Uploaded by jaimejrbarrenechea

BEPP 250 Study Guide

advertisement
BEPP 250 Study Guide
Slides 1
-
Managerial Economics Is the use of (micro)economic theory for the purpose of informing
business/policy decision-making.
- Body of knowledge that studies individual-level behavior and decision-making in
order to provide tools (models), results and ideas to help us:
- Understand observed phenomenon (positive economics)
- Guide decisions (normative economics)
- Key principles:
- Optimization: Individual objectives + constraints → shape decisions and
observed behavior
- Equilibrium: observed outcomes ← interaction across individuals’
decisions, no incentive to change further, “system at rest”
Slides 2 - Choice, Preference and Utility
- Theory of consumer behavior:
- Evaluate willingness to pay, predict demand, anticipate customer reaction, asses
and improve public policy
- Goal: Derive a demand function
- We see making people choices from a ​choice set ​and we want to ​rationalize​ these
choices, we analyze ​preferences and constraints​ - with this we create a ​utility
function​.
- Preferences satisfy the following qualities:
- Completeness - ​When facing a choice between two bundles a consumer can
rank them, in the form that one is preferred over the other or they create equal
utility
- Transitivity​ - consumers' rankings are logically consistent, if a is preferred over b
and b is preferred over c then a is preferred over c.
- Monotonicity - ​All else same more of a good is better
- Budget Constraint
- Budget constraint limits a customer form choosing any bundle, this constraint
defines our budget set
- Budget Set - ​the set of feasible (affordable) bundles given price and income
- I.e set of bundles where expenditure is less than or equal to how much
we spend.
- Budget Line → p1x1 +p2x2 = I
- Utility Function
- Preference relations and indifference curves at not practical in empirical setting,
therefore we use a more convenient set of preferences. If an individual has
preferences that satisfy completeness, transitivity and monotonicity we can
represent this preference with a ​utility function​.
-
-
-
-
Preferences are basically a ranking over bundles. All information can be captured
by a mathematical function that assigns a number for each bundle, such that the
order of preferences is fully captured.
Utility Maximization - Slides 3
- In order to solve the ​utility maximization problem ​ we must link the IC to the
utility functions.
- Given the link between ICs and the utility function the most preferred affordable
bundle is equivalent to finding (x, y) such that
- u(x, y) = U is the largest and (x, y) satisfies the budget constraint.
- I.e maximize utility subject tot the budget constraint
- Optimal bundle - ​ a point where the IC is ​tangent ​ to the budget line
- Mathematically this point of tangency is captured by ​equality of the
slopes of the budget line and the IC at the optimal bundle​.
- Equations in notes
- Slope of IC = Marginal rate of substitution (MRS)
- MRS
- (delta)y/(delta)x tells us how much we are willing to give up in
terms of y in exchange for an increase in x, while keeping utility
constant. This is also the slope between two points on the IC.
- (delta)y/(delta)x is the first derivative dx/dy. This measures the tradeoff
between y and x.
Relating MRS and Marginal Utility
- The increase in x given by Δx increased our utility, say by ΔxU per unit of x
Similarly, the decrease in Δy decreased our utility, say by ΔyU per unit of y
Being on the same IC means that after all these changes in x and y, at the end
of the day our utility does not change: ΔU=0
- Slope of IC is equal to the negative ratio of marginal utility
- equality of the slopes of the budget line and the IC at the optimal bundle​.
- Rearranging this gives us a particular optimality condition which we refer
to as (B4Bs) the ​Equality of bang for bucks​.
Optimality and B4B
Bang - for - buck (B4B) - benefit-cost ratio of the marginal (the very last) unit.
- Thinking at the margin
Optimal Behavior
- As long as one good has a higher bang for buck that the other, allocate
consumption here
- If B4Bs are equal then you stop
- If you hit some constraint, (​you can't consume more or you can't give up
negative quantities)​ then you stop.
Demand Part 3: Demand Function - Slides 4
- Optimality condition
- Interior Solution
- Solution involves consuming strictly positive amounts of each good.
- Mathematically: First order condition is both necessary and sufficient
- Optimality condition→ equality of B4Bs
- Corner solution
- Solution entails spending all your income on the good with the highest B4B
- Mathematically - non negativity constraint binds
- Optimality condition→ B4Bx > B4By then its optimal to set y=0
- Take into account there could be additional constraints one must satisfy.
- You will usually know what solution to look for
- But you can notice by looking at the behavior of the marginal utilities.
- Interior solution → marginal utilities go to infinity when consumption is 0
- Corner solution→ when marginal utilities are non-decreasing
- Note for which values of parameters(prices, income) solution may be non-negative
- Law of Demand : ​Demand for a good is decreasing in its own price, demand curve
slopes downward
- Elasticities (Linear Demand)
- Own price elasticity - % change in quantity with respect to % in the good s price
- Cross Price Elasticity - % change in quantity with respect to % in other products
price
Supply: Part 1 - Production Function
- Theory of Firm Behavior, must know to:
- Predict how much a firm is willing to supply at a given price
- Understand Industry dynamics
- Figure out how to change incentives to encourage/discourage supply
- Learn how to derive the supply function, ​pairing with demand function we can predict
market outcomes
- Assumption: Firm choose quantities in order to maximize profits:
- Profits (q) = Revenue (q) - Cost (q)
- To figure out how much to supply (q), we first need to figure out how to produce a
given quantity q with the goal of minimizing cost, 9z, y) -> Cost(q)
- Key Questions
- What inputs do we need and how do we combine them to produce output q?
- → Production function: transform input bundle (x, y) to q
- What is the optimal input bundle given input prices and required output q?
- Sole cost minimization problem to get cost (q)
- Production Function
- A firm transforms inputs (factors of production) such as capital K and labor L into
output q
- Short vs Long- run
-
Whether inputs can be adjusted depends on decision time horizon:
- Short-run: At least one input (fixed input) can’t be adjusted, suppose k,
therefore only l is the input that can be varied
- Long run: all inputs can be adjusted
- Production function concepts
- Measures of productivity
- Returns to scale→ How much does output change if a firm
increases all its inputs proportionally?
- Marginal and average product
- Law of diminishing marginal returns
- Isoquants
- Marginal rate of substitution
- Marginal and Average Product
- Decisions driven by marginal productivity
- The ​average​ product of labor is the ratio of output to the amount of labor
used
- The ​marginal​ product of labor is the additional output produced by an
additional unit of labor, holding all other factors constant.
- Marginal product drive average product
- Law of Diminishing marginal returns
- As a firm increases its use of and input (holding all else constant), the marginal
product of the input decreases.
- Isoquants
- AN isoquant is a set of input bundles that produce the same quantity of output.
- The slope of the isoquant measures the tradeoff between inputs, i.e the ​Marginal
Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS)
- We can derive an expression for MRTS as a function of the marginal products of
2 inputs
Cost Minimization - Supply: Part 2 - Slides 6
- Isocost Line - collection of bundles that have the same cost
- Optimality - we want to find the cheapest input bundle that will produce at least q units of
output (bundle on or above the isoquant)
- Slope of the isoquant = slope of the isocost (optimal bundle input for interior case)
- Cost minimization in the long run
- All inputs can be varied thus we need two equations
- Optimality condition involving B4Bs
- Production Constraint → f(x, y) = q (be wary different from budget
constraint)
- Short run Cost Function
- Some inputs are fixed which adds an additional constraint to our cost
minimization problem.
-
When one variable is fixed, we only have one unknown, x, so one
equation is sufficient. Typically, this equation is the production constraint
with the fixed input is imposed:
Supply: Part 3 - Supply Function - Slides 7
- We assume firm chooses output q to maximize profit P(q) = R(q) - C(q)
- We refer to economic profit = revenue - opportunity cost
- Profit max problem
- Optimal output q solve the profit maximization problem
- Profit is maximized when marginal profit is 0
- Thus Marginal Revenue = Marginal Cost (proof in
bible)
- Assumption: Perfectly Competitive Markets
- A perfectly competitive market is where firms and
consumers act as price takers (no market power)
- Firm cannot influence market outcomes
- Firm takes market price p as given and fixed regardless of q
- Perfectly elastic demand curve
- Therefore, a price taking firm’s revenue is R(q) = pq
- Since MR(q) = p a price taking firm maximizes profit by choosing q such that p =
MC(q)
- Operate or Shutdown?
- A firm should operate as long as revenues cover its ​relevant costs.
- You only pay variable costs when q>0
- Fixed costs are relevant if they can be recovered or not
- Costs that can’t be recovered are called ​sunk costs​ those that can are
called ​avoidable costs
- Only avoidable costs are relevant to shutdown
- Therefore, operate if: Revenues > Variable costs + Avoidable Fixed costs
- Operating at a Loss
- This rule does not mean a firm operates in positive numbers
- pq - VC(q) - F > 0
- Which requires p>AVC(q) + AFC(q) = AC(q)
- If sunk costs are large this can mean the firm operates at a loss, however its
better to lose less money than shut down
- Shutdown Price
- Lowest price at which a firm will operate
- P = AAC(q)
Midterm #2
Lecture 10: Monopoly Market Power
- Most extreme case of market power→ monopolist
Monopoly→ Firm is only sell of a product that does not have close substitutes (consumers only
alternative is to no consume, and there is 0 cross-price elasticity with any other product)
- Monopolies are usually defined as having 70+% market power has effective control,
these arise from innovative tech, cost advantages, network effects, etc
- SSNIP Test - check if a small price increase leads to consumers switching to
another product, i.e compute cross-price elasticity
- For monopolistic firms it thinks about how q will affect p
- Price is and function of q in the firm's profit maximization problem
- For a firm with market power marginal revenue must me less than 0
-
- When inverse demand is linear, you can find MR by doubling the slope
- MR can be a function of elasticity
Takeaways:
- As demand becomes more elastic the profit maximizing price goes down
- The monopolist only produces on the elastic part of demand e>1
- If demand is inelastic then increasing price leads to more revenue and less cost
therefore profits of up
- Are these bad
- They are not legal but can be regulated (electric grids)
- Welfare under a monopolist
- When a firm has market power, it will produce less than the competitive quantity
in order to keep price high. This is inefficient since there are consumers who
have WTP>MC but are prevented from buying the goods.
SO are they Bad?
- Mad - monopolies supply through high
prices, reduce CS and introduce DWL so it
lowers welfare
- This is a product of innovation routing
form competition
Lecture 12: Monopoly Price Descrimination​(Third Degree)
- Breaking the assumption that firms only price linearly
Types of Price Descrimination
- First degree:​ Firms with perfect knowledge with individual valuations charge
personalized prices.
- Welfare is maximized but there is no Consumer Surplus, aka perfect price
descrimination.
- Very hard to implement and quite unrealistic
- Second Degree:​ ​Firms offer different product quality/quantity so that consumer
self-select form the menu of products
- Business class vs economy, bulk vs single
- Third Degree: ​Firms set different prices for the exact same product in different markets
based on observable characteristics
Multiple markets strategy
- Firms face different types of buyers (loq/highly elastic), you want to set a low price for
the elastic and high for the inelastic. However for this to work:
- Firms must have market power t be able to set the price
- The fir must be able to distinguish consumers
- Consumers cannot engage in arbitrage
- Firms problem: to choose how much supply in each market to maximize profit
- Optimality condition- MR=MC, Why?
- Cuppose MC is come constant and le MR1(q2)>MR2(q2). Than we can increase
profit by selling more to market 1 since it has a higher bang for the same buck
Welfare implications
- If price discimination is not allowed, firm has to choose between selling to obh markets
or just to market that is less price sensitive
- Trade offs
- (+) Larger market since face both markets
- (-) But in order to access more price sensitive market, have to lower the
price below what you would optimally charge the market
- Selling to both market can be profiabel it
- Difference in elasticity is not big
- More price sensitive market is much larger so you don't want to miss out.
- Example in notes
Welfare Implications
- Allowing price discrimination increases profits (unless firm earns 0 profit in hihlhy
sensitve market)
- If is is optimal for a firm to exclude some market when restricted to a sinlge price then
discrimination increases surplus
-
Download