaw cannot indemnify for something not allowed by DGCL, like action not in good faith). 4. D&O Insurance: DGCL 145(g) allows insurance whether or not corp would have the power to indemnify under DGCL 145(a). 5. Mandatory Reimbursement of Legal Expenses: required under DGCL 145(c), even if corp does not indemnify, must pay expenses. B. Liability for Omissions: Duty to Monitor Francis v. United Jersey Bank: Mrs. Pritchard did not intervene in sons’ mismanagement, ignoring red flags until the firm went bankrupt. Holding: breach of duty of care, because she had the power to prevent the losses but failed to do it. Failed to read financial statements and failed to make any reasonable attempt at monitoring for and preventing fraud. Graham v. Allis-Chalmers: Under Delaware law, corporate directors and officers will not be held liable for losses resulting from their failure to supervise and manage the business, so long as those directors and officers reasonably relied on the honesty and integrity of their subordinates. Reliance is no longer reasonable if the directors and officers are put on notice that wrongdoing may be happening. Director and officer liability may be imposed if, after such notice, nothing is done to find and prevent misconduct. Nevertheless, directors and officers are not under a duty to “install and operate a corporate system of espionage to ferret out wrongdoing which they have no reason to suspect exists.” The question of when a director has breached the common law duty of supervising and managing the business is dependent on the surrounding circumstances. Liability is proper if a director recklessly trusts an employee who is clearly untrustworthy, seriously neglects her duties, or willfully or negligently ignores “obvious danger signs of employee wrongdoing.” In this case, the directors had no actual knowledge of wrongdoing. In re Marchese: Friend of controlling shareholder was director and member of audit committee. Never reviewed accounting procedures, signed forms with material misinformation, approved dismissal of auditors who raised red flags. Holding: behavior violated federal laws that prohibit 17 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 disclosure of misleading information in financial statements. Independent and dependent directors both subject to same duty to monitor. In re Caremark: Expands on Allis-Chalmers. Directors must not just respond to red flags, but must seek them out. A poor monitoring system can, by itself, be enough to trigger liability. Stone v. Ritter: Endorsement of Caremark. Absent any red flags, in order for directors to be liable for lack of oversight of officers & employees, there must be a finding that directors either failed to implement any reporting systems or, having implemented such systems, failed to monitor them. In re Citigroup: Citigroup engaged in subprime lending. Had 102(b)(7) waiver. Claim alleges breach under Allis-Chalmers (public reports of mortgage crisis = red flags) and Caremark (board failed to make good faith attempt to follow procedures). Holding: not liable. General market trends are not red flags, and monitoring is required for fraud, not biz risk. Under BJR, corporate directors will not be held personally liable for failure to manage the company's business risk unless their conduct rose to the level of gross negligence. C. Knowing Violations of the Law Miller v. AT&T: Shareholder suit alleging that refusing to collect on loan to DNC is intentional illegal campaign contribution. Holding: Not a biz decision covered by BJR bc it’s an unlawful act. Therefore, shareholders are entitled to recover. VII. The Duty of Loyalty Duty of Loyalty requires directors, officers, and controlling shareholders (corporate fiduciaries) to act in good faith effort to advance the interests of the company rather than their own interests. Duty is owed to the corporation and its shareholders (“shareholder primacy”). Justification: If corporations focus exclusively on maximizing profit, they will engage in Kaldor-Hicks efficient transactions, which increase social welfare. This is controversial: public benefit corporations and constituency statutes are initiatives to ensure that directors act to advance interests of all constituencies in the corporations. Dodge v. Ford Motor Company: Ford lowered prices and eliminated dividend in order to squeeze Dodge Brothers, who owned 10% of stock. Ford claimed it was to share success with public. Holding: Ford has obligation to look out for shareholders first. A.P. Smith v. Barlow: Corporation has authority to make donation to Princeton because (1) authorized by NJ statute; (2) modern corporations can pursue greater social good; and (3) may be in best interests of corp to make this donation. Decision illustrates that nearly any corporate action can be justified as value-maximizing. A. Regulation of Self-Dealing Transactions Self-Dealing Transaction: corporate transaction in which directors, officers, or controlling shareholders have a personal interest. Regulation in Agency: agent can engage in transaction in which he has an interest so long as: (1) transaction was fair; (2) all material facts are disclosed; and (3) the principal approved 18 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Regulation in Corporate Law: (1) Fairness review; (2) disclosure requirement; (3) approval by majority of the disinterested parties (directors or shareholders). A conflicted transaction is NOT VOID if it is fair (i.e., full disclosure). Standard of judicial review to assess fairness varies by the type of interested party. Approval by disinterested parties Conflicted director (burden) Conflicted controlling shareholder (burden) No approval EF (D) EF (D) Approved by disinterested directors BJR (P) EF (P) Approved by shareholders BJR (P) EF (P)* *Majority of the minority approval Approved by (1) disinterested directors, and (2) shareholders BJR (P) BJR (P)* *Majority of the minority approval 1. Self-Dealing Transactions Involving D&Os Entire Fairness Review: no transaction btwn the corporation and any D&Os is void/voidable simply for being conflicted, provided that: (1) transaction is approved in good faith by majority vote (of disinterested directors or shareholders) after full disclosure; OR (2) the transaction is fair. *For EFR, burden of proof is initially on defendant to show that transaction was entirely fair. *If approved by disinterested directors or shareholders, standard of judicial review shifts from entire fairness review to the BJR. 19 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Entire Fairness = fair dealing + fair price - Fair dealing = process (did fiduciary reveal all material facts, negotiate with candor, not pressure corporation?) - Fair price = substantive (did economic conditions resemble terms of a transaction with an unrelated party?) State Ex. Rel. Hayes Oyster v. Keypoint Oyster: CEO & director of Coast Oyster did not disclose interest in transaction where oyster beds were sold to corp. in which CEO got 50% equity. Holding: Violation of fiduciary duty of loyalty by failing to disclose interest even though transaction was fair. Not necessary to prove intent to defraud or injure. Court allowed transaction to remain, but required CEO to turn over 50% interest to Coast. To avoid EFR: get approval by majority of the informed, disinterested directors, and/ or approval by majority of the informed shareholders. Full disclosure is required, but burden shifts to BJR. Cooke v. Oolie: Board votes unanimously to pursue acquisition. Minority shareholders claim that two of four directors breached fiduciary duty bc they were creditors and the acquisition was self-serving bc there were superior options. Holding: Approval by disinterested directors (50% of board) changed review from EFR to BJR and under BJR there is no claim. Lewis v. Vogelstein: BJR applies when disinterested directors approve transaction, EXCEPT when: (1) majority of shareholders had conflict of interest; and (2) transaction constituted waste. *Preventing ratification of waste protects minority shareholders. Situation Neither board nor shareholders approve Disinterested directors authorize (ex-ante authorization) Disinterested directors ratify (ex-post ratification) DGCL § 144 RMBCA § 8.61 ALI §5.02 EF (D) EF (D) EF (D) BJR (P): Cooke v. Oolie. BJR (P): RMBCA §8.61(b)(1) and Comment 2 BJR (P): §8.62(a) and Comment 1 Reasonable belief in fairness (P): ALI §5.02(a)(2)(b) EF (D): ALI §5.02(c), §5.02(a)(2)(A), §5.02(b) BJR (P): Same as above **Why apply EF if the transaction is approved by disinterested directors (ALI)?: Directors have collegial relationships (sympathy, friendship), so high risk of bias.** **Why give less deference when the transaction is ratified ex post?: To create incentives to approve ex ante. Approving ex post involves problems: (1) boards might not reject deals they would reject ex ante; (2) could be costly to void deal; and (3) transaction costs already sunk.** **Why have the Delaware approach?: Because of the benefits of the BJR** 2. Self-Dealing Transactions Involving a Controlling Shareholder Similar to D&O if conflicted, EFR, if no conflict, BJR (Sinclair) 20 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Sinclair Oil v. Levien: Sinclair owns 97% of Siven and dominates board. Siven minority shareholders claim Sinclair payed “excessive” dividends, impeding biz development. Holding: Court applies BJR to find Sinclair not liable. Dividends were paid pro rata, so no conflict of interest. Benefit/Detriment Test: Sinclair received nothing from Sinven to the exclusion to and detriment of Sinven’s minority shareholders. Weinberger v. UOP: Signal owns 50% of UOP and holds 6/13 board seats. 1 UOP director and 1 Signal director issue report stating that max of $24/pps is good investment for Signal but shares only with Signal board. Signal offers $21 (55% premium) conditioned on approval by MOM of UOP. No effort to negotiate, quick agreement. Two Signal directors participate but withdraw for actual approval. 52% of minority shareholders approve. Holding: Court applies EFR: (1) Fair Dealing not met bc did not disclose report and fairness opinion was hastily drafted; (2) Fair Price not met because Chancery court did not consider relevant factors (like report) so cannot be sure price is fair. To increase chance of meeting EFR standard, controller could have formed a special committee of independent directors. Approval by Disinterested Parties (special committee of independent directors): still EFR, but burden shifts from defendant to plaintiff **Special committees act as a bargaining agent for minority shareholders, mitigating collective action problems** **Majority of the Minority requirement acts as a check on the actions of the special committee, since committee may be “captured: or might not be competent** **Failure to disclose = not fair!** B. Corporate Opportunities Doctrine Corporate Opportunities “belong to the corporation” and pose potential conflicts of interest. Ask: (1) Does the opportunity belong to the corporation? (2) If so, is there a conflict of interest? (3) Is the appropriation of the opportunity a breach of the duty of loyalty? Does the opportunity belong to the corporation? Delaware’s 4-Factor test: 1. Corp is financially able to exploit the opportunity a. Did matter come to attention of fiduciary by reason of his corp capacity b. Does opportunity fall within “core economic activities: of corp c. Was corp info used to identify/ exploit opportunity 2. Opportunity is within corp’s line of business 3. Corp has an interest or expectancy in the opportunity 4. By taking the opportunity, fiduciary is placed in conflict with corp Personal Touch Holding Corp. v. Glaubach: *Illustrates expanded line of business test* Corp was interested in acquiring a building, but seller declined. Co-founder and former President of corp secretly negotiated for himself. Holding: Court applied 4-Factor test to find usurpation of corp opportunity. Re: line of biz, court said that it should be applied broadly and flexibly and held that corp wanted to acquire building in order to expand its business. 21 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 A board’s decision to permit a director to take a corporate opportunity will be upheld if the decision was made in good faith. The director taking the opportunity bears the burden of showing that: (1) the decision to reject the opportunity for the corporation was a good-faith business judgment and (2) the directors making the decision were disinterested. Under DGCL, corp can waive corp opportunity constraints in charter. This induces directors to serve, but risks that they will selectively appropriate opportunities for themselves. C. Duty of Loyalty in Close Corporations Close Corporation: - Small number of shareholders - Illiquid shares - Controlling shareholder is involved in mgmt. of the company **Issues with close corporations include illiquidity of the shares and risk of exploitation by controlling shareholder** Donahue v. Rodd Electrotype: Company has 4 owners and 3 board members. Offers to buy half of one director/ family member’s shares. Another shareholder tenders her shares for same price, but is refused (she was offered much less). Holding: Shareholders in close corps owe one another substantially the same fiduciary duty of “utmost good faith and loyalty” as partners (NOT BJR). Remedy: (1) rescind transaction; or (2) honor price for other shareholder. *Specific remedy of equal treatment is not Delaware law* Smith v. Atlantic Properties: Three shareholders. Charter requires 80% vote, giving veto power. One shareholder vetoes every dividend, and corp gets IRS penalty for unreasonable accumulation of earnings. Other two shareholders claim breach of fiduciary duty. Holding: Breach of fiduciary duties bc conduct was “beyond what was reasonable.” VIII. Executive Compensation A. Agency Costs in Executive Compensation Two competing goals: mitigate mgr risk aversion + discourage excessive risk-taking **Exec compensation can involve significant conflicts of interest, resulting in overcompensation** Managerial Power Theory: directors likely to be too deferential to management bc: - CEOs may influence the re-election of directors. - CEOs can benefit directors using corporate resources. - Directors appointed by/ with help from CEO may be loyal to CEO. - Directors want boardroom to be collegial, not argue about salary - Dir own only small % of stock = cheap to favor CEO (but costly to bargain hard) Optimal Bargaining Theory: market forces are strong enough to induce directors to pay executives in ways that are in the shareholders’ best interests 1. Pay-for-Performance Tool to Mitigate Agency Costs 22 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Tie comp to stock price - CEO might still be risk-averse bc he is less diversified than shareholders) Pay 100% in Call Options - Pay 100% in Options o At the money call option: strike price = current market price o In the money call option: strike price < current market price. o Out of the money (underwater): strike price > current market price. - **Helps incentivize execs** - **Problem: incentivizes excessive risk-taking bc downside is neutralized (CEO can elect not to exercise option)** Disclosure requirements o Clawback: must repay bonuses and gains from stock or option payments based on financial statement misconduct (SarbOx) o Say-on-Pay: Shareholders get advisory (non-binding) vote on comp (Dodd-Frank) B. Judicial Review of Executive Compensation In re Goldman Sachs: *Illustrates that BJR is standard of review for non-controller executive comp* Shareholders sued, claiming that comp structure promoted excessive risk-taking and execs were over-comped to the point of waste. Holding: Court applied BJR and upheld comp structure. Directors were disinterested, adequately informed (102(b)(7) waiver, no bad faith), no evidence of waste, no evidence of bad faith. Tornetta v. Elon Musk: applies the MFW blueprint to comp of controller executive officers: • No SC or MOM → Entire fairness • SC or MOM → Entire fairness, with burden of proof shifted to defendants • SC and MOM → Business judgment rule Calma v. Templeton: *Illustrates that EF is standard of review for director comp UNLESS there is sufficiently-specific shareholder approval* Shareholders challenged plan of restricted stock units grated to directors. Approved by majority of disinterested shareholders, but comp was essentially unlimited, thus excessive. Holding: No ratification bc shareholders approved overall plan for entire company, but did not specifically approve the jumbo grants for directors. Thus, EFR: director compensation is self-dealing decision and comp was not fair. 23 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 IX. Shareholder Litigation Direct Suit: brought by individuals who are directly harmed by corp.’s actions - Typically class actions - Damages go to shareholders/ injunctions are for bene of shareholders - Ex. Inspect books and records, require entity to recognize investor’s right to vote, challenging a merger for failure to make disclosures. Derivative Suit: claims of the corporation, brough by shareholder on corp.’s behalf - Two suits in one: (1) suit demanding that directors sue on behalf of corporation; (2) suit for the claims themselves - If brought as class action, governed by FRCP 23.1 - Special procedural hurdles - Damages to corporation - Ex. claim against director that engaged in corporate waste Tooley v. Donaldson Lufkin Jenrette: Shareholder has no right to a merger, so claim should be derivative and direct action was dismissed. Test: Issue of whether an action is properly derivative or direct must turn solely on (1) who suffered alleged harm; (2) who would receive bene of remedy. Benefits of Litigation incentivizes cases, which = compensation and deterrence; can prompt valuable governance changes. Costs of Litigation: atty fees can encourage meritless suits; direct costs; D&O insurance circularity. Fletcher v. AJ Industries: Corp. still deserves atty fees even if it received no money from a restructuring suit because suit generated value and created “substantial benefit” for the corp. A. Procedural Requirements in Derivative Suits 1. Standing (only an injured party can bring suit). Specific conditions: - Must own shares for duration of action (“fairly and adequately represent interests”) - Must own shares at time of alleged injury (don’t buy shares just to sue – remedy limited to those actually harmed) 2. Demand Requirement: Shareholder plaintiff must request board to bring action unless it is futile and can be waived. Aronson v. Lewis: Demand Futility Test: (1) directors are disinterested and independent AND; (2) challenged transaction was the product of a valid exercise of business judgment. Mere threat of personal liability is insufficient to challenge independence/ disinterestedness of the directors. Levine v. Smith: Demand not excused. Clarifies Aronson test: (1) whether the threshold presumptions of director disinterest or independence are rebutted by well-pleaded facts; OR (2) whether the complaint pleads particularized facts sufficient to create a reasonable doubt that the challenges transaction was a product of reasoned business judgment. N.B. second prong does NOT require overcoming BJR—only reasonable doubt is required. 24 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Rales v. Blasband: Clarifies second prong of Aronson test in “double-derivative suits.” Where demand excusal is asserted against a board that has not made the decision that is the subject of the action, the standard for determining demand excusal is whether the board was capable of impartially considering the action’s merits without being influenced by improper considerations. Aronson/Levine Demand Futility Conditions - Directors are interested or lack independence in the decision whether to bring suit. - There is reasonable doubt that the decision is not a valid exercise of business judgment (decision not protected by BJR). - Interest in the challenged transaction generally leads to interest in the outcome of the litigation. i.e. Interest in the challenged transaction = reasonable doubt that BJR protects (prong 2) = interest in litigation outcome (prong 1) Rales Demand Futility Conditions - Directors are interested or lack independence in the decision whether or not to bring a suit. Rales test if: - Board was replaced - No business decisions (i.e. insider trading allegations) - Different corporation *In Delaware, universal practice of no-demand, which reinforces courts’ quality screening role. 3. Special Litigation Committees: when demand is excused, formed by board to consider suit’s merits. Zapata v. Maldonado: P files derivative suit in Delaware, demand is excused, and 4 years into litigation, Zapata board appoints two independent director who serve as SLC. SLC recommends dismissal. Holding: BJR permits independent SLC formed by tainted board to dismiss a derivative action. Court should apply test to evaluate: (1) has the corporation proved independence, good faith, and a reasonable investigation; AND (2) does the court feel, applying its own business judgment, that dismissal is appropriate? Business Judgment Rule shields directors from derivative lawsuits unless shareholders can prove self-dealing, lack of due care or good faith, or conflict of interest by directors. This prevents shareholders from being unfairly trampled by directors while also allowing directors to rid corporation of detrimental litigation. Self-interest of board did not bar properly-appointed SLC from determining that suit was detrimental to corp.’s best interests. In re Oracle Corp. Derivative Litigation: Derivative complaint alleges insider trading (breach of loyalty). SLC produces report concluding that Oracle should not pursue claims against defendant directors. Plaintiff challenged independence of SLC. Holding: SLC cannot be independent when the directors appointed to SLC are personally interested in suit’s outcome. SLC bears the burden of proving its independence. SLC’s decision based on merits of the claim, not extraneous considerations// influences. Focus on directors’ impartiality/ objectivity. No one in silicon valley is independent from Larry Ellison. *Broadened inquiry of SLC’s independence to include considerations other than domination and control. 25 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Joy v. North: SLC bears burden of proving need for dismissal. Court applied Zapata and found that BJR does not apply when SLC recommends dismissal of a shareholder derivative suit in cases involving direct financial harm to the corporation and a diminishing of the value of the shareholder’s investment. 4. Settlement Settlement doctrine + EFP are two ways to reduce meritless suits. If shareholder survives SJ, strong incentives for both sides to settle so court must approve. SLC can be formed to oversee settlement process (rare). Carlton v. TLC Beatrice: court will approve settlement of derivative action negotiated by an SLC if: (1) committee acted independently, reasonably, and in good faith, and (2) court approves of the merits of the settlement under its own independent business judgment. In re Trulia: Settlements must be fair and reasonable. Court rejected settlement bc proposed class of stockholders did not get sufficient value in proposed settlement to warrant release of all claims related to merger. 5. Exclusive Forum Provision Exclusive Forum Bylaws require that any claim related to an internal claim (claims related to: (1) fiduciary duties; (2) other matters governing relationships btwn/among corp and current directors, officers, shareholders) be brought only in designated forum. Upheld by Boilermakers. Corps can adopt EFBs, but same breach can give rise to multi-forum litigation (one in Delaware and others under fed jurisdiction for ‘34 Act violations). EFPs allow all ’33 Act claims to be brought in federal court. Salzberg v. Sciabacucchi: ??? Plaintiff makes demand Board refuses BJR Plaintiff makes demand Board does not refuse Corporation brings suit No demand, Aronson test Demand excused Suit proceeds SLC Zapata No demand, Aronson test Demand excused Suit proceeds No SLC Case continues No demand, Aronson test Demand required (e.g. Levine) Suit dismissed X. Transactions in Control Benefits of Control: may be shared with all shareholders (i.e. successful biz plan); or enjoyed only by controller (“control premium” i.e. salary, notoriety, self-dealing opportunities – these may increase cost of capital by making investors wary). Want to maximize public benefits and minimize private benefits. A. Sales of Control Blocks 1. Market Rule Market Rule: controlling shareholder can freely sell control block and keep control premium. 26 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Zetlin v. Hanson Holdings: Minority shareholders challenged sale of controlling block for $15 while stock traded at $7 (wanted to share in premium). Holding: Absent looting of corporate assets, conversion of a corporate opportunity, fraud or other acts of bad faith, controlling stockholder is free to sell controlling interest at a premium price. 2. Exceptions to the Market Rule Thorpe v. CERBCO: *If sale of control block takes away corp opportunity, controller must share premium* Controllers refused to sell subsidiary but offered to sell controlling stake in holding company. Did not disclose initial subsidiary offer to board and rejected board’s idea to sell subsidiary instead. Minority shareholder filed demand that proposed sale be rejected. Outside directors formed special committee. Sale was not completed. Minority shareholder filed suit claiming that controllers usurped corporate opportunity. Holding: A director violates his duty of loyalty to the corporation when he takes for himself an economic opportunity that belongs to the corporation, or when he does not inform the rest of the board that a corporate opportunity exists. Expectation damages are not appropriate bc corp could not actually have taken the opportunity, but usurping director is prevented from benefitting from breach of duty of loyalty and must return the $75,000 deposit received from prospective buyer. Perlman v. Feldman: Controller sells stake, giving control over steel supply to another company during Korean War steel shortage. Holding: breached fiduciary duties to minority shareholders by taking away opportunity. Remedy: return of control premium. But this is a derivative action, so recovery goes to corp. Therefore, court directed recovery to minority shareholders. Policy: Dissent argues that question should be whether buyer was a looter. Scholars argue that case was wrongly decided bc price rose after deal was announced. Looters are hard (expensive) to detect, so defer to market rule and punish if discovered ex post. Harris v. Charter: *duty of controller to not knowingly sell to a looter is triggered by red flags* Judicial Review: another limit on the shareholder’s right to receive a premium. • If controlled company is sold and controller receives special consideration: EFR. • However, BJR applies if deal was approved by: (1) SC + (2) MOM In re Delphi: *If there is coercion on the minority, the court will intervene through EFR* Charter prohibits a different consideration for two share classes in case of acquisition. B-share controller pressures special committee into amending charter and giving him higher consideration (otherwise, he will oppose deal). Holding: B-share controller exerted coercion, meriting EFR, but court declined to proceed with trial bc it seemed like a good deal even though the process was “imperfect.” B. Tender Offers Williams Act: implements early-warning system and provides substantive regulation of tender offers. Both measures are designed to give shareholders more info and time to decide. Williams v. Dickinson: Acquirer buys 34% by making simultaneous calls to 30 institutional buyers and 9 accredited buyers tendering fixed above-market price for one hour only. Is this a tender offer? Holding: Yes. Court applied 8-part Wellman test and found all were true except not widespread: 1. Active and widespread solicitation 27 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 2. Solicitation made for a substantial percentage of issuer’s stock 3. Offer for premium over prevailing market price 4. Terms of offer are firm, not negotiable 5. Offer contingent on tender of fixed minimum number of shares 6. Open only for limited period of time 7. Offerees subjected to pressure to sell 8. Public announcements of purchasing program precede or accompany rapid accumulation Brascan v. Edper Equities: Edper buys 10% via broker who contacts 40-65 institutional & accredited investors. Tells officials it will not purchase more, but then buys another 14% the following day. Brascan brings suit claiming violation of ’34 Act §14(e) and Rule 10b-5 (fraud). Holding: Not a tender offer bc only three factor met (substantial block; premium; contingent on minimum number of shares). 1. Early-Warning System Basic Rule (Rule 13d-1(a)): - Investor must file 13D report w/in 10 days of acquiring 5%+ “beneficial ownership.” - Must disclose identity and whether plans to take control of company (Rule 13d-1(c)) - Updating requirement (Rule 13d-2): Must amend previous Schedule 13D promptly if there is a material (+/- 1%) change to investor’s holdings - Key Definitions: o Beneficial owner: individual with power to vote or buy/sell stock (13d-3(a)). o Group: anyone who acts together to buy, hold, vote, or sell stock (13d-5(b)(1)). • Each group member deemed beneficially to own each member’s stock. **Policy Considerations** - Advantage: increases pay for minority, who may thus charge less ex ante for their capital - Disadvantage: may deter efficient controllers 2. Regulation of Tender Offers • General Disclosure: (§14(d)(1)): requires tender offeror to disclose identity and future plans, including any subsequent going-private transactions. • Anti-Fraud Provision (§14(e)): prohibits “fraudulent, deceptive, or manipulative” practices in connection with a tender offer. • Terms of the Offer (§14(d)(4)-(7)): governs the substantive terms of the tender offer. • 14e-1: Must be open for 20 business days. • 14d-10: Must be open to all shareholders; all purchases must be made at best price. • 14d-8: Where shares tendered exceed scope of offer, acceptances must be pro-rated. • 14d-7: Shareholders who tender can withdraw while tender offer open. • 14e-5: Bidder cannot buy “outside” tender offer. **Policy Considerations** Regulations increase the price (esp. 20-day window, which creates auction) - Advantage: attracts higher-bidding buyers, increasing pay for minority, who may thus charge less ex ante for their capital 28 Business Associations - Restrepo—Spring 2021 Disadvantage: may deter efficient controllers bc of higher prices/frustration Hart-Scott Rodino Act (HSRA) - Gives FTC and DOJ time to examine antitrust implications of some acquisitions (30 days for mergers and negotiated deals, 15 days for tender offers) (§18a(b)(1)(B)). - DOJ or FTC may extend review window or waive review. - Applies only to large companies. XI. Mergers and Acquisitions Motives That Create Value • Economies of scale: Increasing production volume decreases marginal costs. • Economies of scope: Spreading costs across broader range of related businesses lowers cost of running each business. • Vertical integration: Economy of scope where company acquires supplier of inputs, ensuring uninterrupted supply of materials and reducing production costs. • Management efficiencies: Increase value of acquisition by improving its operations. • Project diversification (“smoothing”): Diversifying corp’s income streams reduces risk. Motives That Transfer Value Harmless transfers • Tax transfers: by shifting NOL (and thus right to deduct previous losses from current income) to a firm that is earning income, value is shifted from government to shareholders of the acquiring, profit-making firm. Potentially harmful transfers • Transfers from consumer:. By acquiring competitors and using market power to increase prices, value is shifted from consumers to the shareholders of the monopolistic firm. • Transfers from minority shareholders: Where majority shareholder acquires the minority shares in the corporation (“freeze out),” majority may extract wealth from minority. Motives that destroy value • Empire building: Managers may pursue mergers simply bc they want to run larger firm. • Poor incentives: Mgrs may pursue value-destroying mergers just to get golden parachute N.B. D&O usually make biz decisions, but bc of agency problems, mergers require shareholder approval. A. Transactional Forms MERGER Voting Rules - Target shareholders always vote (DGCL §251(c)). - Buyer shareholders do not have to vote if, inter alia, buyer issues no more than 20% of its outstanding shares to pay for target (DGCL §251(f). similar to RMBCA § 11.04). - **20% is rough proxy for big transactions; if the deal is not big, it makes sense to avoid the cost and delay of shareholder vote** - Per NYSE Manual § 312.03(c), buyer’s shareholders must vote if the buyer’s shares increase by > 20%. Requires approval of 50% of shares voting on the matter. **Vote ensures that buyer does not become controlled w/o shareholders’ permission.** 29 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Statutory Merger: Target collapses into acquirer; exposes buyer’s assets to target’s liabilities. - Buyer and target boards negotiate merger. - Target’s and (sometimes) buyer’s shareholders vote. - If shareholders approve, target assets merge into the acquiror and target shareholders get cash or stock in the buyer. - Certificate of merger filed with secretary of state. - Dissenting shareholders who had a right to vote often have appraisal rights. Triangular Merger: Addresses liability issue of straight mergers. Forward Triangular Merger: Target is absorbed into wholly owned subsidiary. Reverse Triangular Merger: (most common) Wholly owned subsidiary of acquirer is merged into target. ACQUISITION Voting Rules • Buyer’s shareholders’ do not vote. • Seller’s shareholders must vote in sales of substantially all of the assets of the corp= (DGCL §271; similar rule in RMBCA § 12.02). “Substantially All” • CERBCO: qualitative analysis: “transaction that affects the existence and purpose of the corporation.” • Hollinger Inc. v. Hollinger International: nearly all the assets. **Acquisitions vs. mergers, Disadvantages: High transaction costs: title to each asset must be transferred individually; Advantages: Low liability cost (buyer does not acquire target’s liabilities); Do not require buyer’s shareholders’ approval unless buyer issues more than 20%; Acquirer avoids appraisal rights.** Asset Acquisitions (NOT MERGERS) Under DGCL §271 1. Boards negotiate the deal. 2. Only target’s shareholders get voting and appraisal rights – if “substantially all” of the target’s assets are sold. 3. Buyer generally distributes consideration to its stockholders. Stock Acquisition: buyer acquires controlling block of shares; identity of target unaffected - If buyer wants 100% of shares: o Short form merger If buyer holds ≥ 90% in target, can cash out minority w/o shareholder approval. o Intermediate form merger Merger is treated as having been approved if: Buyer executes tender offer whose terms are fixed by both boards Buyer obtains enough shares in tender offer to approve a merger Merger is for same price as tender offer. De Facto Merger Doctrine: treats business combinations that resemble the effects of a merger as a merger. (e.g. sale of substantially all the assets in exchange for stock in the buyer, followed by dissolution of the seller and distribution of the buyer’s stock to the seller’s shareholders). Rejected in Delaware. **Shareholders may want de facto merger bc appraisal rights may be triggered (RMBCA gives appraisal rights in more restructuring circumstances including sales of “substantially all” assets); buyers get to vote in some mergers.** 30 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Practical M&A considerations: timing, regulatory approvals, deal protection B. Appraisal Appraisal is a remedy that gives shareholders the right to demand that a court calculate the value of their shares and order a cash payment. Delaware allows shareholders to adopt appraisal rights in charter (but they are rare). **Historically, appraisal was part of compromise allowing corps to be acquired with < unanimous consent. Also, merger is “last period” for managers, so their interests may not be aligned with shareholders.** Appraisal Steps • Shareholders get notice of appraisal right at least 20 days before shareholder meeting. • Shareholder submits demand for appraisal to corp before shareholder vote, then votes against or refrains from voting for merger. • If merger is approved, shareholder files appraisal petition with Chancery Court w/in 120 days after merger. • Court holds valuation proceeding under DGCL §262(h). • Not a class action, but Chancery Court can apportion fees among plaintiffs as equity may require. Appraisal is NOT AVAILABLE in acquisitions in Delaware, unless charter provides otherwise. Appraisal IS AVAILABLE under the RMBCA in more restructuring situations, including sales of substantially all the assets. Appraisal IS AVAILABLE in mergers unless the market exception applies: Consideration Type of company Public corporation (traded on an exchange or has more than 2,000 shareholders) Private corporations (with less than 2,000 shares) Stock in the surviving corporation or another public corporation No appraisal rights Appraisal rights* Cash Appraisal rights *In some cases, no appraisal if shareholders have no right to vote. Appraisal rights In Delaware, petitioner must hold >1% of shares or >$1M to petition for appraisal, and firm may pre-pay merger consideration to dissenters when petition is filed, to reduce interest charges. Determining Fair Value 31 Business Associations - Restrepo—Spring 2021 Shareholders are entitled to pro rata portion of firm’s value as a going concern less “any element of value arising from the accomplishment or expectation of the merger.” Synergies are excluded. Since 2015, courts look to deal price, provided there are no significant defects in the sale. If deal price is unreliable, courts use other methods, like unaffected mkt price. **Shift away from using part performance or DCF bc courts are not well positioned to questions use of technical methods and wanted to stop “appraisal arbitrage.”** Verition Partners v. Aruba Networks: Chancery court appraised using mkt price instead of deal price because (1) no other bids emerged when deal became public and (2) court would have to calculate and deduct agency cost reductions bc target was previously widely held and became controlled via acquisition. Holding: Reversed Chancery court. Fair price = deal price – synergies. Mkt price is important indicator of fair value, but deal price is better bc buyer has greater incentives and is better informed than ordinary traders to value target accurately. As long as there was opportunity to bid, sales process is not flawed just bc there were no other bidders. Do not have to calculate and deduct agency costs bc they are already part of synergies and not clear that transaction generates agency cost reductions (transaction is just swapping one group of public shareholders for another, not becoming controlled) Firt Tree Value Master Fund: Chancery court used unaffected stock market price as fair value, said could not use deal price as fair value bc sales process was flawed bc CEO dominated the process and there was no market check (bc board granted buyer exclusivity during due diligence). Also, no comps. Holding: Chancery court did not abuse discretion – no precedent disallowed certain valuation method here. No material nonpublic info about target’s prospects, so market price was good proxy, no good comps, plus flaw in sales process. Quasi-Appraisal • Applies if (material) defective disclosure impaired ability of shareholders to seek appraisal. • Unlike regular appraisal actions, this is an opt-out class action. Appraisal vs. Entire Fairness Action Characteristic Appraisal Entire fairness review action Does the shareholder need to dissent? Yes No Remedy Pro rata share of fair value minus synergies Broader set of remedies (e.g., revision of price, rescission, rescissory damages) Who benefits from the action? Petitioners (opt-in action) The entire class (opt-out class action) Merger & Tender Offer Freezeout: controlling/ majority shareholder(s) negotiate merger agreement with target board. 32 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Tender Offer Freezeout controlling/ majority shareholder(s) buy directly from minority shareholders. Reverse Stock Split: consolidates the number of existing shares of stock into fewer, proportionally more valuable, shares. C. Controlled Mergers EFR Freezeouts are subject to EFR. Court strongly encourages controllers to implement special committee of independent directors. (Weinberger v. UOP) Kahn v. Lynch: * SC OR MOM Approval* Target formed special committees to negotiate with acquirer, which already owned 4.3%. Rejected 3x then recommended a price on threat of hostile bid from acquirer. Minority shareholders alleged breach of fiduciary duty by acquirer. Chancery court said SC had simulated 3rd party transaction, so no breach. Holding: EFR applies. If SC approves transaction, burden of proof shifts to plaintiff. Mere existence of SC does not shift burden—if SC was subject to domination or coercion, then burden remains on defendant. Here, acquirer threatened committee. N.B. Rosenblatt extends the principle in Lynch to MOM approval. In re CNX Gas Corp: *SC AND MOM Approval, tender freezeout* After negotiating with institutional investor that owns 6% in target and 6% in acquirer, 83% owner of target announces tender offer for remaining shares of target. Deal is subject to MOM, which includes institutional investor. Target also formed special committee, which remained neutral. Holding: Applied Cox standard to find that EFR is appropriate if there is no SC and MOM (otherwise, BJR is appropriate). Here, EFR applied bc SC did not recommend deal and MOM was defective since institutional 6% owner was conflicted. Kahn v. M&F Worldwide (MFW): *SC AND MOM in merger freezeout* minority shareholders challenged freezeout arguing for EFR. Chancery court applied Cox and used BJR. Holding: SCOTUS affirmed, but clarified that freezeout is only reviewed under BJR if deal was subject ab 33 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 initio (ab initio = before any substantive economic negotiations begin. The idea is that the controller must disable himself from control from the beginning rather than implement the conditions as a concession when trying to obtain a lower price) to: (1) approval by independent and fully empowered SC which fulfills duty of care and (2) uncoerced and informed vote by MOM. Presence of only one protection would shift burden of proof. ** Only both protections together replicate an arm’s length transaction: (1) SCs provide a negotiating agent; and (2) MOM condition provides a backstop against ineffective directors or directors that are captured by the controller** ** Deal prices are sensitive to the threat of EFR: If investors do not have the protection of EFR, they will simply pay less ex ante for their shares. Tender decision is not a sufficient protections. This matters because controllers might opportunistically freezeout the minority when the price of the company is transitorily lower than the intrinsic value – and this is hard to price ex ante** ** Controlling shareholders do appear to consider the standard of judicial review, possibly with aim of paying lower prices when the standard is lower.** ** Gains of the target did not increase significantly after MFW, meaning perhaps MOM does not make a significant difference, and MFW and EFR provide similar protections** **We let MFW be prevalent standard of review for conflict transactions instead of requiring EFR or prohibiting these transactions bc some conflict transactions may be efficient and applying EFR to all transactions would underestimate the cost of judicial intervention, and courts are not good at determining fair price** N.B. MFW has been extended to non-freezeout transactions: 3rd party acquisitions of controlled companies, executive compensation, corporate recapitalizations XII. Contests for Corporate Control A. Judicial Review of Antitakeover Defenses Unocal v. Mesa Petroleum: Mesa has 13%, makes tender offer for addt’l 37% at $54, and plans to freeze-out remaining 50% for junk bonds with face value of $54. Goldman says minimum liquidation value is $60. Board implements defensive recapitalization with self-tender for 30% at $72, plus, if Mesa gains 50%, will tender remaining 19% at $72 in debt securities. Chancery court cites BJR to grant Mesa an injunction. Holding: Standard of review to evaluate defensive measures is “enhanced BJR,” which evaluates whether: (1) directors had reasonable grounds for believing there was a threat to corp policy and effectiveness (consider: Inadequate price, nature and timing of offer, impact on other constituents, risk of non-consummation, quality of securities offered); and (2) defensive measures must be reasonable in relation to threat posed. * Mesa engaged in greenmail. Prong 1: Mesa offer is structurally coercive bc shareholders are paid unequally. Paid more for first movers and less on back-end. Prong 2: Unocal’s revised offer is a defensive maneuver because it eliminates incentive to tender to Mesa (directly punishes Mesa). Under Unitrin, Prong 2 is a two-part proportionality test: (1) was the defensive tactic coercive or preclusive (draconian); and (2) if not, does it fall within a range of reasonable responses? If defendants can show proportionality, BJR applies. Otherwise, EFR applies. 34 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Board passivity policy argument: as costs and frustration risk of acquisition increase, efficient buyers are deterred. Defensive measure policy argument: shareholders need protection, defensive tactics are ordinary biz decisions and thus merit BJR (but beware bc mgrs. may be selfinterested). Poison Pill: right for shareholders who have not acquired a large block of stock to buy shares at substantial discount. Flip-In Pills: target shareholders can acquire at substantially discounted price Flip-Over Pills: target shareholder arguably have right to buy shares in the buyer (uncommon bc validity is debatable). To Implement Pill: - Board adopts “shareholder rights plan” plan by vote. No shareholder vote necessary. - Rights distributed as dividends embedded in the shares - Triggering event occurs when prospective acquirer buys significant number of shares - Rights are exercised and all shareholders except acquirer can now buy shares at deep discount, cancelling acquirer’s rights Moran v. Household International: Two directors bring suit to enjoin poison pill as outside the board’s authority/ invalid exercise of biz judgment. Holding: DGCL give broad authority to adopt a pill and the adoption of the pill withstands Unocal (it is valid under 2nd prong – does not prevent hostile takeover from ever winning (could try proxy contest), just makes it harder) Smith v. Van Gorkum: board’s personal interests can affect not only its takeover defenses in hostile bids, but also its choice of a merger or buyout partner. Board had been “grossly negligent.” Court signals that antitakeover defenses CAN involve conflicts of interest. B. Choosing A Merger Partner: Judicial Review of Board Actions (Active Battle or When Company is Up for Sale) Revlon v. MacAndrews & Forbes: Hostile all-cash tender offer at $47 when Revlon is trading at $25. Revlon resists with poison pill and buy purchasing 20% of shares with Revlon notes. Notes contain provision that prohibit Revlon from selling or lending against its assets without permission from independent directors. Takeover bid raised to $56.25, offers more if pill is removed. Board elects to go with white knight buyer at $57.25, which requires removing assetsale provision from notes, causing value of notes to fall. White knight gets asset lockup, no-shop provision, and breakup fee in exchange for supporting par value of notes. Holding: Injunction against white knight provisions affirmed. Board breached duty of loyalty by playing favorites between buyers. White knight buyer note provision reduced risk of director litigation, and instead directors should have tried to maximize shareholder value, not look out for own interests. Not maximizing value breached duty of care. Conflicts of interest can exist in a board’s decision to go with one buyer over another. Lockups are OK, but here, the lockup brought about an invalid end to the auction. N.B. Duty of Care (but not loyalty) violations can be waived under DGCL §102(b)(7). Paramount Communications v. Time, Inc.: Time & Warner agreed to stock-for-stock merger, but before shareholders could agree, Paramount announced a tender offer for all of Time’s shares at a premium. Time rejected and changed WB deal to cash & securities deal (avoids required shareholder vote). Paramount raised and Time rejected again bc WB was better long-term value 35 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 option. Claim argued that under Revlon, the WB agreement put Time up for sale so board was obligated to maximize short-term value increase and under Unocal, Time’s belief that Paramount posed a threat was unreasonable and that board failed to fully investigate. Holding: Time’s conclusion that inadequate value was not the only possible threat to its future is reasonable (threat that Time shareholders would tender offer without knowing long-term benefits of the Paramount deal; threat to the Time “Culture”; and general threat to Time’s business model since it would be entering new field of entertainment). A board of directors may enter into a transaction in order to defeat a reasonably perceived threat to the corporation’s business so long as the board’s decision is reasonable in relation to the threat posed. Also, no evidence that under Revlon, breakup was inevitable. In Unocal, threat was “structural coercion,” (offering unequal payment to distort shareholder tender decision) here, it’s “substantive coercion” (risk that shareholders will mistakenly accept underpriced offer in ignorance of the benefits of alternate course of action). Revlon duties are triggered if: (1) target initiates active bidding process to sell itself or effect a reorganization; or (2) in response to an offer, target abandons its long-term strategy and seeks an alternative transaction involving a break-up/ sale. Paramount Communications v. QVC: Merger agreement btwn Paramount and Viacom had no-shop provision and Viacom got $100M termination fee and right to buy %19 if merger failed. QVC offered tender offer, which gave Paramount more leverage to renegotiate with Viacom. QVC raised offer beat Viacom’s new terms, but Paramount rejected as “too conditional.” Holding: Revlon was triggered bc Paramount initiated an active bidding process to sell itself by agreeing to sell control to Viacom. When a corporation undertakes a transaction which will cause a change in corporate control or a break-up of the corporate entity, the directors’ obligation is to seek the best value reasonably available to the stockholders, since change in control could decrease shareholder voting power. Viacom deal transferred all power to Viacom (diminishes voting power, removes shareholders from biz strategy) and shareholders were not adequately compensated for this. No-shop provision could not limit board’s duty to negotiate with both suitors in good faith. Board breached fiduciary duties by not fully informing themselves about QVC deal. 36 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Case Holding Open question Unocal Defensive tactics are judged using intermediate scrutiny: (1) there is a threat; and (2) the tactics are “reasonable in relation to the threat posed.” What constitutes a threat justifying a defensive action? The cases illustrate two: • Structural coercion (Unocal) • Substantive coercion (Time) In dicta, Unocal also mentions inadequate price and consummation risks. Moran Poison pills are authorized in Delaware and survive Unocal. When will a court force a target to redeem its pill because it has “arbitrarily reject[ed] the offer”? In practice, never. The board is not required to give up its long-term business plan for short-term profit “unless there is clearly no basis to sustain it.” (Time) Revlon When Revlon duties are triggered, the board must maximize immediate shareholder value. 1. What situations trigger Revlon duties? 1. In response to an offer or a unilateral decision, the company is up for sale (Time). 2. What is a “sale” of the firm? 2. Some transactions (cash deals & acquisitions by controlled buyers) are more likely than others (QVC) 3. How should the board maximize shareholder value? 3. When several suitors are actively bidding for control, must level playing field among bidders (no playing favorites, like in Revlon) When board considers single offer and has no reliable grounds to judge its adequacy, fairness requires canvas of the marketplace (OK to skip market check if board has reliable body of evidence to determine price). (QVC, Barkan) Judicial review: Enhanced BJR 4. Is board liable for damages if it fails to maximize shareholder value? 4. NO, if there is: (1) a 102(b)(7) liability waiver; and (2) duty of loyalty is not breached and the board acts in good faith. 37 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 Revlon Less Likely Revlon More Likely All Stock Consideration All Cash Widely Held Acquiror Shareholders Controlling Shareholder In general, cash consideration triggers Revlon, stock consideration where target is widely held and buyer is controlled triggers Revlon, and stock consideration where target and buyer are both widely held does not trigger Revlon. Benefits of Revlon: more active bidding contest = higher price for shareholders and can lower cost of capital Costs of Revlon: As costs and frustration increase, may deter efficient buyers. Lyondell Chemical v. Ryan: Lyondell board agrees to sell after rushed process with no market canvas for higher bid. 99% shareholder vote approval, but others claim price is inadequate. Lyondell had 102(b)(7) waiver, but Chancery court denied directors summary judgment Holding: Reversed. Revlon does not create new fiduciary duties, must just perform existing duties to maximize price. So, if there is a liability waiver, then board is not liable for damages absent bad faith or breach of duty of loyalty (a high bar) C. Deal Protection Devices Termination/ break-up fees: cash payments in event that target fails to close merger, triggered by specific events. *After Revlon and QVC, breakup fee becomes dominant form of protection (~3% of value) Asset lockups: right to acquire corp assets at specified price, triggered by specific events Stock lockups: right to acquire block of target stock at specified price, triggered by specific events No-shop: agreement by target board not to shop for alternative transaction No-talk: extreme “no-shop,” requiring target not to talk with other bidders Agreement to recommend merger to shareholder Force-the-vote provision: agreement to submit merger agreement to shareholders for a vote regardless whether board continues to recommend merger Match-rights: right to match any competing offer *becoming increasingly common 38 Business Associations Restrepo—Spring 2021 N.B. Fiduciary Outs: allow target to terminate contract if required by fiduciary obligation to get highest price. Target does not breach, but term fee may still be triggered. **Deal protection devices reduce consummation risk and compensate bidder if deal doesn’t close. This incentivizes first bidders to engage. Risk: makes deal more expensive for subsequent bidders.** - In Revlon deals, lockups are subject to Revlon analysis –must permit shareholder value maximization If Revlon doesn’t apply, lockups still subject to Unocal analysis (Omnicare v. NCS Healthcare) D. Corwin Cleansing Effect Corwin v. KKR Financial Holding: Stock-for-stock merger approved by majority of shareholders. Plaintiffs challenged transaction, seeking damages, and arguing that EFR applies bc, under mgmt. agreement, KKR controls/ manages daily operations of target. Alternatively, even if EFR does not apply, Revlon should apply bc it is a biz sale. Holding: Court rejects EFR bc KKR is not really a controlling shareholder since they only own 1% of stock and no right to appoint directors or contractual veto, plus target had independent assets it controlled. BJR is appropriate standard for post-closing damages where merger is not subject to EFR (no freeze-out) and deal was approved by fully informed and uncoerced majority of disinterested shareholders. Court says it does not matter whether Revlon applies because BJR is appropriate. Unocal and Revlon are primarily intended for injunctive relief. **Corwin’s deference to BJR here has policy benefits of reducing litigation costs and managers’ risk aversion. Judges are also poorly-positioned to second-guess biz decisions.** Corwin is also extended to tender offers (In re Volcano). Corwin does not “cleanse” if a specific director induced an entire board to breach its duties in the sale process, because shareholders would not truly be informed if the disclosures are inaccurate. That director may be individually liable, absent a §102(b)(7).v E. State Antitakeover Statutes 1. Acquiring a Control Block - Control Share Statutes: (Ohio, Indiana) require disinterested shareholder vote to approve purchase of shares by any buyer crossing certain ownership threshold levels - Constituency Statutes: (Pennsylvania, Indian) allow board to consider non-shareholder constituencies in adopting defensive measures to resist hostile bids. - Disgorgement Statutes: (Pennsylvania, Ohio) require bidders to disgorge profits made upon sale of stock in target or assets of target (i.e. if sale is w/in 18 months of becoming a controller). 2. Second-Step Freeze-Out - Business Combination (freeze-out) Statutes: eg DGCL §203 – prevents bidder from freezing out minority before 3-5 years following acquisition of controlling stake—unless target board approves. 39 Business Associations - Restrepo—Spring 2021 Fair Price Statutes: (e.g. Maryland) require that minority shareholders who are frozen out in the second step of a two-step tender offer receive no less for their shares than the price of the first step. F. Proxy Contests for Corporate Control DGCL §203 bars biz combinations btwn acquiror and target for a period of three years after acquiror crosses 15% threshold unless: - Takeover is approved by target board before bid occurs - Acquiror gains more than 85% of shares in a single offer excluding inside directors’ shares - Acquiror gets board approval and 2/3 vote of approval from disinterested shareholders (i.e. minority who remain after takeover). With poison pills, buyer seeking to replace mgmt. has two alternatives: (1) negotiate with board; or (2) run a proxy contest to replace the board. This enhances importance of preventing undue mgmt. manipulation of proxy system. Acquisition Before Pill Control of board was essentially a sure thing after acquisition of majority of shares 1. Bidder makes tender offer and gains majority of shares 2. Board will almost certainly resign bc directors are doomed in next election Acquisition after the Pill Board control is, in practice, a prerequisite to buying a majority of shares 1. XXXXXXXX 2. Once in office, new directors redeem the pill, clearing way for new bidder to proceed 3. If directors stay they will be voted out over one (no staggered board) or two (staggered board) annual elections Blasius v. Atlas: 9% shareholder’s restructuring plan was rejected by board, so it announced intent to solicit shareholder consent to increase size of board from 7-15 and to fill board with its own nominees. Target board preempts by amending bylaws to add two new board seats and fill with own candidates (board packing). Holding: Board actions designed for primary purpose of interfering with shareholder voting are subject to enhanced judicial review, even if taken in good faith. Board bears heavy burden of demonstrating a compelling justification for its actions. Liquid Audio v. MM Companies: *provides guidance on when to apply Blasius instead of Unocal.* Target rejected cash offer, so acquiror plans to (1) challenge two incumbent directors up for reelection; (2) propose bylaw amendment expanding board from 5-9 members. Target adds 2 directors. At meeting, shareholders elect the two acquiror candidates to replace target’s incumbents, but reject adding 4 new seats. Holding: XXXXX 40