10/8/19 O U T L IN E CH 23: PERFECT COMPETITION • The Theory of Perfect Competition • The Perfectly Competitive Firm • Production in the Short Run • Conditions of Long-Run Competitive Equilibrium Jessica Ann C. Jola 1 2 T H E O RY O F P E R F E C T C O M P E T IT IO N M A R K E T ST RU C T U R E A theory of market structure based on four assumptions: • The particular environment of a firm, the characteristics of which influence the firm’s pricing and output decisions. (1)There are many sellers and many buyers, none of which is large in relation to total sales or purchases. (2)Each firm produces and sells a homogeneous product. (3)Buyers and sellers have all relevant information with respect to prices, product quality, sources of supply, and so on. (4)There is easy entry into and exit from the industry. 3 4 1 10/8/19 MARKET DEMAND CURVE AND FIRM DEMAND CURVE IN PERFECT COMPETITION A PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRM IS A PRICE TAKER • A seller that does not have the ability to control the price of the product it sells; it takes the price determined in the market. • The market, composed of all buyers and sellers, establishes the equilibrium price. (a) • A single perfectly competitive firm then faces a horizontal (flat, perfectly elastic) demand curve. (b) 5 6 THE DEMAND CURVE AND THE MARGINAL REVENUE CURVE FOR A PERFECTIVELY COMPETITIVE FIRM M A R G IN A L R E V E N U E (M R ) The change in total revenue that results from selling one additional unit of output. 𝑀𝑅 = ∆𝑇𝑅 ∆𝑄 • By computing marginal revenue, we find that it is equal to price. • By plotting columns 1 and 2, we obtain the firm’s demand curve; • By plotting columns 2 and 4, we obtain the firm’s marginal revenue curve. • The two curves are the same. 7 8 2 10/8/19 IN -C L A SS AC T IV IT Y 2 3 -1 1. IN -C L A SS AC T IV IT Y 2 3 -1 2. Why is a perfectly competitive firm a price taker? If a firm is a price taker, it does not have the ability to control the price of the product it sells. What does this mean? The easy and incomplete answer is that a perfectly competitive firm is a price taker because it is in a market where it cannot control the price of the product it sells. But this simply leads to the question why can’t it control the price? The answer is that it is in a market where its supply is small relative to the total market supply, it sells a homogeneous good, and all buyers and sellers have all relevant information. The firm cannot change the price of the product it sells by its actions. For example, if firm A cuts back on the supply of what it produces and the price of its product does not change, then we’d say that the firm cannot control the price of the product it sells. In other words, if price is independent of a firm’s actions, the firm does not have any control over price. 9 10 IN -C L A SS AC T IV IT Y 2 3 -1 IN -C L A SS AC T IV IT Y 2 3 -1 3.The horizontal demand curve for the perfectly competitive firm signifies that it cannot sell any of its product for a price higher than the market equilibrium price. Why not? 4. Suppose the firms in a real-world market do not sell a homogeneous product. Does it necessarily follow that the market is not perfectly competitive? No. A market doesn’t have to perfectly match all assumptions of the theory of perfect competition for it to be labeled a perfectly competitive market. What is important is whether it acts as if it is perfectly competitive. “If it walks like a duck and it quacks like a duck, it’s a duck.” Well, if it acts like a perfectly competitive market, it’s a perfectly competitive market. If a perfectly competitive firm tries to charge a price higher than equilibrium price, all buyers will know this (assumption 3). These buyers will then simply buy from another firm that sells the same (homogeneous) product (assumption 2) 11 12 3 10/8/19 QUANTITY OF OUTPUT THE PERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRM WILL PRODUCE P RO F IT-M A X IM IZ AT IO N RU L E • Profit is maximized by producing the quantity of output at which MR = MC. • The firm’s demand curve is horizontal at the equilibrium price. Its demand curve is its marginal revenue curve. The firm produces that quantity of output at which MR = MC. 13 • For Perfect Competition, profit is maximized when P = MR = MC* * This condition is unique for perfect competition and does not hold for other market structures. 14 R E SO U R C E A L L O C AT IV E E F F IC IE N C Y CH 25: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, OLIGOPOLY, AND GAME THEORY • Producing a good—any good—until price equals marginal cost ensures that all units of the good are produced that are of greater value to buyers than the alternative goods that might have been produced. • A firm that produces the quantity of output at which price equals marginal cost (P = MC) is said to exhibit resource allocative efficiency. Jessica Ann C. Jola • For a perfectly competitive firm, profit maximization and resource allocative efficiency are not at odds. 15 16 4 10/8/19 O U T L IN E M O N O P O L IST IC C O M P E T IT IO N • Monopolistic Competition The theory of monopolistic competition is built on three assumptions: • Excess Capacity Theorem 1. There are many sellers and buyers. • Oligopoly 2. Each firm in the industry produces and sells a slightly differentiated product. • Cartel Theories • Game Theory 3. There is easy entry and exit. • Theory of Contestable Markets 17 18 M O N O P O L IST IC C O M P E T IT IO N IN -C L A SS AC T IV IT Y 2 5 -1 1. How is a monopolistic competitor like a monopolist? How is it like a perfect competitor? • The monopolistic competitor is a price searcher. • For the monopolistic competitor, P > MR, and the marginal revenue curve lies below the demand curve. A monopolistic competitor is like a monopolist in that it faces a downward-sloping demand curve; it is a price searcher, P > MR; and it is not resource allocative efficient. • The monopolistic competitor produces the quantity of output at which MR =MC. It is like a perfect competitor in that it sells to many buyers and competes with many sellers, and there is easy entry into and exit from the market. • It charges the highest price per unit for this output. 19 20 5 10/8/19 IN -C L A SS AC T IV IT Y 2 5 -1 O L IG O P O LY A theory of market structure based on three assumptions: 2. Why do monopolistic competitors operate at excess capacity? • There are few sellers and many buyers. Essentially, monopolistic competitors face downward sloping demand curves. Because the demand curve is downward sloping, it cannot be tangent to the lowest point on a U-shaped ATC curve. 21 • Interdependence among firms • Firms produce and sell either homogeneous or differentiated products. • There are significant barriers to entry. 22 O L IG O P O L IST C O N C E N T R AT IO N R AT IO • The oligopolist is a price searcher. • Used to define oligopolistic market structure. • It produces the quantity of output at which MR = MC. • The percentage of industry sales (or assets, output, labor force, or some other factor) accounted for by x number of firms in the industry. • Four-Firm Concentration Ratio: CR4 = Percentage of industry sales accounted for by four largest firms • Eight-Firm Concentration Ratio: CR8 = Percentage of industry sales accounted for by eight largest firms 23 24 6 10/8/19 C A RT E L THE BENEFITS OF A C ARTEL (TO C ARTEL MEMBERS) • The key behavioral assumption of the cartel theory is that, within a given industry, oligopolists act as if there were only one firm. • We assume the industry is in long-run competitive equilibrium, producing Q1 and charging P1. There are no profits. • They form a cartel to capture the benefits that would exist for a monopolist. A cartel is an organization of firms that reduces output and increases price in an effort to increase joint profits. 25 • A reduction in output to QC through the formation of a cartel raises prices to PC and brings profits of CPCAB. 26 THE BENEFITS OF CHEATING ON THE CARTEL AGREEMENT PROBLEMS ASSOCIATED WITH C ARTELS • The situation for a representative firm of a cartel: in long-run competitive equilibrium, it produces q1 and charges P1, earning zero economic profits. • the problem of forming the cartel, • the problem of formulating policy, • the problem of entry into the industry, and • As a consequence of the cartel agreement, it reduces output to qC and charges PC. • the problem of cheating. • Its profits are the area CPCAB. • If it cheats on the cartel agreement and others do not, the firm will increase output to qCC and reap profits of FPCDE. 27 28 7 10/8/19 IN -C L A SS AC T IV IT Y 2 5 -2 THE BENEFITS OF CHEATING ON THE C ARTEL AGREEMENT 1. “Firms have an incentive to form a cartel, but once it is formed, they have an incentive to cheat.” What, specifically, is the incentive to form the cartel, and what is the incentive to cheat on the cartel? • Note, however, that if this firm can cheat on the cartel agreement, so can others. Given the monetary benefits gained by cheating, it is likely that the cartel will exist for only a short time. The incentive in both cases is the same: profit. Firms have an incentive to form a cartel to increase their profits. After the cartel is formed, however, each firm has an incentive to break the cartel to increase its profits even further. If there is no cartel agreement, the firm is earning zero profits. But it can earn even higher profits by cheating on the cartel. 29 30 IN -C L A SS AC T IV IT Y 2 5 -2 G A M E T H E O RY 2. Is an oligopolistic firm a price taker or price searcher? Explain your answer. A mathematical technique used to analyze the behavior of decision makers who An oligopolistic firm is a price searcher. A price searcher faces a downward-sloping demand curve, which an oligopolistic firm faces. Also, an oligopolistic firm has some control over the price it charges, which is the hallmark of a price searcher. • (1) try to reach an optimal position for themselves through game playing or the use of strategic behavior, • (2) are fully aware of the interactive nature of the process at hand, and • (3) anticipate the moves of other decision makers. 31 32 8 10/8/19 GAME THEORY EXAMPLE: PRISONER’S DILEMMA CARTELS AND PRISONER’S DILEMMA Nathan and Bob each have two choices: confess or not confess. No matter what Bob does, it is always better for Nathan to confess. No matter what Nathan does, it is always better for Bob to confess. Both Nathan and Bob confess and end up in box 4 where each pays a $3,000 fine. • Both men would have been better off had they not confessed. That way they would have ended up in box 1 paying a $2,000 fine. • • • • 33 • Both firms A and B earn higher profits holding to a (cartel) agreement than not, but each will earn even higher profits if it breaks the agreement while the other firm holds to it. • If cartel formation is a prisoner’s dilemma situation, we predict that cartels will be short-lived. 34 9