Sign Reversal in the Relation between Income Smoothing and Cost of Debt Dan Amiram Columbia University Graduate School of Business Coller School of Management, Tel Aviv University da2477@columbia.edu Edward Owens Goizueta Business School, Emory University ed.owens@emory.edu Accepted Article October 2017 We thank Peter Pope (editor), an anonymous reviewer, Edwige Cheynel, Peter Demerjian, Ilia Dichev, Shane Dikolli, Ron Dye, Ted Goodman (AAA discussant), Trevor Harris, Alon Kalay, Mark Lang, Yun Lou, Mark Maffett, Nahum Melumad, Grace Pownall, Gil Sadka, Cliff Smith, Jason Wei, Chris Williams, Regina Wittenberg-Moerman (Colorado conference discussant), Joanna Wu, Paul Zarowin, Jerry Zimmerman, and workshop participants at the 2011 International Conference on Credit Analysis and Risk Management, the 2011 American Accounting Association Annual Meeting, the 2011 Columbia University Burton Workshop, 2012 Colorado Summer Accounting Conference, Emory University, National University of Singapore, Northwestern University, and Temple University for helpful comments and suggestions. We are grateful to Ryan Ball and Florin Vasvari for providing a matching table between Dealscan and Worldscope. ABSTRACT Despite the fact that income smoothing by managers is a pervasive phenomenon that has been widely researched, extant literature provides incomplete evidence on how smoothing is associated with cost of debt in general, and in the private loan market in particular. The institutional factors associated with private loan contracts, combined with the theoretical motivations for smoothing, make it unclear whether smoothing will be positively, negatively, or not associated with loan spread. Using both cross-country and within-country analyses on an international sample of private loans, we predict and provide evidence that income smoothing is associated with lower cost of debt when the threat of private benefits consumption by managers is low, but is associated with higher cost of debt when the threat of private benefits consumption by managers is high. We provide the first evidence in the literature that the garbling effect of smoothing can predictably dominate the signaling view of smoothing in debt contract design, and we identify private benefits consumption threat as the feature of the contracting environment that empirically reveals a sign reversal in the relation between smoothing and cost of debt. Keywords: Income smoothing; Private benefits; Debt contracts JEL Classification: F34; G15; M41 _______________________________ This article has been accepted for publication and undergone full peer review but has not been through the copyediting, typesetting, pagination and proofreading process, which may lead to differences between this version and the Version of Record. Please cite this article as doi: 10.1111/jbfa.12295 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Despite the fact that income smoothing by managers is a pervasive phenomenon that has been widely researched, extant literature provides incomplete evidence concerning how borrower income smoothing is associated with cost of debt in general, and in the private loan market in particular. The institutional factors associated with private loan contracts, combined with the theoretical motivations for smoothing, make it unclear ex ante whether smoothing will be Accepted Article positively, negatively, or not associated with loan spread. Thus far, extant literature has examined settings where only the signaling effect of smoothing dominates, and therefore concludes that smoothing is associated with lower cost of debt. In this study, we extend the literature. Specifically, we take advantage of an international setting to predict and identify a theoretically motivated feature of the contracting environment that reveals a sign reversal in the relation between smoothing and cost of debt, thereby providing the first evidence in the literature that the garbling effect of smoothing can predictably dominate the signaling effect of smoothing in debt contract design. Income smoothing is the exercise of managerial discretion to alter the time profile of earnings to reduce the variability of a firm's reported income stream (e.g., Beidleman, 1973; Trueman & Titman, 1988; Fudenberg & Tirole, 1995).1 The literature focuses on two key alternative motivations for income smoothing. On one hand, managers may smooth earnings in an effort to truthfully convey their private information about underlying economic earnings and associated risk to capital providers and other market participants (i.e., the information signaling 1 The overall volatility of a firm’s earnings relative to cash flows (i.e., ―income smoothness‖) is determined by two components. The first component, which we refer to as ―fundamental smoothness,‖ is determined by the inherent volatility of the underlying business processes that generate earnings (which is not a function of managerial reporting discretion). The second component, which we refer to as ―income smoothing‖ or simply ―smoothing,‖ is the portion of overall income smoothness that is determined by managerial reporting choices (i.e., managerial discretion), which themselves are affected by managerial incentives. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. view of smoothing) (e.g., Trueman & Titman, 1988). Alternatively, managers may smooth earnings (regardless of their private information about longer-term economic earnings) in an effort to avoid intervention by outsiders to facilitate consumption of private benefits from the firm (i.e., the information garbling view of smoothing) (e.g., Fudenberg & Tirole, 1995).2,3 The information signaling and information garbling views of smoothing yield directionally opposing predictions concerning the association between observed smoothing and cost of debt. The signaling view suggests that smoothing is an attempt by managers to signal that Accepted Article economic earnings are less volatile than would be inferred from unsmoothed (reported) earnings, and therefore smoothing suggests lower probability of default (e.g., Merton, 1974). In contrast, the garbling view suggests that smoothing is associated with higher risk of private benefits consumption. To the extent that private benefits consumption extracts firm wealth at the expense of debtholders (Lin, Ma, Malatesta, & Xuan, 2011), the information garbling view of smoothing would suggest higher loss given default and higher probability of default (Fudenberg & Tirole 1995). In the context of these alternative views of smoothing, ceteris paribus, we predict cost of debt will be lower if lenders take the information signaling view of smoothing, and will be higher if lenders take the information garbling view of smoothing, ceteris paribus. Moreover, as lenders only lose money if a borrower actually defaults, we expect the effects of smoothing on cost of debt to be stronger when the probability of default is higher. 2 We use the term 'private benefits' as a general term that encompasses several concepts, including both valueextractive private benefits and non-value-extractive private benefits, both of which arise from managers' ability to control the firm. Aghion and Bolton (1992) refer to these categories as "pecuniary" and "non-pecuniary," or "monetary" and "non-monetary" private benefits, respectively. To be more precise, we choose the terms valueextractive and non-value-extractive, because, for example, there can be non-monetary private benefits that nonetheless are value extractive (e.g., shirking). Value-extractive private benefits arise from actions such as empire building, rent extraction, perk consumption and expropriation (Tirole, 2001), which reduces the value of the firm to minority shareholders and debt holders. In contrast, non-value-extractive private benefits include social and professional connections, status and opportunities that arise from continually controlling and running the entity (Aghion & Bolton, 1992). 3 We note that in this context, the terms 'signaling' and 'garbling' refer to the intentions of the manager who is making the smoothing choice. Extant literature sometimes refers to these as 'informative' and 'opportunistic' motivations for smoothing, respectively (e.g., Dechow, Ge, & Schrand, 2010). This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Extant literature provides mixed evidence on the association between smoothing and cost of capital in the equity market. This evidence does not translate into debt markets because creditors have different payoff functions than do equityholders, and can protect themselves through other contracting mechanisms (e.g., financial covenants). Existing evidence from research on the effects of smoothing in debt markets provides evidence that either smoothing is associated with lower cost of debt, or that there is no association. That is, extant literature does not document any setting or conditions where smoothing is associated with higher cost of debt, Accepted Article which is noteworthy given the strong theoretical literature that suggests that smoothing can, in some situations, represent garbling by management, which could negatively affect lenders. Our conjecture is that extant literature has not examined the association between smoothing and cost of debt in a setting or manner in which the garbling effect can reveal itself. Evidence from the U.S. bond market that smoothing is associated with lower cost of debt is not generalizable to broader credit markets, because the bond market is populated by relatively high quality, transparent borrowers. Thus, the garbling view of smoothing seems relatively unlikely to manifest (Bharath, Sunder, & Sunder, 2008). Studies that examine smoothing in the private loan market find either a negative or no association between smoothing and cost of debt, either because they do not focus on the subset of borrowers where garbling effects likely dominate, or because lenders can obtain private information from borrowers, which may mitigate any association between smoothing and contract terms. We view the latter possibility as unlikely, because if managers indeed smooth to facilitate consumption of private benefits, it is unlikely they will reveal their motivation to lenders in private communications. On the other hand, if managers smooth to signal, it is indeed plausible that managers may also supply private information to lenders that reinforce this signal. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Importantly, we do not assert that private lenders are the only (or, even, the primary) audience for signal-based smoothing.4 Accordingly, managers would still need to smooth income to signal their private information to other market participants with whom no private channels of communication exist (e.g., equityholders, bondholders).5 Our conjecture is that lenders’ view of smoothing is shaped by their assessment of the likelihood that managers will consume private benefits, which is a function of the extent of enforcement and penalties imposed in a given environment if managers are caught consuming Accepted Article private benefits. Hereafter, we refer to environments with weak (strong) enforcement and weak (strong) punitive consequences for private benefits consumption as posing a ―high (low) threat‖ of private benefits consumption. In a probabilistic sense, we conjecture that in high (low) threat environments lenders are more likely to take the information garbling (signaling) view of smoothing.6 Intuitively, if there are harsh penalties for consuming private benefits, lenders will assess a lower likelihood that managers are attempting to consume private benefits, ceteris paribus, and their view of smoothing will be shaped accordingly. 7 This intuition provides the basis for our empirical design, where our key design choice concerns how to empirically measure the threat of private benefits consumption in the contracting environment. Firm-level governance measures provide one such option for measuring the threat of private benefits consumption. However, because managers choose both the extent of smoothing 4 For example, Dou, Hope and Thomas (2013) provide evidence firm-supplier relationships can provide smoothing incentives. 5 Indeed, the logic of our entire study goes through if, in the extreme, the lender can directly obtain all information from the borrower other than whether the borrower is consuming private benefits or not, and misreporting audited financial statements is more costly than misreporting private information.. 6 Consistent with our conjecture, in informal interviews with bank loan officers in countries where it is easier to consume private benefits, loan officers indeed indicated that they become "nervous" about a borrower if its financial statements look too "stable." In contrast, the loan officers are reassured when they observe smooth earnings in countries where it is harder to consume private benefits. Having said this, our predictions also follow if lenders infer their view of smoothing from other information sources (i.e., not relying on environmental characteristics), as long as borrower smoothing motivations are correlated with private benefits consumption threat. 7 We formalize this intuition in Appendix B. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. and firm-level governance mechanisms, there are standard endogeneity concerns with using firm-level measures. Accordingly, for our primary analyses we use an international sample, which enables us to exploit plausibly exogenous (from the perspective of a manager) countrylevel variation in the threat of private benefits consumption in the contracting environment. Consistent with our predictions, we provide evidence that smoothing is associated with lower cost of debt in countries characterized by low threat of private benefits consumption, and associated with higher cost of debt in countries characterized by high threat of private benefits Accepted Article consumption. Further, we find that the effects of smoothing on cost of debt are particularly pronounced for firms with relatively high credit risk, consistent with the intuition that lenders would be particularly concerned about the implications of smoothing for expected credit loss in cases where it is more likely that borrowers will default. We note that it is unlikely that lenders view smoothing as information signaling (garbling) for all firms in a low (high) threat environment. That is, within either a low or high threat environment, firm-specific threat of private benefits consumption likely influences the relation between smoothing and cost of debt. Although pursuing an analysis based on firm-level governance characteristics naturally raises endogeneity concerns, we repeat our tests using measures of firm-level variation in the threat of private benefits consumption within a given country. Specifically, we use percentage of closely held shares (e.g., Iliev, Lins, Miller, & Roth, 2015) for our primary non-US sample, and repeat our analysis using a firm-specific managerial entrenchment index (Bebchuk, Cohen, & Ferrell, 2009) with a larger US-only sample. Consistent with our primary findings, in both cases smoothing is negatively (positively) associated with cost of debt for firms with relatively low (high) threat of private benefits consumption. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Although our analyses focus on the association between smoothing and cost of debt, private lenders have loan contracting terms other than interest rate at their disposal that may likewise be affected by income smoothing, such as financial covenants, collateral requirements, and loan maturity. Therefore, in all analyses we control for numerous additional loan-level variables. Further, results suggest that the implications of observed smoothing are incorporated into loans primarily through loan spread, although there is some evidence that smoothing is associated with increased use of financial covenant protections in high threat environments. Accepted Article Extant literature documents a correlation among different accounting system characteristics, including smoothing, accruals quality, conservatism, and earnings persistence (e.g., Dechow et al., 2010). However, there are key differences in the underlying constructs captured by smoothing and these other accounting attributes. We find that neither accruals quality, conservatism, nor earnings persistence change sign in their relation with loan spread across threat environments (consistent with our expectations), and our inferences regarding smoothing hold after including controls for potential effects of accounting quality, conservatism, and earnings persistence. The primary contribution of the study is to provide novel evidence that the garbling effect of smoothing can dominate debt contract design, where the sign of the relation between cost of private debt and earnings smoothing depends (predictably) on the threat of managerial private benefits consumption in the contracting environment. Our study directly addresses a call for additional research on the relation between smoothing and cost of debt (Lang & Maffett, 2011a), and contributes new evidence to the international literature that examines the causes and consequences of income smoothing in capital markets (e.g., Black, Sellers, & Manly, 1998; Leuz, Nanda, & Wysocki, 2003; Lang, Lins, & Maffett, 2012; Shuto & Iwasaki, 2014). This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. 2. Background and Motivation Private debt contracts represent an important source of capital for most firms (Sufi, 2007; Ivashina, 2009; Thomson Reuters, 2014). Despite the fact that a deep literature examines income smoothing, there is incomplete evidence on its association with the cost of private debt. Extant literature focuses on two competing views of income smoothing—the information signaling view and the information garbling view.8 The information signaling view suggests that income smoothing is an efficient mechanism for managers to convey their private information about Accepted Article future earnings (e.g., Beidleman, 1973; Barnea, Ronen, & Sadan, 1975; Ronen & Sadan, 1981; Demski, 1998). Consistent with the information signaling view, Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal (2005) provide U.S.-based survey evidence that managers' smooth primarily to convey future growth prospects and lower investor risk perception. Further consistent with this view, Hunt, Moyer, and Shevlin (2000) provide evidence in a U.S. setting that income smoothing enhances the contemporaneous relation between stock price and earnings. Likewise, using a U.S. sample, Tucker and Zarowin (2006) find that the change in the current stock price of firms with more earnings smoothing contains more information about future earnings than does the change in current stock price of firms with lower smoothing. In contrast, the information garbling view suggests that managers smooth income to hide their actions and avoid interventions by outsiders to facilitate private benefits consumption (Fudenberg & Tirole, 1995; Acharya & Lambrecht, 2015). According to extant theory, smoothing can reduce outside intervention by monitors because more recent signals of performance are more informative than less recent signals; therefore, a bad earnings outcome leads to negative consequences for the manager even if the firm had an "offsetting" good 8 We recognize that motivations for smoothing exist aside from signaling or garbling, such as tax minimization. Consideration of other such smoothing motivations does not affect the key logic of our study, as discussed in Section 6. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. earnings outcome in an earlier period, while an average outcome leads to fewer negative consequences (Fudenberg & Tirole, 1995). That is, in a firm where unsmoothed earnings are volatile, managers have incentive to smooth earnings simply to reduce volatility (without regard to their belief about longer term economic earnings), because doing so reduces the probability that they will be caught consuming private benefits (if they have chosen to do so) (Fudenberg & Tirole, 1995; Leuz et al., 2003; Lang & Maffett, 2011b; Defond & Park, 1997). Defond and Park (1997) find empirical evidence of smoothing that appears to be motivated by management Accepted Article concerns about job security, consistent with the theory in Fudenberg and Tirole (1995). International evidence presented in Leuz et al. (2003) suggests that income smoothing is more pronounced in countries where country-level institutions do a relatively poor job in limiting insiders’ consumption of private benefits, which is also consistent with the garbling view of smoothing. Relatedly, Gopalan and Jayaraman (2012) provide evidence that firms with more insider control exhibit relatively more income smoothing than non-insider controlled firms in countries with poor investor protection. Studies that examine the effect of smoothing in debt markets are few. Li and Richie (2016) examine whether smoothing affects cost of public debt in the U.S. bond market. That study predicts and documents a negative association between smoothing and bond yield, and accordingly concludes that the information signaling view of smoothing dominates in public credit markets. Li and Richie (2016) further consider the effect of governance characteristics, and do not provide evidence that the negative relation between smoothing and cost of debt is statistically significantly different between well-governed and poorly-governed firms. Further, their results show that in U.S. public credit markets, the garbling effect of smoothing is not strong enough to dominate debt contract design (i.e., the relation between smoothing and cost of This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. public debt is never positive), even in poorly-governed firms. Using a sample of Japanese loans, Takasu (2013) documents a negative relation (no relation) between smoothing and cost of debt when the lender has a low (high) degree of information production about the borrower. Demerjian, Donovan, and Lewis-Western (2017) examine whether smoothing affects the frequency of covenant violation in U.S. private loan contracts. Although that paper focuses on covenants, the paper also presents a secondary analysis which shows that smoothing is negatively associated with loan spread in the U.S., again consistent with the information Accepted Article signaling view of smoothing in an environment with low threat of private benefits consumption. Relatedly, Gassen and Fulbier (2015) provide evidence that the negative relation between smoothing and cost of debt is stronger in environments with poor contracting efficiency, consistent with lenders’ desire to avoid covenant violations where contract renegotiation is more difficult. As with Li and Richie (2016), Gassen and Fulbier (2015) do not find any evidence that there is ever a positive association between smoothing and cost of debt, even in environments with poor firm governance.9 To summarize, extant evidence leaves a reader of the literature with the unequivocal inference that smoothing is negatively associated with cost of debt. However, these extant credit market studies examine settings (i.e., bond markets and/or U.S. samples) where the information garbling motivation is relatively unlikely to reveal itself. Accordingly, it is not clear whether extant studies fail to find any evidence in the credit markets consistent with the information garbling view of smoothing because it does not exist, or because the chosen settings are inadequate to detect it. Our evidence indicates that it is the latter. 9 Another related literature documents a positive relation between income smoothing and credit ratings, consistent with dominance of the signaling view of smoothing (e.g., Gu & Zhao, 2006; Jung, Soderstrom, & Yang, 2013). This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. 3. Development of Predictions As discussed above, our conjecture is that the sign of the association between smoothing and debt contract terms will depend on whether lenders take the information signaling or garbling view of smoothing, because these alternative views have directionally opposite effects on expected credit loss. If lenders take the information signaling view (i.e., smoothing is associated with lower probability of default, as in Merton, 1974), we predict a negative association between smoothing and cost of debt, ceteris paribus. If lenders take the information Accepted Article garbling view (i.e., smoothing is associated with higher expected loss given default), we predict a positive association between smoothing and cost of debt, as prior literature documents that lenders price protect against the threat of private benefits consumption in the contracting environment (Lin et al., 2011). Further, we predict that, on-average, lenders will more likely take the information signaling (garbling) view in environments where there is stronger (weaker) enforcement and harsher (lighter) penalties associated with managerial private benefits consumption. These predictions raise several natural questions. First, if smoothing is indeed associated with lower cost of debt in environments with low threat of private benefits consumption, why would not all managers in those environments smooth to the same extent? There are at least two reasons. We expect cross-sectional variation in the extent of smoothing among borrowers in low threat environments simply because not all borrowers have the same ability to smooth, or because borrowers that can smooth but do not have smooth economic earnings will forego smoothing in order to report truthfully, because not doing so is costly. A second question that arises is, if firms need to communicate with lenders about firm risk, why would they need to use smoothing, rather than private information channels that are This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. available between borrowers and private lenders? It is indeed true that borrowers have private information channels with lenders, and therefore if a borrower has smooth economic earnings, it can communicate that privately to lenders. However, if such a hypothetical borrower indeed has smooth economic earnings, they will likely tell the truth and reflect that in public financial statements, i.e., they will smooth earnings, if for no other reason than to communicate that reality to other capital market participants with whom the borrower does not have private information channels (e.g., equityholders). Accepted Article A third question is, if smoothing is associated with higher cost of debt in environments with high threat of private benefits consumption, why would any firm smooth - that is, would the lender price protection not remove the smoothing incentive? In short, the answer is no. There are two categories of utility-providing private benefits that managers can consume—those that extract firm value (e.g., excess compensation, tunneling), and those that do not (e.g., status of running the firm, social and professional connections) (Aghion & Bolton, 1992). Lenders would only price protect against consumption of private benefits that are firm-value extractive. Therefore, as long as any non-value-extractive private benefits exist, managers will have an incentive to smooth, even if lenders fully price protect against consumption of private benefits that are firm-value extractive.10 Other possibilities include tax or hedging benefits from smoothing, or only partial price protection for value-extractive private benefit consumption. In any case it is an empirical regularity that smoothing is associated with private benefits consumption (e.g., Leuz et al., 2003). 10 Consider the following motivating example, which we more formally develop in Appendix B. If a manager chooses to smooth to consume non-value-extractive private benefits (e.g., to avoid intervention and keep her job), lenders will observe smooth earnings and will be unable to distinguish whether managers are consuming valueextractive or non-value-extractive private benefits. Thus, the lender will price protect against the potential valueextractive component. The manager knows this, so the manager will go ahead and consume those value-extractive private benefits, along with enjoying the non-extractive private benefits. Even though the price protection offsets the value-extractive benefit consumed by the manager, the manager remains better off from the non-extractive private benefits, which can only be achieved via smoothing. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. In Appendix B, we present a highly stylized framework that imbeds the dynamics we discuss above, which presents one possibility in which the equilibrium we describe can exist in reality. That is, we consider a firm whose manager has private information about the smoothness of economic earnings, and unobservable (to outsiders) ability to either smooth or not smooth earnings. The environment in which the manager operates is characterized as having either high or low costs of getting caught consuming private benefits, and high or low costs associated with misreporting true economic earnings (e.g., Desai, Hogan, & Wilkins, 2006). The manager then Accepted Article chooses whether to consume private benefits and whether to smooth earnings (if able). We also characterize potential private benefits of two forms: private benefits that extract firm value (and will therefore be price protected by capital providers), and those that do not (and therefore will not be price protected). The firm then seeks a private loan. Lenders can observe the threat of private benefits consumption in the environment, and whether income is smooth. We show that in an environment with high consumption threat, smoothing is associated with higher cost of debt in (partial) equilibrium - indeed, lenders fully price protect against expected consumption of value-reducing private benefits, but the existence of non-value reducing private benefits still makes it optimal from the manager's perspective to smooth income. Further, we show that in an environment with low consumption threat, smoothing is associated with lower cost of debt in (partial) equilibrium, because smoothing reveals information about firm risk with low likelihood of private benefits consumption.11 11 Alternatively, for example, we could characterize a framework where the firm is financed with equity, and the manager is making smoothing decisions in that context. Then, in a future period there is an exogenous increase in growth opportunities that causes the firm to seek debt financing. It is straightforward to show that our same predictions would follow in this situation where the smoothing choice is exogenous to the borrowing decision. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. 4. Research Design 4.1. Income smoothing Earnings smoothness is comprised of smoothness that is driven by the natural business processes and operating cycle of a firm and the application of non-discretionary accounting regulations to those processes (i.e., fundamental smoothness), as well as smoothness that is driven by managerial discretion (i.e., discretionary smoothing). A key empirical challenge is disentangling observed smoothness into these fundamental and discretionary components Accepted Article (Dechow et al., 2010).12 To do so, we closely follow the approach in Lang and Maffett (2011b) and Lang et al. (2012).13 Following the Lang et al. (2012) approach we first compute two alternative measures of overall earnings smoothness for firm i in period t, which we denote Smooth1i,t and Smooth2i,t. Smooth1 is the negative of the ratio of the standard deviation of operating earnings to the standard deviation of operating cash flows, where both earnings and cash flows are scaled by lagged total assets prior to computation of the standard deviations. 14 Larger values of Smooth1 indicate more income smoothing. Smooth2 is the negative of the correlation between accruals and operating cash flows (both scaled by lagged total assets) over the three to five year period ending in year t, where higher values of Smooth2 indicate more earnings smoothness. Second, 12 We note that, although lenders may attempt to estimate the extent of a borrower’s discretionary smoothing in an attempt to unravel the manager's intervention relative to the unsmoothed earnings stream, this may not be strictly necessary to generate our predictions. In other words, it is possible that if lenders are unable to do this unraveling and simply use the extent of observed smoothness as a proxy for discretionary smoothing (together with their assessment of whether the threat of private benefits consumption is low or high), cost of debt will be higher (lower) in high (low) threat environments when the borrower has a relatively smooth income stream, on average. 13 We appreciate the difficulties and concerns inherent in performing this decomposition. However, Lang et al. (2012) (pp. 768-770) conduct and report extensive construct validity tests on this measure in their appendix. Moreover, this measure has been used frequently in recent literature (e.g., Hamm, Jung, & Lee, 2017; Lang & SticeLawrence, 2015; Friedman, 2017). 14 We compute operating cash flow as net income before extraordinary items minus accruals. We compute accruals as the change in current assets less the change in current liabilities less the change in cash plus the change in current debt less depreciation and amortization. The standard deviations are estimated using no fewer than three and no more than five annual observations ending in year t. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. we regress Smooth1 and Smooth2 on a set of proposed fundamental determinants of earnings smoothness using the following pooled estimations: 9 Smooth1i ,t 0 f Zi ,ft industry year i ,t (1) f 1 9 Smooth2i ,t 0 f Zi ,ft industry year i ,t (2) f 1 where Z i ,ft is the following vector of nine fundamental smoothness determinants (Lang et al., Accepted Article 2012): natural log of total assets (LSize), a measure of firm size; leverage (Leverage), to capture differences in financing choices; book-to-market ratio (BTM), to capture asset tangibility and expected earnings growth; standard deviation of firm i's annual sales (StdSales) over the three-tofive year period ending in year t, to capture underlying operating volatility; percentage of years firm i experienced negative operating earnings in the three-to-five year period ending in year t (%Loss), to capture differences in accrual properties of loss observations; operating cycle (OpCycle); average annual sales growth over the three-to-five year period ending in year t (AvgSalesGrowth), to capture growth opportunities; operating leverage (OpLev), to capture capital intensity; and average annual cash flow from operations over the three-to-five year period ending in year t (AvgOpCash), to capture general profitability level.15 When estimating Eqs. (1) and (2), we further include industry and year fixed effects to capture different accrual properties across industries, and to control for macro-economic cycles. We define discretionary smoothing (fundamental smoothness) as the residual (predicted value) from Eqs. (1) and (2), denoted DiscSmooth1i,t and DiscSmooth2 i,t (FundSmooth1i,t and FundSmooth2 i,t), respectively. Next, we construct the firm-year measure of income smoothing, DiscSmoothi,t, as the average of firm i's within-country percentile rank values of DiscSmooth1 and DiscSmooth2: 15 Detailed variable definitions are presented in Appendix A. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. DiscSmoothi ,t ( PcntileDiscSmooth1i ,t PcntileDiscSmooth2i ,t ) 2 . (3) By construction, PcntileDiscSmooth1, PcntileDiscSmooth2, and DiscSmooth each ranges from 0 to 99. We similarly construct a firm-year measure of fundamental smoothness, FundSmoothi,t, as the average of firm i's within-country percentile rank values of FundSmooth1 and FundSmooth2. 4.2. Threat of Private Benefits Consumption By definition, value-extractive private benefits consumption by firm insiders is Accepted Article detrimental to all external capital providers, including private lenders. Expropriation of firm assets by insiders leaves fewer resources inside the firm to satisfy the claims of both creditors (e.g., Lin et al., 2011) and minority shareholders (e.g., Djankov, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, & Schleifer, 2008). To capture this broad threat of private benefits consumption in the contracting environment, for our primary test we use the country-level anti-self-dealing index of Djankov et al. (2008), which has been used in prior debt literature to establish that lenders price protect against private benefits consumption threat (Lin et al., 2011). This index, computed for 72 countries, focuses on both public and private enforcement mechanisms (e.g., litigation, fines, prison terms) that govern a hypothetical self-dealing transaction. Higher (lower) values of the index imply more (less) protection and enforcement against expropriation by corporate insiders (i.e., private benefits consumption). We define a country-level indicator variable, PBThreat, that equals one if the anti-self-dealing index of firm i's country is below the sample observation median (suggesting a relatively high threat of private benefits consumption), and zero otherwise. We note that extant literature offers several institutional measures of creditor protection. For example, Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer (2007) develop a debt enforcement index, which reflects the ability of creditors to enforce their claims once a firm becomes insolvent. However, these creditor protections would do nothing to alleviate creditors' concerns that managers may This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. expropriate firm assets, which would leave the lenders with higher loss given default. Therefore, such measures do not directly capture our construct of interest. Stated differently, we are interested in capturing the threat of managerial private benefit consumption prior to insolvency, not the ability of creditors to enforce debt contracts after insolvency. We discuss this issue further in Section 6.5. 4.3. General empirical setup To test our predictions concerning the relation between cost of debt, income smoothing, Accepted Article and the threat of private benefits consumption in the contracting environment, we estimate the following empirical model with country and year fixed effects:16 Spread i ,l 0 1 PBThreati 2 DiscSmoothi ,t 3 DiscSmooth * PBThreat 4 FundSmoothi ,t 5 FundSmooth * PBThreat (4) X i,t + Yi,l country year i ,l , where Spread is the loan spread over LIBOR for firm i's loan facility l. PBThreat is an indicator that equals one (zero) if firm i's environment suggests a high (low) threat of private benefits consumption, as described above.17 We conduct supplemental analyses using firm-level threat measures, which we subsequently describe along with the associated analyses. DiscSmooth (FundSmooth) is firm i's discretionary income smoothing (fundamental earnings smoothness) computed for the most recent fiscal year-end prior to entering the debt contract. We include FundSmooth (and its interaction with PBThreat) to control for any effects of non-discretionary smoothness on cost of debt. Our prediction that the information signaling view of smoothing is 16 We use two-way clustered standard errors by both nation and loan package throughout our analyses. Inferences are not qualitatively altered if we replace the package-based clusters with either firm clusters or calendar month-year clusters (e.g., January 2010, February 2010). Further, although we include industry fixed-effects in our smoothing regressions (i.e., Eqs. 1 and 2), we consider a specification that includes industry fixed effects, and inferences are unaltered. Accordingly, for parsimony we do not include industry fixed effects in our primary specification. 17 When using a country-level threat measure with country fixed effects, the main effect on PBThreat simply captures the incremental average spread of an omitted country. Accordingly, including or excluding this main effect does not change coefficient estimates on any other variables (including the interactions) in the regression. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. dominant in environments with low threat of private benefits consumption suggests β2 < 0 (i.e., smoothing is associated with lower cost of debt). Our prediction that the information garbling view of smoothing prevails in high threat environments suggests 2 3 0 (i.e., smoothing is associated with higher cost of debt). Xi,t is a vector of the following firm-level control variables, where t references the most recent fiscal year-end prior to loan inception: LSize (natural log of total assets in U.S. dollars), BTM (book to market ratio), Leverage (leverage, measured as the ratio of total liabilities to total Accepted Article assets), ROA (return on assets, measured as the ratio of earnings before interest and taxes to total assets), Tangible (asset tangibility, measured as the ratio of property plant and equipment to total assets), and StdRet (standard deviation of firm i's monthly returns). Yi,l is a vector of the following loan-level control variables for firm i's loan facility l: Secure (an indicator that equals one if the loan requires collateral), LMaturity (natural log of loan maturity in months), LFacility (natural log of the loan facility face amount in U.S. dollars), and NCov (the number of financial covenants attached to the loan package that contains facility l). All variables are defined in Appendix A. 5. Data and Descriptive Statistics We obtain international data on bank loans from Dealscan.18 The most primitive unit of observation is a loan facility, where multiple facilities can be included in a loan package between a borrower and lender. Because each loan facility within a package typically has a unique combination of terms (e.g., spread, maturity, collateral requirements, amount) and abstracting away from this detail can lead to biased results, we follow a common approach in the accounting literature and use a loan facility (rather than loan package) as our base unit of observation (e.g., 18 International Dealscan loan data has been used extensively in extant accounting and finance literature (e.g., Qian & Strahan, 2007; Bae & Goyal, 2009; Kim, Tsui, & Cheong, 2011; Lin et al., 2011). This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Bharath et al., 2008; Amiram, Kalay, & Sadka, 2017; De Franco, Hope, & Lu, 2017), and include loan package as a standard error clustering dimension. We collect accounting and stock price data from Worldscope and Datastream, respectively, and convert all non-ratio variables into U.S. dollars. We obtain data on firm-level probability of default (PD) from the Credit Research Initiative (CRI) of the National University of Singapore.19 Our sample begins with 117,817 loan facilities in Dealscan with non-missing loan spread with loan initiation dates ranging from 1996 to 2009, and where borrowers are not banks or Accepted Article utilities (two digit ICB codes 70, 83, 85, and 87). We next match the Dealscan sample to Worldscope by company name, reducing our sample to 48,458 loan facilities. We retain in our sample loans with expected maturity (at loan inception) of greater than twelve months (e.g., Demiroglu & James, 2010), further reducing our sample to 37,550 loan facilities. We next eliminate observations that have missing values for our computed discretionary smoothing metrics, leaving 16,410 facility-level observations. Because of the disproportionate number of U.S. observations in Dealscan, for our primary country-level analysis we exclude all observations for U.S. borrowers, reducing our sample to 4,588 facilities.20 Next, we truncate all continuous variables used in our analyses at the lower 1% and upper 99% values by countryyear, and delete observations with missing values for loan characteristics (i.e., spread, maturity, number of covenants, face amount), accounting data, or any other data necessary for our analyses, as described below. This leaves us with 1,817 facility-level observations across 1,084 loan packages for 639 distinct non-U.S. borrowers across twenty countries. 19 The firm-level probability of default measures we employ are computed by the CRI using a forward default intensity model, as outlined in Duan, Sun, & Wang (2012). Please refer to www.rmimcri.org for more details. 20 We estimate a firm-level analysis using a U.S. sample. We discuss the sample along with the associated results in Section 6.2. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Table 1 presents details of the sample country distribution. The country distribution of firms and facility-level observations are similar, with Taiwan and the United Kingdom representing a large fraction of the sample (22% and 31% of facility-level observations, respectively), where both countries are classified as having low threat of private benefit consumption. Among countries classified as having high threat of private benefit consumption, France and Germany are prominent within the sample (11% and 4% of facility-level observations, respectively). We acknowledge that our sample composition reflects potential Accepted Article selection bias driven by two requirements: firms must exist in both Dealscan and Datastream with data for all of our required variables, and we must be able to obtain valid matches across the two datasets. This may limit the generalizability of our results to loans between relatively large banks and large borrowers. Further, as the data only allow us to examine loans that were actually issued, we note that our sample may underrepresent firms in countries where borrower access to credit is limited because of generally poor contracting environments. However, these limitations are standard in this literature (e.g., Qian & Strahan, 2007). Table 2 presents descriptive statistics for firm and facililty-level variables. Mean total assets in U.S. dollars is $3.8 billion (i.e., mean logged assets of 14.01). Mean book-to-market ratio is 0.71, and mean leverage ratio is 0.59. The median sample loan has a 100 basis point spread over LIBOR, a face amount of U.S. $140 million, a five-year maturity, no collateral requirements and no financial covenants.21 Table 3 presents correlations for facility-level observations. 21 When Dealscan reports no covenant data for a given loan package, we make the assumption that the number of covenants on the loan package is zero. While this assumption is common in the literature, Drucker and Puri (2009) points out that this assumption is questionable, particularly for non-U.S. loans. Throughout the study, inferences are unchanged if we do not include the number of covenants in our analyses. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. 6. Empirical Results 6.1. Country-level threat of private benefits consumption Table 4 presents results from estimation of Eq. (4). Column (3) presents results from our primary specification, which tests our two key predictions. As predicted, 2 is significantly negative (coefficient estimate 0.145; t-statistic 2.38), which documents a negative association between income smoothing and cost of debt for firms within countries characterized by a low threat of private benefits consumption. This is consistent with our prediction that, on average, Accepted Article lenders perceive smoothing to reflect signaling in such environments. In stark contrast, the interaction between smoothing and the high threat indicator ( 3 ) is significantly positive (coefficient estimate 0.410; t-statistic 2.86), resulting in a significantly positive total coefficient on firm-level smoothing in high threat countries of 0.265 ( 2 3 ). As predicted, this provides evidence of a positive association between smoothing and cost of debt for firms within countries characterized by a high threat of private benefits consumption, consistent with lenders onaverage perceiving smoothing to reflect garbling in high threat countries. Although statistically insignificant, there is a negative sign on the association between non-discretionary earnings smoothness (FundSmooth) and loan spread, which is consistent with such smoothness being reflective of lower risk. More importantly, consistent with our intuition there is no difference in the association between non-discretionary smoothness and spread across consumption threat regimes, as reflected by the insignificant FundSmooth*PBThreat interaction (coefficient estimate -0.035; t-statistic -0.11). For parsimony, hereafter we omit this interaction from our (country-level) empirical tests. The results for the firm-level control variables are generally consistent with our expectations. Market-to-book has been used by numerous studies as a proxy for conservatism This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. (e.g., Roychowdhury & Watts, 2007). Because book-to-market is decreasing in conservatism, the positive coefficient on book-to-market (BTM) is consistent with literature that documents that ex ante conservatism lowers cost of debt (e.g., Zhang, 2008). Larger (LSize) firms have lower cost of debt. Firms with more leverage (Leverage) and volatility (StdRet) have higher cost of debt. Consistent with Bharath et al. (2008) and Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman (2011), there is a negative relation between loan amount (LFacility) and spread, and a positive association between maturity (LMaturity) and spread. Further consistent with Bharath et al. (2008) and Berger and Accepted Article Udell (1990), there is a strong positive relation between collateral requirement (Secure) and spread. These relations reflect a complex set of unobservable tradeoffs in the loan contracting process. In terms of economic significance, there is a material difference in the effects of smoothing on cost of debt across low and high private benefit consumption threat environments. In low threat countries, movement across the interquartile range of DiscSmooth results in an approximate 7 basis point decrease in loan spread (i.e., interquartile range of 45 times the coefficient estimate of 0.15), which represents a 7% decrease in spread relative to the median sample spread. In high threat countries, movement across the interquartile range of DiscSmooth results in an approximate 12 basis point increase in loan spread (i.e., interquartile range of 45 times the total coefficient estimate of 0.265), which represents a 12% increase in loan spread relative to the median spread.22 Column (1) reports results from a more naive specification of the relation between smoothing and cost of debt, where we do not partition based on private benefits consumption threat, which indicates an insignificant relation between smoothing and cost of debt. However, 22 These effects are economically significant, with magnitudes comparable to effects documented in Bharath et al. (2008). Specifically, Bharath et al. (2008) finds a 14 basis point increase in loan interest spread over LIBOR in going from firms in the worst to best quintiles of accounting quality. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. we now know from column (3) that this insignificance simply reflects the contrasting negative and positive relations across environments. Accordingly, without considering the forces we reveal, researchers may make inappropriate conclusions concerning the relation between smoothing and cost of private debt. Although our sample includes only a limited number of firms that receive loans more than once during our sample period (i.e., 271 firms), we repeat our main test with firm fixed effects. This design is extremely strict, in that all of the variation in the effect of smoothing on Accepted Article cost of debt comes from within-firm time series variation in smoothing using a very small number of firms with multiple observations. Untabulated findings are nonetheless consistent with our main inferences. That is, within firm there is a significant negative (positive) relation between the extent of smoothing and cost of debt if that firm is operating in a low (high) threat environments. This design further mitigates concern that our primary inferences are driven by correlated omitted variables. 6.2. Firm-level threat of private benefits consumption Our primary results provide evidence that, on average, lenders interpret smoothing in a manner consistent with the signaling (garbling) view of smoothing in countries with low (high) threat of private benefits consumption. However, our results do not imply that smoothing is associated with lower (higher) cost of debt for all firms in low (high) threat countries. To the extent that lenders distinguish among firms within a given country in terms of their view of smoothing, it is likely that there are firm-specific cases in low (high) threat countries where smoothing is associated with an increased (decreased) cost of debt. One issue with pursuing a within-country analysis based on firm-level threat characteristics is that within a country, such firm-level characteristics are likely to be endogenous This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. (i.e., a firm can choose both smoothing and governance structure). However, with that caveat in place, we estimate Eq. (4) using a time-varying firm-level measure of the threat of private benefits consumption. That is, using our foreign sample we replace PBThreat with CloseHeldSharesi,t, which is an indicator that equals one if firm i's percentage of closely held shares in year t is in the top quartile of sample observations (i.e., greater than 45.75%), and equals zero otherwise. Ownership concentration enables more efficient expropriation of private benefits, thus a high level of closely held shares reflects relatively high threat of private benefits Accepted Article consumption (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 2000).23 Column (1) of Table 5 presents results from this analysis, which are remarkably similar to results from our primary analysis using the country-level threat measure. These results provide nice identification, in that the effect we document in our primary analysis likewise operates within country based on time-varying firm-level threat characteristics. That is, 2 is significantly negative (coefficient estimate 0.182; t-statistic 1.65), which documents a negative association between income smoothing and cost of debt for firms that have low threat of private benefits consumption, holding country-level threat characteristics constant. Moreover, there is a significantly positive total coefficient on firm-level smoothing in high-threat firms of 0.471 ( 2 3 ), which provides evidence of a positive association between smoothing and cost of debt. To fix intuition with an example, these results illustrate that, whereas our primary analysis in Table 4 suggests that smoothing firms in the U.K (a low threat country) tend to have lower cost of debt on average, and that smoothing firms in Germany (a high threat country) tend have 23 We acknowledge that in some settings, ownership concentration can provide governance benefits to a firm. However, the prevailing interpretation in the literature is that ownership concentration enables private benefits extraction. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. higher cost of debt on average, within either the U.K. or Germany smoothing firms with low (high) private benefits consumption threat have relatively low (high) cost of debt. We repeat our firm-level threat analysis for a separate sample of U.S. firms for which Bebchuk et al. (2009) compute a firm-level composite managerial entrenchment index.24 The entrenchment index reflects the potential for the threat of private benefits consumption using six Investor Responsibility Research Center provisions (accordingly, the measure ranges from zero to six) (e.g., John, Litov, & Yeung, 2008; Rego & Wilson, 2012). Specifically, we construct an Accepted Article indicator MgrEntrenchi,t that equals one if firm i's entrenchment index in year t is greater than three, and equals zero otherwise.25 The U.S. sample we use in this analysis consists of 6,033 facility-level observations across 4,570 loan packages for 1,453 distinct borrowers. As reported in column (2) of Table 5, inferences from the within-U.S. firm-level analysis mirror those from our primary analysis. 6.3. Borrower credit risk Our results thus far suggest that lenders adjust loan spread based on their interpretation of the implications of observed smoothing for expected credit loss. However, because lenders only lose money if a borrower actually defaults, lenders may be relatively insensitive to the positive or negative implications of smoothing for borrowers with relatively low credit risk. In high private benefits consumption threat environments, if it is more likely that a borrower will default, lenders may be more concerned with the implications of private benefits consumption because such actions will more likely affect their ultimate payoff. Accordingly, we predict that the positive association between smoothing and cost of debt in high threat countries will be 24 The U.S. is a low threat country, having an anti-self-dealing index of 0.65. We note that, in contrast to our primary measure based on the anti-self-dealing index, literature has shown that managerial entrenchment can benefit debtholders by providing takeover defenses (in the presence of shareholderdebtholder conflicts) (e.g., Ashbaugh-Skaife, Collins, & LaFond, 2006). However, as this is a limited setting, we rely on the more general interpretation of entrenchment as enabling private benefits extraction. 25 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. exacerbated if the borrower has relatively high risk of default. To test this prediction, we estimate the following modification to Eq. (4), which includes our new variable of interest, DiscSmooth*PBThreat*PD, where PD is the borrower’s one-year-ahead probability of default as of the end of the month immediately preceding the loan contracting date: Spreadi ,l 0 1 PBThreati 2 DiscSmoothi ,t 3 DiscSmooth * PBThreat 4 DiscSmooth * PBThreat * PD 5 FundSmoothi ,t 6 PDi ,t 7 DiscSmooth * PD 8 FundSmooth * PD 9 PBThreat * PD (5) X i,t + Yi,l country year i ,l , Accepted Article where all variables are as previously defined, and DiscSmooth*PBThreat*PD captures the incremental effect of probability of default on the relation between smoothing and loan spread in high consumption threat environments, which we predict will be positive. We report results in Table 6. As predicted, the coefficient on DiscSmooth*PBThreat*PD is positive and significant (coefficient estimate 0.793; t-stat 2.14). Because PD is a continuous measure, all lower order coefficients are technically uninterpretable; however, signs and significance levels are consistent with prior results. For example, the coefficient on DiscSmooth is significantly negative, reinforcing the result that smoothing reduces spread in countries with a low threat of private benefits consumption. To summarize, these results provide evidence that lenders pay particular attention to smoothing and its implications for potential private benefits consumption for firms that are closer to default, particularly when smoothing more likely reflects garbling which may increase loss given default. 6.4. Non-price loan terms Although our interest in this paper is the relation between smoothing and the cost of debt, we analyze whether income smoothing differentially affects several non-price loan terms that lenders may adjust to reflect perceived borrower risk across environments, including financial This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. covenants, maturity, and collateral requirements. To do so, we use the basic variable structure of Eq. (4), while changing the dependent variable and estimation approach as appropriate. Conceptually, there are competing forces concerning the effect of smoothing on the use of financial covenants. Consider environments with high threat of private benefits consumption—if smoothing represents garbling, then lenders may want to increase the use of financial covenants to provide further protections; however, garbling suggests that the resulting financial data are less reflective of underlying economics, which suggests that lenders may want Accepted Article to rely less on financial covenants (e.g., Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman, 2011). Aside from this tension, investigating the effect of smoothing on the inclusion of loan covenants is problematic because of international Dealscan data issues (Drucker & Puri, 2009). In particular, in Dealscan the absence of covenant data does not necessarily imply that no loan covenants exist, and this problem is particularly acute for the non-U.S. Dealscan sample. Therefore, to empirically explore this relation we first delete all observations with no covenant data, and estimate a variation of Eq. (4) with the number of financial covenants attached to the loan (NCov) as the dependent variable using the resulting sample of 724 observations. As reported in Table 7, we find that smoothing is indeed positively associated with the number of covenants attached to the loan in environments with high threat of private benefits consumption (coefficient estimate on DiscSmooth*Threat of 0.007; t-statistic 2.15). This result suggests that in addition to increasing loan spread, lenders may also use increased covenant protections when smoothing more likely reflects garbling to facilitate private benefits consumption. To examine whether smoothing affects loan maturity (collateral requirements), we estimate an OLS model of the form used in Eq. (4) with LMaturity (Secure) as the dependent variable. To summarize, in untabulated results we find no statistically significant evidence that This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. the threat of private benefits consumption in the contracting environment affects the relation between smoothing and either maturity or collateral requirements.26 6.5. Additional considerations 6.5.1. Private benefits consumption vs. creditor rights As discussed previously, our construct of interest is the threat that firm insiders will consume private benefits as the firm continues its ongoing operations. Our construct of interest is not creditor rights in the event of default, as such creditor protections would do little to alleviate Accepted Article a lender's concern that managers may expropriate firm assets prior to default, which would leave the lenders with fewer recoverable assets in default. Therefore, we do not view creditor rights as a meaningful delineator of the effect of smoothing on cost of debt. Accordingly, we predict that there will be no differential association between smoothing and loan spread across partitions based on the degree of creditor rights that exist in the event of default. To test this prediction, we repeat our primary analysis after replacing PBThreat with WeakCredRightsi, an indicator variable that equals one if firm i's country-level creditor rights index (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1998; Djankov et al., 2007) is zero or one, and equals zero if the index is two, three or four. We then repeat our primary analysis after adding WeakCredRights and its interactions to our main specification. As reported in column (1) of Table 8, using creditor rights to partition the effect of smoothing on cost of debt is essentially equivalent to partitioning on noise, i.e., we recover the apparent result from column (1) of Table 4 that there is no relation between smoothing and cost of debt. Column (2) of Table 5 reports results from a specification that includes smoothing interactions with both creditor rights and private benefits consumption threat. As reported, our main result obtains, in that there is a 26 In addition to equation-by-equation estimation using different loan terms as dependent variables, we estimate the equations simultaneously using seemingly unrelated regression, and find inferences consistent with our reported results across all loan terms we consider, including Spread and NCov. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. differential relation between smoothing and cost of debt across private benefits consumption threat environments, even after controlling for the effect of creditor rights (which remains insignificant). 6.5.2. Other accounting attributes Extant literature documents a negative relation between cost of debt and both accruals quality and accounting conservatism (e.g., Bharath et al., 2008; Zhang, 2008). Further, extant literature documents that different accounting system characteristics, including accruals quality, Accepted Article conservatism, and smoothness, are correlated with one another (e.g., Dechow et al., 2010). To verify that our results are indeed capturing effects of smoothing and not an alternative (correlated) accounting attribute, we estimate a modification to Eq. (4) where we replace DiscSmooth with a measure of accruals quality (AQ) computed following the approach of Dechow and Dichev (2002), and estimate a specification that includes both DiscSmooth and AQ and their interactions with PBThreat.27 As reported in Column (1) of Table 9, we find a negative relation between AQ and Spread, consistent with Bharath et al. (2008), and this negative relation does not vary across private benefits consumption threat environments (as indicated by the insignificance of AQ*PBThreat). Further, our key inference that DiscSmooth changes sign in its relation with Spread across threat environments remains. We repeat (separately) this modification of Eq. (4) with both BTM (as an inverse proxy for conservatism) and the standard deviation of NIEXS computed over the three-to-five year horizon ending in year t as an inverse proxy for earnings persistence (Dichev & Tang, 2009). As with AQ, the signs of the relations between DiscSmooth and these alternative attributes (conservatism and earnings persistence) do not vary across threat environments. Moreover, our primary inferences regarding DiscSmooth hold in the presence of these alternative attributes and 27 Data requirements for computing AQ cause a significant decrease in our sample size, to 976 observations. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. their interactions with PBThreat. Accordingly, we conclude that our inferences are indeed attributable to smoothing, and not an alternative correlated accounting attribute. 6.5.3. Measurement error in smoothness proxies Extant literature presents tests that lend construct validity to the smoothing measure we use in this study (e.g., Lang & Maffett, 2011b; Lang et al., 2012). However, we acknowledge that this proxy for smoothing may contain significant measurement error. Given that measurement error typically introduces attenuation bias in coefficient estimates, any such Accepted Article measurement error would work against our finding significant relations between smoothing and cost of debt. A separate but related concern is whether the relation between smoothing and cost of debt is driven by correlated omitted variables. In order for omitted variables to be the driver of our results, it would be necessary for the omitted variables to be negatively associated with smoothing in low consumption threat environments, but positively associated with smoothing in high consumption threat environments. We view this as an unlikely explanation for our results. 6.5.4. Smoothing motivations Although we position our study within the signaling versus garbling framework of smoothing motivations, we recognize that there exist other smoothing motivations, such as removing risk from earnings-based compensation contracts and tax minimization. However, it is unlikely that these motivations differ across high and low private benefit consumption threat environments in a manner that would affect our inferences. Relatedly, smoothing may be accomplished by methods aside from accounting choice, such as real operational decisions (Fudenberg & Tirole, 1995), hedging via derivative use (Barton, 2001), or asset sales (Black et al., 1998; Peasnell,, 1998). In our framework, smoothing that results from these activities is likely captured by the discretionary smoothing component. We do not attempt to disentangle the This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. sources of smoothing. Because smoothing via these alternative mechanisms can likewise be used to either signal or garble, the logic of our study applies regardless of the smoothing mechanism. 6.5.5. Relationship lending As pointed out in extant literature (e.g., Bharath et al., 2008; Sufi, 2007), lenders with prior relationships with borrowers likely have both extensive operational information about the borrower and well-developed information channels with firm insiders. Thus, existing relationships could lead to mitigated effects of smoothing on loan terms. However, as also Accepted Article pointed out in extant literature (e.g., Rajan, 1992; Murfin, 2012), relationships between borrowers and lenders may lead to lender ability to extract information rents. Following this logic, if smoothing creates opacity as under the garbling view, information rents may increase, enabling lenders to increase loan spread. Therefore, the effects of relationship banking on the association between smoothing on loan spread is an empirical question. In untabulated analysis, we find no difference in the effect of smoothing on loan spread for relationship versus nonrelationship loans. This is consistent with findings in Costello and Wittenberg-Moerman (2011) who find no difference in the effects of internal control weaknesses on financial covenant use for relationship versus non-relationship loans. 7. Conclusion Income smoothing by managers is a pervasive phenomenon that has been widely researched. Despite the fact that private debt markets provide a major source of financing used by most corporations, we have incomplete evidence on how smoothing is associated with cost of debt in the private loan market. The institutional factors associated with private loan contracts, combined with the theoretical motivations for smoothing, make it unclear ex ante whether smoothing will be positively, negatively, or not associated with loan spread. In this study, we fill This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. this gap in the literature. Extant evidence regarding smoothing in the credit markets is incomplete, and presents a one-sided inference that income smoothing lowers cost of debt. This state of the literature is puzzling, given that there are two coexisting views of smoothing that theoretically suggest opposite signs in the association between smoothing and cost of debt. That is, the information signaling view of smoothing suggests a negative association, and the information garbling view of smoothing suggests a positive association. Our conjecture is that lenders’ view of smoothing is a function of the extent of the threat Accepted Article of managerial private benefits consumption in the contracting environment. In high (low) threat environments, we predict that lenders are more likely to take the information garbling (signaling) view of smoothing. Consistent with our predictions, we provide evidence that smoothing is associated with lower cost of debt when the threat of private benefits consumption by managers is low, and is associated with higher cost of debt when the threat of private benefits consumption by managers is high. In so doing, our study is the first to document a positive association between smoothing and cost of debt, and we are the first to identify a feature of the contracting environment that empirically reveals the sign reversal in the association. We use an international sample of private loans so that we can obtain plausibly exogenous variation in the threat of private benefits consumption in the contracting environment. Accordingly, our study is subject to the typical small sample concerns that plague international debt research, which leads to concerns about generalizability of our findings. However, we find consistent inferences using both country-level and firm-level threat measures in our primary nonU.S. sample, as well as using firm-level measures in a much larger U.S.-only sample. The consistency in inference using these multiple approaches and samples provides some comfort with regard to these concerns. In summary, notwithstanding the study’s natural limitations, we This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. contribute important new evidence both to the debt contracting literature and to the literature that examines the effects of income smoothing in international capital markets. Appendix A - Variable definitions Variables prefixed by DS-, WS- and DL- are the mnemonic identifiers of the raw data items obtained from Datastream Advance, Worldscope, and Dealscan, respectively. Subscripts i, t, and l refer to firm, fiscal year, and loan facility, respectively. Accruals,i,t Accepted Article AccrualsS,i,t AQi,t AvgOpCashi,t AvgSalesGrowthi,t BTMi,t CloseHeldSharesi,t DiscSmoothi,t DiscSmooth1i,t DiscSmooth2i,t Facilityi.l FundSmoothi,t FundSmooth1i,t FundSmooth2i,t Leveragei,t LFacilityi,l change in current assets (WS-WC02201) minus change in cash (WS-WC02001) minus change in current liabilities (WS-WC03101) plus change in short-term debt (WS-WC03051) minus depreciation and amortization (WS-WC01151) Accruals,i,t scaled by lagged total assets (TAi,t-1) "accrual quality," measured as negative one times the standard deviation of firm i's residuals from a regression of AccrualsS,i,t on OpCashi,t-1, OpCashi,t and OpCashi,t+1 using no fewer than three nor more than five residuals. average operating cash flow (OpCash) over the three-to-five year horizon ending in year t average sales growth (SalesGrowth) over the three-to-five years ending in year t book-to-market, measured as total assets (WS-WC02999) minus total liabilities (WS-WC03351), divided by market value of equity (WS-MV) firm-level indicator of the threat of private benefits consumption; an indicator that equals one if firm i's percentage of closely held shares in year t is in the top quartile of sample observations (i.e., greater than 45.75%), and zero otherwise composite measure of discretionary income smoothing, calculated as the average percentile ranking (by country) of DiscSmooth1 and DiscSmooth2 residual from the panel regression of Smooth1i,t on industry (two-digit WS-ICB) and fiscal year fixed effects and the following variables for fiscal year t: LSize, Leverage, BTM, StdSales, %Loss, OpCycle, OpLev, AvgSalesGrowth and AvgOpCash the residual from the panel regression of Smooth2i,t on industry (two-digit WSICB) and fiscal year fixed effects and the following variables for fiscal year t: LSize, Leverage, BTM, StdSales, %Loss, OpCycle, OpLev, AvgSalesGrowth and AvgOpCash face amount of loan facility l (DL-facilityamt), in millions of U.S. dollars composite measure of fundamental earnings smoothness, calculated as the average percentile ranking (by country) of FundSmooth1 and FundSmooth2 predicted value from the panel regression of SMTH1i,t on industry (two-digit WSICB) and fiscal year fixed effects and the following variables for fiscal year t: LSize, Leverage, BTM, StdSales, %Loss, OpCycle, OpLev, AvgSalesGrowth and AvgOpCash predicted value from the panel regression of SMTH2i,t on industry (two-digit WSICB) and fiscal year fixed effects and the following variables for fiscal year t: LSize, Leverage, BTM, StdSales, %Loss, OpCycle, OpLev, AvgSalesGrowth and AvgOpCash leverage, measured as total liabilities (WS-WC03351) divided by total assets (WS-WC02999) natural logarithm of Facility This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. LMaturityi,l LSizei,t Maturityi,l MgrEntrenchi,t NCovi,l NIEXSi,t σNIEXSi,t OpCashi,t Accepted Article OpCyclei,t OpLevi,t PBThreati %Lossi,t PDi,m ROAi,t Securei,l SalesGrowthi,t Smooth1i,t Smooth2i,t Spreadi,l StdReti,l StdSalesi,t TAi,t Tangiblei,t natural logarithm of Maturity natural log of total assets (WS-WC02999) in U.S. dollars the term in months of loan facility l (DL-maturity) firm-level measure of the threat of private benefits consumption; an indicator that equals one if firm i's Bebchuk et al. (2009) entrenchment index in year t is greater than three, and zero otherwise. number of distinct financial and net worth covenants attached to the loan facility l's loan package net income before extraordinary items (WS-WC01551) scaled by lagged total assets (TAi,t-1) standard deviation of NIEXS computed over the three-to-five year horizon ending in year t operating cash flow, measured as net income before extraordinary items (WSWC01551) minus Accruals, scaled by lagged total assets (TAi,t-1) operating cycle, measured as the natural logarithm of ((average accounts receivable/sales)*360 + (average inventory/cost of goods sold)*360); accounts receivable (WS-WC02051), sales (WS-WC01001), inventory (WS-WC02101), cost of goods sold (WS-WC01051) operating leverage, measured as property, plant and equipment (WS-WC02501), divided by total assets (TA) country-level indicator of the threat of private benefits consumption; an indicator that equals one if the Djankov et al. (2008) anti-self-dealing index of firm i's country is below the sample observation median, and zero otherwise percentage of years where net income before extraordinary items (WS-WC01551) is less than zero over the three-to-five year horizon ending in year t firm i's one-year ahead probability of default as of month m, obtained from the Credit Risk Institute of the National University of Singapore (NUS CRI). The default probabilities are estimates using a forward intensity model, as outlined in Duan et al. (2012). earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets (WS-WC02999) an indicator variable that equals one if loan facility l requires collateral, and zero otherwise (DL-secured) sales growth, measured as percentage change in sales (WS-WC01001) from year t-1 to t (standard deviation of NIEXS divided by the standard deviation of OpCash) multiplied by -1, where the standard deviations are computed over the three-tofive year horizon ending in year t correlation between OpCash and AccrualsS multiplied by -1, where the correlation is computed over the three-to-five year horizon ending in year t interest rate on loan facility l in excess of LIBOR, in basis points (DL-allindrawn) standard deviation of monthly return (computed from DS-ret_index) for firm i over the twelve-month horizon immediately preceding loan facility l standard deviation of sales (WS-WC01001) over the three-to-five year horizon ending in year t total assets (WS-WC02999) asset tangibility, measured as property, plant and equipment (WS-WC02501), scaled by total assets, TA This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. WeakCredRightsi country-level measure of creditor rights given default, based on the country-level creditor rights index developed in La Porta et al. (1998) and Djankov et al. (2007), which ranges from 0 to 4; our variable is an indicator that equals one if firm i's country-level creditor rights index is 0 or 1, and zero otherwise. Appendix B - Stylized framework that illustrates our key predictions In this appendix we describe a partial equilibrium framework that provides one example of how the forces we describe in this paper interact to yield our predictions under a set of plausible assumptions.28 We are not attempting to create a complete analytical model of a private Accepted Article lending interaction. For example, the framework does not include features such as private information flows, financial covenants, etc. Rather, we use this framework to simply demonstrate key forces that can plausibly lead to our predictions concerning the sign reversal in the association between smoothing and loan spread. As discussed in the paper, these institutional features of the private debt setting provide some tension concerning our predicted associations. Setup Consider an existing all-equity firm with a self-interested manager/owner, i.e., the manager has an incentive to maximize her own utility, where the firm has no minority shareholders (although this framework can easily generalize to a case where there are minority shareholders). At time t = 0, the manager knows that at time t = 1, the firm will require additional financing in the amount $K to fund a project, which we assume will be obtained in the form of debt with interest rate I.29 At time t = 2, the project outcome is realized, with probability of failure (success) PD (1PD). If successful, the project has a gross percentage return R greater 28 For example, an alternative framework could consider a relationship between minority and controlling shareholders, where smoothing is done for the same reasons that are described below. The lending decision could then come later, and exogenously to the smoothing decision by the borrower (i.e., the lender observes smoothing that is the result of the interactions between controlling shareholders and minority shareholders and responds to the observed smoothing). The predictions of this alternative framework regarding the sign reversal in the relation between smoothing and cost of debt will be identical to those we present below. 29 Debt can be the optimal financing source for a variety of reasons, e.g., tax benefits. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. than the risk-free rate (which we normalize to zero for convenience), the lender is repaid, and the firm continues. If the project fails, the firm defaults and the lender receives gross recovery rate V as a percentage of K. At time t = 0, nature endows the manager with two key things that are unobservable to external capital suppliers. First, with probability P (0,1) the manager receives private information that the firm's economic earnings are less volatile than reported cash flows suggest (thus, setting up the possibility that the manager can signal using income smoothing, assuming Accepted Article she has the ability to smooth). Without loss of generality, we characterize firms in binary fashion as either having smooth economic earnings (denoted as 1 ) or not (denoted as 0 ). Further, we assume that smooth economic earnings lowers probability of default, i.e. 0 PD1 PD 0 1 (Merton, 1974). Second, with probability P 0,1 nature endows the manager with the ability to smooth reported income.30 This ability could relate to either managerial skill, or innate smoothness of underlying cash flows (i.e., if cash flows are innately smooth, there will naturally be very little a manager can do to further smooth earnings by applying discretion). Without loss of generality, we simply characterize managers in binary fashion as either able to smooth (denoted as 1 ) or unable to smooth (denoted as 0 ) (e.g., Trueman & Titman, 1988).31 Accordingly, there are four types of managers across these two unobservable dimensions, which we denote as follows: 11;10 ; 01; 00 . For example, type 10 refers to a manager that knows economic earnings are relatively smooth, but is unable to smooth reported income to signal that information. 30 Under certain values of other parameters that can be characterized, the introduction of this "ability" parameter is not necessary. However, it makes the intuition of the framework easier to follow. 31 Alternatively, we could assume differences in smoothing ability across a continuum, or differences in managerspecific costs of smoothing. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. At a time between t = 0 and t = 1 (for simplicity we will call it t = 0.5), the manager chooses whether or not to consume private benefits, and whether or not to smooth earnings, and then externally reports financial results (i.e., earnings, cash flows and accruals). These choices are made with the understanding that she will pursue a loan at t=1, and that lenders will price protect against any anticipated private benefits consumption that extracts firm value. Without loss of generality, we assume if private benefits are consumed, they are consumed as a percentage of firm value that translates into a percentage B 0,1 of the loan K (i.e., $ B K ). Accepted Article Further, assume that the choice to smooth earnings can provide the manager with private benefits that do not extract firm wealth from external capital providers and are therefore not price protected, for example, power, respect, credibility, and connections (e.g., Demsetz & Lehn, 1985; Aghion & Bolton, 1992).32 That is, importantly, these additional benefits will leave an incentive to smooth even if capital providers fully price protect against the anticipated private benefits which the manager consumes to their potential detriment. We denote these additional benefits as , and for simplicity hereafter will refer to them simply as "non-value-extractive" private benefits. For notational convenience we denote the choice to consume private benefits as B1 and the choice to not consume private benefits as B0. We characterize the firm's environment as having either low threat (LT) or high threat (HT) of private benefits consumption (which is observable to capital providers), where low (high) threat of consumption is an environment where there are heavy (light) penalties if "caught" (we denote the probability of being caught as PC). We capture this threat with a punishment parameter LT , HT that reflects the cost to 32 Alternatively, smoothing can provide managers with other pecuniary benefits that are not price protected by external capital providers, for example, smoothing can lower the firm's total tax obligations, which increases the size of the pie for the manager and capital suppliers (e.g., Hepworth, 1953; Graham & Smith, 1999). This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. the manager of being caught, which without loss of generality we express as a percentage of the amount consumed, where 1 HT LT . That is, the expected cost to the manager of consuming private benefits is $ B K PC . We assume that the minimum punishment if caught is repayment of the amount consumed plus a slap on the wrist, i.e., HT 1 , where 0 . Heavier penalties that characterize low threat environments include more substantial fines, reputational costs, criminal penalties, etc. Although we could characterize the point above Accepted Article which the punishment is "high enough", for simplicity we assume that if the manager gets caught consuming private benefits in a low threat environment, LT . If the manager has the ability to smooth income (i.e., type 1 ), the manager chooses to smooth income (S = 1, denoted S1) or not (S = 0, denoted S0 ) at time t = 0.5. This choice is made with the manager's understanding that there is a positive probability at t = 2 that both α and will be revealed, and that there will be an associated cost of lying (L > 0) if the manager had the ability to smooth ( 1 ) but lied about her true type α (i.e., 1 and S0, or 0 and S1) (Desai et al., 2006). Consistent with our characterization of costs of private benefits consumption, we assume that LHT LLT .33 Although we could characterize the point below (above) which the cost is low (high) enough, for simplicity we set LHT 0 ( LLT ). We assume that if the manager chooses to consume private benefits, income smoothing reduces the probability of being caught (Fudenberg & Tirole, 1995). Further, for simplicity we assume that if the manager consumes private benefits but does not smooth, she will be caught. That is, 0 PCS1 PCS 0 1. After the manager chooses B and S at t = 0.5, she reports financials. 33 Alternatively, to reduce the number of parameters we could have used the punishment parameter to describe the misreporting costs. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. The manager's choice of private benefits consumption and smoothing Based on our binary exposition, there are four B-S choice combinations, which we denote BS B0 S1; B0 S0 ; B1S1; B1S0 . For example, type BS B0 S1 refers to a manager that smooths income and does not consume value-extractive private benefits. At time t = 0.5, the manager chooses BS to maximize her payoff, subject to her endowed (unobservable) type 11;10 ; 01; 00 and (observable) LT , HT . Table A1 outlines the payoff Accepted Article structures to the manager under each scenario. Note that the manager's general payoff equals the sum of five terms: (1 PD) K ( R I ) ( PD B K ) ( B K PC ) L . (A1) The first term, (1 PD) K ( R I ) , is the expected payoff if the project succeeds. The second term, ( PD B K ) , is the expected payoff if the project fails (i.e., the manager receives the amount of private benefits consumed). The third term, ( B K PC ) , is the expected cost of consuming private benefits. The fourth term, L, is the expected cost of lying about whether the manager has smooth economic earnings (e.g., Desai et al., 2006). The fifth term, , is the additional non-value-extractive private benefits obtained from smoothing. Consider a manager operating in a high threat of consumption environment, as depicted in Panel A of Table A1. For endowment 11 , choice 2 dominates choice 4 (because the sum of terms two and three is zero in choice 2 and negative in choice 4), choice 3 dominates choice 1 (because the sum of terms two and three is positive in choice 3 and zero in choice 1). The determination of whether choice 2 or 3 is optimal depends on the net benefit of private benefits consumption (the sum of terms two, three, and five in choice 3) relative to the interest rate differential reflected in the first term in both choices. It is straightforward to show (as This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. outlined below) that in setting interest rates, the lender will fully price protect against anticipated private benefits consumption, and the borrower will be indifferent between choices 2 and 3 before considering additional non-value-extractive private benefits, . Therefore, it follows directly that for any positive , the borrower will choose to smooth and consume, even in the face of full lender price protection against private benefits consumption. Specifically, setting the borrower's choice 2 and 3 payoff functions equal, the borrower will choose choice 3 (smooth and Accepted Article consume) if I S 1 I S 0 PD B . As we show in the section below, based on full lender 1 PD 1 PD price protection, I S1 I S 0 PD B . Thus, the borrower will find choice 3 optimal for any 1 PD positive . Continuing across the other endowment possibilities, it follows that the optimal choice for 10 is 2, for 01 is 2 or 3, and for 00 is 2. As depicted in Panel B, following the same approach in analyzing the manager's choice in the low consumption threat environment, the optimal choice for 11 is 1, 10 is 2, for 01 is 2, and for 00 is 2. This structure is understood by the lender, who will use these insights when choosing the interest rate I. The lender's pricing decision At time t = 1, the lender chooses the interest rate I on the loan amount $K. Theoretically, I will be increasing in expected cost of default, i.e., (probability of default)*(loss given default). Literature has established that smoother economic earnings imply lower probability of default (e.g., Merton, 1974). That is, PD1 PD 0 . Further, it is straightforward that managerial consumption of private benefits from capital providers increases loss given default, i.e., This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. decreases the recovery rate in the event of default (V = R-B). That is, VB1 VB0 . Accordingly, the lender would like to base I on the smoothness of economic earnings and the extent of managerial private benefit consumption, but neither factor is directly observable at the contracting date. Therefore, the lender will base I on the observable private benefits consumption threat ( ) and the smoothness of earnings (S), where smooth earnings may reflect either signaling or garbling. Based on our binary characterizations, there are four possible interest rates, which we denote as Accepted Article I S I HT S 0 ; I HT S 1 ; I LT S 0 ; I LT S 1 . Consider the high consumption threat environment. It follows from the analysis outlined in Panel A of Table A1 that if the manager smooths income (S1), the lender knows that the manager consumed private benefits.34 Further, if the manager does not smooth income (S0), the lender knows the manager did not consume private benefits. In either case (S1 or S0), the lender will assess that the firm has smooth economic earnings ( 1 ) with probability P and that the firm does not have smooth economic earnings ( 0 ) with probability ( 1 P ). It is straightforward to then show that I HT ,S1 I HT ,S 0 because VB1 VB0 . Our prediction that smoothing is positively associated with loan spread in countries with high threat of private benefits consumption follows immediately. More formally, we can solve for the interest rate differential I HT ,S1 I HT , S 0 . Consider again endowment 11 . The lender will set rates to equalize expected profit across choices 2 and 3, where the general form of the lender's profit equals (1 PD) K (1 I ) PD K ( R B) K . Setting this lender profit function equal across choice 2 and 3, it is straightforward to show that I HT , S1 I HT , S 0 34 PD B 0 . 1 PD We make an implicit assumption that lenders will have the expectation that if managers consumed private benefits before loan initiation, they will continue to do so after receiving the loan at t = 1. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Next, consider the low consumption threat environment. It follows from the analysis outlined in Panel B of Table A1 that the manager will never consume private benefits. If the manager smooths income (S1), the lender knows the firm has smooth economic earnings ( 1 ) with probability 1.0. If the manager does not smooth income (S0), the lender does not know whether the firm has smooth economic earnings or not, and assesses the probability of smooth economic earnings at less than 1.0. It is then straightforward to show that I LT ,S1 I LT , S 0 , because Accepted Article PD1 PD 0 . Our prediction that smoothing is negatively associated with loan spread in countries with low threat of private benefits consumption follows immediately. More formally, in the low threat environment, setting the lender's profit function equal across borrower smoothing choices yields the following (1 PD1 ) K (1 I S1 ) PD1 (K R) K (1 PD 0 ) K (1 I S 0 ) PD 0 (K R) K . expression: After 1 PD 0 1 R PD 1 PD 0 algebraic simplification: I S1 I S 0 . Because PD1 PD 0 , 1 PD 1 PD 1 1 the term on the right hand side is negative, and the ratio multiplier attached to IS0 on the left hand 1 PD 0 side is less than one. Therefore, if I S1 I S 0 0 , it must be the case that I S1 I S 0 0 , 1 PD 1 thus I S1 I S 0 . This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Table A1 Framework-based predictions of managerial private benefits consumption and smoothing choice This table outlines payoffs to a manager who chooses whether to consume private benefits and smooth reported income prior to obtaining a loan to undertake a project. B0 (B1) denotes her choice to not consume (consume) private benefits. S0 (S1) denotes her choice to not smooth (smooth) reported income. α0 (α1) denotes her endowment of private information that economic earnings are not smooth (smooth). λ0 (λ1) denotes her endowment of the inability (ability) to smooth reported income. The general structure of her payoff is (1 PD) K ( R I ) ( PD B K ) ( B K PC ) L . PD is the probability of project default. K is the dollar amount borrowed. R is the project's gross percentage return. I is the interest rate charged by the lender. B is the amount of private benefits she consumes. γ is the punishment parameter for consuming private benefits. PC is the probability of getting caught consuming private benefits. L is the cost of lying about her type α. φ is an additional smoothing benefit that accrues to the firm. * denotes non-dominated strategies under each possible threat/endowment combination. Panel A: Payoffs to manager in high threat of private benefits consumption HT 1 ; LHT ; PCS1 ; PCS 0 1 Accepted Article Endowment: 11 (has smooth economic earnings and can smooth reported income) Choice 1: BS B0 S1 (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S1 ) 0 0 0 Choice 2: BS B0 S0 * (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S 0 ) 0 0 Choice 3: BS B1S1 * (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S1 ) PD B K (1 ) B K 0 Choice 4: BS B1S0 (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S 0 ) PD B K (1 ) B K 1 Endowment: 10 (has smooth economic earnings but cannot smooth reported income) Choice 1: BS B0 S1 N/A (cannot have S1 for type 0 ) Choice 2: BS B0 S0 * (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S 0 ) 0 0 0 Choice 3: BS B1S1 N/A (cannot have S1 for type 0 ) Choice 4: BS B1S0 (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S 0 ) PD B K (1 ) B K 1 0 Endowment: 01 (does not have smooth economic earnings but can smooth reported income) Choice 1: BS B0 S1 (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S1 ) 0 0 Choice 2: BS B0 S0 * (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S 0 ) 0 0 0 Choice 3: BS B1S1 * (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S1 ) PD B K (1 ) B K Choice 4: BS B1S0 (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S 0 ) PD B K (1 ) B K 1 0 Endowment: 00 (does not have smooth economic earnings and cannot smooth reported income) Choice 1: BS B0 S1 N/A (cannot have S1 for type 0 ) Choice 2: BS B0 S0 * (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S 0 ) 0 0 0 Choice 3: BS B1S1 N/A (cannot have S1 for type 0 ) Choice 4: BS B1S0 (1 PD) K ( R I HT ,S 0 ) PD B K (1 ) B K 1 0 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Table A1, continued General structure of manager's payoff: (1 PD) K ( R I ) ( PD B K ) ( B K PC ) L Panel B: Payoffs to manager in low threat of private benefits consumption LT ; LLT ; PCS1 ; PCS 0 1 Endowment: 11 (has smooth economic earnings and can smooth reported income) Choice 1: BS B0 S1 * (1 PD1 ) K ( R I LT ,S1 ) 0 0 0 Choice 2: BS B0 S0 (1 PD 0 ) K ( R I LT ,S 0 ) 0 0 Choice 3: BS B1S1 (1 PD1 ) K ( R I LT ,S1 ) PD1 B K B K 0 Choice 4: BS B1S0 (1 PD 0 ) K ( R I LT ,S 0 ) PD1 B K B K 1 Accepted Article Endowment: 10 (has smooth economic earnings but cannot smooth reported income) Choice 1: BS B0 S1 N/A (cannot have S1 for type 0 ) Choice 2: BS B0 S0 * (1 PD 0 ) K ( R I LT ,S 0 ) 0 0 0 Choice 3: BS B1S1 N/A (cannot have S1 for type 0 ) Choice 4: BS B1S0 (1 PD 0 ) K ( R I LT ,S 0 ) PD1 B K B K 1 0 Endowment: 01 (does not have smooth economic earnings but can smooth reported income) Choice 1: BS B0 S1 (1 PD1 ) K ( R I LT ,S1 ) 0 0 Choice 2: BS B0 S0 * (1 PD 0 ) K ( R I LT ,S 0 ) 0 0 0 Choice 3: BS B1S1 (1 PD1 ) K ( R I LT ,S1 ) PD1 B K B K Choice 4: BS B1S0 (1 PD 0 ) K ( R I LT ,S 0 ) PD 0 B K B K 1 0 Endowment: 00 (does not have smooth economic earnings and cannot smooth reported income) Choice 1: BS B0 S1 N/A (cannot have S1 for type 0 ) Choice 2: BS B0 S0 * (1 PD 0 ) K ( R I LT ,S 0 ) 0 0 0 Choice 3: BS B1S1 N/A (cannot have S1 for type 0 ) Choice 4: BS B1S0 (1 PD 0 ) K ( R I LT ,S 0 ) PD 0 B K B K 1 0 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Accepted Article REFERENCES Acharya, V., Lambrecht, B., 2015. A theory of income smoothing when insiders know more than outsiders. Review of Financial Studies 28, 2534-2574. Aghion, P., Bolton, P., 1992. An incomplete contracts approach to financial contracting. Review of Economic Studies 59, 473-494. Amiram, D., Kalay, A., Sadka, G., 2017. Industry characteristics, risk premiums, and debt pricing. The Accounting Review 92, 1-27. Ashbaugh-Skaife, H., Collins, D., LaFond, R., 2006. The effects of corporate governance on firms’ credit ratings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 42, 203-243. Bae, K., Goyal, V., 2009. Creditor rights, enforcement, and bank loans. Journal of Finance 64, 823-860. Barnea, A., Ronen, J., Sadan, S., 1975. The implementation of accounting objectives: an application to extraordinary items. The Accounting Review 50, 58–68. Barton, J., 2001. Does the use of financial derivatives affect earnings management decisions? The Accounting Review 76, 1-26. Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., Ferrell, A., 2009. What matters in corporate governance? Review of Financial Studies 22, 783-827. Beidleman, C., 1973. Income smoothing: the role of management. The Accounting Review 48, 653-667. Berger, A., Udell, G., 1990. Collateral, loan quality, and bank risk. Journal of Monetary Economics 25, 21-42. Bharath, S., Sunder, J., Sunder, S., 2008. Accounting quality and debt contracting. The Accounting Review 83, 1-28. Bhattacharya, U., Daouk, H., Welker, M., 2003. The world price of earnings opacity. The Accounting Review 78, 641-678. Black, E., Sellers, K., Manly, T., 1998. Earnings management using asset sales: An international study of countries allowing noncurrent asset revaluation. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 25, 1287-1317. Costello, A., Wittenberg-Moerman, R., 2011. The impact of financial reporting quality on debt contracting: Evidence from internal control weakness reports. Journal of Accounting Research 49, 97-136. Daske, H., Hail, L., Leuz, C., Verdi, R., 2008. Mandatory IFRS reporting around the world: early evidence on the economic consequences. Journal of Accounting Research 46, 1085-1142. Dechow, P., Dichev, I., 2002. The quality of accruals and earnings: The role of accrual estimation errors. The Accounting Review 77, 35-59. Dechow, P, Ge, W., Schrand, C., 2010. Understanding earnings quality: a review of the proxies, their determinants and their consequences. Journal of Accounting and Economics 50, 344-401. DeFond, M., Park, C., 1997. Smoothing income in anticipation of future earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 23, 115–139. De Franco, G., Hope, O., Lu, H., 2017. Managerial ability and bank-loan pricing. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting DOI: 10.1111/jbfa.12267. Demerjian, P., Donovan, J., Lewis-Western, M., 2017. Income smoothing and debt covenants: evidence from technical default. Working paper. Demiroglu, C., James, C., 2010. The information content of bank loan covenants. Review of Financial Studies 23 (10), 3700-3737. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Accepted Article Demski, J., 1998. Performance measure manipulation. Contemporary Accounting Research 15, 261–285. Demsetz, H., Lehn, K., 1985. The structure of corporate ownership: causes and consequences. Journal of Political Economy 93, 1155-1177. Desai, H., Hogan, C., Wilkins, M. 2006. The reputational penalty for aggressive accounting: Earnings restatement and management turnover. The Accounting Review 81, 83-112. Dichev, I., Tang, V., 2009. Earnings volatility and earnings predictability. Journal of Accounting and Economics 47, 160-181. Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., Shleifer, A., 2007. Private credit in 129 countries. Journal of Financial Economics 84, 299-329. Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., 2008. The law and economics of self-dealing. Journal of Financial Economics 88, 430-465. Dou, Y., Hope, O., Thomas, W., 2013. Relationship-specificity, contract enforceability, and income smoothing. The Accounting Review 88, 1629-1656. Drucker, S., Puri, M., 2009. On loan sales, loan contracting, and lending relationships. Review of Financial Studies 22, 2835-2872. Duan, J., Sun, J., Wang, T., 2012. Multiperiod corporate default prediction - a forward intensity approach. Journal of Econometrics 170, 191-209. Francis, J., LaFond, R., Olsson, P., Schipper, K., 2004. Costs of equity and earnings attributes. The Accounting Review 79, 967-1010. Friedman, H., 2017. Capital market development and confidence in disclosure quality. Working paper. Fudenberg, D., Tirole, J., 1995. A theory of income and dividend smoothing based on incumbency rents. Journal of Political Economy 103, 75–93. Gassen, J., Fulbier, R., 2015. Do creditors prefer smooth earnings? Evidence from European private firms. Journal of International Accounting Research 14, 151-180. Gopalan, R., Jayaraman, S., 2012. Private control benefits and earnings management: Evidence from insider controlled firms. Journal of Accounting Research 50, 117-157. Graham, J., Smith, C., 1999. Tax incentives to hedge. Journal of Finance 54, 2241-2262. Graham, J., Harvey, C., Rajgopal, S., 2005. The economic implications of corporate financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 40, 3–73. Gu, Z., Zhao, Y., 2006. Accruals, income smoothing and bond ratings. Working paper. Hamm, S., Jung, B., Lee, W., 2017. Labor unions and income smoothing. Contemporary Accounting Research, forthcoming. Hepworth, S., 1953. Smoothing periodic income. The Accounting Review 28, 32-39. Hunt, A., Moyer, S., Shevlin, T., 2000. Earnings volatility, earnings management and equity value. Working Paper. Iliev, P., Lins, K., Miller, D., Roth, L., 2015. Shareholder voting and corporate governance around the world. Review of Financial Studies 28, 2167-2202. Ivashina, V., 2009. Asymmetric information effects on loan spreads. Journal of Financial Economics 92, 300-319. John, K., Litov, L., Yeung, B., 2008. Corporate governance and risk-taking. Journal of Finance 63: 1679-1728. Jung, B., Soderstrom, N., Yang, S., 2013. Earnings smoothing activities of firms to manage credit ratings. Contemporary Accounting Research 30, 645-676. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Accepted Article Kim, J., Tsui, J., Cheong, H., 2011. The voluntary adoption of International Financial Reporting Standards and loan contracting around the world. Review of Accounting Studies 16, 779811. Lang, M., Maffett, M., 2011a. Economic effects of transparency in international equity markets: a review and suggestions for future research. Foundation and Trends in Accounting 5, 175-241. Lang, M., Maffett, M., 2011b. Transparency and liquidity uncertainty in crisis periods. Journal of Accounting and Economics 52, 101-125. Lang, M., Lins, K., Maffett, M., 2012. Transparency, liquidity, and valuation: International evidence on when transparency matters most. Journal of Accounting Research 50, 729774. Lang, M., Stice-Lawrence, L., 2015. Textual analysis and international financial reporting: large sample evidence. Journal of Accounting and Economics 60, 110-135. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R. 1998. Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy 106, 1113-1155. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 2000. Investor protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics 58, 3-27. Leuz, C., Nanda, D., Wysocki, P., 2003. Earnings management and investor protection: an international comparison. Journal of Financial Economics 69, 505–527. Li, S., Richie, N., 2016. Income smoothing and the cost of debt. China Journal of Accounting Research 9, 175-190. Lin, C., Ma, Y., Malatesta, P., Xuan, Y., 2011. Ownership structure and the cost of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 100, 1-23. Merton, R., 1974. On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance 29, 449-470. Murfin, J., 2012. The supply-side determinants of loan contract strictness. Journal of Finance 67, 1565-1601. Peasnell, K., 1998. Discussion of earnings management using asset sales: An international study of countries allowing noncurrent asset revaluation. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 25, 1319-1324. Qian, J., Strahan, P., 2007. How laws and institutions shape financial contracts: The case of bank loans. Journal of Finance 62, 2803-2834. Rajan, R., 1992. Insiders and outsiders: the choice between informed and arm's‐length debt. The Journal of Finance 47, 1367-1400. Rego, S, Wilson, R., 2012. Equity risk incentives and corporate tax aggressiveness. Journal of Accounting Research 50, 775-810. Ronen, J., Sadan, S., 1981. Smoothing income numbers: Objectives, means and implications. Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA. Roychowdhury, S., Watts, R., 2007. Asymmetric timeliness of earnings, market-to-book and conservatism in financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 44, 2-31. Shuto, A. and Iwasaki, T., 2014. Stable shareholdings, the decision horizon problem and earnings smoothing. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 41, 1212-1242. Sufi, A., 2007. Information asymmetry and financing arrangements: evidence from syndicated loans. Journal of Finance 62, 629-668. Takasu, Y., 2013. Does income smoothing affect the cost of bank loans? Working paper. Thomson Reuters., 2014. Global Syndicated Loans Review. Accessed October 19, 2016 at http://dmi.thomsonreuters.com/Content/Files/4Q2014_Global_Syndicated_Loans_Review.pdf. This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Tirole, J., 2001. Corporate governance. Econometrica 69, 1-35. Trueman, B., Titman, S., 1988. An explanation for accounting income smoothing. Journal of Accounting Research 26, 127–139. Tucker, J., Zarowin, P., 2006. Does income smoothing improve earnings informativeness? The Accounting Review 81, 251-270. Zhang, J., 2008. The contracting benefits of accounting conservatism to lenders and borrowers. Journal of Accounting and Economics 45, 27-54. Table 1 – Non-U.S. sample composition Accepted Article Table 1 presents the country distribution of the sample firms and facility-level observations used in our primary analyses. Anti-self-dealing index (Djankov et al., 2008) takes values in the range zero to one, where higher values indicate a lower threat of private benefit consumption. A country is classified as having high (low) threat of private benefits consumption if its anti-self-dealing index is below (above) the sample observation median. PBThreat is an indicator variable that =1 (=0) for high (low) threat countries. For simplicity, we follow prior research (e.g., Daske, Hail, Leuz, & Verdi, 2008) and refer to Hong Kong as a country. NATION Australia Brazil Canada France Germany Hong Kong India Italy Korea (South) Mexico Netherlands Singapore South Africa Spain Sweden Taiwan United Kingdom Firms N % 14 2.2 2 0.3 69 10.8 72 11.3 28 4.4 25 3.9 18 2.8 8 1.3 23 3.6 5 0.8 8 1.3 8 1.3 2 0.3 12 1.9 4 0.6 143 22.4 198 31.0 Total 639 100.0 Facilities N % 29 1.6 2 0.1 160 8.8 281 15.5 90 5.0 44 2.4 33 1.8 12 0.7 71 3.9 7 0.4 15 0.8 9 0.5 6 0.3 19 1.1 4 0.2 377 20.8 658 36.2 1,817 Anti-Self Dealing Index 0.76 0.27 0.64 0.38 0.28 0.96 0.58 0.42 0.47 0.17 0.20 1.00 0.81 0.37 0.33 0.56 0.95 100.0 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. PBThreat 0 1 0 1 1 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 Table 2 - Sample descriptive statistics Table 2 presents descriptive statistics for the facility-level observations used in our analyses. Variable definitions are presented in Appendix A. Accepted Article Variable N Mean Std P1 P25 Median P75 P99 DiscSmooth 1,817 49.323 26.839 2.000 26.500 50.500 71.500 97.000 FundSmooth 1,817 51.796 27.598 2.500 29.000 51.500 74.500 97.000 Spread 1,817 134.413 108.854 19.000 55.000 100.000 200.000 525.000 Facility 1,817 462.163 987.631 0.183 23.164 140.000 440.767 4708.474 LFacility 1,817 4.301 2.563 -1.699 3.143 4.942 6.089 8.457 Maturity 1,817 64.216 21.929 24.000 60.000 60.000 75.000 144.000 LMaturity 1,817 4.105 0.346 3.178 4.094 4.094 4.317 4.970 Secure 1,817 0.254 0.436 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000 NCov 1,817 0.569 0.929 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.000 4.000 LSize 1,817 14.006 1.477 11.015 12.967 13.923 14.982 17.689 BTM 1,817 0.714 0.480 0.009 0.380 0.612 0.942 2.117 Leverage 1,817 0.591 0.149 0.265 0.491 0.588 0.680 0.980 ROA 1,817 0.080 0.068 -0.109 0.044 0.076 0.114 0.235 NetWorth 1,817 11.396 19.601 0.037 0.666 2.761 12.073 86.318 Tangible 1,817 0.389 0.245 0.015 0.178 0.362 0.565 0.935 StdRet 1,817 0.106 0.052 0.031 0.070 0.097 0.129 0.292 Table 3 - Correlation matrix for facility-level variables Table 3 reports Pearson (Spearman) correlations for our sample above (below) the diagonal. Variable (1) DiscSmo oth (1) FundSmo oth (2) 0.07 7 Spread (3) 0.04 9 LFacility (4) LMaturit y (5) 0.05 1 0.01 3 Secure (6) 0.01 6 NCov (7) 0.00 (2) 0.07 7 (3) 0.02 8 0.11 5 0.13 5 0.01 4 0.11 5 0.00 7 0.35 3 0.09 5 - 0.33 3 - (4) 0.04 1 0.01 2 (5) 0.01 9 (6) (7) 0.01 5 0.00 1 0.02 2 0.09 6 0.31 6 0.34 0 0.03 9 0.16 1 0.01 8 0.01 8 0.25 0 0.11 4 0.06 1 0.02 1 0.15 8 - 0.20 5 0.22 6 - 0.19 4 0.15 (8) 0.11 0 0.00 6 0.22 5 0.56 3 0.11 1 0.14 9 - (9) (10) 0.08 1 0.08 6 0.06 7 0.07 5 0.36 9 0.11 9 0.09 6 0.28 2 0.06 2 0.07 8 0.01 0 0.02 5 0.24 5 0.16 5 0.23 0 0.03 5 0.12 7 0.09 8 0.08 0 - 0.07 5 - 0.08 7 - 0.01 6 0.10 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. (11) 0.05 1 (12) 0.00 2 (13) 0.04 1 0.09 3 0.04 3 0.02 9 0.04 8 0.00 8 - (14) 0.03 0 0.20 8 0.10 8 0.21 3 0.09 1 0.03 2 0.09 4 LSize (8) 0.11 5 BTM (9) 0.04 1 Leverage (10) 0.09 1 ROA (11) Accepted Article NetWorth (12) Tangible (13) StdRet (14) 0.10 1 0.04 7 0.05 8 0.03 9 0.02 1 0.06 1 0.34 0 0.05 1 0.36 3 0.35 8 0.15 7 0.12 6 0.13 3 0.04 4 0.25 4 0.07 4 0.27 3 0.04 1 0.17 9 0.13 4 0.11 6 0.03 6 0.46 0 0.12 2 0.07 6 0.15 8 0.05 2 0.06 6 0.26 4 0.06 7 0.10 9 0.00 3 0.04 5 0.08 5 0.15 4 0.58 9 3 0.03 9 0.13 4 0.07 6 0.00 8 0.21 4 0.07 4 0.04 3 0.08 1 0.00 1 0.04 9 0.15 9 0.15 1 0.34 9 1 0.03 6 0.04 1 0.25 8 0.08 5 0.42 5 0.07 2 0.24 8 0.23 7 0.27 7 0.40 1 0.04 3 0.05 7 0.02 6 0.17 1 0.14 0 0.19 2 0.13 4 0.12 0 0.12 0 0.30 3 0.23 1 0.20 0 0.13 7 0.17 4 0.02 8 0.14 1 0.00 3 0.31 7 0.01 3 0.13 4 0.06 9 0.14 2 0.12 2 0.13 3 0.19 0 0.04 1 0.00 5 0.05 3 0.16 1 0.13 4 0.05 8 0.15 0 0.10 0 0.28 2 2 0.22 2 0.16 1 0.03 7 0.07 6 Table 4 – Country-level threat of private benefits consumption Table 4 presents results of OLS estimation of Eq. (4): Spread i ,l 0 1 PBThreati 2 DiscSmoothi , t 3 DiscSmooth * PBThreat 4 FundSmoothi , t 5 FundSmooth * PBThreat X i,t + Yi,l country year i , l . Spread is the loan interest rate over LIBOR in basis points. PBThreat is an indicator that equals one (zero) if a firm is in a country with high (low) threat of private benefits consumption. DiscSmooth is a rank variable increasing in firm-level discretionary smoothing. FundSmooth is a rank variable increasing in firm-level fundamental smoothness. All variables are further defined in Appendix A. Country, year, and industry fixed effects (including the intercept and main effect of PBThreat) are included where indicated but not reported. Robust t-statistics based on two-way clustered standard errors are reported in parentheses, where C, M, and P indicate clustering by country, calendar month-year, and loan package, respectively. *, **, and *** indicate significance (two-sided) at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Column: (1) (2) (3) (4) DiscSmooth -0.038 -0.145** -0.145** -0.131* (-0.39) (-2.14) (-2.38) (-1.93) DiscSmooth *PBThreat 0.410*** 0.410*** 0.433** (2.64) (2.86) (2.46) FundSmooth -0.184 -0.166 -0.166 -0.368** (-1.16) (-1.38) (-1.37) (-2.38) FundSmooth *PBThreat -0.035 -0.035 -0.101 (-0.11) (-0.11) (-0.36) LSize -14.238*** -14.086*** -14.086*** -12.240*** (-5.91) (-5.65) (-6.11) (-5.84) BTM 22.867*** 22.941*** 22.941*** 20.040*** (4.37) (3.95) (3.74) (3.13) Leverage 46.003*** 43.602*** 43.602*** 35.640*** (4.30) (3.79) (4.07) (2.70) ROA -3.530 -0.809 -0.809 -1.346 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. (-0.07) 1.156 (0.10) 213.822** (1.98) 4.030 (1.16) -10.831*** (-3.09) 70.433*** (3.36) 64.170*** (2.98) Tangible StdRet NCov LFacility LMaturity Accepted Article Secure DiscSmooth + DiscSmooth*PBThreat Included Fixed Effects Standard Error Clustering N Adj. R2 C, Y C, M 1,817 0.437 (-0.02) 2.970 (0.27) 225.143** (2.07) 4.253 (1.23) -10.725*** (-3.03) 70.278*** (3.36) 63.676*** (3.00) 0.265* C, Y C, M 1,817 0.438 (-0.02) 2.970 (0.26) 225.143** (1.98) 4.253 (1.30) -10.725*** (-3.02) 70.278*** (3.34) 63.676*** (2.99) 0.265* C, Y C, P 1,817 0.438 (-0.03) -5.908 (-0.58) 213.077* (1.94) 4.271 (1.23) -11.197*** (-3.28) 68.224*** (3.14) 63.475*** (2.97) 0.302* C, Y, I C, P 1,817 0.442 Table 5 - Firm-level threat of private benefits consumption Table 5 presents results of OLS estimation of Eq. (4) using firm-level threat measures: Spread i ,l 0 1 PBThreatFirmi 2 DiscSmoothi ,t 3 DiscSmooth * PBThreatFirm 4 FundSmoothi ,t 5 FundSmooth * PBThreatFirm X i,t + Yi,l country year i ,l . Spread is the loan interest rate over LIBOR in basis points. CloseHeldShares is an indicator that equals one (zero) if a firm has a high (low) percentage of closely-held shares. MgrEntrench is an indicator that equals one (zero) if a firm has a high (low) Bebchuk et al. (2009) entrenchment index. DiscSmooth is a rank variable increasing in firmlevel discretionary smoothing. FundSmooth is a rank variable increasing in firm-level fundamental smoothness. All variables are further defined in Appendix A. Column (1) uses our primary sample with two-way clustered standard errors by country and loan package. Column (2) uses a sample of U.S. firms with standard errors clustered by loan package. Where indicated, country and year fixed effects are included but not reported, including the intercept and the main effect of PBThreatFirm. Robust t-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance (two-sided) at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. PBThreatFirm Var.: CloseHeldShares MgrEntrench Column: (1) (2) DiscSmooth -0.182* -0.101* (-1.65) (-1.73) DiscSmooth *PBThreatFirm 0.653*** 0.389** (3.18) (2.56) FundSmooth -0.056 -0.396*** (-0.43) (-6.49) FundSmooth *PBThreatFirm -0.399 -0.089 (-1.37) (-0.62) LSize -15.419*** -8.503*** (-5.94) (-5.15) BTM 23.391*** 9.693*** (3.35) (3.32) Leverage 43.972* 113.466*** (1.66) (13.39) ROA 10.825 -141.145*** (0.16) (-6.97) This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Tangible StdRet NCov LFacility LMaturity Secure Accepted Article DiscSmooth + DiscSmooth*PBThreatFirm Included Fixed Effects Standard Error Clustering N Adj. R2 2.977 (0.24) 220.143*** (2.78) 8.142** (2.02) -10.892*** (-5.13) 71.423*** (6.57) 69.988*** (7.16) 0.471** C, Y C, P 1,608 0.454 6.310 (0.97) 180.274*** (6.24) -1.119 (-1.08) -13.063*** (-7.99) 23.156*** (4.53) 78.072*** (22.66) 0.288** Y C, P 6,033 0.465 Table 6 - Borrower credit risk Table 6 presents results of OLS estimation of Eq. (5): Spread i ,l 0 1 PBThreati 2 DiscSmoothi ,t 3 DiscSmooth * PBThreat 4 DiscSmooth * PBThreat * PD 5 FundSmoothi ,t 6 PDi ,t 7 DiscSmooth * PD 8 FundSmooth * PD 9 PBThreat * PD X i,t + Yi,l country year i ,l . Spread is the loan interest rate over LIBOR in basis points. PBThreat is an indicator that equals one (zero) if a firm is in a country with high (low) threat of private benefits consumption. DiscSmooth is a rank variable increasing in firm-level discretionary smoothing. FundSmooth is a rank variable increasing in firm-level fundamental smoothness. PD is firm-level probability of default. All variables are further defined in Appendix A. Country and year fixed effects (including the intercept and main effect of PBThreat) are included but not reported. Robust t-statistics based on two-way clustered standard errors by country and loan package are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance (two-sided) at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Column: (1) DiscSmooth -0.188*** BTM 19.321* (-2.76) (1.90) DiscSmooth*PBThreat 0.188 Leverage 32.707* (0.51) (1.71) DiscSmooth* PBThreat*PD 0.793** ROA 32.072 (2.14) (0.55) FundSmooth 0.120 Tangible 13.163 (0.55) (0.87) PD 79.111*** StdRet 140.198 (3.17) (1.09) DiscSmooth*PD 0.318 NCov 5.647** (1.47) (2.25) FundSmooth*PD -1.542*** LFacility -9.257** (-3.66) (-2.07) PBThreat*PD 13.327 LMaturity 62.597** (0.56) (2.20) LSize -14.894*** Secure 52.883** (-6.42) (2.43) Included Fixed Effects C, Y This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Standard Error Clustering N Adj. R2 C, P 1,309 0.414 Table 7 - Financial Covenants Accepted Article Table 7 presents results of OLS estimation of a modified version of Eq. (4) where NCov (the number of financial covenants on the loan) is used as the dependent variable: NCovi ,l 0 1 PBThreati 2 DiscSmoothi , t 3 DiscSmooth * PBThreat 4 FundSmoothi , t 5 FundSmooth * PBThreat X i,t + Yi,l country year i ,l . Spread is the loan interest rate over LIBOR in basis points. PBThreat is an indicator that equals one (zero) if a firm is in a country with high (low) threat of private benefits consumption. DiscSmooth is a rank variable increasing in firm-level discretionary smoothing. FundSmooth is a rank variable increasing in firm-level fundamental smoothness. All variables are further defined in Appendix A. Country and year fixed effects (including the intercept and main effect of PBThreat) are included but not reported. Robust t-statistics based on two-way clustered standard errors by country and loan package are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance (two-sided) at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Column: (1) DiscSmooth 0.001 (0.44) DiscSmooth *PBThreat 0.007** (2.15) FundSmooth 0.001 (1.13) LSize 0.045 (1.19) BTM 0.028 (0.44) Leverage 0.116 (0.64) ROA -0.289 (-0.72) Tangible -0.459*** (-2.97) StdRet 1.494 (0.99) Spread -0.000 (-0.59) LFacility -0.001 (-0.09) LMaturity -0.046 (-0.74) Secure 0.001 (0.44) Included Fixed Effects C, Y Standard Error Clustering C, P N 724 Adj. R2 0.358 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Table 8 - Creditor rights Accepted Article Table 8 presents results of OLS estimation of an extension of Eq. (4) which includes a variable that captures the extent of country-level creditor rights: Spread i ,l 0 1 PBThreati 2WeakCredRightsi 3 DiscSmoothi ,t 4 DiscSmooth * WeakCredRightsi 5 DiscSmooth * PBThreat 6 FundSmoothi ,t X i,t + Yi,l country year i ,l . PBThreat is an indicator that equals one (zero) if a firm is in a country with high (low) threat of private benefits consumption. WeakCredRights is an indicator that equals one if a firm is in a country with weak creditor rights. DiscSmooth (FundSmooth) is a rank variable increasing in firm-level discretionary (fundamental) smoothness. All variables are further defined in Appendix A. Country and year fixed effects (including main effects on PBThreat and WeakCredRights) are included, but not reported. Robust t-statistics based on two-way clustered standard errors by country and loan package are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance (two-sided) at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Column: (1) (2) DiscSmooth -0.052 -0.120** (-0.50) (-2.01) DiscSmooth*WeakCredRights 0.055 -0.184 (0.28) (-1.25) DiscSmooth*PBThreat 0.501*** (2.71) FundSmooth -0.183 -0.177 (-1.12) (-1.13) LSize -14.210*** -14.177*** (-6.66) (-6.59) BTM 22.916*** 22.828*** (4.02) (3.69) Leverage 46.071*** 42.844*** (4.52) (3.94) ROA -2.635 -2.557 (-0.05) (-0.05) Tangible 1.440 2.282 (0.12) (0.20) StdRet 214.971* 223.200* (1.90) (1.94) NCov 4.035 4.294 (1.22) (1.31) LFacility -10.837*** -10.678*** (-3.07) (-3.05) LMaturity 70.366*** 70.619*** (3.35) (3.40) Secure 64.090*** 63.790*** (2.97) (3.00) DiscSmooth+DiscSmooth*PBThreat 0.381* Included Fixed Effects C, Y C, Y Standard Error Clustering C, P C, P N 1,817 1,817 Adj. R2 0.437 0.439 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved. Table 9 – Other accounting attributes Accepted Article Table 9 presents results of OLS estimation of an extension of Eq. (4) which includes variables that capture other accounting attributes, along with their interactions with PBThreat, where PBThreat is an indicator that equals one (zero) if a firm is in a country with high (low) threat of private benefits consumption: Spread i ,l 0 1 PBThreati 2 DiscSmoothi ,t 3 DiscSmooth * PBThreat 4 Attributei ,t 5 Attribute * PBThreat 6 FundSmoothi , t X i,t + Yi,l country year i ,l . DiscSmooth (FundSmooth) is a rank variable increasing in firm-level discretionary (fundamental) smoothness. AQ is a proxy for accruals quality. BTM is an inverse proxy for accounting conservatism. σNIEXS is an inverse proxy for earnings persistence. All variables are further defined in Appendix A. Country and year fixed effects (including the intercept and main effect of PBThreat) are included, but not reported. Robust t-statistics based on two-way clustered standard errors by country and loan package are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance (twosided) at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. # indicates significance (one-sided) at the 10% level. Attribute: AQ BTM σNIEXS Column: (1) (2) (3) DiscSmooth -0.392*** -0.151*** -0.098# (-5.90) (-2.69) (-1.57) DiscSmooth*PBThreat 0.682*** 0.428*** 0.497** (3.43) (2.62) (2.34) Attribute -0.319*** 26.690*** 89.564*** (-4.13) (4.10) (2.94) Attribute*PBThreat 0.350 -10.401 240.724 (1.04) (-0.65) (0.66) FundSmooth -0.270 -0.177 -0.067 (-1.33) (-1.12) (-0.62) LSize -6.141* -14.158*** -13.958*** (-1.66) (-6.62) (-6.53) BTM 19.865*** 24.727*** (2.71) (4.14) Leverage 65.949*** 46.167*** 47.346*** (2.79) (4.99) (4.64) ROA -62.748 3.118 2.928 (-0.76) (0.06) (0.06) Tangible 12.062 1.817 6.513 (1.28) (0.15) (0.59) StdRet 261.633* 225.563** 224.549** (1.85) (2.00) (2.01) NCov 10.374*** 4.245 4.365 (2.88) (1.29) (1.32) LFacility -10.638*** -10.652*** -10.679*** (-3.04) (-3.02) (-3.15) LMaturity 23.554 70.479*** 69.971*** (1.61) (3.36) (3.36) Secure 58.520** 63.518*** 63.490*** (2.14) (2.97) (3.04) DiscSmooth+DiscSmooth*PBThreat 0.290# 0.277* 0.399* Included Fixed Effects C, Y C, Y C, Y Standard Error Clustering C, P C, P C, P N 976 1,817 1,817 Adj. R2 0.439 0.439 0.441 This article is protected by copyright. All rights reserved.