History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 History of Capitalism Graduate Seminar Department of History, Brown University Professor Seth Rockman Puneet Bhasin Chu Shiu On John Delea Zachary Dorner Oddný Helgadóttir Henk Isom Mookie Kideckel Bryan Knapp Isadora Mota Lindsay Schakenbach Table of Contents Guidelines for Participation Towards a Critical Methodology Macrohistories The Early Modern Economy The Atlantic Slave Trade Enlightenment Political Economy The Industrial Revolution Institutional Regimes The Imperial Reach The Corporation Consolidation and Crisis The Liberal Global Order Deindustrialization and Consumer Society Finance and Shareholder Value Scholarly Resources Miscellaneous Bibliography (unannotated) 1 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Guidelines for Participation This document is organized by the topic of each week’s seminar. Ideally, Professor Rockman’s bibliographic essay and student contributions will be added before the Wednesday session, but adding content retroactively is certainly fine. Each student is responsible for a single annotated entry during eight of the thirteen weeks of the course. If a student has several entries to provide during a given week, that is fine; however, the goal is an entry for eight different weeks, not eight entries in a single week. The titles entered on the bibliography may come from your previous coursework and field-prep reading; they may come from your own expertise; they may come from asking a professor or classmate about a “must read” book or article for the particular topic at hand. Our goal is to develop of bibliography that reflects our geographical and methodological diversity. The optimal entry is something that could prove useful to scholars working in different times and places. Your entry-- in Ariel 11 pt font-- should conform to the Chicago Manual of Style bibliographical form, and be followed by several sentences that describe the book or article and explain why it might be interesting or useful to others. The citation should be in bold, the description in normal text, and the entry should conclude with your name (in 9 pt font). Here is a sample entry: Mandelblatt, Bertie. “A Transatlantic Commodity: Irish Salt Beef in the French Atlantic World.” History Workshop Journal 63 (2007): 18-47. Salt beef was the most important food provision for slaves in the French colonies, and its movement from Ireland to France to St. Domingue called the Atlantic into being as a commercial space in the eighteenth century. This is an exemplary commodity study, especially as Mandleblatt conceptualizes Irish cattlemen, Portuguese salt-harvesters, and numerous others in the supply chain of salted beef as material accessories to plantation slavery in the Americas. Useful for thinking more generally about the relationship of distant producers and consumers. [Seth Rockman] Ultimately each entry will have its own texture, but the above sample is at approximately the level of detail appropriate for this bibliography. At the end of this document is a page devoted to web resources like blogs or discussion boards. Please feel free to supplement as appropriate. And the final page is available for a nonannotated bibliography of articles worth sharing (but for which you don’t want to write a blurb). You can also snag an entry from that bibliography to use for a longer annotated entry. And any title mentioned in one of Professor Rockman’s essays is eligible for an annotated entry. 2 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Towards a Critical Methodology Thomas G. Rawski et al., Economics and the Historian (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1996). Susan Buck-Morss, “Envisioning Capital: Political Economy on Display,” Critical Inquiry 21 (Winter 1995): 434-467. Andreas Langenohl, “’In the Long Run We are all Dead’: Imaginary Time in Financial Market Narratives,” Cultural Critique 70 (Fall 2008): 3-31. It seemed risky to define capitalism at the outset of the semester, lest we set terms that would over-determine how we understand actual phenomena in the past. Nonetheless, there are some decent starting places for a definition, including James Fulcher’s Capitalism: A Very Short Introduction (2004). There is currently much enthusiasm for Ha-Joon Chang, 23 Things They Don’t Tell You about Capitalism (2010). In 2001, Peter Hall and David Soskice published Varieties of Capitalism, a globe-spanning volume that argued against a rigid unitary definition; Business History Review 84 (winter 2010) includes a roundtable on the durability of the “varieties” approach a decade later. Two recent essays that illuminate a great deal are Jeffrey Sklansky, “The Elusive Sovereign: New Intellectual and Social Histories of Capitalism,” Modern Intellectual History 9 (2012); and Jürgen Kocka, “Writing the History of Capitalism,” Bulletin of the German Historical Institute 47 (2010). Insofar as the history of capitalism seems to have colonized several subfields, it might be worth assessing the current state of labor, business, and economic history, as well as political economy. For labor history, see Leon Fink’s essay in Labor: Studies in the Working-Class History of the Americas 8 (2011). For business history, see the editorial manifesto in Business History Review 85 (spring 2011). For the political economy of capitalism as a distinct subfield in US history, see Sven Beckert in Foner and McGirr’s American History Now (2011). For “The Past, Present, and Future of Economics for History,” see Social Science History 35 (summer 2011). An article that easily could have been on our syllabus is Randall Morck and Bernard Yeung, “Economics, History, and Causation,” BHR 85 (spring 2011): 39-63. There is no lack of commentary on the discipline of economics and its pretense of being a predictive science. On more heterodox approaches in the field, see Dan Berrett, “Economists Push for a Broader Range of Viewpoints in their Field,” Chronicle of Higher Education, December 13, 2011; or Peter Monaghan, “Taking on ‘Rational Man,’” CHE January 24, 2003. For critiques of economics, see Steve Keen, Debunking Economics: The Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences (2001), Christopher Hayes, “What We Learn When We Learn Economics,” In These Times, November 27, 2006; Mike Alberti’s Remapping Debate six-part series from 2012; the NYT series on “Rethinking How We Teach Economics”; and the routines of Yoram Bauman, the nation’s leading stand-up economist. For the “good” Deirdre McCloskey, see The Rhetoric of Economics (1998). Cultural theory approaches to capitalism can be mystifying, as in Manuel DeLanda’s “Markets, Antimarkets, and the World Economy.” There are some compelling articles in the special issue of Public Culture 12 (2000), beginning with the framing essay by Jean Comaroff and John L. Comaroff, “Millennial Capitalism: First Thoughts on a Second Coming.” On the distillation of vast swaths of human experience into a quantifiable abstraction, see Daniel Breslau, “Economics Invents the Economy: Mathematics, Statistics, and Models in the Work of Irving Fisher and Wesley Mitchell,” Theory & Society 32.3 (2003): 379-411; Bruce G. Carruthers and Wendy 3 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Nelson Espeland, “Accounting for Rationality: Double-Entry Bookkeeping and the Rhetoric of Economic Rationality,” American Journal of Sociology 97 (1991); Marcel Bouman, “Measure for Measure: How Economists Model the World into Numbers,” Social Research 68 (2001). Perhaps the most assignable essay is Timothy Mitchell, “Fixing the Economy,” Cultural Studies 12 (1998). For some recent discussions of space and materiality, see A.K. SandovalStrausz, “Spaces of Commerce: A Historiographic Introduction to Certain Architectures of Capitalism,” Winterthur Portfolio 44 (summer/autumn 2010): 143-158. Potentially less obnoxious than Economics and the Historian is Douglass C. North’s Understanding the Process of Economic Change (2005). Also useful is the account by sociologist Mark Granovetter, “The Impact of Social Structures on Economic Outcomes,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19 (Winter 2005): 33-50. Granovetter is a key figure in economic sociology, having elaborated the notion of “embeddedness” from Polanyi. See the forum on embeddedness in Socio-Economic Review 2 (2004): 109-134. The new book worth consulting is Francesco Boldizzoni, The Poverty of Clio: Resurrecting Economic History (2011). Marieke De Goede. Virtue, Fortune, and Faith: A Genealogy of Finance. University of Minnesota Press, 2005. Marieke De Goede subverts the imaginary of finance as an orderly and rational set of practices, institutions, and ideas. Drawing heavily on poststructuralist theory, most notably Michel Foucault and Judith Butler, de Goede demonstrates the difficulties that legislatures faced when they sought to legitimize financial speculation while banning gambling. Clear definitions that set one apart from the other proved elusive and de Goede show that to date many financial practices can easily be understood as gambling. In fact, what really separates finance from gambling is nothing but the performance of it as objectively and substantially different. In other words it is not the inherent nature of finance, but the discourses, practices, and institutions constructed around it, all of which are historically contingent and more opportune for certain sectors of society than others, that make it a legitimate pursuit. [Oddny Helgadottir] Landes, David S., Mokyr, Joel, and Baumol, William J., eds. The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010. These eighteen essays (including a number on the non-Western world) try to theorize the entrepreneur as a force of history. Insofar as the book appears in a series funded by the Marion Ewing Kauffman Foundation, it might be somewhat self-serving. The volume makes good on some of the promises that Baumol spelled out in several foundational articles on why entrepreneurs matter, or those articulated in Scott Shane and S. Venkataraman, “The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research,” Academy of Management Review 25 (2000). [SR] Arrighi, Giovanni. The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins of Our Times. New York: Verso, 1994. Arrighi was, alongside Emmanuel Wallerstein, one of the preeminent practitioners of world systems theory—a body of scholarship that treats all economies as interlocked and interacting in one world economic system. As the title suggests, Arrighi attempts in this work to uncover the origins of capitalism and its recurrent patterns. Briefly, Arrighi argues that capitalism is the result of an interaction of market and non-market forces in the upper echelons of society. He begins his synthesis by looking to Italian city-states in late medieval Europe (ca. 13401630) and goes on to explore the Dutch period (ca. 1560-1780) and the British era (ca. 17401930). The current era, in turn, is one of US hegemony. Arrighi’s conclusion is that throughout history we have witnessed what he calls “systemic cycles of accumulation”: A reigning system is impaired as the returns to production and trade decline. As a result, capital is pulled out of 4 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 the system and moved elsewhere—where natural and organizational advantages are in place— in pursuit of higher returns. A new system is thus formed and can prosper until its advantages are used up and the whole process is repeated. While Arrighi gleans this pattern in history, he does not maintain that transitions from one system to the next are neat and predictable or that systems are uniform. Quite the contrary, he sees the systems as distinguished by different forms of organization which lend each its unique character. [Oddný Helgadóttir] Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens. Capitalist Development and Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1992. In this book, Rueschemeyer, Stephens, and Stephens (RSS), develop a theoretical framework to conduct a comparative historical analysis of the relationship between capitalist development and democracy. Their fundamental aim is to resolve the controversy posed by the opposite results of large-N, quantitative studies and small-N, qualitative historical comparisons. By presenting a strong statistical correlation between capitalist development and democracy, largeN analyses provided the basis for modernization theorists such as Seymour Lipset to claim democracy as an inevitable outcome of capitalist growth (and also the basis for US foreign policy to some extent). On the other hand, theorists such as Barrington Moore, Max Weber and even Marxists have argued that democracy was a result of historically contingent factors in the 19th century and a result primarily of the bourgeoisie overthrowing the landed elites and feudalism (“No Bourgeoisie, No Democracy”). In a novel approach, RSS accept the correlation provided by modernization theorists but reject their explanation (i.e., economic growth leads to increases in wealth, education and thus democratic forms of governance). For the causal explanation, RSS tweak the class-based arguments of qualitative analyses, especially Moore. First, RSS argue that democracy of the type Moore and Marxists conceived was really limited, bourgeois democracy, with no universal suffrage and that it has historically not been extended by the bourgeoisie. Second, they conceive democracy as a historical power struggle between classes, which varied as capitalist forms of production advanced. RSS basically argue that the spread of capitalism over the past 250 years or so led to a swelling up of the working class. This massive increase of the working class not only diminished the power of anti-democratic land-owning classes but also by organizing itself and forming alliances with other classes, it is actually the working class—not the bourgeoisie—that historically ushered in complete democracy (universal suffrage) across time and space under capitalism. So capitalism has often led to democracy but only due to working class struggle. RSS successfully test their theoretical framework by analyzing the historical class dynamics in Europe, US, Australia, New Zealand, Latin America, Central America, and the Caribbean to accordingly explain the emergence or demise of capitalist democracies. [Puneet Bhasin] Brawley, Mark R. Power, Money, Trade: Decisions That Shape Global Economic Relations. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2005. Though it is by a political scientist and reads like a textbook, Brawley’s Power, Money, Trade is an invaluable book for anybody looking to understand the study of international political economy. Brawley draws on the insights of scholars from when it was still political economy (i.e. before it split into political science and economics) as well as work since then and provides a readable and concise introduction to some of the major models and levels of analysis in the discipline: i.e. realism, liberalism, institutionalism, constructivism and system/state level. He employs each to try and explain certain historical events - repeal of the Corn Laws, for instance. Historians looking at capitalism are entering into territory that scholars in other disciplines have attempted to tread for years; Brawley offers a nice introduction to theories we may use (or discard) in our inquiries. [Mookie Kideckel] 5 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Macrohistories Gregory Clark, A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2007). Kenneth Pomeranz, “Political Economy and Ecology on the Eve of Industrialization: Europe, China, and the Global Conjecture,” American Historical Review 107 (April 2002): 425-446. R. Bin Wong, “The Search for European Difference and Domination in the Early Modern World: A View from Asia,” American Historical Review 107 (April 2002): 447-469. The excitement over Deep History notwithstanding, the genre of macrohistory continues to veer towards the politically-charged exploration of Western “domination.” Most recently (and shamelessly) is Niall Ferguson, Civilization: The West and the Rest (2011). A flurry of books in the late 1990s made similar claims: David Landes, The Wealth and Poverty of Nations (1998); Thomas Sowell, Conquests and Cultures (1998); and Jared Diamond, Guns, Germs, and Steel (1997). To be fair, Diamond privileged accidents of geography over culture, but he was still abused widely in reviews. Ultimately, these three books elicited review essays that were more insightful than the books themselves, as in the forum on Landes in AHR 104 (October 1999) with Donna Guy and Joel Moykr; several reviews by Joel Mokyr published elsewhere; Gale Stokes, “The Fates of Human Societies: A Review of Recent Macrohistories,” AHR 106 (April 2001); Bruce Mazlish, “Big Questions? Big History?” History & Theory 38 (May 1999); and James Blaut’s devastating essay in Geographical Review 89 (June 1999). One longs for the earlier work of an Alfred Crosby or William McNeill, both of whom gave a lot of attention to microbes. Of course, Crosby also ventured into cultural explanations in The Measure of Reality: Quantification and Western Society, 1250-1600 (1999); see the forum in AHR 105 (April 2000). Within economic history, Clark’s recent rivals in hubris have been Daron Acemoglu et al., “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of Modern World Income Distribution,” which tries to explain why the richest places in 1500 are the poorest places today and vice-versa. Shockingly, it has nothing to do with slavery, colonialism, or anything like that. Nope it is simply a matter of “institutions,” a point reinforced by Dani Rodrik et al. in “Institutions Rule.” In a recent NYRB, Jared Diamond has written a critical review of the book-length treatment of Acemoglu’s institutions argument; see also Gareth Austin, “The ‘reversal of fortune’ thesis and the compression of history: perspectives from African and comparative economic history,” Journal of International Development 20 (2008). On a completely different register is Brown’s Oded Galor, who brings evolutionary biology into economics to generate a “unified growth theory” accounting for the last 100,000 years. A much longer “revisionist” tradition suggests that nothing was foreordained about “the West” and that what did happen owed to accident; happened relatively recently; or was a product of genocidal violence. One might start with Eric R. Wolf, Europe and the People without History (1982); Janet Abu-Lughod, Before European Hegemony (1989); James Blaut, Colonizer’s Model of the World (1993); or Andre Gunder Frank, ReOrient (1998). Scholars of China are now at the forefront of this work, and one finds references to a “California School” in light of the academic homes of scholars like Kenneth Pomeranz, R. Bin Wong, Jack Wills, Jack Goldstone, and Robert Marks (whose Origins of the Modern World is the most succinct and assignable version of these diverse but complementary interventions). A concise appraisal of The Great Divergence is in Historically Speaking 12 (Sept. 2011). See also Pomeranz and Steven Topik, The World that Trade Created, 2nd ed. (2006) for another assignable text. 6 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 There probably deserves to be some discussion of a world systems model, now in a nearly pocket-sized version: Immanuel Wallerstein, World System Analysis: An Introduction (2004). A different assessment of globalization is Michel-Rolph Trouillot, “North Atlantic Universals: Analytical Fictions, 1492-1945,” South Atlantic Quarterly 101 (Fall 2002). Can “culture” ever figure into accounts of economic development without making historians wince? Joyce Appleby hopes so in her 500 year account of capitalism, Relentless Revolution (2010). There is a short version of Appleby-- “The Cultural Roots of Capitalism”-- and several replies in the November 2011 issue of Historically Speaking. Fifteen years ago, the president of the Economic History Association, Peter Temin, asked “Is it Kosher to Talk about Culture?” Journal of Economic History 57 (June 1997). The fact that Temin begins with “Anglo-Saxon individualism” suggests it is not. Comparisons between American and Japanese business practices figure here, as they do also in the much more palatable and influential Kenneth Lipartito, “Culture and the Practice of Business History,” Business and Economic History 24 (Winter 1995). Goldstone, Jack A. “The Rise of the West – Or Not? A Revision to Socio-Economic History.” Sociological Theory 18 (July 2000): 175-194. Goldstone argues that England and Europe developed the cultural climate necessary for industrialization by accident. Seventeenth-century Britain and Japan were similar in terms of work ethic and resource limitations, yet while Japan solved its problems with an inward-looking and burdensome government, England happened to do the opposite, importing resources and settling political conflict with constitutional democracy in the late seventeenth century. More liberal governance combined with religious acceptance of Newtonian science to provide the key ingredients for an “engineering culture” that fused entrepreneurialism with pragmatism. While this article counters Landes-type arguments about inherent European cultural superiority, it still essentially assumes a northwest European cultural superiority (and even adheres to Black Legend characterizations of Iberian backwardness). [Lindsay Schakenbach] Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000. To what degree can we reconcile Clark’s and Pomeranz’ diverging accounts of Malthusian limits and transcendence thereof in early modern Europe and Asia? Like Clark, Pomeranz makes the argument that pre-industrial Asia and Europe were locked into a more or less analogous Malthusian cycle, or “cul-de-sac (264),” out of which the latter was able to break first. Rather than attribute this to knowledge creation and cultural mores, however, Pomeranz argues that western Europe experienced an industrious revolution largely because of the fortuitous location of coal in Britain and because of new opportunities for trade and resources made possible by the colonization of the New World. Thus Pomeranz’ theory of the European exit from Malthusian constraints seems to rely much more on chance than Clark’s socio-cultural explanation. Are the two necessarily mutually exclusive as Clark seems to imply or can useful ideas be combined from each? [John Delea] Kuran, Timur. The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2011. Taking name and inspiration from Kenneth Pomeranz’s The Great Divergence, Kuran’s The Long Divergence shifts the focus of economic comparison from Europe and China to Europe and the Middle East. Kuran notes that in the late Medieval and Early Modern period, the Middle Eastern economy actually outperformed Europe’s not just in terms of output and diversity of trade, but in the innovation of financial institutions. In attempting to dispel the prevailing notion that Islam is inherently incompatible with economic growth (admittedly a straw man), he 7 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 locates the divergence that marked Europe’s ascension and the Middle East’s stagnation in the sixteenth century. Then, Europeans began to collect huge sums of capital which forced their financial institutions to adapt, while Islamic law prevented the same kind of capital accumulation in the Middle East. Although often problematic, it adds another geographical perspective to the discussion of the Rise of the West, one that the extant scholarship on the topic has largely ignored. [Henk Isom] Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent and Roy Bin Wong. Before and Beyond Divergence: The Politics of Economic Change in China and Europe. Cambridge, MA: Harvard UP, 2011. Rosenthal and occasional Pomeranz co-conspirator Bin Wong add to the divergence discussion in this recent book which argues that differences in political institutions were the primary reason for divergence between West and East. Europe's turgid political fragmentation in the medieval and modern period set the foundation for polities and individuals focused on technological innovation, commercial competition and the pursuit of markets abroad. Meanwhile China, united as it was in one imperial polity and relatively peaceful by comparison to Europe, fell behind as it did not need to innovate in an analogous fashion. Chinese merchants wanted for the credit channels and industrial manufactures that propelled Europe in the European period, bringing about divergence. This is a refreshing book in that it somewhat rehabilitates the significance of institutions and the state to the divergence question without defaulting to the cultural arguments embraced by Clarks, Fergusons and Landes...-es.[John Delea] Findlay, Ronald and Kevin O’Rourke. Power and Plenty: Trade, War and the World Economy in the Second Millennium. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007. Findlay and O’Rourke attempt to explain international economic inequality by looking at the past thousand years of world trade and geopolitical development. Medieval and early modern trade was essential to nineteenth-century European economic growth. In contrast to historians who emphasize the importance of New World colonies, Findlay and O’Rourke point to the Mediterranean. In addition to providing lucrative trade opportunities, the region also offered incentives for technological development. The interference of Arab traders in the Mediterranean prompted European merchants to find new ways to Asia. For Findlay and O’Rourke, incentives and inventiveness, not sheer mercantile accumulation, determined growth. Limited cultivatable land in England provided another incentive for technological development; the state needed industrial exports to pay for the importation of food and raw goods and the military capabilities to compete with European nations for resources. While Power and Plenty does little to explain why Asia did not experience an Industrial Revolution, other than to cite the usual reversal of Chinese openness in the fifteenth century, it offers a good overview of a millennium of trade and war in Europe, Asia, and Northern Africa. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Deng, Kent G., “Development and Its Deadlock in Imperial China, 221 B.C.- 1840 A.D.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 51.2 (2003): 479-522. In response to the various “why not China” questions—like the absence of industrial revolution and capitalism in China—historians of China, from Mark Elvin onwards, often refer to a “high level equilibrium trap model” in which the imperial Chinese society lacked profit motive for efficiency improvement, large scale capital accumulation and technological innovation. The emphasis on economic incentive and rational choice marks the difference between this “high level equilibrium trap model” and the Malthus Trap model adopted in Gregory Clark’s A Farewell to Alms. In this article, Kent G. Deng provides a more refined account of the of the “high level equilibrium trap model”. He further suggests that the imperial Chinese peasant was indeed an agent who made collective rational choice through military rebellions—an argument that run contrary to both the “high level equilibrium trap model” and the problematic but influential “Asiatic despotism/production mode model”. Deng’s account may run the risk of 8 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 idealizing the social well being of traditional China, but this article does lead us to important debates in the field of Chinese history and provide a provocative answer to the long-standing questions. [Chu Shiu On] Beaujard, Philippe and S. Fee. “The Indian Ocean in Eurasian and African World-Systems before the Sixteenth Century.” Journal of World History 16:4 (December 2005): 411-465. This article traces economic cycles in the Eurasian and African world-system between the first and eighteenth centuries. In so doing, it offers a critique of Wallerstein’s concept of the European capitalist world-system as Beaujard’s Eurasian and African world-system predates the sixteenth-century birth of the European/Atlantic/West African world-system. Beaujard is particularly interested in the mechanisms of dependence between core and periphery within the Eurasian and African world-system. He suggests, contrary to much scholarship, that the coreperiphery relationship relied on exploitation and “co-evolution” long before the sixteenth century and thus did not change dramatically with the Industrial Revolution. This is a long article and there is much of interest here for scholars interested in the development of capitalism beyond the borders of Europe. The history of the Indian Ocean, for Beaujard, challenges the belief that capitalism was a European invention. Rather, he locates its roots in the merchants and citystates of India, Southeast Asia, and the Swahili coast beginning in the thirteenth century. It was, nonetheless, only in the European world-system that capitalism became the “dominant mode of production.” [Zack Dorner] Emmer, P.C., O. Petre-Grenouilleau, and J.V. Roitman, eds. A Deus Ex Machina Revisited: Atlantic Colonial Trade and European Economic Development. Boston, MA: Brill, 2006. The contributors to this edited collection offer a critical reassessment of the economic effects of Europe’s colonial expansion in the Early Modern and Modern periods. The impact of foreign trade on European economic growth frequently appears in the work of economic historians looking at the “Great Divergence” or the origins of industrial takeoff, including Kenneth Pomeranz and R. Bin Wong. Yet, despite its popularity in the literature, the question of to what extent did the colonial world contribute to the economy of Early Modern Europe remains unresolved. On balance, this collection, with essays taking a macroeconomic scope by Patrick O’Brien and Michel Morineau, argues that European foreign trade did not significantly help bring about the Industrial Revolution. By their calculations, the volume and profits of New World trade were too small in proportion to the overall European economy to make much of a difference. Other essays in the volume examine the issue of foreign trade from a national perspective and come to similar conclusions that the impact of foreign trade on development was marginal in comparison to intra-European trade. While the authors, for the most part, adhere to an economic or quantitative framework, they do acknowledge that cultural and political factors had a greater impact on economic development than has often been described. This point, however, remains undeveloped in a collection that otherwise covers an impressive range of geographic and temporal ground in its analyses. [Zack Dorner] van Zanden, Jan Luiten. The Long Road to the Industrial Revolution: The European Economy in a Global Perspective, 1000-1800. Brill, 2009. True to the title, van Zanden takes a long perspective on Europe’s industrialization, contending that the medieval period was more dynamic and more foundational than the three centuries prior to 1800. Despite occasionally pointing to similarities with parts of Asia, he argues that Europe was exceptional in its institutions, human capital formation and economic performance. Participation in world markets, bottom-up institutions (like guilds), efficient institutions (low interest rates, state-sponsorship of commerce), incentives to save costs on labor, and demography (delayed marriage patterns) made possible the intellectual climate and labor quality necessary for technological development, investment, and economic growth. While 9 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 van Zanden’s emphasis on the medieval period may be overstated and his discussion of nonEuropean parts of the world limited, this book does a good job seeking out deep causes of the Industrial Revolution and provides a nice counterweight to cultural arguments. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Topik, Stephen, Carlos Marichal and Zephyr Frank, eds. From Silver to Cocaine: Latin American Commodity Chains and the Building of the World Economy, 1500-2000. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2006. In this volume of essays edited by Steven Topik, Carlos Marichal and Zephyr Frank, fifteen international historians examine the role of Latin America in the world economy from the sixteenth century up to the present. In contrast to traditional discussions that revolve around the continent’s unfulfilled economic potential or the importance of colonization for the accumulation of capital in Europe, the authors follow the trajectories of twelve Latin American export goods around the globe. They employ a commodity chain approach, which assumes that value is created in the consumption and circulation of commodities, as well as in their production. In such a perspective, Latin American producers cease to be only victims of external influences to assume a more entrepreneurial and defining role in their relationship with Europe, for example. In this volume, global patterns of trade rather than national economic policies take central stage, but contributors do not dismiss the social and political implications of economic processes for the different parties involved in trade. The essays vary in time and space, ranging from silver mining in early modern Peru, to the production of rubber in nineteenth-century Brazil and the globalization of the trade of Andean coca and cocaine from 1860 to 1950. From Silver to Cocaine is an interesting overview of Latin America’s economic history and an insightful alternative to more traditional narratives based on dependence theory. [Isadora Mota] 10 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 The Early Modern Economy Carl Wennerlind, Casualties of Credit: The English Financial Revolution, 1620-1720 (Cambridge Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2011). John Haggerty and Sheryllynne Haggerty, “Visual Analytics of an Eighteenth-Century Business Network,” Enterprise & Society 11 (March 2010): 1-25. John J. McCusker, “The Demise of Distance: The Business Press and the Origins of the Information Revolution in the Early Modern Atlantic World,” American Historical Review 110 (April 2005): 295-321. Since so many of the recent macrohistories of capitalism hinge upon developments in the early modern period, this week functions as a bit of a carry-over from last. With next week devoted to the Atlantic Slave Trade and the following week to Enlightenment political economy, I’d like to devote this segment of our conversation to numerous snapshots of the early modern economy in operation; perhaps we might have read the three volumes of Fernand Bruadel’s Civilization and Capitalism, 15th–18th Century. Yet in the wake of Braudel’s accomplishment, studies of production and consumption in innumerable localities continue to constitute the building blocks of social history, while a focus on long-distance exchange has supported the claim that globalization began many centuries before our own. On global integration, the obvious book is Hal Cook’s Matters of Exchange (2007). Scholars like Jorge Flores, Diogo Ramada Curto, Sanjay Subrahmanyam, Stefan Halikowski-Smith, Timothy Walker, and other scholars of the Portuguese Empire have helped make the Indian Ocean perhaps the most important body of water in the early modern period. The Pacific has its advocates among those focusing on silver flowing westward from New World mines to China. Don’t forget the Mediterranean, especially not the prize-winning Familiarity of Strangers by Brown PhD Francesca Trivellato. And of course, the Atlanticists make their claims, usually through commodity studies (e.g. David Hancock, Oceans of Wine [2009]) and usually in conjunction with the slave trade. The integration of indigenous North American communities into the global economy is told most pessimistically in Denys Delage’s Bitter Feast (1993), but has received a happier gloss in the work of economic historians Ann Carlos and Frank D. Lewis, Commerce by a Frozen Sea: Native Americans and the European Fur Trade (2011). For South America, Michael Taussig’s The Devil and Commodity Fetishism (1980) is still somewhat mindblowing; I am curious about John Tutino, Making a New World: Founding Capitalism in the Bajio and Spanish North America (2011). On the Atlantic’s overall utility in economic history, see Peter Coclanis’s “Atlantic World or Atlantic/World,” WMQ 63 (October 2006). On the internal economies of particular early modern nations, the emphasis has largely switched from production to consumption. Obviously, someone like Jan de Vries can link the two through the concept of an “industrious revolution” [“The Industrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution,” Journal of Economic History 54 (1994)]. Still, much of the attention over the last 20 years has been on consumption, beginning with the massive Consumption and the World of Goods (1993). Talking about cool stuff is more interesting than discussing grain harvests. Jennifer Anderson’s forthcoming Mahogany (2012) offers the state-of-the-field. For the Financial Revolution in England, Craig Muldrew is probably the best-known scholar of the concept of credit, while John Brewer’s Sinews of Power and Bruce Carruthers’s City of Capital are often cited on the rise of the military-fiscal state. More comparatively, see the several volumes on mercantile empires edited by James D. Tracy. Nuala Zehedieh The Capital and the Colonies (2010) is the current economic history of English’s Atlantic empire; she has 11 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 a lot of other articles. Here is a recent conference on political economy and the early modern Atlantic. For coinage, representation, and the state, see the work of Christine Desan and others in the “Money Matters” issue of Theoretical Inquiries in Law 11.1 (2010). In The Social Life of Money in the English Past (2006), Deborah Valenze has a nice discussion of heads (royal state power) and tales (the kinds of stories generated by money in everyday circulation). And of course, the fabulously titled “Big Problem of Small Change” by Thomas Sargent and Francois Velde (in both article and book form). James Surowiecki has a short account of the history of money in a 2012 forum on the future of money. Howell, Martha C. Commerce Before Capitalism in Europe, 1300-1600. New York: Cambridge University Press. 2010. In her book Howell recounts how increased commerce affected certain aspects of private life in early modern Europe. The key characteristic of increasing commerce was the growing drive to render more objects into sellable goods. The commodification of real estate, land and other things that had formerly anchored and stabilized various social practices disturbed the equilibrium of societies in various ways. The bulk of Howell’s study consists of in-depth explorations of three facets of private life that were transformed: the relationships of married couples, the culture of gift giving, and sumptuary codes. Briefly, Howell does not see the stress on conjugal love and the role of the wife as her husband’s business partner in many documents after the fifteenth-century as an expression of female emancipation. Rather, she sees it as symptomatic of a new economic system in which an expanding array of objects could be sold and more wealth had to be managed between husband and wife. The result was not only a modification of marital property and inheritance law but also a cultural change in marriage itself, necessitating a focus on love as an adhesive. The lavish culture of exchanging gifts during this period has often been understood as suggestive of an inefficient and archaic economy. Instead, Howell demonstrates that it was the purview of an increasingly quantified and standardized economy, in which the meaning of gifts shifted from a purely social to a more commercial one. This compromised the social importance of gifts and led to charges of corruption when gifts changed hands. The solution was to reassert the social meaning of gift giving by making it a very public act. Similarly, growing commerce made clothing a commodity in a sense that it was not before. This meant that various kinds of clothing, formerly reserved for specific classes, became available to those with the means to purchase them and sometimes articles of clothing were recycled in unintended ways. This new divorce of identity from appearance was the reason that sumptuary laws were imposed. [Oddný Helgadóttir] Tracy, Patrick D., ed. The Political Economy of Merchant Empires: State Power and World Trade: 1350-1750. Cambridge University Press, 1991. This collection of essays centers on the question of why European concerns eventually achieved dominance in global trade at the expense of rivals. The answer: because Europeans either organized merchant empires as extensions of the State (Portugal’s Estado de India) or as autonomous trading companies (British EIC, Dutch VOC). The essays focus on institutions, relationships between merchants and their respective states, the importance of the military power, piracy and privateering, transportation and transaction costs, colonies as mercantile investments (colonies did pay), and a comparison of the Tokugawa Shogunate and Hapsburg Spain (Japan was like England and Spain combined). This collection as a whole provide a nice overview of why and how merchant empires functioned economically and politically (and to some extent, culturally, as there is an essay on the subtle give-and-takes between Portuguese and South Asians in the Indian Ocean by Sanjay Subrahmanyam). [Lindsay Schakenbach] Hancock, David. Oceans of Wine: Madeira and the Emergence of American Trade and Taste. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2009. 12 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 More than a simple commodity study, Hancock’s Oceans of Wine addresses head-on the development and emergence of an inter-imperial Atlantic community tied together by bonds of capital, taste, and trust in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. Madeira is the star of this work and Hancock reveals in formidable detail every aspect of its transit across the early modern Atlantic; from growers on the island of Madeira, through a variety of middlemen, to the wine connoisseurs and taste makers of the mainland colonies. You will learn more than you ever wanted to know about Madeira from this work. Apparently not satisfied with an exhaustive study of Madeira, Hancock also uses the example of the Madeira trade to illustrate his theory of networks that challenges prevailing notions of a strong center-periphery relationship. Instead, Hancock’s conception of a decentralized, networked and self-organized Atlantic world, which he had been formulating in print for years, emphasizes the role of relationships between individual actors away from imperial centers in shaping the early modern commercial system. [Zack Dorner] Cook, Harold J. Matters of Exchange: Commerce, Medicine, and Science in the Dutch Golden Age. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2007. Employing network theory to explain commercial and scientific developments, Cook argues that early modern science developed in tandem with an increased level of commercial exchanges. Environmental and social circumstances in the Netherlands created a class of merchants whose values and questions began to shape both consumerism and knowledge about the natural world. As merchants scoured the globe for goods, information became extremely valuable. It became important to know where to go for spices, herbal medicines, and other goods and how to procure them, as well as to know something about the actual materials themselves. The investigation of the materials that was essential to commerce thus helped give rise to Descartes’s materialism. All of this knowledge developed not from a limited number of elite natural philosophers, but was instead the culmination of local networks of knowledge all over the globe. This is a wonderfully comprehensive study of how science and capitalism developed together in the early modern world. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Jarvis, Michael J. In the Eye of All Trade: Bermuda, Bermudians, and the Maritime Atlantic World 1680-1783. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2010. At the intersection of maritime history, Atlantic history, colonial American history, and economic history, In the Eye of All Trade centers on British-American mariners based in Bermuda and the role these actors played in forging connections between disparate regions of the Atlantic world. Jarvis, like Hancock, employs up-to-date network models to illustrate how, as a result of its self-organized shipping industry, Bermuda became a hub of commerce and communication in the eighteenth century. While the work contains numerous worthwhile details, Jarvis’s examination of “Atlantic commons” (such as salt flats in the Turks and Caicos) is particularly helpful in illuminating how economic interplay at sites on the margins of imperial control actively contributed to commerce in this era. Additionally, In the Eye of All Trade provides useful information about island life and the impact of the American Revolution on Bermudian intercolonial maritime trade. [Zack Dorner] Zahedieh, Nuala. The Capital and the Colonies: London and the Atlantic Economy, 16601700. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010. Arguing against the decentralized frameworks adopted by by Hancock and Jarvis, Zahedieh focuses on London as the centralized commercial hub for Atlantic trade in the late-seventeenth century. The Navigation Acts, according to Zahedieh, provided the stimulus for English economic growth in the second half of the seventeenth century and laid the groundwork for the eventual Industrial Revolution at the end of the eighteenth century. Mercantilism alone was not responsible for the bulk of commercial development however; and Zahedieh describes how weak enforcement of the Navigation Acts between 1660 and 1688 fostered competition among 13 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 English merchants, which in turn spurred gains in shipping efficiency and innovation. As a result, by the end of the seventeenth century London had become a major European entrepot to rival Amsterdam and English colonial expansion under the Navigation Acts put England on the road toward industrial takeoff. While Zahedieh may overstate the centrality of metropolitan ports, especially in light of concurrent scholarship, the analyses of shipping data and detailed examinations of merchants’ commercial practices in The Capital and the Colonies are important regardless of the model. [Zack Dorner] Sacks, David Harris. The Widening Gate: Bristol and the Atlantic Economy, 1450-1700. Berkeley: Oxford University Press, 1991. Sacks examines the effects of Atlantic market integration in one early modern city. As Bristol’s commercial role changed with the capture of Bourdeaux by France in 1453, Bristol could no longer rely on exporting wool and importing wine. Instead, its merchants had to search for new and diverse economic opportunities. Because ventures into the Mediterranean and to Newfoundland were riskier, merchants required monopoly protection by the Merchant Ventures and then the royal government. Competition between merchant groups ensued, and those shut out from royal protection formed an underclass that turned to New World trade in sugar, tobacco, and indentured servants, for mercantile opportunities. Religious and trust networks were key to commercial operations, but by the late eighteenth century, the consumer boom coupled with post-1688 policies increased economic diversification and helped lessen religious and political. While we do not learn about Bristol’s relationship with surrounding towns, this book provides a useful examination of the social and economic changes wrought by increasingly capitalistic Atlantic trade in one port city. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Greer, Allan. Peasant, Lord, and Merchant: Rural Society in Three Quebec Parishes, 1740-1840. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1988. Although this book functions primarily as a cultural history of the Quebecois peasantry, Allan Greer also tells the story of the shift from feudalism to capitalism in the Canadian countryside. At the start of his work, feudal lords exploit the peasants’, or habitants’, labor through the rent they collect. After the French and Indian War British merchants began to penetrate Quebec and they offered new economic opportunities for the habitants as Canada and its winter wheat became one of the world’s breadbaskets, in addition to turning huge profits for themselves. However, they also locked the Quebecois in yet another fiscal hierarchy through debt and credit that proved just as exploitative as feudalism. Worth reading for the wonderful texture Greer grants to an understudied population, Peasant, Lord, and Merchant also shows the spread of capitalism and British economic Empire from the perspective of the people those institutions exploited. [Henk Isom] Pincus, Steve. “Rethinking Mercantilism: Political Economy, The British Empire, and the Atlantic World in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries.” William and Mary Quarterly 69 (January 2012): 3-70. This description is from the abstract: Atlantic historians and early American historians have by and large maintained that because there was a mercantilist consensus in Europe the differences among empires had to do with the different endowments that the Europeans encountered on the periphery. They have also suggested that deviance from mercantilist goals must have derived from the structural weakness of early modern states. The British Empire in particular, we are told, was incapable of enforcing its mercantilist economic legislation. Against these claims, I suggest that there was a lively debate within the British Empire in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries about political economic issues. Far from accepting the finite nature of wealth, many Britons argued that property was based on human labor and that therefore there was the possibility for limitless economic growth. Because there was no 14 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 mercantilist consensus about political economy, imperial policy both in Britain and the colonies was necessarily a politically contested issue. The essay is followed by 5 responses. [Seth Rockman] von Glahn, Richard. Fountain of Fortune: Money and Monetary Policy in China, 10001700. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. 1996. Because of the assumption of a monolithic Confucian value that discourages any profit seeking activities, the discourse of money and monetary policy among pre modern Chinese scholarofficials is often neglected in western scholarship. With a survey of wide-ranging debates, both in courts and among the literati, from the Song dynasty to the early Qing dynasty, von Glahn’s book demonstrates the importance of money in traditional Chinese political and intellectual discourse. By forming his arguments according to European monetary theories, he may be accused of “Euro-centrism”, but in the case of monetary thought, this approach does have the advantage of avoiding pitfalls of Chinese exceptionalism. In addition to these debates, von Glahn goes into various statistics of late Ming and early Qing (the seventeenth century) and takes on a prevailing argument in Chinese economic history—the inflow of American silver significantly increase the Chinese currency supply, and thus brought to the prosperity of late Ming. He compares several indicators of prosperity, especially the price of rice, to the amount of importing silver, and points out that the Chinese economy in this period did not rise and fall in the same pace with silver imports. The conclusion derived from this comparative approach may not be fully convincing, but it successfully problematizes the simple causal linkage between American silver, Chinese currency supply and economic growth. [Chu Shiu On] Steensgaard, Niels. The Asian Trade Revolution of the Seventeenth Century: The East India Companies and the Decline of the Caravan Trade. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press, 1973. Working in the Annales tradition, Steensgaard uses economic data and a host of correspondence to explore the changing structure of the European-Asian commodity trade upon the arrival of the English (EIC) and Dutch (VOC) East India Companies in the early seventeenth century. The presence of the EIC and VOC precipitated a structural crisis in the Middle East between two different trading systems: the pre-existing caravan trade and the redistributive enterprises that controlled it, and the company sea routes. By internalizing protection costs, according to Steensgaard, the EIC and VOC increasingly were able to control prices, minimize uncertainty, and improve market transparency, facilitating the profitable usage of sea routes at the expense of caravan routes. The companies, however, did not transform Asian trade right away, failing in their attempts to redirect the Persian silk trade away from caravan routes. In fact, caravan trade survived side-by-side with company trade in the seventeenth century as room continued to exist for profits to be had by participants in both trades. Structural factors take center stage at the expense of individuals in the book, and, despite devoting two full sections to political narrative, Steensgaard minimizes the impact of individual agency on the structural trends he describes. [Zack Dorner] McKendrick, Neil, John Brewer, and J.H. Plumb, eds. The Birth of a Consumer Society: The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1982. In this important work, Neil McKendrick first articulates the idea of an early modern “commercial revolution,” locating it specifically in eighteenth-century England. While McKendrick is not the first (or only) scholar to propose a significant moment of commercial change, he argues that all developments prior to the eighteenth century were only prerequisites for this revolution. Objects became within the reach of a larger section of society than ever before, and more and more people entertained aspirations of acquiring objects. By the end of the eighteenth 15 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 century a new class of consumers had emerged. McKendrick does not suggest that the desire to be a consumer was new in the eighteenth century, rather it was the ability to do so that had emerged. John Brewer also contributes a valuable essay to this work that emphasizes the shift from a client economy to a credit economy in eighteenth-century England. This new credit economy underlied the development of consumerism and new forms of politics out-of-doors as the elite were no longer able to maintain a monopoly of purchasing power. Brewer’s essay illuminates nascent linkages between commercialization and politics in England in the 1760s, similar to those described in the North American colonies by T.H. Breen in the Marketplace of Revolution (2004). While McKendrick’s idea of a consumer revolution changed the perspectives that historians could take in studying consumption and many historians agree that something happened in the eighteenth century, consensus as to what, when, why, or for whom commercial change occurred is still lacking. [Zack Dorner] Fine, Ben and Ellen Leopold. “Consumerism and the Industrial Revolution.” Social History 15:2 (May 1990): 151-179. Fine and Leopold offer a critique of Neil McKendrick’s “consumerist approach” from 1982 by pointing out the drawbacks of his trickle-down model of demand that emphasizes fashion and social emulation as the motors of consumerism. Rather, Fine and Leopold stress the role of wages and markets in stimulating demand through examples of coal and second-hand clothing markets in Britain. McKendrick’s idea of a consumer revolution remains relevant, however, because, as Fine and Leopold agree, it has helped shift emphasis from supply to demand in economic models by demonstrating how demand (consumption) alone can influence supply in both quantitative and qualitative ways. [Zack Dorner] Martin, John Frederick. Profits in the Wilderness: Entrepreneurship and the Founding of New England Towns in the Seventeenth Century. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1991; Cronon, William. Changes in the Land: Indians, Colonists and the Ecology of New England. New York: Hill and Wang, 1983; and James Scott, Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed,. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1998. The sun and the earth - for humans, for history and economic systems - are the ultimate material determinants. Historian John Frederick Martin’s Profits in the Wilderness, and William Cronon’s study made explicit the private property regime playing out on sections and slices of continent in the seventeenth century. Land for early Europeans existed as “a form of capital, a thing consumed for the express purpose of creating augmented wealth. It was the land-capital equation” that led to destructive/productive transformations of entire landscapes, and the social adjustments people were forced to make because of their actions. In Profits, Puritan “town fathers” – local elites with the wherewithal to found towns – established incorporated townships and chose who could or could not live within town boundaries. Though James Scott could apply to the Institutional Regimes or Postindustrialism sections, his work adds helpful theoretical perspective on ideas of the private property regimes. Scott detailed the rise of codicil mapping – the fencing, enclosing, and marking of identifiable and defendable plots in order to sell, trade and accumulate. First land, now water and the human genome. Many colonists, hopeful to establish their totally-removed city on a hill, remained connected to Europe in the form of debt structures and economic ideologies. For Cronon, ecology in New England interlinked with economy across the Atlantic, and the “colonists’ economic relations of production were ecologically self-destructive.” Colonists buying land, establishing towns, felling trees for building materials and fuel, and raising livestock “assumed the limitless availability of more land to exploit, and in the long run that was impossible.” The story of New England in the seventeenth century had been of human “growth” and “development” almost everywhere, whether driven by capitalist modes of production or not. People tended to utilize “new land until it was exhausted,” 16 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 shifted it to pastureland and then moved to another tract of forest, whereupon they cut down more trees for fuel, building requirements, or boardwood shipped to the West Indies and Europe, to places that had already lived through deforestation and population expansion. Particularly revealing is Martin’s analysis of land speculation and Puritan justifications, ideologies of land “improvement,” and the “clash of public and private interpretation of towns.” Explicit in problems that Puritan landholders and controllers of towns had in keeping undesirables out of their towns was population growth and mobility – early charters, visions of communal space and land ownership could not keep up with demographic changes in colonial New England. [Bryan Knapp] 17 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 The Atlantic Slave Trade Robin Blackburn, The Making of New World Slavery: From the Baroque to the Modern, 1492-1800 (New York: Verso, 1997). Chris Evans, “The Plantation Hoe: The Rise and Fall of an Atlantic Commodity,” William and Mary Quarterly 69 (January 2012): 71-100. Stephen Behrendt, “Markets, Transaction Cycles, and Profits: Merchant Decision Making in the British Slave Trade,” William and Mary Quarterly 58 (January 2001): 171-204. Almost seventy years after its publication, Capitalism and Slavery by Eric Williams remains the starting point simply by virtue of its title, even as its dual argument-- that profits from Caribbean slavery launched British industrialization, and in turn, profits from industrialization made slave trade abolition and West Indian emancipation economically viable-- has been challenged from every direction. Barbara Solow’s British Capitalism and Caribbean Slavery (1987) assessed the Williams thesis in light of a generation of revisionist scholarship; but as her recent NYRB exchange with David Brion Davis suggests, controversy remains. I am postponing discussion of capitalism and abolition for a few more weeks, when we’ll discuss the Industrial Revolution; likewise discussion of the economies of plantation slavery. The economic origins of African slavery in the Americas are contested. Philip Curtin’s Rise and Fall of the Plantation Complex (1990) stresses the methodical westward expansion of Levant sugar production, first to the Atlantic islands off the African coast and then across to Brazil. Other scholars have been more focused on the “why Africans?” question, provocatively taken up by David Eltis in a 1993 AHR article arguing that it would have been cheaper to enslave other Europeans; the fact that this didn’t happen suggests racial ideology trumped economic logic. Seymour Drescher rebuts this in his “White Atlantic?” essay in Slavery in the Development of the Americas (2004), a very good volume of economic analysis of New World Slavery. In the North American context, this debate has typically asked whether racism caused slavery or slavery caused racism. Two of my absolute favorite articles summarize the historiography while also making compelling claims on American history in its entirety: Nathan Huggins, “The Deforming Mirror of Truth,” Radical History Review 49 (1991); and Barbara J. Fields, “Slavery, Race, and Ideology in the U.S.A.,” New Left Review 181 (May/June 1990). The mechanics of slave purchasing on the West African coast have been explored by Paul Lovejoy and David Richardson, “Trust, Pawnship, and Atlantic History,” AHR 104 (April 1999), while new work by G. Ugo Nwokeji and Roquinaldo Ferreira further illuminates the African side of the trade. The most compelling account of mundane marketplace negotiations is Robert Harms, The Diligent (2002), a microhistory of a single French slaving voyage in the 1730s. Rediker’s Slave Ship and Smallwood’s Saltwater Slavery are both brilliant in their accounts of the Middle Passage, while Emma Christopher’s Slave Ship Sailors and their Captive Cargoes (2006) is worthwhile. Ian Baucom’s Specters of the Atlantic (2005) uses critical theory to make the Middle Passage formative in the logic of finance capitalism. Jennifer Morgan’s Laboring Women (2004) stresses slavery as a regime of reproduction and property built squarely on top of women’s bodies. The Trans-Atlantic Slave Trade Database has introduced vast chronological and geographical complexity into the study of what might be otherwise an undifferentiated account of some 13 million victims over five centuries. The essays in the WMQ “New Perspectives on the Transatlantic Slave Trade,” 58 (January 2001) are useful, while the 2010 Atlas of the 18 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Transatlantic Slave Trade offers amazing maps and charts. For the RI dimension, see Sarah Deutch, “Elusive Newport Guineamen” NEQ 55 (1982); Rachel Chernos-Lin in Slavery & Abolition 23 (2002); Leonardo Marques, “Slave Trading in a New World,” Journal of the Early Republic 32 (2012); and of course Brown’s Slavery & Justice Report and related documents. Slave-grown commodities are central to Atlantic capitalism, with Sidney Mintz’s Sweetness and Power (1985) remaining indispensable. Michael Tadman looks at the demography of the sugar regime in AHR 105 (December 2000). For other commodities, see the work of Michelle Craig McDonald (coffee), and Judith Carney, Peter Coclanis, and numerous others in a contentious debate on rice in AHR 112 (December 2007) and 115 (February 2010). This “black rice” debate raises urgent questions of African expertise and technology in the construction of plantation agriculture. Smallwood, Stephanie E. Saltwater Slavery: A Middle Passage from Africa to American Diaspora. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2007. Saltwater Slavery is a cultural history of the economic processes of the Atlantic slave trade. Drawing on the business records and correspondence of the Royal African Company, Smallwood charts the brutal commodification that occurred between the Gold Coast and English America, as African bodies were rendered objects for sale in both African and American markets. While Africans experienced ceaseless violence on the journey from Old World to New, their deaths were recorded in account books in such a way as to make the European owner the passive victim of this loss of life. The journey itself was a disorienting European construction of time and space so that by the time surviving Africans arrived in the Americas, they did not naturally develop creole cultures, contrary to what some historians have argued. Saltwater commodification had become their homeland and it was not until the second decade of the eighteenth century that slaves put down stable cultural roots in America. This book provides an excellent cultural counterweight to detached studies that focus on slave trade capitalization. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Baucom, Ian. Specters of the Atlantic: Finance Capital, Slavery, and the Philosophy of History. Durham: Duke University Press, 2005. Baucom’s book uses a single incident—the decision of the captain of the slave ship Zong in 1781 to cast 133 living slaves overboard to drown—as an entry point to explore various strand of history, including that of the Atlantic slave trade, the emergence of the abolitionist movement and the rise of financial capitalism and the insurance industry. The unfeeling captain went on to demand full insurance compensation for the slaves he had drowned and the legal documents (part of a civil, not criminal trial) show that the lives lost were never a concern as slaves were, by law, on a par with commodities such as chattel. Rather, the legal wrangling centered on whether the captain’s actions constituted fraud or a breach of contract. In this way, slaves were not only commodified but made part of a financial imaginary through which their lives could be used for abstract financial transactions and speculation. In this way, Baucom contends, the tragic incident was an important watershed not only in the material history of slavery but in the rise of financial thought, noting specifically the precedence it took over any moral concerns. Baucom argues that this moral order of financial capitalism has been carried over into today’s world. [Oddný Helgadóttir] Rediker, Marcus. The Slave Ship: A Human History. New York: Penguin, 2007. Rather than examining the commodification of enslaved Africans through a study of ledgers and tables, Rediker illuminates the mechanism for this transformation: the slave ship. The slave ship was the factory in which sailors and captains transformed enslaved Africans into slaves, commodities for sale, through a litany of violent techniques that also added value to the 19 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 captives. The economic dimension of the trans-Atlantic slave trade takes a backseat to harsh and painful anecdotes in Rediker’s narrative. The Slave Ship, however, does highlight the ways in which sailors, captains, and ship owners treated human beings as commodities and sought to derive maximum profit from their investment. Examples include sailors altering the physical appearance of captives in preparation for the market, and, in some cases, throwing enslaved persons overboard in an attempt to benefit from an insurance policy. Rediker also engages with a number of important historiographical debates here. He seeks to avoid the “violence of abstraction” resulting from an over-reliance on quantitative sources, and argues against the concept of “social death” through his descriptions of experiences aboard ship. To that end, this work, like Saltwater Slavery, reminds readers of the brutality of commodification that occurred not only in ledgers and account books, but also on the ships and in the factories of the transAtlantic slave trade. [Zack Dorner] Curto, José C. Enslaving Spirits: The Portuguese-Brazilian Alcohol Trade at Luanda and its Hinterlands, c. 1550-1830. Leiden: Brill Academic Publisher, 2004. This book focuses on the role of alcohol in underpinning the export slave trade linking the economies of Brazil, Portugal and West Central Africa. First Portuguese wine and, from the seventeenth century on, Brazilian sugar cane rum (jeritiba), became crucial goods in the trade for Angolan slaves. Curto shows, for example, that the introduction of foreign intoxicating beverages was a deliberate strategy on the part of merchant capitalists to erode African social cohesion and diminish resistance to enslavement. Through the prism of the alcohol trade, he also discusses the financing of the transatlantic trade and its profitability, the processes through which trade relations were built and the impact of international commerce in the Luanda hinterland. Enslaving Spirits is a thorough and rare study of the relationship between a Brazilian commodity and the process of slaving in Africa. [Isadora Mota] Morgan, Hiram. "The Colonial Venture of Sir Thomas Smith in Ulster, 1571–1575." The Historical Journal 28.02 (1985): 261-78. Morgan’s article offers insights into the economic and political beginnings of the English colonial project by recounting a failed plantation attempt in northern Ireland by diplomat Sir Thomas Smith. Not the first or last attempt at English private colonization in early modern Ireland, Smith’s “Enterprise of Ulster” predicted future efforts by English officials and nobles to subdue Gaelic communities and establish political hegemony in their wake. Though ultimately confounded by bureaucratic difficulties and native Irish resistance, Smith’s attempt is of interest to historians of the early transatlantic and colonial economy particularly because of its professed motivations. Evidently a student of Thomas More, Smith couched his justifications of the project in terms borrowed from Utopia, arguing that the plantations of Ireland served the “commonweal” of an overpopulated English metropolis. As we have seen this is far from the only time that More’s language, if not arguments, were invoked in service of colonial ends. Morgan’s article succinctly characterizes the competing thoughts, ideologies and motivations that accompanied England’s nascent quest for empire. He argues convincingly that the plantations of Ireland must be understood as a crucial step in the development of England’s transatlantic polity and “the expansion of Europe,” foreshadowing the colonial economy and the establishment of the slave trade (261). [John Delea] Sparks, Randy J. The Two Princes of Calabar: An Eighteenth-Century Atlantic Odyssey. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2004. Randy Sparks tells a remarkable story about two African princes as they navigate eighteenthcentury Atlantic norms of race, commerce, and slaving. The two princes are slave traders who themselves get sold into slavery after disputes with Atlantic merchants. Despite their high station, several captains sell them out. As black skin is by this point associated with slavery to 20 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 many their prospects seem grim. What is remarkable is that they manage to use their money and connections to escape slavery and return to Africa. Perhaps more remarkable is that they resume a life of selling slaves when they do so. Their story thus offers a fascinating glimpse at the relationship between capital, group membership, and slavery. If disembeddedness from traditional communities is a feature of capitalism, the slave trade and the princes of Calabar offer an interesting case: Africans were forced into a created pan-African identity as black slaves as part of the process of commodification. That identity nearly landed two aristocrats as slaves. When they escaped - thanks to capital - they felt no allegiance to their “race” to cease trading, but instead continued to act in their own interests, selling those they viewed as others for their enrichment. Is this a sign of modern slavery, or of a resistance to the modern trade in African slaves and retention of old identities? [Mookie Kideckel] Berlin, Ira. “From Creole to African: Atlantic Creoles and the Origins of African-American Society in Mainland North America.” William and Mary Quarterly 53:2 (April 1996): 251288. With this article, Berlin reverses the traditional progression of an African slave’s relation to North America. Instead of presenting a narrative in which Africans were brought to North America and subsequently became creoles, a narrative that Berlin associates with the largescale labor demands of a plantation economy (mid to late 18th century), Berlin focuses on an earlier period when Atlantic trading factories produced creoles who were enslaved and shipped to North America depending on the imperial vicissitudes of the time (17th and early 18th century). Products of sexual intercourse between European traders and African women on the Atlantic littoral, these Atlantic Creoles had access to a unique combination of cultural and linguistic skills that allowed some of them to achieve great personal success as intermediaries. Atlantic Creole communities proliferated all over the Atlantic rim, drawn by the trade networks and increased European settlement in the New World. Creoles were the first slaves of African descent sent to North America, and their status as intermediaries let them retain a degree of freedom and comfort during their captivity. However, slaves shipped from the African interior to work New World plantations overwhelmed the creole population, and the more distinct racial politics that came with them subsumed creole identity. [Henk Isom] Schwartz, Stuart B. Sugar Plantations in the Formation of Brazilian Society: Bahia, 15501835. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986. The product of more than twenty years of research, this book is considered one of the most important studies on colonial Brazil. Stuart Schwartz traces the history of sugar production since the early sixteenth century and examines its seminal role in the formation of Brazilian slave society. Schwartz is one of the first historians to examine the sugar economy from the perspective of slaves and to argue against the alleged incompatibility of slave labor and industrial organization and technological advance. He covers a wide range of themes that will interest early modern scholars: forms of land ownership, costs and profits of running sugar mills, economic cycles, international markets’ fluctuations, use of slave and free labor, and the conflicted relationship between Brazilian planters and the Portuguese crown. Schwartz concludes that the failure of sugar to produce sustained growth laid not in the deficiencies or unprofitability of slave labor, but in fiscal state policies and the dependent nature of the commercial organization of the staple. [Isadora Mota] Breen, T.H. Tobacco Culture: The Mentality of the Great Tidewater Planters on the Eve of the Revolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1985. In Tobacco Culture, T.H. Breen draws a direct line between the cultivation of tobacco on the great plantations of Virginia and the culture and perspective of the men who owned those plantations. Thomas Jefferson, for example, is a major figure in Breen’s work. The weed 21 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 infused all aspects of the planters’ lives. They judged their personal and social worth by their success in the tobacco business. As growing tobacco led to a common mentality among those planters that emphasized personal autonomy, when they fell into debt to British creditors the anxiety connected to this debt led them to join the American Revolutionary movement. Of course, Breen admits that he cannot prove this statement and thus cannot claim it. Still, Tobacco Culture is pertinent to this course, and to this week, because in addition to a lived culture and manner of thinking, Breen establishes that tobacco provided the political economy of the Virginia planters – through their dealings with British merchants and their political beliefs – the vulnerability of contributed to Revolution in the Tidewater. [Henk Isom] 22 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Enlightenment Political Economy Emma Rothschild, Economic Sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet, and the Enlightenment (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2001). Fredrik Albritton Jonsson, “Rival Ecologies of Global Commerce: Adam Smith and the Natural Historians,” American Historical Review 115 (December 2010): 1342-1363. Sophus Reinert, “Lessons on the Rise and Fall of Great Powers: Conquest, Commerce, and Decline in Enlightenment Italy,” American Historical Review 115 (December 2010): 1395-1425. Economic Sentiments won out over Nicholas Phillipson’s Adam Smith: An Enlightened Life (2010) and Joel Mokyr’s Enlightened Economy (2010). The classic book best known to nonspecialists is Albert O. Hirschman’s The Passions and the Interest: Political Arguments for Capitalism before its Triumph (1977); like Rothschild, it involves a lot of quotes and not a lot of context. For the basic biographies of Smith and his successors, Robert Heilbronner’s Worldly Philosophers (1953-) remains viable, but also see Jerry Muller’s The Mind and the Market (2003). One could also consult the essays in Warren J. Samuels et al.,eds., A Companion to the History of Economic Thought (2007). By one account, the most important book in a generation on eighteenth-century political economy is Istvan Hont’s Jealousy of Trade (2005); it looks a little daunting at 500+ pages, but perhaps the introduction is worth a look. French political economy has gotten a lot of recent attention, especially as related to the Revolution: Michael Sonenscher’s Before the Deluge (2007) on public credit; John Shovlin’s The Political Economy of Virtue (2007) on luxury; and Paul Cheney’s Revolutionary Commerce (2010), a study of the French Atlantic that is willfully indifferent to slavery. Anoush Terjanian’s forthcoming Commerce in Eighteenth-Century French Political Thought should be more attentive to the ironies of a slave-powered doux commerce, while Susan Buck-Morss, Hegal, Haiti, and Universal History (2009) and Charles Mills, The Racial Contract (1997) indicate why political philosophy of this era is incomprehensible without slavery front and central. Also along these lines would be Paul Gilroy generally, and specifically Laurent Dubois, “An Enslaved Enlightenment,” Social History 31 (February 2006). Rebecca Spang will soon publish Stuff and Money in the Time of the French Revolution, but in the meantime see her essay in the special issue on “Money and the Enlightenment” in Historical Reflections/Réflexions historiques 31:1 (winter 2005) and her syllabus on currency and culture. For more on Adam Smith, see Keith Tribe, “‘Das Adam Smith Problem’ and the Origins of Modern Smith Scholarship,” History of European Ideas 34 (2008) [this is about 19th c. debates about Smith in Germany and fairly obscure], and the excellent riff on one of Smith’s key examples in Jaap Harskamp, “In Praise of Pins: From Tool to Metaphor,” History Workshop Journal 70 (2010). See also Amartya Sen, “Uses and Abuses of Adam Smith,” History of Political Economy 43 (2011). For where Smith figures (or doesn’t) in early US political economy, Drew McCoy’s Elusive Republic (1981) remains indispensable. Potentially interesting is Allan Potofsky, “The Political Economy of the French-American Debt Debate: The Ideological Uses of Atlantic Commerce, 1787-1800,” WMQ 63 (July 2006): 489-516. Enlightenment political economy altered the meaning of poverty, and one did not need to be Foucault to see the ways in which projects of surveillance and social discipline figured in the emergence of market capitalism. A recent account comparing Russia and Britain is Alessandro Stanziani, “The Traveling Panopticon,” Comparative Studies in Society and History 51 (2009). See also Sandra Sherman, Imagining Poverty: Quantification and the Decline of Paternalism (2001); Thomas Horne, Property Rights and Poverty: Political Argument in Britain, 1605- 23 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 1834 (1990); and Gareth Stedman Jones, An End to Poverty? (2004). Michael Meranze’s Laboratories of Virtue (1996) remains the most useful for the postrevolutionary US. The social history of the impoverished is an entirely different discussion, not covered here. The late-eighteenth century also generated radical possibilities for rethinking property relations, especially in works like Thomas Paine’s Agrarian Justice (1796). See Seth Cotlar, “Radical Conceptions of Economic Equality and Property Rights in the Early American Republic: The Trans-Atlantic Dimension,” Explorations in Early American Culture v. 4 (2000); or Cotlar’s Tom Paine’s America (2011); or Andrew Shankman, Crucible of American Democracy: The Struggle to Fuse Egalitarianism and Capitalism in Jeffersonian Pennsylvania (2004). For less radical possibilities, see Margaret Jacob and Matthew Kadane (Brown PhD), “Missing Now Found in the Eighteenth Century: Weber’s Protestant Capitalist,” AHR 108 (February 2003). If the key to Rothschild’s argument is empathy, then it seems imperative to talk about humanitarianism and capitalism as concurrent developments in the eighteenth century. This is the subject of the famed debate between David Brion Davis, Thomas Haskell, and John Ashworth over the nature of British antislavery. These exchanges were collected in Thomas Bender, ed., The Antislavery Debate (1992). For our purposes the key essays are Haskell, “Capitalism and the Origins of Humanitarian Sensibility, parts 1 &2,” AHR 90 (April & June 1985). Haskell argues that capitalism is in essence a cognitive style. The market sees the triumph of the self-regulated promise keeper, the man who trusts and counts on people he shares no blood, family, or community ties with. Remote trust on a day-to-day basis makes people feel powerful to control events far away, making it harder to be indifferent. Capitalism doesn’t cause abolition, but it is a precondition to abolition. Haskell talks about Oxfam, Amnesty International, vegetarianism, and a series of contemporary analogies in stressing the relationship between what we ought to do and what we see ourselves capable of doing. Hirschman, Albert O. The Passions and the Interest: Political Arguments for Capitalism before its Triumph. Princeton: Princeton University Press,1977. Hirschman examines the writings of several influential European thinkers in the seventeenth to eighteenth century, uncovering their conceptions of economic growth and commercial activity. He argues that scholars in this period believed that the countervailing “passions” experienced by each individual could be pitted against each other and thus transmogrified into virtues. During the Middle Ages the focus was primarily on the passion of ambition, which was to be transformed into honor and glory. As capitalistic practices became more widespread the focus shifted from ambition to greed, which was to be turned into the more virtuous “interest.” This understanding proved a very useful basis to justify capitalism as seen in Montesquie’s exemplifying formulation of doux commerce as a method to keep base instincts in check. In other words, moderation and gentility could result from avarice and self-interest, an argument that presaged the very influential thought of Adam Smith. [Oddný Helgadóttir] McCoy, Drew. The Elusive Republic: Political Economy in Jeffersonian America. Chapel Hill: UNC Press, 1980. Modern social realities challenged classical republicanism in the years following the American Revolution. McCoy analyzes the Jeffersonian vision for political economy, which he argues was the dominant strand of republican thought, to show how Americans conceived of and implemented solutions to this crisis. Jeffersonians believed that the key was to develop through space rather than time, thus staving off the over-civilization that accompanied a nation’s transition from agriculture to large-scale manufacturing (like Britain). In this light, the Louisiana Purchase provided the perfect solution. The new nation would have abundant land and its citizens would remain virtuous, self-sufficient yeoman farmers. These farmers, though, 24 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 depended on European markets, and this economic vision required massive federal upkeep. Jeffersonians went to war in 1812 to secure free trade, and while the war ended without a clear winner, Jeffersonian political economy lost out to a Hamiltonian manufacturing society. This book does an excellent job balancing intellectual debates and contradictions with material reality. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Drayton, Richard. Nature’s Government: Science, Imperial Britain and the “Improvement” of the World. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2000. Modern Britain was just as much a product of “processes of empire” as modern India, New Zealand, and Barbados argues Richard Drayton. In Nature’s Government he examines both the intellectual history of botany and its value to the British state in facilitating the optimal usage of natural resources. As European governments sought wealth from plants in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, the emerging science of botany became increasingly linked to political economy. Kew and Britain’s botanic stations were central to this process as new ideas of political economy combining economics and science spread through the British botanic network in service of commerce. Of particular interest to Drayton are the individual interactions at both the center and periphery that facilitated the development of mutual knowledge across the British Empire. To that end, the book traces the spread of Enlightenment principles, emphasizing the Enlightenment as a global, rather than European, phenomenon by the nineteenth century. While Smithian free trade eventually came to predominate, according to Drayton, a range of political economies nonetheless existed on the imperial periphery during this period. Nature’s Government stresses the importance of Britain’s botanical exchange and uses this framework to explore the relationship between center and periphery and the reach of British ideas of political economy and scientific improvement. [Zack Dorner] Foley, Duncan K. Adam’s Fallacy: A Guide to Economic Theology. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2006. Economic analyses typically conceptualize the economic sphere of life as distinct from the social, political, and moral sphere. Duncan Folley presents how, starting with Adam Smith, the exclusion of the messier domain of politics, ethics, and morals has enabled economists to not only present parsimonious and law-like determinate arguments but also make claims about social life that are self-contradictory and fundamentally opposed to how humans act. “Adam’s Fallacy” refers to Smith’s contradictory notion that self-interest and selfishness somehow transform to an overall social good in capitalist societies. Folley argues that Smith is not only able to claim this by separating the economic from the ethical or the moral but also Smith never provides a valid logical argument as to why this may be so. Instead, Smith goes a step further to exploit this conceptual split by conveniently moving between a labor theory of value to a different (adding-up) theory of value based on a set of beliefs to support his economic arguments in the The Wealth of Nations. Folley presents how others such as Malthus have made more fallacious claims—charity or support to the poor makes them poorer since it encourages procreation leading to a fall in wages—by, again, considering the economic sphere as a distinct sphere, governed by a set of “objective” laws. He similarly examines the basic tenets of political economy presented by Smith, Malthus, Ricardo, Marx, Jevons, Keynes, and Hayek to show how classical and neoclassical economists have all fallen for this dualistic view of social life and have gone to make grand claims. However, Folley argues, a deeper investigation into these claims reveals just how gloomy a science the study of political economy and its contemporary version, economics, really is. Like Emma Rothschild’s argument in Economic Sentiments, that at the very core there is an optimistic hope in capitalism held by economists since Adam Smith, Folley’s book is useful because it shows why economics, much to chagrin of mainstream economists, is “at its most abstract and interesting level a speculative philosophical discourse, not a deductive or inductive science.” [Puneet Bhasin] 25 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Smith, Adam. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of The Wealth of Nations (Facsimile edition). Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976. Karl Marx. Capital: Volume I in 13 video lectures by David Harvey. http://davidharvey.org/reading-capital/. This is an easy one. No article, book, assessment, roundtable or argument about The Wealth of Nations, neoclassical economics, Marxism or “all the rest of it” is as illuminating or informative as reading the real thing. Smith’s classic is a fantastic primary source and a brilliant piece of literature. His understanding of ecology, agriculture and social organization resided alongside a coherent global perspective. Read the long, hefty Chicago version, spend a few weeks with David Harvey’s breakdown of Capital, and only then can a historian of capitalism write her own essay about these classic works. Sorry. There is no better way than to probe the heart of the matter. And at its basic level, The Wealth of Nations can no longer be an appropriation of neoclassical economics or America’s right wing – because they haven’t studied these texts either. [Bryan Knapp] 26 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 The Industrial Revolution Robert C. Allen, The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2009). Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of our Time (1944; reprint Boston: Beacon Books, 2001), chapters 6-10. Edward Baptist, “The Whipping Machine,” unpublished paper presented at “Slavery’s Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development,” April 2011. My goal was to focus on technological innovation and the material processes of making things- issues that don’t come into focus until the second half of R.C. Allen’s book. A more direct approach would have been Maxine Berg, Age of Manufactures (1986). For a multi-century and comparative account, see Peter N. Stearns, The Industrial Revolution in World History (1993) or Gavin Weightman, Industrial Revolutionaries (2007). William Rosen’s The Most Powerful Idea in the World: A Story of Steam, Industry, and Invention (2010) veers towards “the rise of the west” in its celebration of intellectual property. American historians are presently grappling with David Jaffee, A New Nation of Goods (2010), in which small New England villages foster the design innovation and accelerated production that allowed for a middle-class consumer revolution. Studies focusing on US manufacturing include Paul Rivard, A New Order of Things (2002) and Judith McGaw, ed., Early American Technology (1994), which contain a most amazing bibliography organized by industry. David R. Meyer, a Brown sociologist, has written a great deal about American industrialization, including this encyclopedia essay. Allen is particularly enthusiastic about Paul David’s Technical Choice, Innovation, and Economic Growth (1975); and for purposes of teaching, David’s “Clio and the Economics of QWERTY,” American Economic Review 75 (1985) is a classic on path dependency. One might survey journals like Technology & Culture or Isis for new work such as Nina Lerman’s very useful article on the gender and racial biases in discussions of innovation and manufacturing [“Categories of Difference, Categories of Power: Bringing Gender and Race to the History of Technology,” Technology & Culture 51 (October 2010)] or Paul Lucier’s essay on scientific expertise in the commercial marketplace [“The Professional and the Scientist in Nineteenth-Century America,” Isis 100 (2009)]. The issue of piracy and intellectual property is the subject of Adrian Johns’s Piracy: The Intellectual Property Wars from Gutenberg to Gates (2010) and Doron Ben-Atar’s Trade Secrets: Intellectual Piracy and the Origins of American Industrial Power (2004). For the last thirty or forty years, most scholars have encountered industrial transformation not from the history of technology perspective, but rather through labor and social history, a development undoubtedly attesting to the impact of E.P. Thompson. Books that I found especially compelling include: William Reddy, The Rise of Market Culture: The Textile Trade and French Society, 1750-1900 (1984); Deborah Valenze, The First Industrial Woman (1995); and Sonya Rose, Limited Livelihoods (1992). Joyce Burnette’s Gender, Work, and Wages in Industrial Revolution Britain (2008) was the subject of a recent forum in Social Science History 33 (winter 2009). The book I really wanted to assign this week (had it remained in print) was Richard Biernacki’s Fabrication of Labor (1995), a comparison of textile production in Germany and Britain that connects culturally-specific notions of labor as commodity to shopfloor practices. Baptist’s conceptualization of plantation slavery as industrial advances the “Second Slavery” paradigm introduced by Dale Tomich (in relation to Cuba) and elaborated for Brazil, Louisiana, and elsewhere at a 2010 conference at SUNY-Binghamton. Historians had long accepted the notion that slavery was inherently incompatible with industrial production, but examples 27 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 of “industrial slaves” are numerous [see Charles Dew’s books or T. Stephen Whitman’s article on the Maryland Chemical Works in Journal of Southern History 57 (1993)]. Second Slavery focuses on the plantation as agro-industrial space; see Anthony Kaye’s overview in Journal of Southern History 75 (2009). The relationship of slavery to 19th century US capitalism was the subject of a 2011 Brown-Harvard conference and the subject of my essay, “The Unfree Origins of American Capitalism” in Cathy Matson, ed., The Economy of Early America (2006). I take another stab at this in Journal of the Civil War Era 2 (March 2012). The plantation as a site of business (management and accounting) innovation is discussed in Caitlin Rosenthal’s recent Harvard dissertation, as well as in Bill Cooke, “The Denial of Slavery in Management Studies,” Journal of Management Studies 40 (December 2003); Marcel van der Linden, “Re-Constructing the Origins of Modern Labor Management,” Labor History 51 (2010); Richard Fleischman, David Oldroyd, and Thomas Tyson, “Plantation Accounting and Management Practices in the US and the British West Indies at the End of their Slavery Eras,” Economic History Review 64 (2011); and Fleischman, Oldroyd, and Tyson, “Monetising Human Life: Slave Valuations on US and British West Indian Plantations,” Accounting History 9 (2004). Long ago, Eric Williams argued that industrialization’s profits in Britain made West Indian slavery expendable. Scholars like Seymour Drescher contested these claims outright, while John Ashworth (in the debate with Haskell) posited a more complicated route from capitalism to antislavery, as the wage labor economy resulted in the valorization of the middle-class family which in turn resulted in a critique of slavery as violating the sanctity of both white and black families. All of which is to say, the exact relationship of slavery to capitalism (as catalyst, corrosive, etc.) remains very much debatable. But few pieces I’ve read in the last decade have the power of Baptist’s “Whipping Machine.” See also Joseph Inikori, Africans and the Industrial Revolution in England (2002); Nicholas Draper’s Price of Emancipation (2011) shows how Caribbean slaves figured in nineteenth-century British finance, especially annuities and trusts. Mokyr, Joel. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton University Press, 2003. Mokyr reclaims for economic historians knowledge about the natural world from historians of science. He argues that a widening base of knowledge was responsible for the economic changes associated with the Industrial Revolution. For Mokyr, the Industrial Revolution was a Western, not a British, phenomenon. In fact, Britain’s leadership in technological innovations mattered little; instead reduction in access cost to knowledge throughout Europe made the difference. During the European Enlightenment the proscriptive base (knowledge about the natural world) widened, which supported the sustained development of new, "useful" techniques (prescriptive knowledge), such as efficient cotton mills and coals mines. For the first time in human history, technological development was able to sustain itself because there were enough people who continually questioned how technology worked. While Mokyr stresses diffusion of information as fundamental to economic growth, his interpretation is limited to a fairly small “enlightened” elite. It was these men who competed in a market for ideas. Their winning ideas survived, but we get little sense of how the state and the people ensured their survival. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Tomich, Dale. Through the Prism of Slavery: Labor, Capital and World Economy. Lanham, MD : Rowman & Littlefield, 2004. In this book, Dale Tomich examines the making of the capitalist world-economy during the nineteenth century ‘through the prism of slavery’. His approach is two-folded: he studies not only the asymmetrical insertion of specific slave systems in the international order, but also rethinks the development of capitalism from a New World perspective. Tomich criticizes long-standing approaches to the political economy of slavery - namely the new economic history, Marxism and 28 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 the world-systems theory – for providing models that do not account for the interplay between local histories and larger structural transformations. Thus Tomich articulates a new theoretical framework centered on the concept of “second slavery”: he argues that British industrialization sparked a reformulation of slave relations in the Americas which shifted economic gains from old slave zones to Cuba and the North American cotton south. This new cycle of heightened exploitation of bound labor, however, was not solely dictated by the development of industrial capitalism. Taking the French colony of Martinique as an example, Tomich argues that struggles over the organization of work and labor discipline in New World plantations also contributed to the global economic transformation that replaced direct colonial domination as the main strategy for capital accumulation in the modern world. The ‘second slavery’ world is one in which the most powerful nations are the ones who control the economic flow of commodities. [Isadora Mota] Sewell Jr, William. H. “Artisans, Factory Workers, and the Formation of the French Working Class, 1789–1848.” In Working-Class Formation. Nineteenth-Century Patterns in Western Europe and the United States ed. Ira Katznelson and Aristide R. Zolberg, 45–70. Princeton, Princeton University Press. 1986. Contrary to Marxist theorization, Sewell presents how it was in early 19th century France that we interestingly see the earliest formulation of a working class, not by British type factory workers but instead by artisans! The French economy of the 18th and 19th century exemplified artisanal corporatism—exclusionary associations consisting of master craftsmen and workers— under tight regulations by the crown for discipline and internal solidarity. However, internal solidarity did not mean class-consciousness amongst ‘French’ workers because it did not cut across corporations or even if it did, it did not go beyond the same trade. While the French Revolution transformed the political economy by ‘liberating’ workers from under a corporatist structure, Sewell argues that it did not lead to class formation straightaway due to lingering visions of corporatism. It was not until the political struggles following the July 1830 revolution when artisanal workers began to use a new idiom and revolutionary political discourse to articulate ‘association’ and a ‘right to association,’ which for them was inseparable from the demands of “Liberté,” that a sense of brotherhood developed across previously corporatist boundaries. Although, this sense of brotherhood did not transcend across to textile factory workers immediately, the articulation of artisanal worker experiences as reasons for demanding their right to association, now outside of a corporatist structure, struck a chord with factory workers as well. Eventually, Sewell argues that we not only see the emergence of a class conscious all-encompassing labor movement standing in solidarity with each other but also as part of this process, a ‘French working class’ identity emerges by the end of the 19th century. [Puneet Bhasin] Fenoaltea, Stefano. "Peeking Backward: Regional Aspects of Industrial Growth in PostUnification Italy." The Journal of Economic History 63.04 (2003): 1059-1102. Italian historians and politicians have long debated the origins of the economic divergence between the country’s heavily industrial north and agricultural south. Stefano Fenoaltea addresses the divisive issue in this article with special attention to decadal census data and estimates of regional industrial production from 1871 to 1911. What he finds is not a profound difference in relative industrialization between northern and southern regions in the immediate post-Unification period but rather a seeming economic parity. Nowhere evident, for example, is the later dominant status of the cities of the northern “industrial triangle,” Turin, Milan and Genoa. He argues that the Mezzogiorno’s later economic lag cannot be attributed to preUnification cultural mores as some have claimed but rather to these regions’ inability to keep industrial growth in step with population growth. In the north where terrain and geographic factors were more amenable to industrial development, cities and factory towns came to grow 29 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 at a rate that their southern counterparts could not match even at the turn of the century. As a study of the “late arrival” of industrial capitalism to Italy, Fenoaltea’s article is an interesting and provocative piece of revisionist history.[John Delea] Shammas, Carole. The Pre-Industrial Consumer in England and America. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990. Shammas begins her work with the statement that being poor and being a consumer were not mutually exclusive conditions. From that starting point her work examines consumption, particularly that of non-elites, in the two centuries leading up to the Industrial Revolution in Britain circa 1800. Rather than as a period of stasis, Shammas presents the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries as a period of active and fluctuating consumption available to a wide range of individuals.To that end, she focuses on three key questions in examining consumer trends pre-1800: demand, standards of living, and distribution. Both the rich and the poor, whether malnourished or well nourished, were able to participate in consumer culture by the eighteenth century. While consumptive patterns had previously rested upon trickle-down consumerism from local elites, the decline of this hierarchical system in the seventeenth century allowed laborers and servants more consumer choice leading up to 1800, especially in terms of access to groceries and semi-durables. This book fits in with the growing historiography of the early modern Consumer Revolution, yet Shammas also challenges the bevy of consumer revolutions that have been proclaimed by historians. Instead, she emphasizes the slow development of consumer society before the Industrial Revolution. An exploration of individual demand and the evolution of consumer choice form the core of Shammas’ work; however, she also addresses larger questions of consumer demand’s influence on the early modern British state. The British government increasingly came to rely on revenues from import duties, excises, and taxes; and trade became a key justification for imperial expansion in this period. [Zack Dorner] David, Paul A. “Clio and the Economics of QWERTY.” American Economic Review 75 (1985): 332-338. David uses the development of the QWERTY keyboard arrangement as an example of the principle of path-dependency, a sequence of economic changes in which “important influences upon the eventual outcome can be exerted by temporally remote events, including happenings dominated by chance elements rather than systematic forces.” Path dependencies are important to understand not least because they subvert common methods for understanding history and economics: they do not lend themselves to rational analysis or modeling. The story of the QWERTY arrangement’s popularity, in spite of it being demonstrably less efficient than other arrangements, reveals that it resulted from “technical interrelatedness”, “economies of scale”, and “quasi-irreversibility of investment.” Translated from econo-speak this means that the QWERTY setup was invented to get around early technological impediments, mass produced by a complex web of connected producers in that form and, from that point on, preserved because it had been invested in heavily by both consumers and producers. [Oddný Helgadóttir] Rood, Daniel. “Plantation Technocrats: A Social History of Knowledge in the Slaveholding Atlantic World, 1830-1865.” Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Irvine, 2010. This is a fascinating dissertation that explores how industrial knowledge was produced in nineteenth-century slave societies. Rood focuses on transnational networks of “industrial experts” in the U.S. South, Cuba and Brazil and, in so doing, expands the sociology of the plantation to include “plantation technocrats” such as chemists, machinists, engineers, and statisticians alongside slaves. Rood’s work challenges scholars to revise the role of slavery in the development of industrial capitalism. Arguing that plantations were also sites for the 30 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 development of new sciences of capitalist commodity production, Rood creatively demonstrates how slavery needs to be understood not as a precedent to, but rather as an integral part of capitalism’s maturity. [Isadora Mota] Hoppit, Julian. Risk and Failure in English Business 1700-1800. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987. Hoppit’s principal goals here are twofold. First, he identifies the study of bankruptcy as a means to add complexity to narratives of economic growth, decay, and structural change in eighteenth-century England. As Hoppit demonstrates, rapidly developing sectors of the English economy, such as overseas trade and the cotton and woolen industries, saw a rise in bankruptcy in the eighteenth century as businessmen began to take more risks and competition became more intense. A history of bankruptcy then, suggests Hoppit, helps clarify the close relationship between failure and growth in the long process of capitalist development. Second, Hoppit identifies businessmen (distributors), not producers or consumers, as active agents of change who linked disparate parts of the economy. Throughout the book Hoppit pays particular attention to the risk avoidance strategies and speculation tactics that shaped competition in English business. Ultimately, the narrative of industrial or capitalist development is not a story of heroes like Wedgwood and Arkwright, but rather a series of mistakes, missed opportunities, and failures. What better way to capture this tortuous path than through an exploration of bankruptcy and failure. [Zack Dorner] Genovese, Eugene. The Political Economy of Slavery: Studies in the Economy and Society of the Slave South. New York: Vintage Books, 1967. It does not matter whether he was wrong or right, I feel it is my duty to bring a critical scholar and his classic oeuvre back into the conversation about slavery and capitalism. If students of political economy and slavery should still read Eric Williams, then certainly Eugene Genovese plays a role in our education. His Roll, Jordan, Roll may have overplayed culture-building and slave agency within slave society, at times making slavery seem a viable way of life for slaves. But his work overall, including Fruits of Merchant Capital: Slavery and Bourgeois Property in the Rise and Expansion of Capitalism; The Mind of the Master Class: History and Faith in the Southern Slaveholders’ Worldview; The Political Economy of Slavery, and The World the Slaveholders Made: Two Essays in Interpretation, together provide a more comprehensive understanding of the entire, holistic story of slavery embedded in larger economic and social systems. He argued in The Political Economy of Slavery that southern plantation slavery was incompatible with expanding market capitalism. Today scholars recognize the North and South within a growing Atlantic capitalism system: we note connections between New England mills, New York money, and southern-grown cotton. This new perspective is excellent, of course. But Genovese’s thinking, and his critique, cannot be ignored. Genovese’s study detailed many of the convergences discussed in the history of capitalism seminar, namely political economy of capitalism, state power, resource exploitation, and global connections. He wrote that comprehending a “fully developed capitalist system,” required “full attention to the role of politics, and especially state power, in assuring the ruling class an adequate command over its resources, including labor, and an adequate share of the international market.” Furthermore, he highlighted that everything in cotton-commodity production was tied to sun, soil, growth, and movement. Note but one example, especially the chapter “Cotton, Slavery, and Soil Exhaustion.” He wrote that “Slavery and the plantation system led to agricultural metthods that depleted the soil. The frontier methods of the free states yielded similar results, but slavery forced the South into continued dependence upon exploitative methods after the frontier had passed further west. It prevented reclamation of worn- out lands. The plantations were much too large to fertilize easily. Lack of markets and poor care of animals by slaves made it impossible to accumulate sufficient manure. The low level of capital accumulation made the purchase of 31 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 adequate quantities of commercial fertilizer unthinkable. Planters could not practice proper crop rotation, for the pressure of the credit system kept most available land in cotton, and the labor force could not easily be assigned to the required tasks without excessive costs of supervision” Add this particular insight to his study of emerging cities such as Atlanta, planter fears of poor whites, and the particularities of southern railroad construction and those studying capitalism begin to understand more about the difficulties of a North-South capitalist system. [Bryan Knapp] 32 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Institutional Regimes Karen Orren, Belated Feudalism: Labor, the Law, and Liberal Development in the United States (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991). Naomi Lamoreaux and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, “Legal Regime and Contractual Flexibility: A Comparison of Business’s Organizational Choices in France and the United States during the Era of Industrialization,” American Law and Economics Review 7 (Spring 2005): 28-61. Colleen Dunlavy, “Mirror Images: Political Structure and Early Railroad Policy in the United States and Prussia,” Studies in American Political Development 5 (Spring 1991): 1-35. This week’s other contenders were Morton J. Horowitz’s classic Transformation of American Law (1977) [see this useful appraisal on eh.net] or the recent-- and massive-- Christopher Tomlins, Freedom Bound: Law, Labor, and Civic Identity in Colonizing English America, 1580-1865 (2010). Belated Feudalism is a seminal text in American Political Development (APD), the historically-minded subfield of political science associated with Orren and Stephen Skowronek (see their 2004 book), Theda Skocpol, and the journal Studies in American Political Development. The focus on legal regimes and the state’s administrative capacity connects this conversation to the New Institutional Economics, an economics subfield attentive to rules, customs, and norms that govern transactions. Only within the last few years has “political economy” become the umbrella term for historians studying the structures of capitalism with the basic assumption that markets don’t exist in a vacuum. For the American discussion, see Richard John et al. in Journal of Policy History 18 (2006) [reprinted as a book entitled Ruling Passions in 2010] and John et al. in the “Bringing Political Economy Back In” forum in Enterprise & Society 9 ( September 2008). Robin Einhorn’s two books-- one on property and one on taxation-- are exemplary. William Novak’s People’s Welfare (1996) demolishes the premise of a nineteenth-century laissez-faire state, with particular attention to municipal marketplace regulation. Brian Balogh’s A Government Out of Sight (2009) also writes the national government back into the story. See also the “Sanctity of Property in American Economic History” by the U-Mass economist Gerald Friedman or Naomi Lamoreaux’s “The Mystery of Property Rights” in Journal of Economic History 71 (2011). The study of capitalism in the nineteenth-century US has gone through several incarnations: a 1970s and 1980s “transition to capitalism” debate, a 1990s and 2000s “Market Revolution” framework, and now “political economy of capitalism.” The new book to consult is Michael Zakim and Gary Kornblith, eds., Capitalism Takes Command (2012). I would be delighted to see some accessible books written on banking and finance, joining Stephen Mihm’s Nation of Counterfeiters (2007) and Jane Kamensky’s Exchange Artist (2008). These books, along with Scott Sandage’s Born Losers (2005) and Edward Balleisen’s Navigating Failure (2001), have made failure as key as success to understanding the contours of capitalism. Sharon Murphy’s Investing in Life (2010) considers the financial dimension of the life insurance industry; while John Fabian Witt and Jamie Bronstein have explored tort law related to workplace injuries. Caitlin Rosenthal has a great Common-place essay on accounting and the culture of capitalism. The upcoming Capitalism by Gaslight conference captures the current moment in the scholarship. The rise of credit reporting in this era is a key topic: Hartmut Berghoff, “Civilizing Capitalism? The Beginning of Credit Rating in the United States and Germany, Bulletin of the GHI 45 (2009); Josh Lauer, “From Rumor to Written Record: Credit Reporting and the Invention of Financial Identity in Nineteenth-Century America,” Technology and Culture 49 (2008). 33 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Drawing upon Belated Feudalism, labor historians have devoted much attention to constraints on “free labor” and perhaps the impossibility of the term itself. Marcel van der Linden’s Workers of the World (2008) is fantastic, as were the essays that he and Tom Brass edited as Free and Unfree Labour (1997). Stanley Engerman’s 1999 volume Terms of Labor also explores the slippery terrain of labor status. Robert Steinfeld’s Invention of Free Labor (1991) and Contract, Coercion, and Free Labor (2001) are both very useful, especially the latter’s comparison of British and American enforcement mechanisms. Perhaps the smartest book about nineteenthcentury wage labor is Amy Dru Stanley’s From Bondage to Contract: Wage Labor, Marriage, and the Market in the Age of Slave Emancipation (1998). Railroads must occupy a key place in the history of capitalism. They were the original topic of cliometric research, exemplified by Robert Fogel’s 1964 book and central to the notion of a “transportation revolution” that “collapsed time and space” in economic life. See the forum on British, French, and US railroads in Social Science History 34 (summer 2010). William Cronon’s Nature’s Metropolis (1991) remains the best book to connect transportation technology and legal regimes to landscape. For the most recent assessment of the US “transportation revolution” and its political consequences, see John J. Binder, “The Transportation Revolution and Antebellum Sectional Disagreement,” Social Science History 35 (spring 2011). North, Douglass C., and Barry R. Weingast. "Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England." The Journal of Economic History 49, no. 4 (1989): 803-832. A key argument of institutional economists, especially new institutionalists like North and Weingast, is that efficient institutions (formal and informal rules) lead to economic growth because they reduce the costs—transaction costs—associated with the inherent uncertainties of economic exchange, particularly impersonal exchange. North and Weingast present how prior to the Glorious Revolution, the Crown of England funded its expenses by regularly abusing its powers and the common law system to arbitrarily tax and default on loans from wealthy parliamentarians and members of society. Not only was the period leading upto the Glorious Revolution rife with high transaction costs due to the lack of credible institutions but also it was period of several fiscal crises. The growing discontent with the monarchy and its culmination in the Glorious Revolution led to significant political and institutional changes that also ushered in a fiscal revolution. North and Weigast argue that the containment of the monarchy’s powers, the ascendancy of the parliament, and the emergence of a new fiscal system with predictable taxation rules under the control of the parliament instituted a separation of powers such that a balance of power between the monarchy and the parliament kept the polity and government in check. What followed was a representative government that could not only establish rules but also make credible commitments to enforcing rules, leading to a relatively efficient economy with lower transaction costs. North and Weingast demonstrate how England recovered from its fiscal crisis quickly post the revolution, and how the institutional changes contributed to the emergence of efficient capital markets—a cornerstone of economic growth. [Puneet Bhasin] Bortz, Jeff and Stephen H. Haber (eds). The Mexican Economy, 1870-1930: Essays on the Economic History of Institutions, Revolution, and Growth. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2002. The contributors to this anthology of ten essays employ theoretical insights from the New Institutional Economics as well as traditional archival methods in a study of institutional change and economical performance in Mexico at the turn of the twentieth century. The book focuses mostly on the reforms implemented during the Porfirio Díaz dictatorship (1876-1911), which reignited economic growth amidst grave political instability in the country. The authors demonstrate that state interventionism benefited only a privileged group of “asset holders” 34 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 by restricting entry into the banking system and by artificially protecting industries in favor of oligopolies. Economic growth, therefore, came at the cost of democracy and in detriment of the rest of society, transforming in its path the country’s baking system, foreign trade, property rights and labor relations. The Mexican Economy also addresses the changes ushered in by the Mexican Revolution (1911-17), and ends with a brief overview of the immediate postrevolutionary period (1917-30). Chapter 9 by Aurora Gómez-Galvarriato is an especially interesting example of econometrics applied to Latin American labor history. She examines capital-labor relations in the Mexican textile industry from 1900 to 1930, and details the increase in workers’ legal power during the revolutionary period. In so doing, Gómez-Galvarriato compiles the first index of real wages for this period of Mexican history. The Mexican Economy concludes with an essay by Stephen H. Harber, in which he offers the theoretical concept of ‘crony capitalism’ to describe the oligarchic republic model finally prevalent in Mexico, one in which corporate privileges prevented the establishment of a credible and competitive market structure in the beginning of the twentieth century. [Isadora Mota] Montgomery, David. Citizen Worker: The Experience of Workers in the United States with Democracy and the Free Market during the Nineteenth Century. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994. Montgomery sets out to uncover what advantages political democracy afforded workers in the nineteenth-century United States in comparison to those in the Old World. Working people (and really, he means white men) sought to use their access to the powers of government and to vibrant associational culture to preserve a community of welfare and to achieve a sense of democratic civil identity. Yet social priorities were set by those whose accumulated wealth enabled them to set the terms of production and whose interests were supported by the coercive power of the police, armed forces and the judiciary. Essentially, workers traded blatant domination to subtle oppression in the form of commodity exchange. Democracy could only do so much to save workers from institutions that worked against them in the “free” market. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Beales, Derek Edward Dawson, and Eugenio F. Biagini. "Free Trade, Globalization and the Audit of Unification, 1863-76." The Risorgimento and the Unification of Italy. Harlow: Longman, 2002. 163-75. This short chapter of Beales’ and Biagini’s book focuses on the economic justifications of Italian unification and the problems faced by Piedmontese liberals in attempting to impose an economic regime on the vastly incongruous regional economies of Italy. Of special interest to the authors are the “anti-liberal” and heavily state-funded development of the Italian rail system and the effect this process had on the “internal othering” of the Mezzogiorno in the perception of northern elites. Far from solving all of the country’s economic weaknesses, the Piedmontese right’s emphasis on free trade capitalism had occasionally disastrous effects on the artisan-based industries of the South which had previously survived on high tariff protection in the Bourbon regime. Echoing the opinions of many previous authors Beales and Biagini characterize Italy’s economic unification/liberalization as a period of missed opportunities aggravated by the Piedmont state’s inability to subordinate nationalistic state-building ideology to the particular needs of regional economies especially in the south. The rhetoric of capitalists in Milan and Turin notwithstanding, Italy’s economic troubles persisted in the face of exposure to a global free market, as indicated by the Italian government’s later sale of nationalized railroads and lands previously confiscated from the Church. [John Delea] Sklansky, Jeffrey P. The Soul’s Economy: Market Society and Selfhood in American Thought, 1820-1920. UNC Press, 2002. How did the American democratic ideal shift from Jefferson’s nation of yeomen farmers to a 35 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 collective meld of opinions bound by a similar culture? Why has it been more palatable for the past thirty years for leftist academics to discuss identity politics than land redistribution schemes? And what does the industrial revolution have to do with any of it? Sklansky’s ambitious intellectual history aims to answer all these questions. He sees in the phenomenon of the last generation many links to a change in discourse that took place over the course of the nineteenth century too. As the industrial revolution transformed the American economy from one based on artisan production by landowners to one of renting wage-earners, Sklansky argues that prominent thinkers redefined the basis of the American polity. They did so by moving away from the discourse of political economy to that of social psychology. The result was that the right to political participation and self-hood that had once been linked to possession of property faded into a world in which democratic participation meant voicing opinions and being linked together with people culturally - or as he uses the term “psychically.” Tracing the work of romantics like Emerson and sociologists like George Hughes, Sklansky’s book attempts to provide one answer to the question of why even left-leaning Americans have often accepted the argument that right to participation in the polity is a more important marker of equality than the right to property. [Mookie Kideckel] Klubock, Miller. Contested Communities: Class, Gender, and Politics in Chile's El Teniente Copper Mine, 1904- 1951. Durham and London: Duke University Press, 1998. Klubock tells the story of how a labor force is wrought through an interaction of corporate, state, and personal interests, revealing much about labor processes, gendered identities, and corporate welfare initiatives in the process. In the early years of the twentieth century the Chilean state granted the American Braden Copper Company the right to set up copper mines in Chile’s rural El Teniente. The company, however, struggled to find a stable work force to keep the very lucrative business running smoothly. In an attempt to create such a workforce the company tried to make local workers, which were considered wayward and unreliable, to marry and conform to a set of moral values such as teetotaling and monogamy. Family allowances and social privileges, many of them aimed at women, were used as incentives. These initiatives had little impact and both the miners and single women flouted disciplinary measures until the onset of the Great Depression, when the precarious economic situation forced them to abide by company policies. In the following decades the “stable” family patterns that the company had promoted became prevalent among workers, but the result was not always as the company had desired. Mining families soon began to work together to better the position of miners through unionisation, strikes, and protest. Such initiatives were fueled by the “intensely masculine” culture of the miners. Moreover, the women, most of which had married and given up independent employment, channeled their energy into supporting their husbands’ efforts to increase social mobility, while relying on company welfare policies to protect them from rampant sexual and physical abuse.[Oddný Helgadóttir] Boychuk, Gerard W. National Health Insurance in the United States and Canada: Race, Territory, and the Roots of Difference. Washington, D.C.: Georgetown University Press, 2008. Welfare dispensation is a crucial component of government economic regimes. Boychuk shows that the fight to provide it, especially comprehensive health insurance, has been a key battleground in fights over both economic liberalism and political centralization. He argues that the lack of national health insurance in the United States is directly attributable to the fight over racial integration. The rest of the industrialized world was adopting national health insurance in the 1940s, ‘50s, and ‘60s, but American presidents came up against strong southern opposition when they tried to do the same thing. Some tried, notably Truman in his “fair deal” and to some degree Johnson in his “great society.” Yet many Southern congressmen feared that federal money for health would come with orders to desegregate medical facilities. The fact that the 36 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 deeply segregated AMA also opposed national health insurance while the all-black National Medical Association and the NAACP were some of its staunchest supporters further made it a liability for southern congressmen to support. While they could have in theory “gone it alone,” without federal cost sharing measures few states could afford a comprehensive program. In Canada, that federal cost sharing was key to convincing provinces to adopt public health care programs. But there the game of one-upmanship between provincial and federal governments led to health care: most of the signifcant health care legislation was adopted following bouts of Quebec nationalism, in which Ottawa wanted to gain allegiance to the national project. It was a similar mode, almost, to the fight in the United States (cf Klein, For All These Rights) between employers and the government for the right to provide welfare benefits. Evidently, group identity had a large impact on the formation of seemingly disconnected economic and social regimes. [Mookie Kideckel] Rockman, Seth. Scraping By: Wage Labor, Slavery, and Survival in Early Baltimore. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2009. Considering human temporality, the rising and setting sun is inexorable, as is the flow of the Susquehanna into Baltimore Harbor, waves in the Chesapeake Bay, and the movement of ships from and to the city that was the focus of historian Seth Rockman’s case study. Ineluctable, too, was the flow of shit from too many horses in this burgeoning urban space, and constant sediment accruing in the harbor – realities of dynamic motion that gave rise to the primary sources in Scraping By. Rockman highlighted the underpaid, unfree labor that went into the development of Baltimore’s infrastructure, in addition to the capital that exploited this labor. “No amount of effort could stop sediment filling up Baltimore’s harbor,” Rockman noted, but also “no amount of labor could guarantee a decent living to men on the mudmachine.” The mudmachine allowed Baltimore to happen, as did the daily toil on it. As with Braudel’s Mediterranean, we can see labor, capital, machine and urban development, as well as rivers, mud, earth movements, and photosynthesis yielding grain for people, oats for horses, and manure flowing through the entire system. At numerous points in Scraping By, Rockman illuminated global connections, through geographical combinations, demographics, commodity flows, and credit systems. Equally numerous were continual reminders of the materiality of sedimentation and flow, a global, ecological, Braudelian nonmarket reality. These nonmarket entities at times acted as competitive advantage, and at times as constant obstacles to overcome. Rockman’s analysis focused on legible technologies like the mudmachine and the almshouse, both of which left records. But what was the mudmachine? Why did it exist? It dredged Baltimore’s harbor, prone to constant sedimentation, so that the “third largest city” in the early Republic could engage its vision of a commercial entrepot, a necessary trading zone for the Atlantic, and, as understood by its commodity movements, ties with Asia as well. Thus, the mudmachinists would not have possessed their jobs, nor would their records have existed, without tying the harbor to the Chesapeake, the Atlantic and the rest of the world. This larger vision illuminated the very meaning of people’s lives, their social relations as dictated by new capitalist modes of production, divisions of labor, and the necessary legal and economic means to consolidate local power – all of them explicitly, profoundly, and inextricably tied to a larger web of relations. [Bryan Knapp] 37 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 The Imperial Reach Eric Hobsbawm, The Age of Capital, 1848-1875 (1975, reprint New York: Vintage Books, 1996). Sven Beckert, "Emancipation and Empire: Reconstructing the Worldwide Web of Cotton Production in the Age of the American Civil War," American Historical Review 109 (December 2004): 1405-1438. Gregg Mitman and Paul Erickson, “Latex and Blood: Science, Markets, and American Empire,” Radical History Review 107 (Spring 2010): 45-73. This is a purposefully vague heading, and of course chronologically confusing since the global expansion of capitalism had been underway for several centuries by the mid-nineteenth. Nonetheless, I’ll accept Hobsbawm’s premise that 1850-1875 was the key moment of capitalist consolidation over ever-expanding regions of the globe. This was certainly true in regard to US political dominance in North America, as Patricia Limerick made clear in Legacy of Conquest (1987), the foundational text of the “new western history”; Limerick contends that lawyers and land speculators were far more important to the history of the American west than pioneers and cowboys. David Igler’s Industrial Cowboys (2001) and David Vaught’s Cultivating California (1999) provide compelling case studies. Pekka Hamalainen’s Comanche Empire (2008) features an aggressive Indian empire that forced subordinated polities to generate wealth for the center, but was this related to capitalism? See Alexandra Harmon et al., “Interwoven Economic Histories: American Indians in a Capitalist America,” JAH 98 (December 2011). On global integration, Jeremy Prestholdt’s “On the Global Repercussions of East African Consumerism,” AHR 109 (2004) would have worked beautifully this week, connecting Salem, Massachusetts, to Zanzibar in an unexpected way. Emancipation in the British West Indies did not end the importance of sugar to Britain, as discussed in Richard Huzzey, “Free Trade, Free Labour, and Slave Sugar in Victorian Britain,” Historical Journal 53 (2010). Do latenineteenth- century commodity studies have the same explanatory value as those that have proliferated for the early modern period? See Sucheta Mazumdar’s Sugar and Society in China (1998). On state power to police national boundaries, see Andrew Wender Cohen, “Smuggling, Globalization, and America’s Outward State,” Journal of American History 97 (September 2010). The scholarship on empire-- broadly defined-- is too massive to consider comprehensively, but my sense is that much of it takes capitalism as a given and thus devotes attention elsewhere. One might start with Michael Adas’s work insofar as it addresses instrumental logic and technology. Moving into the twentieth century, Emily Rosenberg’s two books would be worthwhile, especially Financial Missionaries to the World (1999). Greg Grandin’s Fordlandia (2009) and Julie Greene’s The Canal Builders (2009) address the expansion of US capitalism into Latin America. Although we’ll address global labor history later in the semester, it is worth mentioning now the degree to which indigenous labor within empire has tended to confound traditional Marxist categories of class formation. Most famously, see Dipesh Chakrabarty’s Rethinking Working Class History (1989) or Joel Beinin’s Workers and Peasants in the Modern Middle East (2001). Sharma, Jayeeta. “British Science, Chinese Skill and Assam Tea: Making Empire’s Garden.” Indian Economic & Social History Review 43:4 (2006): 429-455. Beginning with a well-known plant transfer—that of tea from China to India—Sharma focuses on the larger geo-political developments that necessitated intervention by the British state to promote tea cultivation in British India. The desire to protect capital investment drove East India 38 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Company attempts to develop a tea industry in India after 1830 as its Chinese monopoly waned in the nineteenth century. Sharma also addresses the question of the labor required to tend the tea plants in a new environment in India. Not only did the EIC need to acquire tea plants, but its Tea Committee also realized it needed to attract Chinese growers and assimilate Chinese tea growing practices into India. Indeed, plant transfers were not simply a quest to find a plant, but were also a matter of securing growing techniques and labor. Sharma goes on to describe the development of a population of Indian peasants to work the new tea plantations in this period. Like other works we have read, this article highlights the impact of a specific commodity and its production on local economies and people. [Zack Dorner] Lucier, Paul. Scientists and Swindlers: Consulting on Coal and Oil in America, 1820-90. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2008. Scientists and Swindlers is a study of capitalism and science (and of the resources necessary for imperial growth…although he doesn’t use the term “imperial”) in nineteenth-century America. Lucier tracks the development of American coal and petroleum industries -- which drew both intense scientific and industrial interest -- as well as debates over the classification and ownership of natural resources. With extensive details about the science behind resource extraction and the marketing travails of scientists, Lucier convincingly argues that the exploration of coal and oil was driven by both scientific theory and commercial and political motives. [Lindsay Schakenbach] Goss, Andrew. The Floracrats: State-Sponsored Science and the Failure of the Enlightenment in Indonesia. Madison, WI: The University of Wisconsin Press, 2011. This book helps us move beyond the traditionally Anglo-American view of imperial reach in the eighteenth, nineteenth, and twentieth centuries. Goss examines the failure of Enlightenment thought to take root in Indonesia, despite the commercial successes of economic botany there. In so doing, Goss recognizes the physical realities of colonial administration on the periphery of empire and confronts a question that underlies much of this week’s reading: to what extent was science a tool of empire or the state? Naturalists in Indonesia created new scientific institutions and knowledge in the nineteenth century, but they fell under the sponsorship of the Dutch state. Local botanic gardens and scientists remained dependent on the Dutch state for economic survival, Goss argues, which prevented the development of autonomous, local scientific institutions. The naturalists, meanwhile, became a new class of what Goss terms “floracrats, state experts of nature,” forced to work within a state-imposed system that stripped away the independence of science to operate in non-state-sponsored spaces. Natural science in Indonesia continued to be strictly tied to the Dutch state into the twentieth century, which contributed to the stunted development Goss identifies during the nationalist and postindependence eras. [Zack Dorner] Bosworth, R. J. B. "The Albanian Forests of Signor Giacomo Vismara: A Case Study of Italian Economic Imperialism During the Foreign Ministry of Antonino Di San Giuliano." The Historical Journal 18.03 (1975): 571-86. Italy was a latecomer to the colonial game for obvious reasons, far more often acquiring colonies as the result of treaties and diplomacy than by military conquest. In the wake of the disastrous Battle of Adowa that frustrated Italian designs in Ethiopia, Italian businessmen and bureaucrats looked to the Balkans for opportunities to expand the Italian economy and assert Italy’s position as a regional Great Power. Bosworth’s article details one such quixotic venture. In the Giolittian years foreign minister Antonino di San Giuliano attempted to persuade Rome to fund a Milanese businessman in Ottoman Albania, Giacomo Vismara, with the aim of securing cheap lumber for Italian state railroads. Aggravated by frequent changes of government in Rome and diplomatic tensions prior to the Italo-Turkish War, San Giuliano’s subsidy project took 39 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 years to complete and did not yield results until World War I. It ultimately foundered as the result of a financial conflict between Vismara and an Italian government which refused to swallow the project’s sunk costs even after the war. This story of a botched attempt at economic imperialism is typical of Italy’s bizarre and often Pyrrhic colonial history, or in the author’s words a testimony to “the absurdity of “Italy’s imperial pretensions and the tenacity with which those pretensions were held (586).” [John Delea] Grandin, Greg. Fordlandia: The Rise and Fall of Henry Ford's Forgotten Jungle City. Henry Holt and Company: New York, 2009. In his book, Grandin tells the story of Henry Ford's hubristic business endeavor in the Brazilian Amazon. In the 1920s Henry Ford decided to begin rubber production on a plot of land the size of Tennessee in the center of Brazil, which his company had purchased and named Fordlandia. This was partially in anticipation of protectionist price raises on European rubber production and in part to fulfill Ford's fantasy of a complete and perfect cycle of production for his automobiles. To this end Ford built an entire town around the rubber production in the Amazon. He envisioned his workers tending to all parts of the production of his cars; spread out over the globe but united in leading wholesome American lives. In this way, Ford styled himself as an entrepreneur in the business of “producing men”—the cars, he suggested, were just a propitious byproduct of this venture. Grandin portrays Ford's losing battle with the Amazonian jungle as animated by personal hubris and blind faith that American successes, values, and lifestyles could be replicated elsewhere. So convinced was Ford of the merit of his vision of Fordlandia that he simply ignored the ecological, social and meteorological realities of the jungle, on which he sought to impose a version of Midwestern idyll. In a sense, then, Fordlandia represented Ford's desperate effort to reproduce, or perhaps preserve, an America that he saw as under siege due to an increasingly consumerist culture at home. He conveniently ignored his own role in fashioning this new phase of American history. [Oddný Helgadóttir] Chomsky, Aviva. West Indian Workers and the United Fruit Company in Costa Rica, 18701940. Louisiana: Louisiana State Press, 1995. This book is among one of the first social histories of multinational corporations in Latin America. Aviva Chomsky looks at the formation of an enclave economy in Costa Rica’s Atlantic coast by the banana and railroad companies that merged to form the United Fruit Company in 1899. She focuses on the lives of black West Indian workers in the banana industry, and explains how they managed to build an alternative social and economic system around the plantations despite the company’s efforts to control their lives. [Isadora Mota] Berger, Carl. The Sense of Power: Studies in the Ideas of Canadian Imperialism, 18671914. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1970. One of the pioneering studies in Canadian imperial thought, Berger’s text links the nationalist, imperialist, and economic values of some of Canada’s leading nineteenth century minds. He argues that (English) Canadian nationalism was imperialism - not in the sense of dependency on the British Empire but in being an equal partner in “the greatest empire the world has ever seen.” This imperial outlook also informed their views of the relationship between society, the market, and the individual. It was an extremely gendered view: the British Empire was strong because it put a premium on bourgeois “manliness,” which is to say manliness defined as adherence to work and discipline. Berger demonstrates that a middle-class individualism also manifested as imperialism and nationalism. It was not necessarily friendly to a nanny state, but did favour a strong state in the sense of one that instilled the values of work and discipline. These are the roots of many other Canadian ideas, and the roots of them appear to be in Hobsbawm. [Mookie Kideckel] 40 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 White, Richard. “It’s Your Misfortune and None of My Own”: A New History of the American West. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press, 1991. As It’s Your Misfortune and None of My Own is a synthetic, sprawling history of the American West, I want to direct our attention to the chapter most pertinent to the subject of a capitalistic imperial reach and the week’s readings – Chapter Five: Exploring the Land (pages 119-136). “Exploring the Land” most clearly connects to the Mitman and Erickson article “Latex and Blood: Science, Markets, and American Empire.” White begins with the expedition of Lewis and Clark but extends his story to include the efforts of the railroads, the California state government, and eventually the federal government through the US Geological Survey to map, catalogue, and examine the West’s geological, botanical, and zoological characteristics. As with Mitman and Erickson, White presents a narrative reminiscent of Said in that “development interests determined the problems that were to be solved.” The deployment of new technology created knowledge about an unknown quantity. This knowledge, in turn, set the parameters for investment in the West by producing sites of potential profit. [Henk Isom] Harnetty, Peter. “Cotton Exports and Indian Agriculture, 1861-1870.” The Economic History Review 24, no. 3, New Series (1971): 414–429. Harnetty looks at how the dramatic increase in cotton production in India was achieved during the American Civil War period and how this impacted agrarian political economy. Contrary to the Marxist account that has generally regarded this period as signifying the extreme commodification of agriculture under British India, Harnetty provides statistical evidence that shows that an increase in cotton production did not necessarily come at the cost of domestic consumption or displacement of food crops. Instead, he finds that an increased demand for Indian cotton was met by a dramatic increase in the total land under cultivation that accommodated both cotton as well as food grain production. Moreover, he argues that there was a significant trickle down effect during this period. This led several cultivators (“Ryots”) to escape the clutches of moneylenders as they could demand, from middlemen and traders, higher harvest price for cotton at sowing time (even though harvest price was obviously less than market price at which traders eventually exported cotton). This view therefore contradicts the standard classical account, which states that peasants in poor economies are often poor because they do not respond well to price fluctuations. Harnetty, on the other hand, shows how the British land revenue policy was the factor that curtailed any sustained prosperity of the Ryots because taxation (under the Ryotwari system, common in cotton growing areas) increased substantially, thereby undercutting the prosperity due to increased demand. Harnetty presents the changing political economy of India’s agrarian economy under British colonial rule during the American civil war period with a lot of interesting subnational data. [Puneet Bhasin] Summerhill, William R. Order Against Progress: Government, Foreign Investment, and Railroads in Brazil, 1854-1913. Stanford: Stanford University Press. 2003. Inspired by the "New Economic History," Summerhill studies the introduction of railroads in late nineteenth-century Brazil. The author argues that savings on transport costs generated by railroad investments transformed a stagnant export-oriented society into a fast growing twentieth-century economy. Although Brazilian railroads relied heavily on British foreign investment, Summerhill contends that government policies on subsidy and regulation enabled Brazil to capture and retain most of the gains resulting from transport improvements. The change in infrastructure then stimulated immigration, agricultural growth and the country’s manufacturing capabilities. The book applies cliometric methods to the Brazilian case and presents interesting data, but Summerhill’s analysis is far less nuanced than Richard White’s in Railroaded. [Isadora Mota] Andrews, Thomas G. Killing for Coal: America’s Deadliest Labor War. Cambridge, MA: 41 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Harvard University Press, 2008. Andrews utilizes the massacre of striking mine workers by the Colorado state militia on April 20, 1914 in Ludlow, Colorado--later known as the Ludlow Massacre--as the central crisis through which to examine larger issues of labor, environment, and industrialization in the twentiethcentury United States. Of particular interest to Andrews is illuminating the labor required to generate the energy required for US industrialization on its “messy periphery.” While Killing for Coal revolves around a narrative of the ten days of what Andrews calls class warfare in Southern Colorado following extensive strikes, the book examines deeper questions of what came to be seen as “American” and why in the twentieth century. To that end, Andrews juxtaposes the actions and dreams of industrialists, immigrants, miners, and politicians as they came into contact as a result of the expanding mineral-intensive economy of coal. Coal and, more specifically, the American dependence on coal function as the central forces driving the events and trends described here. [Zack Dorner] Hymer, Stephen. “Robinson Crusoe and the Secret of Primitive Accumulation.” Monthly Review. September, 1971; Jennifer Morgan. Laboring Women: Reproduction and Gender in New World Slavery. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2004; Silvia Federici, Caliban and the Witch. New York: Autonomedia, 2004. A student of MIT economist Charles Kindleberger, Marxist scholar Stephen Hymer was a much-cited but now-underappreciated thinker in the 1960s and 1970s. For anyone aiming to fully understand Karl Marx’s use of “primitive accumulation,” or imperialism and capitalism more generally, this essay is required reading. The role of theft, coercion and violence in capitalist development is highlighted in a close reading of Robinson Crusoe. Crusoe, in fact, was heavily armed, entirely fortified, and ready to use violence on his island. That he exploited Friday’s labor has been long forgotten. Hymer’s critique of imperialism joined Marx’s own, especially Capital, Chapter 26, “The Secret of Primitive Accumulation.” The secret of American colonialism and land appropriation also resides in Hymer’s interpretation of this famous novel. Read this essay alongside Jennifer Morgan’s, Laboring Women and Silvia Federici’s Caliban and the Witch, both of which underscore the theft of female reproduction in slave regimes; at the very least, appropriations of land, labor and bodies will reinforce empirical and theoretical approaches to capitalism writ large. Plus, why not investigate an essay that begins with a Bertrand Russell quote, “Every living being is a sort of imperialist, seeking to transform as much as possible of the environment into itself and its seed.” It should also be noted that the Monthly Review reprinted Hymer’s essay in September 2011 here: http://monthlyreview.org/2011/09/01/ robinson-crusoe-and-the-secret-of-primitive-accumulation. [Bryan Knapp] 42 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 The Corporation Richard White, Railroaded: The Transcontinentals and the Making of Modern America (New York: W.W. Norton, 2011). Alison Frank, “The Petroleum War of 1910: Standard Oil, Austria, and the Limits of the Multinational Corporation," American Historical Review 114 (February 2009): 16-41. Naomi R. Lamoreaux et al., “Beyond Markets and Hierarchies: Toward a New Synthesis of American Business History,” American Historical Review 108 (April 2003): 404-433. Accounts of American business history have typically begun here, with Alfred Chandler’s Visible Hand (1977). It certainly couldn’t hurt to become familiar with the Chandlerian opus, and this David Landes retrospective essay is worthwhile; his death in 2007 occasioned informative obituaries, tributes, and a special issue of Business History Review 82 (June 2008). Steven Usselman published “Still Visible” in Technology and Culture 47 (2006). Perhaps Thomas C. Cochran is the other figure who looms over the field, and his books and articles are numerous. Graduate students in the 1990s found themselves having to confront books like Martin J. Sklar, Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism (1988) and David Montgomery’s The Fall of the House of Labor (1987), both of which confront the political consequences of the corporation in the late-nineteenth century. Maury Klein, The Genesis of Industrial America (2007), offers a concise account designed for the undergraduate classroom, and perhaps pairs nicely with such classics as Alan Trachtenberg’s Incorporation of America (1982), Robert Wiebe’s Search for Order (1967), and Gabriel Kolko’s Triumph of Conservatism (1963). The Gilded Age remains fascinating. See Richard John, “Robber Barons Redux: Antimonopoly Reconsidered,” Enterprise & Society 13 (2012) for the use of editorial cartoons as a source in business history. The standard for the American elite is Sven Beckert, Monied Metropolis (2001), with some good framing of the larger issues in Steve Fraser and Gary Gerstle, Ruling America (2005). TJ Stiles, The First Tycoon: The Epic Life of Cornelius Vanderbilt (2009) is a stunningly impressive work of biography. One might also pick up Ron Chernow’s House of Morgan (2001) and Titan: The Life of John D. Rockefeller (2004); David Nasaw’s Andrew Carnegie (2004); or Niall Ferguson’s two volume House of Rothschild. This may also be a good place to consider the technologies of managerial capitalism. Start with David F. Noble’s America by Design (1977), the essays in Peter Temin, ed. Inside the Business Enterprise (1991), and then Joanne Yates, Control through Communication (1989). Much of the foundational literature on the firm has been collected in Geoffrey Jones and Walter Friedman, eds., The Rise of Modern Firm (2012). On economic forecasting, see Walter Friedman, “The Harvard Economic Service and the Problems of Forecasting,” History of Political Economy 41 (2009), alongside Adam Tooze’s “Weimar Statistical Economics” article in Economic History Review 52 (1999). On the relationship of corporations to the idea of public welfare, see Sanford Jacoby’s Modern Manors: Welfare Capitalism Since the New Deal (1997) and Peter Swanson, Capitalists against Markets (2002). Chandler, Alfred D. The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1977. In Chandler’s foundational work, the “visible hand” of the middle manager supplanted the “invisible hand” of the market in the period between 1840 and World War I. This revolution in corporate structure – the birth of the modern multiunit business enterprise – took place when administrative coordination permitted greater productivity, lower costs, and higher profits 43 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 than coordination by market mechanisms alone. A new class of managers, who were for the first time in history separate from ownership and outside the owners’ families or close associates, facilitated the process by which independent business units were subsumed within larger structures. The largest and most powerful corporations (such as oil refining and steel) succeeded in deploying technological innovations to reach new levels of efficiency in producing and distributing goods. Chandler’s work has been both celebrated for identifying and explaining a key organizational development in American business history and criticized for neglecting, among other things, broader political/social/cultural causes, contexts, and consequences. Regardless, it remains an important book (if only for its title). [Lindsay Schakenbach] Harris, Stephen J. “Long-Distance Corporations, Big Sciences, and the Geography of Knowledge.” Configurations 6:2 (1998): 269-304. This is a pretty great article. In it, Harris proposes the corporation as a means of conceptualizing global networks. Through the lens of the corporation it is possible to integrate what he defines as micro (individuals), meso (corporations) and macro (inter-corporate activity) scales into bigpicture narratives that stay faithful to “empirical integrity.” With this framework in place Harris addresses the relationship between travel and science in the early modern world, specifically how travel influenced the production of knowledge. The long-distance corporation played a key role in this process. In order to master communicating at a distance, Harris argues, successful long-distance corporations incorporated mechanisms of information gathering and knowledge production into their organization. In fact, individuals generated knowledge about distant locations and contributed to understanding of the “big sciences” (geography, astronomy, botany) as they moved around the globe in service of these corporations. Early modern networks relied on overarching corporate structures to link individuals and institutions across great distances, which simultaneously facilitated the production and distribution of knowledge. [Zack Dorner] Coase, Ronald H. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 4, no. 16 (1937): 386–405. This is the first of two highly influential and widely cited papers published by Ronald Coase. In this essay, Coase makes the case for the importance of private firms for an efficient market economy. He does this by pointing to the entrepreneur or business manager who acting within the hierarchical organizational structure of the firm, allocates resources and labor efficiently. Coase, however, argues that the allocation mechanism of the firm is very different from the (efficient) price mechanism of the market. Unlike the market, labor within a firm does not get allocated due to price fluctuations. Instead, rules and top-down orders allocate resources efficiently. For this reason, Coase suggested that neoclassical economics must conceptualize the price mechanism of the market as an efficient coordination device outside the private firm while conceptualizing the entrepreneur and the structure of the firm as an efficient allocator inside. He later extended his idea of efficient allocation by firms to the market, by pointing to inefficient transaction costs that existed in the market—third party costs such as legal fee or cost such as those for measuring a saleable commodity. By doing this in his second essay, “The Problem of Social Cost,” Coase critiqued orthodox neoclassical theory, which typically conceived the price mechanism of the market as operating free of costs. Reducing transaction costs is the reason why well-formulated institutions—private property rights, rule of law—also began to be considered important for an efficient market economy. This in turn gave rise to a new subfield called New Institutional Economics that has had significant influence especially within development economics. [Puneet Bhasin] Klein, Jennifer. All These Rights: Business, Labor, and the Shaping of America's PublicPrivate Welfare State. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2003. Klein provides a trenchant analysis of the emergence of the US system of “corporate welfare,” under which many Americans rely on their employers for health insurance, retirement, and other 44 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 benefits. The emergence of this system was, according to Klein, the result of a compromise between the government, labor, and large corporations. From the 1930s and well into the 1950s there was substantial popular support for alternative models of government-funded social welfare, proposed by grassroots organizations and organized labor. The goal of such policies was to break the link between benefits and employment. Corporations, on the other side, fought aggressively to quench such initiatives and ensure that workers remained dependent on employers for benefits. They viewed this as a competition between the Democratic Party and the labor movement on one side and corporations on the other. Their ultimate goal was to curtail the growth of the welfare state and undermine the strength of organized labor. It is not without irony, then, that these deliberate strategies have subsequently wound up undermining many businesses. In the early years of the twenty first century many big corporations that have gone bankrupt have cited the “legacy costs” of welfare benefits as an unbearable burden that put them out of business, conveniently forgetting that these were policies that the corporations themselves pursued aggressively. [Oddný Helgadottir] Innis, Harold. The Fur Trade in Canada: An Introduction to Canadian Economic History. Yale University Press, 1930. Toronto University Press, 1999. Innis’ book is one of the foundational works of Canadian economic history, and despite some criticism remains surprisingly enduring. It pioneered the “staples theory” of economic history, which argued that geographically determined exports determined the ultimate economic position of countries. For instance, Canada formed as a unified whole because its geography encouraged an economy based on single staple exports, first the beaver, then timber and wheat. The South’s dependency on Europe (and later New England) can be explained because of its reliance on cotton as a staple crop. New England’s economic diversity and industrialization, on the other hand, led to its economic and political power in relation to the other two regions. Innis also argues that in the Canadian case the beaver trade laid the foundations for future corporate organization. Indeed the Hudson’s Bay Company, one of the world’s first corporations, played a huge role in the trade. More importantly, success in the fur trade necessitated the construction of massive transportation networks and business organization to support it. Successful partnerships in North America tended to be British, partly due to industrialization in Britain that allowed them to trade cheap goods. Innis links this proficiency in industrial and business efficiency to the entire development of North American political and economic organization. Even if you find this claim a bit overblown, however, the identification of the fur trade as the beginning of corporate organization in North America (including White’s railroads) remains a provocative assessment of the roots of North American capitalism. [Mookie Kideckel] Kolko, Gabriel. The Triumph of Conservatism: A Reinterpretation of American History, 1900-1916. Chicago: Quadrangle Books, 1967. Kolko savages sentimental accounts of trust busters or urban reformers of the early twentieth century. According to Kolko, “the period from approximately 1900 until the United States’ intervention in the war, labeled the ‘progressive’ era by virtually all historians, was really an era of conservatism.” He asserts that businessmen sought federal protection and rationalization in an increasingly competitive global environment. But even Kolko seems surprised – or thinks that readers in 1963 should have been – that the national government would take an active interest in economic affairs. Kolko posits that American “political capitalism” was structured in such a way as to master the economy, dominate global competition, and maintain social order in a “manner that will allow corporations to function in a predictable and secure environment permitting reasonable profits over the long run.” American history in the twentieth century has not deviated from this central fulcrum, no matter the ebbs and flows along the liberalismconservatism dichotomy. When one adds the military industrial complex of highly advanced 45 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 modern societies, “state capitalism” and “political capitalism” make more sense as theories, and as structures for a better appreciation of recent historiography on conservatism. [Bryan Knapp] 46 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Consolidation and Crisis Nicholas Wapshott, Keynes-Hayek: The Clash that Defined Modern Economics (New York: W.W. Norton, 2011). Julia Ott, “‘The Free and Open People’s Market’: Political Ideology and Retail Brokerage at the New York Stock Exchange, 1913-1933,” Journal of American History 96 (June 2009): 44-77. Adam Tooze, “Trouble with Numbers: Statistics, Politics, and History in the Construction of Weimar’s Trade Balance, 1918-1924,” American Historical Review 113 (June 2008): 678-700. The obvious place to begin is with the two killer Keynes-Hayek rap videos, the original anthem and the sequel. In addition to Wapshott’s recent book, there is also the new Backhouse and Bateman short Keynes biography, Capitalist Revolutionary (2011), and the much longer Hayek’s Challenge (2004) by Bruce Caldwell. Hayek barely rates mention in Heilbroner’s Worldly Philosophers, but gets more attention in Muller’s Mind and the Market. Nelson Lichtenstein’s collection American Capitalism (2006) has an article by Juliet Williams on Hayek and another by Jennifer Burns on Ayn Rand; consult Burns’s longer Goddess of the Market (2009) on Rand. The Great Depression context of the Keynes-Hayek dispute might guide our attention to Galbraith’s Great Crash, 1929 (1955, most recently reprinted 2009); Charles Kindleberger, The World in Depression (1973); Michael Bernstein, The Great Depression (1987); Dietmar Rothermund, The Global Impact of the Great Depression (1996); or Ben Bernanke’s Essays on the Great Depression (2004). The Depression also serves as the crucial event for the early chapters of Mark Blyth’s Great Transformations (2002). New books on crashes include Reinhart and Rogoff’s This Time is Different (2011) and Scott Reynolds Nelson’s A Nation of Deadbeats (2012). For the New Deal in the US, see Jason Scott Smith, Building New Deal Liberalism: The Political Economy of Public Works (2006); Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America (1994); and Rachel Moran, “Consuming Relief: Food Stamps and the New Welfare of the New Deal,” JAH (March 2011). If there is a robust economic history for WWI and its aftermath, I am not sure what’s beyond Tooze’s footnotes. More recently, Nicholas Lambert, Planning Armageddon: British Economic Warfare and the First World War (2010). For the US, see the Hugh Rockoff essay on EH.net. For a longer account of the century that began with WWI, see Jeffry Frieden, Global Capitalism: Its Fall and Rise in the Twentieth Century (2007). Adam Tooze has also written a massive book on the Nazi war economy, Wages of Destruction (2007), while Gerald Feldman has an article version of his book Allianz and the German Insurance Business in Bulletin of the GHI 31 (Fall 2002). Stefan Link has a piece on the Nazi-Ford connection in the Bulletin of the GHI 49 (Fall 2011). Julia Ott’s article previews her 2011 book, and points the way towards other recent work on the “democratization” of capitalism, or at least the broader processes by which an increasing number of Americans became immersed in the language and culture of financial markets: Bruce Carruthers et al., “Bringing ‘Honest Capital’ to Poor Borrowers: The Passage of the US Uniform Small Loan Law, 1907-1930,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 42 (winter 2012); Peter Knight, “Reading the Market: Abstraction, Personification, and the Financial Column of Town Topics Magazine,” Journal of American Studies 46 (2012); Sung Won Kang and Hugh Rockoff, “Capitalizing Patriotism: The Liberty Loans of WWI,” NBER Working Paper (2006) The money debates of the late-nineteenth century mark another important site of “capitalist learning.” See Michael O’Malley, “Free Silver and the Constitution of Man,” Common-place 6 47 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 (2006); Bruce G. Carruthers and Sarah Babb, “The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America,” American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996). For the regulatory history of financial capitalism, see Thomas McCraw, Prophets of Regulation: Charles Francis Adams; Louis D. Brandeis; James M. Landis; Alfred E. Kahn (1986); Jonathan Levy, “Contemplating Delivery: Futures Trading and the Problem of Commodity Exchange in the United States, 1875-1905,” AHR 111 (2006). You can’t go wrong consulting Stanley Engerman and Robert Gallman’s Cambridge Economic History of the United States (2000). The twentieth-century volume has a Great Depression essay by Peter Temin, a finance essay by Barry Eichengreen, a labor economics essay by Claudia Goldin, and many more. Temin, Peter. Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1991. A compilation of Peter Temin's Lionel Robbins lectures, the book presents how the Great Depression was caused due to a large shock—World War I—to major western economies. Unlike most other accounts that attribute the cause to the stock market crash of 1929, Temin traces a longer causal history. Although the Great Depression started in 1929, Temin argues that World War I created such dramatic shifts in the world's political and economic climate that it made the resumption of the gold standard even more unviable than before. Taking a constructivist position, Temin, however, shows how the dominance of a gold standard ideology constrained policy solutions for the "spoils of war," thereby, bringing back the gold standard in the post-war period. Given that currency devaluation was technically impossible under the gold standard, the post-war period witnessed multiple deflationary shocks that propagated across nations, culminating finally in the Great Depression. Temin sees the obstinate adherence to the gold standard and ideas of "sound money" as not only causing the Great Depression but also prolonging it. He argues that it was only when the gold standard was abandoned and the New Deal and other expansionary policies adopted that recovery finally began, even though at a very slow pace. This highly accessible historical account of the Great Depression—cause, propagation, prolongation, and recovery—is useful for anyone interested in macroeconomics and early twentieth century history. [Puneet Bhasin] Rossi, Nicola, and Gianni Toniolo. "Catching up or Falling Behind? Italy's Economic Growth, 1895-1947." The Economic History Review 45.3 (1992): 537-63. Italy’s experience of the Great Depression was not under a capitalist economy but rather a corporatist one organized by the Fascist regime, which restricted laissez-faire and imports in an attempt to establish an Italian autarky. In this article which seeks to address the question of Italy’s periodic economic weaknesses in the 20th century, Rossi and Toniolo indicate that it was the Fascist period, not unification or anything else, that sowed the seeds of Italy’s later economic troubles (e.g. the traumas of postwar industrialization in the north). The root of these problems, they argue, was the often chronic undercapitalization of Italian industries which became apparent soon after unification but which might have been resolved without the restrictions on capital imports imposed by Mussolini and the Fascists. This article is an illuminating one both for anyone interested in Italy’s experience(s) of capitalism and for those interested in the economic policies of (capital ‘F’) Fascism. [John Delea] Nerozzi, Sebastiano. “From the Great Depression to Bretton Woods: Jacob Viner and international monetary stabilization (1930–1945).” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 18.1 (February 2011): 55-84. Like Nicholas Wapshott’s Keynes-Hayek: The Clash That Defined Modern Economics, Nerozzi’s article is an intellectual history with a narrow focus. However, unlike Wapshott’s book, Nerozzi substantially grounds the ideas and economic analysis of Jacob Viner in the 48 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 political events of the day, thus providing a more satisfying account of the economic debates that sprung from the Great Depression. The article’s subject, Viner, was a Canadian, Harvardtrained economist with close ties to the Roosevelt administration. Nerozzi analyzes Viner’s response to and influence on the significant economic events of the period he covers – the Great Depression, Roosevelt’s economic programs of the mid-thirties, and the Bretton Woods conference. Like Viner, Nerozzi focuses on the importance of gold, noting that Viner opposed Roosevelt’s Gold Purchase Program and derided the British Plan at Bretton Woods because it deemphasized gold. Most significantly, Nerozzi presents Viner as an essential figure to the economic developments of the time. Viner served as a reluctant agent for the Roosevelt administration in Europe during the 1930s to gauge reaction to the president’s policies, and was the leader of the Economic and Financial Group, which advised the State Department. The Canadian also worked on the initial drafts for what would become the international monetary systems established at Bretton Woods, and carried out a heated correspondence with John Maynard Keynes debating the British and American Plans presented there. [Henk Isom] Shiroyama, Tomoko. China During the Great Depression: Market, State and the World Economy, 1929-1937. Cambridge: Harvard University Asia Center. 2008. Under the influence of Milton Friedman, the Great Depression’s impact on China has long been underestimated. Scholars of economic history general follow Friedman’s theory and argue that the Chinese economy performed relatively well during the depression years because of its silver standard of currency. Shiroyama explores beyond the indicators of general economic performance, like the GDP, and points out the depression’s immediate impact on specific sectors in the Chinese economy. Although she eventually return to a general assessment of the Chinese fiscal and financial policy and not move on to the unequal distribution of the depression’s impact, the materials she brings to us are already useful to a new understanding of the early twentieth century Chinese economy. [Chu Shiu On] Gordon, Colin. New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America, 1920-1935. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994. Colin Gordon’s New Deals also adds to studies of the liberal-conservative dilemma more broadly, and is a remarkable contribution to New Deal historiography. His research queries both liberal and radical understandings of the New Deal by repositioning business agitation and interest at the center of the account. But it is not a simple conversation. Gordon maps the extreme difficulties in studying and making generalizations about business involvement in the New Deal. He hopes to “move the debate beyond simple questions of whether the New Deal was liberal or conservative, or of whether the New Deal can be called in as evidence of a certain kind of ‘state.’” He accomplishes this revision by boldly claiming that any aspect of the New Deal, from private corporate welfare in the 1920s, to “the regulatory innovations of 1929-1933, and the labor and welfare law of 1935,” were driven by conservative corporate interests. Even the “progressive turn of the ‘second New Deal,’” -- which yielded the Wagner Act, reaffirmed labor’s participation in industrial processes, and created the Social Security Act and the Fair Labor Standards Act -- resulted from “two decades of business strategy and two years of business-driven recovery politics.” But “business” is not a unified bloc in Gordon’s account, and the dialectic between labor and corporate interests is central to his thesis. Gordon proposes a “disorganizational synthesis,” basically a history that captures the variegated, motive, complex dynamics between economic self-interest, corporate and political competition, shifting relationships between business and government. The disorganizational synthesis includes the diffusion of power and politics in a federal system – something he calls “competitive federalism,” all contained with “democratic capitalism.” Competitive federalism and varying (and competitive) state tax regimes encouraged businesses to relocate in the perpetual search for the cheapest land and labor. [Bryan Knapp] 49 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 The Liberal Global Order Ngaire Woods, The Globalizers: The IMF, the World Bank, and their Borrowers (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2007). Michael A. Bernstein, “Economic Knowledge, Professional Authority, and the State: The Case of American Economics during and after World War II,” in Robert F. Garnett Jr., ed., What Do Economists Know? New Economics of Knowledge, (New York: Routledge, 1999), 104-123. Barry Eichengreen, “The Bretton Woods System,” in Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2008), 91-133. My goal this week was to explore the political economy of twentieth-century global development. From the US History standpoint, Elizabeth Borgwardt’s A New Deal for the World (2005) has a Bretton Woods chapter, and there is no lack of recent work on modernization theory as an engine of foreign policy: David Engerman, ed., Staging Growth: Modernization, Development, and the Global Cold War (2003); Nils Gilman, Mandarins of the Future: Modernization Theory in Cold War America (2007); David Ekbladh, The Great American Mission: Modernization and the Construction of an American World Order (2010); Michael Latham, Modernization as Ideology: American Social Science and “Nation Building” in the Kennedy Era (2000) and The Right Kind of Revolution: Modernization, Development, and US Foreign Policy from the Cold War to the Present (2011); and Bradley Simpson, Economists with Guns (2008) on USIndonesian relations. See also Howard Brick’s Transcending Capitalism (2006) for the vision of a postcapitalist future in mid-century American social thought. Economic Geography has something to contribute to this discussion, perhaps starting with Neil Smith, Uneven Development: Nature, Capital, and the Production of Space (1984), anything by David Harvey, and recently synthesized in the Mackinnon and Cumbers volume, Introduction to Economic Geography: Globalization, Uneven Development, and Place (2007). You might find it worthwhile to scan the table of contents of the Journal of Economic Geography or Antipode: A Radical Journal of Geography. The politics of food and development figure here, as in Ines Prodöhl, “‘A Miracle Bean’: How Soy Conquered the West, 1909-1950,” Bulletin of the GHI 46 (Spring 2010). Key works in economics and political science include Fred Block, The Origins of International Economic Disorder (1978); Eric Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance (1996); Louis Pauly, Who Elected the Bankers? (1998); Ha-Joon Chang, Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective (2002); Jacqueline Best, Limits of Transparency (2005); Leonard Seabrooke, The Social Sources of Financial Power (2006). See the other titles published the “Cornell Studies in Money series” (in which Ngaire Woods appears). Gareth Austin seems to be doing the key work on Africa: “The Developmental State and Labour-intensive Industrialization: ‘Late Development’ Re-considered,” Economic History of the Developing Regions 25 (2010), but see also Robert H. Bates for the political economy of development in Africa (and the coffee trade in particular). David Ludden offers a starting point for South Asia. See also Patrick Heller, Labor of Development: Workers and the Transformation of Capitalism in Kerala, India (1999). Look also for Sanjay Reddy and Thomas Pogge’s “How Not to Count the Poor” paper on World Bank statistics. One might also engage the debate between William Easterly and Jeffrey Sachs on foreign aid and development. Elizabeth Borgwardt, A New Deal for the World: America’s Vision for Human Rights. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2005. 50 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Why, after years of isolationism and the humiliation of an internationalist president after the First World War, did the United States decide to invest so much into creating a system of international regimes after World War II? This is the primary question that Elizabeth Borgwardt addresses, and her answer points to the importance of the New Deal. Multilateralism after the Second World War, in this view, stemmed out of Roosevelt administration desires to “internationalize” the New Deal. It was, moreover, acceptable to Americans because the New Deal had taught them that preserving self-interest was bound up in preserving the whole community. Borgwardt expounds this thesis by exploring the three regimes she views as must vital to the construction of a post-War international community: Bretton Woods monetary policy; the United Nations and its associated charters; and the general body of legislation forged in the Nuremberg trials. Borgwardt’s primary intervention here is to add to the list of key aspirational documents the 1941 Atlantic Charter, claiming that it was the starting point for modern human rights discourse. Though innovative in its tone, Borgwardt argues that the Atlantic Charter was essentially an expansion of the New Deal to an international scale. The organizations she highlights became politicized and, in Borgwardt’s view, the US engagement in the cold war squandered the “heady multilateralist zeitgeist of 1945.” Borgwardt concludes by urging a return to that zeitgeist, which would benefit US interests and the entire world. [Mookie Kideckel] Chibber, Vivek. Locked in Place: State-building and Late Industrialization in India. Princeton University Press, 2003. Why did few developmental states succeed at industrialization post World War II while most others failed miserably? Political sociologists have generally answered this comparative question by highlighting the importance of Weberian style “rational bureaucracies”— autonomous, meritocratic, professional—in disciplining capital and directing it towards industrialization of select key sectors of the economy. In researching the dismal performance of the Indian developmental state with the immensely successful South Korean state, Chibber instead explores why Korean capitalists were open to the state meddling in their affairs (disciplining) while Indian capital was not. What he finds is that in either case, capitalists acted “rationally,” in their self-interest, but responded to diametrically opposite incentives. The incentive for South Korean capitalists was the windfall opportunity presented by Japanese capital’s desire to move out of labor-intensive sectors in the US export market so as to move into hi-tech sectors. Given that export operations to foreign markets are inherently risky—no trust networks—South Korean capital was willing to be disciplined into Export Led Industrialization (ELI) in return for the state’s support for securing Japanese knowledge and capital transfers. Indian capital on the other hand had no incentive to promote industrialization or accept state disciplining. India’s Import Substitution Industrialization (ISI) model guaranteed a large domestic market for a small group of capitalists, protected from domestic competition due to the license raj and from any international competition due to high trade barriers. The result was very low incentive for industrialization compared to South Korea. [Puneet Bhasin] Bardhan, Pranab K. Scarcity, Conflicts, and Cooperation: Essays in the Political and Institutional Economics of Development. Cambridge: MIT Press, 2005. In light of the highly path dependent arguments presented by economists such as Acemoglu and Johnson as well as Engerman and Sokoloff, Pranab Bardhan observes that development economics is often narrowly concerned with establishing a link between the historical existence of specific institutions such as private property rights and the level of industrialization. He warns that relying solely on the historicity of such formal institutions can deflect attention away from indigenous institutions that may have instead evolved to be the real impediments for industrialization and growth. To prove his point, Bardhan argues that several well functioning mercantile economies could not industrialize because there simply were no financial markets capable of coordinating capital needed for large-scale enterprises. While indigenous financial 51 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 institutions embedded in social hierarchies and networks served a mercantile economy well, these very institutions were insufficient when it came to industrialization. In contrast to this, Bardhan points to the East Asian development experience of the 20th century where states stepped in directly to develop specific industries by coordinating capital while also deploying a carrot and stick strategy for private interests. However, in their narrow focus on specific institutions like private property rights, many economists have often overlooked the direct role states play in the developing world. Toward a broader analysis of development then, Bardhan calls for analyzing institutions and institutional change within a context of three, broad and often opposing, coordination mechanisms - the state, the market, and community organizations. Additionally, Bardhan provides multiple arguments for resource scarcity and conflict in the developing world, such as severe collective action problems that exist due to highly unequal mobilization and bargaining capabilities of different social groups. [Puneet Bhasin] Grandin, Greg. Empire’s Workshop: Latin America, the United States, and the Rise of the New Imperialism. New York: Holt, 2006. Grandin is not bashful about emphasizing the negative impact American imperialism has had on Latin America throughout the twentieth and twenty-first centuries. Latin America, according to Grandin, acted as a laboratory for American Empire where US policy-makers honed the three key tenets of today’s imperialism: “punitive idealism,” “free-market absolutism,” and “rightwing Christian mobilization.” Throughout the often polemical narrative Grandin highlights the role of US investment capital in influencing state policy and the close ties between US military intervention and corporate interests. Of particular importance to the history of capitalism is Grandin’s discussion of the free market experiments in Central and South America during the 1970s and 1980s--including Pinochet’s regime in Chile--that illuminates the intertwined histories of twentieth-century imperialism and capitalism in Latin America. Under the auspices of the IMF, multinational banks, and the US Treasury “free-market absolutism” continues today as an important facet of the United States’ “new imperialism.” [Zack Dorner] Almeida, Paul, and Erica Walker. "The Pace of Neoliberal Globalization: A Comparison of Three Popular Movement Campaigns in Central America." Social Justice 33.3 (2006): 17590. Walker and Almeida’s article takes a look at three modes of protest to the imposition of neoliberal legislation and austerity measures in Costa Rica, Nicaragua and Guatemala. In the ‘90s and early ‘00s these countries experienced some of the largest protest movements in their history in response to service cuts and tax hikes intended to help pay off international debt or meet World Bank/IMF loan conditions. Their analysis concludes that popular movements to slow down or repeal neoliberal reforms in Central America are most likely to be successful with the support of one or more strong opposition parties, e.g. the Nicaraguan case in which the Sandinista minority in government proved critical to blocking a major cut in public school funding by the Arnoldo Aleman government.[John Delea] Milanovic, Branko. "Globalization and Goals: Does Soccer Show the Way?" Review of International Political Economy 12.5 (2005): 829-50. Milanovic draws a clever comparison between global labor markets/capital and association football, arguing that the commercialization of the latter in the last twenty years serves as an analogy for the distributive processes of globalization. Utilizing historical data from Premier League, Serie A and FIFA World Cup championships, Milanovic argues that increased labor mobility among soccer players has resulted in the concentration of talent among a few elite clubs (e.g. FC Barcelona, Manchester United) to the detriment of parity both between and within national leagues. Milanovic bridges the gap between soccer and political economy by drawing links to analogous processes of labor movement and income distribution in the global economy, 52 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 closing with some suggestions to restore equity both to weakened national economies and weakened local clubs. [John Delea] Green, Duncan. Silent Revolution: The Rise And Crisis Of Market Economics In Latin America. London: Monthly Review Press, 2003, 2nd ed. Silent Revolution aims at stimulating thinking on why neoliberalism has produced such modest gains in Latin America. The second edition of this book was written in the context of the financial breakdowns in Mexico (1995), Brazil (1998) and Argentina (2002). Green explores in detail the creation of market-driven neoliberal economies in the context of the 1980s debt crisis and examines how the so-called “silent revolution” of neoliberalism in the 1990s has failed to produce an economic miracle in this part of the developing world. Green assesses the structural adjustments imposed by the IMF/World Bank in Latin America and concludes that these institutions could never have lived up to their own claims. His study of the harmful effects of neoliberal reforms on gender relations, crime, families, workers and the environment in Latin America are particularly illuminating. Chapter 3, “Poverty Brokers: The International Monetary Fund and the World Bank” seems especially pertinent to our class discussions this week. [Isadora Mota] Perkins, John. Confessions of an Economic Hit Man. San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler Publishers. 2004. The liberal global economic order has long been criticized in academic discourse, but few of the criticisms deal with the intentions behind the globalizers like American experts works in the IMF and the World Bank. Scholars like Ngaire Woods depict the economic experts trained in American universities as theorists who do not possess enough local knowledge of their overseas clients. This image implies that the detrimental effects on South American and Asian economies brought by foreign (mainly American) interventions are due to ignorance rather than imperialistic conspiracies. John Perkins provides a completely different account: some American experts—he claims that he had been one of them—are in fact “economic hitmen” send to disrupt the local economies and provide the pretext of further foreign interventions. The evidences for this argument may not be convincing to academic readers, but John Perkins effective challenges academic understanding of global financial institutions. When scholars demean such arguments as mere “conspiracy theories”, are they in fact setting a ungrounded restriction on academic discourses? [Chu Shiu On] Borgwardt, Elizabeth. “Bernath Lecture: Commerce and Complicity: Corporate Responsibility for Human Rights Abuses as a Legacy of Nuremberg.” Diplomatic History 34 (September 2010): 627-640. While denaturalizing capitalism, historians have noted the inextricable links between state and corporate power. Following her first book, Borgwardt’s recent work explores the “other trial” at Nuremberg, namely the attempt to bring large German companies like Krupp to heal for manufacturing bombs and chemicals employed in gas chambers. Her next book will illuminate the difficulties involved in corporate responsibility, complicity, and accountability, especially in an international legal context – her specialty. For a contribution to an understanding of the postwar era, and American legal, corporate, and military power in the world (through a lens of international law and human rights), Borgwardt’s, A New Deal for the World: America’s Vision for Human Rights of course was essential. Now her research in the legal structures and arguments in Nuremberg against large corporations rests at the center of new and exciting work on the role of corporations in our daily lives. Borgwardt’s legal and historical investigations centered highlight Nuremberg’s implications for human rights understanding in the global realm. For her, Nuremberg’s impact on today’s corporate accountability movements are equally profound, as are her investigations in the postwar global financial structures. [Bryan Knapp] 53 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Sklar, Richard. Corporate Power in an African State: the Political Impact of Multinational Mining Companies in Zambia. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975. In this text Sklar presented the specific case study that informed his important postimperialism theory and perspective on a rising global bourgeoisie. After World War II and during the independence era, new states were born that needed to choose their political economic routes through interrelated spaces. These negotiations, of course, took place during the Cold War and the exponential rise of multinational corporations. But while bungling along trying to do something according to material, cultural, and ideological influences within the very real pressures of land use, weather patterns, drought, and uneven capitalist development, Africans ended in creating the postimperialist frame that Sklar derived from his researches in the Zambian copper belt. This postimperialism framework detailed global transnational capitalist and laboring classes within which Africa-as-continent existed. Multinational mining companies in Zambia created new relations with the state, and with labor unions, and ultimately helped form a new managerial bourgeoisie. His vital and necessary article “Postimperialism: A Class Analysis of Corporate Expansion,” inspired by Sklar’s empirical work on multinational mining companies, detailed the scholarly formulation of multinational corporations as instruments of the transnational corporate bourgeoisie, and other state bureaucratic actors in the transition to “high modernism.” For Sklar, mixed economies and new technologies and expert civil servants followed on the heels of colonial capitalism and influenced the formation of modern capitalism and globalization.[Bryan Knapp] 54 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Deindustrialization and Consumer Society Aviva Chomsky, Linked Labor Histories: New England, Columbia, and the Making of a Global Working Class (Durham: Duke University Press, 2008). Simon Partner, “Nimble Fingers: The Story of the Transistor Radio,” in Assembled in Japan: Electrical Goods and the Making of the Japanese Consumer (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1999), 193-224. Lizabeth Cohen, “From Town Center to Shopping Center: The Reconfiguration of Community Marketplaces in Postwar America,” American Historical Review 101 (October 1996): 1050-1081. The primary goal is to recognize transnational labor history as a crucial component of the history of capitalism. Michael Hanagan’s “An Agenda for Transnational Labor History,” International Review of Social History 49 (2004) offers a starting point, alongside Marcel van der Linden’s “Transnationalizing American Labor History,” Journal of American History 86 (1999) and subsequent Workers of the World (2008). The journal Labor: Studies in the WorkingClass History of the Americas is essential (as is its parent organization, LAWCHA). Jefferson Cowie’s Capital Moves (1999) follows jobs out of the US, while Cindy Hahamovitch’s No Man’s Land (2011) and Deborah Cohen’s Braceros (2011) track workers into the US. See also Kornel Chang, “Circulating Race and Empire: Transnational Labor Activism and the Politics of AntiAsian Agitation in the Anglo-American Pacific World, 1880-1910,” Journal of American History 96 (December 2009); and Eileen Boris and Rhacel Parreñas, eds., Intimate Labors (2010) for the global workforce in caregiving. Leon Fink’s Sweatshops at Sea (2011) captures the global maritime workforce, as do the amazing photographs in Allan Sekula’s Fish Stories (1995) and Performance under Working Conditions (2003). Walmart has offered scholars the chance to think about post-industrial labor, global supply chains, and consumerism. See Bethany Moreton, To Serve God and Walmart (2009); Nelson Lichtenstein, Retail Revolution (2009); and Shane Hamilton’s Trucking Country (2008). The scholarship on consumer capitalism has gone in many directions since the pathbreaking work of Lizbeth Cohen, William Leach, and others. Perhaps the most surprising entry into the discussion recently has been James Livingston’s Against Thrift: Why Consumer Culture is Good for the Economy, the Environment, and Your Soul (2011). Sandy Zipp recommends this exchange on the US Intellectual History blog: review and response, as well as this earlier Livingston piece. Robert Collins, More: The Politics of Economic Growth in Postwar America (2002) has many followers. See also Gary Cross, An All-Consuming Century (2002) and Bernhard Rieger, “From People’s Car to New Beetle: The Transatlantic Journeys of the Volkswagen Beetle,” Journal of American History 97(June 2010). For global consumer culture, see Peter N. Stearns, Consumerism in World History (2001); and Hartmut Berghoff and Uwe Spiekermann, eds., Decoding Modern Consumer Societies (2012). Setha Low and Neil Smith’s volume The Politics of Public Space (2006) has articles by David Harvey, Dolores Hayden, and Elizabeth Blackmar (among others) that explore corporate appropriation and privatization of space. Burke, Timothy. Lifebuoy Men, Lux Women: Commodification, Consumption, and Cleanliness in Modern Zimbabwe. Durham: Duke University Press, 1996. For Timothy Burke there was “preaching the gospel of consumption” and expert marketing, power-from-above but still African, high-modernist attempt to “create new African subjectivities” in order to sell products such as soap and toothpaste. Burke detailed the rise of marketing and consumer integration in the postwar period. He investigated sources and people from top to bottom along the producer-consumer chain in Zimbabwe and South Africa. The shift from colony to neocolonial relationships revealed multiple power relationships and how these 55 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 change over time., But also the era highlighted how local Africans utilized new social, political and economic relationships within a moment of global commodification. Missionaries in the nineteenth century possessed certain visions of their civilizing mission, from cleanliness, personal behavior, family life, and religious beliefs, and Burke showed how the consumer revolution and new market cultures expressed similar pressures on local populations. African capitalists also saw social order and prosperity arising from their specific actions in the world. Africa very much was an integral piece of the postwar capitalist puzzle. Burke quoted marketers, managers and executives who believed that capitalist political economy would “create a better state of mind amongst backward people.” The capitalist in Africa mirrored those of other regions, nations and continents. Business civilization reached extreme suffusion in the postwar era, and, as Burke noted, “like the missionaries of a century ago, these professionals discovered in their appointed task a ‘civilizing mission’” that functioned to maintain specific power relations during transitions from the colonial to the postcolonial periods. [Bryan Knapp] Jacobs, Meg. Pocketbook Politics: Economic Citizenship in Twentieth Century America. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2005. Central to Jacobs’s work is the notion of “economic citizenship” - the ability to buy goods and to achieve a certain standard of living. In a study that extends from the 1900s to 1960, Jacobs tracks the growing power and eventual dissolution of a coalition of groups – largely formed by labor unions and middle class consumers – who furthered their interests by advocating increased purchasing power for the American people. Jacobs examines the economic and political issues that occurred during her period of study in terms of how they affected people’s capacity to consume, and how the popular pursuit of consumption affected economic and political policy. Jacobs shifts the focus of the conversation surrounding the Great Depression and New Deal era to the way consumers, and particularly women, talked about the economy. Framing economic crises in terms of reduced purchasing power was so prevalent that the AFL adopted the rhetoric in 1925. This shared belief about the efficacy of economic policy and economic justice – that all Americans were entitled to a certain lifestyle and that good economic policy expanded Americans’ ability to consume – presaged the union of female, middle class consumers and organized labor in the New Deal coalition. This coalition, and its purchasing power rhetoric, remained strong through World War II, but its dissolution after the war led to the end of a consumption agenda by 1960. [Henk Isom] Jacobson, Matthew Frye. Whiteness of A Different Color: European Immigrants and the Alchemy of Race. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998. Jacobson is explicit in designating Whiteness of a Different Color a work of cultural American history. He reveals the historical construction of race through novels, movies, newspapers, and magazines while acknowledging that philosophy, politics and science served as the basis for those racial depictions. The broad arc of the book begins in the Early Republic, where slavery, expansion into a Native American-dominated frontier, and the 1790 Naturalization Act (which gave citizenship to all “free white persons”) established an inclusive, privileged whiteness for peoples of European descent in the United States. As European immigration increased in the 19th century, whiteness fractured and different racial categories were created for people of different Continental origin. The final section hinges on the 1924 Johnson-Reed Act, which established immigration quotas along the existing European racial divisions. Conversely, because this legislation alleviated fears associated with immigrants, whiteness once again consolidated around skin color and the culture reestablished broader racial categories. As Jacobson alludes to and Aviva Chomsky demonstrates forcefully in Linked Labor Histories, this racial reconfiguration would have a huge impact on union inclusion and organized labor efforts in the United States throughout the 20th century. [Henk Isom] 56 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Micheletti, Michele. Political Virtue and Shopping: Individuals, Consumerism, and Collective Action. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2003. Micheletti conceives of political consumerism as a novel, post-modern, form of “citizen responsibility-taking.” It blends private and public spheres, mirrors the “virtues” of traditional citizen engagement, and is an outlet for what she terms “individualized collective action.” Micheletti argues that since the 1980s, political consumerism has taken new forms, and her book begins with attempts to understand this through theoretical frameworks. She argues that a globally oriented, post-modern, political consumerism has risen concomitantly with the public’s disengagement from traditional voluntary organizations and state apparatuses. Citizens are no longer joiners in the same degree they once were, and governments increasingly deal with issues that extend beyond their borders. Thus, Micheletti suggests that consumer activism in the 21st century is, at least in part, a response to transforming definitions of citizenship and government. Micheletti supplements her theory with history. She argues that the United States has a particular affinity for political boycotts, something she traces to bouts over tea prices before the country’s revolution, and suggests that, “scholars of history know intuitively that issues of consumption…lie behind all revolutions” (36). Micheletti’s brief history of political consumerism covers various campaigns from the 19th century until the book’s writing in 2002. Reaching the present, Micheletti gives examples of modern consumerism around the world and provides a detailed case study of an eco-labelling campaign conducted by the Swedish Society for Nature Conservation (SSNP). She ends with a sanguine analysis of political consumerism’s importance as a current and future tool of citizen engagement. Ultimately, the book’s value is in applying citizenship theory to questions of political consumerism. It is a useful supplement to more traditional histories of consumerism, like Cohen’s Consumer’s Republic and Lawrence Glickman’s Buying Power (Chicago, 2009). [Mookie Kideckel] Lan, Pei-chia. Global Cinderella: Migrant Domestics and Newly Rich Employers in Taiwan. Durham: Duke University Press. 2006. Southeast Asian migrant domestics played significant but ignored roles in the modernist developments in Asia. Since the 1980s, the newly prosperous countries of East Asia, like Taiwan, Singapore, and Hong Kong, have recruited foreign household workers— many of them come from the Philippines and Indonesia –at a rapidly increasing rate. Lan’s field research reveals the sufferings of these migrant workers as “others” in terms of classes, nationalities, ethnicities, and education levels. Her findings also point to an ironic, but intellectually interesting, relationship. As Chinese employers the new rich countries tends to discriminate and exploit the Southeast Asian workers, they forget the coming of these workers is in fact a part of a system which exploits themselves—only with the migrant workers’ labor the extremely long work hours in these new rich countries become possible. The ignorance of these employers— of both the sufferings of the others and themselves—actually contributes to the weak working class consciousness in East Asian modernization. [Chu Shiu On] Comaroff, John L. and Jean Comaroff. Ethnicity, Inc. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2009. Critical anthropologists Jean and John Comaroff tackle neoliberalism and the incorporation of ethnicity in this engaging long essay. The cover of the book shows a smiling Zulu woman with the slogan “The Zulu Kingdom Awaits You” – a marketing attempt at attracting tourists, creating a brand, and providing a cultural commodity for sale on the global market. This book presents provocative ideas about the co-optation of multiple identities by global capitalism and by multinational corporations. Additionally, the Comaroffs demonstrate how ethnic groups such as the San “Bushmen” incorporate themselves and organize much like corporations. Cultural identity and specificity are for sale. In the case of the San, they attempt to patent local 57 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 plants with the hopes of sales in the millions. The authors compel us to think about multiethnic identities in a totalizing global system, from Scotland the brand to “casino capitalism,” whereby Native American casinos, land grabs, and political struggles provide new spaces for private sphere activities and money-making. According to the Comaroffs, markets are everywhere and everything is for sale. This book works exceptionally well with David Harvey’s A Brief History of Neoliberalism and Neil Smith’s The Endgame of Globalization. [Bryan Knapp] 58 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Finance and Shareholder Value Gerald Davis, Managed by the Markets: How Finance Re-Shaped America (New York: Oxford University Press, 2009). Rakesh Kharuna, From Higher Aims to Hired Hands: The Social Transformation of American Business Schools and the Unfulfilled Promise of Management as a Profession (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007), 333-383. David Graeber, Debt: The First 5,000 Years (New York: Melville House Publishing, 2011), 361-391. Managed by the Markets is one of several recent books dealing with the power of finance to transform economic life and culture. Greta Krippner’s Capitalizing on Crisis: The Political Origins of the Rise of Finance (2011) has generated a lot of interest, especially in the wake of her “Financialization of the American Economy,” Socio-Economic Review 3 (2005). So too has Judith Stein, Pivotal Decade: How the US Traded Factories for Finance in the Seventies (2010). Rawi Abdelal, Capital Rules: The Construction of Global Finance (2009) and Richard Sennett, Culture of the New Capitalism (2007) might also prove useful. See also Ernie Englander and Allen Kaufman, “The End of Managerial Ideology: From Corporate Social Responsibility to Corporate Social Indifference,” Enterprise & Society 5 (2004). Graeber’s Debt could pair nicely with Louis Hyman’s Debtor Nation (2011) and Borrow: The American Way of Debt (2012), but clearly Graeber is pursuing a set of philosophical considerations that put him in conversation with Michael Sandel’s What Money Can’t Buy (2012) [excerpted here in The Atlantic] and Debra Satz, Why Some Things Should Not be For Sale (2010). This might also be a good moment to mention Viviana Zelizer’s two excellent books, The Social Meaning of Money (1994) and The Purchase of Intimacy (2005), both of which deal with the bleeding of “the economic” into presumptively “non-economic” aspects of the human experience. See also Mary Poovey, “For Everything Else, There’s...” Social Research 68 (2001). Kara Swanson previews her dissertation on milk banks, blood banks, and sperm banks in Enterprise & Society 12 (2011). An outpouring of scholarship has sought to diagnose the recent economic crisis, and there are numerous worthwhile journalistic (e.g. the Wired “Recipe for Disaster” article) and documentary accounts (e.g. Inside Job or the current Frontline series “Money, Power, and Wall Street”). But for “how did we get here?” questions, one might start with Joseph Stiglitz, Globalization and its Discontents (2003); David Harvey, A Brief History of Neoliberalism (2005); and Harvey, The Enigma of Capital (2011) [conveniently animated here]. From there, Gerald Friedman, “Economists and the Crisis: A Guide to the Perplexed,” Labor History 51 (2010). Government and Markets: Toward an New Theory of Regulation (2010), edited by Edward Balleisen and David Moss, offers a number of historically-informed policy prescriptions. If you want to antagonize your friends who are management consultants (now that you can abuse your friends who already have MBAs), see Christopher McKenna, The World’s Newest Profession: Management Consulting in the Twentieth Century (2006). The technologies of business deserve analysis, and there is a robust scholarship in such journals as Accounting History. See also Martin Campbell-Kelly, “The Rise and Rise of the Spreadsheet,” in his edited volume The History of Mathematical Tables (2003); Alex Preda, “Socio-Technical Agency in Financial Markets: The Case of the Stock Ticker,” Social Studies of Science 36 (2006). See Marc Levinson’s The Box (2006) for a history of globalization through the shipping container. For a similar sense of things in movement, see Pietra Rivoli, Travels of a T-Shirt in the Global 59 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Economy (2009). This might be a good place to reconsider intellectual property (last discussed during the Industrial Revolution week). See Alex Cummings, “From Monopoly to Intellectual Property: Music Piracy and the Remaking of American Copyright, 1909-1971,” Journal of American History 97 (December 2010); or David Suisman, Selling Sounds (2009). Also consider business histories of new industries, as in Sally Smith Hughes, Genentech: The Beginnings of Biotech (2011). Jensen, Michael C. and William H. Meckling. “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3 (October 1976): 305-360. Some scholars (e.g. Marion Fourcade and John Quiggin) studying firms and corporations believe that Jensen and Meckling’s article influenced the way in which corporations are operated today profoundly, contributing to a practice in which short-term profits are seen as more important than long-term gains and overall stability. With 31,140 citations (on March 18, 2012) on google scholar it does not seem unreasonable to assume that the article has had an important impact. In their article Jensen and Meckling suggest that the use of stock options as compensation for CEOs could be a useful managerial tool, as it would incentivize CEOs to maximize shareholder value. This practice has since become widespread. Many see it as one of the key problems with how publicly traded corporations are operated today, with shortterm gains trumping all other concerns and many instances of executives manipulating their companies’ stock. [Oddný Helgadóttir] Porter, Michael E. and Mark. R. Kramer. “Creating Shared Value: How to Reinvent Capitalism – and Unleash a Wave of Innovation and Growth.” Harvard Business Review, Jan-Feb 2011. Porter and Kramer argue that businesses are trapped in a vicious cycle in which the pursuit of short terms profits for shareholders leads to social and environmental depredations and backlash against business in the form of stifling regulations. To overcome this cycle and create a sustainable and equitable capitalism, businesses need to reinvent their strategies to create “shared value,” which would connect economic progress with social progress. By recognizing that social needs, not just economic ones, define markets, firms will minimize the social harms that end up creating internal costs. Porter and Kramer see this strategy as a broader conception of Adam Smith’s invisible hand. Individuals still act in self-interest (and are better suited to do so than the government), but they do so in ways that create both social and economic gain for the greatest number of people. Whether a new kind of corporate self-interest can actually lead to greater social good is, of course, up for debate . [Lindsay Schakenbach] Miller, James Andrew and Tom Shales. Those Guys Have All the Fun: Inside the World of ESPN. Boston: Back Bay Books, 2011. Shales and Miller conducted over five hundred interviews with people affiliated with ESPN in some capacity and compiled those efforts into a sprawling and thorough oral history of the company. Intended for a popular audience, much of the book deals with the clashes of big personalities and much publicized scandals that have repeatedly put the company in the headlines and gossip pages since its founding. However, Shales and Miller deserve a great deal of credit for balancing these sultry stories with the realities of ESPN’s corporate development. The book begins with the somewhat tragic story of the Rasmussen family, who had the idea for the network in 1979 but who were deemed to lack the television experience and managerial skill to effectively run the company. This serves as a unifying theme throughout the book: certain CEOs or managers are chosen to fit ESPN’s needs at particular times, be they 60 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 creative development, corporate expansion, or budgetary responsibility. In conjunction with these stories of individual leadership, Those Guys Have All the Fun also discusses the mergers and takeovers that dot ESPN’s history, from Getty Oil’s initial investment in the company to Disney’s purchase of network through ABC in 1996. Most interestingly, Shales and Miller have collected testimony about the contingencies and motivations surrounding these corporate maneuverings from the very people involved. The book therefore offers an excellent window into the corporate culture and the corresponding motivations behind financial decisions during the eighties, nineties, and ‘aughts, albeit one that should be taken with a grain of salt. [Henk Isom] Tsai, Kellee S. Back-Alley Banking: Private Entrepreneurs in China. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. 2004. How is private business possible in a communist state? Kellee Tsai’s research points toward the informal but pervasive financial markets which evade the communist state’s suppression. Even after the economic reform began in the late 1970s, credit creation was still legally confined to the state banks which served only state-owned—or owned by the cronies of the party officials— enterprises. In defiance of the national banking laws, small business owners have created a dizzying variety of informal financing mechanisms, including rotating credit associations and private banks disguised as other types of organizations. Tsai’s study not only reveals the struggles of the small business owners under the communist regime, but also suggests an alternative understanding of the Chinese financial market—we should not only look at those modern (western) banks started in the early twentieth century, but also at the long tradition of private financing devices. [Chu Shiu On] Philips-Fein, Kim. Invisible Hands: The Making of the Conservative Movement from the New Deal to Reagan. New York: W. W. Norton & Company, 2009. Philips-Fein displays a deep analysis of the business-activist networks which helped define, and reflected, the conservative era of postwar capitalism. Her archival research unearths relationships between conservative men – their letters, publications, and writings – and traces the fundraising trail between individuals, corporations, and think tanks. These resources led to the creation of university centers like Stanford’s Hoover Institute and the Center for Strategic Studies at Georgetown; enhanced the influence of non-state, conservative civil society actors like the National Association of Manufacturers and various Chambers of Commerce; and contributed to federal lobbying pressure. These efforts influenced electoral politics and gained actual political control. In the 1970s conservative lobbying groups like the Business Roundtable – an organization with a “membership of leading CEOs” – began activism campaigns to resurrect the public’s image of business and attack specific liberal legislation. Her work contributes to understanding institutions, big business and political struggles during the rising neoliberal era. [Bryan Knapp] 61 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Scholarly Resources EH.Net Operated by the Economic History Association, this is an amazing clearinghouse of reviews, and syllabi. More importantly, its encyclopedia features articles on specific topics by very prominent scholars. Also invaluable are the 24 essays on the “Great Books” of Economic History. The Exchange: The Business History Conference Blog This is a very useful source for learning about conferences, new books, etc. from an organization that is increasingly home for scholarship on the history of capitalism Echoes: Economic History with Stephen Mihm This is the Bloomberg economic history blog and they have a lot of good historians contributing. Harvard Program on the Study of Capitalism Sven Beckert and Christine Desan run an amazing workshop that maximizes graduate student participation. Brown students have enrolled for credit (and should do so in the future). Culture of the Market Network Emerging from a mutli-university research program on the 19th-century US, this blog features conference announcements and calls-for-papers of interest to all historians of capitalism. Program in Early American Economy and Society Housed at the Library Company of Philadelphia, this outfit hosts conferences, runs a book series, and offers fellowships for research on the economic past in North America before 1860. The LCP itself has put up a number of exhibitions on the American economy in recent years. Business History Archives in the United States This is a massive state-by-state archive created by the German Historical Institute. The History Project of the Center for History and Economics at Harvard With generous funding from the Institute for New Economic Thinking, this outfit is sponsoring a series of upcoming graduate conferences and offers some fellowships too. 62 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Miscellaneous Bibliography (unannotated) Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J.A. Robinson. Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. National Bureau of Economic Research (2001). Adams, Sean Patrick. “How Choice Fueled Panic: Philadelphians, Consumption, and the Panic of 1837.” Enterprise & Society 12 (2011): 1-29. Anderson, Ralph V. and Gallman, Robert E. “Slaves as Fixed Capital: Slave Labor and Southern Economic Development.” Journal of American History 64 (June 1977): 24–46. Arnesen, Eric, Greene, Julie, and Laurie, Bruce, eds. Labor Histories: Class, Politics, and the WorkingClass Experience. Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1998. Arnold, David. “Plant Capitalism and Company Science: The Indian Career of Nathaniel Wallich.” Modern Asian Studies 42:5 (2008): 899-928. Beaud, Michel. A History of Capitalism, 1500-2000. Monthly Review Press, 2000. Bayly, C.A. Rulers, Townsmen, and Bazaars: North Indian Society in the Age of British Expansion, 17701870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983. Ben-Atar, Doron. “Alexander Hamilton’s Alternative: Technology Piracy and the Report on Manufactures.” WMQ 52 (July 1995): 389-414. Berg, Maxine. “In Pursuit of Luxury: Global History and British Consumer Goods in the Eighteenth Century.” Past & Present 182 (February 2004): 85-142. Bose, Sugata, ed. South Asia and World Capitalism. Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1990. Bouk, Dan. “The Science of Difference: Developing Tools for Discrimination in the American Life Insurance Industry, 1830-1930.” Enterprise & Society 12 (2011): 717-731. Broadberry, Stephen, and Bishnupriya Gupta. “Lancashire, India, and Shifting Competitive Advantage in Cotton Textiles, 1700-1850: The Neglected Role of Factor Prices.” Economic History Review 62 (2009): 279-305. Butler, Kathleen Mary. The Economics of Emancipation: Jamaica and Barbados, 1823-1843. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1995. Chaudhuri, K.N. Asia before Europe: Economy and Civilization of the Indian Ocean from the Rise of Islam to 1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990. Coclanis, Peter A., ed. The Atlantic Economy during the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries: Organization, Practice and Personnel. Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 2005. Coelho, Philip and Robert McGuire. “African and European Bound Labor in the British New World: The Biological Consequences of Economic Choices.” JEH 57 (1997): 83-115. Conkin, Paul K. Prophets of Prosperity: America’s First Political Economists. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1980. Davenport, Stuart. Friends of the Unrighteous Mammon: Northern Christians and Market Capitalism, 1815-1860. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2008. 63 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 David, Paul. “Why are Institutions the ‘Carriers of History’? Path Dependence and the Evolution of Conventions, Organizations, and Institutions.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 5 (1994): 205220. Deeg, Richard and Jackson, Gregory. “Towards a More Dynamic Theory of Capitalist Variety.” SocioEconomic Review 5 (2007): 149-179. Dierks, Konstantin. “Letter Writing, Stationary Supplies, and Consumer Modernity in the EighteenthCentury Atlantic World.” Early American Literature 41 (2006): 473-494. Drescher, Seymour. “The Long Goodbye: Dutch Capitalism and Antislavery in Comparative Perspective.” AHR 99 (February 1994): 44-69. Dublin, Thomas. Transforming Women’s Work: New England Lives in the Industrial Revolution. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1994. Dunlavy, Colleen A. and Welskopp, Thomas. “Myths and Peculiarities: Comparing US and German Capitalism.” Bulletin of the German Historical Institute 41 (Fall 2007): 33-64. Einhorn, Robin. Property Rules: Political Economy in Chicago, 1833-1872. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991. Engel, Katherine Carte. “The Strangers’ Store: Moral Capitalism in Moravian Bethlehem, 1753-1775.” Early American Studies 1 (spring 2003): 90-126. Engerman, Stanley L. and Sokoloff, Kenneth L. “Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies: A View from Economic Historians of the United States.” In Stephen Haber, ed., How Latin America Fell Behind: Essays on the Economic Histories of Brazil and Mexico, 1800-1914, 260-304. Stanford; Stanford University Press, 1997. Fabian, Ann. Card Sharps and Bucket Shops: Gambling in Nineteenth-Century America. New York: Routledge, 1999. Fichter, James. So Great a Profitt: How the East Indies Trade Transformed Anglo-American Capitalism. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2010. Flaherty, Jane. “‘The Exhausted Condition of the Treasury on the Eve of the Civil War.” Civil War History 55 (June 2009): 244-277. Frank, Andre Gunder. ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998. German,James. “The Social Utility of Wicked Self-Love: Calvinism, Capitalism, and Public Policy in Revolutionary New England,” Journal of American History 82 (Dec. 1995): 965-998. Gervais, Pierre. “Neither Imperial, nor Atlantic: A Merchant Perspective on International Trade in the Eighteenth Century.” History of European Ideas 34 (2008): 465-473. Glaisyer, Natasha. “Networking Trade and Exchange in the Eighteenth-Century British Empire.” Historical Journal 47 (June 2004): 451-476. Grafe, Regina. Distant Tyranny: Markets, Power, and Backwardness in Spain, 1650-1800. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2012. Grossman, Richard S. Unsettled Account: The Evolution of Banking in the Industrialized World since 1800. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010. 64 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Grove, Richard. Green Imperialism: Colonial Expansion, Tropical Island Edens and the Origins of Environmentalism, 1600-1860. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995. Hall, John R., ed. Reworking Class. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1997. Hancock, David. Citizens of the World: London Merchants and the Integration of the British Atlantic Community, 1735-1785. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995. Hanes, Christopher. “Turnover Cost and the Distribution of Slave Labor in Anglo-America.” JEH 56 (June 1996): 307–29. Hoffman, Philip T. “Prices, the Military Revolution, and Western Europe’s Comparative Advantage in Violence.” Economic History Review 64 (2011): 39-59. Huston, James L. “Abolitionists, Political Economists, and Capitalism.” Journal of the Early Republic 20 (autumn 2000): 487-521. Knodell, Jane. “Rethinking the Jacksonian Economy: The Impact of the 1832 Bank Veto on Commercial Banking.” Journal of Economic History 66 (September 2006): 541-574. Lamikiz, Xabier. Trade and Trust in the Eighteenth-Century Atlantic World: Spanish Merchants and their Overseas Networks. Rochester: Boydell Press, 2010. Lamoreaux, Naomi. “Economic History and the Cliometric Revolution.” In Anthony Molho and Gordon S. Wood, eds., Imagined Histories: American Historians Interpret the Past, 59-84. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998. Lange, M., J. Mahoney, and M. vom Hau. “Colonialism and Development: A Comparative Analysis of Spanish and British Colonies.” American Journal of Sociology (2006) 111 (5): 1412–1462. Larson, John L. The Market Revolution in America: Liberty, Ambition, and the Eclipse of the Common Good. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2010. Leone, Mark P. “A Historical Archeology of Capitalism.” American Anthropologist 97 (June 1995): 251268. Levinson, Marc. The Great A&P and the Struggle for Small Business in America. New York: Hill & Wang, 2011). Light, Jennifer. “Discriminating Appraisals: Cartography, Computation, and Access to Federal Mortgage Insurance in the 1930s.” Technology & Culture 52 (July 2011): 485-522. Middleton, Simon and Smith, Billy G., eds. Class Matters: Early North America and the Atlantic World. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2008. Mann, Bruce. Republic of Debtors: Bankruptcy in the Age of American Independence. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2002. Matson, Cathy, ed. The Economy of Early America: Historical Perspectives & New Directions. University Park: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 2006. McCusker, John J. and Kenneth Morgan, eds. The Early Modern Atlantic Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000. McCusker, John J. and Russell R. Menard. The Economy of British America, 1607-1789. Chapel Hill: The 65 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 University of North Carolina Press, 1985. Menard, Russell R. “Plantation Empires: How Sugar and Tobacco Planters Built their Industries and Raised an Empire.” Agricultural History 81 (Summer 2007): 309-332. Menard, Russell. “Financing the Lowcountry Export Boom: Capital and Growth in Early South Carolina.” WMQ 51 (October 1994); 659-676. Miller, Peter. “Governing by Numbers: Why Calculative Practices Matter.” Social Research 68 (Summer 2001): 379-396. Morgan, Kenneth. “Remittance Procedures in the Eighteenth-Century British Slave Trade.” Business History Review 79 (Winter 2005): 715-749. Mukherjee, Rila, ed. Networks in the First Global Age, 1400-1800. New Delhi: Indian Council of Historical Research in association with Primus Books, 2011. Muller, Jerry Z. Capitalism and the Jews. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2011. Murphy, Anne L. The Origins of English Financial Markets: Investment and Speculation before the South Sea Bubble. New York, Cambridge University Press, 2009. Newell, Margaret. “Robert Child and the Entrepreneurial Vision: Economy and Ideology in Early New England.” New England Quarterly 68 (June 1995): 223-256. Noll, Mark A., ed. God and Mammon: Protestants, Money, and the Market, 1790-1860. NY: Oxford University Press, 2002. Nugent, J.B., and J.A. Robinson. “Are endowments fate?” Discussion Paper Series-Centre for Economic Policy Research London (2002). Overton, Mark. Agricultural Revolution in England: The Transformation of the Agrarian Economy, 15001850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996. Perelman, Michael. The Invention of Capitalism: Classical Political Economy and the Secret History of Primitive Accumulation. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 2000. Pomfret, Richard. The Age of Equality: The Twentieth Century in Economic Perspective. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2011. Prak, Maarten, ed. Early Modern Capitalism: Economic and Social Change in Europe, 1400-1800. London: Routledge, 2001. Prakash, Om. Bullion for Goods: European and Indian Merchants in the Indian Ocean Trade, 1500-1800. New Delhi: Manohar Publishers, 2004. Preda, Alex. “The Rise of the Popular Investor: Financial Knowledge and Investing in England and France, 1840-1880.” Sociological Quarterly 42 (Spring 2001): 205-232. Rediker, Marcus. Between the Devil and the Deep Blue Sea: Merchant Seamen, Pirates, and the AngloAmerican Maritime World, 1700-1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987. Richardson, David. “Slavery and Bristol’s ‘Golden Age.’” Slavery & Abolition 26 (April 2005): 35-54. Richardson, Heather Cox. The Greatest Nation on Earth: Republican Economic Policies during the Civil War. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1997. 66 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Rockoff, Hugh. “History and Economics.” In Eric H. Monkkonen, ed., Engaging the Past: The Uses of History across the Social Sciences, 48-75. Durham: Duke University Press, 1994. Rozbicki, Michal J. “To Save Them from Themselves: Proposals to Enslave the British Poor, 1698-1755.” Slavery & Abolition 22 (August 2001): 29-50. Schiebinger, Londa. Plants and Empire: Colonial Bioprospecting in the Atlantic World. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2004. Schiebinger, Londa and Claudia Swan, eds. Colonial Botany: Science, Commerce, and Politics in the Early Modern World. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2005. Sen, Sudipta. Empire of Free Trade: The East India Company and the Making of the Colonial Marketplace. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1998. Sheriff, Carol. The Artificial River: The Erie Canal and the Paradox of Progress, 1817-1862. New York: Hill and Wang, 1996. Smith,Woodruff. “Complications of the Commonplace: Tea, Sugar, and Imperialism. Journal of Interdisciplinary History 23 (Autumn 1992): 259-278. Stern, Philip J. The Company-State: Corporate Sovereignty and the Early Modern Foundations of the British Empire in India. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2011. Subrahmanyam, Sanjay. The Political Economy of Commerce: Southern India, 1500-1650. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990. Thompson, Ross. “The Continuity of Innovation: The Civil War Experience.” Enterprise & Society 11 (March 2010): 128-165. Thornton, Tamara Plakins. “’A Great Machine’ or a ‘Beast of Prey’: A Boston Corporation and Its Rural Debtors in an Age of Capitalist Transformation.” Journal of the Early Republic 27 (Winter 2007): 567-597. Tilly, Richard. “Banking Crises in Three Countries, 1800-1933: An Historical and Comparative Perspective.” Bulletin of the German Historical Institute 46 (Spring 2010): 77-89. Trigger, Bruce G. “Early Native North American Responses to European Contact: Romantic versus Rationalistic Interpretations.” Journal of American History 77 (March 1991): 1195-1215. Tucker, Barbara and Tucker, Kenneth. “The Limits of Homo Economicus: An Appraisal of Early American Entrepreneurship.” Journal of the Early Republic 24 (Summer 2004): 208-218. Vickers, Daniel. “Competency and Competition: Economic Culture in Early America.” William and Mary Quarterly 47 (January 1990): 3-29. Weber, Warren E. “Early State Banks in the United States: How Many Were There and When Did they Exist?” Journal of Economic History 66 (June 2006): 433-455. Weil, Francois. “Capitalism and Industrialization in New England, 1815-1845.” Journal of American History 84 (March 1998): 1334-1354. Wills, John E. “Maritime Asia, 1500-1800: The Interactive Emergence of European Domination.” American Historical Review 98 (February 1993): 83-105. Wilson, Mark. The Business of Civil War: MIlitary Mobilization and the State, 1861-1865. Baltimore: Johns 67 History 2980x Bibliography Spring 2012 Hopkins University Press, 2006. Wright, Gavin. “Slavery and American Agricultural History.” Agricultural History 77 (2003): 527-552. Zahedieh, Nuala. “Regulation, Rent-Seeking, and the Glorious Revolution in the English Atlantic Economy.” The Economic History Review 63:4 (2010): 865-890. Zahedieh, Nuala. “The Merchants of Port Royal, Jamaica, and the Spanish Contraband Trade, 16551692.” The William and Mary Quarterly 43:4 (Oct. 1986): 570-593. 68