Business cycle A business cycle is a cycle of fluctuations in the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) around its long-term natural growth rate. It explains the expansion and contraction in economic activity that an economy experiences over time. A business cycle is completed when it goes through a single boom and a single contraction in sequence. The time period to complete this sequence is called the length of the business cycle. A boom is characterized by a period of rapid economic growth whereas a period of relatively stagnated economic growth is a recession. These are measured in terms of the growth of the real GDP, which is inflation adjusted. Stages of the Business Cycle In the diagram above, the straight line in the middle is the steady growth line. The business cycle moves about the line. Below is a more detailed description of each stage in the business cycle: #1 Expansion The first stage in the business cycle is expansion. In this stage, there is an increase in positive economic indicators such as employment, income, output, wages, profits, demand, and supply of goods and services. Debtors are generally paying their debts on time, the velocity of the money supply is high, and investment is high. This process continues until economic conditions become favorable for expansion. #2 Peak The economy then reaches a saturation point, or peak, which is the second stage of the business cycle. The maximum limit of growth is attained. The economic indicators do not grow further and are at their highest. Prices are at their peak. This stage marks the reversal in the trend of economic growth. Consumers tend to restructure their budget at this point. #3 Recession The recession is the stage that follows the peak phase. The demand for goods and services starts declining rapidly and steadily in this phase. Producers do not notice the decrease in demand instantly and go on producing, which creates a situation of excess supply in the market. Prices tend to fall. All positive economic indicators such as income, output, wages, etc. consequently start to fall. #4 Depression There is a commensurate rise in unemployment. The growth in the economy continues to decline, and as this falls below the steady growth line, the stage is called depression. #5 Trough In depression stage, the economy’s growth rate becomes negative. There is further decline until the prices of factors, as well as the demand and supply of goods and services, reach their lowest. The economy eventually reaches the trough. This is the lowest it can go. It is the negative saturation point for an economy. There is extensive depletion of national income and expenditure. #6 Recovery After this stage, the economy comes to the stage of recovery. In this phase, there is a turnaround from the trough and the economy starts recovering from the negative growth rate. Demand starts to pick up due to the lowest prices and consequently, supply starts reacting, too. The economy develops a positive attitude towards investment and employment and hence, production starts increasing. Employment also begins to rise and due to the accumulated cash balances with the bankers, lending also shows positive signals. In this phase, depreciated capital is replaced by producers, leading to new investment in the production process. Recovery continues until the economy returns to steady growth levels. This completes one full business cycle of boom and contraction. The extreme points are the peak and the trough. Explanations by Economists John Keynes explains the occurrence of business cycles as a result of fluctuations in aggregate demand, which bring the economy to shortterm equilibriums that are different from a full employment equilibrium. Keynesian models do not necessarily indicate periodic business cycles but imply cyclical responses to shocks via multipliers. The extent of these fluctuations depends on the levels of investment, for it determines the level of aggregate output. On the contrary, economists like Finn E. Kydland and Edward C. Prescott, who are associated with the Chicago School of Economics, challenge the Keynesian theories. They consider the fluctuations in the growth of an economy not as a result of monetary shocks, but a result of technology shocks, such as innovation. It is generally rejected by mainstream economists who follow the path of Keynes. Theory of Real Business Cycles and Economic Fluctuation Theory of Real Business Cycles and Economic Fluctuation! Introduction: Most Economists believe that the classical model cannot explain the short- run economic fluctuations because in this model prices are flexible. However the new classical economists believe that the classical model can explain the short-run economic fluctuations. They believe that it is best to assume that prices are flexible even in the short-run. Almost all microeconomic analysis is based on the assumption that prices adjust to clear markets. New classical economists argue that macroeconomic analysis should be based on the same assumption. The leading new classical explanation of economic fluctuations is called the theory of real business cycles. According to this analysis, the assumption that have been used for long-run may also apply for short-run study. Most importantly, real-business-cycle theory holds that the economy obeys the classical dichotomy nominal variables are assumed not to influence real variables. To explain fluctuations in real variables, real-business-cycle theory emphasis real changes in the economy, such as changes in fiscal policy and production technologies. This theory excludes the nominal variables to explain economic fluctuations. Here we examine a simple theory of real business cycles. A Review of the Economy under Flexible Prices: The real-business-cycle theory is a new theory of fluctuations which requires the IS-LM model, under the assumption of flexibility of prices. We then modify it to develop a real model of short-run fluctuations. In the IS-LM model we used the following equations for the goods and money markets: Y = C (Y – T) + l(r) + G………….. IS M/P = L(r, Y)…………. LM The first equation is the IS equation, which states that income Y is the sum of C, I, G consumption, depends on disposable income (Y – T) investment depend on the real interest rate, r, Govt. expenditure, G which is autonomous. The second equation is the LM equation which states that the supply of real money balances, M/P equals the demand, which is the function of the interest rate and the level of income. For simplicity we are assuming that expected inflation is zero, so that, the nominal interest rate equals the real interest rate. To analyse the short-run fluctuations with the IS-LM model, we assume that price level is fixed. If prices are flexible, then the price level adjusts so that output is at its natural rate: Y = Y = F (K, L). These three equations determine three endogenous variables: the level of output Y, the real interest rate r, and the price level P. Fig. 17.1 shows the equilibrium of the economy with flexible prices. The level of output is at its natural rate y which is determined by the supply of factors of production and the production function. The interest rate is determined by the intersection of the is curve and the vertical line y the natural rate of output. The price level adjusts, so that the lm curve crosses the intersection of the other two curves. It may be noted that the LM curve is not very important here as the prices are flexible and the price level adjusts to equilibrate the money market where the other two curves intersect. For the purpose of understanding the real variables, such as output and interest rate, we can ignore the money market. The two key relationships under flexible prices can be shown in Fig 17.2. These two relationships are real aggregate demand and real aggregate supply. The is curve is called here the real aggregate demand curve, which shows that the demand for goods and services is a function of the interest rate Real aggregate supply shows the supply of goods and services, which is determined by the supply of factors of production and the availability of technology. In Fig. 17.2, the interest rate is on the vertical axis instead of price level as we have already seen in the case of aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves. In business-cycle theory, we are interested in real variables and not nominal variables, so the price level is unimportant. We are now developing a different theory of economic fluctuations. A Real-Business-Cycle Model: We now turn our model of the economy under flexible prices into a model of fluctuations. The new feature of the model is the behaviour of labour supply. In a classical model the supply of labour is fixed which determines the level of employment. Yet employment fluctuates over the business cycle. II we maintain classical assumption that labour market clears, as new classical economists do, then we must examine what causes fluctuations in the quantity of labour supplied. After discussing the determinants of labour supply, we modify classical model, aggregate income to include changes in labour supply. The supply of output depends in part on the supply of labour, which means that the greater the number of hours people are willing to work, the more output the economy can produce. We examine how various events influence labour supply and aggregate income according to real-business-cycle theory. Inter-Temporal Substitution of Labour: Real-business-cycle theory states that the quantity of labour supplied depends on the incentives that workers receive at any point in time. When workers are well rewarded, they wish to work more hours, and vice versa. This willingness to reallocate hours of work over time is called the inter-temporal substitution of labour. For example, a second year college student has two years summer vacations left before graduation. He wishes to work for one of these summers and to relax during the other summer. How should he choose which summer to work? Let W1 be his real wage in the first summer, and W2 the real wage he expects in the second summer. Choosing which summer to work means comparing these two wages. Since the student can earn interest on money earned earlier, money earned in the first summer is worth more than money earned in the second summer. Let r be the real interest rate. If the student works in the first summer and saves his earnings, he will have (1 + r) W1 a year later. If he works in the second summer, he will have W2. The inter-temporal relative wage is (1 + r) W1/W2. Working in the first summer is more attractive if the interest rate is high or if the wage is high relative to wage expected to prevail in the future. According to real-business-cycle theory, all workers calculate cost-benefit analysis to decide when to work and when to enjoy leisure. If the wage is temporarily high or if the interest rate is high, it is good time to work. If the wage is temporarily low or if the interest rate is low, it is a good time to enjoy leisure. Real-business-cycle theory uses the inter-temporal substitution of labour to explain why employment and output fluctuate. Shocks to the economy that cause the interest rate to rise or the wage rate to be temporarily high cause people to want to work more—which raises employment and output. Real Aggregate Demand and Real Aggregate Supply: Real-business-cycle theory incorporates inter-temporal substitution of labour into the classical model of the economy. Our analysis of labour supply shows that the interest rate influences the attractiveness of working today. The higher the interest rate, the greater the amount of labour supplied, and the greater the amount of output produced. Fig. 17.3 shows the real-business-cycle model of the economy. Because of inter-temporal substitution of labour, the real aggregate supply curve slopes upward rather than vertically, which means a higher interest rate makes working more attractive, which increases labour supply and, thus, output. The real interest rate adjusts to equilibrate real aggregate supply and real aggregate demand. We can use this model to explain fluctuations in output. Any shock to the economy that shifts aggregate demand or aggregate supply changes equilibrium output. Inter-temporal substitution of labour leads to a corresponding change in the level of employment as well. To explain shifts in real aggregate demand and supply, realbusiness-cycle theorists have emphasised changes in fiscal policy and in technology. We now examine these sources of short-run fluctuations. Fiscal Policy: An increase in government purchases is shown in the realbusiness-cycle model. Fig. 17.4 shows an increase in government purchases shifts the real aggregate demand curve rightward. The result is higher output and a higher real interest rate. It may be noted that there are similarities between this explanation of the effects of fiscal policy and the one we saw in the IS-LM model. An increase in government purchases shifts the real aggregate demand curve outwards for the same reason that it shifts the IS curve outwards in the IS-LM model. In both cases, the result is higher output and a higher interest rate. Thus, the two models make similar predictions. However, there are important differences between the two explanations. In the IS-LM model, prices are stable, and aggregate demand determines output and employment; labour supply and inter-temporal substitution play no role in explaining how fiscal policy influences output. In a real-business-cycle model, prices are flexible, and workers inter-temporally substitute labour. The expansion of output results from an increase in labour supply; people respond to the higher interest rate by choosing to work longer hours. Technology: Many theorists emphasise the role of shocks in technology. To see how technological shocks cause fluctuations, suppose some improvements in technology are available, such as, faster computers. According to this theory, this change affects the economy in two ways. Firstly, the improved technology increases the supply of goods and services. As the production function is improved, more output is produced for any given input. The real aggregate supply curve shifts outwards. Secondly the availability of the new technology rises the demand for goods. For example, firms wishing to buy these computers will raise their demand for goods. For example, firms wishing to buy these computers will raise their demand for investment goods. The real aggregate demand curve shifts outwards as well. Fig. 17.5 shows two effects. A beneficial shock to the technology raises both real aggregate supply and real aggregate demand. In Fig. 17.5(a), demand shifts more than supply. In Fig. 17.5(b), demand shifts less than supply. The Debate over Real-Business-Cycle Theory: Economists disagree about the validity of real-business-cycle theory. At the heart of the debate are four basic issues: (a) The importance of technology shocks. (b) The interpretation of unemployment. (c) The neutrality of money. (d) The flexibility of wages and prices. (a) The Importance of Technological Shocks: Real-business-cycle theory assumes that the economy experiences fluctuations in its ability to turn inputs into outputs, and that these fluctuations in technology cause fluctuations in output and employment. When the available production technology improves, the economy produces more output with the same inputs. Because of inter-temporal substitution of labour, the improved technology also leads to greater employment. This theory often explains recessions as periods of technology regress. According to this theory, output and employment fall during recessions because the available production technology deteriorates, which reduces output and the incentive to work. Critics of this theory are sceptical that the economy experiences large shocks in technology. It is common knowledge that technological progress takes place gradually. It is difficult to think that technology can regress. The technological knowledge may slow down, but it is hard to imagine that it would go into reverse. Advocates respond by taking a broad view of shocks to technology. They argue that there are many events that— although not literally technological in nature—nevertheless, affect the economy as much as technological shocks do. For example, bad weather or increases in world oil prices have effects similar to adverse changes in technology. Whether such events are sufficiently common to explain the frequency and magnitude of business cycles is open to question. (b) The Interpretation of Unemployment: Real-business-cycle theory assumes that fluctuations in employment reflect changes in the amount people want to work. Alternatively, it assumes that the economy is always on the labour supply curve: everyone who wants a job at the going wage rate can find one. To explain fluctuations in employment, advocates of this theory argue that changes in wage rates and interest rates cause inter-temporal substitution of labour. Critics of this theory believe that fluctuations in employment do not reflect changes in the amount people want to work. They do not think desired employment is very sensitive to real wage and the real interest rate. They point out that unemployment fluctuates substantially over the business cycle. The high unemployment in recessions suggests that the labour market does not clear: if people were voluntarily choosing not to work in recessions, they are not, in fact, unemployed. These critics conclude that, wages do not adjust to equilibrate labour demand and supply, as the realbusiness-cycle model assumes. Advocates of this theory argue that unemployment statistics are difficult to interpret. The mere fact that the unemployment rate is high does not mean that inter-temporal substitution of labour is unimportant. Individuals who voluntarily choose not to work may call themselves unemployed to received unemployment benefits. Alternatively; they may call themselves unemployed because they would be willing to work. (c) The Neutrality of Money: This theory assumes that money is neutral which means monetary policy is assumed not to affect real variables, such as output and employment. The neutrality of money not only gives this theory its name, it is also the most radical feature of the theory. Critics point out that the evidence does not support the assumption of neutrality of money. They argue that reductions of money growth and inflation are always associated with periods of high unemployment. Monetary policy appears to have a strong influence on the real economy. Advocates of the theory argue that their critics confuse the direction of causation between money and output. They also claim that money supply is endogenous: fluctuation in output might cause fluctuations in money supply. For example, when output rises—because of beneficial technological shock— the quantity of money demanded rises. The central bank may respond by raising money supply to accommodate the greater demand. This endogenous response of money to economic activity may give the illusion of nonneutrality of money. (d) The Flexibility of Wages and Prices: Real-business-cycle theory assumes that wages and prices adjust quickly to clear markets. Proponents of this theory believe that the stickiness of wages and prices is unimportant for understanding economic fluctuations. They also believe that the assumption of flexible prices is methodologically superior to the assumption of sticky prices, because it ties microeconomic theory to macroeconomic theory more closely. Most of microeconomic analysis is based on the assumption that prices adjust quickly to equate demand and supply. Advocates of this theory believe that macroeconomists should base the analysis on the same assumption. Critics argue that money wages and prices are inflexible—which explains both the existence of unemployment and monetary non-neutrality. To explain stickiness of prices, they rely on the various new Keynesian theories. Conclusion: Real-business-cycle theory reminds us that our understanding of economic fluctuations is not good enough. Fundamental questions about the economy remain open to dispute. Is the stickiness of wages and prices a key to our understanding of economic fluctuations? Does monetary policy have real effects? The way economists answer these questions influence the way they view the role of the economic policy. Those who believe that wages and prices are sticky often believe that fiscal and monetary policy should be used to try to stabilise the economy. Price stickiness is a type of market imperfection, which leaves open the possibility that government policies can raise economic benefits. By contrast, the theorists believe that the government’s ability to stabilise the economy is limited. They view the business cycle as the efficient and natural response of the economy to technological changes. Most models of this theory do not include any market imperfection and believe that the invisible hand guides the economy to an optimal allocation of resources. These two views of economic fluctuations are a source of frequent and heated debate. It is this kind of debate that makes macroeconomics an attractive field of study.