Knowledge Management Research & Practice ISSN: 1477-8238 (Print) 1477-8246 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/tkmr20 Coordination contracts in the university technology transfer chain Xuhua Chang, Patrick S.W. Fong, Qiang Chen & Yongqian Liu To cite this article: Xuhua Chang, Patrick S.W. Fong, Qiang Chen & Yongqian Liu (2019): Coordination contracts in the university technology transfer chain, Knowledge Management Research & Practice, DOI: 10.1080/14778238.2019.1596198 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/14778238.2019.1596198 Published online: 31 Mar 2019. Submit your article to this journal View Crossmark data Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=tkmr20 KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT RESEARCH & PRACTICE https://doi.org/10.1080/14778238.2019.1596198 Coordination contracts in the university technology transfer chain Xuhua Changa, Patrick S.W. Fongb, Qiang Chenc and Yongqian Liuc a Shanghai International College of Intellectual Property, Tongji University, Shanghai, China; bDepartment of Building and Real Estate, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Hung Hom, Hong Kong; cSchool of Economics & Management, Tongji University, Shanghai, China ABSTRACT ARTICLE HISTORY Successful university technology transfer requires close cooperation between the inventor and the firm. However, occasionally, this cooperation is not self-conscious for both the inventor and the firm. In this paper, we develop a game model by introducing the concept of the university technology transfer chain. We examine the inventor’s and firm’s inputs and payoffs in case of both the decentralised and centralised decision-making modes. Based on the principal-agent theory, we find that the commonly used license contract with royalties or equity payment cannot help effectively reduce the double moral hazard of both the inventor and the firm, and the portfolio contract only works effectively because of the limitation of transfer factor. The side-payment self-enforcing contract could coordinate the matched inputs to achieve maximum social welfare. We also test these findings through numerical investigation. Lastly, we present new insights for universities and firms as well as implications for policymakers. Received 28 April 2017 Revised 2 October 2018 Accepted 13 March 2019 1. Introduction University-invented technology is critical for national and regional innovation systems. However, the vast majority of licensed university inventions are still in the early technological stage and require further development. J.G. Thursby, Jensen, and Thursby (2001) indicated that over half of the university inventions licensed in US universities were merely a kind of proof-of-concept or lab-scale prototype that still needed to pass the pilot scale test before full-scale production. Hence, the commercialisation of university inventions often requires additional effort from inventors who are employed by the university (hereafter referred to as inventor effort) as well as research & development (R&D) funding and technological investment (hereafter referred to as firm investment) by a firm (Thompson, Ziedonis, & Mowery, 2018), although neither is observable or verifiable. The process of university-industry technology transfer (hereafter referred to as UITT) is fraught with moral hazards (Dechenaux, Thursby, & Thursby, 2011). Many previous studies have indicated that inventors are motivated to participate in this transfer based on licensing income as well as other non-economic factors, such as entrepreneurship, reputation and research funding (Littunen, 2000; Baldini, Grimaldi, & Sobrero, 2005; J. G. Thursby & Thursby, 2011; Haeussler, Jiang, J. G. Thursby, & Thursby, 2014; Chang, Chen, & Fong, 2017). The need for inventor effort results in the moral hazard problem – for example, in case they turn their attention to other research projects – mainly because of CONTACT Xuhua Chang China 15176@tongji.edu.cn © 2019 Operational Research Society KEYWORDS University technology transfer chain; double moral hazard; portfolio contract; side-payment self-enforcing contract incomplete licensing contracts that do not specify the extent of effort needed in advance. Unreasonable distribution of patent licensing revenue and insufficient investment by licensees are other equally important reasons for this in the context of royalty and/or equity payment (Dechenaux, J. G. Thursby, & Thursby, 2011; Jensen & Thursby, 2001; Macho-Stadler & Pérez-Castrillo, 2010; Savva & Taneri, 2011). On the other hand, for firmaccepted university inventions, the need for investment also presents a moral problem, since a firm may lower its investment level either because it is keen to reduce research costs or because the expected benefit is less than originally anticipated (Choi, 2001; Jensen & Thursby, 2001). Therefore, solving the moral hazard problem has drawn much attention in the academic field. In order to eliminate the moral hazard problem in case of inventors, Jensen, Thursby, and Thursby (2003) indicated that the inventor’s effort increases along with the inventor’s share of licensing revenue, and the licence contract with royalties or equity provides ongoing financial incentives to better retain an inventor’s involvement. Crama, Reyck, and Degraeve (2008) and Dechenaux, M. C. Thursby, & Thursby (2009) examined the effect of milestones, annual payments, royalties and upfront fees on inventor effort. Savva and Taneri (2011) also provided a rational explanation for the use of royalties alongside equity payment to mitigate the inventor’s moral hazard in the UITT. Shanghai International College of Intellectual Property, Tongji University, Shanghai 200092, 2 X. CHANG ET AL. Another aspect of previous research on UITT is related to the moral hazard of the firm. Hellmann (2007) discovered that firm investment is always insufficient or excessive in the UITT, because of unobservable inventor effort and incomplete license contracts. Inventor effort can be substituted with firm investment and vice versa. Thus, as soon as one observes that the inventor is overinvesting in the UITT, the firm is always motivated to reduce its investment. Based on this, Crama et al. (2008) adopted the principal-agent model to investigate a firm’s development investment and found that employing different contract terms – such as upfront fee and milestone fee – could partially resolve the firm’s moral hazard problem. While the moral hazard problem of the inventor or firm has been investigated separately, existing research has not yet given comprehensive consideration to the moral hazard problem of both participants in a unified economic environment. More importantly, both the inventor’s and firm’s moral hazard are always closely related. Therefore, there is room for further understanding of the moral hazard of the two participants in the UITT, such as how to reduce the moral hazard for both participants by optimizing the license contract or how to judge whether both the inventor and the firm have simultaneously input the matched effort and investment. In this paper, we regard the process of the UITT as a university technology transfer chain (hereafter referred to as UTTC) that involves the inventor employed by the university, the technology transfer office (hereafter referred to as TTO) and the firm. The inventor creates a valuable invention and discloses it to the TTO. Then, the TTO looks for a potential firm to buy this invention (technology buyer), negotiates the price and identifies any further technical investment. Then, an interested firm accepts the invention and cooperates with the inventor to commercialize the invention. In the UTTC, we assume that the TTO is the principal, while the inventor and the firm are agents. Based on the principal-agent theory, the TTO (principal) in a UTTC has the obligation to solve the moral hazard problem, and coordinates with the inventor and the firm (two agents) to put in sufficient effort and investment. In contrast to previous research, which has only focused on the moral hazard problem of one side to maximise the individual or organisational payoff separately, we believe that this study provides a new research approach from a global perspective that examines whether the inventor and the firm put in the same inputs and optimise the social welfare of the UITT as well as the payoff of all stakeholders. Further, in this paper, we consider the probability of a successful UITT to be closely related to inventor effort and firm investment; we generate a game model of university patent licensing in the context of royalties and equity payment. Moreover, we compare two significant UTTCrelated decision-making modes. In the decentralised decision-making mode (hereafter referred to as the D-D mode), the inventor and the firm make their input decisions independently in order to maximise their own respective payoffs. In the centralised decision-making mode (hereafter referred to as the C-D mode), the inventor and the firm make their decisions together – that is, they make their decisions simultaneously – in order to maximise the overall social welfare of the UTTC. Our findings show that although the social welfare of the UTTC in case of the C-D mode is significantly larger than in that in the case of the D-D mode due to matched inputs, the payoff of the inventor and/or firm would become larger or lesser, which may trigger a double moral hazard problem. In order to resolve this issue as well as maintain the optimization of social welfare, we first considered the use of the portfolio contract with royalties and revenue-sharing as the coordination method and found that it has a few restrictions and only works in specific scenarios. Next, we considered the employment of a side-payment self-enforcing contract (hereafter referred to as the SSEC contract), and the theoretical results showed that it plays an effective role in matching inventor effort and firm investment. To the best of our knowledge, few studies, empirical or theoretical, have considered the double moral hazard from the perspective of optimising the social welfare of the UTTC. This is an original study that attempts to formally simulate the decision-making of all stakeholders in the process of the UITT. The work most similar to ours is that of Hellmann (2007), which examined the sum of all stakeholders’ payoffs as the standard social welfare. The author indicated that under- or overinvestment may occur in case of either the inventor or the firm in the development stage, largely because of incomplete licensing contracts. However, the author did not pay more attention to the moral hazard problem, nor did he provide solutions for how to optimise the social welfare of the UITT. The remainder of this paper is organized in the following manner: Section 2 introduces the UTTC and model set of this study. Section 3 examines the commonly observed licensing contract in the context of royalties and equity payments. Section 4 discusses the coordination effect of the portfolio contract and the SSEC in reducing the double moral hazard problem and optimising the social welfare of the UTTC. Section 5 presents the numerical investigations. KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT RESEARCH & PRACTICE Section 6 provides a series of model extensions, and Section 7 concludes the paper. 2. University technology transfer chain and model set 2.1. University technology transfer chain In the process of the UITT, the majority of TTOs are non-profit organizations since they are normally established by the university or created by university employees. The TTO represents the university administration and is considered as the most significant intermediator between the inventor and the firm as well as between the university and the firm. The TTO’s primary objective is to promote the performance of the UITT (i.e., success rate of the UITT, social welfare etc.) by coordinating the behaviour of all stakeholders. Further, the TTO’s secondary objective is to maximise own economic return in order to keep the operation running. In order to achieve these two objectives, creating a reasonable license contract is a tough task. In fact, most often, the TTO cannot create an ex-ante license contract that specifies the unobservable inventor effort and the unverifiable firm investment, largely because the transfer of university inventions from the inventor to the firm is a dynamic process with double moral hazard. The traditional D-D mode assumes that all participants – that is, the inventor, TTO and firm – are economically driven, choosing the extent of their effort or investment simultaneously in order to maximise their individual payoffs separately but caring little about the social welfare of the UITT. This is the critical reason for the mismatch between inventor effort and firm investment. Therefore, in the D-D mode, it is impossible for the TTO to prejudge whether the inventor and the firm would contribute equally in terms of effort and investment, or design a satisfactory license contract or inventor share rate to address the double moral hazard problem. In order to address these limitations of the D-D mode, we introduce the concept of the UTTC in this paper, and seek to find an effective solution. The UTTC is a process chain that consists of the university inventor, TTO and the firm; the firm’s involvement enables the transfer of university-invented technologies for the purpose of furthering development and commercialisation and linking value chains. In the UTTC, the inventor creates inventions in the academic workplace, discloses these inventions to the university TTO, inputs the required effort and receives a portion of the licensing revenues (Blind, Pohlisch, & Zi, 2018; Macho-Stadler, Martínez-Giralt, & Pérez- 3 Castrillo, 1996). Note that in this paper, we assume that the inventor discloses all inventions to the TTO. The TTO is instrumental in developing the relationship between the inventor and the firm and reducing their double moral hazard. Thus, the TTO is considered an appropriate governing power in the incentive structure for coordinating the economic behaviour of both the inventor and the firm (Brescia, Colombo, & Landoni, 2016). The firm, which brings university inventions to the market, invests technical funding and pays the requisite licensing fees, as per the specific licence contract. Based on the understanding of UTTC, in this paper, we regard all participants as a single stakeholder. This enables the introduction of the C-D mode, which requires the inventor and the firm to input the matched effort and investment, regardless of the internal profit distribution. Thus, the C-D mode could provide a benchmark for the D-D mode from the global perspective of UTTC. In the social economic system, it is common sense that the local optimum must not be greater than the global optimum. In this paper, we consider participants’ inputs and payoffs in the C-D mode as the benchmark. We assume that the TTO is the inside leader of UTTC, which can coordinate inventor effort and firm investment. Thus, we employ two common types of coordination contracts – that is, portfolio contract and SSEC contract – to eliminate the double moral hazard and achieve the benchmarking effect. 2.2. Model set In order to investigate the double moral hazard in the process of the UITT, we develop a theoretical game model related to UTTC, involving one inventor, one TTO and one firm. In this paper, we assume that both the inventor and the firm are economically driven. In addition, we assume that the inventor discloses all inventions to his/her universities, and the firm always has technology demand. The primary objective of the TTO is the optimisation of social welfare, that is, the net economic return of UTTC, and its secondary objective is its own payoff from the licensing service provided. It is widely considered that a successful UITT requires cooperation between the inventor and the firm, as university inventions are usually still in early stages of development. As illustrated in Figure 1, the success probability of the UITT is given by pðsR ; sF Þ, where sR is the inventor effort and sF is the firm’s technical investment. This function partially borrows from Dechenaux et al. (2009, 2011). However, unlike them, we consider both inventor effort and firm investment to have a similar influence on the success 4 X. CHANG ET AL. Figure 1. The traditional process of UITT conducted by TTO. probability of the UITT on account of their substitutive relationship. We relax the restriction of the firm’s fixed influence and assume that the success probability is also an exponential function related to firm investment. The specific functional form is as given below: pðsR ; sF Þ ¼ 1 p0 easR bsF : The success probability pðsR ; sF Þ is an increasing function of both sR and sF . When sR (or sF ) is equal to zero, the probability decreases rapidly and depends solely on firm investment (or inventor effort). Parameter a measures the importance of inventor effort for a successful UITT, while b measures the importance of firm investment. Parameter p0 can be interpreted as a measure of the systemic risk of the UITT. Only when p0 = 1 is pð0; 0Þ ¼ 0. That is, unless the inventor and the firm do not invest in technology transfer, in most cases, the success probability of the UITT does not reduce to zero. The TTO owns and can exclusively licence university inventions to a firm. We assume that the TTO payoff is UT ¼ ð1 αÞR, where 1 α is the licensing share profit that is accrued to the TTO and R is the licensing revenue. We assume that the expected inventor payoff is UR ¼ αR AR esR , where α is the inventor share rate of licensing revenue, AR esR measures the inventor time-cost spent on the UITT and AR is the influence of time-cost. The university TTO offers the firm an exclusive licence contract that specifies a particular type of payment. In this paper, we only consider two types of commonly observed payments, that is, royalty fee (per unit) and equity rate, as the means for engaging the participation of both the inventor and the firm. We denote the patent license contract by O ¼ ðm; rÞ or θ. Payment term m is the upfront fee paid immediately after the firm signs the licence contract. Payment term r is the royalty fee (per unit), which is an ongoing licensing income. Payment term θ is the equity rate related to production revenue resulting from patent utilization. In this paper, the licensing revenue is closely related to the production revenue π and product yield x. The variable ct is the production cost per unit. The total licensing revenue is R ¼ m þ rx (using royalty payment) or R ¼ θπ (using equity payment). Therefore, in case of a successful UITT, the firm’s payoff is given by UF ¼ pðπ rxÞ sF m ct x or UF ¼ pθπ sF m ct x In this paper, the entire process of the UITT is described in the following manner: after receiving an inventor’s technology disclosure (such as patent technology, know-how etc.), the TTO first searches for and provides a specific licence contract to a potential firm. If the firm rejects the licence contract, the bargaining game between the TTO and the firm is over, and the TTO continues searching for another technology buyer. If not, the firm invests sF for further development and pays the upfront fee m. Meanwhile, the TTO assigns a ratio of the licensing revenue to the inventor according to the stipulations of the university’s policies. Finally, the inventor chooses the level of effort sR needed for the success of the UITT. In this paper, we assume that the above process is a sequential structure. Based on the principal-agent theory, the backward-induction method is a more effective means to optimise faculty effort and firm investment. In keeping with this, the sequential decision is inventor → firm → university TTO. This allows the TTO to design a specific contract scheme and the inventor share rate to resolve the moral hazard problem related to faculty effort and firm investment. In addition, in order to prove the theoretical results, following the research by Chang et al. (2017), we simulated participants’ payoff and social welfare under both the D-D and C-D modes based on given contract terms (i.e., royalty fee per unit and equity payment) and the revenue distribution scheme. 3. Common licence contracts In this section, we investigate common licence contracts based on royalties or equity payment. Borrowing from Hellmann’s (2007) research, we assume that the sum of participants’ payoff is the social welfare of the UITT. First, we study inventor effort and firm investment in the D-D mode, and then examine the benchmark in the C-D mode. 3.1. The decentralised decision-making mode 3.1.1. Payment of royalties In the D-D mode with payment of royalties, the firm payoff is UFd ¼ pd ðπ rxÞ sF m ct x, the inventor payoff is URd ¼ αðpd rx þ mÞ AR esR , the KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT RESEARCH & PRACTICE university TTO payoff is UTd ¼ ð1 αÞðpd rx þ mÞ and the social welfare is USd ðα; rÞ ¼ UFd þ URd þ UTd . To ensure that the inventor and the firm voluntarily participate in the UITT, we denote 0 UFd > 0, URd > αm. First, when URd ðsR Þ ¼ 0, then the optimal inventor effort is as given below: 1 αrxapebsF Ln : (1) sRd ¼ aþ1 AR It is evident that sRd meets the requirement 00 URd ðsRd Þ > αm. Meanwhile, URd ðsRd Þ < 0 indicates that URd is a concave function and the maximum payoff can be obtained at sRd . After observing the optimal inventor effort, firm investment sFd is given 0 below, when UFd ðsFd Þ ¼ 0: sFd ¼ a þ 1 bpðπ rxÞ a AR ln þ ln : b aþ1 b αrxap (2) 00 The conditions that UFd ðsFd Þ > 0 and UFd ðsFd Þ < 0 also suggest that sFd is the firm’s optimal investment. Thus, according to Equation (2), we obtain the following optimal inventor effort: sRd ða þ 1Þαrxa : ¼ ln AR bðπ rxÞ (3) 3.1.2. Equity payment If the firm is cash constrained and/or risk averse, equity payment is a common economical means of licensing academic inventions. In this scenario, the firm payoff is given by UFd ¼ ð1 θÞpd π sF ct x, the inventor payoff is URd ¼ αθpd π AR esR , the TTO payoff is UTd ¼ ð1 αÞθpd π and the social welfare is USd ðα; θÞ ¼ UFd þ URd þ UTd . As in Section 3.1.1, we 0 first set URd ðsRd Þ ¼ 0, then 1 aπαθpebsF Ln ; (4) sRd ¼ aþ1 AR where sRd meets the requirements URd ðsRd Þ > 0 and 00 URd ðsRd Þ < 0. Therefore, we suggest that sRd is the optimal inventor effort in the D-D mode with equity payment. We consider the optimal firm investment 0 by denoting UFd ðsFd Þ ¼ 0; then, we have sFd ¼ a þ 1 ð1 θÞbpπ a AR ln þ ln; ; b aþ1 b αθπap (5) 00 where UFd ðsFd Þ > 0, and UFd ðsF Þ < 0 also indicates that the firm obtained its maximum payoff at the point sFd . According to Equation (5), we have the following optimal inventor effort: sRd ¼ ln ða þ 1Þaαθ : AR bð1 αθÞ (6) In the process of university technology transfer, the TTO is motivated to assist both the inventor and the 5 firm to put in the matched effort and investment. Therefore, after estimating the inventor effort and the firm investment in the context of royalties or equity payment, the TTO must design a patent license contract, that is O ¼ ðm; rÞorθ, and inventor share rate α in order to maximise the social welfare (Objective 1) and organisational payoff (Objective 2). Therefore, the payoff function of the TTO is given by UTd ¼ max fI ð1 αÞðrpd x þ mÞ þ ð1 I Þð1 αÞθpd πg; α; γ or θ S:T:maxfUSd ðα; rÞ; USd ðα; θÞg; sR ¼ sRd ; sF ¼ sFd ; 0 < α 1; r > 0; I ¼ 0 or 1 where I is a dummy variable indicating payment selection. If USd ðα; rÞ USd ðα; θÞ, I ¼ 0, otherwise I ¼ 1. This indicates that the TTO first intends to maximise the social welfare of the UITT and then optimise its own payoff. Proposition 1: There exists an optimal license contract for the TTO. When I ¼ 0, the optimal equity rate is qffiffiffiffiffiffi θ ¼ 1 1þa πb , and the optimal inventor share rate is pffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1aÞ πbþa 1þa pffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffi . When I ¼ 1, the optimal royalty α ¼ ðð1þa Þð πb 1þaÞ pffiffi fee (per unit) is r ¼ 1x π πb , and the optimal 1 ffiffiffiffi . (Please refer inventor share rate is α ¼ ð1þaÞ p ð πb1Þ to Appendix for details.) In this paper, we regard the probability of a successful UITT as being dependent on inventor effort and firm investment. Proposition 1 shows that there exist two single points, that is, fα ; θ g and fα ; r g, at which they can maximise the TTO’s payoff. One implication is that the optimal equity rate is related to the importance of inventor effort (negative) and firm investment (positive), while the optimal royalty fee (per unit) mainly depends on the importance of firm investment (positive) and product yield (negative). Another significant implication is that the TTO payoff always decreases with the inventor share rate of licensing revenue from 0 to 1. The TTO must not choose a specific value of inventor share rate because of a conflict of interest. In the D-D mode, because of the substitutional relations between inventor effort and firm investment, the firm is always strongly motivated to reduce its investment once it observes a high level of inventor effort. Meanwhile, the inventor also intends to reduce their input if he/she estimates a decrease in the firm’s investment funding. This continuous chain reaction can easily cause the inventor and the firm to input insufficient effort or investment, which in turn results in a double moral hazard. 6 X. CHANG ET AL. contract to prompt the inventor and the firm to voluntarily put in the same effort and investment. 3.2. The centralised decision-making mode: benchmark of matched inputs In UTTC, all participants (i.e., TTO, inventor and firm) belong to one community of interests. This enables the C-D mode. The TTO represents the interests of the UTTC as a principal and conducts all agents (i.e., the inventor and the firm) to jointly maximise social welfare through matched inputs. Based on the principal-agent theory, the inventor’s effort and the firm’s investment in the C-D mode could be regarded as the benchmark. The social welfare in the C-D mode is given by USc ðsRc ; sFc Þ ¼ pc π AR esRc sF ct x: (7) It is evident that USc ðsRc ; sFc Þ is a concave function of 00 00 sRc and sFc , since USc ðsRc Þ < 0 and USc ðsFc Þ < 0. Then, 0 0 we denote USc ðsRc Þ ¼ 0 and USc ðsFc Þ ¼ 0 and obtain the optimal inventor effort sRc and the optimal firm investment sFc , as expressed below: sRc ¼ ln sFc ¼ ða þ 1Þa ; AR b a þ 1 bpπ a AR ln þ ln : b a þ 1 b apπ 4. Coordination of licence contracts According to Proposition 3, a single royalty or equity payment cannot optimise social welfare because of possible double moral hazard. The TTO, as the UTTC leader, must design a scheme – that is, both the licence contract and inventor share rate – to achieve social welfare as shown in the C-D mode. In this section, we attempt to employ a portfolio contract and an SSEC to coordinate inventor effort and firm investment, respectively. Note that in case of the portfolio contract, we only take into account royalty payment and revenue sharing. We do not consider equity payment, since its operation strategy is similar to that of royalty payment. 4.1. Portfolio contract (8) (9) In the C-D mode, the inventor share rate and license contract are ignored, because maximising the social welfare of the UITT is the only objective and revenue distribution is an internal issue. As shown in Equations (8) and (9), the inventor’s effort and the firm’s investment are not related to the payment terms and inventor share rate. Proposition 2: The success probability of the UITT and the social welfare in the C-D mode are greater than those in the D-D mode. It is indicated that, compared with the participants’ input in the C-D mode, there is a mismatch between inventor effort and firm investment because of a double moral hazard in the D-D mode. Proposition 2 (see Appendix) demonstrates that the social welfare in the C-D mode could be deemed as the benchmark, and there is room for improvement in inventor effort and firm investment. Proposition 3: A single royalty or equity payment cannot resolve the issue that drives an inventor (or firm) to put in matched effort (or investment) in the two decision-making modes. The C-D mode could generate more social welfare than the D-D mode. However, proposition 3 demonstrates that this goal cannot be achieved only through a single royalty or equity payment, as this results in a lack of supplementary means to redistribute the additional profit. Therefore, there needs to be a new coordination 4.1.1. When the inventor’s effort is insufficient In this scenario, we assume that the inventor’s effort is less than required in the C-D mode. Thus, in order to encourage the inventor to put in additional effort, the TTO uses the portfolio contract that transfers a certain part of the social welfare from the firm to the inventor through secondary revenue distribution. It is worth noting that the TTO is excluded from this secondary revenue distribution because it does not make any extra contribution to the additional profit (i.e., the social welfare gap between the C-D and D-D modes). We use variable δ as the factor of revenue redistribution. Then, under the new D-D mode with transfer factor δ, the firm’s payoff is as below: UFt ðsFt Þ ¼ ð1 δÞ½pt ðπ rxÞ sFt m ct x: The inventor payoff is as below: URt ðsRt Þ ¼ δ½pt ðπ rxÞ sFt þ αðrpt x þ mÞ AR esRt : Further, the TTO payoff is UTt ¼ ð1 αÞðpt rx þ mÞ. We also use the backwards induction method to 0 solve this game model. First, we denote URt ðsRt Þ ¼ 0; then, we have the matched inventor effort sRt1 as below: 1 ½αrx þ ðπ rxÞδapebsFt Ln : (10) sRt1 ¼ aþ1 AR In order to achieve social welfare as shown in the C-D mode, the inventor effort and firm investment should meet the requirements, such that sFt ¼ sFc and sRt ¼ sRc . Then, according to Equations (8) and (10), we obtain δ¼ π αrx : π rx (11) KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT RESEARCH & PRACTICE Lemma 1: In order to ensure that the inventor and the firm voluntarily put in matched effort and investment, the new D-D mode with portfolio contract must meet the incentive compatibility constraint (ICC) as well as the participant constraint (PC), as shown below: (1) ICC: Inventor effort and firm investment in the new D-D mode with portfolio contract are equal to those in the C-D mode. (2) PC: The inventor and the firm in the new D-D mode with the portfolio contract both have a higher payoff, and the total social welfare of the UITT is equal to that in the C-D mode. After checking the requirements of the ICC and the PC, the results showed that the firm’s payoff in the new D-D mode with the portfolio contract (which involves royalty and revenue redistribution) becomes negative because δ 1. Therefore, according to Lemma 1, in this scenario, the portfolio contract does not meet the PC requirement, and it cannot solve the issue of redistributing the added profit effectively or optimising the social welfare of the UITT. 4.1.2. When the firm’s investment is insufficient In this scenario, we assume that the firm’s investment is insufficient. Then, the TTO uses a portfolio contract to transfer some part of the social welfare from the inventor to the firm. In the new D-D mode with the portfolio contract, the firm payoff is given by UFt ¼ ð1 δÞ½αðrpt x þ mÞ AR esRt þ pt ðπ rxÞ sFt m ct x; The inventor payoff is given by URt ¼ δ½αðrpt x þ mÞ AR esRt : Further, the TTO payoff is given by UTt ¼ ð1 αÞ ðrpt x þ mÞ. We also order sRt ¼ sRc and sFt ¼ sFc to meet the IIC requirement; then, we obtain δ ¼1 ð1 þ aÞrx aπ ð1 þ aÞαrx αrx ¼ π rx: (12) (13) In order to meet the PC requirement, compared with the D-D mode with no coordination, we have the following two inequalities: URt ðsRt ; sFt Þ URd ðsRd ; sFd Þ; and UFt ðsRt ; sFt Þ UFd ðsRd ; sFd Þ: Then, we obtain the result that factor δ must meet the following requirement: 7 Proposition 4: The portfolio contract with royalty payment and revenue redistribution could influence the inventor and the firm to put in the matched effort and investment only when transferring adds social welfare from the inventor to the firm. The transferring factor depends on the inventor share rate, royalty fee per unit and the importance of inventor effort. Assuming that the new D-D and C-D modes achieve the same social welfare, Proposition 4 indicates a limitation of the portfolio contract with royalty payment and revenue redistribution. In order to encourage the firm to make sufficient investment, the portfolio contract in Section 4.1.2 is designed to transfer the inventor payoff to the firm. More importantly, according to inequality (14), this scenario only could occur under specific conditions. Proposition 5: The TTO could achieve its maximum payoff at the boundary point. In order to ensure that the inventor and the firm put in the matched efforts and investment, the royalty fee per unit and inventor share rate must Þðpd pt ÞþsFt sFd meet the following requirement: ðπrx αðpt rxþmÞAR esRt ðaþ1Þrxaπ ðaþ1Þαrx ÞAR e 1 ααððppdt rxþm rxþmÞAR esRt and αrx ¼ π rx. On the other hand, because the TTO payoff is a strictly monotonic function related to inventor share rate and royalties, compared with the D-D mode without coordination, in this scenario, the TTO always obtains its maximum payoff at the boundary point. sRd 4.2. Side-payment self-enforcing contract Because of the limitation of the portfolio contract indicated in Proposition 4, in this section, the SSEC contract is employed; the SSEC is an alternative coordination scheme to coordinate inventor effort and firm investment from the global perspective of the UTTC. We denote the transferring payoff function in SSEC contract as T ðsR ; sF Þ ¼ σesR þ ωsF þ k, where the factors σ and ω measure the value of inventor effort and firm investment respectively, and k is a constant. Therefore, in the new D-D mode with the royalty payments and SSEC, the firm payoff is given by UFt ¼ pt ðπ rxÞ sFt T ðsRt ; sFt Þ m ct x: Further, the inventor payoff is given by URt ¼ αðrpt x þ mÞ þ T ðsRt ; sFt Þ AR esRt : αðpd rx þ mÞ AR esRd ðπ rxÞðpd pt Þ þ sFt sFd δ 1 s Rt αðpt rx þ mÞ AR e αðpt rx þ mÞ AR esRt (14) 8 X. CHANG ET AL. The only sub-game perfect Nash equilibrium is 1φ1 φ1 φ1 φ2 ; . In this paper, we use this Nash 1φ φ 1φ φ The TTO payoff is given by UTt ¼ ð1 αÞðrpt x þ mÞ: 1 2 The backwards induction method is employed to 0 resolve this issue. First, we denote URt ðsRt Þ ¼ 0, and then we obtain 1 αrxapebsFt Ln : (15) sRt2 ¼ aþ1 AR σ The value of sRt2 meets the conditions URt ðsRt2 Þ > αm 00 and URt ðsRt2 Þ < 0; thus, the inventor can maximise his/her payoff at point sRt2 . After observing the optimal inventor effort, the firm puts in the optimal 0 investment according to UFt ðsF Þ ¼ 0, in which case we obtain sFt2 ¼ a þ 1 bðpM 1 ðπ rxÞ þ σ Þ 1 ln þ ln M; (16) ða þ 1Þð1 þ ωÞ b b where M ¼ Aαrxap , sFt2 meets UFt ðsFt2 Þ > 0 and R σ 00 UFt ðsFt2 Þ < 0. Then, for the given sFt2 , we can calculate the inventor effort in the following manner: sRt2 ¼ ln ða þ 1Þð1 þ ωÞ : bðpM 1 ðπ rxÞ þ σ Þ (17) The SSEC scheme in the UTTC should also meet the requirements of the ICC and the PC. Thus, according to Equations (8), (9), (16) and (17), we denote sFt2 ¼ sFc and sRt2 ¼ sRc ; then, the factors σ and ω are as given below: AR ðπ αrxÞ : π (18) aðπ αrxÞ rx π (19) σ¼ ω¼ In order to determine the value of k, the payoff gap between the inventor and the firm is considered. Under the new D-D mode with SSEC, the additional profit that represents the profit gap between the D-D and C-D modes is given by, ΔUS ¼ USc ðsRc ; sFc Þ USd ðsRd ; sFd Þ: (20) Meanwhile, the additional profit accrued to the inventor and the firm is given by ΔU R ¼U Rc ðsRc ;sFc ÞðσesRc þωsFc ÞkU Rd ðsRd ;sFd Þ and (21) ΔUF ¼ UFc ðsRc ; sFc Þ þ ðσesRc þ ωsFc Þ þ k UFd ðsRd ; sFd Þ: (22) The bargaining between the inventor and the firm can be definitely regarded as a repeated game. Therefore, we use the traditional Rubinstein Bargaining Game to resolve this issue of revenue redistribution. Note that φ1 and φ2 (φ1 þ φ2 ¼ 1) are the discount factors that measure the patience degree of the inventor and the firm, respectively. 1 2 equilibrium rule to redistribute the additional profit. We assume that ΔUR ¼ 1 φ1 ΔUS : 1 φ1 φ2 (23) ΔUF ¼ φ1 φ1 φ2 ΔUS : 1 φ1 φ2 (24) Thus, according to Equations (18)–(24), we obtain the following value of k: k¼ 1 φ1 ½UFc þ ðσesRc þ ωsFc Þ UFd 1 φ1 φ2 φ φ1 φ2 1 ½URc ðσesRc þ ωsFc Þ URd : (25) 1 φ1 φ2 Then, the SSEC function is T ðsR ; sF Þ ¼ σesR þ ωsF þ k, where the values of σ, ω and k are found in Equations (18), (19) and (25). When the inventor over-invests effort, in the new D-D mode with SSEC, the inventor would be awarded a positive additional profit by the firm through side-payment rather than through higher inventor share rate awarded by the TTO. Proposition 6: In the case of the SSEC, after coordinating inventor effort and firm investment, the TTO maximises its payoff at the point fmin α; max rg. Similar to Proposition 5, Proposition 6 suggests that the TTO always obtains its maximum payoff at the boundary point, when the transferring payoff function T ðsR ; sF Þ successfully coordinates inventor effort and firm investment in the entire area. 5. Numerical investigation Following the numerical simulation methods employed by Haeussler et al. (2014), Chang et al. (2017), in order to investigate the efficiency of the portfolio contract and the SSEC, we employ a series of numeric cases. We order x ¼ 100, π ¼ 500, p0 ¼ 3, m ¼ 10, ct ¼ 0:1, a ¼ 1:5, b ¼ 0:1, AR ¼ 11 and φ1 ¼ φ2 ¼ 0:5. Further, we use the variable α and r to control the inventor payoff αrx and the firm payoff π rx. As shown in Table 1, we consider cases in the normally observed licence contract. For the royalty payment at the given level of inventor share rate (α ¼ 0:4), the total social welfare of the UITT is 360.12 in the D-D mode without any coordination, which is less than 404.95 in the C-D mode (see Proposition 2). This indicates the fact that the loss in profit during the UITT reaches 44.83 units because of non-matching inputs. In addition, when the TTO increases the inventor share rate, the inventor inputs KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT RESEARCH & PRACTICE 9 Table 1. Comparison of decentralized and centralized decision-making (r ¼ 3:5 or θ ¼ 0:6). Decentralized decision-making Variables α sR sF USC UF UR UT 0.4 1.16 11.54 360.12 93.45 85.67 181.00 Royalty payment 0.6 1.56 5.46 348.71 99.54 128.50 120.67 0.8 1.85 1.14 335.52 103.86 171.33 60.33 Equity payment 0.6 0.65 14.96 327.45 124.44 113.37 89.64 0.4 0.07 21.05 293.43 103.48 68.87 121.07 more effort but the firm begins to reduce its investment rapidly, and the loss of social welfare increases to 69.43 units. This change demonstrates the phenomenon of double moral hazard. Moreover, in most cases, increasing inventor share rate is not an effective means to promote the success of the UITT. Furthermore, compared with the matched inputs in the C-D mode, Table 1 proves that there exists under-investment or over-investment in case of inventor effort and firm investment in the D-D mode (see Proposition 3). In addition, in the C-D mode, the payoff of all participants is greater than that in the D-D mode. This indicates that there is room for effective contract coordination. Based on the understanding of UTTC, Table 2 presents the improvements made by the portfolio contract with royalties and revenue redistribution. When the inventor share rate is 0.5 or 0.54, the portfolio contract cannot meet the PC requirement 0.8 1.15 10.65 352.10 142.30 160.92 48.88 Centralized decision-making 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.23 22.55 404.95 99.95 99.50 168.00 236.50 205.50 137.00 68.50 because the inventor has a lower payoff (URt < URd ). When the inventor share rate is higher than 0.54, the portfolio contract could play an effective role in improving social welfare. This proves that there is a limitation in terms of coordinating inventor effort and firm investment (see Proposition 4), since the portfolio contract only works under certain specific conditions (see Inequality 14). In addition, when the value of the inventor share rate grows from 0.5 to 0.66, the inventor’s and the firm’s payoff increase slightly, while the TTO’s payoff drops sharply. Another important phenomenon is that the payoff transferred from the inventor to the firm automatically leads to all participants putting in the same effort and investment. Further, the transferring factor δ is negatively related to the inventor share rate but positively related to the royalty fee (per unit). Table 3 presents the improvement in payoff when the SSEC contract is employed as the coordination Table 2. Portfolio contract with royalty and revenue sharing. Variables Decentralized decision making α 0.50 0.54 0.58 0.62 0.66 r 3.33 3.25 3.16 3.09 3.01 UFd 110.11 118.26 126.02 133.42 140.47 URd 109.17 118.23 126.84 135.06 142.90 UTd 146.67 132.65 119.01 105.76 92.93 Portfolio contract with royalty and revenue sharing USd 365.95 369.14 371.87 374.24 376.30 UFt 140.95 142.94 144.61 146.04 147.27 URt 100.67 115.54 129.88 143.69 157.00 UTt 163.33 146.48 130.47 115.22 100.69 USt 404.95 404.95 404.95 404.95 404.95 δ 0.80 0.86 0.91 0.95 0.99 Table 3. The side-payment self-enforcing contract (SSEC). Variables α 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Centralized decision r 2 3 4 2 3 4 2 3 4 2 3 4 UFc 238.66 143.46 48.26 238.66 143.26 48.26 238.66 143.46 48.26 238.66 143.26 48.26 URc 46.56 84.64 122.72 86.64 143.76 200.88 126.72 202.88 279.04 166.80 262.00 357.20 UTc 120.24 177.36 234.48 80.16 118.24 156.32 40.08 59.12 78.16 0 0 0 Decentralized decision USc 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 405.46 UFd 215.67 131.07 51.74 221.34 136.75 57.41 225.37 140.78 61.44 228.50 143.90 64.56 URd 68.64 89.44 71.84 102.96 134.16 107.76 137.28 178.88 143.68 171.60 223.60 179.60 UTd 116.40 164.40 188.40 77.60 109.60 125.60 38.80 54.80 62.80 0 0 0 SSEC USd 400.71 384.91 311.98 401.90 380.51 290.77 401.45 374.46 267.92 400.10 367.50 244.17 UFt 215.97 133.60 67.54 221.68 142.19 85.40 226.28 149.67 102.17 230.28 156.56 118.33 URt 69.25 94.50 103.44 103.63 145.04 163.74 139.10 196.67 225.13 175.18 248.91 287.13 UTt 120.24 177.36 234.48 80.16 118.24 156.32 40.08 59.12 78.16 0 0 0 T 22.69 9.85 −19.28 16.99 1.27 −37.14 12.38 −6.21 −53.91 8.38 −13.09 −70.07 10 X. CHANG ET AL. scheme. First, in the new D-D mode with SSEC, the inventor, firm and TTO all obtain greater payoffs than that in the D-D mode without any coordination. The total social welfare of the UITT is equal to that in the C-D mode. Compared with the portfolio contract, the SSEC works more effectively in the entire area. In addition, when the inventor share rate increases from 0.4 to 1.0, both the inventor’s and the firm’s payoffs increase slightly, while the TTO’s payoff declines rapidly. Meanwhile, the transferring payoff T (from firm to inventor) also decreases significantly with the decrease in inventor share rate and royalty fee (per unit). Specifically, the transferring payoff Treduces to become negative when α and r are sufficiently large. This implies that in certain cases, the inventor transfers part of the payoff to the firm, even though this phenomenon is not common. 6. Discussion 6.1. Complete and incomplete contracts As investigated in previous research (e.g., Crama et al., 2008; Dechenaux et al., 2009), the common patent licence contract with royalty or equity payment is an incomplete contract, because the TTO cannot write any contract terms that directly govern the unobservable inventor effort and the unverifiable firm investment before transferring the university technology. In addition, even an incomplete contract could indirectly affect the faculty effort and firm investment, as this effect is normally too weak with few punishments or incentives. Thus, in the process of the UITT, it is possible for both the inventor and the firm to reduce their inputs due to the unreasonable revenue distribution scheme. In addition, the TTO does not have any knowledge of what the matched inventor effort and firm investment is. In this paper, we introduced the concept of the UTTC, considered participants’ inputs and payoff in the C-D mode as the benchmark and explored cases of complete contracts. In case of the portfolio contract, only when the inventor share rate and royalty fee (per unit) follow a specific requirement (i.e., Inequality 14) does the inventor put in matched effort. In case of the SSEC contract, the transferring payoff function, which could be positive or negative, measures the relative contribution of the inventor effort and the firm investment to the success of the UITT. By considering the SSEC, the inventor can obtain a positive compensatory payment that reflects their time spent and tacit knowledge of the UITT, and this is not only limited to the transfer of patent rights. 6.2. Two objectives of university TTO Many studies have showed the TTO’s decisive role in the UITT and investigated its orientation of economic and social impact (Anderson, Daim, & Lavoie, 2007; Caldera & Debande, 2010; Chapple, Lockett, Siegel, & Wright, 2005; Curi, Daraio, & Llerena, 2012). For example, the TTO in Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) follows the principle of ‘Impact not Profit’. This indicates the fact that social welfare is the primary objective of the MIT TTO. Compared with these previous studies and actual cases, this paper considers that the TTO’s primary objective is to maximise the social welfare of the UITT. As shown in Tables 1 and 3, when the inventor and the firm put in the same effort and investment, their payoffs are not always greater than those in the D-D mode. Thus, this does not follow the PC requirement. It appears that the C-D mode with given inventor share rate intensifies a double moral hazard in certain cases, and the coordination contract is required to redistribute the payoff of all participants. However, the common license contract with a single payment term cannot achieve this goal (Proposition 3). In order to achieve the highest social welfare (in Section 5 is 404.95), adopting the portfolio contract or the SSEC contract is the TTO’s recommended choice. In this paper, we found that the portfolio contract has limitations because it can only resolve the issue of revenue redistribution under certain specific conditions (Inequality 14 and Table 2). In contrast, the SSEC contract can coordinate inventor effort and firm investment more effectively (Table 3). Since many TTOs are independent from their university in the US, China and European countries, the TTO’s second objective is to maximise its own payoff in order to maintain normal operations. Therefore, TTOs must ensure a reasonable inventor share rate that distributes licensing revenue between the inventor and the TTO, and a royalty fee (per unit) that distributes the production revenue between the university (involving the TTO and the inventor) and the firm. In the portfolio contract, the TTO obtains its maximum payoff at the smallest boundary point fminfαg; rðαÞ; θðαÞg (Proposition 5). In the SSEC, after making the transferring payoff function, the TTO would maximise its own payoff at the point fmin α; max rg (Proposition 6). It is worth noting that although the TTO’s payoff is secondary, it cannot be neglected. In US universities, TTO’s intermediary service fee must be paid first. For example, The Office of Technology Licensing (OTL) in Stanford University usually first deducts its cost from royalties or takes 15% equity to support its own running, and reimburses any direct expenses. In contrast, Chinese universities pay little attention to TTO payoff, and there is a particular lack of permanent and effective incentive mechanisms for TTO staff. According to Article 44 of ‘Law of the P.R. C on Promoting the Transformation of Scientific and Technological Achievements’, no less than 50% of net licensing revenue obtained from the UITT should be KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT RESEARCH & PRACTICE awarded to persons who made important contributions to scientific and technological achievement and its transformation. However, there are no official rules regarding how much licensing revenue should be awarded to the TTO and its staff. In practice, the actual inventor share rate generally increases to 70% (e.g., Shanghai, Nanjing and other Chinese cities) or even 90% (e.g., Hubei province in central China). Our finding in Table 1 shows that it does not always work when the TTO promotes inventor’s participation by giving up its own payoff and unilaterally transferring it to the inventor. 6.3. Portfolio contract vs. side-payment self-enforcing contract In this paper, it becomes evident that there are three differences between the portfolio and SSEC contracts. First, the portfolio contract can only coordinate the inventor effort and the firm investment with a limitation of transfer factor, while the SSEC contract works more effectively with fewer restrictions. In addition, the portfolio contract mainly focuses on the transfer factor (redistribution proportion) and redistributes the additional profit in the final stage of the UITT, depending on the product yield. However, the product yield is uncertain; therefore, it is difficult for the TTO to make an accurate revenue sharing contract. In the case of the SSEC contract, the transferring payoff function depends on the inventor effort and firm investment, which could be evaluated and recorded by the TTO during the execution of the contract. For example, The TTO can design a scheme in which the inventor gets his/her reward according to the time spent, and requires the firm to put in sufficient R&D funding and infrastructure support through the “Maximum Effort Clause” stated in the licensing contract. Therefore, according to the SSEC contract, the TTO can easily write an ex-ante contract term that specifies the inventor’s time spent and related labour remuneration. Lastly, the SSEC contract considers the extent of participants’ patience, which reflects their negotiation power expressed through the factors of the Rubinstein Bargaining Game. To conclude, we believe that the SSEC contract is a better coordination method for optimising the social welfare of the UITT and the payoff of all stakeholders. 7. Conclusion A successful university technology transfer mainly depends on inventor effort and firm investment. This process is fraught with incentive problems, largely because of the double moral hazard problem. In this paper, we introduced the concept of the UTTC and used the portfolio contract and the SSEC contract 11 to coordinate the inputs of all stakeholders and maximise the social welfare of the UITT. We assumed that in UTTC, the TTO is the principal and both the inventor and the firm are agents, and attempted to determine the maximum social welfare. This makes our research fundamentally different from previous studies because it (1) investigates whether the inventor and the firm have put in matched effort and investment, based on the benchmark created by the C-D mode; and (2) preliminarily discusses how to coordinate inventor effort and firm investment through the coordination of contracts, clearly demonstrating that inventor effort and firm investment in the traditional D-D mode normally do not match and that there is room for improvement. From the perspective of optimising the social welfare of the UITT, we found that the common license contract with single royalties or equity payment does not work effectively. Further, the portfolio contract only plays a limited role under specific conditions, and the SSEC contract is effective at coordinating participants’ inputs. Our numerical investigation successfully proved these results. In contrast to prior studies that only focused on individual or organisational payoff in the UITT process, this study paid more attention to social welfare. The double moral hazard is regarded as the most significant inherent problem that is not conducive to optimising social welfare from the perspective of UTTC. Our analysis added to the understanding of how to eliminate double moral hazard through the coordination of contracts. The new D-D mode with portfolio contract or SSEC contract can enable matched inputs in terms of inventor effort and firm investment. Like many previous studies, this paper has certain limitations. First, our theoretical assumption ignores certain scenarios. For example, this paper does not consider the fact that an inventor may decide not to disclose inventions to the TTO (Halilem, Amara, Olmos-Peñuela, & Mohiuddin, 2017). We found that this phenomenon is common in Chinese universities (Fong, Chang, & Chen, 2018). Further research must pay attention to this phenomenon, especial when the TTO is managed by both university and firm. Second, data is a common limitation. Our empirical analysis mainly depends on numerical simulation. We were unable to collect actual data or cases concerning inventor effort and firm investment. In further research, we will aim to develop a more comprehensive theoretical model to optimise the UITT process and perhaps allow the inventor and the firm to select their preferred UITT commercialisation models. Disclosure statement No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors. 12 X. CHANG ET AL. Funding This work was supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China [71603184], and National Key R&D Program of China [2017YFB1401102]. References Anderson, T. R., Daim, T. U., & Lavoie, F. F. (2007). Measuring the efficiency of university technology transfer. Technovation, 27(5), 306–318. Baldini,N.,Grimaldi,R.,&Sobrero,M.(2005).Motivationsand incentives for patenting within universities: A survey ofItalian inventors. Academy of Management Proceedings. 2005. Retrieved from https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.718481 Blind, K., Pohlisch, J., & Zi, A. (2018). Publishing, patenting, and standardization: Motives and barriers of scientists. Research Policy, 47(7), 1185–1197. Brescia, F., Colombo, G., & Landoni, P. (2016). Organizational structures of knowledge transfer offices: An analysis of the world’s top-ranked universities. Journal of Technology Transfer, 41(1), 132–151. Caldera, A., & Debande, O. (2010). Performance of Spanish universities in technology transfer: An empirical analysis. Research Policy, 39(9), 1160–1173. Chang, X. H., Chen, Q., & Fong, P. S. W. (2017). University invention disclosure: Balancing the right stage and type. Journal of Technology Transfer, 42(3), 510–537. Chapple, W., Lockett, A., Siegel, D., & Wright, M. (2005). Assessing the relative performance of U.K. university technology transfer office: Parametric and non-parametric evidence. Research Policy, 34(3), 369–384. Choi, J. P. (2001). Technology transfer with moral hazard. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19(1– 2), 249–266. Crama, P., Reyck, B. D., & Degraeve, Z. (2008). Milestone payments or royalties? Contract design for R&D licensing. Operational Research, 56(6), 1539–1552. Curi, C., Daraio, C., & Llerena, P. (2012). University technology transfer: How (in)efficient are French universities? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 36(3), 629–654. Dechenaux, E., Thursby, J. G., & Thursby, M. C. (2011). Inventor moral hazard in university licensing: The role of contracts. Research Policy, 40(1), 94–104. Dechenaux, E., Thursby, M. C., & Thursby, J. G. (2009). Shirking, sharing risk and shelving: The role of university license contracts. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 27(1), 80–91. Fong, P. S. W., Chang, X. H., & Chen, Q. (2018). Faculty patent assignment in the Chinese mainland: Evidence from the top 35 patent application universities. Journal of Technology Transfer, 43(1), 69–95. Haeussler, C., Jiang, L., Thursby, J. G., & Thursby, M. C. (2014). Specific and general information sharing among competing academic researchers. Research Policy, 43(3), 465–475. Halilem, N., Amara, N., Olmos-Peñuela, J., & Mohiuddin, M. (2017). “To own, or not to own?” A multilevel analysis of intellectual property right policies’ on academic entrepreneurship. Research Policy, 46 (8), 1479–1489. Hellmann, T. (2007). The role of patents for bridging the science to market gap. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 63(4), 624–647. Jensen, R. A., Thursby, J. G., & Thursby, M. C. (2003). Disclosure and licensing of university inventions: ‘The best we can do with the s**t we get to work with’. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21(9), 1271–1300. Jensen, R. A., & Thursby, M. C. (2001). Proofs and prototypes for sale: The licensing of university inventions. The American Economic Review, 91(1), 240–259. Littunen, H. (2000). Entrepreneurship and the characteristics of the entrepreneurial personality. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior & Research, 6(6), 295–310. Macho-Stadler, I., Martínez-Giralt, X., & Pérez-Castrillo, D. (1996). The role of information in licensing contract design. Research Policy, 25(1), 43–57. Macho-Stadler, I., & Pérez-Castrillo, D. (2010). Incentives in university technology transfer. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28(4), 362–367. Savva, N., & Taneri, N. (2011). The equity vs. royalty dilemma in university technology transfer. London Business School. Retrieved from http://faculty.london. edu/nsavva/111026_UTT.pdf Thompson, N. C., Ziedonis, A. A., & Mowery, D. C. (2018). University licensing and the flow of scientific knowledge. Research Policy, 47(6), 1060–1069. Thursby, J. G., Jensen, R., & Thursby, M. C. (2001). Objectives, characteristics and outcomes of university licensing: A survey of major U.S. universities. Journal of Technology Transfer, 26(1–2), 59–72. Thursby, J. G., & Thursby, M. C. (2011). Faculty participation in licensing: Implications for research. Research Policy, 40(1), 20–29. KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT RESEARCH & PRACTICE 13 Appendix List of Abbreviations Abbreviations UITT UTTC TTO D-D mode C-D mode SSEC Description University-industry technology transfer University technology transfer chain Technology transfer office Decentralisation decision-making mode Centralisation decision-making mode side-payment self-enforcing contract List of variables Variables UT UTd , UTt , UTc UF UFd , UFt , UFc UR URd , URt , URc USd USc pd , pt , pc sR sRd , sRt , sRc sF sFd , sFt , sFc p a b p0 AR R m r θ I π x ct α δ T σ ω k ΔUS ΔUR ΔUF φ1 and φ2 Description The TTO payoff The TTO payoff in D-D mode without any coordination, in new D-D mode with coordination contract, and in C-D mode, respectively The firm payoff The firm payoff in D-D mode without any coordination, in new D-D mode with coordination contract, and in C-D mode, respectively The inventor payoff The inventor payoff in D-D mode without any coordination, in new D-D mode with coordination contract, and in C-D mode, respectively The social welfare of UITT that is the sum of participants’ payoff in D-D mode The social welfare of UITT that is the sum of participants’ payoff in C-D mode The success probability of UITT in D-D mode without any coordination, in new D-D mode with coordination contract, and in C-D mode, respectively The inventor effort putting in UITT The inventor effort in D-D mode without any coordination, in new D-D mode with coordination contract, and in C-D mode, respectively The firm investment in UITT The firm investment in D-D mode without any coordination, in new D-D mode with coordination contract, and in C-D mode, respectively The success probability of UITT Measure the importance of the inventor effort to successful UITT Measure the importance of the firm investment to successful UITT the systemic risk of UITT Measure the influence of time-cost The total licensing revenue The upfront fee paid by firm when royalty payment is used The royalty fee per unit The equity rate related to production revenue resulting from patent utilization The dummy variable indicating payment selection The production revenue resulting from technology licensing The production yield The production cost per unit The inventor share rate The transfer factor when portfolio contract is used The transferring payoff function when SSEC is used Measure the value of inventor effort Measure the value of firm investment A constant when the transferring payoff function is used The profit gap between D-D mode and C-D mode The added profit which accrued to inventor when SSEC is used The added profit which accrued to firm when SSEC is used The discount factors measuring the patience degree Proof of Proposition 1 Table A1 shows the optimal inventor effort, the optimal firm investment, and the related probability of successful UITT in the traditional D-D mode and C-D mode with the single royalty and equity payment. 14 X. CHANG ET AL. Table A1. Activities of faculty and firm in decentralized and centralized decision making. Faculty’s effort Decentralized decision making with royalties Decentralized decision making with equity Centralized decision making sRd ¼ Þaαrxd ln Að1þa R bðπrxd Þ Firm’s technology investment sFd ¼ bpðπrxd Þ aþ1 b ln aþ1 þ AR a b ln αrxd ap Success rate pd ¼ 1 bð1þa πrx Þ Þaαθ sRd ¼ ln ðA1þa R bð1θÞ ð1θÞbpπ AR a sFd ¼ aþ1 b ln aþ1 þ b ln αθπap pd ¼ 1 πb1þa ð1θÞ Þa sRc ¼ ln ðaþ1 AR b bpπ AR a sFc ¼ aþ1 b ln aþ1 þ b ln apπ pc ¼ 1 1þa πb When USd ðα; rÞ > USd ðα; θÞ, the royalty payment is used in the license contract. Then, for the given level of inventor 0 effort and firm investment, we first denote USd ðαÞ ¼ 0, and 0 have ð1 þ aÞαrx ¼ π rx. Next, we denote UTd ðrÞ ¼ 0, and obtain the optimal royalty fee (per unit) r ¼ pπffiffi 1 and the optimal inventor share rate x π b 1 α ¼ ð1þaÞ pffiffiffiffi . ð πb1Þ Similarly, when USd ðα; rÞ USd ðα; θÞ, we denote 0 0 USd ðαÞ ¼ 0 and UTd ðθÞ ¼ 0, then obtain the optimal equity qffiffiffiffiffiffi rate θ ¼ 1 1þa πb and optimal inventor share rate pffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffi 1aÞ πbþa 1þa pffiffiffiffi pffiffiffiffiffiffi . α ¼ ðð1þa Þð πb 1þaÞ Proof of Propositions 2 and 3 For Proposition 2, as shown in Table 4, it is clear that pc > pd ðθÞ and pc > pd ðαÞ. The comparison between USd and USc also shows that USc USd ðα; rÞ and USc USd ðα; θÞ. In order to maximize the total social welfare, in this paper we consider the inputs required in C-D mode as the benchmark, which enables us to make the following comparison: sRc sRd ¼ ln sFc π rx 1θ or ln αrx αθ sFd a b1 αrx ab π 1b αθ b 1 ¼ ln or ln π rx π rx 1θ 1θ Thus, if αrx π rx or αθ 1 θ, we have sRc sRd and sFc sFd , otherwise the opposite trend occurs, particularly if αrx ¼ π rx or αθ ¼ 1 θ, sRc ¼ sRd but sFc > sFd . For Proposition 3, the result shows that the common license contract with single royalties or equity payments cannot make the sRc ¼ sRd and sFc ¼ sFd at the same time. This suggests that the common patent license contract with single royalty or equity payment cannot ensure matched effort and investment from inventor and firm as in C-D mode.