PART ONE ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS CHAPTER ONE 1.0 Scope of Environmental Economics What is environmental economics? How environmental economics is different from natural resources economics? The definition of environmental economics is narrow and broad. 1.1 Narrow Definition Environmental Economics is distinct from the sister discipline of natural resource economics. It is in the narrow sense concerned with: Welfare economics Economics of pollution Valuation theory, and Environmental policy Narrowly defined, environmental economics is concerned with what we sometimes call brown issues, the topics given above. 1.2 Natural Resources Economic (NRE) in Narrow Sense NRE is concerned with optimal utilisation of natural resources economics and is concerned with what are sometimes called green issues. 1.3 Broad definition of environmental economics Not distinct from natural resource economics in broad sense, environmental economics in concerned with: Welfare economics The economics of pollution Valuation theory Environmental policy and Optimal utilisation of natural resources 1 Economic objective Social objective 1.4 Ecological objective The Nature of Welfare Economics Concerned with what ought to be; that is welfare economics is based on normative economics. Focuses on using resources optimally so as to achieve the maximum well being for the individuals in the society. source: Just Hueth and Schmitz (1982). 1.5 Basic issues in Welfare Economics Deals with 3 questions 1. How should society’s resources be used and what social organization should society adopt. Social organization refers to market system, mixed economy or socialization. 2. How can we tell whether any change we make is for the better? 3. What would be the properties of an acceptable welfare functions (Arrows Impossibility Theorem? 1.6 The Meaning of Efficiency and Social Justice in Welfare Economics The definition of efficiency in welfare economics owes much to the economist Vilfredo Pareto. Therefore an efficiency social state is often called Pareto optimal. 1.6.1 Pareto efficiency (optimality) A situation is efficient or Pareto optimal if it is impossible to make one persons better off except by making someone else worse off. Source: Layard and Walter (1978) P.7 Alternatively, Pareto Efficiency can be defined as a situation in which it is impossible for one individual to gain without another individual incurring a loss. 2 1.6.2 Pareto inefficiency This is a situation in which it is possible for someone to gain without another individual incurring a loss. 1.6.3 Pareto improvement/pareto superior move If an economy is inefficient it is possible to make at least one person better off at no cost to anyone else. 1.6.4 Three conditions for efficiency Three conditions are necessary for efficiency: First condition is, efficient consumption/exchange efficiency Efficient consumption requires that all individuals place the same relative value on all products (value being assessed at the marginal i.e. all individuals have some marginal utility). source Layard P.10 Graphically Exchange efficiency is described by the tangency between two indifference curves. Qy O2 D C B A 1 2 IV 3 4 QX III I II From Z to A is pareto improvement because individual number 2 will gain without individual no 1 incurring a loss. Similarly from Z to B. NB exchange efficiency occurs on the contract curve: points A, B, C, and D. Formally 3 2 n MRS 1XY MRS XY .... MRS XY Where i = 1, 2, …., n are individuals consuming X and Y commodities. Alternatively; i j for all consumers i and j in the economy, on commodities X and Y MRS XY MRS XY Second condition: Efficiency production Efficient production requires that marginal rate of substitution between functions of production be the same in all industries. Source Laynard and Walter P. 12 Graphically Production efficiency is described by the tangency between two isoquants. Edgeworth - Bawley Box Figure 2. Production of X and Y using inputs labour and capital QY D C B A 1 IV 2 K 3 4 II III I QX Efficiency locus NB: Production efficiency occurs on the efficiency loci: A, B, C, and D. These indicate the rate at which marginal rate of transformation of X and Y is equal by varying labour and capital. 4 Third Condition, Efficient product mix Product - mix efficiency requires that the subjective value of commodity X in terms of commodity Y should equal the two marginal costs. Graphically E D B C NB: Exchange and production efficiency occur at points D and E, where: MRS XY MRTXY Formally MRS YX MRTYX Where MRS YX Ux UY MRTYX Yk Xk Additional Condition: Forth condition Social justice and the social optimum There are numerable efficient configurations of the economy, depending, among others, on the initial distribution of resources. However, efficiency does not constitute a social optimum. To obtain the social optimum we need the utility frontier of the economy, known as the Grand utility frontier. We also need the social welfare function. To obtain the grand utility frontier we take each feasible output mix from the transformation curve, and construct its utility frontier. This gives a family of utility frontiers. The overall utility frontier is then the outer envelope of all these frontiers: The slope of the grand utility frontier is 5 U 2x U 1x U2 Utility frontier for (X0,Y0) Grand utility frontier of Pareto optimal points Utility frontier for (X1,Y1) Utility frontier for (X2,Y2) U1 The social welfare function is given as W W U 1 ,U 2 This gives rise to what is sometimes called the Iso-welfare curve. W0 W U 1 ,U 2 With a slope dw / u 1 Wu 1 dw / u 2 Wu 2 To obtain the social optimum (or constrained “BLISS POINT”) we use the social welfare function to pick the preferred utility mix. At the optimum, the slope of the isowelfare curve equals the slope of the grand utility frontier, i.e. U 2 x Wu 1 social optimum U 1 x Wu 2 This is the fourth optimality condition. It is the condition for social justice. This therefore implies that for social justice we need fourth conditions. 6 CHAPTER 2 A MODEL OF EXTERNALITY IN CONSUMPTION 2.0 CONDITIONS REQUIRED FOR A MARKET SYSTEM TO EFFICIENTLY ALLOCATE RESOURCES 1. Markets exists for all goods and services exchanged. 2. All markets are perfectly competitive. 3. All transactors have perfect information. 4. Property rights are fully assigned. 5. No externalities exist. 6. All goods and service are private goods i.e. there are no public goods and common properly resources. 7. Long run average cost are non-decreasing that is there are no natural monopolies. 8. All firms are profit maximisers and all individuals are utility maximisers (profit maximization is a subset of cost minimization) 9. Transactions costs are zero. 10. All relevant functions satisfy convexity conditions (utility functions, production functions). In reality however we find: 1) Missing futures markets 2) Imperfect information 3) Information asymmetry among transactors i.e. imperfect information 4) Property rights are not fully assigned absence of property rights 5) Externalities are present, especially in the use of environment goods 6) Public goods and common properly resources 7) LRAC are decreasing i.e. we have natural monopolies 8) Not all firms or individuals are profit maximisers or utility maximisers 9) There are positive transactions costs 10) Not all relevant functions satisfy convexity conditions (some isoquant are 7 Conclusion Therefore one of the fundamental messages of environmental economics is that we must be pessimistic about the outcomes of unregulated markets. 2.1 Distinction between Private and Social Values Private costs: these are costs that are born to undertake an activity b the economic agent undertaking the activity. Social costs: there are costs that are born to undertake an activity by the economic agent undertaking the activity plus costs imposed on all other economic agents. Social costs = private costs + external costs therefore SC > PC Private Benefits: Benefits obtained from the realization of an activity by the economic agent undertaking the activity plus benefits obtained by all other economic agents. Social benefits = private benefits + external benefits therefore SB > PB PARETO EFFICIENCY AND EXTERNALITIES In the presence of externalities, a competitive equilibrium is not pareto efficient. In other words in the presence of externalities, the pareto efficiency conditions are not the same as the competitive profit maximization or utility maximization conditions. 2.2 TECHNICAL DEFINITION OF EXTERNALITY Externality is the case where the actions of one economic agent affect the utility or production functions of another agent. Non-technical definition of externality An externality is the impact of one person’s actions on the well being of a bystander. If the effect of a bystander is adverse, it is called a negative externality. If the effect is beneficial, it is a positive externality. 8 2.3 Types of Externalities Pecuniary externalities: prevail when changes in industrial output induce changes in the price of one or more inputs employed by firms in the industry. This is not a cause of market failure. They are captured by market system so there no need to worry. Technological externalities: prevail when at least one of the variables in production or utility functions of an agent falls under the control of external economic agents. This is a cause of market failure. Positive externalities occur when there are external benefits. In this case social benefits are greater than private benefits. Negative externality occurs when there are external costs. In this case social costs are greater than private costs. Unidirectional externalities occur when externalities occur in one directional. They are unilateral. Reciprocal externalities occur when externalities are reciprocal e.g. in the case of negative externalities each of the agents damages and gets damaged by all the other agents through its actions e.g. acid rain in the Europe and industrial pollution. 2.4 Impact Of Externalities On The Markets System When there are external benefits, a market system that is unregulated would underproduce the (desired) quality of a given goods. In other words Figure : External Benefits prices MSC (MPC) = SS curve MEB MSB = D1 MSB = D Qm Qs 9 MEB = marginal external benefits, MPB = Marginal private benefits, MSB = marginal social benefits Figure : Alternative Method of Depict a Positive Externality P MC MSB MR Qm Qs Observation Area A is social loss, MR is lower than MSB because the firm does not tae into account the value of the benefits its activity creates for others by the externality. The firms produces at the output where MR = MC instead of choosing the social optimum where MSB = MC. Conclusion When there are positive extenality not enough of the activity is undertaken by the market system. When There Are External Costs Where there are external costs an unregulated market system would over produce the undesired quality of a given goods. Another way (alternative way) of depicting negative externality Observation 10 Area B is social inefficiency, MC is lower than MSC because the firm does not take into account the value of the damage imposed on others by the externality. The firms produces where MR = MC instead of the social optimum where MR =MSC. Conclusion When there are negative externalities too much of the activity is undertaken by the market system. 11 CHAPTER 3 3.0 POLICIES AIMED AT INTERNALISING EXTERNALITIES THE BASIC ISSUES 1) Taxes versus subsidies which ones are better 2) What form should a Pigouvian Tax take? a) Tax on output b) Tax on inputs c) Tax on emissions 3) What other policies generate efficiency 3.1 Taxes Versus Subsidies Which Ones are Better The basic issue in this case is “should an economic agent causing an externality be taxed or subsidized in order to induce the economic agent to internalize the externality?” The following model by Baumol and Oates shades light on this issues. Let a firm’s cost curve be defined as Total cost, TC = TC(Q) Average cost = AC (1) TC Q Q Marginal cost, MC = (2) TC Q (3) Q Case # 1: A tax scheme, a pigouvian tax, t, is levied per unit of output. Then that changes equation (1) to (3) TCt TC Q tQ M Ct TC Q t Q (4) (5) CASE # 2: A subsidy scheme such that S S Q * Q where Q * is the social optimum and Q is the private optimum. The, equation (1) to (3) become. 12 TC s TC Q S Q * Q M Cs TC Q S Q (6) (7) M Cs MC with subsidy In order to compare the two schemes, we set t = s from (6) and (7). Therefore if t = s, MC is the same in both equation (6) and (7) CONCLUSION a) Since AC is lower under subsidy scheme it will encourage an increase in output (Q). b) For a positive externality, social optimum requires an increase in Q; therefore a subsidy is recommended c) For a negative externality social optimum requires a decrease in Q, therefore A Pigouvian Tax is recommended. What form should a pigovian tax take? Consider a model of externality in production where; Firm 1’s output are: (X, Z) X = F(Lx , Kx) Z = Z(Lx , Kx, KA) Firm 2’s output are: (Y) Y = G(LY , KY, Z) where Z = Z(Lx , Kx, KA) Assume that G < 0: negative externality Z 13 Firm 1 (a) Profit maximisation conditions The objective function is: Max 1 Px F Lx , K x WLx rK x K A F .ON.Cs 1 F Px W 0 Lx Lx (1) 1 F Px r 0 K x K x (2) 1 r 0 K A (3) (b) Pareto Efficiency Conditions Are As Follows 1 F G Z Px Py W 0 L x L x Z L x (1) 1 F G Z Px Py r 0 K x K x Z K x (2) 1 G Z Py -r 0 K x Z L x (3) Firm 2 Objective function Max 2 PY GLY , K Y , Z Lx , K x , K A WLY rKY F .ON.Cs 1 F Py W 0 L y L y (1) 2 G Py r 0 K y K Y (2) 14 CASE # 1: A Tax On Output X 1 P F F L X , K X WLx rK x K A where P F Px t PX PY t PY G X G X G 1 Px Py F Lx , K x WLx rK x K A X F .O.N .Cs 1 G F Px PY W 0 L x X L x (1) 1 G F Px Py r 0 K x X K x (2) 1 r 0 K A (3) NB: This is a suboptiomal solution because it does not generate the pareto efficiency conditional for firm 1. CASE # 2: Tax on inputs Lx and Kx Tax t Py G G , andt Py Lx K x G 1 PX F Lx , K x w Py Lx G Lx r Py K x F .O.N .Cs 15 K x KA 1 F G PX W PY 0 L x L x L X PX F G PY w` 0 L x L X (1) 1 r 0 K A 1 F G PX r PY 0 K x K Y K X PX F G PY r 0 K x K X (2) 1 r 0 K A (3) NB: This is a sub-optimal solution. 16 CHAPTER 4 4.0 THE ECONOMICS OF POLLUTION Types of pollution There are essentially three of pollution i. Air pollution ii. Water pollution and iii. Solid waste Most of the substances, which cause pollution, are naturally present in the environment in low (background) concentration are usually considered to be harmless. Thus, a particular substance is considered to be a pollutant only when its concentration is relatively high and causes adverse effects. Pollution is defined as the presence of certain substances beyond the absorptive capacity of the earth or environment. 4.1 The rotation between emission and pollution damage Absorptive capacity of the environment (3) Pollution Accumulation (2) Pollution damage (4) (1) Emission (1) Can either be 3 or 4 (4) Depends on 3 If: 1 > 3 then 2 and 4 occur (i.e. pollution accumulate and cause damage) 4.2 Efficient Pollution Abatement Occurs where the marginal abatement cost is equal to marginal damage cost due to pollution. 17 Definition Marginal Abatement Cost (MAC) Is the cost of abating (controlling) an extra unit of pollution. It is also known as marginal control cost (MCC) Marginal Pollution Cost (MPC) Is the health or environmental damage caused by an extra unit of pollution. It is also known as marginal damage cost (MDC). The relationship between Marginal Damage Cost and quantity of pollution is as follows. DISCUSSION: “There can never be zero pollution if abatement cost are considered” Amount ($) MC MDC Quantity of pollution NB: The marginal damage does not start at zero level of pollution because of the ability of the environment to assimilate a certain amount of pollution without any damage. 18 The relationship between the marginal cost of abatement and the amount of pollution is as follows: Amount ($) MC MAC B O A Quality of pollution NB: The higher the MAC, the lower the quality of pollution, and vice versa. The more we spend to control pollution, quality of pollution is less. OPTIMAL CONTROL OF POLLUTION MC MAC MDC = MPC cost Total damage cost Total control cost Quality of pollution emitted A Q* B At A MAC > MDC At B MAC < MDC At Q* MAC = MDC 19 Point A means we are spending for too much on controlling pollution compared to the damage caused by pollution. Point B means that we are spending far less on controlling pollution than the damage caused by pollution As long as MAC ≠ MDC, there will be an incentive to change i.e. Market forces will not be balanced. Equilibrium occurs at Q* where MAC = MDC equilibrium is a solution in which market forces are balanced such that there is no incentive to change. Optimal Level Of Pollution Control A contrast of perspectives MDC MC MAC Quality of pollution Q* ecologists economic pollution capitalist For ecologists, ecological optimum occurs where there is zero tolerance. For capitalist, optimum occurs where there will be zero amount of money spent on the control of pollution to maximize profits. 20 Summary Of The Basic Results Concerning Externalities And Pollution Abatement i. Private optimum occurs where MPB = MPC ii. Social optimum MSB = MSC iii. Optimal pollution control MAC = MPC or MAC = MDC Formal derivation of the principles of the economic of pollution The purpose in this case is two fold: 1) To show that, for the individual economic agents, optimal pollution control occurs where MAC = MPC (MDC). 2) To show that, for society, optimal pollution control entails equating the marginal cost of reducing pollution across the economic agents causing pollution. Formal Derivation Of The Principle Of Optimal Pollution Control 1) The optimal level of pollution control occurs where the marginal abatement cost is equal to the marginal damage cost due to pollution 2) Suppose the objective of social policy is to reduce pollution to a certain level, say, by 50%. The optimal policy to achieve this goal is to minimize social costs given the target reducing in pollution. This entails equating the MC of reducing pollution across firms FORMALY Suppose we have n different firms in a large city Let Zi = pollution by firm i n Z i Total pollution i 1 The target as to reduce the total pollution to Z say 50%. 21 n _ Constraint is: Z i Z i 1 Cost for firm i is as follows C i Qi , Z i C i where C 0 Q i Q C Zi C i 0 : Marginal cost of reducing pollution MAC Z Cost of MC MC Output, Q C Zi C i 0 Z Cases of an individual firm Costs of MAC MAC Pollution, Z 22 Furthermore n C Q , Z : total cost i i i 1 i The objective of society is to: min zi n n i 1 i 1 C i Qi , Z i s.t. Z i Z NB : Min F X MAX F X Therefore the objective may be restated as max zi n n i 1 i 1 C i Qi , Z i s.t. Z i Z Lagrangean function is: n n L C i Qi , Z i Z Z i i 1 i 1 F .O.N .C L C i 0 Z i Z i - (1) C i Z i (2) shadow price of pollution MDC MAC Since is common to all firms C i Z i MAC I C j Z j (3) MACi Conclusions 1. For the individual firms, the optimal pollution control occurs where MAC = MDC, equation (2) above. 23 2. For society as a whole, optimal pollution control entails equating the marginal cost of reducing pollution across firms equation (3) above. These principles can also be derived from profit maximization condition as follows: Let Pi = price of output of firm i i Pi Qi C i Qi , Z i the objective function is P Q n max Qi , Z i i i n n i C i Qi , Z i _ s.t. Z i Z i 1 n L Pi Qi C Qi , Z i i i n n L C i Z Z i 0 Z i n Z i F.O. N.Cs L C i Pi 0 Qi Qi L C i 0 Z i Z (1) Vi (2) From equation (2), we get C i Z i (3) MDC MAC Since (3) holds for all firms. C i C j (4) Z i Z j Equality of MAC across firms 24 Vi (2) Reference On Policies On Externalities And Pollution Abatement Hanley, Nick, Jason F. Shogren and Ben White (1997) Environmental economics in theory and practice London Macmillan Press Ltd chapter 3 to 5 4.3 Tradeable Pollution Rights The purpose in this case is to show that when there are tradable pollution rights, a profit maximization firm will equate the MC of reducing pollution to the marginal benefit of reducing pollution MAC = MBA. Where MAC = Marginal abatement costs MBA = Marginal benefit of abatement A Model Of Tradeable Pollution Rights Let Zi = pollution by firm i Ri = the number of pollution rights given to firm i. The pollution by firm i cannot exceed the rights given to firm i. If firms can trade the rights to pollute, let the price of pollution rights be denoted by P. furthermore, let R0 = The amount of rights given to a firm, e.g. 40 Ri = The amount of rights each firm retains (keeps to itself) e.g. 25 R0 Ri Rights the firm sells: (40 –25) = 15 PR R0 Ri Revenue from selling pollution rights PR (15) The π function of firm i is i Pi Qi C i Qi , Z i PR R0 Ri The Objective Function Is Max i Pi Qi C i Qi , Z i PR R0 Ri s.t.Z i Ri The Langrangean function L Pi Qi C i Qi , Z i PR R0 Ri Ri Z i 25 F. O. N. Cs L Ci Pi 0 Qi Qi (1) L C i λ0 Z i Z i (2) L PR λ 0 Ri (3) from (2), we obtain C i λ Z i ( 2' ) From (3), we get PR λ ( 3' ) from ( 2' ) and ( 3' ) we obtain C i PR Z i (4) Marginal benefit of reducing pollution MBA Marginal cost of reducing pollution MAC Conclusions When there are tradable pollution rights a profit-maximizing firm will equate the MC of reducing pollution to the MBA (equation 4 above). This is at the desired level of pollution. Tradeable pollution rights are considered to be an easier option then taxing pollution emission, because the role of the planner in this case is to decide on the level of pollution, Zi and then issue Ri. 26 CHAPTER 5 5.0 OPTIMAL UTILISATION OF NATURAL RESOURCES Optimal simply means efficient. Therefore, optimal utilisation of natural resources is about efficient use of natural resources. 5.1 The Methodology Of Environmental Economics (EE) EE is all about the use of limited resources over long periods of time. Soruce Rogre Perman, Yue Ma. And James Mc Gilvary (1996) Natural Resources and Environmental Economics, Londru: Longman PXVIII “….. the subject is eclectic based predominantly on conventional neoclassical micro – economics foundations, but drawing significantly from developments in het natural and physical sciences”. Introduction To Dynamic Optimization Definition: static optimization is about optimal use of resources at a given point in time. Definition: dynamic optimization is about optimal use of resources overtime. Static Optimization 1. Concerned with optimal resource allocation at a given point in time. 2. The optimization problem in this case is to choose instruments from an opportunity set to maximise a given function. 3. The problem is this case is called a mathematical programming problem. Dynamic Optimisation 1. Concerned with optimal resource allocation over time. 2. The optimization problem is to choose time path of control variable from a control set. 3. The problem is this case is called an optimal control problem. Formal Statement Of The Optimal Control Problem A formal statement of the optimal control problem is comprised of the following: 27 TIME, the STATE VARIABLES, the CONTROL VARIABLES the EQUATIONS OF MOTION, the determination of TERMINAL TIME, and the OBJECTIVE FUNCTION. 5.2 Time Time, t, is measured in continuous units and is defined over the internal, from the initial time, t0 which is typically given, to terminal time, T which often must be determined. That is: t = 0, 1, …..T where t = o : is the present time t = T: is the terminal time 5.3 State Variables How much is remaining after extraction or harvested A state variable is a variable describing the system in a given period in time. Each state variable is a function of time. Thus; Xt = Discrete-Time value of X in period t X(t) = Continuous- time value of X in period t. 5.4 Control Variables Is also known as an instrumental variable. It represents a variable for which we have to choose a time path. A control variable is also a function of time Yt = Discrete-Time control variable in period t Y(t) = Continuous-time control variable in period t. 5.5 Equations Of Motion An equation of motion is a difference equation (discrete – time) or a differntial equation (continous – time) defining the change in the state variable from period t to (t + 1), t = 0, 1 ……T – 1. Thus Xt+1 – Xt = F ( Xt, Yt): Discrete time 28 X F X t , Y t . 5. 1 Objective Function An objective function is a function to be maximized. It represents the economic returns in a given period. It consists of two parts: (i) The intermediate function (ii) The final function (i) The intermediate function Is a function of the state variable, the control variable, and time. Formally: V X t , Yt , t : Discrete time V X t , Y t , t : Continuous time (ii) The final function Is a function of terminal state and terminal time. Formally: F X T : Discrete time F X T : Continuous time Therefore, we have J V X t , Yt , t F X T or J V X t , Y t , t F X t The problem is essentially that of determining the optimal values of yt, from t = 0, 1,….., T - 1. The values of yt will, via the difference equation, imply values for xt from t – 1, …., T - 1 Summary Choose, values of yt during t = 0,…. T - 1 29 xt during t = 1,…. T - 1 xT at t = T Lagrangean Function is T 1 L V (.) t 1 X F (.) X t 1 F (.) (1.32) t 0 Note that t 1 is the multiplier associated with X t 1 . The Langrangean multiplier is put on X t 1 because the difference equation is a constraint equation which serves to define X t 1 . y t for t 0,....., T 1 xt for t 1,....., T t for t 1,....., T It is therefore possible to solve the equations simultaneously. For conditions – time the above problem because t = 0, ….., T: Set of time period t = 0: initial period t = T: Terminal time X(t) = State variable Y(t) : critical variable V(.) = V(x(t), y(t), t) : Net economic return F (x(T) : Final function X f x(t ), y(t ) : Equation of motion . x (0) = a : initial condition 30 Objective Function Max T V x(t ), y (t ), t dt F x(t ) y t , xt 0 Subject to X f x(t ), y (t ) . x(0) a The integration operator has replaced the summative operation Taxonomy of dynamic optimization Problems (Distribute relevant photocopies) The Hamiltonian In dynamic analysis, we use Hamiltonian rather than the Lagrangean because the Hamiltonian is concise, yet yields the necessary first order conditions. However the two functions are related as follows. The Hamiltonian is a subset of the Lagrangean Discrete - time Hamiltonian Suppose we have the following objective function T 1 MaxV xt , y t , t F X T s.t. X t -1 X t f xt , yt t 0 X 0 a........Given The Hamiltonian is defined as follows H xt , yt , t 1 , t V X t , yt , t t -1 f xt , yt It is possible to write the F.O.N.C.s directly as partial derivations of the Hamiltonian From the current value Hamiltonian, we obtain F.O.N.Cs for a maximum which we solve for the optimal values of xt , yt and t. The F.O.N.Cs are 31 ~ H 0 y t (1) ~ H t 1 t xt (2) ~ . X t 1 X t H t 1 (3) T F 1 X T (4) X0 a (5) 32 CHAPTER 6 6.0 Discounting and Compounding in Environmental Economics Discounting is a technique for calculation the present value of a future stream of net income. It is opposite of compounding. Compounding A technique for calculating the future value of a present stream of net income. Relationship between discounting and compounding Discounting PV FV Compounding PV = present value FV = future value NB. Most optimal controls problems deal with the issue of discounting. 6.1 Discrete time Let Nt = Future net incomes, t = 0,1,…….,T The present value (PV) of Nt can be calculated as follows, PV N T N N t / 1 t t 0 T P t N t where P t 0 1 discount factor 1 δ δ discount rate 33 6.2 Continuous time Let N(t) future net income t = 0,1,……., T The present value (PV) of N(t) can be calculated as follows; PV N : T N N (t )e rt dt O where e rt continuous time discount factor r = continuous time discount rate NB: sometimes r is denote by Negative Growth yx xt xt yt 10 t V .e rt r = Rate of decay 34 Positive Growth xt xt yt yt V .e rt r = rate of appreciation 6.3 Discrete – Time Optimal Control Problem With PV Objective max T 1 yt , xt P tV xt , yt P T F ( XT ) T O s.t. X t 1 X t f xt , y t XO a Things to note are Time, t, is not an argument any more in V (.). This is because we are now dealing with present and not future values.Both V(.) and F (.) are discounted, by and respectively Since we discount V(.) and F (.) we also need to discount the following expression in the Lagrangrean t 1 xt f xt , yt xt 1 Therefore, we have t 1 xt f xt , yt xt 1 This discounting is up to period t + 1, because t 1 is on xt 1 Since V(.) is discounted to period t, by P , we discount the multiplier term further by P. therefore the discrete – time lagrangean is 35 P V x , y x T 1 L t T O 6.4 t t t 1 t f xt , y t xt 1 T F ( XT ) Continuous Time Optimal Control Problem With Present Value Objective T MAX V xt , y t e t dt F ( X T )e T 0 s.t. X F xt y t . X o a NB: r discount rate The continuous - time current value Hamiltonian is H xt , y t , t V xt , y t t F xt , y t ~ Where t et t Current value shadow price of xt As the resources get scarce, the shadow price is surplus to appreciate (i.e. why is positive) 36 CHAPTER 7 7.0 PRINCIPLES OF THE OPTIMAL UTILISATIION OF NATURAL RESOURCES Taxonomy of resources (1) Resources Non-renewable resources (NRR) Renewable resources (NR) Metal ore - forests Coal - fish Oil - wildlife Stone - rainfall Clay - solar energy Groundwater NB : Focus is on economically significant rate of generation or regeneration. 7.1 Taxonomy Of Natural Resources (2) Stocks (NRR) flows (RR) No deterioration with deterioration use dependent use dependent Metal core oil timber rainfall Coal gas groundwater rive – flow Stone plant nutrients fish solar wildlife energy Clay 37 Sources function. This refers to the role of the environmental as a source of raw materials, energy, and environmental services. Sink functions: This refers t the role of the environmental as a dumping ground for waste and emissions. Stocks: Non-renewable resources, which cannot be increased in supply within a meaningful, time horizon. Flows: Renewable resources, which can be, increase in supply within a meaningful time horizon. Optimal utilization of renewable and non-renewable resources Renewable and non-renewable resources have different characteristics. Therefore the principles of the optimal utilization of these resources are also different. 7.2 Characteristics On Non –Renewable Resources i. They exhibit no growth or regenerative process therefore they are depletable ii. Depletable resources are those whose stock cannot be augmented in a reasonable time frame. iii. Current use of depletable resources precludes future use. There is an opportunity cost i.e. foregone future benefits iv. For a resource, which is finite (fixed) in stock, the cost of extraction rises overtime. This reflects increasing scarcity and the rise in the opportunity cost of current consumption. v. In response to the rising cost of extraction, the quantity extracted falls overtime, until it finally goes to zero. 38 Graphically Illustration Of (Iv) And (V) Extraction quantity costs extracted Time Time Critical Issues In The Optimal Utilization Of Non-Renewable Resources i. How to allocate dwindling stocks among generations ii. How to re-cycle those which can be re-cycled iii. The transition to renewable substitutes, if any are available Critical Issue # 1 How to allocate dwindling stocks among generations This issue is about determining the conditions for optimal depletion of non-renewable resources Environmental economics has, through the years, developed the following conditions for optimal depletion of non-renewable resources Conditions # 1 Price = Marginal (extraction) cost + opportunity cost. This implies that less of the non-renewable resource will be extracted today than if it were renewable resources. For non-renewable. resources, the critical issue is how to determine the optimal rate of depletion why? As long as resource use continue a non-renewable resource will be depleted overtime. The fundamental issue in this case is therefore how to determine the optimal rate of depletion. The opportunity cost of utilization of non-renewable resources The opportunity cost of utilization of non-renewable resources is the foregone future benefits. Since the resource stock is fixed, the use of non-renewable resources sets in 39 motion a process of depletion of the stock. Therefore, current use of a depletable resource precludes future use. Opportunity cost and optimal depletion When the opportunity cost of the use of a non-renewable resources is considered the quality extracted will be such that. Price = marginal cost + opportunity cost General rule for profit maximization Marginal revenue = marginal cost. By definition TR TC 0 (1) MR TR Q (2) M C TC Q (3) Max = Max (TR – TC) > 0 MR – MC = 0 or MR = MC Examples different market structures 1. Competitive firm MR = d = P ; d = demand Max rule is : MR = P = d = MC or simply : P = MC Price MC d = MR Pc Qty Qc 40 2. Monopoly MR P Max rule is : MR = MC MC Pm D MR 3. Monopoly and a competitive firm MC Pm PC D MR Qm QC Qty Based on the foregoing analysis, we add opportunity cost of marginal cost in nonrenewable resource use to obtain the following results. The case of constant MC price Marginal cost + opportunity cost Marginal cost Qty QN QR 41 QN = quantity extracted if this were a non-renewable resource QR = quantity extracted if this were a renewable resources The case of rise MC MC + OPP. C price MC PN PR MR QN QR Qty Conclusion When the opportunity cost is considered the optimal depletion of a non renewable resource implies that less of the resource will be extracted today than if the resource were renewable i.e. QN < QR. Conditions # 2 The second conditions for the optimal depletion of a non-renewable resource is that the present value of the royalty must be the same in all periods. Alternatively, the second conditions states that: The royalty must rise at the same rate as the rate of the interest. The second condition of optimal depletion describes the behaviour of the opportunity cost overtime. This is the same as saying the behaviour of the royalty over time. Note the following: The net social benefit from extracting a depletable resource is called ROYALTY. Royalty is defined as the difference between price (or what consumes are willing to pay) and the cost of extraction. 42 More generally, for any commodity, the net (social) benefit in a single period is conventionally measured as the difference between what consumers are willing to pay for a good and what it costs to produce. Simply stated The net benefit is the difference between the willingness to pay and the cost of production. Geometrically The net benefit is the integral of the demand curve (the total willingness to pay) minus the total cost. Suppose that the relevant details of a non – renewable resource, e.g. a mineral are as follows. Xo = 10 tons : extractive quantity; initial reserves Qt = q0 , q1: quality extracted in periods 0 and 1 respectively. Pt = 20 – qt : demand for the mineral output MC = US$5 per ton: Marginal cost of extraction: assumed to be constant r = 0.10: the rate of discount (interest rate) t = 0, 1 : set of time periods, assumed to be only two periods. XT = X2 = 0 : Final function The net benefit, or the difference between the willingness to pay and cost, can then be written as follows: In period 0 q0 q0 0 0 20 q dq 5dq integral demand minus integral of the cost. Or simply q0 20 q 5dq 0 In period 1 q1 20 q 5dq demand cost 0 The objective functions is 43 Max q0 , q1 q0 q0 0 0 20 q 5dq 20 q 5dq 1 0.10 q0 q1 10 s.t. Max net between in period zero and period 1. NB: 1 1 1 r 1 0.10 : Discount factor. The Lagrangean function is L q0 q1 0 0 20 q 5dq 20 q 5dq 10 q 1 0.10 F.O.N.Cs L 20 q 0 5 0 q 0 (1) L 20 q1 5 0 q1 1.1 (2) L 10 q 0 q1 0 (3) we then solve for q0* , q1* , * , P0 and P1 as follows. From (1) 15 q0 1' from (2) 15 q1 1.1 From 2' 1' and 2' 15 q0 15 q1 1.1 Solving for q 0 we get 44 0 q1 15 q1 q 0 15 1.1 16.5 15 q1 1.1 1.5 q1 q0 1.1 1" 1" into (3) and solving for Substituting q1* , we get 10 1.5 q1 q1 0 1 .1 10 - 1.5 q1 1.1.q 0 9.5 q1 1.1.q1 0 9.5 2.1q1 q1 9. 5 2 .1 2" q1* 4.5 Substitute q0 2' into 1' yields 1.5 4.5 1 .1 q 0* 5.5 From 1' solving for , obtain 15 5.5 * 9.5 Summary 45 q 0* 5.5 q1* 4.5 * 9.5 Substituting the values of q 0* and q1* into the demand function Pt 20 qt For period 0 For period 1 P0 20 q0 P1 20 q1 = 20 – 5.5 = 20 – 4.5 P 14.5 * 0 P1* 15.5 Overall summary In addition we have P0* 14.5 P1* 15.5 CASE # 1 Discounting the royalties Royalty in period 0: P0 MC 14.5 5 Royalty 9.5 Royalty in period 1 : P1 MC 15.5 5 Royalty 10.5 Finding the net present value of the royalty in period 1: 46 P1 MC 15.5 5 1.1 1.1 10.5 95 1.1 Discounted royalty of period 1 9.5 P0 MC P1 MC 9.5 1.1 The present value of the royalty is the same in both periods. More Generally P0 MC P1 MC Pi MC 1.1 1 r t if you deplete your resources optimally the royalty is the same for all periods. Thus, the second condition for optimal depletion is that the present value of the royalty must be the same in all periods. CASE # 2 Compounding the royalties Royalty in period 0: P0 MC 14.5 5 Royalty 9.5 Royalty in period 1 : P1 MC 15.5 5 Royalty 10.5 Finding the future value to the royalty in period 0: 9.5 x 10 0.95 100 future value of 47 9.5 9.5 0.95 10.45 10.5 1 r P0 MC P1 MC n By growing at the rate of interest, the royalty is the same in both periods. Conclusion Another way of stating the second condition for optimal depletion is that the royalty must rise at the rate of interest. Otherwise if beyond that rate you deplete the resources. Condition # 3 The third condition for the optimal depletion of a non-renewable resource is that, along at optimal depletion path, the price of the resource is equal to the marginal cost of extraction plus royalty. From condition # 2 and for the period 0 Case: P0 MC P1 MC 1 r 1 or P0 MC P0 MC 1 r 1 Solving for P1 P1 MC P0 MC 1 r 1 more generally Pt MC P0 MC 1 r t where Pt price in period t M C M arginal cost of extraction P0 MC 1 r t royalty from the resource componded at the rate of interest, r. 48 Therefore the third condition for the optimal depletion of a non renewable resource is that, along an optimal depletion path, the price of the resource is equal to the marginal cost of extraction plus royalty. Reference Fisher, Anthony C. (1981). Restorer and environmental economics, Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. 49 CHAPTER 8 8.0 Renewable Resources (RR) 8.1 Characteristics of RR They have the capacity for reproduction and growth, e.g. plant or animal population they are also inanimate mass or energy source subject to constant or periodic inflow e.g. water, wind or solar radiation. Things to note: For a renewable resource, growth or FLUX is assumed to take place at a “significant” rate when viewed from man’s economic time scale. For renewable resources state variables are often called a standing stock or the biomass of the population. If the age structure, sex ratio, or other population characteristics are constant, the optimal control problem, in this case, will require more than one state variable. For simplicity, however, it is assumed that the resource under consideration can be described by one state variable. 8.2 Growth functions Suppose that we have s biological resource stock whose size at time, t, is denoted but Xt, in discrete time or X(t), in continuous time, In the absence of harvesting, the dynamics of the resource stock can be described by the difference equation. X t 1 X t F X t It can also be described by the differential equation X t . X F X t t These equation simply say that change in the resource stock depends on the current stock size X t or Xt . 8.3 Density Dependent The growth function F X t is defined over the interval and it is usually assumed that there exits two values. 50 XL < XU for which the following is true 0 0 F X t 0 0 Xt XL X L X L XU X t XU Where X U = Upper limit of X X L = Lower limit of X X t = Value of X in t Alternatively, these properties of F(Xt) may be stated as: F ( X ) 0 if 0 X X F ( X ) 0 if X X - - F ( X ) 0 if X X Where X X u : upper limit X X L : lower limit 51 F(X) F(Xt) Growth of X (2) XL XU (3) Depending on the values of XL and the characteristics of F(Xt), we have three cases as follows. Case # 1 XL = 0 and F (XL) is strictly concave from below. For such a growth function, the proportional growth rate: rX f X is a decreasing function of X, that is, F " 0 X This growth function is said to be purely compensatory. Graphically F " 0 growth of X XL XU 52 Population of X CASE # 2 XL = 0 and F(Xt) is initially convex then concave, in other words, it has an inflection point. This growth function is said to be DEPENSATORY. Growth of X Inflection point XL Population of X Xk CASE # 3 XL = 0 and F(Xt) is initially convex and than concave. This growth function is called CRITICAL DEPENSATION and XL is called the MINIMUM VIABLE POPULATION. F(x) F(Xt) Growth of X XL XU Population of Y 53 8.4 Specific Forms Of The Growth Functions There are many possible functional specifications for F(X(t). The best known are: i. The logistic growth model ii. The Gompertz growth model (i) The Logistic Growth Model This model was first proposed in 1830 by P.F Verhust in relation to human population. When written as a differential equation, the Logistic Growth model takes the following form. X F X t rX t 1 X t / K . Where r = the growth rate of the resource, X. k = the environmental carrying capacity or saturation point. Specified in this manner, the logistic equation is purely compensatory, i.e. XL = 0, F(X(t) is strictly concave and Xk = K. X t K from any X (0) >0 as t , that is him X t K provided that X (0) >0 t Graphically Growth rate of X F X rX 1 X Xt = 0 k Xk = k 54 Oty Population of X Logistic growth model time (ii) The Gompertz Growth function when with as a differential equation the Gompertz function takes the form: X F X t . r Xt h k/X t Where r = growth rate of the resource, X. k = the environmental carrying capacity 8.5 Limitations Of These Growth Models These models do not indicate the stochastic nature of the problem (EL NINO EFFECT) or the age and sex distribution of the population. The models do not show competing or complementary species. For example X F X t . r Xt 1 - Xt / K sY t where y(t) = compounding or complementary species s = growth rate of competing or complementary species 55 Case # 1 . X If s 0 s 0 Y t Y t X . In this case, X t and Y t are complementary species. Case # 2 . X If s 0 s 0 Y t Y t X . in this case, X t and Y t are competing species. Reference CLARK, COLIN W. (1990) MATHEMATICAL BIOECONOMICS, OPTIMAL MANAGEMENT OF RENEWABLE RESOURCES New York: John Wiley and Sons Chapter 1 56 CHAPTER 9 9.0 i. PRODUCTION AND YIELD FUNCTIONS Harvest or yield When a renewable resource is harvested it is assumed that the harvest rate is a function of economic inputs devoted to harvesting and of the available stock. That is Y t H Et , X t where (1) Y t = the production function or rate of harvest E t = effort, that is, aggregate measure of various inputs X t = resource stock, such as forests, fish or wildlife. (ii) Rate of growth of resource stock With harvesting, the rate of growth of the resource stock must now reflect: The resource stock, F X t The harvest Y t Thus, we have X t 1 X t F X t Yt or X F X t Yt . (2) . This simply states that the growth in resource, X , is a function of the resource stock F X t minus the rate of harvest, Y t . Note that, without harvesting, equation (2) becomes simply X F X t . The way the Logistic and Gompertz models are stated above. (iii) Sustained Yield Function By sustained yiled, we mean that X, Y and E all remain constant overtime. Therefore, the sustained yield function is an equilibrium concept expressing sustainable harvest (YIELD) as a function of effort. From (1) and (2), we obtain X F X Y 0 . (3) 57 . Since X, Y, and E are constant X 0 Y H ( E, X ) (4) Eliminating X from (3) and (4) gives the sustained – yield function Y Y E (5) Example Suppose we have the logit growth functions X F X t . r Xt 1 - Xt / K (6) And the following production function commonly used in Fisheries models. Y t qEt X t (7) where q = constant the assumption behind (7) are: (i) the catch per unit of effort (Y/E) is directly related to the density of fish in the fishery, and Y t / Et qX t (ii) the density of fish is directly proportional to the abundance of fish X(t). From (6) and (7), we obtain the rate of growth function as: X F X t Y t . r Xt 1 - Xt / K - Y t (8) where Y t qEt X t The sustained yield function is X F X 0 . r X 1 - X / K Y 0 r X 1 - X / K Y (9) But, from (7) 58 Y qEX Substituting this value of Y into (9), we get r X 1 - X / K qEX Solving for X, we obtain: rx rx 2 qEX k rx rx 2 qEX 0 k rx x r qE 0 k r rx qE 0 k Simplifying yields qE X K 1 r (10) Substituting (10) into (11), the sustained yield function is: Y qEX qE Y qEK 1 r (11) This is the Schaefer Fisheries model In equation (11) qE = relative rate of harvest r = intrinsic rate of growth of fish stock (exogenous). Note that if: qE = r, then Y = 0 Interpretation In equation (11), if the relative rate of harvest (qE), exceeds the rate of growth of the fish stock, r, then the population will be driven to extinction and the yield will become zero. 59 Graphically yield of y(t) yield – effort curve Effort (e(t)) The Yield Effort Curve It is concave or bell shaped. It describes the amount of a given resource harvested in relation to effort. The yield rises, reaches the maximum, and then begins to decline as effort increases. Eventually the yield becomes zero and the renewable resources may be driven to extinction because the rate of harvest exceeds the rate of regeneration of the resource stock. Conclusion One of the critical issues in the optimal utilization of renewable resources is that, although the resources are renewable, they can be driven to extinction (depleted) if the rate of harvest exceeds the rate of regeneration of the resource stock. Note that the yield – effort curve is different from the population growth rate curve: X F X t r Xt 1 - Xt / K . F(X) Growth rate of X k Population of X 60 From equation (11): qE Y qEK 1 r Y qEK qE 1 E E r qE qK 1 r or Y K qK q 2 E E r In econometric form: Y a bE E 61 CHAPTER 10 10.0 MANAGEMENT OF RENEWABLE RESOURCES: A COMPARISON BETWEEN THREE EQUILIBRIA The principles of the optimal use of renewable resources are often derived from comparing three types of equilibria. a. The competitive (economics) optimum. b. The maximum sustainable yield (biological optimum) c. The common – property resource equilibrium (free access) MR TR E Graphically : TC = MC A B TR E* EMSY E EFFORT Note that the yield – effort curve is, in essence, the total revenue curve. This is because, it is from fish harvest that revenue is obtained. Therefore, MR TR , the slope of the total revenue curve. E The TC curve deficits the total cost curve representing the cost of fishing, such as wages and salaries capital costs, and so on. The TC curve is directly proportional to effort (economic inputs) because the mkore the effort, the more the cost of fishing. Since the TC curve is a straight line, the marginal cost is everywhere coincidental with the TC line. By definition: MR TC : Slope of the TC curve E 62 (i) The competitive (economic) optimum Based purely on economic considerations, profit maximization occurs at E* where MR = MC. It is important to note that, the level of effort is the lowest among three equilibria considered here. One model for probit maximum is as follows. Let: PY (t ) cE (t ) Net revenues Where P = price per unit of the resource after harvest, c= per unit cost of effort u X t , E t PY t cE t PH X t E t CE t TR TC In other words, society derives utility from net revenues The objective is to T E t , X t PH X t , E t cE t e t dt Max 0 s.t X F X t H xt E t . X 0 X Assignment State the current value Hamiltonian and obtain F.O.N.Cs (ii) The maximum sustainable yield (MSY) (Biological optimum) There are two definitions of MSY, and these give rise to two different ways of formally deriving MSY. Definition #1 MSY occurs when the growth rate of a resource reaches a maximum It is represented by the highest point on the F X t curve Definition 2 63 MSY is the highest possible yield without depleting the resource. It is represented by the highest point on the yield – effort curve (or the TR curve) Mathematically, there are two ways to obtain the MSY By maximizing the sustained yield function Y F x which Requires that F ' X 0 ii) by maximizing the sustained yield function Y Y x which require that Y ' t 0 . CASE # 1 MSY where Y F x and F ' X 0 Suppose we have the logistic function X F X t . r Xt 1 - Xt / K (1) Simplifying, we get F X t r Xt - r 2 X t k (1' ) From (1' ) we get F F ' X t X t r r - 2 Xt k MSY requires that F ' X 0 r r - 2 Xt 0 k Since we are dealing with sustained yield, we drop the t notation: F ' X r - 2 rX 0 k Solving for X, we obtain rk - 2rX 0 k Simplifying, we get: X MSY k 2 64 Substituting X MSY into the sustained yield function X F X Y O . or X MSY rX 1 X k 2 K k K 2 r 1 K 2 YMSY rk 4 F X r X 1 - X / K Growth rate of X X MSY k 2 Population of X CASE # 2: MSY where Y Y E , and Y ' E 0 Consider the sustained yield function 65 k X F X Y 0 . F X r X 1 - X / K - Y 0 Where Y qEX rx 1 x k qEX Solving for x, we get q X K 1 E r Substituting into the equation Y qEX , and Solving for Y we obtain E Y qKE 1 q r (11) Simplifying, we get Y qKE q 2 KE r To obtain MSY, we get Y 0 E Y E qk 1 2q 0 E r Solving for E, we obtain E MSY r 2q 66 Graphically YMSY YIELD Y(t) E MSY r 2q effort Note that at YMSY, the level of effort is greater than at the economics optimum, E*. Clearly then, the MSY is a sub-optimal management strategy. (iii) The common property Resource Equilibrium (Free Access) (CPRE) The CPRE occurs where net economic returns are zero. This is at E , where TR = TC. Why For E E , such as point A, TR > TC; there are positive economic profits Given free access, there will be an expansion of effort, E. For E E , such as point B, TR > TC, there are positive economic profits (economic losses) and therefore a decrease in effort. This, the CPRE will occur at E , where TR > TC Note that E EMSY E * This is often referred to as the tragedy of the common. The Tragedy of the common Simply stated, the concept of the tragedy of the common says that a common – property resource gets used by everybody until is it of no use to nobody. 67 CHAPTER 11 11.0 THE ECONOMICS OF FOREST MANAGEMENT: THE FACISTMANN MODEL The basic problem is how to determine the optimal rotation period. Rotation simply means the period from planting to cutting of a forest stand (a group of trees) Case 1: Single Rotation Consider the following description of a first stand V(t) = stumpage value, i.e. commercial value of stand C = cost of felling the trees V(t) – C = Net value of the stand e.g. = v(t) – C Objective Function is max t t V t C e t F .O.N .C V ' t e t V t C e t 0 t V ' t e t V t C e t Dividing both sides of the equation by e t V ' t V t C (2) Equation (2) is the Faustmann formula for single rotation The equation states that we should harvest the stand at time t*. When the rate of growth of the stand V ' t , is equal to the interest that could be earned if the net value from cutting the stand is invested at the rate of . The equation depicts the opportunity cost of capital now tried up in the trees, that is V t C . However this equation does not show the opportunity costs of the site tied up in the production. Case 2: Multiple Rotation Given the present value of the stand 68 PV e kT V t C K 1 V T C e T 1 The objective is to max T V T C e T 1 T .F .O.N .C e t 1 V ' T V T C e t 0 2 T e t 1 e t e 1 V ' T t 1 2 V T C e e 1 T T 2 Simplifying, we obtain V ' T e T V T C e t 1 eT 12 Cross multiplying V ' T e T e T 1 V T C eT 12 e T e T 1 Then we add a complex zero to the numerator on the right hand side: 69 V ' T e T V T C e T 1 e T 1 e T 1 V ' T T V T C e 1 M ultiplying by V T C , we obtain V T C V ' T V T C T e 1 (4) Equation (4) is the Faustmann formula for multiple rotation. The equation states that we should harvest the stand at T* when the marginal increment to the value of the trees, V ' T , is equal to the sum of the opportunity cost of the investment tied up in the standing trees, V T C , and the opportunity cost of the investment tied up in V T C the site, T . e 1 In the equation V ' T = The increase in the net value of the standing forest V T C = The interest that can be earned if the net revenue from cultures the stand i.e. V T C , is invested at an interest rate . V T C = the interest that can be earned if the present value of the stream of T e 1 future revenues V T C , is invested at an interest rate . e T 1 Assignment (1) Single rotation Optimize and interpret max t t P h V t C e T (2) Multiple rotation 70 Optimize and interpret NPV e KT P h V t C K 1 P h V t C e T 1 (3) Comparative statics Optimize and interpret When C rises from C to C ' : Such that NPV e KT P h V t C ' K 1 P h V t C ' e T 1 where C = Old planting costs C ' = new planting costs C' > C What is the effect of the rise in planting costs on the optimal rotation age? Is it to lengthier or shorten T*? Justify your Answer. Hints Compare the increase in the net value of the standing forest, P hV t C ' in (2 and (3). The one with greater P hV t C ' has shorter T*. 71