The Basis of Communist China's Incentive Policy Author(s): Charles Hoffmann Source: Asian Survey, Vol. 3, No. 5 (May, 1963), pp. 245-257 Published by: University of California Press Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/3023550 Accessed: 17-03-2019 15:26 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms University of California Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Asian Survey This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms THE BASIS OF COMMUNIST CHINA'S INCENTIVE POLICY* CHARLES HOFFMANN Leaders of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) have recognized the importance of stimulating the labor-performance of peasants and workers through effective work-incentives in the drive for rapid industrialization. In a capital-scarce economy, increased labor productivity is the sine qua non of swift capital formation and economic growth. Nevertheless, CCP leaders have accepted classic Marxist-Leninist ideological and economic prescriptions which limit narrowly the amounts of labor income available and the types of incentive techniques acceptable for stimulating work-performance. Within these limitations, however, the CCP has experimented with different techniques, both material and nonmaterial, varying them to achieve maximum results. In this essay, the ideological and economic bases of the CCP's incentive policy, and the interplay of material and non-material incentives will be examined. The narrow limits within which the interplay of incentives must operate suggest the great importance of such interplay, in which differences in the degree of emphasis between material and non-material incentives have become the principal instrument through which desired labor input objectives are to be attained. Policy changes have been signalled by the change in emphasis on material or non-material incentives. Ideological Basis of Incentive Policy Marxists have held, and still hold, that socialism and communism in their very nature stimulate the worker to expend amounts of energy far exceeding the potentials realized under capitalism. "Working for him- self," the laborer is expected to produce tirelessly, to innovate imagin tively, and to cooperate fully at all levels of production. The CCP has hewed to this orthodox line as have the other parties of the communist bloc.1 In the struggle to industrialize and construct socialism rapidly, the The writer is grateful to the Joint Committee on Contemporary China of the Social Science Research Council-American Council of Learned Societies for its research grant for the year, 1961-1962, and to Professor Choh-Ming Li, Chairman of the Center for Chinese Studies, University of California, Berkeley, and his staff for their generous assistance while the author was visiting research fellow. He also acknowledges the constructive suggestions made by Professors Walter Galenson and Li on an earlier version of this article. 1 See First Five-Year Plan for the Development of the National Economy of the People's Republic of China in 1953-1957, (Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1956), pp. 170-71. 245 This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 246 CHINA'S INCENTIVE POLICY CCP has held up the ideal of "communist man" both as a model of behavior today and as an image of what every man will be like in tomorrow's society. While projecting this image of a selfless man, the party leaders have also been quite deliberate in associating exemplary labor performance with the worker's material interests. These two elements, enlightened social behavior and rational economic behavior motivated by material interest, have appeared as essential characteristics of the incentive policy of the CCP. The ideal communist men, we are told: . . . have a high working-class sense of responsibility and boundless revolutionary enthusiasm. For the interests of the Party and the people they refuse to consider their own gains or losses and work for all they are worth. Disinterested, they always help others first and then look after themselves, bringing into play the noble collective spirit of cooperation. Imbued with the revolutionary style of daring to think, speak and act, they study indefatigably and with modesty and have made bold innovations and marvelous achievements in production. With a communist attitude towards labour, they pay no attention to remuneration, but work painstakingly and wholeheartedly for the people, achieving extraordinary successes in ordinary labour....2 While the ideal man may be a useful model, he cannot provide a realistic basis for shaping a work-incentive policy consistent with the needs of a primitive agricultural economy straining to attain rapid growth. Operating within their ideological and economic limits, the CCP leaders have tried to devise work-incentive policies and mechanisms that will transform their relatively abundant labor resources into capital, thus providing the sinews for continuous economic development. Their immediate economic goal is the increase of labor productivity at an expanding or at least continuing rate; their ultimately social goal is to achieve the economic and social conditions which will give birth to communist man. Since "socialist relations of production have been established" in China, the basis of remuneration is the classic socialist principle "from each according to his ability, to each according to his work;" i.e., the amount of pay is ideally determined by the quantity and quality of an individual's work. Thus, material incentives are expected to be a major factor motivating workers to labor tirelessly, efficiently, and ingeniously. Modifications of this socialist principle are ideologically desirable, in the form of nonmaterial incentives that help to develop a communist attitude toward work. These two polar principles-material and non-material motivation-form 2 Liu Ning-i, "Opening Speech," The National Conference of Outstanding G and Workers in Socialist Construction in Industry, Communications and Transport, Capital Construction, Finance and Trade, (Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1960) pp. 9-10. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms CHARLES HOFFMANN 247 the basis of incentive policy in Communist China and various mechanisms have been contrived to implement them effectively.3 Distribution according to labor is not viewed as an unmixed blessing, though its main effects are held to be unquestionably positive. More pay for more work is expected to encourage workers to perform their varied functions zealously and to advance their cultural and technical level. On the management side, the principle is calculated to contribute to efficient supervision over labor and production and facilitate both rational allocation of labor and establishment of a system of responsibility in production. Moreover, the application of this principle is supposed to facilitate the harmonization of the interests of the individual, the collective, and the State as well as prevent the spread of egalitarianism. Although negative effects cannot be fully avoided, they can be contained through political vigilance and indoctrination. In itself, distribution according to labor will not help to eradicate bourgeois mentality nor will it contribute to the development and strengthening of communist consciousness. Given the different levels of technical ability between mental and physical work between workers and peasants, and between urban and rural areas, this necessary income distribution mechanism will admittedly tend to perpetuate these undesirable conditions.4 Within this framework of incentive principles the CCP leaders reject sharply any notions of "absolute egalitarianism," citing the voluminous literature of Marx, Engels, Lenin and others, dealing with that particular problem and pointing out the practical objections that such a policy would raise where labor productivity is a key factor in rapid economic develop- ment.5 On ideological grounds, egalitarianism is held to be a petty bourgeois principle which only superficially attempts to satisfy man's needs and is a weapon used by "Rightists" to try to destroy worker-peasant unity by pointing up disparity in income.6 Ultimately, as socialist society evolves, the stage of communism will be approached and the communist principle of remuneration-"from each 8 See Mao Tse-tung, On the Correct Handling of Contradictions among the People, (Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1960), pp. 25, and Wang Sung-jen, "A Discussion on Remuneration According to Labor," Hsueh-hsi (Study), No. 9, May 3, 1957, translated in U. S. Consulate, Hong Kong, Extracts from Chinese Mainland Magazines (hereafter ECMM) 91, July 22, 1957, pp. 12-14, and Fang Yuan, "Distribution According to Labor Performed and Exchange at Equal Value," Hung ch'i (Red Flag) No. 7, April 1, 1959 in ECMM 168, May 18, 1959, pp. 42-44. 4 "A Discussion on the Problem of 'Distribution According to Labor'," Kuangminig jih-pao, July 21, 1959, translated in U.S. Consulate, Hong Kong, Survey of China Mainland Press (hereafter SCMP) 2077, August 17, 1959, pp. 1-5. ' Chen Yi-yen, "Acknowledgment of Difference Versus Egalitarian Distribution," Nan-fang jih-pao, December 21, 1960 in SCMP 2415, January 12, 1961, pp. 10-11, and Fang Yuan, loc. cit., p. 44. " "Why There Must Be Inequality in Wages," Cheng-chih hsueh-hsi (Political Study), No. 6, March 27, 1959 translated in U. S. Joint Publications Research Service 933D, September 22, 1959, p. 64. (Hereafter JPRS.) This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 248 CHINA'S INCENTIVE POLICY according to his ability, to each according to his needs" will operate as the sole motivating factor behind individual work effort. This is to be attained gradually as communist incentive elements in socialist society grow in scope and as the objective economic and social conditions are created. In other words, the material incentives reflecting the socialist principle of remuneration will gradually give way to the non-material as the conditions of production and work and the attitudes of workers are modified in the progressive development of the economy and society. But "distribution according to labor will remain the primary system of distribution . . . for a considerably long period of time."X7 Even in the period when the communes were being implemented and wild enthusiasm was leading to extravagant hopes and claims, the CCP leaders still seemingly maintained the orthodox position regarding the transition to communism. They pointed out that the transition from collective ownership to ownership of the people as a whole would be an early prerequisite for communism. The requirements for entering the phase of full communism were explicitly set forth: . . . The change from socialism to communism will require much more time than the change from socialist collective ownership to socialist ownership by the whole people . . with social products becoming increasingly plentiful . . . with the proportion of what is supplied gratis . . . gradually growing larger . . . with the consistent raising of the level of the people's communist understanding; with constant progress of education for the whole people; with the gradual reduction of the differences between mental and manual labour; and with the gradual diminution of the internal function of the state power, etc., the conditions for the transition to communism will also gradually mature." In every major respect, this view was congruent with that of the other parties in the communist bloc. The Economic Basis of Incentive Policy In their attempts to implement their ideological prescriptions, CCP leaders at all levels have come up against that perennial societal problem harmonizing the interests of the individual, the collective, and the state. Marxist doctrine clearly sets forth the guidelines to the solution of this problem, but both the relative and absolute incomes paid to peasants, workers, administrative employees, and professionals, have given rise to conflicts, dissatisfaction, and lowered morale. These conditions hamper the effective functioning of incentives. Consideration of the problem of 7 Ho Chun, "Several Problems Concerning Division According to Labor," Hung-ch'i, No. 11, 1959 in JPRS 87213, August 11, 1959, pp. 1-12. 8 "Resolution on Some Questions Concerning the People's Communes," in Sixth Plenary Session of the Eighth. Central Commnittee of the Communzinist Party of China, (Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1958), pp. 21-22. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms CHARLES HOFFMANN 249 harmonizing interests leads inevitably to the economic framework within which incentive policy must operate. Marxian doctrine holds that with the elimination of classes the major contradictions besetting pre-socialist society will no longer exist. Whether any other types of contradictions will arise once classes are eliminated, is not quite so clear. In China, maj or interest in this latter problem was reflected in its wide discussion in newspapers and j ournals, attention being focused mainly on the problem of "combining" the interests of the individual, the collective, and the state both in immediate and longterm contexts. These interests were seen as basically compatible, but it was admitted that contradictions do occur, and discussion of the need to resolve such conflicts of interest was serious and extensive. Of course, it was made clear that individual interests must be subservient to those of the collective and state.9 The public discussion and controversy over "contradictions" in regard to different interests probably had its parallel in high CCP circles, which culminated in a pronouncement by Mao which some interpret as an important modification or extension of orthodox Marxist doctrine. In his On the Correct Handling of Contradictions among the People, which appeared first as a speech in February, 1957,10 Mao acknowledged the existence of contradictions "among the people" which he distinguished from "contradictions between ourselves and the enemy." He maintained: The contradictions between ourselves and our enemies are an- tagonistic ones. Within the ranks of the people, contradictions am the working people are non-antagonistic, while those between the exploiters and the exploited classes have, apart from their antagonistic aspect, a non-antagonistic aspect. . . . certain contradictions do exist between the government and the masses. These include contradic- tions between the interests of the state, collective interests and individual interest; between democracy and centralism; between those in positions of leadership and the led; and contradictions arising from the bureaucratic practices of certain state functionaries in their relations with the masses. All these are contradictions among the people. Generally speaking, underlying the contradictions among the people is the basic identity of the interests of the people.1" As the title of Mao's work indicates, once the existence of "contradictions" is accepted, they must be "correctly" handled. Indeed, his discussion is in effect a guide to party policy on several significant problems, from the handling of counter-revolution to the implementation of industrializa- 9 "Combining the Individual and Public Interests of Workers,"-a summary description of articles on this question and readers' responses Hsueh-hsi, No. 10, October 2, 1955 in ECMM 17, December 5, 1955, pp. 24-30. 10 Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1960. "Ibid., pp. 9-10. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 250 CHINA'S INCENTIVE POLICY tion on a vast scale. Where conflict of interest arises over agricultural income he offers these general principles: . . . We must find the correct way to handle the three-way relationship between the tax revenue of the state, accumulation funds in the cooperative and the personal income of the peasants, and pay constant attention to making readjustments so as to resolve contradictions as they arise. Accumulation is essential for both the state and the co- operative, but in neither case should this be overdone. We should do everything possible to enable the peasants in normal years to raise their personal incomes year by year on the basis of increased production.'2 The quotation itself may seem to be too general to adumbrate specific policies for handling contradictions over income distribution. And yet, given the early emphasis on rapid industrialization and the pragmatic call "to make readjustments," the outlines of the economic limits within which material incentives have to function begin to emerge. Within the frame- work of maximum capital accumulation, the principle of distribution ac- cording to labor was to operate to elicit maximum effort. To that end labor income might be "readjusted" somewhat, but it must ovnerate within the ultimate limit of a high level of capital formation.13 The specifics of the ratio of consumption to capital accumulation would be worked out by the economic planners, but the mandate for a relatively high rate capital formation was clear. Thus, even if economic growth were main- tained at a fairly high rate, a long period of very modest increases in consumption for the masses is inevitable. CCP leaders have attempted to "balance" the interests of the individual, the collective, and the state within the framework of a rather high level of capital formation for such a backward economy. Li Fu-Ch'un, chairman of the State Planning Commission, has put the position as follows: . . . the main point to be considered when dealing with . . . state and private interests is the proper distribution of the national income. . . . In . . . the First Five Year Plan, 22% of the national income . . . will be set aside as accumulated funds, leaving 78% for consumption. As compared with the . . . Soviet Union, the proportion we have set aside for accumulation is lower . . . (because) of the fact that our population is large, that our production is not so fully developed, and some other factors. . . . Our present ratio will . . ensure the requirements of national construction . . . it (also) allows for appropriate improvement in the living conditions of the people.14 12 Ibid., p. 36. (Emphasis in original.) 13 Yang Po, "The Relation Between Accumulation and Consumption in China's National Income," JMJP, October 13, 1958 in SCMP 1901, November 25, 1958, p. 18. 14 "Progress of the First Five-Year Plan for the Development of the National Economy, "New China Advances to Socialism, (Peking; Foreign Languages Press, 1956) pp. 97-98. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms CHARLES HOFFMANN 251 Another observer put the situation of the consumer a little more bluntly: . . . we have let the rate of increase in the accumulation fund be faster than that in the consumption fund . . . (Therefore), we can effect only gradual improvements in the livelihood of our people.... Thus, so long as the production level continues to rise, thereby enabling steady elevation of the consumption level . . . and so long as political indoctrination is carried out well, explaining . . . why the consumption level cannot be drastically raised in a short period of time, then the people will be able to accept hardships and will endeavor to raise the production level....15 Thus, in distributing income within these over-all limitations, the objective is "to improve the life of the masses gradually on the basis of con- stant increase of production. In other words, on the basis of increased production, constant increase in accumulation must be insured while the income for 90% . . . is increased by every means every year."'6 Not only is the high proportion of capital formation considered essen- tial for the proper development of the economy, but an increase in the ratio is held necessary for growth to be sustained and for socialist industrialization to take its required course. With national income increasing rapidly and living levels rising gradually, it was argued, the ratio of capi formation can rise without the people's welfare being impaired. Retrenchment in areas of "social consumption" such as defense and administration supposedly would make possible an increase in the ratio of capital accumulation without affecting either the relative or absolute level of private consumption. With labor productivity rising at a rate faster than con- sumption, capital accumulation can rise relatively and absolutely and consumption absolutely. Thus, so long as total output rises faster than the increase in population, the proportion of investment to consumption can be raised at the same time as consumption can be increased absolutely.17 From this broad policy on the division of national income between investment and consumption, the leaders of the CCP have abstracted a general wage or income policy consistent with their conception of the pattern of economic growth. Increases in income were linked to growth in labor productivity, with the proviso that labor income should not rise as much as the increase in productivity. Increases in earnings were tied mechanically to increases in labor productivity where piece-rate and bonus "Yu Tien, "A Preliminary Discussion on the Proportion Between Consumption and Accumulation . . . ," Peking Ta-kung pao (hereafter TKP), March 24, 1957, in SCMP 1510, April 5, 1957, pp. 24-25. " "Distribution of Income in People's Communes," Chung-kuo ch'ing-nien January 18, 1961 in U. S. Consulate, Hong Kong, Current Background (hereafter CB) 648, March 22, 1961, p. 19. 17 Niu Chung-huang, loc. cit. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 252 CHINA'S INCENTIVE POLICY Systems operated. Policies aimed at raising the level of wages or income had to be carefully implemented to avoid the pitfalls of inflation.18 A rise in labor productivity may contribute to a rise in consumer goods output, it was argued, but it cannot be fully reflected in consumer goods increase. Thus, at the lowest level, a rise in wages or income must be directly related to the rise in consumer goods output, with the increment in consumer goods as the upper limit to an increase in income. An increase in income commensurate with that in labor productivity would raise individ- ual demand by the value of the incremental production much of which is not consumer goods (over 20% is in capital investment which cannot be "consumed"). Such a rise in income would only upset economic plans through the dislocations of price inflation. With these considerations as their operating principles, the regime has set a low ratio of wage increases to productivity increases. Asserting that an appropriate ratio should reflect a rise in level of living should conform to the principle of pay according to work, and should contribute to reducing production costs, the CCP economic planners settled on a ratio of 1:2. That is, wages ought to rise by no more than 50% of the increase in labor productivity in order to meet the various economic requirements of the Party. This patently low rate of increase is explicitly linked to the policy of massive capital accumulation and to the necessity of preventing any further disparity in the incomes of workers and peasants which would tend to weaken "the worker-peasant alliance."-19 This has been called "a rational low wage" policy by CCP leaders, in view of: (1) the necessity for large amounts of capital investment; and (2) the necessity to "provide all with bread." We have already discussed the rationale for the first; the second factor is a reminder of a cardinal fact about China: over 500 million of its people are peasants. With their very low level of living, increases in wages for workers in the cities and rural areas must be held in check. Otherwise, there will be an uncontrollable influx of peasants into the cities where they cannot now effectively be absorbed, and the great income disparity between peasants and workers would inevitably stir up a sense of disunity. While recognizing the desirability of some disparity in income between the two groups because of differences in skills and living costs, CCP spokesmen have been careful to stress the importance of avoiding too great a disparity in income or an elimination of the gap, since either extreme would not accord with the socialist principle of distribution according to work and would impair the incentive mechanism essential to maximum labor exertion and technological advance. Given the size of the peasant population and the com- 18 Hsiao Kung-yu, "The Principle Underlying Wage Increases," Hsueh-hsi, No. August 3, 1957 in ECMM 106, November 4, 1947, pp. 12-14. 9 Ibid., and Yuan Fang, "The Ratio of Increase Between Labor Productivity and Wages," Hsin chien-she (New Construction), No. 12, Dec. 3, 1956 in ECMM 71, Feb. 25, 1957, pp. 10-18. See also Li Fu-ch'un, "Progress of the First Five-Year Plan.... " New China Advances to Socialism, pp. 97-99 on actual ratio. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms CHARLES HOFFMANN 253 mitment to rapid capital accumulation, the restraint on increases in wages, in particular, and income, in general, is indeed "rational." The CCP, fully committed to rapid economic development, has set forth the same broad income distribution rationale as did the Communist Party of the Soviet Union. The actual implementation of this policy, while also paralleling that of the USSR, demonstrates certain inescapable facts about the Chinese situation which have affected the political and economic views of the CCP leaders: the significant position of the peasant in all considerations; the extremely uneven development of agriculture as compared with industry; and the wide variation of conditions and performance within the different sectors of the economy. These have made for rather narrow ideological and economic limits within which work performance incentives can be applied. The Interplay Between Material and Non-material Incentives The two aspects of incentive policy in China since 1953 are reflected in the statement that "our principle is to combine political and ideological education with material encouragement. ." Incentive policy thus involves a duality-material and non-material incentives-the latter to be cultivated by means of political and ideological education exhorting "communist" behavior. The material incentives run the gamut of mechanisms which are familiar to us in capitalist economies where "economic man" still summarizes, if incompletely, our view of individual motivation. These incentives, developed to higher forms from crude methods of payment in kind, include money wages according to hierarchic grades geared to skill differentials and based on time and piece rates, bonuses, money prizes and similar devices. The rationalization and perfection of these instruments calculating the amounts of labor input, according to which the socialist principle of payment is to operate, sensitized them as measures of performance. "Proper" differentials between peasants and city workers, payment in rural areas on increasingly frequent intervals, payment at fixed rates for standardized chores, bonuses and penalties according to degree of task fulfillment-all of these attest to the emergence of a modern system of economic incentives geared in principle to the maximization of labor input and production output. The frequent utilization of piece-rate techniques represents the most complete achievement of the distribution according to labor principle. Supplementing these basic material incentives are fringe emoluments reducing or eliminating the costs of housing, medical care, child care, old age, disability and vacations.21 The rational structuring of 20 Lin Feng, "Carry Out the Cultural Revolution in a Big Way . . . ," The National Conference of Outstanding Groups and Individuals in Socialist Construction in Education, Culture . . . (Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1960), p. 38. 21 If fringe benefits were considered rights of payment held in common a on a graded basis, they might act as a disincentive for more efficient workers; if they were considered supplementary, they might act as positive incentives. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 254 CHINA'S INCENTIVE POLICY these material incentives is viewed by CCP authorities as necessary to the fullest realization of the benefits of the principle of distribution according to labor. Non-material incentives are inextricably linked with ideological and political indoctrination. This type of incentive is employed to exploit the admittedly underdeveloped communist spirit among the mass of workers. For only by emphasizing ideological and political education and implementation of the communist spirit through the development of non-material incentives can the negative elements in material incentives be contained and the more desirable attitudes necessary to communism cultivated if the material incentive is viewed as the only driving force stimulating the positiveness of the working masses' production, then it will become extremely harmful economic thought, which may deprive the people of their direction. The theory of distribution based upon labor still retains a remnant bourgeois concept of legal right. It fails to show the correct relation- ship between individual present profit and collective long-term profit; nor does it show great Communist ideals. Therefore, if wo do not stress the education of political thought and merely emphasize distribution based upon labor and material incentive, we will become short-sighted, will focus our attention solely on our personal gain or loss, and will confine ourselves to the "bourgeois narrow limit of profit".. For this reason, when we put in practice a system of distribution based upon labor, we have to stress educating the masses with Communist thought so that the productive positiveness of the working masses will be built on the foundation of their ever-increasing political awareness, thus gradually creating a social condition favorable to entering the stage of communism.22 The battery of non-material incentives aimed at serving the purpose of ideological and political indoctrination is wide and varied and always involves the individual in group-centered or group-honored activities. Emulation campaigns enlist individuals and groups vying with one another on all levels from basic work units up through factory units, industry units, and on a regional and national level. Mass movements mobilize all workers to achieve some outstanding goal. Worker participation in factory decisions also plays an important psychic function. Such socialist competition not only shapes the individuals and groups involved in the contests but also arouses a wide band of "spectator" workers taking sides and watching results. Winning the "Red Flag" pennant is a reward of great popular significance. Individual workers and groups also struggle to overfulfill quotas in their jobs with a view to being adjudged "advanced" or "model" workers or groups. In addition to the social prestige of the title, attendance at conferences for outstanding workers and groups, 22 Shen Liao-chin, "Politics is the Life-line of All Economic Activities," Kuangmnng jih-pao, June 6, 1960, p. 6 in JPRS 5223, Aug. 8, 1960, pp. 17-18. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms CHARLES HOFFMANN 255 meetings wih Mao and other high officials, invitations to join the Communist Party and similar rewards complete the social prestige "payments" to those who display the "communist spirit." Development of "the spirit of collectivism among the workers" is given powerful impetus when group economic activity is infused with political education. Every non-material incentive has embodied within it important elements of propaganda which have come to be integral parts of the particular incentive. Without doubt, where non-material incentives are used, "politics is in command:" Mass movements are not something temporary or accidental. With correct leadership ... (they) become a constant factor facilitating rapid economic development. They are developed under centralized guidance provided by the Party, which consists in linking political work with economic construction, political education with incentives, for policy is the soul, a commanding force. This is the source of our mass movements....23 The techniques aimed at stimulating mass enthusiasm for the prodigious tasks at hand are viewed as only a few of the many innovations (including, for example, the commune system) which the socialist system is capable of generating. According to Party prescription, not only are non-material incentives to be inextricably linked with "political work," but material incentives, likewise, are to be used in concert with the non-material (politically- oriented) incentives. While the degree of emphasis placed on either ma- terial or non-material incentives has varied with the period and the larger policy in operation, the combining of both kinds of incentives and propaganda wherever feasible has been a constant factor. Thus, both material and non-material incentives are used within a political framework to stimulate individual work-effort and to encourage the development of "communist man." In other words, incentives are required to conform to the guide-lines set by political and ideological considerations. These guide-lines play a dual role: "to educate the masses . . .with socialist thought and to criticize their bourgeois tendencies." Ultimately, the needs upon which material incentives are based will be transformed so that they are fulfilled more completely through the nonmaterial incentive systems which will gradually loom larger and larger as main motivating forces. In dialectical fashion, the contradiction of the material and non-material will give rise eventually to a new form of incentive complex reflecting the conditions and needs of a communist society. In the meantime politics must be in firm control to avoid detours and u-turns on the route to communism.24 23 Liu Shao-ch'i, "The Triumph of Marxism-Leninism in China," World Marxist Review, Oct. 1959, pp. 21-22. 24 Shen Liao-chin, loc. cit., pp. 10-11, 15. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 256 CHINA'S INCENTIVE POLICY Incentive policy is related to strategic and tactical goals, both economic and political (or ideological). In the short-run, CCP leaders are faced with the critical problem of sustaining rapid economic growth. The abundance of labor must be converted somehow into capital. Increased labor productivity and input are the only feasible solutions. Without large- scale mechanization and other capital, increased productivity must come from intensified and more creative labor input; labor enthusiasm is the route to constant and substantial swelling of production. Propor- tionately large capital formation is possible only if consumption expenditures are held down through personal income rising appreciably less than productivity. The combination of increased labor productivity and input with limited increases in income for a population living on the margin of subsistence is the Party's immediate economic aim. In the absence of large-scale coercion, a high degree of political consciousness and manipulation is required if the harsh reality of postponing large increases in consumption is to be accepted. In the long run, incentive policy aims at a population both technically attuned to the changing demands of a rapidly growing industrial society and ideologically imbued with "the communist spirit." Within the present incentive system, therefore, are mechanisms, material and non-material, which explicitly are aimed at developing both the technical and political attitudes that are expected to be pervasive when communism is attained, but which also are expected to serve a positive role in the long intervening period before the conditions necessary for communism exist. Within broad CCP economic strategy, incentive policy has a key role. Changes in policy usually reflect tactical situations calling for pragmatic solutions neither precluded nor prescribed in the larger plan and strategic changes either exacted by harsh realities or made possible by favorable conditions. Since 1953 the ideological and economic basis of incentive policy has remained practically unchanged. Despite the tremendous pressures generated by several years of agricultural failures, commitment to certain incentive forms has continued, although concessions in the form of a larger role to material incentives and relatively more income to be distributed have perforce been made. The actual limits within which incentive policy has operated include general application of the principle of payment according to labor with as little concession to rising levels of living and private economic activity and gain as possible given the general food and morale situation; the constant development of non-material socialist incentives for short-run and long-run purposes and in combination with material incentives wherever feasible; and heavy doses of political and ideological indoctrination administered constantly. Changes in incentive policy in 1958 and 1960 have involved primarily a swing in emphasis, though after 1960 more ouput, relatively, was made available for distribution. In the period to 1958 material incentives were stressed; starting in 1958 the emphasis swung to the opposite pole with This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms CHARLES HOFFMANN 257 non-material incentives highlighted in the Great Leap Forward phase; in 1960, the pendulum moved again to a stress on material incentives. Given the narrow area for maneuver allowed by orthodox ideological and economic considerations, the leaders of Communist China keep trying to exact the maximum output possible from the working force. As conditions change, this amount may very considerably. The only response admissible, since doctrine excludes wide-scale return to private ownership incentives or sharply increased income incentives, is for experimentation and variation in material and non-material incentives. All in all, given the rigid ideological and economic limits, the Party attempts to reap maximum results through a very flexible application of incentive techniques. CHARLES HOFFMANN is Assistant Professor of Economics at Queens College of the City University of New York. This content downloaded from 132.205.120.182 on Sun, 17 Mar 2019 15:26:13 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms