Lesson 12 Collective Bargaining and Labor Relations 12.1 Overview The main source of negotiating leverage for unions is the ability to strike, which interrupts production, sales, and profits. In the end, however, such conflicts must be balanced against the common interests that bind workers and companies together. Worker jobs and income, as well as company profits, depend on the two parties being able to cooperate to assure the ability of the company to be competitive and survive. 12.2 Learning Outcomes At the end of this lesson, you should be able to: Describe what is meant by collective bargaining and labor relations. Identify the labor relations goals of management, labor unions, and society Describe the major labor–management interactions: organizing, contract negotiations, and contract administration. 12.3 Course Materials Topic 1: The Labor Relations Framework John Dunlop, former secretary of labor and a leading industrial relations scholar, suggestedin the book Industrial Relations Systems (1958) that a successful industrial relations system consists of four elements: (1) an environmental context (technology, market pressures, and the legal framework, especially as it affects bargaining power); (2) participants, including employees and their unions, management, and the government; (3) a ―web of rules‖ (rules of the game) that describe the process by which labor and management interact and resolve disagreements (such as the steps followed in settling contract grievances); and (4) ideology.1 For the industrial relations system to operate properly, the three participants must, to some degree, have a common ideology (e.g., acceptance of the capitalist system) and must accept the roles of the other participants. Acceptance does not translate into convergence of interests, however. To the contrary, some degree of worker–management conflict is inevitable because, although the interests of the two parties overlap (e.g., survival of the firm and thus survival of workers‘ jobs and investors‘ profits), they also diverge in key respects (such as how to divide the economic profits between workers and investors). 138 MANAGEMENT One of management‘s most basic decisions is whether to encourage or discourage the unionization of its employees. It may discourage unions because it fears higher wage and benefit costs, the disruptions caused by strikes, and an adversarial relationship with its employees or, more generally, greater constraints placed on its decision-making flexibility and discretion. Historically, management has used two basic strategies to avoid unionization.9 It may seek to provide employment terms and conditions that employees will perceive as sufficiently attractive and equitable so that they see little gain from union representation. Or it may aggressively oppose union representation, even where there is significant employee interest. Use of the latter strategy has increased significantly during the last 30 to 40 years. If management voluntarily recognizes a union or if employees are already represented by a union, the focus is shifted from dealing with employees as individuals to employees as a group. 139 LABOR UNIONS Labor unions seek, through collective action, to give workers a formal and independent voice in setting the terms and conditions of their work. Table 14.1 shows typical provisions negotiated by unions in collective bargaining contracts. Labor unions attempt to represent their members‘ interests in these decisions. Without adequate union representation, not only worker wages, but also their safety and welfare, are more likely to be put at risk. This is particularly true in low-wage economies where regulatory protection may also be lacking. Topic 2: THE NATIONAL LABOR RELATIONS COMMISSION The National Labor Relations Commission is a quasi-judicial agency tasked to promote and maintain industrial peace based on social justice by resolving labor and management disputes involving local and overseas workers through compulsory arbitration and alternative modes of dispute resolution. The NLRC is a subsequent part of the Department of Labor and Employment where its policies and programs [2] are coordinated. The commission dates back to the commonwealth period, when the contract labor law act was passed in the United States Congress on January 23, 1885, it was then implemented in the Philippines on June 6, 1899. RULES OF PROCEDURES The Labor Code of the Philippines which is part of article 218[6] of the revised penal code has issued the NLRC the following set rules for handling its cases: Rule 1 – Title and Construction, only signifies the title of the governing rules. Rule 2 - Definition of Terms, defines the legal terms used in the terms and phrases defined in Article 212 of the Labor Code shall be given the same meanings when used in NLRC cases. Rule 3 - Pleadings, notices and appearances, signifies that the parties involved will be given due notice for any impending proceedings. Rule 4 - Venue, assignment and disposition of cases, advises that cases which Labor Arbiters will file the case in the regional arbitration branch that has jurisdiction over the workplace unless there are justifiable reasons why it should be filled elsewhere. An example of this would be a sensitivity of a case where one party is in danger. Rule 5 - Proceedings before Labor Arbiters, signifies that the Labor Arbiters shall have exclusive jurisdiction to hear and decide all cases involving labor issues. Rule 6 – Appeals, it signifies where to submit an appeal after a case has been decided and this area also advises both parties of the timeframe given for an appeal to be submitted. Rule 7 - Proceedings before the Commission, this rule suggests that the process flow of each case proceeding from the time a case is filled towards the decision or further into the motion for reconsideration. Rule 8 - Execution proceedings, signifies the rules to take place after decisions have been done and how the winning party could claim the damages incurred. Rule 9 - Certified cases, signifies that the NLRC's cases are certified by law and any cases which happened within the proceedings are considered final unless appeals are made. 140 Rule 10 – Contempt, signifies that committing any act of misbehaviour in the presence of the Chairman or any Commissioner or Labor Arbiter will herby be given an additional penalty. Rule 11 – Injunction, illustrates the injunctions that may happen within a labor case. Rule 12 - Commission seal and records, and powers and duties of Commission officials, illustrates the notices to be given, how archives may be accessed and duties of the officials and employees of NLRC. Rule 13 – Effectivity, indicates that these rules are in effect 15 days after August 31, 1990 which means that these rules were officially used starting September 15, 1990. An important characteristic of a union is whether it is a craft or industrial union. The electrical workers‘ and carpenters‘ unions are craft unions, meaning that the members all have a particular skill or occupation. Craft unions often are responsible for training their members (through apprenticeships) and for supplying craft workers to employers. Requests for carpenters, for example, would come to the union hiring hall, which would decide which carpenters to send out. Thus, craft workers may work for many employers over time, their constant link being to the union. A craft union‘s bargaining power depends greatly on the control it can exercise over the supply of its workers. LOCAL UNIONS Even when a national union plays the most critical role in negotiating terms of a collective bargaining contract, negotiation occurs at the local level as well as over work rules and other issues that are locally determined. In addition, administration of the contract is largely carried out at the local union level. Consequently, the bulk of day-to-day interaction between labor and management takes place at the local union level. The local of an industrial-based union may correspond to a single large facility or to a number of small facilities. In a craft-oriented union, the local may cover a city or a region. The local union typically elects officers (like president, vice president, treasurer). Responsibility for contract negotiation may rest with the officers, or a bargaining committee may be formed for this purpose. Typically the national union provides assistance, ranging from background data about other settlements and technical advice to sending a representative to lead the negotiations. UNION MEMBERSHIP AND BARGAINING POWER At the strategic level, management and unions meet head-on over the issue of union organizing. Increasingly, employers are actively resisting unionization in an attempt to control costs and maintain their flexibility. Unions, on the other hand, must organize new members and hold on to their current members to have the kind of bargaining power and financial resources needed to achieve their goals in future organizing and to negotiate and administer contracts with management. Structural Changes in the Economy At the risk of oversimplifying, we might say that unions have traditionally been strongest in urban workplaces (especially those outside the South) that employ middle-aged men in blue-collar jobs. However, much recent job growth has occurred among women and youth in the service sector (in contrast to the manufacturing sector) of the economy. 141 Although unionizing such groups is possible, unions have so far not had much success organizing these groups in the private sector. Despite the importance of structural changes in the economy, studies show that they account for no more than one-quarter of the overall union membership decline. Increased Employer Resistance Almost one-half of large employers in a survey reported that their most important labor goal was to be union-free. This contrasts sharply with 60 years ago, when Jack Barbash wrote that ―many tough bargainers [among employers] prefer the union to a situation where there is no union. Most of the employers in rubber, basic steel and the automobile industry fall in this category.‖ The idea then was that an effective union could help assess and communicate the interests of employees to management, thus helping management make better decisions. But product-market pressures, such as foreign competition and deregulation (e.g., trucking, airlines, telecommunications), have contributed to increasing employer resistance to unions.15 These changes in the competitive environment have contributed to a change in management‘s perspective and goals. Associate Union Membership - A form of union membership by which the union receives dues in exchange for services (e.g., health insurance, credit cards) but does not provide representation in collective bargaining. Corporate Campaigns - Union activities designed to exert public, financial, or political pressure on employers during the union-organizing process. Topic 3: Union and Management Interactions: Contract Negotiation THE NEGOTIATION PROCESS Richard Walton and Robert McKersie suggested that labor–management negotiations could be broken into four subprocesses: distributive bargaining, integrative bargaining, attitudinal structuring, and intraorganizational bargaining. Distributive bargaining focuses on dividing a fixed economic ―pie‖ between the two sides. A wage increase, for example, means that the union gets a larger share of the pie, management a smaller share. It is a win–lose situation. Integrative bargaining has a win–win focus; it seeks solutions beneficial to both sides. So if management needs to reduce labor costs, it could reach an agreement with the union to avoid layoffs in return for the union agreeing to changes in work rules that might enhance productivity. Attitudinal structuring refers to the relationship and trust between labor and management negotiators. Where the relationship is poor, it may be difficult for the two sides to engage in integrative bargaining because each side hesitates to trust the other side to carry out its part of the deal. For example, the union may be reluctant to agree to productivity-enhancing work-rule changes to enhance job security if, in the past, it has made similar concessions but believes that management did not stick to its assurance of greater job security. Thus the long-term relationship between the two parties can have a very important impact on negotiations and their outcomes. 142 Intraorganizational bargaining reminds us that labor–management negotiations involve more than just two parties. Within management, and to an even greater extent within the union, different factions can have conflicting objectives. High-seniority workers, who are least likely to be laid off, may be more willing to accept a contract that has layoffs (especially if it also offers a significant pay increase for those whose jobs are not at risk). Less senior workers would likely feel very differently. Thus, negotiators and union leaders must simultaneously satisfy both the management side and their own internal constituencies. If they do not, they risk the union membership‘s rejecting the contract, or they risk being voted out of office in the next election. Management, too, is unlikely to be of one mind about how to approach negotiations. Some will focus more on long-term employee relations, others will focus on cost control, and still others will focus on what effect the contract will have on stockholders MANAGEMENT’S PREPARATION FOR NEGOTIATIONS 1. Establishing interdepartmental contract objectives: The employer‘s industrial relations department needs to meet with the accounting, finance, production, marketing, and other departments and set contract goals that will permit each department to meet its responsibilities. As an example, finance may suggest a cost figure above which a contract settlement would seriously damage the company‘s financial health. The bargaining team needs to be constructed to take these various interests into account. 2. Reviewing the old contract: This step focuses on identifying provisions of the contract that might cause difficulties by hindering the company‘s productivity or flexibility or by leading to significant disagreements between management and the union. 3. Preparing and analyzing data: Information on labor costs and the productivity of competitors, as well as data the union may emphasize, needs to be prepared and analyzed. The union data might include cost-of-living changes and agreements reached by other unions that could serve as a target. Data on employee demographics and seniority are relevant for establishing the costs of such benefits as pensions, health insurance, and paid vacations. Finally, management needs to know how much it would be hurt by a strike. How long will its inventory allow it to keepmeeting customer orders? To what extent are other companies positioned to step in and offer replacement products? How difficult would it be to find replacement workers if the company decided to continue operations during a strike? 4. Anticipating union demands: Recalling grievances over the previous contract, having ongoing discussions with union leaders, and becoming aware of settlements at other companies are ways of anticipating likely union demands and developing potential counterproposals. 5. Establishing the cost of possible contract provisions: Wages have not only a direct influence on labor costs but often an indirect effect on benefit costs (such as Social Security and paid vacation). Recall that benefits add about 46 cents to every dollar‘s worth of wages. Also, wage or benefit increases that seem manageable in the first year of a contract can accumulate to less manageable levels over time. 6. Preparing for a strike: If management intends to operate during a strike, it may need to line up replacement workers, increase its security, and figure out how to deal with incidents on the picket line and elsewhere. If management does not intend to operate during a strike (or if the company will not be operating at normal levels), it needs to alert suppliers and customers and consider possible ways to avoid the loss of their business. This could even entail purchasing a competitor‘s product in order to have something to sell to customers. 143 7. Determining strategy and logistics: Decisions must be made about the amount of authority the negotiating team will have. What concessions can it make on its own, and which ones require it to check with top management? On which issues can it compromise, and on which can it not? Decisions regarding meeting places and times must also be made. MANAGEMENT’S WILLINGNESS TO TAKE A STRIKE Management‘s willingness to take a strike comes down to two questions: 1. Can the company remain profitable over the long run if it agrees to the union’s demands? The answer is more likely to be yes to the extent that higher labor costs can be passed on to consumers without losing business. This, in turn, is most likely when the price increase is small because labor costs are a small fraction of total costs or there is little price competition in the industry. Low price competition can result from regulated prices, from competition based on quality (rather than price), or from the union‘s organizing all or most of the employers in the industry, which eliminates labor costs as a price factor. Unions share part of management‘s concern with long-term competitiveness because a decline in competitiveness can translate into a decline in employment levels. On the other hand, the majority of union members may prefer to have higher wages, despite employment declines, particularly if a minority of the members (those with low seniority) suffer more employment loss and the majority keep their employment with higher wages. 2. Can the company continue to operate in the short run despite a strike? Although ―hanging tough‖ on its bargaining goals may pay off for management in the long run, the short-run concern is the loss of revenues and profits from production being disrupted. The cost to strikers is a loss of wages and possibly a permanent loss of jobs. Under what conditions is management most able to take a strike? The following factors are important: 1. Product demand: Management is less able to afford a strike when the demand for its product is strong because that is when more revenue and profits are lost. 2. Product perishability: A strike by certain kinds of employees (farm workers atharvest time, truckers transporting perishable food, airline employees at peak travel periods) will result in permanent losses of revenue, thus increasing the cost of the strike to management. 3. Technology: An organization that is capital intensive (versus labor intensive) is less dependent on its employees and more likely to be able to use supervisors or others as replacements. Telephone companies are typically able to operate through strikes, even though installing new equipment or services and repair work may take significantly longer than usual. 4. Availability of replacement workers: When jobs are scarce, replacement workers are more available and perhaps more willing to cross picket lines. Using replacement workers to operate during a strike raises the stakes considerably for strikers who may be permanently replaced. Most strikers are not entitled to reinstatement until there are job openings for which they qualify. 144 If replacements were hired, such openings may not occur for some time (if at all). In some cases, companies can use managers to temporarily replace striking workers. 5. Multiple production sites and staggered contracts: Multiple sites and staggered contracts permit employers to shift production from the struck facility to facilities that, even if unionized, have contracts that expire at different times (so they are not able to strike at the same time). 6. Integrated facilities: When one facility produces something that other facilities need for their products, the employer is less able to take a strike because the disruption to production goes beyond that single facility. The just-in-time production system, which provides very little stockpiling of parts, further weakens management‘s ability to take a strike. 7. Lack of substitutes for product: A strike is more costly tothe employer if customers have a readily available alternative source from which to purchase the goods or services the company provides. Topic 4: Union and Management Interactions: Contract Administration GRIEVANCE PROCEDURE Table 14.11 Steps in a Typical Grievance Procedure Employee-initiated grievance Step 1 a. Employee discusses grievance or problem orally with supervisor. b. Union steward and employee may discuss problem orally with supervisor. c. Union steward and employee decide (1) whether problem has been resolved or (2) if not resolved, whether a contract violation has occurred. Step 2 a. Grievance is put in writing and submitted to production superintendent or other designated line manager. b. Steward and management representative meet and discuss grievance. Manage ment’s response is put in writing. A member of the industrial relations staff may be consulted at this stage. Step 3 a. Grievance is appealed to top line management and industrial relations staff repre sentatives. Additional local or international union officers may become involved in discussions. Decision is put in writing. Step 4 a. Union decides on whether to appeal unresolved grievance to arbitration according to procedures specified in its constitution and/or bylaws. b. Grievance is appealed to arbitration for binding decision. Discharge grievance a. Procedure may begin at step 2 or step 3. b. Time limits between steps may be shorter to expedite the process. Union or group grievance a. Union representative initiates grievance at step 1 or step 2 on behalf of affected class of workers or union representatives. 145 Although the negotiation process (and the occasional resulting strike) receive the most publicity, the negotiation process typically occurs only about every three years, whereas contract administration goes on day after day, year after year. The two processes—negotiation and administration—are linked, of course. Vague or incomplete contract language developed in the negotiation process can make administration of the contract difficult. Such difficulties can, in turn, create conflict that can spill over into the next negotiation process.Furthermore, events during the negotiation process—strikes, the use of replacement workers, or violence by either side—can lead to management and labor difficulties in working successfully under a contract. Arbitration - A procedure for resolving collective bargaining impasses by which an arbitrator chooses a solution to the dispute. The most formal type of outside intervention is arbitration, under which a solution is actually chosen by an arbitrator (or arbitration board). In some instances the arbitrator can fashion a solution (conventional arbitration). In other cases the arbitrator must choose either the management‘s or union‘s final offer (final offer arbitration) on either the contract as a whole or on an issue-by-issue basis. Traditionally, arbitrating the enforcement or interpretation of contract terms (rights arbitration) has been widely accepted, whereas arbitrating the actual writing or setting of contract terms (interest arbitration, our focus here) has been reserved for special circumstances. These include some public sector negotiations, where strikes may be especially costly (such as those by police or firefighters) and a very few private-sector situations, where strikes have been especially debilitating to both sides (the steel industry in the 1970s). What criteria do arbitrators use to reach a decision? In the most common case— discharge or discipline—the following due process questions are important: 1. Did the employee know what the rule or expectation was and what the consequences of not adhering to it were? 2. Was the rule applied in a consistent and predictable way? In other words, are all employees treated the same? 3. Are facts collected in a fair and systematic manner? An important element of this principle is detailed record keeping. Both employee actions (such as tardiness) and management‘s response (verbal or written warnings) should be carefully documented. 4. Does the employee have the right to question the facts and present a defense? An example in a union setting is a hearing with a shop steward present. 5. Does the employee have the right to appeal a decision? An example is recourse to an impartial third party, such as an arbitrator. 6. Is there progressive discipline? Except perhaps for severe cases, an arbitrator will typically look for evidence that an employee was alerted as early as possible that behavior was inappropriate and the employee was given a chance to change prior to some form of severe discipline, such as discharge. 146 7. Are there unique mitigating circumstances? Although discipline must be consistent, individuals differ in terms of their prior service, performance, and discipline record. All of these factors may need to be considered. COOPERATIVE LABOR–MANAGEMENT STRATEGIES Jack Barbash described the nature of the traditional relationship between labor and management (during both the negotiation and administration phases) as follows: “Bargaining is a love–hate, cooperation–conflict relationship. The parties have a common interest in maximizing the total revenue which finances their respective returns. But they take on adversarial postures in debating how the revenue shall be divided as between wages and profits. It is the adversarial posture which has historically set the tone of the relationship.” Topic 5: Labor Relations Outcomes The effectiveness of labor relations can be evaluated from management, labor, and societal perspectives. Management seeks to control costs and enhance productivity and quality. Labor unions seek to raise wages and benefits and exercise control over how employees spend their time at work (such as through work rules). Each of the three parties typically seeks to avoid forms of conflict (like strikes) that impose significant costs on everyone. In this section we examine several outcomes. STRIKES Table 14.14 presents data on strikes in the United States that involved 1,000 or more employees. Of the 11 large strikes in 2014, five were in health care (nurses) and two were in education (teachers, professors). So most of the strikes involved white-collar employees. Because strikes are more likely in large units, the lack of data on smaller units is probably not a major concern, although such data would, of course, raise the figure on the estimated time lost to strikes. For example, for the 1960s, this estimate is 0.12% using data on strikes involving 1,000 or more employees versus 0.17% for all strikes. Although strikes impose significant costs on union members, employers, and society, it is clear from Table 14.14 that strikes are the exception rather than the rule. Very little working time is lost to strikes in the United States (with annual work hours of 1,800, less than 6 minutes per worker and less than one hour per unionized worker in 2014) and their frequency in recent years is generally low by historical standards. 147 PRODUCTIVITY There has been much debate regarding the effects of unions on productivity.79 Unions are believed to decrease productivity in at least three ways: (1) the union pay advantage causes employers to use less labor and more capital per worker than they would otherwise, which reduces efficiency across society; (2) union contract provisions may limit permissible workloads, restrict the tasks that particular workers are allowed to perform, and require employers to use more employees for certain jobs than they otherwise would; and (3) strikes, slowdowns, and working-to-rule (slowing down production by following every workplace rule to an extreme) result in lost production. PROFITS AND STOCK PERFORMANCE Even if unions do raise productivity, a company‘s profits and stock performance may still suffer if unions raise costs (such as wages) or decrease investment by a greater amount. Evidence shows that unions have a large negative effect on profits and that union coverage tends to decline more quickly in firms experiencing lower shareholder returns, suggesting that some firms become more competitive partly by reducing union strength. Similarly, one study finds that each dollar of unexpected increase in collectively bargained labor costs results in a dollar reduction in shareholder wealth. 148